The Economic Impacts of Endemic Diseases and Disease Control Programmes

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 20

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/12826715

The economic impacts of endemic diseases and disease control programmes

Article  in  Revue scientifique et technique (International Office of Epizootics) · September 1999


DOI: 10.20506/rst.18.2.1168 · Source: PubMed

CITATIONS READS

33 885

3 authors, including:

Clement Allan Tisdell


The University of Queensland
1,995 PUBLICATIONS   10,696 CITATIONS   

SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

Loans, Wealth Creation and the Socio-Economic Situation of Agricultural Women in the Taluka Area of the Khairpur District, Sindh, Pakistan View project

PhD study View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Clement Allan Tisdell on 18 August 2014.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 1999, 18 (2), 380-398

The economic impacts of endemic diseases and


disease control programmes
C.A. Tisdell(1) S.R. H a r r i s o n (1)
& G.C. R a m s a y (2)

(1) Department of Economics, University of Queensland, OLD 4072, Australia


(2) Secretariat for the Pacific Community, Private Mail Bag, Suva, Fiji

Summary
T h e authors discuss the evaluation of the economic impacts of endemic livestock
diseases, and economic issues in control of these diseases. Particular attention is
f o c u s e d on helminths and on endemic vector-transmitted infections (particularly
ticks and tick-borne diseases). Decisions relating to disease control have to be
made by g o v e r n m e n t and by the producer. G o v e r n m e n t requires information on
the level of control to adopt, the extent of involvement n e e d e d , and h o w to fund
animal health p r o g r a m m e s (particularly h o w to share costs b e t w e e n t a x p a y e r s
and livestock producers). Individual producers require information as to h o w
much effort to invest in disease control, including information collection effort,
and h o w to design control strategies. E c o n o m i c s can shed light on t h e s e issues.
H o w e v e r , e x p e r i e n c e suggests that animal health policies are particularly difficult
to evaluate f r o m an economic viewpoint, w i t h complex relationships b e t w e e n
animal health, production impacts, market a c c e s s , and non-production benefits of
livestock. W h i l e little information is available concerning the cost of helminth
diseases, m a n y estimates have been made of the costs of ticks and tick-borne
diseases at a regional and national level, sometimes demonstrating that
eradication is w a r r a n t e d .

Keywords
Animal diseases - Disease control - Economics - Helminthiasis - Livestock - Tick-borne
diseases.

Introduction reproduction rates, lactation of mammalian livestock), rather


than just clinical effects. Co-operation between veterinarians
The term endemic diseases covers an extremely wide range and economists is needed at an early stage if information of
and the characteristics of these diseases differ greatly. In this economic relevance is to be collected by veterinarians.
paper, therefore, the example of parasites as a source of
disease will be highlighted, taking helminths as examples of Extra cost is incurred in the collection of extra veterinary data
endoparasites and ticks as examples of exoparasites. Even of economic relevance, however, without this additional step,
with such a focus, the number of parasite species and diseases little progress will be made in the economic evaluation of
is large, and there is, therefore, a need to concentrate on diseases. This point cannot be over emphasised, and is
individual cases. supported in the conclusion of a recent paper ( 3 6 ) .

Endemic parasites are a major source of economic loss in Economic impacts of parasites of livestock may be divided
animal husbandry, especially in tropical areas and developing into two groups - direct and indirect impacts. Direct impacts
countries, but as discussed later, the extent of those losses has are those attributable purely to the presence of the parasite,
yet to be accurately specified, and knowledge about the e.g. reduced economic productivity of the livestock or
economics of treatment of these diseases is inadequate, mostly economic loss due to mortality. Indirect impacts occur
because the damage functions, and in addition, the response because some parasites, such as ticks, are also disease vectors,
functions to treatment are imperfectly known. The response and the vector-borne diseases, if transmitted to a livestock
functions should be specified in relation to economic variables host, often result in much greater economic loss than the
of importance (e.g. depending on the situation, weight gain, presence of the parasite. Furthermore, by weakening the host
Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2) 381

the presence of a parasite may make the animal much more In collecting information on economic impact, the coverage
susceptible to infection and adverse impact from other required must be determined (this depends on the target
diseases, or to environmental stresses such as food deficits group), but in addition, the purpose for which the
(18). information is to be used must be taken into account. For
example, a common objective in relation to disease control is
The range of parasites of livestock is very large. Helminth to estimate the total economic loss caused by the prevalence of
parasites belong to three phyla of invertebrates: disease. But what is the purpose of this? True, it provides an
platyhelminths (flatworms), acanthocephalans (spiny-headed indication of the economic benefits to be had if an inexpensive
worms) and nematodes (roundworms). method could be found to reduce substantially the incidence
of the disease. However, such relative losses from diseases are
In addition to ticks, ectoparasites include mites, lice, fleas, a poor guide to the allocation of research funds, because the
leaches, mosquitoes and flies of various kinds. However, as likelihood and cost of making new discoveries concerning the
mentioned earlier, to deal with the full range of these parasites control of a disease and the economics of remedies discovered
in this article would be impossible, and the focus here is must also be considered ( 3 0 ) .
limited to helminths and ticks. This article first considers
general issues involved in the evaluation of the economic
Information regarding whether the full economic potential
impact of endemic diseases and the economics of disease
from remedying a disease is being obtained, given existing
control. Subsequently, these issues are considered specifically
knowledge about disease control, is useful from several points
for helminths and then for ticks and tick-borne diseases, and
of view. It is important to determine the scope which exists for
general conclusions are drawn.
increasing economic benefits from the use of existing
veterinary knowledge. For an individual livestock holder, the
scope for this will be equal to the difference between the
economic gain using the current control practice and the

Evaluation of the economic economic gain using an optimal economic control strategy. As
discussed later, such an approach has been adopted by several

impact of endemic diseases and researchers ( 1 , 27, 3 0 ) . Similar estimates can be made
regionally, for a nation or globally. However, accurate

the economics of disease estimates cannot always be obtained by merely aggregating


economic gains for individual livestock owners considered in

control isolation. For example, this will be true if an increase in


supply of livestock products, as a result of disease control,
reduces the market price of these products ( 1 8 ) , or if a
Evaluation of the economic impact of endemic favourable environmental health spillover (externality) is
diseases generated by the disease control measures adopted by
individual farmers. In some cases, measures taken by
Endemic diseases cause large economic losses but few precise
individual farmers to control livestock diseases also reduce the
estimates of the magnitude of these losses have been made,
likelihood that the livestock of other farms will contract the
mainly because the amount of information required is large
disease. Where a difference exists between potential and
and the cost of obtaining the information is high.
actual net economic benefits from disease control practices,
Furthermore, as mentioned earlier, veterinary research effort
stockholders may be encouraged by government extension
is not always sensitive to the data needs of economic
services to change control strategies.
evaluation. Economists can only make progress with
economic evaluation if veterinary data is provided in a
required form so that it can be combined with economic data Optimal economic strategies are not always the same for all
and the appropriate economic analysis can be undertaken stock owners and may vary with environmental conditions.
(30). This provides challenges for government extension services,
which cannot, as a rule, target individual clients, and must
Economic evaluations can be undertaken for a variety of target focus on broad groups of clients. Therefore, government
groups, or geographical areas, for example: advice is generally based on average situations, and one has to
decide how finely to structure this advice for target clients in
- an individual livestock holder different regional and environmental situations. To some
- a region extent this involves economic choice - the extra economic
- a nation benefit for more structured and specifically directed advice
- for the global situation. must be weighed against the additional cost (4,44).
Improvement of advice is only socially desirable up to the
Different types and amounts of information are required for point where the extra economic benefits generated equal the
these different levels of coverage. extra cost.
Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2)
382

be formulated by considering the differing objectives of target


Economics of control of endemic diseases
groups and the different cultural practices and habits of these
The economics of control of endemic diseases is complex
groups, especially those relevant to the farming and grazing
since the epidemiology of most is complicated and disease
activities of livestock holders. Nevertheless, fundamental
prevalence often changes radically with alterations in
factors can be identified which are relevant to most analyses of
environmental conditions. In particular, the occurrence of
the control of endemic livestock diseases.
parasitism seems to be greatly influenced by environmental
conditions. This means that simple models of the economics
of control of diseases can often only be applied to particular For example, one needs to know the relationship between
endemic diseases if considerable modification and further possible disease control strategies and the benefit expected by
development is undertaken. livestock holders or other targeted groups. It is necessary to
determine what attributes of the livestock are valued and how
Livestock holders often fail to control endemic diseases in an much value is placed on each to obtain an objective function.
economically optimal manner and convincing individuals to The problem is a holistic one and calls for an interdisciplinary
change this behaviour can be difficult. For example, approach.
particularly in developing countries, the presence of such
diseases is often unrecognised or considered 'normal', and is Ideally, the aim should be to recommend a specific disease
thus fatalistically accepted by livestock holders. For example, control strategy which maximises the objectives of the client.
although the occurrence of bovine fasciolosis is a major Mathematically, the problem can be considered as a
problem in Indonesia ( 4 2 ) , control attempts are uncommon constrained maximisation problem - to maximise the
'because the extent of the problem is largely unrecognised by objective or utility function of the client, subject to the
farmers (the disease is common and unspectacular, and the resource and other constraints faced by the client and taking
main clinical signs of failure to thrive and reduced exercised into account the possibilities generated by the available
tolerance are similar to those of poor nutrition or regarded as disease control strategies.
"normal"), modem anthelmintics are expensive and there is
no reliable information on the benefits of control' (42).
A simple form of this approach (which is particularly relevant
to developed countries and increasingly to less developed
This raises a further aspect, namely that the economics of countries as they become more market-oriented) is as follows:
control of a disease may vary from country to country and
a) the objective of the livestock holder is to maximise net
from region to region. The occurrence of endemic diseases
monetary income (or net discounted cash flow)
can be greatly influenced by cultural practices - both
agricultural practices and wider practices. For example, b) this depends on the quantity and quality of saleable
attitudes to the keeping and handling of dogs influence the products produced by or attributable to having livestock in
occurrence of hydatidosis in humans. Treatment of animal the farming enterprise as well as the prices of these products
manure by humans can influence whether the life-cycle of
some helminths is assisted or thwarted. If cow dung is c) allowance is made for financial outlays on account of these
composted at high temperatures, before being returned to the livestock, which include any outlays on disease control.
field, or burnt for fuel, as in parts of the Indian subcontinent,
the eggs of some species of helminths will be destroyed, In considering this problem, one of the important points for
thereby reducing these populations ( 3 7 ) . attention is the relationship between strategies for control of a
disease and the impact of these strategies on the quantity and

Control strategies for endemic diseases which are quality of the saleable livestock products. In essence this
economically feasible in developing countries often differ means that a production function response or relationship
from those which are economically optimal in more needs to be estimated (30).
developed countries. This is because farmers in developing
countries usually only each keep a small number of livestock, To take a simple case, suppose that a farmer wishes to
and often use communal water and feed sources, capital is maximise annual net income and that, for livestock, the only
usually in short supply, and agricultural activities differ from attribute of relevance is the weight of meat of the livestock.
those in developed countries, with specialised farming being Suppose that preventive treatment for the relevant livestock
more the exception than the rule. In addition, cultural disease is available which can be administered with varying
differences between countries can influence practical control intensities. Intensity, for example, may be the number of
policies. To be relevant, economic advice must be varied to times per year that the stock are drenched to control helminth
take account of all such considerations. In addition, the infestations. Additions to meat weight may increase with the
objective of keeping livestock may vary from society to society number of preventive doses per year, but at a decreasing rate.
and from group to group: the purpose is not always to earn In stationary conditions, a functional relationship exists
the largest stream of net cash income, as seems to be the basic
between the number of doses and meat weight gains, which in
motivation in developed countries. Economic advice needs to
principle can be determined scientifically.
Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2)
383

The following procedure can be adopted to determine the these impacts exist. The opening section of a major
economically optimal number of annual doses of the FAO-sponsored review of helminth diseases states:
treatment to administer: increase the number of doses as long 'Helminthiasis infections of food animals cause significant
as the additional revenue (which equals extra weight of meat economic losses. The effect of the infection is determined by a
in kilograms multiplied by price paid per kilogram for this combination of factors of which the varying susceptibility of
meat) exceeds the cost of an extra dose of the treatment, the host species, the pathogenicity of the parasite species, the
e.g. additional drenching. As a rule, the net income host/parasite interaction, and the infective dose are the most
maximising dose rate will be the highest dose rate for which important. The economic losses are closely associated with
the above condition is satisfied. The optimal number of doses the extent to which the pathogenic effect of helminth
can be expected to vary with factors such as the price of meat infections influences the production of the individual host.
and the cost of dosing the animals. This may vary considerably from clinical disease including
mortality to chronic production losses which may appear as,
In practice, the situation will be much more complicated. e.g., reduced growth rate, weight loss and/or reduced
More than one livestock product may be affected by a disease, fecundity or it may go unnoticed' ( 3 5 ) .
and the economics of treatment may vary with environmental
conditions, which may be relatively unpredictable. Thus, the A further cost arises in that some helminths can be
economic decision to control a disease may have to be made transmitted to man. Many parasitic helminths can in fact be
in uncertain and variable conditions. Therefore, attitudes to transmitted between vertebrate animals and man (i.e. these
risk and instability must be taken into account. In animal helminths are zoonoses) and 'about 2 0 species are of public
health economics, sensitivity analysis is usually used to health importance causing severe or fatal infections. In many
measure these variables (10, 3 0 ) . Sensitivity analyses specify parts of Africa parasitic helminths are responsible for
outcomes for different possible scenarios or states of nature. enormous economic losses, hampering rural development
The likelihood of these may also be indicated. Depending programmes and reducing the pace of economic growth' ( 2 5 ) .
upon the attitude of the decision maker towards the bearing of
risks and income variability, he or she can adopt a particular
Bain and Urquhart estimated that the economic loss from
strategy. Essentially, this was the approach adopted by Meek
stomach worm in British cattle in the mid-1980s would have
(27) in analysing the economics of alternative strategies for the
been approximately £ 4 5 million annually if parasitic
control of ovine fascioliasis in Australia.
gastroenteritis had been completely uncontrolled (2). This
potential loss would show a several fold increase if the figure
The problem becomes more complicated when alternative were to be scaled up to cover the whole of Europe. The
techniques of parasite control exist, since these need to be research was mostly concerned with the economic impact of
compared to decide which are the most economic, including the most pathogenic of the stomach worms in cattle in
possible combinations of these techniques ( 4 3 ) . More detailed Europe, Ostertagia ostertagi. Estimates of financial loss are
analysis of animal health economics is provided by based on mortalities in young cattle and the failure of cattle to
Dijkhuizen and Morris ( 1 0 ) . reach potential normal weights (weight loss). These are
assumed to vary according to the severity of infection. In the
The main purpose of this sub-section is to emphasise that the absence of parasitic control, it is assumed that 5 % of cattle will
economics of control of endemic diseases is especially be severely infected, 2 0 % moderately so, 4 5 % will have
complicated. This is particularly true of diseases related to sub-clinical infections and the remainder will not be affected.
parasitism because of the high degree of sensitivity of these Only the severely infected group is assumed to suffer
(and of the economics of control) to variable environmental mortality; 2 4 % of this group are supposed to die annually,
conditions. Furthermore, especially in the case of helminths, involving a loss of £ 2 0 0 per dead animal on average. Weight
cultural factors and the often complicated helminth life-cycles loss per calf is assumed to decline as the degree of infection
add extra dimensions to difficulties of determining the declines, being 3 5 kg for severely infected animals, 2 0 kg for
economics of control. the moderately infected and 10 kg for sub-clinical cases. Each
kilogram loss is supposed to reduce the value of a calf by
£ 1 . 2 0 . The estimated annual production of calves in Britain
Helminthiasis: economic impact was 3.2 million over the period in question and consequently
the estimate of a £ 4 5 million annual loss can be easily
and economics of control in obtained.

livestock In this analysis, no account has been taken of any possible


Economic impact of helminthiasis impact on prices of livestock nor of the possibility of a
reduction in the milk yields of older cattle. In addition, no
Many qualitative statements can be found in the literature
which indicate that the economic impacts of helminth estimates have been made of profits forgone by not adopting
infections are substantial, but few quantitative estimates of the most economic methods of control of stomach worms of
384 Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2)

cattle, that is economic gains which could be made by cost (C) and control expenditure (E) as illustrated in Figure l.
adopting superior available methods of control of stomach The points along the loss-expenditure frontier may be taken
worms. Therefore, this exercise appears to be of limited value. to represent the capitalised value, or discounted sum, of
Nevertheless, it resulted in Zinsstag et al. (45) proclaiming disease and expenditure costs over a number of years. This
that 'In Africa such estimations are not available, but losses are curve represents the set of choices available to a country in
expected to be even higher due to poor nutrition, which terms of effort on disease control. With no control
substantially enhances the pathogenic effect of parasites (15)'. expenditure, disease cost, c , is high. As control expenditure is
1

increased, disease cost first decreases rapidly, the C-E tradeoff


In an early study of the economics of control of helminthiasis curve being almost vertical. But with increasing expenditure
in weaned lambs (1), it was estimated on the basis of the curve flattens as the marginal rate of improvement with
experimental evidence in Victoria, Australia, that if all young respect to cost declines. If the disease can be eradicated,
sheep in the high rainfall area of Australia were given the control expenditure may fall to zero or to some low amount
critical treatment scheme (anthelmintics at the most representing the cost of preventing new outbreaks.
appropriate time) rather than being treated for clinical
parasitism only, the additional net benefit would be
approximately AUS$6.7 million annually at 1 9 7 0 - 1 9 7 1 wool
prices. In comparison to traditional drenching schedules, the
extra net benefit to wool growers from the critical scheme
would amount to AUS$5.4 million. These economic gains
increase with wool prices. The precise figures are not very
important for this article; what is more important is that
owners of sheep could have considerably increased their
incomes by adopting a superior available strategy for heminth
control.

Unfortunately, the review by Over et al. (35) of helminth


diseases of livestock in developing countries sheds little light
on the economic impact of these diseases. Data such as
infection rates of livestock and rejection rates of offal at
e*
abattoirs due to helminth infections provide a restricted basis Expenditure on disease control (E)
for estimating economic impacts. Furthermore, no indication
is given of economic benefits which are unrealised due to Fig. 1
failure to adopt appropriate available control techniques. The Mclnerney loss-expenditure tradeoff model

Economics of control of helminthiasis


S o c i a l a n d p r i v a t e p e r s p e c t i v e s o n c o n t r o l effort Since both axes are expressed in dollars terms, and a dollar in
The economics of helminth control may be viewed from a disease cost is regarded as equivalent to a dollar in control
government or social perspective, or from the perspective of costs, the line with slope - 1 represents combinations of equal
the individual producer. The government needs to take cost to the country, i.e. an isocost line. One such line is drawn
account of externalities, such as trade impacts and effects on in Figure 1; this is the line which is tangent to the C-E curve.
public health. The individual producer is concerned with Any C-E combination to the right of this line would represent
maximising private goals of revenue, stock quality and other greater overall cost; any point to the left is not achievable.
objectives, within the resource limitations and regulatory Hence e* is the optimal expenditure level and is associated
framework. with a disease cost c* (total cost c* + e*). For this formulation,
the disease cost variable would need to include all relevant
Government wishes to determine the optimal control items including non-market costs (e.g. environmental
expenditure, including public and private sector expenditure. impacts, animal welfare changes).
The social cost-benefit analysis framework generally accepted
for evaluation of animal health programmes involves making The distribution of costs between government and livestock
estimates of all socially relevant costs and benefits, including producers is a further issue. There is increasing emphasis on
both market and non-market items, and hence deriving 'user pays' policies, and this could be applied to animal health
'incremental cash flows'. However, when expenditure levels research, disease control, inspection for export and so on.
vary between alternative disease control policies, it has been However, it is notable that measures which reduce livestock
argued that benefit-cost criteria do not rank alternatives producer costs may lead to greater benefits for consumers
correctly, and that a loss-expenditure tradeoff curve provides than for producers. On the other hand, measures which
a better indication of optimal control effort (21, 22, 2 3 ) . This enhance export markets may impose a cost on consumers, to
takes the form of a concave tradeoff curve between disease the benefit of producers and traders (middlemen).
Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2) 385

I s s u e s in e v a l u a t i n g c o n t r o l e c o n o m i c s Anderson et al. (1) and Morris et al. (29) explored the


economics of anthelmintic drenching of sheep, based on the
The economics of control of helminthiasis tends to be results of experimental work in Victoria. The main helminths
complicated because the life-cycles of helminths can be
of concern were Ostertagia and Trichostrongylus spp. The
complex and are dependent on environmental conditions
economics of four alternative control strategies were
which can vary considerably. Furthermore, in most cases, the
compared:
life-cycles of helminths depend on multiple hosts. Schwabe
(40) suggests that helminths show unusual biological - treatment 1 : no preventive treatment
complexity and points out that 'broadly adapted to causing
- treatment 2: traditional preventive treatment as indicated
disease in other species, parasitic nematodes, cestodes and
by surveys of farmers
trematodes undergo successive stages of development, often
as quite dissimilar forms, including in their feeding and other - treatment 3: varied prophylactic treatment based on critical
habits'. Four types of zoonosis cycle exist: periods in the life of the helminth species involved

- direct zoonoses can be perpetuated by a single vertebrate - treatment 4: fortnightly treatment.


reservoir, e.g. trichinosis
The studies found that both treatments 2 and 3 were
- cyclo-zoonoses require more than one vertebrate species to
economic, with treatment 3 being the most profitable when
complete a life-cycle, e.g. echinococcosis
administered either to weaned lambs (1) or to breeding ewes
- meta-zoonoses require both vertebrate and invertebrate (29). Fortnightly treatment was more profitable than
host species, e.g. schistosomiasis traditional treatment.

- sapro-zoonoses require a non-animal reservoir or


development site to complete a life-cycle, e.g. some species of These results were based on partial budgeting. Sensitivity
nematodes ( 4 0 ) . analysis was applied and the profitability of the fortnightly
treatment was shown to be particularly sensitive to wool
Knowledge of such cycles is essential for the sound economic prices. In the case of breeding ewes, it was concluded on the
and epidemiological control of helminths. For instance, as basis of the economic evidence presented that 'there is no
Zinsstag et al. ( 4 5 ) point out: 'The precise knowledge of the merit for the farmers in considering the option of either the
biology and seasonability of the (gastrointestinal) parasite and 'traditional' treatment scheme or 'two-weekly' treatment
the groups at risk in the various agro-ecological zones are scheme in preference to the 'critical' treatment scheme, since
prerequisites for any economically and epidemiologically the latter was the most financially rewarding under all
sound approach to the control of gastrointestinal parasites'. circumstances evaluated' ( 2 9 ) .

Even in the case of direct zoonoses involving a single While the above contribution is a significant one, the study is
vertebrate reservoir, the question is raised of what is the best based only on a small experimental sample on one farm, of
stage in the life-cycle of the parasites to target for economic limited numbers of sheep and results over one year. Further
control (e.g. the eggs or a later stage in the life-cycle), and at testing at other locations and other replications would be
what time to target these stages. Some anthelmintic treatments desirable to test the robustness of the results. When
are ineffective if the parasites enter a dormant stage (2). If a
experimental research on the control of animal diseases,
parasite has more than one host (e.g. liver flukes depend on
including field experiments, is performed, some doubt must
snails as hosts as well as vertebrates), the question arises of
arise regarding the extent to which the results can be
whether it is economic to control this reservoir in order to
generalised to a wider population. An interesting social
reduce infection in the end-host. Furthermore, can livestock
science question raised by this research (but not explored) is
be economically excluded from sources of environmental
why farmers used the traditional method rather than the more
contamination with parasites or excluded from these at critical
profitable one? Is it because of lack of information or for some
times? To this end, and for the control of particular helminth
other reason?
diseases, strategic rotational grazing of livestock or strategic
cropping and grazing cycles can be practised.
In northern Victoria, Australia, an analysis of the economics of
Usually, a wide range of possible strategies are available for the control of ovine fascioliasis was undertaken in sheep grazing
control of helminths, but only a few of these alternative on irrigated and non-irrigated pasture (27, 3 0 ) . A model was
strategies are explored from an economics point of view. developed to analyse infections of sheep by Fasciola hepatica,
Some may be excluded on a priori grounds because they are taking into account environmental factors, the life-cycle of
clearly uneconomical. Those explored often reflect the F. hepatica, and the impact of ovine fascioliasis on wool
particular expertise of the researcher. Some of the available production (and value of wool sold) and value of sheep sold.
studies of the economics of control of helminthiasis are Parameters in the model were specified using scientific
considered below. literature, expert opinion and two experiments designed to
386 Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2)

supplement this information. Using simulation techniques, Table I


the economics of control were examined for the following: Benefit-cost ratios and internal rates of return for a five-year
vaccination programme against bovine schistosomiasis in the Sudan
- five alternative anthelmintic strategies
- the use of a molluscide to destroy snail hosts High p r o d u c t i o n loss L o w p r o d u c t i o n loss
A r e a and c o v e r a g e
- rotational grazing. avoided avoided
assumed (a) I
B / C RR(b)
B/C IRR
Although most attention is given to anthelmintic strategies,
Central (90%) 22.7 328 1.5 43
the economic study is more comprehensive than most
Western (50%) 5.7 209 1.2 17
because other control possibilities are also considered. The
South-east (50%) 4.0 157 0.7 -12
economic benefit from anthelmintic treatment is shown to
depend on stocking rates and percentage of the paddock Source: based on McCauley et al. (18), p. 738
(used by sheep) occupied by snail habitats. The most a) Benefit-cost ratio based on net present values of benefits and costs
b) Internal rate of return
intensive strategy for anthelmintic treatment (drenching
approximately every eight weeks) was shown to give the
highest financial return. The research provides a valuable
holistic framework for studying the economics of control of estimate the value of losses avoided are clearly described in
ovine fascioliasis (27). In this regard, this study is a relatively the research (18). For the purpose of the exercise, the study
unique contribution to the veterinary economics of the concentrates on sales of meat and takes into specific account
control of helminthiasis. two factors: mortality from S. bovis and growth delay weight
loss. It is recognised that additional factors could be
The case studies mentioned above concern a relatively considered, such as losses in production from reproduction
developed country. Similar case studies for developing inefficiency and condemnation of livers at abattoirs. However,
countries are scarce, but the need for economic evaluation is reliable data was not available concerning increased
often crucial, as is evident from recent research on strategic reproduction inefficiency, and losses due to liver
gastrointestinal nematode control in cattle in The Gambia condemnation are small.
(45). Significant weight loss from nematodes was
demonstrated in cattle, but financial analysis of the While the estimates in this study rely on various assumptions,
recommended control measures was not completed. the systematic framework provides a solid basis for economic
evaluation. The model can be easily reworked for changed
An interesting economic evaluation of the economic returns assumptions or conditions. In addition, scope exists for
from vaccinating cattle in the Sudan against Schistosoma bovis adapting the model to estimate the economic returns from
has been completed (18). Schistosoma bovis vaccine has control of other animal diseases. However, the model
proven to be effective in experiments in the White Nile evaluates one method of control only, whereas comparative
province of the Sudan in reducing mortality and weight loss economic analysis of different methods and techniques of
(or growth delay) from S. bovis infection. The results of these control would be desirable.
experiments are used together with other data to estimate the
economic return to be expected from an 5. bovis vaccination The level of subsidy or the extent to which farmers would
campaign in the Sudan extending over a five-year period. have to pay for vaccination of cattle in the Sudan against
S. bovis is unclear. Even when returns from an investment are
For the purpose of estimation, the Sudan is divided into three high, individual farmers in less developed countries (LDCs)
areas - central, western and southern. T h e area divisions may fail to undertake this investment because of lack of
reflect judgements on the probabilities of infection and finance or because of suspicion of new techniques. Farmers in
vaccine coverage that could be reasonably expected under the LDCs often face different economic constraints to those in
conditions in the different provinces' (18). Returns for developed countries. As highlighted by Roberts and
vaccination in each of the areas are estimated for high and low Suhardono (38), control measures for animal diseases which
levels of production losses avoided as a result of S. bovis are economic in developed countries may be uneconomic in
vaccination. The estimated benefit-cost ratios and internal less developed countries or prevented from being adopted by
rates of return are set out in Table I. Benefits exceed costs in all cultural practices. Therefore, the development of different
areas except southern Sudan where low levels of production strategies for controlling helminths in LDCs may be necessary.
losses are avoided. For central Sudan, estimated economic In relation to the control of fasciolis in ruminants in LDCs, the
benefits are especially high, being well in excess of costs in all following observations have been made : 'Anthelmintics are
circumstances considered, with internal rates of return not affordable. Recent observation of a major fasciola
varying from a low of 4 3 % to a high of 3 2 8 % , depending on resistance gene with substantial dominance in Indonesian
whether low or high productivity losses are avoided. Thin Tail sheep infected with Fasciola gigantica suggest that
parasite control by breed substitution, or cross-breeding and
The methods used to estimate bovine schistosomiasis losses in selection, are feasible. Such control should be inexpensive to
the Sudan and the costs of the vaccination programme, and to implement and sustainable' ( 3 8 ) .
Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2)
387

Breed substitution is in fact often used as a mechanism for occur in the ruminant industries. According to McLeod and
coping with parasites; even in developed countries, including Kristjanson ( 2 4 ) : 'Tick-borne diseases severely constrain cattle
Australia, Bos indicus cattle are often substituted for Bos taurus production in Asia, Africa and Australia. The diseases
in tick-infested areas because the former species has superior theileriasis, babesiosis, anaplasmosis and heartwater can cause
resistance to ticks. However, such substitution can involve mortality, reduced milk and beef production, depressed
economic costs, for example if the market value of products manure production and reduced animal draft power. The
from the substituted breed is less than the alternative. Roberts distribution of these diseases is dictated by the presence of
and Suhardono also suggest that some simple changes to specific tick vectors for each of the diseases. Anaplasmosis and
agricultural cultural practices in LDCs may entail low cost and babesiosis are primarily transmitted by ticks of the genus
provide some control of fasciolosis, however, an economic Boophilus, found throughout Africa, Asia and Australia.
study was not undertaken ( 3 8 ) . The study is nevertheless Heartwater (cowdriosis) is vectored by Amblyomma spp. in
significant in that the importance of relating research on the Africa. Theileriosis, called tropical theileriosis in Asia and
control of animal diseases to the social and economic context northern Africa is vectored by ticks of the genus Hyalomma. It
in which this research is to be applied is emphasised. To is known as East Coast fever (Theileria parva) in Central and
complicate matters, it might also be added that social and Eastern Africa where it is transmitted by the tick Rhipicephalus
economic conditions are rarely stationary. Changes in the appendiculatus.'
direction of research and in the type of advice given to client
groups are generally required as circumstances change. The effects of these agents can be devastating as evidenced by
the outbreak of East Coast fever in southern Africa at the
It should be noted that in undertaking social evaluation of beginning of this century, which decimated the cattle
methods of disease control, as opposed to the calculation of industry. In addition, the consequences to an individual
private economic benefits, factors additional to those producer can be high when naive cattle are introduced into an
mentioned above should be taken into account. For example, area where these diseases occur, or where the vector
the use of molluscides to destroy snails which are hosts for a transmitting a disease is introduced to a new area. The latter
helminth may destroy other biota of value. All externalities may occur either as a result of changes in seasonal conditions
and environmental spillovers should be taken into account in (for example warmer, wetter conditions, favouring tick
a social evaluation. Furthermore, more frequent development and reproduction) or due to changes in tick
administration of anthelmintics may accelerate resistance of control methods. Therefore, the problem confronting
helminths to these chemicals, so the more immediate decision makers is not whether the diseases are important, but
economic benefits must be balanced against loss of economic when the disease should be controlled and which method or
benefits in the longer term. In addition, some anthelmintics
combination of methods is most appropriate.
(and other chemical means of controlling parasites) result in
chemical residues in meat or milk which can limit the
Tick-borne diseases provide many difficulties in determining
marketability and suitability of the product for human
the most economically efficient approach to control. Problems
consumption. This restricts the economic and social value of
arise due to the complexity of the system, including both the
the use of such controls.
large number of tick species present and of diseases
transmitted b y the ticks, and the interactions between
Thus, it can be seen that the economics of control of
animals, ticks and disease agents.
helminthiasis is complex, partly because of the complex
epidemiology involved. A sound knowledge of both biological
Disease control involves a number of activities in various
and economic relationships is needed to evaluate disease
combinations and is not an all-or-nothing event. In addition,
control strategies involving helminths. That few in-depth
disease or vector control activities often affect other vectors or
economic studies of the control of helminthiasis have been
diseases, providing benefits (and in some cases costs) not
completed is therefore not surprising. However, the authors
directly related to the original disease control programme. In
are surprised to find that no substantial studies in the area
addition, control methods for ticks and tick-borne diseases
seem to have been published since 1984.
can be difficult to use and are not always effective. For
example, vaccines are usually live and although of low
virulence, can have side effects requiring close monitoring of
Tick and tick-borne diseases: livestock for signs of vaccine reactions and need for treatment.

economic impact and control Tick control can have additional side effects: the most
commonly applied method (the use of chemical acaricides)
economics produces residues in meat if animals are slaughtered within
Ticks and tick-borne diseases are accepted as major causes of the prescribed withholding period. Environmental
economic loss to livestock industries in tropical and contamination and erosion of areas around dip tanks can also
sub-tropical regions of the world. In particular, these losses occur.
388 Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2)

The factors outlined above, in association with the carried out successfully, an understanding of the potential
interactions that occur between vector ticks and the diseases effects of disease on the productivity of affected animals is
produced, make decisions about tick and tick-borne essential.
disease-control complex on a technical and economic basis.
For example, treatments to control one species of tick will Although systems for the assessment of the effects of chronic
affect other species of ticks, and the introduction of one diseases, in particular internal parasitism, are well
programme such as dipping, for tick control, may require documented, techniques to assess the effects of acute
introduction of another programme involving vaccination infectious diseases on animal production under grazing
against tick-borne disease (due to reduced immunity). These conditions are not. Extensive production of livestock differs
flow-on effects need to be considered in the analysis. The significantly from intensive production, for example, animals
complexity of animal health systems, in particular, the large are rarely observed closely, animal health information is
number of interactions, calls for the development of therefore scarce, inputs are considerably lower per head and
simplified models to enable the important factors in the feed intake is difficult to measure.
system to be determined and considered in the analysis.
Few studies have been carried out to assess the effect of
Economic impacts disease on animal production in extensive areas in Australia.
The costs of outbreaks of bovine ephemeral fever have been
T h e e f f e c t s of d i s e a s e o n l i v e s t o c k p r o d u c t i o n
assessed using crude estimates of disease incidence and the
Disease has a variety of biological effects on animals that are effect of disease on production ( 3 9 ) . In addition, the benefits
exhibited as production losses. Disease affects the ability of an of using an improved vaccine against tick-borne diseases in
animal to survive, grow and reproduce. In addition to the Australia (3) have been estimated, as well as the costs of
effects of disease on individual animals, herd effects are also bovine pestivirus infection in extensively grazed cattle ( 2 0 ) .
seen, including adverse modification of the herd structure However, none of these studies examined in detail the loss in
(26). production due to the disease compared with the loss avoided
when the disease was controlled. No field studies comparing
Close clinical observation, physical measurement and the effect of various disease control measures on animal
laboratory examination of specimens is often required to production have been carried out in extensively grazed areas
determine the effect of a disease on the productivity of an of Australia.
animal (30). The effects of a disease on animal production are
difficult to estimate because of the large number of variables
that are affected, such as age, breed, production status and Effects of disease on livestock productivity
condition of the host, pathogenicity of the disease-causing Morris and Meek divide the effects of chronic disease on the
organism and environmental factors (16). Because productive performance of livestock into two categories,
information is limited on the effects of diseases on production, namely, apparent alterations in efficiency and real reductions
estimates must usually be made using a combination of in efficiency (30). This conceptual framework is expanded by
published data and expert opinion ( 1 1 , 3 3 ) . Morris and Marsh, who have defined apparent alterations in
efficiency as changes in production caused by animals eating
The effects of parasitic infestation (which can produce a less food (31). In some cases, appetite suppression may be
chronic disease) on animal production have been widely due to a direct and specific effect on appetite, while in others
reported (1, 14, 27, 3 0 ) . A system has been developed to the effect may be indirect due to the reluctance of the animal
outline the information needed to determine the effects of a to forage due to pain or discomfort associated with movement
disease on livestock production (30). The system uses a or prehension, caused by the disease.
combination of experimental studies and expert opinion to
determine the effects of a disease on animal production. Real reductions in efficiency are defined by Morris and Meek
as being due to depression of feed digestibility or of feed
In the case of sporadic or exotic diseases there is much less conversion efficiency (30). The estimation of real reductions
certainty about disease occurrence. To perform a field in efficiency is complicated by interactions between these two
experiment or observational study would either involve factors because the level of feed intake can affect the efficiency
artificial infection of a group of animals or the use of a large with which feed is used.
number of sites, which would be expensive. In addition, the
large number of variables which could not be controlled in an The differentiation between a reduction in feed intake and a
observational study would lead to the need for unacceptably true reduction in productive efficiency is important because if
large sample sizes ( 1 7 ) . Under these conditions, the use of a a reduction in feed intake is the factor causing the lost
modelling approach is appropriate to estimate the effect of the production, an increase in stocking rate will increase
disease on production. This is especially true under extensive production as an alternative to controlling the disease ( 3 0 ) .
grazing conditions where the effects of disease on individual Often, the dividing line between apparent and real effects is
animals are difficult to measure. However, for modelling to be not clear, and if feed intake cannot be measured, as occurs in
Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2)
389

extensively-raised caule, the two effects cannot be Although clinical disease does cause weight loss, little work
differentiated ( 3 1 ) . has been done to measure the amount and variation in the
amount of weight lost, the type of weight lost and the ability of
The effects of acute disease contrast with those of chronic animals under various conditions to recover the weight lost.
disease because acute disease is short-lived and affected
animals usually either recover rapidly or die. In addition, Production loss due to product quality
animals that have recovered from acute infectious diseases are Ticks and tick-bome disease can cause downgrading of live
often not susceptible to a second attack of that disease, animals at sales, and of meat, offal, and hides.
whereas in the case of diseases such as mastitis and internal
parasitism, recurrent infections or infestations occur. Production loss due to effects on lactation
Disease can vary both the quantity and the quality of the milk
Categories of livestock production affected by produced. The effects on quantity can vary from a mild
disease temporary reduction to a total cessation of milk production.
While the effects of a disease on animals are extremely The effects vary depending on the stage of lactation at which
variable, a simplified approach must be taken to enable the the disease occurs and the severity of disease. In beef cattle,
examination of these effects. The production loss in grazing the main effect of a reduction in lactation is on the growth and
animals due to diseases can be divided into the following survival of calves.
categories:
Production loss due to reproductive loss
- death
Diseases can have several effects on reproduction. These
- weight loss
effects on reproduction are firstly examined for females and
- reproductive loss
then for males. The effects of disease on female reproduction
- lactation effects.
vary according to the time that the disease occurs in relation to
the reproductive cycle of the individual. The system of
A description of each of these factors is given below.
management, either controlled seasonal breeding or
Production loss due to death continuous breeding, will influence the proportion of females
at each stage of the reproductive cycle at different times of the
The death of animals due to disease can have several effects on
year, and therefore the effect of a disease on reproduction in
herd production. Deaths result in a reduced number of
the herd.
animals available for sale and a modification in the herd
structure. In extensively grazed animals, production loss due
to death is difficult to assess. Diseases can affect reproductive efficiency in the following
ways:
Production loss due to weight loss
- silent oestrus periods
The final effect of weight loss, due to disease, on production
will depend on several factors, the most important of which - prevention of fertilisation
are: - early embryonic loss
- the amount of weight lost due to the disease - loss in mid gestation
- the composition of that weight loss (i.e. body fluid, gut - abortion in the last trimester of pregnancy
content, muscle or fat)
- birth of dead, weak, or deformed calves which die soon
- the rate at which the weight is recovered (this is affected by postpartum
compensatory growth, the level of nutrition and the
composition of the weight loss). - delays in heifers breeding due to body weight and
condition being below optimal.
Considerable information is available on the effects of the
restriction of nutrition on the subsequent growth and The effects on male reproduction are more restricted and
development of cattle ( 3 4 ) . Much of this information is relate to the ability of the male to seek, mate with and fertilise
contradictory but there is general agreement that several receptive females. The effects of a disease in males can be
factors are important in determining if compensatory growth summarised as follows:
occurs and if it does, how much compensatory growth occurs.
- reduced mobility, with the consequence that affected
These factors are as follows:
animals are not able to seek and mate with receptive females
- breed - reduced libido
- age, liveweight and maturity
- stage of growth and condition (ratio of fat:lean meat:bone) - temporary or permanent infertility due to direct effects of a
disease on spermatogenesis
- severity and duration of restriction
- type of feed - temporary infertility due to effects on spermatogenesis and
- level of nutrients in the feed ( 3 4 ) . sperm survival due to pyrexia associated with a disease.
390 Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2)

Temporary effects are especially important if a disease Table II


outbreak occurs during or just before the breeding season. Annual cost of ticks and tick-borne diseases, Australia, 1997
(USS million) (24)

Indirect production effects and non-production


Anaplasma
effects Cost c a t e g o r y Tick worry
and Babesia
Disease can mask genetic differences, making herd
Control costs - chemicals 4.2 0.0
improvement difficult, and can be an impediment to
- labour 0.0 0.8
introducing more intensive systems of livestock production
- vaccines 12.0 0.0
(12,28).
Productivity loss - mortality 0.0 15.1
Apart from impacts on livestock products, tick-borne diseases - milk production 0.7 0.05
can impose costs in terms of reduced consumer surplus, - live weight 3.9 0.0
adverse impacts on human health, reduced draught and Total 20.8 15.9
transport services in countries where cattle and buffalo are
used for these purposes, and impose adverse effects on animal
welfare. Reduced reproduction can lead to lower stock prices). A retrospective economic analysis (5) estimated a
numbers, where stock ownership is a measure of wealth, a benefit-cost ratio of the eradication of 1 4 0 : 1 .
status symbol, source of creditworthiness, or provides other
e) In Argentina, the cost of tick infestation was estimated at
social values. In general, the literature overlooks these costs,
U S $ 1 5 4 . 6 million for weight loss, death and hide damage,
with disease costs defined in terms of production and control
and US$34.9 million for the cost of tick control and tick fever
costs only, as described, for example, by Mukhebi (32).
vaccine ( 4 1 ) .

C o s t s of t i c k s a n d t i c k - b o r n e d i s e a s e s f) The global cost of ticks and tick-borne diseases was


estimated in 1979 at US$7 billion (over AUS$26 billion at
There is no shortage of reported estimates of regional and
current prices) (19).
national costs of ticks and tick-borne diseases. Often these
estimates are made to assist in evaluation of tick eradication
The above studies suggest there are major variations in cost
proposals. A number evaluations in various countries have
estimates, e.g. AUS$90 million and AUS$140 million for
been reviewed by Davis (8, 9 ) , some examples of which
Queensland, and AUS$250 million and AUS$60 million for
follow:
Australia. In addition, the cost of ticks and tick-borne diseases
a) The Bureau of Agricultural Economics (BAE) estimated the in Australia is generally agreed to have fallen sharply with the
annual cost of cattle tick to producers in Australia (including wider use of Bos indicus cattle.
production loss, chemical purchases, capital works, mortality
and hide damage) at £ 9 . 5 million (about AUS$90 million at Control economics
current prices) (6).
Control e c o n o m i c s from a social perspective
b) The cost of Boophilus microplus to beef producers and The optimal level control effort for ticks and tick-borne
government in Australia (including research, loss of diseases may be viewed in terms of the loss-expenditure
production, tick fever vaccinations, labour, dip maintenance tradeoff curve. In this context, Mukhebi ( 3 2 ) views
and chemicals) was estimated by the Cattle Tick immunisation in terms of the tradeoff curve developed by
Control Commission to be AUS$41.27 million (over McInemey ( 2 1 , 2 2 ) . However, often the decision faced will
AUSS250 million at current prices) (7). Indirect costs due to not be to decide the optimal amount of control, but rather to
tick fever deaths or illness were approximated by assuming decide whether to continue current practice or introduce an
1% mortality. No estimates were made for the dairy industry. eradication campaign, on a local, regional or national basis. In
The estimated cost to Queensland in this study was fact, for developed countries engaging in intensive livestock
approximately AUS$140 million at current prices, production, tick eradication may be the optimal policy.
considerably higher than found in the BAE study (6). However, this will be true only for a very few countries (such
as those in the Caribbean where the USA wishes to prevent
c) McLeod and Kristjanson noted that 120 scientists have
the introduction of Amblyomma into the USA). Often
been involved in preliminary estimation of tick-borne disease
eradication will be favoured where the process is moderately
costs in South Africa, Kenya, Tanzania, Zimbabwe, Thailand,
easy technically, e.g. areas of low rainfall or low temperatures.
China, India, Nepal, Indonesia, the Philippines and Australia
In some cases, eradication will proceed incrementally, as
(24). As an example, the cost estimates for Australia of
individual districts work towards and achieve eradication.
US$37 million in 1997 (approximately U S $ 3 8 million at
The Cattle Tick Control Commission noted essential
current prices), are shown in Table II.
conditions for successful eradication: ability to muster all tick
d) In the United States of America (USA), an eradication hosts; adequate treatment facilities; effective industry
campaign for B. microplus and B. annulatus was successfully co-operation; reasonable prospects of avoiding reinfection;
completed in 1947, at a cost of US$53.5 million (at 1953 efficient weapons of control; and adequate funding (7).
Rev. sci. teck Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2) 391

Where livestock production systems are more extensive (such viewpoint of the livestock owner, several questions arise with
as in Australia, South America or Africa), the economics of respect to disease control actions, as follows:
eradication becomes questionable. Here the payoff from
- does the control method work (what is the chance of the
eradication is lower, ticks do not represent an acute problem,
method failing)?
managing a full muster may be difficult, and more wild hosts
are likely to be present, making eradication more difficult. - will production be greater after the control programme is
implemented?
If eradication is warranted, the issue arises as to how the cost - will the benefits derived exceed the costs (including
is shared between government and private sector. Davis opportunity costs)?
suggests that this may be through consolidated revenue,
- can the control programme be put into practice within the
charges on producers, or joint funding, noting that in
constraints in which the livestock owner operates?
voluntary tick eradication programmes in Queensland,
government met 5 0 % of the cost, and had representation on a
At the private producer level, decisions arise concerning the
corporatised local management committee (9).
following options:

It has been argued (13) that in the case of disease (or vector) - to live with the disease, with little or no control measures
eradications, a different form of tradeoff curve is relevant, as - to continue current practice, or standard practice in the
illustrated in Figure 2. Substantial overhead costs ( e ^ may be district, e.g. spraying for ticks when numbers climb
incurred in setting up a tick eradication programme, which in
- to adopt a regular vaccination schedule
themselves do not achieve any reduction in disease cost. In
addition, even at a moderate level of variable expenditure - to increase control incidence, perhaps supported by
(e - e1), little progress may be achieved towards eradication.
2
information collection
At a high level of control expenditure, collapse of the tick - to attempt to achieve a disease-free herd or flock, with
population may take place. If the C-E curve is of this shape, respect to particular diseases.
then the choice is one of either eradication or non-eradication,
and not an intermediate point. Control measures
Davis (8) categorises control measures for the cattle tick
species B. microplus, as follows:

- chemical control
- use of tick-resistant (B. indicus) cattle
- pasture rotation
- use of TickGARD, a cattle tick vaccine.
Disease cost(C)

Davies notes that tick fever - Babesia bovis, the major indirect
effect of the catde tick - can be controlled by reducing cattle
tick populations, selecting cattle which have natural resistance
to tick fever (B. indicus cattle), and using tick fever vaccines.
With constant tick populations, cattle will have an acquired
resistance; vaccination is more critical where outbreaks occur
only occasionally.

Estimating the production loss avoided


In the simplest form, the production loss avoided due to
Expenditure on disease control (E)
disease control equals the reduction in the number of cases of
disease due to disease control multiplied by the production
Fig. 2
Disease cost-control expenditure tradeoff model for an infectious loss per case. However, the production loss avoided will vary
disease which requires a threshold protection level with the age and sex class of the animals and the severity of
the disease. The calculation can be made more accurate if the
production loss avoided is estimated as the sum of the
Control economics from a private perspective production loss of each age and sex class of the animals in the
As noted above, in intensive livestock production systems, the herd and is weighted according to the different severities of
optimal policy is likely to be tick eradication. In extensive disease.
systems and in developing countries, choice of optimal
control measures is more difficult, and strategies need to be Most control studies, models and programmes involve a
compared in terms of expected profit or cost to the individual combination of experimental studies, expert opinion, field
producer. The complexity of the economic evaluation may studies and modelling and simulation. The complexity of the
necessitate a form of modelling and simulation. From the system means the level of knowledge about the biology of a
392 Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2)

disease is limited. However, perfect knowledge of all expenditure and the expenditure could exceed the value of
interactions is not required to make an appropriate decision the information.
about control of the disease. Attempts to collect all
information about the disease and control method before
control is instituted will bear a cost and may be uneconomic. Collection of information
It is necessary that any analysis considers the likely
consequences of action and inaction. Lack of information on Although collecting information is regarded as an essential
the likely effects of disease control does not prevent an part of economic analysis, the economics of obtaining
effective and detailed analysis being carried out. additional information is not usually assessed when designing
animal health programmes. Often, additional data must be
collected and analysed before the presence of a disease
The private use of animal health information problem and the possible benefits of controlling a disease are
Information provides support for private decision makers. recognised (i.e. the efficiency gap is detected). The value of
Any decision in livestock disease control involves uncertainty information will depend on the attitude of the farmer to using
because the aim is to predict what may occur in the absence of information and the degree of confidence the farmer has in
a disease control programme and the effect that a disease the accuracy of the information. Disease control is often
control programme may have on disease occurrence. carried out because a severe disease outbreak in the past has
Decisions are therefore made using the imperfect knowledge stimulated producers to avoid similar losses in the future. Ellis
that is available to the decision maker (in this case knowledge and James (11) note the lack of use of available information on
is defined as the sum of available information). However, disease control by farmers, commenting on the slowness of
perfect knowledge is not required for rational decision- farmers to commence new disease control measures which
making and the optimal decision-making usually involves have been shown to produce financial rewards. Furthermore,
imperfect knowledge and hence imperfect information (4). it is suggested that this is due to the reluctance of farmers to
spend money and effort to obtain a benefit that has not
previously been obtained.
The collection of additional data, which is processed into
information, is one to way to decrease uncertainty. However,
the production of information requires the use of resources, If a producer is already making the most appropriate
and hence bears a cost. Because of these costs, it is often decisions then the private benefit received from the improved
uneconomic to decrease uncertainty through the gathering of animal health information will be small, and will depend on
additional information. Alternatively, the effects of uncertain the value placed on the decreased uncertainty in relation to
events can be reduced by, for example, maintaining flexible decisions and the reduction in the cost of maintaining flexible
policies that enable a rapid response to change in animal policies due to the decreased uncertainty. It is also possible
health status. Examples are: preparation for immediate that additional information will change a specific decision
vaccination if cases of a disease occur in the district, or from the appropriate one to an inappropriate one, resulting in
reduction of the hazard, as in the case of farming a negative pay-off from the additional information (though
disease-resistant B. indicus cattle where there is a risk of not in an expected pay-off sense). It will not be worthwhile for
disease caused by B. bovis infection. However, maintaining a producer to collect additional information on animal health
flexible policies will also bear a cost. unless the benefit gained from using that information exceeds
the costs of collection.
The effect on a decision of the collection of additional
information, leading to increased knowledge, can be to
change the decision, decrease the uncertainty in making the The relationship between cost and value of additional
decision, or decrease the need for flexible policies. information in private decisions

If a farmer decides to gather additional information on the


The benefit gained by a farmer from collecting additional occurrence of disease on the farm, there are many methods of
information will depend on the current level of knowledge. If, collecting that information. While some of these methods will
when using the information currently available, the level of not be feasible, or will be prohibitively expensive, the farmer
knowledge of the producer is at a low level, then the will generally have a choice. To select the method to be used,
collection of additional information will most probably bring the farmer can compare the cost of the method and the value
a large increase in information for a relatively small of the information likely to be produced. In most cases the
expenditure. However, if the level of knowledge is high, the method will not be an all-or-nothing method, and by
benefit from collection of additional information is much less increasing expenditure, the farmer will obtain increasingly
per unit of expenditure. A farmer with a high level of accurate information. However, the relationship between the
knowledge would be expected to gain less benefit from the cost of collecting information and the value of that
same expenditure on information collection than a farmer information to a private decision maker is almost certainly not
with a lower level of knowledge. A farmer with a high level of a linear relationship and several possibilities exist for that
knowledge may gain little information from additional relationship.
Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2)
393

Specific scenarios for animal health decisions Many livestock producers carry out analyses similar to the one
The following sections examine the issues confronting described above, to assist in decision making.
individual producers in a variety of situations, with some
examples of analysis for different production systems. A In some cases, a limited partial budget may provide the farmer
relatively simple situation will be examined first with more with sufficient information to meet decision-making needs.
complex decisions considered in subsequent examples. However, the disease may also have effects such as reducing
cattle growth rates and reducing reproductive efficiency. An
Scenario 1: control of ticks and tick-borne diseases
approach to estimating the production loss avoided and
for an extensive beef producer in Australia
financial benefit gained due to a vaccination programme to
Here, the major tick-borne disease is caused by B. bovis and
control B. bovis is provided by Ramsay (37) and a brief
tick control is often not practised on the property. The
description is presented here. The approach illustrates several
producer faces the decision of whether to vaccinate. The
areas in which additional information may be of use and
questions are whether the benefits from vaccinating exceed
others where information may be of limited use to a decision
the cost, and how the net pay-off compares with alternative
maker.
uses of the money, such as depositing it in a bank account or
investing in shares. In addition to these financial concerns, the
producer may wish to be perceived by other cattle producers The production loss is divided into loss due to deaths, weight
as a good manager who maintains healthy stock, and by the lost and not regained by the time of sale, and reproductive
community as someone who is concerned about the welfare loss. A simulation model is developed which is used to
of animals. Therefore, the producer will also want information determine the production loss avoided for two vaccination
on the effect of vaccination on morbidity and mortality in the programmes, for each of three herds containing cattle that are
herd. resistant, susceptible and of intermediate susceptibility to
disease, following infection with B. bovis at high, medium and
low levels of incidence of infection.
How can this information be provided to the producer?
Discounted cash flow analysis, including partial budgeting,
can provide information on expected returns from The model developed provides an effective method of
vaccination. A variety of information is required to produce examining the production benefits gained from adopting a
annual partial budgets. How extensive does the partial budget vaccination programme. Simulations indicate that the major
need to be, and how accurate need the budget data be? In its production benefit from B. bovis vaccination arises from
simplest form, the calculations might resemble the following: deaths avoided. Considerably less benefit is predicted to be
gained in the form of weight loss avoided due to prevention of
a) 5 0 0 cattle are to be vaccinated each year
clinical disease from which animals recover. The effect of
b) the vaccine costs AUS$1.50 per dose and administration B. bovis vaccination on reproductive efficiency is also
costs AUS$0.50 per head (mainly for labour) predicted to be small.

c) the vaccine is effective and all animals that require


vaccination are vaccinated As expected, the production benefits of B. bovis vaccination
are predicted to be greatest in the susceptible cattle and least
d) cattle only need to be vaccinated once in a lifetime
in disease-resistant cattle. The incidence risk of infection also
e) in the absence of vaccination, three cattle die as a result of affects the production benefits of B. bovis vaccination, with the
B. bovis infection each year and each animal that dies has a loss avoided being highest where the incidence risk of
value of A U S $ 4 0 0 . infection is medium and least where the incidence risk of
infection is high, as in these cases, herd resistance to B. bovis is
From these data, the partial budget would take the following also high.
form:
Livestock producers in extensive grazing areas of Australia
Vaccine costs: 5 0 0 x A U S $ 1 . 5 = AUS$750 suffer from a shortage of animal health information. However,
Administration costs: 5 0 0 x AUS$0.50 = AUS$250 a rational decision can be made without perfect information
Total costs: AUS$ 1,000. and it will not be worthwhile for a producer to collect
additional information on animal health unless the benefit of
Benefits from preventing stock deaths: that information exceeds the cost of collecting the
AUS$400 x 3 = AUS$ 1,200 information. A clear understanding of the interactions
Annual net cash benefit: AUS$200. between the disease incidence and production effects will
enable the livestock producer to consider the decision to
The farmer can see that if the estimate of three deaths is gather additional animal health information systematically
accurate, the gains will exceed the expenditure on disease and examine the potential returns. However, the benefits from
prevention (by AUS$200/year), provided the vaccine is collection of additional information need to be calculated for
effective. each individual situation.
394 Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2)

The information above with respect to the effect of B. bovis on relatively more on control of ticks and tick-borne disease
production demonstrates that collection of additional because although the risk of loss of an animal to tick-borne
information to determine more precisely the weight loss due disease may be low, the loss would have major economic
to disease caused by B. bovis will not be of great benefit to the consequences.
decision maker, nor will be additional information on the
reproductive effects of the disease. However, additional
information on the number of animals likely to die following
infection and on the incidence of risk of infection could be of
Conclusion
use to the decision maker. Economic study of endemic diseases and disease control is a
complex area, with a large number of disease vectors and
Before deciding whether to collect additional information, the diseases, and complex relationships between treatment,
livestock owner needs to determine if the benefit from environment and livestock performance to consider. While
collecting the information is sufficient to justify the costs of considerable technical study of these diseases has been
collection. The collection of additional information does not performed, economic analysis of the effects and the control of
always result in a net gain. When the gain from collection of the diseases remains a relatively neglected f i e l d .
additional information is small, it is possible that the farmer
would gain more by using the money elsewhere rather than Decision-making about livestock diseases needs to be viewed
collecting additional information. In the case of B. bovis, from both social and private perspectives. In making social
vaccine is relatively inexpensive in comparison to the cost of decisions it is necessary to take a broader view than in making
the collection of additional information, and provides private decisions, and consider externality costs, optimal
long-lasting protection. Therefore, it is possible that money overall control effort, and sharing of costs between taxpayers
may be more effectively spent on the purchase of vaccine and livestock owners. Individual producers face complex
rather than on gathering additional information. If vaccination decisions about disease control effort, including whether to
must be carried out annually, or a more expensive and less invest in obtaining further information before making
effective vaccine is used, the benefit from collecting additional decisions.
information would be expected to be greater.

Major differences in livestock systems and in optimal disease


Scenario 2: cattle producer in a country in Africa
control programmes arise in developed and developing
where multiple ticks and tick-borne diseases are
countries, between intensive and extensive production
present
systems, and even between properties, due to differences in
In the case of a large-scale beef producer the question to be
environment, resources and objectives of livestock owners.
asked may be 'How should I control ticks and tick-borne
Non-production costs of diseases can be important, but
disease on my property?' The producer faces a number of
typically are not adequately taken into account in disease cost
decisions which can interact producing flow-on effects. For
studies.
example, dipping practised to control ticks will also affect the
exposure of stock to agents causing tick-borne diseases. If a
While little information is available on the cost of helminth
producer is considering reducing dipping intensity what
diseases, many estimates have been made of the costs of ticks
benefits will be obtained? The livestock might enter a higher
and tick-bome diseases at regional and national level,
priced market for chemical-free beef, and chemical and labour
sometimes demonstrating that eradication is warranted.
costs may be reduced. Environmental contamination on the
Introduction of more tick-resistant cattle appears to have
property could be reduced since the producer is no longer
substantially reduced costs associated with ticks and
using dip wash. In addition, the farmer may wish to protect
tick-bome diseases.
the environment and farm in an ecologically sustainable
manner. However, by reducing dip use, production could be
reduced and greater morbidity and mortalities experienced.

In the case of a small-scale dairy or beef producer, the effect of


losing a single animal may be much larger than for a
large-scale beef producer. For example, a producer with three
cows will lose a third of productive capacity if one cow dies.
Therefore, this producer is more interested in reducing risk of
loss of an animal rather than the average long-term effects of
disease control. The producer may be prepared to spend
Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2| 395

Impact économique des enzooties et des programmes


de prophylaxie
C A Tisdell, S.R. Harrison & G.C. Ramsay

Résumé
L e s a u t e u r s é v a l u e n t l ' i n c i d e n c e é c o n o m i q u e d e s e n z o o t i e s et les e n j e u x
é c o n o m i q u e s liés à l e u r p r o p h y l a x i e . Ils s ' i n t é r e s s e n t e n p a r t i c u l i e r a u x
h e l m i n t h i a s e s et a u x i n f e c t i o n s t r a n s m i s e s p a r u n v e c t e u r endémique
( n o t a m m e n t les t i q u e s et les m a l a d i e s qu'elles t r a n s m e t t e n t ) . L e s d é c i s i o n s
r e l a t i v e s a u x m e s u r e s d e p r o p h y l a x i e d o i v e n t ê t r e p r i s e s à la f o i s p a r les p o u v o i r s
p u b l i c s et p a r le p r o d u c t e u r . L e s p o u v o i r s p u b l i c s o n t b e s o i n d ' i n f o r m a t i o n s s u r le
n i v e a u de p r é v e n t i o n n é c e s s a i r e , s u r l ' i m p o r t a n c e de la p a r t i c i p a t i o n r e q u i s e et
s u r les m o d e s de f i n a n c e m e n t d e s p r o g r a m m e s z o o s a n i t a i r e s ( n o t a m m e n t s u r la
r é p a r t i t i o n d e s c o û t s e n t r e c o n t r i b u a b l e s et é l e v e u r s ) . Q u a n t a u x p r o d u c t e u r s , ils
d o i v e n t ê t r e i n f o r m é s s u r les e f f o r t s qu'ils a u r o n t à f o u r n i r p o u r la p r o p h y l a x i e ,
n o t a m m e n t e n c e qui c o n c e r n e la c o l l e c t e d e s d o n n é e s , et s u r la m a n i è r e de
c o n c e v o i r d e s s t r a t é g i e s d e lutte. L ' é c o n o m i e p e u t a p p o r t e r u n b o n é c l a i r a g e s u r
c e s questions. Toutefois, l'expérience m o n t r e que les politiques zoosanitaires
s o n t p a r t i c u l i è r e m e n t d i f f i c i l e s à é v a l u e r d'un p o i n t d e v u e é c o n o m i q u e , d'autant
qu'il e x i s t e d e s r e l a t i o n s c o m p l e x e s e n t r e la s a n t é a n i m a l e , les e f f e t s s u r la
p r o d u c t i o n , l ' a c c è s a u m a r c h é et les b é n é f i c e s n o n p r o d u c t i f s liés a u x a n i m a u x . Il
e x i s t e p e u d ' i n f o r m a t i o n s s u r le c o û t d e s h e l m i n t h i a s e s , m a i s de n o m b r e u s e s
e s t i m a t i o n s r é a l i s é e s s u r c e l u i d e s t i q u e s et d e s m a l a d i e s qu'elles t r a n s m e t t e n t ,
aux n i v e a u x régional et national, m o n t r e n t qu'une éradication peut parfois se
justifier.

Mots-clés
A n i m a u x d'élevage - Économie - Helminthiase - Maladies animales - Maladies
transmises par les tiques - Prophylaxie.

Impacto económico de fas enfermedades endémicas


y los programas de control
C.A. Tisdell, S.R. Harrison & G.C. Ramsay

Resumen
L o s a u t o r e s e s t u d i a n la f o r m a de e v a l u a r el i m p a c t o e c o n ó m i c o d e e n f e r m e d a d e s
e n d é m i c a s del g a n a d o , junto a otras c u e s t i o n e s de c a r á c t e r e c o n ó m i c o
r e l a c i o n a d a s c o n el c o n t r o l de e s a s e n f e r m e d a d e s , c e n t r á n d o s e e s p e c i a l m e n t e
e n los h e l m i n t o s y e n las e n f e r m e d a d e s e n d é m i c a s t r a n s m i t i d a s p o r v e c t o r e s
( s o b r e t o d o las g a r r a p a t a s y las e n f e r m e d a d e s q u e é s t a s v e h i c u l a n ) . L a s
d e c i s i o n e s de c o n t r o l s a n i t a r i o c o m p e t e n t a n t o a las a u t o r i d a d e s p ú b l i c a s c o m o a
los g a n a d e r o s . El p o d e r p ú b l i c o r e q u i e r e i n f o r m a c i ó n s o b r e la m a g n i t u d de las
m e d i d a s de c o n t r o l q u e s e i m p l a n t e n , el g r a d o de i m p l i c a c i ó n n e c e s a r i o y la f o r m a
de f i n a n c i a r p r o g r a m a s z o o s a n i t a r i o s ( e s p e c i a l m e n t e c ó m o r e p a r t i r s u c o s t e
e n t r e los c o n t r i b u y e n t e s y l o s g a n a d e r o s ) . L o s p r o d u c t o r e s , p o r s u p a r t e ,
n e c e s i t a n i n f o r m a c i ó n s o b r e el n i v e l de e s f u e r z o q u e d e b e n i n v e r t i r e n el c o n t r o l
s a n i t a r i o , i n c l u y e n d o la o b t e n c i ó n d e i n f o r m a c i ó n , y s o b r e el m o d o de e l a b o r a r
e s t r a t e g i a s d e c o n t r o l . La e c o n o m í a p u e d e a r r o j a r luz s o b r e e s a s c u e s t i o n e s . S i n
e m b a r g o , la e x p e r i e n c i a e n s e ñ a q u e la e v a l u a c i ó n de p o l í t i c a s z o o s a n i t a r i a s
d e s d e u n p u n t o de v i s t a e c o n ó m i c o r e s u l t a e s p e c i a l m e n t e difícil, d a d a la
396 Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2)

complejidad de los vínculos existentes entre sanidad animal, efectos sobre la


producción, acceso a los mercados y beneficios no productivos que procura el
ganado. Aunque no existe mucha información sobre el coste de las
enfermedades helmínticas, sí abundan las estimaciones de los costes que
entrañan, a escala tanto regional como nacional, las garrapatas y las
enfermedades que transmiten. Esas estimaciones demuestran a v e c e s que la
erradicación puede justificarse.

Palabras clave
Control de enfermedades - Economía - Enfermedades animales - Enfermedades
transmitidas por garrapatas - Ganado - Helmintiasis.

References

1. Anderson N., Morris R.S. & McTaggart I.K. (1976). - An 9. Davis R. (1997). - A review of economic evaluations of
economic analysis of two schemes for the anthelmintic government policies for the control of cattle tick. Research
control of helminthiasis in weaned lambs. Aust. vet. J., 52, Papers and Reports in Animal Health Economics, No. 32,
174-180. Department of Economics, University of Queensland,
Brisbane, 46 pp.
2. Bain R.K. & Urquhart G.M. (1986). - The significance and
control of stomach worms in British cattle. Outlook Agric., 10. Dijkhuizen A.A. & Morris R.S. (eds) (1997). - Animal health
15 (1), 10-14. economics: principles and applications. Post Graduate
Foundation in Veterinary Science, University of Sydney,
3. Bartholomew R.B. & Callow L.L. (1979). - A benefit-cost 306 pp.
study (ex-post) of the development and introduction of a
new vaccine against bovine babesiosis. In Proc. 2nd 11. Ellis P.R. & James A.D. (1979). - The economics of animal
International Symposium on veterinary epidemiology and health. 1. Major disease control programs. Vet. Rec., 105,
economics (W.A. Geering, R.T. Roe & L.A. Chapman, eds), 504-506.
7-11 May, Canberra. Australian Government Publishing
12. Harrison S.R. & Tisdell C.A. (1997). - Animal health
Service, Canberra, 448-457.
programs in sustainable economic development: some
4. Baumol W.J. & Quandt R.E. (1964). - Rules of thumb and observations from Thailand. In Development that lasts
optimally imperfect decisions. Am. Econ. Rev., 54, 23-46. (K.C. Roy, H.C. Blomqvist & I. Hossein, eds). New Age
International, New Delhi, 201-214.
5. Bram R.A. & Gray J.H. (1979). - Eradication - an alternative
13. Harrison S.R. & Tisdell C.A. (1999). - Economic analysis of
to tick and tick-borne disease control. Wld Anim. Rev., 30,
foot and mouth disease control and eradication in Thailand.
30-35.
Australian Centre for International Agricultural Research,
6. Bureau of Agricultural Economics (BAE) (1959). - The Canberra, 95 pp.
economic impact of cattle tick in Australia. Australian
14. Hawkins C D . (1977). - The effect of disease on
Government Publishing Service, Canberra, 85 pp.
productivity: a study of liver fluke in sheep. PhD
7. Cattle Tick Control Commission (1975). - Cattle tick in dissertation, University of Melbourne, 209 pp.
Australia: inquiry report. Australian Government Publishing
15. Holmes P.H. & Coop R.L. (1994). - Workshop summary:
Service, Canberra, 108 pp.
pathophysiology of gastrointestinal parasites. Vet. Parasitol.,
54, 299-303.
8. Davis R. (1996). - An overview of the status of cattle tick
Boophilus microplus in Queensland. Research Papers and 16. James A.D. & Ellis P.R. (1978). - Benefit-cost analysis in foot
Reports in Animal Health Economics, No. 14. Department of and mouth disease control programmes. Br. vet. J., 134,
Economics, University of Queensland, Brisbane, 21 pp. 47-52.
Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2) 397

17. James A.D. & Ellis P.R. (1979). - The evaluation of 30. Morris R.S. & Meek A.H. (1980). - Measurement and
production and economic effects of disease. In Proc. 2nd evaluation of the economic effects of parasitic disease. Vet.
International Symposium on veterinary epidemiology and Parasitol, 6, 165-184.
economics (W.A. Geering, R.T. Roe & L.A. Chapman, eds),
7-11 May, Canberra. Australian Government Publishing 31. Morris R.S. & Marsh W.E. (1992). - The relationship
Service, Canberra, 363-372. between infections, diseases and their economic effects. In
Modelling vector-borne and other parasitic diseases
18. McCauley R.H., Majid A.A. & Tayer A. (1984). - Economic (B.D. Perry & J.W. Hansen, eds). Proc. Workshop held at the
evaluation of the production impact of bovine International Laboratory for Research on Animal Diseases
schistosomiasis and vaccination in the Sudan. Prev. vet. Med., (ILRAD), 23-27 November, Nairobi. ILRAD, Nairobi,
2,735-754. 199-213.
19. McCosker P.J. (1979). - Global aspects of the management
32. Mukhebi A.W. (1996). - Assessing economic impact of
and control of ticks of veterinary importance. Recent Adv.
tick-borne diseases and their control: the case of theileriosis
Acarol., 1 1 , 4 3 - 5 3 .
immunisation. In Epidemiology of ticks and tick-borne
20. McGowan M.R., Baidock F.C., Kirkland P.D., Ward M.P. & diseases in Eastern, Central and Southern Africa (A.D. Irvin,
Holroyd R.G. (1992). - A preliminary estimate of the J.J. McDermott & B.D. Perry, eds). Proc. Workshop,
economic impact of bovine pestivirus infection in beef herds 12-13 March, Harare. International Livestock Research
in Central Queensland. In Proc. Australian Association of Institute (ILRI), Nairobi, 174 pp.
Cattle Veterinarians, 'New Horizons', 10-15 May, Adelaide.
Australian Association of Cattle Veterinarians, Adelaide, 33. Mukhebi A.W., Perry B.D. & Kruska R.L. (1992). -
129-132. Estimated economics of theileriosis control in Africa. Prev.
vet. Med., 12, 73-85.
21. McInemey J.P. (1988). - The economic analysis of livestock
disease: the developing framework. In Proc. 5th International 34. O'Donovan P.B. (1984). - Compensatory gain in cattle and
Symposium on veterinary epidemiology and economics (P. sheep. Nutr. Abstr. Rev., B, 54, 389-410.
Willeberg, J.F. Agger & H.P. Riemann, eds), 25-29 July,
Copenhagen. Acta vet. scand., 84 (Suppl.), 66-74. 35. Over HJ., Jansen J . & van Olm P.W. (1992). - Distribution
and impact of helminth diseases of livestock in developing
22. McInemey J.P. (1991). — Cost-benefit analysis of livestock
countries. FAO Animal Production and Health Paper No. 96.
diseases: a simplified look at its economic foundations. In
Food and Agriculture Organization, Rome, 221 pp.
Proc. International Symposium on veterinary epidemiology
and economics (S.W. Martin, ed.), 12-16 August.
36. Perry B.D. & Randolph T.F. (1999). - Improving the
Department of Population Medicine, Ontario Veterinary
assessment of the economic impact of parasitic diseases and
College, University of Guelph, 149-153.
their control in production animals. Vet. Parasitol. (in press).
23. McInemey J.P., Howe K.S. & Schepers J.A. (1992). - A
framework for the economic analysis of disease in farm 37. Ramsay G.C. (1997). - Setting animal health priorities: a
livestock. Prev. vet. Med., 13, 137-154. veterinary and economic analysis with special reference to
the control of Babesia bovis in central Queensland. PhD
24. McLeod R. & Kristjanson P. (1999). - The economic impact thesis, Department of Economics, University of Queensland,
of selected tick-borne diseases on cattle in Africa, Asia and Brisbane, 325 pp.
Australia. eSYS Development, Sydney, and ILRI, Nairobi (in
press). 38. Roberts J.A. & Suhardono (1996). - Approaches to the
control of fasciolosis in ruminants. Int. J. Parasitol, 36,
25. Macpherson C.N.L. & Craig P.S. (1991). - Parasitic
971-981.
helminths and zoonoses in Africa. Unwin Hyman, London,
281 pp. 39. St George T.D. (1986). - The epidemiology of bovine
26. Matthewman R.W. & Perry B.D. (1985). - Measuring the ephemeral fever in Australia and its economic effect. In Proc.
benefits of disease control: relationship between herd 4th Symposium on arbovirus research in Australia, Brisbane.
structure, productivity and health. Trop. Anim. Hlth Prod., Commonwealth Scientific and Industrial Research
17, 39-51. Organisation (CSIRO), Division of Animal Health, Brisbane,
281-286.
27. Meek A.H. (1977). - Economically optimal control strategies
for ovine fascioliasis. PhD thesis, Faculty of Veterinary 40. Schwabe C.W. (1991). - Helminth zoonoses in African
Science, University of Melbourne, Melbourne, 178 pp. perspective. In Parasitic helminths and zoonoses in Africa
28. Morris R.S. (1990). - Animal health economics, principles (C.N.L. Macpherson & P.S. Craig, eds). Unwin Hyman,
and applications: how economically important is animal London, 1-24.
disease and why? International Training Centre,
41. Spath E.J.A., Gugielmone A.A., Signorini A.R. & Mangold A.J.
Wageningen Agricultural University, Wageningen, 10 pp.
(1992). - An estimation of the economic costs caused by the
29. Morris R.S., Anderson N. & McTaggart I.K. (1977). - An tick Boophilus microplus and tick-borne disease in Argentina.
economic analysis of two schemes for the control of Report (in Spanish). Instituto Nacional de Tecnología
helminthiasis in breeding ewes. Vet. Parasitol., 3, 349-363. Agropecuaria, Balcarce, Argentina.
398 Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2)

42. Suhardono, Roberts J.A., Copland J.W. & Copeman D.B. 45. Zinsstag J . , Ankers Ph., Itty P., Njie M., Kaufmann J . ,
(1997). - Control of bovine fasciolosis in Indonesia. Pandey V.S. & Pfister K. (1997). - Effect of strategic
Epidémiol Santé anim., 31-32, 0.2.19.1-0.2.19.3. gastrointestinal nematode control on productivity of N'Dama
cattle in the Gambia. Epidémiol. Santé anim., 31-32,
43. Tisdell C.A. (1995). - Assessing the approach to cost-benefit
02.10.1-02.10.3.
analysis of controlling livestock diseases of McInerney and
others. Research Papers and Reports in Animal Health
Economics, No. 3. Department of Economics, University of
Queensland, Brisbane, 22 pp.

44. Tisdell C.A. (1996). - Bounded rationality and economic


evolution: a contribution to decision making, economics and
management. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, 336 pp.

View publication stats

You might also like