Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 56

Financial Derivatives

Continuous Time Option Pricing

Dr Eirini Konstantinid & Dr Ser-Huang Poon

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 1 / 56


Outline

In the previous lecture, we priced options using discrete-time methods.


k Binomial trees.

In this lecture, we turn to continuous-time approaches.


k Black-Scholes-Merton model.

In the next lecture, we shall consider Greeks (partial derivatives of option


value wrt input parameters) and volatility smiles.

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 2 / 56


Outline

Video 1: Intended learning outcomes.

Video 1: Review of stochastic processes.


k Modelling stock prices using Wiener processes.
k Geometric Brownian Motion Process.

Video 2: Itô’s lemma.


k The log-normal property of stock prices.

Video 3: The Black-Scholes(-Merton) model.


k Deriving the Black-Scholes(-Metron) partial differential equation (p.d.e.).
k Practicing the Black-Scholes(-Merton) model.
k Stocks with & without dividends.

Video 4: Probability of ending up ITM.


k Risk-neutral and real world probability.
(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 3 / 56
Intended learning outcomes

By the end of this lecture you should be able to :

Understand basic concepts on stochastic processes.

Discuss the appropriate modelling of stock prices.

Apply Itô’s lemma.

Discuss implications for the stock price (return) distribution.

Derive the Black-Scholes(-Merton) p.d.e..

Use and discuss the Black-Scholes(-Merton) model.

Derive, apply and discuss the probability to end up ITM.

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 4 / 56


Reading list

Hull (7th & 6th Edition): Chapter 12, 13 & 15.

Hull (8th Edition): Chapter 13, 14 & 16.

Hull (9th & 10th Edition): Chapter 14, 15 & 17.

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 5 / 56


Review of stochastic processes

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 6 / 56


Stochastic processes
Assumption: Stock prices evolve randomly over time.
k Stock prices incorporate expectations about the future.
k Hence, stock prices only change with news.
k News cannot be forecasted & arrives in a random fashion over time.

We hence model the stock price using a stochastic process.


k Stochastic process: Describes how a random variable evolves over time.
k They often include both a deterministic & a random component.
k They can be classified as discrete time or continuous time.
k They can also be classified as discrete variable or continuous variable.

Examples:
k Case 1: Each day a stock price increases by $1 with probability 30%, stays
the same with probability 50% & decreases by $1 with probability 20%.
k Case 2: Each day the stock price change is drawn from a normal
distribution with a specific mean & variance.
(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 7 / 56
Markov processes
Markov processes depend only on the current level of the random variable
k Historical values are of no importance.

Do the following variables follow a Markov process?


k The temperature in London.
k The stock price of Barclay’s Bank.

Markov property of prices is consistent with weakly efficiency markets.

Weak-form of market efficiency.


k The spot price impounds all the information contained in past prices.
k Historical prices contain no info about future prices.
k Technical trading is therefore futile.
k Competition ensures that the markets are weakly efficient.

A good example of a Markov process is the random walk: yt = yt −1 + εt


(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 8 / 56
Continuous-time stochastic process: The wiener process

Let N (µ, ν) denote a normal distribution with expectation µ & variance ν.

A random variable z follows a Wiener process if:



1 ∆z = ε ∆t, where ε ∼ N (0, 1).
2 ∆z for any two non-overlapping time periods are independent.
where ∆z is the change in z over a small time interval ∆t.

The Wiener process is a particular type of a Markov process.

The Wiener process is also referred to as Brownian motion.

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 9 / 56


The wiener process
From the definition of the Wiener process we can show that:
E (∆z ) = E (z (T ) − z (0)) = 0 and var (∆z ) = var (z (T ) − z (0)) = T

k Mean of (z(T) - z(0)):


E (z (T ) − z (0)) = E [∆z (1) + ∆z (2) + . . . + ∆z (T )]
= E [∆z (1)] + E [∆z (2)] + . . . + E [∆z (T )]
= 0 + 0 + . . . + 0 = 0.

k Variance of (z(T) - z(0)):


var (z (T ) − z (0)) = var [∆z (1) + ∆z (2) + . . . + ∆z (T )]
= var [∆z (1)] + var [∆z (2)] + . . . + var [∆z (T )]
= (1 − 0) + (2 − 1) + . . . + (T − (T − 1)) = T .

The standard deviation is the square root of the variance ( T ).
k Uncertainty is proportional to the square root of time.
(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 10 / 56
The generalized wiener process
In a generalized Wiener process, the drift rate and the variance rate can
be set to any chosen constants (with the variance > 0).
k Drift rate: Mean change per unit of time for a stochastic process.
k Variance rate: Variance per unit of time for a stochastic process.
k Example of basic Wiener process ∆z: Drift = 0, Variance rate = 1.

The generalized Wiener process can be written as:

∆x = a∆t + b ∆z

= a∆t + b ε ∆t
where a is the mean change in x per time unit, and b2 is the variance of
the change per time unit.

If we let the time increment ∆t become smaller and smaller (i.e. ∆t → 0):

dx = adt + bdz ⇔ dx = adt + bε dt
(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 11 / 56
The generalized wiener process: Sample path

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 12 / 56


Itô Process

Generalized Wiener process: dx = adt + bdz

Itô process: Obtained when a & b are deterministic functions of x and t.

dx = a(x , t )dt + b (x , t )dz

Both the expected drift rate & variance rate are liable to change over time.

The Itô process is a particular type of Markov process.


k The change in x at time t depends on the value of x at t (not on its history).

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 13 / 56


Why generalized wiener process is inappropriate for stocks

Do not use a generalized Wiener process to model stock prices.


k The stock price cannot become negative due to limited liability.
k The expected % change (i.e., return) should remain constant over time - not
the actual change.
k The variance of the actual change should depend on the stock price level
(greater price → greater variance).

The following Itô process, often referred to as Geometric Brownian motion


(GBM), makes more sense:
dS = µSdt + σSdz

where µ is the stock’s expected rate of return and σ is the volatility (i.e.
standard deviation) of the stock price.


The discrete-time equivalent is: ∆S = µS ∆t + σS ε ∆t

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 14 / 56


Simulating a Geometric Brownian Motion

We can sample random paths for the stock price (i.e., the GBM) by
sampling values for ε ∼ N (0, 1).

Suppose µ = 0.15, σ = 0.30, and ∆t = 1 week ( 52


1
= 0.0192 years):

∆S = µS ∆t + σS ε ∆t

⇒ ∆S = 0.15 S 0.0192 + 0.30 S ε 0.0192
⇒ ∆S = 0.00288 S + 0.0416 S ε

A stock price path is simulated by sampling repeatedly ε from N (0, 1).

Assume that the stock price at the begging of week 1 is $100.


k This implies that the stock price at the beginning of week 2 is 100 + ∆S.

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 15 / 56


Simulating A Geometric Brownian Motion (cont’d)

Assume that the stock price at the begging of week 1 is $100.


k This implies that the stock price at the beginning of week 2 is 100 + ∆S.

To calculate ∆S during week 1, we sample ε from N (0, 1).


k For instance, ε =0.52.
k ∆S = 0.00288 · 100 + 0.0416 · 100 · 0.52 = 2.45
k At the beginning of week 2 the stock price is: 100+2.45 = 102.45

The stock price at the beginning of week 3 is 102.45 + ∆S.


k Sample ε from N (0, 1). For instance, ε =1.44.
k ∆S = 0.00288 · 102.45 + 0.0416 · 102.45 · 1.44 = 6.43
k At the beginning of week 3 the stock price is: 102.45 + 6.43 = 108.88

. . . and so on . . .
(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 16 / 56
Geometric Brownian Motion: One sample path

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 17 / 56


Geometric Brownian Motion: More than one sample paths

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 18 / 56


Itô’s lemma

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 19 / 56


Itô’s lemma

The stock options price is a function of the underlying stock’s price & time.
k What process does a function of the stock price follow?

Assume that x follows an Itô process: dx = a(x,t)dt+b(x,t)dz

Itô’s Lemma shows that a function G (x , t ) follows the process:

∂G 1 ∂2 G 2
 
∂G ∂G
dG = a+ + 2
b dt + bdz
∂x ∂t 2 ∂x ∂x

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 20 / 56


Itô’s lemma: Geometric Brownian Motion
If a stock price follows the GBM (dS = µSdt + σSdz) then G(S,t) follows:
∂G 1 ∂2 G 2 2
 
∂G ∂G
dG = µS + + 2
σ S dt + σSdz
∂S ∂t 2 ∂S ∂S

Example 1:
Apply Itô’s lemma when the stock price follows a GBM & G = lnS.

∂G 1 ∂2 G 1 ∂G
= , 2
= − 2, =0
∂S S ∂S S ∂t

   
1 1 2 2 1 1
dG = µS + 0 + − 2 σ S dt + σSdz
S 2 S S
 
1
= µ − σ2 dt + σdz
2
(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 21 / 56
The lognormal property of stock prices

We have shown that:


 
1
dlnS = µ − σ2 dt + σdz
2

This means that:


σ2
  
lnST −lnS0 ∼ N µ− T , σ2 T
2

σ2
   
2
lnST ∼ N lnS0 + µ − T,σ T
2

Prices are lognormally distributed and continuously compounded returns


are normally distributed.
(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 22 / 56
Itô’s lemma: Geometric Brownian Motion (cont’d)

∂G 1 ∂2 G 2 2
 
∂G ∂G
dG = µS + + σ S dt + σSdz
∂S ∂t 2 ∂S 2 ∂S

Example 2:
Apply Itô’s lemma to the price of a forward contract written on a
non-dividend paying stock: Ft ,T = St er (T −t )

∂F ∂2 F ∂F
= er (T −t ) , = 0, = −rSer (T −t )
∂S ∂S 2 ∂t

h i
dF = er (T −t ) µS − rSer (T −t ) + 0 dt + er (T −t ) σSdz

= [µF − rF ]dt + σFdz


= [µ − r ]Fdt + σFdz
(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 23 / 56
Black-Scholes (-Merton) model

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 24 / 56


Towards the Black-Scholes(-Merton) formula

The price of an option is the discounted expected payoff.


k But it is difficult to determine the correct discount rate!

The idea behind the BS formula.


k The idea is identical to that underlying the binomial tree.
k Form a riskless portfolio (long in stocks & short in the option).
k Set the portfolio return over a short period of time equal to the risk-free rate
k This yields a partial differential equation (p.d.e.).

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 25 / 56


Deriving the Black-Scholes(-Merton) p.d.e.

Assume that stock price follows the Geometric Brownian Motion.


dS = µSdt + σSdz

Additional assumptions: (1) No transaction costs, (2) Continuous


trading, (3) Markets do not jump, and (4) Volatility is constant and known.

From Itô’s lemma, the option value f(S,t) follows the process:
 2

∂f ∂f
df = ∂S µS + ∂t + 12 ∂∂Sf2 σ2 S 2 dt + ∂∂Sf σSdz

The discrete version of these equations is:


∆S = µS ∆t + σS ∆z (1)

∂f 1 ∂2 f 2 2
 
∂f ∂f
∆f = µS + + 2
σ S ∆t + σS ∆z (2)
∂S ∂t 2 ∂S ∂S
(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 26 / 56
The replication portfolio
Buy δ units of the stock (S) and short one option (f).

We can set up a riskless portfolio because:


k The stock price & the option price are affected by the same underlying
source of uncertainty (i.e., stock price movements).
k Over a short period of time the stock price and the option price are perfectly
correlated.
k δ can be chosen so that the gain (loss) from the stock position is offset by
the loss (gain) from the option position.

The value of this portfolio is: Π = δS − f

The change in value of the portfolio over the time interval ∆t is:

∆Π = δ∆S − ∆f (3)

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 27 / 56


The replication portfolio (cont’d)
Substituting (1) and (2) into (3) we get:
∂f 1 ∂2 f 2 2
   
∂f ∂f
∆Π = δµS − µS − − σ S ∆t + δ − σS ∆ z (4)
∂S ∂t 2 ∂S 2 ∂S

∆z terms are responsible for the uncertainty in portfolio value.


∂f
k Choose δ = , so that the uncertainty terms cancel out!
∂S

Substituting δ = ∂∂Sf into (4) we get:


∂f 1 ∂2 f 2 2
 
∆Π = − − σ S ∆t (5)
∂t 2 ∂S 2

A risk-free portfolio must pay the risk-free rate:


∆Π = r Π∆t (6)
(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 28 / 56
The replication portfolio (cont’d)

From (5) and (6) we have:


∂f 1 ∂2 f 2 2
 
− − σ S ∆t = r Π∆t
∂t 2 ∂S 2
∂f 1 ∂2 f 2 2
⇔ − − σ S = rΠ (7)
∂t 2 ∂S 2

2
 
Now substitute Π = ∂∂Sf S − f into (7): − ∂∂ft − 12 ∂∂Sf2 σ2 S 2 = r ∂f
∂S S − f

Re-arranging yields the p.d.e.:

∂f ∂f 1 ∂2 f
+ rS + σ2 S 2 2 = rf
∂t ∂S 2 ∂S

Note: As S and t change the δ = ∂∂Sf also changes.


k To keep the portfolio riskless we need to frequently rebalance it.
(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 29 / 56
The Black-Scholes p.d.e. & risk-neutral valuation

Any security whose price is dependent on the stock price and time
satisfies the former p.d.e..
k The particular security being valued is determined using “boundary
conditions” (e.g., the payoffs at maturity).

The p.d.e. is independent of risk preferences.


k We have the risk free rate r and not the expected return on the stock µ.
k Any set of risk preferences can be used → risk-neutral investors.
k Risk neutral valuation.

Risk neutral valuation: A reminder


k We can treat all investors as if they are risk-neutral.
k The expected return on the stock is the risk-free rate.
k The price of the option is the expected payoff under the risk-neutral
probability measure discounted at the risk-free rate.

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 30 / 56


Risk-neutral valuation: European call price
Under risk-neutral valuation, all assets have a risk-neutral drift:
dS = rSdt + σSdZ

Consider a discounted call price, V = ce−rt , then through Ito’s lemma,:


∂V 1 2 2 ∂2 V
 
∂V ∂V
dV = + σS 2
+ rS dt + σS dZ
∂t 2 ∂S ∂S ∂S
1 2 2 ∂2 c
 
∂c ∂c ∂c
= − rc + σ S 2
+ rS dt + σS dZ
∂t 2 ∂S ∂S ∂S
which has exactly the same form as the Black-Scholes p.d.e..

Next from V = ce−rt ,


= V0 = E [VT ] = E e−rT cT
 
c0
= e−rT E [{max (ST − K , 0)}]
Z ∞
−rT
= e (ST − K ) dST (8)
K
(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 31 / 56
The Black-Scholes formula (no dividends)

If the underlying asset pays no dividends, their solutions are:


k Call: c = S0 N (d1 ) − Ke−rT N (d2 )

k Put: p = Ke−rT N (−d2 ) − S0 N (−d1 )

ln(
S0 2
)+(r + σ2 )T ln(
S0 2
)+(r − σ2 )T √
with d1 = K √
σ T
and d2 = K √
σ T
= d1 − σ T

We can interpret N (d2 ) [N(−d2 )] as the risk-neutral probability of the call


[put] option ending up in-the-money.
k N (d2 ) [N (−d2 )] becomes a real-world probability when we swap r for µ.

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 32 / 56


The N(x) function

N (x ) is the probability that a normally distributed random variable with a


mean of 0 and a standard deviation of 1 is less than x:

No closed-form solution for N (x ), although there are several efficient


approximations (see Johnson and Kotz, 1974):

e2y
N (x ) ≈ , with y = 0.7988x (1 + 0.04417x 2 ).
1 + e2y

Use distribution tables to compute N (d1 ), N (d2 ), N (−d1 ), N (−d2 ).

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 33 / 56


Cumulative normal distribution table

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 34 / 56


Practicing the Black-Scholes model

Assume you have a non-dividend paying stock.


k The current stock price is 30 and its volatility is 25%.

What is the price of a European call written on the stock with strike price
K = 36 and time to maturity T = 16 months?
k The continuously-compounded risk-free rate is 2% p.a..

1 Calculate d1 and d2 :
2 2
ln( SK0 ) + (r + σ2 )T 30
ln( 36 ) + (0.02 + 0.25
2
) 16
12
d1 = √ = q = −0.39
σ T 0.25 1216


r
16
d2 = d1 − σ T = −0.39 − 0.25 = −0.68.
12

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 35 / 56


Practicing the Black-Scholes model (cont’d)

2 Look up N (d1 ) and N (d2 ) using a distribution table:


k N (−0.39) ≈ 0.34827
k N (−0.68) ≈ 0.24825

3 Plug into BS formula:

c = S0 N (d1 ) − Ke−rT N (d2 ))


= 30 · 0.34827 − 36 · e−0.02(16/12) 0.24825 = 1.75

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 36 / 56


Properties of the Black-Scholes formula

As S0 becomes very large, c tends to S0 − Ke−rT .


k The call option moves more and more into-the-money.
k We can be relatively certain that the call will be exercised.
k The call becomes similar to a forward contract (c → S0 − Ke−rT ).
k Note also that N (d1 ) → 1 and N (d2 ) → 1.

As S0 becomes very large, p tends to zero.


k The put option moves more and more out-of-the-money.
k We can be relatively certain that it will not be exercised.
k Note also that N (−d1 ) → 0 and N (−d2 ) → 0

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 37 / 56


Properties of the Black-Scholes formula (cont’d)

As σ becomes large, the values of calls and puts increase.


k Holders profit from the upside, but do not suffer from the downside.
∂c ∂p
k In fact, we could show that ∂σ > 0 and that ∂σ > 0.
 
O
k The amount of unit change is determined by vega v = ∂∂σ

As the time-to-maturity increases, the call option value converges to the


stock value, and the put option value converges to zero.

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 38 / 56


Dividends &

the Black-Scholes (-Merton) Model

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 39 / 56


The impact of dividends on Black-Scholes pricing

Dividends change the stock price distribution at maturity.


k In an efficient market, a $5 dividend per share drops the stock price by $5.

Dividend payouts can be modeled in two ways:


1 Continuous payouts occurring at a rate of q.
2 Discrete payouts occurring at specific points in time.

In each case, the dividend payouts shift downwards the distribution of the
stock price at maturity.

Instead of decreasing the stock value at the time dividends occur,


decrease the initial stock price by the value of the dividends.
1 Continuous payouts: S0 e−qT .
2 Discrete payouts: S0 − PV(Dividend payouts).

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 40 / 56


The Black-Scholes formula (continuous dividends)

If there are dividends, the BS formulae become:


Call: c = S0 e−qT N (d1 ) − Ke−rT N (d2 ) .

Put: p = Ke−rT N (−d2 ) − S0 e−qT N (−d1 ) .

ln(
S0 e−qT
+(r + σ2
2
)T ln(
S0 2
)+(r −q + σ2 )T √
with d1 = K √
σ T
= K √
σ T
and d2 = d1 − σ T .

Use these formulae to value European index options:


k Set S0 to current index level and q to average dividend yield.

We can also use them to value European currency options.


k Set S0 to the FX rate and q to the foreign interest rate.

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 41 / 56


Practicing the Black-Scholes model with dividends
Reconsider the previous example in the case where the stock pays
dividends.
k Stock: S0 = 30, σ = 25% and it pays a $2 dividend after ten months.

k European call: K = 36 and T = 16.


k Continuously-compounded risk-free rate: r = 2% p.a..
1 Calculate the present value (PV) of the dividend:
PV (Div ) = 2 · e−0.02(10/12) = 1.97

2 Calculate the "new" stock price: 30 − 1.97 = 28.03

3 Calculate d1 and d2 .
2
ln( S0K−D ) + (r + σ2 )T ln( 2836.03 ) + (0.02 + 0.5 · 0.252 ) 16
12
d1 = √ = q = −0.63.
σ T 0.25 1216


r
16
d2 = d1 − σ T = −0.63 − 0.25 = −0.92.
12
(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 42 / 56
Practicing the Black-Scholes model with dividends (cont’d)

1 Look up N (d1 ) and N (d2 ) in the normal distribution tables.


k N (−0.63) ≈ 0.26435.
k N (−0.92) ≈ 0.17879

2 Plug into BS formula.

c = (S0 − D )N (d1 ) − Ke−rT N (d2 )


16
= 28.03 · 0.26435 − 36 · e−0.02( 12 ) 0.17879 = 1.14

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 43 / 56


Probability of ending up ITM

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 44 / 56


The lognormal risk-neutral distribution

Assume there are no dividends.

Using Itô’s lemma and assuming that dS = rSdt + σSdz and G = lnS, we
have shown that:

   
1 2 2
ln ST ∼ N ln S0 + r − σ T , σ T
2

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 45 / 56


Risk-neutral probability of European put ending up ITM

We have shown that: ln ST ∼ N ln S0 + r − 21 σ2 T , σ2 T


  

Hence:
Pr (ST < K ) = Pr (ln ST < ln K )
 !
ln K − ln S0 − r − 21 σ2 T
= N √
σ T
 !
ln SK0 + r − 21 σ2 T
= N − √
σ T

= N (−d2 )

We can interpret N (−d2 ) as the risk-neutral probability of the put option


ending up in-the-money (ITM).
k N (−d2 ) becomes a real-world probability when we replace r by µ.

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 46 / 56


Risk-neutral probability of European call ending up ITM

We have shown that: ln ST ∼ N ln S0 + r − 21 σ2 T , σ2 T


  

Hence:

Pr (ST > K ) = Pr (ln ST > ln K )


= 1 − Pr (ln S < ln K )
= 1 − N (−d2 )
= N ( d2 )

We can interpret N (d2 )as the risk-neutral probability of the call option
ending up in-the-money (ITM).
k N (d2 ) becomes a real-world probability when we replace r by µ.

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 47 / 56


Summary

In this lecture, we learned about valuing European call and put options
using continuous-time approaches.

We hence reviewed the following topics:


k Basic principles of stochastic processes.
k Replication portfolios in continuous-time.
k The Black-Scholes(-Merton) formula.

We shall next consider the Greeks (partial derivatives of option value with
respect to input parameters) and volatility smiles.

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 48 / 56


Appendix A:
Derivation of Itô’s Lemma

Not examinable!

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 49 / 56


Discretise a Diffusion Process

dx= adt + bdW



∆x = a ∆t + b ε ∆t
∆x 2 = b2 ε2 ∆t + higher order terms of ∆t

As ∆t is very small, order higher than 1 is ignore. Also, since ε ∼ N (0, 1),

=E (ε) 0
Var (ε) = 1
2
 2
Var (ε) = E ε − [E (ε)] = 1
E ε2

= 1
∆x =
2
b 2 ∆t (9)

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 50 / 56


Taylor Series Expansion with Stochastic Time

If the price of a derivative, G, is a function of the price of only the underlying


asset x
∂G 1 ∂2 G
∆G = ∆x + ∆x 2 + · · ·
∂x 2 ∂x 2

When the price of a derivative, G (x , t ), is a function of the price of the


underlying asset x and time t, Taylor Series Expansion on G (x , t ) gives rise to

∂G ∂G 1 ∂2 G 1 ∂2 G 1 ∂2 G 2
∆G = ∆x + ∆t + ∆ x 2
+ ∆ x ∆ t + ∆t + · · ·
∂x ∂t 2 ∂x 2 2 ∂x ∂t 2 ∂t 2

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 51 / 56


Since ∆t is very small in the limit, higher order term of ∆t may be omitted

∂G ∂G 1 ∂2 G
∆G = ∆x + ∆t + ∆x 2
∂x ∂t 2 ∂x 2

From (9), ∆x 2 = b2 ∆t ,

∂G ∂G 1 ∂2 G 2
∆G = ∆x + ∆t + b ∆t
∂x ∂t 2 ∂x 2

As ∆t → 0, we get

∂G ∂G 1 ∂2 G 2
dG = dx + dt + b dt
∂x ∂t 2 ∂x 2
Substituting dx = adt + bdz, we get Itô’s lemma

∂G 1 ∂2 G 2
 
∂G ∂G
dG (x , t ) = a+ + 2
b dt + bdz
∂x ∂t 2 ∂x ∂x

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 52 / 56


Appendix B:
Some Notes on Calculus

Not examinable!

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 53 / 56


Differentiation

Constant
d
k =0
dx
Power
d
kx n = knx n−1
dx
Sum/difference
d d d
[f (x ) ± g (x )] = f (x ) ± g (x )
dx dx dx
Product
d d d
[f (x ) · g (x )] = f (x ) g (x ) + g (x ) f (x )
dx dx dx
Chain rule

z = f (y ) , and y = f (x )
dz dz dy
= ·
dx dy dx

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 54 / 56


Differentiation (cont’d)

Total differential, for z = f (x , y )

∂f ∂f
dz = dx + dy
∂x ∂y
Exponential and log

d
ex = ex
dx
d d
e f (x ) = e f (x ) f (x )
dx dx
d 1
ln x =
dx x
d 1 d
ln f (x ) = f (x )
dx f (x ) dx

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 55 / 56


Integration

Sum Z Z Z
[f (x ) + g (x )] dx = f (x ) dx + g (x ) dx

Multiple Z Z
K f (x ) dx = K f (x ) dx

Integral of normally distributed variable: If y ∼ N (µ, σ) and let



b = σ T − t, then
σ
 
µ−a
Z ∞
f (y ) dy = N
a σ
b
 
µ−a
Z ∞
1 2
ey f (y ) dy = N + σ eµ+ 2 σb
b
a σ
b

(Dr Eirini Konstantinidi, AMBS) Financial Derivatives 56 / 56

You might also like