Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 27

Tax Treaty Monitor

Brian J. Arnold in Cooperation with IBFD’s Tax Treaty Unit

International/OECD Luís Eduardo Schoueri*

Arm’ s Length: Beyond the Guidelines of


the OECD “It is better to be roughly right than precisely wrong.” (John Maynard Keynes)

In the Klaus Vogel Lecture of 25 September The anti-avoidance perspective was clearly the origi-
2015, hosted by the Institute for Austrian and nal intent of transfer pricing legislation. Transfer pricing
International Tax Law (WU), Vienna, Prof. Luís manipulation has been said to be “one of the simplest ways
Eduardo Schoueri undertook an in-depth to avoid taxation”3 and “one of the most common tech-
consideration of the arm’ s length standard (ALS) niques of tax avoidance”.4 In intra-entity transactions,
in relation to transfer pricing issues and the where MNEs are not restrained by market forces to set
current status of the ALS. the transfer prices, there is a concern that such “power may
be used abusively”.5 Originally, transfer pricing rules were
1. Introduction: The Original Intent of Transfer solely designed to exclude from the tax system a distortion
Pricing Legislation engendered by common control in the definition of the
Why do states enact transfer pricing legislation? While taxable income. Viewed in this context, transfer pricing
originally conceived as an anti-avoidance mechanism, rules have been regarded as “a necessary component of any
transfer pricing and the related debates have gradually international income tax law” as such legislation would
moved towards a consideration of the taxation of the “fair “stop MNEs from easily avoiding or significantly reducing
share” on profits derived by multinational enterprises taxation by shifting profits to low or no tax jurisdictions”.6
(MNEs), irrespective of any concern based on the actual These narratives often consider transfer pricing to be
income derived from an activity subject to a state’ s juris- an “important tool in the taxpayers’ arsenal for shifting
diction. income to low- or no-tax countries” in the sense that trans-
fer pricing is deemed liable to a great extent for the phe-
Anti-avoidance legislation is fundamentally connected to nomenon of “stateless or homeless income”.7 In this way,
the concept of ability to pay,1 i.e. the share that each tax- transfer pricing rules would be “meant to prevent abusive
payer should support within a given community. In this or otherwise misleading contractual terms between the
sense, income is generally regarded as a reliable proxy to involved companies”.8
determine the ability to pay, thereby empowering states
to enact income tax, including taxes on profits derived The approach under which transfer pricing rules are
from corporations. From this perspective, anti-avoidance designed within the intent of combating tax avoidance,
legislation does not have legitimacy “per se” but is rather thereby permitting the fair allocation of tax burden among
conceived as a tool to ensure that income is captured and taxpayers, goes back to the very origins of transfer pricing
taxed. One should remember Klaus Vogel’ s classification,2 legislation. In the United States, according to the War
according to which every tax rule, whilst always having Revenue Act of 1917, the Commissioner had the authority
the function of collecting taxes, i.e. Ertragsfunktion, may to require consolidated returns from related corporations
also have the following three other functions, which are if this measure were necessary for a more equitable deter-
not always present simultaneously to: (1) allocate the tax mination of the invested capital or of the taxable income.9
burden among taxpayers, i.e. Lastenausteilungsfunktion, This legislation, as well as the following provisions of the
which implies distributing the financial needs of the state Revenue Act of 1921, was designed to a great extent as
according to the criteria of distributive justice; (2) induct a result of “tax avoidance opportunities afforded by pos-
behaviour on the part of taxpayers, i.e. Lenkungsfunktion; sessions corporations”. “The problem of international tax
and (3) simplify the tax system, i.e. Vereinfachungsfunktion.
Anti-avoidance rules should, therefore, be included in the 3. R.S. Avi-Yonah, The Rise and Fall of Arm’ s Length: A Study in the Evolution
tax burden allocation function. of U.S. International Taxation, Pub. & Leg. Theory Working Paper Series,
Working Paper No. 92, p. 3 (Sept. 2007). The article is based on an article
by the same name in 15 Va. Tax Rev. 1, p. 89 (1995). The references in this
* Professor of Tax Law at the University of São Paulo and Vice President article refer to the most recent publication.
of the Brazilian Tax Law Institute. This article is based on the Klaus 4. Id., at p. 1.
Vogel Lecture delivered on 25 September 2015 at the Vienna University 5. E. Baistrocchi, The Transfer Pricing Problem: A Global Proposal for Simpli-
of Economics and Business (VU). The author would like to acknowl- fication, 59 The Tax Law. 4, p. 949 (2006).
edge the valuable research undertaken by Ricardo André Galendi 6. Y. Brauner, Value in the Eye of the Beholder: The Valuation of Intangibles for
Junior, LL.B in relation to the article. The author can be contacted at Transfer Pricing Purposes, 28 Va. Tax Rev., p. 86 (2008).
schoueri@lacazmartins.com.br. 7. J.C. Fleming Jr., R.J. Peroni & S. Shay, Formulary Apportionment in the U.S.
International Income Tax System: Putting Lipstick on a Pig?, 36 Mich. J. Intl.
1. E. Reimer, Die sieben Stufen der Steuerrechtfertigung, in Demokratie und L. 1, p, 5 (2014).
Wirtschaft: Eine interdisziplinäre Herausforderung p. 131 (B. Gehlen & 8. W. Schön, International Tax Coordination for a Second-Best World (Part
F. Schorkopf eds., Mohr Siebeck 2013). III), 2 World Tax J. 3 (2010), Journals IBFD.
2. K. Vogel, Die Abschichtung von Rechtsfolgen im Steuerrecht, 54 Steuer und 9. Avi-Yonah, supra n. 3 on the development of transfer pricing legislation
Wirtschaft 2, pp. 91-121 (1977). in the United States.

690 BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION DECEMBER 2015 © IBFD

Exported / Printed on 6 June 2016 by biblio1@ibdt.org.br.


Arm’ s Length: Beyond the Guidelines of the OECD

avoidance through related corporations” is considered community, i.e. the ability-to-pay principle, to the alloca-
“one of the original motives” for the enactment of such tion of tax revenues among states.
rules.10 It is often argued that the reason behind the enact-
If one considers, for example, formulary apportionment
ment of transfer pricing was “the fear that profits would be
(FA), it is clear that no attention is paid to the effective
moved to lower tax jurisdictions”.11 In 1918, similar pro-
income of a given taxpayer compared to other taxpayers
visions were enacted in the United Kingdom within the
within the same community. The mere fact that formulae
very same intent.12
suggest an entity approach makes the comparison between
Curiously enough, there is currently a concern among in- MNEs with a global presence and single taxpayers acting
ternational organizations and scholars regarding distin- locally impossible. The ability-to-pay principle is based on
guishing transfer pricing from anti-avoidance legislation. the comparison of comparables, which is certainly not the
The OECD Transfer Pricing Guidelines for Multinational case when one takes into consideration income derived
Enterprises and Tax Administrations (2010) (the “OECD in different jurisdictions, under differing conditions. As
Guidelines”) assert that “the consideration of transfer is demonstrated in section 3., similar conclusions may be
pricing should not be confused with the consideration reached when one notes the distortion of the ability-to-
of problems of tax fraud or tax avoidance, even though pay principle, i.e. a “real universal taxation system”, or even
transfer pricing policies may be used for such purposes”.13 taking the discussion on the ability to pay as irrelevant,
Likewise, the United Nations “Practical Manual on Trans- in the mostly sceptical approaches towards the issue, i.e.
fer Pricing for Developing Countries” (the “UN Practical “hybrid solutions”.
Manual”) considers that transfer pricing “does not neces-
In any case, it appears to be clear that the original intent of
sarily involve tax avoidance, as the need to set such prices
transfer pricing legislation has been left behind in recent
is a normal aspect of how MNEs must operate”.14 Conse-
discussions. Even the debates that take the current regime
quently, if pricing does not accord with “internationally
for granted exhibit a serious preoccupation with how
applicable norms or with the arm’ s length principle under
transfer pricing rules should interact with general anti-
domestic law”, tax administrations may consider this to
avoidance rules (GAARs) and special anti-avoidance rules
be “mis-pricing”, “incorrect pricing”, “unjustified pricing”
(SAARs),18 apparently not taking into account the fact that
or “non-arm’ s length pricing”, and issues of tax avoidance
transfer pricing itself was originally designed to counter
and evasion may potentially arise.15 As stated by Professor
tax avoidance.
Leif Mutén in the very first Klaus Vogel Lecture in 2007,
“it would be naïve to wish for a restoration of the good old The analysis of the original intent of transfer pricing leg-
days when transfer prices were attacked only in cases of islation reveals that it was designed to counter tax avoid-
blatant tax evasion”.16 ance derived from transactions carried out under common
control as means of implementing the equality among tax-
As a result, if transfer pricing legislation has been enacted
payers. Based on this assumption, section 2. draws on the
fundamentally as anti-avoidance legislation, this has
development of the arm’ s length standard (ALS), which
become blurred. Such a change can be noted when one
is still the best method to accomplish this intent. In this
considers some of the main alternatives to the current
respect, section 2. establishes the premises with regard to
transfer pricing regime, which operate as proposals for
the origins and rationale of the ALS and proposes a clas-
general reforms on international income taxation.
sification of the critics to the method.
According to Klaus Vogel, distributive justice, i.e. aus-
Section 3. includes a brief description of the main alterna-
teilende Gerechtigkeit, can be viewed from the following
tive proposals to the current international consensus, so
two perspectives: (1) distribution of tax revenues among
that it may be concluded in section 4. that transfer pricing
the states, i.e. Verteilung des Steueraufkommens unter den
debates have essentially become the battleground for much
beteiligten Staaten; and (2) distribution of the tax burden
broader proposals for reform of international tax regimes
among taxpayers, i.e. Verteilung der Lasten auf die Ge-
worldwide. Section 4. is not intended to describe these
samtheit der Steuerpflichtigen.17 From this perspective, one
propositions in detail but is, instead, intended to demon-
can note that discussions concerning transfer pricing have
strate how transfer pricing debates have progressed from
moved from the fair taxation of a taxpayer within a given
a discussion on the best form to determine the taxable
income of taxpayers to a struggle between states regard-
10. Id. ing the allocation of tax revenues. In summary, it is clear
11. H. Hamaekers, Arm’ s Length – How Long?, 8 Intl. Transfer Pricing
J. 2 (2001), Journals IBFD. that the alternative proposals would require establishing
12. US: Income Tax Act (1918), General Rule 7. new standards on taxation of income, thereby challeng-
13. OECD, Transfer Pricing Guidelines for Multinational Enterprises and Tax ing the concept of entity as a basic unit for determining
Administrations p. 31, para. 1.2 (OECD 2010), International Organiza-
tions’ Documentation IBFD. the ability to pay in business income.
14. United Nations Practical Manual on Transfer Pricing for Developing
Countries p. 2, para. 1.1.7 (UN 2013), available at www.un.org/esa/ffd/
documents/UN_Manual_TransferPricing.pdf.
15. Id.
16. L. Mutén & J. Lüdicke, Lecture in Honour of Klaus Vogel, 62 Bull. Intl. Taxn. 18. This has become a frequent issue on the discussions of the BEPS drafts.
1 (2008), Journals IBFD. See, for example, OECD, Comments Received on Public Discussion Draft:
17. K. Vogel, Die Besteuerung von Auslandseinkünfte – Prinzipien und Praxis, BEPS Actions 8, 9 and 10: Revisions to Chapter I of the Transfer Pricing
in Grundfragen des Internationalen Steuerrechts p. 3 (K. Vogel ed., Otto Guidelines (Including Risk, Recharacterisation, and Special Measures) p. 512
Schmidt 1985). et seq. (OECD 2015).

© IBFD BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION DECEMBER 2015 691

Exported / Printed on 6 June 2016 by biblio1@ibdt.org.br.


Luís Eduardo Schoueri

Section 5. offers a framework for advancing in the applic- be “well-nigh impossible” and “savour too much of the
ation of transfer pricing legislation without deviating from arbitrary”, but suggested that “a certain rough justice” could
its original intent, i.e. privileging the ability-to-pay prin- be reached by allocating all categories of the first division
ciple. The author endorses equality and regards standard- to the place of origin and all of the second to the place of
ization as a solution to the feasibility problems of transfer domicile. According to this logic, “[w]hat each country
pricing legislation, thereby also taking into consideration would lose in the one case it would roughly gain in the
the compatibility between the method proposed, i.e. the other, and there would be the great additional advantage
“rebuttable fixed margins method”, and the OECD Model.19 of comparative simplicity”.25 It is obvious that this conclu-
sion was based on the idea that flows among jurisdictions
Finally, in emphasizing the original intent of transfer
would be balanced. This is clearly the original failure of
pricing legislation, the author considers criticism of the
this study, which did not consider economic differences
recent OECD Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (BEPS) pro-
among countries, which implied unilateral flows of invest-
posals20 with regard to adjustments as to include synergy
ments (and income), thereby turning distortions perma-
rents, as well as of the determination of transfer pricing in
nent. Given the erroneous belief that distortions would
cases concerning intangibles. In this context, the author
be balanced, the very fundamental issue of fairness on the
notes that the BEPS proposals have as an outcome an allo-
allocation of tax revenues among states was simply disre-
cation of tax revenues that significantly deviates from the
garded.
determination of transfer pricing based on what unrelated
parties would have done, as set out in the OECD Model. The report further recognized that, with regard to the allo-
This statement leads to the conclusion that the legitimacy cation of tax revenues, “it is not possible on the grounds of
of the OECD Guidelines is currently being undermined pure economic theory to indicate what proportions should
by the aggressive ambulatory interpretation presented in actually be adopted”, thereby insinuating the limitations of
the BEPS initiative in the relevant transfer pricing actions. the economic allegiance.26 Consequently, it suggested that
“the proportion presenting a true compromise for country
2. The ALS A and the rest of the world may be adopted, which is inap-
2.1. Introductory remarks propriate for the relations of country B to the rest of the
world”.27
The ALS has been said to be “the heart, spirit and the
foundation of the current international transfer pricing The reference to the Four Economists Report is important,
regime”.21 It is also a natural outcome of a system based as it clarifies that the choice of the ALS was made in a
on the separate entity approach for determining taxable context where even the grounds for a generally accepted
income, as well as on the ability-to-pay principle. Unlike allocation of taxing rights were unclear in the international
valuation methods, such as fair value, which are designed debate. This was especially so taking into account that the
to “inform readers of financial statements about the value solution proposed for the division of income among source
of booked assets and liabilities”, the ALS is used for taxa- and residence was not based on an economic reason, i.e.
tion purposes and is “intended to counter income shifting, economic allegiance, but rather on a practical solution
tax base erosion and double taxation”.22 where imbalances were foreseen and expected to be cor-
rected through a (hardly verifiable) equilibrium of invest-
2.2. The origins of the ALS ment flows among countries. Not surprisingly, in 1928, the
representatives of the various tax administrations within
The ALS has its origins in the studies of Mitchell Carroll, the ambit of the League of Nations did not reach a con-
which focused on branches, instead of subsidiaries.23 sensus on the allocation of profits of the units of an enter-
When investigating the economic allegiance between prise among countries. Indeed, there is still no interna-
origin and domicile, the Four Economists concluded tional consensus regarding the content of the ALS or on
that, ideally, all corporeal wealth, including immovables the rules or the methods that would make a transaction
and tangible movables, except for money, jewellery, fur- considered to be at arm’ s length.28
niture, etc., should be allocated predominantly or wholly
to the place of origin, whereas all intangible wealth, except Following the League of Nations Model (1928), the Com-
for mortgages, should be assigned to the domicile or resi- mittee prepared a questionnaire, the answers of which were
dence.24 They recognized that the exact allocation would further submitted to Mitchell Carroll, who wrote the well-
known Carroll Report. The choice of the separate account-
ing theory in the detriment of the FA theory is generally
19. Most recently, OECD Model Tax Convention on Income and on Capital claimed to have been made due to practical reasons, rather
(15 July 2014), Models IBFD.
20. See, for example, OECD, Addressing Base Erosion and Profit Shifting than to the convictions of its author, as separate account-
(OECD 2013), International Organizations’ Documentation IBFD and ing theory was more frequent among the countries ana-
Action Plan on Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (OECD 2013), Interna-
tional Organizations’ Documentation IBFD.
21. Brauner, supra n. 6, at p. 96.
22. J. Wittendorff, The Arm’ s-Length Principle and Fair Value: Identical Twins
or Just Close Relatives?, 62 Tax Notes Intl. 3, p. 227 (2011). E.F.S.73.F.19. 4043 (5 Apr. 1923), in 4 Legislative History of United States
23. M. Carroll, Methods of Allocating Taxable Income vol. 4, League of Nations, Tax Conventions 1962 (hereinafter: the “Four Economists Report”).
Document C.425(b).M.2176(b).1933.II.A (hereinafter: the “Carroll 25. Id.
Report”). 26. Id., at 4050.
24. Report on Double Taxation submitted to the Financial Committee by 27. Id.
Professors Bruins, Einaudi, Seligman and Sir Josiah Stamp (Document 28. Wittendorff, supra n. 22, at p. 238.

692 BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION DECEMBER 2015 © IBFD

Exported / Printed on 6 June 2016 by biblio1@ibdt.org.br.


Arm’ s Length: Beyond the Guidelines of the OECD

lysed.29 However, one cannot disregard the fact that the of the methods to these items.35 Nevertheless, the regu-
Carroll Report includes extensive critiques of FA methods. lations inspired the OECD Report on “Transfer Pricing
Indeed, Langbein (1986) even criticized Carroll for con- and Multinational Enterprises” (1979)36 and are of major
ceiving “his role to be one of developing an international importance for understanding the development of the ap-
approach which would truncate any movement of the in- plication of the ALS.37
ternational community to the development, on a general
The 1968 US Regulations did not specifically include the
scale, of working rules of fractional apportionment”.30
use of the profit split method (PSM) in determining the
Carroll reported a lack of substantive legislation and case arm’ s length price of a transaction. Rather, the use of a
law referring to the allocation of income among the 27 fourth method was allowed if “clearly more appropriate”
countries analysed. He deemed a careful study of practices considering the facts of the case.38
generally followed by tax administrations on the allocation
The PSM commonly applies when there is a high level of
of income to national or foreign sources to be necessary.
integration in the commercial operations of two or more
His report classified the following three “General Methods
controlled entities, which makes it impractical to measure
of Allocation”: (1) the separate accounting method, which
their dealings separately. The PSM may also be applied
takes “the declaration of income supported by the accounts
when the use of the three traditional methods is not pos-
of the local branch, as a basis of assessment”;31 (2) the frac-
sible due to a lack of comparables. There are numerous
tional apportionment method, as per “the determination
examples of cases in which such situations may arise.
of the income of one establishment of an enterprise” to be
Where the parties under common control are engaged in
carried out by “dividing total net income in the ratio of
global trading or global development activities or if the
certain factors – for example, assets, turnover, payroll or a
transactions relate to licences in respect of unique intangi-
fixed percentage”; and (3) other empirical methods, which
bles, the transactions could be compared with the arrange-
were frequently used when the tax administration consid-
ments that would be carried out by independent parties
ered the declaration of income according to the separate
with regard to the division of the earnings derived in the
accounting method insufficient or false.32
business. Consequently, “simulating the profit split”, which
Even though transfer pricing rules had been enacted would have been agreed by independent parties “lies at
for some time, there were no statutory benchmarks for the heart of the PSM”, in the sense that the PSM could be
determining the allocation of income, which would only regarded as a “combination of both the direct and indirect
be introduced in the 1930s. It may not be a coincidence methods of income allocation”.39 As summarized in the
that the enactment of such benchmarks in the US context OECD Guidelines, “the assumption is that independent
was carried out after the Carroll Report. Specifically, parties would have split the combined profits in propor-
the ALS was present in a 1935 US regulation on transfer tion to the value of their respective contributions to the
pricing, whereby “the standard to be applied in every case generation of profit in the transaction”.40
is that of an uncontrolled taxpayer dealing at arm’ s length
An important distinction between the PSM and the other
with another uncontrolled taxpayer”.33 Avi-Yonah (2007)
traditional transaction methods is that the former rely
reports that methods to pursue such a standard were not
on net income, while the traditional methods take gross
established until 1968. The lack of methods resulted in the
margins into account. The PSM should, therefore, not be
increasing importance of case law as a solution to trans-
confused with the formulary allocation of income. Under
fer pricing issues, but the courts were unable to provide
the PSM, only the combined operating profit or loss from
the taxpayer with certainty and coherence on the applic-
certain controlled transactions is allocated between the
ation of the ALS due to the use of multiple standards for
parties and not the earnings of the MNE as a whole. The
the determination of the taxable income.34 This was a first
PSM is also intended to mimic the allocation of profits
hint of the problems of allowing ex post adjudication as
that would be observed in a relation between indepen-
the solution to transfer pricing criteria.
dent parties if a comparable contribution to the success
The 1968 US Regulations, which applied only to associ- of the activity would occur. This statement is sufficient
ated companies and not to branches, introduced the com- to conclude that the PSM is intended to be an ALS-based
parable uncontrolled price (CUP), cost-plus and resale method.
price (RPM) methods. The 1968 Regulations set out rules
However, there are several cases in which the solution to
regarding intangibles and services, despite not includ-
transfer pricing issues can hardly be considered an ALS-
ing satisfactory guidance with regard to the application
based solution. An example noted by Avi-Yonah (2007)41 is
29. Carroll Report, supra n. 23, at p. 189, where it is stated that: “The adop-
tion of separate accounting as the primary method of allocating income 35. Brauner, supra n. 6, at p. 96.
to the various countries in which an enterprise has permanent establish- 36. OECD, Committee on Fiscal Affairs (CFA), Transfer Pricing and Multina-
ments is preferred by the great majority of Governments, and business tional Enterprises (OECD 1979).
enterprises represented in the International Chamber of Commerce, as 37. With regard to the evolution of the US transfer pricing rules, see H.D.
well as by other authoritative groups”. Rosenbloom, The U.S. Approach to Transfer Pricing: Benchmarks and Hall-
30. S. Langbein, The Unitary Method and the Myth of Arm’ s Length, 30 Tax marks, 41 Tax Notes Intl. 4, p. 341 (2006).
Notes 7, pp. 637-638 (1986). 38. US: Treas. Reg. sec. 1.482-2A(e)(1)(iii).
31. Carroll Report, supra n. 23, at p. 87. 39. C. Sommers, Separate Accounting or Unitary Apportionment? p. 71 (EUL
32. Id., at p. 46. Verlag 2011).
33. US: Treas. Reg. (1935), sec. 45-1(b). See also Hamaekers, supra n. 11. 40. OECD Guidelines, supra n. 13, at p. 94, para. 2.110.
34. Avi-Yonah, supra n. 3. 41. Avi-Yonah, supra n. 3.

© IBFD BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION DECEMBER 2015 693

Exported / Printed on 6 June 2016 by biblio1@ibdt.org.br.


Luís Eduardo Schoueri

the French Co. case (1973), which concerned a royalty con- US practice, as super-royalty and its application demands
tract signed for modest amounts for a period of 21 years. that each year taxpayers are subject to review and adjust-
By the time of the agreement, the product still had no wide ments to the royalties charged to ensure that these remain
market penetration and its high profitability was not yet “commensurate” with the income that the intangible pro-
evidenced. According to Avi-Yonah (2007), this case is evi- duces at the hands of the transferee.48 Because of the dif-
dence that the ALS should not always be invoked. Given ficulties in determining the content of this clause, the US
that the outcomes were clearly disproportionate to the Congress decided to reformulate the regulations in force
expectations of the parties when the contract was signed, since 1968 to reflect the new legal requirements. Conse-
the tax administration was forced to challenge the applic- quently, on 18 October 1998, the US Treasury Department
ation of the ALS, up to which time it had been the main published a study on this provision (the “White Paper”).49
supporter. The new position of the tax administration The White Paper initiated discussion50 that lasted until July
was not accepted.42 This reasoning was maintained until 1994, when the final regulations on intangibles were enact-
the reform of 1986. Avi-Yonah (2007) also notes U.S. Steel ed.51 The legislation was complemented in December 1995
Corp. (1980), in which the US Internal Revenue Service and May 1996 to include details on cost sharing agree-
(IRS) did not agree with the freight charge paid to a related ments.52 This standard demands that the revenues real-
enterprise, even though the value did not differ from that ized from the transfer or licence of intangible property are
charged from unrelated parties. The IRS claimed that these commensurate with the income attributable to that form
were different situations, as the quantities traded were very of intangible property item. The concept underlying this
different, as well as the conditions of the transactions, i.e. provision is essentially that the parties should distribute
guarantees, etc. Notwithstanding this, the application of profits according to, inter alia, assets used, costs incurred,
the ALS was retained, which had been strongly enforced functions performed, risks assumed and intangible assets
in the past by the IRS.43 used.53 Brauner (2008) notes the following two “benefits”
regarding commensurability: (1) recognition that the pure
In such circumstances, it is interesting to note the devel-
analysis of ALS is not always required; and (2) emphasis
opments that have occurred in the United States, as noted
on the importance of the transfer of intangible assets and
by Avi-Yonah (2007). That author demonstrates that, even
an admission that one cannot always count on compar-
though the precedents noted previously were sufficient to
able assets.54
indicate the distortions of unrestricted application of the
ALS, there was great hesitation as to the alternative cri- Curiously enough, the US Congress did not accept that
terion that should be adopted. From new cases, alterna- commensurability was incompatible with ALS. However,
tive paths arose that were no longer based strictly on com- even if a fully comparable transaction were found in which
parisons. An example of this is Cadillac Textiles (1975), the same intangible assets were transferred to an unrelated
in which, after denying comparisons proposals, ended up party in the same circumstances for a fixed rate of royal-
adding the profits of the parties involved, thereby sharing ties, it would similarly require the allocation of the super-
them in a way similar to what would later be known as the royalties in respect of a transaction between related par-
PSM.44 Given the lack of regulation of the matter at that ties.55 Avi-Yonah (2007) also notes that the White Paper
time, one must criticize the arbitrary way in which the dis- did not appear to be comfortable to leave the ALS, choos-
tribution was made. The same appraisal was also present ing to refer to the new requirements as the basic arm’ s
in other cases, for example, E.I. Dupont de Nemours & Co length return method (BALRM) and allotting a chapter
(1979)45 and Eli Lilly & Co (1988).46 Both cases resorted to to demonstrate that commensurability and the BALRM
an arbitrary method to allocate profits. were compatible with the ALS. This is difficult to follow
as, in principle, commensurability applies in the lack of
Faced with such difficult cases, the “commensurate with
comparables. In other words, there was, at best, a new def-
income” clause was, in 1986, cumulated and understood to
inition of the ALS, which would no longer be the search
mean the need to adjust the negotiated price in face of ben-
for comparable prices but rather the reconstruction of any
efits from intangibles.47 This provision became known, in
results consistent with those between independent parties.

42. See the decision of the United States Tax Court, 6 Sept. 1973, R.T. French
Co. v. Commissioner, 60 T.C. 836 (1973). 48. The following sentence was added to Section 482 of US: Internal Revenue
43. See the decision of the US Court of Appeals (CA) in US: CA, 12 Mar. 1980, Code (IRC): “in the case of any transfer (or license) of intangible property
United States Steel Corp. v. Commissioner, 617 F. 2d 942 (2d Cir. 1980). (within the meaning of section 936(h)(3)(B), the income with respect to
44. See the decision of the United States Tax Court, Cadillac Textiles v. Com- such transfer or license shall be commensurate with the income attribut-
missioner, 34 T.C.M. (CCH) 295 (1975). able of the intangible”.
45. See the decision of the United States Court of Claims, 17 Oct. 1979, 49. I.R.S. Notice 88-123, A Study of Intercompany Pricing under Section 482
E.I. Dupont de Nemours & Co v. Commissioner, 608 F. 2d 445 (Ct. CIs. of the Code, 1988-2 C.B. 458 (Section 482 White Paper), Administrative
1979). Documentation IBFD.
46. See the decision of the US Court of Appeals (CA) in US: CA, 27 Oct. 1988, 50. E. Maguire, Transfer Pricing for Intangibles. A Commentary on the White
Eli Lilly & Company and Subsidiaries v. Commissioner of Internal Revenue, Paper (F.C. de Hosson ed., Kluwer 1989) and M. Theisen et al., Verrech-
Docket Nos. 86-2911, 86-3116, Tax Treaty Case Law IBFD. nungspreise bei Lizenzen und Dienstleistungen (Beck 1990).
47. For this development in the US Law, see G.N. Carlson et al., The US Final 51. Treas. Reg. secs. 1.482-4-6.
Transfer Pricing Regulations: The More Things Change, The More They Say 52. Treas. Reg. sec. 1.482-7.
The Same, 94 Tax Notes Intl., pp. 333 to 348 (Aug. 1994). A specific and 53. A.C.R. Amaral, O preço de transferência (transfer pricing) no Mercosul –
extensive study on the subject of transfer pricing for intangible property II Jornada Tributária do Mercosul. 6 Revista dos Tribunais, Cadernos de
can be found in J.R. Mogle, Intercompany Transfer Pricing For Intangible Direito Tributário e Finanças Públicas 22, p. 221 (Jan./Mar. 1998),
Property, 6 Tax Mgt. Transfer Pricing 2. Special Report, Report No. 25 (21 54. Brauner, supra n. 6, at p. 100.
May 1997). 55. Avi-Yonah, supra n. 3, at p. 19.

694 BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION DECEMBER 2015 © IBFD

Exported / Printed on 6 June 2016 by biblio1@ibdt.org.br.


Arm’ s Length: Beyond the Guidelines of the OECD

Similarly with the PSM, under the transactional net arbitrary manner that they would hardly fit in ALS-based
margin method (TNMM), income is allocated between reasoning.
the entities by comparing the “net margin earned by the
tested affiliate in a specific transaction to net margins 2.3. The rationale of the ALS
obtained in comparable uncontrolled activities”.56 In this Although the ALS has been said62 to provide for fairness in
respect, the TNMM is similar to the cost-plus method and the distribution of tax revenues among states, its rational-
the RPM, and would generally not apply where the parties ity should be considered based on its original intent, i.e.
to the transaction under consideration make unique con- the need for equality between related and unrelated firms.
tributions. In such cases, the PSM should be applied.57 The Market prices as a tool to evaluate the adequate price of
TNMM also entails a comparison with the transactions transactions would, under this approach, contemplate the
that would be undertaken by unrelated parties. For this neutrality that should be inherent in taxation. The ALS
purpose, the net margins in open-market transactions would provide “broad parity of tax treatment for MNEs
are measured and the calculated uncontrolled margin is and independent enterprises” in granting a more “equal
subsequently applied to the operations between related footing for tax purposes”. This would avoid the creation of
parties. Consequently, the TNMM also entails some effort tax advantages that would distort the “relative competitive
to be regarded as an essentially ALS-based method. positions of either type of entity”.63
In spite of the clear deviation from the beginning of both Behind such a rationale, one can find the ability-to-pay
the TNMM and the PSM from the ALS, it is interesting to principle and, more generally, the principle of equality.
note the effort to deny such divergence. It is often consid- The latter has been defined as “the comparative relation-
ered that, for example, the PSM applies where there are ship that obtains between two or more distinct persons or
no “close comparables”. Even under such circumstances, things by virtue of their having been jointly measured by a
however, “where there is no more direct evidence of how relevant standard of comparison and found to be indistin-
independent parties in comparable circumstances would guishable by reference to that standard”.64 Taxpayers car-
have split the profit in comparable transactions”, the OECD rying out a controlled transaction have sufficient power
maintains that the PSM should apply as it is the alloca- to misprice the operation, thereby jeopardizing the taxa-
tion of profits “based on the division of functions (taking tion of income. This would lead to a situation in which
account of the assets used and risks assumed) between the the entities of an MNE were taxed less than independent
associated enterprises themselves”.58 parties would be, even if they undertook the same trans-
In these cases, the qualification of the PSM and the TNMM action. Transfer pricing legislation is intended to deal with
as ALS-based methods becomes blurred. At this point, one this situation, thereby re-establishing equality among tax-
must question how much fiction can the ALS tolerate? Is it payers by allocating income according to their ability to
possible to answer the question “how would synergy rents pay, irrespective of their power to influence the prices of
be allocated between independent parties”? The OECD controlled transactions.
Guidelines explicitly recognizes that “the separate entity In order to understand the role of equality for transfer
approach may not always account for the economies of pricing legislation, one should refer to Professor Hum-
scale and interrelation of diverse activities created by inte- berto Ávila’ s “theory of tax equality”. His theory is designed
grated businesses”.59 This sort of questioning and the cor- to offer an analytical and functional method to evaluate
responding approach of the OECD to this issue has led to tax equality. According to the Brazilian Professor, the
the statement that the ALS is “slowly but surely being rel- “structural elements” of equality are: (1) the subjects, i.e.
egated to the back seat” of the OECD Guidelines.60 sujeitos; (2) the criterion or standard of measurement, i.e.
In this context, Avi-Yonah (2007) concludes that, if the critério ou medida de comparação; (3) the proxy, i.e. ele-
premise that the ALS does not require comparison is mento indicativo da medida de comparação; and (4) the
accepted, then the ALS is a continuum also comprising scope of the distinction, i.e. finalidade da diferenciação.65
FA, as even this can lead to similar results to those obtained In other words, equality requires (1) taxpayers, or subjects,
by unrelated parties.61 This conclusion does not appear to that are (2) comparable under a specific criterion, which is
be obvious. To argue that the FA, or any arbitrary alloca- measured according to a (3) proxy chosen with (4) a spe-
tion, can achieve similar results to those that would have cific scope, which, in turn, can be the allocation of the tax
been reached by unrelated parties is to affirm a rule based burden according to distributive justice criteria, i.e. the
on eventuality. It is true on the one hand that this method ability to pay, costs for public fees, penalties for crime, or an
is based on effective data, i.e. global income, but on the external measure, for example, behaviour inducing, sim-
other hand the allocation formulae are derived in such an plification for predictability, etc.

56. Sommers, supra n. 39, at p. 73. 62. X. Ditz, Die Grenzen des Fremdvergleichs – Zugleich Plädoyer für ein
57. OECD Guidelines, supra n. 13, at p. 77, para. 2.58. Festhalten am Fremdvergleichsgrundsatz, 97 Finanzrundschau 3 (2015),
58. Id., at p. 94, para. 2.110. pp. 119-125.
59. Id., at p. 34, para. 1.10. 63. OECD Guidelines, supra n. 13, at p. 33, para. 1.7.
60. R. Robillard, BEPS: Is the OECD Now at the Gates of Global Formulary 64. P. Westen, Speaking of Equality: An Analysis of the Rhetorical Force of
Apportionment?, 43 Intertax 6-7, p. 447 (2015). “Equality”in Moral and in Legal Discourse p. 1990 (Princeton U. 1990).
61. Avi-Yonah, supra n. 3. 65. H. Ávila, Teoria da Igualdade Tributária 2nd ed., p. 42 (Malheiros 2009).

© IBFD BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION DECEMBER 2015 695

Exported / Printed on 6 June 2016 by biblio1@ibdt.org.br.


Luís Eduardo Schoueri

The criterion of measurement must be based on reality companies trading with related parties to be measured
and, more importantly, the criterion must be relevant to according to the same parameters employed to deter-
the scope it pursues.66 This is an important feature of Ávila’ s mine the income of independent parties. As the latter are
theory, i.e. the equality examination is broadly “scope-ori- taxed according to the profit derived from transactions in
ented”. The standard of measurement must implement the market conditions, transfer pricing legislation is intended
scope of the distinction. This demonstrates that the scope to convert to market those profits reflecting transactions
of the distinguishing logically precedes the determination within a group. From such a perspective, one could con-
of the standard of measurement.67 sider that there is a reason behind the choice of the ALS,
as it has been seen as an adequate key to “convert” profits
In tax law, the fair distribution of the tax burden has gen-
of related parties into market profits, thereby allowing the
erally been regarded as an area in respect of which ability
principle of equality to work.
to pay appears to be an acceptable standard of comparison
among taxpayers.68 As taxes are intended to finance the While ability to pay is the criterion and market income is
common needs of a community, all of the members are the proxy, one should keep in mind that equality also con-
expected to pay their share. No one should be exempted tains a subjective element, i.e. whose ability to pay is to be
from contributing to common expenses, but the share to compared? This is relevant to support the idea that transfer
be supported by each member should vary according to pricing legislation requires an entity approach, as opposed
the ability to pay. to a consolidated one. As a result, if it is true that the target
of transfer pricing legislation is to determine the market
As ability to pay is generally accepted to be the relevant cri-
income, i.e. the proxy, of an entity to allow the tax burden
terion, as defined in Ávila’ s theory, one can conclude that
to be adequately distributed among the members of a given
those taxpayers within a given community with a similar
community according to the criterion of measurement,
ability to pay should pay similar taxes. Equality requires,
i.e. ability to pay, it is obvious that, even before applying
however, that taxpayers may be compared, i.e. that there
any transfer pricing adjustment, one should define who is
must be conditions to compare taxpayers under a rele-
expected to be subject to taxation, i.e. who is expected to
vant criterion. Profits are regarded as an adequate proxy
be compared and taxed equally. Comparability analysis is,
to compare taxpayers’ ability to pay. This is true if com-
therefore, two-fold, i.e. (1) not only the proxy must be the
panies’ profits are calculated using the same rules. It would
same (in this case, profits earned in market conditions), (2)
be unacceptable, under the ability-to-pay principle, to
but also taxpayers must be comparable. There must be a
compare profits of two companies if these were computed
justification to select a given taxpayer and to require taxes.
in, for example, different currencies. One would immedi-
Residence and source are generally seen as elements of
ately require a conversion of one currency into the other to
connection that are sufficient to legitimize taxation. This
determine which company earned more. Transfer pricing
explains why two companies equal under the same sub-
legislation essentially deals with this. It recognizes that,
jective and objective perspectives should equally share tax
while the profit reflected in the accounts of a company
burden. However, if transfer pricing does not adopt an
may be a good proxy to determine the ability to pay of a
entity approach, but, rather, a consolidated approach, there
company acting in market conditions, the same is not nec-
is a logical fault in the comparison and the rationale for
essarily true for companies trading with related parties.
such legislation may be jeopardized. One should compare
The numbers regarding the latter do not reflect income, at
an entity acting in a country with a group of entities acting
least not the same income that would be realized in market
in different conditions. This is not a mere transfer pricing
conditions. In summary, profits, as a net result of all trans-
divergence but goes further in comparing subjects where
actions of a company, are an adequate proxy for the ability
there is no justification for equal treatment.
to pay as far for a company trading in market conditions.
In the absence of such conditions, profits, rather, reflect, Of course, one could discuss the fundamental choice of
inter alia, the bargaining power of a group entity, which taxing companies, i.e. entities, rather than groups. The
may be able to compel its related parties to trade under decision as to whether to tax legal entities is also not
imposed conditions, which may differ from market ones. obvious, and there is an interesting debate regarding the
Such bargaining power has nothing to do with the ability elimination of corporate taxation.69 However, as long as
of the entity to create income. Companies with weak bar- corporate taxation is entity based, there is no justification
gaining positions may, therefore, suffer losses that do not to require the same burden to be supported by a company
reflect their economic activities. acting within the borders of a community and a group of
companies connected to several jurisdictions and, there-
In these terms, the rationale behind the ALS is obvious.
fore, owing taxes to all of them. The element of connec-
It may be claimed to be the key for converting transac-
tion, i.e. residence, is not the same, and requiring both to
tions among related parties to transactions in market con-
be taxed under the same parameters would not comply
ditions. In other words, the very rationale of the trans-
with the principle of equality. In summary, if unrelated
fer pricing legislation is to provide for income derived by
parties acting in a community are taxed according to their

66. Id., at pp. 44-45.


67. Id., at p. 45. 69. R.S. Avi-Yonah, Corporations, Society, and the State: A Defense of the Cor-
68. B. Griziotti, Intorno al Concetto di Causa nel Diritto Finanziario, 3 Rivista porate Tax, 90 Va. L. Rev., p. 1193 (2004) and Y. Brauner, The Non-Sense
di Diritto Finanziario e Scienza delle Finanze, pp. 372-385 (1939) and Tax: A Reply to New Corporate Income Tax Advocacy, 2008, Mich. St. L.
E. Vanoni, Natura ed Interpretazione delle Leggi Tributarie (CEDAM 1932). Rev., p. 591 (2008).

696 BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION DECEMBER 2015 © IBFD

Exported / Printed on 6 June 2016 by biblio1@ibdt.org.br.


Arm’ s Length: Beyond the Guidelines of the OECD

(individual) profits earned in market conditions, derived are deemed to have been dealt with according to the ALS.
from their (individual) efforts, the ability-to-pay principle Instead of taking into account the actual amount paid or
would (solely) require the related parties to receive equal received by the parties in the controlled transaction, taxa-
treatment, i.e. have their individual market profits calcu- tion will be based “as if ” they had occurred on the prices
lated and taxed. according to the legal fiction, i.e. ALS prices.
In this sense, when adjusting profits by reference to the Transfer pricing legislation not only entails a legal fiction.
conditions that are expected to have been obtained by There is also a legal presumption, i.e. while the legal fiction
independent parties in comparable uncontrolled trans- requires related parties to be taxed as independent parties
actions, the ALS treats the members of an MNE as sepa- would have been under the same conditions, transfer
rate entities and does not consider them to be “inseparable pricing legislation also determines that there is a legal pre-
parts of a single unified business”.70 As a result, a compara- sumption that independent parties negotiate according to
bility analysis is deemed to be central to the application of methods, such as the CUP, RPM, etc. These methods are,
the ALS to treat the members of the MNE group as if they therefore, not necessarily intended to determine the prices
were independent parties. Consequently, the ALS gener- at which related parties actually trade; rather, they are a
ally entails a comparison between controlled and uncon- (legal) presumption of the prices that unrelated parties
trolled transactions in the sense that the taxation of the would trade according to the ALS.
entities of an MNE group is determined by what indepen-
When one considers tax law, in general, one can easily
dent parties would have done.
agree with Professor José Casalta Nabais, according to
The ALS enthrones transactional neutrality, which is one whom taxation is not based on the exact and rigorous
of the aspects of tax neutrality. Consequently, the ALS appreciation of reality, as accounting is itself based on
ensures that similar economic transactions are similarly several assumptions that are not evidence but are, rather,
taxed, irrespective of the form used in carrying on the agreed. The Portuguese professor refers to Einaudi’ s idea
business.71 The OECD emphasizes that “in no case should that searching for a “real” profit is a “pure myth”, which
transactional profit methods be used so as to result in over- only accountants believe in.74 Consequently, it is true that,
taxing enterprises mainly because they make profits lower as it is impossible to be precise regarding the profit of one
than the average, or in under-taxing enterprises that make company, some concessions are necessary; otherwise,
higher than average profits”. As a result, there would be “no taxes would not be determinable, and the very existence
justification under the arm’ s length principle for impos- of the state would be in danger. As a result, the profit of a
ing additional tax on enterprises that are less successful company is calculated by way of a number of accounting
than average or, conversely, for under-taxing enterprises and tax conventions, which allow one to arrive at a profit
that are more successful than average, when the reason for that is sufficiently acceptable, but which is not scientifi-
their success or lack thereof is attributable to commercial cally verifiable. There are several examples of such conven-
factors”.72 tions. Take the mere periodic calculation of profits, which
implies disregarding inter-annual results, or the depreci-
2.4. The ALS as a legal fiction: The methods as a ation of assets, calculated according to determined rates
presumption that may be verifiable, in general, but which hardly cor-
Through legal fictions, the consequences envisaged by a respond to the duration of an asset. This is sufficient to
rule in one case are extended to other cases not originally confirm that taxation is not based on facts but rather on an
intended to be covered by the rule. Instead of regulating acceptable version of facts. Lord Keynes’ s statement that
new cases and determining their respective legal conse- “[i]t is better to be roughly right than precisely wrong” cer-
quences, the legislator simply declares that new cases, i.e. tainly plays an important role in this.
fingierter Tatbestand, should be treated as previous regu- This assumption should also be taken into account when
lated ones, i.e. Fiktionsbasis.73 In tax law, legal fictions are one considers the transfer pricing methods. It is certainly
employed to permit different cases to be subject to the impossible to know how an independent party would
same taxation. react in a specific transaction. Methods are presumptions
From this perspective, one can easily understand the ALS that try to reflect what they probably would consider. One
as a legal fiction. Taking into account the fact that trans- should not expect methods to reflect reality but rather to
actions among related parties are not within the market, reflect the expected, i.e. generally acceptable, reality.
transfer pricing legislation determines that such transac- In the same way, and it is important to make this clear,
tions should be taxed in the same way as comparable inde- presumptions in tax law are always rebuttable, and trans-
pendent transactions would have been treated. In other fer pricing methods are no exception. Taxpayers must be
words, through a legal fiction, the controlled transactions granted the right of bringing evidence contrary to the pre-
sumption. However, if one considers that taxation itself
requires an acceptable version of the facts, the contradic-
70. OECD Guidelines, supra n. 13, at p. 33, para. 1.7.
71. J. Li, Global Profit Split: An Evolutionary Approach to International Income tion of a rebuttable presumption does not require the evi-
Allocation, 50 Can. Tax J., p. 828 (2002).
72. OECD Guidelines, supra n. 13, at p. 61, para. 2.7.
73. F. Bernhoft. Zur Lehre von Fiktionen. Aus romischem und burgerlichem
Recht, Festgabe fur Ernst Immanuel Bekker zum 16. August 1907 74. J. Casalta Nabais. Por um Estado Fiscal Suportável: Estudos de Direito Fiscal,
pp. 241-290 (Weimar 1907). p. 374 (Almedina 2005).

© IBFD BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION DECEMBER 2015 697

Exported / Printed on 6 June 2016 by biblio1@ibdt.org.br.


Luís Eduardo Schoueri

dence of a fact but rather convincing evidence that differ- in a different framework from the solutions to the feasi-
ent circumstances should be considered. bility issue.
Returning to the issue of transfer pricing methods, their
2.5.2. Rationale: The ALS as an inherently flawed
contradiction does not require the parties to prove that
method
independent parties would actually deal differently. It is
sufficient to argue that they would most likely determine Fundamentally, the transactional ALS approach has been
other prices. This is not scientifically verifiable evidence criticized for not reflecting economic reality. Consequently,
but rather an argument that is strong enough to build a there would be “synergy rents” arising from economies of
consensus that could be opposed to the presumption. scale and integration, which the ALS could not take into
account. As a result, it would not be possible to soundly
2.5. The objections to the ALS allocate profits in an integrated firm with bases on com-
parability and market prices. The ALS would not reflect
2.5.1. Opening comments
reality, as MNEs do not treat each subsidiary as a separate
Objections to the ALS can be classified into two different entity but rather as integrated entities, whose prices can
groups. First, there is a very important objection address- be controlled by an MNE, considering the respective tax
ing the rationale behind the ALS, which deserves sepa- implications.78 The possibility of realizing economies of
rate consideration. Most articles, both for75 and against76 integration through the internalization of activities would,
the ALS, argue that there is a conceptual flaw underly- then, be a conceptual flaw in the ALS.79
ing the ALS, which could jeopardize both the determina-
In this sense, the ALS would fail to take into consider-
tion of taxable income and the allocation of taxing rights
ation the reasons why MNEs are created.80 Based on the
among states. Such considerations relate to the very core
theory of the firm,81 the critics of the ALS convincingly
of the ALS.
argue that internalization allows integrated enterprises
Second, there are general objections to the feasibility of to carry out transactions more efficiently than indepen-
the ALS. Such arguments against the ALS do not con- dent enterprises, which must follow market prices. Under
sider its rationale, i.e. the principles underlying the ALS, this reasoning, MNEs are created “because they generate
but, instead, question the possibility of using the method returns internally above what can be obtained in market
in practice. These are generally marginal arguments, not transactions”,82 and this should be considered when setting
against the ALS per se, but, rather, concerning the methods transfer prices. MNEs would specifically choose to benefit
that have been developed to reach it. They are not con- from a certain way of structuring their business instead
cerned with whether the standard is, in principle, fair of engaging in market transactions. Therefore, trying to
or efficient but, instead, consider that, in the real world, compare transactions carried out by independent enter-
methods are neither fair nor efficient, as they simply do prises with intra-company transactions would be “attempt-
not work. ing to compare the incomparable”.83 A good example is
when one considers the costs of transaction on the signa-
Initially, it may appear that this classification is naïve, given
ture of a supply agreement. It is reasonable to imagine that
that, ultimately, a proposal that is not feasible is also flawed
independent parties would spend hours with their legal
in its rationale. In fact, it is valid objection to say, as oppo-
advisors before signing an important agreement, consid-
nents of the ALS generally do say, that the marginal argu-
ering the risks involved, i.e. non-payment, non-delivery,
ments criticizing the feasibility of the ALS exist to an extent
etc. The same risks would be quite remote in the case of
that they do raise questions regarding the very core of the
transactions within a group, requiring much less attention
ALS.
to the terms of the supply agreement.
However, the distinction is useful in demonstrating a
Such synergy returns would also not arise from transac-
pattern on the objections, according to which, as well
tions carried out but could, instead, be explained as “attri-
observed by Kane (2014), “one sometimes begins with
butes of the firm”. As the ALS takes the occurrence of
a statement of the critique that is supposed to point out
transactions as central to the comparability analysis, the
the ‘inherent flaw’ but then this blends seamlessly into a
returns arising from synergies would not be adequately
general discussion of problematic intangibles”77 and other
evaluated by a system based on transactions.84 The ALS
feasibility issues. In section 5.2., the author proposes solu-
would then demand that MNEs “report their income in
tions regarding the feasibility of the ALS, which keep the
problems marginal. Another aspect that justifies the clas-
sification is that this “inherent flaw” is addressed separately

75. M. Kane, Transfer Pricing, Integration and Synergy Intangibles: A Consensus 78. Avi-Yonah, supra n. 3, at p. 24.
Approach to the Arm’ s Length Standard, 6 World Tax J. 3 (2014), Journals 79. R.A. Musgrave & P.B. Musgrave, Public Finance in Theory and Practice p.
IBFD and Baistrocchi, supra n. 5. 394 (McGrawHill 1973).
76. R. Vann, Reflections on Business Profits and the Arm’ s-Length Principle, 80. Vann, supra n. 76, at p. 139.
in The Taxation of Business Profits Under Tax Treaties (B.J. Arnold, J. Sas- 81. R. Coase, The Nature of the Firm, 4 Economica 16 (1937) and O.E. Wil-
seville & E.M. Zolt eds., Can. Tax Fund 2003) and R.S. Avi-Yonah & liamson, Markets and Hierarchies:Analysis and Antitrust Implications (Free
I. Benshalom, Formulary Apportionment – Myths And Prospects: Promoting Press 1975).
Better International Tax Policies by Utilizing the Misunderstood and Under- 82. Vann, supra n. 76, at p. 140.
Theorized Formulary Alternative, 3 World Tax J. 3 (2011), Journals IBFD. 83. Brauner, supra n. 6, at p. 108.
77. Kane, supra n. 75, at sec. 2.5. 84. Vann, supra n. 76, at p. 140.

698 BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION DECEMBER 2015 © IBFD

Exported / Printed on 6 June 2016 by biblio1@ibdt.org.br.


Arm’ s Length: Beyond the Guidelines of the OECD

a way that breaks down the cost saving associated with outside the enterprise should be driven purely by business
being a MNE”.85 reasons. In this sense, “if there is a change in the business
model, the tax reaction should try to adjust to the charac-
This inherent flaw would give rise to a problem of alloca-
teristics of this change”.89
tion of the income. In transactions between parties under
common control, there would be profits that could not be However, if synergy rents exist, the ALS is insufficient to
subject to allocation, either to the seller or to the buyer, arrive at tax neutrality in the make or buy decision, as the
as these profits could only be considered to be an imme- market price is distinct from the ALS price.90 As a result,
diate consequence of the organizational form chosen by the fact that the ALS method does not take into account
the enterprise. Consequently, such profits are not attribut- the existing synergy in an economic group is deemed by
able to any of the parties to the transactions but are rather some to be a necessary outcome of the method, in the sense
directly related to the synergy of the group. As Langbein that the ALS would be “inherently flawed”. The OECD’ s
(1986) argues, the application of ALS-based methods may response to this criticism is that there would be “no widely
result in a situation in which these “residual profits” are accepted objective criteria for allocating the economies
not allocated to any of the states, as the ALS would con- of scale or benefits of integration between associated
ceptually fail to determine the jurisdiction to which these enterprises”.91 Precisely because there is no clear measure
residual profits should be allocated.86 for the allocation of the benefits arising from integration,
the simplistic approach of the OECD, i.e. to allocate the
The residual profit problem clearly occurs when differ-
residual profit solely considering the behaviour of inde-
ent ALS-based methods are applied to each of the associ-
pendent parties, appears to be “naïve” to Schön (2010).92
ated enterprises. Schön (2010) describes the residual profit
problem as an issue of adjusting the price of a transaction According to the classification proposed, this would be
between the parent and the affiliated company in consid- the sole criticism of the rationale of the ALS, i.e. the ALS
ering the “slicing of the joint profit exceeding the risk-free fails to consider the fundamental economic reason why
rate of return on the sunken investment”.87 MNEs are created and, therefore, residual profits are not
adequately allocated. The other criticisms, as are addressed
As summarized by Wittendorff (2011),88 where the con-
in section 2.5.3., are criticisms as to the application of the
trolled transaction is evaluated under a single method, the
standard, i.e. they do not address its rationale but rather
allocation of the income varies according to the method
the feasibility of reaching it.
applied, i.e.: (1) the application of a one-sided method
would result in the allocation of benefits to the enterprise
2.5.3. Feasibility: Difficulties in the application of the
that is not being tested, which would usually engender the
ALS
allocation to “the enterprise that makes the most signifi-
cant contribution of intangibles to the controlled trans- It is a fact that the current ALS-based system is “absurdly
action”; (2) the use of the profit-split method would often complex”,93 as it burdens both taxpayers and tax authorities
result in the allocation in proportion to the contribution with compliance and enforcement costs. The “principal
of intangibles to the transaction under analysis; and (3) the weakness” of the ALS is “its inability to control tax-moti-
application of the CUP method would result in the allo- vated transfer pricing with respect to intra-MNE shift-
cation of the synergy rents in proportion to “the benefits ing of income from intangibles”. The ALS is also based
actually realized by the associated enterprises”. Such con- on a supposed “fallacy” according to which “transactions
clusions are clearly very generic and may be challenged on among unrelated parties can be found and that they can
a case-by-case analysis. However, it is true that, if only one be used as meaningful benchmarks for tax compliance and
country applies a method, there is no lack of profit allo- enforcement”.94
cation, as the “remaining” residual profit is taxed by the The failure of the ALS is also evidenced by the increas-
other country. Such an allocation, however, has nothing ing use of profit split methods by tax authorities when no
to do with the effective participation of the parties in the market comparables are found.95 Under such methods,
transaction and offers no explanation as to why the “other tax authorities would not try to figure out how unrelated
country” should be able to tax all of the residual profit, parties would have priced the transaction; rather, they
irrespective of the fact that synergy derives, by definition, would aggregate the income generated from the trans-
from the common effort of the parties. action and split it among the subsidiaries.
Transfer pricing adjustments based on the ALS are intended Another criticism commonly made is that the content
to promote equal treatment among taxpayers, regardless of the ALS is unknown due to the lack of valuable case
of the business framework they design to carry out their law, thereby giving rise to undesirable litigation.96 The
activities, whether through dependent or independent absence of useful precedents can be partially attributed
business. The ideology supporting this is that there would
be no justification for any tax treatment affecting the make
or buy alternative. The decision whether to acquire in or 89. Schön, supra n. 8, at sec. 4.7.4.
90. Wittendorff, supra n. 22, at p. 240.
91. OECD Guidelines, supra n. 13, at p. 34, para. 1.10.
92. Schön, supra n. 8, at sec. 4.7.5.2.
85. Avi-Yonah & Benshalom, supra n. 76, at sec. 379. 93. Avi-Yonah & I. Benshalom, supra n. 76, at sec. 2.2.
86. S. Langbein, supra n. 30, at p. 625 (1986). 94. Id.
87. Schön, supra n. 8, at sec. 4.7.5.2. 95. Id., at sec. 4.1.
88. Wittendorff, supra n. 22, at pp. 239-40. 96. Baistrocchi, supra n. 5

© IBFD BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION DECEMBER 2015 699

Exported / Printed on 6 June 2016 by biblio1@ibdt.org.br.


Luís Eduardo Schoueri

to the emergence of confidential advance pricing agree- In the previous example, the inefficient company employs
ments (APAs),97 but, in essence, it could be considered to several workers and a positive share of the total income
be a natural outcome of the very nature of comparability of the group is allocated to the potentially loss-generat-
analysis.98 Decisions based on comparability are often too ing subsidiary. It is evident that such an outcome, in addi-
specific to allow a considerable degree of legal certainty for tion to evidencing a distortion of the allocation of income,
the taxpayer on future decisions or, as stated by Baistroc- jeopardizes the very concept of what is income102 and its
chi (2006), such decisions are “unable to produce case law role as a parameter for the application of the principle of
with public good features”.99 equality. Even if it is evident that the subsidiary has not
profited from its activities, a portion of the taxation of
The OECD Guidelines, despite recognizing the difficul-
profits should be allocated to the state in which the subsid-
ties in the application of the ALS, consider that the expe-
iary is located. The ability-to-pay principle is simply disre-
rience arising from its application “has become sufficiently
garded due to the lack of comparison between taxpayers.
broad and sophisticated to establish a substantial body of
common understanding among the business community A relevant problem with this option, from an interna-
and tax administration”. Such experience “should be drawn tional perspective, is that it directly affects the territorial
on to elaborate the arm’ s length principle further, to refine allocation of profits. Mitchell Carroll stated that “[t]he
its operation and to improve its administration by pro- reasons for arguing that this formula is arbitrary are fairly
viding clearer guidance to taxpayers and more timely obvious”.103 The apportionment of the total net income of
examinations”.100 an enterprise carrying on worldwide operations means
that its profits and losses are pooled and then distributed
3. Alternative Proposals fairly evenly, by the use of arbitrary factors, to the various
3.1. FA countries in which it operates, and not to the actual sources
of the income.104
FA, also referred to as a unitary approach, recognizes an
MNE group as a single economic entity, thereby allocat- Some approaches supporting formula-based mechanisms
ing portions of the profit of the group to each related party, instead of the ALS are characterized by a strong scepticism.
with basis on a formula intended to reflect the economic These authors do not argue that FA is not arbitrary. They
contributions of each party for the generation of the profit merely sustain that “formulary alternatives are as arbitrary
of the group. Critics of the ALS argue that FA would be as the ALS”, thereby expressly recognizing that FA “cannot
a better method to counter aggressive transfer pricing.101 penetrate the MNE profit-generating process”.105

The justification of the FA takes as its premise the alleged Such a statement demonstrates that the argument based
“inherent flaw” in the ALS (see section 2.5.3.). In con- on the “inherent flaw” of the ALS is insincere. The spon-
trast to the ALS, FA takes into account the option of the sors of the formula-based solutions take ability to pay as
enterprise to internalize the value chain. Consequently, a secondary, considering it irrelevant or impossible to deter-
common feature of FA methods is that they imply disre- mine the actual income derived by the taxpayer. The idea
garding intra-group transactions. This choice distorts the of comparing taxpayers within a community as a basis for
relationship between companies in a group context, giving sharing the tax burden is disregarded. Practicability argu-
rise to important economic consequences. ments, or better, revenue interests, appear to be the sole
justification for the employment of FA. This scepticism
Under FA, for example, a subsidiary that provides services gives rise to “hybrid solutions”, whereby the ALS should
for the group as a whole in an extremely inefficient struc- continue to apply where comparables are easily found and
ture and, therefore, bears unnecessary labour costs, could formula-based solutions are proposed for the remaining
be deemed to generate profits, even though the activities cases.
carried out are evidently unprofitable. Under the ALS,
the group remunerates the services provided on a market 3.2. Hybrid solutions
basis. If the subsidiary cannot provide the service with the
According to authors who defend the so-called “hybrid
same efficiency as a competitor would in the same circum-
solutions”, the ALS and FA should not be viewed as binary
stances, its profit margin reduces or the company may even
and mutually exclusive alternatives.106 Hybrid solutions,
realize losses, thereby imitating, for tax purposes, what
which consider the strengths and weaknesses of each
would happen in an independent context.
method, have been debated over the last decade. Conse-
However, while adopting a formula-based approach, effi- quently, a “recurrent element” of the debate is “the attempt
ciency within the subsidiaries of the group is irrelevant.

97. D.M. Ring, On The Frontier of Procedural Innovation: Advance Pricing 102. Carroll Report, supra n. 23, at p. 198. This problem was already reported
Agreements and the Struggle to Allocate Income for Cross Border Taxation, by Carroll, who, while criticizing the adoption of formulary apportion-
21 Mich. J. Intl. L. p. 143 (2000). ment in respect of joint net profits, stated that “owing to faulty operating
98. R.S. Avi-Yonah, Analysis of Judicial Decisions Interpreting Section 482, in methods or to economic circumstances, a loss might actually be realised
Transfer Pricing: Judicial Strategy and Outcomes, Tax Management: Foreign in one country, yet it would automatically receive a part of the profit
Income Portfolios, Vol. 888 (D.I. Meyer, A.D. Webber & R S. Avi-Yonah realised in the other country”.
eds., Tax Mgt. Inc. 2003). 103. Id.
99. Baistrocchi, supra n. 5, at p. 951. 104. Id., at p. 189.
100. OECD Guidelines, supra n. 13, at p. 36, para. 1.15. 105. Avi-Yonah & Benshalom, supra n. 76, at sec. 4.1.
101. Fleming Jr., Peroni & Shay, supra n. 7, at p. 4, fn. 7. 106. Id.

700 BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION DECEMBER 2015 © IBFD

Exported / Printed on 6 June 2016 by biblio1@ibdt.org.br.


Arm’ s Length: Beyond the Guidelines of the OECD

to find pragmatic solutions in between these opposing The fundamental critique that can be addressed to the pro-
concepts”.107 posals of Fleming Jr., Peroni and Shay (2014) is the same
that can be generally applied to any and every “real uni-
The OECD, despite the increasing use of profit-split and
versal taxation system”. Specifically, it takes capital export
other methods that are deemed to be “quasi-formulary”108
neutrality (CEN) as the paradigm to be pursued in in-
by opponents of the ALS, does not recognize such a trend.
ternational taxation, thereby ignoring the differences in
In fact, in expressly referring to the fact that FA “would not
infrastructure and provision of public services that exist
be acceptable in theory, implementation, or practice”, the
between states. In their understanding, “worldwide, non-
OECD contends that “no legitimate or realistic alterna-
deferred taxation is the least distortive in regard to the ques-
tive to the arm’ s length principle has emerged”.109 An ALS
tion of where to locate business investment and activity”.115
allocation should be used whenever there is a “clear, easily
Consequently, states that adopt worldwide taxation argue
observable, and consistently priced market benchmark”.
that investors should be subject to the same taxation in
respect of their inbound and outbound investments. This
3.3. The “real universal taxation system”
would avoid a distortion in their decision, and the most
Fleming Jr., Peroni and Shay (2014) contend that MNEs efficient allocation of resources would be realized.
should be taxed on their worldwide income, considering
not only the parent company but also its subsidiaries, pro- There is no international consensus regarding this per-
vided the parent company is owned by US residents.110 The spective. On the contrary, it appears to be obvious that
income of the parent company and the subsidiaries should CEN does not work efficiently. Should the tax credit mech-
be “consolidated and subjected to a current, non-deferred anism work according to its objectives, i.e. to neutralize the
U.S. income tax with a foreign tax credit system having tax burden, this would not imply neutrality in investors’
robust limits that seriously constrain cross-crediting”.111 decisions. On the contrary, the equalization of tax rates
These authors argue that, in such a scenario, the transfer is a mechanism to convince investors not to invest in less
pricing strategy of the MNEs would be far less significant, developed countries.
as the income shifting would not imply circumventing US Klaus Vogel’ s contribution to this debate is precise. One
taxation. can easily assume that there is some relationship between
This proposal is very comprehensive and well structured. tax rates and services provided by states. Although some
It takes into consideration ownership and residency issues, jurisdictions impose high taxes and do not offer their tax-
includes solutions addressing runaway corporations and payers a corresponding level of services, due to a state’ s
is, in fact, well designed to pursue the policy objectives deficiencies, it is true that a state cannot offer good ser-
contended by the authors. It is not within the scope of this vices if taxation is too low. One can generally say that, if
article to describe the details of the proposal, but there the jurisdiction charges lower taxes, taxpayers must be pre-
are some policy considerations underlying the system that pared to supplement some services that could otherwise be
should be addressed. offered by the state. If one considers this perspective in a
relationship between developed and developing states, one
According to the authors, the “real universal taxation can consider that developed states usually impose higher
system” would be preferable compared to FA, as it would taxes, but their taxpayers have a stronger state. Developing
address the problems of income shifting present in the states may have lower taxes, but one easily notes some defi-
ALS, without the distortive and manipulative effects that ciencies, including those relating to infrastructure. In such
are inherent to FA.112 In this sense, these authors consider a scenario, neutralizing the tax burden requires taxpayers
that the ALS is too permissive with regard to aggressive to pay taxes on the same level, independent of whether
transfer pricing strategies, but they also reject the alloca- they invest in their residence state or abroad. This is not
tion of income arising from FA alternatives. neutrality. Given the same level of taxes, investors prefer to
These authors also argue that their proposal would be invest in an environment in which the infrastructure cor-
“the only approach to international income taxation that responds to the level of taxes paid. It does not make sense
is consistent with the fundamental principle of ability to to invest in a jurisdiction that offers poorer infrastructure,
pay that underlies the choice of income as the primary base as an investor must pay for services that would otherwise
for taxation of U.S. residents”.113 In their comprehension of be offered by the state. In other words, when a developed
the issue, both the ALS and FA fail to take the ability to pay state adopts CEN, it invites its taxpayers to invest locally, or
into consideration, as both do not compute the full income in another developed state. Investors only invest in devel-
of the US resident.114 oping states if the remuneration is high enough to make
such an investment attractive in spite of the gap between
the developed state’ s tax level and the developing state’ s
infrastructure. One should not, therefore, be surprised if
one would note a relevant spread between interests paid
107. Schön, supra n. 8, at sec. 4.7.2.4. by developed states with regard to developing states. Vogel
108. Avi-Yonah & Benshalom, supra n. 76, at sec. 4.3.
109. OECD Guidelines, supra n. 13, at p. 36, para. 1.15. (1990) goes further in taking this to an inter-state rela-
110. Fleming Jr., Peroni & Shay, supra n. 7.
111. Id., at p. 19.
112. Id., at p. 53.
113. Id., at p. 19.
114. Id., at p. 20. 115. Id., at p. 19.

© IBFD BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION DECEMBER 2015 701

Exported / Printed on 6 June 2016 by biblio1@ibdt.org.br.


Luís Eduardo Schoueri

tionship.116 CEN is then even more unacceptable, as it to collect tax revenues and also engender the taxation of
implies keeping relevant resources in developed states, profits that would not be taxable, at least by the same state,
while developing states need such means for their devel- under the current regime.
opment. Residence states can also tax the income of their
According to Vann (2003), the conflict between the ALS
resident taxpayers on consumption, but source states can
and FA is a contest as to whether consolidation or sepa-
only tax the income upon payment.
rate-entity concepts should govern.121 Vann (2003) essen-
In addition, the “real universal taxation system” is spe- tially advocates that transfer pricing should evolve from
cifically intended as a reform to the US international a transactional to a “whole of the enterprise approach”.122
tax system. In these authors’ understanding, the United As a result, the fact that consolidation systems are increas-
States currently has a “de facto, poorly designed, and elec- ingly being upheld by domestic legislations would be a
tive quasi-territorial system”, which encourages US-based strong argument in favour of the adoption of FA in trans-
MNEs to locate their businesses in low-tax foreign coun- fer pricing legislation.123
tries.117 Consequently, under its current system, the United
When one advocates the adoption of FA as opposed to
States chooses to “encourage and reward the creation of
the ALS, it is clear that the rationale behind the transfer
low- and zero-taxed foreign source income through
pricing legislation has been put aside. Consequently, as
aggressive transfer pricing”.118
noted in section 2., the ALS is a tool designed to determine
The authors, therefore, adopt premises that could only be the market profit of an entity. FA has nothing to do with
valid in the context of the US tax system. For instance, this. It is not a reliable tool to compare taxpayers within
in addressing a reform to the tax residence rule, which is a community. In other words, there is a subjective diver-
an important part of the proposal, the authors suggest a gence between FA, which is based on consolidated profits,
model based on shareholding instead of place of effec- and profits of local independent taxpayers. FA is also not
tive management. The shareholding-based residency intended to determine the income derived by the entity
rules, however, would only be effective in a “post-FATCA but to split the profits earned by the whole group. While
[Foreign Account Tax Compliance Act] world”,119 where the ALS is designed to determine the market profit, i.e. a
it would be possible for publicly traded corporations to proxy, of an entity, i.e. the subject, to determine its ability
know whether they are controlled by US residents. In to pay, i.e. the criterion of measurement, FA simply disre-
the absence of such knowledge, it is evident that the tax gards this and searches for a different criterion with regard
authorities would lack the necessary means to apply share- to the taxation.
holding-based residency rule.
This demonstrates that it is methodologically incorrect to
This is a limitation of the proposal, which is coherent with compare the ALS with FA. The ALS is a tool to determine
one of its basic premises. The authors consider that a mul- market income. It is a proxy to reach ability to pay that,
tilateral agreement regarding the FA approach would not finally, is a criterion to share the tax burden among tax-
be practical, deeming unilateral action by the United States payers. FA, on the other hand, is a criterion to determine
to be the most viable solution.120 the “fair” amount that an MNE should contribute to each
community where the group is present. This reveals that a
One should note that the proposal would engender a cred-
comparison may be made between ability to pay and FA,
iting issue, unless taxes paid abroad could be credited
both as different criteria for taxation, but never between
against US tax irrespective of whether they relate to foreign
the ALS and FA, as these are logically different categories.
or US income. Accordingly, under the present system, only
taxes on foreign income would be offset against US taxes. This framework is also relevant in demonstrating how FA
Should this rule be maintained, the entire transfer pricing is inferior to the ALS in terms of fairness and of allocation
issue would revive to determine whether there is foreign- of the tax burden among taxpayers, i.e. Lastenausteilungs-
source income. funktion, thereby returning the transfer pricing debate to
the discussion of its original intent.
4. What the Transfer Pricing Debate Has Become
Under the principle of equality, it is insufficient that the
The transfer pricing debate has become the battleground law is applied identically to any and every taxpayer. It is
for broader reforms of the international tax regime. The also mandatory that the law itself does not include an arbi-
opponents of the ALS have suggested approaches that are trary distinction. In this sense, it may be argued that the
more focused on shifting taxing powers than on solving FA is methodologically flawed, as it selects an illegitimate
real feasibility issues of transfer pricing. The alterna- proxy in determining the taxable income in an operation.
tives described imply an increasing capacity of the state If the function of transfer pricing rules is to determine
market income to allocate the tax burden among taxpayers
according to their ability to pay, any standard of measure-
116. K. Vogel, World-wide vs. Source Taxation of Income – A Review and Reeval-
uation of Arguments, in Influence of tax differentials on international com- ment that does not relate to the ability to pay is arbitrary.
petitiveness: Proceedings of the VIIIth Munich Symposium on International Payroll or local of sales are not proxies that ultimately result
Taxation pp. 117-166 (Kluwer L. & Taxn. Pub. 1990).
117. Fleming Jr., Peroni & Shay, supra n. 7, at p. 10; See also J.C. Fleming Jr.,
R.J. Peroni & S. Shay, Worse than Exemption, 59 Emory L. J., p. 79 (2009).
118. Fleming Jr., Peroni & Shay, supra n. 7, at p. 11. 121. Vann, supra n. 76, at p. 134.
119. Id., at p. 33. 122. Id., at p. 135.
120. Id., at p. 9. 123. Id.

702 BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION DECEMBER 2015 © IBFD

Exported / Printed on 6 June 2016 by biblio1@ibdt.org.br.


Arm’ s Length: Beyond the Guidelines of the OECD

in a conclusion with regard to market income. From this ternational scenario. From this perspective, the fairness
perspective, FA harms equality by imposing the tax burden of the method would be derived from the proceeding that
on entities that have not derived any market income and, resulted in its implementation. In other words, the method
at the same time, relieving from taxation entities that have would be fair because it has been voluntarily accepted by
earned profits. the contracting states. The principle of equality, which
is the basis for transfer pricing adjustments, would be
In other words, FA disregards the function of transfer
simply disregarded. On the other hand, as one may not
pricing rules. The immediate function of transfer pricing
take for granted that an identical solution with regard to
rules is not to allocate income among states. The alloca-
the formula would be achieved in every single tax treaty,
tion of income among states is one outcome of the applic-
the risk of double taxation would still be present.
ation of transfer pricing rules. But transfer pricing rules
should be designed to determine the taxpayer’ s taxable, In the same sense, it may be considered that the “real uni-
i.e. market, income according to its ability to pay, which versal taxation system” is a contest of whether CEN should
includes countering the tax avoidance inevitably enabled be the paradigm of international taxation or if the states
by the structure of MNEs. should remain free to decide how to tax the operations of
the MNEs based in their territories. One should recognize
It could be argued that FA does not disregard the ability
that such a system, in contrast to FA, is intended to deter-
to pay. As this argument goes, the taxpayer taken into
mine the income of the parent company and can, there-
account in an FA-based transfer pricing legislation would
fore, be compared with the ALS. It is obvious, however,
be the MNE as a whole, and the formulae would merely
that, while the ALS is a standard that intended to deter-
allocate parts of the calculated income among states, fol-
mine the profit of an entity irrespective of its position as
lowing supposed economic allegiance criteria. Under this
a controlling or an affiliated company, the “real univer-
perspective, the “subject” would be the MNE and not the
sal taxation system” has a much reduced application, as
separate entity.
it only works for some companies within a group. This
However, this argument implies even bigger problems as, is already an explanation for why the ALS should be pre-
in essence, it includes claims under which: (1) there is an ferred. In addition, while the ALS is intended to determine
ultimate unquestionable profit of the MNE, which could the (market) profit of the entity, the “real universal taxa-
be determined by consensus with regard to the consid- tion” system comprehends the profits of several companies
eration regarding revenues and expenses; (2) this profit of a group altogether.
should be considered in the allocation of income among
Further, the “real universal taxation system” is based on
states; and (3) this profit should be allocated by reference
CEN. As already argued in section 3.3., there is no con-
to elements that bear no relation with the profitability of
sensus as to the choice of CEN. Klaus Vogel’ s perspective
the MNE.
of the question should not be disregarded, especially given
Alternatively, still under the theory of equality addressed the present world, where more and more countries tend
in section 2.3., one could argue that the subjects as per an to adopt a territorial system under which dividends from
FA method would actually be the states themselves. They foreign active investments tend to be exempted.
would be compared within the scope of distributing the
Finally, the taxation of intangibles would remain as an issue
fair share of income among them, without taking the tax-
both under FA and the “real universal taxation system”. In
payer into consideration. In other words, this construc-
the latter case, “income would still have to be character-
tion would consider that the FA does not aim at a distri-
ized as foreign-source or domestic-source for purposes of
bution of the tax burden among taxpayers, but focuses on
the U.S. foreign tax credit limitation”.124
the distribution of income among states. However, even
if one accepts such premises, it is not clear which is the These proposals have a common background, i.e. they
criterion of measurement and how the proxy, i.e. the for- imply starting over again, giving away a half-century of
mulae adopted, would be aimed at the scope pursued. The experience on the application of transfer pricing rules. On
elements used in the commonly suggested formulae are determining the factors for FA, it has already been recog-
rather arbitrary and, thus, unable to grant justice in the nized that there is no “magic set of factors” and deciding on
distribution of income among states. Therefore, besides them would be “a complicated process of trial and error”.125
adopting a questionable scope, i.e. equality among nations In other words, if there are problems with the ALS, many
instead of equality among taxpayers, the FA also fails to other problems would also be evident in FA and the “real
provide adequate criteria and proxies for the fair distribu- universal taxation system”.
tion of income among states.
FA would require that parties could estimate the group’ s
The FA, being essentially an unprincipled, consensus- global profits, i.e. what would demand a level of coopera-
based solution, creates the perfect scenario for the preva- tion among jurisdictions and would also demand a con-
lence of “la raison du plus fort”. It must be emphasized that sensus on their distribution. However, as Ditz (2015) cor-
authors supporting the FA rely on the justice of a negoti- rectly notes, a similar problem has appeared on a much
ated solution to transfer pricing. A negotiated solution, smaller scale, i.e. within the 28 EU Member States, and
with no principle-based ground for the taxation of MNEs,
as is the case with FA, would merely shift tax revenues to
states that have a superior bargaining position in the in- 124. Fleming Jr., Peroni & Shay, supra n. 7, at p. 54.
125. Avi-Yonah & Benshalom, supra n. 76, at sec. 4.4.

© IBFD BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION DECEMBER 2015 703

Exported / Printed on 6 June 2016 by biblio1@ibdt.org.br.


Luís Eduardo Schoueri

no consensus appears to have been reached regarding the to multiple comparable data or from applying different
Common Consolidated Corporate Tax Base (CCCTB) transfer pricing methods”.127 The affirmation of an “arm’ s
and the key of distribution. As FA would depend on con- length range” instead of a single and undisputable arm’ s
sensus among much more diversified jurisdictions, its fea- length price implies the acknowledgment of a gradual dis-
sibility does not appear to be great.126 cretion within the application of the ALS. As, however,
the equal treatment of taxpayers derives from equality,
Hybrid solutions are, finally, apparently characterized
there is a need not only for formal consistency, but also
by a very strong scepticism. At first glance, the authors
material congruence, as in any and every examination of
who contend such an approach are not concerned with
equality.128 As noted in section 2.4., the ALS entails a legal
the justice on the allocation of income among taxpayers
fiction, i.e. related parties should be taxed as if they had
or states, as long as income is somehow taxed. However,
traded according to the ALS, and a legal presumption, i.e.
as FA is essentially a negotiated solution with no further
the methods are designed to determine how independent
principle-based grounds, it may be concluded that these
parties would have traded at arm’ s length.
authors take for granted the fairness of such a negotiation.
Legal presumptions, on the other hand, should not be arbi-
This article, as it essentially provides additional consider-
trary. There must be a reasonable relationship between
ations on the application of the current ALS-based rules,
legal presumptions and an acceptable reality. In the case
is intended to build on previous experience. The mere fact
of the ALS, methods should not be arbitrary. They should
that more than 4,000 tax treaties are presently in force that
be reliable enough to ascertain that the prices arrived at
adopt the ALS appears to be an argument strong enough
among the parties trading according to the ALS would
to support this initiative, especially taking into account the
probably be the values determined according to the
fact that the other alternatives are unlikely to be more effi-
methods adopted.
cient or fair, and would also not be in accordance with the
tax treaties in force. This perspective, however, should not In this sense, the cost-plus and RP methods, as devel-
be viewed as a conformist solution but rather as an expres- oped in transfer pricing legislation, are very similar to the
sion of belief in the justice underlying the ALS. pricing methods that Kotler and Armstrong (1999) refer
to as cost-plus pricing,129 whereby an entity fixes prices
5. Back to the Original Intent: Beyond the OECD given the profit margin to be realized. Another pricing
Guidelines method that resembles these methods is breakeven pricing
5.1. Transfer pricing as a matter of equality: Back to the or target profit pricing.130 On the other hand, the CUP
original intent method is very similar to the competition-based pricing,
under which an entity considers its competitors before
The analysis in sections 3., 4. and 5. appears to be suffi- fixing its own prices.131
cient to support the adoption of the ALS. In contrast to
the other solutions proposed in the literature, the ALS is As noted in section 2.4., tax law only admits rebuttable pre-
intended to determine the profits of (single) entities and, sumptions so as to avoid taxation where the facts clearly
therefore, retains profits as the preferred proxy in apply- do not correspond to the tax rules. Rebuttable presump-
ing ability to pay as a criterion of measurement to distrib- tions require that evidences do not require exaggerated
ute the tax burden among taxpayers within a community. costs, otherwise it may be impossible to prove that the facts
In summary, if ability to pay is justified as a criterion, the that transpired were different. Roman Law developed the
ALS is an adequate tool for its application. In addition, concept of probatio diabolica to refer to cases where the
basing such decisions on the ALS is clearly preferable from production of evidences was excessively high, thereby, in
a practical perspective, given that most of the tax treaties practice, denying the rebuttable character of a presump-
concluded to date adopt the ALS as the way of making tion. Taxation is not based on facts, but on an acceptable
transfer pricing adjustments. version of facts. This is an important consideration when
one discusses the costs of the production of evidences, i.e.
Opting for the ALS does not mean that the limitations documentation, with regard to transfer pricing matters
considered in sections 3., 4. and 5. should be disregarded.
However, as the ALS is not an objective in itself but rather
a mere tool to determine the income of an entity trading 127. OECD Guidelines, supra n. 13, at p. 23.
128. Ávila, supra n. 65, at p. 63.
with related parties, some of the issues raised by the use 129. P. Kotler & G. Armstrong, Principles of Marketing p. 314 (Prentice Hall
of the ALS can be resolved, provided that the final objec- 1999), who state that: “[t]he simplest pricing method is cost-plus pricing
tive, i.e. fairness in the distribution of the tax burden, is – adding a standard markup to the cost of the product. Construction
companies, for example, submit job bids by estimating the total project
not jeopardized. the total project cost and adding a standard markup for profit. Lawyers,
accountants, and other professionals typically price by adding a standard
The Glossary of the OECD Guidelines defines “arm’ s markup to their costs. Some sellers tell their customers they will charge
length range” to be “[a] range of figures that are accept- cost plus a specified markup; for example, aerospace companies price this
able for establishing whether the conditions of a con- way to the government.”
130. Id., at p. 313, where it is stated that “[a]nother cost-oriented pricing
trolled transaction are arm’ s length and that are derived approach is breakeven pricing, or a variation called target profit pricing.
either from applying the same transfer pricing method The firm tries to determine the price at which it will break even or make
the target profit it is seeking.” (Emphasis added)
131. Id., at p. 318, where it is stated that “[c]onsumers will base their judge-
ment of a product’ s value on the prices that competitors charge for similar
126. Ditz, supra n. 62, at p. 119. products”.

704 BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION DECEMBER 2015 © IBFD

Exported / Printed on 6 June 2016 by biblio1@ibdt.org.br.


Arm’ s Length: Beyond the Guidelines of the OECD

and the need for simplified alternatives. Evidences to rebut sizes the importance of not losing “sight of the objective
a presumption cannot prove a fact, i.e. it is impossible to to find a reasonable estimate of an arm’ s length outcome
know what independent parties would actually do, but based on reliable information”, in deeming that “transfer
should, rather, present a reasonable version of the fact, i.e. pricing is not an exact science but does require the exer-
what third parties would reasonably do. cise of judgment on the part of both the tax administra-
tion and taxpayer”.137
5.2. Standardization as an alternative to feasibility
Such statements regarding the obtaining of informa-
problems
tion lead to the question as to how the burden to provide
5.2.1. Opening comments this information is allocated between taxpayers and tax
Simplicity and administrative efficiency are universally administrations. The OECD Guidelines note that the
accepted as policy objectives. This ideal dates back to OECD member countries disagree as to whether article
Adam Smith, who asserted that the collection of taxes 9 of the OECD Model entails rules regarding the burden
should involve the lowest cost possible to the taxpayer.132 of proof.138 In any case, the OECD states that “to achieve
Such a concern is still prevalent among economists, who the balance between the interests of taxpayers and tax
emphasize transparency as a characteristic of an optimal administrators in a way that is fair to all parties”, it is nec-
tax system.133 Certainty and simplicity were also included essary “to consider all aspects of the system that are rel-
in the “Ottawa Taxation Framework Conditions”, which evant in a transfer pricing case”.139 However, even when
is intended to be endorsed by all tax administrations in the tax administration bears the burden of proof and the
OECD member countries.134 Nevertheless, simplicity typi- taxpayer has no “legal obligation to prove the correctness
cally demands that equity and neutrality are put into per- of its transfer pricing”, the OECD Guidelines affirm that
spective. This is often raised as an argument by tax admin- “of course, the tax administration might still reasonably
istrations to reject measures that relieve taxpayers from oblige the taxpayer to produce its records” to enable the
compliance costs. When the matter is tax collection, tax tax administration to undertake the examination result-
administrations tend to have a high tolerance to complex- ing in the prima facie demonstration that the pricing of
ity, apparently ignoring the fact that equality and neutrality the taxpayer is incorrect.140 In a statement that sounds
are inevitably sacrificed when a system is too complex, as almost threatening, the OECD suggests that “taxpayers
is the case with current transfer pricing legislation. should recognize that notwithstanding limitations on doc-
umentation requirements, a tax administration will have
The OECD recognizes that “[b]oth tax administrations to make a determination of arm’ s length transfer pricing
and taxpayers often have difficulty in obtaining adequate even if the information available is incomplete”.141
information to apply the arm’ s length principle”, given that
the ALS “usually requires taxpayers and tax administra- Documentation requirements are considered apart from
tions to evaluate uncontrolled transactions and the busi- rules regarding the burden of proof. In fact, taxpayers bear
ness activities of independent enterprises, and to compare the burden of proof even when they do not. If, for example,
these with the transactions and activities of associated en- taxpayers cannot comply with the extensive documenta-
terprises”, which “can demand a substantial amount of data”. tion requirement, the tax administration is entitled to
The problems with obtaining information are extensively “assume relevant facts based on experience”.142 As a con-
described in the OECD Guidelines.135 Available informa- sequence, taxpayers should always be prepared to indicate
tion may be “incomplete and difficult to interpret”. Infor- good faith by “showing that their transfer pricing is con-
mation “may [also] be difficult to obtain for reason of its sistent with the arm’ s length principle regardless of where
geographical location or that of the parties from whom it the burden of proof lies”.143
may have to be acquired”. In addition, the OECD Guide- Not only must the price be “fair and reasonable”, but also
lines note that “information about an independent enter- the means established to reach such a price. If reaching the
prise which could be relevant may simply not exist, or there “fair and reasonable” price is at the expense of time-con-
may be no comparable independent enterprises, e.g. if that suming and burdensome procedures to be followed by the
industry has reached a high level of vertical integration”. taxpayer, one cannot speak of enabling the ability-to-pay
Further, the problems of confidentiality are highlighted principle. In such cases, tax collection, and not the ability
by the OECD Guidelines.136 Yet again, the OECD empha- to pay, is being enabled.
Under these circumstances, the current rules should be
132. A. Smith, The Wealth of Nations bk. V, ch. II, pt. 2 (Capstone Publg. Ltd. reconsidered. If one takes into account that documenta-
2010). tion is, ultimately, necessary for the application of one of
133. J.E. Stiglitz, Economics of the Public Sector 3rd ed. pp. 457-458
(W.W. Norton 1999).
134. OECD, Addressing the Tax Challenges of the Digital Economy p. 50 (OECD
2014). be made to ensure that confidentiality is maintained to the extent pos-
135. OECD Guidelines, supra n. 13, at pp. 35-36, para. 1.13. sible in such proceedings and decisions.”.
136. Id, at p. 185, para. 5.13, where it is stated that: “[t]ax administrations should 137. Id., at pp. 35-36, para. 1.13.
take care to ensure that there is no public disclosure of trade secrets, sci- 138. Id., at p. 21, para. 18.
entific secrets, or other confidential data. Tax administrations therefore 139. Id.
should use discretion in requesting this type of information and should 140. Id., at p. 134, para. 4.11.
do so only if they can undertake that the information will remain confi- 141. Id., at p. 185, para. 5.13.
dential from outside parties, except to the extent disclosure is required in 142. Id., at p. 135, para. 4.12.
public court proceedings or judicial decisions. Every endeavour should 143. Id., at p. 134, para. 4.16.

© IBFD BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION DECEMBER 2015 705

Exported / Printed on 6 June 2016 by biblio1@ibdt.org.br.


Luís Eduardo Schoueri

the methods envisaged by legislation, and the latter implies Consequently, the emergence of the BRICS (Brazil, Russia,
a (rebuttable) presumption as to what would be the price India, China and South Africa) should be viewed as suf-
in a transaction according to the ALS, which is relevant for ficient evidence regarding the limitations of the OECD
the adequate calculation of the market profit of an entity approach if the intention is to reflect global practices.
as a criterion of the measurement of its ability to pay, the
Even though the UN Model144 and the Commentaries on
issue may well present new facets. There is sufficient dis-
the UN Model145 are clearly inspired by the OECD Model
tance between the evidence produced, i.e. documentation,
and the Commentaries on the OECD Model, there are
and the final result, i.e. the ability to pay, and one may ask
clear examples in which the UN Model and the OECD
whether the latter could not be reasonably attained under
Model diverge. An important divergence relates to the
a less burdensome process and whether divergent results
adoption of the Authorised OECD Approach (AOA). The
necessarily mean that one is “correct” and the other is
Commentaries on the UN Model (2011) expressly reject
“wrong”. After all, if the objective is to reach equal treat-
the adoption of the ALS with regard to permanent estab-
ment among taxpayers, fairness becomes a more complex
lishments (PEs), which was included in the OECD Model
issue, i.e. to demand an excessive burden so as to reach an
(2010).146 The United Nations understands that such a pro-
exact number may be far from a fair distribution of the
posal would conflict with article 7(3) of the UN Model,
tax burden.
which prohibits the deduction of amounts paid by a PE to
As a result, the tax burden has been considered to date as its parent company if the amounts represent more than the
the share each taxpayer supports for common expenses. mere reimbursement of effective expenses.147
This is the amount of tax paid. Such a concept, however,
Recently, the United Nations took a very clear step towards
disregards the fact that taxpayers are not only subject to
playing a greater role in the discussions regarding trans-
tax, but that they must also fulfil other requirements envis-
fer pricing. The publication of the UN Practical Manual as
aged in tax legislation. These procedures produce what is
developed by the UN Committee of Experts on Interna-
generally referred to as compliance costs, i.e. invisible ex-
tional Cooperation in Tax Matters should be regarded as a
penses incurred by taxpayers, which, despite not being in-
landmark in this discussion as, in contrast to the approach
cluded in public revenue, clearly represent the assignment
adopted so far by the OECD, the Manual is open to con-
to taxpayers of tasks that are in the interest of tax adminis-
sidering different practices and to evaluating their advan-
trations. If fairness is the final objective of transfer pricing
tages and disadvantages.
legislation, not only the amount of tax has a role to play,
but also compliance costs. It is insufficient to ensure that The UN Model is an important source for countries
two equal, according to their ability to pay, taxpayers are regarding the development of their transfer pricing legis-
subject to the same amount of taxes, when there is a sig- lation. Although the ALS is adopted in article 9 of the UN
nificant difference in the compliance costs incurred. Model, the United Nations also refers to other alternatives,
such as FA, and notes comprehensive material to assist in
Fairness, therefore, requires reasonable means to identify
the understanding of the different approaches to transfer
ability to pay. With regard to transfer pricing, when one
pricing adopted by non-OECD countries.
considers the limitations of the ALS, it is clear that there
is no justification for exaggerated compliance costs if one As the focus of this article is on the ALS, which is present
is aware that the final result is not a precise number but in numerous tax treaties, it is interesting to note how the
rather a range of numbers. A balance between costs and UN Manual evaluates an alternative adopted by Brazil,
results is necessary, and compromise solutions may arrive i.e. the rebuttable fixed margins (RFM) method. This
at better results. article does not intended to describe in detail the Brazil-
ian transfer pricing legislation.148 It is, however, clear that
Given this perspective, the adoption of simplified methods
in several aspects, the Brazilian legislature has not followed
and standardization does not necessarily run counter to
the OECD Guidelines. Especially relevant in this respect
the ALS. On the contrary, this may imply a better result,
is the use of fixed profit margins, which is not addressed
taking into consideration fairness as its final objective.
in the OECD Guidelines.
5.2.2. The rebuttable fixed margins method This article sustains that the fact that the OECD Guide-
Recognizing that simplification and standardization in lines do not refer to fixed margins does not necessarily
respect of transfer pricing may be an important tool in mean that the Brazilian approach cannot be improved
arriving at fairness, this article considers the different so as to be considered an ALS-based method, compati-
alternatives currently discussed in the international sce-
nario. In contrast to FA, the alternatives do not disregard
144. Most recently, UN Model Tax Convention on Income and on Capital (1 Jan.
the ALS but can be regarded as means of making the ALS 2011), Models IBFD.
feasible, as they envisage the main difficulties and suggest 145. Most recently, UN Model Tax Convention on Income and on Capital: Com-
compromise solutions. mentaries (1 Jan. 2011), Models IBFD
146. OECD Model Tax Convention on Income and on Capital (22 July 2010),
Despite its initial inactivity with regard to transfer pricing Models IBFD.
147. A. Yaffar & M. Lennard, United Nations: An Introduction to the Updated
issues, the United Nations should not be disregarded if one UN Model, 66 Bull. Intl. Taxn. 11 (2012), Journals IBFD.
intends to consider transfer pricing from a broad perspec- 148. For an extensive analysis of the Brazilian transfer pricing legislation, see
tive that is not restricted to the OECD member countries. L.E. Schoueri, Preços de Transferência no Direito Tributário Brasileiro 3rd
ed. (Dialética 2013).

706 BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION DECEMBER 2015 © IBFD

Exported / Printed on 6 June 2016 by biblio1@ibdt.org.br.


Arm’ s Length: Beyond the Guidelines of the OECD

ble with both the UN Model and the OECD Model. For Under the fixed margins approach, states may establish
a better understanding of this concept, one should keep “different profit margins per economic sector, line of busi-
in mind the idea presented in section 2.4. regarding the ness or, even more specifically according to the kind of
legal nature of transfer pricing. The author believes that goods or services dealt with, to calculate the parameter
there is a legal fiction to grant the same treatment to con- price”,150 regarding the application of the relevant ALS-
trolled transactions as if they represented the ALS and a based methods. The profit margins must be determined on
rebuttable presumption that the ALS can be arrived at by the basis of market research. Such pricing research could
way of the methods envisaged by law. In this case, fixed be undertaken by the tax administration or purchased
margins are a mere extension of a generally accepted legal from third parties. What is important is that the research
presumption. has been previously submitted to discussion with the eco-
nomic groups to which it is to be applied.
There is apparently little dispute in literature regarding the
generally adopted legal presumption that the application If the legislation establishes numerous and specific
of transfer pricing methods, e.g. the RPM, can arrive at margins, the chances increase that the applicable margins
values that would otherwise be reached in a transaction correspond to a consensus regarding reality. The Brazilian
between unrelated parties, i.e. the ALS. Several states adopt Chapter on the UN Practical Manual emphasizes that, in
similar methods and their efficiency is generally accepted. some cases, the existence of many different margins may
Fixed margins imply a modification of the presumption, not be necessary, depending on the diversity of goods and
i.e. while, in general, states rely on the result of a method services exported and imported by the state.151 Determin-
but do not set a margin for the application of the presump- ing how numerous and how specific the fixed margins are
tion, the Brazilian approach relies on a legal presumption is deemed to be a policy decision, which may vary accord-
that includes a fixed margin. ing to the characteristics of a state’ s economy.152
In other words, while a generally accepted approach would The legislation may establish fixed margins by economic
be, for example, that a price according to the ALS could sector, for example, by distinguishing the extraction or
be obtained by way of a resale price reduced by a margin production of raw materials, manufacturing and services,
to be established according to a margin based on a func- or more specifically by reference to the relevant activities
tional analysis, the Brazilian legislator deems the resale of an MNE. As stated in the UN Practical Model, “the
price reduced by a fixed margin to accord with the ALS. In country could use a margin for the chemical industry as
both cases, there is a presumption that the correct applic- a whole, or different margins for different types of prod-
ation of the method results in a price which accords with ucts of the chemical industry (agrochemical, petrochemi-
the ALS. From this perspective, the discussion on the Bra- cal, explosives, cosmetics etc)”.153
zilian approach is much simpler, i.e. to determine whether
It is important to note that the current Brazilian legislation
there is sufficient reason behind the presumption that un-
does not include such a mechanism. The Brazilian Chapter
related parties deal in accordance with the fixed margin.
in the UN Practical Manual deems it possible to establish
The Brazilian fixed margin approach was not disregarded a “range of profit margins”. In some cases, it could be nec-
in the UN Practical Manual. This, while reporting on essary to determine a maximum and a minimum profit
experiences with FA, considers that Brazilian legislation margin that would statistically correspond to the avail-
“set[s] out a maximum ceiling on the expenses that may able relevant data of uncontrolled transactions. This range
be deducted for tax purposes in respect of imports and would represent “an acceptable divergence margin”.154 This
lay down a minimum level for the gross income in rela- being the case, any legislation should establish ranges
tion to exports, effectively using a set formula to allocate instead of margins. If the pricing research establishes that
income to Brazil”.149 some companies have a 25% margin and that others have
a 38% margin, a range would be advisable instead of fixed
5.2.3. RFM is different from FA: RFM in accordance with margins, in the sense that margins within the 25% to 38%
the ALS range would be acceptable. If the range becomes too wide,
Viewing the Brazilian approach as an FA alternative is this may indicate the need for further specification regard-
misleading. The Brazilian approach does not pursue the ing the products or activities.155
allocation of the global profit of MNEs among the various
entities. Neither does it take into consideration the amount 150. Id., at p. 372, para. 10.2.9.1.
151. Id.
of profit to be allocated to the other entities in the group. 152. Id., at p. 373, para. 10.2.9.4, where it is stated that: “[e]ach country should
Instead, the Brazilian legislation only takes into consider- determine, according to its specific circumstances, the amounts involved
ation the profit of the Brazilian entity. Consequently, the and types of goods and services, how specific the margins should be and
whether more margins are merited. Besides, a country may combine dif-
Brazilian legislation is clearly not an FA-based method, ferent levels of margin specifications if it seems appropriate; it may set
as it neither takes into account the global profit of the forth some general margins for a line of business in addition to more
MNE nor disregards intra-group transactions. The fixed specific margins for some goods.”
153. Id., at p. 373, para. 10.2.9.3, where the Brazilian Chapter emphasizes that:
margins approach is, therefore, essentially a transactional “[t]he differentiation per industry into types of products is adopted by
ALS-based approach. Brazil, where, for the Resale Price Method for imports, the margin for
chemicals sector in general is 30 per cent, while the margin for pharma-
ceutical chemicals and pharmaceuticals is 40 per cent”.
154. Id., at p. 373, para. 10.2.9.5.
149. UN Practical Manual, supra n. 14, at pp. 13-14, para. 1.4.13. 155. Id., at p. 374, para. 10.2.9.7.

© IBFD BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION DECEMBER 2015 707

Exported / Printed on 6 June 2016 by biblio1@ibdt.org.br.


Luís Eduardo Schoueri

The advantages of the fixed margins are immediate. These The only reasonable interpretation of the fixed profit
are that they:156 (1) may avoid the need for specific com- margins is that the margins set out in the legislation are
parables; (2) can be applied both by tax administrations rebuttable. The taxpayer must be entitled to make argu-
and entities without the need for technical knowledge on ments to the effect that an ALS margin in a given trans-
specific transfer pricing issues, which is a scarce human action would probably be distinct from the margin arrived
resource for both tax administrations and entities in devel- at by the tax administration or would not fall within the
oping countries; (3) give legal certainty for taxpayers, as range of margins provided. A distinct interpretation would
this is an ex ante objective alternative that does not rely imply a violation of both domestic legislation and the tax
on further subjective analysis; (4) reduce costs for both tax treaties providing for the ALS.161 When one reads the text
administrations and taxpayers, as they diminish the need of Law 9,430/1996, as amended in 2012, it is clear that
to empirically determine gross margins in a comparability margins may be revised. Unfortunately, this has not been
analysis; and (5) promote competition among enterprises the practice in Brazil. It is, therefore, difficult to determine
in a state in subjecting them to the same taxation. the reasons why taxpayers have not challenged the margins
so determined. Previous legislation required a vast amount
However, if not correctly considered, the approach may
of documentation for the application of a revision of the
be incompatible with the ALS. Despite being important
margins, which made any such request virtually unfea-
for tax policy considerations, the “Comments for Coun-
sible. However, this legislation is no longer in force and
tries Considering the Adoption of Fixed Margins” in the
this could give the tax administration and taxpayers an
UN Practical Manual ignores the need for rebuttable pre-
opportunity to discuss industry-specific margins. The fact
sumptions.
that this has not occurred to date may be considered the
The Brazilian Chapter was written by the Brazilian tax major weakness in Brazilian practice. This demonstrates
administration and, therefore, does nothing more than that current Brazilian practice may not be considered the
express the tax administration’ s interpretation of the Bra- final solution but rather a methodology under construc-
zilian legislation. As a result, a “weakness” of the method tion.
is the “unavoidable” outcome “that some Brazilian enter-
A further failure of the RFM as it presently exists in Bra-
prises will be taxed at (higher or lower) profit margins not
zilian practice is that there is little evidence regarding the
compatible with their profitability”. This is due to the fact
methodology employed to arrive at the fixed margins.
that “the fixed margin method applies regardless of the
Such opacity implies a clear lack of legitimacy of the pre-
cost structures of taxpayers”.157 The Brazilian tax adminis-
sumption itself, as no one can convincingly argue that
tration also notes that “[t]he approach may lead to double
margins are reasonable or not. A further development
taxation in case there is no access to competent authori-
of the method, therefore, appears to be necessary for the
ties to negotiate relief of double taxation”.158
methodology, as well as the data collected and employed,
Consequently, the Brazilian Chapter ignores the fact that to be transparent, thereby permitting control of the pre-
the ALS may be inferred from the Brazilian tax legisla- sumption.
tion159 and is also included in every tax treaty concluded
Under such conditions, the RFM method as advanced in
by Brazil.160 If the tax administration’ s interpretation
this article may be compatible with the ALS and could be
is adopted, the allegedly “unavoidable” outcome of the
viewed as an important tool to circumvent the feasibility
methods applied clearly violates provisions of the Brazil-
issues regarding the ALS noted in section 2.5.3. As noted
ian tax system. This interpretation may risk the worldwide
previously in this section, current Brazilian practice is not
rejection of Brazilian transfer pricing legislation, as, under
what the author would claim to be the final solution and
the terms as advanced by the tax administration, the Bra-
should be considered an alternative under construction,
zilian approach is clearly in breach of the international
which demands further correction.
agreements signed by Brazil.
In order to comprehend how the RFM, provided that the
adaptations again noted previously in this section are
156. Id., at p. 370, para. 10.2.7.1. adopted, is compatible with the ALS, this article now pro-
157. Id., at p. 371, para. 10.2.7.2. vides a theoretical framework that can locate the ALS in
158. Id. the principles that are generally embodied in tax systems.
159. Schoueri, supra n. 148, at p. 60 and R.L. Torres, O Princípio Arm’ s Length,
os Preços de Transferência e a Teoria da Interpretação do Direito Tributário,
48 Revista Dialética de Direito Tributário (1999).
160. Brazil had, at the time of the writing of this article, concluded comprehen-
sive tax treaties with the following states (in order of original date of con-
clusion): Japan (24 Jan. 1967); France (10 Sept. 1971); Belgium (23 June
1972, amended 20 Nov. 2002); Denmark (27 Aug. 1974); Spain (14 Nov.
1974); Sweden (25 Apr. 1975); Austria (24 May 1975); Italy (3 Oct. 1978); 161. Unfortunately, the tax administration still does not share this perspective
Luxembourg (8 Nov. 1978); Argentina (17 May 1980); Norway (21 Aug. (see, for example, the decisions of the Brazilian Administrative Council
1980); Ecuador (26 May 1983); the Philippines (29 Sept. 1983); Canada of Tax Appeals (Conselho Administrativo de Recursos Fiscais, CARF) in
(4 June 1984); Hungary (20 June 1986); Czechoslovakia (now the Czech BZ: CARF, 13 Nov. 2008, Judgement No. 108-09.763 and BZ: CARF, 12
Rep. and the Slovak Rep.) (26 Aug. 1986); India (26 Apr. 1988); Korea June 2012, Judgement No. 1401-000.801). Unsurprisingly, the Agreement
(Rep.) (7 Mar. 1989); the Netherlands (8 Mar. 1990); China (5 Aug. 1991); between the Federal Republic of Germany and the Federative Republic of
Finland (2 Apr. 1996); Portugal (16 May 2000); Chile (3 Apr. 2001); Brazil for the Avoidance of Double Taxation with Respect to Taxes on Income
Ukraine (16 Jan. 2002); Israel (12 Dec. 2002); Mexico (25 Sept. 2003); and Capital (27 June 1975), Treaties IBFD was terminated by Germany on
South Africa (8 Nov. 2003); Venezuela (14 Feb. 2005); Peru (17 Feb. 2006); 7 April 2005 with effect from 1 January 2006 due to disagreements that
Trinidad and Tobago (23 July 2008); and Turkey (16 Dec. 2010). included transfer pricing issues.

708 BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION DECEMBER 2015 © IBFD

Exported / Printed on 6 June 2016 by biblio1@ibdt.org.br.


Arm’ s Length: Beyond the Guidelines of the OECD

5.2.4. The RFM as standardization tified interference by the state on the economic activities
of the taxpayer. The application of a standard should result
The RFM is essentially a method that provides for norms
in neither (excessive) interference with regard to the com-
with a simplification function. The method is intended
petition between companies nor to an excessive burden on
to standardize the application of the ALS and, as a conse-
some taxpayers to the detriment of others. The need for
quence, it may put into perspective the justice of particular
non-excessiveness (5) implies that the application of the
cases. However, the mere fact that the real value and the
standard may not result in confiscatory measures.
value achieved by the application of the fixed margin are
not always identical does not imply the need for rejecting Most importantly, standardization can only be deemed
the standardization. valid if the adjustability (6) is ensured for taxpayers. It may
be that, despite being valid as a general rule, standardiza-
In the standardization, the ability-to-pay principle is not
tion implies a greater effect on given taxpayers, whose par-
left behind. Standardization implies the option for achiev-
ticular circumstances move them away from the general
ing equality by the consideration of elements presumably
rule. As a result, standardization demands the inclusion of
present in the majority of the cases.162 For this reason,
a hardship clause, i.e. Härteklausel, whereby a fair, i.e. jus-
unlike the RFM, the FA alternative may not be deemed as
tifiable, level of differentiation is granted to taxpayers.164
a form of standardization, considering it has no direct rela-
In this sense, it is essential to interpret the fixed margins
tion with the profitability of the entities in an MNE and,
in transfer pricing legislation as a rebuttable margin so as
as a consequence, does not comply with the principle of
to be able to consider this method as compatible with the
the ability to pay.
ALS.
Ávila’ s theory of tax equality proves useful to evaluate
It is important to note that the RFM is only one example of
whether a given standardization is compatible with the
standardization. Its application in the Brazilian tax system
principle of equality. According to this theory, the criteria
is far from the ideal, but, if the relevant taxpayers’ rights
to examine whether the standardization complies with the
are granted, there are reasons to conclude that the stan-
principle of the ability to pay are: (1) necessity; (2) general-
dardization may represent an alternative for the ALS fea-
ity; (3) compatibility; (4) neutrality; (5) non-excessiveness;
sibility issues. This article contends that scholars should
and (6) adjustability.163
seek additional elements that could allow some form of
With regard to necessity (1), the ground for the adoption standardization in transfer pricing issues and provide a
of the RFM is the extreme burden that transfer pricing theoretical framework as to determine their compatibil-
legislation entails for taxpayers to comply with the audit- ity with the ALS.
ing requirements. The proposals for abandoning the
Transfer pricing analysis has become too fact-specific and
ALS, which are generally based on the complexity of the
the measures intended to simplify the system have been
method, are sufficient to conclude that such a measure is
rejected on the grounds of an absolute need for compara-
necessary.
bility analysis. However, the correct comprehension of the
Generality (2) is an important element in analysing the ALS as a standard of measurement oriented toward imple-
feasibility of the RFM in certain cases. The standard must menting the equality among taxpayers and privileging the
concretely reproduce a trend in real cases. The legal stan- principle of the ability to pay results in a reconsideration
dard must be adequate to the majority of the taxpayers of this statement.
the fixed margin covers. In order to determine the group
of taxpayers to which the fixed margin should apply, the 5.2.5. Compatibility between the RFM and the OECD
considerations contained in the Brazilian Chapter of the Model
UN Practical Manual should be followed.
The RFM, as well as any standardization drafted accord-
There are many cases in which finding a standard profit ing to the framework provided for in this article, should be
margin is not possible, as standardization is only valid considered to be compatible both with the OECD Model
where it implies minimal adverse effects. In such cases, and the UN Model. The ALS, as set out in tax treaties,
the RFM should not be used. In other words, standardiza- implies a limitation to states’ taxing powers. Actually, if it
tion is not intended to perpetuate inequality. On the con- is not controversial that taxation cannot exceed a state’ s
trary, it should be specifically designed to pursue equal- jurisdiction, it is also correct to say that domestic tax law
ity among taxpayers. Standardization is only tolerant with cannot provide for a matter that is not within a state’ s juris-
regard to accidental discrepancies between the deemed diction given the limitation in jurisdiction contained in a
profit margin and the profit margins effectively observed tax treaty.165 As a result, an adequate understanding of the
in unrelated parties’ transactions.
Compatibility (3) means that the chosen standard must
164. Id., at p. 105.
reproduce reality not only prior to the enactment of the 165. In this sense, one may recall the recent trend among German scholars
legislation, but also after its application by the adjudicat- and case law to the effect that a treaty override is, in general, deemed
ing authority. Likewise, neutrality (4) prohibits any unjus- to be unconstitutional. For a contextualization of the ongoing debate in
Germany. See A. Rust & E. Reimer, Treaty Override im deutschen Interna-
tionalen Steuerrecht, 24 Internationales Steuerrecht, pp. 843-849 (2005);
M. Lehner, Treaty Override im Anwendungsbereich des § 50d EStG, 11
162. Ávila, supra n. 65, at p. 89. Internationales Steuerrecht, pp. 389-401 (2012); and A. Perdelwitz,
163. Id., at pp. 94-113. Treaty Override – Revival of the Debate over the Constitutionality of Domes-

© IBFD BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION DECEMBER 2015 709

Exported / Printed on 6 June 2016 by biblio1@ibdt.org.br.


Luís Eduardo Schoueri

relation between domestic rules and tax treaties must take From a rational perspective, in this sense, the higher the
into account the concept of jurisdiction, instead of being fixed margin established by domestic legislation, the
addressed as a hierarchy issue.166 higher is the amount of litigation entailed by the fixed
margin system. The fine balance between litigation and
Article 9(1) of the OECD Model states that the profit that
tax collection is a matter of tax policy. Obviously, an exces-
would have been derived in controlled transactions had
sively high fixed margin that does not correspond to reality
they been undertaken at arm’ s length “may be included in
is useless as, instead of bringing simplicity to the system, it
the profits of that enterprise and taxed accordingly”. The
only engenders the need to undertake comparability anal-
authorization included in article 9(1) of the OECD Model
ysis in the form of litigation. Fixed margins are also incom-
is, however, limited by the ALS. According to article 9(2)
patible with the criteria for standardization developed in
of the OECD Model, if “the profits so included are profits
this article. On the other hand, an excessively low margin
which would have accrued to the enterprise of the first-
implies a loss of tax revenue that could otherwise be col-
mentioned State” are at the ALS, “that other State shall
lected if the margins were more precisely determined.
make an appropriate adjustment to the amount of the tax
charged therein on those profits”. Article 9 of the OECD Despite the foregoing, it can still be argued that, given
Model does not demand that all the profit that would the wording of article 9(1) of the OECD Model, the ap-
be derived in an ALS situation is included in the taxable plication of the RFM could result in double taxation. For
base of the enterprise but rather that the contracting state instance, one state could reject the inclusion of profits by
respects any inclusion made by the other contracting state the other state due to the application of the RFM and refus-
if “the profits so included are profits which would have ing to make a corresponding adjustment under article 9(2)
accrued to the enterprise of the first-mentioned State”. In of the OECD Model. In such circumstances, a tax treaty
addition, even if the other contracting state makes no such would not realize its primary function, which is to elim-
inclusion, a state is only entitled to include the profit that inate double taxation.
would have been derived in an arm’ s length situation.
However, this may not be deemed to be an outcome attrib-
Three outcomes are possible from the application of the utable to the RFM, as it is, rather, a consequence of apply-
RFM. These are: (1) the transfer pricing arrived falls within ing the ALS in the conditions set out in article 9 of the
the ALS range; (2) the transfer pricing arrived at does not OECD Model. In other words, the possibility that the
fall within the ALS range to the disadvantage of the tax- contracting states disagree with regard to adjustments is
payer; or (3) the transfer pricing arrived at does not fall not limited exclusively to the RFM, as this is present in all
within the ALS range to the disadvantage of the tax admin- ALS-based methods. Quoting a decision of the German
istration. Federal Fiscal Court (Bundesfinanzhof, BFH) of 2001,167
which correctly stated that there is no single comparable
The first case is the outcome pursued by the drafting of
price but rather a range, i.e. “band”, of them, as well as a
the legislation. If the pricing of the transaction falls within
similar understanding of the German tax administra-
the ALS range, standardization has provided both the tax
tion, Ditz advances a relevant argument. This is that in
administration and the taxpayer with the expected ben-
the market one also finds comparable goods or services
efits. This ensures that the transaction is taxed according
offered for different prices.168 In such a scenario, it is very
to ability to pay.
likely that contracting states will arrive at different adjust-
Where the transfer pricing does not fall within the ALS ments, which are all compatible with the ALS. The OECD
range to the disadvantage of the taxpayer, the taxpayer is Model does not resolve this, as it does not say which state
entitled to question the fixed margin applied. If the profit is entitled to make the adjustment set out in article 9(1).
margin is rebuttable, the taxpayer must be able to dem- Where both states are so entitled, with the other state being
onstrate, based on a comparability analysis, that a profit required to make the corresponding adjustment, it is pos-
margin in accordance with the ALS would be greater than sible that the states will not arrive at the same conclusions
the standard set by the tax administration. with regard to what is the correct adjustment under article
9(1) of the OECD Model, thereby refusing to make the rel-
The fixed margin can only be challenged by the taxpayer
evant adjustment under article 9(2).
if taxation under the fixed margin is higher than taxation
under the actual margin, plus the cost of the litigation that At this point, it is important to distinguish between the
the taxpayer faces, which includes all of the relevant costs deficiencies of the RFM and those of ALS-based methods
arising from the allocation of the burden of proof. If the in general. The risk of a disagreement regarding the inclu-
fixed margin is equal to or lower than the actual margin, sion of profits is certainly not a peculiarity of the RFM, but
the taxpayer should settle for the fixed margin. In this it is an issue that the OECD Model has never managed to
sense, the tax administration should consider reviewing resolve, and it remains an open question with regard to all
the fixed margins whenever it detects a situation that keeps ALS-based methods.
a group of taxpayers away from the standard as defined.
It may well be that the states disagree when applying the
CUP, the RFM, the TNMM and any of the other methods.
tic Treaty Override Provisions in Germany, 53 Eur. Taxn. 9, secs. 2. & 3. Applying the traditional ALS-based methods is no safer
(2013), Journals IBFD.
166. For the author’ s opinion on the relationship between tax treaties and
domestic legislation, see L.E. Schoueri, Treaty Override: A Jurisdictional 167. DE: BFH 17 Oct. 2001, I R 103/00.
Approach, 42 Intertax, 11 p. 682 (2014). 168. Ditz, supra n. 62, at p. 117.

710 BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION DECEMBER 2015 © IBFD

Exported / Printed on 6 June 2016 by biblio1@ibdt.org.br.


Arm’ s Length: Beyond the Guidelines of the OECD

than applying the RFM, i.e. both entail the risk of double fer pricing effectively”.171 The fact that the Revised Section
taxation given the nature of the ALS and the inability of E expressly refers to the UN Practical Manual and to the
the OECD Model to deal with this risk. challenges reported there regarding the obtaining of ade-
quate information to apply the ALS by developing coun-
5.2.6. The RFM from a global perspective tries appears to be a clear indication that the OECD may
The OECD Guidelines require tax administrations to be be willing to consider transfer pricing on a global basis,
prepared to thoroughly understand the controlled trans- in respect of which the difficulties encountered by non-
actions to be audited. Functional analysis and documen- OECD countries would have to be taken into account.
tation are clearly not a simple issue. Taxpayers face enor- When one views matters from the perspective of devel-
mous compliance costs, and tax administrations must oping countries, it is also necessary to consider that these
be adequately prepared for the associated administrative countries usually do not have sufficient savings to finance
demands. their development. Foreign investment is, in this context,
Extending the OECD Guidelines beyond the OECD of paramount importance. Although it is true that foreign
member countries requires that any differences are taken investors may be attracted by reduced taxation, the role of
into account. While developed countries (should) have legal certainty cannot be disregarded. The transfer pricing
sufficient personnel to evaluate such complex issues, this methodologies described in the OECD Guidelines may
is not what can be expected from the majority of states claim to take fairness into account. One could even believe
worldwide. Not only do the tax administrations of devel- that, ultimately, prices resulting from the application of the
oping countries tend to be very small compared to their OECD Guidelines are close to what would be obtained
needs, but also tax auditors’ familiarity with international according to the ALS. However, the methods described
tax issues are not common in such scenarios. It is not in the OECD Guidelines encompass a significant degree
uncommon that tax administrations lack the personnel of uncertainty, which require the tax administration and
who can read documents written in English. Under these the taxpayer to be prepared for a long discussion on the
circumstances, requiring complex auditing procedures is adequate margins to be applied. From the perspective of
not realistic. This is an important factor in support of the foreign investors, there is always the risk that their argu-
adoption of simple procedures, such as the RFM. ment will not be accepted, or even considered, due to
various factors, including the lack of experience of the tax
Of course, one cannot say that the RFM is derived from administration. It is not surprising, therefore, that a recent
the OECD Guidelines. Unlike the UN Practical Manual, research involving German businesses revealed a major-
the OECD does not consider this alternative. However, ity of 94% that indicated legal certainty as the main objec-
one should note that the OECD has moved in the direc- tive to be attained by their transfer pricing strategy. This
tion of considering the difficulties of developing coun- objective was even more important than that of optimizing
tries. In this regard, an important step can be seen in the taxation.172 In such a global scenario, the RFM appears to
OECD’ s revised guidance on safe harbours in the Revised be a convenient solution as it represents, ultimately, a safe
Section E on Safe Harbours in Chapter IV of the Transfer harbour, i.e. a predictable level of taxation.
Pricing Guidelines of 2013 (the “Revised Section E”).169
In this, the OECD stated that the primary objective is to 5.3. The BEPS initiative: Are we still at arm’ s length?
reduce compliance costs for taxpayers and the administra-
5.3.1. The inherent flaw: What has the BEPS initiative
tive demands on tax administrations. However, the OECD
to say?
recognizes that “the careful use of safe harbours – particu-
larly safe harbours that are negotiated on a bilateral basis 5.3.1.1. Initial remarks
between the countries’ competent authorities, can reduce In addressing the criticisms of the ALS, Kane (2014) con-
the need to obtain comparables for specific transactions”, siders that there are cases where comparables: (1) “liter-
which “may provide a viable alternative to comparables ally cannot exist as a conceptual matter”; (2) exist, but the
based analysis in some circumstances”. The OECD admits results that they entail are so divergent that the application
that even “regionally developed safe harbours for regions of comparability is not practicable; and (3) do not exist in
that share common characteristics” and “additional guid- practice, but could exist conceptually.173 In his understand-
ance or direct assistance could be provided to developing ing, the “inherent flaw” would be most present in the cases
countries with regard to safe harbours”.170 It is interesting to of values relating to common control, which, by definition,
note that this statement derives from a request made by the could not be realized in uncontrolled transactions. Values
G8, under the United Kingdom’ s presidency, “to find ways in relation to common control would fall within case (1),
to address the concerns expressed by developing countries where there would be no comparables, even conceptually.
on the quality and availability of the information on com- As he emphasizes, this category should not be confused
parable transactions that is needed to administer trans- with cases “clouded with other complexities that plague

169. OECD, Revised Section E on Safe Harbours in Chapter IV of the Transfer


Pricing Guidelines (OECD 2013), International Organizations’ Documen- 171. Id., at p. 1.
tation IBFD. 172. Horvath & Partners, Studienbericht Spannungsfeld Transferpreise p. 7
170. OECD, Transfer Pricing Comparability Data and Developing Countries (2015).
p. 7, para. 26 (OECD 2014), International Organizations’ Documentation. 173. Kane, supra n. 68, at sec. 2.2.

© IBFD BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION DECEMBER 2015 711

Exported / Printed on 6 June 2016 by biblio1@ibdt.org.br.


Luís Eduardo Schoueri

real world application of comparables analysis”.174 This is Guidelines. In addressing the role of synergy in the tax
compatible with the classification proposed in section 2.5. restructuring of businesses, the OECD Guidelines state
In other words, the inherent flaw argument is not a criti- that “[f]or Article 9 purposes, it would be a good prac-
cism of the practicability of the system. The criticism of tice for the taxpayer to document how these anticipated
the core of the ALS arises, as “[n]o amount of searching, synergies impact at the entity level in applying the arm’ s
whether in competitive equilibrium or not, could ever length principle”.177
hope to identify a comparable for the value associated with
In the recent work of the OECD with regard to the BEPS
common control”.175 Finding comparables, even concep-
initiative, such a trend has become apparent. In this
tually, is impossible in such cases. This is not a mere issue
context, Juan Zornoza Pérez and Aitor Navarro Ibarrola
of practicability.
(2015),178 in commenting on the Public Discussion Draft
on BEPS Actions 8, 9 and 10, have remarked that “it is
5.3.1.2. The inherent flaw from the perspective of the OECD
virtually impossible that transactions exclusively under-
Model and the UN Model
taken by MNEs – and hence transactions that indepen-
Section 5.3.1.1. leads on to the conclusion that the ALS dent parties would not undertake – may respect the ALP
does not take synergy rents into account. This is a strictly [ALS]”.179 On these grounds, they reject the statement in-
legal analysis, based on the interpretation of the ALS in cluded in paragraph 82 of the Draft, according to which “...
its current wording in both the OECD Model and the UN the mere fact that the transaction may not be seen between
Model. The argument is simply that the OECD Model independent parties does not mean that it does not have
does not empower either the source or the residence state characteristics of an arm’ s length arrangement”. Specifi-
to make any form of adjustment by reference to synergy cally, the statement would seem “to imply a direct contra-
intangibles. diction with the nature of the ALP itself ”. In their reason-
In this context, article 9(1) of the OECD Model states that ing, they consider that “it remains quite clear that a TP
any profits that would “have accrued to one of the enter- rule based on the ALP require a reallocation of benefits
prises, but, by reason of those conditions [common control obtained by related parties taking into account what inde-
conditions], have not so accrued, may be included in the pendent parties would have done”.
profits of that enterprise and taxed accordingly”. Synergy Nevertheless, with regard to synergistic gains, it is impos-
rents are not profits that would have accrued in an uncon- sible to state, on the basis of the ALS, that such gains belong
trolled transaction. As extensively argued, and as stated in to one of the entities in isolation or that it “would have
the inherent flaw argument, the ALS fails to take such rents accrued to one of the enterprises”. According to Kane
into account, in the sense that they are not allocated to any (2014), as the gains are a consequence of the organization,
of the entities under consideration. One cannot say that, “it is theoretically defensible to make any allocation of the
at arm’ s length, the synergy rents would have accrued to surplus”.180 Ditz (2015) confirms that, from a theoretical
this or that enterprise. perspective, it is impossible to identify, weigh and deter-
Article 9(2) of the OECD Model also does not cover mine a key of allocation for such profits.181
synergy rents. In the wording of the OECD Model, an No conclusion with regard to the allocation of synergy
adjustment can be made if profits “so included are profits rents can be realized under the ALS. This is clearly a limit
which would have accrued to the enterprise of the first- of the ALS and it says nothing about gains from integra-
mentioned State if the conditions made between the two tion. It is not a failure that can be corrected by way of an
enterprises had been those which would have been made ambulatory interpretation but rather a question of the allo-
between independent enterprises”. Again, synergy rents cation of taxing rights that has not been adequately dealt
would not have accrued between independent parties, in with in tax treaties following the OECD Model or the UN
the sense that the states cannot make adjustments to take Model. The ALS was never intended to take synergy into
synergy rents into account. account and, therefore, there has never been any agree-
However, assuming an ambulatory interpretation of the ment with reference to gains from integration.
ALS, tax administrations have tried to resolve the inherent
flaw by rephrasing the ALS analysis. Under this updated
version of the ALS, arrangements between controlled
parties should be compared, for example, to “arrange- 177. OECD Guidelines, supra n. 13, at p. 254, para. 9.58.
178. OECD, Comments Received on Public Discussion Draft: BEPS Actions 8, 9
ments that would be made between unrelated parties if and 10: Revisions to Chapter I of the Transfer Pricing Guidelines (Including
they could choose to have the costs of related parties”.176 Risk, Recharacterisation, and Special Measures) 511 (OECD 2015).
Given such a rephrasing, the ALS could take synergy rents 179. Id., at 511, where it states that: “[t]he interpretation of a rule should not be
assessed from a policy or de lege ferenda perspective, but from the anal-
into account. ysis of the construction of the rule itself. In this sense, it remains quite
clear that a TP rule based on the ALP require a reallocation of benefits
The OECD has pursued a similar approach, which has obtained by related parties taking into account what independent parties
already been hinted at in some aspects of the OECD would have done. Thus, it is virtually impossible that transactions exclu-
sively undertaken by MNEs – and hence transactions that independent
parties would not undertake – may respect the ALP. Stating the contrary
would imply to go beyond the possible meaning of the rule which at the
174. Id. end of the day amounts to its infringement.”
175. Id. 180. Kane, supra n. 75, at sec. 2.2.
176. I.R.S. Notice 88-123, supra n. 49, at 483. 181. Ditz, supra n. 62, at p. 119.

712 BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION DECEMBER 2015 © IBFD

Exported / Printed on 6 June 2016 by biblio1@ibdt.org.br.


Arm’ s Length: Beyond the Guidelines of the OECD

One must agree that “article 9 is in fact silent about the within a community, it is necessary to identify the sub-
allocation of any common control premium”.182 As a result, jects to be compared in the same way, i.e. an entity-to-
no adjustment intending to reallocate synergy gains is pos- entity approach. Under such a limited, entity approach,
sible under the OECD Model. Consequently, the alloca- the difference in treatment disappears.
tion of income must be retained as declared by the tax-
In summary, a transfer pricing adjustment without the
payer, as the tax administration has no power to adjust,
ALS would require the consideration of residual profits
and there is no provision regarding on what basis such an
that cannot be imputed to an entity. This difference is suffi-
allocation should be made.
cient to demonstrate that the principle of equality does not
require a profit adjustment that does not reflect the ALS.
5.3.1.3. The inherent flaw from the perspective of domestic
law
5.3.1.4. No base erosion and no profit shifting due to the
A consideration of internal law should not result in a dif- inherent flaw
ferent conclusion. In other words, there should be no jus-
The BEPS initiative appears to be the generally accepted
tification for adjustments that would not be based on the
methodology for changes in transfer pricing. States believe
ALS.
that they are missing an opportunity to tax. The inher-
This article has already argued that the ALS is a tool to ent flaw in the ALS identifies the possibility that resid-
reach the profit, i.e. a proxy, to measure ability to pay, i.e. ual profits may escape taxation in contradiction with the
the criterion for comparison, of taxpayers trading with “single tax principle”. The author is doubtful regarding
related parties (see section 2.3.). Transfer pricing legisla- the existence of such a principle, but, in any case, it would
tion adopts a legal fiction under which, instead of dealing demand evidence that some states’ tax bases have been
with such taxpayers according to the relevant numbers in eroded or that profits have been shifted to other jurisdic-
their controlled transactions, taxation is effected as if the tions.
taxpayers had transacted with each other according to the
When one considers the tax base, one should ask how far
ALS. In this sense, the actual values of the controlled trans-
a state’ s tax law may reach. This issue has been debated in
actions are disregarded, and the ALS is used as the tax base.
international tax law for a long time and, currently, there
This implies limiting any adjustments based on transfer appears to be less doubt that taxes may not reach situations
pricing legislation. The numbers presented by taxpayers beyond a country’ s jurisdiction. In this sense, a state’ s tax
cannot be questioned if an adjustment is not based on the base is limited to its jurisdiction, as defined according to
assumption that unrelated parties would have dealt with the elements of connection selected by domestic law. Resi-
the matter in such a way. dence and source are traditionally accepted as elements of
connection.
The ALS has been presented as the key to the conversion
of the values of controlled transactions into market prices. The mere application of the elements of connection,
Any adjustment without the ALS would require a clear however, is insufficient to define a state’ s tax base. If a state
statement that it reflects market conditions. has a constitutional framework based on the rule of law
and equality, the tax base must be defined by law in such
The issue can be expressed the other way round. An adjust-
a way that it allows taxpayers to be compared according to
ment out with the ALS would result in prices that would
criteria that can be objectively tested. As already noted in
not be market prices. Profits determined according to such
section 2.3., comparison has a subjective element, i.e. the
adjustments would also not be market profits. If profits are
subjects to be compared must be in comparable situations.
the proxy for the criterion of comparison, i.e. the ability to
From this perspective, it appears to be questionable as to
pay, it would be unacceptable that unrelated parties would
whether groups of entities can be included within a (single)
have their profits estimated according to market values,
state’ s tax base. As noted in section 2., once a tax system
while related parties would be forced to use non-market
adopts an entity approach to measure the ability to pay in
prices.
uncontrolled transactions, this is a self-limitation on the
One could correctly argue that this conclusion would also tax base. In other words, profits that are not imputable
be unfair, as states could not arrive at the total amount of to entities are not per se part of a (single) state’ s tax base.
the group profit. This would be true if the “residual profit”
For the same reason, it is not the circumstances of claiming
were to be disregarded by both countries in unilaterally
that profit shifting may have arisen as a result of the non-
applying the ALS, especially if the parties apply differ-
inclusion of residual profits within a (single) entity’ s tax
ent ALS methods. However, this reasoning arises from a
base. Profit shifting requires a first step, whereby profits are
failure in the comparison. A difference would only exist in
identified as having been earned by an entity, and a second
as far as one compares, on the one hand, (isolated) entities
step, whereby profits are shifted to a different, low-tax
trading with unrelated parties and, on the other, consoli-
jurisdiction. If residual profits, as explained in section
dated groups acting in different jurisdictions. If the scope
2.5.7., cannot be imputed to any isolated entity but only
of the transfer pricing legislation is to realize fairness in
to the group as a whole, there is logically no profit shift-
the distribution of the tax burden among those acting
ing but merely the non-inclusion of the residual profits.

182. Kane, supra n. 75, at sec. 3.

© IBFD BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION DECEMBER 2015 713

Exported / Printed on 6 June 2016 by biblio1@ibdt.org.br.


Luís Eduardo Schoueri

5.3.1.5. Interim conclusions: The BEPS initiative to tax the 5.3.2. Proposals on intangibles: The OECD Guidelines in
residual income cannot be justified by the current breach of the OECD Model
ALS
From the first BEPS proposals with regard to intangibles,
This article concludes that recognizing an inherent flaw it has been considered that the ALS is “slowly but surely
in the ALS does not imply dismissing it. On the contrary, being relegated to the back seat” in the OECD Guide-
the ALS is a part of the core of tax treaties. Its adoption lines.184 Some approaches contended in the OECD “Guid-
in numerous tax treaties would condemn any initiative to ance on Transfer Pricing Aspects of Intangibles”185 cannot
make the ALS fail. In addition, while the ALS is compatible be explained, either under the ALS or under any of the
with the principle of equality, any adjustment that disre- alternative proposals addressed in this article. The effects
garded the ALS could be claimed not to be based on ability of this statement cannot be minimized. The approaches
to pay, thereby granting similar tax treatment to incom- suggested in the OECD Guidelines are in breach of the
parable realities. tax treaties to which the Guidelines are intended to apply.
Residual profits do occur. The fact that one state does not The ownership of intangibles is central to the creation of
include them in its tax base does not mean that they are MNEs. Intangibles are assets that cannot be easily replaced
not taxed in the other state. This article does not claim that and must be protected against opportunistic behaviour, as
residual profits should be tax free, but rather that the initial they demand large investments from MNEs with regard to
allocation of the residual profit, ultimately decided by the their production. If the transfer of an intangible among the
taxpayers, cannot be legitimately challenged by any juris- entities of an MNE can be deemed to be essentially a feasi-
diction involved. Due to the principle of equality, a juris- bility issue, as establishing the values of such assets implies
diction may expect that income earned by entities located significant divergence from valuation methods,186 the per-
within its territory be taxed according to the respective ception that MNEs are using intangibles as a means to shift
ability to pay. This is the function of the ALS. Requiring income to tax havens has been sufficient to suggest alterna-
MNEs to pay taxes on income that was not generated by tives that cannot be explained under the ALS. More dra-
entities in a state’ s jurisdiction could be deemed to go matically, the intent behind the BEPS initiative has resulted
beyond a fair share. in solutions that have jeopardized the allocation of income
when applied to situations in which an economic group
Any amount without the ALS refers to income that is not
rightfully intends to retain an asset under the legal own-
clearly derived from the activity of the entity but rather
ership of a subsidiary that has not performed functions
from the group as a whole. There is no reason for one juris-
or contributed assets or other factors that, from the per-
diction to claim to be more entitled to tax this amount
spective of the BEPS initiative, engender the creation of
than other jurisdictions. An allocation would always be
value. These solutions are intended to address situations
arbitrary and not based on economic reasons. Ditz (2015)
in which “(i) intangibles are self-developed by a multina-
refers to the allocation of synergies as a question of value,
tional group, especially when such intangibles are trans-
i.e. Wertungsfrage.183 In other words, the allocation made
ferred between associated enterprises while still under
by jurisdictions would not be better, or worse, than the
development; (ii) acquired or self-developed intangibles
allocation derived from the transaction itself.
serve as a platform for further development; or (iii) other
Of course, neutrality derived from the allocation made aspects, such as marketing or manufacturing are particu-
by the taxpayer may be challenged if such an allocation larly important to value creation”.
implies allocating profits to low-tax jurisdictions. Should
One could imagine the example of a Brazilian indepen-
this be the case, a better solution would be simply to resort
dent company performing the extraction of poison from
to discrimination in respect of jurisdictions whose taxa-
snakes for the sole purpose of producing the relevant
tion is deemed to be “too low”. It is clear that the BEPS
serum to supply Brazilian and Bolivian hospitals with
initiative, by distorting the ALS, wishes to counter behav-
such a remedy. The Brazilian company decides to invest in
iour that the OECD member countries deem to be abusive.
research for substances that can stimulate the production
What cannot be accepted is the drafting of an entire model
of poison by the snakes due to increased demand in the
to counter situations that should be regarded as excep-
local market, which is, perhaps, the sole market for such
tions.
product. For this purpose, as the company cannot under-
It is a fact that hard cases make bad law. With regard to take the research itself, it decides to hire a French labora-
intangibles, as drafted, the concept of the transfer pricing tory, which performs all the functions and provides for all
in relation to the BEPS Action Plans is intended to correct the assets relating to the research. The Brazilian company
a very specific situation that could be resolved by discrim- solely funds the research, assuming, on the other hand,
ination. There is no need to jeopardize the allocation of the risks related to the failure of the research. At the end
income among the entities of an MNE to correct an unde- of the research project, an effective formula is obtained
sirable outcome of the ALS. by the French company, whose rights all legally belong to

184. Robillard, supra n. 60, at p. 447.


185. OECD, G20 Base Erosion and Profit Shifting Project, Guidance on Transfer
Pricing Aspects of Intangibles, Action 8 Deliverable (OECD 2014), Interna-
tional Organizations’ Documentation IBFD.
183. Ditz, supra n. 62, at p. 116. 186. For an extensive analysis of this issue, see Brauner, supra n. 6, at pp. 81-122.

714 BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION DECEMBER 2015 © IBFD

Exported / Printed on 6 June 2016 by biblio1@ibdt.org.br.


Arm’ s Length: Beyond the Guidelines of the OECD

the Brazilian company, as previously agreed by contract. that the legal owner is entitled to any income of the business
According to the ownership clause in the contract, the after compensating other members of the MNE group for their
French company is not entitled to any rights derived from contributions in the form of functions performed, assets used,
the exploitation of the intangible so produced. and risks assumed. That is, after appropriately rewarding
other members of the MNE group for their functions per-
It is possible that a similar situation would arise between
formed, for assets used, and for risks assumed, the income
parties under common control. In the same example, if the
of the legal owner related to the intangible may be posi-
Brazilian company is the subsidiary of a US-based MNE,
tive, negative or zero depending on the facts of the case.”
it is possible that the group as a whole has no interest in
(Emphasis added.)190 Consequently, even if, as in the given
developing the intangible. In this case, the only option
example, the Brazilian company adequately remunerates
for the subsidiary is to fund the research from its own
the French company for the activities performed and
resources. Within this intent, the company may choose
assets used, it may be the case that the Brazilian company
to hire another subsidiary of the group, under the same
is not entitled to benefit from the total rents derived in
conditions described in the uncontrolled example, thereby
the exploitation of the intangible. As drafted,191 the OECD
resulting in the ownership of an intangible for the Brazil-
Report leads to the conclusion that the Brazilian entity
ian subsidiary under the same conditions as in the previ-
should remunerate the French company ad aeternum for
ous example.
the functions performed, the assets used and, eventually,
How would these controlled transactions be treated for for the risks assumed by the French subsidiary. The OECD
transfer pricing purposes? Under the ALS, the French sub- Report is permeated by statements that imply that the Bra-
sidiary should be remunerated equally in both examples if zilian company would never be free from the contract it
the transactions involved are identical. However, in apply- had signed with the French subsidiary, and remuneration
ing the approach suggested by the OECD “Guidance on for the exploitation of the intangible would always be pay-
Transfer Pricing Aspects of Intangibles”, there are reasons able.192
to believe that the taxation of the transaction would be
It is not an exaggeration to say that the OECD Report pro-
distinct in each case.
hibits an ALS-style approach, as “[t]he need to ensure that
The OECD Report puts into perspective the legal own- all members of the MNE group are appropriately compen-
ership of intangibles, taking it as a mere “starting point sated for the functions they perform implies that if the
for any transfer pricing analysis of transactions involving legal owner of intangibles is to be entitled ultimately to
intangibles”.187 According to the proposal, “legal owner- retain all of the returns derived from exploitation of the
ship of intangibles, by itself, does not confer any right ulti- intangibles it must perform all of the functions, contribute
mately to retain returns derived by the MNE group from all assets used and assume all risks related to the develop-
exploiting the intangible”.188 The OECD suggests that “[t] ment, enhancement, maintenance, protection and exploi-
he return ultimately retained by or attributed to the legal tation of the intangible”. In other words, if the entity wishes
owner depends upon the functions it performs, the assets to retain all of the rents derived in the future exploitation of
it uses, and the risks it assumes, and upon the contribu- the intangible, it must do everything by itself. Otherwise,
tions made by other MNE group members through their it would always owe something to a related party.
functions performed, assets used, and risks assumed”. The
The BEPS initiative also risks creating uncertainty with
OECD Report even provides the example of an internally
regard to “unanticipated ex post returns”. In the example,
developed intangible where the legal owner performs no
one can imagine an event in which a third party, unre-
functions, uses no assets and bears no risks, i.e. in the case
lated to the MNE, discovers an extremely successful cos-
that it will not be entitled to “any portion of the return
metic application for the snake poison. Consequently, if,
derived by the MNE group from the exploitation of the
in principle, the intangible developed is of restricted use,
intangible other than arm’ s length compensation, if any,
solely relevant for the Brazilian and Bolivian local market,
for holding title”.189
the situation could change, and an Italian subsidiary of
In this example, the application of the approach sug- the MNE could decide to engage in the production of the
gested in the OECD “Guidance on Transfer Pricing cosmetic.
Aspects of Intangibles” implies that, for transfer pricing
It may sound obvious that the Brazilian subsidiary would
purposes, the Brazilian company should not be entitled
derive significant benefits from the supervening event, as
to the total of rents derived from the exploitation of the
the Italian subsidiary would be interested in paying for
intangible. In particular, it is considered that “[a]s stated
the outcome of the intangible produced and the Brazilian
above, a determination that a particular group member
company would be the legal owner of the intangible, as it
is the legal owner of intangibles does not, in and of itself,
imply that the member has the right ultimately to retain
or have attributed to it the receipts that may accrue in the 190. Id., at p. 43, para. 6.47.
first instance to that member as a result of its commercial 191. Id.
192. Id., at p. 49, para. 6.63, for example, according to which: “[t]he identity
right to exploit the intangible, nor does it necessarily imply of the member or members of the group bearing and controlling risks
related to the development, enhancement, maintenance, protection, and
exploitation of intangibles is also an important consideration in deter-
187. OECD, supra n. 185, at p. 40, para. 6.35. mining prices for controlled transactions and in determining which entity
188. Id., at pp. 41-42, para. 6.42. or entities will be entitled to share in returns derived from the exploita-
189. Id. tion of the intangibles”.

© IBFD BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION DECEMBER 2015 715

Exported / Printed on 6 June 2016 by biblio1@ibdt.org.br.


Luís Eduardo Schoueri

had funded the development of the asset at arm’ s length. regarding synergy rents and intangibles are not supported
However, some statements in the OECD proposal demand by the ALS. On the contrary, they significantly deviate
a second look. Under the OECD proposal, the entities ben- from merely determining what independent parties would
efiting from unanticipated ex post returns “may or may not have done.
be the legal owner of the intangible, and may or may not
The RFM, as proposed in this article, is a practicable ALS-
be the entity or entities providing funding for the develop-
based alternative that could resolve several of the feasibil-
ment, enhancement, maintenance, protection, or exploita-
ity problems addressed. In addition, from a global per-
tion of the intangible”.193
spective, which must include the realities of developing
As previously noted, if the problem faced by the BEPS ini- countries, the RFM implies legal certainty, which is essen-
tiative is the allocation of profits to low-tax jurisdictions, tial for promoting foreign direct investment. The theo-
discrimination against such jurisdictions could be an alter- retical framework provided is intended to create a path
native to the BEPS solution to intangibles. This solution for further ALS-based alternatives to transfer pricing
cannot be derived from a correct application of the ALS methods, taking into account the diversity of interests and
and can, therefore, hardly be justified under the principle level of development observed among states in the current
of equality. international situation.
After all, from the taxpayer’ s perspective, the issue of the
6. Conclusions
fairness of the allocation of tax revenues between states is
As academics and practitioners have failed to come up generally irrelevant. The primary concern of taxpayers is
with acceptable innovative alternatives to transfer pricing, certainty. In the struggle between states for tax revenue,
the ALS remains the cornerstone of the international tax the interests of taxpayers are those that are sacrificed the
regime in respect of controlled transactions. Recent devel- most. Due to the lack of a solution to the issue of inclusion
opments with regard to transfer pricing have exposed how of profits in article 9(1) of the OECD Model, if states dis-
harmful it may be to maintain the ALS only in theory. Such agree, the taxpayer is the one that suffers the consequences.
a distortion could result in the allocation of taxing rights
that significantly depart from what the contracting states It is important to note that the RFM, as proposed in this
have agreed on when concluding a tax treaty. It is clear article, derives from the Brazilian practice, but this does
that an ambulatory interpretation that envisages consen- not mean that the author subscribes to the current Bra-
sus where only conflict exists lacks legitimacy. The agree- zilian experience. As a result, the issues of rebuttable pre-
ment proposed by the OECD cannot be realized by inter- sumptions and the reasonability of the fixed margins still
pretation alone. cannot be regarded as a standard in Brazil. Tax admin-
istrations are still very reluctant to discuss reasonable
The original intent of transfer pricing legislation and, margins that would be different from those determined
therefore, of the application of the ALS, must be pre- by law. However, when one considers the initial rejection
served. Transfer pricing rules are intended to determine to all solutions without the OECD Guidelines, it should
the entities’ taxable (market) income according to their be noted that the Brazilian experience demonstrates that
ability to pay, but the amendments to the OECD Guide- the ALS could be interpreted differently, which could
lines proposed in the BEPS initiative go far beyond such offer interesting results. The mere fact that the OECD has
determination. been more flexible regarding unorthodox standards, for
In his report, Mitchell Carroll posed a strongly rhetorical example, the adoption of safe harbours, could indicate that
question to build the argument in favour of the ALS. While alternatives may be under consideration.
the question was primarily an argument against FA, it can This article does not argue that reform of the current trans-
be reproduced generally with regard to any and every con- fer pricing standards is unnecessary but rather that an
sensual approach. The question posed was “[w]ill coun- ambulatory interpretation, mainly in the aggressive form
tries in which profits have clearly accrued agree to giving intended by the BEPS initiative, is not a desirable way to
up a part or all of such profits as a result of an apportion- proceed in promoting structural modifications to the in-
ment of the total net income or loss of the enterprise?” ternational tax regimes adopted worldwide. This article
If at that time, “[t]he great majority of administrations have has demonstrated that, although the ALS may have some
definitely indicated that they would not”, there are reasons flaws, the alternatives proposed by the BEPS initiative do
to believe that the BEPS initiative is intended to change not appear to be better and would require a consensus
the answer to the question. By subscribing to the current that does not seem to be possible in the near future. It is
OECD proposals in the BEPS initiative, many states have true that transfer pricing should be evaluated without the
already agreed to give up tax revenue without any support OECD Guidelines, but one should further consider that
from tax treaties. The content currently attributed to the international taxation as a whole must find its own legiti-
ALS in the OECD Reports goes far beyond the original macy outside of the OECD arena. A sincere evaluation of
intent of transfer pricing legislation, and there is no reason the justice of the current international tax regime can only
to believe that states had such a meaning in mind when be undertaken if the interests of non-OECD countries are
concluding tax treaties. Specifically, the OECD proposals taken into account. The addition of a G20 label to the BEPS
initiative has contributed very little in terms of promoting
such an inclusion.
193. Id., at p. 50, para. 6.67.

716 BULLETIN FOR INTERNATIONAL TAXATION DECEMBER 2015 © IBFD

Exported / Printed on 6 June 2016 by biblio1@ibdt.org.br.

You might also like