Why The "Hot Hand" May Be Real After All

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 3

Jeffrey Zwiebel: Why the “Hot Hand” May Be Real After All

A Stanford finance professor finds that hot streaks in sports are no illusion. Economists should
take heed.

By Edmund L. Andrews
March 25, 2014

Sports fans, rejoice: You may have been right all along about hot streaks. They aren't a figment of
your imagination.

Contradicting academic studies dating back 30 years, researchers at Stanford, Berkeley, and
Harvard are now finding that a "hot hand" in basketball or baseball is not a statistical illusion. In
fact, hot streaks can help predict a player's likelihood of getting another hit or sinking another
basket.

Perhaps surprisingly, this has implications for a raging debate in finance about the rationality, or
lack of it, in markets.

But first, about the sports.

Athletes, coaches, and sports fans overwhelmingly believe in the "hot hand," the idea that a
player whose shooting percentage is higher than normal is likely to keep shooting better than
normal — at least for a while. Indeed, coaches often rotate players in and out of play based on a
sense of who has turned hot or cold.

Academic scholars thought they had debunked this idea years ago. Starting with a famous 1985
study of basketball shooting, experts have argued in dozens of papers that the hot hand is nothing
more than statistical noise. Athletes may seem to go on hot streaks, goes the argument, but these
are just random fluctuations without predictive value. People who believe in hot hands, the
skeptics have argued, are seeing patterns that don't exist.

But in a major new study of baseball data, Jeffrey Zwiebel at Stanford Graduate School of
Business and Brett Green at University of California's Haas School of Business at Berkeley find
that hot hands are real and have predictive power.

Why would business professors jump into a sports debate? Because the "hot-hand fallacy" has
become a staple in arguments by supporters of behavioral economics to argue that individuals can
be irrational. For example, the behaviorists have argued that investors often get lured into bad
decisions by seeing patterns that aren't real. According to the behaviorists, investors make a wide
range of cognitive mistakes that range from overconfidence in their own abilities to a tendency to
over-react to news.

That critique gained a lot of traction in the wake of the mortgage bust and the great financial
crisis. A 2009 paper lays out the theory and potential financial applications of the hot-hand
fallacy. A 2012 paper argues that the hot-hand fallacy explains why people pay for useless
investment advice. And in a brand new paper, German scholars even found evidence that people
who believe in the hot-hand fallacy are more at risk of long-term unemployment.

The hot-hand "fallacy" has its own roots at Stanford. Thomas Gilovich, a graduate student in the
early 1980s, began comparing the widespread perception of hot streaks in basketball to the hard
data. Gilovich, now at Cornell, led a study showing that the hot hand didn't really exist: The
shooting records of the Philadelphia 76ers provided no predictive value of subsequent shots. A
player might be hot one minute, but not the next. Fans and even sports professionals, they
concluded, were making decisions based on myopic impressions.

Zwiebel and Green argue that the original finding failed to account for a key issue. In basketball,
the opposing team quickly adjusts to a "hot" player, devoting extra coverage and forcing that
player to attempt more difficult shots. As a result, it's inevitable that a hot player's shooting
percentage will decline. It's not because the hot streak was an illusion, but rather that the hot
player attracted more opposition.

Baseball is different, because pitchers and coaches have very limited ability to re-deploy
resources against a hitter on a hot streak. Pitchers and coaches do play to a hitter's particular
weaknesses, but they can't put more people in the hitter's way.

To test their ideas, Zwiebel and Green amassed data on 2 million Major League Baseball at-bats
over 12 years. They looked at 10 categories of performance, from batting averages and home-run
percentages to strike-out rates. For pitchers, they looked at data such as the average number of
hits allowed. They also controlled for the fundamental ability of both pitchers and hitters, in order
to isolate the actual "streakiness" of a player's performance.

The result: A player's most recent 25 times at bat was a significant predictor of how that player
would do at his next time up — good enough to justify an adaptive reaction by coaches. When a
player is "hot," the researchers calculated, his expected on-base percentage will be 25 to 30 points
higher than it would be if he just has been "cold." Similarly, a player on a hot streak will be 30%
more likely to hit a home run than if he has been on a cold streak.

"These results are important enough to rationalize common coaching decisions and fan
perceptions with respect to hot players," Zwiebel and Green write in their paper.

Zwiebel says the earlier researchers were too quick to conclude that the belief in a hot hand was
evidence of a cognitive or behavioral mistake. Most likely, what's really at work is not so much a

“Jeffrey Zwiebel: Why the “Hot Hand” May Be Real After All” Page 2
mistake but an "equilibrium adjustment" around the hot-handed player — similar to the kinds of
equilibrium adjustments that occur in finance and economics.

"The behavioral camp jumps too quickly to the conclusion that almost all sports fans and
participants are under a dumb illusion that there are hot hands," Zwiebel says. "They have jumped
to that conclusion because it fits their story that everyone is making cognitive mistakes and that
these mistakes are extraordinarily pervasive."

As it happens, a team of Harvard researchers reached a similar conclusion in a new study of


basketball. The Harvard team looked at data on 83,000 shots made during the National Basketball
Association's 2012-2013 season. But instead of looking simply at completion rates, the
researchers built a model for gauging the difficulty of shots. They found that players who had
exceeded their expectations in recent shots were likely to face tighter opposition and take more
difficult shots. Adjusting for the increased difficulty of the shots, the researchers found that hot
players were likely to continue outperforming. The "hot-hand effect," they estimated, raised their
chances of making a shot by 1.2% to 2.4%.

Zwiebel's larger point is that behaviorists use the supposed hot-hand fallacy to jump to
unwarranted conclusions. They see cognitive mistakes everywhere they look. The problem, he
argues, is that the misdiagnosis of a problem — such as the mortgage bust — can lead to the
wrong remedies.

Investment bankers have been criticized for underestimating the risks of subprime mortgages, for
being irrational in their optimism. But it's possible that their excessive risk-taking wasn't
irrational as much as it was encouraged or even subsidized by regulatory policies, such as those
that protected banks considered "too big to fail." The difference between those two diagnoses of
the financial crisis leads to very different proposals for reform.

"One can portray the financial crisis as being triggered by a bunch of mistakes, or one can portray
it as the consequence of risky decisions that were made based on the incentives and subsidies in
the system," he says. "I see it as more of the latter."

“Jeffrey Zwiebel: Why the “Hot Hand” May Be Real After All” Page 3

You might also like