Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 20

Strategic Management Journal, Vol.

17, 139-157 (1996)

/ THE RED QUEEN IN ORGANIZATIONAL


EVOLUTION
WILLIAM P. BARNETI
Graduate School of Business, Stanford University, Stanford, California, U.S.A.

MORTEN T. HANSEN
Graduate School of Business, Harvard University, Boston, Massachusetts, U.S.A.

We propose that competitive success and failure evolve through an ecology of organizational
learning. An organization fa cing competition is likely to engage in a search for ways to
improve performance. When successf ul. this search results in learning that is likely to increase
the organization's competitive strength, which in tum triggers learning in its rivals-
consequently making them stronger competitors and so again triggering learning in the first
organization. We elaborate the conditions under which this self-reinforcing process, known in
evolutionary theory as the 'Red Queen.' is likely to be adaptive or maladaptive. Adaptive
consequences are predicted only for recently experienced learning. Experience in the more
distant past of an organization 's life, by contrast, is predicted to backfire into a 'competency
trap. ' We predict maladaptive consequences when organizations fa ce many, varied cohorts of
rivals. We empirically distinguish these effects using ecological models of competition. Estimates
of organizational failure rates reveal a Red Queen among Illinois banks, and support our predic-
tions.

Given a set of competing organizations, which ing and control (Sayle s, 1964). Consequently,
will succeed? This question is fundamental to the many aspects of an organization's strategy emerge
field of strategic management, but it is difficult from day-to-day adjustments in organizational
to answer because it requires that we consider routines, often deviating considerably from formal
both the complexity of strategic interaction and strategic plans (Mintzberg and McHugh, 1985).
the limitations of the strategy process. On the How can we predict the outcome of competitive
one hand, competing organizations often engage interactions among such organizations?
in complex strategic interactions, with outcomes In this paper, we develop and test an evolution-
depending not just on what a firm does, but on ary model to answer this question. Our model
what a firm does given what another will do, allows for competitive interaction among organi-
given what it will do, etc. (Dixit and Nalebuff, zations that are limited in their ability to strate-
1991; Saloner, 1991). On the other hand, we gize . In particular, we assume that an organization
know that organizations are extremely limited in facing competition is likely to respond, but that
their ability to cope with such complexity. Strat- its response is likely to be limited-merely 'satis-
egies develop over time through organizational ficing' through a localized search and decision
processes (Barnard, 1938; Bower, 1970; Burgel- process (March and Simon, 1958). This response
man, 1994), and managers are constrained by then marginally increases the competition faced
past organizational practices as they deal daily by the organization's rivals, triggering in them a
with circumstances often beyond their understand- similar process of search and decision-which
ultimately increases the competitive pressures
Key words: strategic management; competition; faced by the first organization. This again triggers
organizational evolution; organizational learning; the search for improvements in the first organiza-
organizational ecology tion, and so the cycle continues . We think that

CCC 0143-2095/96/S 10139-19


© 1996 by John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
140 W. P. Barnett and M. T. Hansen

this reciprocal system of causality, known in AN ECOLOGY OF LEARNING


evolutionary theory as the 'Red Queen' (Van ORGANIZATIONS
Valen, 1973), I is a central, driving force behind
the evolution of competitive success and failure. We assume that strategies develop under uncer-
Our aim is to demonstrate this theoretically and tain conditions and that organizations possess lim-
empirically. ited ex ante rationality (March and Simon, 1958).
For years, researchers in strategy and organiza- Consequently strategies often emerge over time
tions have been intrigued by various aspects of from an accumulation of incremental adjustments
the Red Queen. Evolutionary theorists have noted rather than through a comprehensive strategic
that an organization's 'fitness' is best understood plan (Quinn, 1980; Mintzberg and McHugh,
as relative to that of other organizations (Alchian, 1985). These adjustments may be policy changes
1950; Nelson and Winter, 1982; Hannan and made by top-level managers, but often they
Freeman, 1984), or as something that 'coevolves' include changes initiated at low levels as well
among organizations (Fombrun, 1988). Others (Burgelman, 1994). This view of the strategy
claim that the success and failure of entire process is elaborated in the behavioral model of
national industries can be traced, at least in part, organizational learning developed by James
to whether or not they have endured competition March (1981, 1988) and his colleagues. The most
(Lawrence and Dyer, 1983; Porter, 1990) . Such important parts of that model, for our purposes,
claims imply that Red Queen evolution is ubiqui- are its rules for starting and stopping the search
tously adaptive, but what about the limitations for new routines . Organizational routines that per-
of the strategy process? How are organizations form satisfactorily probably are left alone, so no
constrained when they respond to competition, search for improvements is triggered even if bet-
and what are the consequences of these con- ter practices could be found. But when perform-
straints for Red Queen evolution? We need a ance falls below some acceptable range, members
predictive model that links competition and of the organization notice the problem and then
organizational learning, but that allows for organi- search for possible solutions. This search con-
zations to be constrained in their ability to adapt. tinues until a satisfactory solution (if any) is
To develop such a model, we draw on existing found, at which point the improvement is likely
research in organizational learning (March, 1988) to be adopted by the organization.' Over time ,
and organizational ecology (Hannan and Freeman, an organization's activities and abilities-its de
1989). The resulting synthesi s describes Red facto strategy-change through incremental adap-
Queen evolution within an ecology of learning tations in response to environmentally triggered
organizations. By building on these two well- shortfalls in performance.
developed schools of thought, we are able to We also assume that search and learning are
predict the conditions under which Red Queen costly. It is costly to discover alternatives,
evolution leads to adaptive or maladaptive conse- especially when they require research and devel-
quences for particular organizations-depending opment of new technologies. Of course, it also
on measurable evolutionary constraints. Our is costly to implement new products, product
approach also allows us to specify these con- attributes, services, and routines (Nelson and
ditions as testable propositions, and to estimate Winter, 1982). Aside from the costs of changing
rates of success and failure among a population the content of organizational activity, change per
of organizations that both learn to compete over se is costly because of disruptions in existing
time . organizational procedures to which members and
external constituents must adjust (Hannan and
Freeman , 1984; Barnett and Carroll, 1995).
On balance, whether organizational learning is
I Van Valen ( 1973) coined the term Red Queen when intro-
ducing this idea to the study of biological evolution. He was 2 The particulars of any solution are changed during
referring to Lewis Carroll's Through the Looking Glass, where implementation. so that what ends up being adopted may be
Alice notices that she appears to be stationary even though different from the solution originally intended. Given the fact
she is running a race. The Red Queen's response is that Alice that there is usually considerable ambiguity about what
must be from a slow world, since in a fast world one must accounts for good performance, such alterations may in fact
run just to stay still. tum out to be adaptive (March, 1981).
Red Queen in Organizational Evolution 141

adaptive depends on whether its results are suf- Once search is ended, we usually consider
ficiently beneficial to offset these costs. As a the learning episode to be complete, but when
baseline, we begin by assuming that organiza- competition is the initial trigger the episode con-
tional learning is adaptive on average. This tinues . Alpha has improved its practices in
assumption allows for the fact that some searches response to the shortfall caused by Beta . Its
are not fruitful, that some adjustments are ineffec- improvement, in turn, places greater competitive
tive, and that some changes incur costs that out- pressure on Beta. If strong enough , this pressure
weigh their benefits . It stipulates only that, on will cause a shortfall in performance within Beta
average, organizations tend to adopt changes with sufficient to trigger its own problemistic search,
benefits that outweigh their costs. This assumption which continues until Beta locates satisfactory
allows us to develop baseline predictions for the improvements. These improvements then again
case where Red Queen evolution is an adaptive heat up the competitive pressure on Alpha, and
process. We then investigate evolutionary con- if this competition is sufficiently strong, Alpha
ditions under which this assumption does not again searches for satisfactory improvements in
hold, and so Red Queen evolution is likely to its own practices . In this way, competition trig-
be maladaptive. gers self-reinforcing, reciprocal effects in an ecol-
ogy of learning organizations.
Because it is self-reinforcing, the Red Queen
THE RED QUEEN AS AN ADAPTIVE probably is an important stimulus to strategic
PROCESS evolution. Ordinarily, disequilibrium and organi-
zational change are thought to be triggered by
Typically learning theorists do not specify what large-scale exogenous shocks such as political
causes the initial shortfall in performance that upheaval (Carroll and Delacroix, 1982), techno-
then triggers search. Instead they assume that logical advances (Tushman and Anderson, 1986),
these initial causes are exogenous to the learning or regulatory change (Barnett and Carroll, 1993).
process-a reasonable assumption because these Of course such changes are important to organiza-
causes often are external to the organization. tions, but the changes occur as singular-albeit
We think, however, that one potential cause of dramatic-episodes. By contrast , the Red Queen
performance problems, competition from other emphasizes competition as a force continually
organizations, should be thought of differently. upsetting equilibrium-not necessarily through
Even though competition is external to a given anyone great shock to the system but rather by
organization, it is best understood as part of the an incremental but constant and self-reinforcing
organization's learning process. process. In evolutionary perspective such self-
Consider an organizaton 'Alpha' that faces reinforcing processes, sometimes referred to as
competition from organization 'Beta. ' If Beta 'arms races ' (Dawkins, 1982), can result in
competes strongly enough, some aspects of important long-term developments even though
Alpha's functioning will no longer be able to each individual adaptive change may be small.
bring about satisfactory results. For example, a 'Incremental' change usually is thought to mean
new retail bank may draw customers away from small change, but each small change within the
an incumbent bank in its local market. If this Red Queen triggers the next, accumulating over
competition is strong enough, performance short- time into a potentially large evolutionary differ-
falls will be noticed within the incumbent bank: ence.
demand-deposit customers may be leaving, or This process describes strategic interaction
new loan application rates may fall. These short- among organizations, but it does so without
falls, in tum, are likely to trigger action by the depicting organizations as instruments of top
incumbent to stem the problem, such as visits management strategists. In some cases, responses
to potential commercial borrowers, changes in to competition may well be the deliberate acts of
customer service routines, or changes in product top managers. Through the Red Queen, however,
prices or characteristics. This search will continue ordinary day-to-day reactions to tactical problems
until satisfactory performance levels are regained by lower-level employees accumulate over time.
(or, failing this, until performance expectations Search may lead to a changed routine in customer
are lowered). service or a minor alteration in manufacturing
142 W. P. Barnett and M. T. Hansen

specifications. Such changes may set in motion of competition by including measures of the 'den-
corresponding changes by rivals-which in turn sity' (numbers) of rivals in models of organiza-
may trigger the organization's next changes. In tional founding and failure (Hannan and Freeman,
this way, our model describes strategic interac- 1989; Hannan and Carroll , 1992). Generalizations
tion among competing organizational systems. of this approach allow the strength of competition
Organizations coevolve through these reciprocal to depend on rivals' characteristics, such as their
interactions, developing strategic capabilities ages, sizes, or strategies (Barnett, 1993, 1996).
whether or not by the design of strategic man- In light of our arguments, this approach should
agers. be extended so that the strength of competition
Although potentially important, the Red Queen faced by an organization varies according to its
has eluded systematic analysis because it consists rivals' mean competitive experience. If the Red
of two opposing effects that are likely to disguise Queen is adaptive, then more experienced rivals
one another. On the one hand, the adaptation of will generate stronger competition, implying that
an organization to competitive pressures increases organizations with more experienced rivals will
its resilience, making it better able to perform in be less viable.
the face of competition. On the other hand, the
organization's rivals also have adapted, and so
are stronger competitors. Greater resilience would EVOLUTIONARY CONSTRAINTS AND
increase an organization's performance; more THE MALADAPTIVE RED QUEEN
potent rivals would decrease its performance.
Together, these effects potentially mask one So far we have assumed that the costs of search
another when we observe descriptions of organi- and learning are, on average, outweighed by the
zational performance over time. Assuming that benefits. This assumption is implicit in theories
learning is adaptive, an organization becomes bet- that depict evolution as a consistently improving
ter at serving the market -but so do its rivals- force (Nelson, 1994).3 In the strategy field, this
so observations of organizational performance assumption is the basis of theories that describe
wrongly tell us that nothing has changed. competition as a cause of evolutionary progress-
To study the Red Queen empirically, we need especially in accounts of national economic suc-
to separate these two opposing effects. Each cess and failure (Lawrence and Dyer, 1983;
organization's competitive history needs to be Porter, 1990). This assumption is useful to elabo-
measured, and then this variable can be allowed rate a baseline model, but it does not consider
to have two distinct effects in an empirical model. how constraints may affect organizational evol-
First, each organization's competitive history ution. Unconstrained, organizations may well
should affect its own viability (Barnett, Greve, adopt changes that improve their viability on
and Park, 1994). For instance, suppose one average. A fundamental insight of the evolution-
organization has faced its rivals for a mean dur- ary perspective, however, is that each organization
ation of 8 years per competitive relationship, is constrained by its history. We consider two
whereas a similar second organization of the same such constraints here in order to predict the con-
age has competed with its rivals on average for ditions under which Red Queen evolution is likely
only 2 years. Standard models of organizational to have maladaptive consequences.
viability, such as models of failure, growth, or First, organizations are constrained by lessons
performance, would depict these two organiza- learned in the past. The most notorious form of
tions as equally viable because they are similar historical constraint is the 'competence trap'
and of the same age. If the Red Queen is an (Levitt and March, 1988). Organizations under
adaptive process , however, then the first organiza- this condition respond to new developments using
tion is likely to be more viable than the second , routines that were learned under a previous
because the mean duration of its competitive regime, harming their performance by doing pre-
relationships is longer. cisely what worked well under different circum-
Second, and distinctly, the competitive history stance s.
of each organization's rivals should also affect
the organization's viability (Barnett, 1996). Typi- 3 Gould and Lewontin (1979) coined the term ' Panglossian'
cally, researchers model the evolutionary effects to describe similar theories in evolutionary biology.
Red Queen in Organizational Evolution 143

In light of the Red Queen, we speculate that A second constraint arises when organizations
this trap may be deepen ed by mutual reinforce- are engaged in more than one coevolutionary
ment in an ecology of organizational learning. process. An organi zation facing a single cohort
For instance, established firms have been known of rivals shares with them the same timing and
to collectively deny the possibility that new prac- sequence of strategic interaction s. But what if an
tices and technologies are changing the basis of organi zation has developed within a cohort of
competition in an industry, preferring instead to rivals for some time, but then is confronted with
stay with well-learned but outdated practices new rivals that do not share the organization' s
(Cole, 1996). More generally, as time passes and coevolutionary history? According to our model ,
circumstances change, what was learned in a Red the organization can be expected to enter into a
Queen durin g the previous era may end up harm- new Red Queen process with the new rivals. But
ing organizations although it had once worked to the organization has already evolved, adaptin g to
their advantage (Barnett, Greve, and Park, 1994). competition from others. Adaptati ons made in
This implies that we specify the historical tim- that process represent constraint s, preventing
ing of comp etitive experiences when modeling some forms of adaptation to its new rivals
this proce ss. For recent competitive experience, (Schumpeter, 1934). Similarly , adaptations to its
we continue to assume that the benefits of learn- new rivals may require alterations in adaptati ons
ing are likely to outwei gh the costs. By contra st, made to its earlie r rivals-as when adopting a
we speculate that an organi zation' s experiences new technology destroys existing competen cies
in the more distant past are more likely to have (Tushman and Anderson, 1986 ). In this way,
taught now-outdated lessons. Together these ideas each cohort of rivals brings on the challenge of
suggest both adaptive and maladaptive conse- a new Red Queen, but adaptations made for
quences of competitive experience, depending on each cohort constrain those that can be made
historical timing: for others.
This constraint increases in severity according
Hypothe sis la: A longer mean duration of to the variety of coevolutionary proces ses faced
an organization's competitive relationships in by an organiz ation. An organization facing only
recent times increases its viability. one cohort of rivals can freely coevolve with
them , whereas an organizati on facing several
Hypothesis 1b: A longer mean duration of cohorts-especially cohorts separated by large
an organization 's competi tive relationships in time periods-is likely to face very different and
the distant past decreases its viability. possibly conflicting demands. This suggests that
we distinguish between organizations accordin g
Simil arly, we expect that the strength of rivalry to the variance, as well as the mean, of their
hinges on the same difference in historical timing. competitive experiences. For instance, two organi-
Rivals with more recent competitive experience zations might each have 10 rivals, and each
are likely to be more potent competitors, but we organization might have endured these 10 com-
predict that the opposite will be true of organiza- petitive relationships for the same mean
tions whose competiti ve experience was in the duration-say, 12 years. But say that the first of
distant past. They are more likely to have learned these organizations has been competing with ri-
outdated lessons, and so should be weaker com- vals all from the same cohort-competing with
petitors: everyone of its rivals for 12 years with no
variance among these relationships. By contrast,
Hypothesis 2a: A longer mean durat ion of the second organiz ation might be competing with
the competitive relationships experienced by rivals from variou s cohorts-some that arrived
an organization 's rivals in recent times only I or 2 years ago but other s that have been
decreases the organization's viability. rivals with the organization for decade s. The
mean duration s of these organizations' competi-
Hypothesis 2b: A longer mean duration of tive relationships are equal , but their experiences
the competitive relationships experienced by differ greatly according to the variance in these
an organization's rivals in the distant past durations.
increases the organization 's viability. Controlling for the number and mean duration
144 W. P. Barnett and M. T. Hansen

of competitive relationships, we expect the vari- Differences among organizations would then arise
ance in competitive relationships to reflect mainly at the time of founding (Stinchcombe,
increasing constraints among multiple coevo- 1965), or possibly over time as changes arise
lutionary processes. Each constraint lowers the essentially at random (Levinthal, 1991). If we
probability that an organization can locate and assume that selection processes favor relatively
adopt an adaptive solution to any given competi- more fit organizations, then even under these
tive threat. As these constraints mount, then, it assumptions the survivors of competition would
becomes increasingly unlikely that the benefits of be more fit. But these relatively more fit survivors
adaptation will be sufficient to outweigh the costs would not have learned from competition. They
of search . Consequently, we predict: were more fit to begin with, or became that way
as luck would have it, and survived competition
Hypothesis 3: The greater the variance in as a consequence. In this case, spurious evidence
the durations of an organization's competitive of the Red Queen might be found even in the
relationships, the lower its viability. absence of organizational learning.
We have no doubt that such selection takes
In sum, each organization can be thought of place, but we think that learning takes place too.
as being involved in a number of competitive In our view, models of organizational evolution
relationships. The history of these relationships should allow for the fact that both selection and
can be described for each organization at each learning operate , as do models of cultural evo-
point in time according to an experience distri- lution (e .g., Boyd and Richerson, 1985). In this
bution. The density of competitors reflects just spirit, we treat the question of selection vs. learn-
one aspect of an organization's experience distri- ing as an empirical one, explicitly modeling each
bution: its number of competitive relationships. possibility. This choice requires that we dis-
But density says nothing about the evolutionary tinguish organizations according to the extent to
history of these relationships. Three additional which each is a survivor. Purely selection-driven
variables describe the historical differences among evolution will vary from context to context
organizations' experience distributions: (l) the according to the observed selection rate, which
mean duration of each organization's competitive will be included in our model as a distinct effect.
relationships, measuring how much experience The full model, then, allows for the observed
each organization has had per relationship; (2) distribution of organizations to change both
the historical timing of that experience, which through organizational learning and as a result of
separates the amount of competitive experience selection processe s (Barnett et al., 1994).
according to whether it occurred recently or in
the more distant past; and (3) the variance in
durations of an organization's relationships, gaug- STRATEGIES THAT INHIBIT
ing whether an organization's relationships have COEVOLUTION
been coincident or whether they have been spread
among different cohorts of rivals. We argue that To this point, we have assumed that organizations
each of these properties of the experience distri- respond to their rivals by attempting to outcom-
bution has theoretical significance, and that all pete them. If managers become aware of competi-
three together should be modeled empirically in tive threats, however, they may take strategic
order to reveal both the adaptive and maladaptive actions to lessen rivalry (Porter, 1980). For
consequences of the Red Queen. instance, multimarket organizations may mutually
forbear from competing with one another-
eliminating the engine of Red Queen evolution
SELECTION PROCESSES (Barnett et al., 1994). Alternatively, strategic
alliances among rivals may serve as a mechanism
We introduce selection processes into our model to coordinate their adjustments to one another.
by allowing selection to serve as an alternative Many scholars rationalize such action as ben-
to learning . One could assume that the forces of eficial for the collective fate of cooperating
structural inertia make organizations extremely organizations. In fact, cooperation often is
unlikely to adapt (Hannan and Freeman, 1984). intended to enhance learning among organiza-
Red Queen in Organizational Evolution 145

tions. By reducing compennon, however, such ure rate using a multivariate model so that we can
arrangements may eliminate the self-reinforcing test the hypotheses simultaneously and control for
learning process that we describe. other variables likely to affect survival chances.
Similarly, mergers and acquisitions by organi- To test the hypotheses, each organization's
zations may be targeted especially to eliminate relationship with each of its rivals was measured
the most potent rivals faced by organizations in years and denoted by Tjk, the time that organi-
(Pfeffer and Salancik, 1978). Over time, organi- zation j was exposed to competition from rival
zations taking this strategy in response to rivalry k. Organization j's experience distribution, then,
may still have what appear to be competitive is just the distribution of its Tjk over all rivals k,
relationships, but the remaining rivals will be with a mean represented by J.1j and variance equal
their most impotent competitors. Such an outcome
directly contradicts our predictions-as it should,
to a} = 2: (TjcJ.1Y . The hypotheses require that
k
given that this sort of strategic action is meant we distinguish between j's experience in recent
to eliminate the competitive force responsible for time and its competitive experience from long
accelerating evolution. ago. To do this, we divided Tjk into two terms,
For this reason, empirical evolutionary models T Rjk representing organization j's recent exposure
should control for business policies that inhibit to rival k, and T p j k measuring j's exposure to
the Red Queen. Such policies may differ from rival k in the distant past. For Illinois banks in
context to context depending on the particular this century, we chose 10 years as a cutoff point
strategic configurations that exist. For instance, for defining these two variables. We judged this
organizations that rely on research and develop- window to be sufficient to represent 'recency' as
ment may benefit from patent races. If so, then it is understood within banking. That means that
our predictions are likely to hold-except for for any given rival k, j's recent-experience clock
organizations that pursue a strategy of coordinat- TR;k will tick until it reaches 10 years and then
ing R&D in such a way that it eliminates this sort maintain that value until the sample period ends
of competition. In other contexts, other business or either j or k fails or otherwise disappears.
policies will be more relevant to the particular After 10 years, the distant-experience clock TDjk
kinds of competition involved. Here, we study then begins to tick, recording with each additional
retail banks in Illinois. where over the study year the number of years of competitive experi-
period of this century merger and acquisition ence between j and k before the IO-year window.
activity occurred relatively often. Consequently, To test the hypotheses, means were then con-
we will distinguish empirically between organiza- structed for each organization for each of these
tions according to how frequently they purchased competitive experience clocks: J.1RI and J.1nj' The
their rivals, in case this eliminated precisely their hyoptheses also require that we create variables
most threatening-and stimulating-competitors. representing. for each organization j, the competi-
Whether the net effect of such action increased tive experience of its rivals. We created these
or reduced viability is not clear. Nonetheless, we rivals' experience measures again using the 10-
need to control for organizations that take strat- year window to measure recent and distant
egies designed to preclude the Red Queen, as this
difference among organizations might otherwise
experience, respectively: 2: J.1Rb 2: J.1m·
U j Uj
generate biased results for the other parameters Together these terms constitute the failure rate
of our model. model to be estimated:

r(t)j = rUr exp[a RJ.1Rj + aDJ.1Pj + ba]


EMPIRICAL MODEL
+ cR 2: J.1Rk + cn 2: k*j J.1IJk)
The hypotheses are stated in terms of effects on krj

'viability.' We operationalize this concept here as


organizational failure rates, although one could where r( t)j is the failure rate of organization j, t
adapt the model to predict rates of organizational is organizational age, and rU)/ is the baseline
founding, growth, or performance (e.g., Barnett failure rate including the effects of all control
et al., 1994). We specify the organizational fail- variables. The rate is specified as a log-linear
146 W. P. Barnett and M. T. Hansen

function of the variables in order to avoid the tors over time, so that an organization facing
estimation of meaningless, negative failure rates. older rivals will be less viable. In light of the
Hypothesis Ia is supported if recent experience Red Queen, whether an organization's rivals are
enhances viability, such that QR<O. By contrast, stronger competitors should depend not just on
if more distant experience makes organizations whether the rivals have aged but also on whether
less viable as predicted by Hypothesis Ib, then they have endured competition. For this reason,
QD>O. Hypothesis 2a is supported if recent we separate these effects by including a control
experience by rivals makes them stronger com- for rivals' ages less the mean duration of rivals'
petitors, indicated by cR>O. If distant experience competitive experience.
makes rivals weaker, as predicted by Hypothesis The third set of variables controls for character-
2b, then CD<O. Hypothesis 3 predicts that high istics of each organization likely to influence its
variance in the durations of competitive relation- hazard rate, such as its size, age, and an indicator
ships reduces organizational viability, which is for whether the organization was a first-mover in
indicated by b>O. its market. Also controlled was a measure of the
The baseline rate r(1)/ is specified as a func- cumulative number of rivals absorbed by a given
tion of three kinds of variables. One set controls organization-a strategy that might retard Red
for the 'carrying capacity' of organizations, and Queen evolution. To control for selection effects,
includes period effects and exogenous variables which could otherwise lead to spurious evidence
describing market and institutional conditions of learning, we include the cumulative number of
likely to affect the organizational failure rate organizational failures in an organization's market
(Hannan and Freeman, 1989). The exogenous since the time the organization was founded.
variables include measures of the size of the 'Survivor' organizations will have a high value
human population in each organization's market, for this measure, and they should be more viable
a measure of urbanization, and measures of urban (regardless of learning) simply as a result of
and rural economic development. Also included unobserved factors that caused them to be selec-
was the number of organizational failures in each ted over others in the past.
organization's market in the previous year, a The controls for age dependence are especially
measure that increases as an organizational popu- important for this study. Age dependence could
lation experiences waves of failure (Carroll and spuriously affect estimates of the parameters a
Delacroix, 1982). and C in our model, because age captures devel-
A second set of variables controls for competi- opment over time, as do our competitive experi-
tive effects other than those that we hypothesize. ence effects. By controlling for age, we can also
An indicator variable is included for organizations speak to the renewed debate over age-dependent
that are monopolists in their market as well as a failure rates. For some time it has been thought
continuous measure of organizational density. that failure rates decline with age as organizations
Also included is the number of rivals in an move down 'learning curves,' either over time
organization's market at its time of founding. (Freeman, Carroll, and Hannan , 1983) or with
This term is meant to control for higher failure accumulated output (Lieberman, 1984). By con-
rates among organizations founding under high- trast, Barron, West, and Hannan (1994) recently
scarcity circumstances-so called 'density delay' argued that organ izations suffer a liability of
(Carroll and Hannan, 1989). Two other variables aging-becoming less fit over time because of
are included to control for characteristics of each senescence and obsolescence. In view of the Red
organization's rivals . The aggregate size of each Queen , whether time is good or bad for viability
organization's rivals was measured. Holding con- depends on the ecological context. Isolated
stant the size of the market, this variable allows organizations are likely to suffer from senescence
organizations of different sizes to generate and obsolescence as time passes , for they lack the
stronger or weaker competition (Barnett and Red Queen to stimulate adaptation. By contrast,
Amburgey, 1990) . Similarly, older organizations organizations facing competition benefit from the
are allowed to generate stronger competition by Red Queen, and so are more likely to improve
including the sum of rivals' ages in the model. their relative fitness as a function of their
Barnett (1996) reasoned that through slection and exposure to competition. These two patterns prob-
learning organizations become stronger competi- ably coexist in most industries depending on mar-
Red Queen in Organizational Evolution 147

ket segment. This may explain why there have the intervening years were obtained by linear
been such mixed results in empirical tests of age- interpolation. Literally dozens of types of death
dependent failure rates . Our model, by including events were listed in the directory. From these,
both age- and experience-dependence, will be 'failures' included bank closures that occurred
able to separate these two patterns of develop- because of actual or impending insolvency-
ment. whether or not the closure was managed by
regulators. Failures that eventually were resolved
by restructuring and reopening the bank were
DATA AND METHOD recorded as failures, and the new bank was treated
as such. Of the 2970 banks in the data , 1444
The model can be estimated with organizational failures were recorded over the 107,151 organiza-
life history data , so long as there are ample tion-years . Mergers and acquisitions not associ-
differences between the competitive histories of ated with a bank failure were treated as a compet-
organizations and their rivals . Without these dif- ing risk in the analysis (Kalbfleisch and
ference s, the mean duration of each organization' s Prentice, 1980).
competitive relationships would be equal to that Exogenous variables were coded from several
of its rival s, and so an empirical model including sources. All variables that were measured in inter-
both of these variables would not be identified. vals of greater than I year were linearly inter-
This problem is attenuated the more that organi- polated to provide approximate values for each
zations come and go at different times throughout year of the study period . The size of the human
the data, as each organization's experience then population in each local market was recorded
can differ from its rival s' . Such differences can from the Banker 's Directory series in 5-year inter-
be found within a single organizational population vals. From the decennial census, we included the
as it changes over time, but ideally one would proportion of each county's population considered
study both contemporaneous and temporal differ- urban in 10-year intervals. Also from the census
ences by pooling data on many markets with we included the number of manufacturing estab-
different competitive histories. lishments and the number of farms in each
The data analy zed here fit these requirements county, measured in 10-year intervals, to control
well. They document the life historie s of each of for urban and rural development. Each local bank-
the 2970 retail banks that have ever operated ing market's age in years was included to control
since 1900 in any of the 650 local banking for unobserved factors that develop as the local
markets in the state of Illinois, excluding Chicago. economy matures . This clock begins with the
Illinois retail banking was chosen because compe- founding of the first-ever bank in a locality. Ten
tition is geographically localized in retail banking, historical period effects were included, corre-
and the many local markets of Illinois have sponding to periods of turbulence, stability , and
remained distinct over time because of the state ' s regulatory change over the century: 1900-10,
prohibition of branch banking and intrastate hold- 1910-19, 1920-28, 1929-32, 1933-39, 1940-
ing companies (until recently-see Barnett et al., 45 , 1946-59, 1960-69, 1970-79, and 1980-93.
1994). These facts allow us to separately map Descriptive statistics for all variables used in the
the competitive histories of organizations in each analysis are listed in Table I.
of the 650 local banking markets as if they The failure model was estimated in terms of
were distinct organizational populations. Figure I the instantaneous hazard rate (Tuma and Hannan,
shows the total number of banks in the data over 1984) . We used the piecewise exponential model
this century. as implemented in the statistical program TDA
The data were collected from each yearly issue (Rohwer, 1993). This program was written to
of The Bankers Directory series (Rand McNally , accommodate cases where organizations do not
1900-90; Thomson Financial Publishing, 1991- fail before the end of the observation period .
93) . Data on size (real assets), market location, Excluding these ' right censored' cases leads to
and birth and death events were coded for every severely biased results (Tuma and Hannan , 1984).
bank. Each organization's assets were measured The piecewise exponential specification was
every 5 year s, as well as in the year of the chosen for two reasons . First, it estimates age
bank's birth and death. Estimates of size during dependence without making strong parametric
148 W. P. Barnett and M. T. Hansen
1750

1500

1250

~1000
'iii
c:
(J)
Cl
750

500

250

1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990


Year
Figure 1. Banks in Illinois (excluding Chicago)

Table I. Description of variables

Variables Minimum Maximum Mean S.D.

Age of local market o 148 54 32


Population in local market 16 139426 8596 17815
Proportion of population urban (in county) o I 0.46 0.28
Number of manufacturing estabs (in county) 1 19998 933 2934
Number of farms (in county) 161 5827 2139 1100
Bank failures in locale (prior year) o 3 0.018 0.143
Bank failures in locale (since org.'s founding) o 10 0.687 1.087
Real assets in locale/JO' (focal bank omitted) o 16618 404 1384
Natural log (Bank's real assets) 8.7 20.3 15.6 1.6
Number of banks absorbed by bank o 7 0.14 0.44
Bank was first mover o 1 0.026 0.159
Density of locale at time of founding o 13 1.58 1.62
Bank has monopoly in local market o I 0.47 0.5
Density in local market (other than focal bank) o 13 1 1.6
Bank's competitive experience (mean duration) o 121 11.6 18.7
Bank's recent competitive experience (mean
duration) o 10 4.2 4.5
Bank's distant competitive experience (mean
duration) o III 8.2 16.4
Bank's competitive experience (variance in
duration) o 4802 55 261
:ERivals' ages o 550 37 65
:ERivals' ages less their mean competitive experi-
ence o 318 15 32
:ERivals' competitive experience (mean duration) o 294 22 39
:ERivals' recent competitive experience (mean
duration) o 119 8 13
:ERivals' distant competitive experience (mean
duration) o 305 16 33
Red Queen in Organizational Evolution 149

assumpti ons. We are concerned that misspecifi- Failure rates are lower as a result of an organi-
cation of age dependence might spuriously influ- zation ' s recent competitive experience, but does
ence the comp etiti ve history effects, as they grow this effect count eract the hazard s that come with
alongside organizational age . The piecewi se age and with not being a monopolist? To help
exponential model avoid s this problem, becau se answer this question, Figure 2 combines the
it does not require a parametric specification of effects of recent competitive experience, age
age dependence. Second , the piecewi se dependence, and the monopoly indicator variable,
exponential can be estimated without bias even using the estimates of Model 3. The solid line
when some of the organizations were born before shows how a monopolist' s life chances change
the sample period began , as is the case in our as it ages, starting with an initial adva ntage due
data. These ' left censored' cases wou ld introduce to the monopoly effect but then becomin g
bias to many other commonly used parametric increasi ngly likely to fail because of positive age
hazard rate models (Guo, 1993). dependence. By contrast, the dashed line shows
the failure rate multiplier for an organi zation
with competition. For the first 10 years of life,
RESULTS organizations with rivals are more likely to-fail
than are monopoli sts, and they become increas-
Table s 2 and 3 show the model estimates. In ingly likely to fail because of positive age depen -
Table 2, three different speci fications of the dence. But these organizations benefit from the
model are listed for comp arison, and then Table Red Queen with each passing year, so that the
3 lists the age- and historical-per iod effects corre- pattern reverses by year 5 and then begins falling
sponding to Model 3-the most complete speci- rapidl y. (This nonmonotonic pattern is similar to
fication . Model I omit s the hypothe sis tests, and one attributed sole ly to age in studies that did
so serves as a baseline model for comparison. not consider the Red Queen; see Bruder! and
Model 2 adds the variables correspond ing to our Schu ssler, 1990; Levinthal, 1991. ) By our es ti-
theory, but does not distinguish between recent mates, the hazard s that come with age and not
and distant-p ast experi ences. Tho se distinctions being a monopolist both are strong, but the
are made in the full specification, Model 3. increase in viability due to recent comp etitive
As pred icted by Hypothesis Ia, banks with experience is strong enough to counteract these
more com petitive experiences recently were sig- effects.
nificantly less likely to fail. Mean while, this effect Hypothe ses 2a and 2b also are supported. Riv-
was reversed for banks with experience in the als generated significantly stronger competition
distant past, as predicted by Hypothesis Ib. The when they had more competitive experience-but
relati ve magnitudes of these effects are intere st- this finding holds only for recent experience.
ing. The benefici al effe ct of recent competitive As predicted, rivals with distant-p ast experience
experience is about 15 times greater than the generated weaker competition. As predicted, riv-
deleterious effect of having outdated experiences. als with distant-pa st experience generated weaker
Th is finding means that I year of recent experi- compet ition . These two effects are best under-
ence can compensate for 15 years of old stood by comp arison to the effect of the sum of
experiences - suggesting that these organizations rivals' ages (less their mean experience). That
were relatively corrigible. Of course, this effect age term shows the increase in competitive
might be offse t by having a very large amount strength that develops amon g rivals as they age,
of outdated experience. Comparing the means in as predicted by Barnett ( 1996) . Note that the
Table I indic ates that there was in the sample effect is increased two-fold for banks with
only about twice as much distant-past experience rivals-at least if their experience with rivals is
as recent experience, so the adapti ve effect of recent. Taken together, these effects suggest that
recent experience appears to have been more than the strength of competition depends largel y on
sufficient to make up for most organizations' whether organ izations are part of a Red Queen ,
prior histories. Note also that in Model 2 these but that havin g been in a Red Queen long ago
opposing effects were masked, as the competitive has the reverse effect.
experi ence measure did not distingu ish between It is intere sting to compare the magnitudes of
recent and distant-p ast experience. the effects of an organization's experience and
150 W. P. Barnett and M. T. Hansen
Table 2. Piecewi se expo nentia l models of Illinois bank failures, 1900-93 (excluding Chicago)

Models'
Variable s (I ) (2) (3)

Age of local market -D.OO32 -D.OO8 1** -D.OO71 **


(0.0028) (0.0029 ) (0.0029)
Population in local market/ I000 0.0086 * 0.0119** 0.0119**
(0 .0050) (0.005 1) (0.005 1)
Proportion of population urban (in county) 0.0300 0.0627 0.0390
(0. 1316) (0.13 13) (0. 1315)
Number of manufacturing estabs/lOOO (in county ) 0.0396** 0.0420* * 0.0406 **
(0.0 130) (0.0 127) (0.0 128)
Number of farms/lOOO (in count y ) -D.OO68 -D.0108 -D.0067
(0.0324 ) (0.0324) (0.0325)
Bank failu res in locale (prior year ) 0.4386** 0.1703 -D.0706
(0. 11 56 ) (0.1268) (0.1384 )
Bank failures in locale (since org.' s founding) -0.0742* - 0.0792* -D.0806*
(0.0449) (0.0460) (0.04 57)
Real assets in locale/l 0 5 (focal bank omitted) -0.0002* -0.0003 ** -0.0003 **
(0.000 1) (0.000 I ) (0.000 I )
Natural log (Bank's real assets) -D.7840 ** -D.7869 ** -0.7871 **
(0.0273) (0.0 276 ) (0 .0277 )
Number of banks absorbed by bank 0.2243** 0. 152 1* 0.1059
(0.0842 ) (0.0830 ) (0.0846)
Bank was first mover 0.2377 0.1825 0.1487
(0 .1489) (0.149 7) (0.1510)
Density in locale at time of founding 0.0821 ** 0.1222** 0.1222 **
(0.0406 ) (0.04 12) (0.0400)
Bank has monopol y in local market -0.3613** -0.8473 ** -1 .447 **
(0.0783) (0.1070) (0.1388)
Density in local market (other than focal bank ) 0.0608 -D.0857 -0. 1467*
(0.054 1) (0.0601 ) (0.087 1)
Bank's competitive experie nce (mea n duration) -D.0284* *
(0.0050)
Bank' s recent compe titive experience (mean duratio n) -D.1508**
(0.0 185)
Bank 's distant competitive experi ence (mean duration) 0.0104*
(0.0060 )
Bank ' s competitive experience (variance in durati on ) 0.0015 ** 0.0011**
(0.000 1) (0.0002 )
LRivals' ages 0.0009
(0.00 15)
LRivals' ages less their mean competitive experie nce 0.0092** 0.0103**
(0.0021 ) (0.0023 )
LRival s' competitive experience (mean durati on ) 0.00 13
(0.0024 )
LRival s' recent competitive experience (mean duration ) 0.0195 *
(0.0109)
LRival' s distant competitive experience (mean duration ) -0.0054 *
(0.0031 )
Chi- squared" 785.66 912.26 959.04
dJ. 15 18 20

*p < 0.10; **p < 0.05. Standard errors are in parentheses.


a Models include 9 historical period effects and I I age-period effects. The data include 107,151 organization-years. 2970
organizations and 1444 failures.
b Compared to a model with only the age and historical period effects.
Red Queen in Organizational Evolution 151

Table 3. Age and historical period effects on the bank failure rate" (corresponding to Model 3 in Table 2)

Variables' Estimates Variables Estimates

Age 0-1 4.236** 1910-19 0.0770


(0.6264) (0. 1090)
Age 1-2 6.191** 1920-2 8 0.5660**
(0.4280) (0.1111 )
Age 2-3 6.506** 1929-32 2.541**
(0.4270) (0. 1105)
Age 3-5 6.994** 1933-3 9 2.300**
(0.4055) (0.1272 )
Age 5-10 7.548** 1940- 45 1.139**
(0.4036) (0.2013 )
Age 10-15 7.697** 1946-59 0.0865
(0.4063 ) (0.2565)
Age 15-20 7.646** 1960-69 -1.054**
(0.4139) (0.4816)
Age 20-25 7.745** 1970-79 -1.451* *
(0.4 178) (0.6147)
Age 25-30 7.912** 1980-93 -0.8551**
(0.4190) (0.3512)
Age 30- 40 7.858**
(0.4249)
Age 40- 7.985**
(0.4367)

**p < 0.05. Standard errors are in parentheses.


" For historical period effects. 1900- 09 is the left-out category.

13,--- -- -- - - - - -- - 0 : - - - - -- -- - - - - - - - ,

12

11 .........With Competition
....
10 <.

" .
..'

Wrthoul Competition

2 i

0 + - -- , - - - - , ------,,.----- - . . - - , - - - - - - - . -- , - - - - - - - , - - - , - -----1
o 4 5 6 8 10
Organizational Age

Figure 2. Age, competition and organizational failure


152 W. P. Barnett and M. T. Hansen

.. varia7 in experience (+ 2 sid dey)

1.5

3 456 7 9 10
Recent Competitive Experience
Figure 3. Varied competitive experience and organizational failure

its rivals' experience. By our estimate s, it would tion ' s competitive experience, with this variable
take about 15 experienced rivals to offset the evaluated at its mean, at its mean plus I standard
benefits going to one experienced organization, deviation, and at its mean plus 2 standard devi -
but the maximum number of rivals observed in ations (from Table 1).4 When these plots are
any local market was 13. This finding suggests above I on the vertical axis, the combined effects
that the Red Queen has asymmetric consequences, are predicted to increase the organization' s failure
increasing an organization' s viability more than rate. By contrast, a multiplier below I indicates
it increases the competitive effect of the organiza- that the combined effects reduce the organiza-
tion's rivals . tion 's hazard of failure. According to our esti-
Support also is found for Hypothesis 3, which mates, the combined effects of the Red Queen
predicted that failure rates increase for organiza- were usually adaptive for Illinoi s banks, reducing
tion s with high variance in the durations of their their failure rates. Higher failure rates are pre-
competitive relationships. As expected, then, Red dicted only in the rare case where a bank's
Queen evolution appears to have had both adap- competitive experience was both very high in
tive and maladaptive consequences for Illinois variance and short in mean duration. Otherwise,
bank s-with these effects depending on the du- our model predicts that the Red Queen typically
ration and variance of competitive experience. lowered organizational failure rates.
An interesting empirical question is whether The effects of numbers of competitors were
the adaptive consequences were strong enough to interesting. The powerful and significant mo-
offset the maladaptive consequences according to nopoly effect shows that the arrival of one's first
our estimates. Figure 3 illustrate s failure rate
multipliers as a function of recent competitive
4 In this figure , rivals' recent experience is set equal in
experience, evaluated at difference levels of vari- duration to the organization's, and only variance is changed
ance in competitive experience. The lowest solid from plot to plot. Of course, in reality these durations must
line serves as a baseline, showing the combined differ in order for variance to be defined. We compare plots
with all duration s set equal in order to simplify the illustration.
effect of the mean duration of an organi zation' s More complicated plots with differences among dur ations
recent experience (exp[ -0.1508 D and its rival s' show very similar pattern s. Also, Figure 3 does not include
recent experience (exp [0.0195 x 3 D, assuming the effects of distant-past experience becau se these are smaller
in magnitude and, at the mean, the hazard due to an organiza-
three rival s). The other three solid lines add the tion's past experience is roughl y offset by the effects of
increased hazard due to variance in an organiza- rivals ' past e xperience.
Red Queen in Organizational Evolution 153

competitor accounts for a whopping increase in in a self-reinforcing process. Our results suggest
the hazard rate. After that, additi onal increases in that lone organizations reap the static benefits of
numbers of competitors in a local market actually monop oly, but lack the dynamic adva ntage that
decrea se failure rates. Thi s effect , howe ver, needs comes from exposure to competition. Th is result
to be understood together with the effe cts of the cut s both ways, however, as organ izations with
Red Queen. Model I, which doe s not include the expe rienced rivals were more likely to fail. Tak en
full spec ification of each orga nization's experi- together, these findings support our pred ictions
ence distribution, showed a competitive den sity and demonstrate the usefulness of our model.
effect more co nsistent with the establi shed litera- We also found that the Red Queen has mala-
ture ( although the effect is not significa nt) . Once dapti ve consequen ces, evidence of evoluti onary
the mean and variance of the experience distri- con straints. As predicted, the results of exp osure
bution are included in Model s 2 and 3, the den sity to competition hinge on historical timing, com-
effect then turn s negat ive and significant. pletel y reversing for competitive experience in
Among other effects, larger banks were less the more distant past. In fact, evidence was sup-
likel y to fail, replicating the well-known liability pressed in models that did not con sider historical
of smallness effect. Density at the time an organi- timing and so confounded the opposing effects of
zation is founded has a positive, ongoing effect recent and distant-past experience. Once historical
on its failure rate con sistent with the finding s of timin g was considered, it turned out that organi za-
Carroll and Hann an ( 1989) . Predation by bank s tions with distant-p ast exper ience were both more
(the number of bank s each has absorbed as of a likel y to fail and weaker competitors, evidence
give n year) is significant and positively related consistent with our predic tion that distant-p ast
to failure in Model s I and 2- possi bly evidence exper ience leaves organization s in a competence
that this strategy preclud es Red Que en trap. Neve rtheless, by our estimates this historical
evo lution-but this effec t is not robust in Model constraint was qu ickly ove rcome: I year of recent
3. Larger marke ts as measured by the sizes of competition among Illinois banks was sufficient
riva ls were less hazardous, but larger market s as to offset the deleterious effects of 15 years of
measured by the hum an popul ation turned out to outdated experience . On balance, then, our results
be more hazardous. Similarly, bank s in areas with suggest that Red Queen evo lution rem ains adapt-
many manufac turing establishments were more ive despite this constraint.
likely to fail. A more powerful constraint was revealed in
Finally, two effects includ ed to capture unob- our test of Hypothesis 3, where we found support
served hete rogeneity were statistically significant. for the predicti on that organizations are more
The age of each local banking market was nega- likely to fail if they have competed against rivals
tivel y related to failure rates-an effect over and from varied cohorts. Organizations facing various
above the historic al period effects. Meanwhile, cohorts of rivals, we argued, are con strained in
the contr ol variable for selectivity effect s-the their ability to coevolve with anyone cohort,
number of failures in the local market over an becau se adaptations made for each cohort con-
organization's lifet ime-predicts a lower failure strain adaptations that can be made for other
rate for the surviving orga nizations, as expected. cohorts. As the variance among cohorts of rivals
increases, these constraints compound, redu cing
the marginal benefits of learnin g until they no
DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSION longer offset the cos ts. Thi s result sugges ts that
Red Queen evo lution can tum maladapti ve with
We found ev idence of Red Queen evo lution the entr y of new rivals to a market, as they can
amo ng Illinois bank s. Organizations were less dramatically increase the variance in an orga niza-
likely to fail if they had more competitive experi- tion 's comp etitive experience. Neve rtheless , the
ence, and at the same time they generated magn itudes of our estimates show that the adva n-
stronge r co mpetition- results that hold eve n after tage due to exposure to recent co mpetition is
we co ntrol for the effects of selection on survival. much stronger than the deleterious effect of vari-
Thi s finding supports our baseline pred iction that ance, so that the Red Queen is likely to remain
organizations learn over time as a respon se to adapti ve except in extreme cases of high variance
co mpetition, which in tum inten sifies competition and low mean duration .
154 W. P. Barnett and M. T. Hansen

The full pattern of results suggests that current position into the future. In light of the Red
research on competition would be improved by Queen, however, these prescriptions may be coun-
taking a more evolutionary perspective. As it terproductive. Organizations that achieve an iso-
stands, most work depicts competition as a func- lated strategic position lose the Red Queen in the
tion of the numbers or size distribution of com- process, and so will be disadvantaged over time.
petitors. Such studies acknowledge only one part There appears to be a fundamental contradiction
of an organization's experience distribution-its between the benefits of strategic position and
number of competitive relationships. Meanwhile, those of Red Queen, so that organizations that
other properties of that distribution-the mean aspire for the former do so at the expense of
duration, historical timing, and variance in du- the latter.
ration of these relationships-are unwittingly Our findings have similar implications for the
ignored. If our findings prove robust, these management of strategic resources. It is widely
properties may be decisive predictors of organiza- thought that firms benefit if they can protect
tional viability, and crucial variables that will their strategic resources from imitation by rivals
allow us to discriminate between strong and weak (Mahoney and Pandian, 1992). Strategic manage-
competitors. In fact, our results suggest that com- ment, then, becomes centrally concerned with
petitive effects attributed to numbers of competi- isolating these resources (Rurnelt, 1984). This
tors may be spuriously reflecting the effects of thinking changes entirely when the evolutionary
the mean and variance of the experience distri- source of capabilities is considered. If the devel-
bution. This raises a question about whether the opment of resources depends on the ecological
prevailing view of competition as 'crowding' is context of an organization, then isolation may be
too static, and whether our more dynamic model a disadvantage, as remaining unique today is
of Red Queen evolution would provide a more traded off against developing new strategic
accurate description of the competitive process. resources for tomorrow.
These results imply that strategic evolution has The strategy field may also be able to use the
a maladaptive side, suggesting that we use caution Red Queen as a model of strategic interaction.
when advancing normative prescriptions based on Ordinarily, this topic is analyzed in strategic man-
evolutionary thinking. In particular, Porter's agement by recourse to highly rational, game-
(1990: 586) model of international competition theoretic models. Yet our model allows for stra-
suggests that firms should seek challenging com- tegic interaction among organizations even when
petitors as motivators in order to improve their top-level management are not aware of what has
international competitive strength. Our findings caused performance problems. In fact, even 'dif-
direct attention to whether cultivating competitors fuse' competition from a population of unknown
will increase the variance in a firm's competitive competitors can trigger this evolutionary process.
relationships. If so, this prescription could back- In this light, Burgleman's (1994) study of Intel's
fire as firms are confronted by multiple, conflict- 'bottom up' evolution is a glimpse of one step
ing evolutionary demands. More generally, this taken by the Red Queen in the modern semicond-
problem illustrates the need to consider the con- uctor industry.
straints that inhibit organizational evolution, and Our ideas and findings suggest that competition
to explicitly build these constraints into our theor- is an important cause of disequilibrium among
etical and empirical research on the Red Queen. organizations-in contrast to much current think-
Our findings raise a fundamental problem for ing about competition. Social scientists generally
the theory of strategic management. Current conceive of competition as a mechanism that
thinking suggests that organizations are advan- moves organizational systems toward steady-state
taged by being isolated from competition. In fact, equilibrium (Stigler, 1968; Hannan and Freeman,
this idea is so widely accepted that it practically 1989; Nelson, 1994).5 Although theories differ in
defines the field of strategic management. Some
scholars in the field speculate about how organi-
zations can gain and maintain an isolated position , Disequilibrium arises from some classes of ecological mod-
that allows for market power. Others focus on els. In particular. competition among multiple populations
often generates unstable dynamics (May, 1974). and when
how organizations can build inimitable abilities such systems do equilibrate. the process can take an extremely
that assure them sole occupancy of a strategic long time (Carroll and Harrison. 1994).
Red Queen in Organizational Evolution 155

the particular processes involved, in general two cooperation affects the Red Queen, especially
opposing forces are thought to drive organiza- because many advocate cooperation as a mechan-
tional populations to steady state. On the one ism to increase the rate at which organizations
hand, organizations are expected to conform to learn . For example, it would be interesting to
the behavior of their rivals. This is a central know whether research and development consortia
assumption in the neoclassical economic model inadvertently harm the Red Queen by encouraging
where efficient forms of production diffuse cooperation among competitors.
throughout a market (Stigler, 1968) . Similarly, To conclude, we hope that this study demon-
sociologists argue that organizations respond to strates the potential pay-off from taking an evo-
uncertainty by imitating other, usually competing, lutionary approach to the study of strategy and
organizations (DiMaggio and Powell, 1983; Burt, organizations. Many of the same questions that
1987; Haveman, 1993; Miner and Haun schild, are asked in conventional strategic analysis can
1995; Greve, 1996) . On the other hand, compe- be asked from an evolutionary perspective as
tition also is expected to limit such imitation, well. Our answers , however, are often radically
striking a balance that produces an equilibrium. different-in some cases directly contradictory
Selection pressures place a ceiling on imitation, as to received understandings in the strategy field.
larger numbers of imitators increase competition, Precisely for this reason, we think an evolutionary
increasing failure rates and reducing founding perspective is a useful tool to be used to under-
rates (Hannan and Freeman, 1989; Mezias and stand the difficult but exciting problems of stra-
Lant, 1994). Also, as rivalry intensifies, some tegic change, and to question and , we hope,
organizations try to adapt by differentiating advance what we know about competitive advan-
(White, 1981; Carroll, 1985; Delacroix, Swamina- tage.
than, and Solt, 1989; Amburgey, Dacin , and
Kelly, 1994 )-at least to the extent permitted by
market possibilities. Together, these forces are ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
thought to push competitive systems to an equi-
librium where the diffusion of strategies is bal- This paper was written while Barnett was a fellow
anced by selection and differentiation. at the Center for Advanced Study in the
By contrast, Red Queen evolution depicts com- Behavioral Sciences. We are grateful for financial
petition as a force that continually disturbs equi- support provided by the National Science Foun-
librium. The difference hinges on whether organi- dation (SES-9022192, to Barnett), by the
zations learn from competition. If competition Norwegian Research Council (to Hansen), and
triggers organizational learning, then change may by the Stanford Graduate School of Business. We
be occurring even when aspects of market struc- thank Robert Burgelman, Glenn Carroll, Mike
ture, such as numbers of organizations, are stable . Hannan, Heather Haveman, Dan Levinthal, Dan
Furthermore, if learning in turn intensifies compe- Schendel, Olav Sorenson, and David Stark for
tition, then the system is self-reinforcing- comments and suggestions. We also thank
continually upsetting steady-state equilibrium Kathleen Much for her valuable editorial advice .
rather than producing it. This means that hypoth-
eses about Red Queen evolution cannot be use-
fully formulated as steady-state equilibrium pre- REFERENCES
dictions. Rather, we need to make predictions
about the dynamics that arise among organiza- Alchian, A. (1950). 'Uncertainty , evolution, and eco-
tions involved in the Red Queen, as we do here . nomic theory '. Journal of Political Economy , 58,
pp.211-221.
Our paper demonstrates coevolution among Amburgey, T. L., T. Dacin and D. Kelly (1994).
organizations involved in an ecology of compe- 'Disruptive selection and population segmentation:
tition and learning (Baum and Singh, 1994). Interpopulation competition as a segregation pro-
Additional work needs to investigate the parti- cess'. In 1. A. C. Baum and 1. V. Singh (eds.),
cular processes involved in this evolution. For Evolutionary Dynamics of Organizations. Oxford
University Press , New York, pp. 240 -254.
instance , do research efforts in one organization Barnard, C. I. (1938). The Functions of the Executive .
respond to-and cause-the research efforts in Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA .
other organizations? Similarly, we could ask how Barnett, W. P. (1993). 'Strateg ic deterrence among
156 W. P. Barnett and M. T. Hansen

multipoint competitors', Industrial and Corporate Dawkins, R. (19 82 ). The Extended Phenotype. Oxford,
Change, 2, pp . 249 -278. New York .
Barnett, W . P. (1996 ). 'The dynamics of co mpetitive De lacroix, J., A . Swaminath an and M. E. Solt (1989 ).
intensity ' . Working paper, Stanford Gr adu ate Sch ool ' Density depe ndence versus population dyn am ics:
of Business. An ecological study o f failing s in the California
Barnett, W . P. and T . L. Amburgey (1990). ' Do larger wi ne indu stry', American Sociological Review, 54,
organizations generate stronger competition?' In 1. pp . 245- 262.
Singh (ed. ), Organizational Evolution: New Direc- DiMaggio, P. 1. and W . W. Powell (1983 ). 'The iron
tions, Sage, Newbury Park, CA , pp . 78-102. cage revi sited : Institutional isom orphi sm and collec-
Barnett, W. P. and G. R. Carroll (1 99 3). ' Ho w insti- tive rati onality in organ izati on al field s' , American
tutional constraints affect ed the orga nization of earl y Sociological Review, 48, pp . 147-160.
American telephon y' , Journal of Law, Economics Dixit, A. K. and B. Nalebuff (19 9 1). Thinking Strategi-
and Organization, 9 , pp . 98-1 26. cally. Nort on , New York .
Barn ett, W . P. and G. R. Carroll (1995) . 'Modeling Fornbrun, C. J. (1 988) . 'Crafting an institutionally-
intern al organ izati onal cha nge', Annual Review of informed eco logy of organ ization s' . In G. R. Carroll
Sociology, 21 , pp . 217 - 236. (ed .), Ecological Models of Organizations. Ball-
Barnett, W . P., H. R. Greve and D. Y. Park (1994 ). ' An inger, Cambridge, MA, pp .223-239 .
evo lutionary model of organization al performance' , Freeman, J., G . R. Carroll and M . T . Han nan (1983).
Strategic Managem ent Journa l, Winter Special 'The liab ility of newness : Age dependence in organi-
Issue, 15, pp . 11-28 . zational death rates ' , American Sociological Review,
Barron , D. N., E. We st and M. T. Hann an ( 1994) . 'A 48 , pp. 692 -710.
tim e to grow and a tim e to die : Gr owth and mortality Gould, S. J. and R. C. Lew ontin ( 1979). 'The Sp andrels
of credit unions in New York Cit y, 1914-1990 ' , of San Marco and the Pan glo ssian Par adi gm: A
American Journal of Sociology, 100, pp .381-421. critique of the Adaptationi st Programme' , Proceed-
Baum , J. A. C. and J. V. Singh (eds .) (1 994 ) Evolution- ings of the Royal Society of London, 205 : 581-598.
ary Dynamics of Organizations. Ox ford Univ ers ity Reprinted in E. Sober (ed.) ( 1984). Conceptual
Press, New York . Issues in Evolutionary Biology. MIT Press, Cam-
Bower, J. L. ( 1970) . Managing the Resource Allocation bridge, MA, pp . 252-270.
Process. Harv ard Busine ss Scho ol Press, Boston, Greve, H. R. ( 1996) . ' Patte rns of competition: The
MA . diffus ion of a market position in radio bro adcasting' ,
Boyd, R. and P. 1. Richerson (1985 ). Culture and the Administrati ve Science Quarterly, 4 1, pp . 29-60.
Evolutionary Process. Un iversity of Chicago Pres s, Gu o, G. (19 93). 'Event-history analysis for left-trunc-
Chi cago, IL. ated dat a ' . In P. Mar sden (ed.), Sociological Meth-
Bruderl , J. and R. Schussler ( 1990) . 'Organ izati on al odology, Basil Blackw ell , Cambridge, MA ,
mort ality: Th e liability of newn ess and adolscence' , pp .217-243 .
Administrative Science Quarterly, 35, pp.5 30-547. Hann an, M . T . and G. R. Carr oll ( 1992). Dynamics of
Bur gelm an, R. A. ( 1994) . ' Fading mem ories: A process Organizational Populations: Density, Legitimation,
study of strategic bu siness exit in dy na mic enviro n- and Competition. Oxford Uni ver sity Press, Ne w
ment s', Adm inistrative Science Quarterly, 39, York .
pp . 24 -56. Hann an, M. T . and 1. Freem an ( 1984) . ' Struc tural
Burt , R. S. (1 987 ). ' Social co ntag ion and innovati on: inerti a and organizational change ', American Socio -
Coh esion ver sus structural equivalence', American logical Review, 49, pp. 149-164.
Journal of Sociology. 92, pp . 1287-1335 . Hannan, M . T . and J. Freeman (1989). Organizational
Carroll, G. R. (1985) . ' Co ncentration and specializa- Ecology. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.
tion : Dynamics of nich e width in populations of Haveman, H. A. ( 1993 ). ' Orga nizational size and
orga nizations', American Journal of Sociology, 90, change: Diversifica tion in the savings and loan
pp. 1263 -1283. indu stry after dere gu lation ' , Administrative Science
Carroll , G . R. and J. Delacroix (1982 ). ' Organizational Quarterly, 38, pp .20-50.
mort alit y in the new spaper indu stries of Argentina Kalbflei sch , 1. D. and R. L. Prenti ce (1980) . The
and Irel and : An ecological approach ' , Administrative Statitistical Analysis of Failure Time Data. Wiley,
Science Quarterly, 27, pp . 168-198. New York.
Carroll , G . R. and M . T. Hann an (1989 ). ' Density Lawren ce , P. and D. Dyer (1 983 ). Renewing American
delay in the ev oluti on of organizati onal population s: Industry. Free Pre ss, New York .
A model and five empirical tests', Administrative Le vinthal, D. (1991 ). 'R and om walks and organiza-
Science Quarterly, 34 , pp . 4 11-430. tional mort ality' , Adiminstrative Science Quarterly,
Carroll , G. R. and J. R. Harrison (1994 ). 'On the 36 , pp.397-420.
historical efficiency of co mpetition between org ani- Levitt, B. and 1. G. March ( 1988) . 'Organi zational
zati on al populations' , American Journal of Soci- learning' , Annual Review of Sociology, 14,
ology, 100, pp.720-749 . pp . 319-340.
Cole, R. E. ( 1996). ' Fads, imitati on , and learnin g: The Lieberman, M. B. ( 1984). 'The learning curve and
case of the Am eri can quality movement' , unpub- pricing in the chemic al proc essing indu stries', Rand
lished manu scr ipt, Center for Ad van ced Stud y in Journal of Economics, 15(2 ), pp. 2 13-228 .
the Beh avioral Scien ces, Stanford , CA. Mahoney , J. and J. Pandi an ( 1992) . 'The reso urce-
Red Queen in Organi zational Evolution 157

based view within the conversation of strategic man- (Annual directorie s from 1900-90). Rand McNall y,
agement, Strategic Management Journal, 13(5 ), Chicago, IL.
pp. 363-380. Rohwer , G. ( 1993) . TDA version I , documentation .
March , J. G. (19 81). 'Fo otnotes to organizational Rumelt, R. ( 1984) . 'Towards a strategic theory of
change' , Administrative Science Quarterly, 26, the firm' . In R. Lamb (ed.), Competitive Strategic
pp. 563-577. Management. Prentice-H all, Englewood Cliffs, NJ,
March, 1. G. (1 988). Decisions and Organizations. pp. 556-570.
Basil Black well, Cambridge, MA. Saloner, G. (1991 ). ' Modelling, game theory. and stra-
March, 1. G. and H. A. Simon (1958). Organizations. tegic management' . Strategic Management Journal ,
John Wiley, New York. Winter Special Issue, 12, pp. 119-136.
May, R. M. (1974 ). Stability and Complexity in Model Sayles, L. ( 1964). Managerial Behavior: Administration
Ecosystems. Princeton University Press, Princeton , in Complex Organizations. McGraw-H ill, New York.
N1. Schumpet er, J. A. ( 1934) . The Theory of Economic
Mezias, S. J. and T. K, Lant (1994 ). ' Mimetic learning Development. Harvard University Press, Cam-
and the evolution of organizational population s' . In bridge , MA.
1. A. C. Baum and J. V. Singh (eds.), Evolutionary Stigler, G. 1. ( 1968 ). The Organization of Industry.
Dynamics of Organizations. Oxford, New York. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL.
Miner, A. S. and P. R. Haunschild (1995 ). 'Population- Stinchcombe, A. L. (1965). 'Soci al structure and
level learning' . In B. Staw and L. Cummings (eds.), organizations' . In J. G. March (ed.), Handbook of
Research in Organizational Behavior, Vol. 17, JAI Organizations. Rand-McNally, Chicago . IL,
Press, Greenwich, CT, pp. 115-166. pp.142- 193.
Mintzberg , H. and A. McHugh ( 1985). 'Strategy forma- Thomson Bank Directory. (Annual directori es from
tion in an adhocrac y' , Admini strative Science Quar- 1991-93 ). Thomson Financial Publishing , Skokie,
terly , 30, pp. 160-197. IL.
Nelson, R. R. ( 1994). 'Evolutionary theorizin g about Turna, N. B. and M. T. Hannan ( 1984) . Social Dynam -
eco nomic change ' . In N. Smelser and R. Swedberg ics: Models and Methods. Academic Press, New
(eds.), The Handbook of Economic Sociology. York.
Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, pp. 108- Tushman, M. L. and P. Anderson (1986). 'Technologi-
136. cal discontinu ities and organizational environments' ,
Nelson, R. R. and S. G. Winter (1982 ). An Evolutionary Administrative Science Quarterly, 31 , pp.439-465.
Theory of Economic Change. Harvard University U. S. Department of Commerce (1988) . County and
Press, Cambrid ge, MA. City Data Book. U. S. Department of Commerce,
Pfeffer, 1. and G. R. Salancik ( 1978). The External Social and Economics Statistics Admi nistration,
Control of Organizations. Harper and Row, New Bureau of the Census, Washington, DC.
York. U. S. Department of Commerce (1992). USA County
Porter, M. E. ( 1980) . Competitive Strategy. Free Press, Statistics [CD -ROM database] . U. S. Department of
New York. Comm erce, Social and Economic Statistics Adminis-
Porter, M. E. ( 1990) . The Competitive Advantage of tration, Bureau of the Census, Washington, DC.
Nations. Macmillan , New York. Van Valen, L. ( 1973). ' A new evolutionary law', Evo-
Quinn , J. B. ( 1980). Strategies fo r Change: Logical lutionary Theory, 1, pp. 1-30.
Incrementalism. Irwin, Homew ood, IL. White, H. C. ( 198 1). 'Where do markets come from ?',
Rand McNally International Bankers Directory. American Journal of Sociology, 87, pp.517-547.

You might also like