Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 11

Economic Modelling xxx (xxxx) xxx

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Economic Modelling
journal homepage: www.journals.elsevier.com/economic-modelling

Does eliminating international profit shifting increase tax revenue in


high-tax countries?
Patrice Pieretti 1 , Giuseppe Pulina 1, ∗
University of Luxembourg, Department of Economics and Management, Luxembourg

A R T I C L E I N F O A B S T R A C T

JEL classification: We analyze under what conditions initiatives intended to eliminate profit shifting (such as the OECD BEPS
F21 action plan and the more recent European implementation of the ATAD) can be successful, given that these
F23 actions may induce multinational companies to relocate activities to low-tax countries. We demonstrate that
H25
removing tax-motivated profit shifting increases tax revenue in the onshore region if the low-tax jurisdiction is
H26
not too efficient in providing attractive infrastructure. This outcome is more easily achieved when the high-tax
country is able to counter the shifting of international activity using infrastructure investment to compete with
Keywords: the tax haven rather than being passive. International regulations aimed at combating aggressive tax avoidance
BEPS
should anticipate the adverse effects induced by the resulting emergence of other forms of base erosion.
ATAD
Profit shifting
Activity shifting
Tax havens
Multinational firms

1. Introduction of profits where the economic activities and value creation occur. In
response to the BEPS, the European Commission (EC) adopted the Anti
In recent years there has been growing concern about aggressive tax Tax Avoidance Package in 2015, which includes a proposal for an Anti
avoidance by multinational corporations (MNCs). In particular, MNCs Tax Avoidance Directive (ATAD) (see European Commission, 2016a).1
are accused of paying virtually no taxes in the places where they operate This directive was adopted on 20 June 2016, and all member states
by shifting profit to low-tax jurisdictions. These facts have been clearly have to apply these measures from 1 January 2019.
documented in the recent literature (e.g., Desai et al., 2006a, Desai et In reality, however, pure profit shifting is not the only way compa-
al., 2006b, Huizinga and Laeven, 2008 and Heckemeyer and Overesch, nies can lower their tax liabilities. They can benefit from low taxation
2013). Accordingly, in 2013, the OECD launched an initiative against by shifting real activities abroad if the territorial taxation system,2 cur-
base erosion and profit shifting (BEPS - OECD, 2013a; b, 2014, 2015). rently used by the majority of OECD countries, applies.3 Importantly,
This initiative, consisting of a 15-point action plan, is intended to facil- the BEPS addresses the issue of intangible property (IP) given its poten-
itate intergovernmental cooperation regarding the taxation of multina- tial risk to contribute to aggressive profit shifting.4 The ATAD also pro-
tional corporations. More specifically, the aim is to require the taxing vides tax exit rules to prevent companies from avoiding tax when relo-

∗ Corresponding author.
E-mail addresses: patrice.pieretti@uni.lu (P. Pieretti), gpulina@gmail.com (G. Pulina).
1
We thank the editor, two anonymous referees, Skerdilajda Zanaj, Luisito Bertinelli and Andreas Haufler for their helpful comments and suggestions.
1
In addition to the ATAD, the EC package consists of three other documents: a Communication for an External Strategy for Effective Taxation, an amendment to
the directive on mutual assistance for the automatic exchange of information in country-by-country reporting, and the recommendation on tax treaties adding the
“genuine economic activity”test to the Principal Purpose Test (PPT) rule (see European Commission, 2016b,c,d).
2
According to this regime, multinationals are not taxed at home on their foreign income.
3
In 2006, the European Court of Justice (ECJ) ruled in the Cadbury Schweppes Case (Case C-196/04)) that the U.K. CFC (controlled foreign company) legislation,
under which the profits of a foreign subsidiary of a resident parent-company are attributed to the resident company and taxed domestically can only apply to wholly
artificial tax minimization schemes. Furthermore, trying to attract foreign businesses with low taxation is consistent with the EU Freedom of Establishment.
4
Dischinger and Riedel (2011) show that moving the location of IP to a low-tax jurisdiction is a simple way used by MNCs to reduce tax liabilities.

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2020.01.020
Received 27 March 2019; Received in revised form 22 November 2019; Accepted 25 January 2020
Available online XXX
0264-9993/© 2020 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

Please cite this article as: Pieretti, P., Pulina, G., Does eliminating international profit shifting increase tax revenue in high-tax countries?,
Economic Modelling, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2020.01.020
P. Pieretti, G. Pulina Economic Modelling xxx (xxxx) xxx

cating assets (e.g., valuable intangible assets) to another jurisdiction. multinationals by applying a zero tax rate but requires a fee for profit-
A post-BEPS/ATAD world will focus on economic substance rather shifting services. Moreover, the offshore jurisdiction invests in attrac-
than the legal ownership of intangibles. Accordingly, a subsidiary will tive infrastructure to facilitate the setting up of real businesses, under
be entitled to returns from intangibles with respect to economic sub- payment of a fee. The multinational is assumed to maximize its own
stance criteria rather than legal ownership. Therefore, returns from the net profit by selecting the best mix of the two tax-reducing devices.
exploitation of intangibles will accrue to subsidiaries if there is evidence The model demonstrates that the removal of tax-motivated profit shift-
of value-creating DEMPE functions.5 ing increases tax revenue in the onshore region if the low-tax juris-
In other words, the focus is on artificial profit shifting for tax pur- diction is not too efficient in providing attractive infrastructure. This
poses and not on tax competition per se. In a recent interview in the outcome is more easily achieved when the high-tax country is able to
Sydney Morning Herald (November 14, 2014), the head of OECD tax counter international activity shifting by competing in infrastructure
policy told Fairfax Media that the BEPS would “put an end to harm- with the tax haven rather than being passive. Anti tax avoidance regu-
ful tax competition, but not to tax competition”. Moreover, Alms et al. lations have been designed independently of the possible consequences
(2016) note that the “… relocation of IP to Ireland can still generate on tax and nontax competition. It follows that these measures may be
significant tax savings for U.S. pharmaceutical companies, even in our undermined by the emergence of another type of base erosion resulting
post-BEPS world”. While this additional substance is a greater require- from the intensified use of nontax instruments, such as public infrastruc-
ment than the requirements in the pre-BEPS context, relocating DEMPE ture provision by low-tax countries. Consequently, international regu-
functions and IP ownership allows companies to truly maximize tax sav- lations aimed at combating aggressive tax avoidance should anticipate
ings while remaining compliant with both the IRS and the local OECD the adverse effects induced by the resulting emergence of other forms
territory BEPS perspective. of base erosion.
However, low taxes are not always enough to attract foreign firms. Moreover, our model is consistent with the existence of two types
According to Dharmapala (2008) and Dharmapala and Hines (2009), of tax havens. One type of haven relies mainly on profit-shifting ser-
havens tend to have relatively sophisticated infrastructure6 and Gon- vices (e.g., Panama and the Cayman Islands), and the other offers a
zalez and Schipke (2011, p.45) observe that “strong regulations that mix of profit-shifting and activity-shifting services (e.g., Ireland). We
inspire confidence are a crucial factor” to attract foreign businesses. In demonstrate that the cost of shifting activity for tax purposes relative
a strict sense, infrastructure refers, for example, to telecommunications to shifting profit to the tax haven is crucial in explaining the choice
and transportation infrastructure, universities and public R&D opera- of the representative MNC between the two types of tax havens. This
tions. In a larger sense, we must also consider institutional infrastruc- result seems to be consistent with reality if we proxy capital mobility
ture, such as property rights enforcement, capital market regulations with the relative cost of activity shifting.
and more generally, attractive laws and regulations. In fact, a country Finally, we demonstrate that base erosion and onshore tax revenue
that invests in the quality of its institutions can be perceived as a safe are not necessarily affected in the same way by the elimination of profit
location where business activities can be carried out. It is important to shifting. More precisely, the eradication of profit shifting can increase
note that many infrastructure services (especially institutional infras- tax revenue while not reducing base erosion.
tructure) have the nature of local public goods (non-rivalry and nonex-
clusion), which benefit all firms in the same location, whether they are 1.1. Contribution and related literature
targeted by attractiveness policies, as are MNCs, or not. It follows that
physical and institutional infrastructure together with low taxation are The paper contributes to the existing literature in three ways.
essential to host foreign activities. First, contrary to the previous literature on tax havens, which only
In a recent article, The Economist explains that “to avoid the per- focuses on tax planning and profit-shifting aspects (for example, Slem-
ception of tax-dodging, some firms are starting to shift executives and rod and Wilson, 2009; Bucovetsky, 2014; Peralta et al., 2006), our paper
head-office functions to their new domiciles” and that “America is start- considers that low-tax countries can also be attractive for real business
ing to lose not just tax revenues but jobs too”. Consequently, to lower activities because of the tax advantages they provide. This is in line with
their tax burdens and avoid the perception of pure profit shifting, MNCs Hines (2014), who observes that “the most straightforward way to be
begin to shift part of their real activity to low-tax jurisdictions (The able to report earning taxable income in low-tax jurisdictions is to con-
Economist, 2015). centrate economic activity there”. Moreover, he states that “studies con-
While activity shifting does not violate the ongoing anti tax planning sistently find that multinational firms locate more employment, prop-
regulation, it still remains a form of base erosion from the point of view erty, plants, and equipment in low-tax locations than the structures of
of high-tax countries, as noted by Hines (2014). these economies would ordinarily warrant”.
The following questions then arise. Do international anti-profit shift- Second, we assume that low-tax jurisdictions respond strategically to
ing regulations encourage tax havens to intensify their attractiveness to the tax and infrastructure policies of high-tax jurisdictions by choosing
foreign substance based investments? In this case, will tax havens be a mix of fees and infrastructure investment. Considering that jurisdic-
capable of providing more attractive infrastructure? Could this induce tions compete strategically and independently in tax and nontax instru-
MNCs to engage more in international activity shifting? Is it then con- ments is consistent with the empirical (Hauptmeier et al., 2012) and
ceivable that anti tax avoidance regulations could fail? theoretical literature (Justman et al., 2002, 2005; Bénassy-Quéré et al.,
This paper develops a simple model to analyze under what condi- 2007; Dembour and Wauthy, 2009; Pieretti and Zanaj, 2011). In this
tions initiatives intended to eliminate profit shifting can be successful context, we show that the onshore country is able to mitigate the poten-
given that these actions may induce the relocation of substance-based tial loss of tax revenue when it strategically adapts its infrastructure
activities. In our model, we assume that a representative multinational investment (Section 5).
company is located in a high-tax region (onshore region) and tries to Finally, our paper examines whether policies aimed at the elimi-
reduce its tax liabilities by shifting profit and/or real business to a low- nation of aggressive tax avoidance are able to increase tax revenue in
tax jurisdiction (offshore country). The offshore jurisdiction tries to lure onshore countries, which is ultimately the aim of such initiatives. The
literature on tax havens has, however, concentrated more on policies
5
Development, Enhancement, Maintenance, Protection, and Exploitation.
intended to eliminate tax havens’ aggressive operations, while implic-
6
Infrastructure can take various forms, such as telecommunications and itly assuming that this would coincide with the elimination of tax rev-
transportation infrastructure, universities and public R&D investment, and gov- enue erosion. An example is Elsayyad and Konrad (2012), who ana-
ernance infrastructure, such as property rights enforcement, capital market reg- lyze how the timing of deactivation of the aggressive activity of tax
ulations and more generally attractive laws and regulations. havens impacts the welfare of the onshore region. In particular, they

2
P. Pieretti, G. Pulina Economic Modelling xxx (xxxx) xxx

conclude that eliminating just the activity of a subset of tax havens may on a world market to a given price.9 Each MNC has one unit of cap-
reduce welfare in the OECD. However, eliminating this activity alto- ital that generates a profit ΠH = q + 𝛿 . The fraction q results from
gether would increase welfare. Consequently, fully eliminating aggres- firm specific productivity, whereas 𝛿 is the output fraction that depends
sive tax avoidance is equivalent to an increase in welfare. on the amount of infrastructure provided in the home country.10 For
Our paper is thus related to the literature that analyzes the role of convenience and without loss of generality, we set q = 1 so that
tax havens regarding profit shifting and tax competition, as well as the ΠH = 1 + 𝛿 .
resulting effect on overall welfare.7 One important result of the pre- Assume that the representative MNC contemplates the possibility of
vious literature is that profit shifting lowers the welfare in non-haven shifting part of its capital to the tax haven in order to set up a substance-
countries (Slemrod and Wilson, 2009). In this context, tax havens do based activity and/or the possibility of offshoring, through a special
not compete for investments but only facilitate aggressive tax plan- purpose entity (SPE), part of its profit generated in H. In reality there
ning. However, there are counterarguments according to which non- are many ways to shift income from high-tax to low-tax countries. In
havens can benefit from some profit shifting. Johannesen (2010) shows order to justify the way we model profit shifting, we assume that capital
that profit shifting can eliminate tax rate differences among competing is initially shifted to a SPE and then invested back by intra-corporate
non-haven countries that differ in size. Hong and Smart (2010) suggest loans to the home country, where actual production takes place.11 If
that international tax avoidance schemes may reduce the tax burdens the home country allows firms to deduct interest payments on loans
of mobile capital thus facilitating investments. as an expense item, it follows that interest payments of the MNC to
Other prominent contributions argue that profit shifting allows the SPE located in the tax haven is a means of tax avoidance through
non-havens to discriminate between mobile and immobile capital (see profit shifting. This scheme allows the allocation of income between
Keen, 2001; Peralta et al., 2006; Janeba and Smart, 2006; Bucovet- affiliates of the same legal entity, regardless where the income has been
sky and Haufler, 2008). According to Hines (2010) this allows high- generated.
tax countries “to maintain high capital tax rates without suffering dra- Let 𝜃 denote the fraction of capital moved12 to the tax haven F for
matic reductions in foreign direct investment.” Moreover, profit shifting setting up a substance-based activity and 𝜃 p the portion of the profit ΠH
appears as a substitute for preferential tax treatments, which have come that is merely shifted offshore.
increasingly under scrutiny. Following Johannesen (2010) and Haufler and Schjelderup (2000),
Generally tax havens are described as providers of tax concealment we consider that profit and capital shifting entail moving costs. We
services but not as locations of real local activity, tangible or intangi- assume that the cost of activity shifting increases with the amount of
ble.8 offshored capital,13 while we suppose that the cost of profit shifting
We depart from the previous literature in different ways. Contrary increases with the parameter 𝜃 p that can be viewed as the share of con-
to many prominent contributions (e.g., Bucovetsky and Haufler, 2008; cealed tax-base. The latter assumption that is similar to Haufler and
Slemrod and Wilson, 2009; Johannesen, 2010) and similar to Bucovet- Schjelderup (2000) results from the fact that additional efforts are nec-
sky (2014), we treat havens as strategic players that are able to design essary to increase income concealment and that the probability of being
optimal policies. In addition, we consider that MNCs can benefit from detected increases with the degree of concealment.
low taxation by also shifting real activity to tax havens. In other words, Setting up a real business activity in a foreign location requires
the model we develop is less restrictive since it allows havens to attract shifting capital and possibly specific human resources. We introduce
businesses of substance. Finally, we analyze the implications of activ- a convex cost function to account for the costs involved in the relo-
ity shifting in the context of the BEPS and the more recent European cation of productive resources to a foreign country. Among these, we
response, the ATAD. In fact, these initiatives aim at eliminating profit have to consider moving costs, such as freight costs, storing costs and
shifting but do not consider other sources of base erosion. insurance fees. Moreover, there are costs of renting or buying land and
The basic purpose of the paper is to analyze under what conditions business premises, and costs of relocating high skilled employees (who
anti profit-shifting regulations can make high-tax jurisdictions better are hardly available in the host location) in a foreign country. Mov-
off regarding tax revenue, if we reasonably assume that MNCs can ing costs may increase proportionally with the amount of shifted cap-
shift both real activity and profits to a low-tax country. In this con- ital (business). However, the cost of renting land and premises will
text, attractive infrastructure provision as well as tax advantages plays increase more than proportionally with the magnitude of business if
a critical role. extra physical space is scarce. Finally, given that additional activity
The next section presents the basic model. In section 3, we assume requires more skilled people, it is plausible that relocating employees
that profit shifting can be eliminated. Section 4 compares tax revenue becomes increasingly difficult when more business is shifted abroad (for
before and after the removal of profit shifting. Section 5 extends the example, difficulties to find people who adapt to a new country with a
model to the case of infrastructure competition between high- and low- different language and a different culture).
tax jurisdictions. Section 6 concludes the paper.

2. The model set-up 9 We assume that there are a large number of MNCs located in country H.

Consequently, this rules out individual bargaining situations between the MNCs
We consider a world economy with two countries, a large high-tax and the jurisdictions.
country H and a small tax haven F. 10
Note that our profit function is a reduced form that does not exclude the
There are m (normalized to 1) multinational companies (MNCs) existence of a production function. Also, note that the total amount of capi-
located in country H that produce a homogeneous good that is sold tal that can be invested either at home or abroad is given and normalized to
1. However, this normalization does not prevent that the amount of capital
invested at home may be an endogenous variable.
11
According to UNCTAD (2015), a big part of FDI flowing into tax havens are
not invested in projects based in the country. Instead, they can flow back to the
country of source, which is a process called “round tripping”. As an example
7 For surveys on the theory of tax havens see Dharmapala (2008) and Keen
UNCTAD (2013) reports that “[..] the top three destinations of FDI flows from
and Konrad (2013). the Russian Federation - Cyprus, the Netherlands and the British Virgin Islands
8
The OECD (2015) defines an asset as “intangible” if it is not a physi- - coincide with the top three investors in the Russian Federation [.. ] “.
cal/financial asset that can be owned or controlled for use in commercial activ- 12
It follows that the profit generated at home equals (1 −𝜃 )𝛱 H .
13
ities, and whose use or transfer would be compensated had it occurred in a Offshoring real activities involves costs resulting from building or renting
transaction between independent parties. the business premises as well as from moving the starting material, etc.

3
P. Pieretti, G. Pulina Economic Modelling xxx (xxxx) xxx

We introduce convex costs for profit and activity shifting. The cor- We can now write the following profit equation of the representative
responding cost functions are respectively 12 𝜃p2 and 𝛼2 𝜃 2 . Note that it is MNC
common practice to use convex functions in two-country models (Hau- 1 𝛼
V = (1 − 𝜃p − 𝜃)ΠH (1 − t ) + 𝜃p (ΠH − fp ) + 𝜃(ΠF − f ) − 𝜃p2 − 𝜃 2 . (1)
fler and Schjelderup, 2000 and Stöwhase, 2005) that try to capture the 2 2
costly effort of MNCs to avoid home taxation. The parameter 𝛼 ∈ R+ The first term of (1) represents the net (of corporate tax) income
accounts for the difficulty to shift activity relative to profit. Because generated at home (country H). The second and third terms refer to the
profit shifting can be achieved virtually, we can assume that shifting net income resulting respectively from profit and activity shifting.18
activities is at least as difficult. In other terms, we assume that 𝛼 > 1.14 Finally, the two last terms are respectively the cost of offshoring profit
The onshore country taxes profit at a proportional rate t ∈ [0, 1]. and activity. Note that MNC gross-profit is endogenously determined
Generally, it is not very costly to offer tax sheltering services, but pub- by the capital allocation decision of the MNC and the infrastructure
lic investments are required to guarantee a favorable environment to investments of the tax haven and the onshore country. Moreover, in
attract foreign firms that invest in substance-based activities. In this our setting, profit shifting has a positive effect on the capital invested
context, we do not only consider public investments in physical assets, onshore. In fact, the easier shifting profit offshore becomes, the lower
but also institutional infrastructure such as property rights enforce- will be the incentive to shift activity abroad. As a consequence, the
ment, capital market regulations, labor and environmental regulations, incentive to invest capital onshore will be higher. This positive effect
accounting standards and disclosure requirements. has also been highlighted by previous studies such as Overesch (2009)
Consequently, let G be the amount of public infrastructure provided and Desai et al. (2009).
by the tax haven. Let us assume that G units of infrastructure are needed Let us now consider a two-stage game. We assume that the juris-
to generate G units of net output. Additionally, we suppose that the dictions set their policy instruments in a first stage and that the MNC
cost of infrastructure provision increases at an increasing rate due to decides on its location in a second stage. In fact, it is common that MNCs
diminishing returns to scale. We thus introduce a quadratic function decide to locate in a given country after having been informed, in par-
𝛽 2
2
G , where 𝛽 measures the efficiency of the tax haven in providing ticular, about the tax rules that the national tax authorities of the host
attractive infrastructure. More exactly, the coefficient 𝛽 accounts for the country apply. The national tax authorities guarantee the enforcement
capacity of a jurisdiction to cope with key stages of public infrastructure of these rules in binding agreements (advance pricing agreements),
investments, which consist of planning, allocation and implementation. which allow the MNCs to know the tax conditions they are going to face
The higher the value of 𝛽 , the lower the efficiency in providing G. Given before their investment decision. Therefore, country H sets the corpo-
that the size of 𝛽 plays a key role in the main conclusions of the paper, rate tax rate t while the tax haven F sets the fees fp and f and the infras-
the following clarifications are needed. tructure provision G. These last choices are made simultaneously and
For Pritchett (2000), “the difference between investment cost and non-cooperatively by the jurisdictions. Finally, the MNC decides on 𝜃 p
capital value is of first-order empirical importance”. In this regard, a and 𝜃 , namely, the shares of profit and activity shifting respectively.19
growing body of literature emphasizes the importance of legal, insti-
tutional, and procedural arrangements for public investment manage-
2.1. Reallocation of taxable income and activity shifting
ment. Recent assessments made by the IMF (2015) highlight average
inefficiencies in public investment processes of around 30 percent.15
In this section, we analyze how a representative MNC located in
In the same vein, Esfahani and Ramirez (2003) show, by estimating
country H decides on the mix of taxable income allocation and activity
a structural model of infrastructure and growth, that achieving bet-
shifting. Consequently, after having done some substitutions in (1), we
ter outcomes requires specific institutional and organizational condi-
assume that the MNC maximizes V(𝜃 p , 𝜃) with respect to 𝜃 p and 𝜃 :
tions, which are “more fundamental than simply designing infrastruc-
ture projects and spending money on them”. For example, Kenny (2009) max V (𝜃p , 𝜃) = (1 − 𝜃p − 𝜃)(1 + 𝛿)(1 − t ) + 𝜃p (1 + 𝛿 − fp )
reports differences in the building cost of a kilometer of similar roads 𝜃p ,𝜃

that vary by five to ten times across different countries.16 1 2 𝛼 2


The tax haven levies fees for the tax planning and infrastructure ser- + 𝜃(1 + G − f ) − 𝜃 − 𝜃 , (2)
2 p 2
vices it provides. Accordingly, a fee fp is charged on one unit of capital
subject to
accruing to the SPE to shift profit abroad, and a fee f is levied on one
unit of capital invested in the tax haven. Tax havens may charge dif- 𝜃p + 𝜃 ≤ 1 , (1a)
ferent types of fees. For instance, Cayman Islands17 charge an annual
fee that is proportional to affiliates’ capital. Similarly, affiliates estab-
𝜃p ≥ 0, (1b)
lished in Gibraltar pay a set-up fee of 0.5% on authorized capital. In
Luxembourg, funds have to pay an annual subscription tax at the rate
of 0.05% on their total assets. 𝜃 ≥ 0. (1c)
By analogy to what we did above, capital shifted to the tax haven
yields a net output depending on both firm and jurisdictional charac-
teristics. It follows that a fraction 𝜃 of capital moved to the tax haven 18
In the main text we assume that the fee fp is charged for a unit of capital
generates a profit equal to 𝜃ΠF , where ΠF = 1 + G. shifted to the SPE. However, even if we assume fp charged on shifted profit, the
model solves almost identically.
19
In the first part of our model, the number of policy instruments designed
to improve a country’s economic attractiveness is higher for the tax haven rel-
atively to the onshore country. This assumption reflects the fact that havens
are often small countries that lack productive domestic resources. It follows
that these countries use policy variables in order to lure foreign capital an pro-
14
If 0 < 𝛼 < 1, activity shifting would be relatively easier to achieve. This vide tax mitigation services. Very large countries are less dependent on external
would make the removal of profit shifting less able to augment tax revenues in resources. This is reflected in this paper by assuming an uneven number of pol-
high-tax countries. icy instruments used to attract/retain firms. We relax this assumption in Section
15
Note that such inefficiencies are not particular to developing countries. 5, which assumes that the onshore region adopts a more reactive attitude by
16
Regarding our cost function 𝛽2 G2 , this means that for a given value of G the also using infrastructure as a possible way to retain mobile firms. However, we
coefficient 𝛽 can be vary across different countries. do not exclude that large countries implement other policy variables that are
17
Cayman Islands levies no taxes on income. not relevant to the purpose of our paper.

4
P. Pieretti, G. Pulina Economic Modelling xxx (xxxx) xxx

The first order conditions resulting from the above maximization shifting by MNCs. Accordingly, the tax haven has an incentive to cap-
yield ture a part of firms’ resulting tax gains by increasing its fees.
Solving the system of the above best responses, we obtain the fol-
𝜃p = t (1 + 𝛿) − fp , (3)
lowing equilibrium values
2𝛼(2𝛼𝛽 − 1 + 𝛽𝛿)
t∗ = ,
t (1 + 𝛿) − f + G − 𝛿 (2(3𝛼𝛽 − 1) + 3𝛼(2𝛼𝛽 − 1))(1 + 𝛿)
𝜃= . (4)
𝛼 𝛼(2𝛼𝛽 − 1 + 𝛽𝛿)
fp∗ = ,
Equation (4) highlights that a multinational company can have an 2(3𝛼𝛽 − 1) + 3𝛼(2𝛼𝛽 − 1)
incentive to invest in real offshore activities even if the home coun- 𝛼𝛽(2𝛼 − 𝛿(2 + 3𝛼))
try provides more attractive infrastructure relative to the tax haven f∗ = ,
2(3𝛼𝛽 − 1) + 3𝛼(2𝛼𝛽 − 1)
(𝛿 > G). A sufficient condition for the occurrence of activity shifting is
that the tax gain t(1 + 𝛿) − f has to be higher than 𝛿 − G. 2𝛼 − 𝛿(2 + 3𝛼)
G∗ = .
2(3𝛼𝛽 − 1) + 3𝛼(2𝛼𝛽 − 1)
2.2. The governments’ decisions An interior solution21 is guaranteed by the conditions
1 2𝛼
We assume that the onshore country sets the corporate tax rate t 𝛼𝛽 > and 𝛿< . (5)
2 2 + 3𝛼
that maximizes its tax revenue T. This assumption is similar to that
The equilibrium shares of profit and activity shifting are
used by Kanbur and Keen (1993), Zissimos and Wooders (2008) and
Pieretti and Zanaj (2011). In fact, if one considers that jurisdictions 𝛽(2𝛼 − 𝛿(2 + 3𝛼))
𝜃∗ = ,
are not self-interested governments, it is reasonable to assume that the 2(3𝛼𝛽 − 1) + 3𝛼(2𝛼𝛽 − 1)
collected taxes are used to finance public consumption. This objective 𝛼(2𝛼𝛽 − 1 + 𝛽𝛿)
is consistent with the classical welfarist view in which consumers place 𝜃p∗ = .
2(3𝛼𝛽 − 1) + 3𝛼(2𝛼𝛽 − 1)
a very high marginal valuation on public goods, which are financed by
tax revenue (see Kanbur and Keen, 1993). The equilibrium tax revenue in the high-tax country is
As it is often the case, we assume that the tax haven is a small 4𝛼(1 + 𝛼)(2𝛼𝛽 − 1 + 𝛽𝛿)2
T∗ = . (6)
country whose source of revenue is only derived from foreign affiliates. (2(3𝛼𝛽 − 1) + 3𝛼(2𝛼𝛽 − 1))2
Therefore, the tax haven decides on the fees fp and f and the infrastruc-
ture expenditure G that maximize its net revenue W. The optimization
problems are 3. The elimination of profit shifting

max T = t (1 − 𝜃p − 𝜃)Πh , In this section, we analyze how the elimination of profit shifting
t
can affect tax revenues in the high-tax country H. In other words, we
𝛽
max W = fp 𝜃p + f 𝜃 − G2 . assume that profit shifting is not anymore an option for the MNC and
fp ,f ,G 2
therefore we set 𝜃 p = 0.
subject to the non negativity conditions (1a)-(1c). As the share of capital invested offshore is now the only available
While maximizing their respective objectives, the governments strategy, the MNC’s profit function becomes
anticipate the MNC’s behavior. Taking account of (3) and (4), the best ̂ = (1 − 𝜃)(1 + 𝛿)(1 − t ) + 𝜃(1 + G − f ) − 𝛼
V 𝜃2.
response of the onshore jurisdiction becomes 2
𝛼(1 + fp ) + f − (G − 𝛿) Maximizing the profit function relative to 𝜃 for given t, f and G yields
t br = . the share of activity shifting
2(1 + 𝛼)(1 + 𝛿)
t (1 + 𝛿) − f + G − 𝛿
The onshore country’s best tax response t is increasing in the tax haven’s 𝜃̂ = .
fees and decreasing in the haven’s infrastructure provision G. Intu- 𝛼
itively, the onshore country has an incentive to increase (decrease) its The governments’ best responses are
tax rate any time the tax haven decreases (increases) its attractiveness.
Accordingly, the best responses of the tax haven are ̂t br = 𝛼 + f − (G − 𝛿) ,
2(1 + 𝛿)
t
fpbr = (1 + 𝛿), ̂f br = 𝛼𝛽(t (1 + 𝛿) − 𝛿) ,
2
2𝛼𝛽 − 1
𝛼𝛽(t (1 + 𝛿) − 𝛿)
f br = , t (1 + 𝛿) − 𝛿
2𝛼𝛽 − 1 ̂ br =
G .
2𝛼𝛽 − 1
t (1 + 𝛿) − 𝛿
Gbr = . Solving the above equation system yields the following equilibrium
2𝛼𝛽 − 1
variables
The second order conditions are always satisfied for 𝛼𝛽 > 12 .20 In other
words, we assume that activity shifting and providing attractive infras- ̂t ∗ = 𝛼(2𝛼𝛽 − 1 + 𝛽𝛿) , (7)
(3𝛼𝛽 − 1)(1 + 𝛿)
tructure are jointly difficult enough. Note that when the onshore econ-
omy increases its corporate tax rate, the tax haven’s best response is to ̂f ∗ = 𝛼𝛽(𝛼 − 𝛿) , (8)
raise its infrastructure provision and the fees of the services it provides. 3𝛼𝛽 − 1
The reason is because higher taxation encourages profit and activity
̂∗ = 𝛼−𝛿
G . (9)
3𝛼𝛽 − 1

𝜕2 T 𝜕2 W 𝜕2 W 𝜕2 W
20
It is easy to check that 𝜕t 2
< 0 for all t ∈ [0, 1] and 𝜕f 2
< 0, 𝜕 fp2
< 0, 𝜕 G2
<
𝜕2 W 𝜕2 W 𝜕2 W 2
0. Moreover, 𝜕f 2
· 𝜕 G2
− ( 𝜕f 𝜕G
) >0 if 𝛼𝛽 > 1
2
. 21
It follows that condition 1a is not binding.

5
P. Pieretti, G. Pulina Economic Modelling xxx (xxxx) xxx

These equilibrium variables are positive because of condition (5). nation of profit shifting increases activity shifting relatively more than
The share of activity shifting becomes corporate taxation, tax revenue will decrease. Consequently, the elim-
ination of profit shifting translates into higher onshore tax revenues
𝛽(𝛼 − 𝛿)
𝜃̂∗ = . (10) if tax havens are unable to increase sufficiently their attractiveness to
3𝛼𝛽 − 1
foreign real business.
Note that the elimination of profit shifting increases the share of real The previous proposition shows that the total elimination of profit
business shifted. Indeed, it is easy to show that 𝜃̂∗ − 𝜃 ∗ > 0 given that shifting, which is ultimately destined to increase tax revenue in high-tax
𝛼𝛽 > 12 .22 countries, may not be successful given that it triggers another form of
Finally, the equilibrium tax revenue in the high-tax country equals base erosion, namely activity shifting. However, profit shifting may not
𝛼(2𝛼𝛽 − 1 + 𝛽𝛿)2 be entirely eliminated. In fact, current actions and regulations, such as
̂∗ =
T . (11)
(3𝛼𝛽 − 1)2 the BEPS and the ATAD, allow some profit shifting to low-tax jurisdic-
tions. Moreover, shifted profit can be subject to a minimal taxation in
low-tax jurisdictions (see the “Controlled Foreign Company (CFC) rule”
4. The effectiveness of removing profit shifting in the ATAD Article 7(1)).
Our model can be easily adapted to include a binding cap on profit
Now, we compare the results derived from the non-profit shifting shifting and the imposition of a minimum offshore tax. Then, it can be
scenario of the previous section with those of the bench-mark scenario shown that the main results of the paper, highlighted in Proposition 1,
of Section 2. In the following proposition we establish under what con- still remain.24
dition removing profit shifting can have an adverse effect on the tax Finally, the following proposition highlights cases in which the MNC
revenue in the high-tax country. prefers it when competition is restricted to being only in productive
Proposition 1. The removal of profit shifting decreases the tax revenue in investments.
the high-tax country if the haven is efficient enough in providing attractive Proposition 2. When the tax haven is efficient enough in providing infras-
infrastructure . However, this is less likely to occur the more it is costly to tructure and the provision of infrastructure in the onshore country is not too
shift activities in the tax haven. Formally: ΔT = T̂∗ − T ∗ < 0 if 𝛽 < 𝛽̃, high, the MNC is better off when profit shifting is eliminated. Formally,
where
( )
∗ >0
Va∗ − Vpa ̂
for 𝛽 < 𝛽.
̃ 1 1 1 𝜕 𝛽̃
𝛽= + √ and <0. Proof. In Appendix B.
𝛼 2 6 1+𝛼 𝜕𝛼 ▪

The intuition is that the elimination of profit shifting reduces the


Proof. Let us set
intensity of tax competition for mobile firms and increases infrastruc-
ΔT = A · B, ture competition. The MNC can gain, swapping profit shifting for activ-
ity shifting, as long as the tax haven is very efficient and infrastructure
where provision is not too high in the home country.
𝛼 2 (2𝛼𝛽 − 1 + 𝛽𝛿)2
A= > 0, (12)
(3𝛼𝛽 − 1)2 (6𝛼𝛽(1 + 𝛼) − (2 + 3𝛼))2 5. Infrastructure competition

In this section, we assume that the high-tax region tries to counter


B = 36(1 + 𝛼)𝛼 2 𝛽 2 − 36(1 + 𝛼)𝛼𝛽 + 8 + 9𝛼. (13) international activity shifting by competing in infrastructure with the
tax haven. One important aspect is to check the robustness of the above
It follows that sign (ΔT ) = sign (B). From (13), we see that B is quadratic conclusions by endogenizing the infrastructure choice of the onshore
in 𝛽 . Solving B(𝛽) = 0 relative to 𝛽 yields two distinct positive roots,23 country.
but only the highest value 𝛽̃ of both is relevant if we impose condition In the following, we limit ourselves to the main results and the
(5) that guarantees the existence of an interior solution. So, we conclude computations are relegated to Appendix A. For consistency reasons, we
that redefine 𝛿 as Gh and G as Gf when there is infrastructure competition.
{
≤ 0 𝛽 ≤ 𝛽, ̃ As we did it for the tax haven, we assume that Gh units of infrastruc-
ΔT = ture are needed to generate Gh units of net output in the onshore econ-
>0 otherwise.▪
omy. Hence, Gh accounts for both the infrastructure provision and the
Intuitively, the removal of profit shifting makes MNCs more captive, resulting output that accrues to home investing firms. Once again, we
which induces the onshore region to increase its corporate tax rate t. assume that the cost of infrastructure provision is given by an increasing
G 2
This entices the tax haven to invest in attractive infrastructure designed convex function 2h .
to encourage activity shifting by MNCs which increases 𝜃 . If the elimi- Now the onshore country is supposed to choose the corporate tax

22
More generally, it is possible to demonstrate that in equilibrium the share
of activity and profit shifting are negatively related. To show this, assume that 24
A more general model (available on request) leads to the following con-
the share of profit shifting is bounded from above. The “capped” share of profit clusions. A positive cap on profit shifting rather than the complete elimination
shifting becomes 𝜃p (with 𝜃p ≤ 𝜃p < 𝜃p∗ ). A decrease in 𝜃p can be interpreted as of profit shifting (0 < 𝜃p ≤ 𝜃p ) decreases tax revenue in the onshore country.
a more restrictive policy regarding profit shifting devices, while an increase in Moreover, requiring a minimum offshore tax on shifted profits will result in
𝜃p makes profit shifting easier. After having solved the model with this binding two opposing effects. First, it will reduce profit shifting (positive effect) and
𝜕 𝜃̂∗
cap it is possible to demonstrate that
𝜕𝜃p
< 0 given that 𝛼𝛽 > 12 . It follows that, second, it will induce additional activity shifting (negative effect). Which effect
ultimately dominates depends on the parameter constellation of the model and
the easier shifting profit offshore becomes (increasing 𝜃p ), the lower will be the
in particular, on the efficiency of the tax haven in providing attractive infras-
incentive to shift activity abroad (lower 𝜃̂∗ ). tructure. Finally, note that the more constraining these two regulations, the
( ) ( )
23 ̃
𝛽 = 𝛼1 12 + √1 > 0 and ̃𝛽̃ = 𝛼1 12 − √
1
> 0. more they will be equivalent to the total elimination of profit shifting.
6 1+𝛼 6 1+𝛼

6
P. Pieretti, G. Pulina Economic Modelling xxx (xxxx) xxx

rate t and the amount Gh . Consequently, the problem of the high-tax the loss of tax revenue after the elimination of profit shifting. By con-
country becomes25 trast, if the tax haven is not efficient enough (𝛽 > 𝛽̃′ ), the elimination of
profit shifting results in higher gains in tax revenue when the number
Gh 2
max Wh = t (1 − 𝜃p − 𝜃)(1 + Gh ) − . of immobile firms is relatively higher.
t ,Gh 2
The underlying intuition can be explained as follows. The higher
As already assumed in the previous sections, the tax haven is sup- the number of immobile firms, the less the onshore tax policy will be
posed to decide on the fees fp and f and the infrastructure expendi- sensitive to MNCs’ behavior. This tends to increase the home tax rate.
ture Gf . In the Appendix we solve the game between the onshore and The impact of this increase on the domestic tax revenue depends on
offshore jurisdictions with and without profit shifting. The following how efficient the haven is in providing attractive infrastructure. If it
results can then be highlighted.26 is very efficient (𝛽 < 𝛽̃′ ), the outflow of capital to the tax haven will
First, we show (see Appendix A) that the onshore economy can dominate the home tax increase. As a result, the tax revenue decreases.
provide a higher equilibrium amount of infrastructure than the tax Otherwise (𝛽 > 𝛽̃′ ), the home tax increase will dominate the capital
haven (Gh ∗∗ > Gf ∗∗ and G ̂h ∗∗ > G
̂f ∗∗ ) if 𝛽 > 1 . Notwithstanding this outflow and consequently, tax revenue increases in the country H with
2
case, the onshore economy is not able to prevent activity shifting the elimination of profit shifting.
(𝜃 ∗∗ > 0 and 𝜃̂∗∗ > 0). As we explained in a previous section, this is Now, notice that the BEPS initiative focuses on the concept of base
the case because the relative tax advantage provided by the tax haven erosion. In our model, base erosion () is given by the parameters 𝜃 p
is high enough. and 𝜃 , which stand respectively for the shares of profit and activity
Second, in case of a removal of profit shifting the welfare of the high- shifting. Consequently, the amount of base erosion with and without
tax economy will not unambiguously increase. Indeed, the elimination profit shifting (in case of infrastructure competition) is given by
of tax planning reduces the onshore welfare (the tax revenue net of the
𝛼(2𝛼𝛽 − 1) + 2𝛽(𝛼 − 1)
cost of infrastructure provision) if the low-tax jurisdiction is efficient  = 𝜃 ∗∗ + 𝜃p∗∗ = , (15)
3𝛼(2𝛼𝛽 − 1) + 2d
enough in providing attractive infrastructure (W ̂h ∗∗ < W ∗∗ if 𝛽 < 𝛽̃′ ).
h
However, when the high-tax economy does not compete in infrastruc- ̂ = 𝜃̂∗∗ = 𝛽(𝛼 − 1)
 , (16)
ture provision, the threshold under which the level 𝛽 induces a wel- d
fare decrease is higher than in the case of infrastructure competition. where d = 𝛽 (3𝛼 − 1) − 1.
Indeed, we prove in Appendix A that 𝛽̃′ < 𝛽̃. Let us now check if base erosion and tax revenue losses incurred
by high-tax jurisdictions move in the same direction. To this end we
Proposition 3. When the high-tax jurisdiction uses infrastructure provi-
consider the difference Δ = ̂ −  given by the following expression.
sion strategically, the removal of profit shifting can reduce the welfare in the
high-tax economy if 𝛽 < 𝛽̃′ , namely when the tax haven is efficient( enough
) 𝛼(2𝛼𝛽 − 1)(1 − 2𝛽)
Δ = . (17)
in providing attractive infrastructure. However, for each 𝛽 ∈ 𝛽̃′ , 𝛽̃ the d(3𝛼(2𝛼𝛽 − 1) + 2d)
elimination of profit shifting is beneficial to the high-tax region if it competes It follows that the removal of profit shifting induces base repatria-
in infrastructure and detrimental when it does not. Formally, tion (Δ < 0) if the tax haven is not efficient enough (𝛽 > 12 ) in pro-
viding attractive infrastructure. In this case, base repatriation implies
if 𝛽̃ > 𝛽 > 𝛽̃′ , it follows that W
̂h ∗∗ > W ∗∗ and T
̂∗ < T ∗ . (14)
h increasing welfare in the high-tax jurisdiction because 𝛽 > 𝛽̃′ , given
Proof. In Appendix A. that 12 > 𝛽̃′ .27 Note that a decrease in base erosion is sufficient to induce

increased tax revenue but it is not a necessary condition. Indeed, if
The underlying intuition is the same as explained above. The elim- 𝛽̃′ < 𝛽 < 12 , the eradication of profit shifting increases tax revenue in
ination of profit shifting has two effects. On the one hand, it increases the onshore economy even if base erosion increases. The intuition can
the incentive to raise the tax rate in the high-tax region, but on the be explained as follows.
other hand, it induces more activity shifting. The second effect domi- When profit shifting is eliminated, firms are more exposed to higher
nates when the low-tax country is efficient enough in attracting foreign taxation in their home country. As a reaction, the tax haven tries to
businesses. encourage activity shifting by increasing its infrastructure provision.
A more general and realistic approach should account for the exis- This can result in a higher outflow of taxable income such that base
tence of internationally immobile firms in country H in addition to erosion increases but to a lesser extent than taxation increases as a
MNCs. Given that infrastructure facilities are public goods, we could result of the removal of profit shifting. This is precisely what happens
account for positive spillovers induced by the infrastructure provision when the efficiency parameter is larger than 𝛽̃′ but smaller than 12 .
on the productivity of the whole economy. Moreover, the model could
also account for the size of the onshore jurisdiction, if we reasonably Proposition 4. A reduction of base erosion as a consequence of the
assume that the country size and the share of internationally immobile removal of profit shifting is sufficient to induce increased tax revenue in
firms in the total number of domestic firms are positively correlated. the onshore economy. The reverse is not necessarily true. In particular, if
In this case, the bigger the country H, the less it is likely to condition 𝛽̃′ < 𝛽 < 12 , the eradication of profit shifting increases tax revenue in the
its corporate tax rate on the policy responses of MNCs and foreign tax onshore economy even if base erosion increases.
havens. The corporate tax rate will then be tailored to all the domestic
Proof. In the text.
firms and not only on MNC′s activities.
In Appendix C, we incorporate internationally immobile firms in
our model. It is then possible to demonstrate that Proposition 3 does 6. Conclusion
not change. However, if the tax haven is efficient enough in provid-
ing attractive infrastructure (𝛽 < 𝛽̃′ ), it can be shown that the higher Base erosion through profit shifting is considered a serious problem
the number of immobile firms (or the bigger the country H), the larger since it potentially reduces tax revenue in onshore economies. In this

25
It is easy to check that the following second order conditions are verified:
𝜕 2 Wh
< 0, 𝜕𝜕GW2h < 0 and 𝜕𝜕W · 𝜕𝜕GW2h − ( 𝜕𝜕t 𝜕WGh )2 > 0, given that 𝛼 ≥ 1.
2 2 2 2
h
𝜕t 2 h t2 h h
26
We use the suffix ∗∗ to refer to the case of infrastructure competition and
𝜕 𝛽̃′
the circumflex ̂ is used in the absence of profit shifting. 27
Indeed, lim𝛼 →1 𝛽̃′ = 1
2
and 𝜕𝛼
≤ 0, ∀𝛼 > 1.

7
P. Pieretti, G. Pulina Economic Modelling xxx (xxxx) xxx

context, the BEPS initiative, launched recently by the OECD (OECD, business-friendly infrastructure. Moreover, according to their character-
2013a; b, 2014), and the European directive, the ATAD, should help istics they can only offer certain types of infrastructure services. Indeed,
eliminate profit shifting with the aim of increasing onshore tax revenue. given that most tax havens tend to be small in size and thus lack nat-
This paper demonstrates that the positive effects of the BEPS initia- ural and human resources and have limited land area, they have few
tive and the ATAD could be undermined. In fact, in the same vein as options beyond financial services and tourism (Morriss, 2008). An effi-
Hines (2014), we argue that anti tax planning regulations can induce cient way to specialize in offshore financial activities can be achieved
multinational firms to use other ways to mitigate their tax liabilities, through attractive institutional infrastructure provision. The small size
such as shifting real activities to tax havens. As a result, the removal of of their governments makes them more responsive to changes in the
tax-motivated profit shifting increases the tax revenue in the onshore international economic environment and consequently, they tend to be
region only if the low-tax jurisdiction is not too efficient in providing efficient in adapting and innovating legislation and regulations to facili-
attractive infrastructure. Additionally, we highlight that the BEPS ini- tate financial transactions. According to Morriss (2008), “The most suc-
tiative and its regional implementations, such as the ATAD, are more cessful offshore jurisdictions today have evolved from an initial focus
likely to be successful if the high-tax country is able to counter the shift- on company registries and similar activities to a mix of financial cen-
ing of international activity by competing in infrastructure rather than ter activities that include legal, accounting, and other services in an
being passive. attempt to expand the portion of the economic activity occurring within
Neither the BEPS initiative nor the ATAD account for international their borders”.
activity transfers that could result from anti profit-shifting campaigns. Finally, we also highlight that fighting aggressive tax planning does
However, we could witness the emergence of another form of base ero- not necessarily affect base erosion and onshore tax revenue in the same
sion that deserves official scrutiny. Of course, tax havens must be able way. In particular, a possible eradication of profit shifting can increase
to attract foreign business activity and therefore must provide sufficient tax revenue without the need to reduce base erosion.

Appendix A. the model with infrastructure competition

First we solve the game described in Section 5 in the absence of profit shifting. The resulting equilibrium variables are given as follows:

̂t ∗∗ 𝛼(2𝛼𝛽 − 1)
= ,
d + 2𝛼𝛽 − 1

̂h ∗∗ = 2𝛼𝛽 − 1
G ,
d
̂f ∗∗ = 𝛼−1
G ,
d
̂f ∗∗ = 𝛼𝛽 · G
̂f ∗∗ ,

𝛽(𝛼 − 1)
𝜃̂∗∗ = ,
d
where d = 𝛽(3𝛼 − 1) − 1 > 0 since 𝛼 ≥ 1 and 𝛼𝛽 > 1
2
.
̂h ∗∗ > G
Note that when 𝛽 > 12 , the onshore economy provides more attractive infrastructure than the tax haven (G ̂f ∗∗ ).
The equilibrium tax revenue in the high-tax country is

̂h ∗∗ = (2𝛼 − 1)(2𝛼𝛽 − 1)2


W . (18)
2d2
If we consider the possibility of profit shifting, the game yields the following equilibrium results
( )
2d + 2(2𝛼𝛽 − 1) ̂t ∗∗ < ̂t ∗∗ ,
t ∗∗ =
(3𝛼 + 2)(2𝛼𝛽 − 1) + 2d
⏟⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏟⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏟
<1
( )
2d ̂h ∗∗ < G
̂h ∗∗ ,
Gh ∗∗ = G
3𝛼(2𝛼𝛽 − 1) + 2d
⏟⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏟⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏟
<1
( )
2d ̂f ∗∗ < G
̂f ∗∗ ,
Gf ∗∗ = G
3𝛼(2𝛼𝛽 − 1) + 2d
⏟⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏟⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏞⏟
<1

f ∗∗ = 𝛼𝛽 · Gf ∗∗ ,

t ∗∗
fp∗∗ = (1 + Gh ∗∗ ).
2
The equilibrium levels of profit and activity shifting are
2𝛽(𝛼 − 1)
𝜃 ∗∗ = ,
3𝛼(2𝛼𝛽 − 1) + 2d
𝛼(2𝛼𝛽 − 1)
𝜃p∗∗ = .
3𝛼(2𝛼𝛽 − 1) + 2d
The equilibrium tax revenue in the high-tax country is
2(2𝛼(1 + 𝛼) − 1)(2𝛼𝛽 − 1)2
Wh∗∗ = ,
(3𝛼(2𝛼𝛽 − 1) + 2d)2

8
P. Pieretti, G. Pulina Economic Modelling xxx (xxxx) xxx

It follows that
̂h ∗∗ − W ∗∗ < 0 if
ΔWh = W h
𝛽 < 𝛽̃′
To provide a proof, first set ΔWh = A′ · B′ , where

1 (2𝛼𝛽 − 1)2
A′ = [ ] > 0, (19)
2 d2 3𝛼(2𝛼𝛽 − 1) + 2d 2

[ ]
B′ = 4 4 + 9𝛼(−2 + 𝛼 + 2𝛼 2 ) 𝛼 2 𝛽 2 (20)

[ ]
− 4 3 + 𝛼(9𝛼(1 + 2𝛼)) − 17 𝛼𝛽
[ ]
+ 𝛼 𝛼(7 + 18𝛼) − 12 .
( )
It follows that sign (ΔWh ) = sign B′ . From (20), we see that B′ is quadratic in 𝛽 . Solving B′ (𝛽) = 0 relative to 𝛽 yields two distinct positive
roots,28 but only the highest value 𝛽̃′ of both is relevant if we impose the condition (5) that guarantees the existence of an interior solution.
So, we conclude that
{
≤0 𝛽 ≤ 𝛽̃′ ,
ΔWh =
>0 otherwise.

Recalling the threshold value 𝛽̃, it follows that 𝛽̃ > 𝛽̃′ > 0 for finite values of 𝛼 (𝛼 > 1). The proof is derived from the following properties. The
𝜕 𝛽̃ 𝛽̃′
difference 𝛽̃ − 𝛽̃′ is strictly positive when 𝛼 = 1 and tends to 0 when 𝛼 → +∞. In addition, we verify that 𝜕𝛼 < 0 and 𝜕𝜕𝛼 < 0, ∀𝛼 > 1.

Appendix B. proof of Proposition 2

If competition is restricted to being only in productive investments, the representative multinational can only decide on activity shifting. In this
case, the profit is
( )
𝛼𝛽 2 18𝛼 − 11𝛼 2 + 𝛿 2 + 10𝛼𝛿 + 2𝛼𝛽 (5𝛼 − 5𝛿 − 6) − 2 (𝛼 − 1) + 2𝛿
Va∗ = .
2(3𝛼𝛽 − 1)2
If competition is not restricted to being only in productive investments, the representative multinational can decide on activity and profit shifting. In
this case, the profit is

∗ 𝛼(1 + 𝛼)(−4𝛿 2 (11 + 7𝛿) + 4𝛼 2 (7 + (17 − 6𝛿)𝛿) + 𝛼(72 + 𝛿(16 − 𝛿(31 + 39𝛿))))𝛽 2
Vpa = +
2[3𝛼 + 2 − 6𝛼𝛽 (𝛼 + 1)]2 (1 + 𝛿)
(−4𝛼(2 + 𝛼)(6 + 7𝛼) − 2𝛼(4 + 𝛼(39 + 34𝛼))𝛿 + 2(8 + 𝛼(24 + 𝛼(29 + 12𝛼)))𝛿 2 + 8(1 + 𝛼)(2 + 3𝛼)𝛿 3 )𝛽
+
2[3𝛼 + 2 − 6𝛼𝛽 (𝛼 + 1)]2 (1 + 𝛿)
+8 + 𝛼(16 + 7𝛼) + 𝛼(16 + 17𝛼)𝛿 − 2(2 + 𝛼)(2 + 3𝛼)𝛿 2
.
2[3𝛼 + 2 − 6𝛼𝛽 (𝛼 + 1)]2 (1 + 𝛿)

The representative multinational prefers when competition is restricted to being only in productive investments if Va∗ > Vpa ∗ . This is the case when

the tax haven is efficient enough in providing infrastructure and the provision of infrastructure in the onshore country is low enough.
The proof is given as follows. After having computed the difference Va∗ − Vpa ∗ it follows that the sign of V ∗ − V ∗ equals the sign of the following
a pa
polynomial:
( )
P(𝛽) = 9𝛼 3 (1 + 𝛼)(2𝛼 + 𝛿)(22𝛼 2 (1 + 𝛿) − 16𝛿(3 + 2𝛿) − 𝛼𝛿(11 + 43𝛿)) 𝛽 4 −
( )
6𝛼 2 6𝛼 3 (20 + 21𝛼) + 𝛼(−216 + 𝛼(−239 + 2𝛼(50 + 63𝛼)))𝛿 − (72 + 𝛼(257 + 4𝛼(92 + 45𝛼)))𝛿 2 − (1 + 𝛼)(56 + 81𝛼)𝛿 3 𝛽 3 +
( )
𝛼 531𝛼 4 (1 + 𝛿) − 16𝛿 2 (9 + 8𝛿) + 𝛼 3 (469 + (317 − 744𝛿)𝛿) − 4𝛼 2 𝛿(223 + 𝛿(355 + 48𝛿)) − 𝛼𝛿(720 + 𝛿(799 + 319𝛿)) 𝛽 2 +
( )
2 −81𝛼 4 (1 + 𝛿) + 8𝛿 2 (1 + 𝛿) + 4𝛼𝛿(22 + 𝛿(23 + 5𝛿)) + 𝛼 2 𝛿(121 + 𝛿(197 + 12𝛿)) + 𝛼 3 (−65 + 𝛿(−34 + 111𝛿)) 𝛽 +

18𝛼 3 (1 + 𝛿) − 16𝛿(1 + 𝛿) − 8𝛼𝛿(3 + 5𝛿) + 𝛼 2 (13 + (5 − 24𝛿)𝛿).


1
Solving P(𝛽) = 0 yields two complex roots, and the two non-negative real roots, 𝛽real = 2𝛼+𝛿 and 𝛽̂. The first real root is excluded by the condition
(5),29 and the second is meaningful if 𝛿 is small enough. It follows in this case that
̂
∗ > 0for𝛽 < 𝛽.
Va∗ − Vpa

√ √
̃
28
𝛽̃′ = 𝛼(9𝛼(1+2𝛼)−17)+3(1+(𝛼−1) 1+2𝛼(−2+𝛼+2𝛼 2 ))
2𝛼(4+9𝛼(−2+𝛼+2𝛼 2 ))
and 𝛽̃′ = 𝛼(−17+9𝛼(1+2𝛼))−3(−1+ (−1+𝛼)2 (1+2𝛼(−2+𝛼+2𝛼 2 )))
2𝛼(4+9𝛼(−2+𝛼+2𝛼 2 ))
> 0.
29
In fact, according to this condition, and given 𝛿 > 0, 𝛽 > 1
2𝛼
> 1
2𝛼+𝛿
.

9
P. Pieretti, G. Pulina Economic Modelling xxx (xxxx) xxx

Appendix C. the model with immobile firms

The model developed in Section 5 can be extended in the following way. We further assume that there are m (normalized to 1) identical
multinational companies. In addition, there are n (identical) local firms that are considered as internationally immobile. Their productivity is
positively impacted by infrastructure investments. This increases home production and thus the home tax base. On the contrary, the corporate tax
rate has a negative effect.

• If the tax rate t increases, mobile firms react by shifting profit and activity in a low-tax country and thus decrease the tax base in the home
country. Similarly, the immobile firms reduce their activities, which decreases their profit.
• If infrastructure provision Gh decreases in the home country, mobile firms shift real business abroad. Similarly, immobile firms reduce their
activities, which lowers their profit.

The home tax base of a representative MNC is 𝜋im (t , Gh ) = (1 − θ(t , Gh ) − θp (t , Gh ))(1 + Gh ). The tax base of a representative immobile firm is
𝜋im (t , Gh ). As explained above, 𝜋im (t , Gh ) decreases with corporate taxation ( 𝜕𝜋𝜕tim < 0) and increases with the home country provision of public
infrastructure ( 𝜕𝜋
𝜕G
im
> 0).
h
For simplicity, we assume that the profit of an immobile firm is given by the following form that accounts for the above assumptions,
𝜆Gh Gh
𝜋im (t , Gh ) =
𝜆t t
The coefficients 𝜆Gh > 0 and 𝜆t > 0 account for the profit sensitivity of immobile firms to infrastructure provision and corporate taxes, respectively.
The welfare function of the home country can now be written as follows,

[ ] G2
Wh = t m · 𝜋m (t , Gh ) + n · 𝜋im (t , Gh ) − h .
2
Note that, setting n = 0 brings us back to the particular case of our model without immobile firms, analyzed in Section 5.
𝜆G
To guarantee an interior solution of the game, we require that n 𝜆 h < 23(𝛼−𝛼+2
1)
. After standard calculations, we get the same result as in Section 5
t
of our paper, namely that the onshore tax revenue may decrease after the complete elimination of international profit shifting if the offshore country
is efficient enough in providing attractive infrastructure (𝛽 < 𝛽̃′ ). It follows that the main conclusion of our paper is preserved when accounting for
the size of the onshore country by introducing immobile firms.
However, if the tax haven is efficient enough (𝛽 < 𝛽̃′ ) in providing attractive infrastructure, it can be demonstrated that the higher the number
(n increases) of immobile firms (or the higher the size of country H), the higher the loss of tax revenue will be after the elimination of profit shifting.
By contrast, if the tax haven is not efficient enough (𝛽 > 𝛽̃′ ), the elimination of profit shifting results in higher gains in tax revenue when the number
(n) of immobile firms is relatively higher.

References Haufler, A., Schjelderup, G., 2000. Corporate tax systems and cross country profit
shifting. Oxf. Econ. Pap. 52, 306–325.
Alms, M., Kieran, T., Cliona, D., 2016. Has BEPS signaled the death knell for U.S. Hauptmeier, Sebastian, Mittermaier, Ferdinand, Rincke, Johannes, 2012. Fiscal
Pharmaceutical IP migration to Ireland? Tax Plann. Int. Rev. 43 May. competition over taxes and public inputs. Reg. Sci. Urban Econ. 42 (3), 407–419.
Bénassy-Quéré, Agnès, Gobalraja, Nicolas, Trannoy, Alain, 2007. Tax and public input Heckemeyer, J.H., Overesch, M., 2013. Multinationals′ Profit Response to Tax
competition. Econ. Pol. 22, 385–430 April. Differentials: Effect Size and Shifting Channels. ZEW Discussion Paper, 13-045.
Bucovetsky, S., 2014. Honor among tax havens. J. Publ. Econ. 110, 74–81. Hines, J.R., 2010. Treasure Islands. J. Econ. Perspect. 24, 103–126.
Bucovetsky, S., Haufler, A., 2008. Tax competition when firms choose their Hines, J.R., 2014. Policy forum: how serious is the problem of base erosion and profit
organizational form: should tax loopholes for multinationals be closed? J. Int. Econ. shifting? Can. Tax J. 62, 443–454.
74, 188–201. Hong, Q., Smart, M., 2010. In praise of tax havens:International tax planning and
Dembour, Carole, Wauthy, Xavier, 2009. Investment in public infrastructure with foreign direct investment. Eur. Econ. Rev. 54, 82–95.
spillovers and tax competition between contiguous regions. Reg. Sci. Urban Econ. 39 Huizinga, H., Laeven, L., 2008. International profit shifting within European
(6), 679–687. multinationals. J. Publ. Econ. 92, 1164–1182.
Desai, M.A., Foley, C.F., Hines, J.R., 2006a. The demand for tax haven operations. J. IMF, 2015. Making Public Investment More Efficient. IMF Staff Report, Washington.
Publ. Econ. 90, 513–531. Janeba, E., Smart, M., 2006. Is targeted tax competition less harmful than its remedies?
Desai, Mihir A., Foley, C. Fritz, Hines Jr., James, 2006b. A multinational perspective on Int. Tax Publ. Finance 10, 259–280.
capital structure choice and internal capital markets. J. Finance 59, 2451–2487. Johannesen, N., 2010. Imperfect tax competition for profits, asymmetric equilibrium and
Desai, Mihir A., Foley, C. Fritz, Hines, James R., 2009. Domestic effects of the foreign beneficial tax havens. J. Int. Econ. 84, 253–264.
activities of US multinationals. Am. Econ. J. Econ. Pol. 1 (1), 181–203. Justman, Moshe, Thisse, Jacques-Francois, van Ypersele, Tanguy, 2002. Taking the bite
Dharmapala, D., 2008. What problems and opportunities are created by tax havens? Oxf. out of fiscal competition. J. Urban Econ. 52 (2), 294–315.
Rev. Econ. Pol. 24, 661–679. Justman, Moshe, Thisse, Jacques-Francois, van Ypersele, Tanguy, 2005. Fiscal
Dharmapala, D., Hines, J.R., 2009. Which countries become tax havens? J. Publ. Econ. competition and regional differentiation. Reg. Sci. Urban Econ. 35 (6), 848–861.
93 (9–10), 1058–1068. Kanbur, Ravi, Keen, Michael, 1993. Jeux sans frontieres: tax competition and tax
Dischinger, Matthias, Riedel, Nadine, 2011. Corporate taxes and the location of coordination when countries differ in size. Am. Econ. Rev. 83 (4), 877–892.
intangible assets within multinational firms. J. Publ. Econ. 95 (7), 691–707. Keen, Michael, 2001. Preferential regimes can make tax competition less harmful. Natl.
Elsayyad, May, Konrad, Kai A., 2012. Fighting multiple tax havens. J. Int. Econ. 86 (2), Tax J. 54 (4), 757–762.
295–305. Keen, Michael, Konrad, Kai A., 2013. Chapter 5 - the theory of international tax
Esfahani, Hadi Salehi, Ramirez, Maria Teresa, 2003. Institutions, infrastructure, and competition and coordination. In: Auerbach, Alan J., Chetty, Raj, Feldstein, Martin,
economic growth. J. Dev. Econ. 70 (2), 443–477. Saez, Emmanuel (Eds.), Handbook of Public Economics, Vol. 5. Handbook of Public
European Commission, 2016a. COM(2016) 23 Final, Proposal for a Council Directive Economics, vol. 5. Elsevier, pp. 257–328.
Laying Down Rules against Tax Avoidance Practices that Directly Affect the Kenny, Charles, 2009. Measuring corruption in infrastructure: evidence from transition
Functioning of the Internal Market. and developing countries. J. Dev. Stud. 45 (3), 314–332.
European Commission, 2016b. COM(2016) 24 Final, Communication from the Morriss, A.P., 2008. The Role of Offshore Financial Centers in Regulatory Competition.
Commission to the. European Parliament and the Council. Illinois Law & Economics Research Paper No. LE07-032.
European Commission, 2016c. COM(2016) 25 Final. Proposal for a Council Directive OECD, 2013a. Action Plan on Base Erosion and Profit Shifting. Organisation for
Amending Directive 2011/16/EU as Regards Mandatory Automatic Exchange of Economic Cooperation and Development, Paris.
Information in the Field of Taxation. OECD, 2013b. Addressing Base Erosion and Profit Shifting. Organisation for Economic
European Commission, 2016d. COM(2016) 271 Final, Commission Recommendation of Cooperation and Development, Paris.
28.1.2016 on the Implementation of Measures against Tax Treaty Abuse. OECD, 2014. Explanatory Statement, OECD/G20 Base Erosion and Profit Shifting
Gonzalez, M., Schipke, A., 2011. Bankers on the beach. Finance Dev. 48 (2), 42–45. Project. Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development, Paris.

10
P. Pieretti, G. Pulina Economic Modelling xxx (xxxx) xxx

OECD, 2015. Aligning Transfer Pricing Outcomes with Value Creation, Actions 8-10 - Slemrod, J., Wilson, J.D., 2009. Tax competition with parasitic tax havens. J. Publ.
2015 Final Reports. Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development, Paris. Econ. 93 (11–12), 1261–1270.
Overesch, Michael, 2009. The effects of multinationals′ profit shifting activities on real Stöwhase, S., 2005. Asymmetric capital tax competition with profit shifting. J. Econ. 85
investments. Natl. Tax J. 62 (1), 5–23. (2), 175–196.
Peralta, S., Wauthy, X., van Ypersele, T., 2006. Should countries control international The Economist, 2015. All My Bags Are Packed - Corporate America′s Tax-Driven Exodus
profit shifting? J. Int. Econ. 68, 24–37. Continues. The Economist, August 15th.
Pieretti, P., Zanaj, S., 2011. On tax competition, public goods provision and UNCTAD, 2013. World Investment Report 2013.
jurisdictions′ size. J. Int. Econ. 84, 124–130. UNCTAD, 2015. World Investment Report 2015.
Pritchett, Lant, 2000. The tyranny of concepts: CUDIE (cumulated, depreciated, Zissimos, Ben, Wooders, Myrna, 2008. Public good differentiation and the intensity of
investment effort) is not capital. J. Econ. Growth 5 (4), 361–384. tax competition. J. Publ. Econ. 92 (5–6), 1105–1121.

11

You might also like