Roper,: Walter Reed Army Institute of Research

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 17

JOURNAL OF THE EXPERIMENTAL ANALYSIS OF BEHAVIOR 1991, 56, 377-393 NUMBER 2 (SEPrEMBER)

BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS OF DRUG SELF-ADMINISTRATION AND


DRUG ABUSE POLICY
STEVEN R. HURSH
WALTER REED ARMY INSTITUTE OF RESEARCH
The concepts of behavioral economics have proven useful for understanding the environmental control
of overall levels of responding for a variety of commodities, including reinforcement by drug self-
administration. These general concepts are summarized for application to the analysis of drug-rein-
forced behavior and proposed as the basis for future applications. This behavioral agenda includes
the assessment of abuse liability, the assay of drug-reinforcer interactions, the design of drug abuse
interventions, and the formulation of drug abuse public policy. These separate domains of investigation
are described as part of an overall strategy for designing model projects to control drug use and testing
public policy initiatives.
Key words: behavioral economics, demand curve, elasticity, drug self-administration, cost, unit price,
FR schedule, public policy, design of culture

Concepts of behavioral economics have (Brady & Lukas, 1984; Johanson, 1978). In
proven useful for understanding the environ- general, drugs that maintain recreational use
mental control of overall levels of responding in humans will serve as reinforcers for behav-
for a variety of commodities in closed systems ior in nonhumans, the one general exception
(Foltin, in press; Hursh, 1984; Lea, 1978; Lea being hallucinogens, which follow an atypical
& Roper, 1977; Rashotte & Henderson, 1988). pattern of use in humans as well (Griffiths,
Recently, several publications have demon- Bigelow, & Henningfield, 1980). In a typical
strated the applicability of these same prin- experiment with heroin as the reinforcer (Els-
ciples for describing the strength of perfor- more, personal communication), monkeys were
mances maintained by drug reinforcement prepared with indwelling catheters for the de-
(Bickel, DeGrandpre, Higgins, & Hughes, livery of small-volume infusions of heroin or
1990; Bickel, DeGrandpre, Hughes, & Hig- vehicle dependent on the occurrence of key-
gins, 1991). This paper summarizes the basic press responses. A similar key could provide
principles of behavioral economics as applied 750 mg food pellets. Without special shaping
to drug-reinforced behavior and proposes the procedures, responding for heroin gradually
following agenda for future applications: (a) increased to stable levels above that observed
assessment of abuse liability, (b) assay of drug- when responses produced vehicle (saline so-
reinforcer interactions, (c) framework for de- lution). Over subsequent conditions, the num-
signing drug abuse interventions, and (d) strat- ber of responses required to obtain an injection
egy for formulating drug abuse public policy. (fixed-ratio schedule, FR) was increased from
1 to 240. Figure 1 (bottom panel) shows the
ASSESSMENT OF ABUSE LIABILITY number of injections obtained per day as a
A large variety of drugs have been shown function of the size of the FR. This plot of
to serve as reinforcers for operant behavior daily drug consumption as a function of the
FR (price) is termed a demand curve. When
The views of the authors do not purport to reflect the plotted in log-log coordinates, the slope of the
position of the Department of the Army or the Department
of Defense (para 4-3, AR 360-5). The research described function indicates the sensitivity of consump-
in this report was conducted in compliance with the An- tion to changes in price. If the proportional
imal Welfare Act and other Federal statutes and regula- change in consumption is less than the pro-
tions relating to animals and experiments involving ani- portional change in price, then the slope is
mals and adheres to the principles stated in the Guide for
the Care and Use of Laboratory Animals, NIH publication between 0 and -1 and is termed inelastic; if
86-23, 1985 edition. The author wishes to acknowledge changes in consumption are proportionately
the assistance of Raymond Genovese, Frederick Manning, greater than changes in price, then the slope
Harold Black, and Gregory Galbicka during preparation is more negative than -1 and is termed elastic.
of earlier drafts of the manuscript. Reprints may be ob- For the demand curves in Figure 1, the slope
tained by writing Steven R. Hursh, Division of Neuro-
psychiatry, Walter Reed Army Institute of Research, was less negative than -1, and the correspond-
Washington, D.C. 20307-5100. ing response rates that produced these levels

377
378 STEVEN R. HURSH

; 300
Wa
a
0
0
A Stu
A i
%.100I
HEOI EL WOOD £
100 IO/

300

z
100
z
z

0 Percy

10
110 100 1000
1 3 10 30 100 300 FIXED RATIO (LEVER PRESSES/REINFORCEMENT)
FIXED RATIO (LEVER PRESSES/REINFORCEMENT)
Fig. 2. For 4 rhesus monkeys, daily lever presses for
Fig. 1. Top panel: For 2 rhesus monkeys, daily con- food or heroin, as indicated, as a function of FR schedule.
sumption of food pellets as a function of FR schedule, in
log-log coordinates. Bottom panel: For 4 rhesus monkeys,
dinates, then elasticity may be read as the point
daily infusions of heroin as a function of FR schedule, in
log-log coordinates. slope of the demand curve. A variety of envi-
ronmental and procedural factors contribute
to the level and elasticity of demand. The level
of consumption show an increase with increas- of demand is controlled in part by the size of
ing FR (price) (Figure 2). For comparison, 2 each "package" of the commodity (the scale of
other monkeys were tested under a similar se- measurement of consumption), by character-
ries of FR schedules with food reinforcement, istics of the consumer (such as body weight for
and the results were similarly plotted in Fig- food reinforcers), and by the current state of
ures 1 (top panel) and 2 (dashed lines). For deprivation. The elasticity of demand is largely
food reinforcement, demand sloped downward determined by the nature of the commodity
at a less negative slope than demand for heroin ("necessity" or "luxury" good) and the avail-
(i.e., demand for food was more inelastic) and
responding (Figure 2) increased at a greater
rate with increases in FR value. Thus, demand
(across this range of FR values) was inelastic LEVEL SHIFT
for both commodities, but was more inelastic
for food.
- -l

Demand curves for a variety of commodities,


including drug reinforcers, have been evalu- ENI
ated in the laboratory (see Bickel et al., 1990,
1991; Hursh, 1980, 1984). Demand curves
may be distinguished by two general charac- a
teristics, illustrated in Figure 3. A demand
curve depicts the total consumption of a com- ELASTICITY,SHIFT \

modity as a function of price (the cost per unit


of reinforcement, see unit price below). The
level of demand is the total amount of con-
sumption at minimal price, usually FR 1; the Log Price
elasticity of demand is the rate of change in
consumption with increasing price (see Hursh, ingFig. 3. Diagram of a hypothetical demand curve show-
daily consumption as a function of price, in log-log
1980, 1984, for further explanation). If the coordinates. Also shown are two prototypical changes in
demand curve is plotted in logarithmic coor- demand, a level shift and an elasticity shift.
BEHA VIORAL ECONOMICS OF DRUG ABUSE 379

DEMAND RESPONSE OUTPUT

< 10,000 -
a-
U-
a
(I) cc
L >
a.
CO ui
00o 1000
cL
z
a:
LL cc 1000

1 00 1
tIN

100 1000 10 100 1000


FIXED RATIO FIXED RATIO
Fig. 4. Left panel: Daily consumption of food or saccharin as a function of FR schedule, in log-log coordinates.
Right panel: Total daily lever presses for either food or saccharin as a function of FR schedule, in log-log coordinates.
Data from a representative rhesus monkey.

ability of substitutes or other sources of the Hursh, Raslear, Shurtleff, Bauman, and Sim-
commodity. Figure 4 (left panel) illustrates mons (1988) demonstrated that this measure
demand by a monkey for food and saccharin- was capable of providing a unitary demand
sweetened water; level of demand at a low curve from eight different test conditions all
price was adjusted to be similar by varying the scaled in unit-price terms. When using drugs
size of the saccharin reinforcer. As price in- as reinforcers, unit price may be defined as
creased, consumption of saccharin decreased follows (see Bickel et al., 1990):
much more rapidly than consumption of food,
indicating that elasticity of demand for sac- Unit price
charin, a nonnutritive commodity, was greater Responses per drug reinforcer x Effort
than elasticity of demand for food, a biological Drug dose
necessity. The right panel of Figure 4 shows
the total output of responses (key presses) re- Likewise, consumption across conditions
quired to produce these reinforcers across the should be measured in comparable units across
range of prices. These inverted U-shaped func- conditions, usually total drug consumption per
tions are typical for most commodities studied day (frequency of infusion x dose or total vol-
in a closed economy (Hursh, 1980, 1984; Hursh ume x concentration).
& Bauman, 1987). The level of responding for The application of this methodology with
food was about 10 times that for saccharin at drug reinforcers is illustrated in a study by
its peak and reached its peak at a much higher Lemaire and Meisch (1985). The reinforcer
price. was a liquid mixture of pentobarbital and eth-
Unit price. When assessing demand for a anol. Reinforcer size was studied by varying
commodity across different test situations, it is the number of liquid deliveries per period of
important to insure that the same units of price reinforcement (e.g., 2, 8, or 16 deliveries).
and consumption are used for the analysis. Combined with these sizes were different FR
Price is best understood as a cost-benefit ratio schedules that ranged from FR 2 to FR 256.
that describes the amount and effort of work Figure 5 shows the average demand for this
required for each unit of reinforcement. This drug mixture plotted as a function of unit price.
ratio is defined as unit price: For example, consumption at a unit price of
Unit price 16 was observed under three combinations of
FR and reinforcer size: FR 32 for 2 deliveries,
Responses per reinforcer x Effort FR 128 for 8 deliveries, and FR 256 for 16
Size of reinforcer deliveries. Regardless of the combination, de-
380 STEVEN R. HURSH

mand was similar when plotted in common seen as changes in the L parameter. For the
units of price. The daily output of responses data in Figure 5, the equation accounted for
that generated this demand is shown in Figure about 99% of the variance; in general, the
5. Response output increased up to a unit price equation accounts for 90% to 93% of the vari-
of 32 and decreased at higher prices; that is, ance in consumption in studies conducted to
demand was initially inelastic and became date (Foltin, in press; Hursh et al., 1988, 1989;
elastic at unit prices above 32. FR 32 is defined DeGrandpre & Bickel, personal communica-
as Pm.. the price that produced maximum out- tion).
put and demarcates the boundary from inelas- This method of analysis may have appli-
tic to elastic demand. This general pattern of cations for assessing the abuse liability (like-
initial inelasticity followed by elasticity at lihood of human acquisition and maintenance
higher prices is a characteristic of most rein- of drug taking) of new drugs prior to use in
forcers. Bickel et al. (1990) analyzed a variety humans. Drug self-administration studies with
of drug self-administration studies in terms of nonhuman primates are commonly used to es-
unit-price demand curves and found this same tablish the reinforcing properties of drugs and
pattern for a variety of drug reinforcers. to provide a qualitative assessment of the
Demand curve analysis. The smooth curve strength of performance maintained by them
drawn through the points in Figure 5 is from (Brady & Lukas, 1984; Johanson, 1978). De-
an equation for demand that was fit to the data mand curve analysis based on an application
set (see Hursh et al., 1988; Hursh, Raslear, of Equation 1 under standardized testing con-
Bauman, & Black, 1989). This equation has ditions could provide a quantitative assessment
three parameters: L for initial level of demand of abuse liability. The parameters of the de-
at minimal price, b for initial slope of the de- mand equation provide an estimate of the ex-
mand curve at minimal price, and a for the pected level of consumption (L) and the sen-
acceleration or increase in slope of the demand sitivity of consumption to increases in price
curve with increases in price. The equation is (a). If other aspects of the experiment are held
as follows, stated in the usual logarithmic units constant (e.g., effort of the response, unit of
of price (P) and consumption (Q):1,2 consumption, and the length of daily test ses-
ln(Q) = ln(L) + b(ln P) - a(P). (1) sions), then abuse liability of different drugs
could be compared based on the values of the
Elasticity of demand is the point slope (first parameters of the demand equation.
derivative) of this function and is a linear func- Demand curve analysis is not time consum-
tion of price: ing. Once stable self-administration is estab-
Elasticity = b - a (P). lished at a low FR (e.g., FR 2), a demand
curve can be estimated by increasing the FR
Price yielding maximal output, Pma,s is: in 20% to 40% steps each test day up to a
maximum FR that reduces consumption to
P.. = (1 + b)/a. about 10% of baseline, a procedure that takes
In most cases, the b parameter is negative about 20 to 30 days. The demand curves in
and close to zero so that elasticity differences Figures 4, 13, and 14 were obtained using this
are manifest in changes in a. Level shifts are method. Several repetitions of this procedure
may be used to establish the stability of the
I Equation 1 is derived from an exponential expression parameter estimates in time. Other studies have
so that natural logs are required for accurate parameter used test sequences with even larger step sizes
estimates. The equation may be fit to demand curve data each day that allow exploration of the range
on any IBM-compatible computer using GraphPADs In- of consumption in as few as 7 test days (see
plot (GraphPAD Software, 10855 Sorrento Valley Road,
#9, San Diego, California 92121). The program fits Figure 8; see also Hursh et al., 1988; Raslear,
Equation 1 to the data, estimates the three parameters (+ Bauman, Hursh, Shurtleff, & Simmons, 1988).
standard errors) and the value of r2, and graphs the results Given the speed of the assessment, it is feasible,
(see Figure 5). Consult the author for details. in the same test subjects, to examine the mod-
2 In an earlier
paper, Hursh and Bauman (1987) pro- ification of demand by competing reinforcers
posed a different demand equation derived from economic or substitution of other drugs and to quantify
utility theory. Subsequent work has shown this equation
to be less accurate in fitting actual data; also, it did not the effects in terms of changes in the param-
yield simple expressions for elasticity and P,,,,.. eters of Equation 1.
BEHA VIORAL ECONOMICS OF DRUG ABUSE

Demand for Pentobarbital/ Responding for Pentobarbital/


Ethanol Mixture Ethanol Mixture
1000 8,000
c
0
LU
0
cz 6,400
CLJ
x
z0
cLI
vn 4,800
100 z
0
° 3,200
Av
0 w
0 2 Deliveris
0 o 8 Deliveries 1,600
I- A 16 Deiverie w

I 10 100 1 10 32 I100
UNIT PRICE UNIT PRICE
Fig. 5. Left panel: For a rhesus monkey, total daily consumption of pentobarbital/ethanol mixture as a function
of unit price (see text for explanation), in log-log coordinates. Right panel: For same conditions in left panel, average
daily responses per day as a function of unit price, in semilog coordinates. In each panel, Pma. is indicated by vertical
grid lines at a unit price of 32. Data from Lemaire and Meisch (1985).

Calibration methods. The definition of unit son of demand elasticity; however, this pro-
price and the mathematics of Equation 1 sug- posal requires further systematic investigation.
gest that any comparison of elasticity estimates Likewise, and perhaps more importantly,
across laboratories will require an estimate of the size and value of the reinforcer must be
the effort of each response and calibration of calibrated across experiments. Because rein-
the units and value of each reinforcer. This forcer size and value enter into the calculation
presents a problem for any retrospective anal- of both unit price and daily consumption, dif-
ysis of demand from previous studies with drug ferences in measurement can lead to erroneous
reinforcers; precise comparison of elasticities differences in the parameter estimates of de-
will be inaccurate without measurement of re- mand and elasticity. Correction for units of
sponse effort and comparable units of dose and dose is an easy task; more difficult is calibration
potency. of reinforcer value, because drugs often differ
Future studies can correct for these meth- in pharmacological potency. Hursh et al.
odological differences. The most direct ap- (1989), in a study using food reinforcement,
proach to calibration of effort would be to adopt provided a method for estimating differences
a standard, calibrated operandum for these in reinforcer value from the observed levels of
studies. Standardization may not be necessary, consumption at FR 1. In brief, the ratio of
however, if appropriate measurements are baseline levels of consumption was used to ad-
taken to permit computation of a correction just unit price to obtain a value-independent
factor. A recent study by Bauman (1991) in- measure of elasticity. For example, if Rein-
dicated that response-initiated fixed-interval forcer A supported twice the consumption at
schedules reduced consumption about as much FR 1 as Reinforcer B, then A is estimated to
as fixed-ratio schedules that were executed in have half the potency of B (QB/Q.). This cor-
the same amount of time. By implication, the rection can be made empirically. In the com-
results support a proposal that the amount of parison of demand for food and saccharin
time taken to complete an FR is the critical shown in Figure 4, the saccharin reinforcer
cost factor that decreases consumption. This was adjusted in volume to yield a daily rein-
finding, coupled with the observation by Hursh forcer consumption equal to that of food at FR
et al. (1989) that doubling effort had the effect 1. Having equated the reinforcers for value
of doubling the median interresponse time and (level of consumption at FR 1), demand could
the average time to complete a given FR, sug- then be fairly compared in terms of reinforcers
gests that the time required per unit reinforce- per day as a function of responses per rein-
ment may conveniently summarize the effects forcer. In the hypothetical example given here,
of both effort and FR. This easily obtained Reinforcer A could be dispensed in reinforcer
measure, then, could be used to calibrate cost units twice that of Reinforcer B to yield equal
across different laboratories for the compari- value units of reinforcement at FR 1. Elasticity
382 STEVEN R. HURSH

I
0
-0
,,cT
BE
10
* 0
LUJ
0-

C,,
* FOOD
courtwme ToBITS
O SUCROSE

Fig. 6. Diagram of four hypothetical forms of rein-


1
forcer interactions (see text for explanation). 1 10 100
UNIT PRICE - FOOD
of demand for A and B could then be directly Fig. 8. Mean daily consumption, by 6 rats, of food
and sucrose as a function of the unit price (FR schedule)
compared without concern for reinforcer size for food, in log-log coordinates.
or potency. Additional work with drug rein-
forcers is required to validate these methods.
DRUG-REINFORCER INTERACTIONS to each roughly matches the amount of rein-
Within a behavioral economic framework, forcement received from each (the matching
reinforcer interactions are classified into sev- law; see Davison & McCarthy, 1988). When
eral categories, illustrated in Figure 6. Most the two alternatives require a specific number
studies of choice with nonhumans have ar- of responses per reinforcer delivery, subjects
ranged for the alternative behavior to provide generally show exclusive preference for the least
the same, perfectly substitutable reinforcer, costly of the alternatives (Herrnstein, 1958;
usually food. This yields a specific kind of Herrnstein & Loveland, 1975). This situation
interaction in which the amount of behavior is much like comparison shopping for identical
items from different stores; all else being equal,
one will go to the store with the lowest price.
Most choices are between commodities that
m are not perfect substitutes. The other inter-
actions depicted in Figure 6 are imperfect sub-
stitutes, complements, and independent rein-
25 forcers. Figure 7 illustrates the difference
0
between imperfect substitutes and comple-
ments. Along the x axis is the price of Com-
0
modity A; along the y axis is the quantity of
I
consumption of the alternative Commodity B
z with fixed price. As the price of A increases,
0 consumption of A decreases, the usual demand
a. relation. If, at the same time, the consumption
of B increases in response to these increases in
the price of A, then B is defined as a substitute
zCo
Cj) for A. If the consumption of B decreases, then
0
10
B is defined as a complement of A.
10 100 Choice between two imperfect substitutes is
UNIT PRICE - COMMODITY A illustrated in Figure 8 (Hursh & Bauman,
1986). One alternative was a nutritive food
Fig. 7. Diagram of hypothetical changes in consump- pellet available after pressing a lever; the other
tion of Commodity B as a function of the unit price of
Commodity A. Circles indicate a complementary relation; alternative was pellets of sucrose freely avail-
squares indicate a substitutable relation. able in a cup. The food pellet was a balanced
BEHA VIORAL ECONOMICS OF DRUG ABUSE 383

10001 A
AA A A
AA AA AA
AAA AA A
COD A AA A
00 0
Cl: 0 0 A
0
0 0
0
et
COO
C03
C=
F-
C013 100-
g
Co
0
0 00
Co
-J
UJ
A WATER FR 10 0

00' IO FOOD

10 100 1000
FIXED RATIO
Fig. 10. Diagram of nonreciprocal interaction be-
Fig. 9. For a representative monkey, daily consump- tween ethanol and phencyclidine (PCP). Features of eth-
tion of food and water as a function of the FR for food, anol may substitute for PCP, but features of PCP may
in log-log coordinates. Water was constantly available not substitute for those of ethanol that are outside its
under an FR 10 schedule. domain of stimulation (shaded area).

diet, but less sweet; the sucrose was sweet and dine (PCP) or ethanol (ETOH). The price of
caloric but lacked many essential nutrients. each commodity was varied by altering the
The price of the food pellets was increased concentration of drug in each delivery; lower
across conditions of the experiment; daily con- concentrations represented higher unit prices
sumption of sucrose was measured at each price of the drug. In the first experiment, the unit
of food. Even at the lowest price of food (FR price of PCP was varied, once without ETOH
1), some sucrose was consumed; as the price available and later with ETOH available. As
of food increased and food consumption de- the unit price of PCP increased, consumption
creased, consumption of sucrose increased as of PCP declined, and the decline was greater
a partial substitute. However, even at the high- when ETOH was available as a substitute. At
est price of food (FR 243), some food was con- the same time, ETOH consumption increased
sumed despite the free availability of sucrose. at the highest unit prices of PCP. Thus, ETOH
This reciprocal trade-off between consump- functioned as a substitute for PCP as the price
tion of two reinforcers is typical of imperfect of PCP increased. In a second experiment, the
substitutes. unit price of ETOH was varied, once without
Choice between two complements is illus- PCP available and later with PCP available.
trated in Figure 9. One alternative provided As the unit price of ETOH increased, con-
pellets of food; the other alternative provided sumption of ETOH declined, but the rate of
squirts of water. As the price of food increased, decline was independent of the availability of
decreasing food consumption, daily consump- PCP. Furthermore, there was little change in
tion of water decreased. The value of water as the consumption of PCP as the consumption
a reinforcer declined as the consumption of of ETOH was driven down by increasing price.
food declined. Thus, although ETOH served as a substitute
Drug reinforcers may, by their neurochem- for PCP in Experiment 1, in Experiment 2
ical nature, reflect different forms of interac- PCP did not serve as a substitute for ETOH.
tion that parallel these interactions seen with This study illustrates a nonreciprocal inter-
consumable reinforcers. An excellent example action between two commodities.
of different drug interactions was demon- Figure 10 depicts diagrammatically how
strated by Carroll (1987). In this study subjects such an asymmetry might come about. Con-
were given two drug alternatives, phencycli- ceive of each drug reinforcer as consisting of
384 STEVEN R. HURSH

a group of stimulus features, perhaps coincid- not substitute for the immediate positive re-
ing with areas of central nervous system stim- inforcing consequences of euphoria. One could
ulation. If we think of ethanol as a drug with predict, then, that even if a large price differ-
a relatively large set of stimulus features (it ential existed between the two commodities,
has nonspecific action throughout the brain) some heroin would still be purchased from
and PCP as a drug that stimulates only a sub- illicit sources for its unique reinforcing fea-
set of those same features (it activates specific tures (see Stitzer, Grabowski, & Henningfield,
neural receptors), we can see that ETOH stim- 1984).
ulation would substitute for PCP stimulation In addition, heroin is often consumed as part
of the subset, but that PCP stimulation could of a social ritual, and these social events serve
not substitute for those stimulus features of as complements to the primary reinforcing
ETOH that were outside the PCP domain of consequences of the drug. To the extent that
stimulation. Thus, observations of reciprocal the substitute, methadone, must be consumed
and nonreciprocal reinforcer interactions may in a clinical, nonsocial environment, its value
give some clue to the underlying neural mech- will be diminished as an adequate substitute
anism of action of the two alternative drug for heroin because it is not accompanied by
reinforcers. important complementary social reinforcers
(see Hunt, Lipton, Goldsmith, & Strug, 1984).
DRUG USE INTERVENTIONS Therapy for opiate addiction usually con-
The concepts of substitution and comple- sists of other reinforcers along with metha-
mentarity provide some insights into important done, such as ajob and participation in a therapy
limitations of individual therapy programs for group. The effectiveness of these alternative
the control or elimination of drug abuse in reinforcers as deterrents to further illicit drug
individual clients. Within a behavioral frame- use will depend, in part, on the existence of
work, one can conceptualize the therapeutic direct competition between the two sources of
situation as one in which the therapist or cli- reinforcement. A study by Elsmore, Fletcher,
nician attempts to shape new behavior under Conrad, and Sodetz (1980) illustrates the im-
the control of acceptable reinforcers that com- portance of competition in reducing drug con-
pete with and reduce the occurrence of behav- sumption by a nondrug reinforcer. In this ex-
ior to obtain illicit drugs. Thus, the reinforcers periment, baboons were intermittently
arranged by the therapeutic process interact presented with two keylights that signaled the
with those from the use of illicit drugs (see availability of a choice between an intravenous
Thompson, Koerner, & Grabowski, 1984). infusion of heroin (0.1 mg/kg heroin HCI) or
The effectiveness of this competition will de- delivery of 3 g of food (four 750-mg Noyes
pend, at least in part, on several economic fac- pellets). Trials were separated by an interval
tors: the amount of direct substitution between that was varied across conditions from 2 min
the two sources of reinforcement, the avail- to 12 min. Subjects lived in there test cages
ability of desirable complements to the ther- and received all their food under the test con-
apeutic reinforcers that will maximize their ditions. The results are shown in Figure 11.
effectiveness, and the amount of direct com- When trials were plentiful (every 2 min), fre-
petition that exists between the two sources of quent choices of both food and heroin occurred;
reinforcement (i.e., does performance for one the mere presence of the alternative food re-
preclude or prevent reinforcement from the inforcer did not eliminate heroin consumption.
other). These factors can be illustrated by con- However, as the frequency of trials decreased
sidering the effectiveness of methadone ther- with longer intervals between choices, heroin
apy for users of heroin. choices were placed in competition with main-
Methadone is an imperfect substitute for tenance of food consumption. Under these con-
heroin; it is usually explicitly formulated so ditions of reduced "income" of trials, the sub-
that an oral dose will prevent opiate with- jects allocated proportionately more of the
drawal but will not produce a pronounced eu- available trials to food and less to heroin, as
phoria or "high." It substitutes for heroin to one might expect from the differences in elas-
prevent withdrawal symptoms, the aversive ticity shown in Figure 1. Under the conditions
consequences of nonuse of the drug, but does with most infrequent trials (every 12 min), this
BEHA VIORAL ECONOMICS OF DRUG ABUSE

100

- -
--.&- -------- --_-
-- -

k-0~~~~~~
- - ° - -
A

0
50 11- ~~~~~~Foo 0

4
a
s
IL
LA
0
zU
Food Heroin
20- Baboon P241 a A

Baboon P363 0 0

10
A

4 2 4 8 12
INTERTRIAL INTERVAL (Min.)
Fig. 11. For 2 baboons, choices per day for food and heroin as a function of the intertrial interval. Best fitting
straight lines are drawn through the points. Data are from Elsmore et al. (1980).

competition reduced consumption of heroin an those who do not use drugs and integration
average of 83% compared to conditions with into the social network of drug users (Hub-
frequent trials. This finding of an income effect bard, Rachal, Craddock, & Cavanaugh, 1984;
on choice behavior has been confirmed in sev- see Grilly, 1989, for a review).
eral other studies with primates, mice, rats,
and pigeons (Hastjarjo, Silberberg, & Hursh, DRUG ABUSE POLICY
1990; Sakagami, Hursh, Christensen, & Sil- Specific therapeutic interventions may be
berberg, 1989; Shurtleff & Silberberg, 1990; viewed as one part of an overall public policy
Silberberg, Warren-Boulton, & Asano, 1987). concerning illicit drug sale and use. Behavioral
These laboratory results with nonhuman economics may be used as an important inter-
subjects suggest that procedures that require pretive and analytic tool for evaluating alter-
heroin abstinence as a prerequisite for reten- native public policy initiatives. The first re-
tion of a job or admittance to the therapy group quirement of this strategy is the clear
might be expected to enhance the direct com- specification of public policy objectives. A par-
petition between the drug and nondrug rein- tial list of those objectives might include the
forcers. Of course, unlike the previously de- following: (a) reduction of illicit drug use, (b)
scribed study with food pitted against heroin, reduction of crime by drug users, (c) reduction
the winner of that competition may not be of distribution and sale of illicit drugs, and (d)
therapeutic alternatives, given the other limi- reduction of distribution-related crime.
tations of therapy listed above. However, given These objectives may be restated in behav-
sufficiently attractive therapeutic alternatives, ioral economic terms. In order to make this
such competition may be critical to elimination translation, first consider the total drug mar-
of further illicit drug use. This may be es- ketplace as represented by the demand and
pecially true for beginning drug users prior to supply interaction diagrammed in Figure 12.
the development of tolerance and dependence Demand has been previously defined as the
as a consequence of repeated drug exposure, level of consumption that will occur across a
and prior to isolation from the community of series of prices; supply describes the behavior
386 STEVEN R. HURSH

MARKET EQUILIBRIUM interventions). These two aspects of the pro-


cess are inseparable, and public policy should
DEMAND SUPPLY not be seen as a choice between them. Indeed,
it will be shown below that maximum effects
may require a coordinated application of both
MINIMIZE 1-11 MAXIMIZE kinds of policies.
PRICE / PRICE
Supply-side interventions. Supply-side inter-
ventions are commonly used by government
/
agencies in the United States, and include
criminal punishment for production, impor-
tation, distribution, and sale of illicit drugs;
confiscation of stockpiles; interdiction of im-
ports; destruction of crops (poppies, coca, and
marijuana); and controls on chemical produc-
tion plants that provide the raw materials for
Fig. 12. Diagram of hypothetical market equilibrium the drugs. All of these interventions are de-
between consumer demand and seller supply of a partic- signed to increase the costs associated with the
ular commodity, as a function of market price. Consumer supply process, thus moving the supply func-
attempts to minimize price; seller attempts to maximize
price. The equilibrium market price is shown as the in- tion to the right. Given a constant level of
tersection of these two hypothetical functions. demand, this well have the effect of increasing
the equilibrium price. To evaluate the possible
effects of this change in the market, consider
of the seller of the drug and indicates that the demand curve for pentobarbital/ethanol
higher prices increase the likelihood that in- depicted in Figure 5, which is representative
dividuals will obtain and resell the illicit drug of demand curves for most drugs studied in
to the end user. According to microeconomic the laboratory (Bickel et al., 1990). Demand
theories of price (Watson & Homan, 1977), is inelastic across a broad range of prices, here
these two forces are in competition in the mar- changing to elastic at a unit price of 32. All
ketplace, and the equilibrium market price is increases in price will tend to reduce con-
determined by the intersection of these two sumption (Objective 1), but for price increases
functions. The level of illicit drug use is simply in the inelastic region, the decreases in con-
the total level of drug consumption at the equi- sumption will be small relative to the changes
librium market price. The level of illicit drug in price. In the study illustrated in Figure 5
sale and distribution is that portion of total (Lemaire & Meisch, 1985), an eight-fold in-
drug consumption that is from illicit sources. crease in unit price from 4 to 32 produced only
Crime related to drug use, for the most part, about a 55% reduction in consumption.
can be ascribed to two primary factors-the The response-rate function shown in Figure
need for money to purchase the drugs, on the 5 represents the "total revenues" generated by
one hand, and the loss of self-control that is a the demand curve and indicates that across the
direct result of drug use. The need for money range of unit prices up to 32, revenues to the
may be quantified as the total daily allocation sellers increase. Above that price, revenues de-
of performance (money) for the purchase of crease. Given this inverted U-shaped function
the drug, exemplified in Figure 5 as total re- for total responding, the effect of a price in-
sponses per day. These same dollars, if exclu- crease on total expenditures and revenues to
sively spent on illicit drugs, represent the total the suppliers will depend on the initial market
revenues to the drug sellers. Distribution-re- price, be it in the inelastic or elastic range of
lated crime, such as smuggling and violent the demand curve. Only if the initial equilib-
competition among dealers, likely reflects the rium price is already quite high (i.e., equal to
size of this revenue pool that serves as the or greater than P..) will such a change result
reinforcer for engaging in these activities. in reduced expenditures and revenues. Oth-
Public policy influences on this process may erwise, increased drug prices will increase total
be categorized as those that focus on reducing expenditures, which will, in turn, tend to gen-
supply (supply-side interventions) and those erate more drug-related crime to obtain money
that focus on reducing demand (demand-side to meet the higher prices. At the same time,
BEHA VIORAL ECONOMICS OF DRUG ABUSE 387

DEMAND RESPONSE OUTPUT


0
0
1000
NO FREE
10000I 0

> 100
0
0 0
cc
w ccLU
oL 100
cn
C,
CO-
w CO)
-J z
-J
0
100 I CO)
0
0 cc
0
LL i'U

PRICE ( FIXED RATIO)


Fig. 13. Left panel: Median of 3 rhesus monkeys showing daily food earned in the work session as a function of
price (FR schedule). Three curves are for conditions with no free, or with either one third or two thirds of the baseline
level of consumption at FR 1 provided free after the 12-hr work session. Curves through the points are the best fit of
Equation 1. Right panel: For same conditions in left panel, the total daily responses emitted for food in the work
session, along with the best fitting curves derived from Equation 1. Both panels are in log-log coordinates.

increased supplier revenues will increase the work periods (Hursh et al., 1989). Monkeys
incentive to engage in supplier-related activi- lived in test chambers that provided their total
ties. These outcomes are all counter to Objec- daily ration of food and water. In the first
tives 2, 3, and 4 stated above. This kind of phase of the experiment, each work day started
unintended consequence has been observed at 6:00 a.m. and ended at 6:00 p.m.; during
several times in the petroleum industry; when the work period pressing a push-plate pro-
petroleum suppliers attempt to reduce pro- vided food according to an FR schedule (water
duction and force up prices, the inevitable con- was constantly available). The price of food
sequence is an increase in the revenues (and was increased across 21 conditions from an
profits) of the oil distribution companies, be- initial prices of 10 responses to a maximum
cause demand for petroleum by western coun- price of 372 responses per food pellet. At the
tries is relatively inelastic. end of the 12-hr work period, free pellets could
Demand-side interventions. The limitations be delivered. Three conditions were studied:
of price adjustments for influencing drug con- one free pellet (baseline), one third of a normal
sumption when demand is inelastic suggests ration was free, and two thirds of a normal
that a more effective policy would incorporate ration was free. Free pellets were delivered
methods to alter demand (see Jarvik, 1990). response independently every 3 s immediately
The previous section on individual drug ther- after the end of the 12-hr work period (sig-
apy described approaches to lowering the over- naled by a change in key colors). Consumption
all level of demand by the individual consumer. across the 21 price levels yielded a demand
In this section, a public policy approach to curve under each of the three conditions of free
increase the elasticity of demand will be de- food. The results are shown in Figure 13. The
scribed. This approach can be best understood median consumption of earned pellets is shown
by analogy to an experiment the author con- in the left panels and displays a graduated
ducted to alter the elasticity of demand for food increase in curvature or elasticity with in-
by providing a "free" source of food after the creases in the amount of free food. The re-
388 STEVEN R. HURSH

DEMAND 100,000
RESPONSE OUTPUT

NO FREE
10,000 _
a >- 0 O
a
LL
CEO cn
ILJ CO
LJ O 001000 ONE FREE MEAL
11
a.
a (j) 0
8 w
Cc
0

1000
0
FOUJR FREE MEALS

10 100 1000
PRICE (FIXED RATIO)
Fig. 14. Median of 3 rhesus monkeys showing food earned in four daily 1-hr work sessions as a function of the
price (FR schedule). Curves are from conditions with no free food, one free meal, or four free meals (see text for
explanation).

sponse-rate functions in the right panels show curvature of the demand function. Figure 15
the usual inverted U-shaped pattern, with the is a composite of the fitted curves showing the
peak of the curve shifting to the left (lower orderly increase in elasticity with increasing
prices) with increases in the amount of free amount and immediacy of free food and the
food. orderly shift to lower prices of the peak of the
In a second phase of the experiment, the response output functions (Pm., indicated by
work day was divided into four work periods, arrows).
each 1 hr long, distributed from 6:00 a.m. to Providing free food in this experiment is
5:00 p.m. In the baseline condition, no free analogous to providing the community of drug
food was presented; in two free-food condi- users a low-cost or free source of drugs, such
tions, either a 20-min free meal (a period of as through government-sponsored clinics. The
food available at a price of one response per effects of such "medicalization" of drug use
pellet) was presented at the end of the 12- may be inferred from these results with free
work day or four 5-min free meals were pre- food. Inspection of the functions in Figure 15
sented after each 1-hr work period. This last indicates that at prices above about 50 re-
condition was intended to further increase sub- sponses per pellet, free food had the effect of
stitution by reducing the maximum delay to reducing earned consumption at any given price
food. The results of this phase are shown in compared to baseline and reducing total rev-
Figure 14. The demand curves for earned pel- enues. Further inspection of the response out-
lets show a further increase in elasticity with put functions indicate that even if the market
the four free meals after each 1-hr work pe- price is adjusted to the peak of the response
riod. output (revenue) function (indicated by ar-
The lines through the points in Figures 13 rows), total revenues will drop dramatically
and 14 were fitted using Equation 1 and ac- (here nearly a factor of 10) with increases in
counted for an average of 93% of the variance. free availability of drugs, indicated by hori-
As expected, parameter a showed a consistent zontal grid lines. This reduction in expendi-
increase from 0.004 with no free food to 0.011 tures and revenues would be expected to re-
with four free meals, indicative of increased duce drug-related crime (Objective 2), reduce
BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS OF DRUG ABUSE 389

DEMAND RESPONSE OUTPUT


COMPOSITE COMPOSrTE
1000

, 100 a
a
cc L- 1 0,000
w
Ca LUJ
CO
-10 z
w
-J 0
X .
-J CD)
w
0- cr

-, 1000 -
100 1000 10 100 1000
FIXED RATIO FIXED RATIO
Fig. 15. A composite of the fitted functions from Figures 13 and 14 showing daily earned food (left panel) and
total daily responses in the work session(s) (right panel). Curves are, from top to bottom, no free (12-hr session), one
third free, two thirds free, one free meal, and four free meals. In the right panel, Pm.x is indicated by arrows, and the
peak level of responding is indicated by horizontal grid lines.

the incentive to supply drugs (Objective 3), and behavior would also be expected to increase,
reduce the incentive to engage in risky distri- such as auto accidents, suicide, and assaults.
bution-related crime (Objective 4). Notice, Thus, this approach to reducing illicit drug
however, that all these benefits presume that demand would best be combined with an ag-
the market price is relatively high and beyond gressive and effective program of individual
the point of divergence of the demand curves, therapy to reduce the overall level of drug de-
here a price of 50. This requirement argues mand (see above).
for continued use of supply-side law enforce-
ment measures in combination with this de- BEHAVIORAL UNKNOWNS
mand-side intervention to keep the illicit price This explicit and systematic analysis of the
high enough that illicit demand will be sen- factors contributing to the demand for illicit
sitive to the availability of the free source. drugs serves to highlight some significant un-
Unfortunately, these positive outcomes come certainties for public policy planning that need
at some cost. Consider in the free-food exper- further investigation.
iment just described the total level of food con- Demand elasticity. As indicated above in the
sumption from both sources of food, earned discussion of the effects of price increases on
plus free, shown in Figure 16 (data from a drug consumption and total expenditure, it is
representative monkey). In all but one case for necessary to know the elasticity of demand in
this subject, total food consumption was higher the vicinity of the current market price to make
with free food available than without; in gen- a precise prediction of the sensitivity of con-
eral, the subjects combined earned food and sumption to price increases and the direction
free food to "overeat" across all prices of earned of change in total expenditure of performance
food. In fact, these subjects generally became (money) to obtain the drug. This is because
quite fat, judging from their body weights. By demand elasticity is not constant, and total
analogy, one might expect that in a condition expenditures (and supplier revenues) follow
of both illicit drug availability and clinically an inverted U-shaped function. If the market
dispensed free drugs, overall drug use will in- price is optimally positioned at the point of
crease, at odds with Objective 1. This would maximum revenue for the supplier (P..), then
have the adverse effects of potentially expand- price increases will lead to proportional de-
ing the base of drug users, increasing the gen- creases in consumption and reductions in sup-
eral level of their use, and further reducing plier revenues. On the other hand, if the mar-
the productivity of society. In addition, those ket price is well within the inelastic range, then
crimes that are a direct result of drug-distorted price increases will have a proportionately
390 STEVEN R. HURSH
FREE FOOD may hinge on judgments about other factors
BASELINE that accompany movement toward lower or
higher prices, such as the overall level of con-
sumption and related effects on society, the cost
a (both financial and social) of government in-
cc terventions, and ethical issues, such as those
L
a.
associated with a program of medicalization
cD
that would use tax revenues to subsidize habits
that many regard as offensive, immoral, or
LLI unhealthy (see Gallup & Gallup, 1988). An
-J
CL
economic analysis makes a positive contribu-
tion by disentangling these issues from poten-
0 tially erroneous presumptions about the eco-
0 nomic processes that govern the drug market.
0
LL Supply elasticity. The effectiveness of gov-
ernment-sponsored competition would be
100
10 100
modulated by the elasticity of supply and the
capacity for market prices to adjust to changes
PRICE IN WORK SESSION in market conditions. If wholesale costs are
Fig. 16. For a representative rhesus monkey from the relatively low, if the threat of punishment is
studies illustrated in Figures 13 and 14, the total daily
consumption of food from both work sessions and free low, and if the supply of illicit drugs or raw
sources, in log-log coordinates. Baseline consumption, material is plentiful, then the market price of
shown as the heavier line, is without any free food; open illicit drugs may be able to adjust downward
symbols indicate total consumption including free sources. to maintain a competitive edge. Furthermore,
market prices do not have to match those of-
fered under a government-sponsored program
smaller effect on consumption and will lead to because of the inherent nonsubstitutability of
an increase in user expenditures and supplier the two sources. The government clinic would
revenues. provide the benefits of a pure drug at a reliable
Similarly, the effectiveness of a government- dose, but the illicit suppliers can make their
sponsored medicalized program of distribution product more readily available at any hour and
to increase demand elasticity will also depend without arbitrary limits on dose. Judging from
on the market price (see Figure 15); if market the effects of time delay shown in Figure 14
price is low, relative to the new alternative, (one vs. four free meals), an illicit source that
one might predict little, if any, change in de- provides more immediate availability in a so-
mand elasticity and the frequency of use of cially supportive environment would offer stiff
illicit drugs. Thus, without knowledge of con- competition for a government clinic that may
sumer demand and market price, there is no have set hours of operation, certain limits on
way to predict with any confidence whether daily dosage, and other bureaucratic incon-
specific public policy interventions will in- veniences (forms to be filled out, painful blood
crease or decrease drug use, drug-related crime, tests, and waiting lines).
and supplier revenues. The formulation of Product innovation. Further, the drug supply
public policy in the absence of this information system should be viewed as an active compet-
is analogous to formulating tax policy in the itor; it is unlikely that illicit suppliers will
absence of knowledge of the tax base and seems stand idle while they are put out of business
at best ineffectual, and at worst, counterpro- by government-sponsored clinics. In the legal
ductive. marketplace, when competition from a new
Unfortunately, the inverted U-shaped ex- source occurs, one typical response to prevent
penditure-revenue function virtually guaran- effective competition is to engage in product
tees that drug policy will be controversial. For innovation, that is, make your product distinct
any selected level of drug expenditures, there and nonsubstitutable from that available from
are two prices that produce the same level of the competition. Advertising focuses on these
total funds expended, a low price and a very unique features and persuades the consumer
high price. The choice between policies, then, that the competition provides an inferior prod-
BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS OF DRUG ABUSE 391

uct. In the drug trade, this kind of innovation


will lead to new "designer drugs" or drug com-
binations with higher abuse potential, a stron-
ger "kick," or longer lasting effects, with little
concern for long-term user safety.
Aggregate versus individual demand. During
the foregoing discussion, we have extrapolated
predictions about market demand from obser-
vations of individual demand. This assumes
that the aggregation of demand curves from
individuals introduces no new processes or
variables. There are two ways in which this
assumption may not be valid. First, the elas-
ticity of demand of an aggregation of demand Laboratory Laboratory Clinical
curves may not be as inelastic as each individ- Non-Human H n Research
ual curve; this is an empirical question. Sec- Fig. 17. Flow chart illustration of behavioral economic
ond, the level of demand of the aggregate is strategy for public policy formulation and implementation
not fixed, as is the level for any given individ- based on data and analysis from laboratory, clinical, and
ual. Thus, one response to government policies econometric studies and from practical applications in ex-
to reduce individual demand is to expand the perimental model projects.
market to new communities where resistance
to drug use is lower and availability of gov-
ernment competition is low. These new mar- knowns that are important for prediction of
kets will, in turn, force further government policy outcomes. This establishes the goals of
involvement and an escalation in the cost of an econometric analysis of actual drug use in
the government-sponsored program. the natural marketplace. A program of mon-
Supplier competition. Reductions of demand itoring of drug-use patterns and market prices
and pressures to increase price will likely lead would establish approximations of demand
to heightened competition among drug sup- elasticity for prediction of policy impacts.
pliers for the diminishing market. In the legal However, even the most ambitious economet-
marketplace, such competition is expressed in ric program will be difficult and prone to error
sanctioned marketing techniques-advertis- because the details of supply, distribution, and
ing, sale prices, rebates, and product innova- use are deliberately hidden to avoid criminal
tions. In the illegal marketplace, less benign prosecution. Thus, any public policy formu-
forms of competition prevail, including mur- lation based on this knowledge must be con-
der, extortion, and product fraud. All these by- sidered tentative. To avoid error on a large
products must be anticipated by any effective scale, experimental model projects should be
public policy intervention that reduces demand undertaken to test creative solutions and novel
and/or increases price. public policy initiatives. Coupled with each
such project should be an extensive program
A STRATEGY FOR PUBLIC POLICY of evaluation and improvement. Only after
FORMULATION several iterations of evaluation and modifica-
It is clear that an empirical approach to tion should the methods of a model project be
public policy formulation in the sphere of drug proposed for general application. Even then,
abuse will require an extensive knowledge of because of the uncertainties of scale and the
both the principles of behavior and the pre- diversity of settings, public policy must be for-
vailing dynamics of the illicit drug market. mulated and implemented with provisions for
Figure 17 diagrams an overall strategy for self-evaluation and correction without the need
public policy formulation and implementation. for new legislation.
At the primary level is the need for expanded The strategy envisioned is a self-correcting
basic research on the principles that govern one. The results of evaluations serve as feed-
drug use from laboratory and clinical settings. back to the policy formulation process and to
Based on the knowledge of these basic pro- the research community for needed investi-
cesses, we can then formulate the critical un- gations to improve approaches. Provisions are
392 STEVEN R. HURSH

needed to insure that the system can adjust self-administration. II. A unit-price analysis of ciga-
rapidly to this feedback. Studies of behavior rette smoking. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of
Behavior, 55, 145-154.
in the laboratory clearly show that delays im- Brady, J. V., & Lukas, S. E. (Eds.). (1984). Testing
posed between changes in behavior and changes drugs for physical dependence potential and abuse liability
in the controlling environment can lead to un- (NIDA Research Monograph 52). Rockville, MD:
intended effects on subsequent behavior. Department of Health and Human Services, National
Therefore, an effective behavioral economic Institute of Drug Abuse.
Carroll, M. E. (1987). Self-administration of orally-
system for influencing the dynamic drug mar- delivered phencyclidine and ethanol under concurrent
ket will require an especially responsive bu- fixed-ratio schedules in rhesus monkeys. Psychophar-
reaucracy with minimal feedback delays. macology, 93, 1-7.
Davison, M., & McCarthy, D. (1988). The matching
CONCLUSIONS law: A research review. Hilldale, NJ: Erlbaum.
Elsmore, T. F., Fletcher, D. V., Conrad, D. G., & Sodetz,
Behavioral economics may be defined as a F. J. (1980). Reduction of heroin intake in baboons
special application of behavior analysis that by an economic constraint. Pharmacology Biochemistry
emphasizes environmental and biological fac- and Behavior, 13, 729-731.
tors modulating the total allocation of perfor- Foltin, R. W. (in press). An economic analysis of "de-
mand" for food in baboons. Journal of the Experimental
mance to available reinforcers. When the com- Analysis of Behavior.
modities of interest are drug reinforcers, this Gallup, G., Jr., & Gallup, A. (1988). The Gallup Poll:
method of analysis provides a consistent con- Public opinion 1988 (pp. 124-128). Wilmington, DE:
ceptual framework for quantifying the strength Scholarly Resources.
of drug self-administration in laboratory sub- Griffiths, R. R., Bigelow, G. E., & Henningield, J. E.
(1980). Similarities in animal and human drug-taking
jects, for evaluating interactions between drug behavior. In N. K. Mello (Ed.), Advances in substance
and nondrug reinforcers, for designing and in- abuse (Vol. 1, pp. 1-90). Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.
terpreting the effectiveness of drug abuse in- Grilly, D. M. (1989). Drugs and human behavior. Boston:
terventions in humans, and for formulating Allyn and Bacon.
Hastjarjo, T., Silberberg, A., & Hursh, S. R. (1990).
public policy to deal with drug abuse. Quinine pellets as an inferior good and a Giffen good
These separate domains can be seen as part in rats. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior,
of an overall strategy that would draw on the 53, 263-271.
findings from laboratory research and natu- Herrnstein, R. J. (1958). Some factors influencing be-
havior in a two-response situation. Transactions of the
ralistic econometric investigations to design New York Academy of Sciences, 21, 35-45.
model intervention projects. Evaluation and Herrnstein, R. J., & Loveland, D. H. (1975). Maxi-
improvement of these projects would then serve mizing and matching on concurrent ratio schedules.
as small-scale test-beds for more general public Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 24,
policy initiatives. This empirical and behav- 107-116.
Hubbard, R. L., Rachal, J. V., Craddock, S. G., & Cav-
ioral approach to public policy in the sphere anaugh, E. R. (1984). Treatment outcome prospec-
of drug abuse is representative of a more gen- tive study (TOPS): Client characteristics and behaviors
eral behavioral system for the design of culture, before, during, and after treatment. In F. M. Tims &
as anticipated by Skinner (1953). If future J. P. Ludford (Eds.), Drug abuse treatment evaluation:
work confirms the utility of this behavioral Strategies, progress, and prospects (pp. 42-68). (NIDA
Research Monograph 51, DHHS Publication No.
economic agenda, then we have made the first ADM 84-1329). Washington, DC: U.S. Government
step toward the development of a more humane Printing Office.
society. Hunt, D. E., Lipton, D. S., Goldsmith, D. S., & Strug,
D. L. (1984). Problems in methadone treatment: The
influence of reference groups. In J. Grabowski, M. L.
REFERENCES Stitzer, & J. E. Henningfield (Eds.), Behavioral inter-
vention techniques in drug abuse treatment (pp. 8-22).
Bauman, R. A. (1991). An experimental analysis of the (NIDA Research Monograph 46, DHHS Publication
cost of food in a closed economy. Journal of the Exper- No. ADM 84-1282). Washington, DC: U.S. Govern-
imental Analysis of Behavvior, 56, 33-50. ment Printing Office.
Bickel, W. K., DeGrandpre, R. J., Higgins, S. T., & Hursh, S. R. (1980). Economic concepts for the analysis
Hughes, J. R. (1990). Behavioral economics of drug of behavior. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Be-
self-administration. I. Functional equivalence of re- havior, 34, 219-238.
sponse requirement and drug dose. Life Sciences, 47, Hursh, S. R. (1984). Behavioral economics. Journal of
1501-1510. the Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 42, 435-452.
Bickel, W. K., DeGrandpre, R. J., Hughes, J. R., & Hursh, S. R., & Bauman, R. A. (1986). The physiology
Higgins, S. T. (1991). Behavioral economics of drug and psychology of substitution in a closed economy.
BEHA VIORAL ECONOMICS OF DRUG ABUSE 393

Proceedings and Abstracts of the Annual Meeting of the for behavioral economics. Animal Learning & Behavior,
Eastern Psychological Association, 57, 49. (Abstract) 16, 330-339.
Hursh, S. R., & Bauman, R. A. (1987). The behavioral Sakagami, T., Hursh, S. R., Christensen, J., & Silberberg,
analysis of demand. In L. Green & J. H. Kagel (Eds.), A. (1989). Income maximizing in concurrent inter-
Advances in behavioral economics (Vol. 1, pp. 117-165). val-ratio schedules. Journal of the Experimental Analysis
Norwood, NJ: Ablex. of Behavior, 52, 41-46.
Hursh, S. R., Raslear, T. G., Bauman, R., & Black, H. Shurtleff, D., & Silberberg, A. (1990). Income maxi-
(1989). The quantitative analysis of economic behav- mizing on concurrent ratio-interval schedules of rein-
ior with laboratory animals. In K. G. Grunert & F. forcement. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Be-
Olander (Eds.), Understanding economic behaviour havior, 53, 273-284.
(Theory and Decision Library, Series A, Vol. 2, pp. Silberberg, A., Warren-Boulton, F. R., & Asano, T.
393-407). Dordrecht, Netherlands: Kluwer. (1987). Inferior-good and Giffin-good effects in mon-
Hursh, S. R., Raslear, T. G., Shurtleff, D., Bauman, R., key choice behavior. Journal of Experimental Psychology:
& Simmons, L. (1988). A cost-benefit analysis of Animal Behavior Processes, 13, 292-301.
demand for food. Journal of the Experimental Analysis Skinner, B. F. (1953). Science and human behavior. New
of Behavior, 50, 419-440. York: Macmillan.
Jarvik, M. E. (1990). The drug dilemma: Manipulating Stitzer, M. L., Grabowski, J., & Henningfield, J. E.
the demand. Science, 250, 387-392. (1984). Behavioral intervention techniques in drug
Johanson, C. E. (1978). Drugs as reinforcers. In D. E. abuse treatment: Summary of discussion. In J. Gra-
Blackman & D. J. Sanger (Eds.), Contemporary re- bowski, M. L. Stitzer, & J. E. Henningfield (Eds.),
search in behavioral pharmacology (pp. 325-390). New Behavioral intervention techniques in drug abuse treat-
York: Plenum Press. ment (pp. 147-156) (NIDA Research Monograph 46,
Lea, S. E. G. (1978). The psychology and economics of DHHS Publication No. ADM 84-1282). Washington,
demand. Psychological Bulletin, 85, 441-466. DC: U.S. Government Printing Office.
Lea, S. E. G., & Roper, T. J. (1977). Demand for food Thompson, T., Koerner, J., & Grabowski, J. (1984).
on fixed-ratio schedules as a function of the quality of Brokerage model rehabilitation system for opiate de-
concurrently available reinforcement. Journal of the Ex- pendence: A behavioral analysis. In J. Grabowski, M.
perimental Analysis of Behavior, 27, 371-380. L. Stitzer, & J. E. Henningfield (Eds.), Behavioral
Lemaire, G. A., & Meisch, R. A. (1985). Oral drug intervention techniques in drug abuse treatment (pp. 131 -
self-administration in rhesus monkeys: Interactions be- 146) (NIDA Research Monograph 46, DHHS Pub-
tween drug amount and fixed-ratio size. Journal of the lication No. ADM 84-1282). Washington, DC: U.S.
Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 44, 377-389. Government Printing Office.
Rashotte, M. E., & Henderson, D. (1988). Coping with Watson, D. S., & Holman, M. A. (1977). Price theory
rising food costs in a closed economy: Feeding behavior and its uses (4th ed.). Boston: Houghton Mifflin.
and nocturnal hypothermia in pigeons. Journal of the
Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 50, 441-456.
Raslear, T. G., Bauman, R. A., Hursh, S. R., Shurtleff, Received May 18, 1991
D., & Simmons, L. (1988). Rapid demand curves Final acceptance May 29, 1991

You might also like