Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 2

THE CLAYTON ACT 75

Intellectuals then arrogate the power of these ideas by Peltzman, S. (1976). “Toward a more general theory of regula-
writing intellectual histories in which Adam Smith caused tion.” Journal of Law and Economics, 19(August): 211–40.
free enterprise in England and Keynes rescued the world Rowley, C.K. (1997). “Donald Wittman’s The Myth of Democratic
Failure.” Public Choice, 92: 15–26.
from depression. Stigler, in particular, would take issue
Rowley, C.K. and Vachris, M.A. (1995). “Why democracy does
with such procedures. His reasoning is that this approach is not necessarily produce efficient results.” Journal of Public
hard to test, and causal evidence suggests that it is wrong. Finance and Public Choice, (December): 97–111.
Keynes wrote a book in 1936; perennial deficits in the U.S. Stigler, G.S. (ed.) (1988). Chicago Studies in Political Economy.
began in the 1960s. This emphasis on the secondary role of Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
ideas in CPE is related to the positive economics emphasis Stigler, G.J. (1982). The Economist as Preacher and Other
on understanding the world and not changing it. Moreover, Essays. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
ideas carry little or no weight just like ideological values Stigler, G.J. (1976). “The sizes of legislatures.” Journal of Legal
Studies, V(January): 17–34.
in relation to the basic economic forces which drive the
Stigler, G.J. (1971). “The theory of economic regulation.” Bell
redistribution process.
Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2(Spring):
In 1971, the primary alternative to Stigler’s theory of eco- 3–21.
nomic regulation was the Pigovian or public-interest theory Stigler, G.J. (1979). “Why have the socialists been winning?”
of government, which was already under heavy assault from Ordo, 13: 61–68.
earlier contributions to public choice theory. Today, virtually Tullock, G. (1967). “The welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies, and
no one thinks in such terms. The interest-group theory of theft.” Western Economic Journal, 5: 224–232.
government has accumulated widespread recognition as a Wittman, D. (1995). The Myth of Democratic Failure. Chicago:
valuable theory of government. The interest-group theory University of Chicago Press.
Wittman, D. (1989). “Why democracies produce efficient
has shown its explanatory power in a remarkably wide range
results.” Journal of Political Economy, 97: 1395–1424.
of areas of governmental activity in both a contemporary and
historical context (Ekelund and Tollison, 2001).
The fundamental point is that CPE is founded and
pursued on the grounds of positive economics and price
theory and not only is testability a key criterion of theories, THE CLAYTON ACT
but actual testing is tantamount to being taken seriously by
CPE scholars. Other traditions in public choice embody The Clayton Act of 1914 was one of the major pieces of
certain elements of the CPE approach, but none are so legislation of the Progressive Era in American history. It
rigorously empirical as CPE. prohibited four specific types of monopolistic practices:
(1) price discrimination; (2) exclusive-dealing contracts
ROBERT D. TOLLISON
and tying agreements; (3) the acquisition of competing
companies through stock purchases; and (4) interlocking
REFERENCES directorates among companies with a market value of at
least $1 million, and in the same industry. Its main objec-
Becker, G.S. (1985). “Public policies, pressure groups and dead- tive was to prevent business practices that may tend “to
weight costs.” Journal of Public Economics, 28: 329–347. substantially lessen competition or tend to create a mono-
Becker, G.S. (1983). “A theory of competition among pressure poly.” It underwent several amendments in subsequent years
groups for political influence.” Quarterly Journal of
partly because of lax judicial interpretations. The most
Economics, 98: 371–400.
important ones include the Robison–Patman Act of 1936,
Becker, G.S. (1976). “Comment.” Journal of Law and Economics,
19: 245–248. which strengthened price discrimination prohibition, and
Ekelund, R.B. and Tollison, R.D. (2001). “The interest-group the- the Celler–Kefauver Act of 1950, which prohibited corpo-
ory of government,” in W.F. Shughart and L. Razzolini (eds.) rate mergers that would tend to reduce competition or pro-
The Elgar Companion to Public Choice, Northampton: mote monopolies (Shughart, 1990; Shenefield and Stelzer,
Edward Elgar, pp. 357–378. 2001).
Keynes, J.M. (1936). The General Theory of Employment, Interest The theoretical foundations justifying the existence of
and Money. London: Macmillan.
antitrust laws in general, and the Clayton Act in particular,
Landes, W.M. and Posner, R.A. (1975). “The independent judici-
ary in an interest-group perspective.” Journal of Law and rely on analytical models of industrial organization and
Economics, 18: 875–901. microeconomic theory. These models show that the
Lott, J.R. (1997). “Donald Wittman’s The Myth of Democratic economic paradigm of competitive markets, in which eco-
Failure.” Public Choice, 92: 1–13. nomic decisions are freely made by firms and individuals,
76 THE CLAYTON ACT

each looking out for its own interest, deliver the highest market, these results may no longer hold. The extreme case
possible level of social welfare. The system of prices and would be when there is only one firm, a monopolist, oper-
the allocation of resources in such an environment is the ating in the market. As the only participant, the monopolist
most efficient one in the sense that a reallocation of has the ability to control the market price of its product,
resources cannot make someone better off without making as well as its production level. Because the monopolist’s
someone else worse off. The reason such an outcome objective is to maximize its profit, not society’s welfare,
obtains is because in a purely competitive environment the equilibrium price of the good or service that the
equilibrium prices of goods and services reflect exactly the monopolist charges will be higher than the cost of the
cost of the inputs used in the production of these goods or inputs necessary to produce the good or service. In addi-
the provision of these services. tion, the resulting level of output is lower than what obtains
This result has two socially desirable implications. First, under competition. As a result, a market structure in which
only the correct quantity of goods and services is produced. there is only one firm is seen, in general, as a socially
This follows from the fact that in equilibrium the extra rev- undesirable outcome.
enue the firm receives from selling one more unit of the There are instances in which a monopoly delivers the
good is its price, which exactly equals its production cost. most efficient output level in an industry. This may happen
Increasing the level of production of this good further will when production costs decline as the size of the firm
result in a price decline, and hence, in a negative profit for increases due to, for example, very high initial fixed costs.
the firm. Analogously, a decrease in this level of produc- Public utilities are classic examples of these industries.
tion will result in a price increase, and hence, positive However, even in these instances, the monopolist will
profit for the firm. A positive profit, in turn, will encour- choose to produce below the social’s optimal level, since it
age firms to increase their output levels. The price level has full control of prices and production.
will consequently decline until it finally reaches its Thus, when the effect of a monopolist on society’s wel-
production costs. fare is likely to be severe, public policy is seen as necessary
This well-known result of microeconomic theory to correct or prevent such outcomes (Blair and Kaserman,
was understood even as early as the 18th century. Adam 1985). Although this is a highly simplified description of
Smith ([1776] 1981), for example, made the following how markets operate in reality, it forms an integral part
observation: of the economic rationale for government intervention
(Singer, 1981; Shenefield and Stelzer, 2001).
When the quantity of any commodity which is brought
Few would dispute the validity of these theoretical argu-
to markets falls short of the effectual demand, all those
who are willing to pay the whole value of rents, wages, ments. However, the notion that government intervention
and profit, which must be paid in order to bring it will result in an improvement of social welfare by
thither, cannot be supplied with the quantity which they “correcting” the deficiencies associated with large devia-
want. Rather than want it altogether, some of them will tions from the competitive equilibrium paradigm is not
be willing to give more. A competition will immedi- well founded theoretically or empirically. One of the major
ately begin among them, and the market price will
rise … When the quantity brought to market exceeds tenets of public choice theory is that governments and reg-
the effectual demand, it cannot be sold to those who are ulatory agencies are composed of individuals who, just as
willing to pay the whole value of the rent, wages, and other market participants, seek to maximize their own well-
profit, which must be paid in order to bring it thither. being, and not necessarily social welfare (McChesney and
Some part must be sold to those who are willing to pay Shughart, 1995). When the objective of regulators and
less … The market price will sink more or less below
the natural price. (Smith, 1776 [1981]: 73–74)
politicians is changed from the hypothetical maximization
of social welfare to the maximization of their own well-
A second socially desirable implication is that only the cor- being, there are profound implications, many of which can
rect number of firms prevails in the industry. This follows result in outcomes that, from a social welfare point of view,
from the fact that in equilibrium there are no economic are worse than simply not intervening at all. Consider, as an
profits because positive profits will attract new entrants, example, the arguably sensible proposition that one of the
while negative ones will force some firms to leave the most important objectives of a politician is to maximize his
industry. or her probability of re-election. Because this probability is
These two results obtain when there are a large number an increasing function of campaign expenditures among
of firms in an industry, or when there are no entry barriers other factors, politicians may have an incentive to vote
to keep new entrants from exploiting profitable opportuni- strategically on bills in order to maximize contributions
ties. When there are only a few firms participating in the from constituents and corporate supporters who stand to

You might also like