Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 9

Journal of Product & Brand Management

National culture and inter-tier price competition


K. Sivakumar
Article information:
To cite this document:
K. Sivakumar , (2014),"National culture and inter-tier price competition", Journal of Product & Brand Management, Vol. 23 Iss 2 pp. 131 - 138
Permanent link to this document:
http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/JPBM-08-2013-0374
Downloaded on: 31 January 2016, At: 02:21 (PT)
References: this document contains references to 50 other documents.
To copy this document: permissions@emeraldinsight.com
The fulltext of this document has been downloaded 271 times since 2014*
Users who downloaded this article also downloaded:
Rainer Olbrich, Hans Christian Jansen, (2014),"Price-quality relationship in pricing strategies for private labels", Journal of Product &
Brand Management, Vol. 23 Iss 6 pp. 429-438 http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/JPBM-06-2014-0627
Johan Anselmsson, Niklas Vestman Bondesson, Ulf Johansson, (2014),"Brand image and customers' willingness to pay a price premium for
food brands", Journal of Product & Brand Management, Vol. 23 Iss 2 pp. 90-102 http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/JPBM-10-2013-0414
Downloaded by University of Pittsburgh At 02:21 31 January 2016 (PT)

Audhesh K. Paswan, John C. Crawford, Waros Ngamsiriudom, Thuy Nguyen, (2014),"Consumer reaction to price increase: an investigation in
gasoline industry", Journal of Product & Brand Management, Vol. 23 Iss 3 pp. 220-229 http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/JPBM-09-2013-0377

Access to this document was granted through an Emerald subscription provided by emerald-srm:121184 []
For Authors
If you would like to write for this, or any other Emerald publication, then please use our Emerald for Authors service information about how
to choose which publication to write for and submission guidelines are available for all. Please visit www.emeraldinsight.com/authors for
more information.
About Emerald www.emeraldinsight.com
Emerald is a global publisher linking research and practice to the benefit of society. The company manages a portfolio of more than 290
journals and over 2,350 books and book series volumes, as well as providing an extensive range of online products and additional customer
resources and services.
Emerald is both COUNTER 4 and TRANSFER compliant. The organization is a partner of the Committee on Publication Ethics (COPE) and
also works with Portico and the LOCKSS initiative for digital archive preservation.

*Related content and download information correct at time of download.


Pricing strategy & practice paper

National culture and inter-tier price


competition
K. Sivakumar
Department of Marketing, Lehigh University, Bethlehem, Pennsylvania, USA

Abstract
Purpose – This research aims to examine the role of national culture dimensions in the nature of tier competition between high-tier brands and low-
tier brands.
Design/methodology/approach – It starts with a conceptual framework based on prospect theory to explain the asymmetric inter-tier competition. It
then describes how the national culture dimensions influence the implications of prospect theory and as a result, the nature of inter-tier competition.
The paper uses Hofstede’s framework to operationalize national culture and derives a number of research propositions that explicate the role of
national culture in inter-tier price competition.
Downloaded by University of Pittsburgh At 02:21 31 January 2016 (PT)

Findings – The study finds that the extent of asymmetry favouring high-tier brands over low-tier brands depends on the national culture dimensions.
Whereas high levels of individualism, power distance, uncertainty avoidance, and masculinity increase the asymmetry favouring high-tier brands, higher
long-term orientation decreases asymmetric price competition favouring high-tier brands.
Practical implications – The findings offer important guidelines for understanding the nature of inter-tier price competition as a function of national
culture.
Originality/value – This is the first study to extend inter-tier price competition in the global setting and also the first study that links national culture
with prospect theory to examine the boundary conditions of inter-tier price competition.

Keywords National culture, Prospect theory, Inter-tier competition, Price competition

Paper type Conceptual paper

An executive summary for managers and executive There is a rich tradition of literature in marketing that
readers can be found at the end of this issue. examines various aspects of price promotional strategies and
customer response to price promotions (e.g. Guadagni and
Little, 1983; Srinivasan et al., 2002). The key conclusion from
this research stream is that price promotions do influence
Introduction
choice behavior and such price response has important
This research focuses on the role of national culture on inter- implications for brand market share and profitability.
tier price competition. Thus, our research makes a Researchers have also found that the impact of price
contribution by examining the intersection of three promotions is contingent on customer-, product-, and
dominant research streams in the marketing literature: context-related factors (e.g. Krishnamurthi and Raj, 1991;
1 price competition; Tellis, 1988). As an important sub-domain in price promotion
2 customer response to price changes by brands in different literature, a number of scholars have examined the nature of
tiers; and price competition between brands in different tiers
3 the role of national culture in customer behavior. (e.g. Blattberg and Wisniewski, 1989; Lemon and Nowlis,
2002). One major thrust of this research stream is the nature of
This intersection has not been explored in the existing
price competition between high-tier and low-tier brands and
literature. Figure 1 depicts the positioning of our paper. We
how the effect of price competition is different for different
next briefly describe the background literature and delineate
brand tiers (e.g. Allenby and Rossi, 1991; Hardie et al., 1993;
why exploring the intersection is important for theory Sethuraman et al., 1999; Sivakumar and Raj, 1997).
development and managerial practice. A review of the extant literature reveals that there is a lack of
research focusing on inter-tier competition in the global
The current issue and full text archive of this journal is available at context. Examination of the nature of inter-tier competition in
www.emeraldinsight.com/1061-0421.htm the global setting is crucial for three reasons. First, exploration

The author greatly appreciates the guidance of the Editor and the
Journal of Product & Brand Management
23/2 (2014) 131– 138 insightful comments from the anonymous reviewers. The author is
q Emerald Group Publishing Limited [ISSN 1061-0421] grateful to Jan-Benedict Steenkamp for constructive comments on an
[DOI 10.1108/JPBM-08-2013-0374] earlier draft of the manuscript.

131
National culture and inter-tier price competition Journal of Product & Brand Management
K. Sivakumar Volume 23 · Number 2 · 2014 · 131 –138

Figure 1 Positioning of the proposed research


Downloaded by University of Pittsburgh At 02:21 31 January 2016 (PT)

of the boundary conditions of asymmetric inter-tier Background literature


competition, a phenomenon that has primarily been tested in
US markets and, to a lesser extent, in European markets, is Inter-tier price competition
necessary to broaden the utility of research findings and A number of researchers have investigated price competition
implications of inter-tier price competition; such an exploration between brands. During the past 20-25 years, increasing
will also help identify cases in which this phenomenon applies attention has been paid to the nature of competition between
to different extents and therefore define its boundary brands in different tiers. Research has used the term “tiers” to
conditions. Second, use of constructs such as national culture examine competition between national brands and private
to describe the global environment enables us to conduct a label brands, private label brands and generic brands, private
theoretically relevant and more broad-ranging examination, label brands and premium private label brands, brands with
rather than simply using countries as borders and conducting different quality/price levels, and so on.
empirical analysis in different countries in isolation. Marketing Furthermore, a large body of research has examined
and behavioral literature at the cross-national level has whether high-tier brands benefit more from price promotions
identified national culture as an important variable that can than low-tier brands. This research stream has offered
explain and predict firm and consumer behavior (Clark, 1990; significant insights into the presence and nature of inter-tier
Nakata and Sivakumar, 1996, 2001; Steenkamp, 2001). Using competition. More specifically, Blattberg and Wisniewski
national culture to study inter-tier competition can provide an (1989), Allenby and Rossi (1991), Hardie et al. (1993), and
important contingency perspective of inter-tier competition. Sivakumar (2007) offer different explanations for the
Third, although some researchers argue that the “world is flat” phenomenon of asymmetric competition and demonstrate
(Friedman, 2007), there is general consensus in business that the asymmetry between tiers exists in several product
research that “distance still matters” (Ghemawat, 2001), categories and this asymmetry favors high-tier brands. In
including cultural distance. Surprisingly, however, national addition, Lemon and Nowlis (2002) explain how to develop
culture has not been examined in the context of inter-tier price synergies between promotional strategies by different brand
competition. This is despite the fact that the role of national tiers; Sethuraman and Srinivasan (2002) examine the extent
culture in shaping aspects of price response behavior has been of asymmetry and measurement issues in inter-tier
alluded to in the literature (e.g. Bolton et al., 2010; competition.
Chandrasekaran et al., 2013). Several conceptual frameworks that explain the asymmetric
The objective of this research is to fill this important gap by nature of inter-tier competition are present in the literature.
examining the role of national culture on inter-tier price These include the bi-modal distribution of reservation price
competition. To do so, we begin with the concept of price differentials across customers (Blattberg and Wisniewski,
framing to understand the role of price reductions. More 1989), rotating indifference curves and income effect (Allenby
specifically, we use prospect theory (Kahneman and Tversky, and Rossi, 1991), loss aversion and prospect theory developed
1979) as a theoretical framework to explain asymmetric inter- first by Kahneman and Tversky (1979) (Hardie et al., 1993),
tier price competition. We then describe how national culture and price-quality tradeoffs (Sivakumar, 2007). We use
dimensions influence the elements of prospect theory and prospect theory adopted by Hardie et al. (1993) rather than
explain how this influence in turn helps shape the nature of other explanations as the basic mechanism to explain the role
inter-tier price competition. To date, explanations for inter-tier of national culture on inter-tier competition for three reasons.
competition have only indicated the existence of asymmetry First, cultural dimensions influence prospect theory’s basic
but have not adequately provided a conceptual examination on elements (i.e. reference dependence and loss aversion) but the
the variables that influence the extent of asymmetry, especially connection of national culture with elements of other
in the global context. Our work provides an important explanations (e.g. bi-modal distribution of reservation price
extension by exploring the boundary conditions of inter-tier differential, income effect, price-quality tradeoffs) is unclear.
price competition in the global context. Second, among the four different theoretical frameworks used

132
National culture and inter-tier price competition Journal of Product & Brand Management
K. Sivakumar Volume 23 · Number 2 · 2014 · 131 –138

in the explanations for inter-tier competition, prospect theory (2005) offer a recent integrative review of reference price
has been one of the most applied theories in social sciences. research. We use prospect theory as a starting point for
Third, an economic and quantitatively oriented theory such as conceptualizing inter-tier competition.
prospect theory seems a more natural fit to examine price To understand the role of inter-tier competition based on
competition among brands than other explanations that are prospect theory (Kahneman and Tversky, 1979), we use the
less quantitatively oriented. intuition from the work of Hardie et al. (1993) as a starting
point (also see Sivakumar, 1996). Key aspects of prospect
National culture theory are reference dependence and loss aversion. Reference
National culture has been a ubiquitous variable included in dependence (Kahneman and Tversky, 1979; Tversky and
much global research. A review of the literature indicates Kahneman, 1991) in the context of price competition means
several approaches to operationalizing national culture, that the impact of a given price level is evaluated not only in
although Hofstede’s (1980) national culture dimensions are an absolute sense but in comparison with some reference
among the most widely used measures (Søndergaard, 1994). point (price frame). If the price is less (i.e. more favorable)
Hence, we adopt the framework developed by Hofstede and than the reference price, it is coded as a gain; if the price is
his colleagues. more (i.e. less favorable) than the reference level, it is coded
Hofstede (1980, p. 4) defines national culture as “the as a loss. A manifestation of reference dependence in the
collective programming of the mind distinguishing the context of consumer choice is the concept of transaction
members of one group or category of people from another.” utility (beyond acquisition utility). Transaction utility comes
Hofstede and colleagues (Hofstede, 1983; Hofstede and from the idea that, beyond the acquisition utility determined
Bond, 1984, 1988) identify five distinct cultural dimensions: by the absolute price of the brand, the gains/losses provide
Downloaded by University of Pittsburgh At 02:21 31 January 2016 (PT)

individualism, power distance, uncertainty avoidance, another component of utility specific to the transaction.
masculinity, and long-term orientation. Individualism Loss aversion in the context of price competition means
reflects the “relationship between the individual and the that the magnitude of the negative effect of a higher price
collectivity which prevails in a given society” (Hofstede, 1980, relative to the reference price (i.e. loss) is more than the
p. 213). Power distance refers to “the extent to which less magnitude of the positive effect of a lower price relative to the
powerful members of organizations and institutions (like reference price (i.e. gain). The gain and loss functions also
family) accept and expect the power is distributed unequally” typically incorporate the traditional economic assumption of
(Hofstede and Bond, 1988, p. 10). Uncertainty avoidance diminishing marginal utility.
focuses on people’s aversion in dealing with unknown aspects Based on the above discussion, we can conceptualize the
(Hofstede, 1980). Masculinity refers to the assertiveness utility derived from a given alternative as a function of price
characteristic versus the nurturance characteristic, which and other variables. The importance weight given for the
denotes femininity (Hofstede, 1980). Long-term orientation price variable is denoted v and the importance weight given
(alternatively called Confucian dynamic) focuses on a range of to other variables is denoted by (1-v). Regarding the role of
Confucian-like values (Hofstede and Bond, 1988). price itself, as discussed previously, it can be decomposed into
two components: acquisition utility and transaction utility
Development of research propositions (the latter refers to utility specific to the transaction). These
two components have the weights of (1-t) and t respectively.
Prospect theory as a framework to explain inter-tier Therefore, we can represent the utility from a brand as:
price competition
Researchers in economics, psychology, and other fields have U i ¼ ð1 2 vÞQi
devoted considerable attention to anchoring and adjustment h i
mechanisms in consumer choice (e.g. Carlson, 1990; þ v ð1 2 tÞf – bP i g þ ðtÞ{ðR – P i Þu – ðP i – RÞlu }
Furnham and Boo, 2011). In the more specific context of
pricing, a number of studies have shown that the way price where Qi represents the impact of all variables other than
information is presented, termed price framing, often price, Pi represents price, and R denotes reference price. In
significantly influences perceptions of value from an addition, 2 bPi represents the acquisition component of the
alternative which in turn influences customer choice price-based utility, þ(R 2 Pi)u represents the transaction
behavior (e.g. Heath et al., 1995). Price framing has been utility component if the reference price is higher than the
studied in a number of contexts such as customer evaluation actual price (gain), and 2 (P i 2 R) lu represents the
of price with respect to some thresholds (Emery, 1969; transaction utility component if the reference price is lower
Monroe, 1971), temporal aspects of price framing (Gourville, than the actual price (loss). Loss aversion is manifested by
1998), price framing in the context of product bundling jlj . 1. Diminishing marginal utility, a standard assumption
(Stremersch and Tellis, 2002; Yadav, 1994), merchandize in economic models of choice is incorporated by u , 1 and
organization and price perceptions (Suri et al., 2012), price lu , 1. The functional forms for gain and loss components in
framing in the context of price endings (Anderson and the utility function are patterned after existing literature (e.g.,
Simester, 2003), and other topics. Clearly, one of the most Sivakumar et al., 2014).
salient ways in which price framing has been operationalized When a market consists of two brands, one high-tier brand H
is using the idea of reference dependence advocated by and one low-tier brand L, the reference price can be assumed
prospect theory (Kahneman and Tversky, 1979; Tversky and to be somewhere in between these two prices (Rajendran and
Kahneman, 1974, 1991) and subsequent research on mental Tellis, 1994; Sivakumar, 1996). We discuss more complex
accounting (e.g. Thaler, 1985). Winer (1986) provides an aspects of reference price formation subsequently, but for now,
early application of reference price concept in consumer only this weak assumption that reference price is between the
choice of frequently purchased products and Mazumdar et al. prices of H and L is enough to illustrate the basic explanation

133
National culture and inter-tier price competition Journal of Product & Brand Management
K. Sivakumar Volume 23 · Number 2 · 2014 · 131 –138

for asymmetric competition (e.g. even if the reference price is Since l . 1 due to loss aversion, j ›UH/›PHj-j ›UL/›PL j . 0.
assumed to be a weighted average of the two prices, all our That is, price reduction benefits H more than it benefits
arguments would still be valid). The following discussion is L. This is the degree of asymmetry and is denoted a in
based on Figure 2 and uses Hardie et al.’s (1993) insights into subsequent discussions. That is:
loss aversion as a mechanism to explain inter-tier competition.  
When the price of H is reduced from PH to PH-X, this a ¼ vtlu=ðP H – RÞ12lu j – jvtu=ðR – P L Þ12u  . 0
represents a loss reduction for H; when the price of L is
reduced from PL to PL-X, this represents a gain increase for This result is the starting point for our conceptual
L. Comparing their effects on utility change on the y-axis, we examination in which a is the base case asymmetry favoring
see that a price reduction by H has a more beneficial effect on high-tier brand in benefiting from price reductions. Our
H (because its price reduction represents a decrease in loss) dependent variable is this degree of asymmetric price
than a price reduction by L benefits L (because its price competition favoring the high-tier brand.
Next, we derive research propositions that link national
reduction represents an increase in gain) due to the fact that
culture dimensions to asymmetric inter-tier competition. The
the loss curve is steeper than the gain curve. The changes in the
literature considers national culture from different
non-price component of utility as well as the acquisition
perspectives (e.g. Bearden et al., 2006). For example, it can
component of the price-based utility do not differ between the
be considered as an aggregate index that provides the
two brands.
characteristics of the group – a group of people can be more
The above discussion can be described mathematically as
individualistic than others; alternatively, these dimensions
below. We start with utility functions and compute the first
could also be measured at the individual level – some people
derivatives to measure the effect of price changes.
Downloaded by University of Pittsburgh At 02:21 31 January 2016 (PT)

can be more individualistic than others without regard to the


h i grouping they belong to. Our approach is applicable for both
U H ¼ ð1 2 vÞQH þ v ð1 2 tÞf – bP H g þ ðtÞ{ – ðP H – RÞlu }
these conceptualizations – for the former, our theorizing can
h i be considered as a summation of aggregate market behavior;
U L ¼ ð1 2 vÞQL þ v ð1 2 tÞf – bP L g þ ðtÞ{ðR – P L Þu } for the latter, our theorizing can be considered as a depiction
of individual customer behavior. As mentioned previously, the
degree of asymmetric competition favoring the high-tier
›U H =›P H ¼ – vð1 2 tÞb – vtlu=ðP H – RÞ12lu
brand is the focus of this research. Modifications in the
›U L =›P L ¼ – vð1 2 tÞb – vtu=ðR – P L Þ12u parameters of prospect theory will result in corresponding
changes in price-response behavior and, therefore, in the
›U H , 0 when ›P H . 0ðprice increaseÞ and ›U H degree of asymmetry in inter-tier competition. In examining
the role of national culture dimensions on inter-tier price
. 0 when ›P H , 0ðprice decreaseÞ: competition, we discuss how each dimension of national
culture influences price framing, aspects of prospect theory,
›U L , 0 when ›P L . 0ðprice increaseÞ and ›U L and the overall role of price; then we discuss how they affect
inter-tier competition (see Figure 3). A summary of the
. 0 when ›P L , 0ðprice decreaseÞ: forthcoming discussion is presented in Table I.

Figure 2 Prospect theory-based explanation for asymmetric inter-tier competition

134
National culture and inter-tier price competition Journal of Product & Brand Management
K. Sivakumar Volume 23 · Number 2 · 2014 · 131 –138

Figure 3 A conceptual model of national culture and inter-tier price competition

Table I Aspects of price framing and national culture’s role in inter-tier competition
Aspects of price framing
Downloaded by University of Pittsburgh At 02:21 31 January 2016 (PT)

National culture Importance of Degree of loss Specificity of Stability of Effect on inter-tier


dimension price aversion reference price reference price competition asymmetry
Individualism £ Increase
Power distance £ Increase
Uncertainty avoidance £ Increase
Masculinity £ Increase
Long-term orientation £ Decrease

Individualism reference price being tied to the price of H). The former
We acknowledge that individualism has not been explored in (increase in reference price for L) makes the gain curve flatter
the context of price framing or prospect theory. However, (i.e. PL and PL-X move to the right) and therefore, the impact
some aspects of individualism provide clues toward its role in of a price reduction by L becomes less. The latter (decease in
price framing. The individualized focus (as opposed to a the reference price for H) makes the loss curve flatter (i.e. PH
collectivist perspective) and the idea of con-conformity as and PL-X move to the left) and therefore, the impact of a
manifested in individualism (Hofstede, 1980) allow us to price reduction by H becomes less. Together, these scenarios
extend the concept of individualism to people’s evaluation of result in decrease in asymmetry favoring H (because due to
brands and how price framing is manifested for customers loss aversion, the reduction of the impact of H’s price
with different individualism values. For example, low levels of reduction due to H’s reference price change is larger than the
individualism are linked to the relational aspects of marketing impact of L’s price reduction due to L’s reference price
activities rather than viewing them in an isolated manner change). From the equations derived previously, this can be
(Nakata and Sivakumar, 2001). In addition, in the context of seen mathematically as well. The magnitude of ›UH/›PH for a
stock price movements, broader and interlinked stock price price reduction decreases with R (per Equation 4 presented
movements (stocks considered holistically) are associated with previously) more than the magnitude of ›UL/›PL for a price
low individualism while isolated stock price movements reduction decreases with R (per Equation 5 presented
(stocks being considered in a more granular manner) are previously) due to loss aversion. Thus, overall, such effect
associated with high individualism (Eun et al., 2012; Zhan, will result in a decrease in asymmetry favoring the high-tier
2013). Building on these inferences, we argue that customers brand when common reference prices are used compared to
with high individualism use brand-specific reference prices the scenario when brand-specific reference prices are used:
(they evaluate brands more as individual entities and thus
evaluating them more independent of each other) while those P1. The higher the individualism (collectivism), the
with high collectivism use common reference prices stronger (weaker) is the asymmetric advantage of
(individual brands being compared to some collective notion high-tier brands.
of market place characteristic and brands being viewed less
independently). How this phenomenon specifically influences Power distance
the degree of asymmetry is discussed below. High power distance in a national culture context means that
Compared with brand-specific reference prices, common people are willing to accept differences in terms of power,
reference price (the reference price being some weighted hierarchy, and relationships in societies, families, and
mean of the two prices) will increase the reference price for organizations (Hofstede, 1980; Hofstede and Bond, 1988).
the low-tier brand (compared with the preference price being Power distance is also associated with differentiation and
tied to the price of the low-tier brand L) and decrease the market segmentation (Nakata and Sivakumar, 2001). An
reference price for the high-tier brand H (compared with the extension of this idea can be interpreted to mean that when

135
National culture and inter-tier price competition Journal of Product & Brand Management
K. Sivakumar Volume 23 · Number 2 · 2014 · 131 –138

power distance is high, people readily accept the different all other factors in a product market are fixed, and therefore
price and quality levels of brands in different tiers and are prices becomes more salient aspect to which people pay
willing to accept a marketplace consisting of a wide range of attention when masculinity is high. This increased attention
alternatives, brand performances, and price levels. In turn, to price increases the asymmetric price advantage of the high-
such an acceptance leads to the formation of specific brand tier brand. If a customer does not put much importance on
attributes as reference levels for framing rather than using price as a variable in decision making (in low masculinity or
common attributes across all brands or of the market place as high femininity condition), the impact of price will be weaker,
a whole as frames. In the context of price framing and and therefore based on our explanation of inter-tier
reference prices, high power distance results in the formation
competition, the asymmetric competition favoring the high-
of brand-specific reference prices instead of common
tier brand will be weaker. This is because the weight given to
references prices (that is, each brand has its own reference
price-based responses is lower than that given to other
price rather than a common reference price being associated
with all brands). As discussed previously, the asymmetric variables (as seen in Equation 1). Mathematically this
price advantage favoring high-tier brand increases with brand discussion means that a increases as v increases (as can be
specific reference prices compared to a common reference seen from Equation 6):
price (as seen from Equation 4 and Equation 5 discussed P4. As masculinity (femininity) increases, the asymmetric
previously): advantage of high-tier brands increases (decreases).
P2. As the power distance increases, the asymmetric
advantage of high-tier brands increases.
Downloaded by University of Pittsburgh At 02:21 31 January 2016 (PT)

Long-term orientation
Uncertainty avoidance Pricing research has acknowledged that reference prices can
Uncertainty avoidance is a cultural trait that is related to price be static or dynamic (see Sivakumar, 1995 for a discussion of
framing more than the previous two cultural dimensions. constant and dynamic reference prices) – that is, reference
High uncertainty avoidance essentially refers to the reluctance price can stay constant or change between purchase occasions
of people to take risks, their low ability to face new and in different contexts. With long-term orientation, people take
uncertain situations, and similar characteristics (Hofstede, a long-term rather than short-term perspective (Hofstede and
1980). People with high uncertainty avoidance exhibit greater Bond, 1984, 1988). The long-term orientation has important
loss aversion because loss aversion is another form of
implications for price framing in general and the formation of
uncertainty avoidance or risk aversion (Kahneman and
reference prices in particular. In the context of reference
Tversky, 1979). Indeed, prospect theory was developed as
an alternative economic theory to incorporate uncertainty and prices, long-term orientation means that people do not
risk. Therefore, the connection between uncertainty change their reference prices often but keep a fixed reference
avoidance and price framing is more direct. As explained in price (e.g., being stable at a level between the regular price
our explanation for asymmetric competition, loss aversion is and a promoted price rather than alternating between the
the primary mechanism underlying the explanation for regular price and promoted price according to their previous
asymmetric inter-tier competition. Indeed, if there is no loss purchase experience). An equivalent conceptualization is that
aversion, there is no asymmetric competition according to our customers with long-term orientation incorporate more of a
conceptual framework (Hardie et al., 1993; Kahneman and price history in arriving at the reference price and therefore
Tversky, 1979). Greater loss aversion is represented by a the weight on any one extreme price is likely to be lower and
larger magnitude of slope differential between the gain curve thus leading to less extreme reference prices.
and the loss curve in Figure 2 (or the loss aversion parameter Short-term adjustments (relatively dynamic) to the
l being high). As described previously, this difference in slope reference price mean that the regular price will be the
directly results in asymmetry favoring high-tier brand. reference price for most purchase occasions, whereas long-
Mathematically, a increases as l increases (as seen in term adjustments (relatively stable) mean that the reference
Equation 6). Therefore, the greater the loss aversion, the price will be less than the regular price (a weighted mean of
stronger is the asymmetry favoring the high-tier brand: regular price and the promoted price). Therefore, a long-term
P3. As uncertainty avoidance increases, the asymmetric perspective will decrease reference prices of both H and L
advantage of high-tier brands increases. prior to a price reduction. As discussed previously, decreasing
the reference price for the high-tier brand weakens the
Masculinity asymmetric advantage for the high-tier brand (as seen from
The effect of masculinity on asymmetric price competition is Equation 4); also decreasing the reference price for the low-
rather indirect. Because masculinity focuses on goal tier brand also weakens the asymmetric advantage for high-
orientation and also focuses more on tangible aspects such tier brand (as seen from Equation 5). Thus, the net effect is a
as money compared to intangible aspects (Hofstede, 1980; reduction in asymmetric advantage of the high-tier brand
Nakata and Sivakumar, 1996), we argue that when when the reference prices are more stable. Mathematically,
masculinity is high, the focus to take advantage of the price under long-term orientation, a decreases for a decrease in
changes will be stronger, increasing the importance of price in reference price for L and decreases for a decrease in reference
decision-making (the increase in parameters v, the relative
price for H (as seen in equation 6).
importance of price as a variable as shown in Equation 1
discussed previously). In addition, people with high P5. As long-term (short-term) orientation increases, the
masculinity tend to focus on rational and tangible attributes asymmetric advantage of high-tier brands decreases
(e.g., price) (Nakata and Sivakumar, 2001). This is because (increases).

136
National culture and inter-tier price competition Journal of Product & Brand Management
K. Sivakumar Volume 23 · Number 2 · 2014 · 131 –138

Discussion References
By providing a conceptual examination of inter-tier Allenby, G.M. and Rossi, P.E. (1991), “Quality perceptions
competition in the global context, we explore the boundary and asymmetric switching between brands”, Marketing
conditions of inter-tier competition. In addition, by linking Science, Vol. 10 No. 3, pp. 185-204.
the explanation to the elements of prospect theory, we open Anderson, E.T. and Simester, D. (2003), “Effects of $9 price
up a mechanism for exploring other price-response behaviors endings on retail sales: evidence from field experiments”,
by customers using economic theories and cultural Quantitative Marketing and Economics, Vol. 1 No. 3,
dimensions. Using the notion of price framing originating pp. 93-110.
from prospect theory to formally explore inter-tier Bearden, W.O., Money, B. and Nevins, J. (2006),
competition and price-response behavior and using the “Multidimensional versus unidimensional measures in
national culture theory to conceptualize the boundary assessing national culture values: the Hofstede VSM 94
conditions of price framing and inter-tier price competition example”, Journal of Business Research, Vol. 59 No. 1,
presents a new theoretical approach of integrating two major pp. 195-203.
theoretical frameworks to answer an important research Blattberg, R.C. and Wisniewski, K.J. (1989), “Price-induced
question. Our approach also answers the call for more patterns of competition”, Marketing Science, Vol. 8 No. 4,
conceptual articles in the marketing discipline. pp. 291-310.
This research offers insights for managers of international Bolton, L.E., Keh, H.T. and Alba, J.W. (2010), “How do
companies who are invariably faced with the opportunities price fairness perceptions differ across culture?”, Journal of
and challenges of marketing in different cultural contexts. Our Marketing Research, Vol. 47 No. 3, pp. 564-576.
Downloaded by University of Pittsburgh At 02:21 31 January 2016 (PT)

theory-based propositions offer first insights into culturally Carlson, B.W. (1990), “Anchoring and adjustment in
nuanced development of marketing strategies for brands in judgments under risk”, Journal of Experimental Psychology:
different tiers. These predictions can be empirically verified in Learning, Memory, and Cognition, Vol. 16 No. 4,
field settings and important boundary conditions can be pp. 665-676.
practically identified. Chandrasekaran, D., Arts, J.W.C., Tellis, G.J. and Frambach,
In addition to enhancing managers’ ability to understand
R.T. (2013), “Pricing in the international takeoff of new
customer behavior in a cross-cultural context, our
products”, International Journal of Research in Marketing,
propositions offer important clues in terms of devising
Vol. 30 No. 3, pp. 249-264.
appropriate communication strategies. For example, if a
Clark, T. (1990), “International marketing and national
particular cultural trait is more amenable to considering
character: a review and proposal for an integrative review”,
reference prices, the communication strategies for such
Journal of Marketing, Vol. 54 No. 4, pp. 66-79.
cultures can focus on creating suitable reference price levels
Emery, F.E. (1969), “Some psychological aspects of price”,
or influencing the same. Similarly, if a particular trait
in Taylor, B. and Willis, G. (Eds), Pricing Strategy,
(e.g. uncertainty avoidance) triggers greater loss aversion,
Brandon/System Press, New York, NY, pp. 98-111.
such inferences can be used to devise appropriate pricing
Eun, C.S., Wang, L. and Xiao, S.C. (2012), “Culture and
strategies, such as everyday low pricing or promotional
pricing. stock price synchronicity: the effects of tightness and
A managerial extension of our research would be to individualism”, SSRN, available at: http://ssrn.com/
superimpose cost and profitability characteristics and analyze abstract¼2021614 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.
the effect of inter-tier competition on firm profitability. 2021614 (accessed on January 9, 2014).
Although individual firm/retailer profitability must be Friedman, T. (2007), The World is Flat, Farrar, Strauss and
considered in the context of unique cost structures, our Giroux, New York, NY.
propositions can be combined with the easily available cost Furnham, A. and Boo, H.C. (2011), “A literature review of
information, and broader financial implications for the firms the anchoring effect”, Journal of Socio-Economics, Vol. 40
can be computed. No. 1, pp. 35-42.
Using our framework as a starting point, future research Ghemawat, P. (2001), “Distance still matters”, Harvard
could explore building mathematical models to identify which Business Review, Vol. 79 No. 8, pp. 137-147.
cultural combinations provide the maximum outcome in Gourville, J.T. (1998), “Pennies a day: the effect of temporal
terms of variables of interest – for example, the extent of re-framing on transaction evaluation”, Journal of Consumer
asymmetric competition, the extent of brand switching, Research, Vol. 24 No. 2, pp. 395-408.
profitability, and so on. Such extensions would clearly need to Guadagni, P.M. and Little, J.D.C. (1983), “A logit model of
wait until research in this area is growing and more empirical brand choice calibrated on scanner data”, Marketing
generalizations are possible. Science, Vol. 2 No. 3, pp. 203-238.
Another area for further research is to examine how the Hardie, B., Johnson, E. and Fader, P. (1993), “Modeling loss
national culture dimensions moderate other antecedents of aversion and reference dependence effects on brand
inter-tier competition. For example, much brand choice choice”, Marketing Science, Vol. 12 No. 4, pp. 378-394.
research has examined how the roles of brand loyalty, price Heath, T.B., Chatterjee, S. and France, K.R. (1995), “Mental
sensitivity, and so on, are related to inter-tier price accounting and changes in price: the frame dependence of
competition. A useful research direction would be to reference dependence”, Journal of Consumer Research,
examine if and how national culture dimensions interact Vol. 22 No. 2, pp. 90-97.
with these variables to further inform our understanding of Hofstede, G. (1980), Culture’s Consequences: International
brand competition. Differences in Work-related Values, Sage, Beverly Hills, CA.

137
National culture and inter-tier price competition Journal of Product & Brand Management
K. Sivakumar Volume 23 · Number 2 · 2014 · 131 –138

Hofstede, G. (1983), “The relativity of organizational Sivakumar, K. and Raj, S.P. (1997), “Quality tier
practices and theories”, Journal of International Business competition: how price change influences brand choice
Studies, Vol. 14 No. 2, pp. 75-90. and category choice”, Journal of Marketing, Vol. 61 No. 3,
Hofstede, G. and Bond, M.H. (1984), “Hofstede’s culture pp. 71-84.
dimensions: an independent validation using Rokeach’s Sivakumar, K., Li, M. and Dong, B. (2014), “Service quality:
value survey”, Journal of Cross-Cultural Psychology, Vol. 15 the impact of frequency, timing, proximity, and sequence of
No. 4, pp. 417-433. failures and delights”, Journal of Marketing, Vol. 78 No. 1,
Hofstede, G. and Bond, M.H. (1988), “The Confucius pp. 41-58.
connection: from cultural roots to economic growth”, Srinivasan, S., Pauwels, K., Hanssens, D. and Dekimpe, M.
Organizational Dynamics, Vol. 16 No. 4, pp. 5-21. (2002), “Who benefits from price promotions?”, Harvard
Kahneman, D. and Tversky, A. (1979), “Prospect theory: Business Review, Vol. 80 No. 9, pp. 22-23.
an analysis of decisions under risk”, Econometrica, Vol. 47 Søndergaard, M. (1994), “Hofstede’s consequences: a study
No. 2, pp. 263-291. of reviews, citations and replications”, Organization Studies,
Krishnamurthi, L. and Raj, S.P. (1991), “An Empirical Vol. 15 No. 3, pp. 447-456.
Analysis of the Relationship Between Brand Loyalty and Steenkamp, J-B.E.M. (2001), “The role of national culture in
Consumer Price Elasticity”, Marketing Science, Vol. 10 international marketing research”, International Marketing
No. 2, pp. 172-183. Review, Vol. 18 No. 1, pp. 30-44.
Lemon, K.N. and Nowlis, S.M. (2002), “Developing Stremersch, S. and Tellis, G.J. (2002), “Strategic bundling of
synergies between promotions and brands in different products and prices: a new synthesis for marketing”,
price–quality tiers”, Journal of Marketing Research, Vol. 39 Journal of Marketing, Vol. 66 No. 1, pp. 55-72.
Downloaded by University of Pittsburgh At 02:21 31 January 2016 (PT)

No. 2, pp. 171-185. Suri, R., Cai, Z., Monroe, K.B. and Thakor, M. (2012),
Mazumdar, T., Raj, S.P. and Sinha, I. (2005), “Reference “Retailers’ merchandise organization and price
price research: review and propositions”, Journal of perceptions”, Journal of Retailing, Vol. 88 No. 1,
Marketing, Vol. 69 No. 4, pp. 84-102. pp. 168-179.
Monroe, K.B. (1971), “Measuring price thresholds by Tellis, G.J. (1988), “Advertising exposure, loyalty, and brand
psychophysics and latitudes of acceptance”, Journal of purchase: a two-stage model of choice”, Journal of
Marketing Research, Vol. 8 No. 4, pp. 460-464. Marketing Research, Vol. 25 No. 2, pp. 134-144.
Nakata, C. and Sivakumar, K. (1996), “National culture and Thaler, R.H. (1985), “Mental Accounting and Consumer
new product development: an integrative review”, Journal of Choice”, Marketing Science, Vol. 4, Summer, pp. 199-214.
Marketing, Vol. 60 No. 1, pp. 61-72. Tversky, A. and Kahneman, D. (1974), “Judgment under
Nakata, C. and Sivakumar, K. (2001), “Instituting the uncertainty: heuristics and biases”, Science, Vol. 185
marketing concept in a multinational setting: the role of No. 1124, pp. 1128-1130.
national culture”, Journal of the Academy of Marketing Tversky, A. and Kahneman, D. (1991), “Loss aversion in
Science, Vol. 29, Summer, pp. 255-275. riskless choice: a reference-dependent model”, The Quarterly
Rajendran, K.N. and Tellis, G.J. (1994), “Contextual and Journal of Economics, Vol. 106 No. 4, pp. 1039-1061.
temporal components of reference price”, Journal of Winer, R.S. (1986), “A reference price model of brand choice
Marketing, Vol. 58 No. 1, pp. 22-34. for frequently purchased products”, Journal of Consumer
Sethuraman, R. and Srinivasan, V. (2002), “The asymmetric Research, Vol. 13 No. 2, pp. 250-256.
Yadav, M.S. (1994), “How buyers evaluate product bundles:
share effect: an empirical generalization on cross-price
a model of anchoring and adjustment”, Journal of Consumer
effects”, Journal of Marketing Research, Vol. 39 No. 3,
Research, Vol. 21, September, pp. 342-353.
pp. 379-386.
Zhan, F. (2013), Individualism, synchronized stock price
Sethuraman, R., Srinivasan, V. and Kim, D. (1999),
movements, and stock market volatility, SSRN, available at:
“Asymmetric and neighborhood cross-price effects: some
http://ssrn.com/abstract¼2173060 or http://dx.doi.org/10.
empirical generalizations”, Marketing Science, Vol. 18 No. 1,
2139/ssrn.2173060 (accessed on January 9, 2014).
pp. 23-41.
Sivakumar, K. (1995), “A Procedure to compare promotional
pricing and every day low pricing strategies”, Pricing Further Reading
Strategy and Practice: An International Journal, Vol. 3 No. 3, Bronnenberg, B. and Wathieu, L. (1996), “Asymmetric
pp. 4-15. promotion effects and brand positioning”, Marketing
Sivakumar, K. (1996), “Trade-off between frequency and Science, Vol. 15 No. 4, pp. 379-394.
depth of price promotions: implications for high- and low- Hofstede, G. (1994), “Management scientists are human”,
priced brands”, Journal of Marketing Theory and Practice, Management Science, Vol. 40, January, pp. 4-13.
Vol. 4 No. 1, pp. 1-8.
Sivakumar, K. (2007), “Asymmetric quality-tier competition:
Corresponding author
an alternative explanation”, Journal of Product and Brand
Management, Vol. 16 No. 6, pp. 415-425. K. Sivakumar can be contacted at: k.sivakumar@lehigh.edu

To purchase reprints of this article please e-mail: reprints@emeraldinsight.com


Or visit our web site for further details: www.emeraldinsight.com/reprints

138

You might also like