Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 32

Policy Analysis

July 8, 2020 | Number 895

Testing the “China Shock”


Was Normalizing Trade with China a Mistake?
By Scott Lincicome

T
EX EC U T I V E S UMMARY

here is an emerging consensus among from several flaws that collectively prove fatal for the
American politicians and many citi- anti-PNTR thesis.
zens that trade and globalization have As we approach the 20th anniversary of PNTR, criti-
undermined America’s working class, cism of the law and of the WTO more broadly will surely
resulting in a rise in U.S. populism. This intensify, but a proper accounting of the relevant eco-
view frequently targets the 2000 U.S. law that granted nomics and history reveals most critics to be misguided.
China “permanent normal trade relations” (PNTR) and Labor market and cultural disruptions in the United
China’s 2001 entry into the World Trade Organization States are real and important, as is China’s current and
(WTO) as key drivers of the country’s rise and the unfortunate turn toward illiberalism and imperialism. But
now-famous “China Shock”—the period between 1999 it is a mistake to pretend that there was a better trade poli-
and 2011 during which a sizeable increase in Chinese cy choice in 2000 than PNTR and engagement with China
imports supposedly produced the loss of approximately more broadly. It assumes too much, ignores too much,
2.4 million U.S. jobs. and demands too much. Worse, it could lead to truly bad
However, the view that PNTR was an erroneous governance: increasing U.S. protectionism; forgiving the
policy choice that disproportionately benefited political real and important failures of our policymakers, CEOs,
elites and corporations, directly drove the China Shock, and unions over the past two decades; and preventing a
and, combined with other allegedly “laissez-faire” poli- political consensus for real policy solutions. Indeed, these
cies, permanently scarred America’s working class suffers are happening now.

Scott Lincicome is a senior fellow in economic studies at the Cato Institute and a Senior Visiting Lecturer at Duke University Law School. Previously
he spent two decades practicing international trade law.
2


INTRODUCTION directly drove the China Shock, and, combined
Perhaps the Since Donald Trump’s surprising presiden- with other “laissez-faire” policies, permanent-
simplest, tial victory in 2016, both conservatives and ly scarred America’s working class suffers from
progressives have debated whether and to several flaws that collectively prove fatal for
yet most what extent “Washington elite” policy choices, the anti-PNTR thesis. As PNTR approaches
substantial, in particular international trade liberalization, its 20th anniversary and as U.S.–Chinese rela­
flaw in the have systematically (and perhaps nefariously) tions have deteriorated during the Trump
PNTR thesis harmed members of America’s working class, era, a proper accounting of the economic and
dooming them to lives of drug abuse, isola- historical record is essential. This paper sum-
is that it tion, and despair and creating fertile ground marizes the flaws in the conventional wisdom
ignores the for populists like Trump. In this increasingly on the China Shock. It finds that PNTR and
documented popular view lies a nugget of truth: Americans trade with China are generally more benign—
today face serious and relatively new prob- and far more complicated—than the story that
benefits of lems when forced to adjust to severe economic PNTR critics now repeat.
increased U.S. disruptions, whether those disruptions come
trade with from trade, technology, culture, or anything
China over else. These problems are often caused or exac- U.S.–CHINESE TRADE: AMPLIFIED
erbated by outmoded government policies in COSTS AND IGNORED BENEFITS
the past two


need of reform.1 Perhaps the simplest, yet most substantial,
decades. However, champions of the emerging con- flaw in the PNTR thesis is that it ignores the
sensus that trade liberalization was a mistake documented benefits of increased U.S. trade
err when targeting U.S. trade with China for with China over the past two decades—bene-
particular scorn.2 The policy choice most fits that often accrued to the U.S. working class
commonly criticized in this regard is the and manufacturing sector. For starters, even if
2000 U.S. law to grant China “permanent nor- one were to treat the China Shock literature
mal trade relations” (PNTR) and the coun- as gospel, studies have found that trade with
try’s subsequent entry into the World Trade China in the 2000s also provided ample ben-
Organization (WTO) in 2001.3 These two efits for American consumers—a group that
events are considered key drivers of the now- includes those directly harmed by the shock.
famous “China Shock,” the period between Economists Xavier Jaravel and Erick Sager,
1999 and 2011 during which a sizeable increase for example, found that Chinese import com-
in Chinese imports caused, according to econ- petition between 2000 and 2007—the peak
omists David Autor, David Dorn, and Gordon of the “China Shock”—had substantial “pro-
Hanson, the loss of approximately 2.4 million competitive effects” on U.S. firms and gener-
U.S. jobs.4 A related analysis by Justin Pierce ated over $202 billion in consumer benefits
and Peter Schott specifically targets PNTR via lower prices. That equals $101,250 in ben-
as the China Shock’s root cause, alleging the efits to U.S. consumers per manufacturing job
policy caused concentrated job losses between lost, as calculated by the China Shock papers.7
2001 and 2007 in U.S. industries most exposed The following year, Liang Bai and Sebastian
to Chinese import competition.5 Stumpner concluded in the American Economic
Armed with these studies, it has become Review that Chinese imports “significantly
fashionable, especially on the political right, reduced inflation,” cutting the price index for
to blame PNTR and China’s WTO accession consumer goods by 0.19 percentage points
for the country’s economic rise and unfortu- per year between 2004 and 2015 as a result of
nate recent turn toward illiberalism.6 both changes in the prices of existing goods
However, the view that PNTR was an erro­ and the entry of new goods—signaling strong
neous policy choice that disproportionately pro-competitive effects and improved vari-
benefited political elites and corporations, ety.8 A study by Mary Amiti and others found
3


similarly impressive consumer gains,9 while competition potentially hurts all U.S. manu-
Christian Broda and John Romalis found that facturing jobs. That assumption is proven in- There is
the consumer benefits of trade, already tilted correct by the San Francisco Fed study, which evidence that
toward America’s poor and middle class, were found that one-third of all Chinese imports
even more so for Chinese imports because were intermediate goods that American com-
many U.S.
those consumers frequently shop at places panies used to produce globally competitive manufacturers
that carry such goods, such as Target and products. (Hundreds of manufacturing jobs at adapted
Walmart.10 One can argue that those consum- a Missouri custom hat company, for example,
during the
er benefits are cold comfort to someone who are threatened by President Trump’s tariffs on
lost a job because of Chinese import compe- imported Chinese baseball caps.18) These im- shock and
tition, but they are nevertheless real, wide- ports have helped, not hurt, U.S. manufacturing ended up
spread, and important.11 workers. In fact, Pol Antràs, Teresa C. Fort, and hiring many
Chinese imports have also been found to Felix Tintelnot found that U.S. manufacturing
generate substantial benefits for American firms that increased direct imports from China
Americans
and increasing


companies, including manufacturers and their between 1997 and 2007 experienced growing or
workers. Germán Gutiérrez and Thomas steady employment, likely because of the im- output.
Philippon, for example, found that Chinese porters’ ability to lower prices and raise output
import competition encouraged many (even as nonimporting competitors suffered).19
American manufacturing firms to invest and With respect to these types of complex value
innovate more—another “pro-competitive” chains, the WTO estimates that China in 2015
effect.12 Using a general equilibrium model, was the third-largest user—behind only Mexico
Lorenzo Caliendo, Maximiliano Dvorkin, and and Canada—of “Made In America” manufac-
Fernando Parro found net welfare benefits turing inputs and the largest source of inputs
from the China Shock for U.S. manufacturing for American manufacturers.20
and nonmanufacturing firms across regions.13 Then there are the benefits that American
Zhi Wang and others, after accounting for farmers and workers have derived from ex-
manufacturing supply chains and intermedi- porting to China, still the United States’ third-
ate inputs, found that the overall effect of the largest export destination.21 According to the
China Shock on American jobs and wages has US-China Business Council, exports to China
been quite positive.14 Simon Galle, Andrés in 2019 supported over 1.1 million American
Rodríguez-Clare, and Moises Yi found that jobs in a wide range of manufacturing, logis-
while the China Shock produced losses for tics, and services industries.22
certain groups of Americans, it generated Beyond the benefits of trade with China,
overall gains in social welfare.15 a proper accounting of the China Shock also
Meanwhile, researchers with the Federal requires proper context. There is evidence, for
Reserve Bank of San Francisco have estimat- example, that many U.S. manufacturers adapt-
ed that about 56 cents of every dollar that ed during the shock and ended up hiring many
Americans spent on “Made in China” imports Americans and increasing output. Summariz-
in 2018 actually went to American firms and ing a 2018 paper from Teresa C. Fort, Justin
workers—the highest share of any country.16 R. Pierce, and Peter K. Schott,23 the Financial
Such benefits make sense: 2019 U.S. labor Times’ Gillian Tett notes:
market data show millions more “blue col-
lar” American jobs that might benefit from Between 1977 and 2012, the num-
Chinese imports—in transportation, logistics, ber of “manufacturing firm workers”
construction, and maintenance and repair, for employed in “manufacturing plants”
example—than in manufacturing.17 halved from just under 20m to nearer
Furthermore, this already benign as- 10m. However, the employees in “non-
sessment assumes that Chinese import manufacturing plants” that were owned
4


by “manufacturing firms” rose from 13m of Chinese imports” and that “shocks to man-
The evolution to 23m, primarily due to an explosion in ufacturing that were unrelated to China or
of American service sector jobs such as design and trade (including, presumably, things like rising
IT. As a result, by 2012 the US’s “manu- automation) had very similar effects on local
manu­ facturing” companies employed slightly labor markets to the Chinese import shock.”
facturing more workers than in 1977. Moreover, As a result, they conclude that “policy efforts
raises further that was not because of business churn: to address the adverse labor market effects
concerns 75 per cent of the “manufacturing” job of trade will not reverse the broader trend in
losses in this period occurred at com- manufacturing employment that has signifi-
about panies which remained in business, and cantly weakened labor market options, partic-
attempting it was the incumbents which opened ularly for less educated workers.” They further
to isolate most of the non-manufacturing plants. speculate that persistently depressed low-skill
In plain English, this means that as manufacturing employment in the United
the effects Chinese competition hit, America’s States was likely caused by nontrade issues such
of Chinese “manufacturing” groups quietly re- as a skills mismatch in the U.S. manufacturing
import engineered themselves. Yes, they might sector (which is becoming more skilled com-
competition call themselves “manufacturers”, and be pared to other low-skill professions such as
retail and construction) and declining cross-
defined that way in the data. But they
on low-skill increasingly hire service-sector work- region mobility among U.S. workers during the
American ers, as their output soars.24 2000s compared to earlier periods. As a result,
manufacturing “imposing trade barriers against the rest of the
Nicholas Bloom and others found a similar world is unlikely to substantially increase the
employ­


trend among U.S. workers in “high human- employment prospects of workers with lower
ment. capital areas,” such as the West Coast or New levels of accumulated schooling.”
England, where manufacturers “remained Studies have similarly found it difficult to
open but changed to research, design, man- distinguish the employment effects of trade
agement or wholesale.”25 Low human-capital from those of technology. After document-
areas, by contrast, lost jobs on net—a regional ing the evolution of American manufacturers
discrepancy that might indict policies that in their aforementioned paper, for example,
help Americans gain skills or cope with disrup- Fort, Pierce, and Schott acknowledge that
tion but not the disruption itself. the “data provide support for both trade- and
The evolution of American manufactur- technology-based explanations of the overall
ing—driven by trade, automation, or oth- decline of [manufacturing] employment over
er factors—raises further concerns about this period, while also highlighting the diffi-
attempting to isolate the effects of Chinese culties of estimating an overall contribution
import competition on low-skill American for each mechanism.”27
manufacturing employment. Kerwin Charles, Katherine Eriksson and others provide
Erik Hurst, and Mariel Schwartz, for exam- addi­tional China Shock context. They show
ple, found that the decline in manufacturing that the China Shock was so “shocking” not be-
employ­ment during the 2000s was a substan- cause of China or PNTR but because of when
tial cause of rising American unemployment, it hit the United States: during regional shifts
especially for less-educated prime-age work- in the U.S. production of certain goods.28 In
ers.26 However, they also found that a mix of particular, “late stage” industries—with now-
both import competition and nontrade factors standardized processes and technologies that
caused these declines. They show that “manu- are susceptible to global competition (particu-
facturing employment declined substantially larly in developing countries)—had moved out
over the 2000s, even in markets where there of higher education/innovation U.S. regions
was essentially no manufacturing loss because to places with less education and innovative
5


capacity, thus explaining “why the shock hurt in (to China and other countries).36 Reynolds
these areas to the extent that it did.” This tim- adds that extending the period beyond 2011, ‘Late stage’
ing adds to the uniqueness of the China Shock, during which the U.S. economy was still affect- industries
as the authors find that previous U.S. trade ed by the Great Recession, causes half of the
shocks—involving Japan and the Asian Tigers, job loss attributed to the China Shock to “dis-
were well
for example—had no such dynamic (and thus la- appear.” Charles Freeman, who ran the Office on their way
bor market effects that were far more limited). of the U.S. Trade Representative’s Office of out of the
The analysis also shows that these “late stage” China Affairs during the George W. Bush
United States
industries were well on their way out of the admin­istration, recalls:
United States regardless of the China Shock. regardless
Many other experts have questioned Among the things that has troubled me of the China


whether the China Shock literature tells the about the Autor study is the lack of cor- Shock.
whole story about Chinese imports, U.S. man- relation between [Harmonized Tariff
ufacturing jobs, and related issues. As noted, Schedule] level imports from China and
numerous economists have found substan- US job losses in those sectors. We were
tial net benefits for the United States when deeply attuned to those losses at [the
more fully accounting (e.g., through a general Office of the U.S. Trade Representative]
equilibrium model) for Chinese import com- at that time because we had such a pow-
petition. The Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro erful tool in the special safeguard in sec-
model further shows far fewer manufacturing tion 421. We just didn’t see any profound
job losses caused by the China Shock (only direct US job losses in sectors exposed
15 percent of the observed decline between to new direct competition from China.
2000 and 2007).29 Similarly, a pair of papers Most of the post PNTR surge in China
by lead author Robert Feenstra found offset- imports was in sectors that had already
ting job gains in U.S. manufacturing exports shifted overseas. The small blip in accel­
and services,30 while Brad DeLong estimated eration of manufacturing job losses was
that China’s WTO entry resulted in a net loss actually far below anything any of us
of only 300,000 U.S. jobs—just 0.22 percent could have anticipated. We were ready
of nonfarm employment.31 Adam Jakubik and to be protectionist, but the numbers
Victor Stolzenburg found one-third fewer never justified it. We actually had the
manufacturing job losses and much differ- [International Trade Commission]
ent regional effects when using value-added, prepped to do a study showing the lack
instead of gross, trade flows to measure the of linkage between what were primar-
China Shock (and that the job losses basically ily productivity-related manufacturing
ended in 2008),32 while Yuan Xu, Hong Ma, job losses and China trade policy but a
and Feenstra found 20–30 percent fewer job political decision was made to blame
losses when accounting for booms and busts China rather than domestic [economic]
in the U.S. housing market.33 realities.37
Other experts have voiced skepticism re-
garding the China Shock findings themselves34 Phil Levy, a member of the George W.
(including on cultural effects35). The Cato Bush administration’s Council of Economic
Institute’s Alan Reynolds notes, for example, Advisers, adds that the fungibility of Chinese
that the China Shock’s “microeconomic mod- and other developing country imports under-
el designed for local ‘commuting zones’ cannot mines the argument that Chinese imports—as
properly be extended to the entire national opposed to imports more generally—were
economy” and therefore misses important to blame for some of the manufacturing job
macroeconomic effects of U.S.-Chinese trade losses that occurred during the China Shock
liberalization such as increased U.S. exports period. The proof came in Levy’s personal
6


examination of domestic industry petitions None. That’s why we recommended
That for relief from Chinese imports under the against imposing tariffs.38
economists Section 421 special safeguard mechanism:
Levy concludes from this experience that it
repeatedly and In each of the two Section 421 cases I “calls into question the premise of [the China
openly express heard, the importers made credible pre- Shock] analysis. If the alternative to imports
reservations sentations that, were tariffs to be im- from China was imports from other develop-
about blaming posed, they would switch their sourcing ing nations, then the impact of China on U.S.
from China to Vietnam, or to India, or workers was negligible.”
China should Brazil. In one case, the factory move was The data tend to corroborate Freeman’s
foment estimated to take three weeks. In anoth- and Levy’s claims. First, Figure 1 shows only
similar levels er, contingent contracts were already in a modest change in trend for manufacturing
place. Producing in those places cost a bit jobs as a share of the U.S. workforce before
of caution more than in China, which is why they and after PNTR passed and China entered
among U.S. weren’t the original sourcing countries, the WTO:39
politicians and but they were cheaper than the United Second, data indicate, pace Levy, that


pundits. States. So what benefit would U.S. work- Chinese imports simply replaced other imports
ers have seen in blocking China trade? (as opposed to domestic production) during the

Figure 1
Manufacturing share of total U.S. employment
45

40

35
tnemyolpme .S.U latot fo egatnecreP

30
China’s “permanent normal
25 trade relations” status begins

20 China enters World


Trade Organization
15

10

0
1491
2491
4491
5491
7491
8491
0591
1591
3591
4591
6591
7591
9591
0691
2691
3691
5691
6691
8691
9691
1791
2791
4791
5791
7791
8791
0891
1891
3891
4891
6891
7891
9891
0991
2991
3991
5991
6991
8991
9991
1002
2002
4002
5002
7002
8002
0102
1102
3102
4102
6102
7102
9102

Source: “All Employees, Manufacturing/All Employees, Total Nonfarm,” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, https://fred.stlouisfed.org/graph/?g=mcsO.
7


China Shock. According to the Congressional the overall import content of U.S. consumer
Research Service, the total share of imports into goods has remained relatively constant while PNTR
the United States from Pacific Rim countries the Chinese share has increased demonstrates probably
between 1990 and 2017 remained constant at that Chinese gains have come, in large part, at the
47.1 percent, but “the role of China as a supplier cost of other exporters, namely Japan.”41
accelerated
of U.S. manufactured products among Pacific That economists repeatedly and openly Chinese
Rim countries increased sharply, while the rela- express reservations—supported by various exports to
tive importance of the rest of the Pacific Rim trade and employment data—about blam-
the United
(excluding China) for these products sharply ing China trade for massive declines in U.S.
decreased,” (see Figure 2) a result “partly due to manufacturing employment should foment States, but
many multinational firms shifting their export- similar levels of caution among U.S. politi- China’s own
oriented manufacturing facilities from other cians and pundits. reforms—far
countries to China.”40 Finally, there is the matter of putting the
The San Francisco Federal Reserve also China Shock’s effects into perspective. For
beyond the
found that Americans’ total import consump- example, Douglas Irwin (citing a 2014 Robert control of
tion, as measured by 2017 personal consump- Lawrence paper42) notes that “imports from Washington
tion expenditures, remained relatively steady China may have resulted in involuntary dis-
policy­
during the China Shock period. This further placement of 97,000 manufacturing workers
signifies that Chinese imports displaced oth- per year (on average, adjusted to account for makers—
er imports far more than American produc- voluntary separations), but that is less than one- also fueled
tion. According to the report, “the fact that fifth of total involuntary job loss in manufacturing the China


Figure 2 Shock.
U.S. manufactured imports from Pacific Rim countries as a percentage of total U.S.
manufactured imports
50

45
3.6
tnemyolpme .S.U latot fo egatnecreP

40

35

30

25

20 26.4

15

10

0 43.5 21.1
1990 2017

Paci c Rim minus China China


Source: Wayne M. Morrison, China–U.S. Trade Issues (Washington: Congressional Research Service, July 30, 2018).
Note: This uses the Standard International Trade Classification definition of manufactured imports.
8


and less than 5 percent of all involuntary job losses Square protests and the presidential election
Contrary to over the same period.”43 As previously noted, of Bill Clinton, who ran against MFN, which
allegations DeLong estimates that the China Shock re- was subsequently renamed “normal trade rela-
sulted in the loss of less than 0.25 percent of tions” (NTR).46 Only once between 1990 and
from all U.S. nonfarm jobs. Autor himself has called 2001 was China’s MFN/NTR status truly in
President his estimate of 2 million jobs lost an “up- doubt: in 1992, when a presidential veto was
Trump and per bound” (the more likely central estimate needed to maintain it. As a result, Chinese
others, the was about half that number), and it includes imports to the United States increased more
around 1 million nonmanufacturing jobs. than six-fold in the decade preceding PNTR,
United States Autor’s more recent paper on China trade and by the late 1990s the rational expecta-
did not simply and U.S. marriage trends, moreover, acknowl- tion of most U.S. importers was more of the
‘rubber- edges that the “analysis does not imply that same. Indeed, a 1998 Congressional Research
surging import competition from China over Service analysis of congressional votes and the
stamp’ the last two decades has been the sole or pri- broader annual MFN/NTR renewal debate
China’s WTO mary driver of these [marriage and childbirth] concluded that, by the late 1990s, MFN/NTR
accession or trends” but only a “plausible contributor.”44 was “a largely settled issue” in Congress:
base it on These analyses should make us skeptical of the
claimed benefits of recent proposals for gov- In 1993, newly elected President Clinton
Pollyannaish ernment to remake the U.S. economy because announced he would link China’s MFN
dreams of of the China Shock. status to human rights progress begin-
Chinese That said, the numerous academic stud- ning in 1994. Although ultimately the
ies discussed above are not intended to argue President reversed himself, the 1993 deci-
democ­


that Chinese import competition in the de- sion appears to have been a pivotal cata-
ratization. cade following China’s WTO accession was lyst in the declining importance of MFN
purely beneficial to the United States or that status as a tool with which to influence
the U.S. labor market and certain communi- China policy. Neither the House nor the
ties are problem free. Instead, they reveal that Senate has passed MFN-related legisla-
the claims of harm from Chinese trade are tion during the Clinton Administration.
likely wildly overstated while the substantial Instead, Members have turned to legis-
economic benefits are usually ignored. These lative alternatives, most of which have
studies also reveal that the China Shock issues included more specific, more targeted
are more uncertain and complex than the cari- sanctions on China’s activities.47
cature painted by PNTR/China critics.45
The run-up to the PNTR vote in 2000 per-
mits the same conclusion. In 1999, the House
THE REALITY OF CHINA’S vote to deny MFN/NTR for China was de-
WTO ACCESSION AND feated by a 170–260 margin; the Senate vote
EXPORT COMPETITIVENESS was an even more lopsided 12–87. As former
Critics also often distort the circumstances Office of the U.S. Trade Representative staffer
of China’s WTO accession and the effects of Erin Ennis recalls: “I was part of the Clinton
PNTR. First, PNTR did not actually open administration’s annual efforts to ensure that
the United States to Chinese imports: China MFN was continued each year. We never took
had previously held “most favored nation” it for granted and contacted every House of-
(MFN) trade status, renewed on an annual fice each time a vote was in order, but the out-
basis, since 1980, meaning the country faced come was rarely in doubt—particularly since
no greater trade barriers than most other (“fa- there was only one vote in the Senate during
vored”) U.S. trading partners. MFN status that time and it failed by a wide margin.”48
was even renewed right after the Tiananmen Table 1 lists these votes.
9
10

Sources: Kerry Dumbaugh, Voting on NTR for China Again in 2001, and Past Congressional Decisions (Washington: Congressional Research Service,
updated July 17, 2001); and K. William Watson, “Free Trade, Free Markets: Rating the Congress,” Cato Institute Free Trade Bulletin no. 53, June 4,
2013.

Nevertheless, there is evidence that the of MFN/NTR, and U.S. jobs.49 Kyle Handley
certainty of “permanent” trade relations accel- and Nuno Limão found similar results (along
erated the growth of Chinese imports into the with substantial consumer gains) in their 2017
United States. The most well-known paper on paper.50 Other experts, however, question the
the effect of PNTR’s certainty on Chinese im- magnitude of the PNTR “uncertainty driver.”
ports and U.S. manufacturing jobs, from Pierce For example, George Allesandria, Shafaat
and Schott, found a substantial connection Khan, and Armen Khederlarian in 2019 found
among PNTR, Chinese imports in sectors that that the annual MFN/NTR votes actually in-
would have faced high tariffs in the absence creased Chinese imports into the United States
11


as a result of importers’ increasing shipments attributing approximately two-thirds of the
in advance of any potential tariff increases.51 effect of China’s WTO entry on U.S. manufac- Congressional
They also found, consistent with the afore- turing not to PNTR but to China’s own tariff record and
mentioned congressional and anecdotal evi- reductions resulting from WTO entry.53 As shown
dence, that the probability of NTR denial in Figures 3 and 4, average Chinese import tar-
Chinese trade
averaged only about 5.5 percent between 1990 iffs went from about 15 percent in 2000 to less flow data
and 2001, reaching a mere 1.4 percent in 2001 than 9 percent in 2006, and even lower on a contradict
right before China joined the WTO. Based on trade-weighted scale.
the popular
these data, they found the trade-dampening The Autor, Dorn, and Hanson China Shock
effects of MFN/NTR uncertainty to have papers even emphasize that China’s internal assertion that
evaporated by the late 1990s. reforms—on privatization, trading rights, and an isolated
Regardless of which expert is correct, the (again) import liberalization, often in response U.S. policy
congressional record and Chinese trade flow to new WTO commitments—were major
data contradict the popular assertion that an contributors to China’s export competitive-
choice in 2000
isolated U.S. policy choice in 2000 first ex- ness in the late 1990s and 2000s.54 Jakubik first exposed
posed the U.S. market and U.S. workers to and Stolzenburg subsequently confirmed this the U.S.
view.55 Several papers have shown significant,
Chinese import competition. At most, PNTR
market and
merely accelerated a bilateral economic inte- though often different, effects of Chinese im-
gration that was already well underway. port competition on firms and workers across U.S. workers
More importantly, there is ample evidence Europe, which was obviously not affected by to Chinese
that PNTR was not the only, and perhaps not PNTR (and had granted China MFN status import
even the main, driver of the China Shock years earlier).56 In other words, PNTR proba-
compe­


that occurred in United States. Handley and bly accelerated Chinese exports to the United
Limão, for example, found that a reduction States, but China’s own reforms—far beyond tition.
in trade policy uncertainty accounted for only the control of Washington policymakers—also
about one-third of the growth in Chinese ex- fueled the China Shock.
ports to the United States between 2000 and Furthermore, China’s WTO accession was
2005.52 Amiti and others found similar results, not “shocking” for anyone paying attention to

Figure 3
Tariff rate, applied, simple mean, all products—China
40

35

30

25
egatnecreP

20

15

10

0
2991
3991
4991
5991
6991
7991
8991
9991
0002
1002
2002
3002
4002
5002
6002
7002
8002
9002
0102
1102
2102
3102
4102
5102
6102
7102

Source: The World Bank.


12


Figure 4
The reforms Tariff rate, applied, weighted mean, all products—China
that China 40

undertook 35

during 30
its WTO
accession
25
egatnecreP

were so 20

substantial 15
as to drive 10
China’s
incredible 5

export 0

compet­
2991
3991
4991
5991
6991
7991
8991
9991
0002
1002
2002
3002
4002
5002
6002
7002
8002
9002
0102
1102
2102
3102
4102
5102
6102
7102

itiveness. Source: The World Bank.

U.S. trade policy in the 1990s (a group that pre- concessions from the Chinese government
sumably included U.S. manufacturers, unions, over a contentious 13-year negotiation.59 Con-
and politicians). China first applied to join trary to allegations from President Trump
the WTO (under its predecessor, the General and others, the United States did not simply
Agreement on Tariffs and Trade) in 1985, then “rubber-stamp” China’s WTO accession or
reapplied in 1995 when the WTO came into be- base it on Pollyannaish dreams of Chinese de-
ing, and finally acceded to the body in 2001.57 mocratization. In an interview about his book
As shown in Table 2 and Table 3, China’s acces- Schism: China, America, and the Fracturing of the
sion over this time involved dozens of bilateral Global Trading System, journalist Paul Blustein
and multilateral (“working party”) meetings, describes his research into the U.S.–Chinese
negotiating texts, disclosures, and—as previ- bilateral accession negotiations:
ously noted—internal reforms. China’s final
accession package—a “Working Party Report” I did a lot of research on the negotiations
and “Protocol of Accession,” plus liberalization leading to China’s entry into the WTO,
schedules for goods and services—contained interviewing many of the key players on
hundreds of pages of commitments (by far the both sides. I found that both sides played
most of any acceding member to that point and extreme hardball—if anything, it was the
considered still today to be some of the deep- Chinese who felt bruised and humiliated
est ever). This included many “WTO-plus” by the way the talks were conducted. The
commitments that the United States and other Americans . . . were usually the ones to
members dictated (via bilateral accession agree- walk away from the table. . . . China had to
ments) and have since been used, for example, agree to open its economy and reform in
to challenge Chinese laws through dispute set- ways that exceeded the requirements im-
tlement or to restrict Chinese imports.58 posed on other countries. For example,
Notably, the United States was the final China had to promise that it would re-
holdout among large industrialized nations duce its tariffs on [manufactured] goods
to approve China’s WTO accession via bi- to an avg of about 9% in 2005. China
lateral negotiations, demanding ever more had to lower its tariffs to less than 1/3 the
13
Table 2
China’s WTO accession multilateral track
Event Date
General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) application received July 10, 1986
Memorandum on the Foreign Trade Regime (MFTR) Feb. 18, 1987
GATT accession working party established Mar. 4, 1987
Meeting Mar. 4, 1987
GATT terms of reference and accession working party membership June 19, 1987
Meeting Oct. 22, 1987
Initial cycle(s) of questions and replies, following the circulation of the MFTR Nov. 27, 1987
Meeting Feb. 23–24, 1988
Factual summaries of points raised Mar. 29, 1988
~Updated Dec. 9, 1988
Meeting Apr. 26–27, 1988
Meeting June 28–29, 1988
Tariff negotiations June 30, 1988
Supplementary information July 19, 1988
Meeting Sept. 27–28, 1988
Meeting Feb. 28–Mar. 1, 1989
Supplementary information Mar. 29, 1989
Meeting Apr. 18–19, 1989
Initial cycle(s) of questions and replies, following the circulation of the factual summary June 3–Sept. 14, 1988
Meeting July 11–12, 1989
Nov. 10, 1989
Additional information on China’s foreign trade regime (postings) Oct. 15, 1991
Mar. 17, 1992
Sept. 7, 1993
Meeting Dec. 12–13, 1989
Meeting Sept. 20–21, 1990
Meeting Feb. 13–14, 1992
Meeting Oct. 21–22, 1992
Meeting Dec. 9–10, 1992
Meeting Mar. 15–16, 1993
Meeting May 24–28, 1993
Meeting Sept. 28–Oct. 1, 1993
Meeting Mar. 15–18, 1994
June 7, 1994
Agriculture, including questions and replies Apr. 17, 1996
June 20, 2000
Sept. 14, 2000
Meeting June 28–July 1, 1994
Meeting July 29, 1994
Noti cation of readiness to enter into negotiations July 22, 1994
Meeting Dec. 20, 1994
World Trade Organization (WTO) application received and WTO accession working party established Dec. 7, 1995
June 7, 1994
Agriculture, including questions and replies Apr. 17, 1996
June 20, 2000
Sept. 14, 2000
Table 2
Meeting June 28–July 1, 1994
14
China’s
Meeting WTO accession multilateral track July 29, 1994
Event
Noti cation of readiness to enter into negotiations July 22,Date
1994
General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) application received
Meeting July 20,
Dec. 10, 1986
1994
Memorandum
World on the Foreign
Trade Organization Trade
(WTO) Regime received
application (MFTR) and WTO accession working party established Feb.
Dec.18, 1987
7, 1995
GATTsessions
1st accession working party established Mar.22,
Mar. 4, 1996
1987
Meeting
Terms of reference and accession working party membership Mar. 4, 1996
Apr. 2, 1987
GATTsession
2nd terms of reference and accession working party membership June
Nov.19,
1, 1987
1996
Meeting
3rd session Oct.
Mar.22, 1987
6, 1997
Initial cycle(s) of questions and replies, following the circulation of the MFTR
4th session Nov.
May 27,
23, 1987
1997
Meeting
5th session Feb. 23–24,
Aug. 1, 1988
1997
Factual
6th summaries of points raised
session Mar. 29,
Dec. 5,1988
1997
~Updated Dec. 9, 1988
7th session Apr. 8, 1998
Meeting Apr. 26–27, 1988
Additional questions and replies July 13, 1998
Meeting June 28–29, 1988
8th session July 24, 1998
Tariff negotiations June 30, 1988
9th session Mar. 21, 2000
Supplementary information July 19, 1988
Updated MFTR and comprehensive list of China’s laws and regulations Mar. 21, 2000
Meeting Sept. 27–28, 1988
Draft report of the working party June 14, 2000
Meeting Feb. 28–Mar. 1, 1989
Sanitary and phytosanitary June 19, 2000
Supplementary information measures checklist Mar. 29, 2000
July 24, 1989
Meeting
10th session Apr.June
18–19, 1989
23, 2000
Initial cycle(s)
Additional of questions
questions and replies, following the circulation of the factual summary
and replies June 3–Sept.
July 14,
18, 1988
2000
Meeting barriers to trade checklist
Technical July July
11–12,
18, 1989
2000
Trade-related aspects of intellectual property rights questionnaire Nov.
July 10,
18, 1989
2000
Additional information on China’s foreign trade regime (postings) Oct. 15, 1991
11th session Mar. 17, 2000
July 27, 1992
Sept. 7, 1993
12th session Sept. 28, 2000
Meeting Dec. 12–13, 1989
– Nov. 8, 2000
Meeting Sept. 20–21, 1990
13th session Nov. 9, 2000
Meeting Feb. 13–14, 1992
14th session Dec. 8, 2000
Meeting Oct. 21–22, 1992
15th session Jan. 17, 2001
Meeting Dec. 9–10, 1992
16th session July 4, 2001
Meeting Mar. 15–16, 1993
17th session July 20, 2001
Meeting May 24–28, 1993
18th session Sept. 17, 2001
Meeting Sept. 28–Oct. 1, 1993
Comprehensive legislative action plan Sept. 22, 2000
Meeting Mar. 15–18, 1994
Nov. 9, 2000
Import licensing procedures questionnaire June 7, 1994–
Agriculture, including questions and replies Apr. 17, 1996
Customs valuation checklist June 20, 2000 –
Sept. 14, 2000
States-trading questionnaire –
Meeting June 28–July 1, 1994
Draft subsidies noti cation –
Meeting July 29, 1994
Rule-speci c action plans –
Noti cation of readiness to enter into negotiations July 22, 1994
Legislation and implementing regulations –
Meeting Dec. 20, 1994
Consultation documents –
World Trade Organization (WTO) application received and WTO accession working party established Dec. 7, 1995
Source: “Accession: China,” World Trade Organization.
1st sessions Mar. 22, 1996
Terms of reference and accession working party membership Apr. 2, 1996
15
Table 3
China’s WTO accession bilateral track
Country Date Type
Hungary 1997 Bilateral agreement is reached
New Zealand Aug. 6, 1997 Bilateral agreement is reached
South Korea Aug. 26, 1997 Bilateral agreement is reached
Czech Republic 1997 Bilateral agreement is reached

Slovakia Oct. 13–24, 1997 Signed an agreement on ending the bilateral market access negotiations
for China’s accession to the World Trade Organization (WTO)
Turkey N/A N/A
Singapore N/A N/A

Pakistan Oct. 13–24, 1997 Signed an agreement on ending the bilateral market access negotiations
for China’s accession to the WTO
Indonesia N/A N/A

Japan Nov. 1–16, 1997 Bilateral market access negotiations between China and Japan
on China’s accession to the WTO basically ended
Australia Dec. 1–12, 1997 Conducted bilateral consultations
Chile Oct. 13–24, 1997 Ended China’s WTO accession negotiations
United States Mar. 13, 2000 Signature dates of bilateral market access agreement
Canada Fall 1999 Signed bilateral accession agreement
Venezuela Sept. 25, 2000 Signature dates of bilateral market access agreement
Cuba N/A N/A
Brazil Jan. 20, 2000 Signature dates of bilateral market access agreement
Sri Lanka Jan. 21, 2000 Signature dates of bilateral market access agreement
Uruguay Jan. 27, 2000 Signature dates of bilateral market access agreement
Peru Jan. 27, 2000 Signature dates of bilateral market access agreement
Iceland Jan. 28, 2000 Signature dates of bilateral market access agreement
Norway Jan. 28, 2000 Signature dates of bilateral market access agreement
Philippines N/A N/A
India Oct. 13–24, 1997 Ended China’s WTO accession negotiations
Colombia Oct. 13–24, 1997 Ended China’s WTO accession negotiations
Argentina Oct. 13–24, 1997 Ended China’s WTO accession negotiations
Thailand N/A N/A
European Union May 19, 2000 Bilateral agreement is reached
Costa Rica Sept. 28, 2000 Signature dates of bilateral market access agreement
Ecuador N/A N/A
Guatemala N/A N/A
Kyrgyz Republic N/A N/A
Latvia May 16, 2000 Bilateral agreement is reached
Malaysia Apr. 12, 2000 Bilateral agreement is reached
Mexico Sept. 13, 2001 Bilateral agreement is reached
Poland N/A N/A
Switzerland Sept. 26, 2000 Bilateral agreement is reached
Ecuador N/A N/A
Guatemala N/A N/A
Kyrgyz Republic N/A N/A
Table
Latvia3 May 16, 2000 Bilateral agreement is reached
16
China’s
Malaysia WTO accession Apr.
bilateral track
12, 2000 Bilateral agreement is reached
Country
Mexico Sept. 13,Date
2001 Type
Bilateral agreement is reached
Hungary
Poland 1997
N/A Bilateral agreement is reached
N/A
New Zealand
Switzerland Aug.26,
Sept. 6, 1997
2000 Bilateral agreement is reached
South Korea
Sources: “China’s WTO AccessionAug. 26, 1997
Reaches Final Stage,” People’s Daily Online; Sina Corp, “Information: Memorabilia of Bilateral agreement
China’s WTO Accessionis reached
Negotiations”;
Czech RepublicSina Corp, “Background Information:
1997 China’s Accession to the WTO Negotiations for 15 Years”; and WorldBilateral
Trade Organization,
agreement “Register of
is reached
Bilateral Market Access Agreements: The Accession of China Taipei.”
Slovakia Oct. 13–24, 1997 Signed an agreement on ending the bilateral market access negotiations
comparable figures for Brazil &forother
China’s accession to the
celebration of World Tradedemocratization
inevitable Organization (WTO)
nor


Turkey comparable
N/A countries. China also had to a credulous declaration of China subsumingN/Ait-
Singapore agree
N/A that its trading partners could use self to American leadership,” and instead com-
N/A
It is either several unusual mechanisms anthat portedthe
could on ending with “the dominant argument used by
1997 the inflow ofSigned agreement bilateral market access negotiations
mistaken or
Pakistan Oct. 13–24, restrict Chinese products. PNTR advocates to sway legislators”
for China’s accession to the WTO(i.e., that
misleading
Indonesia All
N/A in all, it’s hard to imagine how the “engagement with China was not primarily N/A
US could have driven a harder bargain aimed at changing China, but rather focused on
Japanto claim that Nov. 1–16, on 1997 Bilateral market access negotiations between
[economic] issues and still gotten a on benefitting America”).
China’s accession
62 China and Japan
to the WTO basically ended
the WTO hasDec. 1–12, deal.
Australia 1997
Chinese officials are resentful to Thus, from a simple legal and historical per-
Conducted bilateral consultations
Chile
utterly failed this
Oct. 13–24, 1997
day; they feel China was forced to ac- spective, there was nothing really “shocking”
Ended China’s WTO accession negotiations
cept 2nd class citizenship on a [number] or “naïve” about PNTR and the China Shock.
to discipline
United States Mar. 13, of issues.60
2000 Signature dates of bilateral
It is also a stretchmarket access
to assert thatagreement
based on the
China’s
Canada Fall 1999 facts at the time that Washington policymakers
Signed bilateral accession agreement
unfair
Venezuela trade Beyond
Sept. 25, 2000 driving a hard bargain, U.S. Signature dates of of
trade had much a choice
bilateral whenaccess
market deciding whether
agreement
Cubapractices
representatives for multiple presidents from to grant PNTR to China (a move that every
N/A N/A
each major party also frequently consulted with other WTO member had done years earlier).
Brazilwhen the Jan. 20, 2000 and the private sector, including labor
Congress Signature
Asdates of bilateral
Levy wrote market
in 2018, the access agreementto
two alternatives
sole means of Jan. 21,
Sri Lanka unions,
2000at every step (as required by U.S. law). 61
PNTR—letting
Signature China
dates of bilateral in the
market WTO
access but con-
agreement
imposing such Jan. 27, With
Uruguay 2000 respect to the supposed U.S. dream tinuing the annual NTR process (or
Signature dates of bilateral market access agreement even rais-
of Chinese democratization, the Paulson ing tariffs on Chinese goods) or keeping China
Perudiscipline— Jan. 27, 2000 Signature dates of bilateral market access agreement
Institute’s Neil Thomas has shown that cre- from the WTO entirely—were inferior, in
dispute
Iceland Jan. 28, 2000 Signature dates of bilateral market access agreement
ating a liberal democracy in China was not a terms of both the economics and geopolitics,
settlement— Jan. 28,
Norway 2000 reason for the U.S. government’sSignature
primary ap- to dates
grantingof bilateral
PNTR: market access agreement
has never
Philippines proval
N/Aof China’s WTO accession. Instead, N/A
key Clinton administration speeches and poli- A policy of denying MFN . . . would
India
been fully Oct. 13–24, 1997 Ended China’s WTO accession negotiations


cy documents demonstrate that U.S.–Chinese have forsaken the benefits of Chinese
utilized.
Colombia Oct. 13–24, 1997
engagement “was a balancing act with multiple
Ended China’s WTO accession negotiations
membership while having retained all
Argentina Oct. 13–24, 1997
objectives”—most of them pragmatic—includ- Ended China’s
the costs thatWTO accession negotiations
accompanied low bar-
Thailand ing “increasing
N/A bilateral dialogues, preventing riers toward Chinese goods. Further, N/A
European Union [weapons
May 19, 2000 of mass destruction] nonprolifera- this move would
Bilateralhave dividedisthe
agreement in-
reached
tion in East and South Asia, preventing the ternational community on China, giv-
Costa Rica Sept. 28, 2000 Signature dates of bilateral market access agreement
nuclearization of the Korean Peninsula, coop- en most [Organisation for Economic
Ecuador N/A N/A
erating on disease and environmental issues, Co-operation and Development] coun-
Guatemala N/A
better market access [for U.S. companies] and tries supported its accession at the N/A
Kyrgyz Republic intellectual
N/A property rules, fighting organized time. This split would have dramatically N/A
Latvia crime,
May 16, 2000 ensuring stability in the Taiwan Strait, weakened the WTO in its early stages,
Bilateral agreement is reached
and WTO accession on ‘commercial terms,’ thus undermining a major U.S. foreign
Malaysia Apr. 12, 2000 Bilateral agreement is reached
among others.” Democratization, on the oth- policy goal to strengthen the global
Mexico Sept. 13, 2001 was mentioned rarely. Thomas shows
er hand, Bilateral
trading system. . . . agreement is reached
Poland that N/A
the Clinton administration’s engagement [Raising tariffs] would have not only N/A
Switzerland policy
Sept. 26, 2000with China was “neither a triumphant hurt U.S. consumers and businesses that
Bilateral agreement is reached
Sources: “China’s WTO Accession Reaches Final Stage,” People’s Daily Online; Sina Corp, “Information: Memorabilia of China’s WTO Accession
Negotiations”; Sina Corp, “Background Information: China’s Accession to the WTO Negotiations for 15 Years”; and World Trade Organization, “Register of
Bilateral Market Access Agreements: The Accession of China Taipei.”
17


benefited from those imports, but would and progress toward nuclearization, even in
have also been interpreted as an act of the face of economic sanctions and isolation The current
enmity by Beijing. And on top of this, that would never have been applied to 1990s populist
it would likely have been ineffective in China (or to China today for that matter). Per-
stopping China’s rise. As China drove haps more importantly, China—unlike those
backlash
down the prices of toys and t-shirts in rogue regimes—at the time of WTO accession against trade
other global markets, it would have been had possessed nuclear weapons for decades. with China
very difficult for the United States to Though its recent military actions are con-
ignores the
insulate itself from the effects. Further, cerning, it beggars belief that—given recent
China has ultimately emerged as a major experience with Iran and North Korea (as mountain of
global economic player by tapping into well as other targets of U.S. sanctions such as government
global value chains. Since China is the Cuba)—unilateral attempts to isolate a massive interventions
last stage in the chain, a finished product nuclear power would have produced a better
can appear to have come from China, geopolitical outcome than did engagement.
that have
even if Chinese value-added is relatively Indeed, marshalling the necessary WTO- been used
small. Since U.S. tariffs are applied based wide consensus to deny more than a billion to protect
on where a good is finished, not based people in a modernizing economy access to an
American


on value-added, China could have eas- open multilateral trade organization—one that
ily affected U.S. markets by performing already included communist Cuba and for de- workers.
earlier-stage tasks and then having the cades had tolerated Eastern Bloc command-
goods finished in Malaysia or some other and-control economies and “socialist” countries
neighboring country. This is the prob- with pervasive state-owned industries—was not
lem with conducting bilateral policy in realistic, especially given what U.S. policymakers
a multilateral world. In sum, this second could have known at the time about China’s
alternative is no better than the first, and relatively liberal leadership and impressive eco-
decidedly worse than the current policy. nomic reforms. This last point bears emphasis:
[Excluding China from the WTO as previously noted, the reforms that China
entirely] appears dangerous, implau- undertook during its WTO accession—along
sible, and infeasible: dangerous because with additional reforms made shortly after ac-
trying to isolate China with the open in- cession—often in direct response to WTO
tent of blocking Chinese growth would require­ments (and member demands), were so
likely have elicited a hostile response; substantial as to drive China’s incredible export
implausible because the United States competitiveness. To assert that U.S. policymak-
was, in late 2001, trying to rally the ers in the 1990s should have somehow known
world to respond to terrorism emerg- that these reforms would cease or reverse a
ing from the Middle East; and infeasible decade later under different Chinese political
because the United States has had a dif- leadership, and thus either convince over 140
ficult time trying to isolate countries other WTO members to deny a nuclear China
with much smaller economies, such as entry into the WTO or reject PNTR (becom-
Iran and North Korea. Trying to isolate ing the only WTO member to do so), is apply-
China would have been orders of magni- ing an impossible standard.
tude more difficult.63

The Iran and North Korea examples are CHINA’S BACKSLIDING SINCE
especially relevant to the current debate, ACCESSION CANNOT BE BLAMED
given today’s foreign policy justifications for ON PNTR OR THE WTO
opposing PNTR. Neither country is a WTO PNTR critics also ignore the missed
member, but each has continued to militarize oppor­tunities since China’s WTO accession,
18


especially the unused checks on Chinese antidumping rules, and internet gambling.
If the trade abuses that were among China’s alleg- The refusal of the United States and oth-
supposed edly weak WTO commitments. As previ- er WTO members to pursue more disputes
ously noted, China undertook substantial against China—or open “compliance pro-
lessons from trade and economic liberalization before and ceedings” when China does not fully com-
PNTR are, as shortly after WTO accession and made doz- ply—is a policy choice worth criticizing, but
some intend, ens of “WTO-plus” commitments to become this says nothing about the original decision
a guide for a member. Since then, problems have un- to admit China to the WTO. Indeed, it is
doubtedly arisen, but as Cato’s James Bacchus, either mistaken or misleading to claim that
future U.S. Simon Lester, and Huan Zhu have document- China’s WTO accession terms were weak
decisionmaking ed, most of those problems—for example, on and that the WTO has utterly failed to disci-
on trade and industrial subsidies and intellectual property— pline China’s unfair trade practices when the
are covered by WTO rules and can be litigat- sole means of imposing such discipline—dis-
globalization ed through dispute settlement.64 Moreover, pute settlement—and the “WTO-plus” rules
writ large, such litigation has proven effective. Accord- that China accepted have never been fully
then the ing to the Peterson Institute for International utilized. This is declaring defeat before ever
firing a shot.68
debate must Economics’ Jeffrey Schott and Euijin Jung, for
example, the United States was undefeated Other U.S. policy choices since the passage
consider the at the WTO when challenging Chinese trade of PNTR also deserve scrutiny. Among these
many factors practices between 2002 and 2018.65 Four other are the United States’ withdrawal from the
supporting cases were pending at the time of that paper’s Trans-Pacific Partnership, a treaty that was
publication, but the United States has since designed in part to counterbalance China’s
freer trade won two more—one on agricultural subsidies economic and geopolitical ambitions; its fail-
and opposing and one on barriers to U.S. imports of wheat, ure to reform tax, trade, and immigration
protec­ rice, and corn.66 policies that inhibit American companies’


global competitiveness;69 its failure to mod-
tionism. Furthermore, Bacchus, Lester, and Zhu
demonstrate that when China loses WTO dis- ernize adjustment assistance and worker re-
putes, it tends to comply with the decisions: training programs intended to mitigate trade,
technological, or cultural disruptions;70 or
Of the 27 matters litigated against China, its continued imposition of tax, education,
5 are still pending, 12 were litigated all occupational licensing, criminal justice, zon-
the way through, and 10 were resolved ing, and other policies that discourage labor
through some kind of settlement, or not adjustment and economic dynamism.71 Such
pursued after the measure was modified. policies are indeed worthy of criticism and de-
These cases addressed a wide range of bate, but they have nothing to do with the deci-
issues: export restrictions, subsidies, in- sions to pass PNTR, allow China to join the
tellectual property protection, discrimi- WTO, or otherwise “normalize” trade with
natory taxes, trading rights, services, and China. And blaming China for these policies’
trade remedies. In all 22 completed cases, inevitable failures relieves the policies—and
with one exception where a complaint the American politicians who implemented
was not pursued, China’s response was to them—of the scrutiny that they deserve.
take some action to move toward greater
market access.67
THE CURIOUS FAILURE TO
Chinese compliance is not perfect (nor is any NOTE THE PROBLEMS WITH
other WTO member’s), but it is arguably bet- U.S. MARKET INTERVENTIONS
ter than that of the United States, which has Those wishing to blame the problems of
famously shirked WTO rulings on subsidies, the American working class on PNTR and
19


freer markets more broadly often ignore the The U.S. government also has long provided
United States’ own long history of market financial and other support to favored indus- The broader
inter­ventions and their failures to help com- tries and workers, for example through auto economic and
panies and workers. A core tenet of the current bailouts, steel industry bailouts, alternative
populist backlash against trade, and par- energy subsidies, manufacturing tax credits,
geopolitical
ticularly trade with China, is that American Export–Import Bank loans and other export benefits of
“elites” opened the floodgates to Chinese assistance, procurement preferences such as trade and
imports with only a timid threat of the WTO the Buy American Act and the Davis–Bacon
globalization
dispute process to protect American workers Act, shipping restrictions such as the Jones Act
from “unfair” competition. This ignores the and the Passenger Vessel Services Act,77 and are essential
mountain of government interventions that the billions of other taxpayer dollars that the to any
have been used—at the federal level alone—to United States has doled out to “blue collar” in- discussion
restrict Chinese imports, otherwise protect dustries and workers over the past few decades
or subsidize American manufacturers, and at the federal level alone. As I documented in a
of trade
assist American workers. 2012 paper on global subsidies and antisubsidy liberalization,
On trade, the United States still maintains disciplines, “despite the obvious economic, le- elite policy
significant tariffs and tariff-rate quotas on im- gal, and political problems associated with do-
choices, and
ports of “sensitive” products such as trucks, mestic subsidies, the United States remains one
apparel, footwear, and food.72 Moreover, ac- of the world’s largest subsidizers.”78 the American
cording to Global Trade Alert, the United States The U.S. government has also repeatedly working class.
has been one of the most frequent users of tried to fund and retrain workers, most nota- Unfortunately,
“harmful” nontariff government trade inter- bly through the Trade Adjustment Assistance
ventions—ones that far outnumber its “liber- (TAA) program, which offers generous subsi-
these points
alizing” measures over the same period.73 This dies to U.S. workers affected by import com- always
includes, as of late 2019, almost 190 special petition. Unfortunately, TAA has proven to seem to be


duties (“trade remedies” such as antidump- be a “notorious failure”: as I noted in a 2016
missing.
ing and antisubsidy measures) on a variety of article, “multiple studies commissioned by the
Chinese imports, two-thirds of which (127 of Labor Department have found that TAA par-
187) use a special “non-market economy” an- ticipants are worse off, as measured by future
tidumping methodology that practically en- wages and benefits, than similarly situated job-
sures prohibitive duty rates on those goods (a less individuals outside the program.”79 The
“WTO-plus” accession commitment special Wall Street Journal’s Eric Morath in December
to China and a few others).74 These duties 2018 noted additional research into the failure
target “unfair” trade and subsidies that injure of TAA to help workers allegedly displaced
U.S. manufacturers and workers, and—as the by trade in 2018 and a move by certain states
numbers indicate—American companies and to “de-emphasize programs such as TAA in
unions have been successful in petitioning for favor of getting workers back into jobs more
them. (There are around 500 duty orders in quickly.”80 Other federal job-training pro-
place overall.) grams have been found to be similarly ineffica-
Dozens of other Chinese imports are cious, and related reform efforts have thus far
barred from the U.S. market as a result of been underwhelming.81
Section 337 actions that remedy intellectual These and other government programs
property rights violations.75 Chinese invest- raise serious concerns when it comes to help-
ment in U.S. industries, meanwhile, can be ing American workers adjust to trade and oth-
(and has been) restricted by the Committee on er shocks, and they need to be reformed. But
Foreign Investment in the United States, and that does not change the simple fact that these pro-
U.S. technology exports to China are often grams do exist and have for decades. These poli-
blocked on national security grounds.76 cies refute the claim that U.S. policymakers
20


simply passed PNTR and walked away from The literature on the local labour mar-
American the American working class out of some sort ket effects of Chinese import compe-
protectionism of “market fundamentalism” or rigid adher- tition has been cited extensively as an
ence to “laissez faire ideology.” argument for limiting trade with China
has repeatedly The real problem was that these interven- despite the fact that the results do not
been shown tions did not work very well. A classic example support this conclusion. . . . Even if pol-
to impose is the U.S. steel industry, whose companies and icy were narrowly focused on direct im-
immense workers since the 1970s have arguably received port competition effects ignoring price
more government assistance than any industry and indirect effects, there is no case for
economic in the country. This includes hundreds of im- limiting trade with China [because] US
harms; to fail port restrictions; tens of billions of dollars in local labour market adjustment to the
to protect state, local, and federal subsidies and bailouts; China Shock has largely concluded.84
exemptions from environmental regulations;
American special “Buy American” rules; federal pension Put another way, if there will never be an “India
firms and benefit guarantees; and even its own caucus in Shock” or a “Vietnam Shock,” then there is
workers; and Congress.82 The result: dramatic historical de- no reason to reset American trade and labor
to breed elite clines in employment and capitalization, nu- policy or to reorganize the U.S. economy more
merous bankruptcies, and of course, continued broadly in preparation for such a moment.
corruption, demands for even more government protection On the other hand, if the supposed les-
cronyism, (as the current Section 232 tariffs make clear). sons from PNTR are, as some intend, a guide
and political The steel industry certainly is not alone. As for future U.S. decisionmaking on trade and
a 2013 Congressional Research Service report global­
ization writ large—pundits such as
dysfunc­


concluded about the state of American manu- Tucker Carlson seem to aim wider85—then the
tion. facturing, “Although Congress has established debate must consider the many factors sup-
a wide variety of tax preferences, direct subsi- porting freer trade and opposing protection-
dies, import restraints, and other federal pro- ism. Those factors include the following:
grams with the goal of retaining or recapturing
manufacturing jobs, only a small proportion of y the wide body of research showing sig-
US workers is now employed in factories.”83 nificant economic gains from import
In short, there is scant evidence that liberalization and multilateral trade—
Washington elites abandoned the American even trade “shocks”—and the over-
working class after liberalizing trade with whelming support for these policies
China. The government’s interventions may from economists on the political left,
have failed, but they were interventions right, and center;86
nonetheless. y the unseen benefits of import competi-
tion on American economic dynamism,
providing Americans with not merely
TRADE AND GLOBALIZATION cheaper goods and services but better
BRING UNAMBIGUOUS BENEFITS (and once unimaginable) ones, as well
If the China Shock’s disruptions are unique as better jobs, better companies, and
to that country and time period, the debate better lives;87
over PNTR and China trade is academic. y the morality of freer trade—both for
Most economists believe that the China Americans and the global poor—and the
Shock ended years ago and that if its effects political problems that arise from gov-
are unlikely to happen again, then the histori- ernment putting the desires of favored
cal analysis is not instructive regarding future producers above those of all consumers;88
trade policies. As Jakubik and Stolzenburg re- y the fact that much of “globalization” is
cently concluded: driven not by elite policy choices such
21


as free trade agreements but by seismic These points do not prove that free trade is
changes in communications and tech- seamless or that economists accurately predict- If one looks
nology, such as shipping containers, ed regional labor market frictions in response to restrict
that are far beyond the control of any to large-scale trade disruptions, but—unless the
policymaker;89 China Shock is truly sui generis (and in that case,
trade to solve
y the extensive research showing that again, the historical and economic analyses are the problems
trade complaints through the WTO not instructive)—the broader economic and facing
are more effective than unilateralism in geopolitical benefits of trade and globalization
America’s
bringing about trade reforms;90 are essential to any discussion of trade liberal-
y the longstanding geopolitical benefits of ization, elite policy choices, and the American working class,
trade, including the WTO’s role in pre- working class. Unfortunately, these points al- the ‘solution’
venting world war and the strong con- ways seem to be missing. will most
nection between trade and peace;91
y the unique position of American manu-
likely be
facturing and workers post–World War PROTECTIONISM KEEPS FAILING worse than
II, when much of the rest of the world When critics decry “normalized trade” as the alleged


was either recovering from war or de- an elite policy “choice,” they necessarily im-
problem.
scending into communism;92 ply—but rarely state—a trade policy alterna-
y the fact that, historically, productiv- tive. The only apparent alternative is some
ity shocks such as automation have form of protectionism (i.e., government re-
been just as disruptive as trade (if not strictions on imports of goods and services),
more so) in terms of low- and middle- and it has repeatedly proven a failure. For ex-
skill manufacturing job losses and that ample, International Monetary Fund econo-
U.S. production occupations are today mists in 2018 examined data for 151 countries
among the most vulnerable to future over 51 years (1963–2014) and found that “tariff
automation-led disruptions;93 and increases lead, in the medium term, to eco-
y that trade economists have for decades nomically and statistically significant declines
acknowledged that adjustment to trade in domestic output and productivity” as well as
shocks “may be neither quick nor easy.”94 more unemployment and higher inequality.96
The same is true for American protectionism,
A fuller accounting of these points is be- which has repeatedly been shown to impose
yond the scope of this paper, but each has am- immense economic harms that far outweigh
ple support. For example, a 2019 International any possible benefit to protected workers; to
Monetary Fund cross-country analysis of trade fail to protect American firms and workers
and technology shocks found that while both over the longer term; and to breed elite cor-
can have adverse regional employment effects ruption, cronyism, and political dysfunction.97
(raising unemployment and lowering labor Two instances warrant mention in this regard:
force participation), only automation has long-
lasting harms and that regions hit by trade y Using the Section 421 safeguard mecha-
shocks actually ended up better off a couple nism tied to China’s WTO accession,
years later. That same paper also found that President Obama in 2009 imposed 35
national policies encouraging more flexible la- percent tariffs on Chinese tires. The
bor markets can improve both adjustment in result was, even under the best assump-
regional labor markets and their resilience to tions, a handful of jobs saved at an an-
shocks and that countries with less stringent nual cost to U.S. consumers of over
product market regulation, lower administra- $900,000 per job, plus a substantial
tive costs for starting a business, and greater increase in non-Chinese imports in-
trade openness had lower regional inequality.95 stead of new U.S. production.98 Today,
22


the industry’s prospects are no better.99 American footwear workers, for example, ben-
The fact that (Such inefficacy is precisely what Levy efited from a political decision (dating back to
the longer- predicted because of the interchange- the Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act) to protect foot-
ability of Chinese and other imports.100) wear jobs through hidden restrictions on the
term effects y A 2017 review of all U.S. antidumping voluntary commercial decisions of other, un-
of Chinese investigations against Chinese imports knowing Americans—restrictions that forced
import between 1998 and 2006 revealed that these citizens to subsidize U.S. footwear jobs
by paying more for shoes.104 Today, former
competition the duties reduced Chinese imports and
increased prices of subject merchandise “big steel” lawyers and executives, now in the
vary in the U.S. market.101 However, these Trump administration, dole out tariff protec-
dramatically effects “dissipate approximately 2 years tion to their former colleagues who lobbied
from place after the antidumping decision,” and for it; those well-connected colleagues, in
imports from other countries simply in- turn, get to decide the fate of their American
to place creased to replace the declining Chinese customers’ requests for steel-tariff relief, even
undermines imports. Such results “cast doubt on though the steel-consuming customers are a
the notion the effectiveness of antidumping ac- far larger share of the U.S. economy and work-
that the China tions against China as mechanisms for force than is the steel industry. Trade-related
protecting US producers.” Specific lobbying expenditures over the past two
Shock was a case studies, such as Daniel Ikenson’s years of “trade populism” have unsurprisingly
national trade review of antidumping measures on skyrocketed.


problem. wooden bedroom furniture from China, Trade liberalization cures this malady,
show similar results: “Instead of pre- whether intended or not, while also improving
serving or returning domestic jobs . . . the living standards of most Americans. And
import restrictions will cause a shift in though it is legitimate to ask after government
sourcing from China to places like the removes import protection whether it owes
Philippines, Indonesia, Brazil, and Viet- the affected workers more in terms of adjust-
nam—places from which many of the ment welfare or job training, removing the
petitioners have begun or are poised to protection was clearly the right thing to do.
begin importing themselves.”102

These studies reveal both the futility and WHY DID SOME
cronyism surrounding past U.S. attempts to PLACES “MOVE ON”?
stop Chinese imports during the China Shock Finally, those seeking to blame PNTR or
period. Thus, if one looks to restrict trade to Chinese imports for the current plight of
solve the problems facing America’s working the American working class ignore the many
class, the “solution” will most likely be worse places in the United States that were affected
than the alleged problem. by Chinese import competition but did adjust
Those who object to “normalizing” trade and have thrived economically—often with
with China (i.e., removing U.S. restrictions on the help of trade and foreign investment. In-
Americans’ consumption of Chinese imports) deed, the fact that the longer-term effects of
must also acknowledge that liberalization was Chinese import competition vary dramatically
not merely an economic and geopolitical deci- from place to place—even in states or regions
sion but also a moral one that removed inequi- that face intense competition105—undermines
ties in the previous, more protectionist system. the notion that the China Shock was a national
The now-eliminated trade restrictions typi- trade problem (necessitating national protec-
cally resulted from political “elites” seeking to tionism) as opposed to a local adjustment prob-
support certain industries and workers at most lem (necessitating local solutions).
Americans’ (especially poor ones) expense.103 Many cities and towns in America that
23


were once known for low-skill manufactur- these gains were especially large in “auto
ing and faced intense import competition in alley”—a narrow motor vehicle produc- The problem
the 1990s and 2000s have since adapted and tion corridor stretching from Michigan the shock
thrived. As previously noted, several studies south to Alabama—while much of the
show that most U.S. regions ended up bet- Northeast continued to shed manufac-
revealed was
ter off following the China Shock, though turing jobs.110 not import
some areas—particularly those with low hu- competition
man capital—struggled. A 2018 Brookings The contrast between now-thriving
but many
Institution report, moreover, finds that 115 American towns and those still reeling from
of the 185 U.S. counties identified as having a a trade shock that ended a decade ago again communities’
disproportionate share of manufacturing jobs indicates that the problem the shock revealed inability
in 1970 had “transitioned successfully” from was not import competition but—as Autor, to adjust
manufacturing by 2016 and that of the remain- Dorn, and Hanson themselves concede—
ing 70 “older industrial cities,” 40 exhibited many communities’ inability to adjust to seis-
to seismic
economic


“strong” or “emerging” economic performance mic economic changes. The International
between 2000 and 2016.106 The “strong” lo- Monetary Fund study on trade shocks, labor changes.
calities, achieving high marks for growth, market policies, and regional adjustment reit-
prosperity, and inclusion, include not only erate these conclusions at a cross-country lev-
well-known success stories such as Pittsburgh el. Thus, commentators and politicians who
and cities close to Boston and Manhattan but blame China trade for the difficulties of the
also smaller places such as Beaumont, Texas; American working class should stop asking,
Waterloo, Iowa; and Bethlehem, Pennsylvania. “Why did elites normalize trade with China in
Anecdotal evidence reiterates these the 1990s?” and instead ask, “What did many
findings: towns that once depended on American towns, companies, and workers do
low-skill manufacturing, such as Greenville– right in the face of intense import competi-
Spartanburg, South Carolina; Hickory, North tion, and how can local, state, and federal poli-
Carolina; Warsaw, Indiana; and Danville, cies encourage that important improvement?”
Virginia, are now home to thriving companies
that succeeded by adapting to the market,
including through international trade and in- CONCLUSION
vestment.107 Journalist James Fallows has doc- The historical record before and after
umented many of these lesser-known success PNTR and the numerous academic analyses of
stories in his 2018 book, Our Towns: A 100,000- the “China Shock” provide a straightforward
Mile Journey into the Heart of America, and in a explanation for the past 20-plus years of U.S.
regular column for The Atlantic.108 trade policy toward China: engagement and lib-
Anyone still doubting such successes need eralization, exemplified by PNTR and China’s
only drive down Interstate 85 from Charlotte, WTO accession, were a pragmatic and bipar-
North Carolina, to Montgomery, Alabama, to tisan policy choice made in the face of nonex-
see the multinational factories firsthand.109 istent or inferior alternatives, especially given
The Federal Reserve Bank of New York em- the information when the choice was made.
phasized this region in its examination of the Engage­ment, moreover, produced real econom-
recent surge in U.S. manufacturing jobs: ic benefits for most Americans while bolstering
the multilateral trading system and removing
While job losses during the 2000s were historical inequities under the previous, more
fairly widespread across the country, protectionist U.S. trade policy regime.
manufacturing employment gains since The resulting economic disruption and
then have been concentrated in par- adjust­ment were difficult for some U.S. regions
ticular parts of the country. Indeed, and workers—more difficult than many experts
24


expected—and certainly post-liberalization communist China while dogmatically refusing
Pre­tending policy mistakes were made (though often in to support—through trade, labor, or any other
today that the direction of less liberalization, not more). policies—the working class. Such narratives
With the benefit of two decades of hindsight, are unsupportable.
there was a one can legitimately claim that certain specific Labor market and cultural disruptions in
better trade “WTO-plus” rules should have been drafted the United States are real and important, as is
policy choice differently during China’s accession. China’s current and unfortunate turn toward
in 2000 than That said, the facts simply do not sup- illiberalism and imperialism. But pretending
today that there was a better trade policy choice
port popular assertions from American poli-
PNTR and ticians and pundits that engagement with in 2000 than PNTR and engagement more
engagement China in the 1990s and 2000s was an obvi- broadly is misguided. It assumes too much,
more broadly ous mistake and that denying China admis- ignores too much, and demands too much.
sion to the WTO was realistic a policy choice Worse, it could lead to truly bad governance:
is misguided. that would have improved U.S. economic increasing U.S. protectionism; forgiving the
It assumes too and geopolitical standing today or that the real and important failures of our policymak-
much, ignores real labor and cultural issues in America to- ers, CEOs, and unions over the past two de-
too much, and day are the fault of “Washington elites” who cades; and preventing a political consensus
for real policy solutions. Indeed, these things
blithely pursued normalized trade with China
demands too


to benefit corporate donors and democratize are happening now.
much.

NOTES Non-Compliance,” International Trade Reporter, Bloomberg BNA,


1. Scott Lincicome, “The Truth about Trade,” National Review, January 25, 2018.
April 11, 2016.
7. Xavier Jaravel and Erick Sager, “What Are the Price Effect of
2. Dani Rodrik, “What’s Driving Populism,” Project Syndicate, Trade? Evidence from the US and Implications for Quantitative
July 9, 2019. Trade Models,” Bureau of Labor Statistics Working Paper no. 506,
September 2018.
3. Normal Trade Relations for the People’s Republic of China,
Pub. L. 106-286, 114 Stat. 880 (October 10, 2000). 8. Liang Bai and Sebastian Stumpner, “Estimating US Consumer
Gains from Chinese Imports,” American Economic Review 1, no. 2
4. David H. Autor, David Dorn, and Gordon H. Hanson, “The (September 2019): 209–24.
China Shock: Learning from Labor-Market Adjustment to Large
Changes in Trade,” Annual Review of Economics 8, no. 1 (2016): 9. Mary Amiti et al., “How Did China’s WTO Entry Affect U.S.
205–40. Prices?,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper
no. 23487, June 2017, revised December 2018.
5. Justin R. Pierce and Peter K. Schott, “The Surprisingly Swift
Decline of US Manufacturing Employment,” American Economic 10. Christian Broda and John Romalis, “Inequality and Prices:
Review 106, no. 7 (July 2016): 1632–62. Does China Benefit the Poor in America?,” University of Chicago
working paper, March 10, 2008. To see how the consumer ben-
6. Oren Cass, “Is Technology Destroying the Labor Market?,” efits of trade are already heavily tilted toward America’s poor and
City Journal, Spring 2018; Michael Brendan Dougherty, “Personal middle class, see Pablo D. Fajgelbaum and Amit K. Khandelwal,
Responsibility Is No Substitute for Political Reflection,” National “Measuring the Unequal Gains from Trade,” National Bureau of
Review, January 10, 2019; Reihan Salam, “Normalizing Trade Re- Economic Research Working Paper no. 20331, July 2014.
lations with China Was a Mistake,” The Atlantic, June 8, 2018; and
Bryce Baschuk, “U.S. Issues Scathing Review of China’s WTO 11. Maximiliano Dvorkin, “What Is the Impact of Chinese
25

Imports on U.S. Jobs?,” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, May 21. “Top Trading Partners—October 2018,” U.S. Census Bureau.
15, 2017; W. Michael Cox and Richard Alm, Onward and Upward!:
William J. O’Neil Center for Global Markets and Freedom 2015–16 An- 22. The US–China Business Council (USCBC), 2019 State Export
nual Report (Dallas: Southern Methodist University’s Cox School Report: Goods and Services Exports by US States to China Over the Past
of Business, 2016). Decade (Washington: USCBC, updated July 2019).

12. Germán Gutiérrez and Thomas Philippon, “Declining Com- 23. Teresa C. Fort, Justin R. Pierce, and Peter K. Schott, “New
petition and Investment in the U.S.,” National Bureau of Eco- Perspectives on the Decline of US Manufacturing Employment,”
nomic Research Working Paper no. 23583, July 2017. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper no.
24490, April 2018.
13. Lorenzo Caliendo, Maximiliano A. Dvorkin, and Fernando
Parro, “Trade and Labor Market Dynamics: General Equilibrium 24. Gillian Tett, “The ‘China Shock’ Has Not Been as Bad as
Analysis of the China Trade Shock,” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Donald Trump Thinks,” Financial Times, January 10, 2019.
Louis Working Paper no. 2015-009H, August 19, 2015, revised
February 21, 2019. 25. Nicholas Bloom et al., “The Impact of Chinese Trade on
U.S. Employment: The Good, the Bad, and the Apocryphal,”
14. Zhi Wang et al., “Re-examining the Effects of Trading with March 19, 2019.
China on Local Labor Markets: A Supply Chain Perspective,” Na-
tional Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper no. 24886, 26. Kerwin Kofi Charles, Erik Hurst, and Mariel Schwartz, “The
August 2018, revised October 2018. Transformation of Manufacturing and the Decline in U.S. Em-
ployment,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Pa-
15. Simon Galle, Andrés Rodríguez-Clare, and Moises Yi, “Slicing per no. 24468, March 2018.
the Pie: Quantifying the Aggregate and Distributional Effects of
Trade,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 27. Fort, Pierce, and Schott, “Decline of US Manufacturing Em-
no. 23737, August 2017. ployment.”

16. Galina Hale et al., “How Much Do We Spend on Imports?,” 28. Katherine Eriksson et al., “Trade Shocks and the Shifting
FRBSF Economic Letter, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, Landscape of U.S. Manufacturing,” National Bureau of Economic
January 7, 2019, https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/ Research Working Paper no. 25646, March 2019, revised January
publications/economic-letter/2019/january/how-much-do-we- 2020.
spend-on-imports/amp.
29. Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro, “Trade and Labor Market Dy-
17. “Household Data Annual Averages: 11. Employed Persons by namics.”
Detailed Occupation, Sex, Race, and Hispanic or Latino Ethnic-
ity,” Labor Force Statistics from the Current Population Survey, 30. Robert C. Feenstra, Hong Ma, and Yuan Xu, “US Exports
Bureau of Labor Statistics, last modified January 22, 2020, https:// and Employment,” National Bureau of Economic Research
www.bls.gov/cps/cpsaat11.htm. (NBER) Working Paper no. 24056, November 2017; and Robert
C. Feenstra and Akira Sasahara, “The ‘China Shock’, Exports
18. David Nicklaus, “Higher Tariff Puts a Squeeze on Missouri and U.S. Employment: A Global Input-Output Analysis,” NBER
Cap Company,” St. Louis Post-Dispatch, September 8, 2019. Working Paper no. 24022, November 2017.

19. Pol Antràs, Teresa C. Fort, and Felix Tintelnot, “The Margins 31. J. Bradford DeLong, “NAFTA and Other Trade Deals Have
of Global Sourcing: Theory and Evidence from US Firms,” Ameri- Not Gutted American Manufacturing—Period,” Vox, January 24,
can Economic Review 107, no. 9 (September 2017): 2514–64. 2017.

20. World Trade Organization, “United States: Trade in Value 32. Adam Jakubik and Victor Stolzenburg, “The ‘China Shock’
Added and Global Value Chains,” https://www.wto.org/english/ Revisited: Insights from Value Added Trade Flows,” World
res_e/statis_e/miwi_e/US_e.pdf. Trade Organization Staff Working Paper ERSD-2018-10,
26

October 26, 2018. (emphasis added); and Paul Krugman (@paulkrugman), “One of
the things I’m revisiting is the ‘China shock’ issue, which I think
33. Yuan Xu, Hong Ma, and Robert C. Feenstra, “Magnification remains widely misunderstood. The claim is not that rapid im-
of the ‘China Shock’ through the U.S. Housing Market,” National port growth cost the U.S. jobs on net. It is that the jobs created
Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper no. 26432, Novem- were different from the jobs lost, and in particular in different
ber 2019. places 2/,” Twitter, January 12, 2019, 8:14 a.m., https://twitter.com/
paulkrugman/status/1084076103638179840.
34. Phil Levy, “Did China Trade Cost the United States 2.4 Million
Jobs?,” Foreign Policy, May 8, 2016; Scott Sumner, “Autor, Dorn, 44. Douglas Clement, “Interview with David Autor,” Federal
and Hanson on the China Shock,” The Library of Economics Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, September 7, 2016; David Autor,
and Liberty, February 26, 2016; and Katharine G. Abraham and interview by Stephen J. Dubner, Freakonomics Radio, January
Melissa S. Kearney, “Explaining the Decline in the U.S. Employ- 25, 2017; and David Autor, David Dorn, and Gordon Hanson,
ment-to-Population Ratio: A Review of the Evidence,” National “When Work Disappears: Manufacturing Decline and the Falling
Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper no. 24333, February Marriage-Market Value of Young Men,” National Bureau of Eco-
2018, revised August 2019. nomic Research Working Paper no. 23173, February 2017, revised
January 2018.
35. Charles Fain Lehman, “What We Talk about When We
Talk about Deaths of Despair,” Washington Free Beacon, June 24, 45. For a claim that net benefits from trade from the “China
2019. Shock” accrue overwhelmingly to elites, see Autor, Dorn, and
Hanson, “When Work Disappears.”
36. Alan Reyolds, “Did the U.S. Lose 2.4 Million Jobs from China
Imports?,” Cato at Liberty (blog), Cato Institute, September 15, 46. Wikipedia, s.v. “Permanent Normal Trade Relations,” last
2016. modified March 17, 2020, 7:41 p.m., https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/
Permanent_normal_trade_relations.
37. Charles Freeman (@AsiaPac_Freeman), “A Failure to Adjust,”
Twitter thread, January 15, 2019, 1:58 p.m., https://twitter.com/ 47. Kerry Dumbaugh, China’s Most-Favored-Nation (MFN) Status:
AsiaPac_Freeman/status/1085249972767997954. Congressional Consideration, 1989–1998 (Washington: Congressio-
nal Research Service, updated August 1, 1998).
38. Levy, “Did China Trade Cost the United States 2.4 Million
Jobs?” 48. Erin Ennis, email message to author, January 17, 2019.

39. “All Employees, Manufacturing/All Employees, Total Non- 49. Pierce and Schott, “Decline of US Manufacturing Employ-
farm,” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, https://fred.stlouisfed. ment.”
org/graph/?g=mcsO.
50. Kyle Handley and Nuno Limão, “Policy Uncertainty, Trade,
40. Wayne M. Morrison, China–U.S. Trade Issues (Washington: and Welfare: Theory and Evidence for China and the United
Congressional Research Service, July 30, 2018), pp. 10–11. States,” American Economic Review 107, no. 9 (September 2017):
2731–83.
41. Hale et al., “How Much Do We Spend on Imports?”
51. George A. Alessandria, Shafaat Y. Khan, and Armen
42. Robert Lawrence, “Adjustment Challenges for U.S. Workers,” Khederlarian, “Taking Stock of Trade Policy Uncertainty: Evi-
in Bridging the Pacific: Toward Free Trade and Investment between Chi- dence from China’s Pre-WTO Accession,” National Bureau of
na and the United States, eds. C. Fred Bergsten, Gary C. Hufbauer, Economic Research Working Paper no. 25965, June 2019.
and Sean Miner (Washington: Peterson Institute for Internation-
al Economics, 2014). 52. Handley and Limão, “Policy Uncertainty, Trade, and Welfare.”

43. Douglas A. Irwin, Clashing over Commerce: A History of US Trade 53. Mary Amiti et al., “How Did China’s WTO Entry Affect U.S.
Policy (Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 2017), p. 668 Prices?,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper
27

no. 23487, June 2017, revised December 2018. 57. “Accessions: China,” World Trade Organization, https://www.
wto.org/english/thewto_e/acc_e/a1_chine_e.htm.
54. Autor, Dorn, and Hanson, “When Work Disappears”; and
Autor, Dorn, and Hanson, “The China Shock.” 58. Vicky Chemutai and Hubert Escaith, “An Empirical Assess-
ment of the Economic Effects of WTO Accession and Its Com-
55. Jakubik and Stolzenburg, “The ‘China Shock’ Revisited.” mitments,” World Trade Organization Staff Working Paper
ERSD-2017-05, February 6, 2017.
56. Lee G. Branstetter et al., “The China Shock and Employment
in Portuguese Firms,” National Bureau of Economic Research 59. U.S.-China Bilateral Trade Agreement and the Accession of
Working Paper no. 26252, September 2019; Giordano Mion China to the WTO: Hearing, Before the Committee on Ways and
and Linke Zhu, “Import Competition from and Offshoring to Means, 106th Cong. (February 16, 2000); and Keiji Nakatsuji,
China: A Curse or Blessing for Firms?,” Journal of International “Essence of Trade Negotiation: A Study on China’s Entry for
Economics 89, no. 1 (2013): 202–215; Damoun Ashournia, Jakob WTO,” June 2001.
Munch, and Daniel Nguyen, “The Impact of Chinese Import
Penetration on Danish Firms and Workers,” Institute of La- 60. Centre for International Governance Innovation (@CIGIon-
bor Economics (IZA) Discussion Papers no. 8166, May 2014; line), “#USChinaSchism Twitter Interview,” Twitter, August 15,
Hale Utar, “When the Floodgates Open: ‘Northern’ Firms’ Re- 2019, https://twitter.com/i/moments/1162066586641063936.
sponse to Removal of Trade Quotas on Chinese Goods,” Amer-
ican Economic Journal: Applied Economics 6, no. 4 (October 2014): 61. See, e.g., Accession of China to the WTO: Hearing, Before the Com-
226–250; Katariina Nilsson-Hakkala and Kristiina Huttunen, mittee of Ways and Means, 106th Cong. (May 3, 2000).
“Worker-Level Consequences of Import Shocks,” IZA Discus-
sion Paper no. 10033, July 18, 2016; Clément Malgouyres, “The 62. Neil Thomas, “Matters of Record: Relitigating Engagement
Impact of Chinese Import Competition on the Local Struc- with China,” Macro Polo, September 3, 2019.
ture of Employment and Wages: Evidence from France,” Jour-
nal of Regional Science 57, no. 3 (June 2017): 411–441; Wolfgang 63. Philip Levy, “Was Letting China into the WTO a Mistake?,”
Dauth, Sebastian Findeisen, and Jens Suedekum, “The Rise of Foreign Affairs, April 2, 2018.
the East and the Far East: German Labor Markets and Trade
Integration, Journal of the European Economic Association 12, 64. James Bacchus, Simon Lester, and Huan Zhu, “Disciplining
no. 6 (December 2014): 1643–75; Wolfgang Dauth, Sebastian China’s Trade Practices at the WTO: How WTO Complaints
Findeisen, and Jens Suedekum, “Trade and Manufacturing Can Help Make China More Market-Oriented,” Cato Institute
Jobs in Germany,” American Economic Review 107, no. 5 (May Policy Analysis no. 856, November 15, 2018.
2017): 337–42; Wolfgang Dauth, Sebastian Findeisen, and Jens
Suedekum, “Adjusting to Globalization in Germany,” IZA Dis- 65. Jeffrey J. Schott and Euijin Jung, “In US-China Trade Dis-
cussion Paper no. 11299, January 2018; Ragnhild Balsvik, Sissel putes, the WTO Usually Sides with the United States,” Peterson
Jensen, and Kjell G. Salvanes, “Made in China, Sold in Norway: Institute for International Economics, March 12, 2019.
Local Labor Market Effects of an Import Shock,” Journal of
Public Economics 127, no. C (2015): 137–44; Tiago Pereira, “The 66. Appellate Body Report, China—Domestic Support for Agri-
Effect of Developing Countries’ Competition on Regional La- cultural Producers, World Trade Organization DS511 (adopted
bour Markets in Portugal,” Gabinete de Estratégia e Estudos April 26, 2019); and Appellate Body Report, China—Tariff Rate
Paper no. 58, March 2016; Vicente Donoso, Victor Martin, and Quotas for Certain Agricultural Products, World Trade Organization
Asier Minondo, “Do Differences in the Exposure to Chinese DS517 (adopted May 28, 2019).
Imports Lead to Differences in Local Labour Market Out-
comes? An Analysis for Spanish Provinces,” Regional Studies 67. Bacchus, Lester, and Zhu, “Disciplining China’s Trade Prac-
49, no. 10 (September 2014): 1–19; and Matthias Flückiger and tices at the WTO,” p. 6.
Markus Ludwig, “Chinese Export Competition, Declining Ex-
ports and Adjustments at the Industry and Regional Level in 68. Scott Lincicome, “Chinese Intellectual Property Policies
Europe,” Canadian Journal of Economics 48, no. 3 (August 2015): Demand a Smart U.S. Trade Policy Response—One President
1120–51. Trump Doesn’t Appear to Be Considering,” Cato at Liberty (blog),
28

Cato Institute, January 2, 2018. Workers,” Wall Street Journal, December 30, 2018.

69. Daniel J. Ikenson, “Beyond the American Manufacturing 81. Lincicome, “Truth about Trade.” “A 2011 Government Ac-
Competitiveness Act: Congress Should Get More Serious countability Office study, for example, found that the federal
about Tariff Reform,” Cato Institute Free Trade Bulletin no. government had 47 different, often overlapping job-training
67, April 26, 2016; and Daniel J. Ikenson, “Economic Self- programs spanning nine federal agencies at a cost of $18 billion
Flagellation: How U.S. Antidumping Policy Subverts the per year. Only five had been subject to any sort of impact analysis
National Export Initiative,” Cato Institute Trade Policy Analy­ since 2004; thus, ‘little is known about the effectiveness of [the]
sis no. 46, May 31, 2011. employment and training programs’ identified. A 2014 reform
of this system, the Workforce Innovation and Opportunity Act,
70. Mike Lee, “More Populist, More Conservative,” National Re- eliminated 15 programs (while maintaining the rest, despite their
view, January 11, 2019. long history of subpar results) but failed to impose any sort of rig-
orous multi-site evaluation and accountability system. Without
71. Lincicome, “Truth about Trade.” these simple reforms or other more radical ones, there is no way
to ensure that the ‘reformed’ federal job programs won’t continue
72. Scott Lincicome, “‘Unfettered’ Free Trade? If Only . . .,” Cato their long record of failing American workers and taxpayers.”
at Liberty (blog), Cato Institute, November 17, 2016.
82. Claude Barfield, High-Tech Protectionism: The Irrationality of An-
73. “Number of New Interventions Per Year,” Implementing tidumping Laws (Washington: AEI Press, 2003).
Country: United States of America, Global Trade Alert, https://
www.globaltradealert.org/country/222/affected-jurisdictions_42/ 83. Marc Levinson, “Hollowing Out” in U.S. Manufacturing: Analysis
flow_all. and Issues for Congress (Washington: Congressional Research Ser-
vice, April 15, 2013).
74. According to the U.S. International Trade Commission, as of
August 20, 2019, there were 490 total trade remedy measures in 84. Jakubik and Stolzenburg, “The ‘China Shock’ Revisited.”
place, 187 of which target China. See also Lincicome, “‘Unfet-
tered.’” 85. Tucker Carlson, “Tucker Carlson: Mitt Romney Supports the
Status Quo. But for Everyone Else, It’s Infuriating,” Fox News,
75. “Section 337 Statistics: Types of Unfair Acts Alleged in Ac- January 3, 2019.
tive Investigations, FY 2006–FY 2015,” U.S. International Trade
Commission. 86. For the wide body of research, see Gary Clyde Hufbauer and
Zhiyao (Lucy) Lu, “The Payoff to America from Globalization:
76. “The Committee on Foreign Investment in the United States A Fresh Look with a Focus on Costs to Workers,” Peterson In-
(CFIUS),” U.S. Department of the Treasury; and International stitute for International Economics Policy Brief no. 17-16, May
Trade Administration, “U.S. Export Controls,” last published 2017; Veronique de Rugy, “Twenty-Five Years of NAFTA,” Law
April 8, 2020, https://www.trade.gov/us-export-controls. & Liberty, January 2, 2019; and U.S. International Trade Commis-
sion, “Economic Impact of Trade Agreements Implemented un-
77. “The Jones Act & The Passenger Vessel Services Act,” U.S. der Trade Authorities Procedures, 2016 Report,” Publication no.
Customs and Border Protection, September 27, 2019, https:// 4614, Junes 2016. For economic benefits to the working class, see
help.cbp.gov/s/article/Article-23?language=en_US. Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro, “Trade and Labor Market Dynam-
ics.” For benefits from the World Trade Organization, see Bryan
78. Scott Lincicome, “Countervailing Calamity: How to Stop the Schonfeld, “Why the U.S. Needs the World Trade Organization,”
Global Subsidies Race,” Cato Institute Policy Analysis no. 710, Washington Post, September 20, 2016. For the overwhelming sup-
October 9, 2012. port of economists, see “Free Trade,” IGM Forum, Chicago
Booth, March 13, 2012; “Trade Disruptions,” IGM Forum, Chi-
79. Lincicome, “Truth about Trade.” cago Booth, July 24, 2018; “Fast-Track Authority,” IGM Forum,
Chicago Booth, November 11, 2014; “Import Duties,” IGM Fo-
80. Eric Morath, “Retraining Programs Fall Short for Some rum, Chicago Booth, October 4, 2016; Zeeshan Aleem, “‘Another
29

Kick in the Teeth’: A Top Economist on How Trade with China immense strength as many of the world’s most advanced so-
Helped Elect Trump,” Vox, March 29, 2017; and Josh Barro, “So cieties were in ruins after WWII. When they recovered,
What Would It Mean to ‘Beat China’ on Trade?,” New York Times, they became extremely competitive. /5,” Twitter, Janu-
January 28, 2016. ary 5, 2019, 10:19 p.m., https://twitter.com/DavidAFrench/
status/1081752153398628352.
87. Russ Roberts, “The Human Side of Trade,” Medium, Decem-
ber 11, 2016. 93. Srikant Devaraj et al., “Executive Summary: How Vulnerable
Are American Communities to Automation, Trade, and Urban-
88. “Trade Theory, Philosophy, and Morality,” Cato Institute; ization?,” Ball State University Center for Business and Economic
Donald J. Boudreaux, “Trade’s Costs Are Not Losses,” Ameri- Research, Rural Policy Research Institute Center for State Policy,
can Institute for Economic Research, January 2, 2019; Scott June 19, 2017; Scott Sumner, “Automation Causes Trade,” The Li-
Lincicome, “The Case for Free Trade,” National Review, May 2, brary of Economics and Liberty, November 26, 2018; and “Technical
2019. Automation Potential and Wages for US Jobs by State and Metro-
politan Statistical Area,” McKinsey Global Institute, October 1,
89. William Lincoln and Andrew H. McCallum, “Decomposing 2018; and Greg Cancelada, “Workplace Automation: Should We
Globalisation,” Vox policy portal, Centre for Economic Policy Fear the Robots?,” Open Vault Blog (blog), Federal Reserve Bank of
Research, July 10, 2018; Luigi Pascali, “The Wind of Change: Mar- St. Louis, October 16, 2019.
itime Technology, Trade, and Economic Development,” Universi-
tat Pompeu Fabra Department of Economics and Business Eco- 94. Levy, “Did China Trade Cost the United States 2.4 Million
nomics Working Paper no. 1428, 2014; and “Boxes: The Unsung Jobs?”
Innovation at the Heart of the Global Economy,” NPR, http://
apps.npr.org/tshirt/#/boxes. 95. International Monetary Fund (IMF), “Chapter 2: Closer To-
gether or Further Apart? Subnational Regional Disparities and
90. Vincent Anesi and Giovanni Facchini, “Coercive Trade Pol- Adjustment in Advanced Economies,” in World Economic Outlook:
icy,” American Economics Journal: Microeconoimcs 11, no. 3 (August Global Manufacturing Downturn, Rising Trade Barrier (Washington:
2019): 225–56; William J. Davey, “Evaluating WTO Dispute Set- IMF, October 2019), pp. 65–92.
tlement: What Results Have Been Achieved through Consulta-
tions and Implementation of Panel Reports?,” Illinois Public 96. Davide Furceri et al., “Macroeconomic Consequences of Tar-
Law and Legal Theory Research Paper no. 05-19, November 30, iffs,” International Monetary Fund Working Paper no. 19/9, Janu-
2005; William J. Davey, “The WTO Dispute Settlement System: ary 15, 2019.
The First Ten Years,” Journal of International Economic Law 8, no.
17 (March 2005): 46–48; William J. Davey, “Evaluating WTO 97. Scott Lincicome, “Doomed to Repeat It: The Long History of
Dispute Settlement: What Results Have Been Achieved through America’s Protectionist Failures,” Cato Institute Policy Analysis
Consultations and Implementation of Panel Reports?,” in The no. 819, August 22, 2017; Matt Peterson, “The Making of a Trade
WTO in the Twenty-first Century: Dispute Settlement, Negotiations, Warrior,” The Atlantic, December 29, 2018; Inti Pacheco and Bob
and Regionalism in Asia, eds. Yasuhei Taniguchi, Alan Yanovich, and Tita, “Tariff Exclusions for Certain Steel Imports Sow Confu-
Jan Bohanes (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2007). sion,” Wall Street Journal, January 2, 2019; and Inti Pacheco and
Josh Zumbrun, “The Steel Industry Gets What It Wants on Tar-
91. Robert Kagan, “Welcome to the Jungle,” Washington Post, Octo- iffs,” Wall Street Journal, October 22, 2018.
ber 9, 2018; and see, e.g., Jong-Wha Lee and Ju Hyun Pyun, “Does
Trade Integration Contribute to Peace?,” Review of Development 98. Gary Clyde Hufbauer and Sean Lowry, “US Tire Tariffs: Sav-
Economics 20, no. 1 (2016): 327–44. “Our empirical analysis, based ing Few Jobs at High Cost,” Peterson Institute for International
on a large panel data set of 243,225 country-pair observations from Economics Policy Brief no. 12-9, April 2012.
1950 to 2000, confirms that an increase in bilateral trade interde-
pendence significantly promotes peace.” 99. “Tire Manufacturing,” Data USA.

92. David French (@DavidAFrench), “As for the previous as- 100. Levy, “Did China Trade Cost the United States 2.4 Million
cendancy of American manufacturing, never forget we gained Jobs?”; and Freeman, “A Failure to Adjust.”
30

101. Minsoo Lee and Donghyun Park, “Trade Effects of US Anti- 107. Nanette Byrnes, “Learning to Prosper in a Factory Town,”
dumping Actions Against China,” Asian Economic Journal 31, no. 1 MIT Technology Review, October 18, 2016; Craig Torres and
(March 2017): 3–16. Catarina Saraiva, “The New Startup South,” Bloomberg Business-
week, June 21, 2018; Kate Allen, “Shrinking Cities: Population
102. Daniel J. Ikenson, “Poster Child for Reform: The Decline in the World’s Rust-Belt Areas,” Financial Times, June 16,
Antidumping Case on Bedroom Furniture from China,” Cato In- 2017; Eric Cunningham, “No, Wall Street Journal, Chinese Im-
stitute Free Trade Bulletin no. 12, June 3, 2004. ports Didn’t Kill My Hometown,” The Federalist, August 16, 2016;
Danielle Paquette, “In This Part of the Midwest, the Problem
103. Jay Cost, “Terrible Tariffs,” National Review, August 8, 2018; Isn’t China. It’s Too Many Jobs,” Washington Post, June 20, 2017;
Douglas A. Irwin, Clashing Over Commerce: A History of US Trade Michael Sasso, “Lost Jobs of North Carolina Are Gone for Good.
Policy (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2017); and Peterson, Few Seem to Mind,” Bloomberg, August 23, 2019; and James Fallows,
“Making of a Trade Warrior.” “‘Lessons From Danville,’” The Atlantic, September 19, 2019.

104. Edward Gresser and Bryan Riley, “Give Shoe Taxes the Boot,” 108. “James Fallows,” The Atlantic, https://www.theatlantic.com/
Heritage Foundation Issue Brief no. 3576, April 24, 2012; and author/james-fallows/.
Edward Gresser, “Toughest on the Poor: America’s Flawed Tariff
System,” Foreign Affairs 81, no. 6 (November/December 2002). 109. Michael Warren, “What Trump Doesn’t Understand about
South Carolina and BMW,” Weekly Standard, June 26, 2018, https://
105. Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro, “Trade and Labor Market Dy- www.weeklystandard.com/michael-warren/what-trump-doesnt-
namics.” understand-about-south-carolina-and-bmw.

106. Alan Berube and Cecile Murray, “Renewing America’s Eco- 110. Jaison R. Abel and Richard Deitz, “Where Are Manufactur-
nomic Promise through Older Industrial Cities,” Brookings Insti- ing Jobs Coming Back?,” Liberty Street Economics (blog), Federal
tution, April 2018. Reserve Bank of New York, February 6, 2019.
RELATED PUBLICATIONS
FROM THE CATO INSTITUTE

Disciplining China’s Trade Practices at the WTO: How WTO Complaints Can
Help Make China More Market-​Oriented by James Bacchus, Simon Lester, and
Huan Zhu, Policy Analysis no. 856 (November 15, 2018)

Where’s the Beef? Finding a Better Way to Resolve U.S.-China Trade Conflicts by
Simon Lester and Huan Zhu, Free Trade Bulletin no. 71 (November 8, 2017)

Responsible Stakeholders: Why the United States Should Welcome China’s


Economic Leadership by Colin Grabow, Policy Analysis no. 821 (October 3, 2017)

Cybersecurity or Protectionism? Defusing the Most Volatile Issue in the U.S.-China


Relationship by Daniel J. Ikenson, Policy Analysis no. 815 (July 13, 2017)

It’s Time to Negotiate a New Economic Relationship with China by Simon Lester
and Huan Zhu, Free Trade Bulletin no. 70 (April 4, 2017)

Into the Abyss: Is a U.S.-China Trade War Inevitable? by Daniel J. Ikenson, Free
Trade Bulletin no. 69 (February 6, 2017)

Will Nonmarket Economy Methodology Go Quietly into the Night? U.S.


Antidumping Policy toward China after 2016 by K. William Watson, Policy
Analysis no. 763 (October 28, 2014)

Trade Policy Priority One: Averting a U.S.-China “Trade War” by Daniel J. Ikenson,
Free Trade Bulletin no. 47 (March 5, 2012)

Manufacturing Discord: Growing Tensions Threaten the U.S.-China Economic


Relationship by Daniel J. Ikenson,Trade Briefing Paper no. 29 (May 4, 2010)

Growing Pains: The Evolving U.S.-China Trade Relationship by Daniel J. Ikenson, Free
Trade Bulletin no. 28 (May 7, 2007)

Who’s Manipulating Whom? China’s Currency and the U.S. Economy by Daniel
Griswold, Trade Briefing Paper no. 23 (July 11, 2006)

Nonmarket Nonsense: U.S. Antidumping Policy toward China by Daniel J. Ikenson,


Trade Briefing Paper no. 22 (March 7, 2005)

Poster Child for Reform: The Antidumping Case on Bedroom Furniture from
China by Daniel J. Ikenson, Free Trade Bulletin no. 12 (June 3, 2004)

Bull in a China Shop: Assessing the First Section 421 Trade Case by Daniel J.
Ikenson, FreeTrade Bulletin no. 2 (January 1, 2003)
RECENT STUDIES IN THE
CATO INSTITUTE POLICY ANALYSIS SERIES

894. Kicking the Habit: The Opioid Crisis and America’s Addiction to
Prohibition by Josh Bowers and Daniel Abrahamson (June 29, 2020)

893. Nuclear Anti-Proliferation Policy and the Korea Conundrum: Some Policy
Proposals by John Mueller (June 22, 2020)

892. “Money as a Weapons System”: The Promises and Pitfalls of Foreign


Defense Contracting by Renanah Miles Joyce and Brian Blankenship (June 3,
2020)

891. Rightsizing Fed Ed: Principles for Reform and Practical Steps to Move in
the Right Direction by Mary Clare Amselem, Lindsey Burke, Jonathan Butcher,
Jamie Gass, Neal McCluskey, and Theodor Rebarber (May 4, 2020)

890. Illegal Immigrant Incarceration Rates, 2010–2018: Demographics and


Policy Implications by Michelangelo Landgrave and Alex Nowrasteh (April 21,
2020)

889. Transit: The Urban Parasite by Randal O’Toole (April 20, 2020)

888. The Case for Congressional Regulatory Review by William Yeatman (April 14,
2020)

887. The Development Dimension: What to Do about Differential Treatment in


Trade by James Bacchus and Inu Manak (April 13, 2020)

886. Environmental Costs of the Jones Act by Timothy Fitzgerald (March 2, 2020)

885. Maryland’s BOOST Is Promising, but More Work Is Needed by Russell


Rhine (February 26, 2020)

884. Ineffective, Immoral, Politically Convenient: America’s Overreliance on


Economic Sanctions and What to Do about It by Richard Hanania (February
18, 2020)

CITATION
Lincicome, Scott. “Testing the ‘China Shock’: Was Normalizing Trade with China a Mistake?” Policy Analysis
No. 895, Cato Institute, Washington, DC, July 8, 2020. https://doi.org/10.36009/PA.895.

The views expressed in this paper are those of the author(s) and should not be attributed to the Cato Institute, its
trustees, its Sponsors, or any other person or organization. Nothing in this paper should be construed as an attempt to
aid or hinder the passage of any bill before Congress. Copyright © 2020 Cato Institute. This work by Cato Institute is
licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlike 4.0 International License.

You might also like