Nalebuff, Barry J. & Adam M. Brandenburger - 'Co-Epetition - Competitive and Cooperative Business Strategies For The Digital Economy'

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 10

Strategy & Leadership

Co-opetition: Competitive and cooperative business strategies for the digital economy
Barry J. Nalebuff, Adam M. Brandenburger,
Article information:
To cite this document:
Barry J. Nalebuff, Adam M. Brandenburger, (1997) "Co‐opetition: Competitive and cooperative business strategies for the
digital economy", Strategy & Leadership, Vol. 25 Issue: 6, pp.28-33, https://doi.org/10.1108/eb054655
Permanent link to this document:
https://doi.org/10.1108/eb054655
Downloaded on: 15 July 2018, At: 12:28 (PT)
References: this document contains references to 0 other documents.
To copy this document: permissions@emeraldinsight.com
The fulltext of this document has been downloaded 5663 times since 2006*
Users who downloaded this article also downloaded:
(2004),"Co-opetition: the organisation of the future", Marketing Intelligence &amp; Planning, Vol. 22 Iss 7 pp. 780-790 <a
Downloaded by University of Sydney Library At 12:28 15 July 2018 (PT)

href="https://doi.org/10.1108/02634500410568600">https://doi.org/10.1108/02634500410568600</a>
(2008),"Identifying and prioritizing critical success factors for coopetition strategy", Industrial Management
&amp; Data Systems, Vol. 108 Iss 4 pp. 437-454 <a href="https://doi.org/10.1108/02635570810868326">https://
doi.org/10.1108/02635570810868326</a>

Access to this document was granted through an Emerald subscription provided by emerald-srm:616673 []
For Authors
If you would like to write for this, or any other Emerald publication, then please use our Emerald for Authors service
information about how to choose which publication to write for and submission guidelines are available for all. Please visit
www.emeraldinsight.com/authors for more information.
About Emerald www.emeraldinsight.com
Emerald is a global publisher linking research and practice to the benefit of society. The company manages a portfolio of
more than 290 journals and over 2,350 books and book series volumes, as well as providing an extensive range of online
products and additional customer resources and services.
Emerald is both COUNTER 4 and TRANSFER compliant. The organization is a partner of the Committee on Publication
Ethics (COPE) and also works with Portico and the LOCKSS initiative for digital archive preservation.

*Related content and download information correct at time of download.


Downloaded by University of Sydney Library At 12:28 15 July 2018 (PT)

The words we use influence how we think. For example, For example, in Columbia, S.C., the local newspaper,
when we think about business, most of us would prob- The State, has lost market share to USA Today. The State tried
ably say "Business is War." A company has to capture cutting prices, adding more color, including more local
J the market, beat the competition, make a killing, bury news—all in an effort to keep its share of the pie. What the
the competition. Using this metaphor, we have a whole paper's executives really needed to do was find ways of cre-
vocabulary of winners and losers. Yet, in reality, that's often ating more pie and getting a slice of that bigger pie. The
misleading. We may think there will be victors and van- State's large Sunday edition requires 50 percent greater
quished in a price war, but in the end, no one wins. printing capacity than its weekday edition. Thus, some of
At the other extreme, when we consider the importance its presses sat idle for most of the week. USA Today doesn't
of partnerships, alliances, working together, listening to the have a weekend edition. The co-opetition solution: The
customer, and working with suppliers, it would seem that a State now prints USA Today during the week using its
more appropriate metaphor might be "Business is Peace." Sunday printing presses. While the two papers compete for
But that can't be right either, because we know there is customers and advertisers, they have found a way to coop-
conflict with rivals over market share, conflict with cus- erate in creating a larger pie.
tomers over price, and conflict with suppliers over cost. Using Game Theory as a Tool
If "business-as-war" is wrong, and "business-as-peace" In traditional economics, markets are fixed; companies set
is too simplistic, what's the right mindset? It's War and prices, and customers take the price or vote with their feet.
Peace—simultaneously. Creating value, a bigger pie, is The "old" economy was based on decreasing returns to
fundamentally a cooperative activity involving customers scale—if you wanted more gold, you had to dig deeper. In
and suppliers that a company can't accomplish alone. On the information economy, by contrast, the costs are upfront
the other hand, the act of dividing up the pie is fundamen- —the more people that want a product, the cheaper it is for
tally competitive. everyone.
A company has to keep its eye on both balls, creating Just as when cars first came out and we were missing
and capturing, at the same time. We have chosen to call roads, gas stations, and mechanics, much of the infrastruc-
this "co-opetition," because it combines competition and ture to support the information economy hasn't yet been
cooperation.1

Strategy E leadership November/December 1997

28
by Barry J . Nalebuff and Adam M. Brandenburger
Barry Nalebuff is the Milton Steinbach Professor at the Yale School of Management. Adam Brandenburger is a
professor at the Harvard Business School. They are pioneers in the practice of applying game theory to the art of
management. Their recent booh, Co-opetition, was published by Currency Doubleday in 1996. This article was
derivedfrom Professor Nalebuffs presentation at the International Strategic Leadership Conference in April 1997.

CO-OPETITION:
Downloaded by University of Sydney Library At 12:28 15 July 2018 (PT)

COMPETITIVE AND COOPERATIVE BUSINESS STRATEGIES FOR THE DIGITAL ECONOMY


developed. Online commerce doesn't work if you don't It was focused on solving games rather than asking if it was
have online payment devices. As the infrastructure is still the right game.
being developed, Adam Smith's invisible hand won't work, To make the theory more useful to business, we had to
because many of the markets are missing. Succeeding in move away from finding the answer to a particular game.
the new economy requires a different approach. Instead, we looked at the meta-game of designing the right
Because we're in a period of transition, today's firms game. To do this, we went back to von Neumann's roots of
have the ability to influence what that future will be like. game theory and put value creation at center stage.
Instead of accepting what is, they can ask, "What game In thinking of business as a game, it is misleading to
would I like to play?" That's a difficult question to answer, imagine games such as poker, football, or chess. First, in
because, normally, we learn these things through experi- order to win at those games, someone else has to lose. That
ence. But by the time we're in a new game, it's too late to rule doesn't always apply in the game of business. Intel's
shape it. Game theory allows us to analyze the game success hasn't hurt Microsoft, and Microsoft's success hasn't
before we get into it. hurt Intel.
The inventor of game theory was John von Neumann. The second difference between business and most other
Now, fifty years later, game theory is coming into its own. games is that in most games the playing field, the players,
The FCC used game theory to design what has become a and the rules are set. In business, the action comes from
$20 million auction of radio spectra. We are now teaching changing the game.
game theory in management schools, and management A game has players and the added, value that each
consulting companies are bringing it into their practices. player brings. A game has rules that structure the inter-
Game theory had its beginning in the early days of action between players. The game is also affected by
World War II when the British air force was playing cat and perceptions—what the players believe. And a game has
mouse with German submarines. The British discovered scope or boundaries and linkages to other games—where
that by applying what later became known as game theory, one game ends, and another begins. (In reality, there's
they could increase their hit rate. In those early days, game only one big game, but that game is so complex we pre-
theory was used primarily to analyze particular problems. tend there are a lot of little games and think about how
they're connected.)

Strategy E leadership N o v e m b e r / D e c e m b e r i 1997


29
"A player is a complementor if customers value your product more when they have that player's product
than when they have your productalone.Aplayer is a competitor if customers value your product less when
they have that player's product than when they have your product alone."

If you want to change a game, you must change one of plementors. If your customers' other suppliers sell products
these components. In this article, we spend most of our that make yours less valuable, they are your competitors.
time addressing the players and their added value, because Similarly, your suppliers have other customers. If sup­
they are the most fundamental elements. However, when plying those other customers, makes it harder for those
you make a systematic change in one aspect of the game, suppliers to supply you, those other customers are your
it is very likely you will create change in one or more of competitors. If supplying them makes it easier to supply
the other aspects as well. you, then you have a complementor on the supply side.
Knowing the Players To figure out if somebody is your competitor or your com­
In the game of business, we sometimes list players as cus­ plementor, you must see the world from the customers' and
tomers, suppliers, and competitors. Then there's the gov­ suppliers' perspective. You must be allocentric —centered
ernment, which often pulls strings from behind the scenes on others, rather than egocentric—centered on yourself.
and sets some of the rules of the game. But there's yet A company should have a strategy for every relationship
another type of player that is often overlooked. in its Value Net. A case in point is Intel. Its chief executive,
Downloaded by University of Sydney Library At 12:28 15 July 2018 (PT)

Think about the relationship between Intel and Andy Grove, has a strategy for each type of player. His
Microsoft. Is one a customer of the other? Not really. The competitor strategy is to be constantly innovative, to make
real relationship between Microsoft and Intel is not cus­ sure that by the time competitors catch up with his technol­
tomer, nor supplier, but complementor. The Pentium chip ogy, he's advanced to the next improvement. Toward cus­
makes Windows 95 work better, and Windows 95 gives tomers, Grove's strategy was to create the branded ingredi­
people a reason for upgrading to the Pentium chip. ent, the "Intel inside" campaign. He also has an incredibly
Similarly, WindowsNT and the Pentium II chip each make well-thought-out complement strategy of pushing his cus­
the other more valuable. tomers to the next level of technology. He understands that
software alone will not push the limits of processing cycles,
Complementors are not just in the high-tech industries.
and without that push, why would people demand the
When cars first came out, the auto makers got together
faster and faster chips his engineers have built?
with the headlight people and the tire manufacturers to
form the Lincoln Highway Association, which helped sub­ Grove recognizes that it's video rather than numbers
sidize the building of the first cross-country road. They and words that will create the next big push for upgrades.
knew they could sell more cars if there were more roads. He has formed an alliance with Hollywood Creative Artists
Auto makers soon recognized that they could sell more cars to create virtual reality video games for the PC; he's invest­
if people could borrow money, so General Motors formed ed in ProShare for desktop video conferencing; he's
GMAC and Ford started Ford Motor Credit. (Ford now formed an alliance with MCI to get more fiber into
makes more money on car loans than it does selling cars.) intranets to increase their capacity. Grove has asked: What
A player is a complementor if customers value your prod­ are all the things that will make my chips more valuable?
uct more when they have that player's product than when What can I do to engineer a demand for my product?
they have your product alone. A player is a competitor if The traditional strategic approach to business strategy
customers value your product less when they have that has been "stick to your knitting." But you can't stick to
players product than when they have your product alone.
The only difference between complementor and competi­
tor is that the word more is replaced by less, which tells us
that every strategy a company aims toward a competitor
should be applied in exactly the opposite way toward a
complementor.
Exhibit 1 contains the Value Net—a map of the whole
game, the players and their relationships to one another.
Money goes from the customers to the business and from
the business to its suppliers. Your customers have other sup­
pliers, and some of those suppliers are going to be good for
you in the sense that when customers buy their products,
your products become more valuable. These are your com­

Strategy & Leadership November/December 1997


30
your knitting if there isn't enough demand for sweaters. architecture policy, which allowed companies like
You have to prod the market to discover what type of Compaq, Dell, and Osgood to build IBM clones. The
activities the market is not providing. advantage of these moves was that a larger pie was created
For example, Carnival Cruise Lines created Carnival Air sooner. But Intel and Microsoft got the majority of the
to overcome high airfares from the west coast to Florida. benefit, because they controlled the necessary technology
Carnival Air's low fares brought more people into the cruise and software. IBM had to share its profits with its hard­
market and forced United and Delta to bring their fares ware competitors. In retrospect, many people say that IBM
down as well. Carnival Cruise Lines doesn't own and oper­ should have kept one piece of the puzzle, probably the
ate the planes, but it made the change happen. architecture, to itself.
Why hasn't the Internet taken off in Japan? Japan's local We don't agree. A closed architecture would have made
phone calls are metered. If you were on AOL for ten hours a much smaller pie. Another way to share in the gain is to
in Japan, you'd have a $100 phone bill. No matter what invest in complementer companies. IBM owned 20 per­
the price of the AOL service is, the Internet is not going to cent of Intel and had options on another 10 percent; it had
Downloaded by University of Sydney Library At 12:28 15 July 2018 (PT)

take off. The complements have to be cheaper. a chance to buy half of Microsoft for $300 million. If IBM
This is a general problem. If companies price their had kept its Intel stake and bought Microsoft, it would be
competing products independently, prices will come down $50 billion richer today.
as companies try to compensate for lower margin by gain­ Of course, we have the benefit of hindsight. But when
ing profit from increased market share. The reverse situa­ you own all the pieces, as IBM did in the beginning, you
tion is true for complements. The natural incentive is to can write the rules. You're protected because you have
set prices too high, which makes the total package too equity stakes in all the key players, so you don't have to
expensive. Complementors should agree to lower prices. guess right. You'll be there with whichever one turns out
In this case, a monopoly that prices complements actually to make the money. If you have helped other people to
leads to higher profits and lower prices for consumers. This become more valuable, you should share in some of their
is also why we see so much bundling. It's a way of bringing gain. Too often we ask how much money other people
the prices of a complementary package down. can help us make, rather than what we can do to make
Unlike the invisible hand of Adam Smith, complements the pie larger for others and then how we can share in the
don't take care of themselves. Complements tend to be gain we created.
missing or too expensive. Often, the best solution is to get The Value Net is a place to start. It is a complete map
involved. There are three approaches you can take. of a business' relationships; it helps counter limited think­
♦ Do it yourself. If you are sufficiently large and you ing, focusing only on competition and forgetting coopera­
own enough of the market to get a large fraction of the tion; it is a prompt to understand the business from the
benefits, then it may be worthwhile for you to undertake outside in; and it provides a shared template for discus­
the new venture alone. Think of Intel and chips. sions of strategy. Before you redefine a business strategy,
♦ Form an alliance. Sometimes the project is too big, you should write down your Value Net and the Value Nets
e.g., building the roads for cars or building the infrastruc­ of your customers and suppliers. It's a challenging exercise,
ture for electronic commerce. In these cases, you may need but the insights are well worth it.
to join with competitors as well as customers and suppliers. Assessing Added Value
♦ Set up a proprietary business. Barnes & Noble The concept of added value helps determine how a pie will
and Starbucks have joined hands because coffee brings be divided. By estimating the size of the pie when you're
people into the stores, and the stores bring people to in the game, and then subtracting the size of the pie when
the coffee. you're out of the game, you can determine what would be
Identifying complements in the Value Net can help lost if you weren't in the game. You also need to identify
determine how to make a business more profitable. The what others would lose if you were not in the game, and
Value Net can also help determine what makes a business what alternatives they have.
more valuable. When IBM was in a hurry to launch its PC, For example, what's the added value of NutraSweet,
it abandoned its tradition of internal development and the high intensity sweetener used in Diet Coke and Diet
subcontracted the chip to Intel and the operating system Pepsi? It's the value that customers get from drinking Diet
to Microsoft. At the same time, IBM decided on an open- Coke and Diet Pepsi compared to Tab and Fresca. And it's

Strategy & Leadership November/December 1997

32
the profits Coke and Pepsi make selling Diet Coke and United Airlines customer, United charges you less than an
Diet Pepsi compared to the profits they used to make sell­ American Airlines customer, because the American person
ing Tab and Fresca. Add the profits that Monsanto makes doesn't get the upgrade, the Mileage Plus program, or the
selling NutraSweet compared to the profits that were special toll-free reservation number. In effect, the
made selling saccharin, plus all the profits Ajinomoto American customer pays a higher price to fly on United.
makes supplying amino acids to Monsanto compared to Creating loyalty by rewarding it actually creates added
the petroleum makers who supply their products to sac­ value. If all the customer looks at is the product, the trans­
charin makers. What would be lost in the entire market if action becomes anonymous—a commodity. But if cus­
NutraSweet didn't exist? tomers invest in the relationship, they will seek not only a
In thinking about added value, you have to think about flight to Chicago, but a flight on United. The relationship
the entire value chain and understand where your added is a form of differentiation and a source of added value.
value comes from. To the extent that a company can make Thus, charging competitors' customers more adds value.
sure it has added value throughout the game, it can claim a Sometimes you have to reward people for wanting to
bigger piece of the pie. repeat the same experience and form that relationship.
At the same time that you're trying to raise your added ♦ Say thank you in kind, rather than with cash. If an
value, you're also concerned with limiting the added value airline gives someone a free trip to Hawaii, the airline's
of the other players. The best way to lower the added cost is $40 and some peanuts, but for the customer the
value of a supplier is to bring more suppliers into the value added is $300.
game, so that any single one has less added value. How ♦ Save the best thank you for your best customers.
can you bring more suppliers into the game? ♦ Don't forget to say thank you, even if you have a
Downloaded by University of Sydney Library At 12:28 15 July 2018 (PT)

♦ Pay new suppliers to play. Give them a guaranteed monopoly.


contract to get them to enter the game. ♦ Say thank you to suppliers as well as customers.
♦ Form a buying coalition to become a larger buyer. ♦ Say you're going to say thank you.
American Express joined with RJR, Sears, IBM, and oth­ ♦ Say thank you in a way that builds your business.
ers to buy $1 billion worth of HMO coverage rather than ♦ Allow competition to have loyal customers, too.
the $15 million worth they would buy alone. That brought Just because you have added value doesn't mean you
200 HMO suppliers into the game, which guaranteed that should collect on it today. Sometimes the best way to use
none of them would have much added value. the power of added value is to restructure the game—
♦ Form a buying coalition with your future self. Instead change the rules, write down-stream revenue contracts,
of buying for one year, go to a seven-year contract. create a branded ingredient. Then, if your product later
♦ Become your own supplier. becomes a commodity, you will have created an environ­
These same principles apply to customers. It's harder to ment that will preserve your added value.
bring more customers into the game, but you can: What to Do if You Have No Added Value
♦ Educate customers—the more people know about When the NutraSweet patent was due to expire, a compa­
your products and services, the more uses they may find ny called Holland Sweetener built a new factory to pro­
for them. duce aspartame, the generic form of NutraSweet.
♦ Pay customers to play by giving away part of the ser­ Monsanto had been in the business for 17 years and
vice. This works best in the early adopter stage. owned the customer-preferred brand name NutraSweet.
♦ Bring in better and cheaper complementary products, When Holland Sweetener entered the market, it lowered
as in the Intel example. the added value of Monsanto, but it had no added value of
♦ Become your own best customer. It's not a coinci­ its own. The company spent $50 million to build a plant,
dence that automakers own car rental agencies. entered the game, and watched Coke and Pepsi re­
Differentiation Through Loyalty negotiate their contracts with Monsanto and save them­
If you could charge a different price to your customers ver­ selves $200 million a year.
sus your competitors' customers, to whom would you offer Holland Sweetner did not realize that what it was really
a lower price? selling was competition. If you can't make money in the
Most people are tempted to give a lower price to their game, you can get money for changing the game. Here are
competitors' customers. That's a poor strategy. What busi­ a number of ways of getting paid to play.
nesses do we know that give their competitors' customers ♦ Ask for contributions for bidding expenses.
lower prices? Telephone companies—switch and get the ♦ Ask for a guaranteed sales contract.
lowest prices. Cellular phones—switch and get a free cel­ ♦ Ask for a last-look provision.
lular phone. Credit cards—teaser introductory rates. All of ♦ Ask for better access to information.
those businesses are plagued by massive churn. ♦ Ask to deal with someone who will appreciate what
Let's think about the businesses that charge their own you bring to the table.
customers less than competitors' customers. If you're a

Strategy & Leadership November/December 1997


34
"Creating loyalty by rewarding it actually creates added value. If all the customer looks at is the product, the transaction
becomes anonymous - a commodity. But if customers invest in the relationship, theywillseek [your product]."

♦ Ask to bid on other pieces of business. Describe the whole game. Identify all the players and their
♦ Ask the customer to quote a price at which he would relationships. Think about complements. List the players
give you his business. you would like to bring into the game.
♦ Cash is okay, too. ♦ Calculate your added value. Think about how you
When bidding for new business, you should think about can increase your added value. Use the concept of added
how to bring new customers into the market versus how to value to understand who has the power in your game.
steal another company's customers. However, if you do go Game theory is a systematic approach to discovering
after another company's customers, make sure you're get­ new strategies and changing the game. It helps you to
ting something for it. By negotiating what you're going to keep your eye where the real action is and to find a differ­
get, you can make your bid more likely to succeed. ent and better game to play.
A Checklist for Change Note
Game theory is a tool to incorporate into your way of 1. T h e term "co-opetition" was coined by Ray Noorda, founder of the
thinking. You don't have to accept the game you find your­ networking software company Novell.
self in. You have the freedom to change it. And that's
Downloaded by University of Sydney Library At 12:28 15 July 2018 (PT)

where great future success will come from.


♦ Use the co-opetition mindset. Think about creating
and capturing pie—competing and cooperating.
♦ Write out the Value Net for your organization.

Strategy & Leadership November/December 1997


35
This article has been cited by:

1. Roland Bel. 2018. A property rights theory of competitive advantage. Strategic Management Journal 39:6, 1678-1703.
[Crossref]
2. Claude Compagnone, Béatrice Simon. 2018. Cooperation and competition among agricultural advisory service providers. The
case of pesticides use. Journal of Rural Studies 59, 10-20. [Crossref]
3. Vik Pant, Eric Yu. 2018. Modeling Simultaneous Cooperation and Competition Among Enterprises. Business & Information
Systems Engineering 60:1, 39-54. [Crossref]
4. Wojciech Czakon, Arkadiusz Kawa. 2018. Network myopia: An empirical study of network perception. Industrial Marketing
Management . [Crossref]
5. Riccardo Bonazzi, Vincent Grèzes. United We Stand: Exploring the Notion of Cooperation Support System for Business
Model Design 167-188. [Crossref]
6. Steven Pattinson, John Nicholson, Adam Lindgreen. 2018. Emergent coopetition from a sensemaking perspective: A multi-
level analysis. Industrial Marketing Management 68, 25-35. [Crossref]
7. Luis Maurício Martins de Resende, Isabela Volski, Leozenir Mendes Betim, Gustavo Dambiski Gomes de Carvalho, Rodrigo
de Barros, Fabio Pietrobelli Senger. 2018. Critical success factors in coopetition: Evidence on a business network. Industrial
Marketing Management 68, 177-187. [Crossref]
8. Naomi A. Gardberg, Stelios C. Zyglidopoulos, Pavlos C. Symeou, Donald H. Schepers. 2017. The Impact of Corporate
Philanthropy on Reputation for Corporate Social Performance. Business & Society 35, 000765031769485. [Crossref]
Downloaded by University of Sydney Library At 12:28 15 July 2018 (PT)

9. Marcel M. Zondag, Elisabeth F. Mueller, Bruce G. Ferrin. 2017. The application of value nets in food supply chains: A
multiple case study. Scandinavian Journal of Management 33:4, 199-212. [Crossref]
10. Yongrae Cho, Choonghyun Lee, Eunji Mok. The effects of cooperative activities with competitors on the performances of
innovation and management 166-170. [Crossref]
11. . Bibliography 197-243. [Crossref]
12. Sascha Kraus, Fabian Meier, Thomas Niemand, Ricarda B. Bouncken, Paavo Ritala. 2017. In search for the ideal coopetition
partner: an experimental study. Review of Managerial Science 17. . [Crossref]
13. D. Menival, H. Han. Wine Consumption in China 101-115. [Crossref]
14. Maria Bengtsson, Tatbeeq Raza-Ullah. 2016. A systematic review of research on coopetition: Toward a multilevel
understanding. Industrial Marketing Management 57, 23-39. [Crossref]
15. Ben R. Martin. 2016. Twenty challenges for innovation studies. Science and Public Policy 43:3, 432-450. [Crossref]
16. Netsanet Haile, Jörn Altmann. 2016. Value creation in software service platforms. Future Generation Computer Systems 55,
495-509. [Crossref]
17. Nazanin Eftekhari, Marcel Bogers. 2015. Open for Entrepreneurship: How Open Innovation Can Foster New Venture
Creation. Creativity and Innovation Management 24:4, 574-584. [Crossref]
18. Artur Steiner, Jane Atterton. 2015. Exploring the contribution of rural enterprises to local resilience. Journal of Rural Studies
40, 30-45. [Crossref]
19. Cristina Ziliani, Marco Ieva. 2015. Retail shopper marketing: the future of promotional flyers. International Journal of Retail
& Distribution Management 43:6, 488-502. [Abstract] [Full Text] [PDF]
20. Yenming J. Chen, Shihtung Shu, Stephen Strombeck. 2015. Pricing management between partnering rivals: a coopetitive
diffusion analysis. International Journal of Systems Science: Operations & Logistics 2:1, 15-24. [Crossref]
21. Andrew M. Cox, Stephen Pinfield. 2014. Research data management and libraries: Current activities and future priorities.
Journal of Librarianship and Information Science 46:4, 299-316. [Crossref]
22. Katia Angue, Cécile Ayerbe, Liliana Mitkova. 2014. A method using two dimensions of the patent classification for measuring
the technological proximity: an application in identifying a potential R&D partner in biotechnology. The Journal of Technology
Transfer 39:5, 716-747. [Crossref]
23. M. Panizzon, L. B. Roldan, M. A. Menegotto, E. C. H. Dorion. New changes in organizational design to instigate co-creation
dynamics and innovation: A model based on online multiplayer games 467-474. [Crossref]
24. Steve Charters, Nathalie Spielmann. 2014. Characteristics of strong territorial brands: The case of champagne. Journal of
Business Research 67:7, 1461-1467. [Crossref]
25. Francois Duhamel, Sophie Reboud, Michel Santi. 2014. Capturing value from innovations: the importance of rent
configurations. Management Decision 52:1, 122-143. [Abstract] [Full Text] [PDF]
26. Mehmet Gençer, Beyza Oba. Open Innovation Ecosystems in the Software Industry 277-292. [Crossref]
27. Andrew M. Cox, Sheila Corrall. 2013. Evolving academic library specialties. Journal of the American Society for Information
Science and Technology 64:8, 1526-1542. [Crossref]
28. A. Sloane, S. O’Reilly. 2013. The emergence of supply network ecosystems: a social network analysis perspective. Production
Planning & Control 24:7, 621-639. [Crossref]
29. Susan Luckman. Precariously Mobile: Tensions between the Local and the Global in Higher Education Approaches to
Cultural Work 69-86. [Crossref]
30. Susan V. Scott, Markos Zachariadis. 2012. Origins and development of SWIFT, 1973–2009. Business History 54:3, 462-482.
[Crossref]
31. Alexandre Largier, Nicolas Lot. 2012. Secourir un train en panne : limites et difficultés à l’écriture des règles de sécurité.
Activites 09:1. . [Crossref]
32. Marcel Bogers, Henrik Sproedt. 2012. Playful Collaboration (or Not): Using a Game to Grasp the Social Dynamics of Open
Innovation in Innovation and Business Education. Journal of Teaching in International Business 23:2, 75-97. [Crossref]
33. Andreas I. Nicolaou, D. Harrison McKnight. 2011. System Design Features and Repeated Use of Electronic Data Exchanges.
Journal of Management Information Systems 28:2, 269-304. [Crossref]
34. Jin-Su Kang, Hong-Yuh Lee, Julio Tsai. 2011. An analysis of interdependencies in mobile communications technology: The
case of WiMAX and the development of a market assessment model. Technology in Society 33:3-4, 284-293. [Crossref]
35. Riccardo Bonazzi, Charlotte Ceccaroli, Stéphanie Missonier. The Man behind the Curtain: Exploring the Role of IS Strategic
Consultant 57-68. [Crossref]
36. Azaddin Salem Khalifa. 2010. Rethinking the current dominant approach to business school strategy. European Business
Downloaded by University of Sydney Library At 12:28 15 July 2018 (PT)

Review 22:6, 591-607. [Abstract] [Full Text] [PDF]


37. Sang M. Lee, Taewan Kim, Yonghwi Noh, Byungku Lee. 2010. Success factors of platform leadership in web 2.0 service
business. Service Business 4:2, 89-103. [Crossref]
38. Bill Doolin. 2010. Making sense of context. Journal of Systems and Information Technology 12:2, 88-104. [Abstract] [Full
Text] [PDF]
39. Elisa Rancati. 2010. Market-Driven Management, Global Markets and Competitive Convergence. Symphonya. Emerging Issues
in Management :1. . [Crossref]
40. Keith Walley, Paul Custance. 2010. Coopetition: insights from the agri-food supply chain. Journal on Chain and Network
Science 10:3, 185-192. [Crossref]
41. Felicity Kelliher, Anthony Foley, Anne-Marie Frampton. 2009. Facilitating small firm learning networks in the Irish tourism
sector. Tourism and Hospitality Research 9:1, 80-95. [Crossref]
42. Andreas I. Nicolaou. 2008. Research issues on the use of ERPS in interorganizational relationships. International Journal of
Accounting Information Systems 9:4, 216-226. [Crossref]
43. 김김김, HoYeol Bang. 2008. DETERMINANTS OF US CVB’S WEBSITE SERVICE QUALITY. International Commerce
and Information Review 10:4, 125-151. [Crossref]
44. Elena Bonel, Paolo Pellizzari, Elena Rocco. 2008. Coopetition and Complementarities: Modeling Coopetition Strategy and
Its Risks at an Individual Partner Level. Management Research: Journal of the Iberoamerican Academy of Management 6:3,
189-205. [Abstract] [PDF]
45. Garyfallos Fragidis, Konstantinos Tarabanis, Adamantios Koumpis. Conceptual and Business Models for Customer-Centric
Business Ecosystems 94-99. [Crossref]
46. Michael Reiß, Tobias Bernecker. 2006. Conjoint Controlling: Organisationsgerechte Controllingsysteme zwischen Better
Budgeting und komplex-hybrider Steuerung. Zeitschrift für Planung & Unternehmenssteuerung 17:1, 5-26. [Crossref]
47. Greg Hearn, Cassandra Pace. 2006. Value‐creating ecologies: understanding next generation business systems. foresight 8:1,
55-65. [Abstract] [Full Text] [PDF]
48. T.J. Vapola, Tomi T. Seppälä. The Performance Impact of Membership in a Global Alliance: Evidence on the Revenue
Growth Rate of Mobile Operators 119-137. [Crossref]
49. Øystein D. Fjeldstad, Manuel Becerra, Sathya Narayanan. 2004. Strategic action in network industries: an empirical analysis
of the European mobile phone industry. Scandinavian Journal of Management 20:1-2, 173-196. [Crossref]
50. Alexander Osterwalder, Yves Pigneur. An ontology for e-Business models 65-97. [Crossref]
51. Espen Andersen, Øystein D. Fjeldstad. 2003. Understanding interfirm relations in mediation industries with special reference
to the Nordic mobile communication industry. Industrial Marketing Management 32:5, 397-408. [Crossref]
52. T.R. Eikebrokk, D.H. Olsen. Co-opetition and e-Business Success in SMEs: An Empirical Investigation of European SMEs
162a-162a. [Crossref]
53. Junying Zhong, Marko Nieminen. Platform as a Strategy 160-180. [Crossref]
54. Riccardo Bonazzi, Zhan Liu, Simon Ganière, Yves Pigneur. A Dynamic Privacy Manager for Compliance in Pervasive
Computing 793-815. [Crossref]
55. Riccardo Bonazzi, Zhan Liu, Simon Ganière, Yves Pigneur. A Dynamic Privacy Manager for Compliance in Pervasive
Computing 285-307. [Crossref]
Downloaded by University of Sydney Library At 12:28 15 July 2018 (PT)

You might also like