Berndt Chapter 11

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 56

592 Parameter Estimation in Siructurai and Reduced Form Models

mators for Functions of Parameters and Structural Coefficients of Econometric


Models,” Journal of the American Statistical Association, 74:365, March, (85-
Chapter I
193,
Zellner, Arnold and Henri Theil [1962]. hree-Stage Least Squares: Simultancous
Estimation of Simultaneous Equations, ‘onometrice, Wz), January, 54-78.

FURTHER READINGS Whether and How Much


Addison, John T. and W,Stanley Siebert [1979]. The Marketfor Labor: An Analytical
Treatment, Santa Monica, Calif: Goodyear. See especially Chapter 12, “Wage
Inflation,”pp, 414-464.
Women Work for Pay:
Barro, Robert J. [1987], Macroeconomics, Second Edition, NewYork: John Wiley and
Sons. See especially Chapter 16. “The Interplay between Nominal and Real Vari- Applications of Limited
ait Is the Evidence?,” pp. 455-461.
de Marchi, Neil and ChristopherL. Gilbert, eds. [1989]. “History and Methodology Dependent Variable
of Econometrics,” Special Issue of the Oxfard Economic Papers, 41:1, January. A
lively discussion on the historical development of econometrics with special
emphasis on simultaneous equations procedures.
Procedures
Desai, Meghnad (1976], applied Econometrics, New York: McGraw-Hill, See espe-
cially Chapter 7, “Dynamic Simultaneous Equation Models: Wages and Prices.
pp. 205-232, and Chapter 8. “Macroeconomic Models: Simulation and Policy most of the available evidence suggests that female labor
Applications,” pp. 233-268.
Ehrenberg, Ronald G. and Robert S. Smith [1985]. Modern Labor Ecomomies, Second supply, measured either as laborforce participation or as hours of
Edition, Glenview, INL: Scott, Foresman. Sce especially Chapter16, “Inflation and work, is considerably more wageand propertyincomeelasticthan
Unemployment,” pp. 524-564. matelabor supply.
Feisher, Belton and Thomas Kniesner[1984], Labor Econontics: Theory, Evidence MARK R KILLINGSWORTH (1983. p 432]
and Policy, Third Edition, Englewood Cliffs, NJ.: Prentice-Hall. See especially
Chapter 12, “Unemploymentand Wage Inflation,” pp. 462-527 “Oneunexpectedfinding is that working wives in Canada tendto
Lue: . Robert E., Jr. and Thomus J. Sargent [1981}, eds., Rational Expectations und
Econametric Practice, Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press. A collection work fewer hours per year whenpaid moreper hour... Our
of oft-cited papers dealing with rational expectations. resulting uncompensated wageelasticities of hours of work are
McCallum, Bennett T, [1989], Monetary Economics: Theoryand Policy, New York: shownto be very similar to those reported by other researchers for
Macmillan. See especially Chapter 9, “Inflation and Unemployment: Alternative men.”
Theories,” pp. 174-200, ALICE NAKAMURA, MASAO NAKAMURA, and DALLAS CULLEN (1979. p. 787}
Sargent, Thomas J. [1987], Macroeconomic Theory, Second Editivn, Bostun: Aca-
demic Press, See especially Chapter 16, “The Phillips Curve.” pp. 438-446.
Tauchen, George, ed. [1990}, Special Issue on “Sabving Nontinear Rational Expecta- “High taxes, sometimes bydiminishing the consumptionaf the
tions Models,” Journal of Business and EconomicStatistics, 8:1, January. 1-52. taxed commodities, and sometimes by encouraging smuggling.
Acollection of eleven articles introducing and comparing alternative computa- frequently afford a smaller revenueto government than what might
tional algorithmsfor solving nonlinear rational expectations models. be drawnfrom more moderate taxes.”
Wallis, Kenneth F. [1973], Tupics itt Applied Econometrics, London: Gi ADAM SMITH (4776, BookV. p. 835)
lishing, Ltd. See especially Chapter 4, “Simultaneous Equation §
127.
_ reasonableestimates ofan aggregatelabor supply elasticity and
ofan overall marginal labor tax rateare both low enough to suggest
that broad-based cuts in labor tax rates would not increase
[government] reventa
DION FULLERTON(4982. p. 20)
593
$94 Whether and How Much Women Wark for Pay Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay $9

Manycontemporary public policy debates involve issues concerning the aggregate LFPR has beenrelatively stable, decliningslightly from araund 96%
supply oflabor. For example, controversies surrounding welfare payments, or 97% in 1949 to about 94% in 1984,
socialsecurity, and the income tax systemoften focus on incentives for work, Thedecline in the overall LFPR of males since World War I is due
Even macroeconomic analyses of unemployment and wage rigidity often primarily to decreases in the LFPR ofthose in the 55-64 and 65 and over age
taise microeconomic issues concerning choices between leisure and labor groups. While the sharp drop in the LFPR ofmales who are 65 years ofage
supply. and over from 47% in 1949 to 16.1% in 1984 might not be surprising, given
Thenotion oflabor supply, however, encompasses several dimensions: growth in earned benefits available from private pension and U.S.social secu-
the size and demographic composition of the population, the proportion of city programs,there has also been a substantial decrease in the LFPR of males
the working-age population that is working for pay or seeking such work in thetraditional preretirement years ofages 55-64; in 1949, for example, this
(called the laborforce parti ion rate, LFPR), the numberof hours worked LFPR was 87.5%, while by 1984 i1 had fallen 18.9 percentage points to
per week or per year, and the quality of labor. In this chapter we focus on 68.6%?
factors that affect the decisions of household members, particularly women, Econometric research on labor supply has 2 tong history. Much ofthis
on whetherto work for pay and,if so, for how many hours. The econometric cesearch has been policy oriented, attempting to measure the eflects on labor
tools that we employincludevarious limited and censored dependent variable supply of changesin transfer programs ortheeffecis on tax revenues and labor
procedures. supply of changes in incometax rates. Although the ordinaryJeast squares
In the United States since World WarI] the agggregate LFPR was fairly estimatorwasused in much early econometric research, several factors caused
stable to 1968 and then trended upward. In (948, for example, the aggregate econometricians to worry about biases resulting from the use of OLS. For
LFPR was 58.8%, in 1968 it was 59.6%, but in 1988 it stood at 65.9%. This example, the domain of the dependentvariable in many regressions—hours
trending pattern in the aggregate LFPR, however, masks two dramatic and worked—is censored; observed hours worked are never negative, and in many
almostoffsetting drifts, those of males and those offemales, For example, in samples the numberof hours worked is zero for a large numberofindividuals.
1948, 1968, and 1988 the LFPR rate for females increased from 32.7%to Further, labor supply data are often truncated in that data on wages are typ-
41.6% to 56.1%, while that for males decreased from 86.6% to 80.1% to ically unobserved for individuals who are not working.’ Finally, for those
76.2%." working individuals for whom the wageis observed, issues emerge concerning
Labormarket analysts have offered numerous exptanations for growth the simultaneity of wages and hours worked.
in the female LFPR.’ Although increases in male real wages and male real To deal with limited dependent variable, sample selectivity, censored
incomes since World War II have provided opportunities for married women and truncated data, and otherstatisticalissues that arise in the empirical anat-
10 reduce their commitment to the labor force (an income effectJ, this nega- ysis of labor supply, within thelast two decades, econometricians have devel-
tive effect has apparently been more than offset by improvements in the real oped and implemented a hostofsophisticated econometric techniques.In this
wages offered women (both incomeandsubstitution effects) and by increased chapter we examineseveral of the more common limited dependent variable
availability of daycare services for children, as well as by the enhanced estimators, focusing on the analysis of labor supply, particularly the labor
employmentpossibilities that are available to women. Moreover, the greater force decisions of women.
educational attainment of females not only has resulted in improved real Webegin in Section 11.1 with definitions of variables and 2 briefdis-
‘wages (see Chapter 5), but may also have changed women's preferences cussion of common data sources. Then in Section 11.2 we review the ect
toward obtaining meaningful work outside the home. These factors, plus nomic theory oflabor force participation and labor supply. Here we examine
widespread growth in the availability ofbirth control, have undoubtedly con- individual and household labor supply decision making, summarize the
\ibuted to the substantial decline in birth rates since World War ll, a phe- effects on labor supply of changes in aggregate demand, briefly discuss the
nomenon that has greatly facilitated increased femate labor force participa- allocation of time over thelife cycle, and note implications for labor supply
tion. Finally, rising productivity in the household due to labor-saving ofthe fixed costs of employment.
technological progress (such as freezers, microwave ovens, self-defrosting In Section 11.3 we consider econometric issues and representative
refrigerators, and automatic dishwashers)hasalso contributed to encouraging empirical findings, using the paradigm of Mark R. Killingsworth [1983] that
women to engage in part- and full-time employment in the labor market, distinguishes first- and second-generation studies of labor supply. We then
Theexplanations underlying the gradual decline in the LFPR of males assess the sensitivity of empirical results to alternative econometric proce-
are somewhatdifferent from those explaining the increased female LFPR and duresthatrely on differingstatistical and economic assumptions; this discus-
are highlighted when onedisaggregates the male population by age. For male sion is drawn in large part from Thomas A, Mroz [1987]. We conclude this
teenagers there has been little if any change in the LFPR from World War Il section with an overview ofissues in dynamic labor supply.
to the present, and for prime-aged males (those in the 25~54 age group) the Finally, in the hands on portion ofthis chapter we enable you to obtain
596 Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay 11.1 Definitions and Common Data Sources 597

first-hand experience with implementing empirically 4 variety of estimation force, and many in fact participate on a part-time or part-year basis. Separate
techniques,including the OLS, instrumental variable, logit, probit, Tobit, and data are kept on the civilian and total laborforces; the latter adds resident
generalized Tobit (Heckit) procedures. This is accomplished by engaging you military personnelto thecivilian labor force. For our purposesin this chapter
in a numberofexercises, each of which uses a portion of Mroz'soriginal 1976 the focus of the economic theory and econometric analyses of labor supply
Panel Swdy of Income Dynamicsdata set. will be confinedto the civilian portion of the laborforce.”
The employed are defined as those individuals who worked one hour or
more for wages orsalary during the reference week or did 15 hours or more
of unpaid work in a family business or farm. Individuals who were absent
DEFINITIONS AND COMMONDATA SOURCES
from work because ofvacation,illness, inclement weather,or strikes and lock-
The supply oflaboris typically defined as the amount of effort offered by a outs are also counted as employed but are included in the separate subcate-
population ofa givensize. In turn, this amount is conveniently decomposed gory “with a job but not at work.” The wnemployed are those who are on
into four factors: (1) the percentage of the population engaged in or seeking layoff from a job, who have nojob but have looked for work during the pre-
gainful employment, usually called the labor force participation rate; (2) the ceding four weeks and were available for work during the reference week, or
number of hours people are willing to work per day, per week, or per year who are waiting to report to 4 new job within the next 30 days.
while they are in the labor force;(3) the amountof effort that people put forth On thebasis of questions asked by the interviewer the labor force status
per hour or day while at work; and (4) the level of training and skills that of eachcivilian aged 16 or overis determined in an ati-or-nothing manner. A
workers bring to their jobs. In this chapter we focus attention primarily on person is either in or out ofthe laborforce; bydefinition, one cannot be partly
components 1 and 2 of labor supply and emphasize the lahor supply of in the labor force and partly out. Thustheentire civilian noninstitutionalized
women.’ Not much is known yet concerning component 3;° some aspects of population P is decomposed into employed, £, unemployed, L/N, and out of
component4 are discussed in Chapter 5 of this book. the labor force. O, where
In practice, researchers have used a wide variety of measures of labor
Pok+ UN+0 CLL)
supply; a survey by Glen Cain and Harold Watts {1973a, Table 9.3], for
example,identified [8 distinct measures of labor supply. li is therefore imper- The laborforce LFis limited to those who are employed or unemployed,
ative that we devote some attention to measurementissues.’
Statistics on labor force participation rates (LFPR) and numberof hours LFoE + UN (1.2)
supplied are gathered by a number ofprivate and governmental organiza- while the labor force participation rate, in percentages, is measuredas
tions. In terms of LFPR in the United States, official data on mortthly labor
force, employment, and unemploymentstatistics are typically announced by LFPR = 100 (LF/P) (1.3)
the Bureau of LaborStatistics on thefirst Friday of each month and are drawn
The unemployment rate UR, also measured in percentages, is
from the Current Population Survey.” This survey is based on interviews con-
ducted by an employee of the U.S. Bureau of the Census during the week UR & 100 (UN/LF) (1.4)
following the twelfth day of the previous month—called the reference week.
The sampleconsists of people in about 60,000 households in over 700 sepi An importantfocusofthis chapteris the LFPR of women. Asis seen in
rate geographic areas. Households are chosen to reflect the principal charac Table 11.1, this LFPR varies considerably by age and has increased dramat-
teristics of the population (e.g., age, gender, race, ethnicity, and marital sta- ically over timeforall age groups. In 1988, for example, the LFPR for women
tus), as taken from the most recent decennial census. The same household is aged 25-34 was 72.7%, more than twice the 34.9% of 33 years earlier. Sharp
included in the survey for four consecutive months, is removed from the sur- increases in the LFPR of women aged 20-24 and 35~44 also occurred atter
vey for eight months, and thenis included again for a final four consecutive 1955 (especially after 1965), while the LFPR of women aged 45~54 increased
months, more than 50% from 43.8% in 1955 10 69.0% in 1988.
As currently defined in the United States, the /abor forceis limited to In terms of hours oflabor supplied, in practice most empirical labor
those individuals 16 years of age and older who are notinstitutionalized in economists use hours of employment as a measure of hours supplied. How-
prisons, mentalinstitutions, and the like and who either are employed, are ever,this employment measure might notreflect the number of hours an indi-
searchingfor gainful employment, or are unemployed. Any labor supplied by vidualis willing to supply at a given wagerate. This raises severalissues. Many
individuals under age 16 is ignored, presumably because such an amount is employers specify standard weekly hours of work equa) to, say, 35, 37.5, or
small. Note that students aged 16 or over are counted as being in the labor 40 hours per weck, but to someextent, employces can choose among employ-
598 Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay 11.2 Economic Theory of Labor Force Participation $99

Table 11.4 U.S. Female LaborForce vided by business firms and establishments for all manufacturing firms are
Participation, 1955-4985, collected by the U.S. Census Bureau once every five or six years (Censusof
Women Aged 20-54 Manufactures), while a smalier sample of manufacturing firms is surveyed
Year 20-24 25-34 35-44 45-54 each year (Annual Survey ofManufactures)."' Data from a samipte of all firms
and establishments, including those in nonmanufacturing sectors, are gath-
1955 45.9 34.9 4t6 43.8
ered on a monthly basis and are published in summary form by the Bureau
1960 46.1 36.0 43.4 49.8
of LaborStatistics (the Employment and Earnings Surveys). Although labor
1965 49.9 38.5 46.1 50.9
economists have long advocated that the government match data from its
1970 «$7.7 45.0 Sul 54.4 household surveys with those from establishments, such data have not yet
1975 64.1 54.6 55.8 54.6 been developed, in part because ofissues of confidentiality and budgetary
1980 69.0 65.4 65,8 59.9 considerations.”
1985 1B 9 TB 64.4
A numberof nongovernmentalinstitutions produce data on individual
i983 7: 72.7 75.2 69.0
and household labor supply. Two that are ofparticular importance to empir-
Susaver Reproduced from Duniel $. Hamermesh and Albert ical labor economists are the Center for Human Resource Research at Ohio
Rees, The Ecurumas of Work und fay. Fourth Edition, New
York: Harper & Raw, 1988, Table 1,2, (948 dats are from the State University, which conducts National Longitudina! Surveys (NLS), often
January 1989 issue of US. Hureau of Labor Statistics, Zenploy=
‘mend anut Earnings called the Parnes data, and the Survey Research Center at the University of
Michigan, which provides data from its Survey of Working Conditions. Qual-
ity of Employment Survey, and the Panel Study of Income Dynamics
ers with differing standard workweeks. Employers also vary in terms of pos {PSID).” The NLS andthe PSID have becomeincreasingly useful to empir-
sibilities for part-time and overtime work. Furthermore,firms with the same ical researchers, owing in part to the fact that both generate panet data, that
40-hourstandard workweek often offer different yearly hours of work because is, they interview the same households yearafter year. Moreover, in the PSID,
ofvarying layoff, vacation, and holiday policies. Finally, occupational choice attempts are madeto distinguish desired hours oflabor supply from hours at
has a working-hours dimension. The weekly or yearly hours of work maydif work.
fer if one chooses to becomean elementary school teacher rather than a real- Although labor force participation and hours of labor supply are the
tor, an assembly line worker rather than a funeral director, or a New York principalfocus ofthis chapter, other variables are also typically used in empir-
City lawyer rather than a small-town one. Hence, although there are con- ical studies explaining labor supply. Such variables include the wage rate,
straints, employees canstill exercise a substantial choice over hourg at work. measures of experience, the educational attainment of the individual, and
ft is also useful to distinguish hours at work from hours paid. Since nonlabor (often called property) income. Measurement ofthese variables
World War il in the United States, the wedge between hours at work and introduces additional problems of accuracy andinterpretation. For a discus-
hours paid has increased, owing to the growing importance of paid holidays, sion of measurement issues for the wage and education variables, see Section
paid vacations, and other paid leaves. The U.S. Chamber of Commerce has 5.2.A of Chapter 5 in this book; the measurement of property income and
estimated, for example, that paid time not at work as a percent of total wage other variables in the context oflabor supply is discussed by, amongothers,
and salary costs increased from 5.9% in 1955 to 7.3%, 9.4% and 10.3% in MarkKillingsworth (1983, pp. 87-100}.
1965, 1975, and 1985, respectively." In this chapter, unless otherwise speci- {t is important that difficulties in the measurement of labor supply and
fied, the measure oflabor supply used refers to hours at work, not hours puid. its determinants be borne in mind when working through the economic the-
One important measurementissue concerns the source of the hours at ory and econometric analyses surveyed in this chapter. As we shall sec, mea-
work data. The monthiy Current Population Survey asks the respondent to surementissues turn out to be very important.
list not only his or her hours at work during the reference week, but also the
hours ofworkfor all other adult household members. Inability to recall one’s
own hours the previous week or those of other household members canresult THE ECONOMIC THEORY OF LABOR FORCE
in serious measurement error. Moreover, the self-employed and many sala- PARTICIPATION AND LABOR SUPPLY
ried workers might not accurately recoltect when they were working and when
they were not. Measures of hours at work are thereforelikely to includeerrors, We now briefly review the economic theory underlying labor supply. We
Analternative governmental source of data on hours at work is based begin by examining the individuat’s participation decision and the hours sup-
‘on surveysoffirms and establishments rather than of households. Data pro- plied by the individual, given that participation. This framework is then
600 Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay 11.2 Economic Theory of Labor Force Pat

extended to encompass the household rather than the individual as a decision Goods
unit. Hypotheses concerningthe effects of demandshifts, knownas the added 6c
and discouraged worker hypotheses, are addressed. A more general treatment
ofthe allocation of time, both static and over thelife cycle, is presented, fol-
lowed bya discussion of implicationsoffixed costs of employment, By neces-
sity this review of the economic theory underlying labor supplyis brief; more
thorough anddetailed analyses are found in the labor economics textbooks
listed underthe heading Further Readings at the end of this chapter, and espe-
hy
cially in Mark Killingsworth [1983, Chapters 2, 5 and 6).
Slope = ~ P/F,
41.2.A Individual Labor Supply
‘The neoclassical model of the supply oflaboris in essence an application of
the theory of consumer behavior. The individual is assumed to allocate time
to market work and to nonmarketable activities; the latterare typically called,
erroneously, “leisure.” Utility is maximized by choosing combinations of
goods andleisure hours subject to time, price, and income constraints.’
More specifically, let the individual's preferences be represented by a
twice differentiable utility function / = U(G. L), indicating the utility (UV)
obtained from consuming alternative quantities of goods (G) andleisure (L).
{Note: Hereafter, U refers toutility, not to the unemployed; further, L islei
sure, not labor.) The marginalutilities of G and of L (AfU, = 8U/aG and
MU, = aUsaL) are both assumed to be positive, and the utility function is
concave in G and L, implying that 2U/8G", PU/IL? < 0, and eUs8GAL > HoursofLeisure L—
0. Figure 14.4 indiflerence Curves and the Budget Constraint
Along an individual's indifference curve, alternative combinations of L
and G generate the samelevelof satisfaction. In Fig. 11.1, four indifference Since indifference curves that are farther away from the origin represent
curves are drawn, Jy, /,, 42, and J;, each corresponding with successively successively higher levels of utility, the utility-maximizing individual will
greaterlevels of U. choose the highest possible indifference curve. given his or her budget
‘Two important properties ofthe indifference curve are its slope andits constraint.
shape. Theslope is derived as follows. The total differential oftheutility func- Three factors affect the budget constraint—prices. nonlabor income,
tion UG, £)is and time. First, Ict the unit price of goods be P,, and let the exogenous and
(@U/AG)dG + (@U/AL)dL = dU (15) constant wage rate be P,; thus the individual's real wage is P,/P,. Second, tet
the individual's nonlabor or property income be denoted as ¥: in terms of
Along given indifference curve, dU’ = 0. Substituting dU= 0 into Eq. (11.5) consumption goods the real amount of nonlabor income is V//P,. Third,
and rearrangingyield the slope ofindifference curves in Fig. 11,1, dG/dL, also because only a finite number of hours 7 are available in any time period,
knownasthe negative of the marginalrate of substitution ofleisure for con- leisure (nonmarket) hours £ plus hours devoted to market work H must
sumergoods and denoted here as — MRSz6. exhaust 7. that is, L + H = T. Further, labor income equals the product
PH, and thereal labor income forgone by choosing one more unitof leisure
Oe rs, (116) instead of working equals P,/P..
If it is further assumed thatthe individual spends all of his or her avail-
Since by assumption, A/U, and MU,are both positive, indifference curves able income, the above three factors imply the budget constraint
slope downward. Further, concavity implies that indifference curves are con-
vex to the origin. Hence, although it is possible to substitute £ for G and hold YoPH+V = P(T-L)+¥ = PG (1.7)
utility fixed, the greater the ratio of L to G, the greater the marginal amount where ¥, total money income,is the sum oflabor and nonlabor income. —
of L required to compensate for giving up a marginal amountof G. Equation (11.7) is often rewritten in two ways. To emphasize the notion
11.2 Economic Theoryof Labor Foree Participation 603
602) Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay

individual would earn were he or she to work in the markel was ?;, which is
that an individual's “full income” F is spent on goods and leisure, Gary
Becker [1965] has added P,L to both sides of Eq. (11.7), obtaining tower than P,. Further, let the individual have the same aonlabor income 7
and preferencesas before. In such a case the budget constraint facing the indi-
FoY¥t+PbsPiG+PLorhT+ ¥ (11.8) vidual would be PuG = Pi(T — L) + V, which is drawn in Fig. 11.1 as the
Hatter budget line 8” 8. Now the highest indifference curve the individual
In this formulation the full income budget constraint consists ofthe total could attain, given his or her preferences and the budget constraint 8” B. is
amountoftime available, T. evaluated at the constant wagerate P,. plus non-
1,. Al point # the indifference curve /, touches the budget line B’#, where L
labor income F. This full incomeF is then totally expended onleisure (PL) = Tand H = 0, that is, at the point at which the individualis « nonpartici-
and on goods (PG). in the laborforce, spendingall of his or hertimein leisure (nonmarket
Alternatively, to facilitate graphical analysis, one can rewrite Eq. (11.7) ies). Anyhigher indifference curveis simply unattainable toindividuals
in termsofreal income, with such preferences and budget constraints.
tee *| ra Points such as B represent a corner solution to the individual’s utility
G -T+—|- Tek (19) maximization problem, rather than an interior solution. Note in particular
Py Py Py
that at the corner solution 8, instead of Eq. (11.11) holding, whereMRS,, =
When Eg.(11.9) is graphed as in Fig. #1.1, the budget line embodying the p./P,, the slope of the indifference curveis steeper than that of the budget
incomeconstraint is line 8’B, with intercept equal to ((P,/P.) - T + ¥/Pe) line, implying that MRS, > P,/P.. This suggests thatthe labor force partic.
and slope cqual to —(P,/P,). Note that even if L = T (when all time is ipation decision can be simply envisaged as corresponding to whether the
devoted to feisure and none to market work), the budget line 8°8 docs not individual'sutility maximization problem, given budget constraints, yields a
cross the horizontal axis unless nonlabor income¥is zero. corner solution or an interior solution. Specifically, if at the solution point,
Maximization of utility subject to the budget constraint Eq. (11.9) MRS, P,{P,, then H > Qand L < T—aninterior solution occurs; but
involves choosing the set of G and L thatis feasible (on the budget linc) and if instead at the solution point, AARS,., > P./P,, then H 2 Qand L = T—
on the highest indifference curve that touches the budget line 2’8. In acornersolution obtains.
Fig. 11.1, such a point is at P, where the slope of the indifference curve An important concept underlying the labor force participation decision
4, (—MRS,,) equals the slope of the budget line — P,/P,. At this point the is the notion ofthe reservation wage. At point # the slope ofthe indifference
individual purchases goods OG’. chooses leisure OH’, and supplies hours of curve /,, ~MRS;,; indicates how much exira earnings the individual would
labor #7’T to the market. require to be induced to give up one unit ofleisure, when he or she is not
More formally, the individual solves his or her maximizatioa problem working at all, This amount of extra earnings is called the reser lion wage.
by maximizing U = U(G, L) subject to the budget constraint 2,G = P, which we denote as »*.' Note that as drawn in Fig. 11.1 budget line
(f — L) + ¥. This is done by setting up the Lagrangian function, B’B,thereservation wage ¥* is greater than the market wage P,. that is, the
W = UG. L)— MPG — PAT -— Ly - 14 (1.10) extra satisfaction from an hourof leisureis greater than the wage rate. How-
ever, if the wage rate rose so that the budgetfine rotated upward from B°B
takingfirst partial derivatives of W with respect to G and L,setting them equal to BB, then at some point the wage rate would exceed the reservation wage,
to zero, and then solving. This yields resulting in a positive labor force supply. Hence the condition for positive
PB labor force participation is simply that P, > w*.
aval _ MU: = MRSiy = R aL Several important implications of this economic theory of labor force
aujaG MU, participation are worth noting. First, for individuals with identical reservation
Notice that according to Eq. (11.11), at the point at whichutility is maxi- wages those with higher (potential) wage rates are more likely to be in the
mized, the AfRS,,; (the negative of which. by Eq. (11.6). equals the slope of laborfarce. Second, for individuals with identical potential wage rates those
with lower reservation wages are more likely to be the labor force. Since
lhe indifference curve) is equal to the real wage rate P,/P,; (the negative of
which, by Eq, (11.9), equals the slope of the budget line 8’B). “workaholics” have lower reservation wages than, say, avid hobbyists, given
The way in which Fig. 11.1 has been drawn allows the individual to identical potential wage rates, workaholics are morclikely to be in the labor
maximizehis or herutility at an interior solution point P where L << T and force. Similarly, womenwith very young children at home and with onlyvery
#H > 0, that is, where the individual participates in the laborforce with non- expensive daycare possibilities are likely to have higher reservation wages than
zero H. This need notbe thecase and in fact is critical to understanding the single, career-oriented women with no children; other things being equal, we
laborforce participation decision. To see this, assume that the wagerate the would expect the fatter to have higher laborforce participation rates. Note
604° Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay 11.2 Economic Theoryof Labor Force Participation 605

that such differences in preferences among individuals are reflected in the


shape andslope oftheir indiflerence curves. Moreover,for a given individual
the shape ofthe indifference curve may change at variouspoints during his
orherlife cycle.
Thetheoretical framework presented above can be generalized lo cases
in which only several options for hours at work are available to employees,
for example, one could only work zero, 20, or 40 hours per week. In such
situations the optimal cornersolution is the largest amountof hours of work
for which the market wageis greater than or equalto the reservation wage.
We now consider the effects on labor supply of changes in nonlabor
incomeandin the wage rate. Suppose that the nonlabor incomeofthe indi-
vidual increased from TB to TC in Fig. 11.1 but that the wage rate remained.
constantat P,. This results in a new budgetline C’C parallelto the old budget
line B’B. Relative to the initial equilibrium at P, the increase in nonlabor
income now permits the utility-maximizing individual to move to a higher
indifference curve, 7,, tangent to the new budget line C’C at point P’, where
the hours ofleisure consumed increases to OH”, the amountoflabor supplied
decreases 10 H” 7, and the amount of goods consumed increases to OG". This
outward movement from P to P’reflects a pure income effect in which Z and
G both increase in response to the increase in nonlabor income. Note, how-
ever, that the pure incomeeffect on hours oflabor supplied is negative, reflect-
ing the implicit assumption here thatleisure is a normal good.
Matters are not quite as simple when the individual experiences a HoursofLeisure £ ~ —~
change in the wage rate, since the response reflects both income and substi-
ttion effects. To see this, consider Fig. 11.2. Let the initial equilibrium be at Figure 44.2 Income andSubstitution Effects in Response to
a Changein the Wage Rate
point P, where the /y indifference curve is tangent 10 the origina! budgetfine
B’B, sesulting in OG units of goods and O# hours ofleisure cortsumed and
HT hours oflabor supplied. NowIct the wage rate increase while goodsprices, Asis shownin Fig. | !.2, the movementfrom P to P” is the compensated
preferences, and nonlabor income remain unchanged. The increase in the substitution effect: it results in reduced leisure OH” and increased labor sup-
wage rate results in an upwardly rotated new budget line 8” 8, tangent to the ply "7, reflecting the fact that leisure has become more expensive as the
higher indifference curve /, at point P’. At this new equilibrium the ntility- wage rate has increased. Once this compensated substitution effect has been
maxitaizing individual increases goods consumed from OG to OG’, decreases isolated, the pure incomeeffect(with no prices changing)is the residual move-
the amountof leisure chosen from OH to OH", and increases hours oflabor ment from P" to P’, with leisure increasing from OH” to OH" andlabor sup-
supplied to the market from HT to H‘T. plied to the market falling from H’T to H’T. Incidentally, although the
It is useful to decompose the movement from P to /” into pure income nomenclature can be confusing,it is worth noting that in muchofthelitera-
and compensated substitution effects. The compensated substitution effect is ture the total movement from P to P’ in response to an increase in the wage
defined as the response ofthe individual to a change in the wagerate holding tate is called the uncompensated or gross substitution effect. Hence the
utilityfixed. Hence the compensated substitution effect involves a movement uncompensated or gross substitution effect is the sum of the compensated
along the origina! indifference curve Jy. To show this graphically, let us substitution effect and the pure income effect.
notionally decrease the individual's nonlabor income by imposing a tax onit An important implication of the above graphical analysis is that in
such that the new notional budget line D’D has the same slope as the new response to an increase in the wage rate, the utility-maximizing individual
budget line 8” B (reflecting the higher wage rate) but is just tangent to the respondsin two different ways: The uncompensated substitution effect results
original indifference curve /, at point P”. Note that in termsof utility this in more labor supply andless leisure, while the pure incomeeffect results in
notional budget line D’D just offsets or compensates for the improvement in less labor supply and more leisure. Figure 11.2 has been drawn in such a way
earning powerthat results from the increased wagerate. that the positive compensated substitution effect on labor supply dominates
606 Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay 11.2 Economic Theoryof Labor Force Participation 607

the negative pure incomeeffect, but this need not be the case. Had we drawn 14.2.8 Household Labor Supply
the indifference curves with different shapes (but still downward sloping and
convex to the origin}, we could have obtained a new equitibrium in which the Thetheoretical framework just presented envisages an individual as making
pure incomeeffect dominated the compensated substitution effect. [t is there- labor supply decisions in isolation. in fact, however, the labor supply decision
fore important to note that even whenleisure is a normal good, on the basis is typically made in the context of decisions taken by other members of the
of economic theory, one cannot determinea priori whether an increase in the household or family within which the individual resides. Kittingsworth (1983,
wage rate, ceteris paribus, results in increased or reduced hours oflabor sup- Chapter 2] distinguishes three approaches that link family membership to
labor supply.
Dlied; this depends on the relative magnitudes of the compensated substitu-
tion and pure income effects, which in turn are empirical, not theoretical In the “male chauvinist” modelit is assumed that, when making her
issues. In termsoftraditionallabor supply curves, therefore, one needs empir- labor supply decisions, the wife views her husband's earnings as a form of
ical evidence to determine whether the labor supply curve is upward sloping Property or nonlabor income, whereas the husband decides on his labor sup-
or backward bending, ply solety on the basis of his own wage and the family's actual nonlabor
Two further remarks are worth noting. First, the above analysis of income,without reference to his wife's labor supply decisions."’ The only dif:
incomeandsubstitution effects has assumed thatinterior solutions occur both ference in this model compared to that considered in Section 11.2.4 is that
before and after the wage rate increase, thatis, it is conditional on positive in the male chauvinist framework the property income V relevant to the
labor force participation. Although it is not demonstrated here, it can be wife's labor supply decision is assumed to include the husband’slabor income
shownthat if the original solution was a corner one with no participation, as well as all nonlabor income,"
then a sufficiently large wageincrease, ceteriy paribus, could result in positive A second approach assumes the existence of a family or household
labor force participation, as could a reduction in nenlabor income, ceteris aggregate utility function U = U(G, £,, L,,..., £,), where £,is the leisure
paribus, Hence participation decisions can also be assessed in terms of income consumed bythe ith individual in the family. This family utility function is
and substitutioneffects. maximized subject to a family budget constraint."
Second, following the traditional theory of consumer demand as, for The family utility approach has becomea familiar one in labor supply
example, in R. G. D. Alien [1938] and Angus Deaton and John M. Muell- analyses, owing in part to the fact that many of the well-known comparative
bauer [1980], one can write the gross, compensated substitution and pure statics results of the individual utility maximization framework carry over
incomeeffects of a wage rate change in termsof the calculus and in elasticity with lite adaptation. An important generalization that is afforded by the
form. In particular, this results in the well-known Slutsky equation, family utility function approach is that there now are four substitutioneffects.
In particular, not only do both family members have own-substitution effects
aH
oa) aH au (the response of the ith family member's labor supply to a change in his or
BPlam” ae
aPleew * of
ay L
(142) her own wagerate), but two cross-substitution effects also occur, involving the
ith family member's labor supply response to a change in the wagerate of the
where Yis money income. Thefirst term on theright-handside of Eq. (1 1.12) jth family memberand vice versa.
is the compensated substitution effect with utitity held constant, and the sec- Because of the assumed existence of an aggregate family utility function,
ond term is the pure incomeeffect. If one multiplies the entire expression in the compensated cross-substitution effect of a change in the ith individual's
Eq. (11.1) by P,/f/ and then multiplies and divides the incomeeffect by Y, ‘wagerate on the jth member's iabor supply must equal the effect of the jth
oneobtains a Slutsky relation in elasticity form. member's wage rate on the ith member's labor supply. Further, although
these compensated cross-substitution effects must be equal in magnitude,
oH P, oH P, Hoon ¥
So aS + ses 11.13; their signs can beeither positive (indicating substitutability) or negative {com-
OP, Hi yon OP, Hlynt Y or a » plementarity). However, because the pure income effects on the two family
which in turn can be rewritten as members need not be identical, the gross (uncompensated) cross-substitution
effects are not necessarily equal. Hence the gross effect of a change in the
in, = Cue + 5° tee (14) wife's wage rate on the husband's labor supply need not equal the grosseffect
of a changein the husband’s wagerate on the wife’s labor supply.
where 5S;is the share of labor in total money income and where the g and ¢ A special case of the family utility function framework, considered in
superscripts on the substitution elasticities refer to gross and compensated detail by Malcolm S. Cohen, Samuel A. Rea, and Robert I. Lerman [1970]
changes, respectively.’* and by Orley Ashenfelter and James J. Heckman (1974), occurs when the
608 Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay 11.2 Economic Theory of Labor Furee Pas

compensated cross-substitution effects equa! zero forall family members. In 41.2.C Effects on Labor Supply of Changesin
this instance a change in the ith member's wage rate imparts only a pure Aggregate Demand
income effect on the labor supply of the jth individual. This implies that the
labor supply function of the jth family member depends only on his or ber ‘Therelative importanceof incomeandsubstitution effects hasalso played an
wage rate and on the sum ofall other family members’ labor incomes plus important role in assessing the effects on labor supply ofcyclical changes in
family nonlabor income. aggregate demand. Here the important issue concerns the net impact on
Becauseofits analytical simplicity, the family utility function approach LFPR ofchanges in aggregate demand,for example, of recessions or booms.
is common in empirical labor supply studies. It is worth noting, however, that In the 1930s an hypothesis emerged that when the usual breadwinner became
this framework has a number of drawbacks. Because the aggregate utility unemployed, additional members of the household enter the labor force in
function implies that the family derives utility from consumption as a whole, order to maintain the family’s income,the implication being that labor force
the distribution ofgoods consumption does not matter; while this might make Participation rates would rise along with unemployment. This wascalled the
sense for family “public goods” such as heat andlight, it is obviously ques- added-worker hypothesis.” A counter view, known as the discouraged-worker
tionable for “private goods” such as food, clothing, and entertainment. More- Aypothesis, holds that when unemploymentincreases, searching for employ-
over, the family utility function approachis silent concerning the process that ment becomesso disheartening that some of the unemployed give up and
actually generates an aggregate utility function that is mutually agreeable to withdraw from the labor force, while others who would ordinarily enter the
all family members. laborforce choose not to do so.
Owing in part to such considerations, a variety of alternative frame- These two hypotheses have very different implications for the measure-
works have been developed thattreat labor supply within a householdsetting, ment and interpretation of the aggregate unemployment rate. According to
yet emphasize the individual behavior of family members. Jane Leuthold the added-worker hypothesis, the labor force is above the long-term trend dur-
[1968], for example, has presented a model in which individuals’ reactions to ing recessions. implying that the unemploymentrate is overestimated in the
other family members’ labor supplies and wage rates are analogous to the sense that creating one new job might reduce the number of unemployed by
Cournot or Stackelberg reaction curves of duopolists or oligopolists. As in two people. Onthe other hand, accordingto the discouraged-worker hypoth-
modern game theory, such a framework requires stringent assumptions to esis, the size of the aggregate laborforce varies in the same direction as aggre-
ensure the existence and stability of a unique equilibrium.” gate demandrather than in the opposite direction. Since unemploymentis
Bargaining models of family members’ behavi fe another example of measured as the number of people who report themselves as secking work.
recent developments in “family economics” emph: 2 the individual util- the discouraged-worker hypothesis suggests that unemployment is underesti-
ities approach. As formulated by, among others, Marilyn E. Manger and Mur- mated, since one should add to those enumerated as unemployed another
ray Brown (1979, 1980] and Marjorie B. McElroy and Mary Jean Horney group, the hidden unemployed, who would be searching for employment
[1981], family members arrive at decisions about labor supply and consump- were the search notas likely to befruitless. Which of these two hypothesesis
lion spending through a complex process of bargaining. Without stringent most valid has been viewed as having important poticy implications, since the
assumptions, such models seldom generate closed form solutions that are theories can differ sharply in implying whether increases in the measured
amenable to empirical implementation, As with the aggregate utility function unemployment rate might warrant expansionary or contractionary mucro-
approach, in these bargaining models, the total effects of changes in, say, the economic policy responses.
husband's wage on the wife’s labor supply need not equal the total effects of In terms of economic theory the added-worker hypothesis essentially
changesin the wife’s wage on the husband's labor supply.” However, unlike invoives a houschold incomeeffect. since it implies that the reduction in
y utility function framework,in the bargaining models, both thelevel aggregate demand lowers the income of those family members whoare in the
n of consumption among household members can affect the labor force (those who lose their jobs or are put on shorter workweeks),
labor supply of each member. Unfortunately, these bargaining models have thereby reducing the nonlabor income available to family members who are
not, as yet, generated any discriminating testable restrictions. not currently in the labor force. Given this reduction in nonlabor income,
Manitalstatus is clearly important in the modeling of houschold labor reservation wages drop, the demand for leisure (a normal good) falls, and
supply. In this context, recent work by Gary Becker (1974, 5981, 1988] secks labor supply increases,
to endogenizejointly the marital status, consumption, and labor supply deci- In contrast, the discouraged-worker hypothesis involves a substitution
sions of individuals, but at this point, no fully empirically implementable effect for wo reasons. First, when aggregate demandforlaborfalls, real wage
model has been developed. rates will often also tend to fall, making leisure hours less expensive. Second,
610 Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay 41.2 Economic Theory of Labor Force Participation 611

the probability of successfully finding a job with a given wagefalls during a work the individual's supply oflabor hours is determined jointly with con-
recession.If one defines the expected wage from job search as the product of sumption; it no longer involves just a tabor-leisure tradeoff.
the wage rate of people who have the job and the probability of finding the More formally, a model with such time consumption costs begins with
job, then both components of the expected wage from job search may fall a utility function U = U(Z,, Z;,.... Zn). where the Z, are household activ.
‘during recessionaryperiods, thereby towering theattractiveness ofjob search ities depending on both goods and time inputs.” Households are assumed to
and reducing the opportunity costofleisure hours. combine time and market goods to produce the “basic commodities” Z,, sub-
It is of course possible that both the added-worker (income)effect and Ject to household production functions Z, ZAG,.4).i= 1 2a), where
the discouraged-worker (substitution) effect coexist; the added and discour- the G, and ¢, are goods and time inputs. Beckerspecifies that the household
aged workers might well be different groups of people. Which group tends to production function is of the fixed coefficient type,
dominate is again an empirical issue. Although rescarchers such as Jacob
Z=Gfa and Z = t/b, Lt)
Mincer[1962], Shelly Lundberg, [1985] and Olivia S. Mitchell [1980] have
obtained results suggesting a significant number of added workers, many of where the 4, and 6, are units of goods and units of time per unit ofactivity,
them married women, the added-worker impact emerges only from families respectively, Since the time and money income constraints imply that
whose normal breadwinnerloses a job, and this income effect tends to occur
for only a relatively smalt portion ofthe labor force (unemployment rates in T=D,+H and TPG =P + (LI6)
the United States seldom go above 10%). By contrast, the fall in expected real : 7
wages that occurs in recessionsaffects nearly every household. and so itis not one can rewrite the full income constraint (11.8}—the income that would be
surprising that empirical researchers have generally concluded that the dis- realized if T = H—as
couraged-worker(substitution) effect is considerably larger than the added-
worker effect2> Hence, other things being equal, the labor force tends to
shrink during recessions and grow during periods of economicrecovery.” Dd PaG, + Phe =H PP+ hak (IL ET}

When Eq. (11.15) is substituted in Eq. (11.17), one obtains the


44.2.D The Allocation of Time: A More General
Treatment expression

The theoretical framework that we havediscussed so far assumes that all time a+ PY Zb = xy Z, (11.18)
is allocatedeither to market workorte leisure. This is clearly unrdalistic, since
much nonmarket time is spent in “producing” consumable services at home,
where
using both time and goods. For example, the preparation of meals at home
consumesboth time and food; this timeis neither leisure nor market work. mos Poa, + Pb, is... mt 11.19)
fn an important paper, Gary Becker [1965] called such activities nonmarket
work, We now briefly examinefactors that affect market labor supply when Notethat 2, is the full cost of consuming or producing activity Z,, including
the choiceset ofalternative activities is expanded to also include nonmarket both the goods cosi and forgone-carnings components.
work. If one maximizes the utility function subject to the budget constraint
Becker’sessential insight was that neither time nor consumer goodsare (11.19), one obtains from thefirst-order conditions the equilibrium relation
consumed by themselves, since time is usually not enjoyed without goods, MU,
and virtually all goods require time in order to be consumed. This implies —
MU, igedc.ym
j as
miei :
(11.20)
that consumption decisions of individuals and households are made from a
menu ofalternative activities with varying amounts of both goods and time According to Eq. (11,20), the utility-maximizing individual consumes/pro-
inputs. The total price of any consumption activity is the sum ofits market duces activities and j such that the marginalrate of substitution between any
goods price plus the value of time required to produce or consume it, Other two activitics just equals the ratio oftheir full costs, including timecosts.
things being equal, increase in the wage rate raises the relative price of To see the uscfulness of this more general (ramework, considertheeffect
time-intensive activities, induces substitution against them, and thereby ofa wage increase on an individual’s marketlabor supply. The incomeeffect
mightresult in an increase in hours worked. Note that in this broader frame- will bring about an increase in the consumption ofall normal commodities;
612) Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay (2.2 Economic Theory of Labor Force Pai pation 613

if the time-intensive nonmarket commodities are normal, the income effect between children has also declined, implying that the time devoted
to child-
will cause less time to be devoted 10 market work and more to be allocated to rearing has been compressed, while that allocated to market laborsup
ply has
nonmarketactivities. In termsof substitution effects, however, note that the expanded.
wage increase will raise the cost of all commodities (assuming that each
requires a nonzero amountoftime) but will raise the relative cost of the more 14.2.E traplications of Costs of Employment
time-intensive ones. This results in a shift away from more time-intensive
toward less time-intensive nonmarket activities and toward market labor In general, it is costly to hold a job. Afeneycosts mustbe incurred by workers,
supply. to pay for transportation to work, purchase appropriate work clothing,
buy
meals away from home, and, in manycases, pay for
otherchild care services. Timecosts are also typicallybabysitti ng, daycare, or
Within the household, for example, the increased wage mightresult in
purchases of time-saving devices such as a microwave oven and a computer- incurred by workers,
since most people take timein traveling from home 10 job; further,
activated water-sprinkling system. Note that although the income and substi- children
tution effects on an individual’s labor supply are therefore essentially similar must often be transported to child care locations before the
Parent can travel
in sign to those derived in the earlier, simplercase, in this more general frame- to work. There are also nonpecuniary costs to job holding, such
as dealing
work, insights can be gained into factors aflecting the division of nonmarket withtraffic hassles or traveling through arcas where personal safety
may be at
time into more andless time-intensive activities. Further, to the extent that isk, A substantial portion of these job costs are fixed in the sense
that they
technological advances result in increasing the labor productivity of home are incurred regardless of whether one works ten utes or eight hours per
activities, such advances could be viewed as facilitating increased market day: a portion ofchild care costs, however, is variable, depending on
the
labor supply. Hence, although this more general treatment of time probably amountoftime for which child care is required. We now briefly consider
the
has principal implications for “home economics,” it also has a nontrivial effects on labor force participation and labor supply of changes in fixed
and
impact on market labor supply because of interactions among market and variable costs of employment.
nonmarket activities, John F. Cogan (1977, 1980b, 1981] has modeled the effects ofjob costs
The most important contribution ofthe more general treatment oftime on labor force participation and labor supply.** When job-holding costs
are
to understanding family labor supply behavior, however, concerns household only lime costs and are fixed, the budget constraint line of Fig. 11.1 becomes
decisions regarding family size and child-rearing. Since child-rearingis clearly kinked, with a flat, horizontal segment emanating from H = 0 to,
say,
a time-intensive process, the full costs of having children depend in part on H = h’, indicating that thefixed time costof/’ contributes nothing
to earn-
the opportunity costs of the parents’ time. Although beyondthescope ofthis ings. Asa result, eitherindividuals tend to perform no market work
at all (a
chapter, it is worth noting that a substantialliterature exists relating fertility corner solution) or they enter the labor force ata significant numberof hours
rates to, among other things, wage rates of married women and incomes of per week (a “very interior” solution); hencefixed job time costs imply
that
married men; not surprisingly, empirical evidence suggests that other things interior solutions are Jess likely to occur near the corner point where H =
0,
being equal, married women with higher earnings potentials appear to have One implication is that because ofthe fixed time costs of holding a job, much
fewerchildren and participate to a greater extent in the laborforce.» A num- of the upward-sloping portion oflabor supply curves will not be observed
in
berofstudies have also been made of howone might valuate the contribution data on hours of work.
of the nonmarket working time of married women, including that portion Coganalso showsthat ifan exogenousincrease in fixed timecosts occurs
allocated to child-rearing; on this, see, for example, Reuben Gronau [1973a. (say, an increase in traffic congestion, implying a ionger commuti
ng time),
b, c. 1977, 1986]. the individual's reservation wage 1is raised, and owing to the reduced
full
Muchrecent research in the labor supply literature has involved an even incomethatis available as a result ofthe increased fixed timecost {a down-
more general treatment oftime, analyzing the allocation oftime overthelife ward parallel shift in the budget constraint, total hours available stilt
fixed at
cycle.” Significantly, once one considers the longerlife cycle horizon, deci- T), hours of labor supplied H will decrease; provided that L is
a normal good,
sions involving education, training, hours of labor supplied at different ages, hours in £ will also decrease, compensating in part for the increased fixed
and retirement ail become interdependent and 10 a certain extent endoge- time costs of employment.
nous, What may have been exogenous or predetermined in a static context | Costs of employment are in practice very significant and are of prime
Row becomes in part endogenous. Someofthese issues are discussed briefly importance in determining the labor supply behavior of married women.
For
in Chapter5, particularly in Section §.1. For our present purposes, however, working women, Cogan [1981] estimates that in the United States in 1967,
it is worth noting that not only do married women currently appear to be average annualfixed costs as a percentage of the average annual carnings
of
having smaller families than in previous decades, but the time duration working women were 28.3%; furthermore,this figure increases considerably
614 Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay
11.3 Econometric Issues 615

with the numberof children in the household under age six and with addi-
where H is hours work time, JVis the real wage rate, V is per period real
tional years of education for the mother. Cogan also reports that for an aver- property income, ¢ is a stochastic term, and the i, j subscripts refer to differing
age woman thediscontinuity in the labor supply function from H = 0 to
houschold members. Equation (11.21) refers to the labor supply of a given
H > Ooccurs at about 1300 hours annually (more than half-time work), indi-
individual, Eq. (11.21b) to the labor supply of a given household member
cating that when the equilibrium solution changes from a cornerto an interior
allowing for nonzero intrahouschold (cross-substitution) effects on /’s labor
one, the result is a very substantial increase in the numberof hours worked.
supply, and Eq. (11.2ic) constrains these intrahousehold substitution effects
This concludes our brief overview of the theoretical issues underlying
to zero, Intercept termsin these equations are often made a function ofvar-
the lshor force participation and labor supply decisions of individuals and
ious variables such as age, gender, and race,reflecting tastes for work. Further,
households. We now move on to a moredetailed discussion of econometric
in many studies, transformations of the variables in Eqs. (11.21) are used,
issues and empiricalresults, focusing particular attention on factors thataffect
including iogarithmsand polynomials. Finally. as Killingsworth notes, ques-
female labor supply.
tions concerning the sources underlying the error term « are typicallyignored
in first-generation studies. Most ofthis research proceeds on the assumption
11.3 ECONOMETRIC ISSUES AND REPRESENTATIVE thatthe errorterm is randomlydistributed and makes nodistinction between
EMPIRICAL FINDINGS the measurement error or omitted regressors that might have generated «. As
weshall see,this last issue receives much more explicit treatment in second-
Thevast proportion of empirical studies of labor supply, beginning with the generation research.
pioneering effort of Erika Schoenberg and Paul H, Douglas [1937], has been in terms of empirical findings, most first-generation studies conclude
based on the neoclassica? analysis of choice, as outlined in the previous sec- that female labor supply is considerably more sensitive to changes in wage
tion. This empirical literature has been surveyed by, among others, Mark R. rates and property incomethan is male labor supply. Most also find thatJei-
Killingsworth [1983] and Killingsworth and James J. Heckman [1986]. For sure is a normalgood for both men and women. Another commonfindingis
our purposesit is useful to employ the paradigm developed by Killingsworth, that an income-compensated increase in one’s own wage increases one’s labor
in which studies are classified as first or second generation depending on the supply.
attention paid to econometric issues and the underlying economic theory.” Although these qualitative conclusions are roughly consistent across
studies, the quantitative estimates of the labor supplyelasticities obtained
from first-generation studies of labor supply differ very dramatically. As
11.3.A_ First Generation Studies
. Heckman, Killingsworth, and MaCurdy (1981, Table 1.1, p. 80] note, esti-
First-generation studies of labor supply are characterized by Killingsworth as mates of the compensated own-wage rate laborsupplyelasticities range widely
relying on ordinary least squares estimation of parameters in equations whose from ~0.05 to +0.96 for males and from —0.05 to +2.00 for females; gross
functional form is chosen either arbitrarily or on the basis of specific ad hoc own-wage rate labor supply elasticities vary from —0.45 to +0.55 for males
considerations; in particular, the functional forms are not derived explicitly and from ~0.!0 to + 1.60 for females, while labor supply elasticities with
from utility or indirect utility functions. Although dates are not precise, first- fespect to property income extendfrom 0 to —0.16 for males and from —-0.1
generation research began in the 1930s and continued into the early 1970s; a to —0.75 for females. Moreover. in almost ali cases the symmetry of com-
well-known first-generation study using aggregate data is by Glen Cain pensated wage effects among household members is rejected byfirst-genera-
[1966], while representative studies using microdata are found in the volume tion empirical results, and at times the estimated compensated own-wage
edited by Glen Cain and Harold Watts (1973b]. effect on laborsupply has been positive, contrary to theory. These disappoint-
Someexamples oflinear specifications that are commonly used in first- ing results (and some well-timed financial support from research funding
generation research include agencies) have fed labor researchers to examine more ctosely the theory
H=a+ bW+ Vite (11.21a)
underlying labor supply models,as well as the econometric andstatistical pro-
cedures that have been used to obtain parameterestimates.
! Three issues have received particularly close attention because of the
H,= 4,4 2 bW, + o¥ +6 (11.21) unsatisfactory first-gencration results, First, althoughfirst-generation empiri-
=
cal studies appear to have used interchangably alternative measures of labor
4
supply H such as labor force participation, hours worked per week, weeks
A, a+ bW,+e(V+ 30 WH) +6 (11.21¢) worked per year, lifetime participation, and the fraction ofa lifetime spent
pier
working, in second-generation research,distinct theoretical models have been
616 Whether and How Much Women Workfor Pay 11.3 Econometric Issues 617

constructed to consider separately the participation, hours of work per week, straints. Once oneintroduces into the model common incometax structures,
lifetime participation, and lifetime hours of work decisions. These distinct varioustypes ofincometransfer programs, fixed costs of work, or employers"
theoretical models have helped in part to reconcile persistent differences in preferences for minimum hours of work, the simplestraight-line budget con-
estimates of labor supply responses obtained by fitting the same function to straints drawn in Figs. 11.1 and 11.2 disappear and give way to complex forms
data on temporally different perspectives of labor supply. with kinks, discontinuities, gaps, and nonconvexities. Moreover, when tax
Second, empirical labor economists began focusing more attention on rates depend on thelevel of income,the after-tax wage rate becomes endog-
functional form and econometric technique. In turn, this entailed a more enous, and simultaneous equations problems can emerge. Mostfirst-genera-
explicit treatment of unobservable variables and introduced theissue of sam- tion work ignored these phenomenaaltogether,in spite ofthe fact that in the
ple selection bias. Equations such as (11.21) were now viewed more formally late 1960s and early 1970s a great deal of policy-oriented econometric
as representing the outcomeofutility maximization and in that context were rescarch focused on the labor supplyeffectsofalternative social benefit pro-
found to be woefully inadequate. Specifically, with even the simplest type of grams{such as the negative income tax), programsthat clearly implied com-
utility maximization model, the labor supply function for a single individual plex budget constraints.
can be stated as These shortcomings of first-generation studies suggested numerous
opportunities for improvement. As Heckman, Killingsworth, and MaCurdy
H=at b+ ch +¢ ifandonlyif Ww > W, (11.228) noted,
H=0 otherwise (11.226) analysis and technique go together, and first-gencration work, which
glossed over some ofthe structural aspects of labor supply decisions and
where H/, is the individual's reservation wage, derived by setting // in Eq. used empirical techniques that did not adequately address some ofthe
(11.22a) equalto zero and solving for complexities of that structure, suffered from 2 numberofserious prob-
First-generation studies ignored this distinction,typically either by fit- lems. The results ofsecond-generation work . . . suggest that solving these
ting equationssuch as Eq. {11.21a) to a random sample taken from the pop- problems makes a considerable difference for estimates oflabor supply
ulation with the labor supply of nonworkingindividuals set at zero”—here-
parameters, with correspondingly considerable implications for analysis
after called Procedure I—orby fitting the equation by OLSusing population
und policy.”
subsamples that consist only of working individuals—called Procedure II."
Procedure I (setting H for all nonworkers equal to zero) implicitly assumes 11.3.8 Second-Generation Studies
that Egs. (11-21) or Eq. (11.22a) holds for all values of W”, not just gor values We now turn to a dicussion of second-generation studies, Wefirst consider
in excess of the reservation wage, and therefore involves a model misspecifi- issues of specification and estimation, then we introducetaxes into the labor
cation,yielding inconsistent estimates of the parameters. Use of Procedure I supply model, andfinally, we briefly summarize empirical findings from sec-
(limiting the sample to workers) results in a nonrandom selection ofc, since ond generation research.
by Eq.(11.22a) an individual will be included in the estimation subsampleif
and only if H > 0, thatis, ifand only ife > —(a + 6W + cV) —J. Hence 11.3.8.1 SPECIFICATION AND £STIMATION ISSUES A distinguishing feature
the data on H is censored, and « must necessarily be correlated with HW and of: second-generation modelsoflabor supplyis the explicit treatment ofutility
V(unless & = c 0,or if everyone in the population works, as was virtually functions and unobservable variables. As an example, consider the utility
thecasein certain studies of the labor supply of prime-aged males). function
Since observations under Procedure If are systematically selected into
Us (WUE + 0) + PL Ur + ep (1.23)
theestimation subsample according to the criterion « > —J, OLS parameter
estimates based on such subsamples do not provide consistent estimaies of where HW’ and are real wage and real property income,total time 7" is nor-
the total labor supply response parameters. This « > —J condition therefore malized to | so that // is the proportion oftime spent at market work, | ~ df
draws attention to corner solutions in which labor force participation {a = is the proportion oftimein leisure (nonmarket aclivities), ¢ is an unob-
binary variable} is determined and interior solutions in which hours of work servable error term varying from one person to another, and the term in the
are then determined, given positive LFP. As Heckman etal. [1981] empha- first set of square brackets is real goods consumption G, The error term ¢is
size, while generated from the same preference function, the hours of work interpreted as representing interpersonaldifferences in tastes for leisure and
equation and the participation equation are fundamentally very different. for goods consumption.” Note that Eq.(11.23) implies that even though two
Thethird issue that drew the attention of researchers who were unsat- people have identical W and V, they are permitted to derive differing utility
isfied with first-generation empirical studies wasthat of nonlinear budget con- U from the same amountofobservable H.
618 Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay 11.3 Economerric Issues 619

The marginal rate of substitution Af implied by the utility function Initially, assume that measures ofthe real wage rate }Vare available for
(11.23), Af (@U/OL)/(8U/AG), can be shown to equal all individuals in the population, including nonworkers. For the ah individ-
(0124) ual, from Eq. (11.26), denote values concerning tastes for work as en, 2 —¢,
M = [BAL ~ by (WUE + 0) + MAL — + ey) andthe value of J given 5, W,, V,, and e, as J,. A common assumptionis that
where 6 & B/(« + ). To computethe reservation wage W’, evaluate Af in ¢#, has a mean ofzero, has a standard deviation of oy, and is normally dis-
Eq. (11.24)at the point where H = Oand L = 1. Atsucha point, tributed in the population as a whole, implying that the standardized normal
(11.25) variable ¢z/¢ has a meanofzero and a variance of |.
W, = [BL — by] De + VIAL - e] Giventhis assumption concerning the population distribution of¢,,, the
Anindividual with a given valueof ¢will provide positive labor supply if and probability that a given individual/ will workis given by
only if (hereafter abbreviated as iff) 1’ > HW. Setting H’> Wand rearranging Pi works) = Pien/on) > (~Jfen)
implies that H > Qiffe, > —J, where
gee and J=[(t— 6)— bY/W] (11.26) =f Aodt = 1 ~ F(-Ffou) 11.30)
iow
This implies that where fand are the standard normal and cumulative normaldensity func-
H>o iffe>-J (27) tions, respectively. Using Eqs. (11-27) and (11.28), write thelikelihood func-
tion for a sample ofindividuals who are either working or not working as
H=0 iff < -J (11,28)
eT]
“ - Fl-c ~ 8)" + busty -
Further, if H > 0, then H is determined by the condition that theJ = W
in Eq. (11.24). Therefore if one sets Mf = W’ in Eq. (11.24) and solves for TL A1-a - 4)+ (131)
H, one obtains the empirical labor supply function (given H > 0) as <r
He(l-b)-byW+a H>o (11.29) where 2 is the set of people who are working, @is the set of people who are
not working, b* = b/oy, and (1 — 6)" 3 (1 — boy.
More generally, one can specify a utility function U = U(G. L, e), in Equation (11.31) is the standard probit equation, andits parameters &*
which case the marginal rate of substitution function Af is M(G, L. ¢) = and (1 — 5)* can be estimated by maximizingthe samplelikelihood function
MOVH + ¥. 1 — #, e)andthe reservation wage function at Hf = Ois HW, = é (orits logarithm) with respect to 5* and (1 — b)*.* Given these estimates,
M(V, I, e). The individual will work iff 17 > HW, and for these individuals, one can then uniquely compute the maximum likelihood estimates of a, as
W’equals M, implying thatthe labor supply function can be derived by solv- /fo* + (1 — 5)*] and of b as b*/[5* + (1 — &)*}. Hypothesistests can be
ing W = M(WH + V1 — H, e) for H > 0. implemented usingthelikelihood ratio test procedure.
Although the labor supply function (11.29) looks quite similar to first- An interesting feature of this probit modelis that although it provides
generation equations such as Eq.(11.21), in fact the equation system (1 1.27), estimates of # and «,, and therefore provides information on parameters gov-
(11.28), and (11.29) provides much more information and does so in an inte- erning labor supply,its computation in Eg.(11.31) uses information only on
grated and coherent manner. To see this, first note that Eqs. (11.27) and V,, W,, and whether the individual works, but does notutilize any informa-
(11.28) emphasize a crucial threshold condition summarizing the labor force tion on hours worked, H,, Further, the conditional expectation of F[—J/oy]
participation (LFP) decision (for given V and W’, an individual will work iff in Eq. (11.26) simply equals the probability that individual / is not working,
& > —4J). Second, the equation system (11.27)-(11.29) highlights the fact thatis, the probability that H; = 0. A numberofalternative procedures can
that the labor supply function is in fact two functions—Eq. (11.29), which be used to incorporate the additional information provided by nonzero data
holds if W > W, and Eq. (11.28), which holds iff #’ < 3. Third, notice on H,,
that the same observable variables, unobservable variables, and parametcrs— Forthe moment, assumeagain that data on wagesare available for both
namely, W, V, ¢, and b—affect both the LFP decision and the amount of workers and nonworkers. The probability that individual { works 4, hours
labor force supply conditionalon positive LFP. While first-generation models and that this amount #,is positive can be written as
overlooked these aspects of labor supply, second-generation models empha-
size Them.Let us now briefly examine someofthe principles of estimation Pli works H, hours and H,; > 0] =
implied by second-generation models of jabor supply. Pli works H] - P[H, > Oli works H,] = P[i works HJ + 1 = fl)
620) Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay (1.3 Econometric issues 621

where the probability density of observing individual i working exactly H, has been emphasized by Amemiya [1973], the expected
value of H for obser-
hours is fley/o)/on, Hence the likelihood function for the entire sample of vations that are above the threshold (with positive labor
supply}, now called
2 workers and 2’ nonworkers is H*. is simply X¢ plus the expected value ofthe truncated normal
error term,
€ = T] Menfoudton) « TT Ft-sion 1132) EUP) = EWU > 0) = EU[ty > — Xp) = X68 + of(zyF
(z) (1134)
eu ne
This implies that the celationship amongexpected
values ofall observations,
where ey, © H, — J,and J, [(1 — 6) — B(V,/1%,)]. Equation(11.32) is called E(H), the expected value conditional upon being above
the limit, EU"), and
a Tobitlikelihood function.” Nonlinear methods can be employed to find the probability of being above the limit, F(z), is EH) = FIZJEU
P),
estimates of 5 and o, that maximize the samplelikelihood function (1 1.32), John F. McDonald and Roben A. Moffitt [1980] have noted
thatif one
and hypotheses can be tested by using thelikelihood ratio test procedure.” differentiates this last expression with fespect to X,, where
Y, is the kth regres-
Thefirst part of the right-hand side of Eq. (11.32) refers to workers, sor, one obtains
while the secondrefers to nonworkers. Moreover,the first part is identical to
the likelihood function that is implicit in a traditional OLS regression, SEU) yay SEUPY ep y GED)
whereas the secondpart resembles the nonworking probability portion of the ax, A) ae + BUY Se (11.38)
probit likelihood function (11.31). In a sense, therefore, Tobit combines
In the labor supply context the total effect of a change
fegression and probit frameworks. Notealso that if everyone worked, then in XY, on E(H) can
therefore be decomposed into two intuitively appealing
thelast part of Eq. (11.32) would disappear, and estimation of Ea. (I 1.29) vy components: ( 1) the
change in hours worked for individuals who are already
OLS would yield unbiased estimates of 6 and s,. However, if some indi working, weighted by
the probability of working, plus (2) the change in the probabi
uals do not work, Tobit is more appropriate than OLS, since Tobit not only lity of working,
weighted by the expected value of hours for those who work.
predicts the number of hours worked for each worker (see Eq. (11.29)), but
McDonald and Moffitt go on to show thatit is relatively simple
also produces the estimated probability that an individual will not work and to com-
pute these two componentsof the totaleffect, as well as
thereby helps explain why a number of observationsare clustered at the point their relative impor-
lance. Specifically, one can use as an estimate of F(z) the
H = 0 (see Eq. (11.28). fraction of the sam-
ple abovethelimit (thatis, the samplelaborforce particip
The probit and Tobit models that we have discussed so far are based on ation rate), and one
can estimate E(#*) using Eq. (1 1.34), along with entries
a simple form of J derived from the specific utility function(1 1.23), namely, from standard nor-
mal tables evaluating F(z), parameter estimates, and data
J.= [( — 8) — b(V,/5¥)]" In a more generalcase, one might write a labor means. Also, the derivative 8E(H*)/A.X, equals 8, - 4, where
evaluated at sample
supply model A = {l — [xft2y
F(z)) — [(=)'/F(z)']}, a fraction between zero and 1° Finally
, since d#(2z)/
Ha XG t+ uy, if X6 + ty > 0 (11.33) 8X, = f\z)Bi/o, one can estimate the Proportion ofthe
total effect of a change
in X, on labor supply dueto the effect from those alread
H.=0 ifXP + tn SO, P= N.S N A”
y working simply as

where X,is a vector ofregressors, 8 is the corresponding unknowncoefficient The fraction 4therefore not only provides the appropriate adjust
ment
vector, Nis the total numberofindividuals, and ty, is an independently nor- on 4, to obtain consistent estimates ofthe effects of change
s in Y; on H for
mailydistributed “tastes for work” random variable with mean zero and va those already abovethe threshold index, but also indicat
es the proportion of
ance o*, The stochastic index X,8 + uy, is observed only when it is positive the total effect due to induced changes in the behavior
of those above the
and thus results in censored samples. This index can be substituted into the threshold. Thisdistinction can be important; for exampl
e, not only is it often
probit likelihood function (11.31) or the Tobit likelihood function (11.32) in useful for policy purposes to know the effect of a Policyv
ariable such as as a
place of J, and maximum lihood estimates of # and 6 can then be specific income tax rate change on total labor supply,
but i is also pertinent
obtained by using nonlinear optimization procedures. | to be able to distinguish what portion ofthe total effect
fepresents a change
It is tempting but incorrect to interpret the Tobit ¢ coefficients as mea- in LFPR (and hence a change in unemployment rates)
irom that portion of
suring the effect on E(#,) given a change in X for individuals who are work- the effect on people who are already working.
ing, that is, QE(H,)/@X, = 8 for those H, > 0, where EC) refers to the Although the Tobit procedure utilizes information on
both LFP and
expected value operator. In the above mode!(11.33), and ignoring individual hours supplied given positive Participation, it is but one
of several procedures
subscripts i, the E(H) = XBF(z) + af{z}, where z= XBjo, fiz) is the unit that are available for estimating labor supply models. Two
variants on one
normaldensity, and F(z) is the cumulative normal distribution function. As Prominent alternative,called the selection bias-corrected regress
ion method,
622 Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay 11.3 Econometric Issues 623

use both regression analysis and probit techniques, but as we now see, they regression equation H, = X,8 + ty, James Heckman [1976, 1979, 1980] has
do so in a manner thatis very different from Tobit. suggested adding an estimateof 4, as a regressorto such an equation and then
To understandsclection bias more clearly, considera labor supply func- estimating the expanded regression equation by OLS while limiting the sam-
tion generated from a utility-optimizing framework and having the form H, ple to individuals for which H > 0.
= V6 + up, where the normally distributed t¢, have a population mean of Heckman suggests estimatingA, initially on the basis ofa probit regres-
zero and standard deviation of¢,as in Eq. (11.33). (Often, //, or someof the sion using data from all workers and nonworkers and shows that when this
X, are logarithmic transformations.) Suppose that one estimated this equation estimateofA, is appended asa regressorto the equation #/, = X,8 + ity. OLS
by OLS using data only from working individuals. As was noted in the pre- estimates of the labor supply parameters are consistent, However, since the
vious section, such a procedure results in inconsistent estimates of the param- disturbance term from this expanded regression equation turns out to be het-
eters in Eg. (11.33), since with such sampies, the conditional expectation of eroskedastic, OLS estimates of 6 are inefficient. and estimates of standard
My, is HONZErO and ity, is correlated with X. errors are biased and inconsistent.
The nature of the OLS bias has been considered by, among others, | Yet another alternative procedure for handling this sample selectivity
Arthur S. Goldberger (1981] and William H. Greene [1981]. Under the ue has been suggested by Randall J. Olsen [1980]. Olsen proposes estimat-
assumption that all independent variables and the dependent variable are ing by OLS 2 linear probability model in which the dependent variable is a
multivariate normalitydistributed in the population (this therefore excludes 0-1 dummy variable (equaling1 if Hf > 0, otherwise zero) and the regressors
dummyvariables as regressors), Goldberger obtains the strong result that the are the sameas jn Eq. (11.33), then retrieving the fitted values from this OLS
OLS regression coefficients are biased downward in the sense that the OLS Tegression (calling them /), and finally, adding (P — ) as a regressor in the
coefficient vector is a scalar multiple of the “true” labor supply coefficient hours worked equation confined to the sample for which // > 0. Olsen shows
vector, where thescalarlies within the 0-1 interval. Moreover, Greene shows that under the uniform distribution this procedure provides consistent esti-
that to obtain consistent estimates of the true labor supply parameters in Eq. matesof the labor supply parameters in (11.33)."'
(11.33), all one need dois divide each clementof the OLS coefficient vector The Goldberger-Greene, Heckman, and Olsen two-step procedure:
by the proportion of observations for which, in our context, // > 0. in a sense generalizations of the Tobit technique, since the undertyingutility
Although Goldberger shows analytically that this remarkable result does function and labor supply parameters in thefirst-stage probit estimation are
not hold when the multivariate normality assumptionis relaxed, Greenefinds not constrained to equal numerically the values that sre obtained trom the
that with a variety of nonnormalsituations (including dummyvariable regres- OLS oradjusted OLS estimates in the second stage, even if the underlying
softs), this simple adjustment of OLS estimates providess surprisingly robust economic theory suggests that they should be identical, By contrast, the Tobit
approximation to maximum likelihood estimates ofthe labor supply param- procedure constrains these parameters to be equal in both the labur force par-
eters in Eq. (11.33). The OLS-based estimates of standard errors, however, ficipation and labor supply equations. Note, however, that if one initially
are inconsistent, and as Greene shows, they cannotbe easily adjusted. Hence specifies a more general model with discontinuities in the labor supply sched-
one possible wayofdealing with sampleselectivity is to do probit estimation ule ducto, say, fixed costs of work, then the Iwo-stage estimator might well
of the LFP decision based on all observations, then do OLS estimation ofthe be preferable.
hours worked equation, limiting the sample to workers, and finally, obtain Unfortunately, the Goldberger-Greene, Heckman, and Olsen two-step
consistent estimates of the hours worked parameters by multiplying the OLS structural procedures require wage data for workers and nonworkers, as does
coefficient vector by the sample proportion of observations for which H > 0. Tobit. A major problem confronting second-generation researchers, however,
Note thattestsof significance cannot be done with this procedure, since OLS- is the fact that typically wage data are available only for workers. This data
based estimated standard errors are unreliable. problem creates other econometric issues, to which we now turn our
A second variant on the sampleselectivity bias procedure involves OLS attention.
estimation of an expanded regression equation. Recall that, using Eq. (11.34), A numberofalternative procedures have been employed by second-gen-
one can write the conditional expectation of hours worked for workers as eration researchers to obtain estimates of labor supply parameters when wages
E(H*)= E(H|H > 0) = X68 + K (11.36) are unobserved for nonworkers. Many ofthese approaches use an additional
population wage equation of the form
where K,, the conditional mean of u, given H > 0,is
W,= ZT + en, (11,38)
Kao: AAR Z)) = 0 (11.37) where Z, is a vector ofvariables observed forall workers, including, for exam-
}, is oftencalled the inverse of Mill's ratio, andin reliability theory it is known ple, age, education, gender, region, and experience, and «,, is a mean zero
as the hazard rate.Since KX, is essentially an omitted variable in the linear normally distributed random error term representing the effects of unob-
624 Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay
Ty 11.3 Econometric issues 625

served factors such as motivation and abilities.” Killingsworth [1983] has dis- where the X* matrix is the Y matrix of Eq. (11.39) plus an additional column
tinguished eight estimation procedures that attempt in alternative ways to vector, hours worked H,, and where the mean zero normallydistributed ¢s,
deal with missing wage data for nonworkers.” We now summarize his random error term represents unobservable taste factors. When expression
detailed discussion. (11.40) is solved for that wage rate at which Hf = 0, one obtains the reserva-
In Procedure1, wo steps are taken. First, the wage equation (11.38) is tion wage equation
estimated by OLS using data on workers only, and then the resulting OLS
parameters and data on Z, are used to create predicted wages H’, for both W, = XF0+ «, unary
workers and nonworkers, Second, the predicted wages are used as a repressor where the X** matrix is the X* matrix of Eq. (11.40) with the W, and #,
in the hours worked equation H, = X,8 + ty, which is estimated by OLS vectors deleted.
using data on all individuals and setting hours worked of nonworkers equal Heckman begins by adopting an analytically convenient proportionality
to zero. As was noted carlier, this procedure produces inconsistent parameter hypothesis (consistent with linear labor supply) where hours of work //, are
estimates, since it assumes that the hours worked equation applies to all pco- proportionalto the difference between W, and Hi, whenever HY > 1, and
pie, rather than only to those for whom H > 0. otherwise are zero:
ProcedureHf is simply a one-step procedure in which the hours worked
equation H, = 6(W, — BY) = DW, — XO — beg, iP, > W, U1.42a)
H,=0 iis W, (1142b)
H, = X68 + tn (1139)
Theparticipation equation implied by this equation system is
is estimated by OLS using data only on workers. A variant of Procedure [1
uses predicted rather than actual wages as 3 regressor but still limits the sam- Pli works) = PEW, > WW) = PIZT + en > XO + ea]
ple for which Eq. (11.39) is estimated to individuals who work. Recalt that = Pl> ~4) (11.43)
since people for whom H = 0 are excluded from estimation, Procedure [I where ¢p, 3 eu, — €2, and J, = Z,P ~ XT6. Since eu, and ¢g, are zero mean
suffers from sample selectivity and yields biased parameter estimates.
normally distributed random variables, so toois tn; the varianceoftp, iS ob
Procedure If is the Tobit estimator discussed above bul uses as a mca-
= of, + oh + 2owg. The likelihood function for LFP observations from a
sure of the unobserved wage for nonworkers the predicted wage from Proce-
sample consisting of workers 2 and nonworkers 2 can then be written as
dure I. Unfortunately, this procedure results in inconsistent parameteresti-
mates, since it is highly likely that sample selectivity problems also bedevil e= TP - F-sool TF adeo)l (11.44)
estimation of the wage equation (11.38), which by necessity is estimated by nr
using data only on workers.“ Specifically, the disturbance term ey, in Eq. whose estimation involves standard probit procedures.
(11,38) reflecting unobserved factors thataffect wagerates (such as productiv- The hours of work equation that is consistent with this framework is
ity, abilities, and motivation) is very likely correlated with the disturbance most interesting. Heckman first estimates the wage determination equation
term #,, tepresenting unobservedfactors that influence labor supply (such as (11.38) by OLS or GLS, using data for workers only, and then directly sub-
tastes for work). This implies that aw», the covariance between en, and uy,is stitutes this into Eqs.(11.424) and (11.42b), resulting in
sonzero; alternatively, it implies that the wage variable in the hours worked
equation (11.39) is endogenous, correlated with the u,,, disturbance term. As H, = UZ) - XFe+ y, iT) >0 (1145a)
a result, neither use of imputed wage duta derived from OLSestimates nor H,=0 W[-}<a i1.45b)
use of actual wage data (if they were somehow available for al} workers) would
yicid consistent estimates ofthe labor supply model under any of Procedures Hence by substituting out the endogenous wage in Eqs. (11.42) using Eq.
1, II, or Ut. To be valid, each of these procedures would require that 1’, be (11.38), Heckman obtains a seduced form equation (11.45), whose right-hand
exogenousor, equivalently, that oy, be zero. variables are all exogenous. Three issues merit brief discussion.
Procedure {V is one of several different procedures discussed by Heck- First, note that certain variables in the Z matrix from the wage deter-
man (1974b, 1976a}. It attempts to deal with this endogeneity issue by using mination equation (11.38) might be identicalto those in the X** matrix from
a reduced form procedure. Let the marginal rate of substitution function the reservation wage equation (11.41), for example, age, education, gender,
derived from a utility function have the linear form race, and years of work experience. This raises issues of identification, a prob-
lem that arises whenever wages are endogenous. Heckman [1974b, 1979]
M, = X3& + tn (11.40) notes that a condition sufficient foridentification is that at least onc variable
626 Whether and How Much Women Warkfor Pay 11.3 Econometric Issues 627

included in Z must be excluded from ¥**." Second, the data in the Z and tion parameter constraints fully imposed. This FIML specification builds on
X** matrices of the reduced form equations (11.45) are typically observed for the assumptionof joint normally distributed random disturbance terms ew, in
both workers and nonworkers, in contrast with traditional labor supply equa- the wage equation (11.38) and ¢g, in the reservation equation(11.41), having
tions such as Eq, (11.29), for which data on H’ are available only for workers. covariance gue and implying that the random variable ep, = ey, — ¢4, in the
Hence it appears possible to utilize data on the entire population, not just hours equation (11.42) is also joint normally distributed with ey, having
workers. Third, note that one could estimate Eq. (11.454) by nonlinearleast covariance ope © oly — dwg. AS a result, the likelihood function for the wage
squares (or by OLS with the parameterestimates from Eq. (11.38) directly tate, hours of work, and participation decisions of working individuals in set
substituted in), using data on the entire population and setting J2 0 for {and nonworking individuals in set 1” is
nonworkers. Killingsworth [1983] calls such a reduced form estimation
method Procedure IV. @ = [Tf
ren
Aben/bom enfow) «TE
ver
Fl-Jyo) (1.47)
A majorproblem with Procedure IV, unfortunately, is that if it is based
on data for all individuals with nonworkers #f set to zero,it involves a mis- where j is the joint probability density function for ¢,, and ¢,, and other terms
specification similar to Procedure I, since in fact Eq. (11.45a) refers only to are as defined above.
workers. If one instead estimates Eq. (11.45a) only for workers, sample selec- The important distinction between the FIML (11.47) and Tobit (11.32)
tivity problems emerge, similar to those in Procedure {1. Hence while it is likelihood functionsis therefore that while FIML treats W’ and H us simul-
apparently promising, Procedure IV does not solve the hours worked-wage tancously determined becauseof the possible correlation between ev and ¢,,
rate endogencity problem. Tobit treats H’ us strictly exogenous. Further, unlike the Tobit specification
There is, however, a related two-stage estimation procedure that effec. (11.45), the FIML estimation of Eq. (11.47) utilizesall available information
tively deals with this problem. In Procedure V, one takes advantageof the fact on Wand H for workers.
thatép, in Eqs. (11.45a) and (11.45b) is normally distributed and that H, can A common feature ofall the above estimation proceduresis that they
never be negative. One then specifies the Tobit likelihood function (11.32) assume that labor supply falls continuously to zero as wage rates or property
adjusted to accountfor the fact that the disturbance term de,is the product incomedec! ; Se , for example, Eqs. (11.33) and (11.42a). If there are fixed
of an unknown parameterto be estimated and the mean zero normallydis- costs of employment, however, one might want to develop a procedure that
tributed random variable ¢p,. This yields allows for discontinuous labor supply schedules, that is, one that permits the
lowest nonzero number of hours supplied by a worker to be substantially in
€ = TT RoeatbooVben) - [] Fi—SJon) (11.46) excess of zero. Two estimation procedures, hoth known as generalized Tobit
estimators and often called Heckit procedures, allow for such discontinuities.
where be, = H, — bJ,and J, is defined underneath Eq.(11.43). In Procedure VI/ a three-stage method is implemented. Stage | is the
In the second stage the parameter estimates that are obtained by maxi- sameas in Procedure V, except that one now estimates parametersof a probit
mizing the Tobit samplelikelikood function (11.46) with respect to &. I’, #, {not a Tobit) likelihood function for participation, such as Eq. (11.44). By
and op, along with data on X** and Z,, are used to calculate the inverse Mills using a probit rather than a Tobit specification, continuity ofthe labor supply
ratio A, = fl—J/op[1 — A—J/op)], that is, one uses parameters and data scheduleis not imposed. In the second stage of Procedure VII, one uses the
to estimate the probability that an individual with given XY and Z,will work. probit parameter estimates to computeprobit estimates of the inverse Mills
This estimateof 4, is then inserted as an additionalvariable in the wage equa- ratio X, = A—Jfon)/{1 ~— F(-J/ep)] and then appends A, as an additional
tion (11.38), whose parameters are estimated by OLS using data on workers regressor to the wage equation (11,38) to obtain OLS selection bias-corrected
only. Note that with Procedure V, estimation of the panticipation-hours parameterestimates using data on workers only; Killingsworth [1983, p. 159}
worked equationsis based on a reduced form Tobit specification, while esti- notes that the parameter estimate on A, in this second stage should be inter-
tation ofthe wagestructural equation for workers allows for sample selectiv- preted as an estimate of oy», the covariance between ey, and en.
ity. However, since the underlying parameters in the reduced form equation {n the third and final stage of Procedure VII, one estimates by OLS the
are not constrained to equality with structural parameters of the wage equa- reduced form hours equation (1 {.45a) with the probit inverse Mills ratio vari-
tion, parameter estimates are notefficient. able added, based on data for workers only, which, along with the siructurat
In Procedure VI, also discussed in Heckman [1974b], parameters ofthe wage parameter estimates from Stage 2, yields consistent estimates of the
entire equation system consisting of Eqs. (11.38) and (11.41) and the Tobit labor supply structural parameters. In this case the parameter estimate on A,
equations(11.42a) and (11.42b) are estimated by usingfull information max- is interpreted as an estimate of [(ouo/e) + blewo/op)], where oyp is the
imum likelihood (FIML)simultaneous equation techniques, with cross-equa- covariance between u,,, and ¢,,. Formulaefor the asymptotic variance-covari-
628 Whether and How Much Women Workfor Pay
11.3 Econumetric Issues 629

JAMES HECKMAN ance matrix of estimates obtained from this three-stage procedure have been
derived by Lung-Fei Lee (1982], but consistent estimates of Standard errors
Labor Econometrician for the third-stage parameters can be obtained in a computationallyless bur-
densome mannerby using the Halbert White (1980} robust estimator,
ore than any ration data. Someofthis Finally, in Provedure VIIT thefirst two Stages are identical to those in
other econo research has involved new Procedure VII, but in the third stage, instead of using the reduced form
spec-
mist in the last uses of semiparametric ification (1 1.45a), one employs instrumentat variable and selectivity bias-cor-
two decades, James Heck- and nonparametric meth- rected techniques to estimate parameters of the structural hours equation
man has affected the ods. (11,33) for workers, More specifically, A, is added as a regressor to thefirst
econometric modeling of Born in Chicago in equation in (11.33), and instrumental variable estimation is undertaken with
the labor force participa- 1944, Heckman pursued the actual wage rates of workers replaced by fitted values derived from the
tion and labor supply de- undergraduate studies at second-stage selectivity bias-corrected wage equation estimates: hence the
cisions. Heckman’s con- Colorado College, major- probit A, appears as a regressor in both the wage and hours equations.
tributions began with his ing in mathematics, earn- {t is worth noting thatif in fact the labor supply schedule is continuous,
197} Ph.D. thesis at ing a Phi Beta Kappa key, parameter estimates from the Heckit multistage Procedures VII and VIII
Princeton, “Three Essays and graduating summa should be identicalto those from the FIML Procedure Vi. On the other hand,
on Houschold Labor Sup- cum laude. He then went if the labor supply schedule is discontinuous owing to, say, fixed costs of
ply and the Demand for Market on to study economics at Princeton, employment, then the Heckit multistage generatized Tobit estimators of Pro-
Goods.” Since then, as detailed in and after spending a summer as Jun- cedures VII and VIII shoulddiffer from FIML. However, unless one specifies
this chapter, Heckman’sresearch has ior Economist at the Council of Eco- explicitly the nature of the optimization problem facing individuals—includ-
essentially built the core of what are nomic Advisors in Washington, ing, for example, the budget constraint implicationsoffixed casts of employ-
now called the “second-generation D.C., Heckman was awarded the ment, the Heckit parameterestimates are “black box”in the sense that they
models” of labor supply. Two distin- Ph.D.degree in 1971, studying under arc unable to provide insights on what factors have generated the disconti-
guishing features of this research are Stanley Black, E. Phillip Howrey, nuities. For further discussion of such importantspecificationissues, see Kil-
that the various estimating equations Harry Kelejian, Riehard Quandt, lingsworth [1983, pp. 161-168], who considers theoretical and econometric
are derived explicitly from neoclassi- and Albert Rees. aspects of several explicit models of discontinuous labor supply.
cal utility theory and that the sto- Heckman’s first academic ap-
chastic disturbance termsare an in- poiniment was at Columbia Univer- 14.3.8.2 INCORPORATING TAXES INTO LABOR SUPPLY To this point, our
tegral part of the model, rather than sity. In 1973 he accepted a position discussion of labor supply has ignored the presence oftaxes, Since consump-
being “tacked on™ at the end ofthe at the University of Chicago, and tion expenditures derive from after-tax income,the relevant budget constraint
derivation. Heckman's analysis of in 1985 he was named its Henry sel for the analysis of individual labor supplyis the after-tax constraint, not
self-selection in labor supply has pro- Schultz Professor of Economics. In the before-tax one. Taxes on wage and Property income can significantly
duced a new methodologyforsolving 1988 he moved to Yale University, affect labor supply, in part because taxes ofien introduce a wedge between
self-selection and sample selection where he nowis the A. Whitney Gris- average and marginalafter-tax wage rates. Moreover, since much public pol-
problems, often called the “Heckit” wold Professor of Economics. Heck- icy discussion has focused on the labor supply effects of changing statutory
procedure;it is now widely used in a man has been elected a Fellow of the provisions ofthe incometax code,it is important that we focus attention
on
vanity ofcontexts. Although they are Econometric Society and of the the effects of taxes on labor supply. Second-generation research on this topic
not discussed in this chapter, Heck- American Academy of Arts and Sci- has been substantial, with noteworthy contributions made by Harvey S.
man has also developed and imple- ences. In 1983 he was awarded the Rosen [1976], Gary Burtless and Jerry A. Hausman [1978], Hausman [1979;
mented empirically a numberof dy- distinguished Jobn Bates Clark 1980; [981a, b; 1985], Terence J. Wales and Alan D. Woodland [1979],
namicdiscrete choice models, as well Medal by the American Economics James J. Heckman and Thomas E. MaCurdy (1981), and Alice Nakamura
as models for the analysis of du- Association. and Masao Nakamura (1981a].
Tosee the impactof taxcs, let us assumethattheindividual receivesreal
property income V and carns a gross (before-tax) real wage of Wper hour
worked, As is shown in Fig. 11.3, in the absence oftaxes the budget constraint
630 Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay H1.3 Econometric Issues 631

Goods, G| rium point of tangency between the indifference curve and the budgetsetis
unique andoccurseither at oneof the kinksor at an interior location between
kinks.
However, if one introduces other real-world statutory tax provisions
into the analysis such as exemptions, deductibles, and transfer paymentstied
to hours worked, then the budget constraint set may include nonconcave
regions, and as a resuli, multiple tangenciesofindifference curves to the bud-
get set might occur. As Wales and Woodland [£979] and Hausman [198 1a]
emphasize,in such cases, to determine the utility-maximizing hours of work,
one must know the form of theutility function and compare utility at the
various tangencypoints. This introduces complications into the estimation of
the effects oftaxes on labor supply.
Slope = One way of simplifying the potentially complex budget constraint set
WU = 2) involves linearization; this has been implemented empirically by, among oth-
ers, Hall [1973] and Wales [1973]. Specifically, for an individual who works
somewhere along segment VX, when confronted with the budget set | /.XF,,
that individual could be assumed to act as if he or she faced a simple
straight-line budget constraint 1 /,XF, with reat property income equalto V,
and a real marginal wage rate of H’(1 — 1,). The effects of small changes in
property incomeor before-tax wagerates could then be analyzed by assuming
that the individual does not shift onto a different segment of the budget con-
straint set. Incidentally, in this casc the after-tax property income I, is the
amountofdisposable income that is available to the individual assuming that
Leisure Proportion — H = Oand L = }. Following W. Erwin Diewert [1971], Burtless and Haus-
man [1978] call this the individual'svirtual income: hence virtual income cor-
Figure 11.3. The Effects of Varying Marginal Tax Rates on responds with the before-tax property income V and the tax rate 7).
the Budget Constraint
Similarly, for an individual who is working somewhere along segment
XF,, when confronted with the same kinked budget constraint set, that indi-
is 1F, with the nonvertical portion having a slope of ~ #’. Suppose, how- vidual might be envisaged as acting as ifhe or she faced the simple straight-
ever, that the individualis taxed on the sum of property and wage income.If line budget constraint 1 V,XF; with a virtual income of V; and a real marginal
this total incomeis C, or less, let the tax rate be 100 - +, percent;if total wagerate of W(t ~ 7;). Hence complex budget constraints can be made con-
incomeis greater than C,, let the marginaltax rate on total income above C, siderably less complicated simply by linearizing them at the individual’s equi-
be 100- 7, percent, where +; > 7,. In Fig. 11.3 this implies thatif the individ- librium point. Note that in econometric implementation, at each observation
ual works hours between zero and | — L, and chooses leisure amount the measures ofafter-tax W and virtual income V used must be changed to
between L, and 1, the marginal after-tax wage rate is W(1 - 7,), while if the reflect the after-tax wage and property income corresponding with the indi-
individual works more than | — L, hours (chooses less £ than £,), the mar- vidual’s marginal tax rate at the equilibrium point,
ginal after-tax wage rate is (1 — 7;); thus the kinked after-tax budget con- Althoughthis linearized budget constraint approachis attractive, it also
straint is 1/,XF;. Note also that in Fig. 11.3 the vertical distance between the introduces new econometric problems, Several issues are of particular impor
two budget constraints represents the total amount of taxes paid at various tance in empirical implementation, First, because the after-tax JV and ¥ mea-
proportions of L. . sures depend on # (the marginal tax rate + varies with A = | — ZL) the
The budget constraint set in Fig. 11.3 is rather simple. It is relatively disturbanceterm in the hours worked equation is by construction correlated
straightforward to extend the analysis to a progressive tax structure with m with the after-tax measures of Wand V; hence estimation by OLSprovides
distinct and successively flatter linear segments, correspondingto increasing inconsistent estimates of the parameters, and instrumental variable (IV) esti-
marginal tax rates 7, > T,-) > * + + > 11; in such a case the budget constraint mation maybe preferable, 1V estimates have been reported by, amongothers,
set would be quasi-concaveto the origin. Note that with such a quasi-concave Jerry A. Hausman and David A, Wise [1976] and Harvey S. Roscn [1976].
budget constraint set, given strictly convex indifference curves, the equilib- Rosen's studyis of special interest, since in it he examines tax perception.
632 Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay 11.3 Econometric Issues 633

Rosen findsthat he cannotreject the null hypothesis that individuals perceive _The above discussion therefore suggests that while the presence of taxes
theeffects of taxes andreactto the net after-tax wage rather than to the before- considerably complicates the analysis of labor supply, empirical analysis can
lax gross wage, proceed, provided that one is willing to make tradeoffs concerning computa-
Second, and closely related to the previous point, it might be that in tional complexity and flexibility of the functional form. This type oftradeoff
response to a change in before-tax V or W, the individual would shift to an is, of course, a familiar quandary to the practicing econometrician.
entirely different segment on the budget constraint set. Estimation and model
predictions based on predetermined marginaltax rates would therefore be 11.3.8.3 EMPIRICAL FINDINGS We now conclude ourdiscussion of second-
unreliable. As might be expected, such estimation problemsincrease when the generation researchin labor supply by providing a brief summary ofempiricat
concave budgetset is kinked rather than continuous, that is, when marginal findings. More detailed surveys can be found in, among others, Heckman,
tax rate changes are discrete rather than continuous. Problems of estimation Killingsworth, and MaCurdy[1981, pp. 106-112}. Kiltingsworth [1983, pp.
become even more severe if the budget set has nonconcave and kinked 179-206}; and Killingsworth and Heckman [1986, pp. 185-197].
portions. Mostofthe second-generation studies avoid the pitfalls associated with
Such problems with the linearization or local approximation approach first-generation research. In particular, second-generation analyses explicitly
have given rise to a variety ofalternative procedures in which the complete distinguish the LFP function from the hours supptied fisnction, yet they also
‘budget set is evaluated.” In one procedure the previous no-tax estimation note that both derive from a common utility-maximizing framework. Within
framework in which the probability of H > 0 is estimated along with an hours this framework a substantial proportion of second-generation studies treat
worked equation conditional on H > O—a single-threshold framework—is hours worked and the wage rate as endogenous. Finally, most of the second-
generalized to include multiple marginal tax rates by permitting multiple generation studies take account of theselectivity bias in estimating tabor sup-
thresholds, each corresponding with a different segmentof the budget set in ply functions, using one or more of the Procedures V through VII summa-
which the hours worked decision entails a different marginal tax rate. This sized above,
type of modelcan be estimated by using the ordered probit function; see Ta- _ A vast majority of second-generation work has been concerned either
Antoni
keshi Amemiya [1975, 1981] for a discussion ofthis estimator and with fixed costs and discontinuities in the labor supply function (Cogan
Zabalza [1983] and John C. Ham and Cheng Hsiao (1984) for empirical [5980b, 1981}, Giora Hanoch [1976, 1980], Heckman [1980], and T. Paul
implementations. Schultz (1980]) or with taxes and nonlinear budget constraints (Burtless and
Yet another procedure assumes that random disturbances arise either Hausman [1978], Rosen [1976], and Wales and Woodland [1979]). With the
from individuals’ errors in optimization or from measurementerror of and notable exception of Hausman [1980; 198ta, b; 1983] and Alice Nakamura
involves evaluating utility at each point ofthe individual's budget constraint and Masao Nakamura [1981a}, most studies have focused on either fixed
sel (including the kink points), given values ofthe relevant structural param- costs or taxes but have not considered them jointly. As might be expected,
eters of an assumed direct or indirect utility function. This procedure, which the numerous second-generation studiesdiffer not only in estimation proce-
is oftencalled the complete budget constraint approach (CBC).literally solves dures. employed, but also in terms of the underlying data samples, This het-*
the individual's utility maximization problem foreach set of parameter values erogeneity makes it somewhatdifficult to provide a concise comparison and
andis obviously very computationally intensive. Notice in particular thatfor summary of research results,
is
each set of parameter values, the individual's entire maximization problem Two criteria might be used in assessing this research. First, do second-
solved: estimation procceds, as has been noted by Wales and Woodland generation results suggest important stytized facts of labor supply that ure not
[1980]. by maximizing the likelihood of observed hours with respect to the apparent from first-generation studies? Second, do estimates oflabor supply
entire set ofstructural parameters ofthe utility or indirectutility function. responses based on second-generation researchdiffer appreciably from those
The Wales-\WWoodland approach has been generalized by Burtless and basedon OLS estimation of first-generation equations? The answertothefirst
Hausman [1978] and by Hausman [1980] to allow the disturbance term in question appears to be “perhaps,” while the answer to the second is an
the hours worked equationto originate not only from errors in optimization emphatic “yes.”
orerrors in the measurement of H. but also from omitted variables that are In termsof thefirst criterion, like thefirst-generation studies, most (but
known by the individual but are not observable by the econometrician, notafi, as we shall soon see) second-generationresults generally conclude that
Remarkably, this more general conceptual framework can be implemented female labor supply is considerably more responsive to changes in propery
withoutresort to the laborious Woodland-Wales maximizing procedure, pro- income and wagerates than is malelabor supply. Killingsworth (1983, p, 206}
vided that one makes very strong assumptions aboutthe functional form of goes even further, concluding that “female labor supply responses are some-
the hours worked equation. whatlarger than was apparentin first-generation research” (sce also his quote
634 Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay 11.3 Econometric Issues 635

at the beginningofthis chapter). He notes as well that second-generation stud- presented later in Nakamura and Nakamura [1981a: 1985a,b]. This contro-
ies that are based on continuous labor supply schedules (using Procedures It, versy about whether males and females respond differentially to wage rate
V, and VI) tend to produce greaterestimatesof female labor supply elasticities changes is of considerable interest, and therefore in Section 11.3.C we will
than do second-generation studies that allow for a discontinuous labor supply discuss it further when we consider the Mroz [1987] anticle.
schedule (Procedures VII and VIII), Moreover, most second-generation Finally, in terms of analyzing the effects of taxes on labor supply, not
research explicitly considering discontinuities in the labor supply schedule much is known yet concerning the consequences andrelative merits of using
finds that such discontinuities are substantial. Estimates of the “pointofdis- linearized (LBC) or compicte budget constraint (CBC)estimation procedures.
continuity”—the minimum amountof annual hours at which wages are suf- Kilingsworth (1983, pp. 204-205] notes that the LBC and CBC estimates
ficiently high to overcomefixed costs—are reasonably consistent over diverse differ considerably, but since most CBC studies employed restrictive utility
studies. For example, Heckman [1980] and Cogan [1980b, 1981) report esti- function specifications or limited samples,it is not clear how muchof the
mates that range between only 1126 and (383 hours, while Hanoch’s lowest difference is due to LBC versus CBC,versus the choice ofa restrictive func-
estimate is 820 hours. | tional form.
Unfortunately, however, like their first-generation counterparts, in The empirical results ontheeffects oftaxes on labor supply reported by
terms of wage and incomeelasticity estimates, the second-generation esti- Hausman [1981a] are of particularinterest. however. Hausman incorporates
mates of labor supply responsesare verydiverse. In fact, noting that estimates effects of a progressive incometax schedule,as well as provisions of numerous
of the female uncompensated wageelasticity of annual hours vary from US. transfer programsresulting in budget constraint sets with both concave
—0.30 10 + 14.00, Killingsworth and Heckman (1986, p. 185] reach the sad- and nonconcave regions. Following the previous tradition, Hausman treats
dening conclusion that the husbandas the primary workerin the family and specifies that in making
her labor supply decisions, the wife treats the husband's income as predeter-
it is not uncommonfor authors of empirical papers on labor supply to mined.” Significantly, the functional form and stochastic specification
pointto results in otherstudiessimilar to the ones they have obtained. but employed by Hausman constrain leisure to be a normal good. Fixed costs of
...such comparisons may not always be informati ts all too casy to
working are incorporated into the model. Hausman computes virtual
find at least one otherset of results similar to almost anyset of estimates
‘one may have obtained.* incomes correspondingto cach individual's equilibrium marginal tax rate and
employsa specification in which increases in income neverraise desired hours
In spite ofthis diversity, and in termsofthe secondcriterion for evalu- of work. However, heterogeneity in preferences among individuals can result
ating second-generation studies, on the basis of research to 1980, Heckman, in income effects that vary across the population. A CBC estimation proce-
Killingsworth, and MaCurdy [1981] have argued that clasticity ‘estimates dure is employed, and estimation results are compared on the basis of a com-
obtained from sccond-generation studies tend to be greater—sometimes con- bined concave, nonconcave budget constraintset with results from a globally
siderably greater—in absolute value than those based on first-generation tech- concave approximation to a complex budget constraint set.
niques. Theycite two types of evidence to support their tentative conclusion. For husbands, Hausman finds that the uncompensated wageelasticity
First, an important Monte Carlo study by Wales and Woodland[1980] indi- is essentially zero but that the incomeeffect is negative and substantial.
cated that, given joint normality, OLS estimates are badly biased toward zero Results from the concave and nonconcare estimation procedures are similar.
(though perhaps not as much in the wage equation asin the hours equation), Given these estimated incomeeffects, Hausmanconcludes that for husbands
whereas techniques that correct for sample selection bias are much closer to with averagetastes and in the $8000~$ 12.000 federal tax bracket in 1980, the
the “true” parameter values. Second, studies of female labor supply by, Progressive income tax structure reduces labor supply by 8%compared 10 a
amongothers, Cogan [1980a], Heckman (1976a}, and Schultz [1980], found No-tax situation and by 7% compared to a proportionaltax system generating
that labor supply elasticity estimates that were based on second-generation equaltax revenue.
estimation procedures were consistently larger than those based on first-gen- For wives, Hausman usesresults from his carlier research that suggested
eration OLS methods. that the wives’ wage rates before taxes are not a function of hours worked;
Notall labor econometricians agree with Heckman, Killingsworth, and Mmorcover, he also concludes that sampleselectivity is not a significant prob-
MaCurdy's assessment. In particular, already in the late 1970s, Alice Naka- temin the female wage rate equation. Hausmanestimates the uncompensated
mura and Masao Nakamura [1979] reported results of a second-generation wageclasticity for the average woman workingfull time as being equal to a
study that found female labor supply to be basically unresponsive to changes rather substantial 0.995 and,iffixed costs are taken into account, at 0.906.
in wage rates, similar to the findings reported by others for males (sce their Theincomeelasticity is negative and substantial, reflecting in part the leisure
quote at the beginning ofthis chapter); additional supporting findings were Rormality assumption. These results imply that progressive income taxes
JERRY A. HAUSMAN 11.3 Econometric Issues 637

Modeling the Effects of Taxes on Labor Supply


reduce wives’ labor supply in large part by decreasing the net after-tax wage.
Specifically, to the extent that the wife is a “secondary” worker, Hausman
erry Hausman’s con- manhas published empir- hotes that she faces a “marriage tax,” since thefirst dollar of her earnings is
J tributions to the the- ical studies on the effects taxed at the rate that is applicable to the last dollar of her husband's earn-
ory and practice of of alternative rate struc- ings.** Hausman also examinestheeffects oftaxes on labor supplyof female
econometrics have been tures on the demand for headsoffamilies and reports significant sensitivity to taxes.
numerous and wide rang- electricity, on factors af- Overall, Hausman estimates that the progressive federal U.S.incometax
ing. While students might fecting the purchase and structure existing in 1980 results in an 8.6% declinein labor supply compared
recognizehim bestfor the utilization of energy-using to a no-tax situation and estimates that the deadweightloss as a percent of
oft-used specification test durable goods, on the re- incometax revenuesraised is 28.7%. Owing to progressivity, deadweight loss
procedure that he devel- lationship between pat- increases sharply with market wage rates and associated marginal taxes. By
oped, Hausman has writ- ents and research and de- contrast, 2 proportional incometax system that generated identical tax reve-
ten extensively in econo- velopment, and most Nues would reduce labor supply by onlyslightly more than 1%, and the aver-
metric theory on simul- recently, on the effects of age deadweight loss as a proportion of tax revenues raised would be only
taneous equations estima- competition and technical 7.19, Arguing that a proportional tax system with an initial exemption pro-
tion, the interpretation ofinstrumen- progress in telecommunications. vides an alternative way of implementing progressivity without entailing as
talvariable estimators, estimation of Born in West Virginia in 1946, large a deadweight loss, Hausman concludes that “the progressive income tax
models with errors in variables, com- Jerry Hausmanobtained his A.B. de- sysiem may be a costly way to seek incomeredistribution. Other, more cost-
putational algorithms for nonlinear gree (summa cum laude) from Brown. effective means of incomeredistribution maywell exist.”
structural models, and panel data es- University in 1968. Aftcr spending Hausman’s findings are not universally accepted, however. For exam-
timators. twoyears with the U.S. Army Corps ple, in commenting on Hausman [1983]. Heckman (1983) conjectures that
Although Hausman has made of Engineers in Anchorage, Alaska, Hausman’s ratherlarge wage responsiveness estimates reflect at least in part
major contributions in econometric Hausman resumed studies at Oxford the effects of his assumption, imposed on the data, that leisure is a normal
theory, he considers himself essen- University, where he was a Marshall good.
tially an applied econometrician. He Scholar. At Oxford, Hausman earned
has long been interested in public f- a B.Phil. degree in 1972, and a
nance (he currently serves as a Mem- D.Phil. in 1973; his‘dissertation was 11.3.C On the Sensitivity of Results to Alternative
ber of the Massachusetts Governor's entited “A Theoretical and Empiri- Statistical and Economic Assumptions: The
Mroz Study
Advisory Council for Revenue and cal Study of Vintage Investment and
Taxation), and this interest led him Production in Great Britain.” In reviewing second generation empirical results in the previous section we
to research the effects of taxes on Hausman’s first academic ap- emphasized thatthe substantial heterogeneity that is observed in the estimates
jJabor supply. One of Hausman’s im- pointment was at MIT in 1972, and of wage and incomeelasticities could be ducin part to the fact that the various
portant econometric findings, dis- aside from occasional visiting ap- studies differin terms of estimation method,functional form, and data base.
cussed in this chapter,is that the U.S. pointments, he has been there cver This suggests that an informative research project would involve undertal ing.
income tax system leads to greater since, teaching courses in economet- detailed sensitivity analyses of existing alternative second-generation estim:
deadweight loss than had previously tic theory, microeconomics, public tion methods but using a common dala base and functional form. That is
been believed and that an equal rev- finance and a course in the industrial Precisely the approach taken by Thomas Mroz [1987], who employs data
enue-generating tax structure with organization of tclecommunications. from the 1976 Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID) sampleconsisting of
personal exemptions and then a pro- Hausman has beenelected a Fellow 753 white married women aged 30-60, of whom 428 worked al some time
portional tax would involve much of the Econometric Society, and in during 1975, Using these data, Mroz compares elasticity estimates based on
smallerefficiency losses. (985 he was awarded the John Bates a variety ofalternative statistical and economic assumptions that were made
In addition to his work on the ef- Clark Medal by the American Eco- by authors of previous studies,
fects of taxes on labor supply, Haus- nomic Association. Mroz's study is of considerable interest because, although it does not
focus on new methodological developments, it yields important results con-
cerning sensitivity, and it follows up on Nakamura and Nakamura (1979;

636
638 Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay 11.3 Econometric Issues 639

198 1a; 1985a, b} in challenging the conventional wisdom of labor economists ate positive, the range is substantial, varying from —499 to +1462 for a $1
that the responsivencss of female labor supply to changes in wage rates and change in the wagerate; estimated incomeeffects per $1000 in 1975 dollars
incomeis larger than that of men.” We now examine the Mroz study and the are primarily negative but range from — 125 to +51. Further, there does not
associated sccond-generation empiricalliterature in more detail. appear to be any obviousrelationship between the estimation method thatis
Mroz begins by noting the very large diversity af reported estimates of employed and the magnitudeorsign ofthe estimated labor supply response.
female labor supply responses to variations in wage rates and income.” To Mroz proceeds by choosing a simple functional form for the labor sup-
makethe results of various studies comparable, Mroz evaluates the implied ply equation, one that Nicholas Stern [1986] derived explicitly from an indi-
effects of these studics on annual hours worked in 1975, assuming that the rectutility function. This labor supply equation is
wife's wage is $4.50 and her hours worked are 1500, the husband’s wage is
$7.00 and his hours are 2000, the household nonlabor incomeis $1000, and H, = dy + a, In(W) + a ¥, + aZ, + (11.48)
the labor and nonlabor marginal tax rates are 0.339 and 0.280, respectively. where H,is the ith woman's hours of work in 1975, HV, is a measure of her
Mcoz’s evidence on the wide range oflabor supply response estimates is pre- wage rate, V, is a measure of other incomereceived by the household in
sented in Table 11.2, which reproduces Table | of Mroz[!987, p. 766]. There thousands of 1975 dollars, Z, is a vector of additional control variables
it is scen that while the vast majority of uncompensated wage effect estimates (including the wife’s age, her years of schooling, the numberofchildren less
than six years old in the household, and the numberofchildren between the
ages ofsix and 18), and¢; is a stochastic disturbance term. Al a given wage
Table 11.2 MROZ's Survey of Estimates of Marrled Women's Labor Supply fate, Mroz computes the uncompensated wageeffect on hours worked for a
Responses $1 wage rate change as simply dO’, = a,/W’, and the income effect as
Estimation Method Wage Effect incomeEffect of/aV’, = a;. The corresponding uncompensated wage and incomeelastici-
ties are then computed as 3 in H./d in W, = a,/H,and dln Hfain Vi = aVs
[1973] Instrumentalvariables 29 ~16.9 H,, respectively.
‘Cogun[1980a] Tobit 865 —32,3 The 1976 PSID data sample (for year 1975) is employed by Mroz in this
Cogan (1980a] Instrumental variables 349 study because only in 1976 did the PSID survey directly interview wives in
Cogan [1980b} Tobit 632 households. Duringall other years the household head supplied information
Cogan [1980b) Fixed costs 196 aboutthe wife’s labor market experiences during the previous year. As Mroz
Cogan[1981] Fixed costs 269 notes, “one suspects that the own reporting is more accurate,andit is for this
Greenhalgh [1980) Instrumentalvariables 213 feason that many recent studies of married women’s labor supply have used
Hausman [!981a] Convex budgetsets 328 Of these data.”* Annual hours worked H, is measured as the product of the
Hausman[19813] Nonconvex budget sets 335 numberof weeks the wife worked for pay in (975 and the average number of
Hausman [1981a] Fixed costs 305 hours of work per week during the weeks she worked. The wage rate 1’, is
Heekman [1976a] Tobit 1462 measured as average hourly earnings, calculated as total labor income of the
Heckman [19763] Generalized Tobit -499 wife in 1975 divided by H,. Note that if there is a random measurement error
Heckman[1980] Generatized Tobit i401 in annual hours worked, a spurious negative correlation will emerge between.
Layard etal. [1980] Tobit 128 hours worked and this wage rate measure. Finally, the Property income mea-
Layard et al. [1980] Instrumental variables 22 sure V, is defined as the houschold’s total money income minus the wife's
Leuthold [1978] 1967estimates 14 labor income,in thousands of 1975 dollars.
Leuthold [1978] 1969estimates 45 For a “base case estimation,” Mroz reports results when parameters in
Leuthold [1978] 1971 estimates 33 Eq. (11.48) are estimated by OLS and the sampleis restricted to those who
Nakamura and Generalized Tobit -16 work(recall from Section 11.3.B.1 thatthis is Procedure It)
Nakamura (198ta)
Schultz (1980] Tobit 123 -67.0 Hy = a — 17 n( WW) — 4.2 V, — 342 KL6, ~ 115 K618, + others
Schultz [1980] Instrumentalvariables —26 19 (81) 3.2) (131) (29)
‘eter Ties effects are evaluated ot 3 wife's wage of$4.30, wife hours at £500, buaband's wage of$7.00, ustand?s hour at (11,49)
2000, huosehold nantshut income of 51000, and Tabor and rontabar raarginal tax rite of€.339and 0.280especie, The
‘Suurce effect
iacomne is per$1000
Data from ThamasinA.1975
Mrozdtiare
“The Serutvtyofan Empirical Model ofMarried Women’s HoursufWark to Economic Here KL6,is the numberofchildren underage six in the household, K618,
a SiatitenAtsumptionn” Economica. Vol. $8, No.4, 1987, TAB 1,9. 766 is the numberofchildren between ages six and 18, numbers in parentheses
od Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay IL3 Econometric issues 64

are estimated standard errors (adjusted for arbitrary formsof heteroskedastic- toward work. If this were true,it is likely that a variable such as the wile’
ity, using the Halbert White [1980] procedure), and “others” refers to the labor market experience would alse be correlated with the disturbance tern
additional variables (wife's age and wile’s education), whose paramcleresti- and that as a result this variable andits square would not be legitimate instru
mates, along with the intercept, are nol reported by Mroz. Note that these ments. Mroz therefore recstimates Eq. (11.48) by 2SLS but excludesthe expe
OLS estimates imply that both the uncompensated wageeffect and income rience variable andits square as instruments. This yields an equation with ;
effect are negative (the elasticities are — 17/1500 = —09l 13 and —4,2/1500 much smaller andstatistically insignificant estimated wageeffect:
= —0,0028, respectively) and that the presence of children in the household. H, = dy + 46 In (WV) — 4.4, - 337 KL6, - 112 K618, + ~~
(particularly those under age six) reduces labor supply substantially, other (220) (3.3) «31 (30)
things being equal. The negative OLS estimated wage effect is not surprising.
since as was noted above, if there is a random measurementerrorin //,, then
(151
a spurious negativerelationship occurs between #/, and 1, ; With the experience variables excluded as instruments the uncompensatec
With Eq. (11.49) as a basis of comparison, Mroz then examines the wageelasticityfalls to 46/1500 0.031, and the incomeelasticity to —4.4#1,
effects of three variations: (1) alternative exogeneity assumptions on the 1500 = —0.0029. Such low estimates match someof the smallest estimate:
fegressors. issues that are raised in particular by Nakamura and Nakamura reported in Table 11.2. The estimated effects of children on labor supply
[1981a]; (2) statistical controlforself-selection into thelabor force—a classic however, are not affected as muchandin factare quite similar in the various
issue; and (3) the impacts of controlling for taxes. We begin by summarizing OLS and 2SLS specifications. These results therefore demonstrate that esti-
results that occur once Mroz controls for possible correlation between regres- mates of the wage and incomeresponses are very sensitive to assumptions
sors and the disturbance term in Eq. (11.48) through the use of an instru- concerning the endogeneity ofregressors and the choice of instruments.
mentalvariable procedure such as two-stageleast squares QSLS). To makethe choice of instrumentsless arbitrary, Mroz proceeds with 3
Treating In (3¥,) as an endogenous variable that might be correlated variant of the Durbin-Wu-Hausman-Whitespecification test.* In this context
with the disturbance term ¢, in Eq. (11.48). Mroz uses as instruments the the null hypothesisis that the experience instruments are uncorrelated with
wife’s reported labor market experience (the number of years the woman has «, and the alternative hypothesis is that they are correlated. Mroz showsthat
worked for pay since her eighteenth birthday), this variable squared, and seve a test of this hypothesis amounts to testing whetherthe estimated wage coel-
erat different polynomials in the wife's and husband's age and education. This ficient in the 2SLS equation (11.50) with the experience variables included as
variant on Procedure II {sce Section 11.3.B.1) results in an estimated 2SLS instruments is equal to the estimated wage cocfiicient in the 2SLS equation
equation whose wage and income parameters are much different from the (11.51) with experience variables excluded as instruments. He derives the for-
OLSestimates of Eq. (11.49): mulae for the asymptotic variances and covariances and obtains an asymp-
totic normaltest statistic of 3.0, impiying that the null hypothesisis rejected
H, aa + 672 In (IK) — 64, — 283 KL6,— 85 K618, + --- at any reasonable level of significance. Mroz therefore concludes that the
(217) (3.6) (47) (36F wife's previous labor market experienceis not exogenous in the labor supply
(11.50) equation and that as a result the experience variables are invalid instruments,
Note that unlike the OLS estimates, here the 2SLS estimate ofthe uncom- consistent with the Nakamura and Nakamura {19813} conjecture. Interest-
pensated wage response is positive and highly significant; in fact. this large ingly, Mroz undertakes similar exogeneitytests for the KL6,. K618,, and ¥,
2SLS estimate on the wage coefficient is similar to some ofthe largest wage variables andfinds that the exogeneityofthese children and nonwite income
effects reponed in Tabie 11.2. The 2SLS incomeeffect, however, is more neg- variables cannotbe rejected at reasonable levels of significance.”
ative than the OLS estimate, and the 2SLS estimates of theeffects of children Second, as was discussed in Section !1.3.B.1.a major problem with each
on labor supply, while also negative, are smaller than OLS estimates. Further, of the above Procedure II estimatesis that they are based on a subsample of
using the clasticity formulae underneath Eq. (11.48) and evaluating deriva- working women only and therefore do not control for self-selection into the
tives at H, = 1500 and V, = I (recall ¥, is measured in thousands of 1975 laborforce. To examine the impactofignoringself-selection Mrozesti-
dollars), we see that the implied 2SLS. uncompensated wage clasticily estimate mates the labor supply equation using the Heckit multistage Procedure VINE
is 672/1500 = 0.448, while the income elasticity estimate is very small, In particular, using the full sample of 753 married women, Mrozfirst esti-
—6.41/1500 = —0.0043. mates a probit model of labor force participation in which the explanatory
Fellowing 3 conjecture by Nakamura and Nakamura [1981a, p. 480], variables include KL6, K618, J” polynomials in the wife’s age and education,
Mroz then examines whetherthe disturbance term in Eq. (11.48) reflects in the education of the wife’s mother and father. the county's unemployment
part the unobservable preferences of the individual, inctuding her attitude fate, a dummy variable for large city. and the wife's previous labor market
642) Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay 11,3 Econometric tssues 643

experience and its square (note that the wife’s wage is not included). Of the These results suggest that whether the experience variables are assumed
18 regressors, only the coefficients on KL6, V, experience, and its square are to be exogenous has a decisive impact on whether theself-selection bias is
more than twice their estimated standard error. Mroz then uses this probit statistically significant in the labor supply equation. Totest for exogeneity of
modelto estimate the inverse Mills ratio \ (see the discussion in Section the experience variables, Mroz uses the samespecification test procedure as
11.3.B.1, especially that on Procedures VII and VIII) and appends this vari- was described earlier, but with the asymptotic variance formulae adjusted to
able as a regressor in a wage rate determination equation in which the other include sample selectivity. The nui! hypothesis of exogeneity reduces again to
tight-hand variables are the samc as in the estimated probit equation but @ very simple test—whether the estimated wage coelticient in Eq. (11.53) is
where the sampleis limited to workers (428 of the 753 observations). In the equalto that in Eq.(11.52); since the difference in estimated coefficientsis 58
third andfinal stage, Mroz uses thefitted value from the wage determination (122 — 64) and the estimated asymptotic standard error is 163, the null
equation as an instrument in a 2SLS estimation of the hours worked equation hypothesis of exogeneity is not rejected.
(11.48) but with the inverse Mills ratio 4, added as a regressor. It is worth ‘On thebasis ofresults from these fourestimated equations, Mroz draws
noting that since the wife’s previous labor market experience andits square a umberofconclusions, First, the estimated uncompensated wageeffect is
are regressors in the first two stages of this Heckit procedure, this particular positive but typically very smail, provided that one treats the wife's experience
estimation assumes that these experience variables are exogenous. variables as “endogenous” and/or oneallows for sampleselectivity bias in the
The resulting estimated labor supply equation has a small positive wage determination andlabor supply equations. Further, under the sameesti-
uncompensated wage effect and a smail positive incomeeffect, neither of mation procedures the incomeeffect is usually negative butalso rather small,
whichis statistically different from zero: Mroz[1987, p. 794] therefore concurs with Nakamura and Nakamura
H, = ay + 122 In(W} + 3.9 V, + 53 KL6; (1979; 1981a; 1985a, b] and rejects the conventional wisdom based on sec-
(225) (45) (173) ond-generation studies, concluding that
— 87 K618, — 7584, + --- the small income and wage effects found in this study provide a much
G4) a7 152) more accurate picture of the behavioral responses of working women to
variations in nontabor income and wages than those found in most pre-
In this case, when evaluated at the same wage and incomeas earlier, the esti-
viousstudies.
mated uncompensated wage elasticity is but 0.081 (122/1500), and the
incomeelasticity is 0.0026 (3.9/1500). Surprisingly, the estimated coefficient Suchfindings suggest as well that the modest responsiveness of married wom-
on young children KL6 is now positive (but insignificantly different from en's labor supply to changes in wage rates and incomeis not muchdifferent
zero), while that on K618 is still negative but considerably smailer in absolute from that foundin studies of the labor supply of prime-aged matried males.
value than in Eq. (11.50). Since the ratio of the estimated coefficient on 4, to Second, the sampleselectivity bias is significant only if the wife’s experience
its standard erroris 753/171 = 4.43, a numberthalis greaterthanthecritical variables are treated as exogenous. Third, the wife’s labor market experience
value for the normal distribution at reasonablelevels of significance, Mroz variables are exogenousprovided that oneallows for sampleselectivity bias,
rejects the null hypothesis that there is noself-selection bias. Fourth,theresults are consistent with the view that a woman'stastes for work
However, when the same multistage Heckit estimation Procedure VII are unobserved omitted variables that affect both her previous and current
is employed but the wife’s labor market experience andits square are omitted labor marketparticipation and hours of work, over and abovetheir influence
as regressors in the probit and wage determination equations, a rather differ- on her wagerate.”
ent labor supply equation is obtained: In addition 10 estimating the labor supply equation using the Heckit
multistage Procedure VII, Mroz employs the full Tobit simultaneous equa-
H, = a + 641n(W) ~ 1.0 V, — 183 KL6, tion estimation Procedure VI. Recall that unlike Procedures VII and VIU,
(227) (9.2) (408) which allow for discontinuities in the labor supply schedule dueto,say,fixed
— 106 K618, — 294a,+ --- costs of employment, the Tobit Procedure VI assumes continuity. In fact, the
(34) (467) (11.53) Procedure V1 estimates will be equal to those from Procedures VI] and VII
Not only is the uncompensated wage effect coefficient small and insignifi- whenever the labor supply schedule is continuous in wages. Mroz reports that
cantly different from zero, but the incomeeffect is negative, small, and also his Procedure VI Tobitestimates of the labor supply equation are
insignificant. Further, the estimated coefficient onA, is insignificantly different H, = a, + 261 In(W,) — 22.9 V, — 1035 KL6, ~ 97 K618, + - + -
from zero, implying that one cannotreject the null hypothesis that there is (357) (4) (140) (48)
noself-selection bias.* (11.54)
$44 Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay 11,3 Econometric Iss eS 645

Hence the Tobit uncompensated wage elasticity estimate is also quite small 44.3.0 Issues in Dynamic Labor Supply
(261/1500 = 0,174) and insignificantly different from zero, while the income
effect is significant and larger than those estimated above {—22,9/1500 = Oneinterpretation of Mroz's results on the importance ofthe Sabor force
0.015)but is stil! rather small, Further,with the Tobit specification the null experience variablesis that labor supply might better be viewed in a dynamic
hypothesis of exogeneityof the experience variables is rejected. Mrozthen life cycle context, Before concluding this chapter, therefore, we briefly over-
tests for this Tobit specification (11.54) as a special case of the muitistage view the rapidly growing theoretical literature an dynamic labor supply.
Heckit Procedure VIII and in all cases rejects the null hypothesis, This leads Within thelast decade, considerable theoretical research has focused on
Mroz to conclude that the restrictions implied by the Tobit Procedure VI dynamic labor supply models. In dynamic models oflabor supply, economic
must be rejected, a conclusion thatis consistent with the view that fixed costs agents act knowing that today’s decisions will have consequences in the
of employment are substantial. . | | future. Further, in dynamic models, the accumulation of nonhuman and/or
In the third phase of his study, Mroz assesses the effects of including a human capital is modeled explicitly. Our overview ofthis literature is by
measure of the marginal tax rate into the labor supply equation. Following necessity brief, more detailed discussions can be found in Killingsworth
Hall [1973]. Mroz uses a linearization ofthe budgetset in which themarginal [1983, Chapter 5], Killingsworth and Heckman (1986, pp. 144-179], and,
in
afler-tax wage rate replaces the previous wage measure and virtual income is particular, Pencavel [1986]. We begin by discussing models in which
wages
measured as the intercept of the linearized budget set at zero hours of work; at each point in time are exogenous and then examine models in which
wages
untike Hall, however, Mroz treats both the after-tax wage rate and virtual are determined endogenously through human capital accumulation,
income as endogenous variables. Using similar estimation Procedures as Although discussions of the timing of labor supply and human capital
before,” Mroz finds that the estimated wage coefficient falls and in fact accumulation duringthe life cycle uf women have a longhistory in labor eco-
becomes negative but that the magnitude of the change is at most 33 hours nomics, one ofthe most influential early contributions on dynamic issues
is
andis always within 20% of one standard deviation oftheestimates obtained that by Jacob Mincer [1962]. Mincer suggested that one way of thinking
without taxes. This leads Mroz [1987, p. 786] to conclude, “{n the light of the through dynamicissues is simply to reinterpret the static analyses of
labor
other possible sources of bias examined in the previous sections, the influ- supplyin lifetime terms, where variables such as consumption,leisure, work
encesof taxes on the estimates of the labor supply parameters appears to be at home, wages, budget constraints, and time are envisaged aslifetime vari-
at most a second order effect.” . | ables. Note that in this view, the woman's real asset holdings should be rein-
Finally. following Rosen [1976], Mroz rewrites Eq. (11.48) in after-tax terpreted as those occurring at the beginningof the (lifetime) time period and
form as the expanded equation not as her actual lifetime or current exogenous income,
Following Killingsworth and Heckman [1986], tet us assume that the
H, = a) + a,in[Wl — 7)} + bn — 1) life cycle consists of T periods, and let us then sort single-period reat
wage
+ aV,+ mYV, + aiZ,+ 6 . (11.58) rates in descending order so that w(1) denotes the highest real wage and
w(7")
denotes the lowes. For the moment, ussume that consumptionand leisure at
where z, is the marginal tax rate and YV, is virtual income. The null hypoth- different points in time are pertect substitutes. Under these conditions an
esis that married women optimally take taxes into consideration is that b = individual will work sometime duringherlife if #(1) exceeds her lifetime
res-
ad, = 0, while the alternative hypothesis is that 6, # 0, a; # 0. One might ervation or shadow wage rate A{RS(O), where the latter is the mutrginal rate
of
also consider testing the hypothesis that married women completely ignore substitution evaluatedat zero lifetime haurs of work. To determine the total
taxes when making labor supply decisions. This corresponds lo the null numberof periods worked, compare discounted real wage rates to (he
MRS;
hypothesis that 6, = —a, and b, = 0, while the alternative hypothesis is b, the individual will work exactly & time periodsif
# ~ay, b; # 0. Unlike Rosen, Mrozfindsthat neither of these two distinct
w(k) = MRS(K) > wik + 1) (11.56)
null hypotheses can be rejected, perhapsreflecting the relatively large standard
errors on the estimated wage coefficients and income terms. | where at least oneof the inequalitiesis strict." Thus the total number ofperi-
As can be seen, therefore, the significance of Mroz’s study is that ods worked & is a function of an unobserved taste or houschold production
it highlights the empirical consequences of employing alternative assump- variable ethat aflects lifetime utility, real initial wealth A, and the “marginal
tions concerning exogeneity, sample selectivity, and taxes on estimates of wage" w(K), that is,
the labor supply responsiveness of married women. These assumptions do
matter. k= KDWAT, e] (1.87)
646 Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay 11.3 Economettic Issues 647

In this case the proportion ofall periods in the woman’s lifetime that is tion for period 1, depending on consumption C(¢) andleisure L(2). Inciden-
devoted to work, #. is simply A = &/T. which together with Eq. (11,57) tally, in this additively separable specification, C(s) and C(z’), as well as L(0)
implies that and L 1), are not assumed to be perfect substitutes for ¢ # £5?
h = Alntk), A. T, e] (10.58) Lifetime utility is maximized subject to a lifetime budget constraint
r
Onepractical problem with implementing empirically equations such AQ) + SO + yt FO) — PCI) = 60)
as Eq.(11.57) or Eq. (11.58) is that it would appear that each requires & or /t =o
data on labor supply over the entirelife cycle——a truly formidable obstacle.
As Mincer[1962] and Heckman [1978] have noted. however,if one abstracts where A(0)is the individual's initial asset holdings, r is the market rate of
from “transitory”factors, one might assumethatthe timing of work over the interest, and (2), H(¢), and P(1) are the wagerate, hours of work, and price
life cycle is random. If this were true, andif all individuals worked at some levels in period 1, respectively.
point in their lives, then one could estimate parameters of Eq. (11.58) by More formally, using Lagrangian procedures, maximize Eq. (11.59)
replacing /t (whichrefers to lifetime participation) with, say, Q, where @ now over C(t) and H(z) subjectto the lifetime budget constraint (11.60), and inter-
refers to participation as of a given date; the resulting parameter estimates. pretthe Lagrangian multiplier in front of Eq. (11.60), say, A, as the marginal
could then be used to obtain estimates ofelasticities of labor supply with Iifetime utility of initial asset holdings. Thefirst-order conditions yield an
respect to (permanent) wage changes and with respect to income (here,initial intertemporal equilibrium plan, given a set of wage rates andprice levels P(r)
wealth). and Pt), 2 = 0,..., T. for C(t), £0), and A. Onecan ofcourse assess how
While apparently promising, however, this approach suffers from the the equilibrium paths of differing individuals would vary as a result of their
practical ambiguity of determining the appropriate measure of the “marginal holding different -1(0) or facing diverse wage rates #¥(1); such mental experi-
wage” w(k) that could clearlydiffer from the wage prevailing as of the date ments are called comparative dynamics and should be distinguished {rom the
referenced by the Q variable; specifically. while data on lifetime labor supply individual's initial intertemporal equilibrium sequence,called her equilil-
might not be necessary, onestill needs to be able to determine which partic- riwn dynamics.
ular wage rate—of al! the wages the individual will carn during her lifetime— | In carrying through comparative dynamics, one mustof course be care-
happensto be the appropriate marginal wage rate in Eq. (11.56). ful in specifying what is being held fixed. One commonapproach,called the
Another problem with this approach, emphasized by Killingsworth and Frisch 4-fixed or Frisch demand notion, examines the equilibrium timepath
Heckman [1986, pp. 148-149], is that using estimates of Eq. (11.58) with @ effects of a changein, say, (1), treating the marginallifetimeutility ofassets
replacing / to obtain measures of substitution and incomeeffects is appro- a as fixed; an alternative procedure, dubbed A-variable, allows this marginal
priate only when is strictly positive, that is, only when individuals have an

fat
utility of assets to vary in response to a change in #(2)."In either case it can
interior solution 10 their lifetime labor supply optintization problem. As be shown thatvariation in a wage at any given date may have consequences
Heckman (1978) notes, although appropriate data are rather scarce, there is notonly at that peint in time, but also at other dates.
reason to believe that a nonnegligible portion ofthe female population never ; It is worth noting here that within the labor economics literature, much
undertakes market work for pay. Therefore this approach might not provide ink has been spilt concerningthe effects of changes in “permanent”or “tran-
usefulestimates of income and substitution effects. sitory” income onlabor supply overthelife cycle. Controversy has occurred,
Muchrecent work has focused on modeling more explicitly the factors for example, concerning whether one should include only measures of per-
that affect an individual's equilibrium sequence of lifetime labor supply, lei- manent incomein labor supply equations or whether one should also include
sure, and consumption; the solution to thelifetime optimization problem is a measure of transitory income. Although muchofthisliterature is informal
often called the individual's equilibrium dynamics. A common approach is rather than rigorous, it can be assessed within a comparative dynamics
to assumeperfect certainty and specify lifetime utility as an additively sepa- framework.
rable utility function Specifically, define permanent income W’, as the present value of the
r stream of anindividual's future rates from ¢ = 0 tor = T, discounted at rate
v= Vast syei(cw, LO) (11.59) r, and transitory income w,as the difference between the actual wage (1)
= and the permanent wage W,, that is, w, = 4() — W, AsKillingsworth and
Heckman [ 1986} emphasize, empirical measures of W, have been constructed
where Tis fixed, L(f) + (4) exhausts all available time during period ¢, 5 is in practice by using essentially ad hoc procedures, dependingin large part on
the individual's subjective rate of time preference, and t[-] is the utility func- the nature ofthe available data.
648 Whether and Row Much Women Work for Pay U4 Additional Remarks on Econometric Analyses 649

‘One body ofliterature adopts whatKillingsworth and Heckman [1986] much empirical insight into the dynamics of women’s work and wages. How-
call the PO position, according to which hours of work and labor foree pat- ever, this topicis currently attracting a great dealofattention both from the-
ticipation in any period ¢ depend on the permanent wage only, analogous to orists and from econometricians.”
Mikon Friedman’s [1957] permanent income theory of consumption. Under
the PO hypothesis, one need never include the transitory wage measure w, in ADDITIONAL REMARKS ON ECONOMETRIC
ati equation such as Eq. (11.50), since its coefficient should be zero. ANALYSES OF LABOR SUPPLY
An alternative to the PO position, called PT, hypothesizes that both MH,
and w(1) should appearin labor supplyequations; moreover. accordingto this As we haveseen, the literature on factors that affect female labor supply
literature, the coefficient on w, should be positive and algebraically greater vides a useful example of how economic theory, measurement issues, and
than the coefficient on H,, since the latter represents the sum of a positive econometric technique caninteract 10 enhance our understanding of impor-
substitution effect and a negative incomeeffect, whereas the formerreflects tant public policy issues, But this literature has also amplyillustrated that in
only a positive substitution effect.” Spite of enormous progress in theory, technique, and, to some extent, mea-
Using comparative dynamic procedures with both A-constant and d- surement, it is still frustratinglydifficult to “nail down”precise estimates of
variable, Killingsworth and Heckman [1986, pp. 156-158] show that con- imponant clasticities. While critics of recent econometric practice might
trary to PO,leisure and labor supply arc responsive to transitory wage differ- interpret this difficulty as further evidence that the payofis of state-of-the art
ences, owing to thefact thatlife cycle asset accumulationis affected. Further, econometric research are often meager, many economelricians who work on
contrary 10 PT. it is not necessarily the case that labor supply at time 7 is labor supply remain strongly optimi: Killingsworth [1983,
positively correlated with ,. However, if one examines instead the compar- example, concludes his summary ofwhat we do and don't know p.about
432], for
labor
ative dynamics of changes in exogenous income (such as the incomeof other supply by stating, “At least temporarily, then, uncertainty about. and varia-
famity members) on an individual’s equilibrium dynamics (rather than tion in, actual magnitudes oflabor supply estimates seems larger than it used
changes in her 4’, or w,), it turns out that labor supply depends only on per- to be.” Whether Killingsworth’s 1983 assessmentthat this large rangeofelas-
manent exogenous income and not on transitory exogenous income.** licity estimates is but a temporary condition in the history of the analysis of
Not surprisingly, Killingsworth and Heckman conclude that much of labor supply remainsto be seen, .
the ambiguity in the transitory-permanent income controversyarises because Finally,it is worth noting that somestudents oflabor supply argue that
of a lack of proper theoretical foundations. As an alternative, they suggest nereason for the large variability in labor supply elasticityestimates, which
employing the Frisch demand framework, in which the marginal utility of is evident in Table 11.2, is that existing theoretical models of labor supply are
assets X constitutes a type of “permanent wage” and variations in the simply too crude. Although we have attempted in this chapter to discuss the
observed wage #1/(4) with d constant correspondtoa type of “transitory” wage currentlabor supply literature in a relatively thorough mannerand have dem-
variation. since with A constant it can be shownthat diffegences in f’(r) must onstrated some ofits complexity, in fact the labor supply literature is
always be negatively correlated with L(1}. extremely large, muchofit still needs to be synthesized, and by necessity we
Our discussion on dynamic labor supply to this point has assumed that have ignored potentially important strandsofresearch. For example, we have
wages are exogenous. By contrast, and as discussed morefully in Chapter 5 only skimmed theliterature on family or household d ion-making pro-
ofthis book {see especially Section 5.1},there is a great deal of literature sug- cesses, as well as the significance of hours worked quantity restrictions on
gesting that wage rates for women are endogenous.affected in large past by labor supply.” Further, we have entirely overlooked labor supply ues Con
imtermittent labor supply and expectations concerning child-rearing. More cerning the quality of work, the amountofleisure time spent at work, and the
specifically, since current wagerates dependin part on human capital endow- tisk and uncertainty ofjob search. In terms of econometric matters we have
ments, and since human capital formation is affected by educational attain- considered only the relatively simple limited dependent variable models.*
ment and on-the-job training, the choices that women make concerning mar- and among other omissions we have not dealt with issues concerning the pos-
riage, child-rearing, and work affect their time paths of wagerates. As a result, sibility of obtaining better econometric estimates of labor supplyelasticities
in the more complete and necessarily more complex dynamic models of by employing data from well-designed experiments,”” nor have we examined
female labor supply, educational attainment, marriage, the desired number issues ofspecification, estimation, and inference whenthe labor Supply obse:
and spacing of children, the time path of market labor supply, and the time vations are taken from a pane! datasel.” Fortunately, readers whoare inter-
paths of wages and consumption are all endogenous. ested in pursuingthese related issues can begin by working through the tefer-
In large part because of their mathematical complexity, formal theoret- ences given here and those provided in leading labor economics textbooks,
ical models of joint labor supply and wage determination have not yet yielded such as thosereferenced al the end ofthis chapter.
650 Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay Exercises 65)

44.5 HANDS ON WITH LIMITED DEPENDENT VARIABLE y Manyofthe data sets that are used to estimate models oflabor supply
TECHNIQUES TO ASSESS THE LABOR SUPPLY OF are large,often involving over 16,000 observations, and it is simply infeasible
MARRIED WOMEN to provide such a large data base on your 360K data diskette. However, the
1976 PSID data set employed by Mroz [1987] in his sensitivity study is useful
We have now cometo the hands-on portion ofthis chapter. The goal of the and convenient, since it is rather small(it contains 753 observations on 19
following exercises is to engage you in obtaining firsthand experience in variables and occupies only about 60K ofspace on yourdata diskette), andit
implementing and interpreting alternative procedures that attempt to mea- permits replication of some of Mroz’s most important findings.”
sure factors affecting female tabor force participation and hours worked; in In the subdirectory called CHAPILDAT ofyourdata diskette you will
particular. you will have the opportunity to carry out on your own a number find a data file called MROZ.This data file contains 753 observations on mar-
of estimation methods, including most of the second generation procedures ried white women aged 30-60 in 1975 for i9 variables. The first 428 obser-
discussed in Section 11.3.B.1. vations are those for women whose hours of workin 1975 were positive, while
Note: Althoughthe exercisesof this chapter have been carefully designed the final 325 observations are those for women who did not work for pay in
to introduce you to someofthe most important computational and interpre- 1975, Each 80-column row ofthis data set corresponds to one observation.
tive issues in the econometric analysis of labor supply, they are but an intro- Thefirst variable, LFP. is a labor force participation dummyvariable
duction, and yourinstructor may use the data set in this chapter for other that equals 1 if the woman's hours of work in 1975 were positive; olherwise,
useful and more elaborate exercises. For example, although data on the hus- it equals zero. WHRSis the wife’s hours of work in 1975, while KL6 and
band’s hours of work and wages are provided in the MROZdata file on your K618 indicate the numberof children in the houschold under age six and
diskette, we make no use of those data in the exercises. Such data could be between ages six and 18, respectively. WA is the wife’s age in years, WE is the
useful in a model offamily labor supply. Alternatively, your instructor might wife’s educational attainment in ycars of schooling, WWis the wife's 1975
wantto provide you with a different set of data. Hence we urge you to en- average hourly earnings in 1975 dollars, and RPWG is the wife's wage
visage these exercises as a beginning step to understanding better the applic- reported at the time ofthe 1976 interview,in dollars. The HHRSvariable is
ability of limited dependent variable procedures to the analysis of labor the husband's hours worked in 1975, HA is his age, HE is his educational
supply. attainment in years of schooling, and HW is his 1975 wage in 1975 dollars.
Theexercises of this chapter can be summarized as follows. Because it FAMINCis the family incomein 1975dollars; henceto calculate the wife's
is extremely important to examine data sets before becoming involved in property income, one must subtract the product of WW and WHRSfrom
econometric estimation, we highly recommendthatall readers work through FAMINC. MTRis the wife’s marginal tax rate evaluated if her hours of work
Exercise 1, “Inspecting Mroz’s 1975 Panel Study of Income Dynamics Data,” were zero. MTRis taken from published federal tax tables (it excludes state
Moreover,this exercise is essential because in it you generate two dataseries andlocal incometaxes but includes any applicable social security benefits).
that are necessary for completion of subsequent exerciseg. In Exercise 2 we WMED isthe wife’s mother’s years of schooling, and WFED is the wite’s
intcoduce you to a common but inappropriate estimation procedure in which father’s years of schooling. UN is the unemployment rate in the county of
an hours worked equation is estimated by OLS with hours of nonworkers set residence,in percentage points, while CIT is a dummy variable that equals |
to zero (Procedure I). Then in Exercise 3 we invite you to explore the female if the family lives in a large city (a Standard Metropolitan Statistical Area,
laborforce participation decision using OLS,probit, and logit estimation pro- SMSA);otherwise,it equals zero. Finally, AX is the wile’s previous labor mar-
cedures and to examine numericalrelationships among them. In Exercise 4 ket experience, in years. Further details on these variables are given in the
we ask you to compare the conditiona! OLS and Tobit estimators ofthe hours he oe file in the subdirectory CHAPII.DAT and in Mroz
worked equation (Procedures 1] and [1f) and to implement the Goldberger-
Greeneprocedure for assessing the OLS bias. Next, in Exercise 5 we have you
consideridentification issues when both the wage rate and labor supply equa-
tions are estimated by using Procedure IV. In Exercise 6 we lead you through
estimation of the hours worked equation based on theincreasingly common EXERCISE 1: Inspecting Mroz’s 1975 Panel Study of Income
Heckit multistage procedure (generalized Tobit), which Killingsworth called Dynamics Data
Procedure VIII. In Exercise 7 we have you estimate a Heckit model in which
taxes are taken into account, and finally, in Exercise 8 we work with you in The purpose of this exercise is to help you become familiar with salient fes-
specifying and estimating an extended Tobit model (Procedure V1). tures of the data series in the MROZdata file. While exploring this data set,
Cercecocce you will compute arithmetic means, standard deviations, and minimum and
652 Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay Exercises 653

maximum values for variables in the entire sample and for the data sorted calls this sum the wife’s property income and computes it as total family
into various subgroups. You will also construct and save two variables that income minusthe labor income earned by the wife. For the entire sam-
will be used in the subsequent exercises ofthis chapter. ple of 753 observations, computethis property incomevariable (named,
say, PRIN) as PRIN = FAMINC — (WHRS - WW).Also calculate and
(a) To check whether the data are the same as those employed by Mroz print its mean and standard deviation; these should equal 20129 and
{1987, Table 111, p. 769], compute and print outthe arithmetic means 11635, respectively. Save PRIN for use in subsequent exercises ofthis
and standard deviations ofeach of the 19 variables in the MROZ data chapter.
file, using the entire sample of 753 observations. The results that you d One ofthe variables that is often employed in empirical analyses of
obtain from sucha calculation should equal (for each variable named, laborforce participation is the wage rate. As was emphasizedearlier in
followed with parentheses enclosing first the mean and then the stan- this chapter, however, the wage rateis typically not observed for women
dard deviation): LFP (0.56839, 0.49563), WHRS (740.57636, whoare not working. Some analysts have attempted to deal with this
871.31422), KL6 (0.23772, 0.52396), K618 (1.35325, 1.31987), WA problem (albeit in an unsatisfactory manner—see Section 1 (.3.B.3) by
(42,53785, 8.07257), WE (12.28685, 2.28025), WW (2.37457, 3.24183), estimating a wage determination equation using data on workers only
RPWG (1.84973, 2.41989), HHRS (2267.27092, 595.56665), HA and then using the resulting parameterestimates and characteristics of
(45.12085, 8.05879), HE (12.49137, 3.02080), HW (7.48218, 4.23056), the nonworking sample to construct fitted or predicted wages for each
FAMINC (23080.59495, 12190.20203), MTR (0.67886, 0.08350), ofthe nonworkers.
WMED (9.25100, 3.36747), WFED (8.80876, 3.57229}, UN (8.62351, Restricting your sample to workers (the first 428 observations},
3.11493), CIT (0.64276, 0.47950), and AX (10.63081, 8.06913). Do take the natural logarithm of the wife’s wagerate variable WW andcall
your results match those of Mroz? (Because ofdiffering rounding con- this log-transformed variable LWW. Compute and print out the mean
ventions, your computer software program might generateslightly dif and standard deviation of LWW for this sample. Then, for the entire
ferent valucs. But the means and standard deviations should be very sample of 753 observations, construct the square of the wile’s experience
close to those reported here.) Also compute minimum and maximum variable and call it AX2, thatis, generate AX2 = AX*AX< (and, for later
values for each of these variables; this is a particularly useful practice, use, the squareof the wife’s age, WA2 = WA*WA), Next, following the
since by doing this, one can often spot data coding errors. Are any of humancapitalliterature on wage determination summarized in Chapter
your min-maxvalues “suspicious? Why or why not? 5 ofthis book and using only the 428 observations from the working
(b) Now comparethe sample of working women(thefirst 428 observations sample, estimate by OLS a typical wage determination equation in
in the MROZ data file) with those not working for pay in [975 (thefinal which LWWis regressed on a constant term, WA, WE,CIT, AX, and
325 observations). Compute arithmetic means and standard deviations AX2. Does this equation make sense? Why or why not? Then use the
for cach of the 19 variables in these two subsamples, then print and parameterestimates from this equation and values of the WA, WE, CIT,
compare them. Mroz notes that arithmetic means in the working and AX, and AX2 variables for the 325 women in the nonworking sample
nonworking samples are quite similac for variables such as WA, WE, 1o generate the predicted orfitted log-wage for the nonworkers. Call this
K618, HA, HE, and HHRS.Doyoualso find this to be the case? How- fitted log-wage variable for the nonworkers FLWW, Computethe arith-
ever, meansin the working and nonworking samples tendto differ more metic mean and standard deviation of FLWW for the nonworkers, and
for variables such as KL6 and HW. Howdotheydiffer, and what might compare them to those for LWW from the working sample. Is the dif=
this imply concerning the reservation wages of women in these two sam- ference in means substantial? How do you interpret this result? Finally,
ples? Why? To the extent that the previous labor market experience of fortheentire sample of 753 observations andfor use in subsequent exer-
women (AX) reflects their preferences or tastes for market work, one cisesof this chapter, generate a variable called LWW for whichthefirst
might expect means of AX to differ between the working and nonwork- 428 observations(the working sample) LWWI = LWW andfor which
ing samples. Is this the case? Interpret this difference. Are there any the last 325 observations (the nonworking sample) LWWI = FLWW
otherdifferences in meansofvariablesin the two subsamples that might from above. Note that your constructed LWW variable should include
affect labor force participation or hours worked? Ef so, comment on either the actual or a predicted wagefor each individual in the sample.
them. To ensure that you have computed the data series LWW! correctly,
(c) In the model of labor supply estimated by Mroz,it is assumed that in compute and print out its mean and standard deviation; they should.
making her labor supply decisions the wife takes as given the house- equal 1.10432 and 0.58268,respectively. Save the LWW data series for
hold’s entire nonlabor income plus her husband’s labor income. Mroz use in subsequent exercises ofthis chapter,
654 Whether and How Much Women Workfor Pay Exercises 655

fa) Econometrics textbooks typically point out that if the dependent vari-
EXERCISE 2: Estimating the Hours Worked Equation Using Procedure | able in an equation is a dichotomous dummy variable, and if an equa-
tionis estimated by OLS in which this dependentvariableis related lin-
The purpose ofthis exercise is to introduce you to a common, but unfortu- carly to an intercept term, a numberof regressors, and a stochastic crror
nately inappropriate, procedure for estimating the hours worked equation. term, then the resulting equation (often called a linear probability
Specifically, in this exercise you implement Procedure 1, in which youesti- model) suffers from at least two defects: (1) thefitted values are not con-
mate by OLS an hours worked equation using the entire sample of 753 obser- fined to the 0-1 interval, and so their interpretation as probabilities is
valions and predicted wages for nonworkers and you set hours worked for inappropriate; and (2) the residuals from such an equation are hetero-
nonworkers equal to zero. Such an equationis often called a truncated nermal skedastic. Note that in our context, LFP is such a dichotomous depen-
regression equation. You also compute the implied responses to changes in dent variable.
the wage rate and in property income, both in level and in elasticity form. Using OLS estimation procedures and the MROZ data file for all
753 observations, estimate parameters of a linear probability model in
{a) Inspect the WHRSvariable (wife's hours worked) and verify that when-
ever the LFP(labor force participation) variable equals zero, the value which LFP is related linearly to an intercept term, the LWW1 variable
constructed in part (d) of Exercise 1, KL6. K618, WA. WE, UN, CIT,
of WHRSis also zero. Then,using the OLS estimation procedure and
thewife's property income PRIN (constructed in part (c) of Exercise 1),
theentire set of 753 observations in the MROZ data file, regress WHRS
and a stochastic error term. Do signsof these OLS estimated parameters
on a constant term and on the variables KL6, K618, WA, WE, LWW!
make sense? Why or why not? Comment on the appropriateness of
(constructed in part (d) of Exercise 1), and PRIN (constructed in part
using the OLS estimated standard errors to conducttests of sta 1
(c) of Exercise 1). Do thesigns of the estimated parameters agree with
significance. Next retcieve and print outthe fitted values from thisesti-
your intuition? Why or why not? Whatis the value of R*? Why might
mated linear probability model. For how manyobservationsare the fit-
this value be so low when Procedure I is employed?
ted values negative? For how many are they greater than 1? Why does
(b) Using the above OLS parameter estimates and theelasticity formulae
this complicate the interpretation of this model? What is &? in this
underneath Eq. (11.48) evaluated at the same points as noted at the bot-
model? Does it have any useful interpretation? Why or why not?
tom of Table 11.2, computetheelasticity of hours worked with respect
to wages and with respect to property income. Is the wageelasticity a
(b) Onepossible estimation procedure that is more appropriate when the
dependent variable is dichotomousis based on the assumption that the
compensated or an uncompensated one? Why? Then, following Mroz’s
cumulative distribution of the stochastic disturbances is the logistic;
procedures, which are also discussed underneath Eq. (11.48), compute
the resulting maximum likelihood estimatoris usually called logit.”
the implied response of hours worked to a $1 change in the wage rate,
evaluated at the same point. How doesthis estimate compare with those
With LFP as the dependent variable and with a constant term,
LWWI (from part (d) of Exercise 1). KL6. K618, WA, WE, UN, CIT,
presented in Table 11.2? Finally, compute the implied response of hours
and PRIN (from part (c} of Exercise 1) as eaplanatoryvariables, use the
worked te a $1000 increase in property income. Camment on how this
entire sample of 753 observations in the MROZdatafile and estimate
estimate compares with those presented in Table 11.2.
Parameters based on a logit maximum likelihood procedure. Do the
(c} Although this Procedure | is simple and easy to implement, it has a
signs of these estimated logit parameters make sense? Why or why not?
numberofserious flaws. Whatare the principal shortcomings?
Whichof the estimated logit parameters is significantly different from
zero? interpret. Does the nonlinear logit computational algorithm in
your computer software program reach convergence quickly, after only
EXERCISE 3: Comparing OLS, Problit, and Logit Estimates of the a few iterations(say, fewer than five)? Some computer programs provide
LaborForce Participation Decision “goodness-of-fit” output for the estimated logit model, such as a pseudo-
R? measure or a measure indicating what percent ofthe predictions are
Thegoal of this exercise is to help you gain experience with simple limited “correct.” Check your computer output and manual!for the interpreta-
dependentvariable estimation techniques by computing and then comparing tion of any such goodness-of-fit measures.” Finally, compare your logit
OLS, probit, and logit estimates of a typical labor force participation equa- estimates to the OLS orlinear probability mode! estimates from part (a).
tion, The numerical comparison of these various estimators is based in large In particular,following Takeshi Amemiya [1981], each of the OLS slope
part on the work of Takeshi Amemiya [1981], who has derived relationships Parameterestimates should approximately equal 0.25 times the corre-
among them.” sponding logit slope parameter estimate. How well does Amemiya’s
656 Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay Exercises 657

approximation work in this sample? Further, Amemiya shows that each one mullplies the logit parameter estimates by 0.625 and then com-
of the OLS intercept and OLS dtunmyvariable imtercept terms should pares these transformed logit parameters to the probit estimates. Which
approximately equal 0.25 times the correspondinglogit parameteresti- of these two approximations best transforms your logit estimates to
mate, plus 0.5. Do your OLSandlogit intercept and dummy variable comparable probit estimates? Why?
intercept terms correspond well with Amemiya’s approximation? (f) In this exercise we have compared OLS linear probability model, logit,
«c) Another commonestimation procedure thatis used in the estimation of and probit estimates of a labor force participation equation and have
dichotomous dependent variable models is based on the assumption focused on numericalrelationships amongthe estimated parameters. As
that the cumulative distribution of the disturbances is normal; this is was pointed out in Section 11.3.B.1, however, there are seriousstatisti-
usually called the probit model. Likelihood functions based on the cal problems with each of the particular OLS,togit, and probit proce-
probit model have been discussed in Section 11.3.B.1 of this chapter. dures that were employed in this exercise. What are these problems?
With LFP as the dependent variable and with a constant term,
LWW1 (from part (d) of Exercise 1), KL6, K618, WA, WE, UN, CIT,
and PRIN (from part (c) of Exercise 1) as explanatory variables, use the
EXERCISE 4: Relating the Tobit and Conditional OLS Estimates
entire sample of 753 observations in the MROZdata file and estimate
parameters based on a probit maximum likelihood procedure. Do the
The purposeofthis exercise is to engage you in the estimation and interpre-
signs of these estimated probit parameters make sense? Why? Which of
tation of a labor supply model based on the Tobit Procedure {Lf and to enrich
the estimated probit parameters is significantly different (rom zero?
your understanding of how this Tobit model relates to the conditional OLS.
Why? Does the probit computational algorithm in your computer soft-
frameworkofProcedure II, You will also have the opportunityto implement
ware program reach convergence quickly, after onlya fewiterations? Is
empirically the analytical results of Goldberger [1981], Greene [1981], and
convergence more orless rapid than with the logit model? As in part (b),
McDonald and Moffitt [1980], which were discussed in Section 11.3.B.1.
interpret any goodness-of-fit measures that are provided as output by
your computer software program. (a) First, estimate a conditional OLS model of labor supply (Procedure [1).
{d) Because the cumulative normaldistribution and thelogistic distribution In particular,restricting your sample to the women who worked for pay
are very close to each other, in most cases thelogit and probit estimated in 1975 (thefirst 428 observations in the MROZdatafile), run a regres-
models will be quite similar.” Are the sample maximized log-likelinoods sion of WHRSon constant term, KL6, K618,. WA, WE, PRIN, and
in your estimated logit and probit models similar? Which is larger? LWW(sec part (d) of Exercise 1 for a discussion of LWW and PRIN).
Whataboutthe signs and statisticalsignificance ofthe estimated param- Compare your results to those obtained by Mroz, reproduced in Eq.
eters—are they similar? The estimatedeffect of a change in a regressor (11.49). Your standard error estimates might differ from those reported
on the probability of participating in the labor force. aP/AX,, is equal to by Mroz,since his estimates are adjusted for heteroskedasticity using the
Pe( — P)*B;, the logit model and fUP)*B», in the probit model, where Halbert White [1980] robust estimation procedure. If your computer
Pis the probability of LFP, 8,; and @,, are the estimated logit and probit software program permits, also compute the White robust standard
coefficients, respectively, on the fh explanatory variable, and /( P) is the errors; your results should be very close to those reported by Mroz.
cumulative normal function corresponding to P.”* Evaluate these esti- (b) In Section 11.3.B.1 it was pointed out that these conditional OLS esti-
mated derivatives for the logit and probit models, using the sample mates are biased estimates of the parameters in Eq. (11.33). Whyare
LEPR of 425/753 = 0.568 as an estimate of P and notingthat f(?) = theybiased? Following Goldberger and Greene, computeconsistent esti-
{(0.568) = 0.393. At this sample mean, are the estimated effects similar mates of cach ofthe labor supply parameters using the LFP adjustment.
for the logit and probit models? What happens if you evaluate these In particular, catculate the sample proportion of observations for which
effects at thetail of the distribution, such as at P = 0.9 where f(P) = WHRSis positive—in the MROZdatafile this is 428/753 = 0.568.
0.175? Then divide each ofthe conditional OLS parameterestimates from part
(e) Sincethelogistic distribution has a variation of «7/3, whereas the vari- {a) by this proportion. According to Goldberger and Greene, these trans-
ation from the probit modelis usually normalized to unity, one way to formed conditional OLS estimates are consistent estimatesof thelabor
compare the logit and probit estimates is to multiply cach of thelogit supply parameters in Eq. (11.33). Are these transformed, consistentesti-
estimates by Vile & 1.73205/3.14159 = 0.5513, and then compare mates plausible? What can yousayregarding thestatistical significance
these transformed logit parameters to the actual probit estimates. Ame- ofthese transformed parameters? Why?
miya [1981] argues, however, that a better approximation emerges if (c} Now obtain consistent estimates using the Tobit estimation method
658 Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay Exercises 659

(Procedure II). In particular, using the Tobit maximum likelihood pro- equation using a sample of workers only, then using the entire sample of
cedure {the sample likelihood function corresponding to Eq. (11.33) is observations with hours of nonworkers set to zero to estimate a reduced form
Eq. (11.32) with J, now equal to X,8 + iy,) and the same functional hours worked equation derived from a reservation wage relationship, and
form as in part (a), compute the Tobit parameterestimates and asymp- finally, identifying the structural parameters ofthe reservation wage equation
totic standard errors, How do these estimates compare to the Goldberger by using the reduced form and the wage equation parameterestimates. As we
and Greene approximations from part (b)? What can you sayregarding, shall see, the reservation wage equation is underidentified,just identified, or
thestatistical significance of these Tobit parameters? overidentified depending on whetherzero, one, or more than oneregressorin
(d) As was discussed in Section 11.3.B.1, McDonald and Moffitt have the wage equation is excluded from the reservation wage equation.
shown (see Eq. (11.35)) that the total effect of the change in a regressor (a) Retrieve from Exercise 1, part (d), the parameterestimates from the
on expected hours worked in the Tobit model can be decomposed into
OLS wage determination equation in which LWW wasregressed on a
two parts: the change in hours worked for those already working
constant, WA, WE, AX, WA2, and CIT and the sample was confined
weighted by the probability of workingplus the changein the probability
to those who worked (the first 428 observations). This corresponds to
of working weighted by the expected value of hours worked for those
the equation, with / subscripts deleted for simplicity,
who work. Using the sample proportion of those who work (428/753 =
0.568) as an estimate of F(z), the Tobit parameter estimates from part LWW = g. + WA + g, WA2 + g, WE
{c), and data evaluated at sample means,calculate 4 as outlined under- + g CIT + g, AX + ew (11.61)
neath Eq. (11.35). Note: For F(z) = 0.568, z = 0.175 and f(z) = 0.393.
Ofthetotal change in hours worked due to a $1 change in the wagerate, where the g's are OLS parameter estimates and ey. is the OLS residual.
what amountresults from changesin hours worked from those who are (b) Next specify three alternativestructuralreservation wage equations, and
already working? What amount comesfrom new entrants into the labor then using a transform of Heckman’s proportionalityrelation (11.42),
force? Whatis the proportion ofthetotal effect on hours worked of a write out their corresponding reduced form representations. Specifically,
changein any ofthe variables that derives from those women who arc three possible structural representations for the log of the reservation

i a
already working? wage (L.WR) equation, analogousto Eq. (11.41). are
Thelikelihood function (11.32) for the Tobit model indicates that the Just identified:
(e)
Tobit can be envisaged as combining a probit modelof laborforce par- LWR = ay + a, WA + a WA2 + a, WE + a, CIT
ticipation with a standard regression model of hours worked for those + ds KL6 + a, K618 + a, PRIN + a, UN + (11.62)
who work {see Section 11.3.B.1). One might therefore concludethatif
the sample were limited to those who work, Tobit estimates would be Overidentified:
numerically equivalent to OLS estimates. Would such a conclusion be LWR = by + b, WA + b, WA2 + b, WE + b, KL6
correct? Why or why not? Verify your intuition numerically, using data
in the MROZdata file, by estimating a Tobit model,restricting the sam-
+ b, K618 + 6, PRIN + 4,UN + ¢ (11.63)
ple to the first 428 observations(the workers) and-comparing these Tobit Underidentified:
estimates with the OLS estimates ofpart (a).
fn this exercise we have numerically related the Tobit and conditional LWR = @ + ¢, WA + ¢, WA2 +c WE + CIT + 6, AX
OLS estimates in a model oflabor supply. As was pointed out in Section + o KL6 + ¢, K618 + & PRIN + 6 UN + ¢ (11.64)
11.3.B.1, however,there are scriousstatistical problems with the Tobit where PRIN is the property incomevariable construcied in part {c) of
and conditional OLS procedures that were employed in this exercise. Exercise { and « is a random disturbance. Note that in Eqs. {11.62},
Whatare these problems? a 1.63), and (11.64) there are one (AX), two (AX and CIT), and zero
variables, respectively, included in the LWW equation (11.61) but
excluded from the LWR equation. For each of these three reservation
EXERCISE 5: Identifying Parameters In a Reduced Form Estimation wage cquations, first employ a log-transformation of Heckman’'s pro-
portionality relation (£1.42),
The purpose ofthis exercise is to explore issues of identification of the struc-
tural parameters when the reduced form Procedure [V method is imple- H, = d(LWW, — LWR,) iff LWW, > LWR, (11.65)
mented empirically. In essence, this procedure involves first estimating a wage H,=0 iff LWW, < LWR, (11.65b)
Exercises 661
60 Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay

then substitute into Eqs. (11.65) for LWW the OLS estimated wage EXERCISE 46: Implementing the Heckit Generalized Tobit Estimator
determination equation (11.61) and for LWR one of the LWR specifi-
cations in Eqs. (11.62)-(11.64), Having done this, you should bave The purpose of Exercise 6 is io have you implement and interpret the Heckit
obtained three alternative reduced form equations for hours worked,
multistage Procedure VIIL. This is accomplished by having you replicate
each in terms of the underlying structural parameters, exogenous vari- results reported by Mroz (1987]. Youalso will compare the Heckit sample
ables, and disturbances. selectivity procedure to an OLS-based method due to Olsen [1980].
(ec) Using the entire sample of 753 observations in the MROZ data file
andsetting hours of nonworkers to zero, estimate by OLS the reduced (a) In the first stage of the Heckit procedure, one estimates a probit LFP
form equation corresponding to the just identified equation (11.62) equation and retrieves from this estimated equation the inverse Mills
derived in part {b), using the g estimates from Eq. (11.61) to solve ratio A. Mrozfirst generates a numberof polynomial transformationsof
for the @ parameters in Eq. (11.62). This procedure is often called the wife's age, education and experience variables to be used as explan-
indirect least squares, Do these structural estimates of the a param- atory variables in the LFP equation. Forthe entice sample of753 obser-
eters make sense? Why or why not? What about your estimate of vations in the MROZdata file, following Mroz, generate AX2 o
d? Next, employ a more direct estimation procedure. Specifically. AX#AX, WA? & WAsWA, WE2 & WE*WE, WA3 = WA2*WA, WE3
using your reduced form equation corresponding to Eq. (1 1.62), = WE2+WE, WAWE = WA*WE, WA2WE = WA2«WE, and WAWE2
construct transformed regressors variables as the product of the = WA*WE2. With this sample, estimate by maximum likelihood a
original regressors in Eq. (11.61) and their estimated g coetticients, probit model in which LFP is the dependent variable and the explana-
and then estimate by OLS the resulting equation with these trans- tory variables include 2 constant term, Ki.6, K618, WA, WE, WA2,
formed variables as regressors. Verify that you obtain the same WE2, WAWE, WA3, WE3, WA2WE, WAWE2, WFED, WMED,UN.
structural estimates of the @ and d parameters as you did with the CIT, and PRIN (this last variable was calculated in part (c) of Exercise
indirect least squares procedure. Are the standard error estimates 1). From this estimated probit model, calculate the inverse Mills ratio
from this direct procedure appropriate for doing inference? Why or for each observation,save this variable, and call it INVRI. (Some com-
why not? . puter software programsofferthis calculation as an optional command:
(a) To understand complicationsthat arise when the reservation wage equa- for others, it must be computed bybrute force, using Eq. (11.37) and
tion is over-identified,first show thatin the reduced form equation cor- values from the normal distribution.) Now redo the probit estimation,
responding to Eq, (11.63) derived in part (b) 2 parameter restriction this time adding the experience variables AX and AX2 and calling the
must be imposed so that a unique estimateof d is obtained. Using the corresponding inverse Mills ratio values INVR2, Commenton the sta-
entire sample of 753 observations in the MROZ data file and setting listical significance of parameters estimated in these two probit equa-
hours of nonworkers to zero, impose this parameterrestriction, estimate tions. Note that the LWW! wagevariable is excluded as an explanatory
by OLS the constrained, overidentified reduced form equation. and variable in this probit model. Since econumic theory supgests that LFP
solvefor the b parameters in Eq. (11.63) and for d. Do these structural is affected by the wage rate, why is this LWW varisble excluded? In
estimates of the # and ¢ parameters make sense? Why or why not? what sense, however, might it be included indirectly?
Derive, interpret, and then implement empirically a test for the over- {b) Next, restricting your sample to those who work for pay(the first 428
identified model (11.63) as a special case of the just identified model observations in MROZ). estimate by OLS a wage determination eqt
11.62). tion allowing for sample selectivity and compare results to an equation
cS Show at if you were to estimate by OLS the reduced form equation that does not take into account the sampleselectivity. In particular, fol-
corresponding to the underidentified reservation wage equation a 1.64) lowing Mroz, let LWW be a linear function of a constant term, KL6,
derived in part (b), there is no way that you can obtain unique estimates K618, WA, WE, WA2, WE2, WAWE, WA3, WE3, WA2WE, WAWE2,
of the ¢ and ¢ structural parameters. If you nonetheless estimated this WMED,WFED,UN, CIT, and PRIN. Callthis set of explanatoryvari-
feduced form equation by OLS, what woutd the R? be relative to that ables "Set A,” Estimate this equation by OLS (if your software permits,
from the just identified reduced form estimation ofpart (c)? Why does employ the White [1980] robust standard error procedure), and com-
this occur? ment onthe signs andstatistical significance of the estimated parame-
(fy There is a serious drawback with the Procedure IV estimation you have ters. Redo this OLS estimation, addingto Set A the experience variables
donein this exercise. Whatis this problem? AX and AX2. Interpret any changes in results. Then, with the same 42%
162 Whether and How Much Women Workfor Pay s 663

observations, estimate by OLS two wage determination equations that form closely with these reported by Mroz, reproduced in Eq. (11.52). Is
allow for sampleselectivity:first, an LWW wage determination equation sample selectivity important when the experience variables are treated
with the Set A variables and the INVR1 inverse Mills ratio variable as exogenous? Why or why not?
(from part (a)) included as regressors and second, an LWW wage deter- {d) Interpret your findings in part (c), commenting in particular on the
mination equation with the Set A variables included, but with the AX, importance of allowing for sampleselectivity and how this sensiti is
AX2 experience measures and the corresponding INVR2 variable also affected by the assumption of exogeneity of the experience variables.
included. Commenton the sensitivity of the estimated parameters to Mroz concludes that with his preferred specifications the uncompen-
inclusion of the experience variables and to the sample sclectivily adjust- sated wage effect for his sample is smail, as is the estimated income
ment.Is sample selectivity significant? (You may use large sample dis- effect. Do you agree? Why or why not? (You might want to compare
tribution theory and the White {1980] robust standard error method to results here with those from other studies, reported in Table 11,2.)
conduct statistical inference.) {e) Now compare the Heckit inverse Mills ratio procedure to the OLS-based
() Finally, restricting your sample to those who workfor pay {the first 428 linear probability model method proposed by Olsen [1980]. In particu-
observations in MROZ), use the fitted values from the wage determi- lar, using a mode! either with or without the AX and AX2 experience
nation equation in part (b) as instruments in a sample selectivity- variables, follow the Olsen procedure outlined in Section 11.3.B.1
adjusted two-stage least squares estimation of the hours worked equa- undemeath Eq. (11,37) and use as a regressor in the wage rate deter-
tion. Specifically, following Mroz, for a base case comparison, first mination and hours worked equations,instead ofthe inverse Mills ratio,
employ instrumental variable (IV) estimation (with the White robust thefitted probability minus | from an OLS-estimated linear probability
standard error procedure if it is available in your software} of an hours model. Compare these results with those obtained from the Heckit pro-
worked equation in which WHRSis the dependent variable and the cedure. Do they differ substantially?
explanatory variables include a constant term, KL6, K618, WA, WE, Tn whatsense is the estimation procedure ofthis exercise a generalized
LWW,and PRIN;call this set of explanatory variables “Set B.” fn this Tobit estimator?
IV or 2SLS estimation, treat LWW as an endogenousvariable, and use
the Set A variables defined in part (b} to form instruments. How do your
results compare with those reported by Mroz, reproduced in Eq.
EXERCISE 7: Incorporating Income Faxesinto a Modelof Labor
(IL51)? (Note: Mroz’s standard error estimates employ the White
tobust standard error procedure. If your sofiware does not permit this,
Supply
your OLS standard error estimates will differ slightly from those in Eq. The purpose ofthis exercise is to enable you to assess the impacts of incor-
(11.51). Next allow for sample selectivity, but exclude the experience Pporating income taxes on your estimates of the wage and income responsive-
variables. Specifically, using the same Set A variables plus the INVRI
hess of labor supply. This will involve creating virtual income and after-tax
inverse Mills ratio variable to form the instrument for LWW,estimate wagerate variables that are consistent with a linearized budget constraint
by IV or 2SLS an hours worked equation with the Set B variables as (LBC) budget constraint specification, estimating by using the Heckit gener-
fegressors (using robust standard error methods if possible), but with wen procedure, and comparing results with those reported by Mroz
INVR! added as a regressor. How do your results compare with those 1 .
reported by Mroz, given in Eq. (11,53)? Is sampleselectivitysignificant?
Whyor why not? (Vote: Mroz’s standard error estimates are based on a @ Ourfirst task is to create several tax-related variables. For the entire
formula derived in his Appendix—his estimates will difler slightly from sample of 753 observations in the MROZdaia file,first create and save
those of the White robust standard error procedure.) Then estimate a a virtual property income variable defined as VPRIN = (1 —
model by 2SLS in which the experience variables AX and AX2 are MTR)*PRIN, where PRIN was created in part (c) of Exercise { and
included along with the Set A variables in thefirst-stage wage determi- MTRis the marginaltax rate variable provided in the MROZdata file.
nation equation, but in which sample selectivity is not taken into Next, generate and save LTAX = LOG(I— MTR) andthelogarithm of
account and only the Set B variables are regressors. Compare your an after-tax wage variable as LTWW = LTAX + LWW1, where LWWI
tesults with those of Mroz, reproduced in Eq. (11.50). Finally, include is the wagevariable created in Exercise J.
the experience variables AX and AX2, the Set A variables, and the (b) To implementthe Heckit multistage procedure thatallows for sample
INVR2 inverse Mills ratio as variables in forming the instrument for selectivity, we must initially estimate a probit LFP equation for the
LWW,andthenestimate by 2SLS the hours worked equation including entire sample of 753 observations and compute from this estimation the
as repressors the Set B variables and INVR2. Your results should con- Heckman inverse Mills ratio. Following Mroz,first generate polynomial
364 Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay Exercises 665

transformations ofthe wife's age, education, and experience variables, mated simultaneously by using the method of full information maximum
10 be used as explanatory variables in the LFP cquation. In particular, likelihood (FIML), with cross-equation parameter constraints imposed. As
for the entire sample of 753 observations in the MROZdata file, gen- wasnoted in Section 11.3.B.1, Killingsworth [1983] hascalled this Procedure
erate and save WA2 = WA*WA, WE2 = WE*WE, WA3 = WA2=WA, Vi.
WE3 = WE2*WE, WAWE = WA*WE, WA2WE = WA2*WE, and
WAWE2 = WA*WE2. With this sample, estimate by maximum likeli- (a) We begin by specifying the wage equation for workers only, where
hood a probit model in which LFP is the dependent variable and the LWWisspecified to be a linear function ofa constant term, WA, WA2,
explanatory variables include a constant term, KL6, K618, WA,
WE, WE, CIT, AX,and a random disturbance term ex, as in Eqs. (11.38)
WA2, WE2, WAWE, WA3, WE3, WA2WE, WAWE2. WFED, and (11,61), Next we specify the functional formofthe reservation wage
WMED,UN, CIT, and PRIN (thislast variable was calculated in part equation derived from the marginalrate ofsubstitution function. In par
(c) of Exercise 1), From this estimated probit model, calculate the ticular, let the logarithm of the reservation wage equation be LWR and
inverse Mills ratio for each observation,save this variable, and call it tet it have the functional form as in the overidentified equation (11.63)
INVR. (Some computer software programs offer this calculation
as an but denote the disturbance term in Eq. (11.63) by ex, as in Eq. (141),
optional command; for others it must be computed bybrute force using Finally, following Heckman [1974b], specify that hours worked,
Eq. (11.37) and values from the normal distribution.) . WHRS,is a proportion ¢of the difference between LWWand LWR iif
(c} Nowestimate a model with ae included , similart o walPre sentedi n LWw, > LWR,andis zero iff LWW, < LWR, analogous to Eqs.
. (11.55), by 2SLS, Specifically, using as exogenous variables a - (11,65a) and (1).65b). Finally, analytically substitute into the hours
aot cm KL6, K618, WA, WE, WA2, WE2, WAWE, wa3, WE3, worked equations (11.65a) and (11.65b) your specifications for the
WA2WE, WAWE2, WMED, WFED,UN, CIT, PRIN and the inverse LWW and LWR equations. and note that in Eq. (11.65a) the distur-
Mills ratio variable INVR from part (b), form an instrument for the log bance term. now denoted dep,is equal to dep, = dew, — em). which is
of the after-tax wage rate variable LTWW (created in part (a).
With similar to Eq. (11.45a) but with dreplacing b.
these instruments for LTWW, estimat e by 2SLS a model in which (by) Now assume that ey, and eg, are joint normally distributed with vari-
WHRSis a linear function of a constant term, LTWW, LTAX, KL6, ances oj. and o} and covariance ows. This implies that in the hours
K618, WA, WE, PRIN, VPRIN, INVR, and a random disturbance worked equation that you constructed in part (a) the disturbance term
term. If your software permits, obtain the White robust standard ertor €p, is normally distributed with variance oj, = 6% + o) — 2owe and is
estimates. Comment on the sign and magnitude of the estimated wage, joint normallydistributed with e», having covariance guy = ah ~ one.
property income, and tax coefficients. Using the information given Given these distributional assumptions, write out thelikelihood func-
underneath Eq. (11.35) and your estimated variance-covariance matrix tion for the entire sample of 753 observations, analogous to Eq. (11.47).
of the estimated coefficients, formulate and test the hypothesisthat where d now replaces and othertermsare as defined by Eq. (11.47).
women optimally take income taxcs into account when making
labor (c) Using the appropriate computersoftware and the 753 observations from
supply decisions. Then formulate and test the bypothesis tha women the MROZdatafile aswell as thelikelihood function constructed in part
entirely ignore income taxes when making labor supply decisions, Inter- (b), estimate by maximum likelihood the parameters appearing in the
reported by extended Tobit model consisting of the wage and hours worked equa-
pret your test results. Do your conclusions agree with those
Mroz and by Rosen [1976]? Why or why not? | tions. Mroz reports that whenhe estimated a model similar 10 this, he
{d) Experiment with any two other plausible specifications for the probit, obtained a large positive and statistically significant coefficient on LWW
wage determination, and/or hours worked equations with laxes but a negative and marginally significant coefficient on PRIN. Are your
included, and commentonthesensitivity of your results to changes in results qualitatively similar to those of Mroz?
taxes
specification. Do Mroz’s results on the unimportance of income {d) Finally, following Mroz,specify an alternative modelin which the expe-
appear to be robust? rience variable AX is excluded from the wagerate determination equa-
tion, Asin parts (a) and (b). write out the correspondinglikelihood func-
tion, and then estimate parameters using the FIML method. Compare
EXERCISE 8: Specifying and Estimating an Extended Tobit Modei yourresults to those obtained in pact (c). Mroz found that when the AX
experience variable was omitted from the wage determination equation,
us
In thisexercise you will specify and estimate an extended Tobitsimultanco the estimated FIML coefficient on LWWin the hours worked equation
equations model in which paramete rs of the wage fate, reservati on wage {and was positive but much smaller than when AX was included (and statis-
ly, hours of work), and labor force participation equations are estl- tically insignificantly different from zero). However, the estimated coef
666 Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay Notes 667

ficient on PRIN was negative andstatistically significant, but smaller in . Descriptionsofthe data gathered at Ohio State are found in Parnes et al. [1970],
absolute value than when the AX variable was included in Eq. (11.61). white those ofdata collected at the University of Michigan are presented in Mor.
Do your results conform with those of Mroz? Why or why not? gan et al, [1966, 1974].
The mode!specified and estimated in this exercise is based implicitly on }. Fora classic presentation of the individual labor supply model, sce H. Gregg Lewis
an important assumption concerning the continuity of the hours
(1957),
}. This reservation wage notionis apparently ducto Jacob Mincer[1963]. Important
worked relationship. Whatis this assumption, and under whatpractical extensions and applications include those of Reuben Gronau{1973b] and James
considerations might it be violated? What estimation procedures are Heckman (1974b};also sce Gronau { 1986).
available that do not require this strong assumption? . The expressions in Eqs. (11.12}-(11.14) implicitly assumethat interior solutions
occurboth before and after the small change in P,.
- This choice of nomenclature is somewhat unfortunate, since while chauvinism is
CHAPTER NOTES clearly undesirable, this particular model might or might not be a reasonable
description of houschold decision making.
. These data are taken from the 1989 Economic Report ofthe President, Washing- . For examples ofthe use of the male chauvinist model, see, amongothers, Bowen
ton, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, Table B-36,p. 349. and Finegan [1965, 1969] and Hausman (1981a).
. For a detailed discussionoffactors affecting the timeseries growth ofthe female . Applicationsofthis model include Marvin Kosters [1966]: Malcolm Cohen, Sam
jabor force supply, see James P. Smith and Michael Ward [1985] and the refer- Rea, and Robert Lerman [1970}; Robert Hail [1973]: Orley Ashenfelter and
ences cited therein. James Heckman [1974]; and Jerry Hausman and Paul Ruud (1984).
. Reasonsfor this decline are discussed and surveyed by, amongothers, John Pen- This duopoly type of model of labor supply has been implemented by J. S. Ash-
cavel (1986). worth and David T. Utph (1981).
|. To a first approximation the effect of truncation occurs when sample data are . Fora discussionof such indirect incomeeffects, see Killingsworth (1983, pp. 36-
drawn from a subset of'alarger populationof interest (e.g., those in the laborforce 38}.
are selected from those in the population as a whole), whereas censoring occurs |. The added worker hypothesis appears to have been first pointed out by Wladimir
whenvalues over a range of a variable are reported simply as beingless than (or S. Woytinsky[1940].
greater than) some given value(e.g., the unobserved reservation wage is less than ‘Onthis, see, for example, Mincer [1962, 1966] and Belton M. Fleisher and George
the market wage facing an individual). Unlike truncation, censoringis essentially P. Rhodes, Jr. [1976].
a defect in the sample data. }. Ronald G. Ehrenberg and Robert S. Smith [1985. p. 204] note that if one incor-
Fora survey ofissues concerning the labor supply of maies, see John Pencavel porated estimates of discouraged workers into official unemployment rale statis-

1986}. tics, thea the U.S. unemployment rate in 1973, for example. would have increased
Veeever, see theclassic study by P. Sargant Florence (1924). from 4.9 to 5.6%. There is some evidence, however,that for a substantial aumber
as

For a more detailed discussion of measurementissues, see, for example, Harold ofdiscouraged workers the attachment to the laborforce is loose, and soit is not
‘Watts et al. [1977] and Shirley J. Smith [1983]. clear how one should interpret the welfare consequences of the discouraged
Detailed data on U.S, government household surveys are found in two U.S. workereffect; see, for example, Pau! Flaim [1984]. For this and other reasons.
Bureau of LaborStatistics publications, an occasional one called Handbook of considerable controversy exists concerning whether published unemployment
Labor Statistics, Technical Notes, and the monthlypublication called Employ rates should include estimates of discouraged workers. A usefuldiscussionofthis
ment and Earnings. International comparisonsof laborforce participation and set of issues is found in the final report of the National Commission on Employ-
international data sources are discussed in, among others, Constance Sorrentino ment and UnemploymentStatistics (1979. pp. 44-49].
11983]. The discussion that follows is based in farge part on Danie) Hamermesh . The discussion that follows is based in large part on Addison and Sieben {1979
and Albert Rees [1988], Chapter 1. pp. 79-85).
Issues involved in assessing factors that affect the supply of laborto the U.S. mil- . For a discussion of such family economics issues and additional references, see
2

itary are discussed in, among others, Cotin Ash, Bernard Udis, and Robert F. Gary S. Becker (1981, 1988).
McNown [1983]. . A partial list of studies includes the theoretical and econometric analyses by Mare
. These figures are taken from Hamermesh and Rees {1988, Table 2.5}. tin Browninget al. (1985), Kim B. Clark and Lawrence H. Summers [1982], Gil-
. Another,less commonly used data set is one that focuses particular attention on bert R. Ghez and Gary S. Becker (1975), James J, Heckman [1978], James J.
the variety of sources of income.I is the U.S. Bureau of Census Survey ofIncome Heckman and Thomas E. MaCurdy(1980, 1986], Richard Layard and Jacob
and Program Participation, undertaken as a joint project with the U.S. Depart- Mincer [1985], Thomas E, MaCurdy [1981], Robert A. Moffitt [1984}, Alice Nak-
ment of Health and Human Services. For a discussion ofthis data set, see U.S. amura and Masao Nakamura [1985a, b], and T. Paul Schultz [1980].
Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census [1987]. 28, Other earlystudies cstimating the effectsoffixed costs on labor supply include
. For additionaldiscussion, see Daniel S. Hamermesh [1990]. those by Giora Hanoch (1976, 1980] andJerry A. Hausman (1980).
368 Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay Notes 669

29. Thisclassification scheme was actually developed earlier by James J. Heckman, 47, There are other important problemsin analyzing thelabor supplyeffects oftaxes.
Mark R. Killingsworth, and Thomas &, MaCurdy [1981]. To determine the appropriate marginal after-tax wage rate, researchers typically
30. Sce, for example, Robert E. Hall (1973). must employpublished statutory tax cate information. However, actual marginal
B. This procedure is foliowed by cach of the authors in Cain and Watts [1973b], after-tax wage rates may differ substantially from statutoryrates, owing to com-
except for Hall (1973]. plex exemptionsand deductible expense provisions, underreporting or cunceal-
32. Heckman,Killingsworth, and MaCurdy [198t, pp. 83-84), mentofincome by individuals, and/orto discretionary administrative behavior
33. Whenthis type of modelis implemented using paneldata, it is often assumed that bytax-collecting agencies. With the exception of William Gould [1979], hardly
although ¢varies across people at anygiven point in time, for any oneperson it any empirical work has been doneto date on the labor supply implicationsoftax
is fixed overtime. A discussion of econometric techniques that exploit panel data avoidance and tax evasion; however, for theoretical discussiuns ofthis Topi, see
is beyondthe scope ofthis chapter: see, however, Zvi Griliches, Bronwyn H.Hall, Jonathan C. Baldry [1979]. Ame J. Isachsen and Steiner Strom [1980], Agoar
and Jerry A. Hausman [1978]. Griliches and Hausman [1986}; and Cheng Hsiao Sandmo {1981}, and James J. Heckman (1983). Further,it widely believed that
[1986]. the available data on hours worked measure actualhours worked witherror, which
<3 Recall that the first-order conditionsforut maximization at an interior solu- implies that the budget consiraint segmentfacing the individual might be misspec-
tion implythat the marginal rate of substitution Af equals the real wage rate 1’, ified. This issue has been addressed by, among others. Burtless and Hausman
that is, that the slope of the indifference curve equals the slope ofthe budgetline. (1978), Hausman [1980], and Wates and Woodland [1980].
35. Probit analysis has a long history in biometrics; sce, for example, David J. Finney 48. This is slightly beter than the cynical summaryoffered George Johnson (1976,
[1947] and Jerome Corfield and Nathan Mantel [1950}. For early discussions in P. 107, fa. 9] concerning estimates of input substitutability in production: “In
the context of econometrics, see James Tobin {1955] and Arthur S. Goldberger Fecent years, economists have narrowedits value duwn to a ringe between zero
[1964, pp. 248-251]. andinfinity.”
36. Forfurtherdiscussion, see, itter afia, Tobin (1958), Amemiya {1973}, and Mad- 49. Wales and Woodkaind [1979] and Zabalza [1983] employ the CES direct utility
dala [1983, Chapter 6]. The etymology of Tobitis unclear, although Goldberger function, while Burttess and Hausman [1978] and Hausman (1980. 19819, 1983]
[1964, p. 253] refers to it as Tobin's probit. Maddala (1983, p. 151] suggests that adopt a form that places a priori inequality (negative) restrictions on the totul
there is presumably no connection with the prophet Tobit or the book of Tobit in income elasticity. Ashworth and Ulph { 1981] restrict their sample to people who
the Apocrypha. It is known that James Tobin achieved a distinguished record in work at least cight hours per week bul donot corrcct for the potent
the U.S. Navy during World Waril, including anti-submarineduty, Further, Kil-
lingsworth (1983, fo. 7, p. 142) notesthat the novelist Herman Wouk wasa class- 50. Orley Ashenfelter and James J. Heckman [1974] consider a joint labor supply
mate of Tobin's in naval officer training school and that in his best-seller The mode! but do not incorporate the effects of taxation. For another attempt at
Woukcreated a midshipman character named “Tobit.” including tases in the family labor supply context, see Jerry A. Hausmanand Paul
. Computationalissues concerning estimation of the Tobit model have been con- Ruud {1984).
sidered by. amongothers, Richard N. Rosett and Forrest D. Nelson [1975] and SI. Note that in countries such as Canada where spouses file separate income tax
RayFair [1977]. returns, Unis marriage taais less of an issue. For further discussion, see Alice Nak-
. For a discussion of more general utitity functions and their implied consumer amura and Masao Nakamura [198 la}.
demandand labor supply equations, see Arthur S. Goldberger [1987]. $2. Hausman(19814, p. 63]. Also see Hausman [1986].
. McDonald and Moffitt emphasize that 4 will equal | only if X is infinity, in which 53. This conventional wisdom has also been persistently attacked by Alice Nakamurs.
case F(z) = 1 and f(z) = 0. ‘ and Masao Nakamura [1981b; 1985a, bj.
. In practi . this is typically done byevaluating the expressions at sample means 34. A more complete survey offemale labor supply is presented in Table 2.26ofKil-
ofthe variables and using estimated parameters. lingsworth and Heckman [1986, pp. 189-192].
- Forfurtherdiscussion, see Olsen [ 1980). and for a generalization to accommodate 55. Mroz [1987, p. 769].
other distributions, see Lung-Fei Lec [1982]. 56. See James Durbin [1954], De-Min Wu (1973), Jerry Hausman (1978). and Hale
. For further discussion ofissues concerning the functional form ofthe wage deter bert White (198:
mination equation (11.38), see Chapter 5 ofthis book. $7, That KL6,the number of children under age sin, and perhaps KG18, are exoge-
a
43, See Killingsworth [1983, Table 4.1, p. 15t] and Killingsworth and Heckman. Rous is 4 somewhat surprising finding. One possibilityis that the power of the
Durbin-Wu-Hausman-White specification test may be low, Particularly when the
(1986, Table 2.26,p, 192] for a very brief tabular summary ofthese cight methods.
44, Oneofthe first statements of this sample selectivity problem in the context of fit from the first-stage regressionsis low, For a discussion of such powerissues far
laborsupply is found in Reuben Gronau [1973a). this test, see Nakamura and Nakamura { [985c}.
45. In practice, this factor of proportionality often applics to the differencein the nat- 58. It is worth noting Uvat when the two experience variables are excluded fromthe
ural logarithms of W, and ¥,, first-stage probit equation, the sample likelihood function falls from — 39% to
46. Forfurtherdiscussion of identification issues, see Killingsworth [1983, pp. 154~ — 450, and ofthe 16 regressors, only KL6, and V haveestimated coefficients that
156, especially footnotes 14 and 17) and Olsen [1980]. are more than twice their estimated standard errors.
dustin
&
70 Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay References 671

59. Mrozalso reports thatthese findings are essentially unchanged whenthefirst-stage ipation is .50, .. . , the results ofall three statistical techniques are similar. How-
probit equationis altered to reflect alternativedistributions such as thelogit or log ever, when the actual probability of panicipation is nearer to zero or onc. then the
normal. Furthermore,tests for the exogencity of KL6, K618. and 1 uniformly probit orlogit results differ substantially from the finear probabilityfunction.”
indicate nonrejectionof the null hypothesis of exogeneity. 73, Historical aspects ofthelogit specification in bioassay studies are discussed bricily
. It is worth noting, however, thal use of the simple conditional mean or inverse in Joseph Berkson [1951].
Mills ratio adjustment to account for sample selectivity is at best a “first-order 74. A discussion ofgoodness-of-fit measures in the context oflimited dependent vari«
approximation” when taxes afe incorporated into the model; unless strong able models is given in, for example, G. S. Maddala [1983. pp. 37-41, 76-77].
assumptions are made similar to those specified by Hausman [1981a], the appro- 75, However, amongothers, Joseph Berkson [1951] has argued thatthelogit is pref
priate procedure is very complex and computationally cumbersome. Mroz’s crable to the probit.
results concerningthe effects of taxes shouid therefore be viewed as lentative. 76. For a discussion andderivation, see G. S, Maddala (1983, pp. 23-24).
6h. Note the similarity of this frameworkto thatof progressive taxationin static labor
supply discussed in Section 11.3.B.2; in both cases the budget constraint set con-
sists of numerous segments havingdiffering slopes.
62. ion ofthis additive separability is that C(z) or L£(2) does notaffect the CHAPTER REFERENCES
marginal utility of Cir’) or £(°) for ¢ # 2". Further, if leisure is a normal good in
eachtimeperiod, then additive separability implies thatleisure times at different Addison, John T, and W.Stanley Siebert [1979]. TheMarketfor Labor: An Analytical
points overthelife cycle must be net substitutes (holdinglifetimeutility constant). Treatment, Santa Monica, Calif: Goodycar.
Forfurtherdiscussion, sce Angus Deaton [1974]. Aigner, Dennis J. [1979]. “A Brief Introduction to the Methodology of Optimal Exper-
63. Forfurtherdiscussion, see Martin Browning, Angus Deaton, and Margaret Irish imental Design,” Journal ofEconometrics, L121, September, 7
[1985] andthereferences cited therein. Allen, R. G. D. (1938), Afathematical Analysis for Economists, London: Mac!
}. See Harold Waits, Dale Poirier, and Chris Mallar [1977], among others, for 2 Altonji, Joseph G. 11986), “Intertemporal Substitution in Labor Suppl
study implementing PO and Edward Kalachek, Wesley Mellow, and Fredric from Micro Data,” JournalofPolitical Economy, 94:3, Part 2. June, S176-S215.
Raines [1978]for PT. Amemiya, Takeshi [1973]. “Regression Analysis When the Dependent Variable Is
65. Fordetails, see Killingsworth and Heckman [1986. pp. 159-161]. Truncated Normal,” Econometrica, 41:6, November, 997-1017.
66. Fora generaltheoretical discussion on models ofendogenous dynamicwage deter- Amemiya, Takeshi [1975], “Qualitative Response Models,” Annats of Economic and
mination, see Yoram Weiss [1986]. Recent econometric studies on various aspects Suciul Measurement, 4:2, Summer, 363-372.
ofdynamic labor supply include Joseph Altonji [1986], Richard Blundell and Ian Amemiya, Takeshi [1981}, “Qualitative Response Models: A Survey,”Journal ofEco-
Walker [1982]. James Heckman and Thomas MaCurdy[1980}, Richard Layard nomic Literature, 19:4, December, 1483~1536.
and Jacob Mincer (1985), Thomas MaCurdy[1981], Robert Moffitt [1984], Alice Amemiya, Takeshi, ed. [1984], “Censored or Truncated Regression Models,” Journal
Nakamura and Masao Nakamura [1985a,b], and James P. Smith [1977, 1980]. ofEconometrics, 24:12. January/February, 1-222.
67. The labor supply effects of such quantity restrictions have been considered by, Ash, Colin, Bernard Udis, and Robert F. McNown {1983}. “Enlistments in the All-
amongothers, Angus Deaton and John M. Muelibauer {1981}, Robert A. Moff Volunteer Force: A Military Personnel Supply Model and Its Forecasts,” tuneri-
[1982], and John C. Ham [1982,1986]. can Economic Review, 73:1, March, 145-155.
68. For a survey of econometric problems with more general qualitative dependent Ashenfelter, Orley and James J. Heckman {1974}. “The Estimation of Income and
variable specifications, see, for example, Takeshi Amemiya [1981. 1984], Richard Substitution Effects in a Model of Family Labor Supply," Econometrica, 42:1,
Blundell [1987], James Heckman [1976b], G. S. Maddala [1983], and Daniel January, 73-86.
McFadden [1984]. In the context offa laborforce participation studies, see Ashworth, J. $. and David T. Ulph (1981), “Endogenecity 1; Estimating Labor Supply
Jules Thecuwes [1981] for an application of the multinomiallogit specification. with Piecewise Linear Budget Constraints,” in Charles V. Brown, ed., Taxation
69. Fordiscussions on inference from experimental data,sce, for example, Dennis J. and Labor Supply, London: Allen & Unwin, pp. $3-68.
Aigner (1979}; Michael C. Keetcy [1981]; Michael C. Keeley, Philip K. Robins, Baldry, Jonathan C. [979], “Tax Evasion and Labor Suppl Economies Letters, 3:4,
Roben G.Spiegelman, and Richard W. West [1978]; and Charles E. Metcalf January, 53-56.
[1973}. Becker, Gary S. [1965], “A Theory of the Allocation of Time Econontic Journal,
70. Paneldata issues are discussed by. amongothers, Zvi Griliches, Bronwyn H. Hall, 75:299, September, 493-517.
and Jerry A. Hausman [1978]; Gritiches and Hausman [1986]; and Cheng Hsiao Becker, GaryS. [1974], “A Theoryof Marriage,”in Theodore W. Schultz, ed., Eco
[1986). nomies ofthe Family, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 293-344.
Mm. Thanksare due to Thomas Mroz, who madethis data set available for our use. Becker. Gary S. [1981], 1 Treatise on the Family, Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard Uni-
72. Foran empirical comparison ofthe OLS,logit, and probit estimators in the con- versity Press.
text of the laborforce participation decision, see Morley K. Gunderson [1980]. Becker, Gary S. [1988] “Family Economics and Macro Behavior.” American Evo
Gunderson [1980,p. 217] finds that, “Whenthe probability oflabor force partic- nomic Review, 78: » March, 1-13.
{Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay References 673

Berkson, Joseph [1951}. “Why 1 Prefer Logits to Probits," Biometrics, 7:4, December, Deaton, Angus [1974], “A Reconsiderationof the Empirical Implications of Additive
327-339. ; Preferences,” Economic Journal, 84:334, June, 338-348.
Blundell, Richard, ed. [1987], “Specifica tion Testing in Limited and Discrete Depen- Deaton, Angus and John M. Muelibauer [1980], Economics and Consumer Behavior,
dent Variable Models,” Journal of Econontet ries, 3421/2, January/F ebruary, 1 New York: Cambridge University Press.
274, Deaton, Angus and John M. Muellbauer [1981], “Functional Forms for Labor Supply
Blundell, Richard and lan Walker [1982], “Modelling the Joint Determination
of and Commodity Demands with and without Quantity Restrictions,” Economet-
Household Labor Supplics and Commodity Demands,” Economic Journal, 92, rica, 49:6, November, 1521-1532.
June, 351-364. ; Diewert, W. Erwin ({971], “Choice on Labour Markets and the Theory of the Allo-
Boskin, Michael J. [1973], “The Economics of Labor Supply,” in Glen C. CainRand and cation ofTime,”Ottawa, Ontario: Government of Canada, Department of Man-
Harold W. Watts, eds., Income Maintenance and Labor Supply, Chicago: power and Immigration, Research Branch, mimeo.
MeNally, pp. 163-181. ; Durbin, James [1954]. “Errors in Variables.” Reviewof the International Statisticat
Bowen, William G.and T. Aldrich Finegan [1965], “Labor Force Participator ion and Institute, 22:1, 23-32.
Unemployment,” in Arthur M. Ross, ed., Employment Policy andtheLab Mar- Ehrenberg, Ronald G. and Robert S. Smith [1985}, Modern Labor Economics: Theory
ket, Berkeley, Calif.: University ofCalifornia Press, pp. 115-161. ; and Public Policy, Second Edition, Glenview, Scott, Foresman.
Bowen, William G.and T, Aldrich Finegan [1969], The Economics of Lubor Force Fair, Ray C. [1977], “A Note on the Computation of the Tobit Estimator.” Keuno-
Participation, Princeton, NJ.: Princeton University Press. metrica, 41:7, October, 1723-1727.
Browning, Martin, Angus Deaton, and Margaret Irish [1985], “A Profitable Approach Finney, David J. [1947], Probit Analysis, Cambridge, England: Cambridge University
to Labor Supply and Commodity Demands over the Life-Cycle/ ,” Ecunametrica, Press
53:3, May, 503-543. Sup-
Flaim, Paul O. [1984], “Discouraged Workers: How Strong Are Their Links to the Job
Burtless, Gary and Jerry A. Hausman(1978}, “The Effect ofTaxation on Labor ofPolitica l
Market,” Monthly Labor Review, 107:8, August, 8-11.
ply: Evaluating the Gary Negative Income Tax Experimen t,” Journal Fleisher, Belton M. and George F. Rhodes, Jr. [1976], “Labor Force Participation of
.
conumy, 86:6, December, 1103-1130. Married Men and Women: A Simultaneous Modct,” Review of Economics and
Cain, Glen G. [1966], The Labor Faree Participat ion of Married Women, Chicago: Statistics, $8:6, November, 398-406,
University of Chicago Press. - Florence, P. Sargant [1924], The Economics ofFatigueand Unrest, New York: Holt.
Cain, Glen C. and Harold W. Watts (1973a], “Toward a Summary and Synthesis of Friedman, Milton [1957], A Theory ofthe Consumption Function, Princeton N.J.:
the Evidence,” in Cain and Watts, eds., Income Maintena nceand Labor Supply, Princeton University Press.
Chicago: Rand McNally, pp. 328-367. j Fullerton, Don [1982], “Onthe Possibility of an Inverse Relationship between Tax
Cain, Glen C. and Harold W. Watts, eds. [1973b}, Income Maintena nce and Labor Rates and Government Revenues,” Journal ofPublic Economics, 19:1, October,
Supply, Chicago: Rand McNally. _ 3-22.
Clark, Kim B. and Lawrence H. Summers [1982], “Labour Force Participati
ot Ghez, Gilbert R. and Gary S. Becker [1975], The Allocation ofTime and Goods over
ing and Persistence.” ReviewofEconomic Studies, 49, Supplement,825-844 $44,, theLife Cycle, New York: Columbia University Press,
Cogan, John F. [1977], Labor Supplywith Timeand Money Costsof Participat ion: Goldberger, ArthurS, [1964], Econometric Theory, New York: John Wiley and Sons.
Report No. R-2044 to the U.S, Departme nt ofHealth, Education and Welfare, Goldberger, Arthur S. (1981), “Linear Regression after Selection,” Journal ofEcono-
Santa Monica,Calif.: The Rand Corporation. | metrics, 15:3, April, 357-366.
Cogan, John F. [1980a]. “Married Women’s Lubor Supply*A Comparis onof Aiter- Goldberger, Acthur S. [1987], Functional Form and Urility: A Revi ofConsumer
native Estimation Procedures,” in James P. Smith, ed., Female Labor pp. Supply: Demand Theory, Boulder, Colo: Westview Press.
Theory and Estimation, Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 90- Gould, William [1979], “Taxes and Female Labor Supply.” unpublished Ph.D. dis-
18.
es sertation, University ofCalifornia at Los Angeles.
Cogan, John F. [1980b), “Labor Supply with Fixed Costs of Labor Market Entry,” in Greene, William H. [1981], “Onthe Asymptotic Bias of the Ordinary Least Squares
ames P. Smith, ed., Female Labor Supply: Theory and Estimatio; n, Princeton, Estimator,” Econometrica, 49:2, March, 505-513.
NJ.: Princeton University Press, pp. 327-364. Greenhalgh, Christine (1980), “Participation and Hours of Work for Murried Women
Cogan, John F. 1981}, “Fised Costs and Labor Supply,” Econometrica, ,49:4, July, in Great Britain,” Oxford EconomicPapers, 32:2, July, 296-318.
945-963. Griliches, Zvi and Jerry A. Hausman [1986}, “Ervors in Variables in Panel Data,”
Cohen, Malcolm S., Samuel A. Rea, and Robert I, Lerman [1970], “A Micro Model Journal ofEconometrics, 31:1, February, 93-118.
of Labor Supply,” Washingt on, D.C.; U.S. Bureau of LaborStati stics, BLS Staff Griliches, Zvi, Bronwyn H. Hall, and Jerry A. Hausman[1978], “Missing Data and
Paper No. 4, ; Self-Selection in Large Panels,” Anmules de INSEE, No, 30/31, April/Septem-
Cornfield, Jerome and Nathan Mantel {1950}, “Some New Aspects of the Appli ber, 137-176.
of MaximumLikelihood to the Caiculation ofthe Dosage Response Curve, Gronau,Reuben [1973a], “The Effect ofChildren on the Housewife’s Value ofTime.”
nalofthe AmericanStatistical Association, 45:250, June, 181-210. Journal ofPolitical Economy, 81:2, Part tt, March/April, $168-S199.
‘4 Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay References 675

Gronaw, Reuben [1973p], “Home Production: A Forgotten Industry.” ReviewofEco- Hausman, Jerry A. [1985]. “Taxes and Labor Supply, in Alan Auerbach and Martin
nomies and Statistics, 62:5, August, 408-415, . - Feldstein, eds., Mandbuvk ofPublic Econamic New York: Elsevier Science Pub-
Gronau, Reuben [1973 ‘The Intrafamily Allocation of Time: The Value of the lishers BY, pp. 213-263.
Housewives’ Time," -vnerican Econontic Review, 63:4, September, 634-65 1. Hausman,Jerry A. and Paul Ruud [1984], “Family Labor Supply with Tases,” Aster:
Gronau, Reuben [1977], “Leisure, Home Production, and Work—The Theoryof the ican Economic Review, 74:2, May, 242-248.
Allocation of Time Revisited.” Journal ofPolitical Economy, 85:6, December, Hausman,Jerry A, and David A. Wise [1976], “The Evaluationof Resulis fromTrun-
1099-1124, . catcd Samples: The New Jersey Income Maintenance Experiment.” tanaly of
Gronau, Reuben [1986], “Home Production: A Survey,” Chapter in Orley Ashen- Economicand Social Measurement, 5:4, Fall, 391-420.
felter and Richard Layard, eds., Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol. |, New Heckman, James J. [1971], “Three Essays on the Supply of Labor and the Demand
York: Elsevier Sciences BV, pp. 273-304. . a for Market Goods.” Ph.D. dissertation, Princeton University, Deparment of
Gunderson, Morley K.[1980], “Probit and Logit Estimates of Labor Foree Pantici- Economics.
pation,” fndustrial Relations, 19:2, Spring, 216-220. . Heckman, James J. {1974a], “Life Cycle Consumption and Labor Supply: An Expla-
Hall, Robert E. [1973], “Wages, Income and Hours of Workin the U.S. Labor Force, nation of the Relationship between Income and Consumption over the Life
in Glen C. Cain and Harold W. Watts, eds., Income Maintenance and Labor Sup- Cycle.” American Economic Review, 64:1, March, 188-194,
ple, Chicago: Rand MeNaily, pp. 102-162. ; . Heckmun, James J. [1974b}, “Shadow Prices, Market Wages and Labor Supply,”
Ham, John C.[1982], “Estimation of a Labour Supply Model with Censoring Due to Econometrica, 42:4, July, 679-694,
Unemployment and Underemployment,” Review: of Economic Studies, 49:3, Heckman, James J. [1976a], “The Common Structure ofStatisti
July, 335-354, cation, Sample Sclection and Limited Dependent Variables, and a Simple
Ham, John C. [1986], “Testing Whether Unemployment Represents Intertemporal matorfor Such Models.” -trnals ofEconomic and Sacial Measurement, 54,
Labour Supply Behavior,” Reviewof Economic Studies, 53:4, August, 559-578. 475-492,
Ham,John C. and Cheng Hsiao [1984], “Two Stage Estimation of Structural Labor Heckman,James J., ed. [1976b}, “Special (ssue on Discrete, Qualitative and Limited
Supply Parameters UsingInterval Data from the 1971 Canadian Census,” Journal Dependent Variables,” Annals ofEconomic and Social Measurement, 5:4, Fall,
ofEconometries, 24:1/2. January/February, 133-158. ows ; Heckman, James J. [1978], “A Partial Survey of Recent Research an the Labor Supply
Hamermesh, Daniel S. {1990}, “Data Difficulties in Labor Economics,” in Ernst R. of Women,” American Economie Rev May, 200-207.
Berndt and Jack E. Triplett. eds., Fifty Years ofEconomic Measurement, Chicago: Heckman,James J. {t979], “Sample Selection Bias as a Specilication Error,” Econu-
University of Chicago Press. ; metrica, ATA, Fanwary, 153-162.
Hamermesh, Daniel S. and Albert Rees (1988}, The Economics of Work and Pay, Heckman, James J. [1980], “Sample Selection Bias as a Specification Error,” in James
Fourth Edition, New York: Harper & Row. P. Smith, ed., Female Labor Supply, Princeton, : Princeton University Press,
Hanoch, Giora [1980], “A Multivariate Model of Labor Supply: Methodology and pp. 206-248.
Estimation,” in James P. Smith, ed., Female Laber Supply, Princeton, NJs Heckman, James J. [1983], “Comment on Hausman, Manin S. Feldstein, ed.,
Princeton University Press, pp. 249-326. | | Behavioral Simulation Methods in TaxPolicy Analysis, Chicago: University of
Hausman, Jerry A. [1978], “Specification Tests in Econometrics,” Econometrica, Chicago Press for the National Bureau of Economic Research, pp. 70-82,
46:6, November, 1251-1272. Heckman, JamesJ. and Thomas E. MaCurdy [1930], “A Li
Hausman,jerry A. [1979], “The Econometrics of Labor Supply on Convex Budget LaborSupply,” ReviewofEconomic Suadies, 47:1, 5:
Sets,” Economics Letters, 3:2, \7t- 174, ‘ . Heckman, James J. and Thomas E, MaCurdy (1981}, “New Methodsfor Estimating
Hausman, Jerry A.[1980], “The Effects of Wages, Taxcs and Fixed Costs on Women's Labor Supply Functions: A Su in Ronald G. Ehrenberg, ed., Rexearch in
Labor Force Participation.” Journal ofPublic Economics, October, 161- Labor Economics, Vol. 4, Greenwich. Conn: JAI Press, pp. 65-102
194. Heckman, James J. and Thomas E. MuCurdy (1986), “Labor Econometrics.” Chapter
Hausman,Jerry A. (1981a]. “Labor Supply.” in Henry J. Aaron and Joseph A. Pech- 32 in Zvi Griliches and Michael D. Intriligator, eds.. Handbouk of Econometrics,
man, eds., HowTaxes Affect Economic Behavior, Washington, D.C.: The Brook- Vol. 3, New York:Elsevier Science Publishers, pp. 1917-1977.
ings Instiution, pp. 27-72. ; ; Heckman, James J., Mark R. Killingsworth, and Thomas E. MaCurdy (1981),
Hausman, Jerry A. [1981b), “Income and Payroll Tax Policy and Labor Supply.” in “Empirical Evidence on Static Labour Supply Models: A Surveyof Recent Devel-
Lawrence H. Meyer, ed., The Supply-Side Effects ofEconomicPolicy, St. Louis, opments,” in Zmira Hornstein, Joseph Grice, and Alfred Webb, eds.. The Eeu-
Mo.: Center for the Study of American Business, Washington University, 173- nomics ofthe Labour Market, London: Her Majesty's Stationery Office, pp. 73-
202. 122.
Hausman, Jerry A. [1983], “Stochastic Problemsin the Simulation of Labor Supply,” Hsiao, Cheng [1986], Analysis of Panel Data, Cambridge, England: Cambridge Uni-
in Martin S. Feldstein, ed., Behavioral Simulation Methods in Tax Policy Anal- versity Press.
ysis, Chicago: University of Chicago Press for the National Burcau of Economic Isachsen, Arne J. and Steiner Steam {1980}, “The Hidden Economy: The Labor Mar-
Research, pp. 47-69, ket and Tax Evasion,” Scandinavian Journalof Economics, 82:2, 04-311,
Whether and How Much Women Work for Pay References 677

Johnson, George E. [1976], “Evaluating the Macroeconomic Effects of Public McElroy, Marjorie B. and Mary Jean Horney [1981], “Nash-Barguined Houschold
Employment Programs,” in Orley Ashenfelter and James Blum, eds., Evaluating Decisions: Toward a Generalization of the Theory of Demand,” International
the Labor Market Effects ofSocial Programs, Princeton, N.J.: Industrial Relations Ecanomic Review, 22:2, June, 333-349.
Section, Princcton University, pp. 90-123. McFadden, Daniel (1984), “Econometric Analysis of Qualitative Response Models,”
Katachek, Edward D., Westey Meltow, and Fredric Raines [1978]. “The Male Labor Chapter 24 in Zvi Griliches and Michael D. Intriligator, eds., Handbook ufEcono-
Supply Function Reconsidered,” Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 31:3, metrics, Vol. 2. New York: Elsevier Science Publishers BV, pp. 1395~1457.
April, 356-367. Metcalf, Charles E. [1973], “Making inferences from Controlted Income Maintenance
Keeley, Michael C. [1981], Labor Supply and Public Policy, New York: Academic Experiments.” American Economic Review, 63:3, June, 478-583.
Press. Mincer, Jacob |1962}, “Labor Force Participation of Married Women: A Studyof
Keeley, Michael C., Philip K. Robins, Rabert G.Spiegeiman, and Richard W. West LaborSupply.” in H. Gregg Lewis, ed., Aspects ofLabor Economics, Princeton,
[1978], “The Estimation of Labor Supply Models Using Experimental Data,” N.J.: Princeton University Press, pp. 63-97.
American Economic Review, 68:5, December, 873-887. Mincer, Jacob {1963}, “Market Prices, Opportunity Costs, and Income Elftets.” in
Killingsworth, Mark R. [1983], Labor Supply, New York: Cambridge University Carl Christ, ed.. Meusurement in Economics: Essays in Honor ofYehuda Gran-
Press. feld, Stanford, Calif: Stanford University Press, pp. 67-82.
Killingsworth, Mark R. and James J. Heckman[1986], “Female Labor Supply: A Sur- Mincer, Jacob [1966], “Labor Force Participation and Unemployment: A Reviewof
Chapter 2 in Orley Ashenfelter and Richard Layard, eds... Handbuok of Recent Evidence,” in Robert A. Gordonand Margaret S. Gordon, eds., Prosperity
Labor Economics, Vol. |, New York: Elsevier Science Publishers BV. pp. 103- and Unemployment, New York: John Wiley and Sons, pp. 73-112.
204, Mitchell, Olivia . [1980],“Labor Force Activity of Married Womenas a Response to
Kosters, Marvin [1966], “Incomeand Substitution Effects in a Family Labor Supply Changing Jobless Rates,” Monthly Labor Review, 103:6, June.
Model,” Santa Monica, Calif: The Rand Corporation, Report No. P3339. Moffitt, Robert A. [1982], “The Tobit Model, Hours of Work and In: ional Con-
Layard, Richard, Margaret Barton, and Antoni Zabalza [1980], “Married Women’s straints,” Review ofEconomics and Statistics, 64:3, August, 510-515.
Participation and Hours,” Economica, 47;185, February, 51-72. Moffitt, Robert A. {1984], “Profiles of Fentifity, Labour Supply and Wages of Married
Layard, Richard and Jacob Mincer, cds. [1985], “Trends in Women's Work, Educs- ‘Women: A Compicte Life-Cycle Model.” Review: of Economic Studies, 51:2,
tion and Family Building.” Journal ofLabor Economics, 3:1, Supplement, kan- April, 263-278.
uary, S1-S396. Moffitt, Robert A, and Ken Kehrer [1981}, “The Effect of Tax and Transfer Programs
Lec, Lung-Fei [1982], “Some Approaches to the Correction of Selectivity Bias, on Labor Supply: The Evidence from the Income Maintenance Experiments,”in
ReviewofEconomie Studies, 49:3, July, 355-372. Ronald G, Ehrenberg. ed. Research in Lubor Economics, Vol. 4, Greenwich,
Leuthold, Jane H. (1968), “An Empirical Study of Formals income Transfers and the Conn.: SAI Press, pp. 103-150.

site
Work Decision ofthe Poor," Journal of Human Resources, 3:3, Summer, 312- Morgan, James N., etal. {1966], Productive Americans: A Study uf HewIndividuals
323. Contribute to Economie Progress, Ann Arbor, Mich.: SurveyResearch Center,
Leuthold, Jane H. [1978], “The Effect ofTaxation on the Hours Worked by Married University of Michigan.
Women,” industrial and Labor Relations Review, 31:4, Juty, 520-526. Morgan, James N. et al, [1974], Five Thousand American Famities—Patterns of Eeo-
Lewis, H. Gregg [1957], “Hours of Work and Hours ofLeisure,” Proceedings of the nomic Progress, Ano. Atbor, Mich: Survey Research Center, University of
Industrial Relations Research Association, pp. 196-206. Michigan.
Lundberg, Shelley [1985], “The Added WorkerEffect.” Journ ofLubor Economics, Mroz, Thomas A. (1987), “The Sensitivity ofan Empirical Model of Married Wom-
3:1, Supplememt,January, SI1-S37. en's Hours of Work to Economic and Statistical Assumptions,” Econometrica,
MaCurdy, Thomas E. [1981], "An Empirical Model of Labor Supplyin a Life-Cycle 35:4, July, 765-799,
Setting,” Journal ofPolitical Economy, 89:6, December, 1059-1085. Nakamura, Alice and Masao Nakamura (198 1a]. “A Comparison of the Labor Force
Maddala, G. S. (1983], Limited Dependentand Qualitative Variables in Econometrics, Behavior of Married Women in the United States and Canada, with Special
Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press, Econometric Society Mono- Attention to the Impact of income Taxes.” Econometrica, 49:2, March, 451-489.
graphs No. 3. Nakamura, Alice and Masao Nakamura (1981b], "On the Relationships among Sev-
Manser, Marilyn E. and Murray Brown [1979], “Bargaining Analyses of Houschold eral Specification Error Tests Presented by Durbin, Wu and Hausman.” Econ
Decisions,” in Cynthia B. Lloyd, Emily S. Andrews, and Curtis L. Gilroy, eds.. metrica, 49:6, November, 1583-1588.
Women in the Labor Market, New York: Columbia University Press, pp. 3-26. Nakamura, Alice and Masso Nakamura [1985a}, “Dynamic Models of the Labor
Manser, Marilyn E. and MurrayBrown [1980], “Marriage and Household Decision- Foree Behavior of Married Women Which Can Be Estimated Using Limited
Making: A Bargaining Analysis," fnternational Economic Review, 21:1, February, AmountsofPast Information,” JournalofEconometrics, 27:3, March, 273-298.
3-44, Nakamuru, Alice and Masao Nakamura (1985b]. The Second Paycheck: 4 Sociovco-
McDonald, Jobn F. and Robert A. Moffitt [1980], “The Uses of Tobit Analysis,” nomic Analysis ofEarnings, Orlando, Fla: Academic Press.
ReviewofEconomies and Statistics, 67:2, May, 318-321. Nakamura, Alice and Masao Nakamura [1985c}, “On the Performance of Tests by
aether and How Much Women Workfor Pay Further Readings 679

‘Wuand by Hausmanfor Detecting the Ordinary Least Squares Bias Problem.” ProgramPanicipation: Users’ Guide, Washington, D.C: Customer Services, Data
Journal of Econometrics, 29:3, September, 243-227. UserServices Division.
ckamura, . Masao Nakamura, and Dallas Cullen [1979], “Job Opportunities, Wales, Terence J. [1973], “Estimation of a Labor Supply Curve for .
the Offered Wage, and the Labor Supply of Married Women,” American Keo Business Proprietors,” International Econumic Review, 14:1, February, 69-80.
nontic Rev 69:5, December, 787-805. Wales, Terence J. and Alan D. Woodland [[977}, "Estimation ofthe Allocation of
itional Commission on Employment and UnemploymentStatistics [1979], Cont- Timefor Work,Leisure and Housework,” Econometrica, 45:1, January, 115-132.
ing the Labor Force, Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office. Wales. Terence J, and Alan D. Woodland [1979], “Labour Supply and Progressive
sen, Randall J. {1980}, “A Least Squares Correction for Selectivity Bias," Keoau- Taxes,” Review ofEconomic Studies, 46:1, January, 83-95.
metrica, 48:7, November, 1815-1820, Wates, Terence J. and Alin D, Woodland [1980]. “Sample Select and the Esti-
aes, Herbert S. et al. [1970]. The Pre-Retirement Years: A Longitudinal Suadyof mation of Labor Supply Functions,” faternational EconomicRen 2, June,
the Labur Market Experience ofMen, Vol. 1. Washington, D.C.: U.S, Department 437-468.
of Labor, Manpower Administration, Watts, Harold, Dale Poirier, and Charles Mallar [1977], “Sample, Variables and Con-
sncavel, John [1986], “Labor Supply of Men: A Survey.” Chapter | in Orley Ash- cepts Used in the Analysis,” in Harold Watts and Albert Rees, eds,, The New
enfelter and Richard Layard, eds.. Handbook of Labor Economics, Val. |, New Jersey Income Maintenance Experiment: Labor Supply Response, Vol. 2, New
York: Elsevier Science Publishers BV, pp.3-I01. York: Academic Press, pp. 33-56.
osen, HarveyS. [1976], “Taxes in a Labor Supply Model with Joint Wage-Hours Weiss, Yorum [1986}, “The Determinantsof Life Cycle Earnings: A Survey.” Chapter
Determination,” Feonemetrica, 44:3, May, 485-507, 11 in Orley Ashenfelter and Richard Layard, eds... Hunelbouk of Labor Economics,
osett, Richard N. and Forrest D. Nelson [1975], “Estimation of the Two-Limit Vol. 1, NewYork: Elsevier Science Publishers BV,pp. 603-640.
Probit Regression Model,” Econvmvtrica, 43:1, January, 141-146, White, Halbert J., [1980], “A Heteroskedasticity-Consisteat Covariance Matrix Esti-
andmo, Agnar {1981}, “Income Tax Evasion, Labour Supply and the Equity-Eth- mator and a Direct Test for Heteroskedasticity.” Heonumetricu, 48:4, May, 817
ciency Tradcoff.”* Journal ufPublic Economics, 6:1, February, 37-54, 838. :
choenberg, Erika and Paul H. Douglas [ [937], “Studies in the Supply Curve of Labor. White, Halbert J, [1982], “Maximum Likelihood Estimation of Misspecified Models,”
The Relation between Average Earnings in American Cities and the Proportion Econometrica, 50:2, March, 483-499,
Seeking Employment,” Journal ofPolitical Economy, 45:1, February, 45-62. Woytinsky. Wladimir S. [1940], Additionat Workers and the Volume of Unemplay-
chult, T. Paul [1980], “Estimating Labor Supply Functions for Married Women, ment in the Depression, Washington, D.C.: Social Science Research Council.
in James P. Smith, ed., Female Labor Supply. Princeton N_J.; Princeton Uni Wu, De-Min [1973], “Tests of Independence between Stochastic Regressors and Dis-
sity Press, pp. 25-89. turbances,” Econometrica, 41:4, July, 733-750.
mith, Adam [1776], The S¥ealth of Nations, London: M. Dent & Sons. Reprinted Zabalza, Antoni[1983], “The CES Utility Function, Nonlinear Budget Constraints
in 1937 as the Cannan edition by The Modern Library, Random House, New and Labour Supply: Results on Female Participation and Hours.” Ecrnumic Jour-
York. nat, 93:370, June, 312-320.
mith, James P. [1977], “Assets, Savings and Labor Supply.” Economic Inquiry. 15:4.
October, 551-373.
«mith, James P. [1980]. “Assets and Labor Supply,” James P. Smith, ed., Female FURTHER READINGS (All are textbooksin labor economics)
LaborSupply. Princeton N.J.: Princeton University Press, pp. 166-205.
imith, James P. and Michact Ward [1985] ‘ime-Series Growth in the Female Labor Addison, John T. and W. Stanley Siebert [1979], TheMarketfor Labor: An anabytical
Force,” Journalof Labor Economic |. January, Supplement, S59-S90_ Treatment, Santa Monica, Calif: Goodyear.
imith, Shirley J. 1983], “Estimating Annual Hours of Labor Force Activity.” Ehrenberg, Ronald G. and Robert S. Smith [1985], Modern Labor Eeunumics: Theory
Monthly Labor Review, (06:2, 13-22. und Pablic Policy, Second Edition, Glenview, IIL: Scott, Foresman, ‘
jorrentino, Constance {1983}, “International Comparisons of Labor Force Participu- Fleisher, Belton and Thomas Kniesner [1984], Labur Economics: Theory, Evidence
tion, 1960-1981," Afonthiy Labor Review, 106:2, 23-36. andPolicy, Third Edition, Englewood Ctiils, N.J.: Prentice Hall.
stern, Nicholas [1986], “Onthe Specification of Labor Supply Functions.” in Richard Gunderson, Mosley and W. Craig Riddell {1988}, Labor Market Economics: Theory,
Blundell and tan Walker, eds., Unemployment, Search and Labour Supply, Cam- Evidence ‘and Policyin Canada, Second Edition, Toronto: McGraw-Hill Ryerson,
bridge, England: Cambridge University Press, 143-189, Ad.
Theeuwes, Jules [1981], “Family Labour Force Participation: Multinomial Logit Esti- Hamermesh, Daniel S. and Albert Rees [1988], The Economics of Work und Pay.
mates,” Applied Economics, 13:4, December, 481-498. Fourth Edition, NewYork: Harper & Row.
Tobin, James [1955], “The Application of Multivariate Probit Analysis to Economic MeConnell. Campbell R. and Stantey L. Brac [1986], Contemporary Labor Econom.
SurveyData," Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper 1. ies, New York: McGraw-Hill.
Tobin, James [1958], “Estimation of Relationships for Limited Dependent Variables,” Reynolds, Lloyd G., Stanley H. Masters, and Colletta H. Moser {1987], Economics of
Econometrica, 26:1, January, 24-36. Labor. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice Hall.
USS. Departmentof Commerce. Bureauof the Census [1987], Surveyof Income and
its continued from copyright neering and Econometric Interpretations of
Energy-Capitat Complementarity.” Ameri-
ral Seties No. 73, NY: Columbia Uni- can Economic Review, 69:3, June 1979, p.
y Press for the National Bureau of Eco- 351. Reprinted with permission, Fried-
¢ Research, 1961, p. 35. Reprinted with man, “The Role ofMonetary Policy.” Anter.
issiun. Griliches: Technology, Edu icun EconomieReview, 5B:1, Macch 1968, p.
dand Productivity, NY: Basil Blackwell, UL Reprinted with permission. Okun,
1988, p. 120. Reprinted with per- “Poswar Macroeconomic Performance,” in
Martin S. Feldstein, ed., The American Econ.
on. Forester, oll, The Information
nology Review, Cambridge, MA. omy in Transition, Chicago: The University Author Index
MITPress, 1985, Reprinted with of Chicago Press. 1980, p. 166. Reprinted
ission. Machlup, Journut of Political with permission. Solow, “What We Know
omy, 82:4, July/August, 1974, p. 892, and Don't KnowAbout Inflation.”” Technol-
inted with permission. Halll and Tay- ogy Review, 81:3, December 1978/Jan- Almen,Shirley. 237,
dtacrocconomics: Theory, Petformance. wary 1979, p. 31. Reprinted with permission Aaker, David, 407, 441, Ashley, Richard, 356f,
from Technology Review, copyright 1978, 4a7 288, 299 357, 374, 383, 398,
. 237, Reprinted with Lucas, Jr. and Sargent, “After Kenyesian Aaron, Henry J., 674 Altonji, Joseph G., 539, 427, 438f, 4408,
liches, “Commems on Macroeconomics,” in After the Phillips Abel, Andrew, 260, 584, 670f, 671 441
tor/Kendrick, eds... Fron Curve: Persistence of High Inflation and 296f, 297f, 298, Alworth, Julian, 302 Ashworth, 5. S., 667f,
ofQuantitative Econumics, Vol. Il, Am- High Unemployment, BOSTON: Federal 299 Amel, Dean F., 146f, 6698
im; North-Holland, 1974, p. 335. Re> Reserve Bank ofBoston, ConferenceSeries, Abernathy, William J., 146 Assmus, Gert, 392
xd with permission, Koopmans: No, 19, p. 69. Gordon, “The Theory of 676, 96f, 98 Amemiya, Takeshi, Atkinson,Scott E., 484,
ited from “Report ofthe Modeling Re- Domestic Inflation.” american Economic 621, 632, 654-656, Sol
¢ Group, 1978, with permission from Review, 67:1, March 1977, p. 132, Reprinted Abowd,John M., 210f,
670f, 671 Atrostic, B. K., 211f.
ativnal Academy ofSciences, Washing- with permission. Killingsworth, Labor 214, 522, 5810, 584
DC. Reprinted by permission of Supply, NY: Cambridge University Press, Abraham, Katherine, Anderson, Richard G.. 214
RICAN SALESMAN, © TheNational 1983, p. 432. Reprinted with permission. 176, 214, 218, 219 475, 501 Auerbach,Alan J.,
ich Bureau, Inc., 424 North Third St, Nakamura, Nakamura, and Cullen, “Job Ackley, Gardner, 363, Anderson, Theodore 297f, 299, 675
ngton, lowa 52601-5224. Clarke, Opportunities, the Offered Wage, and the 437f, 441 W.. 186 Angarten,Stan, 196,
nometric Measurement ofthe Duration Labor Supply of Married Women,” stmert- Adelman,Irma, 144f, Ando,Albert, 269, 145f, 146
Svertising Effects on Sales.” Journal of” can Econumics Review, 69:5, Devernber 146 297f, 299 Ayanian, Robert, 4401,
eting Research, 13:4, Novem! 1979, p. 787, Reprinted with permission. Andress, Frank J., 966. 44t
. p. 355. Reprinted with permission. Fullerton, “On the Possibility of an Inverse Addison, John T., 211f,
98
talensee, The Econumics ofAdvertising, Relationship between Tax Rates and Gav- 214, 222, 592,
Andrews. Emily S., 676 Bailey, Elizabeth E.,
jorth-Holland, 1972, p. 38. ernment Revenues,” Journal uf Public Evo- 667£, 671, 679
mied. with permission. Fuss, Mc numnies, 19:1, October 1982, p. 20. Reprinted Ager, MargaretE., 505 Andrisani, Paul, 189, 500f, 501
en and Mundlak, “A Survey of Fune- with permission. Jack Johnston, Ecouv- Ahl, David H., 186 216 Bailey, Martin J., 504
1 Formsin the Economics Analysis of metic Methods, Ye, © 1984, p. 335. Re» Aigner. Dennis J., 182, Anton,James J., 96f, 98 Baily, Martin N., 587
action,” in Fuss/MeFadden, eds. Prom printed with permission of McGraw-Hifl, 214, 310, 354f, Arbeiter, Larry. 407 Bain, Joseph, 415, 441
-mEconomics: A Ducal Approach to The- Inc. Rudiger Dornbusch and Stanley 356, 357, 439f, Archibald, G. Baldry, Jonathan C.,
ind Applications, Amsterdam: North- Fischer, Macrovcunomics, 4Je, © 1987, p. 441, 447, 4996, Christopher, $81f, 669f, 671
ind, 1978, p. 266. Reprinted with 315. Reprinted with permistion of McGraw. 503, 670f, 671 585 Barnett, Wiliam A.,
ission, Berndt and Wood, “Engi- Hill, Ine. Aitchison, John, 144f, Arndt, Johan, 414, 446 299, 501f, 501
TO CREDITS: 146 Arnold, Stephen J., 407, Barquin-Stolleman.
4: courtesy of Guy Orcutt. Page 5: tesy of Robert Hall Page 258: counesy of Akerlof, George A., 437, 441 Joan A., 146
ice V. Wilkes, David J. Wheeler, and James Tobin. Page 329: courtesy of Hea- 219, 212f 214 Arrow, Kenneth J.. 157. Barro, Robert J., 582f.
+y Gill, Preparation ofProgramsjor ant drik Houthakker. Page 334: photo of Alberts, William, 96f, 214, 365, 444, 452, 585, 592
cpnie Digital Computer. © V9S1, ce Daniel McFadden: courtesy ofTito Simboli. 97f, 98 50% Bartik, Timothy, £30,146
1 1985; Adgison-Wesley Publishing Page 395: courtesy of Richurd Schmnalensee. Albion, Mark S., 440£, Ash, Colin, 666f, 671 Barton, Margaret, 676
any. Reprinted with permission ofthe Page 406: courtesy of Harry V. Roberts. 443 Ashenfelter, Orley, 179, Basmann, Robert L.,
cher. Page 24: courtesy of Harry M. Page 459: courtesy of W. Erwin Diewen, Alchian, Armen, 96f, 210f, 2436, 214, 371, 441, 583f, 585
owitz. Page 38: courtesy ofSteven A. Page 440: courtesy of Dale Jongenson. 98 215, 216, 218, 221, Bass, Frank M., 380,
Page 82: courtesy of Mare Nerlove. Page 537: courtesy of Rubert E. Lucas, Je, 222, $39, 585, 607, 391, 43Bf, 441. 442
Page 546: courtesy of Ray C. Fair. Page Aliber, Robert Z., 586
115: courtesyof Zvi Griliches. Page 667f, 6698, 671, Beach, Charles M...
zourtesy of Gregory Chow. Page 628: courtesy of James Heekman. Page Allen, R.G. D., 606,
674, 676, 678, 679 356f, 357
sourtesy of Jacob Mincer. Page 185: 636: courtesyof Jerry A. Hausman. 67
sy of Alan Blinder, Page 246: cour-
681
Author Index Author Index 683

Jeauvais, Edward, 358 Blattenberges, Gail R., Brown, James A. C., Chamberiain, Gary, Cobb, Charles, 68, 451, Day. George S., 96f,
Becker, Gary, 152, 155, 315, 354f, 355f, 198, 1440, 146, 167, 215 4986, 503 97f, 98, 99
156, 169, 170, £80, 359 356f, 357 Chambertin, Edward Cochrane, Donald, 5 Daymont, Thomas,
181, 211f, 2126, Blaug, Mark, 212f, 215 Brown, Murray, 505, H., 368, 442 Coen, Robert M., 296f, 189, 216
214, 216, 602, 610, Blinder, Alan, 156, 676 Chambers, Robert G., 297f, 300. 583f, Deaton, Angus, 606,
667f, 671, 673 182-184, 188, 191, Brown, Philip, 56f, $7 S00f, 502, 506 585 670f, 672, 673
Begg, David K. H., 549, 203-208, 211f, 215 Brown, Randall S.. 484. Chapman, L. Duane, Cogan, John F., 613, de Leeuw, Frank, 236,
585 Bloch, Fasrelt, 178, 202, 502 3558, 358 633, 634, 638, 672 300
Behrman,Jere R., 189, 215 Browning, Martin, 667f. Chen,Carl R., 560, 57 Cohen, Malcoim S., Deloitte, Haskins and
215 Bloch, Harry, 441f, 442 670f, 672 607,6674, 672 Sells, 263, 300
Ben-Porath, Yoram, Bloom,David, 182, 215 Brue, Stanley L.. 180f, Cole, Rosanne, 124, de Marchi, Neil, 550,
210f, 215 Blum, James, 676 218, 222, 679 126f, 138~139, 585, 592
Bentzel, Ragnar, 577, Blume, Marshall E., Brunner. Karl, 303, 296f. 299, 452, S01 143, 1448, t45f, Desai, Meghnad, 295f,
585 55f, 56 447, 588. 590 Chiang, Judy S. Wang. 146 300, S80f, 585, 592
Ben-Ur, Joseph, 438f, Blundell, Richard, 670f, Buchanan, Norman, 482, 502 Comanor,William S.. Dhalta, Norman K.,
446 672, 678 365, 442 Chirinko, Robert S., 4408, 4411, 442 439F, 442
Bergman,Barbara R.. Bohi, Douglas R.. 328, Bultez, Alain V.. 437f, 298f, 299 Comins, KathyA., Dhrymes, Phoebus,
223 S31, 344, 357 43RE, 442, 444 Chiswick, Barry. 187, 228f, 296f, 301 145f, 147, 296f,
Bergson, Abraham, 453, Bojanek, Robert, 415, Burdett, Kenneth, 212f, 2110, 2138, 214, Constuner Reports, 300, 3558, 357
301 445 215 ans 4408, 442 Diamond, Peter A..
Berkson,Joseph, 671f, Borden, Neil H., 363, Burmeister, Edwin, 55f, Chow, Gregory C., 56f, Conway, Delores, 191, 5811, 585
672 380, 424, 442 57, 58 57, 97f, 98, 104, 215 Diewen, W. Erwin,
Berndt, Ernst R., 146f, Boskin, MichaelJ., 638, Burridge,Peter, 580f, 118, 119, 136-137, Cooper, Guy M., 55f, 100, 304, 453,
146, 217, 297f, 672 585 139-142, 1456, 58 459-460, 4991,
299, 301, 311f, Boston Consulting Burstein. Meyer L., 146, $49, 585. Cooper,J. Phillip, 288, S00f, 501, 503,
355f, 357, 449, Group, 60, 96f, 98 1446, 146 Chow, Simeon,440f, 300 631, 673
450, 454, 456, 472, Bowen, Howard R., 216 Burtless, Gary, 355f, 442 Corcoran, Mary, 184, Dillon,John, 453, 503
479, 484, 486, 487, Bowen,William G., 357, 631-633. Christ, Carl F., 54f, 57, 188, 215 Dolan, Robert J. 96f,
SOOF, SIF, 501, 6670, 672 669F, 672 99, 505, 677 Corio, Marie, 3556, 357 98
$02, 504, 505, 06, Bowles, Samuel, 213f, Butler, John £., 951, 98 Christensen, Laurits R., Cornfield, Jerome, 668f, Donner, Arthur, $16,
674 215 Butler, Richard, 186, 81-84, 90-92, 98, 672 586
Betancourt, RogerR., Box, George E. P., 145f, 215 247, 299, 354f, Court, Andrew T., 110, Dorfman, Robert, 365,
298f, 299, 354f, 146, 299, 320, 357 357, 453, 480, 482, 144f 147 442
356f, 357 Boyer, Kenneth D., Cable, John, 439f, 442 484, 499f, 502 Cowing, Thomas G.. Dornbusch, Rudiger,
Bischoff, Charles W., 4411, 442 Cain, Glen G., 182, Chu, Shih-Fan, 499f, 81, 98, 482, 503 224, 300, 5831, 86
250, 253. 286, 293, Bradford, David F., 214, 215, $96, 614, 503 Cowles, Alfred W. II, Douglas, Paul H., 68,
2981, 299 297f, 299 8686, 672, 674 Ciccolo, John H.. Jr. 20. $4f, 57 450, 451, 4981,
Bitros, George C., 296f, Brealey, Richard, 54f, Card, David, 539, 585 2971, 300 Cowling, Keith, 439f 503, 614, 678
299 558, 56f. 57 Carliner, Geoffrey. 187, Clark, J. Maurice, 233, Cox, David R., 1456, Douglass, George K.,
Black, Fisher, 38, 55f, Brechling, Frank P. R., 25 296f, 300 146 2121, 216
56 S80f, 585 Carman, David, 407, Clark, Kim B., $22, Cragg, John G., 59 Dréze, Jacques, 499f,
Blanchard, Olivier J.. Breusch, TrevorS., 568, 441 585, 6671, 672 Culten, Dallas, $93, 506
260, 296f, 2978, S84f, 585 Cartwright, David W., Clark, Peter K., 298f, 678 Dubin, Jeff, 334
298, 299, S81f, Brinner, Roger E., 5810, 125, 126f, 144f, 300 Dubrul, Stephen M.,
S836, 585 585 146 Clarke, Darral G., 361, Dasgupta, Partha, 96f, 144f, 147
Blank, David M., 393, Brown, Charles, 210f, Caves, Douglas W., 387, 389-391, 398, 98 Duesenberry, James,
398, 4376, 439f, 218 354f, 357, 482, 502 415, 4398, 440f, Davies, Nicholas, 439f, 239, 296f, 298f,
442 Brown, Charles V., 67! Ceef, Christopher, 18F 442 300, 586
684 Author Index Author Index 685

Dutberger, Ellen R., Farris, Paul W., 440f, French, Kenacth R.. Goett, Andrew A., 3566, Griffiths, William E.. Hamitton, David. 97,
145f, 146f, 146, 443 56f, 57 357 57, 99, 148, 218 99, 135, 148
147 Feldstein, Martin S., Friedlacnder, Ann F.. Goldberger, Arthur S., Griliches, Zvi, 97f, 99, Hanoch, Giora, 170,
Duncan, Greg, 184, 269, 296f, 301, 481, 482, SO0E, 97f, 99, 1440, 147, 102, 115-116, ITF, 217, 476,
188, 210f, 215, 216 590, 674, 675 50t, 502, 505 191, 192, 216, 144f, 1456, 1468, 500F, 503, 633,
Durbin, James M., 282, Ferber, Marianne A., Friedman, James W., 298f, 301, 3551, 146, 147, 148, 149, 667f, 674
296f, 300, 347, 192, 216 A37f, 443 356f, 358, 4381, 166, 167, 217, 224, Hansen, Alvin, 363,
357, 438f, 442, Ferguson, James M., Friedman, Milton, 210f, 443, 499f, $03, 236, 237, 264, 301. 437f
568, 582f, 584f, 4a0f, 443 216, 314, 357, 507, 550, 5531, 535. 304, 305, 3551, Hansen, Bent, S80f, 587
586, 669f, 673 Field, Barry C., 502, 521, 586, 648, 673 574, $80f, 5831, 358, 387, 396, 443, Hansen, Lars P., 298f,
Dutton, John M., 95f, 504 Frisch, Ragnar, 452, 587, 588, 622, 657, 504, 587, 668f, 301, $01f, $03,
98 Filer, Randall K., 189, 503 668f, 673 670f, 673, 675, 677 564, 5830, 587
216 Fromm, Gary, 297, Gollop, Frank M., 506 Gronau, Reuben, 2136, Hansen, W. Lee, 169,
Eastlack, Joseph O., Finegan, T. Aldrich, 300 Gordon, Margaret S., 217, 612, 667f, 207
4401, 442 6676, 672 Fudenberg, Drew, 96f, 677 668F, 673, 674 Hanser, Philip, 359
Eatwell, John, 445 Finney, David J., 668f, 9 Gordon, Robert A., 677 Grunfeld, Yehuda, 239, Hanssens, Dominique
Eckstcin, Otto, 586, 588 Fullerton, Don, 297f, Gordon, Rober J., 301 M,, 4408, 443
Ehrenberg, Ronald G., Fischer, Stanley, 224, 299, 301, 302, 593, 143f, 1458, 147, Guilkey, David, 482, Hanushek, Eric A..
213f, 216, 220, 300, 582f, 586 673 149, 507, 540, 503 2 217
222, 592, 672, 675, Fisher, Franklin M., Fuss, Melvyn A., 2976, SBIE, S820 S83, Gujarati, DamodarN.. Harberger, Arnold C.,
677, 679 56f, 57, 1436, 145f, 299, 449, 501f, 587 56f, 57 308, 504
tein, Albert, 20, 57 146f, 147, 312, 502, $03, 504, 506 Gorman,John A., 228f, Gunderson, Morley K.. Harman,Harry H.,
Eisner, Robert, 252, 354f, 355f, 357, 295f, 301 213f, 217, 222, 1456, 148
269, 296f, 2971, 371, 442, 577, Gabor, Andre, 354f, Gorman, William M.. 6701, 674, 679 Harper, Michael! J.,
300 SB2f, 586 144f, 147 2978, 301
Ekelund, Robert B., Jr., Fisher, Irving, 516, Galbraith, John Gould, John P.. 298f, Haavelmo, Trygve, 243, Hart, Peter, $90
393, 443 S80f, 586 Kenneth, 363, 301 297f, 301. 584f, Hartman, RaymondS.,
England. Paula, 213f, Flaim,Paul, 667f, 673 437f£, 443 Gould, William, 669f, 587 328, 3556, 358
216 Fleisher, Belton M., Gallant, A. Ronald, 96f, 673 Hall, Bronwyn H., 6681, Harvey, Andrew C.,
Epple, Dennis, 130, 147 222, 592, 6676, 99, 500f, 503 Gramm,William P., 670f, 673 289, 298f, 302,
Epstein, Roy J., 19f, 673, 679 Garber, Peter M., 549, 393, 443 Hall, Robert E., 146f, 304, 359
550, 583f, 586 Flemming, John S., 586 Granger, Clive W.3., 148, 153, 217, 224, Haugh, Larry D., 382.
Estes, William K., 95f, 269, 301 Gardner, David, 99 289, 301, 359, 374, 245, 246, 247, 445
98 Flood, Robert P., 549 Geisel, Martin S., 355f, 383, 398, 427, 2966, 297f, 301, Haugh, William D.,
Evans, MichaelK., 236, Florence, P. Sargant. 359 439f, 441, 443 S81f, 582f, $87, 212¢
301 666f, 673 Ghemawat, Pankaj, 79, Green, Carole A., 192, 631, 644,6671. Hausmun, Jerry A.,
Fomby, Thomas B.. 80f, 80, 97f, 99 216 668f, 674 355f, 357, 4388,
Fair, Ray C., 266, 292, 97f, 98 Ghez,Gilbert R.. 156, Greene, William H.. Hallett, A. J. Hughes. 443, 499f, 503,
301, 304, 4411, Foot, David K., 296f, 216, 667f, 673 81-84, 90-92, 98, S83f, 587 550, 565, SOF.
443, 535, 545, 546, 301 Gilbert, Christopher L., 622, 657, 673 Halvorsen, Robert, 325. 587, $88, 629,
549, $52, 583F, Forester, Tom, 102, 147 515, 550, 580f, Greenhalgh, Christine, 358, 484, 501 631-638,6671,
586, 668f, 672 Frankel, Marvin, 4991, 5B5, $86, 592 638, 673 Ham,Joho C., $39, 668F, 6691, 670f,
Fama, Eugene F., $50. 503 Gilroy, Curtis L.. 676 Greenwood, Joen, 1456, 587, 632, 6708, 672, 673, 674, 675
56f, 57, 59 Franklin, Benjamin, Gintis, Herbert, 213f 1468, 147 674 Hausman, Leonard J.,
Farber, Henry S.. 176, 150 Gloricux, G., 269, 302 Gregory, Allan W., Hamermesh, Daniel, 215
179, 2146, 218, Fraumeni, Barbara, Goddeeris, John H., S00f, 503 172, 214f, 217, Hax, Amoldo.60, 96f,
216 486, 500f, 504, 506 2108, 216 Grenier, Gilles, 187, 222, 5798, $87, 9
Farley, John U., 392, Freeman, Richard B.. Godfrey, Leslie G., 568, 216 SORE, 6668, 674. Hayashi, Fumio, 260,
439f, 441,443 171, 181, 216 S84F, $86 Grice, Joseph, 675 679 297f, 302
Author Index Author Index 687

Haydel, Juanita M.. Holmiund, Bertil, 2108, Jenkins, Gwilym M., Keim, Donald B., 56f, Knox, A. D., 296f, 303 Langford, David, 18f
56f, 57 216 289, 299, 320, 357 37 Koopmans, Tjalling C.. Laslavic, Thomas J..
Heady, Earl, 453, 303 Holt, Charles C., 581%, Jensen, Michaet, 38, Kelejian, Harry H., 18f, 306, 358, S84f, S6f. 57
Heck, Jean Louis, 57 588 55f, 56 296f, 2986, 299, 588 Lau, Lawrence J., 453,
Heckman, JamesJ., Holtmann, Alphonse, Jeuland, Abel P., 96f, 3560, 357 Kopcke, Richard W., 480, 4991, SO0f,
157, 186, 191, 482, 503 98 Kelly. Michael, 439f, 226, 237, 240, 241, 502, 564
2116, 212f, 215, Holzer, Harry, 2136, Jhally, Sut, 4370, 444 442 254, 261. 270, 279. Lau, Sheila, 32, 59
217, 607, 614-617, 217 Johnson, George E., Kemmis, Robyn, 581f, 284-287, 291, Layard, Richard G.,
623-629,633, 634, Hood, William C., 584f, 179, 2116, 2138, 585 2958, 2971, 303 215, 216, 218, 221,
637, 638, 645-648, 588 214, 217, 6698, Kendrick, David A., Kosters, Marvin, 667f, 222, 505, 638,
665, 667f, 668. Horney, Mary Jean, 676 301, 503 676 6671, 6708, 674,
6696. 6708, 671. 677 Johnson, Samuel, 362 Keynes, John M., 305 Kotler, Philip, 437f, 676, 678, 679
675, 676 Hornstein, Zmira, 675 Johnson,Stanley R.. Khaled, Mohammed S., 444, 487 Lazear, Edward, 156,
Heien, Dale M., 144f, Horsky, Dan, 440f, 443 978, 98 5008, 501 Koyck, Leendert M.. 176, 186, 218
148 Hough, Douglas E.. Johnson, Thomas, 182, Kiefer, Nichotas M., 148, 303, 355f, Lec, Lung-Fei, 629,
Helliwell, John F., 269. 2126 218 217 2126, 218 358, 4391, 444, 591 668f, 676
302, 305 Houston, Franklin S.. Johnston, J., 100, 449, Kiker, Billy F., 2108, 218 Krinsky, Itzhak, SOOf, Lee, Tsoung-Chao, 57,
Helpman, Elhanan, 96f, 4396, 443, 447 504 Killingsworth, Mark ., 504 99, £48, 218
9 Houthakker, Hendrik Jones, Deborah J., 505 157, 182, 213%, Krishnamurthi, Lehmann,Donald R..
Helvacian, Nurhan, S., 2-3, 5-6, 196, Jones, F, L., 2136 217 215, 216, 218, 223, Lakshman, 440f. 392, 439, 441, 443
146-147 144f, 148, 212f, Jorgenson, Dale W., 593, 595, 599, 600, 444 Leibowitz, Arlecn, 211f,
Henderson, J. Stephen, 217, 308, 310, 328. 124f, 147, 149, 607, 614, 615, 617, Krueger, Alan B, 2116, 28
384f, 358 329-330, 356f, 237, 242, 247, 250, 624, 626-627, 629, 212f, 218 Leiss, William. 437f.
Hendry, David F.. 305, 387, 358, 439f, 296f, 297F, 2986, 633-635, 645-649, Krugman, Pau! R., 96f, 444
583f, 588 443, 501 299, 301, 302, 453, 665, 6674, 668F, 99 Lenin, Viadimir I., 306
Herriges, Joseph A., Hsiao, Cheng, 668f, 479-481, 486, 6698, 670f, 675, Kuh, Edwin E., 239, Leone, Robert P., 391,
354f, 357 670f, 674, 675 499f, SO0f, SOI, 676 303 439f, 441, 444
Hesse, Dieter M.. 484, Huang. Chi-fu, 59 502, 503, 504, 506, King, Mervyn A., 297f, Kulatilaka, Nalin, 475, Lerman,RobertI., 607,
50! Hubbard, Elbert 582f, 588 302 504 667f. 672
Hickman,Bert G., (Green), | Joskow, Paul L., 96f, 99 Kirshner, Daniel. 3556, Kuskin, Mark, 178, Lerner, Abba P.. 437f,
296f, 302, 5836, Hudson, Edward A., Jovanovic, Boyan, 176, 358 202, 215 444
585 SOOF, 504 2426, 217, 219 Klaassen, Leo H.. 148, Kuznets, Simon, 2108, Leuthold.Jane H., 638,
Hicks, Sir John R., 227, Hulten, Charles R., Judge, George G.. 56, 591 216 676
2959, 302 231, 296f, 299, 302 57, 97f, 99, 145f, Kleidon,Allan W., 56f. Levy, Haim, 58
Hill, M. N., 216, 223 Hunter, Jerald, 2976, 148, 214f, 218 37 Labrune, Francis, 358 Levy, Robert A.. 558,
Hill, R. Carter, 57, 976, 298f, 302 Kein, Benjamin, 410, Lafontaine, Francine, 58
98, 99, 148, 218 Huss, William R., 349, Kalachek, Edward, 432, 446 500f, 504 Lewis, H. Gregg, 176,
Hirsch, Wemer, 96f, 99. 354f, 358 670f, 676 Klein, Lawrence R., Laidler, David E. W., 178, 179, 202,
Hirschberg, Joseph G., Kaldor, Nicholas, 365, VBF, 296f, 303, 510, 580f, 585, 588 2U3Ef, 218, 6671,
310, 356, 357 Ibbotson, Roger, 55f, 57 444 550, 575. 576, Lakonishok, Josef, 56f, 676, 677
Hirschey, Mark, 441f, Intriligator, Michael D., Kalish, Shlomo, 440f, S79F, SBOE, 583f. 57 Lieberman, Marvin B.,
443 301, 304, 305, 503, S8df, 588 Lambin, Jean-Jacques, 96f, 99
Hirschleifer, Jack, 212f, 504, 587, 675, 677 Kamalich, Richard, Kline, Stephen, 437f, 438f, 444, 447 Lilien, Gary, 447
217 Irish, Margaret, 670f, 175, 191, 218 444 Lancaster, Kelvin, 149 Lindsay, Robert, 302
Hirschmann,Wilfred Kaysen, Carl, 146f, 147, Kmenta, Jan, 437, 440f, Lancaster, Kent M., Lintner, John, 550, 58
B., 96f, 99 Isachsen, Arne 3., 669f, 312, 3546, 355f, 444, 4991, 504, 44, 442 Lipsey, Richard G..
Hodge, James H.. 147 675 357 305, 5836, 589 Lancaster. Tony, 2126, 518, 524, $26.
Hogben, Lancelot, 329 Keeley, Michael C., Kaiesner, Thomas J. 218 S8If, 588
Holland, Daniel M., James, S. F., 19F 670f, 676 204f, 218, 222, Landau, Ralph, 124f. Little, John D. C., 414,
297, 302 Jefferson, Thomas, 361 Kehver, Ken, 677 592, 679 147, 149, 302 415, 448
8 AuthorIndex Author Index 689

Litzenberger, Robert Malkiel, Burton G., 20, McGowan,John J., Modigiliani, Franco, Myers, John G., 447 Newbold, Paul, 439f,
HL, 59 550, 566, 58, 59 145£, 1461, 147 S550, 58, 269, 2978. Myers, Kenneth H.. 442
Liviatan, Nissan, 395, Mailar, Chris, 670f, 679 McGuinness, Tony, 299, 303, $39, 4371, 444 Newman,Peter, 445
444 Mankiw, N. Gregory, 439f, 442 S82f, 589 Myers, Stewart C., $4f, Nicholls, William H..
Lloyd, Cynthia B., 2134, $39, 589 McNown,Robert F., Moff, Robert A., 621, 358, 566, 57, 297F, 424, 445
258, 223, 676 Mann, Henry B., 58éf, 666f, 671 657, 6676, 668f, 302 Nicholson, Walter, 96f,
Lorenz, Wilhelm. 2118. 589 Medoff, James, 176, 6701, 676, 677 100
221 Manser, Marilyn E., 219 Montgomery, David B.. Nadisi, M. ishag, 252, Nickell, Stephen J.,
Lorie, James, 406 676 Mellow, Wesley, 670f, 96f, 97f, 98, 99, 297F, 298f, 300, 296f, 303
Lovell, C. A. Knox, Manser, Martin H., 18f 676 439f, 440f, 444 302, 485, 505 Niemi, Beth T.. 213f,
482, 503 Mantel, Nathan, 668f, Melrose, Kendrick B., Montmarquette, Naert, Philippe A.. 218, 223
Lucas, Robert E., Jr., 672 380, 444 Claude, 391, 501 37, 438F, 442, Norsworthy,
270, 298f, 303, Marden, William D., Meltzer, Aian N., 303, Morgan, Chris, 18f 444 Randolph, 500f,
455, 504, 507, 509, 2126 218 447, 588, 590 Morgan, James N.. Nakamura, Alice, 593, 505
527, 530, 531, 534, Markowitz, Harry M., Menill, Lynch,Pierce, 210f, 219, 667f, 677 629, 633-635, 637, Norton,Peter, 19f
536, $37, 549, 23, 24, 55f, 58, 59 Fenner and Smith, Moriguchi, C., 391, 444 638, 640, 641, 643,
582f, 588, $89, 592 Marsh, Terry A... 56f, 39 Morimune, Kimio, 6671, 669f. 670f. Oaxaca. Ronald, 182,
Lundberg, Shelly, 610, ST Messer. Karen, 208, A38f, 444 677, 678 188, 191, 203-208,
676 219 Nakamura, Masao, 593, 20

waist
Marshall,Alfred, 450 Morley, J. Kentfield, 20
Lutkepohl, Helmut, 57, Martin, Stephen, 441f, Metcalf, Charles B.. Moroney, John R.. 357, 629, 633-635, 637, Oberhofer, Walter,
99, 148, 218 444 670, 677 359, 502 638, 640, 641, 643, 499f, 505, 5831,
Lydall, Harold, 210f, Mason, William, 166, Meyer, John R., 239, Morison, Catherine J.. 6671, 6691. 670f. 589
218 217 303 484, 485, SOIT, 677, 678 O'Connor, Charles J.,
Massy, William F., 371, Meyer, Lawrence H., 502, 504, 505, 506 Nathan,Felicia, 211f. 2101, 224
MacBeth, James D.. 44a 674 Moser, Colletta H., 222, 219 Ofek, Haim, 174, 189,
556, 57 Masters, Stanley H., Middleton, Kenneth A., 679 National Bureau of 219
Machlup, Fritz, 150, 218 222, 679 96F, 99 Mount, TimothyD., Economic Ohta, Makoto, 130.
MacKinnon, James G.. McCallum, Bennett T.. Milgate, Murray. 445 3550, 358 Research. 102, 148 146F, 148
356f, 357 345, $49, 561, 562. Miller, Merton H., Mroz, Thomas A., 595, Navasky,Victor, 18f Oi, Walter, 159, 210f,
MaCurdy, Thomas, 563, 5B1f, S82, 2976, 303 635, 637, 638-644, Naylor, Thomas H., 210 219
179, 218, 615, 617, 589, 592 Miller, P. B., 414, 445 650, 652, 661, 663, 96f, 9 Okun, Arthur M., 507,
629, 633, 634, McCann, John M., 387, Mills, Gordon, 590 6691, 677 Nefici, Salih, 582f, 589 540, 541, 583f.
6678, 6686, 6708, 442 Milne, A. A.. 116 Muellbauer, John M.. Nelson,Charles R.. 56f, 589, 590
675, 616 McCollum, James F., Mincer, Jacob, 152, 606, 670f. 673 58, 289, 303, 308, Olsen, Randall J.. 623,
Madansky, Albert, 584f, $16, 586 * 155, 163, 168, 169, Mueller, M. G., 300 310, 3141, 350, 661, 663, 6680, 678
589 McConnell, Campbell 172, 174, 176, 188, Muller, Eitan, 414, 444 352, 353, 354f. Olson, Kenneth, t
Maddala, G. S., 549, R.. 180, 218, 393, 189, 196, 208, Mundlak,Yair. 391, 359, 360 Orcutt, Guy H., 3-5.
553K, SB4P, 589, 446, 679 206, 24208 2138, 444, 449, 503 Nelson,Forrest 0.. 18f, 19f
668F, 6708, 6711. MeDonald, John F., 219, 610, 645, 646, Murphy, Kevin M.. 668f, 678 Oswald, Andrew J.,
676 96F, 99, 621, 657, 667f, 670F. 676, 172, 187. 219, 410, Nelson, Randy A., SOIL. 179, 219
Mahajan, Vijay, 414, 668f, 676 677 432, 446 505 Otuteye. Eben, 440f,
444 McElroy, Marjorie B., Minhas, Bagichs, 452, Murray, Michael P., Nerlove, Mare, 81-84, 445
Majd, Saman, 966, 99 55f, $8, 471, 504, 501 354f, 358 87-94, 99, 100, Our,Tae H., 407, 436,
Majluf, Nicholas, 60, 677 Mishkin, Frederic, 549, Musgrave,John C.. 237, 303, 365, 401, 441
96f, 99 McFadden, Daniel, 334, 589 228f, 296, 301 417, a37f, 444,
Makridakis, Spyros G., 355F, 3568, 357, Mitchell, Bridger M., Mussa, Michael, 298f, 303 454, 457, 505, Packard, Vance, 437f,
386f, 358, 359 358, 449, 499F, 328, 358 Muth, John F.. 268, 583f, 589 445
Malinvaud, Edmond, SOOF, 503, 504, Mitchell, Olivia S., 610, 298f, 303. 319, Neumark, David, 213f, Padilla, Arthur H..
345, 589 306, 670f, 677 677 358, 536, 589 219 2146, 218
Author Index Author Index 691

Pagan, Adrian R., 305 Pierce, David A., 382, Rasche, Robert, 269, Ross, Stephen A., 37, Schmalensec, Richard, Silverstein, Gerald,
Palda, Kristian S., 380, 4398, 445 299 38, 52, 55f, $7, 58 361, 365, 368-372, 228f, 296f, 301
390, 402, 438f, Pindyck, Robert S., 96f, Rasmussen, Arne, 365, Rotemberg, Julio R., 374, 376, 380, 383, Simon, Hermann, 414,
440, 445 98F, 99, 100, 356f, 445 484, 505, 539, 393-396, 398, 410, 446
Palm, Franz, 264, 297f, 359, 484, 505, Rea, Samuel A., 607, 583f, 589, 590 415, 427, 429, 430, Simon,Julian L., 370,
304 583f, 590 667f, 672 Rothenberg. ThomasJ., A37E, 438F, 4391, 414, 4381, 4398,
Papademos, Lucas, Plourde, Andre, 356f, Reder, Melvin W.. 467, 505 440F, 445 AAIE, 446
$82f, 589 359 214f, 220 Rothschild, Michael, Schmidt, Peter, 179, Simon, Leonard S.,
Park, Joon Y., 50Of, Pogue, Gerald A., 55f, Rees, Albert, 172, 214, 2968. 298f. 301, 213f, 220 SOF, 443
505 38 217, 222, $79, 403 Schneider, Lynne, 410, Sims, Christopher A..
Park, Rolla E., 358 Poirier, Dale, 670f, 679 587, 598L, 666f, Rowe, Robert D., 391, AIL, 432, 446 2976, 304, 4391,
Park, Soo-Bin, 584f, Polachek, Solomon, 674, 679 445 Schoenberg, E. H.. 380, 4401, 446, 582,
391 174, 175, 188, 191, Rehn, Gésta, 580, 587 Rowley, John C. R., 410, 446 390
Parkin, J. Michael, 524, 211, 213f, 214f, Reimers, Cordelia, 187, 295f, 303 Schoenberg, Erika, 614, Singer, Burton. 212f,
526, S80f, 581f, 207, 218, 219 220 Roy, A. D., 165, 220 678 217
588 Pollak, Robert A., 143f, Reinganum, Marc R., Ruback, Richard S., Scholes, Myron, 38, Singleton, Kenneth J.,
Parnes, Herbert S., 148, 189, 215 58 S6f, 58 55f, 56 2981, 301, 564,
2108, 219, 667f, Pollay, Richard W.. Renahack, Robert, 315, Rubinfeld, Daniel L.. Schudson, Michael, $831, 587
678 404, 445, 448 3548, 3558, 359 986, 100, 356f, 359 437f, 446 Sinquefield, Rex, S5f.
Parsons, Leonard J., Porter, Michael E., 96f, Reynolds, Lloyd G., Russell, R. Robert, 96f, Schultz, George P., 586 37
380, 438f, 440f, 100 679 100 Schulz,Henry, 405, Smeeding, Timothy,
442, 443, 448 Poterba, James M., Rhodes, George F., Jr., Ruud,Paul, 667£, 6691, 446 241f, 220
Patterson, J. Wayne, 2971, 303, 581f, 590 667f, 673 675 Schultz, Randall L., |. Seymour, 56f. 57
96f, 100 Prais, S. J., 196. 356f, Riddell, W. Craig, 222, Ryan, David, 356f, 359 4391, 440f, 443, , Adam, 150, 152.
Pazderka, Bohumir, 357 679 444, 448 210F, 220, 593, 678
407, 436, 441 Prucha,IngmarR., 485, Riley, John G.. 210f Salinger, Michacl A., Schultz, T. Paul, 633, ‘Smith, James P.. 186,
Pechman, Joscph A., 505, 578, 590 Rizzuto, Ronald, 211. 297f, 303 634, 638. 667f, 678 187, 2136,
674 Psacharopoulos. 220 Samuelson,Paul A., Schultz. Theodore W.. 666. 670,
Peck, Stephen C., 308, George, 171, I71f, Robb, A.Leslie, 500f, 97f, 100, 498f, 505, #52, 220, 671 674, 675, 678
310, 311f, 350, 212f, 220 504 517, 518, $80f, $90 Scarle, Allan D., 96f, Smith, Robert S., 210£.
352, 353, 354f, Puig, Carlos, 355f, 358 Roberts, Harry V., 191, Sandmo, Agnar, 669, 100 221, 222, $92,
359, 360 Pulley, Lawrence, 358 215, 405-407, 678 Selickacrts, Willy, 302 6671, 673, 679
Pencavel, John, 79, Purdy, David L., 385 440f, 445 Sargan, J. Denis, 305, Shapiro, Carl, 222, 220 Smith,Shirley J., 666f.
218, 220, 645, Robins, Philip K., 670f, 4998, 505, 590 Sharpe, William F., 40,
666f, 678 Quandt, Richard, 380, 67% Sargent, Thomas J., S46, 55f, 561, SB Smith, V. Kerry, 81, 98
Perkins, J. W., S84f, A38f, 445 Roester. Theodore W., 2986, 303, SOIf, Sheffrin, Steven M., Snetsinger, Douglas W..
585 Quigley, John M., 211f, 393, 446 503, 507, 549, 549, 591 407, 436, 441
Perloff, Jeffrey M., 540, 217 Roll, Richard, 55f, 566, S8If, 5821, 589, Shell, Karl, 143f, 147, Solnik, Bruno, 55f, $8
590 57, 58 590, 592 371, 443 Solow, Rober M., 363.
Perry, George L., 581, Raines, Fredric, 670f, Rose, Nancy L.,. 96f, 99 Sarnat, Marshall, 58 Shoven, John B., 504 446, 452, 301. 507,
5820, 583f, 590 676 Rosen, Harvey S., 629, Sasieni, Maurice W.. Sicktes, Robin C., 482, 517, 518, S80f,
Petly, Sir William, 152 Raj, S. P., 440%, 444 633, 644, 66d, 678 414, 445 503 S81f, 590, 591
Phelps, Edmund S., Rao, Ambar G., 414, Rosen, Sherwin, 130, Savin, N. Eugene, 479, Siebert, Calvin D., 297f, Sorrentino, Constance,
521, $89, 590 440f, 442, 445 148, 2108. 211f, SO0f, 502 666f, 678
Phillips. A. William, Rao, Ram C., 440f, 445 2U2F, 214, 216, Sawa, Takamitsu, 584f, Siebert, W. Stanley, Spady, Richard H., 481.
512, 513, 515, Rapping, Leonard J., 220, 372, 445 591 2Ibf, 214, 222, 505
579f, 580f, 590 96f, 100, 309, 527, Rosenberg. Nathan, 101 Scarf, Herbert E., 504 592, 667f, 671, 679 Spann, Robert, 358
Phillips, Peter C. B., 530, 531, 534, Rosett, Richard N., Scherer, F. Michael, Silk, Alvin J., 415, 439f, Spence, A. Michael, 60,
SO0F, 505, 545, 590 582f, 588 668F, 678 956, 100 AAOf, 442, 444, 445 96f, 100, 157, 221
92 Author index Author Index 693

Spiegelman, Robert G., Taylor, John B., 224, Toyama, Nate. 359 Wachtel, Paul, 2118, Wayne, Kenneth, 671, Winer, Russel S., 439,
670f, 676 301, 359, 510, $41, Treadway, ArthurB., 220 96f, 98 447
Spitzer, John 3. 145f, $49, 582F, 583f, 270, 298f, 304 Wachter, Michacl L.. Webb, Aifted, 675 Winfrey, Robert, 227,
146f, 148 586, $87, 591 Tretheway. Michael W., 540, 582f, 590, 591 Weil, Robman, 406 296f, 304
Stafford, Frank P,, 211f, Taylor, Lester D., 315, 482, 502 ‘Wagner, Joachim, 21 If, Weinberg, Charles B., Wise, David A., 210F.
204f, 217, 221 321, 323, 328, 343, Treynor, Jack L., 55f. 221 391, 392, 447 222, 631, 675
Steiner, Peter O.. 365. 354f, 355f, 359, 59 ‘Wagner, Wayne,32. 59 Weisbrod, Burton, 240f, Witteveen, Hendrik J.
442 397, 439f, 443, 446 Triggs, C. M., 439%, 442 Wakeman,Frederic, 148, 591
Stern, Nicholas, 639, Telser, Lester G., 365, Triptett, Jack E., 120, 437%, 447 Weiserbs, Daniel, 397, Wold, Herman, 577,
678 380, 384, 410, 411. 123, 124f, 128, Wald, Abraham, 584f 439%, 446 585
Stevens, Joseph C,, 438f, 4408, 446 1446, 1456, 148, Wales, Terence J., 210f, Weiss, Doyle L., 391, Wolf, Barbara L., 211,
4381, 446 Teng, Sinn-Tsair, 440f, 149, 217, 219, 220, 211f, 221, 355f, 392, 439f, 443, 447 221
Stigler, George J., 440f, 446 614 359, 500f, 503, Weiss, Yoram, 156, Wolfe, JN. 443
446 Thaler, Richard H.. 56f, Trivedi, Pravin K.. 629, 631-634, 157, 215, 222, Wolpin. Kenneth, 210f,
Stigler, Stephen M., 149 58, 59 295f, 303 669F, 679 6701, 679 22
Stiglitz, Joseph,96f, 98, ‘Theeuwes,Jules, 670f. Turnovsky, Steven J., Walker, lan, 670f, 672, Welch,Finis, 171f, 172, Wormer. N. Keith, 96f,
2108, 2L1f, 2126, 678 269, 299, 582f, 391 678 186, 187, 2121, 100
220, 221 Theil, Henri, 97f, 100, Twain, Mark, 20, 59 Wail, Kent D., 55f. 57 213f, 219, 221, Woo, Chi-Keung. 354f,
Stoker, Thomas M., 298f, 304, 355, ‘Tyrrell, Timothy J., Wallis, Kenneth F., 222 359
S796, 591 359, 391, 446, 3550, 358 295f, 298f, 304, Wenz, Kenneth L.. 96f, Wuod. David O.. 297F,
Stone, Richard, 116, 5530, SB4f, 591, 4400, 447, 525, 99 301, 449, 430, 472,
144f, 148 392 Udis, Bernard, 666f, 671 527, 549, 580f, West, Richard W., 670f, 486, 487, SOIL.
Strauss, Lewis L., 306, Thomas, Annie, 95f, 98 Uhler, Robert G., 311f, S81f, 585, 591, 676 502
359 Thomas, Howard, 99 353, 354f, 359 592 ‘Weyant, John P., 360 Woodland, Alan D.,
Strauss, Robert, 179, Thomas, R. L.. 295f, Ulph, David T., 667f, Walsh, John R., 210f, Wheelwright, Steven C.. 355K, 359, S0OF.
220 304 669f, 671 221 356f, 358, 359 506, 629, 631-634,
Stromm,Steiner, 669f, Thompson, Gerald L., Usher, Dan, 302, 304 Walters, Alan A., 101, Whitaker, John K., 669f. 679
675 440f, 446 Uzawa, Hirofumi, 499f, 4998, 506 590 Wouk, Herman,
Strowz, Robert H.. 270, Thurow, Lester, 170, 506 Walwick, Nancy J., White, Halbert, 53, 59, est
300 182, 2128, 2138, 515, 591 208, 209, 219, 222, Woytinsky, Wladimir.
Summers, Anita A.. 2148, 221 Vandaele, Walter, 356f, Ward, Michacl, 666f, 299, 356f, 359. 6671, 679
2016 221 ‘Thursby, Jerry G., 475, 359 678 629, 640, 657. 661, Wu, De-Min, 4381, 447,
Summers, Lawrence H., 501 Varian, Hal R.. 96f, Watkins, G. Campbell, 662. 6691, 679 584f, $91, 669F.
2U1f, 2N2E 218, Thurstone, L. L.. 95f, 100 501f, 502 White, Kenneth J., 679
297f, 304, 522, 100 Veall, Michael R., SOOf, Watson, Mark W., 580f Svor, 504 Wykoff, Frank, 231.
539, 580f, SBE Tidwell, Paul W., 1456, Watson, Thomas J.. 1, Wildasin, David, 297f, 296f, 302
585, 589, 590, 591, 146 Verdon, Walter A., 393, 18f 304 Wyplosz, Charles, 297f,
6671, 672 Tinbergen, Jan, 144f, 446, ‘Wats, Harold W.. 135, Wilkes, Maurice V.. 299
Swan, Craig, 2951, 304 148, 2981, 304, Verleger, Philip K., Jr., 149, 596, 614, it
Swinton, David, 2134, $50, 579f, 583f, 355f, 359 666F, 6636, 6701, Wilkinson, Maurice, Yao, Dennis A.. 96f,
221 50 Verma, Vinod K., 372. 672, 674, 679 96f, 100 98
Tirole, Jean. 96f. 99, 447 ‘Waugh,Frederick V.. Willis, Robert, 162, Yelle, Louis E.. 95f.
Taubman, Paul, 166, 100 Vernon, John M., 96f, 104, 106-110, 167, 171f, 172, 100
189, 2108, 211f, Tobin, James M., 55f, 99 132-135, 142, 208, 210f, 212f, Yellen, Janet L., 211f,
215, 221 59, 256, 258-259, Viscusi, W. Kip. 216f, 144f, 145£, 1466, 222 212f, 214, 222
Tauchen, George, 304, 582f, 591, 221 149, 401, 417, Wilson, Thomas A.. Yoshikawa, Hiroshi,
592 668F, 678 von Furstenberg, 4378, 444 4401, 441f, 442 260, 297f, 304
Taylor, Jim, 580f, Toevs, Alden L., 500f, George M., 297f, Waverman, Leonard, Windal, Pierre, 391, Youmans, Kenwood C.,
591 505 304 SOIL, $02 392, 439, 447 213f, 217
1 Author Index

Zabalza, Antoni, 632, Zeliner, Arnold, 214f, 506, 522, S8tf,


669F, 676, 222, 264, 297f, S84f, 584, 591, ]
679 304, 355f, 359, 592 q
Zeides, Stephen P., 539. 391, 438f, 4391, Zimmenman,Martin

Subject Index
591 441, 447, 4998, L., 96f, 100

ies: effects ofban on cigarette Autocorrelation:


distribution of, 161 consumption, 409-414, Breusch-Godireytest for,
as omitted variables, 166- 432-436 $67-570
167 expenditures, 362, 373 Cochrane-Oreutt estimation
Accelerator model of frequency. 374 procedure, 5, 54, 92,
investment: Granger causality with sates, 93, 283, 345, 348, 356f,
alternative distributed lags 380-383, 427-429 388, 558
for, 234-237 importance ofcopy quality, Durbin-Watsontest for, 54,
empirical implementations, 407-409, 436-437 92, 347, 497
237-239, 281-283, as information, 372 Durbin’s m- and h-test
291-292 Fingering effects models of, procedure, 235, 347,
flexible, 234 386-393, 423, 534, 567-568
naive, 233 measurementof, 373-375 estimation with lagged
theory, 233-234 optimal advertising-sales dependentvariable.
Adaptive expectations, See ratios, 366-371 281-283, 294-295,
Expectations 520, 423- 424, $52
Added worker hypothesis, See Hitdeeth-Lu estimation
Labor supply procedure, 54, 92, 93,
Adding-upconditions ofshare role ia changing consumers’ 253, 282-283, 345,
‘equations, 470-474, tastes, 371-372 347, 388, 424, 558
478-479, 491-492 rote ofregression analysis in local-giobat problems, 348
Adjusiment cost models, 269— analyzing, 416 maximum likelihood
270, 484-485 scale economics in, 415-416 estimation procedure,
Advertising: shape of advertising 345, 348
as barrierto entry, 415, response function, $14~ Prais-Winsten estimation
brand loyalty model of, 388, als procedure, 356f
392, 423-424 simultancity with sales, with simmultaneity, 291-292,
consistent market share 375-380, 417-420, 432, 534-535, $52,
specifications, 383-385 429-432 586, $58, 561-565. 569
to counteract cyclical stock of, 435 in systemsof equations,
TMacrocconomic temporal aggregation and 476-479, 497
fluctuations, 363 data interval bias, 389~ testing with lagged
cumulative effect on sales, 393 dependentvariable,
387-390, 401-404 theoretical determinants of 235, 281-283, 294~
current elfects models of, advertising outlay, 365- 295, 347, 404, $34-
387-389, 423 at $35, 556, 567-570
distributed lag models of, theoretical effects on sales, vector, 477-479
385-389, 423 31-373 Autoregressive integrated
duration levels, 389-393 Arbitrage pricing model, 37- moving average
effects on aggregate 38, 52-53 (ARIMA)models, 268,
consumption, 393-400, AREMOS/PC, 16, 17 289-291, 353, 382,
427-429 ASCII code, 7 427-829
695
396 Subject Index
Subject Index 697
Auniliary regression equation, Cash flow model of Consumption function, $51~
16-77, 322 investment, 239-242, 555, 566, 370-572, 576 rational tag, 237, 582f demand charges, 310 electricity demand, 307~
284-286, 5St Cost function: with simuhtancity, 291-292 double-in-ten formula, 307, 308, 344-346, 349-352
BASSSTAT.16, 17 Causality, See Granger briefhistory of functional Tobin's ¢ model, 287-289 339 exponential growth,
Bayesian procedures, 39 causality formsfor, 457-458 Double-in-ten formuis, 307, empiricat evidence on, 328 Procedure, 349
Bertrandoligopoly model, Censored data, 595, 616, 6666 choice between production 339, 354f 335 ‘ex post dynamic, 274-276,
69 ‘Center for Research on and cost function, 457- Duality theory, 65 energy charges. 310
Beta value: Securities’ Prices, 37 460 Dummyvariables, 48-50, 51, with equipmentstocks Holt’s two-parameter
definition, 27, 33 CHANCE,12, 19f general, 63 TEI-114, 136-14: included explicitly, exponential smoothing
different in January, 50-51 Chow test, 48, $1, 93-94, generalized Leontief, 460- 151, 161-166,19: 312-315 provedure, 351
estimation of, 34-41 139-141, 201-208, 465 Durationintervals, 389-393, with equipment stocks investment in fixed business
exemstudies, 48-50 525-526 multiproduct, 481-482 421-422 included indirectly, capital, 271-276, 294-
for gold, 45 Cigarette advertising ban, Iransiog. 81, 470-475, 483 Durbin-Watson test statistic: 315-320 295
stability, 35-36, 48 effects of, 409-414, variable cost function, 482- test for first order essential facts, 308-312 single exponential
Blinder, Atan, [85-186 432-436 434 autocorrelation, 54 forecasting, 310, 344-346, smoothing procedure,
BMDP/PC,16, 17 Cobb-Dougias production Cournotoligopoly model, 369 349-353 380
Boston Consulting Group, 60, function, 68-75, 248- Cowles Commission, 2, 21 functional form for models. static, 271
960 256, 266, 286-287, Cross-correlograms, 399, 428- use with lagged dependent of, 326-328 timeseries procedures,
Box-Coxtransformation, 128, 450-452, 488-489 any variables, 235, 281~ heteroskedastic errors in
142-143, 211f, 231 Cochrane-Orcutt procedure, Current effects model, See 283, 386, modeis of, 34) unit costs with learning
Box-Jenkins ARIMA models, See Autocorretation Advertising marginal and intramarginal curve effects, 94-95
268, 289-291, 319- Coefficientofdetermination: Economies ofscale: prices, 321-324 Fourier functionall form, 482
320, 352~353, 382- Partial, 108 DATA-FIT, 16, 17 definition, 63 multicblock rate schedules, Ful income, 602
383, 390-400, 564 relationship to R?, 108-110 Data interval bias, 389-393 empirical evidence, 81~83 309, 321-326 Full information maximum
Box-Pierce Q statistic, 290, separate, 109 Dirichlet distribution, 500f general, 61 short-run model, 312-313 likelihood, 463, 485,
Compensated substitution Discrimination,effects on imponance of, 61 simuhtaneity ofprice and 545, 552-554, 556,
Sox-Tidwell transformation, effect, 604, 65-008 wages: and shape of average cost quantity, 324-326, 573-875,578, 626-
128 Computer commands and by gender, [8B-190, 205 ‘curve, 64 38 627, 665
Brand loyalty model, See operations: six-tenths rute, 61 Typicai Etectric Bills data, Functional form:
Advertising BASIC,10 by race, 181-187, 203-205 ECONOMIST 325-326 Bor-Cox procedure, 128,
CD(change directory), 9 theory and measurement WORKSTATION,16, Enteringdata, 13-15 142-143, 2116
‘CADET, 246 COPY, 8-9 issues, 180-184 7 Error correction process, 529 choice of, 127-128, 161~
Capital asset pricing model: DISKCOPY,8 Discouraged worker EDSAC Computer, 5-6, 356 ET, 16, 17 162, 326-328
beta value, 27, 33-34 DOS(disk operating hypothesis. See Labor Education,rate of return to: Event studies, 48-30 flexible production and cost
estimation of, 34~41 system), 8 supply empirical evidence, 169- Expectations: models, 482
sisk-return linear EDLIN,10 Distributed lags: 172 adaptive, 267-269, 317~
telation: F=32 FORMAT,6 accelerator model, 234-237, stability over time, (71-172 320, 529-530, $38- GAUSS,16, 17
as special case of APM, 52- MD(inake directory), 9 281-283 Elasticity ofsubstitution: 539, 544, 564 Genera? equilibrium models,
33 operating system, & . advertising-sales models, for generalized Leantiet rational, 268-269, 319-320, 479-481
test of, 37-39 pathnames, 8-9 385-389, 401-408 function, 464465, 484-485, 509, $38- Generatized Box-Cox
use in constructing RENAME. 9 Almonlag, 236, 284-289 492-494 539, 541, $44, $49, functional form, 482
portfolios, 47 texteditor, 10 with autocorrelation, 292- Hicks-Alten partial in 556, 561-568, $79 Generalized Leontief
Capital stock: TYPE,10 294, 316 multiple input case, Experience curves, See functional form, 327,
constant exponential decay, word processors, 10 cash flow model, 241-242, 463 Learningcurves 460-455, 478, 489-498
228-232 XCOPY, & 284-286 production function with Generalized Tobit model,
detetioration and ‘Computers in econometrics: specification, 236 constant, 482-457 Feedback, 382 Limited dependent
depreciation, 230-232 briefhistory, 2-6, short: and long-run, 484 Final form, 399, 428-429 variable models
gr055, 228 Pioneering studies, 340 models, 316-320 for anslog function, 475, Forecast Geometry mean,
mortalitydistributions, 227 Conoco takeaver, 48-50 geometric, 235, 317, 386 492-494 advertising-sales computation of, 194
net, 228 Constant elasticity of inverted V-Ing, 236 two-input case, 452 relationships, 398-400, Gord, 45
one-hoss shay deterioration, substitution (CES) neoclassical model of Electricity demand: 433 Government spendingimpact
production function, invesiment, 249-256 autocorrefationin models double exponential muhtiplier, $24
perpetual inventory 252-254, 292-294, polynomial distributed lag, of, 346-348 smoothing procedure, Granger causality, 380-383,
method, 228 452-457, 488-489, $30 236-237, 284-289 data guality for analysis of, 350 427-429
34-315 dynamic, 271, 274-275 Gross output, 488
Subject Index 699
98 Subject Index
erative three-stage feast measurementissues, $96- Tobit, 596, 620-624, 626~
iross substitutioneffect, 605- transformation of data to Instrumental variable squares (13SLS) 599 627, 629, 643, 644,
606 ensure imation: estimator, 463, 474, second generation studies 650, 657-658
homoskedasticity, 137, consistency with rational 484, 485, 492, $82, of, 617-637 Limited information
Jausman specificationtest, 328, 341-52 eapectations $53, $56, 573 and taxes, 617, 629-633, maximum likelihoot
379-380, 409, 419, hypothesis, 267-268, Iterative Zellner-fficient 644, 663-664, 6697 estimator,552
430-432,565-567, 641 , White test 561-565 (IZEF)estimator, 463, theory, dynamic tabor in prices,
Jazard rate, 622 for, 53, 208-209 general, 316, 319, 378-379, 474, 488-496, 556 supply, 645-649
leckit model, See Limited Houthakker-Taylor state 395~396, 484-985, theory, household labor Linear probability model, 655
dependent variable adjustment model, 556, 569, 664 Jacobian, 576-578 supply. 607-609 Lingering effects models, Sev
models 397-398 Interaction terms, 163, 165, theory, individual labor Advertising
Yedonic prices: Humancapital theory: 197-199, 200 Klein's Modet 1 of the US. supply, 600-606 Logit model, See Limited
for advertising copy quality, equalizing differences. 152- Intertemporal utility function, economy, 550-558, See also Unemployment dependent variable
409 153 527-528, 539-540, $65~567, 572-578 Lagrange multiplier test models
‘measurementissues in 646-648 Kolmogorov-Smimovtest for procedure, 465-467, Lydiametries, 364, 404
empirical Inverse Mills ratio, See normality, 54, 195 474-475, 494-496
wy implementation, 159- sampleselectivity Koyck transformation, 235, Lagrangianfunction, 65, 602, MacUser, 12, 19f
applied to asparagus, 105- 160 Investment in fixed business 267, 318, 386, 529 MacWeek, 12, 19f
110, 132-135, 142 on-the-job training as capital: Learning curves: MacWorld, 12, 19f
143 investment, 155-157 accelerator model, 234-239, Laborforee, measurementof, autocorrelation, 92 Marginal rate ofsubstitution,
applied to automobiles, general training, 155 281-283, 295-292 See Unemployment, ‘empirical evidence, 79-80 600-605, 618, 624,
110-116 specific training, 155- adjustment cost models, labor supply estimation of, 85 645
applied to computer 156, 178 269-270 Laborforce participation rate, and experience curves, 66
industry, 118-126, role ofabilities, 155 autocorrelation, 293-294 1. 5594-595, forecasting units costs with,
136-143 schooling as investment, cash flow model, 239-24 94-95
briefhistory, 105-116 ESI-158 284-286, 551 general, 13, 61-62 estimation, 463, 473-
chained, 141-142 serecning as an alternative changes in business added worker hypothesis, integration with Cobb- 475, 494-497, $73-579
incorporated by U.S, hypothesis, 157-158 ventaries, 226 609-610 Douglas function, 71- Mcanvalue function, 453
Bureau of Economic Hypothesis testing: ‘empirical comparison of allocation oftime 18 Meta-analysis, 392-393
Analysis, 125 individual tests, 36, 78, 86~ models, 270-277, 294- framework, 610-613 measurementissues, 75-76 MicroTSP, 15, 17
make effects, 129 87, 113, 137 295 backward bending function, ‘omitted variable bias, 76-78 Minflex Laurentfunctional
in models of cost and joint tests, 78-79, 86-87, forecasting, 294-295 606 overview, 66-68 form, 482
production, 481—482 T13-EE4, 139-141 gross, net and replacement, comparative dynamics, 647 slope, 67, 80, 85 Minimum chi-square
as outcome ofsupply- Lagrange multiplier test, definitions of, 229 complete budget constraint Lemer index of monopoly estimator, 462-463
demand relationships, 465-467, 494-496 moving average errors in, approach to, 632, 635 power Minimumdistance estimator,
117118, 129-131 likelihood ratio test, 465- 267-268 discouraged worker Likelihood test 545,547
parameter stability, 12 467, 494-496, 554, neoclassical model, 242~ hypothesis, 609-610, procedure, 465-467. Minimum expected loss
131 $75, 579 256, 286-287 667F 474-475, 494-496, estimator, 584f
test for constantrate of nonlinear, 97f, 475, 534 non-static expectations, effects from cyclical $54, 575, 579, 619, 620 MINITAB,16, 17
price change, 139 overidentifying restrictions, © 268-269 aggregate demand, LIMDEP, 16, 17 Mode! T Fords, 66-65
with unobserved attributes, $54, $57, 873-575, $79 putty-clay model, 250-254, 609-610 Limited dependent variable Money illusion, 536, 538
128-129 relation to A? vatue, 468- 286-287 equilibrium dynamics. models: Monte Carlo techniques, 475,
leteroskedasticity: 469, 519, SBIE eesidential construction, 637 general, $9S 573
in electricity demand Wald test, 465-867, 494- 226 first generation studies of, generalized Tobit, 596, Movingaverage error models,
equations, 328, 34 496 simuttancity issues, 266— 614-617 627-629, 650, 661- 20, 413, 427
in labor force particip: 267, 291-292 Frisch demand notion 664, 665
equations, 655 Identification, 376-378, 419- time series/autoregressive implications ofcosts of Heckit, $96, 627-629,651, 64,
obtained when using 420, 479, $24-525, model, 263-265, 283- employment, 613-614, 642-644, 650, 661-664 Multicollinearity, 136, 319,
averaged data, 127 552, 556, $70-573, 284, 289-291 627-629, 666 logit, 333, 596, 650, 654- 339
robust standard errors with, 625-626, 658-660 Tobin's q model, 256-263, linearized budget constraint, 657 Multifactor productivity
53, 208, 209, 341, 629, Indirect least squares, 377~ 287-289 631, 63: Brobit, 596, 619-620, 623, growth, 485-486, 497-
640, 657, 661, 662 379, S71, 660 Iterative minimum distance male chauvinist model, 607, 625, 627, 629, 641, 498
Info World, 12, 19 estimator, $45, $47- 667t 642, 650, 654-658, 668 MYSTAT,16
functions, 208-209 Information set, $43, 561-565 549, 579
00 Subject Index Subject Index 701

PDQ, 16. 17 R? measure: definition, 63 Share models: Symmetric generalized


datural rate of
unemployment, 522 Permanent income measure, changes in to conduct empirical evidence, 80-83 adding-up conditions for, ‘McFadden functions!
Acoctassical model of 314, 647-648 hyportiesis tests, 519. estimation of, 87-94 470-471, 491-492 form, 482
investment: Phiblips curve: Seif and shape ofaverage cost autocorrelationin, 477-479 SYSTAT,16, 17
‘empirical implementation, carly history, 312-517 high value docs not imply consistent specification in
248-256, 286-287 expectations augmented, valid model, 499 advertising context, Taylor's series expansions, $53
theory, 243-245 interpretation in CAPM 383-385, 424-426 Technical progress:
user cost ofcapital, 245— framework, 40, 47 for translog function, 476 in cost functions, 470-474, biased, 498
interpretation in linear Reverse regression, 45, 134, 491-492, disembodied, 485, 397
248
Neo-Keynesian models, $39, precursors to, 516-517 probability model, 655 191-192,455-456 SHAZAM, 15, 18 embodied, 486
stability, 517-527 relation to correlation Risk: Shephard's Lemma, 461, 370, and the measurement of
S41
Nested logit model, 333 underlying theory, 512-513, coefficient, 131-135 definition, 22 983, 485 multifactor
Net marginat revenue 518-520 relation to partial and linearrelationship with Simultaneous equations productivity growth,
product, 366 Pinkham,Lydia E. Medicine separate coefficients of return, 27-32 estimation: 485486, 497198
New classical school, 538 Company, 402, 420- determination, 108- market, 32 in advertising-sales models, and shifts in average cost
409, 131-135 378-380, 429-432 curve, 64-65
Non-aceelerating inflation rate 424
Pooled crass-section, time in reverse regressions, 456,
and portfolio diversification,
of unemployment, 540 2-27 alternative estimators, $50- Temporal aggregation, 389~
Nonhomothetic functions, 469 series estimation, 436— 489 premium, 22 558, $70-$73 393, 420-422
Nonlinearleast squares, 377, 4ayT in simple and mukipte tiskefree return, 22 with autocorrelation, 291- Theil’s incquality coefficient,
418, 434, 626 Ponfolio: regressions, 86-87, specif, 32 292, 569 295
Normality: aggressive, 14 131-135 systematic, 32 in cost and production ‘Three Mite Island, 48-50
chi-square goodness of fit defensive, 34 in systems of equations, unique, 32 models, 474-475 Three-stage least squares, 463,
teat, 54, 195 diversification, 23-27, 32 468-469, 496 unsystematic, 32 in electricity demand 474-475, 485, 492,
Kolomogorov-Smirnov test efficient, 31 value in regression ofactual Root mean squared error: $45, 552, 553, 556,
procedure, 54, 195 optimal, 27 on fitted y. 135 to evaluate forecasts, 272- in investment models, 291~ 564, 570, 573
Potentiat output, 522, $41 Rate of retum: 277, 291, 294-298 292 ‘Time SeriesAutoregressive
‘Okun's Law, $40 Price elasticities, 464-165, definition, 21-22 Singular equation systems, investment models:
Omitted variable bias: Price indexes: marginal return, 26 Sales: 345, 472-474, 478-
auxiliary regression, 76-77, chained priceindexes, 141- marginal variance, 26 effects from advertising, 479, 491-492
empitical implementation,
24-265, 283-284,
322, 344 142 risk-free, 22 371-373, 393-400 Slutsky equation, 606 249-291
in clectricity demand quality change via matched risk premium, 22 Granger causality with SORITEC,15, 18 theoretical foundations,
context, 321-324, 343- model procedure, 101— to schooling, 161-163 advertising, 380-383 Sorting data. 195, 652-653 263-264
a 105 Rational expectations, See See also Advertising SPSS/PC +, 16, 18 Tobin's g model of
Jearning curves, 76-78, 86 See also Hedonic prive Expectations Sample selectivity: SST,16, 18 investment:
retums to schooling, 166- indexes Rational predictor, 319 general, SBIf, 595 STATA, 16, 18 average vs. marginal g, 259-
167 Probit models, Sec Limited RATS, 15, 17 inverse Milts ratio, 191, STATGRAHICS,16, (8 261
On-the-job usining. rate of dependent variable Reduced form model: 622, 627, 642, 661~ empirical implementation,
relum to: models to compute indrect feast 664, 670F 259-263, 280, 287-289
affected by intermittent Production function: squares estimates, 571 in labor supply equations, Statistical software programs: theory, 257-259
labor force briefhistoricat review of equivalence to structural 616-629, 642-644, data, VL Tobit model, See Limited
nal forms for, estimates, 573-575 661-666 data terminator, U1 dependent variable
participation, 174 gencral, 376-380, 533, 535,
empiricat evidence, 172- in wage rate equations, header, 11 models
196 choice between production $84, $45, 555-555, 556 190 overview, 15-17 Transfer function, 428-829
‘Overidentifying restrictions. and cost function, 457-- tase in forecasting or SAS/STAT,16, 17 reviews of, 12 Transitory income, 647-648
test for, $54, 337, 573~ 460 simulation, 526-527 Saturation model, 313 vendors for, 17-18 Translogfunction, 81, 327.
575, 579 ‘Cobb-Douglas, 68-75, 248- use in fabor supply models, SCA SYSTEM, 16, 18 STATPRO,16, 18
256, 450-452 624-626, 658-660 Screening hypothesis of STATVIEW 512+, 16, 18
469-476, 480, 489-398
Truncated data, $95, 666F
Panel data, 167, 649, 668f constantelasticity of Reservation wage, 603, 613, education, 157-158 ‘Structural equation modet, Truncated normal repression
Partial adjustment hypothesis, substitution (CES) 616, G18, 625, 645 Scemingly unrelated 375, 380, $45, 558, equation, 654
315, 320, 346-348, 408 function, 452-457 Residential End-Use Energy estimator, 462-263, 570, $73-875 ‘TSP, 15, $48, $53, 555f
PC-GIVE, 16, 17 definition, 63 Planning System S71, S74 Structurally recursive models, ‘Two-stage least squares:
PC Magazine, 12, 190 integration with learning (REEPS), 332-335 Setection biss-corrected 556, 575-578 in advertising-sales models,
PC-TSP, 15, 17, 18, 348 curves, 71-75, Returns to scale: tegression, 621-623 Successiveleast squares, 556, 379-340, 398, 417-
PSTAT, 16, 17 for Cobb-Douglas function,69 Shadow values, 484 317 420, 432-433
PC Week, 12, 196
eo

702 Subject Index

Two-stage least squares (cont) Fefation to suycessiye least effects of cyclical variations,
with autgcorrelation, 432, Squares estimator, 577 192
534-535 efficiency wages, 175, 192
consistency with rational Uncompensated substitution empirical evidence on, 167~
‘expectations effect, 605-608, 639- 179
hypothesis, 267-268, G44, 654, 662 estimating experience-
561-565 Unemployment, measurement carnings profiles, 199--
in cost of production of, 530-512, $31-532, 200
function content, 463, oo7t human capital theory, 152+
474 User cost ofcapit
difference from two-step definition, 245 sample selectivity issues, 191
ordinary east squares expected capital gains term, sercening hypothesis, 157-
estimation, 420, 5$8— 248 188
561 measurement of, 245-248 union-nonunion relative
general, $52 wages, 176-179, 196—
in investment models, 291- Value-added output, 188 197, 201-203
2 Virtual income, 631, 663 Wald test procedure. 465-467,
in labor supply models, 474, 194-196
640 Wage rates, determinants off WeberFechner law of
in macro-cconomenic differences forsingle and psychophysics, 372
models, 545, 552-554, married women, 197
556-567, 570-573 198 Zelingr-cfficient estimator,
in Phillips curve context, discrimination as source, 462-463, 474, 488—
525, $33-535 180-190 492, 545, S71, 578

You might also like