Effect of Fiscal Deficit On Real Interest Rates

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 10

Effect of Fiscal Deficit

on Real Interest Rates


This paper examines the proposition that an increase in the fiscal deficit, financed
by government borrowing, necessarily raises the real rate of interest and thus ‘crowds out’
private investment. It finds that theoretical positions that affirm this point of view
assume that the economy is in full employment, a condition that is not fulfilled
in most developing countries. The existence of a definitive positive relationship between
real rates of interest and the fiscal deficit-GDP ratio is tested empirically for India and for a
number of other countries in the world. The finding is that interest rates do not
necessarily depend on the fiscal deficit and that policies based on this
understanding are erroneous.
SURAJIT DAS

I Let us now discuss different versions of the theory, which say


Introduction that the fiscal deficit will necessarily raise the rates of interest
and as a result cause crowding out.

I
n mainstream economics literature it is a widely believed
theory that the fiscal deficit necessarily raises the real (do- II
mestic) rate of interest. IMF-World Bank policy directives Theoretical Overview
say that a fiscal deficit (above a certain ratio of the GDP) is
necessarily bad for the health of the economy (no matter what Let us consider the ‘treasury views’3 or the fixed pool of savings
the actual state of aggregate demand be) because it necessarily view. Throughout we assume that the price level is constant so
raises the rate of interest and hence, either lowers the level of that the nominal and real rates of interest are same, if not specified
private investment via the so-called ‘crowding out’ effect, or otherwise. In pre-Keynesian literature the rate of interest was
increases the country’s net external indebtedness. The same believed to be determined by the savings-investment equality.
understanding is being echoed in the official position of the First, we consider the simple case where savings do not depend
government of India and in top policy-making bodies in the upon the rate of interest. If investment demand increases due
country. Therefore, the fiscal deficit-GDP ratio has to be kept to increased government investment expenditure (say by deficit
below a certain level under all circumstances. But as we know, financing) then the rate of interest has to be adjusted in such
expansionary fiscal policy is a key instrument of the Keynesian a way that full crowding out takes place and the ex post savings-
demand management theory. Now, if an increase in the fiscal investment identity is maintained. In other words, savings cannot
deficit necessarily causes crowding out (ignoring for the time increase with an increase in investment demand but increased
being its effect on net external indebtedness1 and on inflation2) investment demand has to be curtailed by increasing the rate of
then surely the whole idea of raising demand by larger govern- interest to maintain the ex post identity.
ment expenditure or by deficit financing is questionable. In fact, In Figure 1, the initial rate of interest ro is determined by the
if ‘crowding out’ occurs then expansionary fiscal policy cannot equality (at point Eo) between savings (SoS*) and investment
have the effect of reducing unemployment and maintaining a high (IoIo). Now if the government investment increases by deficit
level of activity, contrary to what has historically been the case. financing the negatively sloped investment curve shifts rightward
In our present paper we want to investigate whether there is any (from I0I0 to I1I1) and the new intersection point (E1) of the
reason to believe that a higher fiscal deficit-GDP ratio necessarily investment and savings schedules occurs at a higher level of rate
increases the real rate of interest and hence causes a crowding of interest (r1).
out of private investment. The dependence of savings on income was never recognised
The next section concentrates on different theoretical by the treasury view. If we restate the treasury view taking into
arguments or various versions of the theory that claims the fiscal account the dependence of the level of savings on the level of
deficit must cause interest rates to go up. The third section income, it would be as follows: for any given level of real income
deals with the empirical evidences available for the Indian (y) there would be an amount of real savings (s = private savings
economy and the fourth section discusses the empirical + government savings), for any given distribution of income and
evidences of thirty-six different countries, it takes into consider- rate of taxation. If government investment increases, private
ation different kinds of interest rates like government bond investment is bound to fall by the real rate of interest adjustment
yields, treasury bill rates, prime lending rates, deposit rates to maintain the ex post savings-investment identity, because
and money market rates of interest. This paper ends with a savings out of the given income cannot increase any more. Let
concluding section. the given level of output be y* and the private savings and

Economic and Political Weekly March 20, 2004 1299


government savings (i e, tax net of government consumption) Figure 1 Figure 2
generated from that level of income be sp* and sg* respectively. R I1 S0 S1
Now if private investment is denoted by IP and government r I0 I1 S0
investment by Ig then in a simple closed economy framework I0
r1 E1
the ex post identity sp* + sg* ≡ Ip + Ig (sg <0 in case of deficit)
r* E0 E1
must hold. Since the left hand side of the equation is constant,
given the implicit assumptions of the treasury view, on the right r0 E0
I1
hand side if Ig component rises then Ip has to be lower by an I1
exactly equal amount, because the sum of these two has to remain I0 I0
constant. From the above argument it follows that if the fiscal O S* I,S O S0 S1 I,S
deficit for financing government investment rises, the rate of
interest in the economy would necessarily rise to crowd out
private investment (exactly the same conclusion would follow shifts upward right to say I1I1, then at any given nominal interest
if the fiscal deficit rises for financing government consumption rate, the savings curve would also shift rightward from its initial
as well, with private savings remaining unchanged). position (i e, from SoSo to S1S1) through income adjustment. If
But why is the theory propounded as if the level of income the income adjustment takes the form exclusively of output
is given? This is because there is an underlying assumption that adjustment, with no change in price in terms of the ‘wage unit’
the economy is at full employment, which determines the fixed (as would happen, for instance, in a world of oligopoly with mark-
pool of savings (since full employment output cannot be in- up pricing and horizontal prime cost curves), then the real interest
creased, the level of full employment savings (S*), which is a rate (at r* in the diagram) need not be affected at all. Again,
function of output cannot be raised too). That is precisely why if the price level changes, then too savings would increase to
the savings schedule is vertical and rise in investment demand match the investment demand through redistribution of income,
does not lead to output adjustment or increased ex post investment i e, forced savings. The equilibrium point, i e, the intersection
(which has to be identically equal to savings), but as an obvious of investment and savings curves can shift from Eo to E1 and
consequence, raises the rate of interest (from ro to r1). Therefore, both ex post investment and savings can come to equality at a
according to the treasury view, there can be only one level of higher level as compared to the initial situation.
investment at full employment, which is not compatible with an Another, a bit more sophisticated, version of the treasury view
autonomous investment function. states that investment and savings are both functions of the real
In today’s world, the existence of large-scale involuntary un- rate of interest (where, dI(r)/dr<0 and dS(r)/dr>0) (Figure 3). Now
employment is an undeniable fact. Therefore it is inappropriate if aggregate investment demand increases, due to say an increase
to use theories assuming full employment (directly or indirectly) in government investment through deficit financing, the rate of
to draw policy conclusions. We have in the Keynes-Kahn multiplier interest would increase but there would not be full crowding out
analysis an alternative suited to a demand constrained economy. because aggregate savings would also increase, due to the rise
Moreover, even if there is full employment there would also be in interest (since, dS(r)/dr>0). As a result of this, the rate of
price adjustment and, instead of interest adjustment ex post interest would not increase to such a level that full crowding
savings-investment identity can be reached through forced sav- out takes place. Both ex post investment and savings, however,
ings. There is in fact no reason to believe that if the government would be higher and the rate of interest also would increase. This
raises demand by deficit financing there would not be any output is called the theory of partial crowding out due to an increase
adjustment. With the rise in demand, both income and savings in government investment financed by a fiscal deficit (via higher
increase through various rounds of the multiplier. In fact in a real rate of interest).
demand-constrained economy, which is operating well below full Graphically if the rate of interest is ro determined by the
employment, if aggregate demand rises, aggregate supply would intersection of negatively sloped investment (IoIo) and positively
also increase until the two (measured in ‘wage units’) are exactly sloped savings (SS) curves (at Eo), then due to the increase in
equal. To put it differently, the process of increase in income government investment financed by a fiscal deficit the IoIo curve
and employment due to an increase in demand, would continue shifts upward-right say to I1I1. The new interest rate (at E1) would
until an amount of savings, which is exactly equal to the increase be r1, which is higher than ro but lower than r*, (i e, the rate
in home and foreign investment is generated. That means, in fact of interest corresponding to full crowding out). This version of
‘investment determines savings’, which is diametrically opposite the treasury view also says that if government investment in-
to the pre-Keynesian position of ‘savings determines investment’. creases, the rate of interest would necessarily rise and in turn
Hence, a fiscal deficit finances itself in the sense that it generates cause crowding out (though partial).
an equal amount of ‘excess private savings’, i e, savings in private While this view allows savings to depend on the interest rate
hands in excess of private investment, at any given level of the it is still pre-Keynesian in the sense that it takes the level of income
interest rate. Even if we assume that output adjustment is not as given. However, once again in the context of a demand
possible anymore, there would still be forced savings, via, price constrained economy, there is no valid reason to believe that
adjustment, to equalise ex post savings with investment. There- increased government investment financed by borrowing would
fore, there is no valid reason to believe that increased government necessarily increase the real rate of interest and cause crowding
investment financed by borrowing would necessarily increase the out of private investors to maintain ex post savings-investment
real rate of interest and cause crowding out of private investors, identity. Even if we believe that the rate of interest affects, ‘ceteris
to maintain ex post savings-investment identity. paribus’, the level of savings then too it is obvious that aggregate
In Figure 2, if the initial investment function is IoIo and after savings can rise with a rise in aggregate investment demand
an increase in investment financed by a fiscal deficit the curve through an increase in output, even if the interest rate is kept

1300 Economic and Political Weekly March 20, 2004


Figure 3 Figure 4 Figure 5
r r I1
I0 I1 X S I0 S0 S1 r SLF

r* E2
r1 E1
r1 E1
r* E0 GD E1 E0
r0
r0
E0 I1 DLF1
S I1 S0 S1 I0 DLF0
I0 O DLF,SLF
O X0 X1 I,S
O X0 X1 I,S

unchanged. As savings are a positive function of income, Now both the demand and supply of the loanable funds are
if exclusive output adjustment takes place with an increase taken to be functions of only the rate of interest and, therefore,
in aggregate demand (leaving prices in terms of the wage unit equality of demand and supply of loanable funds determines
unchanged), which is perfectly possible in an economy operating the rate of interest in any given period. Now if the demand
well below full employment, savings will increase and ex post for loanable funds increases due to say deficit financing then
savings-investment identity can be attained at any particular real the rate of interest increases.
rate of interest in the economy. In fact, even in the case of full In Figure 5, if fiscal deficit increases, the demand for loanable
employment, instead of output adjustment price adjustment takes funds would also increase and the DLF curve would shift right-
place; an increase in the level of aggregate investment demand ward (from DLF0 to DLF1) and, as a result, the rate of interest
reduces the real income of wage earners and increases the real will increase (from ro to r1) since the SLF curve is positively
profit share. Since a larger proportion is saved out of profit as sloped (a positive function of rate of interest).
compared to wages, aggregate savings rises, called ‘forced savings’ Any theory that draws the supply of a loanable fund (or supply
in the literature of economics. Finally in this case, ex post of savings) curve as a function of interest rate only is implicitly
aggregate savings can become equal to aggregate investment assuming a given level of income. If it is not explicit, then it
demand without increasing the real rate of interest. Therefore is only because of intellectual failure. For every level of income,
it is clear that increased investment demand can always generate there must be a different supply of loanable fund curve. One can
an equal volume of aggregate savings, at any given level of the think of a single ‘supply of loanable fund’ curve only by assuming
interest rate, so that attributing a rise in the interest rate to the income to be given, and the level of income as a full employment
higher investment demand is plain wrong. one. This assumption is crucial for the loanable funds theory;
In Figure 4, it is perfectly possible that the savings curve can as once we recognise that the supply of loanable funds depends
shift rightward (from S0S0 to S1S1) with the increase in gov- on the level of output as well, we can have a new equilibrium
ernment investment (i e, shift of investment curve from I0I0 to with a higher fiscal deficit, higher income and an unchanged real
I1I1) and leave the real rate of interest (r*) unaltered (the assump- rate of interest.
tion being that there is no price adjustment). Thus in Figure 6, starting with the initial equilibrium E0, as
The initial savings-investment equality is at point Eo and the the demand for loanable funds goes up (shift of DLF curve
after adjustment equality can be at point E1 which implies that upward-right from DLFo to DLF1) its supply can also rise (shift
the increased aggregate investment demand results in both the of SLF curve rightward from SLFo to SLF1) due to a rise in
ex post investment and savings increasing from X0 to X1 at an income, and interest rates can be unaffected (at r*) at the new
unchanged rate of interest (r*). equilibrium E1.
Pre-Keynesian economists regarded the rate of interest as the Thus the loanable funds theory shares with the treasury view
factor, that brings the demand for investment and the willingness the counterfactual assumption of a given level of income and
to save into equilibrium with one another. But according to fails to be relevant to the real world. Yet, in one sense it is an
Keynes the rate of interest is not the ‘price’ that brings into improvement over the latter, since by explicitly taking into
equilibrium the demand for resources to invest and the readiness account the hoarding and dishoarding of cash it recognises the
to abstain from present consumption (i e, savings), It (the rate income velocity of money as an endogenous variable, depending
of interest) is the price which equilibrates the desire to hold wealth on the interest rate. However, this advance is not enough since
in the form of cash with the available quantity of cash”4 (i e, without an independent theory of interest rate determination, the
nothing but demand for and supply of money equilibrium) [Keynes loanable funds theory is still dependent on a full employment
1936:167]. This difference has serious consequences for macro- assumption for its logical consistency.
economic policy decisions. In Keynes’s own words “a decreased There exists another version of the theory of crowding out due
readiness to spend will be looked on in quite a different light to financing larger government investment through borrowing.
if, instead of being regarded as a factor which will, cetris paribus, According to this theory banks can create only a certain amount
increase investment, it is seen as a factor which will, cetris of credit in any period.4 If the government takes more, out of
paribus, diminish employment” [Keynes 1936:185]. that banks would substitute government bonds for private bonds
Let us now consider Dennis Robertson’s loanable funds theory or in other words, private investors would be rationed out because
[Kahn 1945]. In any given period the supply of loanable funds the government is more attractive as a borrower. This theoretical
equals the sum of cash dishoarded and savings while the demand understanding is an improvement on the fixed pool of savings
of loanable funds equals the sum of investment and hoarding. or the loanable fund arguments in the sense that it does not assume

Economic and Political Weekly March 20, 2004 1301


Figure 6 Figure 7 Figure 8

r
r DLF1 r I0 I1 M
D
DLF0
S’
r* E0 E1 r1 E1
E1
S1
r1 S’ GovtDebt S
r0 E0
r0 E0
SLF0 SLF1 L S0
S D
O Y0 Y1 Y
O X0 X1 DLF,SLF O K1 K0 K

that increased investment demand, via, deficit financing cannot rise, and crowding out of private investors takes place. As
increase the savings or the supply of loanable funds. In the fixed an obvious consequence of this, “in the long-run equilibrium,
pool of bank credit theory, it is said that banks can create only the capital stock falls”.
a certain amount of credit in any period. For this to be at all Samuelson and Nordhaus are essentially comparing steady
true, it must be the case that the banks have no unutilised capacity states for an exogenously given ‘natural’ rate of growth. There-
to create credit. But in most demand constrained developing fore, firstly, their argument is dependent on a full-employment
countries it is seen that the commercial banks always have excess (or, at least, a constant rate of unemployment) assumption.
capacity to create fresh credit. For example they are seen to hold Secondly, even if we grant such an assumption, the only con-
more government securities, including low yield securities, than clusion that we may logically reach is that there will be a fall
the minimum requirement under the statutory liquidity ratio due in private per capita holding of productive capital. What happens
to lack of adequate demand for credit. to the aggregate per capita capital stock depends on what we
Let r and r’ be the rates of interest on government securities assume about the composition of government expenditure. If the
and on credit, then banks would get rid of excess holding of entire government debt is used to finance accumulation then the
securities if 1/c times r’ exceeds r, where c is the cash reserve per capita steady state capital stock will in fact remain unchanged.
ratio or, in other words, banks would never hold excess gov- Thus ultimately Samuelson and Nordhaus’ argument amounts
ernment securities over and above the SLR requirements, as long to a dynamic version of the treasury view.
as r’/c > r (we assume that commercial banks expand credit in According to the Keynesian tradition the rate of interest is
a coordinated manner, so that they take into account the multiplier determined in the money market by the supply and demand for
effects of a credit expansion). Therefore if there is sufficient credit money. In the IS-LM framework [Branson 1989] (whether in its
demand banks will not resort to excess holding of government original closed economy version or for its extensions to an open
securities. In a situation like this, it is erroneous to believe that economy) the supply of money is taken to be exogenously given
if in a particular period the credit creating ability of commercial (along with the assumptions of given prices and money wages)
banks is limited, and demand for credit increases due to an while the demand for money – taken as the aggregate of trans-
increased fiscal deficit the rate of interest would necessarily go action and asset demand – is believed to be a function of aggregate
up. Even if for the sake of argument we accept that banks cannot output and the rate of interest (where, Md = f[Y, r]: dMd/dY>0
create extra credit given the existing stock of reserve money, if and dMd/dr<0). Now if the fiscal deficit financed by borrowing
they can get additional reserve money when they need, credit increases demand (consumption and/or investment) and, as a
cannot be seen as a constraining factor. Monetary policy in other result, aggregate output of the economy increases, the demand
words is the crucial factor here. for money will also increase. Since the supply of money is
According to Samuelson and Nordhaus (1989) “the most serious exogenously given the increased demand for money will cause
consequence of a public debt is that it displaces capital from the the rate of interest to rise. This in turn would cause private
nation’s stock of wealth” and “private capital is displaced by investment demand to come down and the level of employment
government debt” (p 403). As an explanation of this it is argued and output to fall (though in magnitude it will have to be less
that as the supply of government bonds increases, peoples’ than the initial increase in output otherwise the very reason for
holding of other assets (except government bonds) must be the increase in interest rate would have ceased to exist). Accord-
reduced since total desired wealth holdings are fixed for a given ing to these models if the fiscal deficit increases (in fact if
real rate of interest. The authors have assumed that both demand employment and output increase for a given stock of money) the
and supply of capital are functions of the real rate of interest rate of interest increases, too. In the r-y plane, the slope of the
(where, dKd(r)/dr<0 and dKs(r)/dr>0) i e, as interest rates rise, LM curve would be positive. If the IS curve (commodity market
firms demand less capital, while individuals may want to supply equilibrium condition) shifts rightward due to, say increased
more. government demand, then the rate of interest increases and partial
Now an increase in government debt shifts the household’s crowding out takes place. Ultimately, we get a new equilibrium
supply-of-capital schedule upward-left (from SS to S’S’ in the point at a higher level of output and definitely at a higher rate
Figure 7) because this schedule represents the amount of capital of interest.
that people willingly hold at each rate of interest. The capital In Figure 8, if y increases due to say increased government
holdings are equal to the total wealth holdings minus the holdings expenditure then the commodity market equilibrium curve, i e,
of government debt. The market equilibrium moves north-west IS curve shifts upward right (from I0S0 to I1S1), the rate of interest
(from Eo to E1) along the demand for capital curve, interest rates increases from r0 to r1. In the money market as y increases the

1302 Economic and Political Weekly March 20, 2004


Figure 9 Figure 10 Figure 11
r M 1d
r I0 I1 P D0 D1 S0 S1
0
M d
M0s M1 s
r1 E1

r* E0 E2 r* L E0 E1 M P* E0 E2

P’ E1
S0 S1
M0s M 1s
S0 S1 D0 D1
M0d M 1d
O M 0s M 1s Md,Ms O X0 X1 D,S
O Y0 Y1 Y

transaction (and precautionary) demand for money increases. (equality of demand for and supply of money) can occur at
Since the money supply is exogenously given, the rate of interest any given rate of interest (say at r*). Now if the IS curve shifts
rises which in turn causes speculative demand for money to fall. rightward (from IoSo to I1S1) equilibrium shifts (from Eo to E1),
Ultimately the money market comes to equilibrium at a rate of and as a result, the income level increases (from Yo to Y1) leaving
interest that higher than the initial level. The new equilibrium the interest rate unaffected (at r*).
point E1, i e, the intersection point of I1S1 and LM is situated In an economy where there is a lack of demand both in the
upward right as compared to the initial equilibrium point E0. commodity and credit markets, and unutilised excess capacity
As the theory evolved (particularly after the Keynesian revo- of credit creation with commercial banks, increased government
lution), economists accepted the fact that the level of output is expenditure, by borrowing from the market, increases output in
not given and hence the dependence of savings on income became the commodity market and raises the demand for money in the
important. Simultaneously theories of the interest rate depending money market: However the supply of money also increases and
on the investment-savings equality were replaced by theories, the rate of interest does not rise.
which saw interest rates as being determined in the asset market. Another very widely believed argument is that if the govern-
Following exactly this line of thinking models like the IS-LM ment has to borrow from the market to finance the budget deficit
came into the literature of economics. But in the IS-LM frame- then the supply of government securities has to be increased and,
work (closed or open economy) the money supply (Ms or Ms/P) as a result, the price of government securities must fall in general.
is taken as exogenously given. Given this assumption any increase Then the rate of interest would rise, which will in turn cause
in the demand for money would, cetris paribus, cause the rate crowding out of private investors. For example, the Reserve Bank
of interest to rise. The proponents of endogenous money argued of India in its Report on Currency and Finance for the year
that money supply is not something, which is exogenously given, 2002-03 expressed the fear that the demand for government
but it is determined endogenously. securities has reached saturation. Any further increase in gov-
Figure 9 shows that if the demand for money increases due ernment borrowing, would cause unwanted pressure on the interest
to any expansionary measure on the fiscal front, the Md curve rates preventing commercial banks from meeting the demand for
shifts upward right (from Mod Mod to M1d M1d). Now the new credit if it rises in the future. In other words, any further gov-
demand for money curve cuts the old money supply curve at E1 ernment borrowing would cause rates of interest to rise and,
and the corresponding rate of interest becomes r1 which is higher necessarily, cause crowding out.
than r*. But an appropriate expansionary monetary policy can The belief that the increased supply of government securities
increase the money supply and the Ms curve can also shift must lower security price in general is based on an assumption
rightward from Mos to M1s. The interest rate can remain the same that the total demand for securities is given (or more generally,
(r*) in the new equilibrium E2 as in the initial situation (Eo). the demand curve for securities as a function of the interest rate,
Even if we consider that money supply is a positive function even if not vertical, is given). But a fiscal deficit not only increases
of r, then too the results not change. The dotted money supply the supply of securities but also their demand, i e, it shifts both
curve implies that money supply is interest responsive. the demand and supply curves outwards. The demand for secu-
Now if money supply happens to be endogenous then it implies rities increases precisely because the fiscal deficit increases the
that the rate of interest is set exogenously by policy-makers. Even level of private savings, which in turn have to be placed in various
if money supply is not endogenous, interest rate still is a matter financial assets. The identities (S – I) ≡ (G – T) and (S – I) +
of monetary policy. Therefore, the rate of interest is a policy (M – X) ≡ (G – T) hold for closed and open economies respec-
variable and is fixed at a particular level, though it can vary from tively. A fiscal deficit always generates in a closed economy an
period to period according to the monetary policy. Therefore for amount of private excess savings over private investment (in case
any period, the LM curve would be horizontal in the IS-LM of open economy an excess of S+M over I+X), equal to itself,
framework since money supply would be adjusted according to at any given level of interest. In case of a demand constrained
the demand for money leaving the rate of interest unchanged. economy, it happens through output adjustment and, in the case
Then if government investment financed by a fiscal deficit of a supply constrained economy, it happens through price ad-
increases, the IS curve can shift upward right. Hence the level justment via income redistribution and forced savings. Hence,
of employment and output may rise but the rate of interest would there is no reason that an increase in the supply of government
be unaffected because of the horizontal LM curve. securities would necessarily decrease the price of securities and
In Figure 10, the LM curve in the interest rate-income plane in turn increase the rate of interest in the economy in general.
is shown to be horizontal, i e, in money market equilibrium In Figure 11, if the supply of the government securities in-

Economic and Political Weekly March 20, 2004 1303


creases, the supply curve shifts from SoSo to S1S1. If the section, the data on fiscal deficit GDP ratio and interest rates
demand for it does not increase then the equilibrium point deflated by WPI have been considered for the sake of analysis.
is E1 and the corresponding price of the securities is P’ which All the data used in this chapter are taken either from the
is lower than P* (initial price). But if an the increase in supply government of India or from the Reserve Bank of India (RBI).
increases the demand for government securities, as it must, In the case of lending and deposit rates, we have taken into
the demand curve shifts rightward from DoDo and the price account only the upper limits (provided by RBI) of the respective
of securities rises. In figure DoDo shifts to D1D1, the new rates for different years. If crowding out is caused by high interest
intersection point becomes E2 and the corresponding price rates then the upper limits of rates of interest deserve much more
is P* which is the initial price level corresponding to initial attention. In the case of 91-days treasury bill rates, the annual
equilibrium Eo. This is a special case of security prices averages are calculated as the simple arithmetic mean of 52 weeks
returning to their initial level, either if additional private and, in the case of 364-days treasury bill rates, the annual data
savings are fully held in the form of government securities, are simple averages of the fortnightly rates.
or if the money supply is endogenous. Thus the monetary To check whether any definite positive linear relationship exists
system stands by to convert government securities to money, between real rates of interest and the fiscal deficit-GDP ratio
to the extent required, in order to maintain a constant interest on the basis of above data, we have used some
rate. elementary econometric tools. First, we have tested every series
From the above arguments it is seen that there is absolutely for the ‘unit roots’ or for the existence of ‘random walk’ by using
no reason to believe that the fiscal deficit, financed through the McKinnon p-value as well as Dickey Fuller test statistic. Any
market borrowing by issuing government securities necessarily series is considered to be stationary if either the McKinnon p-
raises the real rate of interest and causes crowding out. In a world value (through Monte Carlo simulations) is less than 5 per cent
where widespread unemployment and large-scale unutilised (i e, Z(t)<0.05) or the absolute value of the Dickey Fuller test
capacity persists, i e, where the level of actual output is much statistic is greater than its critical values (either -3.750 for 1per
less than the potential level of output, aggregate output is likely cent or -3.000 for 5 per cent or -2.630 for 10 per cent level).
to increase with an increase in government demand, rather than That is, the null hypothesis [Yt = @ Yt-1 + ut , null hypothesis
price adjustment or inflation. Again as the rate of interest is is @ = 1] that the series is non-stationary or unit roots exist must
determined by the money market equilibrium condition, i e, by be nullified (accordingly with 99 per cent or 95 per cent or 90
the demand for money-supply of money equality, if money supply per cent level of confidence respectively). Then we have made
is endogenously determined and adjusted according to its demand the time series stationary by taking appropriate differences (in
through appropriate monetary policies, rates of interest become all the cases here either the series are stationary or they are
mere policy variables. According to the monetary policy of the stationary at the first difference level) for all the variables under
government it may be high or low irrespective of the level of consideration. The first differences are calculated simply by
fiscal deficit or government borrowings. The question however subtracting the previous year’s values from the current year’s
is: how empirically valid is this theory? In the next two sections values of each variable, for different years between the time
of this present work, the empirical evidences in India as well period 1990-1991 and 2000-2001. Then (y=AX+B, where A,B
as in other countries are examined. are constants was regressed. The generalised form of the regres-
sion coefficient is given by b=(X’X)–1X’y), taking every station-
III ary series of different rates of interest into account and the fiscal
Indian Case deficit-GDP ratio as the explanatory variable. R2 or the coef-
ficient of determination (R2 = b2 Φxx/Φyy, where y is the de-
Now we shall look at the available empirical evidence on the pendent variable and x is the explanatory variable, Φxx = Γi(xi–
Indian economy during the period 1990-91 to 2000-01, i e, the Γixi/n)2 and Φyy = Γi(yi–Γiyi/n)2 is a measure of how well the
so called deregulated regime of interest rates to find out whether regression line fits the data. The adjusted R2 is used sometimes
interest rates in India are in any way dependent on the fiscal depending on the degrees of freedom.
deficit-GDP ratio or not. The preceding years (i e, before 1990s) A function of sample observations whose computed value
were characterised by the regime of regulated interest rates, and determines the final decision regarding acceptance or rejection
may not throw much light on the issue being considered. In this of the null hypothesis is called a test statistic. Here we have
Table 1: Results of Unit Root Test, Order of Co-Integration and Regression
of Different Interest Rates on Fiscal Deficit-GDP Ratio for India (1990s)
Category Order Obs P>F R2 AdjR2 Coeff P>|t|

GBY (central government) 2 10 0.3126 0.1268 0.0176 1.347053 0.313


GBY (state government) 2 10 0.2600 0.1552 0.0496 1.502225 0.260
GBY (mt) 2 10 0.4387 0.0767 -0.0388 0.9643648 0.439
GBY (lr) 2 10 0.2120 0.1870 0.0853 1.496926 0.212
DR (sr) 2 10 0.5850 0.0389 -0.0812 0.5796948 0.585
DR (mt) 2 10 0.6462 0.0276 -0.0939 0.5190213 0.646
DR (lr) 2 10 0.6462 0.0276 -0.0939 0.5190213 0.646
LR (SBI) 1 11 0.9064 0.0016 -0.1093 0.1450044 0.906
LR (min rate) 2 10 0.9923 0.0000 -0.1250 0.0103754 0.992
91 days TBR 2 7 0.8694 0.0060 -0.1929 0.4261541 0.869
364 days TBR 2 8 0.6405 0.0387 -0.1215 0.8689711 0.641
Call MMR 1 11 0.4564 0.0630 -0.0411 -1.112384 0.456

Source: Reserve Bank of India.

1304 Economic and Political Weekly March 20, 2004


used F (in general F[K–1, n–K] = [{R2/(K–1)}/{(1–R2)/(n– deficit-GDP ratio are insignificant. The real average lending rate
K)}], [K–1, n–K] is the degrees of freedom) or t (here these of all major lending institutions series in India is stationary at
two are equivalent because our regression model has only its first difference level but both correlation coefficient of change
one explanatory variable) as the test statistic. Here our null in real lending rate and change in fiscal deficit-GDP ratio and
hypothesis is that the regression coefficient will be zero and regression coefficient of change in real lending rate on change
hence the alternative hypothesis is that the regression in fiscal deficit-GDP ratio are highly insignificant. Therefore,
coefficient is non-zero. That is, if the null hypothesis cannot in the case of lending rate also, according to our observations
be rejected (with 90 per cent level of confidence) we cannot there is no definite relation between real lending rate and fiscal
say that the alternative hypothesis will be necessarily true, deficit-GDP ratio. In other words it will be erroneous to argue
i e, the rates of interest necessarily depends positively on that high fiscal deficit-GDP ratio raises the lending rates and in
the fiscal deficit-GDP ratio. turn, necessarily causes crowding out of private investment.
In the first column of Table 1 we have mentioned the kind As far as the short or long term real treasury bill rates are
of rates of interest taken into consideration. The numbers in the concerned we see that both the series are stationary at their first
second column denote the level at which both the series of interest difference level. In case of real 91-days (short-term) treasury bills
rate and fiscal deficit-GDP ratio are stationary, i e, 1 denotes that the correlation as well as the regression coefficients between the
both the series are stationary at their current values, 2 denotes change in treasury bill rate and change in fiscal deficit-GDP ratio
that both the series are stationary at their first difference level are highly insignificant. In case of real 364-days (long-term)
and 3 means they are stationary at their second difference levels. treasury bills, we get the same insignificant correlation and
Other columns carry the usual meanings of their respective regression coefficients. Therefore in general we can tell that it
column headings. The meanings of abbreviations used in Table 1 will not be justified to claim any necessary relation between fiscal
are as follows, Order ⇒ Order of co-integration where both the deficit-GDP ratio and real treasury bill rates in India during the
series are stationary, Obs ⇒ Number of observations, Coeff ⇒ period under consideration.
(Linear) Regression coefficient, P>F/|t| ⇒ Probability of The results of correlation between real call money rate and
null hypothesis that regression coefficient is zero to be true, fiscal deficit-GDP ratio and between the first differences of both
R2/AdjR2 ⇒ their usual meanings. the variables and the results of unit root tests are also given. From
As far as real government bond yields are concerned we see Table 1, it is observable that the real call money rate series
from Table 1 that the yield from the central government security becomes stationary at its first difference level but both correlation
series is stationary at its first difference level. However, neither and regression coefficients are highly insignificant. Therefore in
correlation nor the regression coefficients, at the first difference India it cannot be said that the real money market rate of interest
level with respect to fiscal deficit-GDP ratio,5 is significant. It essentially depends on the fiscal deficit-GDP ratio, particularly
is evident that the real government bond yield series is stationary in the period under consideration.
at its first difference level but here too neither correlation In this section, we have tried to examine whether any necessary
nor regression coefficients are significant. Both in case of real relationship exists between rates of interest and fiscal deficit-
medium- and long-term government bond yields it is evident that GDP ratio in the Indian context considering various real rates
the series are stationary at their first difference level but none of interest such as the government bond yield, deposit rate,
of the correlation and regression coefficients are significant. In lending rate, 91 and 364 days treasury bill rates, call money rate
other words the null hypotheses cannot be rejected even at 90 during the time span 1990-1991 to 2000-2001. On the basis of
per cent level of confidence. Therefore, from our above men- available empirical evidence we can conclude by saying that there
tioned results, it will be erroneous to argue that government bond is absolutely no reason to believe that the rates of interest would
yields are necessarily affected by the fiscal deficit-GDP ratio or necessarily rise if the fiscal deficit, as a proportion of GDP, is
a higher fiscal deficit-GDP ratio will necessarily cause govern- raised under the so-called deregulated regime of interest rates,
ment bond yields to increase. in the context of Indian economy.
Now let us consider the deposit rates. The real short-term
deposit rate series in our country is stationary at its first difference IV
level but neither the correlation nor the regression coefficients International Evidence
are significant. If the medium- or long-term real deposit rates
are taken into consideration, the result still does not alter in the In this section we want to see the empirical evidence on the
sense that the series become stationary at the first difference level relationship between the fiscal deficit and the level of interest
However, the correlation and the regression coefficients are rates for countries other than India. Here we wish to test whether
insignificant when we take fiscal deficit-GDP ratio as the ex- the statement that ‘the fiscal deficit-gross domestic product ratio
planatory variable. Therefore the change in real deposit rates in necessarily affects the real rates of interest’ is valid for different
India does not necessarily depend upon the change in the fiscal countries all over the world. Moreover on the basis of the
deficit-GDP ratio during the last decade. available information, we want to examine whether a fiscal deficit
Now we will consider lending rates and their relation with the is necessarily bad for the health of the economy, in the sense
fiscal deficit-GDP ratio in India during the time period 1990- that it necessarily raises interest rates and causes a crowding out
1991 to 2000-2001. It is evident that both the current SBI lending of private investment.
rate series and its first difference are stationary but their corre- We have used International Financial Statistics (IFS) data
lation coefficients with the fiscal deficit-GDP ratio or the change available in the ‘Yearbook of International Financial Statistics
of fiscal deficit-GDP ratio are insignificant. The regression co- 2000’ provided by International Monetary Fund (IMF). We have
efficients of real SBI lending rate on the fiscal deficit-GDP ratio taken the data of 17 years (1983-1999) into consideration. We
or of the change of real SBI lending rate on the change in fiscal have calculated the real rates of interest for five kinds of interest

Economic and Political Weekly March 20, 2004 1305


Table 2: Results of Unit Root Test, Order of Co-Integration and Regression of Different Interest Rates on Fiscal Deficit-GDP Ratio
No Category Order Country Obs P>F R2 Adj R2 Coefficient P>|t|

1 GBY 1 Austria 12 0.1874 0.1669 0.0835 122.467 0.187


2 GBY 1 Sri Lanka 10 0.8067 0.0079 -0.1161 53.1277 0.807
3 GBY 1 Venezuela 15 0.8566 0.0026 -0.0741 40.99107 0.857
4 GBY 2 Belgium 14 0.9216 0.0008 -0.0824 -15.18239 0.922
5 GBY 2 Ireland 15 0.0479 0.2685 0.2122 129.3144 0.048
6 GBY 2 Pakistan 16 0.3919 0.0528 -0.0148 61.3544 0.392
7 GBY 2 Sweden 11 0.2176 0.1634 0.0704 -36.87868 0.218
8 GBY 3 Norway 9 0.4842 0.0455 -0.0413 -42.48041 0.484
9 GBY 3 Denmark 15 0.0038 0.4866 0.4472 -220.1706 0.004
10 GBY 3 Thailand 12 0.5032 0.0460 -0.0494 -141.6749 0.503
1 TBR 1 Bulgaria 8 0.4921 0.0819 -0.0711 1818.653 0.492
2 TBR 1 Israel 15 0.0006 0.6100 0.5799 -820.1708 0.001
3 TBR 1 Poland 6 0.2035 0.3657 0.2071 -525.5587 0.203
4 TBR 1 Sri Lanka 16 0.7732 0.0061 -0.0649 -47.5655 0.773
5 TBR 2 Hungary 10 0.2530 0.1594 0.0544 492.7953 0.253
6 TBR 2 Malaysia 13 0.0494 0.3070 0.2440 102.7307 0.049
7 TBR 3 Zimbabwe 7 0.3656 0.1652 -0.0018 -158.3041 0.366
1 LR 1 Bulgaria 9 0.4493 0.0840 -0.0468 1840.43 0.449
2 LR 1 El Salvador 17 0.1546 0.1303 0.0723 238.6198 0.155
3 LR 1 Venezuela, Rep Bol 15 0.9217 0.0008 -0.0761 24.94039 0.922
4 LR 2 Colombia 13 0.4312 0.0572 -0.0285 -54.82819 0.431
5 LR 2 Czech Republic 6 0.4731 0.1353 -0.0809 -131.8965 0.473
6 LR 2 Egypt 13 0.2592 0.1140 0.0335 -72.39933 0.259
7 LR 2 Hungary 9 0.1958 0.2261 0.1155 563.024 0.196
8 LR 2 Peru 12 0.0583 0.3136 0.2449 -14049.61 0.058
9 LR 2 Poland 9 0.3248 0.1381 0.0150 -494.4919 0.325
10 LR 3 Belarus 5 0.1252 0.5978 0.4637 59769.05 0.125
11 LR 3 Chile 15 0.2231 0.1118 0.0435 502.6915 0.223
12 LR 3 Denmark 15 0.0101 0.4105 0.3651 -216.9105 0.010
13 LR 3 Ecuador 10 0.4911 0.0611 -0.0562 196.2485 0.491
14 LR 3 Thailand 12 0.4118 0.0683 -0.0248 -149.3268 0.412
1 DR 1 Argentina 12 0.6473 0.0218 -0.0761 -77615.32 0.647
2 DR 1 Austria 12 0.1231 0.2209 0.1430 151.1763 0.123
3 DR 1 Bulgaria 9 0.4799 0.0737 -0.0587 1739.613 0.480
4 DR 1 El Salvador 17 0.1508 0.1326 0.0748 222.9907 0.151
5 DR 1 Israel 17 0.4367 0.0408 -0.0231 73.90268 0.437
6 DR 1 Venezuela Rep Bol 15 0.8881 0.0016 -0.0752 -34.7868 0.888
7 DR 2 Belgium 14 0.8619 0.0026 -0.0805 29.33359 0.862
8 DR 2 Colombia 13 0.3692 0.0738 -0.0104 -62.90698 0.369
9 DR 2 Czech Rep 6 0.3670 0.2052 0.0065 -172.3902 0.367
10 DR 2 Hungary 15 0.2193 0.1136 0.0454 330.1716 0.219
11 DR 2 Jordan 7 0.8642 0.0064 -0.1923 -11.62897 0.864
12 DR 2 Poland 5 0.4513 0.1992 -0.0678 -785.2854 0.451
13 DR 2 Slovenia 5 0.9287 0.0031 -0.3291 -7.927066 0.929
14 DR 3 Belarus 5 0.1333 0.5825 0.4434 59174.54 0.133
15 DR 3 Chile 15 0.1819 0.1327 0.0660 547.1868 0.182
16 DR 3 Denmark 15 0.0028 0.5101 0.4724 -222.3814 0.003
17 DR 3 Norway 13 0.5646 0.0311 -0.0570 -35.54968 0.565
18 DR 3 Thailand 12 0.3177 0.0996 0.0095 -175.0124 0.318
1 MMR 1 Argentina 9 0.0244 0.5388 0.4729 4042.467 0.024
2 MMR 1 Bulgaria 9 0.5002 0.0673 -0.0659 1640.381 0.500
3 MMR 1 Indonesia 15 0.1322 0.1656 0.1014 -326.5479 0.132
4 MMR 1 Sri Lanka 17 0.6458 0.0145 -0.0512 -64.90381 0.646
5 MMR 2 Austria 11 0.5475 0.0416 -0.0649 68.28616 0.548
6 MMR 2 Belgium 14 0.6992 0.0129 -0.0694 65.51469 0.699
7 MMR 2 Ireland 16 0.0172 0.3427 0.2957 182.9615 0.017
8 MMR 2 Kuwait 11 0.3666 0.0912 -0.0097 7.059883 0.367
9 MMR 2 Malaysia 13 0.0875 0.2423 0.1734 82.79058 0.087
10 MMR 2 Morocco 6 0.0571 0.6367 0.5459 -253.3792 0.057
11 MMR 2 Pakistan 16 0.3306 0.0676 0.0010 79.14081 0.331
12 MMR 2 Singapore 14 0.0271 0.3454 0.2909 -86.56216 0.027
13 MMR 2 Slovenia 5 0.8553 0.0130 -0.3160 -22.00739 0.855
14 MMR 2 Tunisia 16 0.4669 0.0384 -0.0303 22.84936 0.467
15 MMR 2 Turkey 12 0.3434 0.0900 -0.0010 259.4499 0.343
16 MMR 2 Uruguay 5 0.4910 0.1695 -0.1073 194.3757 0.491
17 MMR 3 Norway 13 0.9937 0.0000 -0.0909 0.5710075 0.994
18 MMR 3 Poland 4 0.9603 0.0016 -0.4976 -55.32075 0.960
19 MMR 3 Thailand 12 0.2513 0.1291 0.0421 -215.2747 0.251
20 MMR 3 Denmark 15 0.0072 0.4379 0.3947 -245.0373 0.007
21 MMR 3 Finland 14 0.9796 0.0001 -0.0833 -1.561747 0.980
22 MMR 3 Korea 15 0.6174 0.0197 -0.0557 -58.46089 0.617

Source: Calculated from IFS CD-ROM – 2001, IMF.

1306 Economic and Political Weekly March 20, 2004


rates, viz, government bond tield (GBY), treasury bill rate will be zero, less than 10 per cent. For Malaysia, the sign of
(TBR), money market rate (MMR), lending rate (LR) and the correlation coefficient is positive but it is negative for
deposit rate (DR) with respect to wholesale prices of the Israel. Hence it will not be justified to conclude that the fiscal
respective years for each country for which data are available. deficit-GDP ratio necessarily affects the rate of interest
If the nominal rate of interest is R per cent and the inflation positively, particularly when the short-term treasury bill is
rate is û = (dP/P)X100, then the real rate of interest is concerned. From the above results, in fact, there is no reason
calculated as r = R- û. We have calculated the fiscal deficit- to believe that a higher fiscal deficit-GDP ratio will necessarily
GDP ratio simply by dividing fiscal deficit in the national raise the real treasury bill rates.
currency for each country by GDP in the national currency For Bulgaria, El Salvador and Venezuela both fiscal deficit-
for the respective years. Exclusion of countries is dictated GDP ratio and real lending rate (LR) series are stationary; they
entirely by the non-availability of data. For those countries are stationary at their first difference level for countries Colom-
where the so-called regulated regime of rate of interest was bia, Czech Republic, Egypt, Hungary, Peru and Poland and at
previously in operation, we have excluded them or the years their second difference level for Belarus, Chile, Denmark, Ecuador
during which interest rates were regulated. In this section also, and Thailand. Among the total of 14 countries, only for Peru
we used the same technique and same econometric tools as in and Denmark is the probability of null hypothesis, that the
the preceding section. regression coefficient will be zero, less than 10 per cent. More-
In the second column of Table 2, we have mentioned the kind over, both the significant coefficients are negative, i e, if fiscal
of rates of interest taken into consideration. The numbers in the deficit-GDP ratio increases the lending rate decreases and vice
third column denote the level at which both the series of interest versa. As far as the real prime lending rate is concerned we see
rate and fiscal deficit-GDP ratio are stationary, i e, 1 denotes that that there is not even a single country under consideration where
both the series are stationary at their current values, 2 denotes the regression coefficient of real lending rate on fiscal deficit-
that both the series are stationary at their first difference level GDP ratio or of change in real lending rate on change in fiscal
and 3 means they are stationary at their second difference levels. deficit-GDP ratio significant as well as positive. Therefore, this
Other columns carry the usual meanings of their respective case as well, there is no reason to believe that the fiscal deficit-
column headings. We did not take industrially developed coun- GDP ratio necessarily affects the real lending rate or an increase
tries called the G7 countries into consideration and exclusion in the fiscal deficit, as a percentage of GDP, will necessarily cause
of some other countries are strictly because of unavailability of the prime lending rate to go up.
data. All the calculations are done in STATA – 7 package and The real deposit rate (DR) and the fiscal deficit-GDP ratio
all the data are collected from International Financial Statistics become free of unit roots for Argentina, Austria, Bulgaria, El
CD-ROM – 2001 (provided by IMF). The meanings of abbre- Salvador, Israel and Venezuela; for Belgium, Colombia, Hun-
viations used in Table 2 are as follows: Order ⇒ Order of co- gary, Czech Republic, Jordan, Poland and Slovenia at their first
integration where both the series are stationary, Obs ⇒ Number difference level and for Belarus, Chile, Denmark, Norway and
of observations, Coeff ⇒ (Linear) Regression coefficient, P>F/ Thailand at their second difference level. Out of a total of 18
|t| ⇒ Probability of null hypothesis that regression coefficient countries only in the case of Denmark do we get a significant
is zero to be true, R2 /AdjR2 ⇒ their usual meanings. regression coefficient but that coefficient also has a negative sign.
Let us first consider the government bond yield (GBY) and Therefore, from here also, it will not be prudent to argue that
see its relationship with the fiscal deficit-GDP ratio. For Australia, a higher fiscal deficit, as a proportion of GDP, necessarily leads
Venezuela and Sri Lanka both the series, viz, fiscal deficit – GDP to a higher real deposit rate in the economy.
ratio and the real government bond yield are stationary; for If we take into account the real money market interest rate or
countries like Belgium, Ireland, Pakistan and Sweden both the MMR we see that both interest rate and the FD-GDP ratio series
series are stationary at their first difference level and for Norway, become stationary for the countries Argentina, Bulgaria, Indo-
Denmark and Thailand both the series are stationary at their nesia and Sri Lanka; both the series become stationary at their
second difference level. Out of a total of 10 countries only for first difference level for countries Austria, Belgium, Ireland,
two countries, namely, Ireland and Denmark, are the regression Kuwait, Malaysia, Morocco, Pakistan, Singapore, Slovenia,
coefficients significant at 90 per cent level of confidence. But Tunisia, Turkey and Uruguay. Both the series become unit root
for Ireland the sign of the regression coefficient is positive, and free at their second difference level for Norway, Poland, Thai-
in the case of Denmark it is negative. As far as the government land, Denmark, Finland and Korea. Out of a total of 22 countries,
bond yield is concerned, we can conclude that it does not nec- only in the case of Argentina, Ireland, Malaysia, Morocco,
essarily depend on the fiscal deficit-GDP ratio, except in the case Singapore and Denmark are the regression coefficients signifi-
of Ireland. Only in case of Ireland are the regression coefficients cant, i e, we can reject the null hypothesis with at least 90 per
positive and significant. Otherwise our results show that the cent level of confidence. Among them, for Argentina, Ireland
regression coefficients are either insignificant or negative. and Malaysia the coefficients are positive but for Morocco,
Therefore it is not true that if the fiscal deficit-GDP ratio in- Singapore and Denmark the coefficients are negative. Therefore
creases, the real government bond yield will necessarily rise. this empirical evidence also does not support the widely believed
In case of treasury bill rate (TBR) we see that for countries proposition that a higher fiscal deficit or higher fiscal deficit-
Bulgaria, Israel, Poland and Sri Lanka both real interest rate and GDP ratio necessarily raises the real rate of interest (in this case
fiscal deficit – GDP ratio series are stationary; for Hungary and the real money market rate of interest) in the economy.
Malaysia at their first difference level and for Zimbabwe at their In this section we have considered five kinds of rates of interest,
second difference levels both the series are free of unit roots. viz, real government bond yield, short-term treasury bill rate,
Among seven countries, only for Israel and Malaysia, is the prime lending rate, deposit rate and money market rate of interest.
probability of the null hypothesis, that the regression coefficient In fact there are only a few countries where the correlation

Economic and Political Weekly March 20, 2004 1307


between the real rate of interest and fiscal deficit-GDP ratios, lending rates, deposit rates and money market rates of interest
or the change in the real rate of interest and change in fiscal deficit- and their relation with the fiscal deficit-GDP ratio were analysed.
GDP ratio are significant and positive, i e, move in the same This section concluded that, as far as the empirical evidence from
direction. The regression results of the rates of interest on the different countries all over the world is concerned, it would not
fiscal deficit-GDP ratio show that, for very few countries, the be justified to argue that the fiscal deficit, as a proportion of
regression coefficients are significant as well as positive. That GDP, necessarily raises real rates of interest in the economy and
is, for very few countries it can be said that the fiscal deficit, hence affects growth by crowding out private investors.
as a proportion of GDP, rises, as a result of which the rates of This paper ends with the conclusion that interest rates do not
interest rise. Again, when we regress the change in real interest necessarily depend on the fiscal deficit -29and that policies based
rates on change in fiscal deficit-GDP ratio, we get similar results on this understanding are also erroneous. The argument that ‘the
as before, in the sense that, for very few countries, it gives interest rates are high because of government borrowing’ has
significant positive results. It means that for very few countries neither any theoretical nor any empirical basis, neither in India
it is true that changes in the fiscal deficit-GDP ratio cause rates nor in other countries around world.
of interest to change in the same direction. Therefore, we can
conclude from this section that it is not justified to say – at least Address for correspondence:
as far as empirical evidence of different countries (obviously dsurajit_jnu@yahoo.com
those countries which we have considered in our present work)
is concerned – that the fiscal deficit, as a proportion of GDP Notes
necessarily raises the rates of interest in the economy and, hence,
in turn necessarily causes crowding out. [For this paper, I am very much indebted to Prabhat Patnaik, Prasenjit Bose
and Jyotirmoy Bhattacharya. Without their academic help and moral support
this work would not have been completed.]
V
Conclusion 1 From the ex post identity (S-I) + (M-X) º (G-T) we get that a fiscal deficit
always generates an amount of (S+M) over (I+X) equal to itself. Therefore
In the second section of this paper, different theoretical argu- the current account crisis is not necessary.
2 In the presence of huge involuntary unemployment and unutilised capacity
ments which say that a fiscal deficit financed by borrowing from
there is absolutely no reason to believe that there will be only price
the domestic market necessarily raises the real rates of interest adjustment instead of output adjustment. In fact there will be output
in the economy, were discussed along with their counter argu- adjustment through Keynes-Kahn multiplier and that adjustment will
ments. The pre-Keynesian positions were discussed and it was continue until supply matches the increased demand in the long run
shown how full employment is the underlying assumption of (provided the economy does not reach full employment before that).
3 See Kahn 1972,
these theoretical prescriptions. This assumption is necessary for
4 See Patnaik 2001.
the logical tenability of the argument, irrespective of whether 5 Fiscal deficit-GDP ratio is stationary and its first difference is also
the savings curve (as a function of the interest rate) is vertical stationary.
or upward sloping. The loanable fund theory of Dennis Robertson
was also discussed along with its counter arguments. The fixed References
pool of bank credit view and its limitations were discussed
together with the ‘displacement of private capital by government Branson, W H (1989): Macroeconomic Theory and Policy, Harper and Row
debt’ argument of Samuelson and Nordhaus. Having discussed Publishers, third edition, New York.
the above mentioned versions of the theory that ‘the fiscal deficit Kahn, R (1954): ‘Some Notes on Liquidity Preference’, Manchester School
of Economics and Social Studies, September, pp 229-57.
necessarily causes real interest rates to rise,’ we have reached – (1972): ‘Selected Essays in Employment and Growth’, Cambridge University
the conclusion that the theory is untenable in its various versions. Press, Cambridge.
There is absolutely no reason to believe that real rates of interest Keynes, J M (1936): The General Theory of Employment, Interest and
would necessarily rise due to the fiscal deficit or due to deficit Money, Harcourt, Bruce and Company, New York.
financing of the government in any economy. Patnaik, P (2001): ‘On Fiscal Deficits and Real Interest Rates’, Economic
and Political Weekly, April 14.
In the third section of paper, data on the Indian economy was Samuelson, P A and W D Nordhaus (1989): Economics, Mcgraw-Hill Book
analysed. Here, with the help of some elementary econometric Company.
tools like correlation, unit root tests and regression, it was tested
whether any definite positive relationship between real rates of
interest and the fiscal deficit-GDP ratio exists. We considered
different kinds of interest rates, viz, government bond yields,
deposit rates, lending rates, 91-day and 364-day treasury bill rates
and the call money rate of the Indian economy, during the time
period 1990-1991 and 2000-2001 or the period of deregulated
rates of interest. Finally, we came to the conclusion that it would
be erroneous to argue that a higher fiscal deficit-GDP ratio would
necessarily raise the real rates of interest in the Indian economy.
The fourth section of our present work concentrates on the
empirical evidence available for different countries all over the
world during the last two decades (1980s and 1990s). In this
section also, the data of different real rates of interest, viz, real
government bond yields, short-term treasury bill rates, prime

1308 Economic and Political Weekly March 20, 2004

You might also like