Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 16

Journal of Business Ethics

https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-020-04578-2

ORIGINAL PAPER

A Commons Strategy for Promoting Entrepreneurship and Social


Capital: Implications for Community Currencies, Cryptocurrencies,
and Value Exchange
Ana Cristina O. Siqueira1 · Benson Honig2 · Sandra Mariano3 · Joysi Moraes3

Received: 20 December 2018 / Accepted: 16 July 2020


© Springer Nature B.V. 2020

Abstract
Examining how new forms of currencies diffuse is important to uncover their impact on the organization of communities,
and thus motivates our study of community currencies. Community currencies provide a medium of exchange by using
alternative banknotes or electronic money, which circulates only within particular communities, allowing members to trade
goods, increase social cohesion, and achieve collective goals. In this study, we examine how community currencies help
facilitate social commons by serving as a setting for building community relationships and a catalyst for other social activities
beyond market relations. We analyze cases of community banks that provide microfinance and issue community currencies
in Brazil. We find that microfinance entrepreneurs who involve a greater diversity of stakeholders from public, private, and
nonprofit sectors in decision making even prior to startup, while also facilitating the formation of supportive social capital
from diverse cross-sector stakeholders, increase opportunities for developing new community currencies. By exploring
the implications of entrepreneurial actions that promote inclusive participation of diverse stakeholders for accomplishing
collective goals, our findings are relevant for other activities that create a common pool of resources while also developing
the vitality of the community, including initiatives that use cryptocurrencies and other emerging forms of currencies for
building social commons.

Keywords  Commons · Entrepreneurship · Social capital · Currencies · Microfinance

Introduction

The concept of money, which essentially represents a debt


obligation, encompasses one of the most binding and divi-
sive institutional aspects of nations, having expedited rev-
* Ana Cristina O. Siqueira olutions and insurrections, resulting in the destruction of
siqueiraa@wpunj.edu debt records, and the redistribution of land (Graeber 2012;
Benson Honig Rosales 2019; Sonenscher 1997). Focusing on the institu-
bhonig@mcmaster.ca tional nature of declared value, the chartalist perspective
Sandra Mariano holds that it is the state that determines how certain pay-
sandramariano@id.uff.br ments are made and what medium is utilized (Bell 2001).
Joysi Moraes According to the concept of embedded economy, markets
jmoraes@id.uff.br are institutions and economies are embedded within these
1 institutions (Polanyi 1944). As communities determine their
Cotsakos College of Business, William Paterson University,
1600 Valley Road, Wayne, NJ 07470, USA own conception of virtual economic and social value, they
2 have a new opportunity to influence supportive prosocial
McMaster University, DeGroote School of Business, 1280
Main Street West, Hamilton, ON L8S4M4, Canada activities by setting unique rules of exchange.
3 More recently, we observe the rise of decentralized vir-
Department of Entrepreneurship and Management,
Universidade Federal Fluminense, Rua Mario Santos Braga, tual currencies that represent debt and obligations, which
S/N ‑ 7o. Andar ‑ Centro, Niteroi, RJ 24020‑140, Brazil transcend national boundaries and physical constraints,

13
Vol.:(0123456789)
A. C. O. Siqueira et al.

such as precious metals (Pieters 2017). Emergent innova- Money, Debt, and Social Relations
tive blockchain assets, such as bitcoin and the proposed
Facebook libra, suggest the growing influence of globally Money represents a universal instrument of commerce,
traded and unregulated alternative currencies, many of through which goods of all kinds are bought and sold, or
which evade national regulation, certification, and taxation exchanged for one another (Smith 1776). The view that
(Pilkington 2019). As part of the increasing complexity of markets are efficient has essentially become the dominant
value exchange systems, countries are exploring the possibil- paradigm of neo-classical economics (Stiglitz 1988), with
ity of issuing their own national digital currencies, such as economists identifying money as a medium of exchange,
the crypto yuan, which is expected to be fully backed by the a storage of value, and a measure for accounting purposes
central bank of China (Mukherjee 2019). Examining how (Mitchell and Mickel 1999). Yet, an alternative view is
parallel currencies that exist alongside their traditional coun- that economic transactions emerged partially as a com-
terparts diffuse and are leveraged represents an important munity building process, in which debt served as a reason
element of social and economic organization, which may to engage in and maintain social relationships (Graeber
yield significant impact on the political and social organiza- 2012).
tion of communities, and thus motivates our study of com- Anthropologists have examined the question of social
munity currencies. relations and exchange (Tax 1953), occasionally observ-
Community currencies represent an important type of ing human activity that disputes Adam Smith’s notion of
commons, which have been promoted in various environ- the “invisible hand” (Smith 1776). For example, when
ments worldwide as a means to maintain wealth inside explaining the Algerian Kabyle relationships, Bourdieu
marginalized areas, and thereby achieve social goals and points out that what he observed was not simply a matter
alleviate poverty (Meyer and Hudon 2017). Community cur- of reciprocal exchange, but rather intricate social relations
rencies are defined as an alternative medium of exchange (Bourdieu 1990). Moreover, recent research has made
by using banknotes or electronic money, which circulates an important distinction between a debt, something that
only within particular communities, allowing members to requires a precise quantification in terms of money, and
trade goods and increase mutual support (Seyfang 2004). an obligation, something that generates expectations of
From a commons perspective, we examine what facilitates behavior in a certain way (Graeber 2012). Furthermore,
the diffusion of community currencies, the construction of a scholars (Polanyi 1944; Patomaki 2014) have highlighted
“social commons” (Meyer and Hudon 2018), and their use as the view of the state as a site for regulation as well as the
a social adhesive or catalyst for other social activities beyond rise of collective forms of governance, which aim at pre-
market relations. Thus, we focus on the following question: venting the destruction of social relations caused by undue
market commodification.
Research question  How do entrepreneurial actions and Community land trusts and worker cooperatives rep-
interaction with diverse stakeholders influence the develop- resent two examples of institutions that challenge the
ment of social commons and new community currencies? commodification of land and labor (Peredo and Murdith
2019), invoking ownership qualities that expand beyond
The study of community currencies is critical because supply and demand, bankruptcy and monetary policy,
they provide a unique platform with which communities toward common ownership and the decommodification of
can redefine their economic development. In this study, we labor in support of collective decision making. Numerous
address the following topics. First, we develop our theoreti- scholars have pointed toward similar decommodification
cal reasoning centering on how community currencies help of goods as diverse as carbon markets (Stuart et al. 2019),
build and maintain social commons. Second, we analyze two food labels (Guthman 2008), agricultural markets (Mer-
cases of community banks that provide microfinance and cado et al. 2018), and the information highway (Rosen and
issue community currencies in Brazil to understand stake- Carr 1997). Perhaps the most impactful arena for examin-
holder interaction and development of social commons and ing collective forms of governance rests in the utilization
community currency. Third, we describe the findings from of currency, and we turn now to its context, followed by
our analysis and develop two propositions regarding the role its relation to the commons.
of interaction with diverse stakeholders and formation of Some scholars argue that paper money is an unbacked
cross-sector support in the development of new community social construction reflecting a collective agreement, and
currencies. Finally, we discuss the implications of the find- that people should be able to create and use their own
ings and our propositions for theory, and how our findings forms of money to fill the gap caused by a lack of state-
can be relevant to alternative new forms of currencies, such created money (North 2018). Determining and enforcing
as cryptocurrencies (Malherbe et al. 2019), and other com- rules to regulate transactions provides both an opportunity
munity development activities for building social commons.

13
A Commons Strategy for Promoting Entrepreneurship and Social Capital: Implications for…

and a responsibility absent in top-down currency para- develop social equity and community building, which are
digms. Social movement theory recognizes identity poli- typical characteristics of the commons. They do so by facili-
tics in challenging existing institutional structures in order tating the creation of social exchange networks, as well as
to gain control and reformulate categories established by providing access to credit not normally extended to margin-
the state (Bernstein 2005). Thus, it is important to pay alized persons (Williams 1996).
attention to the selection of incentives, cost-reducing The commons paradigm encompasses shared knowledge
mechanisms, and career benefits that typically shape col- including digital content, such as Wikipedia and free soft-
lective behavior (McCarthy and Zald 1977). ware, as well as urban spaces and citizen protest movements
Social capital plays an important role in establishing this (Bollier 2007; Harvey 2012; Ostrom 1990). Community cur-
collective consciousness through the development of social rencies represent an opportunity for a special type of com-
networks of multilateral reciprocal exchange (Williams mons, which have been promoted in various environments
1996; Dolfsma et al. 2009). Integrating peripheral individu- worldwide as a means to maintain wealth inside marginal-
als into new networks of collective behavior requires cred- ized areas, and thereby achieve social goals while fostering
ibility and trust (North 2006). Trust is leveraged by bonding community self-sufficiency. Because they carry a commu-
social capital, which is also referred to as closure between nity-oriented message instead of an individually based one,
members of tightly connected groups, as well as bridging they can act as catalysts for civic participation and commu-
social capital, which is accomplished by linking networks nity development (Meyer and Hudon 2017).
and utilizing weak ties (Putnam 2000; Granovetter 1973; An emphasis on community currency as social commons
Coleman 1988). is consistent with the perspective of “communion” by Bra-
Social capital sometimes reduces entrepreneurship, zilian social theorist Paulo Freire (1970). From Freire’s per-
instead of always promoting it, when the social capital of spective, human development is best accomplished through
powerful groups prevents subordinate groups from equally communion (Medeiros 2008; Romao 2008). This perspective
participating in entrepreneurship (Adler and Kwon 2002). highlights the notion of liberation from individualism, antag-
Indeed, in Old Harbor, Alaska, Alutiiq people have abun- onism, and isolation, while pursuing a better reality through
dant social capital but did not employ their social capital fellowship and solidarity (Freire 1970; Henz 2008). Freire’s
for commercial entrepreneurship (Light and Dana 2013). construct of communion is congruent with the concept of
Conversely, certain middleman minorities endorsing busi- “social commons” by Meyer and Hudon, given that social
ness ownership as a vocation compared to other ethnic and commons refer to a system based on the values of solidarity,
immigrant minorities have demonstrated greater levels of reciprocity, and stewardship, which prioritizes social cohe-
entrepreneurship (Light and Gold 2000). In this way, poten- sion and sustainable development (Meyer and Hudon 2018).
tial detrimental effects of social capital can be transcended Beginning in the 1980s, hundreds of community curren-
by enabling the formation of social capital supportive of cies have been introduced in North America, Europe, Aus-
entrepreneurship or the construction of social commons. tralia, and Japan (Helleiner 2000). Between 1991 and 2004,
there were eighty two community currencies operating in
the United States (Collom 2011). Community currencies
Community Currency and the Commons have been promoted in a wide range of environments, with
estimates of as many as 2500 operating worldwide (Grover
Community currency represents an important avenue for 2006). For instance, the community currency known as
the provision of resources and incentives for the establish- “Ithaca Hours” in Ithaca, United States, were printed locally
ment of community commons, by unlocking identity politics (Salstrom 1997) and a website was used to track policies
and reestablishing innovative and new social relations to (Crowther et al. 2002). Over 10,000 Ithaca Hours have been
solve existing institutionalized problems (Hudon and Meyer issued to thousands of participants and spent at 400 busi-
2016). Definitions of the commons vary by scholarship; for nesses, inspiring at least 82 attempts to create other com-
example, one perspective has focused on the impact of the munity currencies in the United States (Collom 2011).
enclosure laws whereby the poor lost their share in the com- Table 1 shows definitions of community currency in the
mon with the consequential dislocation and forced migration existing literature. The journals listed in the table are gener-
to the cities (Polanyi 1944). Another perspective has been ally from the economics, development, social science, and
operationalized as self-managed common-pool resources social policy literatures. Notably, studies on community cur-
based on design principles, such as defined boundaries, rencies in the management and entrepreneurship literature
congruence between appropriation and provision rules, are scarce (Meyer and Hudon 2017). Although studies in
collective-choice arrangements, and recognition of rights to
organize (Ostrom 1990; Hudon and Meyer 2016). In addi-
tion to economic objectives, community currencies seek to

13
A. C. O. Siqueira et al.

Table 1  Definitions of community currency


Source Journal Terminology Definition

(Clayton 2010) Social and Economic Studies Local currency (1) A local currency is, in effect, a reinvention of
local banking which, by supplying money, can
play a positive but transitional role in improving
social cohesion and thereby encouraging economic
regeneration in poor areas within otherwise pros-
perous countries. (p. 243)
(2) The basic idea is to generate credit and foster
exchanges of goods and services within a com-
munity, partly in order to increase the number
of people who can take part in (legitimate) local
economic activity, and partly to confine the pur-
chasing power thereby created in the area… (pp.
254–255)
(3) Local currencies are a form of soft money, with
easy borrowing, and they are limited to particular
geographic areas. (p. 272)
(Pacione 1999) Debates and Reviews Local currency [A]n independent currency system, operating along-
side a national currency (p. 65)
(Richey and Ikeda 2009) Social Science Quarterly Community currency Community currencies reward volunteers who
contribute to the local area with credits they can
use only in local stores or governmental facilities.
(p. 91)
(Seyfang and Pearson 2000) The Society for International Community currency Community currencies are local initiatives which let
Development people exchange goods and services without using
conventional money. (p. 57)
(Seyfang 2004) Journal of Social Policy Community currency These are local initiatives which provide a comple-
mentary medium of exchange to mobilize informal
mutual support, by allowing members to trade
goods and services among themselves without
using cash. (p. 50)
(Seyfang 2006) Regional Studies Community currency (1) [L]ocal exchange systems using new types of
money (p. 783)
(2) [T]he generic term for a wealth of contempo-
rary alternative exchange systems which exist
alongside mainstream money, and which have
been springing up in developed and developing
countries since the 1990s as a response to social,
economic and environmental needs. (p. 784)
(Seyfang and Longhurst 2013) Ecological Economics Complementary currencies [T]he term complementary currencies is used to
reflect the broader family of parallel money sys-
tems that exist in a range of different forms, from
loyalty points systems to business barter schemes.
(p. 65)
(Meyer and Hudon 2017) Organization Community currency alternative currencies exist alongside their con-
ventional counterparts, circulate within a defined
geographical region or community, and arbitrate
the exchange of goods and services without bear-
ing interest (p. 630)

the existing literature shown in Table 1 have provided con- Methods


tributions to document and describe community currency
initiatives, currently there is little theoretical development Case Study Method
regarding factors that influence the development of com-
munity currencies. This study employs a case study approach based on the Gioia
methodology (Gioia et al. 2012). When the state of prior the-
ory is nascent, the Gioia methodology is particularly helpful
(Edmondson and McManus 2007). To our knowledge, the

13
A Commons Strategy for Promoting Entrepreneurship and Social Capital: Implications for…

state of prior theory and research is nascent because there documents (Myers 2009), which included websites of the
are very few studies on community currency in management banks, magazine articles, and interviews with the founders
and entrepreneurship journals thus far, as shown in Table 1. of the banks issuing the community currency. They are con-
Due to the nascent state of the management literature on sistent with the multiple data sources that are common in the
community currency, approaches such as the Gioia method- Gioia methodology, such as archives and media documenta-
ology (Gioia et al. 2012) can be helpful to identify patterns tion (Gioia et al. 2012). We used these materials to obtain
in qualitative data as a means to open up nascent lines of information about the environment and context of each bank
research (Edmondson and McManus 2007). and community currency.
We used semi-structured interviews which are typically
the most important data source in the Gioia methodology Case Selection
because they provide both retrospective and present accounts
by individuals experiencing the phenomenon of theoreti- Our goal was to select community currencies for which we
cal interest (Gioia et al. 2012). We focused on founders could investigate their launching process, while focusing on
and leaders at each bank who have sufficient knowledge entrepreneurial actions and the context for the development
to speak comprehensively and authoritatively about their of the community currency in each community. Cases are
organizations and community currencies. The goals of our helpful in a case study design when they enable researchers
semi-structured interview protocol were to focus on the to “learn” from them (Stake 2005) to generate theoretical
research question, avoid the use of terminology that could insights. To that end, we selected the cases of two commu-
lead interviewees in their answers, and maintain flexibility nity currencies: Currency C issued by Bank C in the state
to explore spontaneous themes during the interviews (Gioia of Piaui, and Currency A issued by Bank A in the state of
et al. 2012). To achieve these goals, the interview protocol Sao Paulo.
centered on the context faced by each bank and on the events To select our cases, we used theoretical sampling, which
and issues that led to creation of each community currency. refers to the notion of pursuing new interviews that are
We interviewed the banks’ founders and also borrowers of increasingly focused on the concepts and themes under
the banks, employees of the banks, as well as representatives study, until a saturation point when the goal of enabling
of influential organizations that are part of the microfinance theoretical insights is fulfilled (Gioia et al. 2012). We were
environment in the country. Two coauthors traveled to dif- able to reach the point of theoretical insights from our two
ferent states to conduct most of the interviews in person at cases because they provided sufficiently rich contextual data.
the banks’ premises. Subsequent interviews for clarification On the one hand, both community currencies were launched
took place by phone when required. Twenty-six participants by banks that provide microfinance to low-income individu-
were interviewed, either once or across multiple sessions als. These two banks are a part of a countrywide system
in 2012, 2013, and 2014. The interviews typically lasted of microfinance organizations (Palmas 2019), linked to the
between 30 min to two hours and were audio-recorded and emergence of the first Brazilian community bank in a grass-
transcribed. roots manner (Siqueira et al. 2014b).
In addition to the interview data, we used published However, what makes our data particularly rich is the
information about the community currencies in various fact that our two cases share major differences. The two

Table 2  Community currencies Currency Location Issued by Community where the community currency circulates
in the study
C City of Sao Joao Bank C (Com- Circulates within a rural community, which is one of
do Arraial, state munity Bank), the poorest Brazilian municipalities, ranking 5444
of Piaui, Brazil founded in out of 5565 in the Human Development Index of
2007 Municipalities in Brazil (PNUD 2013). In 2005,
a survey conducted by the city administration
concluded that most products were purchased and
produced outside the municipality (Costa 2014)
A City of Sao Paulo, Bank A Circulates within an urban community of low-income
state of Sao (Community residents served by Bank A, which has provided
Paulo, Brazil Bank), founded microfinance for community members to cover
in 2010 their expenses or to start new businesses (Garcia
2011). A law provided governmental funding for the
creation of this community bank and its community
currency, and regulations established that such
governmental funding should be managed by public
agencies

13
A. C. O. Siqueira et al.

community currencies were launched in communities informant terms, then themes, and finally aggregate theo-
located in different states, were developed by banks that retical dimensions (Gioia et al. 2012). Figure 1 summarizes
experienced different founding processes with distinct the data structure.
founders, and the development of these currencies were First, we identified first-order categories based on our
characterized by different circumstances in each commu- interviews with individuals who influenced the develop-
nity. Table 2 summarizes different contextual characteristics ment of the community currencies. Our first categories rep-
of the foundation of the community banks and their com- resent descriptive labels for the activities they described.
munity currencies. Notably, even though Bank A is part of The categories portrayed the vocabulary of the interviewees
the Brazilian Network of Community Banks, Bank A was in an initial phase, which we conceptualized later during
not started in a grassroot manner but instead by a top-down our analytical procedure. For instance, we changed “engag-
law by the government. Thus, the contextual data from our ing public, nonprofit, and/or private constituencies to create
two community currencies are ideal for us to develop our the bank” to “interacting with public, nonprofit, and private
investigation, while focusing on entrepreneurial actions and agents prior to startup.” As a result, this iterative process
interaction with stakeholders involved in the creation of each produced four main categories: “interacting with public,
community currency. private, and nonprofit agents prior to startup,” “involving
The Gioia methodology can be effectively used to ana- cross-sector stakeholders in decision-making processes,”
lyze samples with a smaller number of cases like the one “building a cross-sector support system,” and “building on
in our study. The Gioia methodology is different from the the community’s internal culture.”
multiple case studies approach (Eisenhardt 1989) because Second, we developed second-order constructs by ana-
it does not focus on comparing a certain number of cases lyzing the first-order categories to identify themes. We
(Eisenhardt and Graebner 2007). Instead, the Gioia meth- conducted this second phase through an iterative process to
odology centers on eliciting a data structure composed of identify more abstract constructs. For example, congruent
first-order, second-order, and aggregate dimensions based on with Mair et al. (2012), when we analyzed the categories
theoretical sampling (Gioia et al. 2012) sufficient to generate that referred to “interacting with public, private, and non-
theoretical insights. profit agents prior to startup” and “involving cross-sector
stakeholders in decision-making processes,” we realized that
Data Analysis founders’ experiences prior to startup and their cross-sector
interaction were connected with the way they developed
One of the coauthors led the data coding and analysis pro- their organization’s capability of issuing a community cur-
cess guided by the Gioia methodology (Gioia et al. 2012) rency. To represent this notion, we developed a second-order
in interaction with two other coauthors. The Gioia meth- construct named “developing a new organization that can
odology refers to the notion of using independent coders issue a community currency.” Using this process, we gener-
and reporting intercoder agreements as positivist practices ated the following two second-order constructs: “developing
that can be seen as incongruent with interpretive studies a new organization that can issue a community currency”
that use the Gioia methodology, so we aligned our analyti- and “encouraging cross-sector support for a new community
cal process with an interpretative orientation (Gioia et al. currency.”
2012). In doing so, we used the following approach. If agree- Third, we identified key theoretical dimensions derived
ment between coauthors about some interviewees’ terms and from the second-order constructs. One dimension repre-
interpretations were low, we revisited the data and engaged sented conditions that inspired the creation of a new com-
in mutual discussions to arrive at interpretations that multi- munity currency, while another represented conditions
ple coauthors understood as reflecting the data. To reinforce that impacted the diffusion or adoption of the community
our confidence in our assertions and interpretations, in addi- currency. Building on these ideas, we named these two
tion to our interview data, we used published documents, dimensions “launching a new community currency” and
such as newspaper articles and websites of various organiza- “expanding the adoption of a new community currency.”
tions (Gioia et al. 2012), for triangulation to ensure multiple Both theoretical dimensions represent the data and provide
points of information about the history and context of each guidance to help understand the development of new com-
bank and community currency. munity currencies.
Our analytical procedure entailed three main phases of Next we advanced from the data structure described
coding, which generated a data structure characterizing above to relationships between concepts (Gioia et al. 2012).
first-order, second-order, and final theoretical dimensions. For this purpose, we used our data to formulate a set of
This type of data structure does not represent a chain of theoretical propositions. Propositions represent a contribu-
events and interactions among concepts, but instead it is tion because they provide a description or explanation of
ordered according to hierarchical categories representing emergent theories, which help make them extensible to other

13
A Commons Strategy for Promoting Entrepreneurship and Social Capital: Implications for…

Fig. 1  Categories and coding First-order Second-order Theoretical


categories constructs dimensions

Interacting with Developing a Launching a new


public, private, new organization community
and nonprofit that can issue a currency
agents prior to community
startup currency

Involving cross-
sector
stakeholders in
decision-making
processes

Building a cross- Encouraging Expanding the


sector support cross-sector adoption of a
system support for a new community
new community currency
currency

Building on the
community’s
internal culture

domains (Gioia et al. 2012), while providing direction for Brazil’s National Office of Solidarity Economy adopted
future research. the methodology developed by Palmas Institute as a refer-
ence to develop community banks in the country. Created
Findings as a microfinance solidarity organization, Palmas Bank was
the first community bank in Brazil, designed by its local resi-
The two banks in our study are part of a system in Brazil dents to provide small loans to local entrepreneurs. Palmas
emphasizing the notion of “solidarity economy,” which gen- Bank developed a methodology for the creation of the new
erally fits main criteria (Ostrom 1990) in identifying factors community banks, and formed Palmas Institute to dissemi-
that support a community commons. The Brazilian solidar- nate its methodology across the country. In 2006, Palmas
ity economy is a strategy for inclusion of populations living Institute created the Brazilian Network of Community Banks
in poverty, which may include associativism, cooperativism, (Siqueira et al. 2014b), now with over 100 banks nationwide
as well as collective action, such as collective purchases of (Palmas 2019), which includes the two banks in our study.
inputs and collective marketing of products (SEDS 2015). Community banks are an association initiative involving
To coordinate the country’s solidarity economy system, in residents in a specific community, who seek a solution to
2003 the Brazilian government created the National Office problems in their living conditions by promoting the creation
of Solidarity Economy (Secretaria Nacional de Economia of socioeconomic activities (Franca Filho 2007). Table 3
Solidaria), which supports community banks that offer presents representative quotations from the interviews and
microfinance and community currency (Singer 2009). summary of findings.

13

Table 3  Representative quotations from the interviews and summary of findings

13
Com- Interacting with public, private, Involving cross-sector stakehold- Building a cross-sector support Adoption of the community cur- Summary of findings
munity and nonprofit agents prior to ers in decision-making processes system rency
currency startup

C We took a bus with teachers, We decided to create a “mixed” In the beginning, we started 700 or 800 businesses…about 90 Stakeholders in decision-making
business owners, legislators, organization…The bank belongs registering the businesses [that percent of the businesses [in the processes:
members of community groups, to a nonprofit organization, would accept the community community] (Senior employee, Broad range of stakeholders from
and union representatives, and Center C, and the City Admin- currency]… We walked from Bank C) public, nonprofit, and private
we went there [to Palmas Bank, istration is part of its local one business to another, all of We even have been paying 25 sectors
considered the most influential Board…We make decisions, so them…We explained how Bank percent of the salary of govern- Supportive social capital:
microfinance organization in we have everyone there (Co- C was going to work (Senior mental employees in Bank C’s Higher levels of supportive social
the country, located in the city founder) employee) [community] currency. It is a capital toward Bank C’s com-
of Fortaleza]. Palmas Bank had Bank C is directed by Center C, There is a regional cultural municipality law (Co-founder) munity currency, deriving partly
indeed an interesting experi- an institution that makes all festival in which all awards are from pre-startup engagement of
ence. When we came back, we decisions concerning the bank… paid in community currency. So, diverse stakeholders
decided to create Bank C. It The Center C is composed of the awards are spent in the city Impact:
took some time [to define] who representatives from the City (Co-founder) Higher impact, with over 700 busi-
in fact would own the bank: the Administration, legislators, rural nesses accepting the currency,
City Administration, the union, workers, unions, churches, rural and 25% of the salary of public
[etc.] (Co-founder) and urban associations, [etc.]… employees paid in community
Twelve individuals representing currency
each institution…Center C is a
nonprofit organization we cre-
ated…(Senior employee)
A We noticed the need to generate We have a partner named “[Business owners] ask what Interviewer: Do you know how Stakeholders in decision-making
income in this community… Nonprofit N, which is part of advantages they would have many local businesses accept processes:
once members have housing. SP University [a major public by accepting the [community] Bank A’s community currency? Narrow range of stakeholders,
Then assemblyman Robert G… university]…It is a Civil Society currency…I say that it can Founder: Almost 20. Those who primarily focused on stakeholders
wrote an amendment to provide Organization of Public Interest, increase your clientele, com- really accept it…, who go [to from the public sector
R$1,000,000 [US$325,956] for an entity that can administer munity members will purchase Bank A] exchange Brazilian Supportive social capital:
the development of the local funds from the government, for from you because you accept reais for Bank A’s community Lower levels of supportive social
solidarity economy…With this example, which the commu- the [community] currency, you currency, so they have change capital toward Bank A’s com-
funding, there was a partnership nity banks cannot do directly will sell more…Then he [says in community currency for munity currency, partly due to
between the Housing Move- because they would have to be he] will think and provide his customers limited engagement of stakehold-
ment, SP University [a major a Civil Society Organization answer later. It is a daily strug- ers
public university], and the of Public Interest legally…The gle, every day you have to go Impact:
Ministry of Labor (Founder) legal form [of the community there, and ask whether they will Lower impact, with less than 20
bank] is an Association of Inclu- accept the [community] cur- businesses accepting the com-
sion and Local Development…a rency” (Founder) munity currency
non-governmental organization”
(Founder)
A. C. O. Siqueira et al.
A Commons Strategy for Promoting Entrepreneurship and Social Capital: Implications for…

Launching a New Community Currency can administer funds from the government, for exam-
ple, which the community banks cannot do directly
One main distinct feature between our cases is how entrepre- because they would have to be a Civil Society Organi-
neurs have interacted with cross-sector actors prior to start- zation of Public Interest legally…The legal form [of
ing up their microfinance organizations and respective com- the community bank] is an Association of Inclusion
munity currencies. In this way, we help illuminate resource and Local Development…a non-governmental organi-
acquisition and the role of the state and other nonaffiliated zation (Founder, Bank A)
groups in facilitating a social movement’s resource mobiliza-
Interestingly, Bank C’s co-founder has helped create a
tion (McCarthy and Zald 1977; North 2006). Building on his
“mixed” organization, which includes public and private
role as a governmental representative in the municipality, the
stakeholders in charge of decisions concerning the bank.
co-founder of Bank C proactively interacted prior to startup
He used the term “mixed” for including diverse cross-sector
with a diverse range of public and private agents, such as
representatives in decision making. As he explained:
business practitioners, representatives of nongovernmental
organizations, and public officials. As he stated: We decided to create a ‘mixed’ organization…The
bank belongs to a nonprofit organization, Center C,
We took a bus with teachers, business owners, leg-
and the City Administration is part of its local Board…
islators, members of community groups, and union
We make decisions, so we have everyone there (Co-
representatives, and we went there [to Palmas Bank,
founder, Bank C)
considered the most influential microfinance organiza-
tion in the country, located in the city of Fortaleza]. Accordingly, Bank C has involved public and private
Palmas Bank had indeed an interesting experience. stakeholders in decision-making processes. As one inter-
When we came back, we decided to create Bank C. It viewee stated:
took some time [to define] who in fact would own the
Bank C is directed by Center C, an institution that
bank: the City Administration, the union, [etc.] (Co-
makes all decisions concerning the bank…Center C is
founder, Bank C)
composed of representatives from the City Administra-
By contrast, the founder of Bank A interacted mostly tion, legislators, rural workers, unions, churches, rural
with public agents prior to startup. One main reason was and urban associations, [etc.]…Twelve individuals
that Bank A was created by the government in a top-down representing each institution...Center C is a nonprofit
manner, when a law was passed to provide governmental organization we created (Senior employee, Bank C)
funding for the creation of new community banks and new
Bank C has been able to develop its community currency
community currencies. As the founder of Bank A stated:
further than Bank A. According to one interviewee:
We noticed the need to generate income in this com-
[Bank C’s leaders] registered about 700 or 800 busi-
munity…once members have housing. Then assem-
nesses... So, I believe that about 90 percent of the
blyman Robert G…wrote an amendment to provide
businesses [in the community] accept the community
R$1,000,000 [US$325,956] for the development of the
currency (Senior employee, Bank C)
local solidarity economy...With this funding, there was
a partnership between the Housing Movement, SP Uni- In contrast, Bank A engaged considerably fewer busi-
versity [a major public university], and the Ministry of nesses than Bank C. The interviewer asked Bank A’s
Labor (Founder, Bank A) founder: “Do you know how many local businesses
accept Bank A’s community currency?” Bank A’s founder
Moreover, Bank A has faced regulations that have encour-
answered:
aged interaction with mainly public actors. These regulations
restrict how governmental funding can be administered. Almost 20. Those who really accept it…, who go [to
Partly due to these legal circumstances, the founder of Bank Bank A] exchange Brazilian reais for Bank A’s com-
A interacted mostly with public agents prior to startup. For munity currency, so they have change in community
example, Bank A has involved in decision-making process currency for customers (Founder, Bank A)
representatives of organizations like Nonprofit N as part of
As a result, the pattern evident in our data is that involv-
SP University, which are mostly public representatives. As
ing cross-sector stakeholders in decision-making processes
the founder of Bank A said:
is likely to increase opportunities for developing new com-
We have a partner named Nonprofit N, which is part of munity currencies, particularly when the founder interacts
SP University [a major public university]…It is a Civil with multi-sector stakeholders prior to startup. Thus, we
Society Organization of Public Interest, an entity that develop the following proposition.

13
A. C. O. Siqueira et al.

Proposition 1:  Entrepreneurs who involve stakeholders in Development Index of Municipalities in Brazil (PNUD
decision making tend to increase opportunities for devel- 2013). Additionally, a survey conducted by the City Admin-
oping new community currencies, and these effects amplify istration in 2005 concluded that most products were pur-
when they interact with a greater diversity of stakeholder chased and produced outside the municipality (Costa 2014).
groups even prior to startup. Thus, governmental employees have reasons to support their
payment in community currency, in order to maintain wealth
within the municipality and thereby alleviate poverty in their
Expanding the Adoption of a New Community community.
Currency In Bank C’s community, in addition to the law regarding
the partial payment of public employees’ salaries in com-
Bank C’s leaders have obtained strong support from local munity currency, other payments have also been made in
businesses by visiting each business and explaining the con- community currency. As the co-founder of Bank C states:
cept of the community currency. They have taken initiatives
There is a regional cultural festival in which all awards
to build an extensive support base involving not only actors
are paid in community currency. So, the awards are
of the public and nonprofit sectors, but also representatives
spent in the city (Co-founder, Bank C)
of private businesses. As one senior employee of Bank C
stated: In the community of Bank C, there is evidence of political
and legal circumstances facilitating the formation of sup-
In the beginning, we started registering the businesses
portive social capital toward the adoption of its community
[that would accept the community currency]… We
currency.
walked from one business to another, all of them…
By contrast, the founder of Bank A indicates much less
We explained how Bank C was going to work (Senior
supportive social capital in Bank A’s community. Bank A’s
employee, Bank C)
founder states that:
In contrast, Bank A’s leader has been able to foster only
A city in the Northeast [unlike the Southeast metropol-
limited support from private businesses, while having sup-
itan location of Bank A], a small city is good because
port mostly from public sector representatives. Support from
you know everyone, you trust people. Also, someone
local business owners who agree to accept the community
who does not pay her bills…will not receive credit in
currency has been particularly difficult. As the founder
local businesses. A small city is good because of this
explains:
(Founder, Bank A)
[Business owners] ask what advantages they would
The founder of Bank A alludes to their location in a large
have by accepting the [community] currency…I say
Southeast urban center, which promotes a different culture
that it can increase your clientele, community mem-
inside their communities compared to that in a Northeastern
bers will purchase from you because you accept the
small rural city, like the community of Bank C. Further, the
[community] currency, you will sell more…Then he
absence of political and legal frameworks, such as a local
[says he] will think and provide his answer later. It is
law establishing that the salaries of governmental employees
a daily struggle, every day you have to go there, and
in Bank C’s community must be paid partly in community
ask whether they will accept the [community] currency
currency, resulted in lower levels of supportive social capital
(Founder, Bank A)
toward Bank A’s community currency.
Our analysis reveals the existence of political and legal In conclusion, our analysis suggests that the formation of
circumstances capable of influencing attitudes among com- supportive social capital moderates the development of new
munity members toward their community currencies. In the community currencies. The pattern we observed in our data
case of the community of Bank C, a city law established that was that the political and legal conditions in Bank C’s com-
the salaries of governmental employees in that community munity facilitated the formation of supportive social capital
must be paid partly in community currency. As Bank C’s to a greater extent than those of Bank A’s community. This
co-founder states: made it easier for Bank C’s to develop its community cur-
rency, such as through the expansion of its adoption by local
We even have been paying 25 percent of the salary
businesses and community members. Thus, we develop the
of governmental employees in Bank C’s [community]
following proposition.
currency. It is a municipality law (Co-founder, Bank
C)
Proposition 2:  Entrepreneurs who involve stakeholders in
This community is one of the country’s poorest decision making tend to increase opportunities for devel-
municipalities, ranking 5444 out of 5565 in the Human oping new community currencies, and these effects amplify

13
A Commons Strategy for Promoting Entrepreneurship and Social Capital: Implications for…

when they facilitate the formation of supportive social which we built propositions. In the next section, we discuss
capital. the theoretical implications of this research.
Table 4 shows the comparative features of the two dif-
ferent community currencies we examined. While there is
much similarity in the physical, virtual, and geographical
Discussion characteristics of the two currencies, they differ in terms of
their governance. Having a wide range of actors invested in
This study has examined how interaction with diverse the community currency, by engaging pre-startup discussion
stakeholders and a community’s supportive social capital with diverse community members, had significant implica-
influence the development of social commons and new com- tions in acceptability. As shown previously in Table 3, cur-
munity currencies. Given the rise of cryptocurrencies that rency from Bank C accounted for 25 percent of public salary
are supported by communities as opposed to governments disbursement, and incorporated over 700 local businesses.
(Fantacci 2019), we believe our findings have implications This community “buy-in” generated through decision
about the use of social capital beyond the applicability to making conducted by a diverse array of participating stake-
community currencies. By conducting a qualitative analysis holders, including rural residents, churches, business own-
of community currencies in two different low-income loca- ers, legislators, and unions, likely led to the widespread
tions, our comparative study provided theoretical insights on adoption of the currency. These findings are insightful for

Table 4  Features of the currencies


Dimension Features Currency A Currency C

Physical currency Paper banknotes are issued by the community bank ✓ ✓


Community members exchange the community currency for the coun-
try’s currency (Brazilian reais) in the community bank
Business owners in the community receive the community currency
from customers and exchange it for Brazilian reais in the community
bank
Virtual currency Potential of enabling methods created by Palmas Bank and dissemi- ✓ ✓
nated by Palmas Institute for solidarity economy development,
through which the community currency serves as an instrument
to enhance social cohesion and the circulation of financial capital
within the community, such as:
Mobile-enabled currency: the customer opens an account with the
community bank, the business owner opens an account with the
partner governmental bank (Caixa), and the customer receives a
chip from the partner mobile phone company. When the customer
makes a purchase from the cell phone with the chip, the payment
is transferred from the customer’s account to the seller’s account.
The virtual currency is enabled only inside the specific community
(Siqueira et al. 2014a)
Governmental deposits: community members can receive governmen-
tal benefits (bolsa familia) by opening an account with the commu-
nity bank, which has electronic terminals from the partner govern-
mental bank (Caixa), in Brazilian reais or community currency
(Siqueira et al. 2014a)
Community identification Name of currency mirrors the name of the community ✓ ✓
Geographical coverage Currency circulates only within the community ✓ ✓
Component of public employees’ wages Municipality’s government pays 25% of the salary of governmental ✓
employees in community currency
Governance of the bank issuing the currency “Top down” decision making mainly by public actors: ✓
Government established a law that provided funds to create the bank
Nonprofit organization that is part of a public institution administers
the funds
“Bottom up” decision making by cross-sector actors: ✓
Group of representatives from public, private, and nonprofit sectors
initiated the creation of the bank
Nonprofit organization comprising representatives from public, pri-
vate, and nonprofit sectors administers the bank

13
A. C. O. Siqueira et al.

individuals or organizations seeking to develop community- (Pinkse and Groot 2015). This has the effect of transform-
led social activities, including those employing blockchain ing adherents into constituents (McCarthy and Zald 1977).
and cryptocurrencies for community development purposes Just as governments set the rules of currency, thereby deter-
(Gomber et al. 2018). For example, community development mining the economic value of labor and its taxation, so our
activities may include fundraising campaigns for charity example of bottom-up community organization, particularly
(Gomber et al. 2018) and, as in the case of Bank C, provision as depicted by Bank C, demonstrates the importance of
of awards in community currency at cultural festivals in low- socially embedded “buy-in.” In this way, community cur-
income communities, which enabled the awards to be spent rencies open a door to participation and exchanges relevant
within these communities for local economic development. to a community, transcending the centralized governmen-
tal system while aligning the participation of cross-sector
stakeholders.
Implications for Theory Third, we provide new theoretical connections between
the literature on commons and the concept of communion
This study contributes to the literature on commons and and solidarity by Brazilian social theorist Paulo Freire.
community currency in the following ways. First, our find- Our Proposition 1 emphasizes cross-sector interaction with
ings our congruent with a chartalist perspective on cur- representatives from governmental, nonprofit, and private
rency that supports the conception of embedded economies sectors. An emphasis on cross-sector interaction is consist-
(Polanyi 1944). Chartalist theory examines the social as well ent with Freire’s (1970) perspective of “communion.” For
as the historical value of money, including nonmarket-based Freire, individuals live in a world shaped by social, cultural,
factors (Bell 2001). State-backed currency is designed as a and historical conditions, which they impact not in isolation
method of taxing a population and encouraging economic but through interaction and communion (Henz 2008).
activity. Community currencies, and potentially new emerg- Freire’s work is known by many for his arguments sup-
ing forms of cryptocurrencies (Costantini 2019), provide porting individuals’ liberation from oppression and social
opportunities to build a common pool of resources, while injustices, but it is less known that Freire also developed
also developing the vitality of the community. In theory, a the complementary construct of “communion.” This con-
municipality could offer community currency in exchange struct entails the pursuit of social change while avoiding
for socially regarded activities, such as quality child care. an excess of power by a particular agent or social group
Opportunities for developing exchange markets and eco- (Rossato 2008). Community currency relates to collective
systems with cryptocurrencies could lead to similar trans- engagement and development (Taub 1988). Our Proposition
actions, which clearly reflect the concept of an embedded 1 addresses the role of cross-sector interaction in the devel-
economy. Their ability to cross national borders also sug- opment of community currencies. Our findings support the
gests important opportunities for community-to-community- involvement of cross-sector community members inclusive
level transactions and exchanges. of individuals with ties to multiple sectors (Siqueira et al.
Second, our study shows that stakeholder diversity helps 2014a), while not excluding private capital and those that
increase opportunities to launch new community-specific shepherd capitalism, including bankers (Taub 1988). Rather,
enterprises. Our Proposition 1 maintains that entrepre- our findings point to the relevance of interaction with an
neurs who involve stakeholders in decision making tend to entire constellation of actors that yield these often comple-
increase opportunities for developing new community cur- mentary approaches to community and collective capitalism.
rencies, and these effects amplify when they interact with a Freire’s concept of communion is aligned with the notion
greater diversity of stakeholder groups even prior to startup. of social commons. This is because social commons repre-
This proposition contributes to underscore the importance of sents a system that pursues sustainable development, while
broader stakeholder diversity in the context of “social com- encouraging participative governance, social cohesion, and
mons,” as a system that prioritizes development goals and collective actions that benefit users and the community as a
the involvement of members in decision-making processes whole (Meyer and Hudon 2018).
(Meyer and Hudon 2018). Fourth, this study helps uncover the processes involved
The participation of multiple community members may in establishing linkages throughout different networks
involve public and private stakeholders (Babiak and Thiba- including government and civil society, which contribute
ult 2009). For instance, the involvement of governmental to develop community currencies and social commons. Our
stakeholders can provide resources such as improved infra- Proposition 2 states that entrepreneurs who involve stake-
structure important to entrepreneurs (Musacchio et al. 2015). holders in decision making tend to increase opportunities
Enterprises that reconcile private and collective interests for developing new community currencies, and these effects
often try to mobilize a wide range of tangible and intangi- amplify when they facilitate the formation of supportive
ble resources such as financial capital and political support social capital. This proposition emphasizes the moderator

13
A Commons Strategy for Promoting Entrepreneurship and Social Capital: Implications for…

role of supportive social capital. In our study, social capital of inequality or simply its reproduction (Fama et al. 2019).
supportive of new community currencies was enabled by Future studies may benefit from examining other cases from
political and legal actions, which included a municipality developing and developed countries, gathering information
law defining that the wages of governmental employees in from different sources, and using diverse qualitative and
that particular community should be paid partly in commu- qualitative research methods.
nity currency. Given that this community currency circulates
only inside this particular community, these political and
legal actions helped maintain wealth within that community,
while also promoting supportive social attitudes toward the Conclusion
use of the currency.
Considering this case as an example, entrepreneurs are This study has emphasized that microfinance entrepreneurs
more likely to expand the adoption of new community cur- who involve a greater diversity of stakeholders from public,
rencies when there are such conditions that enable sup- private, and nonprofit sectors in decision making even prior
portive social capital. We can also envision community- to startup, while also facilitating the formation of support-
to-community linkages being established by employing ive social capital from cross-sector stakeholders, increase
cryptocurrency (Costantini 2019), as relevant actors in opportunities for developing new community currencies.
two or more cooperating communities can determine these Our propositions link entrepreneurial actions and interaction
exchanges, despite geographical constraints. Possibilities with stakeholders to the development of community curren-
might open up to enhance vertical integration by bypassing cies. In this way, this study helps answer a recent call for
intermediaries and connecting both producers directly with research exploring entrepreneurial actions that benefit others
manufacturers. As new opportunities for micro-lending and and how actors in resource-constrained environments can
micro-investing emerge with cryptocurrency (Varma 2019), still create new ventures to alleviate others’ suffering, which
our study suggests the importance of supportive social capi- are lines of research viewed as sources of vitality for the
tal for these activities. future of the entrepreneurship literature (Shepherd 2015).
One important theoretical implication of Proposition 2 is This study serves as a basis for future research by offering
that the presence of social capital in a community will not propositions on the development of community currencies,
necessarily facilitate the development of community cur- on which new studies can draw as a foundation to extend the
rencies, unless there are conditions that enable supportive study of this important type of social commons. They may
social capital. In our study, both communities have social also apply our findings to the diffusion of cryptocurrencies
capital, but not all of them have conditions that enable social or other emerging forms of currencies, while focusing on
capital supportive of their respective community currencies. building social commons (Gomber et al. 2018). Rather than
Therefore, conditions that enable supportive social capital criticizing the use or effectiveness of community currencies,
are necessary to expand adoption of community currencies. including those issued by microfinance organizations with
either a successful or unsuccessful pattern, we uncovered
specific multi-stakeholder entrepreneurial actions and their
Future Directions different contexts that were associated with greater com-
munity currency development. Our findings are relevant to
This study generates several opportunities for future other community development activities, including initia-
research. We developed our analysis with a set of commu- tives that use emerging forms of currency, such as cryptocur-
nity currencies in low-income locations in Brazil utilizing a rencies (Costantini 2019), by exploring the implications of
particular research method. One of our challenges was the entrepreneurial actions that promote inclusive participation
collection of data from marginalized areas due to transpor- of diverse stakeholders for accomplishing collective goals.
tation difficulties and safety concerns. New studies should
explore further factors and conditions that influence and
Funding  Funding was provided by Duquesne University (Paluse Fac-
moderate the development of community currencies, as well ulty Research Grant).
as the implications of utilizing emerging forms of curren-
cies, such as cryptocurrencies, for economic development Compliance with Ethical Standards 
(Sudzina 2018).
One important avenue of future research is the examina- Conflict of interest  Ana Siqueira has received a Paluse Faculty Re-
tion of the influence that various constituents have on the search Grant from Duquesne. The other authors declare that they have
no conflict of interest.
overall outcome of the currency system. Future scholarship
should examine whether community currencies or the pro- Ethical Approval  All procedures performed in studies involving human
motion of cryptocurrencies contribute to the improvement participants were in accordance with the ethical standards of the insti-

13
A. C. O. Siqueira et al.

tutional and/or national research committee and with the 1964 Helsinki Franca Filho, G. C. (2007). Considerations about a theoretical-analyt-
declaration and its later amendments or comparable ethical standards. ical mark for the experience of community banks (Consideracoes
sobre um marco teorico-analitico para a experiencia dos bancos
Informed Consent  Informed consent was obtained from all individual comunitarios). In J. T. Silva Jr., R. T. Masih, A. C. Cancado,
participants included in the study. & P. C. Schommer (Eds.), Gestao social: Praticas em debate,
teorias em construcao (pp. 113–124): https​://gesta​osoci​al.pagin​
as.ufsc.br/files​/ 2011/07/Livro​- 1-Cole%C3%A7%C3%A3oEn​
apegs​V 1_Gest%C3%A3oSo​c ialP​r atic​a sDeb​a tesT​e oria​s Cons​
tru%C3%A7%C3%A3o.pdf.
Freire, P. (1970). Pedagogy of the oppressed. New York: Continuum.
References Garcia, D. B. (2011). Bancos comunitarios de desenvolvimento: Um
estudo sobre a implementacao dos bancos comunitarios ligados
Adler, P. S., & Kwon, S.-W. (2002). Social capital: Prospects for a new ao movimento de moradia no municipio de Sao Paulo. Fundacao
concept. The Academy of Management Review, 27(1), 17–40. https​ Getulio Vargas, Sao Paulo, Brazil, https​://bibli​oteca​digit​al.fgv.
://doi.org/10.2307/41343​67. br/dspac​e/bitst​ream/handl​e/10438​/8223/62090​10000​1.pdf?seque​
Babiak, K., & Thibault, L. (2009). Challenges in multiple cross-sector nce=1
partnerships. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 38(1), Gioia, D. A., Corley, K. G., & Hamilton, A. L. (2012). Seeking quali-
117–143. https​://doi.org/10.1177/08997​64008​31605​4. tative rigor in inductive research: Notes on the gioia methodol-
Bell, S. (2001). The role of the state and the hierarchy of money. ogy. Organizational Research Methods, 16(1), 15–31. https​://doi.
Cambridge Journal of Economics. https ​ : //doi.org/10.1093/ org/10.1177/10944​28112​45215​1.
cje/25.2.149. Gomber, P., Kauffman, R. J., Parker, C., & Weber, B. W. (2018). On the
Bernstein, M. (2005). Identity politics. Annual Review of Sociology, fintech revolution: Interpreting the forces of innovation, disrup-
31, 47–74. tion, and transformation in financial services. Journal of Manage-
Bollier, D. (2007). The growth of the commons paradigm. In C. Hess ment Information Systems, 35(1), 220–265.
& E. Ostrom (Eds.), Understanding knowledge as a commons: Graeber, D. (2012). Debt: The first 5000 years. Brooklyn, NY: Melville
From theory to practice (pp. 27–40). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. House.
Bourdieu, P. (1990). The logic of practice. California: Stanford Uni- Granovetter, M. S. (1973). The strength of weak ties. American Journal
versity Press. of Sociology, 78(6), 1360–1380.
Clayton, A. (2010). Do local currency systems have a role in economic Grover, D. (2006). Would local currencies make a good local economic
regeneration? Social and Economic Studies, 59(1/2), 243–287. development policy tool? The case of Ithaca Hours. Environment
Coleman, J. S. (1988). Social capital in the creation of human capital. and Planning C: Government and Policy, 24(5), 719–737. https​
American Journal of Sociology, 94, S95–S120. ://doi.org/10.1068/c1p.
Collom, E. (2011). Motivations and differential participation in a Guthman, J. (2008). The Polanyian way? Voluntary food labels as neo-
community currency system: The dynamics within a local social liberal governance. In B. Mansfield (Ed.), Privatization: Property
movement organization. Sociological Forum, 26(1), 144–168. and the remaking of nature-society relations (pp. 64–85). Malden,
Costa, C. (2014). Previously without any bank branches, city in Piaui MA: Blackwell.
create a local bank and own currency (Sem agencia bancaria, Harvey, D. (2012). Rebel cities: From the right to the city to the urban
cidade do Piaui cria banco local e moeda propria). Retrieved revolution. Brooklyn, NY: Verso.
Dec 8, 2014 from https:​ //g1.globo​.com/pi/piaui/​ notic​ia/2014/02/ Helleiner, E. (2000). Think globally, transact locally: Green political
sem-agenc​ia-banca​ria-cidad​e-do-piaui​-cria-banco​-local​-e-moeda​ economy and the local currency movement. Global Society, 14(1),
-propr​ia.html. 35–51. https​://doi.org/10.1080/13600​82005​00011​12.
Costantini, O. (2019). Cryptocurrencies: Will machines replace your Henz, C. I. (2008). Anthropological (condition) (Antropologica (con-
banker? International Journal of Political Economy, 48(2), dicao)). In D. R. Streck, E. Redin, & J. J. Zitkoski (Eds.), Paulo
101–104. Freire Dictionary (Dicionario Paulo Freire) (pp. 43–45). Belo
Crowther, D., Greene, A.-M., & Hosking, D. M. (2002). Local eco- Horizonte, Brazil: Autentica Editora.
nomic trading schemes and their implications for marketing Hudon, M., & Meyer, C. (2016). A case study of microfinance and
assumptions, concepts and practices. Management Decision, community development banks in Brazil: Private or common
40(4), 354–362. https​://doi.org/10.1108/00251​74021​04263​49. goods? Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 45(4_suppl),
Dolfsma, W., Van der Eijk, R., & Jolink, A. (2009). On a source of 116S–133S.
social capital: Gift exchange. Journal of Business Ethics, 89(3), Light, I., & Dana, L. P. (2013). Boundaries of social capital in entrepre-
315–329. neurship. J Entrepreneurship: Theory & Practice, 37(3), 603–624.
Edmondson, A. C., & McManus, S. E. (2007). Methodological fit in https​://doi.org/10.1111/etap.12016​.
management field research. The Academy of Management Review, Light, I., & Gold, S. (2000). Ethnic economies. Bingley, UK: Emerald.
32(4), 1155–1179. https​://doi.org/10.2307/20159​361. Mair, J., Marti, I., & Ventresca, M. J. (2012). Building inclusive mar-
Eisenhardt, K. M. (1989). Building theories from case study research. kets in rural bangladesh: How intermediaries work institutional
Academy of Management Review, 14(4), 532–550. https​://doi. voids. Academy of Management Journal, 55(4), 819–850. https​://
org/10.2307/25855​7. doi.org/10.5465/amj.2010.0627.
Eisenhardt, K. M., & Graebner, M. E. (2007). Theory building from Malherbe, L., Montalban, M., Bedu, N., & Granier, C. (2019). Cryp-
cases: Opportunities and challenges. The Academy of Management tocurrencies and blockchain: Opportunities and limits of a new
Journal, 50(1), 25–32. https​://doi.org/10.2307/20159​839. monetary regime. International Journal of Political Economy,
Fama, M., Fumagalli, A., & Lucarelli, S. (2019). Cryptocurrencies, 48(2), 127–152.
monetary policy, and new forms of monetary sovereignty. Inter- McCarthy, J. D., & Zald, M. N. (1977). Resource mobilization and
national Journal of Political Economy, 48(2), 174–194. social movements: A partial theory. American Journal of Sociol-
Fantacci, L. (2019). Cryptocurrencies and the denationalization ogy, 82(6), 1212–1241.
of money. International Journal of Political Economy, 48(2), Medeiros, L. B. (2008). Mobilization (Mobilizacao). In D. R. Streck,
105–126. E. Redin, & J. J. Zitkoski (Eds.), [Paulo Freire Dictionary

13
A Commons Strategy for Promoting Entrepreneurship and Social Capital: Implications for…

(Dicionrio Paulo Freire) (pp. 269–271). Belo Horizonte, Bra- Polanyi, K. (1944). The great transformation. Boston: Beacon Press
zil: Autentica Editora. https​://inctp​ped.ie.ufrj.br/spide​r web/pdf_4/Great​_Trans​forma​
Mercado, G., Hjortso, C. N., & Honig, B. (2018). Decoupling from tion.pdf.
international food safety standards: How small-scale indigenous Putnam, R. D. (2000). Bowling alone: America’s declining social capi-
farmers cope with conflicting institutions to ensure market par- tal. In L. Crothers & C. Lockhart (Eds.), Culture and politics (pp.
ticipation. Agriculture and Human Values, 35(3), 651–669. https​ 223–234). New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
://doi.org/10.1007/s1046​0-018-9860-x. Richey, S., & Ikeda, K. (2009). Institutional incentives and trust: Mar-
Meyer, C., & Hudon, M. (2018). Money and the commons: An inves- ginalized groups and the creation of trust in local government.
tigation of complementary currencies and their ethical implica- Social Science Quarterly, 90(4), 911–926. https​://doi.org/10.111
tions. Journal of Business Ethics, 160, 1–16. 1/j.1540-6237.2009.00669​.x.
Meyer, C., & Hudon, M. J. O. (2017). Alternative organizations in Romao, J. E. (2008). Education (Educacao). In D. R. Streck, E. Redin,
finance: Commoning in complementary currencies. SAGE Jour- & J. J. Zitkoski (Eds.), Paulo Freire Dictionary (Dicionario Paulo
nals, 24(5), 629–647. Freire) (1st ed., pp. 150–152). Belo Horizonte, Brazil: Autentica
Mitchell, T. R., & Mickel, A. E. (1999). The meaning of money: An Editora.
individual-difference perspective. Academy of Management, The Rosales, A. (2019). Radical rentierism: Gold mining, cryptocurrency
Academy of Management Review, 24(3), 568–578. and commodity collateralization in Venezuela. Review of Inter-
Mukherjee, A. (2019). Say goodbye to banking as we know it, China national Political Economy, 26(6), 1311–1332.
is poised to launch the first national digital currency: There will Rosen, C. M., & Carr, G. M. (1997). Fares and free riders on the infor-
be no counting the disruption. Bloomberg athttps​://www.bloom​ mation highway. Journal of Business Ethics, 16(12), 1439–1445.
berg.com/opini​on/artic​les/2019-12-29/china​-has-edge-over-silic​ https​://doi.org/10.1023/A:10057​91300​561.
on-valle​y-to-end-banki​ng-as-we-know-it. Rossato, R. (2008). Praxis. In D. R. Streck, E. Redin, & J. J. Zitkoski
Musacchio, A., Lazzarini, S. G., & Aguilera, R. V. (2015). New vari- (Eds.), Paulo Freire Dictionary (Dicionario Paulo Freire) (1st ed.,
eties of state capitalism: Strategic and governance implications. pp. 331–333). Belo Horizonte, Brazil: Autentica Editora.
Academy of Management Perspectives, 29(1), 115–131. https​:// Salstrom, P. (1997). The bucks start here: Alternative currencies and
doi.org/10.5465/amp.2013.0094. the coming welfare disaster. Appalachian Journal, 25(1), 84–97.
Myers, M. D. (2009). Qualitative research in business & manage- SEDS (2015). Special Office of Social Development (Secretaria Espe-
ment. London: SAGE Publications. cial do Desenvolvimento Social). https:​ //mds.gov.br/assunt​ os/brasi​
North, P. (2006). Constructing civil society? Green money in transi- l-sem-miser​ia/inclu​sao-produ​tiva-urban​a-1/econo​mia-solid​aria.
tion Hungary. Review of International Political Economy, 13(1), Seyfang, G. (2004). Working outside the box: Community currencies,
28–52. time banks and social inclusion. Journal of Social Policy, 33(1),
North, P. (2018). Alternative currency movements as a challenge 49–71. https​://doi.org/10.1017/S0047​27940​30072​32.
to globalisation?: A case study of Manchester’s local currency Seyfang, G. (2006). Sustainable consumption, the new economics and
networks, Routledge. community currencies: Developing new institutions for environ-
Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: The evolution of institu- mental governance. Regional Studies, 40(7), 781–791. https:​ //doi.
tions for collective action. Cambridge: Cambridge University org/10.1080/00343​40060​09591​73.
Press. Seyfang, G., & Longhurst, N. (2013). Growing green money? Map-
Pacione, M. (1999). The other side of the coin: Local currency as a ping community currencies for sustainable development. Eco-
response to the globalization of capital. Regional Studies, 33(1), logical Economics, 86, 65–77. https​://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecole​
63–72. con.2012.11.003.
Palmas (2019). Brazilian Network of Community Banks (Rede Bra- Seyfang, G., & Pearson, R. (2000). Time for change: International
sileira de Bancos Comunitarios). https​://www.insti​tutob​ancop​ experience in community currencies. Development, 43(4), 56–60.
almas​.org/rede-brasi​leira​-de-banco​s-comun​itari​os. https​://doi.org/10.1057/palgr​ave.devel​opmen​t.11101​97.
Patomaki, H. (2014). On the dialectics of global governance in the Shepherd, D. A. (2015). Party on! A call for entrepreneurship research
twenty-first century: A Polanyian double movement? Globaliza- that is more interactive, activity based, cognitively hot, compas-
tions, 11(5), 733–750. sionate, and prosocial. Journal of Business Venturing, 30(4),
Peredo, A. M., & Murdith, M. (2019). Decommodification in action: 489–507. https​://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusv​ent.2015.02.001.
Common property as counter movement. Organization. https​:// Singer (2009). Public policies of the National Office of Solidarity
doi.org/10.1177/13505​08419​86720​2. Economy in the Work and Employment Ministry (Politicas pub-
Pieters (2017). The potential impact of decentralized virtual currency licas da Secretaria Nacional de Economia Solidaria do Ministe-
on monetary policy. Globalization Monetary Policy Institute rio do Trabalho e Emprego). https​://repos​itori​o.ipea.gov.br/bitst​
Annual Report: Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas ream/11058/​ 4788/1/bmt39_​ 06_ES1Pau​ l.pdf, Institute for Applied
Pilkington, M. (2019). The Libra project: A transnational monetary Economic Research (Instituto de Pesquisa Economica Aplicada,
dystopia—Analysis of the disruption generated by the Face- IPEA)
book-led stable coin. SSRN 3434079, https​://paper​s.ssrn.com/ Siqueira, A. C. O., Mariano, S. R., & Moraes, J. (2014a). Supporting
sol3/paper​s.cfm?abstr​act_id=34340​79 innovation ecosystems with microfinance: Evidence from Brazil
Pinkse, J., & Groot, K. (2015). Sustainable entrepreneurship and and implications for social entrepreneurship. Journal of Social
corporate political activity: Overcoming market barriers in the Entrepreneurship, 5(3), 318–338.
clean energy sector. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Siqueira, A. C. O., Mariano, S. R., Moraes, J., & Gorse, G. (2014b).
39(3), 633–654. https​://doi.org/10.1111/etap.12055​. Creating innovative solutions in microfinance and the role of
PNUD (2013). Sao Joao do Arraial, PI, Atlas of human development organizational ingenuity. In B. Honig, J. Lampel, & I. Drori
in Brazil (Atlas do desenvolvimento humano no Brasil), United (Eds.), Handbook of organizational entrepreneurial ingenuity
Nations Development Program (Programa das Nacoes Unidas (pp. 203–222). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
para o Desenvolvimento). Retrieved Dec 8, 2014 from https​:// Smith, A. (1776). The wealth of nations: An inquiry into the nature and
www.atlas​brasi​l.org.br/2013/pt/perfi​l_m/sao-joao-do-arrai​al_pi. causes of the wealth of nations. Hampshire: Harriman House Lim-
ited, https​://books​.googl​e.com/books​?hl=en&lr=&id=4HPdA​
gAAQB​ A J&oi=fnd&pg=PP1&dq=The+wealt ​ h +of+natio​

13
A. C. O. Siqueira et al.

ns:+An+inqui​ry+into+the+natur​e+and+cause​s+of+the+Wealt​ Sudzina, F. (2018). Distribution of foreign aid in cryptocurrencies: Ini-


h+of+Natio​ns,+adam+smith​&ots=ywdxI​z8C-n&sig=DVtfa​ tial considerations. International Advances in Economic Research,
L-tQLGw ​ 7 71_bsp2p ​ w O6Av ​ k #v=onepa ​ ge&q=The%2520w​ 24(4), 387–388.
ealth​%2520o​f%2520n​ation​s%3A%2520A​n%2520i​nquir​y%2520i​ Taub, R. B. (1988). Community capitalism. Boston, MA: Harvard Busi-
nto%2520t ​ h e%2520n ​ a ture ​ % 2520a ​ n d%2520c ​ a uses ​ % 2520o​ ness School Press.
f%2520t ​h e%2520W​e alth​% 2520o​f %2520N​a tion​s %2C%2520a​ Tax, S. (1953). Penny capitalism: A Guatemalan Indian economy (Vol.
dam%2520s​mith&f=false​. 16). Washington: United States Government Publishing Office
Sonenscher, M. (1997). The nation’s debt and the birth of the modern (Smithsonian Institution, Institute of Social Anthropology).
republic: The French fiscal deficit and the politics of the revolution Varma, J. R. (2019). Blockchain in finance. Vikalpa: The Journal for
of 1789 (part II). History of Political Thought, 18(2), 268–325. Decision Makers, 44(1), 1–11.
Stake, R. E. (2005). Qualitative case studies. In N. K. Denzin & Y. S. Williams, C. C. (1996). The new barter economy: An appraisal of local
Lincoln (Eds.), The Sage handbook of qualitative research (3rd exchange and trading systems (LETS). Journal of Public Policy,
ed., pp. 443–466). Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications Ltd. 16, 85.
Stiglitz, J. E. (1988). Economic organisation, information and devel-
opment. In H. Chenery & T. N. Srinivasan (Eds.), Handbook of Publisher’s Note Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to
development economics (vol. 1, pp. 92–160). Amsterdam: Elsevier jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Science Publishers.
Stuart, D., Gunderson, R., & Petersen, B. (2019). Climate change
and the Polanyian counter-movement: Carbon markets or
degrowth? New Political Economy, 24(1), 89–102. https​://doi.
org/10.1080/13563​467.2017.14173​64.

13

You might also like