Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 5

Oil and the Middle East: The End of US Hegemony?

Author(s): Simon Bromley


Source: Middle East Report, No. 208, US Foreign Policy in the Middle East: Critical
Assessments (Autumn, 1998), pp. 19-22
Published by: Middle East Research and Information Project (MERIP)
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3013404 .
Accessed: 08/10/2013 22:08

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Middle East Research and Information Project (MERIP) is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and
extend access to Middle East Report.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 128.233.210.97 on Tue, 8 Oct 2013 22:08:37 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
these and other issues arise, how are they resolved? Is
there a price for crude oil which will simultaneously sat?
Oil and the Middle East isfy the core OPEC (Organization of Petroleum Export?
ing Countries) and Saudi objectives, a price that is: a)
low enough so that demand increases with economic
The End of US growth; b) low enough to deter significant investment in
Hegemony?
non-OPEC oil and alternative energy sources; and c) high
enough to cover the social costs of OPEC states?
Simon Bromley In the past, I argued that the US-Saudi relationship
centered on an attempt to reconcile these objectives and
that the attempt was, on the whole, successful.1 That ar?
There is now a very real challenge to US hegemony and gument was based on an identification of common inter?
ests between the United States and Saudi Arabia that
the American role as guardian of the West's oil, although stemmed from US security guarantees and the down?
stream integration of Saudi Arabia and the Gulf states
it does not lie primarily in the sands of Arabia. The key into the consumer markets and investment opportuni?
ties of the consuming West. In this context, Robert Vitalis'
shift has been the resolution and after? observations concerning the "closing of the Arabian oil
geopolitical
frontier" miss the point.2 Vitalis argues that the era of
effects of the Cold War. the 1940s and 1950s, "when Aramco was in effect the
kingdom's public works agency and oil ministry and
America's private diplomatic and intelligence operation,"
has passed, and the influence of the United States over
contemporary international political economy of the Saudi
regime has diminished accordingly.3 Regard?
The oil presents a puzzle: political instability in regions
ing direct control, this is correct, as Vitalis avers: "The
where oil is found coexists with steadily falling prices.
era of empire... is over for the US in the Gulf...The over?
This combination of continuing political conflict and un?
seas Arabian oil resource frontier is closed because that
certainty in the Middle East (particularly the Gulf), and state has secured overarching control inside this zone."4
the continuing slide in the real price of crude oil encour?
Of course it has.
ages consideration of relations between world oil mar? The long-term objective of US hegemony after the Sec?
kets, Middle East politics and the international role of ond World War was never to achieve
political and economic
the United States. To comprehend these relations, one
objectives through direct territorial control and influence
must consider both the political and geopolitical objec?
over other sovereign states; that was always a fall-back
tives of the states involved and the economic motivations
position necessitated by the opposition to?or the lack of
of the key actors in the international oil industry.
development of?forms of political independence consis?
tent with a liberal world-wide economic order. Where those
The End of the Cold War and the Erosion liberal forms were secure, or where non-liberal domestic
forms were prepared to operate internationally within the
of US Hegemony
dominant liberal order, the "market," armored by the po?
The geopolitics of oil are complex because the objectives of litical and military power of the US and its allies, could
the major states are varied and often contradictory. Until generally be relied upon to deliver. Yes, the "Pax Ameri?
recently, US policy in the oil-rich Middle East has aimed cana remains open to continuous challenge and reversal."5
at dual containment of Iraq and Iran, maintenance of the However, the argument about US-Saudi relations does not
authoritarian regimes of the Arabian Gulf, protection of depend on US imperial control over Saudi Arabia, under?
both domestic and international US oil interests, the con? stood either in terms of territorial domination or direct
tinuation of large contracts for the US defense industry influence over Saudi policy. A shift from a zero-sum direct
and the provision of secure and not-too-expensive crude control (where the powers of the United States and its
oil to allies in Western Europe and the Pacific. Dual con? corporate contractors were exercised at the expense of lo?
tainment, however, has run into increasing opposition from cal states, ruling classes and people), to an indirect, posi?
the European Union and Japan as the latter has supported tive-sum arrangement mutually beneficial to the parties
their own oil companies at the expense of American firms involved is precisely the achievement of US hegemony as
prohibited from action by the US government. distinct from empire.
What price of crude satisfies US interests, the Saudi Nevertheless, larger questions relating to the chang?
Arabian government and the allies? When conflicts over ing nature of US hegemony and the role of oil politics
within it remain. It is in this context that one must lo?
SimonBromley isa senior inInternational
lecturer Political
Economy at the
Univer? cate power and influence in the contemporary interna?
ofLeeds.
sity Heis theauthorofAmerican
HegemonyandWorld Oil (Cambridge:
Polity tional
1991).
Press, political economy of oil. For there is now a very

Middle East Report ? Fall 1998 19

This content downloaded from 128.233.210.97 on Tue, 8 Oct 2013 22:08:37 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
real challenge to US hegemony and the US role as guard? easier to access, effectively raising the level of reserves
ian of the West's oil, although it does not lie primarily in available at any given price level, thus weakening the
the sands of Arabia. The key geopolitical shift has been link between economic growth and the demand for oil.
the resolution and after-effects of the Cold War.6 Four Together, these factors may extend the lifetime of the in?
implications are especially pertinent: First, it has freed dustry into the foreseeable future.
the hand of the US to deploy military power while under? So far, however, neither OPEC governments nor non-
mining the domestic and international rationale for do? OPEC private capital have fully exploited known reserves.
ing so; second, it has weakened the position of some Arab The area where the cheapest and most productive reserves
states (including important OPEC members, most nota? lie is, of course, the Gulf and the other Middle East OPEC
bly Iraq) opposed to US strategy in the region; third, it members. (The Middle East accounts for 65 percent of
has undercut the last remaining material and ideologi? proven reserves, and OPEC's reserves-to-production ratio
cal bases for planned, statist models of development, in? averages nearly 90 years.) Yet, even in the Gulf, the capi?
cluding those based directly or indirectly on oil rents; and tal needed to increase production is beyond the domestic
fourth, it has shifted the competition between the United budgets of most producers, requiring outside financing
States and its capitalist allies into more strictly "economic" and technical participation. OPEC believes that the West
channels, thus complicating US efforts to devise general will have to invest in new capacity since world oil demand
strategies of geopolitical and economic leadership. has to be met increasingly from OPEC sources. Economi?
The US's elevation to sole military superpower status cally, such a strategy certainly makes sense. The problem
and the enfeeblement of "radical" Arab regimes has cer? is political. As Hartshorn pointed out in the early 1990s:
tainly allowed the US to deploy military power in the
region on an unparalleled scale. Equally, the ascendance The capital requirements per daily barrel of output
of the market and private property is working its way reported for some of the Gulf producers now appear
across the Middle East now that the protection afforded to overlap quite significantly the lower figures in
to statist models by petroleum rents is falling, which can the cost range reported for non-OPEC oil develop?
only be welcomed in Washington. Against these favorable ment. In nearly all other areas, private oil compa?
shifts, one has to balance the absence of a clear rationale nies can get easier terms, including equity interests
for intervention and the growing unease of the advanced in production, than in much of OPEC and almost
capitalist allies about US regional strategy. Although it anywhere in Gulf OPEC. They may still consider
is still too early to judge how far the Cold War magnified the other places politically safer, too.8
the influence of the United States over its capitalist al?
lies in the North and its regional partners in the South, The political risks have since worsened.
the fall-out so far has been considerable.7 The problem confronting US strategy, therefore, is that
allies who in the past depended heavily on Gulf oil, and
The Market for Oil hence on US protection of access to that oil on favorable
Changing
terms, may start to look elsewhere, undermining any le?
Simultaneous with post-Cold War geopolitical shifts and verage the United States once had and leaving it the pro?
the attendant reduction of US leadership, there has been tector of the most closed and brittle societies in the region.
a significant evolution of the international oil market. In part, that is why the recent changes in Iran have
The combination of uncertainty about US strategy in the proved so destabilizing for US regional strategy and why
Middle East and the political future of the Gulf in par? post-sanctions Iraq presents such difficulties. Lacking the
ticular, along with developments in the market, have close associations with the Gulf states, and less single-
raised fundamental questions about the future of the mindedly pursuing military options to the political prob?
industry as a whole as well as the place of OPEC (and lems of the region, the European powers (excluding
the Gulf) within it. This is a difficult area to assess be? Britain), Japan, and now Russia and China may forge
cause it depends on both geology and economics and there policies substantially independent from those favored by
is little agreement between earth scientists and econo? Washington. Specifically, they may seek non-Gulf oil sup?
mists. Broadly speaking, most geologists reckon that with plies within OPEC and non-OPEC supplies where pos?
current prices and technology there may be a peak sup? sible. If the geopolitical and geographical structure of
ply of world oil of 70-100 million barrels per day (MBD). international oil fragments in this manner, what lever?
It is clear that 5-10 MBD extra capacity could be achieved age can the United States derive from its friends in the
in the Arabian Gulf and non-OPEC capacity could also Gulf? By contrast, if the world is driven back to OPEC,
be raised by 5-10 MBD. Together these give a potential and thence to Gulf OPEC (Kuwait, the UAE and Saudi
world capacity of 80-90 MBD by 2000 (in the middle of Arabia in particular), then Saudi strategy will continue
the range for peak supply defined by the geologists), so to play a crucial role. In that case, contra Vitalis, US-
the industry as a whole could be maturing. Many econo? Saudi connections will remain important for the nature
mists dispute these claims, arguing instead that techno? of the oil market?subject to the present regime holding
logical progress is continually making oil in the ground onto power in Riyadh.

20 Middle East Report ? Fall 1998

This content downloaded from 128.233.210.97 on Tue, 8 Oct 2013 22:08:37 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Whither OPEC? oil expansion? Why does the demand for oil not match the
supply? Why has high-cost oil been displacing low-cost sup?
The future of OPEC hinges upon the changes in the world ply? For many analysts the story of oil between 1973 and
market for oil that have occurred since OPEC's "rise," 1986 was the story of the rise and (partial) fall of OPEC.
between 1973 and 1986. The oil industry has grown rap? OPEC and the "energy crisis" became synonymous. By ar?
idly throughout the 20th century; between 1913 and 1948 tificially restricting supply, OPEC raised the price of crude
the annual growth rate of production was about 6.5 per? to such an extent that it was unable to sell even the amount
cent, and from 1948 to 1973 (the post-war boom) the an? that it wanted. High prices kept high-cost oil outside OPEC
nual growth rate was 7.5 percent. The end of the post-war in business. The story since 1986, when Saudi Arabia dra?
boom, however, caused a fundamental shift in the pat? matically increased production to lower prices and increase
tern of demand. In 1979 production was only 12 percent the demand for oil, has been one of perpetual disarray
higher than in 1973 and by 1985 it was 12 percent lower within OPEC as attempts to restrain production have failed
than in 1979. By 1991-92 production had just recovered and the demand for oil has remained weak.
to the 1979 level. Since then the industry has seen a Certainly, oil price increases in the 1970s and the per?
steady but lower increase of around two percent annu? ceived instability of the main source of supply, the Middle
ally, falling to just over one percent with the recent eco? East, reduced the demand for oil and encouraged the search
nomic slowdown and the crisis in the Asia-Pacific region. both for greater efficiency of energy use and for alterna?
Meanwhile, total energy demand faltered during the re? tive sources of supply (whether non-OPEC oil or other fu?
cessions of the 1970s and early 1980s and then recov? els). However, energy demand (and energy ratios) were
ered, currently expanding at an energy-ratio (the falling in the OECD bloc because of a shift away from en?
amount of energy used per unit of GDP) of less than ergy-intensive manufacturing to services. This trend pre?
one-to-one in the OECD bloc, and somewhat more than dated the oil crisis and continued after the fall of the real
this in the developing world. Whether the demand for price of oil in 1986. On the supply side, the key changes
oil will achieve earlier rates of ex? since 1973 have had even less to
Table 1
pansion remains a basic yet un? do with OPEC. The two largest
answerable for the World Oil Production
question changes in supply during the
future of the geopolitics of oil. 11111111 1970s and '80s were in the US and
There is a paradox at the heart Russia: production in the US
of the modern international oil in? UnitedStates 10.9
peaked in 1970, tapered off at a
dustry: despite the fact that oil Hi nils lill.,, slightly lower level for nearly two
!Ill fiIB
markets have become structurally decades and then began to fall in
Mexico 4.9
freer and more transparent since the late 1980s. Soviet production
the 1970s, a major imbalance re? continued to grow until the early
WBBBB^SSSk
mains between supply (and re? 1980s, then flattened out. Oil pro?
FormerSoviet Union,excludingRussia 1.7
serves) and demand: the world duction in the Soviet successor
demand for oil does not absorb all l^llllllliffl states may now have peaked?at
ilillilllt-lift
the supply that is on offer,yet oil least for the medium-term. To?
Iraq T7
prices do not fall far enough so that gether, these two countries ac?
demand increases to match supply. iHiiiii itiiiliii SS counted for 40 percent of the
IBBE
Moreover, much of the new capac? growth of world oil production in
Saudi Arabia 12.9
ity developed since the 1970s is the post-war period. In addition,
higher in cost than most of the ex? IIIBBIIMB the largest newcomers to non-
isting under-utilized capacity, and Rest ofthe Middle East 3.7
OPEC production were in the
most of the production "shut-in" North Sea?Alaska, Siberia and
(i.e., proven and available re? HHHHI rn the new oil provinces of Mexico?
serves which are not being used) all projects that began before
Europe 9.4
during the 1980s and 1990s is of 1973. Thus, much more has been
lower operating cost than much of li going on than the actions of, or
the production taking place else? within, OPEC. In any case, the
Asia Pacific 10.5
where. Finally, capacity in low- price increases in the 1970s were
cost regions could be expanded iSli not solely due to OPEC.10 Finally,
more cheaply than most new post- Total OPEC as recent events have once again
41.5
OPEC developments, yet total ca? demonstrated, OPEC does not and
jilli!
pacity in low-cost regions was cannot act as a cartel to rig the oil
only about half utilized in the Total iooJ market. When it attempted to do
1980s and early 1990s.9 so in 1982-1985, the result was a
What explains the slowdown of Source:BP Statistical Review ofWorld Energy, 1998. signal failure.11

Middle East Report ? Fall 1998 21

This content downloaded from 128.233.210.97 on Tue, 8 Oct 2013 22:08:37 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Disarray within OPEC is more or less a constant. Even aggressively low price for crude at the expense of higher-
Saudi-Iranian cooperation cannot stabilize the market cost (and non-OPEC) producers would probably be met
because no one, not even the Saudis, can afford to drive by tariffs to protect "security of supply" and would not
the price low enough to displace the higher cost produc? be passed on to consumers, since consuming states would
ers of oil and other energy sources. As long as higher- likely raise taxes on refined products. (Currently, the
cost producers can survive in the market, OPEC (and relatively high-cost producers of North and Central
Saudi Arabia in particular) cannot control the industry. America?the United States, Canada and Mexico?are
To understand the phenomenon of continuing over-sup? producing nearly as much oil as Gulf-OPEC countries.
ply in the oil market we must ask why the comparative See Table 1.)
costs of oil production are not properly reflected in crude
oil prices, and why the prices of oil products are not a And the Gulf?
simple function of crude oil prices and technology. The
single most important technical factor influencing the The global oil market is characterized by structural over?
cost of crude oil production is the productivity per well. supply. Low-cost producers cannot afford to drive the
But the productivity per well is itself a function of price, high-cost suppliers from the market, nor do they have
through the impact of price on the choice of technique. any real incentive to do so. The coincidence of interests
Thus, high-productivity (low-cost) oil will not automati? between the production and marketing strategies of the
cally displace low-productivity (high-cost) oil at prices Gulf states, multinational oil interests and the govern?
above the competitive level. Low-cost producers will sim? ments of the consuming nations constitutes the material
ply earn larger rents. In addition, since the costs of oil basis of US-Saudi relations. With an historically weak
production are considerably smaller than the start-up growth of demand, at any price significantly above the
costs (finding oil and sinking a well are costly; running running costs of the existing high-cost capacity, OPEC
an existing well is cheap), new sources of low-cost oil will has little control over the market and the Saudis have
not generally displace existing high-cost sources. Even little leverage within OPEC. On the other hand, if and
given these facts, one still must ask why low-cost pro? when demand picks up, and as non-OPEC sources di?
ducers do not increase production in order to increase minish, then OPEC and Saudi influence will increase.
their market share at lower oil prices. The simple an? Whether the Washington-Riyadh axis is still in place
swer, noted above, is that they cannot afford to do so. when that happens remains to be seen. As the Iranian
There is also a more subtle strategy at work, however, Revolution demonstrated, no amount of external support
related to the production decisions of low-cost producers can indefinitely maintain a regime that has lost its do?
with large reserves and high reserve/production ratios? mestic legitimacy. Thus, rather than the closing of the
essentially the Arabian Gulf producers. Arabian frontier to American imperialism so vividly de?
Before turning to the politics of Gulf producers, it is scribed by Vitalis, it is the broader shifts in geopolitics
important to note that the prices of oil products do not (the end of the Cold War and the erosion of US hege?
simply reflect the price of crude oil and the technology mony) and the long-term evolution of the oil industry that
that turns crude into products. Taxes imposed on both have?for the moment at least?side-lined the US-Saudi
the products of crude oil at the point of sale and the relationship in the political economy of international oil.
activities of firms that transform crude into products By the same token, falling production outside OPEC
also play a role. This means that rents generated in the would quickly reinstate the importance of America's
oil sector accrue not only to the producers of crude but friends in the Gulf, and that is why?for Washington at
also to private (generally multinational) firms and gov? least?they remain so important. ?
ernments in the main consuming states. Struggles over
the size and the division of rents involve the actions of Endnotes
all three parties?producing and 1 SeeAmerican Hegemony andWorld Oil(Cambridge: Press,1991),
Polity chapter6.
states, multinationals
2 Robert "TheClosing
Vitalis, oftheArabianOilFrontier andtheFuture ofSaudi-American
consuming governments?not simply the decisions of Relations," MiddleEastReport 204(Summer 1997).
producers. Put another way, oil rents may be appropri? 3 Ibid.,p.19.
ated at any point in the chain from production to final 4 Ibid.,p.16.
sale of refined products in the form of producer-rents, 5 Ibid.,p.20.
6 Someofthiswasanticipated inAmerican Hegemony andWorld OilbutI didnotforesee
industry surplus-profits and government taxes. This is anything likeitsfulleffects,
anditisprobably stilltooearly todoso.
why some Gulf producers, notably Kuwait and Saudi 7 Fora thoughtful reflection onthesequestions, see RonaldSteel,Temptationsofa
Superpower (Cambridge, MA:Harvard UniversityPress,1995).
Arabia, have moved downstream and established a pres?
8 J.E.Hartshorn, OilTrade: PoliticsandProspects (Cambridge:Cambridge University
ence in Western (and now Asian) consumer markets. This Press,1993), p.66.
gives them similar interests in pricing as Western oil 9 Foranauthoritative analysis ofthepost-OPEC oilindustry throughtotheearly1990s,
for their inte? seeibid.
firms, as they seek higher value-added
10Fora fullanalysis, seeAmerican Hegemony andWorld Oil,chapter4.
grated petroleum concerns, rather than the highest pos? 11 Forthebestaccount seeIan Skeet,OPEC:Twenty-five YearsofPricesandPolitics
sible prices for crude oil. Financial investments from (Cambridge: Cambridge UniversityPress,1988).Alsohelpful onOPECisPierre Terzian,
crude profits further cement this linkage. Moreover, an OPEC:TheInsideStory (London: ZedPress,1985).

22 Middle East Report ? Fall 1998

This content downloaded from 128.233.210.97 on Tue, 8 Oct 2013 22:08:37 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

You might also like