Document Type: Book Chapter

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 20

Copyright Information (bibliographic)

Document Type: Book Chapter

Title of Book: The Webs of Humankind A World History Volume 2 (1st Edition)

Author(s) of Book: J.R. McNeill

Chapter Title: Chapter 20 The First Global Economy, 1500 to 1800 (pp. 583 – 601, sections titled
“Trade”, “New Business Formats”, and “Global Links and Commercial Revolutions”)

Author(s) of Chapter: J.R. McNeill

Year: 2021

Publisher: W.W. Norton & Company, Inc.

Place of Publishing: the United States of America

The copyright law of the United States (Title 17, United States Code) governs the making of
photocopies or other reproductions of copyrighted materials. Under certain conditions specifies in
the law, libraries and archives are authorized to furnish a photocopy or other reproduction. One of
these conditions is that the photocopy or reproduction is not to be used for any purpose other than
private study, scholarship, or research. If a user makes a request for, or later uses, a photocopy or
reproduction for purposes in excess of fair use, that user may be liable for copyright infringement.
How did the spice, cotton, and silver trades help Integrate the global economy? 383

populations in the deeper past shrank when they transi-


tioned from hunting and foraging to farming, so, perhaps,
the buffalo hunters of the plains grew in stature from an
increasingly protein-rich diet.
While we don't have data yet for Africa, China, and
India before the nineteenth century, it appears that
the global trend-to which North America was an
exception-was that people grew smaller even as econ-
omies grew larger. The benefits of expanding economies
(outside of North America) seem to have flowed over-
whelmingly to elites while the standard ofliving for most
people fell between 1500 and 1800.

The Laboring Poor Peasants and laborers-ordinary people­


FALLING INCOMES FOR were hit hardest by major environmental, demographic, and eco­
nomic shifts. A seventeenth-century French painting depicts t he
WAGE LABORERS realities of subsistence life for a peasant family: ragged c lothing
and a few basic dishes empty of food.
The evidence on incomes for ordinary city folk supports
this discouraging conclusion. In Beijing, Delhi, London,
Amsterdam, and Florence, laborers' real incomes climbed such as eastern North America, saw their economic posi-
during the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries. The plague tion weaken as their numbers grew.
pandemic of the 1340s had had one silver lining for sur-
vivors: the resulting scarcity of people drove wages up.
Unskilled laborers earned three to four times what they
required for subsistence in 1450, which meant each one TRADE
could support a small family. But in the late fifteenth cen-
tury, laborers' incomes began a long slide, which in Bei- The burst ofoceanic voyaging after the 1490s linked mar-
jing, Delhi, and Florence bottomed out around the years kets as never before. This created opportunities for buying
1750-1800. At that point, a laborer barely earned enough cheap in one market and selling dear in another. To do
to feed one mouth, which meant in families everyone had this optimally, one needs more market knowledge than
to work. In Amsterdam and London, laborers' incomes competitors have-exactly what the people who made the
slipped rather less; they climbed a bit in the seventeenth voyages acquired. These voyagers were mainly Aclantic
century, before falling again in the eighteenth. Every- Europeans, not the maritime traders of the East China
where, the constraints of an economy based on human Sea or the Indian Ocean, nor the caravan merchants of
and animal muscle meant that the great majority ofpeople Iran or Central Asia, who by and large did not go global.
lived close to subsistence levels. Britain's North American Certain trades, such as cotton, rewarded market
colonies, again, were an exception to the dismal trend. knowledge more than others. You needed to know a loc
In the mid-eighteenth century, unskilled free laborers in in order not co lose your shirt in che cotton business.
Boston and Philadelphia earned four or five times what On the production side, some varieties of cotton planes
they needed for subsistence, more than anywhere else in produced better fiber than others. Spinners and weavers
the world for which data exist. had several techniques for making yarns and cloths of
Why did ordinary people grow poorer while economies different quality and cost. Different dyestuffs and printing
grew faster than ever before? At any time of large-scale methods produced an array of colors and patterns. And
economic reorganization, some people are better situated at every stage, spinners, weavers, and other workers had
co benefit from change than others. Most of the eco- varying skill levels. So "cotton" amounted co dozens of
nomic growth from 1500 to 1800 created rewards for chose different produces.
involved in trade, finance, and government. Ordinary On the demand side, communities of consumers had
peasants and laborers, outside of a few favored locations particular preferences, and these might change over time.
CHAPTER 20 The First Global Economy

Egypt, was the central arena of long~distance seaborne


trade. The sea lanes ofthe Atlantic, the Baltic Sea, North
Sea, and the coasts as far south as Senegal were busy too,
but not on the same scale. Regular transatlantic traf-
fic began in the wake of Columbus, and the slave trade
extended it ro African coasts as far south as Angola and
Mozambique. Almost all Atlantic trade took place in ships
owned and operated by Aclantic Europeans. By the 1550s,
this burgeoning Atlantic trade was increasingly linked to
the Indian Ocean commerce. European merchants grad-
ually got involved in the trade circuits of Indian Ocean
and East Asian waters, although never outstripping Asian
trading communities.
Three commodities accounted for a sizeable chunk of
world trade during the early modem centuries: spices,
Cotton Production Technological advances and market know­ cotton, and silver. While many other things (as well as
how enabled Europeans to begin to compete in the global cotton
trade. In this painting, mid-seventeenth-century French peasants
millions of people) were traded, these three played cen-
spin cotton on a spinning wheel and weave it into cloth on a large tral roles in tightening the commercial webs ofrhe world,
frame loom within their own cottage-the typical form of cotton integrating far-flung regions in particular.
production at the time.

SPICES AND THE SPICE TRADE


During the early modern centuries, most Chinese markets
valued plain white cotton. West African markets preferred Cooks have flavored food with spices for several thousand
vivid hues, while Latin American consumers paid more years. When people thought that good health rested on
for floral motifs. But beneath these generalizations, spe- a proper balance of hoc and cold influences, spices such
cific villages and individuals had different preferences. as pepper, ginger, and cinnamon acquired reputations as
Knowledge of these complexities helped people make health foods. (In fact, many spices are rich in micronutri-
money in the long-distance cotton trade. This favored ents and antioxidants.) The lands that produced the most
literate people and chose who actually did the voyaging spices were the islands ofSoutheast Asia. Spices featured
and trading: they accumulated broader knowledge faster. prominently in local diets, but more than 2,000 years ago
Atlantic Europeans had another important edge in they also became staples in long-distance trade to both
long-distance trade, noted in the previous chapter. Their India and China. Ancient Rome imported spices too, as
sturdy ships, built to withstand Atlantic gales, accom- did, lacer on, the Muslim caliphates based in Damascus
modated heavy cannon. European merchants active in and Baghdad, and Byzantine markers in Constantinople.
oceanic trade almost always carried serious armament. Eventually, spices, especially peppers, were grown in south
They could fight back against pirates and hope to prevail. India as well as Southeast Asia. In addition to peppers, the
They could engage in piracy themselves when it suited most marketable spices included nutmeg, cinnamon, and
them, attacking, say, Bengali or Malay ships and seizing doves, valued for their flavor and purported medicinal
their cargoes. They could threaten co bombard port cities value. The port cities of the Indian Ocean world, from
until local princes and merchants offered their goods at Malacca to Basra, all had spice bazaars.
lower prices. Well-armed ship captains could sell "pro- In 14001 China and India remained the chief markets
tection" to the less well armed, allowing them to live in for spices. Europe's supply, maybe 2,000 tons annually,
peace for a price. These twin advantages, in information came mainly via Egypt to Venice. Vasco da Gama sought
and seaborne firepower, went a long way toward enriching a route to the Indian Ocean around Africa in the 1490s,
Atlantic Europe's merchant classes. with the backing of the Portuguese Crown, in part to
Before 1500, the Indian Ocean world, from China to cur out the middlemen in rhe spice trade and get to the
How did the spice, cotton, and silver trades help Integrate the global economy? 585

>
• Spice-producing area
• SuItanate of Aceh
- Spice trade route

A S I A
PORTUGAL
Lisbon. .OTTOMAN
EMPIRJ=
• I
,-. ~ JAPAN
SAFAVID ' :.!::'\
,... MPJRE ~~
uz !

AT
PA C/FIC
mbay OCEAN
DIA '\
Manila
' ~ FR/CA PHILIPPINES
(Spain)

Ma/ucCiJs

IND/AN OCEAN

~ ---~a====>
0
0 1,000
1,000
2,000 km
2.000ml
...

The Spice Trade, ea, 1600 The spice trade had flowed along the maritime routes of the Indian Ocean world for millennia. The main
production zones were Southeast Asian islands such as the Moluccas and Bandas, and eventually southwestern India. The biggest
markets by 1600 were China, India, Southwest Asia, and Europe. Before the Portuguese voyages around the southern tip cf Africa,
spices had arrived in Europe overland via Ottoman territories. By 1600, the Ottomans were losing that trade to seagoing European
merchants. The suItans of Aceh kept their grip on the trade passing west from the spice islands th rough the Straits of Malacca until 1600.

source-Southeast Asia and India. An all-sea route low- naval firepower permitted tiny Portugal to play this out-
ered the price ofspices in Europe, boosting demand. After sized role.
da Gama's return in 1498, Lisbon soon became one ofthe The spice trade initially brought spectacular profits for
world's great spice markets. merchants who survived the dangers oflong sea voyages.
The best spices grew wild on islands such as the Moluc- When da Gama first arrived in India, the market price
cas and the Bandas, now parts oflndonesia. Much ofthe of pepper there was 4 percent of the price in Europe. In
trade flowed through the port ofMalacca, a great trading the Moluccas, spices could be had for 1/700 the Lisbon
city with perhaps 100,000 people by 1500. Superior fire- price. In the years from 1500 to 1630, an average of seven
power enabled the Portuguese to defeat the Muslim sul- Portuguese ships set out each year for Asian spice markets.
tanate ofMalacca in 1511 with a force of only 1,200 men. Storms, shipwrecks, and pirates claimed an average of
This strategic conquest was the most important step in the three, but the surviving four brought magnificent profits.
Portuguese quest for a commanding position in the spice The quantities of spices going to China, India, and
trade. Tome Pires, a Portuguese who visited Malacca in Islamic lands remained greater than chat headed co
151I, wrote that one could hear 84 languages spoken on its Europe. In the pepper trade perhaps a quarter or a third
streets on any given day. Its connections with northwest went co Lisbon, while the rest found its way to Asian mar-
India were so strong that Pires wrote: "Melaka cannot kets, often in Portuguese ships. For cloves, more expen-
survive without Cambay, nor Cambay without Melaka." sive and profitable than pepper, the proportion (for the
Portuguese merchants now carried increasing shares of sixteenth century) was roughly 90 percent to Asia and 10
the trade not only to Lisbon, but also to markets in India percent to Europe.
and China. The Portuguese language became the lingua After 1550, the sultan ofAceh (on the northern end of
franca ofthe spice trade. Superior market knowledge and Sumatra) sought to control the spice trade. With allies
586 CHAPTER 20 The First Global Economy

a century before Venetians had purchased pepper co sell


in Europe. Portuguese, Dutch, and English traders also
carried spices from Southeast Asia to Japan, China, and
India, competing with Malay, Gujarati, and other Asian
merchants on their home turf. The spice trade contin-
ued to grow into the eighteenth century. But its relative
importance in global trade dwindled as cotton became
the staple of the long-distance trade between the Indian
Ocean world and the Atlantic.

COTTON AND THE COTTON TRADE


Cotton grows only in lands where there are at least 200
frost-free days and either 20 inches (50 cm) of rainfall
annually or irrigation water. The earliest evidence we have
ofcotton cultivation comes from the ancient Indus valley
about 5,000 years ago. Its cultivation spread outside of
India to Southwest Asia and Egypt mainly during the era
oflslamic expansion, the eighth through the tenth centu-
ries. But world production remained centered on India.
Women In the Marketplace An engraving from a Dutch book of Chinese farmers in the southeastern province of Fujian
the late seventeenth century shows women involved in market
transactions on the island of Java. In Southeast Asia, women grew cotton too. When the Ming decided co accept cotton
often took part in market trading. as a means ofpaying taxes in the fourteenth century, the
crop spread widely in southern China.
Before 1450, cotton was raised, spun, and woven into
in Gujarati traders and even Ottoman sultans, Aceh's cloth, and traded chiefly in India and China. It was grown
sultan became a formidable competitor for Portuguese mainly on small farms, spun into thread by women and
merchants after 1550. They acquired more competitors children in villages, and woven into cloth usually by men
after 1590 when the Dutch, and soon English traders in village workshops. During the fifteenth through the
too, tried to get a share of the spice trade. By 1620, the seventeenth centuries, India's cotton farming and manu-
Dutch and English between them sent about ten ships facturing was concentrated in the regions ofGujarat and
laden with spices back to Europe annually, more than Punjab, in northwest India, which specialized in cheap
twice what Portugal managed. The more competitive cottons; and in Coromandel, in the southeast; and Ben-
market meant less profit for everyone, but Durch data gal, in the northeast, both of which specialized in fine
show the spice trade returned an annual profit averaging muslins and high-quality printed cloth such as calicoes
27 percent from 1602 to 1650. By the late seventeenth and chintzes.
century, Amsterdam prices were only about 5 times High-quality cotton, like silk, was well suited for
Malacca prices for pepper, and 15 times for cloves. The long-distance trade. It was lightweight and durable, and
fabulous profits ofthe early years of the spice uade were it could be folded or rolled into nearly any shape. In the
gone forever. But more people were able to enjoy spices' fifteenth century it was valued from Japan to Spain to East
flavors and healthful effects. Africa. Merchants traded it by land and sea, including
With their market knowledge and shipboard can- along caravan routes ofAsia, many ofwhich were "cotton
non, Portuguese, Dutch, and English merchants won a roads" as much as "silk roads." In the mid-seventeenth
large share of the world's spice trade after 15n. They cut century, Iran imported 25 to 30 thousand camel loads of
Egyptian and Venetian middlemen out of the trade to cotton annually from India.
Europe. By 1615, English merchants were trading pepper As with spices, it was European oceanic merchants
to Ottoman markets in the eastern Mediterranean, where who most conspicuously expanded the scope ofthe world
How did the spice, cotton, and silver trades help Integrate the global economy? S87

r~-
~ "j
l

~ ::. ~- SIA • ~-
P. \r\. ' I
I \.., J.(P~N
• ~ CHIN . P ACIFIC
v1c_gRo/ T'tr ATLANTJC CEAN .---
From OFN_EW~N
OCEAN . ?o
I
A Cllpu Co .. PINES
AFRICA
d h aln)

L a
'
~
. .
PACIFIC
OCEAN . Luan a ·

JNDIAN OCEAN /lj~


Sofal --,
AUSTRALIA )

• Cotton manufacturing area o_ _,,,,,1,,,,,000==2.=ooo m,


- Cotton trade route 0 l.000 2.000 km

The Cotton Trade, ca. 1700 Cotton grew well in several zones around the world in 1700, but India was the biggest producer. With
markets almost everywhere, cotton was one of the first truly global trade commodities. The seaborne circuits shown here include
both transatlantic and transpacific routes to markets in the Americas. Southeast Asia, both East and West Africa, the Ottoman lands,
and Atlantic Europe were also major importers of cotton.

cotton trade. They carried it co new markets in Africa, skirts ofembroidered muslin. Portuguese merchants sold
Europe, and the Americas. They also competed with Asian Indian cotton cloth in Brazil.
traders carrying cotton from one Asian port to another. European markets eventually bought more Asian cot-
In the course of the sixteenth century, the Atlantic tons than did either Africa or the Americas. The Portu-
slave trade came to involve cotton. West Africans already guese trade to Indian Ocean ports had initially focused on
had a taste for Indian cottons, available at considerable spices, but by 1620 textiles-mainly cotton-made up 60
cost via trans-Saharan routes from North Africa and percent ofit (by value). In 1708, the English man ofletters
Egypt. Between 1500 and 1800, some 50 to 60 percent Daniel Defoe (author of Robinson Crusoe) complained that
of African imports in the slave trade were Indian doth imported cotton had "crept into our Houses, our Closets
offered by Portuguese, Dutch, or English merchants. Of and Bed Chambers, Curtains, Cushions, Chairs, and at
the roughly 8 million Africans bought for shipment to last Beds themselves were nothing but Calicoes or Indian
the Americas in those centuries, over 4 million were pur- stuffs." Indian cotton was sufficiencly good and cheap
chased with Indian textiles. that it menaced Europe's wool and linen business and put
People in the Americas also bought Indian cotton thousands ofweavers out ofwork. Responding ro weavers'
goods. Cotton cloth, like Chinese silk and porcelain, riots and complaints voiced by men such as Defoe, France
crossed the Pacific to Spanish America via Manila and and Britain enacted tariffs and outright bans on Indian
Acapulco. But it also came through Spain's ports and cloth imports, starting in the 1680s. In 172.0, the British
across the Atlantic. Women in Mexico City wore fine Parliament passed a law forbidding the use or wearing of
calicoes from India. According to one eighteenth-century imported calico cloth.
account, even slave women in Veracruz (Mexico) wore These protectionist measures spurred domestic cotton
588 CHAPTER 20 The First Global Economy

The Cotton Trade Painted cloth from the Madras region of India shows an Indian woman (center)-perhaps a cotton-spinner her-
self-conversing with European traders. Traders shipped Indian textiles to western Europe, where they became the basis for luxury
commodities such as this fashionable eighteenth-century gown made of Indian muslin. The pleated, floor-length fabric at the back
falls loosely as a slight train.

manufacturing industries in England and France, using trusts. In practice, the cash ofthe early modern world, as
imported raw cotton. By the 1760s, European cotton mills before, came in the form ofprecious metals such as gold,
could compete successfully against Indian producers in silver, and copper. In long-distance trade, silver emerged
African and American markets. Cotton was now a global as the best option because copper wasn't valued enough,
business-one that, as much as anything else, brought the gold was too rare, and paper money or promises offuture
Indian Ocean and Atlantic Ocean into a unified trading payment were unreliable.
world, providing a strong strand in the Global web. The silver needed to keep governments going and
long-distance trade humming came mainly from Span-
ish America, central Europe, andJapan. New silver strikes
SILVER AND THE SILVER TRADE
Silver became another ofthe first global trade commod-
ities, but with a difference. It served primarily as money,
whereas cotton was most often used for clothing and only
occasionally as money. There were two main reasons for
silver's expanded role. First, governments, always in need
of revenue, found it advantageous to demand that taxes
be paid in silver as opposed to grain, cotton, livestock,
labor, or anything else. Silver gave them the flexibility
to pay for weapons, soldiers, or whatever else they might
need on short notice. The Mughals gradually put tax pay-
ments in India on a silver basis. The Ming did the same
in China, where tax had previously come most often in
the form of rice. In the 1570s they changed the laws to
require everyone, even peasant families, to pay taxes in
silver. A huge proportion of the world's population now
needed silver.
Silver Production An illustration of the patio process shows
The second reason for the rise of silver as a global workers at a mine in Mexico refining silver on an industrial
commodity was that it solved a problem of mistrust that scale-producing the pure silver that was increasingly fueling
the global economy. Transmission of the most efficient mining
hampered long-distance trade. When people don't know and ore-refining technologies of the day boost silver output
and trust one another, they need money that everyone around the world.
How did the spice, cotton, and sllver trades help Integrate the global economy? 589

-,, ·.r-

" ljing · .,;f


-..- REA ·
"FAVID Y...!~PAN
PIRE
"'-

( )
PACIFIC
CEAN
1

t A i'RIC
....Elmi

PACIFIC
\ . .
OCEAN
ATLANTI . -i
OCEAN ~

INOIAN OCEAN
,,.
• AUSTRALIA
,.,..,.,-'14
• Spanish territory, ca. 1600
a_ _,,,1.,sooo...==2~,000 mi "?.___.._
o Silver mine
- Silver trade route 0 1,000 2,000 km r;/

The Sliver Trade, ca. 1600 Silver became a truly global commodity in the sixteenth century. The main silver-mining zones were in
Japan, central Europe, and Spanish America-especially in Zacatecas, Mexico, and Potosr. Silver was crucial to the Spanish Empire's
finances. However, it commanded a higher price in India and China than anywhere else, so silver flowed across land and sea to the
Mughal and Ming empires. Silver was so prized in China that it could bear the high transport costs across the length of Asia by
overland caravan.

took place in Japan in the 1520s through the 1540s, in as never before and tightened the Global web through the
Mexico during the years 1545 through 1558, and the biggest enhanced use ofsilver in global trade.
ofall-as we've seen-at Potosi (in today's Bolivia) high
in the Andes, in 1545. In Japan, Chinese and Korean min- FINANCING THE SPANISH AND JAPANESE
ing technology adopted in the 1550s improved the yield of STATES The rising tide of silver production floated the
silver veins. In the Americas, the latest German technol- Spanish and Japanese states and tempted them to over-
ogy was applied in Mexico in the 1550s and at Potosi in reach. Despite Spain's small population (about 7 million)
the 1570s. Japan's mines adopted it, via Mexico, by 1580, and poverty ofnatural resources, it became a great power
leading to a peak in production from 1602 to 1630. in Europe and controlled much of the Americas and the
These technologies, especially the so-called patio Philippines after the mid-sixteenth century. In Europe,
process in Spanish America, made it easier to separate sil- the Spanish Crown-a branch of the Habsburg dynasty
ver from its surrounding rock, so lower-grade ores became from 1519 to 1700-used its silver bonanza to fight end-
worth mining. Japan in the sixteenth century mined about less wars and champion the Catholic effort to roll back
30 percent ofthe world's silver, and in the seventeenth cen- Protestantism. Spanish monarchs also committed to con-
tury about 15 percent. Spanish American mines produced tinual warfare against the Ottomans (and Muslims more
a good deal more, and Potosi alone accounted for 60 per- generally) in the Mediterranean. A Spanish friar writing
cent of world silver production between 1550 and 1650. in 1638 put it this way: "Potosi lives in order to serve the
Thus the transmission of technology along international imposing aspirations of Spain: it serves to chastise the
circuits helped advance a silver mining boom on three Turk, humble the Moor, make Flanders tremble and ter-
continents. The effects enabled some monarchs to spend rify England." By law, the Crown was entitled to one-fifth
1590 CHAPTER 20 The First Global Economy

Spanish Power A painting depicts the port city of Seville at the height of Spanish power in the late sixteenth century. Seville's port
played a key role in the silver trade that contributed mightily to the Spanish Crown's vast wealth.

of all silver production in the Spanish Empire. At times, both the Ming and the Mughals insisted on silver for tax
upward of40 percent ofSpain's government revenue came payments in the sixteenth century, silver became more
from Potosi alone. valuable in those lands than anywhere else. People could
The silver mountain's bounty peaked in rhe 1590s and exchange silver for more goods, or more gold, in India
slipped sharply after about 1640. Spanish kings managed and China than elsewhere. Anyone who could survive
to spend all the silver that crossed the Atlantic on royal the risks oftrading across the seas could do well exchang-
account and then some. When pinched for funds after ing silver for Indian cotton cloth and pepper, or Chinese
production started to fall, they sometimes grabbed private silk and porcelain. As a Portuguese official in Macau,
traders' silver as it came ashore. Felipe IV (r. 1621-1665) Manuel de Comara de Noronha, put it in 1630, "When
said, "Nothing do I regret more than having to seize sil- the Chinese smell silver, they will bring mountains of
ver." But he did it anyway to fight wars. merchandise." In the same year, He Qiaoyuan, a Ming
Similarly, in Japan, the military entrepreneurs who scholar and official, remarked that silver acquired through
unified the country-Oda Nobunaga (1534-1582), Toy- foreign trade resulted in massive exports, thereby ensuring
otomi Hideyoshi (ca. 1536-1598), and Tokugawa Ieyasu «employment for weavers, potters, and merchants, whose
(1543-1616)-financed their campaigns against rival war- waxing affluence augured higher standards of living for
lords with silver. They converted the mines into a state all." The ceramic kilns at the southern town ofJingdezhen
monopoly exploiting convict labor. Silver revenues also employed more than 10,000 workers during the late Ming.
helped pay for Hideyoshi's unsuccessful invasion ofKorea Silver Hows helped to bolster both the Chinese economy
in the 1590s. Like Habsburg Spain (and, for chat matter, and world trade.
like Athens of the fifth century BCE), Tokugawa Japan's Merchants sent Japanese silver to China, often in
hard power rested largely on military force supported by Dutch or Portuguese ships becauseJapanese were officially
the yields ofsilver mines while they lasted. By 1640, Japan's forbidden to trade with foreigners. American silver flowed
silver production had shrunk to halfits peak levels of1621. along many pathways. Some bullion crossed the Pacific via
Acapulco to Manila in the Philippines, and on to China
PROMOTING ECONOMIC GROWTH IN CHINA from there. In this way, Chinese silk and ceramics entered
AND INDIA The silver that was mined in Spanish markets in Mexico and Spanish America generally. The
America and Japan traveled around the world. Most of it bulk ofAmerican silver crossed the Aclantic, usually via
eventually went to China or India, where it served to pro- Cuba's main port ofHavana, to Seville in Spain. But it did
mote commerce and underpin economic growth. When not rest there long. Some of Spain's incoming silver went
What was the significance of the new business formats that emerged during this period? 591

to repay loans from in the early modern centuries were plantations, trading
Italian and German companies, and banks.
bankers, including the
house ofFugger. After
PLANTATIONS
the 1560s, plenty of it
went to finance Spain's A seventeenth-century Barbadian slave was quo red in 1676
army, which was at as saying, "The devil was in the Englishman that he makes
Chinese Ceramics The export of
Chinese luxury goods, like this war with the Dutch. everything work; he makes the Negro work, he makes
intricate Ming-era painted and Once delivered to the horse work, the ass work, the wood work, the water
enameled porcelain box, brought
bankers or the Spanish work and the wind work." But it was not the devil that
the silver needed for coinage and
tax payments in China. army, American silver inspired Englishmen on Barbados to try to force everyone
flowed through Otto- and everything to make sugar. It was the opportunity to
man lands, the Baltic, and Russia, or traveled in European get rich by selling sugar grown, harvested, and processed
ships sailing around Africa, always heading for India and by enslaved labor on plantations.
China, as ifpulled by a magnetic attraction. Plantations are large-scale commercial farming opera-
For two centuries nothing produced in the rest ofthe tions with labor forces ofdozens or hundreds ofpeople-
world, except at times European cannon, interested Chi- sometimes free wage workers, sometimes unfree laborers,
nese and Indian merchants as much as silver. But by 1750 and often both. They have existed here and there since
or so, China had enough silver in circulation to satisfy ancient times. But the interconnected commercial world
demand and reduce its price to about the same as the that developed after the 1490s improved the economic
world price. Silver flows slowed and no longer quickened logic of plantations. When many markets were within
global commerce. reach, the rewards co large-scale production (known as
Silver, cotton, and spices: they could be produced only economies of scale) multiplied. Nothing worked better
in some places but were in demand everywhere. They as a plantation crop than sugar.
formed the lifeblood of global trade between 1500 and Sugar is a grass native to Southeast Asia. It will grow
1750, and they exemplify the process by which merchants in tropical and subtropical latitudes where temperatures
connected far-flung markets in a global commercial web. are warm for most of the year. It needs either abundant
Tea, sugar, silk, gold, ivory, and many other items- rain or irrigation, and fertile soils. In the harvest season,
even dried fish-were traded across the oceans as well.
So were millions of slaves. At any given time after 1550,
hundreds of ships were sailing on well-traveled routes,
linking ports such as Guangzhou, Manila, Cambay, Goa,
Basra, Cape Town, Elmina, Seville, Amsterdam, Lon-
don, Bahia, Havana, Acapulco, and many others. Year
after year ships and cargoes sailed, tightening the web of
global commerce.

NEW BUSINESS
FORMATS: PLANTATIONS,
COMPANIES, BANKS Sugar Plantations In this early nineteenth-century scene repre-
senting a sugar plantation in Antigua, a British Caribbean colony,
The quickening pace ofglobal commerce invited creative enslaved men and women prepare the ground for planting. The
world's sugar trade rested on the plantation system and slave
entrepreneurs to invent or refine the institutions through labor. The windmill provided the power that squeezed cane juice
which they did business. Three of the most important from harvested sugarcane.
592 CHAPTER 20 The First Global Economy

/lfadeirao

Canary ls. .c,


\

ATLANTIC
OCEAN
\(\:~RICA
o Sugar cullival ion area, s.w, Tom~ o { . ,
beginning prior to 1620
~
O Sugar plantation area,
after 1620
O Sugar refining center, 1750
\ '
,.
1
Colonial lerrltorles, ca. 1750



British
Dutch
French
Portuguese
Spanish
0_ __,,,=;;;;;;;,===
1,000 2,000 ml
C-t -)
0 1,000 2,000km

The Sugar Industry, ca. 1750 People had been cultivating sugar for millennia, but it became a major commodity, produced on
plantations with slave labor. in the Mediterranean world around 1000 CE, In the sixteenth century, Portuguese and Spanish entre-
preneurs brought sugar plantations into the Atlantic world, first to islands such as Madeira, the Canaries, and S~o Tome, then across
the ocean to the Caribbean and coastal Brazil. Sugar refining was concentrated in Hamburg, Amsterdam, and London, with smaller
centers elsewhere in Europe and in British North America, especially Boston and Philadelphia.

it needs a burst of labor. Its economies of scale came in and Spaniards did the same on Atlantic islands such as
the processes of milling and refining, in which juice is Madeira, the Canaries, and Sao Tome.
squeezed by rollers from sugar cane and then boiled into
a goopy mass that dries into crystals. To make sugar THE SPREAD OF THE SUGAR PLANTATION Sao
pay, one needed to make big investments in land, labor, Tome, in the Gulf of Guinea, pointed the way toward
machinery, buildings, and other infrastructure. Sugar is a large-scale slave-and-sugar complex. Portuguese mari-
rarely a small farmer's crop, and for the last thousand years ners settled the formerly uninhabited island in the 1490s.
it has been mainly a plantation crop. Its volcanic, nutrient-rich soils and rainy climate proved
Sugar was grown on a modest scale in China and India ideal for sugar. By the 1550s, the island's economy focused
in ancient times. By 650 CE it had appeared in Iraq and so tightly on sugar chat it raised too little food for its
Egypt. By 800 its cultivation had spread to several Med- population. Merchants brought food from Portugal, a
iterranean islands, southern (Islamic) Spain, and river month away by sail. The plantations required a constant
valleys ofMorocco. In the Muslim lands of the Mediter- influx of people-slaves from Kongo on the mainland
ranean, slaves-mainly captives from Christian Europe- ofAfrica, and settlers, often unwilling migrants, mostly
formed the backbone ofthe sugar labor force. In Morocco from the communities of Portuguese Jews, debtors, and
by 1450, entrepreneurs and emirs imported African slaves criminals, and other populations the Portuguese Crown
across the Sahara to work on sugar plantations. Portuguese was happy to deport. For nearly halfa century, Sao Tome
What was the significance of the new business formats that emerged during this period? 598

served as the leading example of a new business format, and the sugar industry gradually shifted to bigger islands
che large-scale slave plantation. such as Jamaica, Hispaniola, and Cuba. The big islands
In the rnos, Portuguese businessmen took the planta- had more land and forests that, when burned, released
tion format to the northeast of Brazil. There they found in their ash a pulse of nutrients to the soil from which a
good soils and climate for sugar cultivation, but a short- bumper crop could spring for a few years.
age of labor. They tried enslaving the Amerindian pop- The exploitation of people was more consequential.
ulation, but extremely high death rates from disease and From 1550 to 1850, about halfofthe nearly n million Afri-
maltreatment convinced them that the answer to their cans shipped across the Atlantic went to sugar planta-
problem was massive imports of African slaves. By the tions in Brazil and the Caribbean. The majority were field
1590s, Brazil led the world in sugar production. By the slaves who worked long hours in labor gangs overseen
1640s, the tandem of sugar and slavery was booming in by armed men. During the harvest and milling seasons,
the Caribbean too, where planters on Spanish, French, men, women, and children worked around the clock with
British, and Dutch islands all raised cane in quantity. scant rest. A combination of strenuous work, brutality,
Some Caribbean planters at first tried using enslaved Scots and a lethal disease environment made sugar plantations
and Irish, but too few could be found. Next came inden- notoriously unhealthy and contributed co the short life
tured European laborers, who were bound to work for a expectancy of slaves on these plantations: shorter than
fixed number ofyears in exchange for free passage across anywhere else in the Americas, averaging about 10 years
the Atlantic. But too few volunteered (or could be kid- after arrival for those born in Africa. (Free blacks' life
napped), and once in the Caribbean they died fast from expectancy was marginally longer, indentured Europe-
diseases. So, as in Brazil, Caribbean planters turned to ans' slightly shorter.) Among slaves on sugar plantations,
Aclantic Africa, where local merchants offered slaves in deaths outstripped births until the nineteenth century. So,
great numbers at advantageous prices. Thereafter, for 200 after more than two centuries ofcontinuous slave imports,
years, Brazil and the Caribbean led the world in sugar the population on sugar plantations in the Americas in
exports and slave imports. 1790 stood at about 2 million people, 90 to 95 percent of
The slave-and-sugar plantations in Brazil and the them slaves.
Caribbean were a novel form of enterprise, far larger and Brutality stood at the core ofsugar plantation society.
more efficient than their predecessors in Sao Tome or the Masters and overseers resorted to violence and the threat
Mediterranean. The plantations, at least on the smaller of violence as the chief means of enforcing discipline
islands ofthe Caribbean such as Barbados, imported most among the labor force. Thomas Thistlewood, an overseer
of their food from afar, as had Sao Tome-so they could on a Jamaican plantation starting in 1750, left a diary in
specialize on one product, sugar. Plantations usually held which he derailed the various punishments and tortures
between 100 and 500 slaves, and sugar districts supported he inflicted on slaves. His diary also recounts his sex life
the densest rural populations anywhere in the Americas. with slave women, showing him to be a sexual predator
They were all located near the seacoasts because sugar was and a rapist. Thistlewood's conduct was not unusual for
an export crop, destined for European markets in Lisbon, overseers and slavemasters. Their brutalities were calcu-
Seville, Bordeaux, Antwerp, Amsterdam, or London- lated to make slaves choose obedience over defiance. That
and after r730 or so also North American ones such as calculation worked most but not all of the time. Slaves
Baltimore, Philadelphia, or Boston. They were often enor- defied Thistlewood on occasion, for which he made them
mously profitable for planters. suffer.
Slaves from time to time risked everything on attempts
SUGAR AND PLANTATION SLAVERY Sugar prof- to run away or rebel. In 1760, some 1,500 slaves, led by
its rested on a double exploitation. Sugar monoculture Akan-speakers from what is now Ghana, tried to rake over
depleted soil nutrients, so planters periodically had to the island ofJamaica. Tacky's War, as it is called, lasted a
move to virgin fields, usually to forested land. In time, few months and shook the foundations ofthe plantation
often about 50 to 75 years, plantations on smaller Carib- regime on that island. As we've seen, in northeast Brazil
bean islands became unprofitable due to nutrient loss, a community of runaway slaves, Palmares, managed to
594 CHAPTER 20 The First Global Economy

defend its independence from 1605 to the 1690s. The great-


est ofall slave risings took place in the 1790s in the French
sugar colony of St. Domingue, as we will see in Chapter
21. By and large, slaves on the smaller islands were less
likely to try co run away because recapture was more likely
there than on bigger islands or in Brazil, where sparsely
populated forests beckoned slaves yearning to escape the
plantation.
Sugar was not quite the global commodity that silver
or cotton was. Because it does not keep as well as silver
or cotton, and could be grown widely, it was not traded
from the Atlantic basin into the Indian Ocean or Pacific
on any scale. The primary significance of sugar for the
global economy was that it demonstrated the viability of
the large-scale slave plantation.
Other crops in the Americas, notably tobacco, cotton,
rice, and indigo, would also be produced on the planta-
tion model. The particulars varied from place to place
and from crop to crop. But plantation owners all used Stock Exchanges The Dutch painter Emanuel de Witte made this
slave labor, relied heavily on terror for labor discipline, painting of the Beurs, or Amsterdam stock exchange, in 1653.
systematically sought economies of scale, and filled dis- Investors met in this busy courtyard to trade shares in increas-
ingly popular and profitable joint-stock companies.
tant markets with their products. By the mid-eighteenth
century, some ofthe richest men in the world made their
money this way. along the coast ofChina or che merchant empire ofVirji
Vora in India.

CHARTERED JOINT-STOCK COMPANIES


ORIGINS During the sixteenth century, more anon-
The commercial opportunities of the Global web offered ymous forms of partnership developed to spread and
economies of scale in long-distance trade as well as in share the risks of long-distance trade. Some were char-
cash-crop production. Just as the slave planration brought tered companies, granted monopoly rights over certain
new levels ofefficiency, human suffering, and profit to the trades by governments. Others were joint-stock compa-
business ofsugar production, so the joint-stock company nies in which hundreds or thousands of investors might
did for oceanic trade. own shares, as in modern corporations. Some were both,
Intercontinental shipping was risky business. Storms, such as the English Muscovy Company, founded in 1555,
pirates, disease outbreaks, and other hazards could ruin or the Levant Company, chartered by England's Queen
any voyage. To make business sense, ventures needed to Elizabeth in 1581 to conduce trade with Ottoman lands.
be big: big enough to fight offpirates, negotiate bulk dis- All had professional managers. This was a business model
counts on trade goods, and ensure that some ships would that could expand to indefinite size more readily than the
surely survive a storm. Sending several ships together kin-based business empires of the Zhengs or Virji Vora.
made sense, and sending a fleet was better still. The English pioneered chartered joint-stock
To achieve economies of scale in long-distance trade, companies. France and the Netherlands soon followed,
merchants found ways to cooperate and pool their and during the eighteenth century Spain, Denmark, and
resources. Traders and businessmen had done this for others did too. One ofthese, the Hudson's Bay Company,
millennia, usually with family members or close friends begun in 1670 to handle the fur trade in Canada, still
because mutual trust was crucial. These kin-based con- exists, albeit in much different form. The gold standard
cerns could be gigantic, like the Zheng family operations ofchartered joint-stock trading companies was the Dutch
What was the slgnlffc:ance of the new business formats that emerged during this period? 595

East India Company, the VOC, founded in 1602, which


we've already encountered in South Africa and in East
Asian waters.

THE DUTCH EAST INDIA COMPANY (VOC) The


VOC was a chartered joint-stock company, formed to
share the risk ofvoyages to the spice islands oflndonesia.
Voyages in the seventeenth century from Amsterdam to
Indonesia and back typically took 200 to 300 days out-
bound, and more than 300 on the return. About 3 to 5
percent never returned, better than the 40 percent rate for
Portuguese ships in the sixteenth century.
The VOC proved a spectacular success for nearly voe Conquests This detail of an illustration of voe forces
assaulting a local sultanate in the spice islands (part of Indonesia
200 years. Between 1602 and 1796, the company sent today) Indicates the typically violent methods that the VOC used
nearly 5,000 ships around Africa to the Indian Ocean. to establish a foothold in lucrative trading locations.
They brought back some 2.5 million tons of trade goods
and exchanged countless cargoes between Asian ports.
Detailed records for a 300-ton ship, the Ceulen, which a local town and rebuilt it as Batavia in 1619. In an effort
sailed from Java to Amsterdam in 1697, reveal something to monopolize the clove and nutmeg trades in the 1620s,
of the business: in addition to a crew of 105 seamen and they attempted to kill the entire population of the Banda
30 soldiers, it carried a cargo ofJapanese copper, tin from Islands and replace them with loyal settlers. They tried to
Thailand, ceramics from China, aromatic wood, saltpe- burn all pepper vines and clove or nutmeg trees not under
ter, tea, ginger, nutmeg, cloves, cardamom (another spice), their control to undermine their competition. They took
bird's nests, cotton, silk yarn-and black pepper equal part in a slave trade in Southeast Asia that specialized in
to the ship's weight. The Ceulen was small as VOC East the sale ofwomen from the island of Bali.
Indies ships went, less than one-third the size of a typical In general, the VOC's business model consisted of
East India man, as the biggest ships were called. The VOC's using force or the threat of force to extract favorable terms
most lucrative trade was buying Indian doth and selling of trade-preferably a monopoly-from local rulers and
it for spices destined for European or Chinese markets. merchants. The approach was backed up with merciless
As part of its strategy, the VOC captured port cities, punishment of anyone who traded with rivals. The cen-
many such as Malacca in 1641 taken from the Portuguese, trality of violence to their business is captured in a letter
and built others, such as Cape Town, founded in 1652.. It from the governor general of the Dutch East Indies, Jan
held dozens of fortified posts and at times had as many Pieterszoon Coen, in 1614 to the directors of the VOC.
as IOO hundred heavily armed merchant ships cruising Coen, the man later responsible for the effort to extermi-
Indian Ocean waters. By 1669 it had 50,000 employ- nate the Banda Islanders, wrore: ~You gentlemen ought
ees, 10,000 soldiers, and a navy of 40 warships. It con- to know from experience that trade in Asia should be
stituted a privately funded, state-sanctioned, maritime conducted and maintained under the protection and with
empire devoted to commercial gain, a smaller version of rhe aid ofyour own weapons, and those weapons must be
the Zheng family business empire but with more global wielded with the profits gained by the trade. So trade can-
reach and governmental support. not be maintained without war, nor war without trade."
The VOC captains enjoyed a military edge in the Violence half a world away was part of the price for add-
Indonesian archipelago. VOC forces were frequently out- ing a pinch of nutmeg to millions of cakes, sauces, and
numbered, but rarely outgunned. Wherever they could glasses ofcider.
maneuver their big floating fortresses, they could concen- This business strategy worked brilliantly for Coen and
trate firepower enough to destroy a city in hours. In order the VOC. Before it was liquidated amid a morass of cor-
to found their center ofoperations on Java, they destroyed ruption in 1799, the VOC averaged roughly 18 percent
696 CHAPTER 20 The First Global Economy

first had to discard the idea that lending money at interest


was immoral. Hindu, Buddhist, Islamic, and Christian
scripture and tradition include objections to the practice
ofcharging interest, or too much interest, for loans. Jewish
law prohibits lending at interest to fellow Jews, although
not to ochers. Plato, Aristotle, Cicero, the Buddha, Jesus,
Muhammad, and Aquinas all denounced lending at inter-
est, and Confucius disdained money-grubbing ofall sorts.
Luther got his start railing against usury, and early Prot-
estants generally regarded lending at interest as sinful. So
robust banking required cultural change.
In Europe the moral objections and legal prohibitions
Dutch Colonlsts Some merchants settled down in voe colo- against lending at interest weakened in places such as
nies-such as the Dutch merchant Pieter Cnoll, who managed northern Italy, where small fumily banks emerged as early
trade in Batavia, the capital of the Dutch East Indies. Cnoll is
shown here with his half-Dutch, half-Japanese wife, their chil-
as the thirteenth century, and Barcelona (northeastern
dren, and their servants. Spain), where a city-owned bank appeared by 1381. Else-
where in Europe, those objections eroded during the six-
teenth and seventeenth centuries. The intellectual climate
annual profit on the totality of its business. Other com- in which old truths were subject to renewed question-
panies imitated its formula, most notably the English East ing, combined with economic changes that heightened
India Company (EIC). But in its entire career, 1600 to the demand for finance, probably both contributed to
1857, the EiC managed to carry only about one-fifth the this cultural trend. Lending at interest gradually lost its
goods traded by the VOC. taint among Protestants, and eventually Catholics as well,
despite repeated papal pronouncements about the evils
of usury.
BANKS
The Bank of Amsterdam, founded in 1609, was the
As long-distance trade grew in volume and reach, busi- first modern bank. It attracted depositors, cleared debts,
nesses more often needed to finance their operations by offered quick transactions, and maintained public trust
borrowing money. They borrowed to mount large trad-
ing ventures that could realize economies of scale. They
also borrowed to cover the period between their purchase
of goods and the subsequent sale of those goods, which
might be years in trade between Europe and Southeast
Asia or China. So the demand for private finance grew
dramatically after 1500.
New institutions evolved quickly in response to this
demand and governments' constant need for cash to pay
military expenses. Most notable among these institu-
tions were modern banks, bond markets (in which people
traded governments' debt), and stock exchanges (in which
people traded shares ofcompanies). All these institutions
helped both governments and merchants get cash when
they needed it and earn a return on their money when
they didn't need cash.

Banking The Bank of Amsterdam, the first modern bank, was


LENDING AT INTEREST Ofthese, thernostimporcanc
originally located inside the Amsterdam town hall-shown here
were banks. To have a flourishing banking sector, societies in a 1672 painting.
CONSIDERING THE EVIDENCE
mum11111111111111m111u111n1m111111111111111u11mmu1n11m11m1111111111u1u111111u1111111m1UllllllllllUIIIIIIIIIIUIIIIIIIIIIUJIIIIIIIIIUIIIIIIIUlltlHU11Ul1UllllUUIIIIIIUIIUIIUllllllll111111111111111UllmllUlll1111UIUIIIIUllllllll111tlllmlnllllllllnllllllltlllllllllUIIIIIIIUIIIUlll

On the Circulation ofBlood and Money


Usually, the value of a commodity drops when more of For the Italian scholar Bernardo Davanzati, usury
lt is in clrculat!on. However, as the gold and silver mined was Just one of the mischiefs people could make with
in the Americas became more plentiful in Europe, their money. In a 1588 lecture on coins, he described money
value increased because more people demanded cold as the lifeblood of states to illustrate why money must
hard cash instead of accepting bartered goods. Some circulate to retain its value. Although a scientific descrip-
people even began shaving small slivers of metal off of tion of blood circulation eluded Europeans until William
coins before passing them on. Bankers and loan sharks Harvey published his research on the subject In 1628, it
simply lent the money they had in return for a larger was commonly understood that blood moved through
amount of money later. Today that difference is known the heart and lungs to nourish the rest of the body. Over
as interest, but European theologians and politicians a century after Davanzatl delivered his lecture, a Brit-
saw interest as a euphemism for the sin of usury (i.e., ish philosopher named John Toland translated it into
lending at Interest) that should be banned, or at least English, introducing Davanxatl's Ideas to a new gener-
regulated. It seemed right to be paid for a hard day's ation of thinkers and bankers on the other side of the
work or a risky Investment in overseas trade, but making continent. As the center of banking moved from Italy to
money from money struck Christians, Jews, and Muslims England, so did the demand for ideas about how to deal
alike as immoral.
- ______
... ...................................._..
with money problems.
_ _______.......................................... ____
Some grave and famous Authors have call'd Money the Sin- the livingMember ofthe Common-wealth, and to preserve it
ews ofWar and Government; but, in my Opinion, it may be from those Mischiefs which usually befal it, when not care-
more properly stil'dthe Second Blood thereof. [F]or as Blood, fully look'd after; such as Counterfeiting, Monopolizing,
whichis the Juice and Substance ofMeat inthe natural Body, Simony [buying religious privileges), Usury, and the like,
does, by circulating out ofthe greater into the lesser Vessels, already decri'd, and known everywhere. But, ... I shall now
moisten all the Flesh, which drinks it up as parch'd Ground confine my Discourse only to ••• debasing ofCoin.
soaks Rain Water; so it nourishes and restores as much of Source: Bernard o Davaozatl, A Discourse upon Coins, trans. John Toland
it as was dri'd up and evaporated by the natural Heat: In (London: 1696).
like manner, Money, ••. does, by circulating out ofthe richer
Purses into the poorer, furnish all the Nation.... From the ----·--....-....._.... ____
poorer it returns again into the richer Purses; and thus cir- '
' QUESTIONS FOR ANALYSIS
culating without Intermission, it preserves alive the Civil
Bodyofthe Common-wealth. Hence ... every Statemust have
1, How is the circulation of money in a state like the
a quantity of Money, as every Body a quantity of Blood to circulation of blood in a body?
circulate therein. But as the Blood stopping in the Head or 2, Why does Davanzati think that concentrating
the larger Vessels puts the Body naturally into a Consump- money in a few hands is dangerous?
tion, Dropsy, or Apoplexy, etc. so [if] all the Money be only 3, In what ways did ideas about how to manage
in a few Hands, as in those ofthe rich for Example, the State money, and money problems, circulate in
falls unavoidably into Convulsions, and other dangerous ' Europe?
Distempers.... We ought therefore to set a high Value upon ·-······-······-····-···-···-···,.

by reliably allowing anyone ro withdraw a deposit on problem by creating a new bank chat kept accounts of
demand. In 1609, at least Boo different coins circulated merchants' deposits and converted them to a single stan-
in Amsterdam, including copper, silver, and gold coins dard, at first a tally ofwho owed whom how much of an
from dozens of countries as far away as Japan. Doing abstract accounting unit, called bank money. lhis prac-
business amid this diversity of money-like conducting tice reduced transaction costs and attracted yet more busi-
conversations in Boo languages-was enormously ineffi- ness to Amsterdam. The city required merchants to use
cient. The city council ofAmsterdam sought to solve this the bank for all big transactions. Soon the bank routinely
698 CHAPTER 20 The First Global Economy

standing armies put pressure on royal treasuries. Borrow-


ing was one of the few solutions monarchs could find. If
che costs of, say, five years ofcampaigning could be spread
out over the next 50 years, then the need to raise taxes
would not be so sharp, making tax revolts less likely. Early
modern monarchs had every reason to wish to see healthy
banking systems in their countries. The Habsburgs had
relied heavily on the banking house of Fugger to attain
and retain power.
In practice, northwestern European monarchs, and
the Dutch Republic, had the most extensive banking sys-
tems to draw upon. Creditworthiness became a strategic
asset for states: in the eighteenth century, bankers lent the
British government money at half the rate they charged
the French Crown. Indeed, the British government's rep-
Financial Power A detail of an illustration of Jacob Fugger's lav"
ishly decorated house in Augsburg shows visitors bowing before utation for repaying debts enabled it co spend as much on
the powerful merchant, Fugger is a key example of someone who war as could the far larger Qing empire: it could borrow
leveraged the opportunities presented by long-distance trade
and rulers' need for loans to amass vast wealth, at low rates and the Qing could not borrow at all. Banks
kept kings and governments solvent, and kings and gov-
ernments, ifthey paid their debts, helped keep banks prof-
lent out more money than it held, a practice typical of itable. Governments without access to banks, or deemed
modern banks called fractional reserve banking. This poor credit risks by bankers, struggled financially.
innovative, expansive practice had the effect of creating Large-scale plantations, joint-stock companies, and
money in the form of credit; although if all depositors banks were among the new business formats that devel-
demanded their money at the same time, the bank would oped in response to the opportunities and challenges pre-
be unable to pay. To avoid this problem, any bank engaged sented by the Global web. Partnerships and family-run
in this practice had to maintain a solid reputation, as the businesses survived, of course. But they could not take
Bank ofAmsterdam did for nearly 200 years. Fractional full advantage ofpotential economies of scale in produc-
reserve banking helped lubricate the wheels ofcommerce tion, commerce, and finance that resulted from the newly
by making credit more easily available to merchants. global reach of ships, the connections among far-flung
markers, and che frequent need for ready cash on the part
BANK NOTES AND CREDIT Bank notes boosted of kings and merchants.
commerce too. The Bank of Amsterdam did not issue
paper money. Other banks had cried and found custom-
ers mistrustful, often rightly so. Banks sometimes would
print coo many notes and then refuse co honor chem. Bur
GLOBAL LINKS AND
the Bank of Sweden in the 1670s, and then the Bank of COMMERCIAL REVOLUTIONS
England, founded in 1694, managed to win public trust
in bank notes. They successfully lobbied for government In eastern Canada about 1680, a Mi'kmaq told a French
monopoly rights on printing bank notes and issued chem priest, "In truth, my friend, the beaver does everything to
only in modest quantity. Both fractional reserve banking perfection. He makes for us kettles, axes, swords, knives,
and the use of paper money-if trusted-expanded the and gives us drink and food without the trouble of cul-
amount of money in circulation and reduced the trans- tivating the ground." By trapping beaver and selling fur,
action costs of commerce. Mi'kmaqs and other Amerindians could buy an array
Banks often found that their best cusromers were kings. of useful goods produced across the Atlantic in Europe.
As we've seen, the spiraling costs of warfare, navies, and A Khoisan raising cattle in South Africa or a Dayak in
Which world regions experienced commercial revolutions, and why? G99

during the Song dynasty (960-1279). This second one,


under the late Ming and then the Qing, was something of
an economic miracle. China doubled its population with-
out impoverishing it. This was achieved partly by conquest
of new lands, not only in Mongolia and Tibet (econom-
ically not all that helpful) but also in western Sichuan
and other southwestern lands populated by non-Han
minorities. China absorbed, killed off, or pushed out these
peoples and put their lands to more intensive use with
state-of-the-an agricultural technologies. This resulted in
more rice paddies and millet fields, and less swampland,
forestland, and grassland-hence a bigger economy and
more tax receipts for the emperors.
But even more than frontier conquest and territorial
Chinese Commercial Revolution In this 1696 painting, a peasant
and a water buffalo prepare the soil for rice planting. The poem in
expansion, China builc its economy through increased
the upper left praises the farm tool depicted, which flattens the commercialization of both agriculture and manufactur-
ground. New, intensive agricultural practices enabled late Ming ing. Regions came to specialize more in certain products,
and Qing China to become more commercialized.
such as tea or cotton, and to import their food from else-
where in China or even Vietnam. Most of chis special-
Borneo gathering sandalwood might have said much the ization and exchange took place within China. Bue some
same thing. They all found advantages in caking part in of it linked up to foreign markets, especially for silk and
global commerce, selling something they were good at porcelain.
producing in order to buy other things they could not The Ming and Qing governments had ambivalent
easily produce. People had taken part in such exchanges views about foreign trade. Sometimes they tried to ban
for millennia before 1500. But now more people did so it, and sometimes they encouraged it. In the 1560s the
more often, and over longer distances.
During the early modern centuries (1500-1800) the
world's trade networks fused into one giant, but patchy,
commercial web. Regular shipping linked places chat
had previously been isolated, such as Caribbean islands
or southernmost Africa. Strong links emerged across the
Atlantic where none had existed before, such as the trade
routes between Mexico and Spain, or Angola and Brazil.
New routes also spanned the Pacific between Acapulco and
Manila. Strong links also developed where only weak ones
had existed before, such as between south China and the
Philippines or between Atlantic Europe and West Africa.
These links and shifts to a more commercial orientation
touched some places more than others. The commercial
transformation ran deepest in coastal China and Atlantic
Europe, ac the two ends of the Eurasian landmass.

CHINA Chinese Manufacturing Chinese goods manufactured in large


industrial workshops, such as those in the town of Guangzhou,
Between 1550 and 1800, China underwent a second could be traded worldwide. Guang;,:hou's manufacturing district
commercial revolution. The first one had occurred is shown here in an 1807 painting.
600 CHAPTER 20 The First Global Economy

Ming rescinded an earlier ban, helping to create a surge in and large they were not. Bur their societies were richer and
foreign trade. Restrictions returned, but under the Qing included more prosperous families, generally merchant
between the 1680s and 1760s foreign trade again gener- families and owners of agricultural estates. In Atlantic
ally met with official approval and grew apace. Shipping Europe, but less so in China, rulers became more respon-
from south China to Manila tripled from 1684 to 1715, to sive to the wishes ofcommercial elites, nowhere more so
some 20 ships per year. Silver imports increased by nearly than the Dutch Republic, where the rulers and the com-
sixfold between 1728 and 1800, and exports increased by a mercial elite were the same people.
similar proportion. By 1800, some IO percent of Chinese
grain, 25 percent ofcotton, 90 percent ofsilk, and 95 per-
OTHER REGIONS IN THE
cent of tea was produced for markets, whether domestic
or foreign. Only a few other spots in the world matched
GLOBAL ECONOMY
this degree of commercialization. India's connections also expanded after 1500, thanks
above all to the cotton trade. They now reached to the
Americas and West Africa, although rather thinly. The
ATLANTIC EUROPE
older links to Southeast Asia, East Africa, and Southwest
One was Atlantic Europe, which also underwent a com- Asia only strengthened, although some ofthe actual con-
mercial revolution. Here, as in China, frontier expansion necting was now done by European merchants, including
played a role. Some settlement and agricultural expansion the VOC. In general, India's position with respect to the
took place in drained wetlands in Europe, especially in world's webs changed less than coastal China's or Atlan-
England, the Netherlands, and along Baltic shores. But tic Europe's: it had long been tightly linked throughout
the main thrust came overseas. The plantation zones of the Indian Ocean trading world, by foreigners-Malays,
Brazil and the Caribbean were under the control ofAtlan- Persians, and Arabs mainly-as much as by Indian mer-
tic Europeans. By the 1690s, smaller plantation regions chants, and that remained true after 1500, although the
were taking shape in South Carolina (rice) and around the foreigners involved now sometimes included Europeans.
shores of the Chesapeake (tobacco). Most of the wealth Those parts of India where cotton growing, spinning,
squeezed from plantations enriched Atlantic Europeans. and weaving were concentrated-Gujarat and Bengal
But, as in China, the heart of the commercial revolu- especially-became yet more commercial in orientation.
tion in Atlantic Europe took place at home. Ever-larger So did Kerala, in the southwest, where peasants and land-
shares of agricultural harvests went to nearby markets. owners found that raising peppers for export and buy-
Wool and cotton textile businesses expanded. In Atlantic ing food was a preferable strategy to subsistence food
Europe as a whole, the proportion ofpeople working the production.
land in 1500 was about 75 to 80 percent-less in the Neth- Europe east of the Elbe River also underwent a shift
erlands, more in Iberia. By 1750 that proportion had fallen to a more commercial economy after 1500 or 1550. Land-
to about 60 percent, and in England and the Netherlands owners in Prussia, Poland-Lithuania, and Russia devel-
was well under hal( Manufacturing and services made up oped big grain-producing estates and sold their harvests co
the rest, both attuned almost entirely to market produc- cities around the Baltic and in Atlantic Europe. Like the
tion. Market towns sprouted and financial centers, such as plantations ofthe Americas, these estates relied on forced
Antwerp, Amsterdam, and London, flourished. By 1600, labor. Peasants-called serfs because they were legally
even bulk items were traded over long distances, such as tied to the land and not free to leave-increasingly were
grain from Poland to Amsterdam or to north Italian cities. required to work several days a week on their landlord's
This slow but steady march toward market societies in estate. In Russia, serfs could also be bought and sold, and
China and Atlantic Europe distinguished them from the their status differed little from that of slaves in Brazil or
rest ofthe world. Elsewhere, except in the plantation zones the Caribbean. Landlords also monopolized the right to
and India's cotton districts, markets and commercial pro- make alcohol from excess grain and sell it. Commercial-
duction existed in pockets but did not pervade societies. ization in eastern Europe was agrarian: it did not lead to
This did not mean ordinary people in Atlantic Europe rapid urban growth but to the proliferation ofbig estates,
and coastal Chinawere better off than those elsewhere. By each one a world unto itself but with ties to ports and
Which world regions experienced commercial revolutions, and why? 601

through them to overseas urban markets-again like the


plantations of the Americas.
Southwest Asia before the 1490s had stood at the cen-
ter of the Old World web, a crossroads of trade, travel,
and information. Under Ottoman control by 1550, this
region together with Egypt had long been among the
most commercialized in the world-since the cloth
workshops ofancient Sumer. By 1800, it was still closely
linked to neighboring lands, and by sea to the Indian
Ocean's ports. But the biggest flows ofworld trade now
passed it by. The relative importance of caravan trade
across the steppe lands ofAsia declined, even if absolute
quantities did not. Trade and information flows else-
where in the world-across the Atlantic, for example, or
between China and Southeast Asia-grew far faster than
The Fur Trade An 1845 watercolor depicts a white trapper and
anything involving Southwest Asia. Its economic impor- his Amerindian family navigating the waters of interior North
tance in the world dwindled, and its former advantages in America. Mixed families like this worked at the source of what
was a transatlantic trade in furs.
access to information about distant markets and foreign
technologies disappeared. In a sense, Atlantic Europe
dethroned Southwest Asia between 1500 and 1800. were thoroughly enmeshed in the commercial web that
One indication of that change is the connections in now spanned the globe. By 1800 even some small-farming
which Africa was enmeshed. Before 1500, Africa's stron- districts, such as those of southern New England, were
gest linkages, by far, were with Southwest Asia, both by substantially market oriented and took part in a transat-
land via Egypt and by sea. But in the course of the next lantic economy that extended not only to Atlantic Europe
few centuries, while these connections persisted, stronger but to the Caribbean and West Africa too. Many of the
ones developed linking Africa to Atlantic Europe and to Amerindian peoples had also linked up to market econo-
India, mainly in the form of the slave and cotton trades. mies, whether through the mines ofthe Spanish Empire,
Nonetheless, the bulk ofAfrica's economies, devoted the fur trade ofFrench North America, or a deerskin trade
to farming and pastoralism, bore little connection to the that thrived in the Carolinas in the eighteenth century.
outside world except for the gradual spread ofAmerican Only a few people in 1800, maybe 2 to 4 million in all the
food crops. Most families produced for themselves. Few Americas, conducted their economic lives locally without
sought to maximize production in the ways that Chinese reference to distant markets.
or Indian cotton-producing peasants did in response to This patchiness of the global economic web carried
market incentives. The African entrepreneurs attuned consequences that we will return to in later chapters. The
to distant markets were mainly slave traders or in the most momentous of them flowed from the fact that by
elephant-hunting and ivory export business. They were the late eighteenth century the most connected place of
just as ruthless profit-maximizers as Dutch VOC trad- all-not the happiest, not the most just, not the best in
ers or Gujarati cotton merchants, but this culture of any moral sense, but the most connected-was Atlantic
commercialism was a rarity in Africa. Where the vio- Europe.
lence and commercial opportunities ofthe slave trade did
not intrude, African economic life was more stable, less
dynamic and disruptive, and less market oriented than in
either coastal China or Atlantic Europe. CONCLUSION
The Americas, in contrast, became much more pow-
erfully, and disruptively, connected to the wider world In the three centuries after 1500, a true global economy
between 1500 and 1800. The plantation zones, the mining developed for the first time in world history. Like all eco-
regions, and the northern lands devoted to the fur trade nomic shifts, it benefited some and hurt ochers.

You might also like