Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 9

Journal of Development Economics 87 (2008) 300 – 308

www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase

The growth–inequality association: Government ideology matters


Christian Bjørnskov
Department of Economics, Aarhus School of Business, University of Aarhus, Prismet, Silkeborgvej 2, DK-8000 Aarhus C, Denmark
Received 29 August 2006; received in revised form 19 April 2007; accepted 29 April 2007

Abstract

This note suggests that the association between income inequality and economic growth rates might arguably depend on the
political ideology of incumbent governments. Estimates indicate that under leftwing governments, inequality is negatively
associated with growth while the association is positive under rightwing governments. This may provide a qualification to recent
studies of inequality.
© 2007 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

JEL Classification: D31; O40


Keywords: Income inequality; Ideology; Growth

1. Introduction conflicting findings: depending on the specific research


design and sample, inequality is either bad for growth,
Economic growth theory has suggested a number of good for growth, or perhaps irrelevant. To understand
objective channels leading from inequality to economic these seemingly incompatible findings, it may be worth
growth and performance: incentive structures may suffer noting that differences in political ideology continue to
from combating inequality (Kaldor, 1956; North, 1991; be reflected in individuals' beliefs about, for example,
Olson, 1996), human capital accumulation can be income inequality and the resulting political and eco-
hindered (Perotti, 1993; Barro, 2000), inequality may nomic outcomes (Scott et al., 2001; Michelbach et al.,
cause political instability and distortions from increased 2003; Bjørnskov, 2005). However, the potential effects
government activity (Persson and Tabellini, 1992, 1994; of governments' political ideologies on the relation
Perotti, 1996), and the quality of the legal system can be between inequality and growth remain uncharted land.
undermined by social polarization (Keefer and Knack, The question explored in this note is to what extent
2002).1 While the theoretical literature is rich in governments' political ideology affects the inequality–
transmission mechanisms to be explored in empirical growth association. The standard theoretical treatment
studies, these studies have yielded a mass of mutually of politics in the inequality literature deals with median
voter effects of income inequality on government policy
E-mail address: ChBj@asb.dk. (Persson and Tabellini, 1992; Perotti, 1996). While it is
1
Aghion et al. (1999) go through virtually all arguments for a a priori valid to take the view that income inequality
negative association between inequality and growth, thereby providing leads voters to demand more redistribution, either
an excellent survey of the literature from the 1990s. Yet they dismiss
Forbes' (2000) positive findings as a pure effect of her estimation through transfers and progressive taxation, public
strategy (GMM) and fail to discuss Barro's (2000) equally positive goods provision or some third mechanism, the ideolog-
results, both of which were available as working papers at the time. ical position of the incumbent government might play a
0304-3878/$ - see front matter © 2007 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.jdeveco.2007.04.002
C. Bjørnskov / Journal of Development Economics 87 (2008) 300–308 301

role in this mechanism. At least two reasons for section. For this purpose, both economic data and a
ideologically differential effects can be thought of: measure of political ideology are needed. On the latter
1) the likelihood of introducing redistributive policies point, I follow the general approach in Bjørnskov (2005)
may vary with partisan differences; and 2) even if the by using national election results categorized in the
median voter demands such redistribution, the way Beck et al. (2001) Database of Political Institutions,
that redistributive policies are designed and imple- which defines the three largest government parties in
mented may differ substantially according to partisan 178 countries at any time between 1975 and 2000
preferences. according to whether they have a leftwing, centrist or
As such, even if redistributive policies with similar rightwing political orientation. By coding leftwing
intentions are introduced to affect the existing income parties − 1, centrist parties 0, and rightwing parties 1,
distribution, their growth effects could potentially differ and weighting single party ideologies with their share of
across government ideologies. For example, casual seats in parliament, a proxy of the self-professed relative
observations of differences across the US would suggest ideology of governments can be obtained. In order to
that Democrat administrations probably favor redistri- make the measure comparable across time, I average
bution through direct transfers to the relatively poor these scores over five-year periods for which data are
while Republican administrations, perhaps best exem- available.2 The resulting index is distributed between
plified by the Reagan governments, tend to favor tax − 1 and 1, where countries that have had a fully leftwing
cuts and exemptions as a way to boost possibilities for government throughout the period are assumed to have a
all citizens. As such, ideologically implemented redis- population in which the majority has leftwing sympa-
tributive policies could have very different incentive thies and ideology and which defines the policy set.
effects. It must be stressed that measures of political ideology
However, redistributive policies are not the only only make sense where voters are free to vote for
candidates for how ideology could mediate the effects of whomever they choose and thus reveal their true
inequality. To the extent that inequality breeds social preferences. Likewise, the measure only reflects the
unrest and thus lowers growth, an observable part of the ideological content of government policies in the
unrest in the form of strikes and riots may arguably absence of extra-parliamentary influences such as the
depend on how receptive the government is to such military or other de facto non-elected powers. Hence,
problems. Given that leftwing governments historically even though there is little reason to believe that specific
have closer ties to labor unions and other organizations policies differ between democracies and non-democra-
responsible for part of such unrest, the growth effects of cies (cf. Mulligan et al., 2004), the full sample used in
this type of inequality-induced problems may also differ this paper only includes observations from countries that
with government ideology. A third option could arise if have been democratic in any given five-year period
leftwing governments facing high inequality prioritize between 1975 and 2000, defined as having an average
redistribution over the protection of property rights, as score in a five-year period on the Gastil index of less
has recently been the case in certain Latin American than three (Freedom House, 2005). Alternatively, I use a
countries and most clearly in the Venezuela of Hugo smaller sample of countries that have been democratic
Chavez. Undermining property rights or prioritizing by this criterion in at least four of the five periods in
other policies than institutional improvements would question. The stricter exclusion criterion is applied to
also tend to lower growth in the medium run, creating an avoid a number of potential problems of newly-
association between inequality and growth depending democratic countries in which voters may not be
on political ideology. A number of other possible accustomed to the democratic process, where political
narratives could be told, implying that the effects of
income inequality vary across different types of 2
governments. The overall possibility that the inequali- Averaged over longer periods of time, this measure is also likely to
roughly correspond to the political ideology of the median voter and
ty–growth association is mediated through the political may therefore proxy for his or her tolerance of inequality. It should be
ideology of the incumbent government is what is tested noted that data from the Comparative Manifestos Project may be an
in this note. alternative source of political ideology. However, these data to a larger
extent depend on the actual situation in countries as, for example, the
2. Data and estimation strategy Democratic Party in the US seems to put more focus on labor unions
than e.g. Scandinavian socialist parties, the reason being that union
membership is high in Scandinavia. Such complications make the
The potential implications for economic growth simple ideology measure adopted here preferable as it is relatively
outlined in the introduction are tested in the next free of context.
302 C. Bjørnskov / Journal of Development Economics 87 (2008) 300–308

parties may not yet have formed clear ideological variables in all regressions include a number of standard
positions, where voters initially may chose to elect the factors found in the growth literature. It consists of the
opposite political side as a protest against former non- logarithm to GDP per capita to control for conditional
democratic governments, and increases in the political convergence, openness to trade (volume in percent of
voice of relatively poor groups in society (cf. Lindert, GDP), the real investment price level, defined as the
2004), all of which could give rise to spurious findings investment price level as a ratio of the general price
pertaining to the ideology measure. level, population growth, ethnic diversity, government
In the following, I estimate a set of standard Barro consumption (percent of GDP), and dummies for the
regressions of growth across the five five-year periods postcommunist countries, Asia, Sub-Saharan Africa,
between 1975 and 2000, relying on generalized least North Africa and the Middle East and Latin America, as
squares estimates with random effects while also well as for the time periods. 5 All variables are
reporting the fixed effects estimates. With random summarized in the Appendix; Table A1 gives descrip-
effects, most relevant country-specific characteristics tive statistics and Table A2 reports the sources.
should be sorted out while allowing for stable levels of A potential reason to worry would be multicollinear-
inequality to have some long-run effects.3 In these ity if either a rightwing ideology leads to less effective
regressions, the ideology measure is added to a set of redistribution, or if some confounding variable – for
standard control variables and a measure of income example cross-national differences in culture, social
inequality, as well as an interaction term to take into norms or mental models – affects both. However, the
account the potentially heterogeneous effect of inequal- correlation between inequality and political ideology is
ity. As such, given the control of ideological reactions, only .07–.09 in the two samples, indicating that even
any ‘pure’ effects of income inequality, such as those though the association might be statistically significant,
arising from capital market imperfections, should be it is hardly substantial in economic terms.6 Even though
measured with greater accuracy when taking ideology multicollinearity may not be a problem here, I rescale
into account. ideology and inequality by centering them on their
Inequality is measured by comparable Gini coeffi- means and dividing by their standard deviations. As
cients in any five-year period taken from the World such, all associations are evaluated around the sample
Income Inequality Database (UNU, 2005), which is means and are therefore relevant to the typical country
mainly based on the Deininger and Squire (1996) although the findings may not apply in the tails of the
dataset. Specifically, I use Gini coefficients based on inequality distribution (cf. Brambor et al., 2006).
gross income, following Deininger and Squire's (1996)
approach of adding 6.6 to coefficients estimated using 3. Results
data on expenditure instead of income.4 The control
As a first indication of the possible association
between income inequality and growth, the simple
3
In general, Hausmann tests favor the use of fixed effects
correlation in the present sample is a meager − .02.
(Chi2 = 150.03 in the large sample and 52.89 in the smaller sample), However, splitting the sample as in Fig. 1 reveals the
which I therefore report in a separate panel. However, neither the possible story to be told. In the figure, the observations
estimate on political ideology nor that on the interaction term differ with governments to the left of the political middle are
significantly between the two methods. What instead appears to be
driving the Hausmann test difference is the convergence term, which
is strongly negative in the fixed effects estimates, while other control
5
variables remain the same. As such, I mainly report the random effects In the present sample, the correlation between ethnic diversity and
estimates since they are likely to pick up more of the long-run effect inequality is .44. The inclusion of ethnic diversity may therefore
of inequality. potentially be important, as income inequality could proxy for effects
4
The use of gross income instead of net income or other measures pertaining to ethnically diverse countries, with the exception of fixed
is chosen due to theoretical considerations. In particular, Atkinson and effects estimates.
Brandolini (2001, 789–790) note that “differences across countries, 6
Regressing inequality on political ideology, the logarithm to initial
and across time, are to be expected as a result of differences in GDP and initial GDP squared, i.e. estimating a Kuznets curve, shows
government fiscal policies and in tax incidence” which could give rise that government ideology is not significantly associated with Gini
to spurious findings as “a more progressive tax system may cause coefficients based on gross income. While the present sample of
behavioral reactions that widen the distribution of market income”. democratic countries shows some support for the curve, the turning
Furthermore, in the context of voting behavior voters do not observe a point is rather low, indicating that inequality becomes negatively
potential pre-policy income distribution, but only the distribution after associated with economic development at an average income of about
all policies have had their effect, which is necessarily what they act USD 4500, which is less than half of the average in the present
politically on. sample.
C. Bjørnskov / Journal of Development Economics 87 (2008) 300–308 303

Fig. 1. Ideology, inequality and growth.

marked with a circle while the ideologically opposite line). At a very first glance, government ideology thus
observations are marked with triangles. Drawing simple seems to mediate the growth-inequality association.
regression lines through these two clusters of points Turning to the empirical findings, Table 1 shows the
reveals that the association is negative for the former results of estimating the growth model with the upper
group (the full line) and positive for the latter (the dotted panel reporting the full results of employing random

Table 1
Main results
Sample 1 2 3 4
Gastil b= 3 Four periods
Log initial GDP − 1.5118⁎⁎⁎ (.5273) − 1.3166⁎⁎⁎ (.5048) −.8552⁎ (.4994) − .7417 (.4974)
Postcommunist − 4.0274⁎⁎⁎ (1.0334) − 4.0667⁎⁎⁎ (.9866)
Openness to trade .0175⁎⁎⁎ (.0065) .0172⁎⁎⁎ (.0062) .0109⁎⁎ (.0053) .0097⁎ (.0053)
Population growth − .1403⁎⁎ (.0570) − .1526⁎⁎⁎ (.0549) −.1172⁎⁎ (.0539 − .1257⁎⁎ (.0529)
Ethnic diversity − 2.4454 (1.5551) − 1.7923 (1.4713) .0096 (1.0468) .0366 (1.0569)
Investment price − .9129⁎⁎ (.4664) − .8718⁎ (.4489) −.4348 (.6685) − .2245 (.6517)
Government consumption − .0138 (.0321) − .0146 (.0309) −.0472 (.0316) − .0540⁎ (.0308)
Inequality .0659 (.3815) − .1146 (.3725) −.1537 (.4146) − .3989 (.4094)
Political ideology .4649⁎⁎ (.2361) .6896⁎⁎⁎ (.2382) .3146 (.2194) .5654⁎⁎ (.2243)
Ideology⁎inequality 1.0258⁎⁎⁎ (.2849) 1.0381⁎⁎⁎ (.2937)
Observations 228 228 170 170
Countries 73 73 38 38
R square within .267 .294 .179 .233
R square between .215 .299 .369 .433
Chi squared 65.00 81.18 51.13 65.83

Fixed effects estimates


Inequality .7340⁎ (.4303) .5595 (.4217) .7474 (.4616) .4583 (.4550)
Political ideology .3428 (.2352) .6658⁎⁎⁎ (.2511) .2261 (.2258) .5697⁎⁎ (.2439)
Ideology⁎ inequality .9893⁎⁎⁎(.3197) 1.0219⁎⁎⁎ (.3253)
R square within .475 .508 .324 .376
Note: Random effects GLS estimates in upper panel; fixed effects estimates in lower panel include full specification. ⁎⁎⁎ (⁎⁎) [⁎] denotes significance
at p b .01 ( p b .05) [ p b .10]. All regressions include dummies for Asia, Sub-Saharan Africa, North Africa and the Middle East and Latin America, and
period dummies.
304 C. Bjørnskov / Journal of Development Economics 87 (2008) 300–308

effects while the fixed effects estimates on the central Bjørnskov (2005) although the present study uses
variables are reported in the lower panel. Columns 1 and shorter time periods. What is more, the association
3 report the results of a standard specification while with political ideology increases with the level of
columns 2 and 4 add the interaction term. Columns 1 inequality or, stated alternatively, the growth-inequality
and 2 report the results estimated on the democratic association depends crucially on both the direction and
sample, which consists of 74 countries, and columns 3 strength of the ideology of the government. The results
and 4 report the results using the smaller sample of 38 in Table 1 thus provide support for the hypothesis
countries with a longer democratic history. brought forward in this note.
First, the results of the control variables are fairly The fixed effects estimates presented in the lower
standard. Postcommunist countries grow slower, as the panel of the table serve to corroborate these results.
observations from these countries are necessarily from While some of the control variables may change (not
the 90s in which they went through their transition to shown), the central coefficient estimates on ideology,
market economy; this is also the obvious reason why inequality, and the interaction term do not change
they are all excluded from the smaller sample. The significantly, only the ideological value around which
coefficient on the initial income level is always negative the effect of inequality turns positive. Whereas the
but only strongly significant in the full sample. Ethnic random effects estimates suggest that government
diversity also fails to be significant, although being ideology has to be slightly to moderately rightwing
close to significance in the full sample. Openness, on the (.25–.5), the alternative estimates in the lower panel
other hand, is significant throughout as is population show that ideology only has to pass a point of being
growth, which exerts a negative influence. Second, two
variables are more doubtful: the real investment price is
significant only in the larger sample and government
Table 2
consumption exerts a significant negative effect in only Robustness tests
one case in the smaller sample of countries with a
Political Inequality Ideology⁎ Observations/
democratic history. While the first lack of significance in
ideology inequality countries Chi
the smaller sample may be due to the substantially squared
smaller variation in countries with a long democratic
Without:
history, the latter probably reflects that the average Outliers .5472⁎⁎⁎ .3492 1.1521⁎⁎⁎ 206/69
income level is substantially larger in this sample, and (.1713) (.2743) (.2049) 138.34
that the adverse effects of government consumption Sub- .5557⁎⁎ .1051 .7459⁎⁎ 212/64
either only arise in relatively rich countries or that data Saharan (.2546) (.3781) (.3217) 72.87
Africa
are sufficiently comparable between these countries to
Latin .7925⁎⁎ −.3734 1.2249⁎⁎ 170/53
identify the effect (cf. Fölster and Henrekson, 2001; America (.3133) (.4109) (.3722) 99.31
Schaltegger and Torgler, 2006). GDP b 6000 .7323⁎⁎ .1185 .9897⁎⁎ 159/45
Continuing to the purpose of this note, the results in USD (.3286) (.4324) (.4095) 85.01
columns 1 and 3 reflect the difficulty of the literature in
Including:
documenting a robust association between growth and
Schooling .5559⁎⁎ .1503 .9339⁎⁎⁎ 217/66
income inequality. Both estimates are negative but are (.2340) (.3839) (.2904) 61.09
far from being significant. Political ideology, on the Economic .4906⁎⁎ .0259 .8344⁎⁎⁎ 226/71
other hand, is strongly significant in the larger sample in freedom (.2251) (.3454) (.2663) 120.02
columns 1 and 2 while failing to be significant in Investments .6605⁎⁎⁎ −.0268 .9975⁎⁎⁎ 228/73
(.2365) (.3714) (.2829) 87.73
column 3. However, this changes in columns 2 and 4
Transfers .6229⁎⁎⁎ .2865 1.1603⁎⁎⁎ 210/64
that allow for the effects of inequality to vary with the and (.2273) (.3582) (.2914) 72.35
political ideology of the incumbent government. subsidies
First, political ideology per se becomes highly All four .3736⁎ .3309 .9622⁎⁎⁎ 205/59
significant in both samples with almost the same variables (.2185) (.3513) (.2806) 105.65
coefficient, indicating that a half-point change in the Note: Random effects GLS estimates; all estimates include full
index – for example from a centrist to a moderately specification and use the larger sample (Gastil b= 3); ⁎⁎⁎ (⁎⁎) [⁎]
rightwing government – is associated with an improve- denotes significance at p b .01 (p b .05) [p b .10]. Outliers are defined as
observations with residuals larger than ÷1.5 standard deviations;
ment in the growth rate of approximately half a excluding all observations from Sub-Saharan Africa yields the smallest
percentage point, or about a fifth of a standard deviation. conditional association with inequality, excluding those from Latin
The estimate is therefore of about the same size as that in America yields the largest.
C. Bjørnskov / Journal of Development Economics 87 (2008) 300–308 305

moderately leftwing (around − .5) for inequality to be inequality — schooling, economic freedom, invest-
positively associated with economic growth. As such, ments and a measure of transfers and subsidies as
while the findings are substantially different from much percent of GDP to control for the potential influence of
of the inequality literature, they still generate the direct redistributive policies. First, none of the
standard picture that the use of fixed effects techniques additional variables yield the main findings insignifi-
is much more likely to show that inequality is beneficial cant even if entered jointly. Even the inclusion of the
to growth. The qualitative results, on the other hand, do measure of transfers and subsidies, which in itself (not
not differ between the two sets of estimates.7 shown) is far from significant, does not affect the
The findings in Table 1 clearly point towards a central estimates, although it would a priori be treated
differential association with inequality that depends on as a direct measure of the extent of redistributive
the political ideology of the incumbent government, policies. As a very simple first robustness test, the
although the estimates may seem unrealistically large. inclusion of these four variables therefore yields the
However, this finding could in principle be entirely conclusion that inequality is differentially associated to
spurious; Table 2 therefore provides a set of simple growth unaltered.8
robustness tests. In the upper panel, the table reports As a last option, there is a theoretical possibility that
tests for the exclusion of countries from different rightwing governments cause an increase in the
regions of the world and for potential outliers that skewness of the income distribution. While political
could bias the results. The first row reports the results ideology does not seem likely to lead to inequality in the
of excluding the 22 observations with a residual in the present sample,9 the results in Table 3 nevertheless
baseline specification (from Table 1, column 2) larger control for the possible non-linearities explored in
than ± 1.5 standard deviations, which leaves the results Banerjee and Duflo (2003). The random effects
virtually unchanged. In the following rows, I report the estimates indeed show some support for a non-linear
results of excluding all observations from single effect, indicating that particularly high levels of
regions; the table only shows the largest and smallest inequality are associated with slower growth per se.
estimates arising from this exercise. While excluding The fixed effects estimates that take out any long-run
Latin American countries from the sample yields a effects, on the other hand, do not support this finding.
slightly larger interaction term and a somewhat larger Either way, allowing for non-linearities does not change
coefficient on political ideology, the exclusion of the findings in previous tables as political ideology and
observations from Sub-Saharan Africa results in a its interaction with inequality remains significant, linear
significantly reduced interaction term, although it and of the same size throughout. Overall, the additional
remains significant at p b .05. Excluding all low- tests in Tables 2 and 3 therefore leave the main findings
income countries (defined as those with a GDP per unaltered. As they, on the basis of the preliminary
capita less than 6000 USD) also leaves the findings evidence presented in this note, seem robust and causal,
untouched, even though one could have expected either
stronger political polarization in relatively poor
countries or specific problems of human capital and 8
Another robustness issue is that of causality, as it could be the
capital market imperfections to affect the results (cf. case that faster economic growth makes voters more likely to elect
Barro, 2000). rightwing governments and more tolerant of inequality. Ideally, an
instrumental variables approach would be used, but it proved
The following rows of Table 2 report the result of
virtually impossible to find proper instruments for government
including four additional variables often found in ideology. Yet, judging from the literature on partisan politics dating
growth regressions and theoretically connected to back to Nordhaus (1975) and Hibbs (1977), the problem seems
unlikely. Both find that leftwing governments historically have opted
for a high-inflation/low-unemployment/fiscally expansive policy
configuration while rightwing governments opted for the opposite.
7
One might well speculate on the difference between the random As such, even if reverse causality is a natural and omnipresent
and fixed effects estimates. For example, even if inequality is always concern in growth empirics, the existing literature would indicate
insignificant, the positive sign in the latter estimates that only pick up that it would bias the estimates in the present paper in the opposite
short-to-medium run effects tend in the direction of the positive direction.
9
findings in Forbes (2000) while the negative sign in the former tend in The present data display a standard Kuznets curve with turning
the direction of the conclusions from earlier cross-sectional studies. It point at a GDP per capita of approximately 2600 USD. Strong
may therefore seem an a priori valid assertion that inequality can regional effects also pertain – Sub-Saharan Africa (+12 points) and
have negative effects in the long run, for example through its Latin America (+9 points) are more unequal, the postcommunist
influence on median-voter preferences or social trust (cf. Alesina and countries less so (÷6 points) compared to the West – but government
Angeletos, 2005; Zak and Knack, 2001). ideology is not significant.
306 C. Bjørnskov / Journal of Development Economics 87 (2008) 300–308

Table 3
Allowing for non-linearities
Sample 1 2 3 4 5 6
Random effects Fixed effects
Inequality − .0014 (.0036) − .0027 (.0035) −.0027 (.0035) .0066 (.0044) .0049 (.0043) .0049 (.0043)
Inequality squared − .0047⁎⁎ (.0019) − .0051⁎⁎⁎ (.0019) −.0051⁎⁎⁎ (.0019) − .0022 (.0027) −.0021 (.0026) − .0019 (.0026)
Political ideology .0053⁎⁎ (.0024) .0067⁎⁎⁎ (.0023) .0067⁎⁎ (.0029) .0036 (.0024) .0068⁎⁎⁎ (.0025) .0071⁎⁎ (.0031)
Ideology⁎ inequality .0107⁎⁎⁎ (.0027) .0107⁎⁎⁎ (.0027) .0099⁎⁎⁎ (.0032) .0097⁎⁎⁎(.0033)
Ideology⁎ inequality squared −.0001 (.0026) − .0007 (.0035)
Observations 229 229 229 229 229 229
Countries 74 74 74 74 74 74
R square within .210 .237 .237 .477 .510 .510
R square between .352 .453 .452 .024 .015 .015
Chi squared 76.52 98.46 97.98
F statistic 9.98 10.50 10.73
Note: All estimates include full specification and use the larger sample (Gastil b= 3); ⁎⁎⁎ (⁎⁎) [⁎] denotes significance at p b .01 (p b .05) [p b .10].

I therefore discuss the implications of the results in the note. Given that the main findings here apply to both
final section. random and fixed effects estimates, this otherwise
theoretically valid possibility does not seem a likely
4. Conclusions explanation for any medium-run relation between
growth and inequality, although it provides interesting
The lessons of the empirical growth literature have perspectives for long-run growth. Another possibility is
been ambiguous with respect to the effects of income that the findings are spurious, which is addressed by
inequality on economic growth by showing negative, testing their robustness to excluding groups of observa-
positive and zero results. Most theoretical explanations tions and including a small set of additional relevant
of the potentially negative effects of inequality have factors. The findings prove robust to these very simple
rested on the growth-reducing effects of either social tests although it should be noted that the exclusion of
unrest or redistributive government policies introduced five Sub-Saharan African countries reduces the esti-
to combat inequality itself or its social consequences. As mates to a more plausible size. Consequently, as a first
such, the association between inequality and growth impression the results therefore appear to be more than
may arguably be mediated through the reactions of the spurious correlations.
government, yet no studies to date have explored The size of the estimates also warrants attention. In
whether the ideology of the incumbent government the present sample, the mean growth rate is 1.86% per
affects this association. The results presented in this note year, yet the estimates suggest that at the mean income
suggest a necessary qualification to both standard inequality – a Gini coefficient of 39 – a move from a
theoretical explanations of the negative effects of center government, which in most countries would
inequality as well as the positive effects found in recent mean a social democrat government, to a center-left
empirical studies: allowing for the growth-income government would be associated with a reduction of the
inequality association to vary with government ideology annual growth rate of .28 percentage points. Symmet-
reveals that income inequality is likely to be positively rically, a move to a moderately rightwing government as
associated with growth when the incumbent government the current German coalition between social democrats
leans to the political right, but negatively associated and Christian democrats, would imply a similar growth
with growth in the opposite political situation. increase. Yet, in countries with an income inequality
As these findings are new, they must necessarily be five points above the mean, such as Costa Rica or
subject to further scrutiny. In principle, for example, it is Mauritius, these differences increase by about two
entirely possible that the present measure of government thirds, and may thus tend to account for their more
ideology simply proxies for the ideological proclivities unstable growth performance. Alternatively, in countries
of society and thus picks up an effect of the tolerance of with a very equal income distribution such as in
inequality of the median voter (cf. Alesina et al., 2001; Scandinavia, the association between political ideology,
Alesina and Angeletos, 2005). However, such social inequality and growth becomes negligible.
norms are likely to change only slowly over time, and A possible first interpretation of these findings could
probably only little across the five-year periods in this rest on the fact that income inequality as measured by
C. Bjørnskov / Journal of Development Economics 87 (2008) 300–308 307

Gini coefficients is remarkably stable over time, not robustness of the findings as well as which policies
least in democratic countries. Hence, redistributive may generate the results seem potentially fruitful
policies adopted by most countries are probably directions of future research.
relatively ineffective (cf. Rodriguez, 1999); the results With respect to the theoretical considerations fol-
presented here are therefore a priori most likely to lowing from the present findings, most political
indicate a differential relation between growth and economy analyses of the inequality–growth relation
political ideology, depending on the existing level of posit a crucial role of government in mediating the
income inequality. As such, the growth rate may tend to inequality–growth relationship, yet virtually all do so in
increase if a rightwing government comes to power in a a median-voter setting. On a somewhat broader scale,
country with a relatively skewed income distribution, however, there seem to be no good reasons to assume
since it will be less likely to introduce policies aimed at that other economic and political outcomes exist
reducing inequality or increasing the provision of irrespective of the ideology of the government. Given
public goods that could possibly weaken the incentive that the findings in this paper can be replicated by future
structure in society, or it could design and implement studies, one of the many possible ways forward for the
such policies in a less heavy-handed way than political economy literature may therefore be to relax
governments leaning to the political left. Yet, the the assumption that all governments follow similar goals
incentives to introduce such ideological government with similar means and thus to allow for the ideology of
policies depend on the initial inequality in society – the the government to affect real economic relations.
perceived need for redistribution – which could give
rise to heterogeneous effects of ideology as well as a Acknowledgements
negligible growth-ideology association in fairly equal
societies. I am indebted to Niels Buus, Eric Crampton, Mogens
Similar theoretical stories consistent with the Kamp Justesen, Karsten Bjerring Olsen, Anna
empirical findings could be told in at least two other Rubinchik-Pessach, Lant Pritchett, participants at the
areas. First, in the case of the effects of social unrest 2004 meeting of the Public Choice Society and two
caused by inequality such events might be more likely anonymous referees for valuable discussions and
under leftwing governments if either the organizers or comments on previous versions.
participants of e.g. demonstrations perceive such
governments to be more likely to give in to their pres- Appendix A
sure. Second, prioritizing redistributive policies high-
ly could potentially imply assigning low priority to Table A1
other policies such as institutional investments that Descriptive statistics
would be more conducive to growth. Given that such Variable Mean Standard Observations
priorities differ with political ideology, they could deviation
also provide some explanation for the present find- Economic growth .0186 .0254 275
ings. Surely, a number of other parallel theoretical rate
possibilities exist that could be explored in future Log initial GDP 8.9716 .8607 275
(10,612) (7079)
research. Postcommunist .0691 .254 275
It must be stressed that the empirical results are Openness 68.5759 42.5423 275
entirely preliminary and, consequently, so is any Population growth .0619 .0559 274
attempt at interpreting these results. The findings Ethnic diversity .3391 .2269 275
here, which are necessarily short-to-medium run due Investment price 1.4033 .7276 273
Government 17.6563 8.5548 273
to the choice of five-year periods, also do not exclude consumption
the possibility that inequality could have overall Income inequality −.1981 .8959 233
negative effects in the long run. Perhaps most (39.2696) (9.3457)
importantly, given the necessary qualifications the Political ideology .0706 .6916 272
existing literature yields only limited insights into Schooling 7.1235 2.6314 251
Economic freedom 6.3416 1.0339 267
which policies connected to ideological reactions to Investments 18.7566 7.4756 273
inequality may drive the association with growth, Transfers and subsidies 12.2132 8.8672 243
although recent studies have begun exploring the topic Average democracy 1.5748 .6895 275
(cf. Besley and Case, 2003; Lee et al., 2004). Yet, given Note: Numbers in parentheses are GDP per capita and unscaled Gini
the clarity of the findings, empirical explorations of the coefficients.
308 C. Bjørnskov / Journal of Development Economics 87 (2008) 300–308

Table A2 Deininger, K., Squire, L., 1996. A new data set measuring income
Data definitions and sources inequality. World Bank Economic Review 10, 565–569.
Fölster, S., Henrekson, M., 2001. Growth effects of government
Variable Source Description
expenditure and taxation in rich countries. European Economic
Initial GDP per Heston et al. Penn World Tables, Mark 6.1. GDP; Review 45, 1501–1520.
capita (2002) Growth in real GDP; price of Forbes, K., 2000. A reassessment of the relation between inequality
GDP growth investment relative to and growth. American Economic Review 90, 869–887.
Population consumer prices; government Freedom House, 2005. Freedom in the World 2005. The Annual
growth share of GDP; trade volume as Survey of Political Rights and Civil Liberties. Rowman and
Government percent of GDP; investment Littlefield, Lanham.
consumption share of GDP. All data are Gwartney, J., Lawson, R., 2005. Economic Freedom of the World:
Openness adjusted for purchasing power 2005 Annual Report. The Fraser Institute, Vancouver, BC.
Investments and are in 1995 US prices. Heston, A., Summers, R., Aten, B., 2002. Penn World Tables, Version
Democracy Freedom Gastil index from 1 (full political 6.1. Center for International Comparisons (CICUP), University of
House rights) to 7 (no rights). Cut-off for Pennsylvania.
(2005) full rights is a score of 3. Douglas, A., 1977. Political parties and macroeconomic policy.
Inequality UNU Gross income Gini coefficients; 6.6 American Political Science Review 71 (4), 1467–1487.
(2005) is added to estimates based on Kaldor, N., 1956. Alternative theories of distribution. Review of
expenditure data. Economic Studies 23, 83–100.
Ethnic Alesina Probability that two random citizens Keefer, P., Knack, S., 2002. Polarization, politics and property rights.
diversity et al. (2003) share ethnic origin. Links between inequality and growth. Public Choice 111, 127–154.
Political Bjørnskov See text. Lee, D.S., Moretti, E., Butler, M.J., 2004. Do voters affect or elect
ideology (2005) policies? Evidence from the US House. Quarterly Journal of
Economic Gwartney Economic freedom index, distributed Economics 119, 807–859.
freedom, and Lawson from 0 (no freedom) to 10 (full Lindert, P.H., 2004. Growing Public. Social Spending and Economic
transfers and (2005) freedom); transfers and subsidies as Growth since the Eighteenth Century. Cambridge University Press,
subsidies share of GDP. Cambridge.
Schooling Barro and Average years of schooling Michelbach, P.A., Scott, J.T., Matland, R.E., Bornstein, B.H., 2003.
Lee (2001) attainment. Doing Rawls justice: an experimental study of income distribution
norms. American Journal of Political Science 47, 523–539.
Mulligan, C.B., Gil, R., Sala-i-Martin, X., 2004. Do democracies have
References different public policies than nondemocracies? Journal of
Economic Perspectives 18, 51–74.
Aghion, P., Caroli, E., Garcia-Peñalosa, C., 1999. Inequality and Nordhaus, William, 1975. The political business cycle. Review of
economic growth: the perspective of the new growth theories. Economic Studies 42, 169–190.
Journal of Economic Literature 37, 1615–1660. North, D.C., 1991. Institutions. Journal of Economic Perspectives 5,
Alesina, A., Angeletos, G-M., 2005. Fairness and redistribution: US 97–112.
vs. Europe. American Economic Review 95, 913–935. Olson, M., 1996. Big bills left on the sidewalk: why some nations are
Alesina, A., Glaeser, E.., Sacerdote, B., 2001. Why doesn't the US rich, and others poor. Journal of Economic Perspectives 10, 3–24.
have a European-style welfare state? Brookings Papers on Perotti, R., 1993. Political equilibrium, income distribution, and
Economic Acitivity 2001, 187–254. growth. Review of Economic Studies 60, 755–776.
Alesina, A., Devleeschauwer, A., Easterly, W., Kurlat, S., Wazciarg, R., Perotti, R., 1996. Growth, income distribution and democracy: what
2003. Fractionalization. Journal of Economic Growth 8, 155–194. the data say. Journal of Economic Growth 1, 149–187.
Atkinson, A.B., Brandolini, A., 2001. Promise and pitfalls in the use of Persson, T., Tabellini, G., 1992. Growth, distribution and politics.
“secondary” dataset: income inequality in OECD countries as a European Economic Review 36, 593–602.
case study. Journal of Economic Literature 39, 771–799. Persson, T., Tabellini, G., 1994. Is inequality harmful for growth?
Banerjee, A., Duflo, E., 2003. Inequality and growth: what can the data American Economic Review 84, 600–621.
say? Journal of Economic Growth 8, 267–299. Rodriguez, F.C., 1999. Does distributional skewness lead to
Barro, R.J., 2000. Inequality and growth in a panel of countries. redistribution? Evidence from the United States. Economics and
Journal of Economic Growth 5, 5–32. Politics 11, 171–199.
Barro, R.J., Lee, J.-W., 2001. International data on educational attainment: Schaltegger, C.A., Torgler, B., 2006. Growth effects of public
updates and implications. Oxford Economic Papers 53, 541–563. expenditure on the state and local level: evidence from a sample
Beck, T., Clarke, G., Groff, A., Keefer, P., Walsh, P., 2001. New tools of rich governments. Applied Economics 38, 1181–1192.
in comparative political economy: the database of political Scott, J.T., Matland, R.E., Michelbach, P.A., Bornstein, B.H., 2001.
institutions. World Bank Economic Review 15, 165–176. Just deserts: an experimental study of distributive justice norms.
Besley, T., Case, A., 2003. Political institutions and policy choices: American Journal of Political Science 45, 74–767.
evidence from the United States. Journal of Economic Literature UNU, 2005. World Income Inequality Database v2.0. United Nations
41, 7–73. University-World Institute for Development Economics Research,
Bjørnskov, C., 2005. Does political ideology affect economic growth? Helsinki.
Public Choice 123, 133–146. Zak, P., Knack, S., 2001. Trust and growth. The Economic Journal 111,
Brambor, T., Clark, W.R., Golder, M., 2006. Understanding interaction 295–321.
models: improving empirical analyses. Political Analysis 14, 63–82.

You might also like