Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 6

THEMATIC ISSUE ON ECONOMICS OF TOBACCO CONTROL IN THE AMERICAS

Original research Pan American Journal


of Public Health

Implications of raising cigarette


excise taxes in Peru
Martin Gonzalez-Rozada1 and Alejandro Ramos-Carbajales2

Suggested citation Gonzalez-Rozada M, Ramos-Carbajales A. Implications of raising cigarette excise taxes in Peru.
Rev Panam Salud Publica. 2016;40(4):250–5.

ABSTRACT Objective.  To assess how raising cigarette excise taxes in Peru might impact cigarette con-
sumption, and to determine if higher taxes would be regressive.
Methods.  Total demand price elasticity was estimated by income groups using two datasets:
quarterly time-series data from 1993 – 2012 and data from a cross-sectional survey of income
and expenses conducted in 2008 – 2009 . A functional form of the cigarette demand in Peru
was specified using the quarterly data set, and the demand price elasticity was estimated for the
short and long run. Using the second data set and Deaton methodology, the implementation of
elasticity estimation and by groups’ elasticity was done in a two-step procedure.
Results.  Demand price elasticity was −0.7, implying that a 10% price increase via a new tax
would reduce consumption by 7%. Demand price elasticity estimations by income group sug-
gested that poorer families are not more price sensitive than richer ones, which implies that
increasing cigarette taxes could be regressive.
Conclusions.  Increasing cigarette taxes is the most efficient policy for inducing a reduction
in smoking. However, in the case of Peru, an increase in cigarette taxes could be regressive.

Keywords Taxation of tobacco-derived products; consumption of tobacco-derived products;


smoking cessation; health economics; Peru.

Raising taxes on tobacco is by far the through higher taxes, which creates the this burden (4–6). A tax increase may not
more cost-effective policy for reducing ciga- win-win of reduced c­onsumption and in- be regressive if the poor are much more
rette consumption (1, 2). There are at least creased revenue. sensitive to the price change than the rich
two reasons for this: first, raising cigarette However, raising cigarette taxes can are and they respond by quitting smok-
taxes increases government revenue de- also have bad consequences: it can be re- ing or reducing consumption. In this sce-
spite decreasing demand. This is because gressive, meaning that the poor will pay a nario, the change in tax expenditure for
smoking is addictive, and so tax revenue higher percentage of their income to cover the poor would be less than for the rich.
from consumption proportionately sur- the tax than the rich will. Regressivity is Therefore, if the poor have a much larger
mounts the decrease. Second, by increasing an important topic because the tobacco demand price elasticity,3 in absolute
the cost of cigarettes, and thereby reducing industry frequently uses this argument to value, then an increase in cigarette taxes
consumption, the detrimental health effects oppose government policy that might would not be regressive.
of smoking on smokers and non-smokers raise taxes to reduce consumption. How much a tax increase reduces con-
alike are reduced. These impacts support a In most nations, the poor smoke more sumption and whether or not it is regres-
policy of controlling tobacco consumption than the rich do (3). As a result, the poor sive are important empirical questions.
­often spend a substantially larger pro- One can design effective public policy
1
Universidad Torcuato Di Tella, Buenos Aires, portion of their income on cigarettes,
Argentina. Send correspondence to Martin bearing a disproportionate share of the 3
“Price elasticity” measures the sensitivity of
Gonzalez-Rozada, email: mrozada@utdt.edu ­consumption to price changes. If cigarette prices
2
Interamerican Heart Foundation, Montevideo, cigarette tax burden. Therefore, increas- increase, the price elasticity indicates how much
Uruguay. ing the tax disproportionately increases consumption will decrease.

250 Rev Panam Salud Publica 40(4), 2016


Gonzalez-Rozada et al. • Implications of cigarette taxes in Peru Original research

to reduce tobacco consumption by tak- as a control variable in the demand function primary school, 66% secondary school,
ing into account the answers to these for cigarettes. The quarterly series used in and 20% a college degree.
questions. this work corresponds to the average inter-
The objectives of this study were to em- bank exchange rate (sell) of the Central Re- Specifying cigarette demand using
pirically assess how raising cigarette serve Bank of Peru, from the first quarter of time series data
taxes would impact consumption in Peru 1993 to the last quarter of 2012.
and to determine whether or not an in- The average quarterly consumption Specifying a conventional demand func-
crease would be regressive. was about 35 packs of 20 cigarettes, tion for cigarettes requires stationarity of
ranging from a low of 14 packs to a high the individual variables involved. If not,
MATERIALS AND METHODS of 63. The real price in Peruvian Nuevos then the specification of the demand func-
Soles (PEN) varied from PEN 1.00 – tion depends on whether the variables
Datasets 1.75, with the real median price of PEN contain a common trend or not. For a com-
1.45 over the whole sample. Note that plete description of the functional form of
Two distinct datasets were used for esti- this price was computed as a ratio of the demand for cigarettes, tests, and esti-
mating cigarette demand in Peru. The first two price indices (cigarette price index mation procedures with time series data,
was a time-series database composed of divided by consumer price index) that see Gonzalez-Rozada (11).
quarterly data from 1993–2012. It provided do not have an interpretation regarding The order of integration for each vari-
information on apparent consumption, av- the Peruvian currency. The monthly av- able was identified using the Augmented
erage real price of cigarettes, and the aver- erage real income in the sample was Dickey-Fuller test (ADF) (12). The ADF
age monthly income per rolling quarter around PEN 1 600 (US$ 540), ranging statistic suggests that the apparent con-
reported by the National Institute of Statis- from nearly PEN 1 200–2 000 (US$ 405 – sumption of cigarettes, the average real
tics and Informatics (INEI) of Peru (7). The 676). The average exchange rate in the price, the average real income, and the ex-
second dataset came from the ENAPREF sample was PEN 2.96 : US$ 1.00, and change rate are individually non-station-
2008–2009 (8), a household survey of in- ranged from PEN 1.76–3.50. ary variables. The Johansen test procedure
come and e­ xpenditure that includes ciga- (13–16) was used to check for cointegra-
rette ­expenses and quantities purchase by Cross-sectional database tion between these series. The result of
­individuals in a household. Johansen’s sequential procedure suggests
The ENAPFRE has a module that col- that there is a cointegration relationship
Time-series data lects data on individual spending on cig- between the mentioned variables during
arettes. It quantifies cigarette spending the period under analysis. The specifica-
The consumption of cigarettes variable per person in a household, but does not tion of the demand for cigarettes, in the
was constructed from the macroeconomic identify the smokers. So, for example, it long run, was established by a model for
identity that takes cigarette production is possible that the person who purchases the steady-state path growth of the
and adds to it the cigarette imports and the cigarettes is not the smoker. In this variables.
subtracts the cigarette exports (called ap- regard, the survey can be used to charac- Demand price elasticity (l1) states that
parent consumption) using the data terize the percentage of households with a 1% increase in the real price of ciga-
records of the Superintendencia Nacional de at least one smoker. Of the 35 000 house- rettes reduces consumption by l1%, while
Aduanas y de Administración Tributaria (Na- holds in the survey, a little less than 8% the income elasticity (l2) indicates that a
tional Customs and Taxation Authority). had at least one smoker. 1% increase in a consumer’s real income
Since 2005, the demand for cigarettes in The unit value was computed as the increases the amount consumed by l2% in
Peru has been satisfied mainly by imports ratio between expenditure on cigarettes the long run. In the short-run, the vari-
from Chile, where British American To- and physical quantities bought. The esti- ables may not be in the path of long-run
bacco Chile Operaciones S.A. (Santiago, mation of the demand for cigarettes was equilibrium; therefore, a general model
Chile) has its production plant. performed in two ways, using the quan- was specified that allowed the estima-
The source of the cigarette price series tity of cigarettes purchased by each and tion of the short-run elasticities of ciga-
was the consumer price index (CPI), with the unit value of every purchase. This rette consumption.
the real price of cigarettes computed by same information was aggregated for the The demand price elasticity for the
dividing the CPI of cigarettes by the gen- household level. The methodology ad- short-term (b0) states that a 1% increase
eral CPI as per the INEI (7). These vanced by Deaton (10) was employed. in price causes a drop of b0% in the num-
monthly statistics were then converted to To measure the sensitivity of the ciga- ber of cigarettes consumed in a quarter,
quarterly figures to compute the average rette demand to a price change, individ- while the short-term income elasticity
real price per quarter. uals who reported any spending on (g0) indicates that an increase of 1% in
For the series of income, the average cigarettes and who received income dur- real income of consumers produces an
monthly income per mobile quarter re- ing the reference period of the survey increase of g0 % in the number of ciga-
ported by INEI in its Permanent Employ- were selected. A total of 3 642 people re- rettes consumed in a quarter.
ment Survey (9) was used. This nominal ported having purchased cigarettes dur-
income was transformed in real terms ing the reference week, but of those only Specifying cigarettes demand
using the general CPI. 3 153 also reported some income. There- using cross-sectional data
Given the tobacco market in Peru, where fore, estimations were performed using
cigarette demand is supplied by imports, it this latter group, of which 95% was male Household surveys, such as ENAPREF,
was necessary to include the exchange rate and the level of education was 14% do not report the price of cigarettes. The

Rev Panam Salud Publica 40(4), 2016 251


Original research Gonzalez-Rozada et al. • Implications of cigarette taxes in Peru

ENAPREF asks households to report not that poorer families are not more price 6.9%, and a 10% increase in real income in-
only their spending on each good, but sensitive than richer ones, implying that creases total consumption of cigarettes in
also the physical quantity purchased. increasing cigarette taxes in Peru could the long run by 6.6%.
The ratio of these two figures is a mea- be regressive. The results presented here are similar
sure of price, or more accurately, a unit Some of the characteristics of both to those of other time-series studies of
value. One reason the unit values are not datasets—time series and cross-­sectional— countries in the Region of the Americas
the same as the prices is that unit values follow. Figure 1 shows the evolution of (11, 17–21). Cigarette demand is inelas-
are affected by the level of quality of the the apparent consumption of cigarettes tic to price and income, however, the
product purchased. For example, in the measured in millions of packs of 20 cig- demand price elasticity is a bit larger in
case of a pack of cigarettes, a premium arettes per quarter. Apparent consump- absolute value than the income elastic-
brand costs more than a pack of black tion was highly volatile in these ity. That is, with a growing economy
market ones since, in general, smuggled estimations, as expected, due to abrupt and, therefore, increasing real income
cigarettes are of lower quality. The unit changes made in imports/exports among the population, a more than pro-
values include this quality feature. Unit made by importers, decisions not nec- portional increase in the real price is not
values were computed by dividing the essarily tied directly to cigarette smok- required to cause a drop in cigarette
expenditure by the physical quantities so ing. It is important to reiterate that demand.
that premium cigarettes have higher unit during the study period (and pres-
values. As a result, and in contrast to a ently), there was no national tobacco Cross-sectional estimation results
market price on which the consumer has industry in Peru.
no control, in this case the consumer Table 1 summarizes the main sociode- Table 3 presents estimations of the to-
“chooses” a unit value, at least to some mographic characteristics of the popula- tal demand price elasticity evaluated
extent. In particular, since richer house- tion in the ENAPREF survey used to for the average per-capita household
holds tend to buy higher quality prod- estimate the sensitivity of cigarette de- income and the same elasticity by ter-
ucts, unit values are positively related to mand to price change. In the average ciles of per-capita household income.
income. household, there were four people older The estimations included the following
The basic ideas underlying the than 13 years of age who had purchased control variables: proportion of women
model that allows this estimation can an average of two cigarettes during the over 18 years of age in the household,
be found in the work of Deaton (10). A survey’s reference week. Variability is the proportion of individuals with a
more detailed explanation of the pro- large, showing some households pur- university education in the household,
cedures necessary for price estimation chasing up to 34 cigarettes in the and dummy variables for the location
and income elasticity are explored ­reference week. of the houses.
elsewhere by Ramos-Carbajales and The first tercile corresponds to the group
colleagues (17). Time series estimation results of families with the highest per-capita
spending, and the third tercile to those
RESULTS Table 2 reports that the long-run de- with the lowest. Per-capita spending is a
mand price elasticity of cigarette consump- good approximation of per-capita house-
A demand price elasticity of −0.7 was tion in Peru was −0.689 (P = 0.06), while the hold income, and it follows that the first
found in Peru, implying that increasing long-run income elasticity of cigarette con- tercile is composed of the richest house-
prices by 10%, via taxes, reduces con- sumption was 0.658 (P = 0.06). With these holds and the third tercile, the poorest.
sumption by 7%. Demand price elasticity figures, a 10% increase in real price reduces Table 3 shows an average demand
estimations by income groups suggested total cigarette consumption in the long run price elasticity of −0.738 (P = 0.01) and an
income elasticity of 0.112 (P = 0.01). The
FIGURE 1. Apparent consumption of cigarettes, Peru, 1993 – 2012 income elasticity shown by this study
appears to be lower in magnitude than
70 that found in the literature. The demand
price elasticity is similar to what was
60 found through the time series ­estimation.
Consumption (in millions of

The demand price elasticity by terciles of


packs of 20 cigarettes)

50 per-capita household income shows an


increasing trend. As per-­ capita income
40 increases, the demand price e­lasticity
was larger in absolute value. This evi-
30 dence suggests that richer ­ households
were more sensitive to price changes
20 than the poorest ones, contrary to what
has been assumed and found in the liter-
10 ature for developed countries (18). If unit
1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 values are a good approximation of
­cigarettes prices, these estimates suggest
Consumption of cigarettes
that an increase in cigarette taxes could
Source: Produced by the authors from the study data. be regressive.

Rev Panam Salud Publica 40(4), 2016  252


Gonzalez-Rozada et al. • Implications of cigarette taxes in Peru Original research

TABLE 1. Sociodemographic characteristics of study sample from the National Survey the unit value. The demand price elas-
of Family Budgets (Encuesta Nacional de Presupuestos Familiares) Peru, 2008 – 2009 ticity for the total sample ranged from
−0.675 to −0.800 (P = 0.01). These values
Number of persons
Average quantity of
were similar to both the demand price
Age > 14 years of age in the elasticity estimated assuming that unit
single cigarettes purchased
household
values reflect prices, and the one that
Average 36.2 3.9 2.03 was estimated using time series data.
Median 33.0 4.0 1.14 This evidence generates a certain ro-
Standard deviation 13.7 1.7 2.87 bustness for the study results. If the
Minimum 14.0 2.0 0.15 breakdown by terciles of per-capita
Maximum 88.0 14.0 34.20 household expenditure is considered,
Source: Produced by the authors from the survey data. the picture is similar to the one pre-
sented above. This evidence seems to
suggest that poorer households (or
TABLE 2. Long run price and income elasticity of cigarette demand using quarterly lower per-capita expenditure) do not
data, Peru, 1993 – 2012 have a larger elasticity in absolute value
than households in the first tercile. Thus,
Dependent variable: Lna (consumption of cigarettes) tax increases on the consumption of cig-
Variable T-statistic P-value arettes in Peru are very likely to be re-
Coefficient Standard error
gressive in the sense that the increased
Ln (real cigarette prices) −0.689 0.321 −2.144 0.035
tax burden would fall on the shoulders
Ln (real income) 0.658 0.345 1.907 0.060
of poor more so than on the rich.
Ln (exchange rate) 1.459 0.207 7.056 0.000
The elasticity of total expenditure is
Intercept −2.722 2.513 −1.083 0.282
between 0.19 – 0.22 (P = 0.01), suggesting
Seasonal controls Yes Yes Yes Yes
that a 10% increase in total spending in-
Adjusted R-squared 0.5104
creases cigarette consumption by ap-
F-statistic 42.0724
proximately 2%. The estimate of the
P-value 0.000
quality elasticity with respect to the total
Source: Produced by the authors from the study data. expenditure is about 0.09 (P = 0.01). Both
Note: Least squares estimations. The table shows heteroskedasticity robust standard errors.
a
Natural logarithm.
panels of Table 4 show that the quality
elasticity is statistically significant for
those with the lowest total household
expenditure per capita. This result is
­
TABLE 3. Average price and income elasticity estimations from the Encuesta Nacional expected since when total expenditure
­
de Presupuestos Familiares (National Survey of Family Budgets) Peru, 2008 – 2009 decreases, the expectation is that the
poor are more inclined to reduce quality.
Demand price elasticity, tercile 1 (richer) −0.831a
  (0.00048) DISCUSSION
Demand price elasticity, tercile 2 −0.762a
  (0.00038) This study sought to answer two
Demand price elasticity, tercile 3 (poorer) −0.619a e­mpirical questions: How much does
  (0.00125) raising the price of cigarettes through
Total demand price elasticity −0.738a taxes reduce consumption and would an
  (0.0010) increase in cigarette taxes be regressive?
Income elasticity 0.112a Increasing cigarette taxes is important
  (0.00152) public policy for reducing tobacco use.
Source: Produced by the authors from the study data. The appeal of increasing cigarette taxes is
Note: Figures in parentheses are standard errors computed using the Delta method. obvious. Since smoking is bad for one’s
a
P = 1%. health and for the health of others, in-
creasing taxes can induce people to quit
To see if the unit values are a good ap- age. Included among the variables related or cut back.
proximation for prices, demand price to the individual were the age of the head Using two information sets, we esti-
elasticity was estimated according to of household and age squared, and a set mated the total demand price elasticity to
Deaton’s methodology (10). Estimations of categorical variables indicating gender be −0.7, implying that a 10% increase in
were performed using households and and whether university or secondary the price of cigarettes would reduce con-
individuals as the unit of analysis. Both school education had been attained. sumption by 7%. Since 14 January 2010,
estimations included control variables. Table 4 shows the estimates of the de- Peru has had a specific Selective Con-
Among the variables associated with the mand price elasticity, the total expendi- sumption Tax of PEN 0.07 per unit of
household were the number of people in ture elasticity with respect to the number ­imported cigarette (Supreme Decree 004-
the household and the proportion of of cigarettes consumed, and the total 2010-EF), that is, PEN 1.40 per pack of 20.
males and females older than 18 years of expenditure elasticity with respect to Hence, to increase the retail price of

Rev Panam Salud Publica 40(4), 2016 253


Original research Gonzalez-Rozada et al. • Implications of cigarette taxes in Peru

TABLE 4. Cigarette demand price elasticity and household total expenditure from the consumption, which is highly volatile
sample taken from the Encuesta Nacional de Presupuestos Familiares (National Survey of due to sudden changes made by import-
Family Budgets) Peru, 2008 – 2009 ers that might be completely unrelated to
cigarette smoking. The cross-sectional
  Terciles of per capita expenditure ENAPREF survey did not permit analy-
Total
  First Second Third sis of certain groups by gender or geo-
Estimations by individuals graphic area, which could be relevant. In
  Demand price elasticity −0.800a −0.870a −0.760a −0.900a spite of these limitations and potential
(0.198) (0.160) (0.130) (0.120) biases, the similarities among the time
  Total expenditure elasticity 0.190a 0.240a 0.237a 0.215a series and cross sectional results suggest
(0.030) (0.070) (0.080) (0.060) that the estimations were robust.
 Expenditure elasticity of 0.090a 0.090b 0.006 0.035b
 quality (0.018) (0.050) (0.050) (0.019) Conclusions
Estimations by households
  Demand price elasticity −0.675a −0.810a −0.570a −0.750a Evidence found by this study suggests
(0.212) (0.142) (0.068) (0.142) that implementing an effective policy of
  Total expenditure elasticity 0.218a 0.250c 0.170 0.230a increasing taxes to reduce consumption
(0.030) (0.100) (0.230) (0.070) should be complemented by public health
 Expenditure elasticity of 0.088a 0.013 0.130 0.050c
policies targeted at the poor. Such policies
 quality (0.018) (0.060) (0.110) (0.020) would aim to reduce the adverse effects of
spending a larger percentage of their in-
Source: Produced by the authors from the study data.
Note: Figures in parenthesis are standard errors computed by the bootstrapping procedure for the demand price elasticity come on the cigarette excise tax.
and by the Delta method for the rest of the estimates.
Statistical significance: a 1%, b 10% and C 5%. Acknowledgements. The authors grate-
fully acknowledge the International Devel-
cigarettes, this selective tax should be households than for poorer ones. This opment Research Centre (Ottawa, Canada)
raised, and the total demand price elastic- finding suggests that poorer families are and its funding for this project.
ity estimate provides an answer to how not more price sensitive than richer ones,
much cigarette consumption would be which implies that increasing cigarette Conflict of interests. None declared.
reduced. For the regressivity question, we taxes could be regressive.
used the cross-sectional database and esti- Disclaimer. Authors hold sole respon-
mated the demand price elasticity by in- Limitations sibility for the views expressed in the
come and expenditure groups. We found manuscript, which may not necessarily
that, in absolute value, the demand price This study had some limitations. The reflect the opinion or policy of the RPSP/
elasticity of cigarettes is larger for richer time-series analyses considered apparent PAJPH and/or PAHO.

REFERENCES

1. Chaloupka FJ, Straif K, Leon ME. 8. Instituto Nacional de Estadística e In-


1 4. Engle RF, Granger CWJ. Co-integration
Effectiveness of tax and price policies in formática del Peru. Encuesta Nacional de and error correction: representation, esti-
tobacco control. Tob Control. 2010;20(3):​ Presupuestos Familiares, 2008–2009. Lima: mation, and testing. Econometrica. 1987;55:​
235–8. INEI; 2009. 251–76.
2. Currie L, Townsend J, Leon Roux M, 9. Instituto Nacional de Estadística e In- 15. MacKinnon JG. Critical values for cointe-
Godfrey F, Gallus S, Gilmore AB, et al. formática del Peru. Encuesta Permanente gration tests. In: Engle RF, Granger CWJ
Policy recommendations for tobacco tax- de Empleo. Lima: INEI. Available from: eds. Long-run economic relationships: read-
ation in the European Union. Integrated http://webinei.inei.gob.pe/anda_inei/ ings in cointegration. Oxford: Oxford Uni-
Research Findings from the PPACTE proj- index.php/catalog/19 Accessed on 1 June versity Press; 1991.
ect. Dublin: Pricing Policies and Control 2016. 16. MacKinnon JG, Haug AA, Michelis L. Nu-
of Tobacco in Europe Consortium; 2012. 10. Deaton A. The analysis of household sur- merical distribution functions of likelihood
3. Jha P, Chaloupka FJ. Tobacco control in de- veys. A microeconometric approach to ratio tests for cointegration. J Appl Econom.
veloping countries. Oxford: Oxford Uni- development policy. Baltimore: John
­ 1999;14(5):563–77.
versity Press; 2000. Hopkins University Press; 1997. 17. Ramos-Carbajales A, Vallarino H, Gonza-
4. Chaloupka FJ, Warner KE. The economics 11. Gonzalez-Rozada M. Economía del con- lez-Rozada M. Peru--tributación sobre los
of smoking. In: Culyer A, Newhouse J, trol del tabaco en los países del Mercosur y productos del tabaco. Panorama general y
eds. Handbook of health economics. estados asociados. Argentina, 1996–2004. propuesta de reforma. Lima: Comisión
Amsterdam: North Holland; 2000. Washington, DC: PAHO; 2006. Nacional Permanente de Lucha Anti-
5. Warner KE. The economics of tobacco: myths 12. Dickey DA, Fuller WA. Distribution of the tabáquina; 2014.
and realities. Tob Control. 2000;9(1):​78–89. estimators for autoregressive time series 18. Gonzalez-Rozada M, Rodriguez Iglesias
6. Remler DK. Poor smokers, poor quitters with a unit root. J Am Stat Assoc. 1979;​ G. Análisis de la demanda de cigarrillos en
and cigarette tax regressivity. Am J Public 74(366):427–31. Argentina. Buenos Aires: Interamerican
Health. 2004;94(2):225–9. 13. Johansen S. Estimation and hypothesis Heart Foundation of Argentina; 2014.
7. Instituto Nacional de Estadística e In- testing of cointegration vectors in Gaus- 19. Ramos-Carbajales A, Curti D. Política fis-
formática del Peru. Available from: www. sian Vector Autoregressive Models. Econ- cal, asequibilidad y efectos cruzados de
inei.gob.pe/ Accessed on 1 June 2016. ometrica. 1991;59(6):1551–80. precios en la demanda de productos de

Rev Panam Salud Publica 40(4), 2016  254


Gonzalez-Rozada et al. • Implications of cigarette taxes in Peru Original research

tabaco: el caso de Uruguay. 2010. Available elasticidades precio e ingreso en la de- how could cigarette tax increases be pro-
from: http://bvs.insp.mx/rsp/anteriores/ manda de cigarrillos en El Salvador. gressive? J Policy Anal Manag. 2008;27(2):​
numero.php?year=2010&vol=52& Buenos Aires: Universidad Torcuato Di 376–400.
num=2&tipo=suplemento Accessed on 18 Tella; 2013.
May 2016.
21. Colman GJ,Remler DK. Vertical equity
20. Ramos-Carbajales A, Gonzalez-Rozada M. consequences of very high cigarette tax in- Manuscript received on 3 December 2015. Revised
El modelo econométrico y estimaciones de creases: If the poor are the ones smoking, version accepted for publication on 25 April 2016.

RESUMEN Objetivo.  Examinar los efectos que podría tener un aumento de los impuestos
­indirectos sobre el tabaco en el Perú sobre el consumo de cigarrillos y determinar si el
alza de los impuestos tendría un efecto regresivo.
Efectos de aumentar Métodos.  La elasticidad de la demanda total en función del precio se determinó, por
los impuestos indirectos grupos de ingreso, a partir de dos conjuntos de datos: datos trimestrales de series
sobre tabaco en el Perú cronológicas para el período de 1993 al 2012 y datos obtenidos en una encuesta trans-
versal de ingresos y gastos para el período del 2008 al 2009. El tipo de función mate-
mática que capta la demanda de cigarrillos en el Perú se determinó a partir de los
datos trimestrales; la elasticidad de la demanda en función del precio se calculó tanto
para el corto como para el largo plazo. El segundo conjunto de datos y el método de
Deaton se usaron para calcular en dos pasos la elasticidad y la elasticidad por grupos.
Resultados.  La elasticidad de la demanda en función del precio fue de -0,7. Esto
implica que un aumento de precio de 10% por efecto de un impuesto nuevo reduciría
el consumo en 7%. Los cálculos de la elasticidad de la demanda en función del precio
por grupos de ingreso revelaron que las familias más pobres no reaccionan más a los
cambios de precio que las familias más prósperas, o sea, que un aumento de los
impuestos sobre el tabaco podría tener un efecto regresivo.
Conclusiones.  El aumento de los impuestos sobre el tabaco es la política más eficiente
para reducir el tabaquismo. Sin embargo, en el caso del Perú dicho aumento podría
tener consecuencias regresivas.

Palabras clave Tributación de los productos derivados del tabaco; consumo de productos derivados
del tabaco; cese del tabaquismo; economía de la salud; Perú.

Rev Panam Salud Publica 40(4), 2016 255

You might also like