Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 44

ON-SITE RENEWABLES

AN APPRAISAL OF THE COSTS


AND BENEFITS OF DELIVERING
EMISSIONS REDUCTIONS IN
CENTRAL LONDON OFFICES
SEPTEMBER 2012
ABOUT THE BCO IMAGES
The British Council for Offices’ (BCO) mission is to COVER
research, develop and communicate best practice Heron Tower, 110 Bishopsgate, London
in all aspects of the office sector. It delivers this by Courtesy of Heron International
providing a forum for the discussion and debate of
relevant issues. PAGE 16
Heron Tower, 110 Bishopsgate, London
Courtesy of Heron International

ABOUT THE AUTHORS PAGE 18


101 New Cavendish Street, London
Gareth Roberts MRICS FRSA MSc BSc, Research Courtesy of Peter Durant
Director, Sturgis Carbon Profiling

Glen Irwin CEng BEng (Hons) MCIBSE, M&E


Sustainability Manager, Stepnell

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
June Taylor, Patrick Dwyer and Simon Sturgis of
Sturgis Carbon Profiling, Sarah Cary of British Land,
Daniel Winder of Sheppard Robson, Jenny MacDonnell
of the British Council for Offices and Steven Clark and
David Selby from Hopkins Architects.

COPYRIGHT © BRITISH COUNCIL FOR OFFICES 2012


All rights reserved by British Council for Offices. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored or transmitted in any form or by
any means without prior written permission from the British Council for Offices. The BCO warrants that reasonable skill and care has
been used in preparing this report. Notwithstanding this warranty the BCO shall not be under liability for any loss of profit, business,
revenues or any special indirect or consequential damage of any nature whatsoever or loss of anticipated saving or for any increased
costs sustained by the client or his or her servants or agents arising in any way whether directly or indirectly as a result of reliance on
this publication or of any error or defect in this publication. The BCO makes no warranty, either express or implied, as to the accuracy
of any data used by the BCO in preparing this report nor as to any projections contained in this report which are necessarily of any
subjective nature and subject to uncertainty and which constitute only the BCO’s opinion as to likely future trends or events based on
information known to the BCO at the date of this publication. The BCO shall not in any circumstances be under any liability whatsoever
to any other person for any loss or damage arising in any way as a result of reliance on this publication.
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

CONTENTS

Terms of reference 4 Question 2: What are the dominant factors


affecting the financial cost of using on-site
Executive summary 5 renewables to reduce building emissions? 25
Introduction 5 Question 3: How do these costs and benefits
Findings 5 compare with other policy alternatives? 27
Recommendations 6 Question 4: How do these costs compare
with the forgone environmental damage? 30
Introduction 8
Conclusions 33
Aims 8
Key conclusions 33
Report structure 9
Key recommendations 33
Policy background 9
Summary evaluation of renewable References 35
technologies 12
Appendix 1: Defining costs 37
Case studies – the use of renewables on
five buildings 13 Appendix 2: Regression model 40
Ropemaker Place 13 Appendix 3: Modelling the costs per tonne
The Peak 14 of a policy alternative 42
Heron Tower 16 Appendix 4: Calculating the value of forgone
Portcullis House 17 damage 44
New Cavendish Street 18

An evaluation of the costs and benefits 19


Question 1: What are the financial costs
and benefits to developers and occupiers
of reducing emissions using on-site
renewables? 19

© BCO 2012 3
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

TERMS OF REFERENCE

This research was commissioned by the British market, for example by acting as an incentive to
Council for Offices (BCO) to follow up its 2007 report retain and refurbish older stock
on the Greater London Assembly’s (GLA’s) policy I identify alternative policy structures that would offer
for achieving emissions reductions through on-site different compliance costs and generate additional
renewable energy provision. emissions reductions
I identify building types that are more capable of
Specifically, it set out to:
compliance, to aid investment decisions and offer
guidance to design teams
I quantify the impact of the GLA policy on the
environment (represented by the opportunity cost of I advise on which measures yield the greatest carbon
alternatives that could yield higher carbon savings) returns on financial investment
and on developers (represented by the additional I examine whether and to what extent the 2007
costs of building and operating renewable measures) report’s predictions have been fulfilled.
I examine whether this policy may have had
secondary effects on the City of London property

4 © BCO 2012
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

INTRODUCTION
This research was commissioned by the BCO to follow
up its 2007 report on achieving emissions reductions
through on-site renewables. That report was written in
the context of the GLA’s proposal to increase its target
for the proportion of emissions reductions delivered by
on-site renewables from 10% to 20% of a building’s
regulated energy demand. It expressed concerns over
whether the policy offered an effective way of achieving
emissions reductions, and called for a more flexible
approach. This report seeks to identify whether these
concerns were justified.

The less prescriptive emphasis of the current GLA policy


is welcomed by this report, as it offers an opportunity
to review strategies for achieving emissions reductions,
Figure 1 Evacuated tube solar collectors used on
focusing investment on those offering the greatest
Ropemaker Place.
potential for cost-effective reductions. However,
as the Building Regulations demand more stringent Courtesy of Sturgis Carbon Profiling LLP
energy-reduction targets in the coming years, the
use of on-site renewables will continue to be an
ever-increasing challenge for developers and designers
to accommodate in dense urban environments.
This report offers a crucial insight into the implications
In this report we explore the issues involved in the use of using on-site renewables, identifying the factors
of renewable technologies, by analysing the costs and driving performance and the potential to cut costs and
benefits of their use in central London office development increase environmental benefits from reduced emissions
projects over the period 2006 to 2010. in the future.

FINDINGS
This report includes five case studies that suggest I many technologies can be integrated within building
valuable lessons for other developers: services design.

I there are many discrepancies between modelled Costs and benefits to developers
energy use and actual use
The report analyses 77 central London commercial
I more attention should be paid to renewable cooling office developments, and finds that:
solutions in commercial buildings
I occupiers should be given advice on optimising and I on-site renewables can generate modest financial
monitoring their energy use returns to investors and occupiers in the presence

© BCO 2012 5
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

of subsidies, but in most cases represent a financial I Cost is extremely sensitive to external factors – for
burden once indirect losses have been accounted for example, increasing by £208 if a building is subject
I the range of costs and benefits varies widely across to conservation area status (based on statistically
the sample (Figure 2) significant evidence at the 5% significance level
(P < 0.005)).
I the cost per tonne of emissions reduced also varies
widely, from a net present value (NPV)1 of £145 per I The cost per tonne is £360 higher where subsidies
tonne gain to a loss of £2800 per tonne, with an have been claimed (based on statistically significant
average cost of £380 per tonne even with the aid evidence at the 5% significance level (P < 0.005)).
of subsidies.

Comparing costs with other policy


Dominant factors driving costs alternatives
I Saving one extra tonne of CO2 on a project reduces I Switching to an alternative policy mechanism such
the absolute cost per tonne by £20 (based on as combined heat and power (CHP) could achieve
statistically significant evidence at the 1% savings of £335 per tonne, or £153 million if applied
significance level (P < 0.001)2). across the UK.
I However, the relationship between the quantity of
emissions reductions and cost is not linear.

1,000,000
Benefit to developer: 10-year payback period, 8% discount rate
Benefit to developer: 7-year payback period, 13% discount rate
800,000
Benefit to developer: 3-year payback period, 33% discount rate
600,000 Total costs (PV)

400,000

200,000

–200,000

–400,000

–600,000

–800,000

–1,000,000

Figure 2 Costs and benefits of on-site renewables by project.


Courtesy of Sturgis Carbon Profiling LLP

1 Figures for NPV profit and loss take account of all carbon saved by a measure, and the associated financial costs and benefits, over its
lifetime.
2 The P value is the probability of the null hypothesis that the effect detected is due to random variation of the sample and does not
represent the population. A low P value indicates that there is a very small chance that the null hypothesis is correct, and so the
regression coefficient is significant.

6 © BCO 2012
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

Cost to taxpayers

£59
million
454,000 £18 million
tonnes
£174 million
Figure 3 Aggregate costs and benefits
Social value
CO2 saved
of on-site renewables.
Cost to developers Courtesy of Sturgis Carbon Profiling LLP

Comparing costs with forgone I It is acknowledged that these figures represent


environmental damage early stage implementation costs. However, as
I Aggregate net costs to developers are approximately illustrated by comparison with other policy
£174 million, which exceeds the forgone damage to alternatives, many other similarly early stage
the environment (approximately £18 million) by a technologies can deliver carbon savings much
factor of ten (Figure 3) every year in the UK. more cheaply.

RECOMMENDATIONS
This report recommends working towards higher I investigating more flexible policies, such as allowable
emissions reductions by: solutions or market-based alternatives, which can
provide a mechanism for delivering emission
I acknowledging that, economically, renewables have reductions in the most cost-effective way
more in common with conventional energy generation I making a more detailed enquiry into how these findings
processes than previously considered (returns to relate to other land markets and commercial building
scale and high fixed costs). types across the UK. (Currently, in the majority of
I carrying out a wider examination of the costs and circumstances, in the office sector renewables are
benefits of achieving emissions reductions across being installed simply to secure planning consents. This
the built environment – i.e. comparing the social has the negative impact of leading the renewables
and financial benefits from renewables on a level market through false market signals, and thus of
playing field with other alternatives such as embodied diverting resources from areas of technological
carbon reductions, decentralised power, community development that are more cost-effective.)
retrofit and better metering initiatives
I reviewing the efficiency of subsidies applicable As such, this report should be taken as a scoping
to on-site renewables – i.e. questioning whether study for a wider review of the economic and
it is possible to target subsidies more effectively environmental benefits of low-carbon legislation
to large-scale developments and thus encourage affecting commercial property in the UK, with the aim
developers to profit seek by using renewables of delivering the greatest carbon reductions at the
rather than through achieving minimum levels least cost to developers, building owners and occupiers.
of compliance
I examining the scope for district power solutions or
large-scale renewable installations, and the barriers
to their implementation

© BCO 2012 7
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

INTRODUCTION

AIMS
The construction and use of the built environment is
one of the largest sources of greenhouse gas emissions
in the UK, accounting for about half of total emissions
(CABE, 2007). Every year, construction of commercial
buildings in the UK produces over 80 million tonnes
of carbon dioxide (CO2) emissions (United Nations
Statistics Division, 2012), more than the combined
CO2 emissions of the Irish, Kenyan and New Zealand
economies.

Over the past decade the need to reduce the emissions


associated with buildings has become increasingly
clear, given the contribution they make towards global
warming. The UK government’s Low Carbon Transition
Plan has set a target for the non-domestic buildings Figure 4 Fuel storage reduces lettable area.
sector (including both existing and new-build stock) Courtesy of Arun Woodfuels
of achieving a 13% reduction on 2008 levels by 2020
(Department of Energy and Climate Change, 2009).

Responses to this challenge have included the surrounding the use of on-site renewables. Crucially, we
formulation of policies that directly or indirectly require consider the full range of costs and benefits, including:
developers to include on-site renewable energy
generation capacity in all new developments. I tax benefits
I the indirect cost to taxpayers of subsidies
To date, various studies have been conducted to quantify I loss of lettable area (e.g. storage of fuel such as
the emissions reductions delivered by these policies wood chips can take a considerable amount of
(Day et al., 2007, 2009) and the predicted capital space (Figure 4))
cost of meeting the emissions reduction targets they
I sensitivity of future financial savings to occupiers’
specify (BCO, 2007). However, there has been limited
perceptions
progress in understanding either the actual capital
costs or the wider indirect costs. Likewise little work I hidden costs such as maintenance, repair and
has been done to quantify the benefits of on-site replacement fuels
microgeneration in terms of reduced running costs I forgone damage to the environment.
and forgone damage to the environment.
The study is based on a sample of 77 commercial
This study makes a unique contribution, by investigating buildings in London in which on-site renewables were
and developing an understanding of the fuller3 picture installed during the period 2006–2010.

3 The authors acknowledge that defining the range of relevant factors affecting costs is as much a subjective judgement as an empirical
question. To help clarify this stuation, only those items that have been shown to have a statistically significant impact on compliance have
been included.

8 © BCO 2012
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

REPORT STRUCTURE
First, a brief review is given of the policies driving Question 2: What are the dominant factors affecting
the adoption of on-site renewable energy generation the financial cost of using on-site renewables to
capacity in new London developments. This is followed reduce building emissions?
by a brief summary evaluation of the most widely
Question 3: How do these costs compare with those of
available renewable technologies. The installation
other policy alternatives?
of these technologies in five case study buildings
in London is then described, with an explanation Question 4: How do these costs compare with the
of the project teams’ rationale for choosing specific forgone environmental damage delivered by using
technologies and a review of their performance. on-site renewables?

To investigate the issues surrounding the use of on-site These questions were selected to provide insight into
renewables, four key questions have been identified, the efficiency of policies requiring the use of on-site
and these are addressed in sequence. Each question renewables in central London, a topic not yet addressed
is accompanied by a brief description of the data and in other reports in the public domain.
methods used in answering it, the results that arose,
and a discussion of the implications of these results. The report concludes with a discussion of the broader
implications of the study’s findings.
The four key questions identified by this report are:

Question 1: What are the financial costs and benefits to


developers and occupiers of using on-site renewables
to reduce emissions?

POLICY BACKGROUND
The primary factor driving the adoption of on-site Plan, there is evidence to suggest that the intended
renewable energy generation capacity in new London reductions did not materialise (London South Bank
developments is the London Plan.4 It does so through University, 2009). A study by London South Bank
an explicit requirement for a reduction in building University (2009), reviewing emissions reductions through
emissions to be achieved using on-site renewables on-site renewables over progressive 12-month periods
wherever feasible. across 147 developments, found a significant reduction in
the average emissions reductions achieved, particularly
The origins of this requirement can be traced back to in early 2009 (Figure 6). This trend is partly explained
Merton Council’s introduction of a planning policy in 2003 by the fact that since the 2008 Plan, other alternatives
(Figure 5), requiring at least 10% of building energy to be have been allowed to be considered towards targets.
delivered by on-site renewables wherever feasible. This
requirement subsequently became known as ‘the Merton The most recent revision of the Plan, issued in 2011, is
Rule’, and was incorporated in the 2004 London Plan less prescriptive, stating only that: ‘major development
as part of a wider range of policies aimed at reducing proposals should provide a reduction in expected CO2
building emissions. The Plan was revised in 2008, emissions through the use of on-site renewable energy
when the required proportion of emissions reductions generation, where feasible’.5 Although it is no longer
from on-site renewables was increased to 20%. stated as an obligation, the policy's supporting text
includes a presumption that major developments will
Despite the more challenging target for emissions achieve a reduction of at least 20% through using
reductions from on-site renewables introduced in the 2008 on-site renewables.

4 The London Plan is a set of policies developed by the Mayor of London, which together make up London’s spatial development strategy
(Mayor of London, 2004, 2008, 2011b).
5 No definition of what constitutes ‘feasible’ is provided in the London Plan. Where a developer believes that compliance with the full
percentage requirement is not feasible, the onus is on him to justify his position and to provide evidence of having investigated possible
solutions.

© BCO 2012 9
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

Reviews Policies
2001 Enhanced capital allowance scheme introduced
2002
2003 Merton Council introduces 10% renewables requirement
2004
BCO first report 2005 The London Plan adopts the Merton Rule
2006
LSBU first review 2007 Feed-in tariffs scheme introduced
2008
2009 London Plan renewables requirement increased to 20%
LSBU second review
2010
2011 New target emission rate in the Building Regulations
2012
GLA monitoring review 2013 No requirement in the London Plan, but a presumption of 20%
2014
2015 Target date for 20% reduction on 2010 TER
2016
2017 Target date for 40% reduction on 2010 TER
2018
2019 Target date for zero-carbon commercial buildings

Figure 5 Policy timeline.


Courtesy of Sturgis Carbon Profiling LLP

12 However, the Mayor of London’s Energy Strategy


(Mayor of London, 2011a) proposes a move away
10 from prescriptive technological targets. Where
Emissions reduction (%)

meeting emissions targets is not economically viable,


8 the strategy allows developers the alternative of
London Plan renewables contributing to offsetting funds that will be held by
requirement increased to 20%
6 local boroughs. The purpose of these funds will be to
achieve further emissions reductions, for example by
4 developing large-scale decentralised energy networks
or investing in retrofitting poorly performing existing
2
stock, which can also yield significant carbon
reductions. However, in practice, few of these
schemes have materialised as yet.
0
2007 2008 2009
The use of renewables is seen as the third in a
Figure 6 Average percentage emissions reductions hierarchy of three generic strategies for reducing
across 147 developments. emissions (Figure 7). As such, developers are
Courtesy of Sturgis Carbon Profiling LLP expected to consider it after having achieved

10 © BCO 2012
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

reductions by reducing demand for energy and by


increasing the efficiency of energy supply.
Use
Although the requirements of the London Plan have renewables
been relaxed, revisions to Part L of the Building
Regulations6 continue to drive a reduction in building
emissions rates. Figure 8 illustrates the impact of Improve energy efficiency
successive revisions to Part L on the permissible rate
(referred to in the Regulations as the ‘target emissions
rate’ (TER)).
Reduce energy demand
Achieving these rates is vitally important, given the
need to reduce the future contribution of buildings to
global emissions. However, as Figure 8 illustrates, after Figure 7 The energy hierarchy in the 2011 London
2013 developers will be unable to design compliant Plan.
buildings using energy-efficient design alone. Once Courtesy of Sturgis Carbon Profiling LLP
the design threshold has been exceeded, unless more
flexibility is introduced into how emissions reductions
can be delivered (such as through allowable solutions),
generating energy from on-site renewables will be the increasingly find that on-site renewables are a necessary
only remaining means of meeting the emissions rates component of their development plans, even where
permissible under Part L. Developers may, as a result, these are not financially viable.

2002 2006 2010 2013 2016 2019

Target emissions rate Emissions saved through energy-efficient design


Emissions saved through renewables Possible role for allowable solutions

Figure 8 Potential likely future changes to the Part L target emissions rate.
Courtesy of Sturgis Carbon Profiling LLP

6 The scope of Part L covers only regulated emissions (fixed services), while the London Plan covers all emissions within a building.

© BCO 2012 11
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

SUMMARY EVALUATION OF RENEWABLE TECHNOLOGIES


Table 1 Summary of the advantages and disadvantages of the most common renewable energy technologies.

ICON DESCRIPTION CAPITAL ONGOING CARBON


COSTS COSTS FOR YOUR
MONEY
Relatively easy to integrate developments but does not £CAP £OTHER £/CO2
suit all architectural styles £CAP
£CAP
Cost-effective relative to other technologies £CAP £OTHER £/CO2
but needs space for the boiler and for fuel storage £CAP £OTHER £/CO2
£OTHER
Better suited to rural locations, as wind speeds in £CAP £OTHER £/CO2
built-up areas are usually too low and roof shape can £CAP £OTHER £/CO2
dramatically affect performance
Cost-effective assuming year-round demand for hot £CAP £OTHER £/CO2
water, but requires roof space and provides only minor £OTHER £/CO2
emissions reductions £/CO2
Can provide very efficient cooling but depends on £CAP £OTHER £/CO2
suitable geology, and cost of preparing and connecting £CAP £/CO2
to heat source is high £CAP
Slow to fire up and better suited to wider area £CAP £OTHER £/CO2
developments with continuous heat and power base £CAP £OTHER £/CO2
loads; requires space for boiler and fuel storage £CAP £OTHER £/CO2

CAPITAL ONGOING CARBON


COSTS COSTS FOR YOUR
MONEY
LOW £CAP £OTHER £/CO2
MEDIUM £CAP £OTHER £/CO2
Source: Sturgis Carbon Profiling LLP HIGH £CAP £OTHER £/CO2

12 © BCO 2012
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

CASE STUDIES
THE USE OF RENEWABLES ON FIVE BUILDINGS

ROPEMAKER PLACE

Architects: Arup Associates Location: 25 Ropemaker Street, London EC2


Developer: British Land Floorspace: 52,183 m2
M&E: Balfour Kirkpatrick Use: Office

Rationale for installation: Following intensive design


efforts to reduce energy use, particularly cooling
loads, three renewable technologies were selected to
meet planning requirements and further demonstrate
the building’s green commitments.

Renewable technologies installed

Performance of the systems: The solar thermal and


photovoltaic (PV) panels function well and integrate
easily with the base building M&E, the former providing
hot water for toilets in one main core and the latter
providing electricity towards base building usage such as
car park and lift lighting. The biomass boiler was sized
for full heating load, and so its use was initially delayed
until the building was fully occupied. It has now
undergone a month’s trial, and British Land is working
towards an approach where it is used in winter months.
Biomass fuel costs (when used only for full building
load) are not significantly different to the costs of gas.

Lessons learnt: Energy modelling done at design


stages to meet Part L and EPC requirements can be
significantly different from actual energy consumption
during building use, and planning for the installation and
future use of renewables should take account of this.
Heating demand in city centre offices tends to be
very low, and greater energy savings can be found in
improvements to the cooling and ventilation system
than by installing renewable technologies that generate
hot water. There have been significant teething issues
with the delivery and hopper mechanisms for the
Photo courtesy of British Land biomass boiler, which have hampered its use.

© BCO 2012 13
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

THE PEAK

Architects:Sheppard Robson Location: 5 Wilton Road, London SW1


Developer: Heron International Floorspace: 9105 m2
M&E: Foreman Roberts Use: Office and retail

Rationale for installation: To comply with the London


Plan requirements for carbon savings from
renewables (an 11.7% saving in energy and a 7.1%
carbon saving delivered) and Part L (2006) TER
requirements and to assist with the Energy credits for
BREEAM (a rating of ‘Very Good’ was achieved). The
renewables were also seen as an important element
of the environmental sustainability credentials of the
building, which was seen as an important issue by
target tenants.

Renewable technologies installed

Performance of the systems: The Peak incorporates


250 m2 of monocrystalline PV arrays to generate the
equivalent of 2.0% of the building’s total annual
energy consumption. The electrical output from the
PV cells is converted to alternating current and fed
directly into the building’s main low-voltage electrical
switchgear panel in parallel with the incoming utility
electrical supply to feed all the electrical services
throughout the building. The PV cells have been
generating electricity since the building was
commissioned and, with the benefit of the Feed-in
The Peak was awarded ‘West End Development of Tariff Scheme (FITS), this has dramatically shortened
the Year’ at Property Week’s Offices 2010 Awards. payback periods. The building is currently only partly
occupied, and so the solar thermal and ground-source
Photo courtesy of Heron International heat pump systems have not yet been fully used.
The Peak incorporates 50 m2 of flat panel solar thermal collectors integrated in the south-facing façade to
generate approximately 60% of the summer hot water demands for domestic use at teapoints and toilets.
Solar thermal is also likely to become popular with the impending introduction of the Renewable Heat
Incentive, although this project is not able to claim this tariff.
Groundwater is extracted by a pump located in a 140 m deep abstraction borehole and typically has a constant
year-round temperature of 12–14°C. After passing through a plate heat exchanger where it cools the neutral
water temperature loop, it is returned to the ground via a recharge borehole. The lack of consumption of
groundwater in this process minimises any environmental impact.
This technology reduces the use of fossil fuels in cooling the building by using the ground and groundwater as a
renewable heat sink. The amount of electrical energy used to drive the heat pumps is less than that traditionally
used for an air- or water-cooled chiller installation, thus reducing the amount of CO2 emitted into the atmosphere.
(continued)

14 © BCO 2012
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

THE PEAK – continued

Lessons learnt: The incorporation of PV cells onto buildings is becoming more common due to the FITS.
Relatively easy installation, coupled with minimal maintenance, makes PV cells a perfectly viable technology.
Although solar thermal is less common on office buildings, The Peak does have catering facilities, and so good
carbon savings are expected.
The Colt Colaris system is designed to use the near-constant year-round temperatures of chalk aquifer water
to improve heat-pump efficiency in both cooling and heating modes. When considering the constrained site
footprint in Victoria, the system made sense in terms of integrating services design with renewables requirements.

Photo courtesy of Heron International

© BCO 2012 15
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

HERON TOWER

Architects: KPF Location: 110 Bishopsgate, London EC2


Developer: Heron International Floorspace: 66,629 m2
M&E: Foreman Roberts Use: Office and retail

Rationale for installation: To comply with the London


Plan requirements for energy from renewables (2.2% of
building energy supplied by PV) and Part L (2006) TER
requirements, and to assist with the energy credits for
BREEAM (a rating of ‘Excellent’ was achieved).

Renewable technologies installed

Performance of the system: This project incorporates


1153 m2 of glass/glass-laminated PV cells. This was
the only feasible renewable technology for the highly
constrained city centre site. The cells are positioned
in the vertical south-facing lift core, which offered the
largest area for mounting the largest number of cells,
and thus the greatest possible carbon saving. They
also offer a shading function to the lift core void, and
a commitment to the use of renewable energy that is
highly visible to occupants and visitors.

Lessons learnt: Although representing a high capital


cost, the PV cells have successfully helped to raise
the environmental credentials of the building, and to
achieve other benchmarks such as the BREEAM
‘Excellent' rating. This is demonstrated by the fact that
the carbon management firm Eco Global Markets has
taken up a tenancy specifically because of the tower’s
environmental credentials. Target tenants would be
expected to have corporate social responsibility
policies requiring them to rent low-impact office space.

The PV cells have been generating power since


commissioning in spring 2011, and there have been
no significant maintenance issues with the system.
Photo courtesy of Heron International

16 © BCO 2012
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

PORTCULLIS HOUSE (not part of the study sample, as it was opened in 2001)

Architects: Michael Hopkins and Partners Location: Bridge Street, London SW1
Developer: Parliamentary Works Directorate Floorspace: 20,000 m2
M&E: Crown House and Kaverner Rashleigh Weatherfoil Use: Parliamentary Offices

Rationale for installation: The borehole cooling system was a part of a pre-BREEAM ground-breaking sustainable
design approach backed by EU-funded research. It entailed passive elements of thermal mass, solar shading
and daylight enhancement.

Renewable technologies installed


The landmark ventilation chimneys of the natural ventilation utilise borehole ground water cooling,
and the exhaust allows pre-heating of the incoming air. It was designed to use one-third of the
energy consumed by a conventional high prestige air-conditioned building.

Performance of the system: Some initial teething issues were evident before the building management and
occupants were able to ‘get the best out of the building’, which is not surprising as the system had not
been experienced before. After this initial period
of familiarisation with the building’s sustainable
features, dynamic seasonal variations etc., the use
of more sophisticated controls than those originally
utilised when the building was occupied enables
the building management team to make significant
reductions in the use of energy and water.

Lessons learnt: Monitoring of performance and


occupant engagement is essential to understand
and control the environmental performance and
‘swings’ of the building fabric and thereby maintain
the effectiveness of the ground source cooling. For
such a large building with a complex range of uses
and a greater occupancy than anticipated, borehole
groundwater, used in combination with the building’s
other sustainability elements integrated into the
fabric and façade, continues to be effective as the
only means of cooling the building.

Photo courtesy of Sunil060902


(http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/File:Westminster_station_building_Portcullis_House.JPG)

© BCO 2012 17
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

NEW CAVENDISH STREET

Architects: Sturgis Associates Location: 101 New Cavendish Street, London W1


Developer: City Office Real Estate Floorspace: 1300 m2
M&E: JB&B Use: Office, retail and residential units

Rationale for installation: Solar thermal heating and PV cells were installed during the refurbishment of the
building to improve its environmental performance.

Renewable technologies installed


These technologies were selected because they could be easily integrated into the building
services and resulted in no loss of lettable area. The design also incorporated measures to
reduce solar gains, including chilled beams and external louvres. The constraints of working
on an existing building in a conservation area, while residential units remained occupied, also
influenced the choice of technologies, and the residential component guaranteed a high level of demand for heating.

Performance of the system: The system has remained fully functional since its installation, delivering heating
and hot water, and significantly reducing the carbon footprint of the building’s occupants.

Lessons learnt: Solar thermal and PV cells were found to be cost-effective methods of improving the
environmental performance of a mixed-use building undergoing refurbishment, given the constraints of existing
structural loads and restricted floor-to-ceiling heights.

Photo courtesy of Peter Durant

18 © BCO 2012
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

AN EVALUATION OF THE COSTS AND BENEFITS

QUESTION 1:
WHAT ARE THE FINANCIAL COSTS AND BENEFITS TO DEVELOPERS AND
OCCUPIERS OF REDUCING EMISSIONS USING ON-SITE RENEWABLES?
Motivation involving the application of renewable technologies
Understanding the separate costs and benefits of were included in the sample, reducing the sample size
on-site microgeneration helps to examine whether to 82 in total. A further five buildings were removed
efficient decision-making is possible in the context from the sample as they used highly visible renewable
of energy efficiency. This is especially relevant given technologies, and thus valuing their aesthetic benefit
the incentive misalignment problems that frequently with any certainty was considered to be too complex.
result in non-optimal outcomes in this sector. These In total, 77 buildings were examined. Given this
problems include: relatively small sample size, generalisations made
later in this report to other office markets should be
I Landlord/tenant issues – capacity installed by the treated with some caution.
landlord delivers benefits to the tenants, and the
developer may not capitalise these benefits in rents.
Defining costs
I Allocation of risk – energy savings generated can
The specification given in Figure 9 was used to define
be subject to heavy discounting due to policy and
the present value of financial costs. It incorporates the
energy market uncertainty, which may not align with
main ongoing cost elements involved in using renewable
the risk profile of the building’s owner.
technologies, over the lifetime of the renewable measure:
I Developer/resale issues – capacity installed by the loss of rent derived from loss of lettable area; materials
project’s developer may not result in capitalisation in and labour used in maintenance; and replacement
the building’s value at sale, if it involves additional fuel. Appendix 1 provides a more detailed description
complexity in facilities management (as is often the of the methodology, discount rate and variables used
case with biomass). and the sources of data.

Because of these misalignments, building owners


frequently fail to consider ‘net’ costs attributable to Defining benefits
renewable technologies, and simply seek methods of The specification given in Figure 10 was used to define
compliance with policy requirements for renewable energy the present value of financial benefits. It incorporates
installation that minimise upfront capital expenditures. the value of renewable obligation certificates and other
By examining the costs and benefits separately, we subsidies for which the building is eligible, and the
can begin to develop a simple picture of the impacts price of the electricity and gas usage that has been
of this policy before introducing assumptions that are displaced by the renewable energy generated, over
necessary for more detailed analysis. the lifetime of the building. Appendix 1 provides a more
detailed description of the methodology and variables
used and sources of data.
Data
Over 3354 buildings in central London, for which
planning applications were made during the period Findings
2006–2010 were reviewed as part of this study. Of The total costs and benefits for each building in the
these buildings, only commercial office buildings sample are illustrated in Figure 11. The benefits have

© BCO 2012 19
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

Construction Value of
cost renewable
obligation
– certificates
Tax benefit on
construction +
cost
Benefit = Value of
Deflated to other
2005 values subsidies
Discount
+ + ÷ rate and
Displaced period
gas use
Net area loss
× ×
Price of gas
Lost rent
(basement)
+
+ Displaced
Net area loss electricity use
Cost = × ×
Lost rent Price of
(above ground) OVER LIFETIME
Discount electricity
OF BUILDING
+ ÷ rate and
Maintenance period
materials
Figure 10 specification for defining benefits.
Courtesy of Sturgis Carbon Profiling LLP
+
Maintenance
labour Important Finding: The average costs and benefits of
+ the sample are £570 and £190, respectively. Figure 12
illustrates how these are broken down into their
Replacement
fuels OVER LIFETIME components from the specification described earlier.
OF BUILDING
Figure 13 illustrates a basic marginal abatement cost
Figure 9 Specification for defining costs. curve (dividing the net cost of a renewable technology
used on a building by the total number of tonnes of
Courtesy of Sturgis Carbon Profiling LLP carbon emissions displaced by the use of renewables in
a given year) constructed in order to compare renewable
technologies on a cost per tonne basis across the
been calculated for three distinct discount rates (8%, 13% sample. Further details are given in Appendix 1.
and 33% – see Appendix 1 for discussion on discount
rates). The variation in benefits at different discount For each building in the sample, the emissions displaced
rates illustrates how different occupiers might view over the lifetime of the technology were assessed, with
the risks associated with the returns from renewable each year of emissions given equal weighting. The total
technologies. For a technology with a 20-year lifespan, emissions displaced were then ranked according to
these discount rates correspond to an implied range of ascending costs along the horizontal axis in Figure 14,
payback periods of between 3 and 10 years, which is with the width of the bars representing the amount of
consistent with other occupier behavioural studies displaced emissions for each building. Thus the area
undertaken for small-scale microgeneration (Element of each bar becomes the total net cost or benefit of a
Energy, 2009). renewable technology.

20 © BCO 2012
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

1,000,000
Benefit to developer: 10-year payback period, 8% discount rate
Benefit to developer: 7-year payback period, 13% discount rate
800,000
Benefit to developer: 3-year payback period, 33% discount rate
600,000 Total costs (PV)

400,000

200,000

–200,000

–400,000

–600,000

–800,000

–1,000,000

Figure 11 The costs and benefits for the 77 developments assessed in this study.
Courtesy of Sturgis Carbon Profiling LLP

Average cost Average benefits

£190 Total cost


£570 over lifetime
of building


Cost of each Total benefit
tonne of CO2 = over lifetime
saved of building

Value of initial
÷
Capital cost subsidies
Total emissions
Indirect cost of Value of displaced fuel displaced
lettable area lost and heat
(over lifetime
Maintenance and Value of post-installation of building)
materials subsidies

Figure 12 Average costs and benefits to developers. Figure 13 Marginal abatement cost curve.
Courtesy of Sturgis Carbon Profiling LLP Courtesy of Sturgis Carbon Profiling LLP

© BCO 2012 21
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

Savings 1.7 tCO2e saved at a cost of £1596.91/tCO2e to developer


1500 Costs
Subsidised abatement cost (£/tCO2e)

1000

500

37.1 tCO2e saved resulting in a net benefit of £145.77/tCO2e to developer

0 500 1000 1500 2000 2500 3000 3500


Carbon savings achieved (tCO2e)

Figure 14 Subsidised marginal abatement costs associated with on-site renewables.


Courtesy of Sturgis Carbon Profiling LLP

Savings
1.7 tCO2e saved at a cost of £1620.94/tCO2e to developer
Costs
Subsidised abatement cost (£/tCO2e)

1500

1000

89.7 tCO2e saved at a cost of £0.47/tCO2e to developer


500

0 500 1000 1500 2000 2500 3000 3500


Carbon savings achieved (tCO2e)

Figure 15 Unsubsidised marginal abatement costs associated with on-site renewables.


Courtesy of Sturgis Carbon Profiling LLP

22 © BCO 2012
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

Figure 14 incorporates the value of any subsidies that most instances the direct financial costs significantly
were applicable to specific buildings in the sample. Figure outweigh the direct financial benefits (associated
15 shows the same data with these values removed, environmental benefits will be considered later in
to illustrate the impact on costs of withdrawing subsidies. the report).
I The level of benefits varies significantly, even
between buildings that incurred similar costs.
Discussion
Two observations can be made on comparing the costs As illustrated in Figures 14 and 15, the net costs per
and benefits of installing renewable technologies in tonne of displaced carbon emissions across the
different building types: sample range from:

I Regardless of the discount rate chosen (based on a I £0.47/tonne CO2 to £3089/tonne CO2 when subsidies
comparison of three rates: 8%, 13% and 33%), in are not in place, to

Gas plant CCS retrofit


Reduced slash and burn agriculture Iron and steel CCS new build
conversion
80 Reduced pastureland conversion Coal CCS new build
Lighting – switch incandescent
to LED (residential) Grassland management Coal CCS retrofit
60
Appliances electronics Organic soils restoration
40 Motor systems efficiency
First-generation biofuels
Abatement cost (€/tCO2e)

20
Cars full hybrid
0
5 10 15 20 25 30 35 38
–20
Geothermal Abatement potential (GtCO2e per year)
–40 Rice management
Small hydro Solar CSP
–60 Waste recycling Reduced intensive
Efficiency improvements other industry agriculture conversion
–80
Landfill gas electricity generation High penetration wind
–100 Clinker substitution by fly ash Solar PV
Low penetration wind
–120 Building efficiency new build Degraded forest reforestation
Insulation retrofit (residential) Pastureland afforestation
–140 Tillage and residue management Degraded land restoration
Cropland nutrient management Nuclear
–160 Cars plug-in hybrid
Retrofit residential HVAC
–180
Second-generation biofuels
–200 Appliances residential

NOTE: The curve presents an estimate of the maximum potential of all technical GHG abatement measures below
€80 per tCO2e if each lever was pusued aggressively. It is not a forecast of what role different abatement measures
and technologies will play.

Savings Strategies sorted by cost-efficiency


Costs

This graph attempts to show ‘all in one’ the various measures for greenhouse gas reduction, with both reduction (in carbon
dioxide equivalents (CO2e)) and cost (in Euros (€)) quantified.
Read from left to right, it gives the whole range of strategic options, ranging from ‘low hanging fruit’ (in green), such as
building insulation (coming with economic savings), to the increasingly ‘higher hanging ruit’ (in red), such as afforestation
and wind energy.
Figure 16 Global cost curve for greenhouse gas abatement measures beyond ‘business as usual’ (greenhouse
gases measured in GtCO2e1).
Courtesy of McKinsey & Company

© BCO 2012 23
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

I –£145/tonne CO2 to £2806/tonne CO2 when subsidies


are in place.

A negative cost indicates that, in these cases, profits


are realised when subsidies are in place. It is, however,
important to emphasise that only a small minority of
the sample achieve a profit. The requirement to use
on-site renewable technologies to generate electricity
acts, in effect, as a levy or tax on new development.

As Figures 14 and 15 illustrate, the majority of the


cost per tonne values from the sample are in excess
of £280/tonne CO2. In comparison to the potential for
reducing carbon emissions from other sectors of the
economy and other sources within the construction Figure 17 Carbon capture and storage.
industry, on-site renewable technologies represent an Courtesy of Statoil
extremely inefficient investment. McKinsey & Company’s
(2010) research (illustrated in Figure 16) can be used to
help understand what marginal cost per tonne is required
to deliver different levels of greenhouse gas reductions. Even the high-cost emerging technology of carbon capture
Our view of these figures is that for governments to and storage (Figure 17) represents a more cost-effective
stabilise global greenhouse gases at around 450 parts means of reducing emissions than most of the on-site
per million, which is seen as the threshold value at renewable technologies examined in the sample.
which to avoid dangerous climate change, will require
a cost of carbon of around €20-30 per tonne so long This finding gives rise to serious concerns about
as governments can efficiently target each sector of the efficiency of policies requiring the use of on-site
the economy best placed to deliver these reductions.7 renewable energy technologies.

QUESTION 2:
WHAT ARE THE DOMINANT FACTORS AFFECTING THE FINANCIAL COST
OF USING ON-SITE RENEWABLES TO REDUCE BUILDING EMISSIONS?
Motivation
Given the range of costs and the variation in size of
benefits of different buildings in the sample, the next
stage of the investigation sought to discover which
characteristics were driving these costs. Understanding
these costs may then help developers or owner-occupiers
to identify opportunities to reduce the cost of compliance
at an early stage and to understand the economic
fundamentals driving the costs of using renewable
technologies in commercial buildings (Figure 18).

This stage seeks to address issues such as:


Figure 18 Thermal storage needs space, and may be
I whether returns to scale occur, making larger problematic if demand for heat falls.
installations more cost-effective, or whether an
Courtesy of SolarVision
optimum size can be identified for renewable

7 ‘Efficiency’ here refers to the ability of governments to introduce legislation on the most cost-effective measures first. It is, however,
recognised that this can often cause other political complications due to matters such as distribution of wealth effects that make the most
efficient outcomes impossible.

24 © BCO 2012
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

installations given the limits of energy demand the use of on-site renewables and the other variables
(e.g. for heating) in a building deemed likely to affect emissions. The variables used
I whether other planning policies impact on the costs are: the maturity of the technology used; the quantity
of meeting requirements for on-site renewable of CO2 saved; the existence of supply incentives; the
technologies, for example by restricting the choice existence of tax incentives; whether the building is
of measures that could be used listed or located in a conservation area; the size of the
building; and whether the building is new or refurbished.
I whether it is easier and more cost-effective to install
The development of the regression model and the data
renewables in tall buildings or in low-rise structures.
used are described in more detail in Appendix 2.

Data
The sample used is the same as the one identified in Findings
Question 1 (a total of 77 buildings in central London Figure 19 gives an intuitive feel for the data and the
in which renewable technologies were installed). To trends within it, illustrating the relationship between net
identify the impact of various building characteristics average cost on a specific building (the dependent
on costs, a range of other explanatory variables are variable) and a single variable (the total quantity of
identified for each building. CO2 saved on the building) (explanatory variable X3).
Examining this relationship suggests a number of
basic trends, even without carrying out a complex
Methodology regression analysis:
The ordinary least squares (OLS) method of regression
analysis was used to identify the association between I Costs appear to be high at low values of total
the net average cost of emissions reductions due to emissions reduction, which could imply either that

500
Profitable installations
50 100 150 200 250 300 350
0
Carbon savings achieved (tCO2e)

Low cost installations


–500
Abatement cost (£/tCO2e)

–1000

–1500

–2000 High cost installations

–2500

–3000

Figure 19 The relationship between abatement costs and total carbon savings from renewables on each building.
Courtesy of Sturgis Carbon Profiling LLP

© BCO 2012 25
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

small installations are inefficient, or that there is I To capture this relationship of rapidly decreasing
selection bias, in that only high-cost measures are costs followed by slowly increasing costs suggests
capable of delivering low levels of carbon reductions a cubic function relating to quantity, hence the
(e.g. PV). explanatory variables X4 and X3 in the final
I The initial high costs per tonne of carbon abated regression specification.
may be explained by high fixed costs such as those
incurred by maintenance, where it can cost similar Table 2 shows the results from the final OLS model
amounts for a yearly service for a small or large described above.
renewable installation, or marginal costs increasing
at a lower rate than the marginal benefits. The minimum cost of compliance can be proven
(within this sample) to occur around the level of
I Costs decrease as the amount of emissions 90 tonnes of CO2 saved on each individual project.
reductions required increases, up to a point around
40–100 tonnes.
I Around this point, some buildings can realise a Discussion
profit from operating on-site renewables (green Of the explanatory variables investigated using the
points in Figure 19). regression model, the following are worthy of note:
I After this point, costs increase, but less rapidly than
they had decreased before, suggesting that there I The total quantity of emissions reduced on a building
may be competing influences on costs that are not was found to have a highly significant impact on
captured in this scatter plot. For example, technology cost in all the model terms (Quantity – linear,
becomes more economically efficient at higher levels Quantity – squared, Quantity –cubic, specifications).
of energy generation, but limits in demand for heat In statistical terms we are thus 99.9% confident that
may serve to restrict these potential gains. a 1 tonne increase in total emissions saved on a

Table 2 Results of regression analysis

COEFFICIENT t-VALUE P
Quantity 20.460 5.22 0.000
Quantity 2 –0.147 –5.35 0.000
Quantity 3 0.0003 5.04 0.000
New technology –232.111 –1.89 0.063
Supply incentive –368.714 –3.02 0.004
Tax incentive –113.969 –1.37 0.174
Conservation area –208.321 –2.02 0.048
New building 12.253 0.12 0.904
Number of floors –1.526 –0.77 0.443
Size –0.003 –0.76 0.452
Constant –432.456 –2.42 0.018
Observations 77
R2 0.524
Robust standard errors used: * significance at the 10% level; ** significance at the 5% level; *** significance at
the 1% level.
Source: Sturgis Carbon Profiling LLP

26 © BCO 2012
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

project will halve the cubic relationship to cost supply incentives for renewable measures on a
described in the specification. given building. This result is counter-intuitive, as
I To illustrate this effect through a point estimate, the supply incentives would be expected to reduce
effect of saving an additional tonne of carbon at a rather than increase costs. However, the reader
level where 50 tonnes are currently saved will is reminded that association does not constitute
reduce net average costs by £5.80 per tonne. causality; the most likely explanation in this case is
I The regression analysis indicates (at a 95% confidence that the regression model has identified a correlation
level) that, if a given building is subject to conservation between subsidies being in place for expensive
area legislation, the average cost of saving 1 tonne technologies, rather than a tendency for subsidies
of carbon will increase by £208 on that building. to make technologies more expensive.
I This conservation area effect could operate in one I Finally, there is weak statistical significance (at the
of two ways: 10% significance level) for the following variables:
– the cost of applying the same technologies could – whether the development is a new or refurbished
increase as a result of higher indirect associated building – new development is associated with
costs (e.g. installing the technology without reducing net average costs by £12 per tonne,
affecting the appearance of the building could compared with refurbishments
increase the area of lettable space lost) – the maturity of the technology – using a new
or technology is associated with increasing net
– the choice of measures that could be employed average costs by £232 per tonne.
on a building in a conservation area could be I The remaining three variables, size of building,
limited to those that are more expensive. number of floors and the existence of tax incentives,
I It can also be shown that a statistically significant were found to have no significant impact on costs in
and negative effect is associated with the use of the sample examined.

QUESTION 3:
HOW DO THESE COSTS COMPARE WITH OTHER POLICY ALTERNATIVES?
Motivation by choosing the optimum size of installation in the
At present, policies on the use of renewable energy presence of a uniform carbon-reduction subsidy.
target reductions in emissions at the level of individual In practice, however, while reducing the burden on
developments. In the discussion of Question 1 (see developers, such a policy might not deliver the quantity of
page 19) evidence was presented of the substantial emissions reductions deemed necessary by legislators.
variation in costs incurred, with net average costs per This approach would also depend on some quite strong
tonne ranging from –£2806 to +£145 (enabling building rational economic behavioural assumptions, which
owners to make a modest profit from the installation may not be realistic in practice, given the range of
of renewable technologies). discount rates observed and the problems of incentive
misalignment previously discussed.
Equally important to these findings are the sensitivity of
these costs to scale, with strong statistical evidence to An alternative approach would be for local authorities to
suggest that up to 37% of the variance in these costs be responsible for commissioning new renewable energy
can be explained by a single variable, the quantity of installations, identifying the most cost-effective and
emissions, alone.8 carbon-efficient generating solutions for each district, and
funding these projects through planning charges. Such
These findings could support arguments for an alternative an approach would provide greater certainty for legislators
policy instrument that encourages developers to target on the delivery of carbon reductions. While it might
more cost-effective levels of emissions reductions be less efficient than the ‘first best’ solution identified
and seek profits from the installation of renewable above, it could deliver carbon emissions reductions
technologies, subject to their respective constraints, at a significant cost saving over the status quo.

8 In the simplified OLS regression model, NACb = α + β2X2,b + β3X3,b + β4X4,b + εb, using robust standard errors R2 =37.65%.

© BCO 2012 27
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

To examine these issues, a simple comparison is scheme in Aberdeen (Energy Saving Trust, 2004)
made between the compliance costs associated with and adjusted to account for various factors specific to
the current policy and those associated with a district London (e.g. the higher cost of land and labour). The
CHP scheme.9 It is worth stressing here that it is not costs per tonne associated with the existing policy on
the intention of this report to advocate greater use of on-site renewable energy were taken from the average
CHP, but merely to question whether other policy of the sample used in the preceding sections.
alternatives exist that are more efficient.

This approach has also been advocated by the Zero Methodology


Carbon Hub through their work on allowable solutions, As described above, this section serves only to consider
which envisages local energy funds or the use of a simple comparison of the cost of achieving a 1 tonne
embodied carbon to deliver savings more cost-effectively. reduction in emissions through on-site renewable
technologies (the status quo) and of a large-scale
The basis for using CHP (Figure 20) as an alternative efficient off-site CHP installation, adjusted to take
is three-fold: it can be considered as an alternative to account of London-specific opportunity costs. Full details
renewables by the GLA today; it can deliver emission of these adjustments and the analysis underlying this
reductions in a non-location-specific way (i.e. it can be comparison are given in Appendix 3.
generalised with relevant land-value conversion factors),
and technology and price effects are likely to be correlated
with renewables (as renewables become cheaper, it Findings
is likely that CHP units will become cheaper also, as
Figure 21 provides a simple comparison on a cost per
they share similar markets and both will be subject to
tonne basis of the current policy for on-site renewable
technological advancement over the coming years).

It is recommended that more research should be carried On-site renewables District CHP
out in this area, and that the comparison outlined below
should simply be regarded as framing the problem to
be investigated. £130

Data £175
Data for the comparison exercise were taken from an
Energy Saving Trust study of a large-scale community
£380

Cost to private sector (developer)

Cost to public sector (subsidies)

Figure 21 Comparison of the abatement cost


associated with on-site renewables and an alternative
Figure 20 A CHP plant in Aberdeen. policy.
Courtesy of Aberdeen Heat and Power Company Ltd Courtesy of Sturgis Carbon Profiling LLP

9 For those wishing to find out more, London First’s report Cutting the Capital’s Carbon Footprint (2008) provides a detailed critique of the
challenges and opportunities associated with decentralised energy.

28 © BCO 2012
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

energy and the policy alternative of large-scale


installations. The total net costs per tonne associated
with the existing policy were identified in the discusiion
on Question 1 (see page 19) as being £380, whereas
for the large-scale alternative the total costs are £175
per tonne.

Discussion
This illustrative comparison suggests that, while
commissioning a large-scale district energy installation
could be both costly and practically complex, it could
also offer significant savings both to taxpayers (who Figure 22 Wildlife Mitigation Bank, California.
would incur less cost in subsidies) and developers. The Courtesy of Burns & McDonnell
comparison made here suggests that savings could be
in the region of £205 per tonne of CO2 abated to the
private sector and around £130 per tonne to taxpayers.
If indicative of relative costs across the UK as a whole,
I A private-sector approach: Developers could provide
the savings to both the private sector and taxpayers
carbon savings on-site and, where they are able to
could be in the region of £153 million every year.10
save in excess of their reduction requirements, then
sell excess reductions to other developers who are
Further research on the potential of large-scale
unable to achieve reductions as cost-effectively.
renewable energy installations is recommended to
explore these issues more fully, with reference to other Issues: Robust measurement and verification
UK locations and large-scale renewable technology procedures are required, which, due to transaction
alternatives. The type of approach adopted would costs, may wipe out the gains that a market-based
also need further consideration, and three options approach may provide.
are briefly outlined below: I A flexible approach: This is similar to the wetland
banking system used in the USA (Figure 22), in which
I A direct approach: Local authorities provide a default all developers are required to reduce emissions by an
means to achieve carbon emissions reductions, amount decided centrally by government, and where
through large-scale retrofitting projects or district-level compliance can be achieved through either buying
schemes, which could capitalise on economies of allowances from other parties (e.g. local authorities,
scale. These projects could be supported financially energy service companies or other developers who
through planning contributions, with an effective exceed their targets) or through providing low-cost
price per tonne of £125–175.11 At these price levels, renewables on site. Such a scheme may help change
efficient renewables will be encouraged that are attitudes towards carbon reduction, by fostering a
capable of being delivered for less than this, while partnership-based approach, allowing the sharing
the more expensive and inefficient renewable of risk more effectively and through the bargaining
applications will not be pursued. power benefits that local authorities may bring to
Issues: Weak evidence of successful local authority the table.
roll-out to date; lack of capacity and skills of local Issues: Again robust measurement and verification
authorities; no market incentive for good performance. procedures are required.

10 Based on an average annual number of tonnes reduced per square metre of 0.0027 tonne and a 10-year average new-build construction
for commercial properties of 8,301,000 m2. Although a crude estimate, it is believed that this should provide a conservative lower bound
for the potential savings, given that commercial property uplift figures do not take into account replacement (as occurs through demolition
and rebuilding) and do not include refurbishment projects. In addition, if retrofitting of existing stock and embodied carbon were also
considered, significant additional savings could be realised.
11 Such a price level should be based on the capacity of renewables to become cheaper over time due to the market maturing and
improvements in technology. Comparisons with similar technology sectors would suggest that 50–70% price reductions may be feasible,
supporting an initial price of carbon of £50/tonne.

© BCO 2012 29
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

QUESTION 4:
HOW DO THESE COSTS COMPARE WITH THE FORGONE
ENVIRONMENTAL DAMAGE?
Motivation forgone environmental damage is time dependent,
Earlier sections of this report have focused only on the the introduction of this particular policy might be
financial costs and benefits to developers and the costs more easily justified at a point in time when its cost
to taxpayers in the form of subsidies. These, however, better reflects the environmental benefit.
represent only half of the equation, as the purpose of
on-site microgeneration policies is to avoid harm to the Data
environment caused by the build-up of greenhouse This section uses the average measure of the costs and
gases such as CO2, which result in global warming. benefits of the sample, as a tonne of carbon saved on
one project is of equivalent value to society as any other
Although a discussion of the science associated with tonne of carbon saved on any other project. The value
these wider issues is outside the scope of this report, of forgone environmental damage is calculated using
we believe that examining the value placed by the shadow price of carbon. Although this is by no
government on avoiding this damage is an important means a perfect measure, it is widely used, its limits are
stage in appraising the on-site renewable energy well known12 and it provides considerable improvements
policy. Our reasons for doing so are three-fold: on the accuracy of measures employed previously.13

I The values placed by government on avoiding


environmental damage (shadow prices of carbon) Methodology
take into account the possible costs of delivering The value of forgone environmental damage associated
emissions reductions in other sectors of the economy, with each building in the sample is calculated using
given the government’s policy targets (as illustrated the formula for the present value illustrated in Figure 23.
in the MAC curve shown in Figure 25). Therefore, if A more detailed explanation is given in Appendix 4.
the costs per tonne considerably exceed the shadow
price, it should be possible to achieve significant
carbon reductions in other sectors of the economy
far more cost-effectively.
I Retaining a policy that delivers a benefit that is far
outweighed by the cost could, however, be justified,
if the relatively high cost is a short-term problem Emissions
and costs are expected to fall over time. Comparing saved
shadow prices with the observed costs of the policy
enables an assessment of how much these costs
×
would need to fall in order for a matching long-term Value of Value in given
equilibrium situation to be achieved. forgone = time period
I
damage
Comparing these costs and benefits with those of
similar technological sectors could provide a measure ÷
of whether this justification is realistic for this
particular policy. Social discount
I Comparing the costs of the policy with its OVER LIFETIME rate @ 35%
environmental benefit allows consideration of OF BUILDING
whether it is preferable to apply this particular policy
today or at a later date. This is not to question the Figure 23 Present value of forgone environmental
urgent need to reduce greenhouse gas emissions damage.
now, but emphasises that, given that the value of Courtesy of Sturgis Carbon Profiling LLP

12 For further discussion, see Dietz (2007).


13 See, for example, Clarkson and Deyes (2002) and Price et al. (2007), which relied solely on demand side estimations of value.

30 © BCO 2012
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

Findings made in the UK. Included in the figure are both


Figure 24 provides a simple analysis of costs and reductions associated with legislative requirements
benefits on a per tonne basis, from the perspective of (including successive target emission rates required
a private owner/occupier’s cash flow and from the under Part L of the Building Regulations) and those
perspective of society. The cost of saving each tonne means by which further reductions could be made
of carbon using on-site renewables and through the at lower compliance costs than those of the on-site
alternative policy analysed in the discussion on renewables in this sample.
Question 3 (see page 27) is equated to the shadow
price of a tonne of carbon in each case. The costs of complying with a requirement for on-site
renewables would need to fall by a factor of ten to
The aggregate analysis indicates that, even once the justify the installation of such resources in the long-term.
value of forgone environmental damage is included, While the price of the technology is expected to change,
the burden generated by this policy is in excess of a change of the required magnitude seems most
£470 per tonne. unlikely at present.

As discussed above, given that the social value of


carbon changes over time, a more pragmatic approach
Discussion would be to reintroduce this policy at a later period,
These findings suggest that the costs to building owners, when the costs would be easier to justify given the
occupiers and UK taxpayers far exceed the value of the higher values placed on avoiding CO2 emissions at
forgone environmental damage generated by the policy. that time.

The figures suggest, in accordance with the cost curve Some evidence exists to support this course of action,
developed by McKinsey & Company (see Figure 16), in that the value of avoiding carbon emissions will
that many sectors of the UK economy are capable of increase to over £200 per tonne by 2050. However, it
delivering these savings in a far more cost-effective way. is clear that, without significant reductions in the costs
of the technology, most on-site renewable energy
Figure 25 shows an approximate ranking in terms of installations would continue to represent a financial
cost of the means by which carbon savings are being burden on developers, taxpayers and the environment.

Cost to taxpayers
On-site renewables

£130

1 tonne £40

£380
Social value
CO2 saved
Cost to developers

vs

District CHP

£175 1 tonne £40

Social value Figure 24 Costs and benefits per tonne.


Cost to developers CO2 saved
Courtesy of Sturgis Carbon Profiling LLP

© BCO 2012 31
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

Improved lighting efficiency


Low-cost renewables
Cavity-wall insulation
Net benefit

Cost-effective requirements under Part L


Energy-efficient appliances
Occupiers reducing energy consumption

Use of materials with low embodied carbon


Solid-wall insulation
Non-cost-effective requirements under Part L
District low-carbon energy networks
Net cost

Average cost of renewables: CHP, heatpumps, borehole cooling, etc.

High-cost renewables: CHP, fuel cells

Figure 25 Approximate ranking of abatement technologies by cost per tonne.


Courtesy of Sturgis Carbon Profiling LLP

32 © BCO 2012
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

CONCLUSIONS

KEY FINDINGS
The findings from this research indicate that on-site the range of technologies available and the scale at
renewable energy installations can generate modest which they can be deployed, and reduces the level of
financial returns to investors and occupiers in the emissions reductions that can be achieved through
presence of subsidies, although they rarely do. this means.

Taking account of all the costs and benefits, the In response to this concern, a simple policy alternative
average net position is a cost of £382 per tonne, even has been examined, which suggests that similar
with the help of subsidies. environmental benefits could be delivered at lower
costs. This report, however, does not advocate a
The research has also shown that costs are sensitive specific technological solution: a wide range of
to external factors, such as conservation area status measures could reduce emissions far more cost-
(which increases costs by restricting the range of effectively than on-site renewables.
technologies that can be used).
The implications of these findings suggest that, as
Our calculation of the forgone value of environmental further carbon savings will be required from
damage in the UK, based on the government’s appraisal commercial buildings in the UK in the near future,
method, suggests grounds for serious concern. The other strategies to supplement on-site renewable
negative NPV to developers (£173 million) exceeds energy must urgently be explored. Only by doing so
the environmental benefits (£18 million) by a factor can the burden on occupiers and developers be
of ten each year. minimised and emissions reductions delivered in the
most cost-effective way.
These high costs are a consequence of the physical
constraints of dense urban environments, which limit

KEY RECOMMENDATIONS
I A wider review of the costs and benefits of achieving on-site renewable technologies where it is possible
emissions reductions across the built environment is to do so profitably, while local authorities should use
required, using MAC curves for a range of building their collective bargaining power to remove barriers
types and carbon reduction processes. in the delivery of large-scale solutions.
I The efficiency of subsidising on-site renewables, as I More flexible policy mechanisms should be
a means of reducing emissions, should be reviewed. investigated, allowing combinations of on-site
I Local authorities should explore the role of district solutions and purchase of carbon allowances at a
and large-scale renewable installations as realistic price in order to drive behavioural change
alternatives to on-site microgeneration, especially in (e.g. £125–175 per tonne), encouraging local
the context of hard-to-treat stock such as that in authorities to take an active role in creating and
historic city centres. delivering large-scale low-carbon power projects
and to make best use of their bargaining positions
I All parties should play to their strengths: developers
to reduce transaction costs.
should be encouraged to seek profits by installing

© BCO 2012 33
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

I A more detailed enquiry should be undertaken into for a larger investigation of the economic and
how these findings relate to other land markets and environmental benefits of low carbon legislation on
commercial building types across the UK. As such, commercial property in the UK.
this report should be perceived as a scoping study

34 © BCO 2012
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

REFERENCES

British Council for Offices (2007) Renewables and the London Plan. London: British Council for Offices. Available at:
http://www.bco.org.uk/uploaded/Renewables_report.pdf (accessed 3 June 2012).
Building Cost Information Service (2001) Life Expectancy of Building Components. London: Royal Institution of Chartered
Surveyors.
CABE (Commission for Architecture and the Built Environment) (2007) Sustainable Design, Climate Change and the Built
Environment. London: CABE. Available at: http://www.designcouncil.org.uk/Documents/Documents/Publications/CABE/
sustainable-design-and-climate-change.pdf (accessed 3 June 2012).
Carbon Trust (2010) Introducing Combined Heat and Power. Available at: http://www.carbontrust.com/media/19529/
ctv044_introducing_combined_heat_and_power.pdf (accessed 11 July 2012).
C B Richard Ellis (2010) Prime Rent and Yields Monitor Q2 2010. London: CB Richard Ellis. Available at:
http://www.cbre.co.uk/uk_en/news_events/news_detail?p_id=5167 (accessed 11 July 2012).
Clarkson R and Deyes K (2002) Estimating the Social Cost of Carbon Emissions. Government Economic Service Working
Paper 140. London: HM Treasury. Available at: http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/d/SCC.pdf (accessed 3 June 2012).
Day T, Ogumka P and Jones P (2007) Review of the impact of the energy policies in the London Plan on applications referred
to the Mayor (Phase 2). London: London South Bank University. Available at:
http://london.gov.uk/archive/mayor/planning/docs/lsbu-research.pdf (accessed 3 June 2012).
Day, T, Ogumka, P & Jones, P (2009). Monitoring the London Plan: Energy Policies – Phase 3. Part 1 Report. Final. London:
London South Bank University. Available at: http://static.london.gov.uk/mayor/priorities/docs/lon-plan-energy-policies-
monitoring-1.pdf (accessed 3 June 2012).
Department of Energy and Climate Change (2009) The UK Low Carbon Transition Plan. London: Department of Energy
and Climate Change. Available at: http://www.decc.gov.uk/assets/decc/White%20Papers/UK%20Low%20Carbon%
20Transition%20Plan%20WP09/1_20090724153238_e_@@_lowcarbontransitionplan.pdf (accessed 3 June 2012).
Department for Business Innovation and Skills (BIS) (2008) The Growth Potential for Microgeneration in England Wales and
Scotland. London: BIS. Available at: http://webarchive.nationalarchives.gov.uk/+/http://www.berr.gov.uk/files/file46003.pdf
(accessed 11 July 2012).
Dietz S (2007) Review of DEFRA paper: ‘The Social Cost of Carbon and the Shadow Price of Carbon: What They
Are, and how to Use Them in Economic Appraisal in the UK’. London: London School of Economics. Available at:
http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/21613 (accessed 3 June 2012).
Element Energy (2009) Uptake of Energy Efficiency in Buildings. Available at: http://downloads.theccc.org.uk/docs/
Element%20Energy_final_efficiency_buildings.pdf (accessed 3 June 2012)
Energy Saving Trust (2004) Aberdeen City Council: A Case Study of Community Heating. London: Energy Saving Trust.
Available at: http://www.energysavingtrust.org.uk/england/Publications2/Housing-professionals/Heating-systems/
Community-heating-Aberdeen-City-Council-case-study-2004-edition (accessed 3 June 2012).
HM Treasury (2011) The Green Book. Appraisal and Evaluation in Central Government. Treasury Guidance (updated
version of 2003 edition). London: TSO. Available at: http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/d/green_book_complete.pdf
(accessed 3 June 2012).
Mayor of London (2004) The London Plan: Spatial Development Strategy for Greater London. London: Greater London
Authority. Available at: http://legacy.london.gov.uk/mayor/strategies/sds/london_plan/lon_plan_all.pdf (accessed 3 June 2012).
Mayor of London (2008). The London Plan: Spatial Development Strategy for Greater London. Consolidated with Alterations
since 2004. London: Greater London Authority. Available at: http://www.london.gov.uk/thelondonplan/docs/londonplan08.pdf
(accessed 6 June 2012).
Mayor of London (2011a) The London Plan: Spatial Development Strategy for Greater London. London: Greater London Authority.
Available at: http://www.london.gov.uk/sites/default/files/The%20London%20Plan%202011.pdf (accessed 3 June 2012).

© BCO 2012 35
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

Mayor of London (2011b). Delivering London’s Energy Future. The Mayor of London’s Climate Change Mitigation and Energy
Strategy. London: Greater London Authority. Available at: http://www.london.gov.uk/sites/default/files/Energy-future-oct11.pdf
(accessed 3 June 2012).
McKinsey & Company (2010) Impact of the Financial Crisis on Carbon Economics: Version 2.1 of the Global Greenhouse Gas
Abatement Cost Curve. Available at: http://www.mckinsey.com/client_service/sustainability/latest_thinking/greenhouse_
gas_abatement_cost_curves (accessed 17 August 2012).
Price R, Thornton S and Nelson S (2007) The Social Cost of Carbon and the Shadow Price of Carbon: What They Are, and
how to use them in Economic Appraisal in the UK. London: Department of Environment, Food and Rural Affairs. Available
at: http://archive.defra.gov.uk/evidence/series/documents/shadowpriceofcarbondec-0712.pdf (accessed 3 June 2012).
Royal Institute of Chartered Surveyors (RICS) (2007) Code of Measuring Practice: A Guide for Property Professionals, 6th
edn. London :RICS.
United Nations Statistics Division (2012) Millennium Development Goals Indicators: Carbon Dioxide Emissions (CO2),
thousand metric tonnes of CO2 (CDIAD). Available at: http://mdgs.un.org/unsd/mdg/SeriesDetail.aspx?srid=749&crid=
(accessed 11 July 2012).

36 © BCO 2012
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

APPENDIX 1:
DEFINING COSTS

COMMENT ON DISCOUNT RATES


Discount rates enable cash flows from future time rate of 3.5% is used (see page 30) (as prescribed in the
periods to be placed alongside present-day cash HM Treasury Green Book, 2011) this low rate reflects the
flows. They take into account a range of general time long-view that the government takes on the damage or
uncertainties, as well as how risky receiving the future benefits that may accrue at a long time in the future and
cash flows might be. Within this report, various that they believeit is important not to discount too heavily
discount rates are used to reflect the degrees of risk (in fact, some would argue that this is still too high).
associated with the different cash flows being However, the opportunity costs of forgone lettable area
analysed. The more risky the future cash flow might in this report are discounted at the higher rate of 6.13%
be, the higher (larger percentage) the rate used. (see page 20), which reflects the mean 15-year yield
rate for offices, sourced from CB Richard Ellis (2010).
An example of this is how the government carries out This higher rate reflects the rental income and asset
the valuation of forgone environmental damage, where a risk that private investors perceive in the office market.

DEFINING COSTS
The following specification was used to define the R2 rent in area 2 (above ground)
present value of financial costs: Mb maintenance materials on building b
Lb maintenance labour on building b
Costb = {[CCb – (Taxe – CCb) × Defy]} +
Fb replacement fuel(s) on building b
t = lifespan

∑ (NIAb1 × R1) + (NIAb2 × R2) + Mb + Lb + Fb r discount rate


t discount time period.
t=1
(1 + r)t

where the total cost of the renewable technology on Data


building b is Costb. Values for these data were sourced as follows:
The various cost variables are: CCb, the capital costs paid by developers to purchase
the items of technology intended to achieve the required
CCb construction cost of the renewable technology CO2 reductions, were sourced from the Corporation of
on building b London’s Planning Archive, where available, or provided
Taxe any tax benefit from the use of technology b directly by the developer, or based on general cost
Defy cost deflator to 2005 prices from year y estimates provided by Davis Langdon.
NIAb1 net area loss on building b in area 1
Data for Taxe, the value of the enhanced capital
(basement)
allowance (ECA) and other tax subsidies to the
NIAb2 net area loss on building b in area 2 (above developer were derived, in the absence of developers’
ground) tax records, on the basis of a number of assumptions:
R1 rent in area 1 (basement) if it were possible to claim the ECA in that year with

© BCO 2012 37
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

the item of technology identified, a developer would do R1 and R2, the value of forgone lettable areas
so (developers act rationally and are well informed); all (in the basement and above ground, respectively),
developers pay tax at a uniform rate of 28%; and, finally, were sourced from IRIS Engineering and Technology,
when a developer chose a technological measure a building consultancy firm specialising in asset
benefiting from ECA, they were expecting to make an management and environmental appraisals of
accounting profit from which the ECA could be deducted buildings in central London.
(projects would not be given the go ahead on a no-profit
basis). With these conditions holding true, the value of Data for Mb and Lb, the cost of materials and labour
the ECA variable would be 28% of the capital cost if required each year to maintain specific renewable
the measures used appeared on that year’s ECA list. technologies, and Fb, the cost of fuel, were provided
by the Energy Saving Trust.
A deflating factor, Defy, corrects for time-related cost
differences between observations by adjusting to 2005 A value of 6.13% was chosen for r, the discount rate
prices. The deflator was chosen on the basis of used by developers to capitalise future payments and
information from the Department for Business Innovation income into a present value, based on the 15-year
and Skills. Although the use of one deflator for different mean yield rate for offices sourced from CB Richard
costs is far from ideal, given the short time period of Ellis. It is acknowledged that yields are typically lower in
this study and the fact that all major cost variables central London, but evidence suggests that developers
positively correlate with construction costs, it was may discount future cash flows relating to renewable
decided that using a single value would not overly measures more heavily (Department for Business
compromise the specification. Innovation and Skills, 2008). Given this uncertainty
over a correct rate, various alternatives were
NIAb1 and NIAb2, the net internal areas (in the basement examined in the calculations of benefits.
and above ground, respectively) forgone by using a
particular technological solution, were measured (in Data for t, the lifespan of the renewable technologies
accordance with the Royal Institution of Chartered employed, were sourced from the Building Cost
Surveyors’ (RICS) Code of Measuring Practice (2007)) Information Service (2001).
from the plans submitted with planning applications
held by the Planning Archive.

DEFINING BENEFITS
The following specification was used to define the Eg energy generated that displaces gas use
present value of financial benefits: Ee energy generated that displaces electricity use
Pe price of electricity
Benefitb =
Pg price of gas
t = lifespan
r1,2,3 range of different discount rates used

t=1
ROCb + SUBb + (Eg × Pg) + (Ee × Pe)
(1 + r1,2,3)t
t time period of discount rates.

where the total benefit of the renewable technology on Data


building b is Benefitb. Data for ROCb, the value of Renewable Obligation
Certificates awarded, were sourced from IRIS
The various other benefit variables are: Engineering and Technology.

ROCb value of renewable obligation certificates Eg and Ee, the quantity of energy generated that
generated by the renewables on building b displaces the use of gas and electricity, respectively, were
SUBb value of other subsides now introduced on obtained from the Energy Statement for each building
building b held in the Corporation of London Planning Archive.

38 © BCO 2012
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

Pe and Pg, the prices of gas and electricity, are the prices All prices and costs are baselined to 2005 to enable
offered on a commercial tariff in 2005 by Powergen, a comparisons to be made between projects within the
large utilities provider in the UK. sample carried out in different periods. Checks of
robustness were done by taking different alternative
Values for t are as defined for costs above. baseline time periods, none of which resulted in a
substantial change the findings of this report.
Three values (8%, 13% and 33%) are used for r, the
discount rate applied by occupiers.

MARGINAL ABATEMENT COST CURVE


The marginal cost abatement (MAC) curve is where Costb and Benefitb are defined as previously,
calculated as follows: and Emissionsb is the total number of tonnes of CO2
displaced by the use of renewables in a given year
Costb – Benefitb,r = 13% in building b.
Net average costb =
t = lifespan

∑ Emissionsb
t=1

© BCO 2012 39
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

APPENDIX 2:
REGRESSION MODEL

MODEL
Ordinary least squares (OLS) regression analysis14 expectations described above and after viewing the
was used to test the explanatory power of the different scatterplot, which supports the cubic functional form.
control variables on the variance of the net average I Model IV – the most parsimonious regression model,
costs per tonne. The basic estimation model is: introduces the new technology control and is given by:

Regulatory compliance cost (RCC)i = α + β1Quantity Net average costb= α + β1X1,b + β2X2,b + … β9X9,b + εb
+ γ1′ X + αi
The dependent variable is the net average cost on
where the dependent variable is the regulatory cost building b, given by the explanatory variables:
of CO2 abatement of building i. The main coefficient of
interest is β1, which measures the effect of one unit X1 the maturity of the renewable technology used
of emission reduction required. The other control
X2 the quantity of CO2 saved by the technology
variables are part of X, and εi is the error term.
Robust standard errors were used in all regressions. X3 (quantity of CO2)2
X4 (quantity of CO2)3
Four models of estimating the RCC were examined: X5 existence of supply incentives
X6 existence of a tax incentive
I Model I – a linear specification of all variables.
X7 building located in a conservation area or listed
I Model II – introduces a quadratic expression of
the Quantity variable (Quantity 2). X8 size of the building
I Model III – introduces a cubic specification into the X9 new or refurbished
Quantity variable (Quantity 3), in response to εb error term.

DATA
The variables used are explained in more detail below. of scale may help reduce regulatory compliance costs,
as the ‘output’ of emission reductions increase (by
Maturity of the renewable technology used. A control reducing the impact of fixed costs, such as yearly
dummy is introduced into the specification, as it is maintenance costs, or reducing heat losses through
anticipated that new methods of emission reduction higher efficiency components via the installation of
may be more expensive. A dummy variable of 1 is larger plants). The second effect, which contrasts with
given if the technology is new, and the expected this, may be that output constraints start to bind and
coefficient is negative. limit a developer’s ability to choose the most efficient
factors of emission reduction. For example, use of
Quantity of CO2 saved. It is anticipated that various the surrounding ground as a thermal store may be
effects may occur through this variable. First, economies constrained by fears of raising bedrock and water table

14 OLS regression analysis is a means of identifying the association between a single continuous variable (in this case, the net average cost
of emissions reductions using on-site renewables) and one or more other variables deemed likely to affect it. The method of estimation
involves identifying values for the parameters β1 to β9 in this model that are capable of predicting a value for the net average cost that is
as close as possible to the actual value. Tests of statistical inference are then carried out on these parameter values to decide if their
least squares estimates have significance and are robust.

40 © BCO 2012
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

temperatures. It is thus expected that, after a given level Size of building. It is expected that, as a building
of emission reduction, costs may again begin to rise, becomes larger, it will become easier to accommodate
although benefits from economies of scale may persist. a renewable measure (because of the additional
For these reasons, it is anticipated that the regulatory flexibility). The expected coefficient is positive.
compliance cost function, rather than being a quadratic
average cost curve function, may follow a cubic Number of floors. It is expected that the ratio of roof
relationship restricted within certain bounds. Thus area to energy demand will decrease as the building
three terms for the quantity of CO2 saved are included. height increases. The expected coefficient is negative,
as low-cost measures requiring large amounts of roof
Dummy variables are applied to control for projects on space (e.g. solar water heating) will become
which supply incentives have been awarded through increasingly difficult to apply.
ROCs or on which ECA tax incentives apply. The
expected coefficients are positive. New or unrefurbished space. This is typically less
efficient and less capable of accommodating new
Conservation area and listed building status. Buildings mechanical and electrical plant because of constraints
in these categories are subject to stricter planning of the existing structure. A dummy variable of 1 is
controls than others. This is expected to increase given if the space is new, and zero if it is refurbished;
developers’ costs and indirectly restrict their choices. the expected coefficient is negative.
A dummy variable of 1 is given if a building is inside
a conservation area or the property is a listed building.
The expected coefficient is negative.

RESULTS
The size of installation that minimises compliance –(–0.2932) ± (0.2932)2 – 4 × 20.46040 × 0.00075
Q=
costs was identified by taking the derivative of the 2 × 0.00075
fitted model with respect to quantity, setting the first
derivative equal to zero and solving with respect to Q = 90.9 (1 dp), 299.9 (1 dp)
quantity, as shown below:
to derive which point is a maximum and which is a
Net average cost (NAC) = α + β1X1 + β2X2 + … β9X9
minimum. Taking the second derivative
where β1 = 20.46040 (to 5 decimal places (dp)), Δ2NAC/ΔQ2 = –0.29320Q + 0.00150Q
β2 = –0.14660 (5 dp), β3 = 0.00025 (5 dp), and X1 = Q
(quantity saved on building b), X2 = Q1 and X3 = Q1. where
Taking the first derivative Q = 90.9 Δ2NAC/ΔQ2 < 0, therefore a maximum

ΔNAC/ΔQ = 20.46040 – 0.29320Q + 0.00075Q2 = 0 Q = 299.9 Δ2NAC/ΔQ2 > 0, therefore a minimum

and solving using the quadratic formula

© BCO 2012 41
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

APPENDIX 3:
MODELLING THE COSTS PER TONNE OF
A POLICY ALTERNATIVE

In this illustration, the methodology was revised slightly The prices per kilowatt-hour of gas and electricity (pg
to reflect the variables for which data were available and pe, respectively) are those offered by Powergen
(values are given in Table A3.1). on a commercial tariff in 2005 (as in Appendix 1), and
the annual net benefit (B) is calculated as the cost of
Data for the capital cost (CC) and whole-life cost (WLC) the displaced gas and electricity, minus the annual fuel
of the CHP plant (the latter including annual fuel (f) and maintenance cost and opportunity cost:
and maintenance (m) costs over 25 years (t)), and for
the total CO2 emissions (e) produced were sourced B = [(g × pg) + (e × pe) – [(f + m) + OC
from the original case study report (Energy Saving
Trust, 2004), where: The net average cost per tonne (NAC) is defined as the
difference between the capital cost and the net present
t = 25

WLC = CC + ∑ (f + m) value of B (NPVB, based on a discount rate of 13%


t=1 over 20 years), divided by the total CO2 emissions over
20 years, where:
A similar scheme in central London would also involve
the opportunity cost (OC) of lost lettable area. The NAC = CC – NPVB
value of this opportunity cost is based on assumptions
∑t = 1 E
t = 20

made for the space required for a typical CHP plant


and the notional rent rate (assuming the plant is
located in a basement in central London).
Data
The literature on CHP technology (e.g. Carbon Trust, Table A3.1 Values used in the model
2010) commonly assumes an efficiency rate (R1, the
proportion of CO2 that is converted to usable energy)
OVERVIEW
of 75% and a rate of transfer from heat to power (R2, Capital cost (CC) £1,530,000
the proportion of the usable energy that is available as Annual fuel and running cost £14,678.24
electricity, the remainder providing heating that displaces
(f + m)
an equivalent amount of gas) of 20%. The Carbon Trust
issues conversion factors (cg and ce, respectively) that Whole life cost (WLC) £1,896,956
can be used to calculate the kilowatt-hours of displaced CO2 emissions (E) 936,000 kgCO2
gas and electricity that would be generated annually
from the equivalent of the total kilograms of CO2 Heat energy (g) 2,726,214 kW-h
produced (g and e, respectively), where: Electrical energy (e) 681,553 kW-h

E OPPORTUNITY COST
g=
[( ) ]
cg
× R 1 × (1 – R 2 )
Building (site)
Notional rent rate
2,500 ft2
£22.50
and extra over
Rent (OC) (£) 56250
e=
()E
ce
× R 1× R 2
Continued

42 © BCO 2012
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

Table A3.1 Values used in the model (continued)

SUMMARY NET COST


Capital costs £1,530,000.00 Average saving per tonne £277.90
Yearly costs £70,928.24 (NPV)
936,000 kgCO2 Mean cost £453.20
Yearly savings £204,466.02 Net average cost per tonne £175.30
1,104,798 kgCO2 (NAC)
Net saving (B) £133,537.78
168,798 kgCO2
Payback (years) 11.46

© BCO 2012 43
ON-SITE RENEWABLES

APPENDIX 4:
CALCULATING THE VALUE OF FORGONE DAMAGE

Value of forgone damage = notional cost per tonne of CO2 emissions that can
be incorporated in policy and investment appraisals.
t = lifespan

∑ Emissionsb,t × Valuet The SPC set at that time was £25.50 per tonne: the
Department of Energy and Climate Change (2009) has
t=1
(1 + rsdr)t since proposed a short-term schedule of prices in the
non-tradable sector, increasing from £50 per tonne in
2008 to £60 per tonne in 2020.
where:
The social discount rate (rsdr), which is set out in
Emissionsb,t emissions saved in a particular time the government’s official guidance on appraisal and
period t in building b evaluation of projects (The Green Book, HM Treasury,
2011), adjusts for the timing of the occurrence of costs
Valuet value of forgone atmospheric damage
and benefits by discounting them to present values.
in a given time period
The recommended rate of 3.5% in real terms was
rsdr social discount rate of 3.5%, as introduced in the 2011 version of The Green Book,
recommended by HM Treasury replacing the previous recommended rate of 6%.
t the lifespan (in years) of a given
renewable technology.
Note
To ensure consistency in the comparison of the average
Data costs per tonne of CO2 emissions saved in the buildings
Emissionsb is the total number of tonnes displaced by in the sample, the value of forgone damage was divided
the use of renewables in a given time period in building by the total quantity of emissions saved over the lifespan
b, as defined in Appendix 1. of the technology. It is recognised that this makes an
‘absolute’ interpretation of the findings complex: if the
The amount of forgone atmospheric damage in a given reader seeks such an interpretation, reference should
time period (Valuet) is based on the shadow price be made to the original total NPV costs identified in
of carbon (SPC) as defined by Price et al. (2007), a Question 1.

44 © BCO 2012

You might also like