Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 410

Corporate Finance

Edited by
Ştefan Cristian Gherghina
Printed Edition of the Special Issue Published in
Journal of Risk and Financial Management

www.mdpi.com/journal/jrfm
Corporate Finance
Corporate Finance

Editor
Ştefan Cristian Gherghina

MDPI • Basel • Beijing • Wuhan • Barcelona • Belgrade • Manchester • Tokyo • Cluj • Tianjin
Editor
Ştefan Cristian Gherghina
Bucharest University of Economic Studies
Romania

Editorial Office
MDPI
St. Alban-Anlage 66
4052 Basel, Switzerland

This is a reprint of articles from the Special Issue published online in the open access journal
Journal of Risk and Financial Management (ISSN 1911-8074) (available at: https://www.mdpi.com/
journal/jrfm/special issues/Corporate Finance).

For citation purposes, cite each article independently as indicated on the article page online and as
indicated below:

LastName, A.A.; LastName, B.B.; LastName, C.C. Article Title. Journal Name Year, Volume Number,
Page Range.

ISBN 978-3-0365-0570-1 (Hbk)


ISBN 978-3-0365-0571-8 (PDF)

© 2021 by the authors. Articles in this book are Open Access and distributed under the Creative
Commons Attribution (CC BY) license, which allows users to download, copy and build upon
published articles, as long as the author and publisher are properly credited, which ensures maximum
dissemination and a wider impact of our publications.
The book as a whole is distributed by MDPI under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons
license CC BY-NC-ND.
Contents

About the Editor . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . vii

S, tefan Cristian Gherghina


Corporate Finance
Reprinted from: J. Risk Financial Manag. 2021, 14, 44, doi:10.3390/jrfm14020044 . . . . . . . . . . 1

Cuong Nguyen Thanh


Optimal Cash Holding Ratio for Non-Financial Firms in Vietnam Stock Exchange Market
Reprinted from: J. Risk Financial Manag. 2019, 12, 104, doi:10.3390/jrfm12020104 . . . . . . . . . . 7

Geetanjali Pinto and Shailesh Rastogi


Sectoral Analysis of Factors Influencing Dividend Policy: Case of an Emerging Financial Market
Reprinted from: J. Risk Financial Manag. 2019, 12, 110, doi:10.3390/jrfm12030110 . . . . . . . . . 21

Georgeta Vintilă, Ştefan Cristian Gherghina and Diana Alexandra Toader


Exploring the Determinants of Financial Structure in the Technology Industry: Panel Data
Evidence from the New York Stock Exchange Listed Companies
Reprinted from: J. Risk Financial Manag. 2019, 12, 163, doi:10.3390/jrfm12040163 . . . . . . . . . . 39

Victor Dragotă and Camelia Delcea


How Long Does It Last to Systematically Make Bad Decisions? An Agent-Based Application
for Dividend Policy
Reprinted from: J. Risk Financial Manag. 2019, 12, 167, doi:10.3390/jrfm12040167 . . . . . . . . . . 55

Lious Agbor Tabot Ntoung, Helena Maria Santos de Oliveira, Benjamim Manuel Ferreira de
Sousa, Liliana Marques Pimentel and Susana Adelina Moreira Carvalho Bastos
Are Family Firms Financially Healthier Than Non-Family Firm?
Reprinted from: J. Risk Financial Manag. 2020, 13, 5, doi:10.3390/jrfm13010005 . . . . . . . . . . . 89

Jeffrey (Jun) Chen, Yun Guan and Ivy Tang


Optimal Contracting of Pension Incentive: Evidence of Currency Risk Management in
Multinational Companies
Reprinted from: J. Risk Financial Manag. 2020, 13, 24, doi:10.3390/jrfm13020024 . . . . . . . . . . 107

Ingrid-Mihaela Dragotă, Andreea Curmei-Semenescu and Raluca Moscu


CEO Diversity, Political Influences, and CEO Turnover in Unstable Environments:
The Romanian Case
Reprinted from: J. Risk Financial Manag. 2020, 13, 59, doi:10.3390/jrfm13030059 . . . . . . . . . . 137

Teresa Barros, Paula Rodrigues, Nelson Duarte, Xue-Feng Shao, F. V. Martins,


H. Barandas-Karl and Xiao-Guang Yue
The Impact of Brand Relationships on Corporate Brand Identity and Reputation—An
Integrative Model
Reprinted from: J. Risk Financial Manag. 2020, 13, 133, doi:10.3390/jrfm13060133 . . . . . . . . . . 159

Haroon ur Rashid Khan, Waqas Bin Khidmat, Osama Al Hares, Naeem Muhammad and
Kashif Saleem
Corporate Governance Quality, Ownership Structure, Agency Costs and Firm Performance.
Evidence from an Emerging Economy
Reprinted from: J. Risk Financial Manag. 2020, 13, 154, doi:10.3390/jrfm13070154 . . . . . . . . . 181

v
Micheal Forzeh Fossung, Lious Agbor Tabot Ntoung, Helena Maria Santos de Oliveira,
Cláudia Maria Ferreira Pereira, Susana Adelina Moreira Carvalho Bastos and
Liliana Marques Pimentel
Transition to the Revised OHADA Law on Accounting and Financial Reporting: Corporate
Perceptions of Costs and Benefits
Reprinted from: J. Risk Financial Manag. 2020, 13, 172, doi:10.3390/jrfm13080172 . . . . . . . . . 215

David K. Ding, Hardjo Koerniadi and Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti


What Drives the Declining Wealth Effect of Subsequent Share Repurchase Announcements?
Reprinted from: J. Risk Financial Manag. 2020, 13, 176, doi:10.3390/jrfm13080176 . . . . . . . . . . 235

Joanna Błach, Monika Wieczorek-Kosmala and Joanna Trzęsiok


Innovation in SMEs and Financing Mix
Reprinted from: J. Risk Financial Manag. 2020, 13, 206, doi:10.3390/jrfm13090206 . . . . . . . . . . 249

Róbert Štefko, Jarmila Horváthová and Martina Mokrišová


Bankruptcy Prediction with the Use of Data Envelopment Analysis: An Empirical Study of
Slovak Businesses
Reprinted from: J. Risk Financial Manag. 2020, 13, 212, doi:10.3390/jrfm13090212 . . . . . . . . . 269

Kojima Koji, Bishnu Kumar Adhikary and Le Tram


Corporate Governance and Firm Performance: A Comparative Analysis between Listed Family
and Non-Family Firms in Japan
Reprinted from: J. Risk Financial Manag. 2020, 13, 215, doi:10.3390/jrfm13090215 . . . . . . . . . 285

Marek Gruszczyński
Women on Boards and Firm Performance: A Microeconometric Search for a Connection
Reprinted from: J. Risk Financial Manag. 2020, 13, 218, doi:10.3390/jrfm13090218 . . . . . . . . . 305

Marcin Kedzior, Barbara Grabinska, Konrad Grabinski and Dorota Kedzior


Capital Structure Choices in Technology Firms: Empirical Results from Polish
Listed Companies
Reprinted from: J. Risk Financial Manag. 2020, 13, 221, doi:10.3390/jrfm13090221 . . . . . . . . . 319

Oliver Lukason and Marı́a-del-Mar Camacho-Miñano


Corporate Governance Characteristics of Private SMEs’ Annual Report Submission Violations
Reprinted from: J. Risk Financial Manag. 2020, 13, 230, doi:10.3390/jrfm13100230 . . . . . . . . . 339

Maria Aluchna and Tomasz Kuszewski


Does Corporate Governance Compliance Increase Company Value? Evidence from the Best
Practice of the Board
Reprinted from: J. Risk Financial Manag. 2020, 13, 242, doi:10.3390/jrfm13100242 . . . . . . . . . 359

Frode Kjærland, Ane Tolnes Haugdal, Anna Søndergaard and Anne Vågslid
Corporate Governance and Earnings Management in a Nordic Perspective: Evidence from the
Oslo Stock Exchange
Reprinted from: J. Risk Financial Manag. 2020, 13, 256, doi:10.3390/jrfm13110256 . . . . . . . . . . 381

vi
About the Editor
Ştefan Cristian Gherghina, Ph.D. Habil., is an Associate Professor of the Department of Finance,
Faculty of Finance and Banking and Ph.D. supervisor at the Finance Doctoral School, Bucharest
University of Economic Studies, Romania. His areas of interest are focused on corporate finance,
corporate governance, quantitative finance, portfolio management, and sustainable development. He
authored and co-authored several books, as well as articles published in top journals, and exhibited
his studies at many international conferences. He serves as a referee for various leading journals,
being also Editorial Board Member of the Journal of Risk and Financial Management, among other
journals indexed Clarivate Analytics—Web of Science—Social Sciences Citation Index (SSCI), Science
Citation Index Expanded (SCIE), and further reputed international databases.

vii
Journal of
Risk and Financial
Management

Editorial
Corporate Finance
S, tefan Cristian Gherghina
Department of Finance, Bucharest University of Economic Studies, 6 Piata Romana, 010374 Bucharest, Romania;
stefan.gherghina@fin.ase.ro

Academic Editor: Michael McAleer


Received: 21 December 2020; Accepted: 23 December 2020; Published: 21 January 2021

Corporate finance deals with the financing and investment decisions set by the corporations’
management in order to maximize the value of the shareholders’ wealth. However, due to the separation
of ownership and control, managerial goals are pursued at the expense of the shareholders. Stockholder
prosperity is enlarged through financial managers making rational investments, financing, and dividend
resolutions. Moreover, for the longstanding success of the corporation, the board should be operative and
be jointly accountable.
Corporate finance is concerned with the efficient and effective administration of the company funds
so as to accomplish the aims of that business, comprising forecasting and monitoring the supply of capital
(where funds are brought up), the distribution of funds (where resources are directed), and the supervision
of resources (whether funds are being used effectively or not) (Watson and Head 2016). Corporate finance is
grounded on three principles, namely the investment principle (establishes where corporations invest their
funds), the financing principle (manages the mixture of funding—debt and equity—laid down to finance
the investments), and the dividend principle (sets the amount of earnings that should be reinvested back
into the firm and how much should be repaid to the owners of the corporation) (Damodaran 2014). The
supreme objective is to augment wealth for the supplier of capitals, especially stockholders (Vernimmen
et al. 2018). Therefore, the secret of triumph in financial management is to increase value (Brealey et al.
2018). Legally, managers have a fiduciary obligation to the owners, which imply that management should
prioritize the interests of the shareholders over their own (Parrino et al. 2011). However, due to the
split of ownership and control, corporations encourage managerial goals at the expense of shareholders
(Ross et al. 2015). Such a dispute is an entitled agency problem (Ross et al. 2017). Corporate governance
addresses the challenges that ensue from the division of proprietorship and management, being focused
on the internal structure and guidelines of the board of directors, the formation of independent audit
committees, standards for information reporting to stockholders and lenders, as well as management
oversight (Fernando et al. 2018). Therefore, corporate governance regulates and monitors corporate
behavior, considers the interests of stakeholders, pledges for a trustworthy enterprise conduct, and has
the final purpose of reaching the utmost level of efficiency and profitability for the company (Plessis et al.
2011). In this regard, corporations are responsible to the entire society, upcoming generations, and the
natural world (Solomon and Solomon 2004).
This book comprises 19 papers published in the Special Issue entitled “Corporate Finance”, focused
on capital structure (Kedzior et al. 2020; Ntoung et al. 2020; Vintilă et al. 2019), dividend policy (Dragotă
and Delcea 2019; Pinto and Rastogi 2019) and open market share repurchase announcements (Ding et al.
2020), risk management (Chen et al. 2020; Nguyen Thanh 2019; Štefko et al. 2020), financial reporting
(Fossung et al. 2020), corporate brand and innovation (Barros et al. 2020; Błach et al. 2020), and corporate
governance (Aluchna and Kuszewski 2020; Dragotă et al. 2020; Gruszczyński 2020; Kjærland et al. 2020;
Koji et al. 2020; Lukason and Camacho-Miñano 2020; Rashid Khan et al. 2020), covering companies

JRFM 2021, 14, 44; doi:10.3390/jrfm14020044 www.mdpi.com/journal/jrfm

1
JRFM 2021, 14, 44

worldwide (Cameroon, China, Estonia, India, Japan, Norway, Poland, Romania, Slovakia, Spain, United
States, Vietnam), as well as various industries (heat supply, high-tech, manufacturing).
Capital structure policies are among the essential part driving the orientation of decisions that fulfill
several contradictory objectives which demanding stakeholders place before a financial director (Agarwal
2013). With regard to the papers concerning capital structure, Vintilă et al. (2019) established that factors
such as tangibility, growth, size, or liquidity have an important influence on long-term and short-term
debt rates of corporations part of the technology industry and listed on the New York Stock Exchange.
Furthermore, Kedzior et al. (2020) concluded that liquidity, firm age, and investments in innovativeness
determine capital structure of companies listed in the Warsaw Stock Exchange that are classified as
high-tech firms. For a sample consisting of 888 Spanish unlisted small and medium size firms, Ntoung et al.
(2020) proved that most family companies use less debt financing than non-family firms, and therefore
preserve a lower level of debt.
Dividend decisions are a kind of financing decision that influence the amount of earnings that a
corporation allocates to stockholders against the portion it holds and reinvests (Baker 2009). Amid the topic
of dividend policy, Dragotă and Delcea (2019) suggested an agent-based model for assessing the duration
of systematically making bad decisions and noticed that this period can be very long. For a balanced data
covering 424 companies out of the NIFTY 500 NSE-index, Pinto and Rastogi (2019) found that corporations
with a larger size, higher interest coverage ratio and profitability, but low business risk and debt, are
likely to distribute higher dividends in India. In addition, a different way to pay cash to investors is
through a share repurchase or buyback (Berk and DeMarzo 2017), the frequent method being open market
share repurchase whose approval is granted by the board of directors or subsequent to a shareholders
meeting (Vermaelen 2005). The paper of Ding et al. (2020) documented for the case of the United States
that, compared with companies which do not repeat share repurchase announcements, corporations
that reiterate their share repurchase programs register higher growth opportunities, have more free cash
flows, are more profitable, less undervalued, larger, and show significantly lower cumulative abnormal
announcement period returns.
Corporations encounter an extensive variety of risks that can influence the outcome of their activities
(Hopkin 2017). Nevertheless, the financial risk that ensues from uncertainty can be handled (Crouhy
et al. 2006). In addition, to pay off purchases of resources and services for the daily operation of business,
companies require cash (Paramasivan and Subramanian 2009). Concerning the papers regarding risk,
Nguyen Thanh (2019) explored 306 non-financial companies listed on the Vietnam Stock Exchange and
highlighted that a proportion of cash holding within a threshold of 9.93% can contribute to improvement of
the company’s efficiency. By means of a sample of 1625 multinational companies out of the United States,
Chen et al. (2020) proved that pension incentive should promote executives to more actively manage firms’
risk. For 497 companies operating in Slovakia in the heat supply industry, Štefko et al. (2020) supported
that the data envelopment analysis (DEA) method is an appropriate alternative for predicting the failure
of the explored sample.
Inside and outside stakeholders use the financial reports for taking decisions (Gibson 2007). With
reference to the manuscripts regarding financial reporting, Fossung et al. (2020) emphasized, based
on a questionnaire distributed to 80 professional accountants drawn mostly from the Institute of
Chartered Accountants of Cameroon (ONECCA), that financial statements prepared in conformity with
the International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS) are more suitable in presenting a true and fair view.
The essential features that outline the corporate brand as a distinct field are intangibility, complexity,
and responsibility (Ind 1997), whereas its subjects are the whole persons interested in the merchandise offer
(Ormeño 2007). Corporate branding enables companies to use their culture and values as an advertising
instrument and as a guarantee of value to the market (Roper and Fill 2012). In this respect, the study of
Barros et al. (2020) demonstrated that the concept of brand relationships covers three dimensions: trust,

2
JRFM 2021, 14, 44

commitment, and motivation. Furthermore, the transformation of governance structure can influence the
outcomes regarding innovation by assigning managers focused on innovation, by supporting investments
in the scientific and technological sector, and by appealing associates in the share capital so as to take on
fresh business initiatives and hence alleviate perils (Rangone 2020). The paper of Błach et al. (2020) focused
on small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) in the European Union and found that SMEs from the new
member states try to catch up with SMEs from nations with a higher level of development, concentrating
on product innovations.
With the purpose of preserving rightfulness and reliability, corporate management needs to be
effectively responsible to some independent, experienced, and inspired delegate (Monks and Minow
2004) so as to balance the interests of varied stakeholders (Minciullo 2019). In this respect, corporate
governance deals with how the board of a corporation acts and specifically how it sets the values of the
firm (Simpson and Taylor 2013). The board of directors manage and govern a company and, accordingly,
an effective board is vital to the success of the corporation (Mallin 2013). Among the papers related
to the corporate governance, Dragotă et al. (2020) investigated 36 companies listed on the Bucharest
Stock Exchange and noticed the political inference in Chief Executive Officer (CEO) turnover decision.
Furthermore, Aluchna and Kuszewski (2020) explored declarations of conformity for a sample of 155
companies listed on the Warsaw Stock Exchange and revealed a negative and statistically significant
association among corporate governance compliance and company value. Lukason and Camacho-Miñano
(2020) explored 77,212 private SMEs from Estonia and showed that the presence of woman on the board,
higher manager’s age, longer tenure, and a larger proportion of stock owned by board members lead to
less-likely violation of the annual report submission deadline, but in turn, the presence of more business
ties and existence of a majority owner behave in the opposite way. With reference to boardroom gender
diversity, the manuscript of Gruszczyński (2020) explored 1194 companies out of 18 European countries
and found that female presence on a board is not significantly related to firm performance. As regards the
influence of corporate governance on earnings management, Kjærland et al. (2020) found for a sample
of 168 companies listed on the Oslo Stock Exchange that board independence and share ownership by
directors positively influence earnings management, whereas board activity and directors as majority
shareholders did not reveal a statistically significant effect. With reference to the impact of corporate
governance on firm performance, Koji et al. (2020) explored 1412 Japanese manufacturing firms and
established that institutional shareholding and foreign ownership promote the performance of both family
and non-family companies. Rashid Rashid Khan et al. (2020) concluded for 2248 Chinese A-listed firms a
positive moderating effect of corporate governance quality and ownership concentration on the connection
between agency cost and firm performance, whilst non-state (state) ownership of companies positively
(negatively) moderates the agency–performance link.
As a final remark, the set of manuscripts covered by this Special Issue broadened the knowledge on
corporate finance worldwide and proposed fascinating future research directions.

Funding: This research received no external funding.


Conflicts of Interest: The author declares no conflict of interest.

References
Agarwal, Yamini. 2013. Capital Structure Decisions: Evaluating Risk and Uncertainty. Solaris South Tower. Singapore:
Wiley.
Aluchna, Maria, and Tomasz Kuszewski. 2020. Does Corporate Governance Compliance Increase Company Value?
Evidence from the Best Practice of the Board. Journal of Risk and Financial Management 13: 242. [CrossRef]
Baker, H. Kent. 2009. Dividends and Dividend Policy. Hoboken: Wiley.

3
JRFM 2021, 14, 44

Barros, Teresa, Paula Rodrigues, Nelson Duarte, Xue-Feng Shao, F. V. Martins, H. Barandas-Karl, and Xiao-Guang Yue.
2020. The Impact of Brand Relationships on Corporate Brand Identity and Reputation—An Integrative Model.
Journal of Risk and Financial Management 13: 133. [CrossRef]
Berk, Jonathan B., and Peter M. DeMarzo. 2017. Corporate Finance, 4th ed. Harlow: Pearson.
Błach, Joanna, Monika Wieczorek-Kosmala, and Joanna Trz˛esiok. 2020. Innovation in SMEs and Financing Mix. Journal
of Risk and Financial Management 13: 206. [CrossRef]
Brealey, Richard A., Stewart C. Myers, and Franklin Allen. 2018. Principles of Corporate Finance, 12th ed. New York:
McGraw-Hill Education.
Chen, Jeffrey, Yun Guan, and Ivy Tang. 2020. Optimal Contracting of Pension Incentive: Evidence of Currency Risk
Management in Multinational Companies. Journal of Risk and Financial Management 13: 24. [CrossRef]
Crouhy, Michel, Dan Galai, and Robert Mark. 2006. The Essentials of Risk Management. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Damodaran, Aswath. 2014. Applied Corporate Finance, 4th ed. Hoboken: Wiley.
Ding, David K., Hardjo Koerniadi, and Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti. 2020. What Drives the Declining Wealth Effect
of Subsequent Share Repurchase Announcements? Journal of Risk and Financial Management 13: 176. [CrossRef]
Dragotă, Victor, and Camelia Delcea. 2019. How Long Does It Last to Systematically Make Bad Decisions? An
Agent-Based Application for Dividend Policy. Journal of Risk and Financial Management 12: 167. [CrossRef]
Dragotă, Ingrid-Mihaela, Andreea Curmei-Semenescu, and Raluca Moscu. 2020. CEO Diversity, Political Influences,
and CEO Turnover in Unstable Environments: The Romanian Case. Journal of Risk and Financial Management 13:
59. [CrossRef]
Fernando, A. C., K. P. Muraleedharan, and E. K. Satheesh. 2018. Corporate Governance: Principles, Policies and Practices,
3rd ed. Uttar Pradesh: Pearson.
Fossung, Micheal Forzeh, Lious Agbor Tabot Ntoung, Helena Maria Santos de Oliveira, Cláudia Maria Ferreira
Pereira, Susana Adelina Moreira Carvalho Bastos, and Liliana Marques Pimentel. 2020. Transition to the Revised
OHADA Law on Accounting and Financial Reporting: Corporate Perceptions of Costs and Benefits. Journal of
Risk and Financial Management 13: 172. [CrossRef]
Gibson, Charles H. 2007. Financial Reporting and Analysis: Using Financial Accounting Information, 11th ed. Mason:
South-Western Cengage Learning.
Gruszczyński, Marek. 2020. Women on Boards and Firm Performance: A Microeconometric Search for a Connection.
Journal of Risk and Financial Management 13: 218. [CrossRef]
Hopkin, Paul. 2017. Fundamentals of Risk Management: Understanding, Evaluating and Implementing Effective Risk
Management, 4th ed. Croydon: Kogan Page.
Ind, Nicholas. 1997. The Corporate Brand. Hampshire: Macmillan.
Kedzior, Marcin, Barbara Grabinska, Konrad Grabinski, and Dorota Kedzior. 2020. Capital Structure Choices in
Technology Firms: Empirical Results from Polish Listed Companies. Journal of Risk and Financial Management 13:
221. [CrossRef]
Kjærland, Frode, Ane Tolnes Haugdal, Anna Søndergaard, and Anne Vågslid. 2020. Corporate Governance and
Earnings Management in a Nordic Perspective: Evidence from the Oslo Stock Exchange. Journal of Risk and
Financial Management 13: 256. [CrossRef]
Koji, Kojima, Bishnu Kumar Adhikary, and Le Tram. 2020. Corporate Governance and Firm Performance: A
Comparative Analysis between Listed Family and Non-Family Firms in Japan. Journal of Risk and Financial
Management 13: 215. [CrossRef]
Lukason, Oliver, and María-del-Mar Camacho-Miñano. 2020. Corporate Governance Characteristics of Private SMEs’
Annual Report Submission Violations. Journal of Risk and Financial Management 13: 230. [CrossRef]
Mallin, Christine A. 2013. Corporate Governance, 4th ed. Hampshire: Oxford University Press.
Minciullo, Marco. 2019. Corporate Governance and Sustainability: The Role of the Board of Directors. Cham: Palgrave
Macmillan.
Monks, Robert A. G., and Nell Minow. 2004. Corporate Governance, 3rd ed. Malden: Blackwell Publishing.
Nguyen Thanh, Cuong. 2019. Optimal Cash Holding Ratio for Non-Financial Firms in Vietnam Stock Exchange
Market. Journal of Risk and Financial Management 12: 104. [CrossRef]

4
JRFM 2021, 14, 44

Ntoung, Lious Agbor Tabot, Helena Maria Santos de Oliveira, Benjamim Manuel Ferreira de Sousa, Liliana Marques
Pimentel, and Susana Adelina Moreira Carvalho Bastos. 2020. Are Family Firms Financially Healthier Than
Non-Family Firm? Journal of Risk and Financial Management 13: 5. [CrossRef]
Ormeño, Marcos. 2007. Managing Corporate Brands: A New Approach to Corporate Communication. Deutscher: Deutscher
Universitätsverlag.
Paramasivan, C., and T. Subramanian. 2009. Financial Management. New Delhi: New Age International.
Parrino, Robert, David S. Kidwell, and Thomas W. Bates. 2011. Fundamentals of Corporate Finance, 2nd ed. Hoboken:
Wiley.
Pinto, Geetanjali, and Shailesh Rastogi. 2019. Sectoral Analysis of Factors Influencing Dividend Policy: Case of an
Emerging Financial Market. Journal of Risk and Financial Management 12: 110. [CrossRef]
Plessis, Jean Jacques du, Anil Hargovan, and Mirko Bagaric. 2011. Principles of Contemporary Corporate Governance, 2nd
ed. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Rangone, Adalberto. 2020. Managing Corporate Innovation: Determinants, Critical Issues and Success Factors. Cham:
Springer International Publishing.
Rashid Khan, Haroon ur, Waqas Bin Khidmat, Osama Al Hares, Naeem Muhammad, and Kashif Saleem. 2020.
Corporate Governance Quality, Ownership Structure, Agency Costs and Firm Performance. Evidence from an
Emerging Economy. Journal of Risk and Financial Management 13: 154. [CrossRef]
Roper, Stuart, and Chris Fill. 2012. Corporate Reputation: Brand and Communication. Harlow: Pearson.
Ross, Stephen A., Randolph W. Westerfield, Jeffrey F. Jaffe, and Gordon S. Roberts. 2015. Corporate Finance. 7th
Canadian ed. Whitby: McGraw-Hill Ryerson.
Ross, Stephen A., Randolph W. Westerfield, and Bradford D. Jordan. 2017. Essentials of Corporate Finance, 9th ed. New
York: McGraw-Hill Education.
Simpson, Justine, and John Taylor. 2013. Corporate Governance, Ethics and CSR. Croydon: Kogan Page.
Solomon, Jill, and Aris Solomon. 2004. Corporate Governance and Accountability. Chichester: Wiley.
Štefko, Róbert, Jarmila Horváthová, and Martina Mokrišová. 2020. Bankruptcy Prediction with the Use of Data
Envelopment Analysis: An Empirical Study of Slovak Businesses. Journal of Risk and Financial Management 13:
212. [CrossRef]
Vermaelen, Theo. 2005. Share Repurchases. Foundations and Trends® in Finance 1: 171–268. [CrossRef]
Vernimmen, Pierre, Pascal Quiry, Maurizio Dallocchio, Yann Le Fur, and Antonio Salvi. 2018. Corporate Finance: Theory
and Practice, 5th ed. Hoboken: Wiley.
Vintilă, Georgeta, Ştefan Cristian Gherghina, and Diana Alexandra Toader. 2019. Exploring the Determinants of
Financial Structure in the Technology Industry: Panel Data Evidence from the New York Stock Exchange Listed
Companies. Journal of Risk and Financial Management 12: 163. [CrossRef]
Watson, Denzil, and Antony Head. 2016. Corporate Finance: Principles and Practice, 7th ed. Harlow: Pearson.

© 2021 by the author. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article
distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY)
license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).

5
Journal of
Risk and Financial
Management

Article
Optimal Cash Holding Ratio for Non-Financial Firms
in Vietnam Stock Exchange Market
Cuong Nguyen Thanh
Faculty of Accounting and Finance, Nha Trang University, Nha Trang City 650000, Vietnam;
Cuongnt@ntu.edu.vn

Received: 27 May 2019; Accepted: 16 June 2019; Published: 20 June 2019

Abstract: The purpose of this research is to investigate whether there is an optimal cash holding
ratio, in which firm’s performance can be maximized. The threshold regression model is applied
to test the threshold effect of the cash holding ratio on firm’s performance of 306 non-financial
companies listed on the Vietnam stock exchange market during the period of 2008–2017. Experimental
results showed that a single-threshold effect exists between the ratio of cash holding and company’s
performance. A proportion of cash holding within a threshold of 9.93% can contribute to improvement
of the company’s efficiency. The coefficient is positive but tends to decrease when the cash holding
ratio passes the 9.93% check point, implying that an increase in cash holdings ratio will continue
to diminishment of efficiency eventually. Therefore, the relationship between cash holding ratio
and firm’s performance is nonlinear. From this result, this paper provides policy implications for
non-financial companies listed on the Vietnam stock exchange market in determining the proportion
of cash holding flexibly. In detail, non-financial companies listed on the Vietnam stock exchange
market should not keep the cash holding ratio over 9.93%. To ensure and enhance the company’s
performance, the optimal range of cash holding ratios should be below 9.93%.

Keywords: cash holding ratio; firm’s efficiency; threshold regression model; non-financial companies;
Vietnam stock exchange market

1. Introduction
The amount of cash held plays an important role in most companies because it provides the ability
to pay in cash and directly affects the performance of the company. The amount of cash held by the
company is understood as cash and cash equivalents such as bank deposits and short-term securities
which are able to be quickly converted into money (Bates et al. 2009; Ferreira and Vilela 2004). If the
company holds a large amount of cash, the opportunity cost will arise. However, if a company holds
too little cash, it may not be enough to cover the regular expenses. Therefore, the amount of cash held
by the company must be sufficient to ensure regular operations solvency, contingency for emergencies,
and also future projections (if needed). Dittmar and Mahrt-Smith (2007) stated that in 2003, the sum of
all cash and cash equivalents represented more than 13% of the sum of all assets for large US firms.
Al-Najjar and Belghitar (2011) found that cash represents, on average, 9% of the total assets for UK
firms. In Vietnam context, the cash and cash equivalents account for more than 10% of total assets of
firms. Thus, cash represents a sizeable asset for firms. Cash management may therefore be a key issue
for corporate financial policies.
Regarding this topic, the first studies looked at antecedents of corporate cash holdings (Ferreira
and Vilela 2004; Kim et al. 1998; Opler et al. 1999; Ozkan and Ozkan 2004). Most of these papers
assume that cash holding is determined by the firm characteristics (i.e., leverage, growth opportunities,
cash flow, investment in fixed assets, and size of the firm) and industry sector. In addition, Sheikh
and Khan (2016) showed that cash holding is determined not only by the firm characteristics but

JRFM 2019, 12, 104; doi:10.3390/jrfm12020104 7 www.mdpi.com/journal/jrfm


JRFM 2019, 12, 104

also by the manager characteristics (i.e., age, gender, whether or not the manager is a chief executive
officer, and whether or not the manager is a board director). Besides, corporate governance may also
affect the value of a firm’s cash holdings. Evidence by Dittmar and Mahrt-Smith (2007) shows that
investors value the excess cash holdings of well-governed firms at nearly double the value of the
poorly governed firms.
Despite the increasing amount of literature on corporate cash holding, there are not many studies
focusing on the relationship between cash holding and company performance. At the same time,
corporate cash holdings have benefits and costs for the firm and, consequently, an optimum cash
level may exist at which the performance of the firm is maximized. Evidence by Martínez-Sola et al.
(2013) shows that in US industrial firms there exists an optimal cash holding ratio. This finding is also
consistent with Azmat (2014), which found the existence of optimal cash level for a sample of listed
Pakistani firms. Following this optimal level, firms will adjust their cash reserve to maximize firm
value. On the other hand, most of the research work has been carried out in developed economies and
very little is known about the cash holding of firms in developing economies.
According to Horioka and Terada-Hagiwara (2014), Asian firms are heavily constrained by
borrowing limits and will hold more cash for future investments than firms in developed countries.
Hence, our focus on an emerging country, Vietnam, allows us to offer a number of new insights
beyond the existing studies of the relationship between cash holdings and firm’s performance.
In Vietnam context, given the great opportunities and challenges now, companies need to focus on cash
management, as lifeblood of the company. Therefore, the current question for listed companies on the
Vietnam stock exchange market is how to manage cash in order to improve operational efficiency and
contribute to increase of the company’s value. To solve this problem, listed companies on the Vietnam
stock exchange market need to know how the cash holding ratio affects the firm’s performance.
In this study, the goal is to indicate to what extent the cash holding ratio will have a positive
effect on increase of the company’s performance and to what extent the cash holding ratio will have a
negative effect on reduction of company’s performance. Different from previous studies, this study
applies the threshold regression model of Hansen (1999) to build the model to investigate the impact
of cash holding ratio on the performance of the listed companies on the Vietnam stock exchange
market. The results show empirically that an optimum level of cash holdings exists where firm’s
performance is maximum, for a sample of 306 listed non-financial Vietnamese companies during
2008–2017. Deviations from the optimum level reduce firm value. It means that firms should balance
the costs and benefits of cash holdings to find the optimal cash level to maximize firm’s performance
and value. If a firm has a cash holding above or below the optimal level, its performance and value
will decrease. The results of this study can help managers of listed companies on the Vietnam stock
exchange market to adjust the cash holding ratio to improve operational efficiency and contribute to
the increase of the company’s value.
To the best of author’s knowledge, until now, there has been no published research on the
application of threshold regression model to study this relationship. Hence, by using the threshold
regression model developed by Hansen (1999), this study further fills the gap in the literature on the
behavior of firms, and focuses on evidence of cash policies and firm’s performance.
The paper includes five parts: Section 1 introduces research issues; Section 2 presents a theoretical
overview and a research model; Section 3 presents data collection and methods; Section 4 presents
the results of empirical research; the final section summarizes the findings and implications for
cash management.

2. Literature Reviews and Hypothesis


Making a decision to hold an amount of cash in the company will affect efficiency or dynamics
and corporate value. Each company has different reasons for holding cash; according to previous
studies, there are major motives for the company to hold cash, that is:

8
JRFM 2019, 12, 104

Trading motive: Cash is the mean of exchange, so companies need cash to conduct daily
transactions; however, the demands for cash of different companies are not the same (Bates et al. 2009;
Opler et al. 1999). According to Nguyen et al. (2016), when firms have insufficient internal funds
or liquid assets, they will raise funds from external capital markets, liquidate existing assets, limit
dividend payouts, and reduce investment opportunities. However, all of these activities are costly.
Prevention motive: In addition to keeping cash for daily transactions, companies also need
cash reserves for unexpected spending needs. According to Ferreira and Vilela (2004), the company
holds cash to finance financial or investment activities when other resources are unavailable or very
costly; however, each company has various demands for cash reserves in obtaining different objectives
depending on situations.
Signal motive: Because of information asymmetry between managers and shareholders, managers
will signal the prospects of the company to investors through their dividend payment policy. According
to Harford (1999), the payment of dividends is more positive than the purchase of treasury shares by
cash, because dividend payment generates a signal of a commitment to a higher dividend payment in
the future; meanwhile, buying treasury securities is considered to be this year’s event only, and should
not continue in the next year.
Represent motive: Managers can decide whether the company will withhold cash or pay
dividends to shareholders. The free cash flow might increase discretion by managers, which goes
against shareholders’ interest (Jensen 1986). The study of Harford (1999) confirmed that companies with
large amounts of cash tend to spend a lot of money to conduct numerous acquisitions. Furthermore,
the study of Blanchard et al. (1994) provided evidence that firms do not pay dividends during a period
of time but making zero acquisitions will spend their cash in many other investment activities.
The corporate cash holding determinants have been a subject of explanation in the framework of
three theories, namely the trade-off model, pecking order theory, and free cash flow theory.
The free cash flow theory suggests that managers hold cash to serve their own interests,
thus increasing the conflict between investors and company’s managers (Harford 1999; Jensen 1986).
The theory of free cash flow also highlights the representative cost of holding cash. Companies with
high growth opportunities have high agency costs, so they will tend to store more cash in order to be
proactive in their capital. If there is a conflict between management and shareholders, management
tends to store as much cash as possible to pursue their goals. Cash can be paid not only for making
profits, but also for projects where investors are not ready to raise capital. Moreover, the board can also
hold cash because of risk aversion.
The pecking order theory of Myers and Majluf (1984) suggests that managers can decide the
order of capital financing to minimize the cost of information asymmetry and other financial costs.
This theory implies that companies prefer internal financing. The directors adjust the dividend payout
ratio to avoid the sale of ordinary shares, preventing a major change in the number of shares. If external
funding is available, Myers and Majluf (1984) believed that the safest securities should be issued first.
Specifically, debt is usually the first security to be issued and equity sold outside is the last solution.
However, Myers and Majluf (1984) also argued that there will be no optimal level of cash holdings, but
holding cash should serve as a buffer between retaining profits and investment needs.
The trade-off theory suggests that companies can finance by borrowing or retaining cash and they
all have their advantages and costs. With the trade-off theory, also called transaction cost model of
Opler et al. (1999), the company can determine a level of cash holdings by balancing the marginal cost
of holding highly liquid assets and the profit margins of holding cash. Profit margins of cash holdings
will reduce the likelihood of financial distress, allowing the company to make optimal investments
and avoiding the costs incurred by external funding or liquidation of assets of company. Because
the market is imperfect, it is difficult for companies to access the capital market or to bear the cost of
external funding. The marginal cost of holding cash is the opportunity cost of holding cash when it
offers less benefit than investing in an equal risk condition (Ferreira and Vilela 2004; Opler et al. 1999).
When companies need cash to meet their expenses, they need external funding from the capital market

9
JRFM 2019, 12, 104

or liquidate their assets. Since the capital markets are imperfect, transaction costs can be avoided by
holding an optimal cash level.
Based on the benefits and costs of holding cash, there have been a few recent studies on the
relationship between the amount of cash held and the performance or value of the company. The real
impact of cash on firm’s performance or value is still being debated on the basis of empirical theory
and evidence, creating many different perspectives.
The first view is that a high ratio of cash reserves will reduce the performance or value of the
company. Supporting this point of view, Harford (1999) examined the relation between a firm’s
acquisition policy and its cash holding. It was shown by the results that firms with a large amount
of cash are more likely to make acquisitions that will decrease operational efficiency and firm value.
The results of this empirical study are explained based on the theory of free cash flow. It means that
managers of firms with a large amount of cash desire to increase the scope of their authority. In another
study, Harford et al. (2008) concluded that firms with poor governance will spend more cash than other
similar firms since the entrenched managers will prefer to overinvest rather than reserving cash for
firms. Therefore, firms with a high level of cash holdings will have a lower firm performance or value.
The second opinion supports the existence of a positive relationship between business value and
the amount of cash held. Saddour (2006) studied the relationship between firm’s value and the amount
of cash held on the French stock exchange market in the period of 1998–2002. The results indicate that
high cash reserves will increase operational efficiency or company’s value. Similarly, Bates et al. (2009)
also found evidence that firms hold more cash when firms’ cash flow becomes riskier. This evidence
strongly supports the precautionary motivations of cash holdings and implies a positive relationship
between firm value and cash holdings.
The third view believes in a nonlinear relationship between cash holding and firm’s performance
or value. Supporting this perspective, Martínez-Sola et al. (2013) used US industry’s data from
2001 to 2007, and found a nonlinear relationship between cash holding ratio and company’s value.
They explained that the concave relationship between cash holdings and firm value exists because
firms balance the costs and benefits of cash holdings to identify the optimal level of cash. Following
this optimal level, firms will adjust their cash reserve to maximize the firm value. This result was also
discovered earlier by Azmat (2014), who found the existence of optimal cash level for a sample of
listed Pakistan firms from 2003 to 2008. In Vietnam, Nguyen et al. (2016) investigated the nonlinear
relationship between firm value and corporate cash holdings in a sample of non-financial Vietnamese
firms from 2008 to 2013. Authors focused on both static and dynamic regressions to test for a nonlinear
relationship. Their results reveal an “inverse U-shape” relationship between firm value and cash
holdings, which is in line with the trade-off theory.
According to the trade-off theory, in the context of Vietnam firms, author still expect there is a
nonlinear relationship between cash holdings and company’s performance. Agreeing with thes studies
above, for this relationship, we set the hypothesis as following:

Hypothesis 1 (H1): There is a nonlinear relationship between cash holdings and company’s performance in
Vietnamese listed non-financial companies.

3. Data and Methodology

3.1. Data and Sample Collection


Data includes the annually audited financial statements which can be collected from the website:
https://vietstock.vn/. The companies selected for the sample are active non-financial companies,
with full financial reporting for the period of 2008–2017. With this sampling method, data collected
includes 306 non-financial companies operating in the 2008–2017 period. Consequently, the final dataset
is a strongly balanced panel dataset, which includes 3060 firm-year observations of 306 companies
(306 companies × 10 periods = 3060 observations).

10
JRFM 2019, 12, 104

3.2. Variables

3.2.1. Dependent Variable


When studying the relationship between firms’ cash holdings and performance, to measure
firms’ performance, Shinada (2012) used the return on asset (denoted by ROA). Iftikhar (2017) and
Vijayakumaran and Atchyuthan (2017) also used the ROA to measure company’s performance. Agreeing
with these above studies, we used the book value to calculate firms’ performance. The measurement
of firms’ performance was defined as below:

Profit before tax and interest


ROA = (1)
Total assets

3.2.2. Threshold and Explanatory Variables


There are two categories of explanatory variables in our panel data and threshold regression
model. One is the threshold variable, which is the key variable used to assess the optimal cash holding
ratio of a firm and to capture the threshold effect of cash holding on company’s performance.
The threshold variable is a variable. When the threshold variable is bigger or smaller than the
threshold value (γ), the samples can be divided into two groups, which can be expressed in different
slopes β1 and β2 . The explanatory variable is a variable, reflecting its impact on the dependent variable.
In the threshold regression model, explanatory variable impacts are not fixed but depend on the
threshold value of the threshold variable.
In this study, the measurement of threshold and independent variables through the cash holdings
ratio (denoted by CASH) was performed. Following previous studies (Azmat 2014; Martínez-Sola et al.
2013; Nguyen et al. 2016; Opler et al. 1999; Vijayakumaran and Atchyuthan 2017), the cash holdings
ratio was calculated as cash and cash equivalents divided by total assets. We used the book value to
calculate the cash holdings ratio. The measurement of firms’ cash holdings ratio was defined as below:

Cash and cash equivalents


CASH = (2)
Total assets

3.2.3. Control Variables


On the basis of previous studies (Azmat 2014; Martínez-Sola et al. 2013; Nguyen et al. 2016;
Vijayakumaran and Atchyuthan 2017), our threshold regression model includes several additional
variables to control for a set of firm-specific characteristic that are likely to be correlated with company’s
performance. These include firm size (denoted by SIZE), leverage (denoted by LEV), and firm’s growth
(denoted by MB). The following section will analyze interconnection between these variables relative
to company’s performance.
Firm size (SIZE): According to Dang et al. (2018), in empirical corporate finance, the firm size is
commonly used as an important, fundamental firm characteristic. They examined the influences of
employing different proxies (total assets, total sales, and market capitalization) of firm size. The results
show that, in most areas of corporate finance, the coefficients of firm size measures are robust in sign
and statistical significance. In addition, the coefficients on repressors other than firm size often change
sign and significance when different size measures are used. Therefore, the choice of size measures
needs both theoretical and empirical justification.
The firm size is considered one determinant of firm performance and value. Abor (2005) and
Vijayakumaran and Atchyuthan (2017) suggested that enterprises of higher size generally have higher
firm performance. On the other hand, researches by Cheng et al. (2010), Martínez-Sola et al. (2013),
and Nguyen et al. (2016) suggest that enterprises of higher size generally have lower firm performance
and value. Thus, the relationship between the size and the performance of companies is unclear.
To measure the firm size, there exist different perspectives. According to Azmat (2014), Nguyen et
al. (2016), and Vijayakumaran and Atchyuthan (2017), the firm size is defined by a natural logarithm

11
JRFM 2019, 12, 104

of total assets. Further, Martínez-Sola et al. (2013) showed that the firm size is defined by natural
logarithm gross sales. In this study, we only used the book value of total asset to calculate the firm size.
The measurement of firm size was defined as below:

SIZE = Ln(Book value of Total assets) (3)

Growth (MB) is considered to be a factor related to firm performance. Abor (2005) suggested that
enterprises of higher growth opportunities generally have higher profitability. On the other hand,
researches by Nguyen et al. (2016) suggest that enterprises of higher growth generally have lower
firm performance and value. In addition, Vijayakumaran and Atchyuthan (2017) suggested that sales
growth is not significantly related to firm performance. Thus, the relationship between the growth and
the firm performance is unclear. To measure growth, there exist different perspectives. According to
Abor (2005), Nguyen et al. (2016), and Vijayakumaran and Atchyuthan (2017), growth is defined by
the growth rate on operating sales. Further, Cheng et al. (2010) showed that growth is defined by the
growth rate of operating sales and growth rate of total assets. In this study, growth was measured by
market value over the book value of stocks. The measurement of growth was defined as below:

Market value of stocks


MB = (4)
Book value of stocks
Leverage (LEV) is considered one determinant of firm performance and value. Abor (2005),
Nguyen et al. (2016), and Vijayakumaran and Atchyuthan (2017) suggested that enterprises of higher
leverage generally have lower profitability. On the other hand, researches by Martínez-Sola et al. (2013)
suggest that enterprises of higher leverage generally have higher firm value. In addition, the empirical
results by Cheng et al. (2010) strongly indicate that triple-threshold effect exists between leverage
and firm value. Thus, the relationship between the leverage and the firm performance is unclear.
To measure leverage, there exist different perspectives. According to Abor (2005), Azmat (2014),
and Nguyen et al. (2016), leverage is defined by total debt over total assets. Further, Martínez-Sola et
al. (2013) and Vijayakumaran and Atchyuthan (2017) showed that leverage is defined by total debt
over total equity. In this study, we only used the book value of total debt and total asset to calculate
leverage. The measurement of leverage was defined as below:

Market value of total debt


LEV = (5)
Book value of total assets

3.3. Models and Estimation Methods


This study aimed to test whether there is an optimal threshold between the cash holding ratio
and company’s performance. According to the trade-off theory, the optimal ratio of cash holdings is
determined by a trade-off between marginal cost and profit margin of cash holdings (Opler et al. 1999).
Therefore, this study assumed the existence of an optimal ratio of cash holdings, and tried to use
the threshold regression model to estimate this ratio. To test the hypothesis, this study applied the
threshold regression model of Hansen (1999). Single-threshold and multi-threshold models were based
on the threshold regression model of Hansen (1999) as follows.
The single-threshold regression model was shown as:

μi + θ Hi,t + β1 CASHi,t + εi,t if CASHi,t ≤ γ
ROAi,t = , (6)
μi + θ Hi,t + β2 CASHi,t + εi,t if CASHi,t > γ

where θ = (θ1 , θ2 , θ3 ) and Hi,t = (SIZEi,t , MBi,t , LEVi,t ); ROAi,t represents for firm’s performance,
measured by profit before tax and interest on total assets; CASHi,t represents the proportion of cash
held by the company, measured by the ratio of cash and cash equivalents on total assets; (CASHi,t )
is the explanatory variable and also the threshold variable, estimated at each different threshold;

12
JRFM 2019, 12, 104

Hi,t are control variables that affect company performance, including company size (SIZEi,t ), company
growth (MBi,t ) and leverage (LEVi,t ); θ1 , θ2 , and θ3 are the estimated regression coefficients of
the corresponding control variables; γ is the value of the estimated threshold; μi is a fixed effect
representing the heterogeneity of companies operating under different conditions; β1 and β2 are
regression coefficients of the proportion of cash held by the company;  the error εi,t is assumed to
be independent and has a normal distribution εi,t ∼ iid(0, σ2 ) ; i represents different companies;
t represents different periods.
According to Hansen (1999), for estimating procedures, this study first removed the fixed effect
(μi ) by using the techniques of estimating “internal transformation” in a traditional fixed-effects model
for panel data. By using the ordinary least square estimation method and minimizing the sum of
squared error (S1 (γ)), the test can obtain the estimation of the threshold value (γ̂) and the residual
variance (σ̂2 ).
For testing procedures, this research first tested the hypothesis that there is no threshold effect
(H0 : β1 = β2 ), using the likelihood ratio: F1 = (S0 − S1 (γ̂))/σ̂2 , where S0 and S1 (γ̂) are the sum of
squared error under hypothesis H0 and the opposite hypothesis (H1 : β1  β2 ), respectively. However,
since the asymptotic distribution of F1 is not normal, we used the bootstrap procedure to determine
critical values and probability values (p-value). When the p-value is less than the desired condition
value, we reject the H0 hypothesis.
When a threshold effect exists (β1  β2 ), Hansen (1999) considered that γ is consistent with γ0
(actual value of γ) and asymptotic distribution is not normal at a significant level. Therefore, we needed
to check the asymptotic distribution of the estimated threshold with the hypothesis H0 : γ = γ0 ,
by applying the likelihood
√ ratio: LR1 = (S1 (γ) − S1 (γ̂))/σ̂2 with asymptotic confidence intervals of
c(α) = −2 log (1 − 1 − α), where α is the significance level (1%, 5%, and 10%). With the significance
level α and LR1 (γ0 ) > C(α), we can reject the hypothesis H0 : γ = γ0 , meaning that the actual
threshold value is not equal to the estimated threshold value.
If there exists a double threshold, the model can be modified as follows:


⎪ μi + θ Hi,t + β1 CASHi,t + εit , if CASHi,t ≤ γ1

⎨ 
ROAi,t = ⎪
⎪ μi + θ Hi,t + β2 CASHi,t + εit , if γ1 < CASHi,t ≤ γ2 , (7)

⎩ μ + θ H + β CASH + ε ,
i i,t 3 i,t it if CASHi,t > γ2

where γ1 < γ2 . This can be extended to multi-threshold models (γ1 , γ2, γ3 , . . . , γn ).


According to Li (2016), in econometrics, the endogeneity problem arises when the explanatory
variables and the error term are correlated in a regression model, leading to biased and inconsistent
parameter estimates. Particularly, this problem plagues almost every aspect of empirical corporate
finance. To solve for the endogeneity problem, among all the remedies, the generalized method
of moments (GMM) has the greatest correction effect on the coefficient, followed by instrumental
variables, fixed-effects models, lagged dependent variables, and control variables.
Earlier literature on corporate cash holdings showed that there exist problems of endogeneity
and omitted variable bias (Ozkan and Ozkan 2004). The endogeneity problem might arise in cash
literature for several reasons. For example, firm-specific characteristics are not strictly exogenous,
and have shocks affecting firm performance as well as influencing dependent variable CASH like size
and leverage. Additionally, the presence of dependent variables may be correlated with past and
current residual terms. To solve for the endogeneity problem that appears in the empirical analysis
of cash holdings and firm value, Martínez-Sola et al. (2013), Azmat (2014) and Nguyen et al. (2016)
applied the dynamic regression model—GMM estimation.
The threshold regression methods by Hansen (1999) were developed for non-dynamic panels with
individual specific fixed effects. Least squares estimation of the threshold and regression slopes was
proposed using fixed-effects transformations. This method has the disadvantage that the independent
variables in the model are exogenous assumptions, which may in fact be endogenous. Therefore,

13
JRFM 2019, 12, 104

this method explicitly excludes the presence of endogenous variables, and this has been an impediment
to empirical application, including dynamic panel models.

4. Results and Discussions

4.1. Descriptive Statistics for Variables in the Model


Table 1 below presents descriptive statistic for the variables in the model. All of these variables
were calculated based on the financial information collected from the balance sheet and income
statement of 306 non-financial companies listed on the Vietnam stock exchange market in the period
of 2008–2017.

Table 1. Descriptive statistic of variables.

Variables Observations Mean Median SD Min Max


ROA 3060 0.0955 0.0850 0.0991 −1.6451 1.1362
CASH 3060 0.1049 0.0625 0.1189 0.0001 0.9546
SIZE 3060 26.6859 26.6279 1.4318 22.6384 31.6017
MB 3060 1.1012 0.8640 0.8965 0.1001 9.2005
LEV 3060 0.4852 0.5043 0.2306 0.0056 0.9982
Note: ROA represents company performance, measured by profit before tax and interest on total assets; CASH
represents the percentage of cash held by the company, measured by the ratio of money and cash equivalents to
total assets; MB represents company growth, measured by market value over book value of stocks; SIZE represents
company size, measured by Ln (total assets); LEV represents company leverage, measured by total debt over
total assets.

The statistical results described in Table 1 showed that the average ROA is 9.55%, indicating that
in average with 1 VND (VND commonly refers to Vietnamese đồng, the currency of Vietnam) of capital
used annually, firms can generate about 0.0955 VND profit before tax and interest. The average cash
holding ratio (CASH) is 10.49%, indicating that cash and cash equivalents account for 10.49% of the
company’s total assets. The average firm’s size is 26.6859, equivalent to 389 billion VND, the ratio of
market value to book value is 1.1012 on average, and the average leverage (LEV) is 48.52%. Observation
numbers, median values, standard deviations, and minimum and maximum values of variables are
also presented in Table 1.

4.2. Stationary Test Results of Variables in the Model


In fact, the threshold regression model of Hansen (1999) is an extension of the ordinary least
squares (denoted by OLS) traditional estimation method. This method requires that all variables
considered in the model must be stationary variables to avoid spurious regression. This study uses
the Levin et al. (2002) and Im et al. (2003) standards to test the stationarity of variables in the model.
By using STATA software with the dataset described in Section 4.1, the results of the unit root test and
stationarity test of the variables are shown in Table 2 below.

Table 2. Unit root test results.

LLC IPS
Variables
t-Statistic p-Value z-Statistic p-Value
ROA −8.6771 *** 0.0000 −3.4253 *** 0.0000
CASH −9.4776 *** 0.0000 −5.3907 *** 0.0000
SIZE −7.6484 *** 0.0000 −2.2162 ** 0.0133
MB −17.2837 *** 0.0000 −3.5020 *** 0.0000
LEV −13.0545 *** 0.0000 −2.9177 *** 0.0018
Note: LLC and IPS are unit root tests of Levin et al. (2002) and Im et al. (2003) respectively. *** and ** give 1% and
5% significance, respectively.

14
JRFM 2019, 12, 104

Table 2 shows that according to LLC and IPS accreditation standards, all variables representing
profitability (ROA), cash holding (CASH), scale (SIZE), growth (MB), and leverage (LEV) are stationary
sequence and statistically significant at 1% and 5%. Thus, the use of these variables in the threshold
regression model is completely acceptable.

4.3. Threshold Regression Results


This study used GAUSS software and applied the bootstrap method to obtain an approximation
of F-statistics and then calculated p-value. F-statistics include F1, F2 and F3, to evaluate H0
hypotheses for zero, one, and two thresholds, respectively. Table 3 provides results of single-threshold,
double-threshold and triple-threshold tests.

Table 3. Test results of threshold effect of cash holding ratio on firm’s performance.

F-Statistics Test Critical Values


Threshold Value
F-Statistic p-Value 1% 5% 10%
Single-threshold test
0.0993 21.3377 *** 0.004 18.1411 14.3497 12.8103
Double-threshold test
0.0993
0.1715 10.1255 0.156 17.4561 13.5491 17.4561
Triple-threshold test
0.0722 7.4726 0.334 18.1409 13.1731 10.6866
0.0993
0.1715
Note: F-statistics and p-value were obtained by executing a repeating bootstrap procedure 500 times for each
bootstrap test. *** indicates significance at 1%.

First of all, this study examined the existence of a single-threshold effect. By using bootstrap to
perform 500 times, the obtained F1-statistics and p-value are 21.3377 and 0.004 (<1%), respectively.
This suggested that the null hypothesis is rejected at the 1% significance level. Next, this study
examined the existence of a double-threshold effect. Similarly, using bootstrap to perform 500 times,
the obtained F2-statistics and p-value are 10.1255 and 0.156 (>10%), respectively. This suggested that
the hypothesis that a double threshold is rejected. Finally, this study examined the existence of a
triple-threshold effect. Similarly, by using bootstrap to perform 500 times, F3-statistics are 7.4726 and
the p-value is 0.334 (>10%). This showed that the triple-threshold hypothesis is rejected.
Thus, the results of the threshold effect test showed that there is a single-threshold effect on cash
holding and company efficiency. Figure 1 below shows the construction of confidence intervals for a
single-threshold model.
Table 3 above presents the estimated values of the single threshold at 0.0993. The first-step threshold
estimate is the point where the LR1 (γ) equals zero, which occurs at γ̂1 = 0.0993. All observations in the
sample were divided into two sets by the CASH threshold variable (above and below the threshold
value of γ = 0.0993). Accordingly, this study identified two modes formed by threshold values from 0
to 9.93% and above 9.93%.
Table 4 shows the estimated coefficients, standard deviations according to the OLS, and White
Methods for two models mentioned above. When the cash holding ratio (CASH) is smaller than
9.93%, the estimated coefficient βˆ1 is 0.4078 and statistically significant at 1%, indicating that ROA
will increase by 0.4078% when the cash holding ratio increases by 1%. When CASH is higher than
9.93%, the estimated coefficient βˆ2 is 0.1556 and statistically significant at 1%, indicating that ROA
will increase by 0.1556% when CASH increases by 1%. The results showed that the ROA regression
coefficient by CASH is not a fixed value but depends on each threshold of cash holding ratio. Thus,
it is clear that the relationship between cash holding ratio and operational efficiency (slope values)

15
JRFM 2019, 12, 104

varies according to different changes in cash holding ratio. This suggested the existence of a nonlinear
relationship between cash holding ratio and company’s performance.

Figure 1. Confidence interval for the single-threshold model.

Table 4. Estimated results of regression coefficient for the cash holding ratio.

Regression Coefficient Estimated Value OLS SE tOLS White SE tWhite


***
βˆ1 0.4078 0.0670 *** 6.2620 0.0801
5.4124
***
βˆ2 0.1556 0.0187 *** 8.8011 0.0340
5.1182
Note: βˆ1 and βˆ2 are the coefficients of the cash holding ratio variable corresponding to each value of the threshold.
*** indicate the meaning of 1% respectively.

Table 5 shows the estimated coefficients, the standard deviation according to the OLS, and White
methods of three control variables, company size, growth, and leverage.

Table 5. Estimated results of coefficients for control variables.

Regression Coefficient Estimated Value OLS SE tOLS White SE tWhite


θˆ1 0.0135 0.0021 *** 5.7517 0.0032 *** 3.7767
θˆ2 −0.0169 0.0042 *** −5.8027 0.0057 *** −4.9657
θˆ3 −0.1146 0.0153 *** −7.4835 0.0199 *** −5.7470
Note: θˆ1 , θˆ2 , and θˆ3 are the estimated coefficients of company’s growth (MB), company’s size (SIZE), and leverage
(LEV). *** indicates significance at 1%.

Table 5 above shows the estimated coefficients, the standard deviation according to the OLS,
and White methods of three control variables, company size, growth, and leverage.
Table 5 shows that the estimated coefficient of company’s growth θˆ1 is 0.0135 and has a positive
relationship with ROA at the 1% level, implying that company’s growth is a motivation to increase
company efficiency. This result is consistent with empirical research by Abor (2005). Meanwhile,
the estimated coefficient of company’s size θˆ2 is −0.0169 and is inversely related to ROA at the 1%
level. This implied that scaling up the company is not an incentive to increase company efficiency.
The empirical finding is consistent with Cheng et al. (2010), Martínez-Sola et al. (2013), and Nguyen

16
JRFM 2019, 12, 104

et al. (2016). At the same time, the estimated coefficient of company’s leverage θˆ3 is −0.1146 and is
inversely related to ROA at the 1% level, suggesting that the use of more debt capital in the capital
structure is harmful to firm’s performance. This finding is consistent with the finding of Abor (2005),
Nguyen et al. (2016), and Vijayakumaran and Atchyuthan (2017).
From Tables 4 and 5, the estimated model can be rewritten as follows:

μi + 0.0135MBi,t –0.0169SIZEi,t –0.1146LEVi,t + 0.4078CASHi,t + εi,t if CASHi,t ≤ 9.93%
ROAi,t = .
μi + 0.0135MBi,t –0.0169SIZEi,t –0.1146LEVi,t + 0.1556CASHi,t + εi,t if CASHi,t > 9.93%

Table 6 below shows the number of companies in each threshold by year.

Table 6. Number of companies in each threshold by year.

CASHi,t of ≤9.93% CASHi,t of >9.93%


Year
Number Percentage (%) Number Percentage (%)
2008 212 69% 94 31%
2009 189 62% 117 38%
2010 197 64% 109 36%
2011 193 63% 113 37%
2012 195 64% 111 36%
2013 179 58% 127 42%
2014 184 60% 122 40%
2015 186 61% 120 39%
2016 202 66% 104 34%
2017 211 69% 95 31%
Total 1948 64% 1112 36%

Table 6 shows that about 64% of companies fall into the category of having a cash holding
ratio within the threshold of 9.93% (meaning that about 179 to 212 companies fall into this threshold
each year), and about 36% companies fall into the threshold of having a cash holding ratio above 9.93%
(meaning that about 94–127 companies fall into this threshold each year).

5. Conclusions and Recommendations


The decision on the cash holding ratio could have a significant impact on firm’s performance and
value. This study used the threshold regression model of Hansen (1999) to examine the threshold effect
of cash holding ratio on the performance of 306 listed non-financial companies in the Vietnam stock
exchange market during the period of 2008–2017. ROA was used to represent company performance,
and the ratio of money and cash equivalents on total assets (CASH) was used to represent the company’s
cash holding ratio.
Experimental results showed that the single-threshold effect exists between the ratio of cash
holding and company’s performance. In addition, the coefficient is positive when the cash holding
ratio is less than 9.93%, which means a proportion of cash holding within this threshold could
contribute to improvement of company’s efficiency. The coefficient is positive but tends to decrease
when the ratio of cash holdings is higher than 9.93%, implying that an increase in cash holdings
ratio beyond this threshold will further reduce the company’s performance. Therefore, this result
might conclude that the relationship between cash holding ratio and firm’s performance is a nonlinear
relationship. These results are consistent with the trade-off theory, in that the optimal cash holding
ratio is determined by a trade-off between marginal cost and profit margin of cash holdings (Opler
et al. 1999). At the same time, this result is also consistent with some previous empirical research
(Azmat 2014; Martínez-Sola et al. 2013; Nguyen et al. 2016). Among the control variables, firm size and
leverage have a significant negative effect on company’s performance whereas market-to-book value
ratio of stocks has a significant positive effect on company’s performance.

17
JRFM 2019, 12, 104

From the research results above, this study suggested a few recommendations for non-financial
companies listed on the Vietnam stock exchange market in deciding the cash holding ratio as follows:
Firstly, companies should not hold cash more than 9.93% of total assets. To ensure and improve the
company’s performance, the optimal range of cash holding ratio should be below 9.93%. Secondly,
for companies that currently have a cash holding ratio higher than 9.93%, it is necessary to reduce
the cash holding ratio to approach the optimal ratio as discussed above. In order to accomplish
this task, it is necessary to identify the factors that affect the motive of holding cash, thereby having
specific policies to adjust the cash holding ratio more suitable for each specific group of companies.
From this idea, we will conduct research on the factors that affect the cash holding motive for each
group of companies at each specific cash holding rate threshold. Hopefully, our next research results
will provide practical suggestions in determining the optimal percentage of cash holdings to improve
firm’s performance and value.
This study has used panel threshold regression by Hansen (1999), that is, for non-dynamic panels,
studies can be conducted by using extended threshold panels (for dynamic panels and considering
the issue of endogeneity) and for more rigorous results. This would be a worthwhile subject for
future research.

Funding: This research received no external funding.


Acknowledgments: We are grateful to the anonymous reviewers for their very helpful comments and suggestions.
Conflicts of Interest: The author declares no conflicts of interest.

References
Abor, Joshua. 2005. The effect of capital structure on profitability: An empirical analysis of listed firms in Ghana.
The Journal of Risk Finance 6: 438–45. [CrossRef]
Al-Najjar, Basil, and Yacine Belghitar. 2011. Corporate cash holdings and dividend payments: Evidence from
simultaneous analysis. Managerial and Decision Economics 32: 231–41. [CrossRef]
Azmat, Qurat-ul-ann. 2014. Firm value and optimal cash level: Evidence from Pakistan. International Journal of
Emerging Markets 9: 488–504. [CrossRef]
Bates, Thomas W., Kathleen M. Kahle, and René M. Stulz. 2009. Why do US firms hold so much more cash than
they used to? The Journal of Finance 64: 1985–2021. [CrossRef]
Blanchard, Olivier Jean, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, and Andrei Shleifer. 1994. What do firms do with cash
windfalls? Journal of Financial Economics 36: 337–60. [CrossRef]
Cheng, Yu-Shu, Yi-Pei Liu, and Chu-Yang Chien. 2010. Capital structure and firm value in China: A panel
threshold regression analysis. African Journal of Business Management 4: 2500–7.
Dang, Chongyu, Zhichuan Frank Li, and Chen Yang. 2018. Measuring firm size in empirical corporate finance.
Journal of Banking & Finance 86: 159–76.
Dittmar, Amy, and Jan Mahrt-Smith. 2007. Corporate governance and the value of cash holdings. Journal of
Financial Economics 83: 599–634. [CrossRef]
Ferreira, Miguel A., and Antonio S. Vilela. 2004. Why do firms hold cash? Evidence from EMU countries. European
Financial Management 10: 295–319. [CrossRef]
Hansen, Bruce E. 1999. Threshold effects in non-dynamic panels: Estimation, testing, and inference. Journal of
Econometrics 93: 345–68. [CrossRef]
Harford, Jarrad. 1999. Corporate cash reserves and acquisitions. The Journal of Finance 54: 1969–97. [CrossRef]
Harford, Jarrad, Sattar A. SMansi, and William F. Maxwell. 2008. Corporate governance and firm cash holdings in
the US. Journal of Financial Economics 87: 535–55. [CrossRef]
Horioka, Charles Y., and Akiko Terada-Hagiwara. 2014. Corporate cash holding in Asia. Asian Economic Journal
28: 323–45. [CrossRef]
Iftikhar, Raja Muddessar. 2017. Impact of cash holding on firm performance: A case study of non-financial listed
firms of KSE. University of Haripur Journal of Management (UOHJM) 2: 189–99.
Im, Kyung So, M. Hashem Pesaran, and Yongcheol Shin. 2003. Testing for unit roots in heterogeneous panels.
Journal of Econometrics 115: 53–74. [CrossRef]

18
JRFM 2019, 12, 104

Jensen, Michael C. 1986. Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers. The American Economic
Review 76: 323–29.
Kim, Chang-Soo, David C. Mauer, and Ann E. Sherman. 1998. The determinants of corporate liquidity: Theory
and evidence. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 33: 335–59. [CrossRef]
Levin, Andrew, Chien-Fu Lin, and Chia-Shang James Chu. 2002. Unit root tests in panel data: Asymptotic and
finite-sample properties. Journal of Econometrics 108: 1–24. [CrossRef]
Li, Frank. 2016. Endogeneity in CEO power: A survey and experiment. Investment Analysts Journal 45: 149–62.
[CrossRef]
Martínez-Sola, Cristina, Pedro Juan García Teruel, and Pedro Martínez Solano. 2013. Corporate cash holding and
firm value. Applied Economics 45: 161–70. [CrossRef]
Myers, Stewart C., and Nicholas S. Majluf. 1984. Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms have
information that investors do not have. Journal of Financial Economics 13: 187–221. [CrossRef]
Nguyen, Thi Lien Hoa, Le Ngan Trang Nguyen, and Thi Phuong Vy Le. 2016. Firm value, corporate cash
holdings and financial constraint: A study from a developing market. Australian Economic Papers 55: 368–85.
[CrossRef]
Opler, Tim, Pinkowitz Lee, Stulz René, and Williamson Rohan. 1999. The determinants and implications of
corporate cash holdings. Journal of Financial Economics 52: 3–46. [CrossRef]
Ozkan, Aydin, and Neslihan Ozkan. 2004. Corporate cash holdings: An empirical investigation of UK companies.
Journal of Banking & Finance 28: 2103–34.
Saddour, Khaoula. 2006. The Determinants and the Value of Cash Holdings: Evidence from French Firms (No.
halshs-00151916); Centre de Recherches sur la Gestion. Université Paris-Dauphine. Available online:
http://www.finance.dauphine.fr/wp-content/uploads/2015/07/cereg200606.pdf (accessed on 27 May 2019).
Sheikh, Nadeem Ahmed, and Muhammad Imran Khan. 2016. Effects of Excess Cash, Board Attributes and Insider
Ownership on Firm Value: Evidence from Pakistan. Australasian Accounting, Business and Finance Journal 10:
29–39. [CrossRef]
Shinada, Naoki. 2012. Firms’ Cash Holdings and Performance: Evidence from Japanese Corporate Finance; Research
Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry (RIETI). Available online: https://www.rieti.go.jp/jp/publications/
dp/12e031.pdf (accessed on 30 May 2012).
Vijayakumaran, Ratnam, and Nagajeyakumarn Atchyuthan. 2017. Cash holdings and corporate performance:
Evidence from Sri Lanka. International Journal of Accounting & Business Finance 3: 1–11.

© 2019 by the author. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access
article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution
(CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).

19
Journal of
Risk and Financial
Management

Article
Sectoral Analysis of Factors Influencing Dividend
Policy: Case of an Emerging Financial Market
Geetanjali Pinto 1,2, * and Shailesh Rastogi 3
1 SCRI, Symbiosis International (Deemed University), Pune 412 115, India
2 ITM Business School Navi Mumbai, ITM Group of Institutions, Navi Mumbai 410 210, India
3 Symbiosis Institute of Business Management Pune, Symbiosis International (Deemed University),
Pune 412 115, India
* Correspondence: geetanjalip@itm.edu; Tel.: +91-022-6226-7062

Received: 27 May 2019; Accepted: 22 June 2019; Published: 26 June 2019

Abstract: This study aims to determine whether a firm’s dividends are influenced by the sector to
which it belongs. This paper also examines the explanatory factors for dividends across individual
sectors in India. This longitudinal study uses balanced data consisting of companies listed on the
National Stock Exchange (NSE) of India for 12 years—from 2006 to 2017. Pooled ordinary least squares
(POLSs) and fixed effects panel models are used in our estimation. We find that size, profitability, and
interest coverage ratios have a significant positive relation to dividend policy. Furthermore, business
risk and debt reveal a significantly negative relation with dividends. The findings on profitability
support the free cash flow hypothesis for India. However, we also found that Indian companies prefer
to follow a stable dividend policy. As a result of this, even firms with higher growth opportunities
and lower cash flows continue to pay dividends. We also find evidence that dividend policies vary
significantly across industrial sectors in India. The results of this study can be used by financial
managers and policymakers in order to make appropriate dividend decisions. They can also help
investors make portfolio selection decisions based on sectoral dividend paying behavior.

Keywords: dividend policy; emerging market; industrial sectors; NSE India; panel data

JEL Classification: C33; G11; G35

1. Introduction
All investors expect a certain amount of return on their investment for the risk taken. Firms can
allocate profits to their stockholders either through dividends or share repurchases. Investors can get
a return on their investment through dividends (current income). Alternatively, if a company has a
lucrative investment opportunity available, it may not distribute its profits. The outlay in a profitable
venture will also increase the value of a company, resulting in capital gains (future income) to investors.
Theoretically, both dividend payout and retention lead to shareholder wealth maximization. Thus,
as concluded by Miller and Modigliani (1961), investors should not differentiate among dividends and
retaining profits. However, Miller and Modigliani’s assumptions of a perfect capital market, no taxes,
certainty, and fixed investment strategy does not really exist.
Certain studies consider that the dividend decision influences the value of a firm (Walter 1963),
and is interlinked with the firm’s investment policy. Researchers also theorize that generally, investors
are risk-averse and give preference to receive certain dividends rather than uncertain capital gains,
which are riskier. It is referred to as the “bird-in-hand” argument, as investors prefer current income
rather than future income (Gordon 1963). Also, the tax treatment of dividends and capital gains is
different. Furthermore, tax preference determines the stocks selected by investors, depending on the

JRFM 2019, 12, 110; doi:10.3390/jrfm12030110 21 www.mdpi.com/journal/jrfm


JRFM 2019, 12, 110

stocks’ specific dividend policies. It is denoted as the “clientele effect.” However, Allen et al. (2000)
report that dividends are not used by managers to attract investor clientele.
The signaling theory by Solomon (1963) and Ross (1977) suggests that dividend policy gives
information about a stock. Dividends can be distributed out of profits, and require the existence of free
cash flows; hence, the payment of dividends provides a positive signal to investors (Bhattacharya 1979;
Miller and Rock 1985). According to Jensen (1986), the agency cost of the free cash flow model predicts
that companies with larger free cash flows tend to distribute higher dividends rather than investing
in projects with a lower net present value (NPV). It also assumes that such firms also take a higher
amount of debt, which involves the payment of fixed interest charges. The obligation on the part of the
company to make timely payments of principal and interest will ensure that the company does not
invest in less profitable investment opportunities, and thus helps in reducing agency cost.
Various factors influencing a firms’ dividend policy have been evaluated by researchers.
The outcome of these studies has not entirely resolved the controversies linked to dividend decision.
Hence, it is not astonishing that “dividend controversy” has been listed by Brealey and Myers
(2002) as one among ten of the most important unsolved corporate finance problems. Also, the
determinants of dividend decision are not uniform across firms. Nevertheless, researchers have
reported that determinants of dividends vary across countries and over different periods of time e.g.,
(Ramcharran 2001). Studies have also reported that variations in dividends across countries occur
because of differences in economic policy for each country, including corporate governance policy
(Mitton 2004; Sawicki 2009) and pertinent laws applicable (La Porta et al. 2000b; Sawicki 2009).
Emerging and developed markets also differ in many ways. Glen et al. (1995) report that
dividends in emerging market firms are more volatile than U.S. firms. Aivazian et al. (2003b) find
that country-specific factors have an impact in determining dividend policies in emerging markets.
They have also reported that compared with U.S. firms, higher dividends are paid by emerging market
firms, which itself is puzzling. Reddy and Rath (2005) have also reiterated that dividend behavior in
emerging markets has not been evaluated extensively. Hence, it is necessary to evaluate the dividend
paying behavior of emerging market firms in further detail.
Lintner (1956) postulates that sectors influence the dividend policy. This sectoral influence is
mainly because firms belonging to a sector have similar earnings prospects, investment prospects,
and accessibility of resources. As a result of these similarities, firms in the same sector have similar
dividend policies (Michel 1979; Baker 1988; Dempsey et al. 1993). However, very limited studies have
evaluated the variances in dividend policy behavior across sectors. Also, the economy has undergone
multiple changes, thereby altering this relationship. Furthermore, these studies have focused on
developed markets.
Considering the above facts, this paper contributes to the existing literature in two ways. Firstly,
it provides insight into the dividend policy issue for an emerging market. India has developed as
the fastest expanding major economy across the globe, and hence it is considered for the purpose of
this study. It is attracting many major economies for strategic investments, owing to the presence of
an immense variety of industries, investment prospects, and increasing integration into the global
economy. Secondly, this study strives to bridge a significant gap in the existing literature by evaluating
the dividend behavior across industrial sectors.
The remaining paper is organized as follows. Section 2 appraises the present literature, develops
the hypotheses and also provides an ephemeral overview of the Indian economy and its implication
on dividend-paying behavior; Section 3 defines the source of our data and the variables involved,
and also lays down the construction, relevance, and validity of the tools and techniques used for
empirical analysis; Section 4 presents and discusses the outcomes from the analysis of collected data;
and Section 5 provides the summary and conclusion of the paper.

22
JRFM 2019, 12, 110

2. Review of Literature and Institutional Background


Dividend policy is a crucial corporate finance decision, which is interrelated to financing and
investing decision. The existing literature has identified various dividend policy determinants.
However, researchers agree that there is no solitary description of the dividend-paying behavior
of firms. In fact, the more we look at the dividend behavior of firms, the more it seems like an
unresolved “dividend puzzle” (Black 1976). Ooi (2001) has also cited that although dividend payout is
considered as a vital management decision, it continues to puzzle managers, researchers, and investors.
The puzzle circles around the factors influencing the dividend payout and whether investors pay
attention to dividends?

2.1. Factors Affecting Dividend Policy


Lintner (1956) has reported that managers give importance to the stability of dividends. They do
not like to cut or omit dividends. Instead, companies generally set a target payout ratio and consider
current years’ earnings and dividend of the previous year as essential dividend policy determinants.
Present as well as future earnings, the stability of earnings, and shareholders’ needs are considered as
essential factors for dividends by Indonesian firms (Baker and Powell 2012).
Al-Najjar and Kilincarslan (2017) have reported that publicly listed firms in Turkey generally
adopt long-term payout ratios, and hence the stability of the dividends is followed (comparatively
less than the developed markets of the U.S.). They also report that the concentration of ownership
affects the target payout ratios. Mehar (2005) has stated that dividends are related positively to insider
ownership and inversely to liquidity for Pakistan listed firms.
Kevin (1992) finds that a change in profitability does not influence the dividends of Indian
companies, as they tend to follow a sticky dividend policy. Mahapatra and Sahu (1993) have found
that Lintner’s model finds no support in the Indian context. They establish that mainly cash flows
and then the net earnings are essential for a dividend payout in India. However, Bhat and Pandey
(1994) surveyed the finance directors of the Economic Times 250 top Indian firms, and found that
dividend payment depends on present and future earnings, as well as preceding years’ dividend per
share. Hence, these findings explain that Lintner’s model is applicable in India. Mishra and Narender
(1996) also report similar findings for state-owned-enterprises in India. Pandey and Bhat (2007) have
found that restricted monetary policy leads to a reduction in dividend payments. They also report
that the previous two years’ dividends and the current year’s dividend are significant for a dividend
payout in India. However, they report an instability of dividend policies and not much of a tendency
of smoothing dividends in Indian companies.
Fama and French (2001) have reported that large firms with a high profitability and low investment
opportunities tend to pay dividends, and vice versa. Hence profitability, investment opportunities,
and size are the three important characteristics that enable the differentiation between dividend paying
and non-paying firms in the United States. These findings are consistent with studies conducted
in developed economies by (Fama and French 1999; Easterbrook 1984; Benito and Young 2003;
Ferris et al. 2006; Renneboog and Trojanowski 2007; Von Eije and Megginson 2008).
In addition to profitability, investment opportunities, and size, Yarram (2015) reports that
dividends of Australian firms are also positively related to corporate governance. Chowdhury et al.
(2014) however, report that dividend payments by Chinese firms do not indicate future profitability,
but demonstrate good corporate governance.
For profitability, investment opportunities, and size, Al-Najjar (2009) report similar findings
for Jordan listed firms. However, they also find that debt is inversely related to cash dividends.
Yusof and Ismail (2016) also report similar findings for listed companies in Malaysia. Additionally,
they also state that profitability and liquidity significantly influence dividends for Malaysia.
Bhole and Mahakud (2005) have reported that the retention ratio has a positive relation with
profit after tax, investment level, borrowing cost, and rate of growth for Indian firms, and has a

23
JRFM 2019, 12, 110

negative association with borrowed funds, tax rate, and cost of equity. These results are similar to
Auerbach (1982) and Bhole (2000).
Reddy and Rath (2005) have reported that more profitable companies, having lesser opportunities
to invest with a larger size, are likely to distribute dividends in India. Subhash Kamat and Kamat
(2013) have reported that for Indian companies, the tangibility of assets, size, and earnings are
significant for determining payout policies. The results are consistent with (Fama and French 2001;
DeAngelo et al. 2004; Denis and Osobov 2008).
Setia-Atmaja (2010) has found that firms controlled by families pay higher dividends because of
the existence of a larger proportion of independent directors, for publicly listed Australian companies.
Gul (1999) has reported that government ownership is positively associated with debt financing and
dividends for Shanghai-listed companies.
Extending the Baker and Wurgler (2004) theory of catering incentive to increase and decrease in
dividend payments, Li and Lie (2006) have reported that companies tend to pay more dividends if they
are profitable and large, and have low past dividend yield, debt ratio, cash ratio, and price-to-book
ratio. Baker et al. (2007, 2013) have reported that firm size, profitability, investment opportunities,
and catering incentives are essential factors for Canadian firms. Tangjitprom (2013) finds the support
of catering theory of dividend in Thailand.

2.2. Factors Affecting Dividend Policy—A Comparison across the Globe


La Porta et al. (2000a) compare the dividends for 33 countries across the world. They report that
the dividend payout is higher in countries that have a stronger system of investor protection. However,
in such countries, the payout is lower for those companies who have high growth opportunities.
Ramcharran (2001) has examined the differences in dividend yields for twenty-one emerging market
economies (including India) from 1992–1999. The study found that in countries with a higher
country risk, firms tend to have lower dividend payouts to use cash flows for financing future
growth opportunities.
Aivazian et al. (2003b) have compared the factors influencing the dividends of emerging market
firms with U.S. firms. The results show that the level of dividends paid by emerging market companies
is similar to U.S. firms, excluding Turkey (because of the imposition of legal constraints). Also, a similar
relationship is found between dividend policy and the following three variables: profitability ratio,
debt ratio, and the ratio of market to book value as revealed by U.S. firms. For both size coefficient and
business risk coefficient, the signs are inconsistent. Further results have shown that in comparison
with the United States, the companies in six emerging market countries with higher tangible assets
tend to pay lesser dividends.
Mitton (2004) states that companies having strong corporate governance and lesser investment
opportunities pay higher dividends, for firms across 19 countries. Brav et al. (2005) have compared
dividend payout policies in the 21st century for the United States and Canadian public and private
companies. They report that the existence of good investment avenues is essential for dividend
decision. Taxes are not found to be significant.
Denis and Osobov (2008) have examined the dividend payout determinants for six countries with
well-established financial markets, namely: the United States, Canada, the United Kingdom, Germany,
France, and Japan. In line with (Fama and French 2001), this study also confirms that firm size, growth
opportunities, and profitability are significant factors that help to determine dividends. The retained
surplus to total equity ratio is also established as a significant factor of dividend policy.
Brockman and Unlu (2009) have found that there exists a positive relation between creditor rights
and probability to pay dividends, as well as the amount of dividend payout for 52 countries across the
globe. Abor and Bokpin (2010) have evaluated the dividend policy for 34 emerging markets, and report
that investment opportunity and dividends have a significant negative relationship. Furthermore,
profits and the market capitalization of stock also influence dividend decision. However, additional

24
JRFM 2019, 12, 110

measures, namely, external financing, financial leverage, and debt finance, do not significantly impact
the dividend payout.
Farooq and Jabbouri (2015) have found that dividends and cost of debt are negatively associated
with each other for the Middle East and North African region (MENA) firms. They also report that this
phenomenon is more prevalent in firms having higher information asymmetries.

2.3. Dividend Policy and Industry Influence


While selecting a payout policy, a firm considers various factors such as earnings, profitability,
size, debt, cash flows, and many other economic factors as discussed above. Additionally, a firm
also evaluates the payout policy of other firms in the same sector, before deciding its dividend policy.
While a few past studies have evaluated the industrial sector’s influence on dividend payout, there is
no consensus.
Michel (1979) have evaluated twelve industries in the United States using the Kruskal–Wallis
one-way analysis of variance. They have reported statistically significant variations in the dividend
payouts for these sectors. Marsh and Merton (1987) also propose that firms detect industry practice
before selecting a target dividend payout for themselves. However, its effect has not been tested
explicitly by them. Baker (1988) has updated the study conducted by Michel. He also finds support for
industry influence on dividends.
Pandey (2003) has studied the dividend payout for six industrial sectors of Malaysia. The author
uses non-parametric, Kruskal–Wallis (K–W) one-way analysis of variance of ranks (Michel 1979;
Scott and Martin 1975), and finds that the dividends of these companies differ across industrial sectors.
However, Baker et al. (2002) report that the company’s industry type does not influence the
manager’s views in respect of dividends.
Mohamed et al. (2012) have suggested that the study of dividend policy can be widened by
including an analysis across industries, and adding other characteristics that influence dividend policy.

2.4. Institutional Background


Major economic reforms in 1991 led the Indian economy towards economic liberalization and
globalization. The major changes include the lowering of import tariffs and taxes, the deregulation of
markets, and a rise in foreign investment. Also, since the formation of the Securities and Exchange
Board of India (SEBI) in 1992, there has been an increase in the overall development, regulation,
and supervision of the Indian stock market. As a result of significant improvements in the capital
market regulations in India since the last two decades, companies can now issue shares using the
book-building process, and raise funds through foreign capital. Indian companies thus have access to
many alternative sources of finance, instead of relying on retained earnings. All of this has led to a
change in their shareholding pattern. Accordingly, this will influence their dividend policy.
Furthermore, the Indian stock market consists of stocks covering the entire gamut—financial,
industrial, and energy—thus providing exposure to a wide range of sectors. Another distinctiveness of
the Indian stock market1 is that more than 55% of the equity market is held by promoters, thereby
reducing the overall free float of the stock. In order to address this peculiarity, the SEBI mandated
all listed companies to raise public shareholdings to 25% by mid-2013. In the framework of this
transformed economic setting, the objective of this study is to evaluate the factors influencing the
dividends of companies in India across sixteen industrial sectors.

1 Further details on Indian stock market are available under https://www.nseindia.com/.

25
JRFM 2019, 12, 110

3. Data and Methodology

3.1. Sample Selection


The Indian stock market consists of two main stock exchanges, namely, the Bombay Stock Exchange
(BSE) and the National Stock Exchange (NSE), apart from many other regional stock exchanges. Almost
all of the significant Indian companies are listed on both these exchanges. We considered the data
of all of the companies in NIFTY 500 NSE-index for the period of 2006 to 2017. The sample period
was chosen to signify the current state of companies in India. NIFTY 500 index represents the top
500 companies listed on NSE based on full market capitalization. It represents 95.2% of the free float
market capitalization of stocks listed on the NSE as of 31 March 20172 . The financial data of all of the
companies were obtained from the Prowessdx database. The financial performance of all of the Indian
companies were provided by the Centre for Monitoring Indian Economy (CMIE) in this database.
It is the largest database, and the financial statements contained therein are standardized and do
not suffer from any deliberate survival bias. Although data were extracted for all 500 companies,
because of the absence of data for a few companies for entire time-period from 2006 onwards, the final
analysis was done on 424 companies only. Outliers were also removed using a statistical three-sigma
method. Hence, a balanced panel data of companies for 12-years, from 2006 to 2017, was used. Every
company in CMIE is associated with an industry group. These industry groups have been formed
by studying the number of companies in the clusters of industries, as per the detailed products and
services classification3 . Based on these industry group codes provided by CMIE, the 424 companies
under selection have been grouped into sixteen sectors.
Total dividend divided by total assets was used to determine the dividend policy of a company,
and is considered as the dependent variable in this study. The dependent variable, as well as the
explanatory variables, were carefully chosen based on the literature review. Table 1 presents the
number of companies considered under each industrial sector, along with the sector codes used in the
paper and the sector-wise mean of the dividend/total assets (Div/TA).

Table 1. Summary of the number of companies considered under each industrial sector along with
the sector codes and the sectoral mean of dividend/total assets (Div/TA). IT—information technology;
ITES—IT enabled service.

Sr. No. Sector Sector Code NIFTY 500 Final Sample Mean (Div/TA)
1 Agro-based AGRO 13 12 0.0106
2 Mineral-based MINING 66 62 0.0173
3 Engineering ENGG 24 21 0.0198
4 Automobile and ancillary AUTO 27 24 0.0277
5 Power and fuel POWER 24 21 0.0160
6 Textile TEXTILE 13 13 0.0135
7 Drugs and pharmaceuticals PHARMA 30 28 0.0311
8 Consumer goods and appliances CONSGDS 39 32 0.0427
9 Other manufacturing M-OTH 32 32 0.0185
10 Entertainment, health, and tourism MEHH 25 18 0.0209
11 Trading/services (others) S-OTHS 38 21 0.0217
12 Construction and infrastructure CONSTR 29 22 0.0070
13 logistics LOGISTICS 21 19 0.0259
14 IT, ITES, and telecommunication ITTELE 30 26 0.0468
15 Banking BANKING 33 32 0.0015
16 Other financial services FINSER 56 41 0.0194
TOTAL 500 424

2 A detailed description of NIFTY 500 companies is available under https://www.nseindia.com/products/content/equities/


indices/nifty_500.htm.
3 The detailed definition of all variables is available under prowess dictionary at https://prowessiq.cmie.com.

26
JRFM 2019, 12, 110

3.2. Description of Variables and Hypothesis

3.2.1. Dependent Variable—Dividend/Total Assets (Div/TA)


The following were used for determining the dividend payout policy of firms, out of four measures
examined by (Aivazian et al. 2003b): dividend payout ratio, dividend yield, Div/TA, and dividend/book
value per share; it was found that Div/TA is the most appropriate measure. The authors stated that
the ratio of the dividend payout is extremely unstable and non-normal if the earnings reach near
zero. Secondly, the dividend yield ratio uses market price, which is not in control of the management.
Finally, the dividend to book value per share is prone to more misrepresentations, as it depends on
the net worth of the company, which includes free reserves and can be easily distorted by companies.
Compared to that, the total assets are less likely to be inaccurate (Aivazian et al. 2003b). Hence,
this study also uses the total Div/TA as the dependent variable, and is referred to as dividend policy or
payout policy hereafter.

3.2.2. Explanatory Variables


These are constructed on the theoretical framework of (Aivazian et al. 2003b) and an extensive
literature review conducted herein. Apart from the sector, the remaining 12 explanatory variables have
been broadly divided into the following three measures: operating measures (5), debt measures (3),
and summary measures (4).
Sector. The Nifty 500 companies have been classified into 16 sectors. Classification into these 16
sectors is based on the CMIE classification of industry groups, as discussed in the previous sub-section.
On the basis of the literature review conducted in the previous section, it is hypothesized that dividend
policy differs significantly across industrial sectors.
Apart from the three operating measures as defined by (Aivazian et al. 2003b)—tangibility,
business risk, and scale of operations (log of sales)—this study also considers two more operating
measures—operating profit and size (log of market capitalization). The three debt measures include
debt ratio, interest coverage ratio, and current ratio. Summary measures are further sub-divided
into profitability, growth, and liquidity. To measure profitability, in addition to the return on equity
(ROE), this study also considers the return on investment (ROI), following Reddy and Rath (2005).
Mehmood et al. (2019) have also used both accounting measures, ROE and ROI, to measure profitability.
Price to book value is used as a proxy for growth measure. Cash flow per share is used to measure
liquidity, following Bhat and Pandey (1994) and Mohamed et al. (2012).
Table 2 defines each of these explanatory variables, now referred to as factors influencing dividend
payout policy, and gives the nature of the relation expected with dividend payout policy.

3.3. Model Specifications


Firstly, we analyzed whether the dividend policy for the NSE-listed companies varies across sectors.
We used a one-way analysis of variance test to analyze whether there are any statistically significant
variations between the means of three or more independent (unrelated) groups. This technique tests
the null hypothesis that the mean values of dividend policy are the same for all sectors. The null
hypothesis is rejected if the calculated F statistics is greater than F critical value, or if the p-value is less
than ∝, where ∝ denotes the level of significance.
The study then uses the panel data techniques to develop a model establishing a relation between
the dividend policy and the explanatory factors. Hsiao (2003) has highlighted that using panel data
sets for research provides researchers with more advantages compared with using conventional
cross-sectional or time-series data sets, for example (Hsiao 1985, 1995; Hsiao and Sun 2000).

27
JRFM 2019, 12, 110

Table 2. Description of variables with expected signs. ROE—return on equity; P/B—the price-to-book value.

Variable Name Definition Symbol Expected Relationship


Dividend policy Total dividend paid divided by total assets Div/TA
A. Operating measures
Tangibility (Total assets minus current assets) divided by total assets Tangibility +
Standard deviation of return on investment (ROI; lagged
Business risk BusRisk −
three years)
Scale of Operations Natural logarithm of sales in local currency LgSales +
Scale of Operations Natural logarithm of market capitalization in local currency LgMCap +
Operating profit Earnings before interest and tax (EBIT) divided by total sales OpProfit +
B. Debt measures
Debt ratio Long term debt divided by total assets DebtRatio −
Interest coverage ratio EBIT divided by interest IntCover +
Current ratio Current assets divided by current liabilities CurRatio +
C. Summary measures
i. Profitability
Net profit after tax (NPAT) divided by net worth (where net
Return on Equity ROE +
worth = equity share capital + reserves and surplus)
EBIT divided by capital employed (CE; CE = net worth +
Return on Investment ROI +
long term debt)
ii. Growth measure
Market price per share divided by book value at the end of
price to book value ratio P/B −
the year
iii. Liquidity measure
Net cash flow from operating activities divided by the
Cash flow per share CFPS +/−
number of equity shares outstanding

The relation between dividend policy and the factors affecting it for selected NIFTY 500 companies
and for each of the sectors is expressed in the form of an empirical model, as follows:

Divi, t
n
=∝ i+ βi, j Xi, j, t + εi, t (1)
TA i, t
j=1

where i = 1, . . . , N, where N is the number of cross-sectional units = 16 sectors, t = 1, . . . , T, where T is


the time period = 12 years and j = 1, . . . , n, and where n is the number of explanatory variables = 12
(Hill et al. 2007). Xi,j,t is the explanatory variable j for firm i at time t, βi,j is the slope for explanatory
variable j for sector i, εi,t is the random error term for sector i at time t, Divi,t /TAi,t is dividend-to-total
asset ratio subscripted for sector i at time t, and αi is the intercept.
Table 2 summarizes the dependent and explanatory variables, which form part of the empirical
model expressed in Equation (1). For some companies, the data for LgSales, OpProfit, the price-to-book
value (P/B), and CFPS are not available, hence the regression equation is estimated with the remaining
variables, as the absence of this data limits the sample size of these sectors.
The major benefit of panel data is that it improves the efficiency of the econometric estimation by
giving researchers more data points, which increases the degrees of freedom and reduces collinearity
between explanatory variables (Gujarati 2009). Hence, this study uses the panel data technique, which
will enable the maximum utilization of data by considering both cross-sectional and time-series data.
There are four basic models available in the panel data model, namely: pooled ordinary least
squares (POLS), fixed effect model (FEM), random effect model (REM), and Seemingly Unrelated
Regression Equations (SUR) model (Adkins 2010). For determining the most suitable panel data model,
panel diagnostic tests are available in GRETL (Baiocchi and Distaso 2003). The first-panel diagnostic
test being F-statistics. It suggests that if the p-value is less than alpha, then the null hypothesis is
rejected, and FEM is more suitable than the POLS model. Secondly, the Breusch–Pagan test helps
to determine whether POLS or REM is applicable. It suggests that if the p-value is less than alpha,
then the null hypothesis is rejected, and REM is more suitable than the POLS model. If both the
F-statistics and Breusch–Pagan test are found to be positive, then finally, the (Hausman 1978) test is
used for determining whether FEM or REM is suitable for estimation. The SUR model is used to
estimate panel data models that have large time periods and a small number of cross-sectional units

28
JRFM 2019, 12, 110

(Adkins 2010). Using these test results, we determine the appropriate model to be used for estimating
the regression equation.

4. Empirical Results and Discussion

4.1. Discussion on Consolidated Regression


In this sub-section, we present our panel regression results, which identify the factors influencing
the dividend policy for selected NSE companies. As discussed in the methodology section, the
panel diagnostic test results are utilized to determine the appropriate panel data model. The results
in Table 3 reveal that the p-value of F-statistics is 0.935 which is >∝ (i.e., 0.05), hence we cannot
reject the null. This suggests that POLS technique is more suitable than FEM (Adkins 2010;
Cottrell and Lucchetti 2017). Hence, the findings are reported based on the POLS regression estimate.

Table 3. Consolidated (NIFTY 500) panel regression.

Independent Variable Coefficients


Constant 0.001 (0.698)
Tangibility 0.000 (0.981)
BusRisk −0.011 (0.000) ***
LgSales 0.001 (0.000) ***
LgMCap 0.000 (0.034) **
OpProfit 0.000 (0.463)
DebtRatio −0.036 (0.000) ***
IntCover 0.000 (0.020) **
CurRatio 0.000 (0.000) ***
ROE 0.001 (0.004) ***
ROI 0.020 (0.000) ***
P/B 0.001 (0.000) ***
CFPS −0.000 (0.004) ***
F-Statistics: 0.894 (0.935) Breusch–Pagan test: 2.392 (0.122)
Hausman test: 22.312 (0.034) Appropriate model: POLS
Durbin Watson = 1.845 Overall R-square = 0.147
Number of Companies (N) = 424 Number of years (T) = 12
No. of observations (balanced) = 5088
Notes: Regression coefficients are estimated using pooled ordinary least squares. Dividends divided by total assets
is the dependent variable. The independent variables are as follows. Tangibility is total assets minus current
assets divided by total assets. BusRisk is the standard deviation of ROI (lagged three years). LgSales is the natural
logarithm of sales in local currency. LgMCap is the natural logarithm of market capitalization in local currency.
OpProfit is EBIT divided by total sales. DebtRatio is the long-term debt divided by total assets. IntCover is EBIT
divided by interest. CurRatio is current assets divided by current liabilities. ROE is NPAT divided by net worth.
ROI is EBIT divided by CE. P/B is the market price per share divided by book value per share at the end of the year.
CFPS is net cash flow from operating activities divided by the number of equity shares outstanding. The t-statistics
are given in parentheses. *** Significant at the 1% level; ** significant at the 5% level. POLS—pooled ordinary
least squares.

The results in Table 3 reveal that scale of operations, interest coverage ratio, current ratio, ROE,
ROI, and P/B ratio have a positive relation to the dividend policy. This suggests that companies
with the larger scale of operations, higher interest coverage ratios, current ratio, profitability and
growth opportunities are likely to pay higher dividends. However, there is evidence that business risk,
debt ratio, and CFPS have a negative relation with dividend policy for NSE firms. This implies that
firms with higher business risk, debt levels, and cash flows are likely to pay lower dividends.
The results for the scale of operations, interest coverage ratio, current ratio, ROE, ROI, business
risk, debt ratio, and CFPS, except for the P/B ratio, are in line with our hypotheses. We had expected
that companies having more growth opportunities would most likely pay lower dividends, but for our
sample, the P/B ratio had a marginal positive coefficient. For the remaining variables—tangibility of
assets and operating profit—we found no significant relationship with dividend policy.

29
JRFM 2019, 12, 110

4.2. Sectoral Influence on Dividend Policy


Table 1 shows that the highest Div/TA ratio is of the information technology (IT), IT enabled
service (ITES), and telecommunication (ITTEL)-sector (0.0468), followed by the consumer goods and
appliances (CONSGDS)-sector (0.0427). The logistics (LOGISTICS), automobile and ancillary (AUTO),
and drugs and pharmaceuticals (PHARMA) sectors have a mean Div/TA ratio in the range of 0.025–0.03.
The banking (BANKING)-sector shows the lowest ratio (0.0015), followed by the construction and
infrastructure (CONSTR)-sector (0.007) and agro-based (AGRO)-sector (0.0106).
The one-way analysis of variance test was used for determining the relation between dividend
policy and sectors. These results (not reported here) show that the means of the dividend policy
of each of the 16 sectors vary significantly. The p-value of 0.000 < ∝ (i.e., 0.05), hence we reject the
null hypothesis. This signifies that the dividend policy significantly differs across sectors. Thus,
the industrial sector influences the dividend policy in India.

4.3. Discussion on Sectoral Regression


In this sub-section, we present our panel regression results to detect the sector-wise factors
influencing dividend policy. As discussed in the methodology section, the panel diagnostic test
results are used to determine the panel data model favorable for each sector. As seen in Appendix A,
the p-value of the F-statistics for the AGRO sector is 0.016, which is <∝ (i.e., 0.05), hence we reject the
null. This recommends that the FEM technique is more suitable than POLS for estimating the factors
influencing the dividend policy in the AGRO-sector. The results reveal that for all other sectors, the
p-value of F-statistics is greater than 0.05. Thus, for the remaining fifteen sectors, the POLS model is
suitable. Accordingly, based on the panel diagnostic test results (Baiocchi and Distaso 2003), we report
the findings using the FEM regression estimates for the AGRO-sector, and the POLS regression estimate
for the remaining 15 sectors.
The overall R2 is the highest for the AUTO-sector (0.82) and lowest for PHARMA-sector (0.12).
For the LOGISTICS, textile (TEXTILE), and AGRO sectors, R2 ranges between 0.61–0.67. The overall
R2 for the power and fuel (POWER), other financial services (FINSER), and ITTEL sectors lies between
0.50–0.55. Also, for the BANKING, other manufacturing (M-OTH), and CONSGDS sectors, it is
between 0.44–0.46. For the remaining sectors—CONSTR, trading/services (S-OTHS), engineering
(ENGG), entertainment, health, and tourism (MEHH), and mining-based (MINING)—the overall R2
value ranges between 0.31–0.38. These overall R2 values in the range of 0.31–0.82 suggest a good
indication regarding the explanatory power of the individual sector panel regressions.

4.3.1. Operating Measures


The sector-wise panel regression in Appendix A reveals a strong positive relation between the
tangibility of assets (TANG) and the dividend policy for firms from the AGRO, MINING, ENGG,
TEXTILE, CONSGDS, CONSTR, and LOGIS sectors. This implies that the companies in these sectors
tend to pay dividends if they have higher TANG, in line with past studies e.g., (Aivazian et al. 2003a;
DeAngelo et al. 2004; Denis and Osobov 2008; Subhash Kamat and Kamat 2013). However, TANG has
an inverse relation with dividend policy for firms of the BANKING-sector.
The business risk variable displays inconsistent signs. Although we find that it is inversely
associated with dividends in the CONSTR, BANKING, and S-OTHS sectors, their importance is
opposite in the ITTEL and FINSER sectors. This variable is found to be insignificant in the remaining
sectors. A possible explanation for this is that all sectors are exposed to risks that are pertinent to their
line of business and sector-specific regulations in which they function. Aivazian et al. 2003a also report
mixed results for the business risk variable when comparing the dividend policy of the United States
with emerging market firms.
For the scale of operations as measured by the log of sales (LgSales), although we expected
a positive association with the dividend policy, the findings suggest that none of the sectors are

30
JRFM 2019, 12, 110

significantly influenced by it. The LgSales variable is not considered for panel regression estimation
in the BANKING and FINSER sectors, because of the difference in revenue parameters. The log of
market capitalization (LgMCap) is used to evaluate the influence of the size on the dividend payout
for these sectors. Information on LgMCap was not available for all companies of the TEXTILE-sector,
hence it is excluded for the panel regression estimation of this sector. The results show a positive
association of LgMCap with dividends of the ENGG, AUTO, PHARMA, CONSGD, M-OTH, MEHH,
and CONSTR sectors. The positive impact indicates that firms from these sectors that are greater in
size are likely to pay more dividends. This is likely, as such firms can access capital markets without
difficulty, thereby having lesser dependence on retained surplus, thus allowing them to distribute
more dividends (Mohamed et al. 2012; Al-Najjar and Kilincarslan 2017).
Furthermore, Appendix A shows that operating profits have a positive effect on the payout policy
for the MINING, POWER, and MEHH sectors. This means that the sectors reporting a poor operating
income will pay lower dividends, consistent with (Li and Lie 2006). However, the results are opposite
for the AUTO, M-OTH, and ITTEL sectors. A possible explanation for this could be that the firms
of these sectors continue to pay dividends, although the operating profits are low, as they prefer to
distribute stable dividends, as reported by (Bhat and Pandey 1994) for Indian firms.
The operating measures are used to evaluate the impact of the size/scale of operations. Many studies
as discussed in the literature review have reported that larger size firms are likely to pay higher
dividends. We also find that either a higher tangibility of assets/market capitalization/operating profits
or lower business risk positively influences dividends. At least one or more operating measures are
found to be significant for the consolidated sample and for each of the individual sectors.

4.3.2. Debt Measures


The results reveal a negative association between debt and dividend policy for the AGRO,
MINING, POWER, MEHH, CONSTR, LOGISTICS, ITTEL, and FINSER sectors. This implies that
sectors with high debt levels appear to pay low dividends (Aivazian et al. 2003b; Li and Lie 2006;
Al-Najjar and Kilincarslan 2017). However, for the BANKING-sector, the results depict a significant
positive effect. A possible explanation is that the easy availability of external sources of funds for
banks enables them to pay higher dividends and rely less on retentions (Auerbach 1982; Jensen 1986;
Bhole 2000; Bhole and Mahakud 2005). Furthermore, for the remaining sectors, debt levels do not
significantly influence dividends. This means that the dividend policy of the ENGG, AUTO, TEXTILE,
PHARMA, CONSGDS, M-OTH, and S-OTH sectors do not depend on the debt levels, as found by
(Abor and Bokpin 2010; Farooq and Jabbouri 2015; Yusof and Ismail 2016).
Denis and Osobov (2008) have observed that a lower interest coverage ratio leads to the
abandonment of dividend payout. We also show that the interest coverage ratio positively influences
the payout policy for the TEXTILE, LOGISTICS, and BANKING sectors. However, for the remaining
sectors, the results show no significant impact.
Similar to the consolidated panel estimates, the sector-wise panel results also reveal that the
current ratio and dividend policy are significantly positively associated in the AGRO, MINING, ENGG,
AUTO, POWER, MEHH, CONSTR, and LOGISTICS sectors. This implies that higher short-term
liquidity enables these sectors to pay higher dividends.
Overall, we found that a higher interest coverage ratio and current ratio, and lower debt ratios
tend to influence the dividends of Indian firms. Except for the PHARMA, CONSGDS, M-OTH and
S-OTHS sectors, either of the debt measures were found to be significant.

4.3.3. Summary Measures


We found another positive relationship between profitability and dividend policy. Although this
study uses two variables (ROE and ROI) to measure profitability, we found a significant positive impact
of ROI in 14 sectors, but ROE shows a significant positive impact in three sectors only (MEHH, S-OTH,
and LOGISTICS). In the MEHH and S-OTH sectors, the ROI variable is found to be insignificant.

31
JRFM 2019, 12, 110

The analysis thus indicates that firms having a higher profitability in these sectors are likely to
distribute higher dividends. These findings support Jensen (1986)’s free cash flow hypothesis, and are
consistent with prior studies e.g., (Fama and French 2001; Benito and Young 2003; Aivazian et al. 2003b;
DeAngelo et al. 2004; Mitton 2004; Reddy and Rath 2005; Baker et al. 2007, 2013; Bostanci et al. 2018).
However, the profitability measure may differ for each sector.
We found that the price-to-book value (P/B) ratio is significantly positively related to the
dividend policy for four sectors only (AUTO, TEXTILE, LOGISTICS, and FINSER). This is consistent
with studies such as (Nizar Al-Malkawi 2007; Foroghi et al. 2011; Al-Shubiri 2011; Imran 2011;
Yusof and Ismail 2016). However, it is significantly negatively related to the dividend policy
for the BANKING-sector only. This is in line with our expectation, and also in line with prior
studies (Auerbach 1982; Easterbrook 1984; Jensen 1986; La Porta et al. 2000b; Bhole 2000; Fama and
French 2001; Benito and Young 2003; Mitton 2004; Reddy and Rath 2005; Bhole and Mahakud 2005;
Li and Lie 2006; Ferris et al. 2006). Information on the P/B ratio was not available for all companies
of the AGRO and PHARMA sector, hence it was excluded for the panel regression estimation of
these sectors.
As anticipated, we found that liquidity will be either positively or negatively related to dividend
policy, depending upon the industry. Our panel regression estimates show that there is a significant
positive impact of CFPS on payout policy for the CONSGDS and S-OTH sectors. This signifies that
firms with a higher liquidity are likely to pay higher dividends in these sectors. However, results are
opposite for the MINING, AUTO, and M-OTH sectors. This implies that companies in these sectors
continuously distribute dividends, although they have fewer cash flows. Bhat and Pandey (1994) have
found that in India, as companies prefer to follow a stable dividend policy, the availability of cash is
not a significant factor for evaluating payout policy. The agency theory also explains the payment
of dividends through borrowed funds in case of the non-availability of cash. Information on the P/B
ratio was not available for all companies of the AGRO, TEXTILE, and PHARMA sector, hence it was
excluded for the panel regression estimation of these sectors.
Generally, we can conclude that the factors influencing dividend policy differ across sectors in
India. For the LOGISTICS sector firms, tangibility, LgMCap, debt ratio, interest coverage ratio, current
ratio, ROE, ROI, and P/B ratio significantly impact the dividend policy. For the AUTO-sector firms,
operating profit, LgMCap, current ratio, ROE, ROI, P/B ratio, and CFPS significantly influence payout
policy. For the BANKING-sector, tangibility, business risk, debt ratio, interest coverage ratio, current
ratio, ROI, and P/B ratio significantly influence the dividend policy. For the MINING-sector, firms,
tangibility, operating profit, debt ratio, current ratio, ROI, and CFPS influence the dividends. In the
CONSTR sector companies, tangibility, business risk, LgMCap, debt ratio, current ratio, and ROI are
important dividend determinants. For the AGRO and ENGG sectors, tangibility, current ratio, and ROI
influence the firms’ dividend policy. Additionally, the debt ratio is an important dividend policy
determinant in the AGRO sector, and LgMCap in the ENGG sector. In the CONSGDS sector, tangibility,
LgMCap, ROE, ROI, and CFPS influence the dividend decision, whereas for the M-OTH sector,
operating profit plays an important role instead of ROE for determining the dividend policy. For the
MEHH sector, the operating profit, LgMCap, debt ratio, current ratio, and ROE influence the dividends.
In the POWER sector, only four factors—operating profit, debt ratio, current ratio, and ROI—are
important dividend policy determinants. For the TEXTILE sector, also only four factors—tangibility,
interest coverage ratio, ROI, and P/B ratio significantly influence the payout policy. Moreover, for the
S-OTHS-sector, only three factors (business risk, ROE, and CFPS), and PHARMA-sector, only two
factors (LgMCap and ROI), significantly influence the payout policy. A possible explanation could be
that macro-economic factors rather than firm-specific factors influence the payout policies of these
sectors. Lastly, the sectoral regression results show that the scale of operations as measured by LgSales
does not significantly influence the payout policy for any of the sectors in India.

32
JRFM 2019, 12, 110

5. Overall Summary and Conclusions


This study offers fresh evidence on the key determinants of the dividend policy for an emerging
market economy using financial data for Indian-listed firms. This study uses pooled OLS and fixed
effect panel data models to examine the factors affecting dividends.
Our findings suggest that in general, firms with a larger size, higher interest coverage ratio
and profitability, and low business risk and debt are likely to distribute higher dividends in India.
The results on profitability indicate the applicability of the free cash flow hypothesis in India. However,
the findings also reveal that companies with more growth opportunities and lower cash flows also
continue to distribute dividends. We attribute this to the condition that Indian firms prefer to maintain
stability in dividend policy, such that availability of investment opportunities and the non-availability
of cash is insignificant for determining dividend policy.
We also scrutinize the variation in dividend policy across sixteen industrial sectors in India. The
results suggest that the factors influencing dividend policy differ across sectors. The sector-wise results
show that size (either tangibility/LgMCap) is found to significantly influence payout policy in all
sectors except AUTO and POWER. Also, either one or more of the debt measures (debt ratio/interest
coverage/current ratio) are also found to be significant in all of the sectors, excluding PHARMA,
CONSGDS, M-OTHS, and S-OTHS. For summary measures, we found that profitability has the same
positive relation for all industrial sectors. Whereas growth measure and liquidity measure do not
significantly influence the dividend policy in eleven sectors. Moreover, for the remaining sectors,
the signs are mixed.
Hence, sectoral results suggest that there are no uniform set of factors influencing dividend
policy for all sectors. Although a “one-size fits all” technique is unsuitable for evaluating the factors,
our finding suggests that the dividend policies of firms across sectors are generally sensitive to
size, debt, and profitability. Preferences of one variable over another may occur as a result of
firm-level and sector-level effects on dividend policy recognized in past empirical research (such as
Sawicki 2003). Furthermore, these findings provide unbiassed guidelines to investors regarding the
factors that influence the dividend policies of Indian companies.
Lastly, the findings reveal that the majority of the theories on dividend policy that are classically
based on developed markets can be applied to emerging market countries such as India, as most of
the characteristics found to important in determining dividend policies in India are consistent with
those established in developed economies. However, further research is needed for investigating the
influence of other firm-specific characteristics, such as corporate governance policies and investor
demographics, which are not included in this study.

Author Contributions: Conceptualization, G.P. and S.R.; data curation, G.P.; formal analysis, G.P. and S.R.;
investigation, G.P.; methodology, G.P. and S.R.; resources, G.P. and S.R.; software, G.P.; supervision, S.R.; validation,
G.P. and S.R.; visualization, G.P.; writing (original draft), G.P.; writing (review and editing), S.R.
Funding: This research received no external funding.
Conflicts of Interest: The authors declare no conflict of interest.

33
Appendix A

Table A1. Sector-wise panel regression.


No. of Obs. Overall R Breusch-Pagan Hausman
Sector Constant Tangibility BusRisk LgSales LgMCap OpProfit DebtRatio IntCover CurRatio ROE ROI P/B CFPS F-Statistics
JRFM 2019, 12, 110

(Balanced) Square Test p-Value


AGRO 0.022 0.017 0.024 −0.003 0.001 0.018 −0.036 0.000 0.001 −0.013 0.065 N/A N/A 144 0.674 2.237 1.116 9.200
(0.128) (0.005) *** (0.204) (0.034) ** (0.382) (0.101) (0.000) *** (0.364) (0.073) * −0.158 (0.000) *** - - (0.016) (0.291) (0.513)
MINING −0.007 0.012 −0.013 0.001 0.000 0.017 −0.025 0.000 0.001 0.000 0.058 0.000 −0.000 744 0.386 1.245 1.282 30.697
(0.221) (0.003) *** (0.396) (0.151) (0.341) (0.000) *** (0.000) *** (0.192) (0.005) *** (0.814) (0.000) *** (0.567) (0.002) *** (0.106) (0.258) (0.002)
ENGG −0.011 0.046 −0.014 −0.004 0.003 −0.007 −0.024 0.000 0.005 −0.001 0.073 0.000 0.000 252 0.334 1.053 0.007 17.269
(0.236) (0.000) *** (0.558) (0.001) *** (0.002) *** (0.505) (0.153) (0.598) (0.008) *** (0.208) (0.000) *** (0.856) (0.829) (0.401) (0.935) (0.140)
AUTO 0.047 0.017 −0.018 0.000 0.001 −0.125 0.014 0.000 0.005 −0.002 0.216 0.001 0.000 288 0.824 0.694 1.832 11.287
(0.001) *** (0.135) (0.658) (0.936) (0.029) ** (0.000) *** (0.202) (0.316) (0.012) *** (0.000) *** (0.000) *** (0.099) * (0.000) *** (0.851) (0.176) (0.504)
POWER −0.007 0.005 −0.013 0.001 0.000 0.020 −0.030 0.000 0.000 −0.003 0.071 0.000 0.000 252 0.499 0.647 1.437 7.909
(0.448) (0.507) (0.528) (0.109) (0.980) (0.000) *** (0.000) *** (0.906) (0.056) * (0.819) (0.000) *** (0.875) (0.250) (0.874) (0.231) (0.792)
TEXTILE −0.010 0.015 0.050 −0.001 N/A 0.000 0.003 0.000 0.000 −0.005 0.062 0.002 N/A 156 0.641 0.807 0.448 10.407
(0.286) (0.087) * (0.175) (0.303) (0.462) (0.740) (0.028) ** (0.375) (0.483) (0.000) *** (0.000) *** (0.643) (0.503) (0.406)
PHARMA 0.011 −0.030 0.051 −0.003 0.004 −0.057 −0.017 0.000 0.002 0.005 0.159 N/A N/A 336 0.122 0.852 0.341 9.279
(0.819) (0.367) (0.279) (0.459) (0.033) ** (0.121) (0.526) (0.967) (0.423) (0.539) (0.000) *** (0.680) (0.559) (0.506)
CONSGDS −0.100 0.061 0.044 0.001 0.003 −0.004 −0.005 0.000 0.005 −0.027 0.171 0.000 0.000 384 0.463 1.022 0.000 8.760
(0.002) *** (0.002) *** (0.159) (0.626) (0.071) * (0.920) (0.733) (0.896) (0.107) (0.031) ** (0.000) *** (0.427) (0.093) * (0.438) (0.991) (0.723)
M-OTH −0.053 0.025 0.001 0.000 0.005 −0.070 −0.003 0.000 0.000 0.008 0.108 −0.001 0.000 384 0.459 1.257 0.450 19.434

34
(0.000) *** (0.000) *** (0.956) (0.679) (0.001) *** (0.001) *** (0.730) (0.927) (0.538) (0.535) (0.000) *** (0.245) (0.093) * (0.168) (0.502) (0.079)
MEHH −0.016 −0.003 −0.005 0.000 0.002 0.011 −0.027 0.000 0.008 0.010 −0.002 0.000 0.000 216 0.359 0.534 2.274 9.218
(0.353) (0.835) (0.508) (0.830) (0.045) ** (0.066) * (0.049) ** (0.167) (0.000) *** (0.011) ** (0.687) (0.817) (0.133) (0.933) (0.132) (0.684)
S-OTHS −0.018 0.008 −0.006 0.001 0.002 0.001 −0.014 0.000 0.000 0.061 0.002 0.000 0.000 252 0.316 1.494 1.611 23.513
(0.279) (0.396) (0.002) *** (0.395) (0.114) (0.717) (0.379) (0.531) (0.909) (0.000) *** (0.259) (0.122) (0.000) *** (0.085) (0.204) (0.024)
CONSTR −0.011 0.008 −0.020 −0.001 0.002 0.002 −0.010 0.000 0.001 0.007 0.020 0.000 0.000 264 0.313 1.215 0.010 21.069
(0.009) *** (0.002) *** (0.060) * (0.127) (0.001) *** (0.300) (0.005) *** (0.626) (0.000) *** (0.133) (0.005) *** (0.424) (0.848) (0.239) (0.921) (0.049)
LOGISTICS 0.010 0.030 −0.002 0.001 −0.003 0.002 −0.044 0.000 0.001 0.014 0.027 0.003 0.000 228 0.611 0.902 0.153 15.415
(0.372) (0.010) *** (0.947) (0.279) (0.000) *** (0.710) (0.000) *** (0.000) *** (0.005) *** (0.001) *** (0.054) * (0.000) *** (0.944) (0.576) (0.696) (0.220)
ITTEL −0.024 0.040 0.152 −0.002 0.001 −0.045 −0.047 0.000 0.002 0.005 0.223 0.002 0.000 312 0.550 1.262 0.334 27.815
(0.376) (0.1264) (0.000) *** (0.327) (0.785) (0.001) *** (0.065) * (0.807) (0.101) (0.611) (0.000) *** (0.155) (0.481) (0.186) (0.563) (0.006)
BANKING 0.000 −0.005 −0.002 N/A 0.000 N/A 0.002 0.005 0.000 −0.001 0.001 0.000 0.000 384 0.444 0.636 2.211 7.928
(0.855) (0.000) *** (0.067) * (0.694) (0.021) ** (0.000) *** (0.019) ** (0.319) (0.001) *** (0.000) *** (0.805) (0.936) (0.137) (0.636)
FINSER −0.040 0.018 0.107 N/A 0.000 N/A −0.022 0.000 0.000 −0.001 0.285 0.007 0.000 492 0.533 1.318 1.311 18.757
(0.003) *** (0.206) (0.004) *** (0.879) (0.004) *** (0.178) (0.989) (0.555) (0.000) *** (0.000) *** (0.118) (0.098) (0.252) (0.043)

Note: Sector is the industrial sector to which a company belongs based on CMIE classification. Numbers within parentheses show number of firms in each sector. Regression coefficients
are estimated using fixed effect model for AGRO sector and using pooled ordinary least squares for the remaining sectors. Dividends divided by total assets is the dependent variable.
The independent variables are as follows. Tangibility is total assets minus current assets divided by total assets. BusRisk is the standard deviation of return on investment (ROI) (lagged
three years). LgSales is the natural logarithm of sales in local currency. LgMCap is the natural logarithm of market capitalization in local currency. OpProfit is the earnings before interest
and tax (EBIT) divided by total sales. DebtRatio is the long-term debt divided by total assets. IntCover is EBIT divided by interest. CurRatio is current assets divided by current liabilities.
ROE is Net profit after tax (NPAT) divided by net worth. ROI is EBIT divided by capital employed (CE). P/B is Market Price Per share at the end of the year divided by book value per
share for the year. CFPS is net cash flow from operating activities divided by number of equity shares outstanding. The t-statistics are given in parentheses. *** Significant at the 1 percent
level, ** Significant at the 5 percent level & * Significant at the 10 percent level.
JRFM 2019, 12, 110

References
Abor, Joshua, and Godfred A. Bokpin. 2010. Investment Opportunities, Corporate Finance, and Dividend Payout
Policy: Evidence from Emerging Markets. Studies in Economics and Finance 27: 180–94. [CrossRef]
Adkins, Lee C. 2010. Using Gretl for Principles of Econometric. Version 1.3131. Boston: Free Software Foundation.
Aivazian, Varouj, Laurence Booth, and Sean Cleary. 2003a. Dividend Policy and the Organization of Capital
Markets. Journal of Multinational Financial Management 13: 101–21. [CrossRef]
Aivazian, Varouj, Laurence Booth, and Sean Cleary. 2003b. Do Emerging Market Firms Follow Different Dividend
Policies from U.S. Firms? Journal of Financial Research 26: 371–87. [CrossRef]
Allen, Franklin, Antonio E. Bernardo, and Ivo Welch. 2000. A Theory of Dividends Based on Tax Clienteles.
The Journal of Finance 55: 2499–536. [CrossRef]
Nizar Al-Malkawi, H. 2007. Determinants of Corporate Dividend Policy in Jordan: An Application of the Tobit
Model. Journal of Economic and Administrative Sciences 23: 44–70. [CrossRef]
Al-Najjar, Basil. 2009. Dividend Behaviour and Smoothing New Evidence from Jordanian Panel Data. Studies in
Economics and Finance 26: 182–97. [CrossRef]
Al-Najjar, Basil, and Erhan Kilincarslan. 2017. Corporate Dividend Decisions and Dividend Smoothing:
New Evidence from an Empirical Study of Turkish Firms. International Journal of Managerial Finance 13: 1–38.
[CrossRef]
Al-Shubiri, Faris Nasif. 2011. Determinants of Changes Dividend Behavior Policy: Evidence from the Amman
Stock Exchange. Far East Journal of Psychology and Business 4: 1–15.
Auerbach, Alan J. 1982. Issues in the Measurement and Determinants of Business Saving. NBER Working Paper 1024.
Cambridge: NBER.
Baiocchi, Giovanni, and Walter Distaso. 2003. GRETL: Econometric Software for the GNU Generation. Journal of
Applied Econometrics 18: 105–10. [CrossRef]
Baker, H. Kent. 1988. The Relationship between Industry Classification and Dividend Policy. Southern Business
Review 14: 1.
Baker, H. Kent, and Gary E. Powell. 2012. Dividend Policy in Indonesia: Survey Evidence from Executives.
Journal of Asia Business Studies 6: 79–92. [CrossRef]
Baker, Malcolm, and Jeffrey Wurgler. 2004. Appearing and Disappearing Dividends: The Link to Catering
Incentives. Journal of Financial Economics 73: 271–88. [CrossRef]
Baker, H. Kent, Gary E. Powell, and E. Theodore Veit. 2002. Revisiting the Dividend Puzzle. Do All of the Pieces
Now Fit? Review of Financial Economics 11: 241–61. [CrossRef]
Baker, H. Kent, Samir Saadi, Shantanu Dutta, and Devinder Gandhi. 2007. The Perception of Dividends
by Canadian Managers: New Survey Evidence. Edited by David Michayluk. International Journal of
Managerial Finance 3: 70–91. [CrossRef]
Baker, H. Kent, Bin Chang, Shantanu Dutta, and Samir Saadi. 2013. Canadian Corporate Payout Policy. International
Journal of Managerial Finance 9: 164–84. [CrossRef]
Benito, Andrew, and Garry Young. 2003. Hard Times or Great Expectations? Dividend Omissions and Dividend
Cuts by UK Firms. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 65: 531–55. [CrossRef]
Bhat, Ramesh, and Indra M. Pandey. 1994. Dividend Decision: A Study of Managers’ Perception. Available
online: http://search.proquest.com/openview/58cefb4c10c1cf9e9acab02494e5f48f/1?pq-origsite=gscholar&
cbl=1818288 (accessed on 15 February 2016).
Bhattacharya, Sudipto. 1979. Imperfect Information, Dividend Policy, and ‘the Bird in the Hand’ Fallacy. Bell Journal
of Economics 10: 259–70. [CrossRef]
Bhole, Laxman M. 2000. Financing of the Private Corporate Sector: Trends, Issues, and Policies. Mumbai: Himalaya
Publishing House.
Bhole, L. M., and Jitendra Mahakud. 2005. Trends and Determinants of Private Corporate Sector Savings in India.
Economic and Political Weekly 40: 4234–50.
Black, Fischer. 1976. The New Dividend Puzzle. Journal of Portfolio Management 2: 5–8. [CrossRef]
Bostanci, Faruk, Eyup Kadioglu, and Guven Sayilgan. 2018. Determinants of Dividend Payout Decisions:
A Dynamic Panel Data Analysis of Turkish Stock Market. International Journal of Financial Studies 6: 93.
[CrossRef]

35
JRFM 2019, 12, 110

Brav, Alon, John R. Graham, Campbell R. Harvey, and Roni Michaely. 2005. Payout Policy in the 21st Century.
Journal of Financial Economics 77: 483–527. [CrossRef]
Brealey, Richard A., and Stewart C. Myers. 2002. Principles of Corporate Finance. Boston: Irwin
McGraw-Hill Education.
Brockman, Paul, and Emre Unlu. 2009. Dividend Policy, Creditor Rights, and the Agency Costs of Debt. Journal of
Financial Economics 92: 276–99. [CrossRef]
Chowdhury, Reza H., Min Maung, and Jenny Zhang. 2014. Information Content of Dividends: A Case of an
Emerging Financial Market. Studies in Economics and Finance 31: 272–90. [CrossRef]
Cottrell, Allin, and Riccardo Jack Lucchetti. 2017. Gretl User’s Guide: Gnu Regression, Econometrics and Time-Series
Library. Boston: Free Software Foundation.
DeAngelo, Harry, Linda DeAngelo, and Douglas J. Skinner. 2004. Are Dividends Disappearing? Dividend
Concentration and the Consolidation of Earnings. Journal of Financial Economics 72: 425–56. [CrossRef]
Dempsey, Stephen J., Gene Laber, and Michael S. Rozeff. 1993. Dividend Policies in Practice: Is There an Industry
Effect? Quarterly Journal of Business and Economics 32: 3–13.
Denis, David J., and Igor Osobov. 2008. Why Do Firms Pay Dividends? International Evidence on the Determinants
of Dividend Policy. Journal of Financial Economics 89: 62–82. [CrossRef]
Easterbrook, Frank H. 1984. Two Agency-Cost Explanations of Dividends. The American Economic Review 74: 650–59.
Von Eije, Henk, and William L. Megginson. 2008. Dividends and Share Repurchases in the European Union.
Journal of Financial Economics 89: 347–74. [CrossRef]
Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French. 1999. The Corporate Cost of Capital and the Return on Corporate
Investment. Journal of Finance 54: 1939–67. [CrossRef]
Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French. 2001. Disappearing Dividends: Changing Firm Characteristics or Lower
Propensity to Pay. Journal of Financial Economics 60: 3–43. [CrossRef]
Farooq, Omar, and Imad Jabbouri. 2015. Cost of Debt and Dividend Policy: Evidence from the MENA Region.
Journal of Applied Business Research 31: 1637–44. [CrossRef]
Ferris, Stephen P., Nilanjan Sen, and Ho Pei Yui. 2006. Are Fewer Firms Paying More Dividends? The International
Evidence. Journal of Multinational Financial Management 16: 333–62. [CrossRef]
Foroghi, Dariush, Farzad Karimi, and Zahra Momeni. 2011. The Investigation Relationship of Dividend Behaviour
and Likelihood of Paying Dividend with Financial Variables in Tehran Stock Exchange: Interdisciplinary.
Journal of Contemporary Research in Business 3: 390–97.
Glen, Jack D., Yannis Karmokolias, Robert R. Miller, and Sanjay Shah. 1995. Dividend Policy and Behavior in
Emerging Markets: To Pay or Not to Pay. IFC Discussion Papers. Washington: The World Bank.
Gordon, Myron J. 1963. Optimal Investment and Financing Policy. The Journal of Finance 18: 264–72.
Gujarati, Damodar N. 2009. Basic Econometrics. New Delhi: Tata McGraw Hill Education.
Gul, Ferdinand A. 1999. Government Share Ownership, Investment Opportunity Set and Corporate Policy Choices
in China. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 7: 157–72. [CrossRef]
Hausman, Jerry A. 1978. Specification Tests in Econometrics. Econometrica 46: 1251–71. [CrossRef]
Hill, R. Carter, William E. Griffiths, and Guay C. Lim. 2007. Principles of Econometrics, 3rd ed. Hoboken: Wiley.
Hsiao, Cheng. 1985. Benefits and limitations of panel data. Econometric Reviews 4: 121–74. [CrossRef]
Hsiao, Cheng. 1995. Panel Analysis for Metric Data. In Handbook of Statistical Modeling for the Social and Behavioral
Sciences. Boston: Springer, pp. 361–400.
Hsiao, Cheng. 2003. Analysis of Panel Data, 2nd ed. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Hsiao, Cheng, and Baohong Sun. 2000. To pool or not to pool panel data. Contributions to Economic Analysis 244:
181–98.
Imran, Kashif. 2011. Determinants of Dividend Payout Policy: A Case of Pakistan Engineering Sector. The Romanian
Economic Journal 41: 47–59.
Jensen, Michael C. 1986. Agency Cost of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance, and Takeovers. The American
Economic Review 76: 323–29.
Kevin, S. 1992. Dividend Policy: An Analysis of Some Determinants. Finance India 6: 253–59.
La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny. 2000a. Investor Protection
and Corporate Governance. Journal of Financial Economics 58: 3–27. [CrossRef]
La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny. 2000b. Agency problems and
dividend policies around the world. The Journal of Finance 55: 1–33. [CrossRef]

36
JRFM 2019, 12, 110

Li, Wei, and Erik Lie. 2006. Dividend Changes and Catering Incentives. Journal of Financial Economics 80: 293–308.
[CrossRef]
Lintner, John. 1956. Distribution of Incomes of Corporations among Dividends, Retained Earnings, and Taxes.
The‘American Economic Review 49: 97–113.
Mahapatra, R. P., and P. K. Sahu. 1993. A Note on Determinants of Corporate Dividend Behaviour in India-An
Econometric Analysis. Decision 20: 1–22.
Marsh, Terry A., and Robert C. Merton. 1987. Dividend Behavior for the Aggregate Stock Market. The Journal
of Business 60: 1–40. [CrossRef]
Mehar, Ayub. 2005. Corporate Governance and Dividend Policy. Pakistan Economic and Social Review 43: 93–106.
Mehmood, Rashid, Ahmed Imran Hunjra, and Muhammad Irfan Chani. 2019. The Impact of Corporate
Diversification and Financial Structure on Firm Performance: Evidence from South Asian Countries.
Journal of Risk and Financial Management 12: 49. [CrossRef]
Michel, Allen. 1979. Industry Influence on Dividend Policy. Financial Management 8: 22–26. [CrossRef]
Miller, Merton, and Franco Modigliani. 1961. Dividend Policy, Growth, and the Valuation of Shares. The Journal of
Business 34: 411–33. [CrossRef]
Miller, Merton H., and Kevin Rock. 1985. Dividend Policy under Asymmetric Information. The Journal of Finance
40: 1031–51. [CrossRef]
Mishra, Chandra Sekhar, and Vunyale Narender. 1996. Dividend Policy of SOEs in India: An Analysis. Finance India
10: 633–45.
Mitton, Todd. 2004. Corporate Governance and Dividend Policy in Emerging Markets. Emerging Markets Review
5: 409–26. [CrossRef]
Mohamed, Norhayati, Wee Shu Hui, Normah Hj Omar, Rashidah Abdul Rahman, Nor’azam Mastuki, Maz Ainy
Abdul Azis, and Shazelina Zakaria. 2012. Empirical Analysis of Determinants of Dividend Payment:
Profitability and Liquidity. Accounting Research Institute. Available online: https://www.researchgate.net/
profile/Mohamad_Zakaria2/publication/267220756_EMPIRICAL_ANALYSIS_OF_DETERMINANTS_OF_
DIVIDEND_PAYMENT_PROFITABILITY_AND_LIQUIDITY/links/54bce7080cf24e50e940b674.pdf (accessed
on 17 May 2016).
Ooi, Joseph. 2001. Dividend Payout Characteristics of UK Property Companies. Journal of Real Estate
Portfolio Management 7: 133–42.
Pandey, Indra M. 2003. Corporate Dividend Policy and Behaviour: The Malaysian Evidence. Asian Academy of
Management Journal 8: 17–32.
Pandey, Indra M., and Ramesh Bhat. 2007. Dividend Behaviour of Indian Companies under Monetary Policy
Restrictions. Managerial Finance 33: 14–25. [CrossRef]
Ramcharran, Harri. 2001. An Empirical Model of Dividend Policy in Emerging Equity Markets. Emerging Markets
Quarterly 5: 39–49.
Reddy, Y. Subba, and Subhrendu Rath. 2005. Disappearing Dividends in Emerging Markets? Evidence from India.
Emerging Markets Finance and Trade 41: 58–82. [CrossRef]
Renneboog, Luc, and Grzegorz Trojanowski. 2007. Control Structures and Payout Policy. Managerial Finance
33: 43–64. [CrossRef]
Ross, Stephen A. 1977. The Determination of Financial Structure: The Incentive-Signalling Approach. The Bell
Journal of Economics 8: 23. [CrossRef]
Sawicki, Julia. 2003. An Investigation into the Dividend Policy of Firms in East Asia. Working Paper. Singapore:
Nanyang Technological University School of Business Anyang Avenue.
Sawicki, Julia. 2009. Corporate governance and dividend policy in Southeast Asia pre- and post-crisis.
European Journal of Finance 15: 211–30. [CrossRef]
Scott, David F., and John D. Martin. 1975. Industry Influence on Financial Structure. Financial Management 4: 67–73.
[CrossRef]
Setia-Atmaja, Lukas. 2010. Dividend and Debt Policies of Family Controlled Firms: The Impact of Board
Independence. International Journal of Managerial Finance 6: 128–42. [CrossRef]
Solomon, Ezra. 1963. The Theory of Financial Management. New York: Colombia University Press.
Subhash Kamat, Manoj, and Manasvi M. Kamat. 2013. Economic Reforms, Determinants and Stability of Dividends
in a Dynamic Setting. Edited by Arif Khurshed. Journal of Asia Business Studies 7: 5–30. [CrossRef]

37
JRFM 2019, 12, 110

Tangjitprom, Nopphon. 2013. Propensity to Pay Dividends and Catering Incentives in Thailand. Studies in
Economics and Finance 30: 45–55. [CrossRef]
Walter, James E. 1963. Dividend Policy: Its Influence on the Value of the Enterprise. The Journal of Finance 18: 280–91.
[CrossRef]
Yarram, Subba Reddy. 2015. Corporate Governance Ratings and the Dividend Payout Decisions of Australian
Corporate Firms. International Journal of Managerial Finance 11: 162–78. [CrossRef]
Yusof, Yusniliyana, and Suhaiza Ismail. 2016. Determinants of Dividend Policy of Public Listed Companies in
Malaysia. Review of International Business and Strategy 26: 88–99. [CrossRef]

© 2019 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access
article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution
(CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).

38
Journal of
Risk and Financial
Management

Article
Exploring the Determinants of Financial Structure in
the Technology Industry: Panel Data Evidence from
the New York Stock Exchange Listed Companies
Georgeta Vintilă, Ştefan Cristian Gherghina * and Diana Alexandra Toader
Department of Finance, The Bucharest University of Economic Studies, 6 Piata Romana, 010374 Bucharest,
Romania; vintilageorgeta@yahoo.fr (G.V.); diana.tda29@gmail.com (D.A.T.)
* Correspondence: stefan.gherghina@fin.ase.ro; Tel.: +40-741-140-737

Received: 10 September 2019; Accepted: 20 October 2019; Published: 22 October 2019

Abstract: This paper aims to analyze the influencing factors on the financial structure of 51 companies
listed on the New York Stock Exchange, in the technology industry, from 2005–2018. The objective is to
see the impact of independent company-specific variables such as company size, tangibility of assets,
growth opportunity, effective tax rate, current liquidity, depreciation, stock rotation, financial return,
working capital, price to book value, price to earnings ratio, as well as the impact of governance
variables and macroeconomic variables such as inflation rate, interest rate, market size, gross domestic
product per capita. Using panel data and multiple linear regressions, we analyze the relationship
between the independent variables listed above and the dependent variables, namely the total debt
ratio, the long-term debt ratio and the short-term debt ratio. The results of the analysis showed that
variables such as size, tangibility, liquidity, profitability have a significant influence on the dependent
variables in accordance with the theories regarding the capital structure.

Keywords: financial structure; panel data; regression analysis

1. Introduction
The first decade of the 21st century has undergone major changes in the recession and boom
periods. These cycles in the economy have had an important impact on the value of the company.
Seeing as how an enterprise is also evaluated from the point of view of investments, both those of
the past and those of the future, and in order to support these investments, it is essential to choose a
financial mix. The financial decision depends on the dynamics of the business environment, whether it
is in a period of growth or decrease. When a financial crisis occurs, the creditors dictate their preferred
method of financing to companies. If a manager searches for capital, he should be aware of the
preferences of investors and precisely respond to the conservative behavior of creditors, because they
face a big dilemma, to invest or not. The firm’s manager should understand their dilemma and try
to attract the confidence of the investors through the firm-specific features. The effects of the Euro
Crisis resulted significantly negatively related to leverage in the study of Moradi and Paulet (2019).
During the financial crisis, firms which are vulnerable to the shocks in the financial markets absorb the
negative impact earlier than other firms. Hence, financial difficulties can lead to bankruptcy and can be
the result of wrong decisions in choosing the financial structure. The financial structure is the result of
some decisions that managers take in order to support long-term investments, identifying appropriate
sources of financing to contribute to the optimal development of the company. Investments were
affected after the economic crisis in 2008 in different ways, depending on firm’s debt structure and
whether firms had access to the public debt market. Iwaki (2019) found that accessibility to the public
debt market, as well as, the differences in debt structures have an important influence in investment.
The author underlined the fact that bank-dependent firms faced more underinvestment after crisis

JRFM 2019, 12, 163; doi:10.3390/jrfm12040163 39 www.mdpi.com/journal/jrfm


JRFM 2019, 12, 163

than firms with access to public debt market. Thus, the capital structure is a fundamental element of
the organization. Financial resources can be divided into two broad categories, namely, equity and
debt, and the financial structure can be defined as a merger between the two, more precisely, a ratio in
which they are allocated. An optimal combination of these results in a reduction in the price of capital.
The empirical literature highlighted the effects of firm-specific and country-specific factors on firm
leverage, such as size, growth, asset tangibility, profitability, tax shields, liquidity, earnings volatility
and interest rate, inflation rate, gross domestic product etc. Capital structure decisions are affected by
the firm’s own characteristics and country characteristics. Previous research demonstrated that the
effects of capital structure determinants are not equal across countries. Ramli et al. (2019) emphasized
that the impact of firm-specific factors and country-specific differ in terms of significance, sign and
intensity level in Malaysia and Indonesia. Industry-specific factors have also a contribution to capital
structure decisions. Li and Islam (2019) showed that industry-specific factors can both directly and
indirectly affect the capital structure choice. In terms of direct impacts, the authors showed that GDP
significantly influences the capital structure. In terms of indirect impacts, their findings showed that
companies tend to be more leveraged, if they operate in economically significant industries.
It is important to study which factors have an influence on the financial structure, as this in turn has
an influence on the economic performance of the company. Identifying an optimal financial structure
is relevant to reduce risk and increase performance. An imbalance in loans and their ability to generate
financial efficiency can lead to bankruptcy. Therefore, it is vital to have a balanced report on the use of
equity and borrowed capital as sources of financing, but also to know the factors and their influence in
order to make a precise delimitation of the proportions. The database consists of 51 companies from
the technology industry listed on the New York Stock Exchange. The companies in this sector are
constantly evolving and they contribute to the change of human culture and it seems relevant to study
which factors have an influence on financial structure of these companies. The studied period of time
2005–2018 is also relevant because it includes the recession period as well as the post-recession period,
when the companies had to take important financial decisions in order to survive in front of the crisis
The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 discusses the existing theories and related
literature. Section 3 presents the database, selected variables and quantitative techniques. Section 4
reveals the empirical findings. The last section concludes the study.

2. Literature Review
The first theories were formulated by Modigliani and Miller (1958), who wrote in an early article
that the structure of capital does not influence the value of the firm. In their article MM started
from the premises that the market is perfect and there are no factors that significantly influence the
market, taxation does not exist, trading costs and bankruptcy are absent. In reality this theory is not
valid because the perfect market does not exist and taxation is present. After the criticisms received
regarding the first theory, a few years later, Modigliani and Miller (1963) considered the possibility of
revising the first hypotheses, introducing taxation and developing the first theory. MM acknowledged
that taxation has an effect on debt and capital and has some advantages since interest is deductible.
Agent theory developed by Jensen and Meckling (1976) captures the idea of agency costs that arise
as a result of conflicts between managers, shareholders, and creditors. These conflicts are supposed to
arise due to the inconsistency of interests. Managers tend to use the firm’s resources in projects that
bring more personal benefits than maximizing the value of the company. Shareholders can discourage
such a behavior through monitoring and control activities. However, these actions also involve costs,
called agency costs. Debt can reduce agency costs and affect the performance of the company at the
same time, by determining the managers to act in the interest of the company rather than in their own
interest. Thus, the option of a company to be financed through debt reduces the cash flow available at
the discretion of managers, reducing agency costs.
Following the same line of thinking, the trade-off theory takes into account industry-level effects,
taxes, bankruptcy costs and agency issues. Kraus and Litzenberger (1973) are the ones who grounded

40
JRFM 2019, 12, 163

this theory and argue that a firm can determine its financial structure by balancing the costs and
benefits related to external financing. In this theoretical approach, the leverage is considered to
bring advantages, under certain conditions, and managers prefer to use debt as a source of financing
instead of the available internal funds. If a company becomes too indebted, the tax savings will be
higher and therefore bankruptcy costs will rise. That is why it is recommended in theory to avoid
over-indebtedness and to rationalize the indebtedness index. This theory starts from the premise that
there is a positive relationship between the capital structure and the performance of the enterprise.
In contrast to previous theories, the pecking order theory developed by Myers and Majluf (1984)
implies an ordering of financing sources, which presents greater flexibility and lower trading costs
and is based on information asymmetry between companies and creditors. Due to the fact that the
company has more information about the future than the creditors, the need for monitoring increases
the borrowing costs, and this encourages companies to finance with their own funds, thus the first
source would be internal financing. The second source is the external financing if it is required after
the exhaustion of the internal funds, first resorting to the most secure sources, that is to say, the debt,
then issues of securities. As soon as the internal funds become available, it is preferable to cancel the
debt before maturity. The last source is the capital increase through the issue of shares. Therefore,
the pecking order theory suggests that debt has an adverse effect on performance.
Unlike the pecking order theory, where firms use internal funds to eliminate the problems of
adverse selection and loss of value, where they cannot show their quality using the financial structure,
the signal theory, developed by Ross (1977), which uses the capital structure as a signal of private
information, starts from the information asymmetry and underlines that the managers know the truth
regarding the distribution of the company’s results, but the creditors do not have this information.
Investors see a high degree of debt as a signal of performance, because the company is considered to
have the ability to repay the debt at maturity. Therefore, by contracting a loan, managers give a signal
on the market to potential investors, as well as existing ones.
The market timing theory, developed by Baker and Wurgler (2002), starts from the idea that
raising capital by issuing shares depends on market performance. In corporate finance, market timing
involves in practice, issuing high-priced shares and repurchasing them at a lower price, in order to
benefit from fluctuations in the ratio between the cost of equity and other forms of capital.
From most of the studies I have included in this paper, I have looked at the main indicators that
have proved to be of undeniable importance and influence. Among them, indicators such as tangibility,
profitability, liquidity and so on can be listed.

2.1. Tangibility
A company may choose to have higher debt if it has a high tangibility ratio. A high tangibility
ratio will probably also have low financial costs according to the trade-off theory. (Chaklader and
Chawla 2016; Cortez and Susanto 2012; Rajan and Zingales 1995; Song 2005) obtained in their papers a
positive association between tangibility and indebtedness. (Chittenden et al. 1996; Demirgüç-Kunt and
Maksimovic 1999; van der Wijst and Thurik 1993) obtained a negative relationship.

2.2. Profitability
A high degree of profitability leads to a decrease in the degree of indebtedness, as it is assumed
that firms will resort to indebtedness to prevent managers from spending from the available cash
flow. A high level of rentability also means the ability of the company to borrow more easily. (Cortez
and Susanto 2012; Krishnan and Moyer 1996; Psillaki and Daskalakis 2009; Rajan and Zingales 1995;
Titman and Wessels 1988) obtained a negative association between profitability and indebtedness,
while (Alipour et al. 2015; Song 2005) obtained a positive one. Chaklader and Chawla (2016) show an
insignificant relationship.

41
JRFM 2019, 12, 163

2.3. Liquidity
A high degree of liquidity implies a lower degree of debt. An optimal level of liquidity presumes
less requirement for borrowing and external funds, according to pecking order theory and agency
theory. In contrast, based on trade-off theory, the companies should ensure an optimal level of liquidity
in order to fulfil their engagement. Chadha and Sharma (2015) found that liquidity is statistically
insignificant. Alipour et al. (2015) obtained a negative relationship between liquidity and leverage.

2.4. Size
It is assumed that there is a positive relationship between firm size and debt, according to trade-off
theory, because larger firms are more diversified and tend to have lower variance of profits, allowing
them to tolerate higher debt ratios. In contrast, pecking order theory predicts a negative relationship,
due to the fact that larger firms deal with lower adverse selection and have the ability to issue equity
more easily compared to small businesses. (Chaklader and Chawla 2016; Psillaki and Daskalakis 2009;
Rajan and Zingales 1995; Song 2005) achieved a positive association. Alipour et al. (2015) obtained
an inverse relationship, concluding that small companies have no option but to resort to bank loans.
(Cortez and Susanto 2012; Viviani 2008) found the relationship between size and debt ratio insignificant.

2.5. Growth
The pecking order theory states that there is a positive relationship between growth and debt.
Companies with high growth rates need sufficient funds to support their investment opportunities and
internal funds are unlikely to be enough to support them. Trade-off theory states that there is a negative
relationship, assets intangibility of firms with high growth rates implies the risk of losing value in
case of financial distress. (Chaklader and Chawla 2016; Psillaki and Daskalakis 2009) showed that the
growth variable is statistically insignificant, contrary to (Alipour et al. 2015; Cortez and Susanto 2012)
who concluded that the relationship between the growth variable and the dependent variable is
significantly negative.

2.6. Inflation
Chadha and Sharma (2015) found that inflation is statistically insignificant. Bokpin (2009) obtained
a significant relationship. In most cases, firms will resort to internal sources of financing during periods
when inflation is high, as this pressure will increase the cost of obtaining capital from creditors.

2.7. Gross Domestic Product Per Capita


The improvement of the general economy determines the companies to resort to internal sources
of financing to the detriment of external sources. Bokpin (2009) obtained an inverse relationship,
contrary to Bas et al. (2010), who obtained a significant positive relationship with the debt, explaining
that an economic growth determines the companies to be more willing to contract the loans in order to
be able to support the new investments.

2.8. The Interest Rate


The effect of the interest rate on the financing option is certainly not to be neglected, because
the costs of external financing reflect the weighted average cost of capital of firms. Increasing the
interest rate positively influences the choice of short-term funds, rather than opting for long-term debt.
(Bas et al. 2010; Bokpin 2009) obtained a positive but statistically insignificant relationship between
the two.

2.9. Effective Tax Rate


A company that has a high effective rate of corporate income tax will seek external financing to
benefit from the tax deduction of interest expenses. Alipour et al. (2015) show a positive association.

42
JRFM 2019, 12, 163

2.10. Risk
Trade-off theory states that risky businesses should not be highly levered, according to this theory,
there is a negative relationship between risk and debt. From pecking order theory perspective there
is also a negative association between operating risk and debt. A company with high volatility in
earnings is more likely to face a debt burden and to go bankrupt. Psillaki and Daskalakis (2009)
obtained a negative relationship.

2.11. Corporate Governance Variables (Board Size, CEO Status)


There is a positive relationship between board size and debt. Companies with large boards
are much more capable to find external funds and at the same time, financial institutions are more
confident while lending firms with large size boards. Sheikh and Wang (2012) obtained a positive and
statistically significant relationship between board size and debt. CEO status refers to duality of the
CEO, namely when the CEO of the company serve as chairman in the board. It is expected that there
is a conflict of interest when the same person serves in both positions, because that gives too much
power and control. Buvanendra et al. (2017) obtained a negative statistically significant relationship
between CEO duality and debt.
In all the abovementioned studies, there can be observed a pattern to be observed, since all
included independent variables are related to the structure of assets, profitability, taxation. Only in a
few works there were macroeconomic variables included such as inflation rate, interest rate or even
the gross domestic product. The results are similar and showed that the tangibility, the profitability,
the increase in size, for example, are factors with a significant influence on the financial structure.
There were also variables that proved to be insignificant, but these results are also influenced by the
chosen database and the processing of data in advance. Theoretically, from a broader perspective, the
choice of capital structure must be viewed from three perspectives: the advantage of tax exemption,
the risk assumed and the quality and type of assets. This indicates that a low-risk, high-profit firm
with few intangible assets and robust growth opportunities should find a relatively high ratio between
debt and equity less attractive.

3. Data and Methodology


The process of forming the database for analyzing the influencing factors on the financial structure
consisted in the initial collection of the financial data of 75 companies listed on the New York Stock
Exchange, companies that are part of the technology industry. Because there was not enough data for
the analyzed period, 2005–2018, the database consists of only 51 companies. The financial data was
taken from the Thomson Reuters databases, respectively The World Bank, from which the independent
variables such as inflation rate, interest rate, gross domestic product per capita were taken.

3.1. Database Construction and Variables Presentation


The dependent variables included in the analysis are included in Table 1. I chose three dependent
variables, which explain to a certain extent the financial structure, namely, the rate of total debt, the rate
of long-term and short-term debt. These debt ratios show which proportion of assets are financed
by debt. A high value of these ratios reveals the leverage of the company, and also the financial risk.
Debt ratios vary across industries, businesses with intensive capital such as transportation sectors or
telecommunications have higher debt than other industries such as technology sector.

43
JRFM 2019, 12, 163

Table 1. Dependent variables included in the empirical study.

Variable Name Symbol Formula Authors


Bokpin (2009), Chaklader and Chawla (2016), Psillaki
Total debt rate TD Total debts/total assets
and Daskalakis (2009), Su (2010), Viviani (2008)
Amidu (2007), Eldomiaty and Azim (2008), Ezeoha
Long-term debt/total
Long-term debt rate LTD (2008), Hall et al. (2004), Titman and Wessels (1988), van
assets
der Wijst and Thurik (1993), Viviani (2008)
Short-term debt/total Amidu (2007), Eldomiaty and Azim (2008), Ezeoha
Short-term debt rate STD
assets (2008), Hall et al. (2004), van der Wijst and Thurik (1993)
Source: Author’s own work.

Estimating separate relationships for long-term and short-term debt rates (long-term and
short-term debt over total assets) allows for an influence on the maturity of the debt structure
as well as the leverage. Total assets are included as a size variable to test scale effects in the ratio of
debt to total assets.
Table 2 below shows the independent variables classified according to the level of influence,
namely, microeconomic, macroeconomic and corporate governance indicators.
(Barton et al. 1989; Titman and Wessels 1988) agreed that companies with high rates of profit
will maintain a low rate of debt, because they are able to generate funds from internal sources, so the
profitability indicator was included as a variable. Companies with very high growth rates will seek
external sources of funding to support their growth rate. Auerbach (1985) also argues that the leverage
is inversely proportional to the growth rate, because the tax deduction of interest expense is not
significant for fast-growing firms. Michaelas et al. (1999) found a positive expected growth related to
leverage and long-term debt, while (Chittenden et al. 1996; Jordan et al. 1997) found mixed evidence.
Graham (1996) concluded that, in general, taxes affect the financial decisions of enterprises, but the
impact is not major. Myers (1977) argues that tangible assets, such as fixed assets, can support a higher
level of debt compared to intangible assets. Assets can be used as collateral to reduce potential agent
costs associated with borrowing (Smith and Warner 1979; Stulz and Johnson 1985). The size of the
company plays an important role in determining the financial structure of a company. Researchers
have found that large firms are less likely to go bankrupt because they tend to be more diverse than
smaller companies (Ang et al. 1982; Marsh 1982; Smith and Warner 1979; Titman and Wessels 1988)
report a negative relationship between the debt and the size of the firms. Marsh (1982) argues that
small firms, due to their limited access to the capital market, tend to rely heavily on loans. Titman
and Wessels (1988) argue that small firms are less reliant on equity because they may face a higher
cost per issue unit. Ooi (1999) argues that firms with relatively higher operational risk will have
incentives to have a lower leverage than firms with more stable incomes. Öztekin and Flannery (2012)
have observed that firms that have more liquid assets can use them as an internal alternative of funds
instead of debt. I included four macroeconomic indicators, GDP per capita, inflation rate, interest
rate, and market size in the study (Bartholdy and Mateus 2008; Demirgüç-Kunt and Maksimovic 1996,
1999). I also included the GDP per capita because with its growth, the countries become richer and
implicitly there are more financing resources. Thus, I expect this indicator to be positively correlated
with debt. Inflation provides a perspective on the stability of the national currency. Countries with
a high inflation rate are associated with a high degree of uncertainty. In general, loans are nominal
value contracts, and the inflation rate influences the value of loans, making them riskier. I expect the
inflation rate to be negatively correlated with debt. When the interest rate increases, companies are no
longer willing to resort to bank loans, because the cost of the loan is higher. Therefore, I expect the
interest rate to be inversely proportional to the debt. The size of the market was included because it
indicates how easy it is to access the market. The corporate governance indicators were also included
in the empirical study to see if they influence the financial structure. Vintilă and Gherghina (2012)
obtained mixed results regarding the relationship between the size of the board and the performance
of the company. The paper had a database of 155 US companies listed from different industries and
investigated the relationship between corporate governance mechanism, CEO characteristics and

44
JRFM 2019, 12, 163

company performance. It turned out that the number of board members is in a negative relationship
with Tobin’s Q, but in a positive relationship with ROA. From the point of view of the status of the
CEO, no results have been obtained that suggest a relationship with the performance of the company,
whether or not he is chairman of the board. Therefore, I expect that the size of the board, the status of
the CEO and the existence of the committees will not influence the financial structure.

Table 2. Independent variables included in the empirical study.

Variable Name Symbol Formula Authors


 Microeconomic Indicators
The size of the Chaklader and Chawla (2016), Psillaki and Daskalakis
Size Natural logarithm of total assets
company (2009), Su (2010)
Bokpin (2009), Chaklader and Chawla (2016), Cortez and
Tangibility of assets Tang Tangible assets/total assets
Susanto (2012), Su (2010), Titman and Wessels (1988)
Eriotis et al. (2007), Karadeniz et al. (2009), Ooi (1999),
Growth opportunity Growth Sales variation
Psillaki and Daskalakis (2009)
Effective tax rate Etax Tax/earnings before taxes Karadeniz et al. (2009)
Current liquidity Liq Current assets/current debt Bokpin (2009), Chaklader and Chawla (2016)
Depreciation of total assets
Depreciation Depr van der Wijst and Thurik (1993)
(adjustments)
Stock rotation Stock (Stocks/turnover) × 360 van der Wijst and Thurik (1993)
Size / Proportion Prop Natural logarithm of turnover Own considerations
Financial return ROE Net income/equity Chaklader and Chawla (2016)
Price earnings ratio PER Market capitalization/net income Own considerations
Price to book value PBV Market capitalization/equity Own considerations
Working capital WC Current assets—current liabilities Own considerations
 Macroeconomic Indicators
Inflation rate Inf_r Inflation rate Bokpin (2009)
Interest rate Int_r Interest rate—annual percentage rate Bokpin (2009)
Gross domestic Gross domestic product/number of
GDP_cap Bokpin (2009)
product per capita inhabitants
Market size M_size Market value/gross domestic product Bokpin (2009)
 Corporate governance indicators
Board size Board Number of board members Own considerations
Dummy variable
Remuneration If there is a remuneration committee = 1
C_r Own considerations
Committee If there is no remuneration committee =
0
Dummy variable
Audit Committee C_a If there is an audit committee = 1 Own considerations
If no audit committee = 0
Dummy variable
Nomination
C_n If there is a nomination committee = 1 Own considerations
Committee
If there is no nomination committee = 0
Dummy variable
If the CEO is the chairman of the board
CEO Status S_CEO =0 Own considerations
If the CEO is not the chairman of the
board = 1
Source: Author’s own work.

The general objective is to analyze the factors which have an influence on the financial structure.
Firstly, I will start from a set of hypotheses, which will be tested afterwards, in accordance with the
studies mentioned above.

Hypothesis 1 (H1). There is a positive relationship between size and debt ratio (Chaklader and Chawla 2016;
Cortez and Susanto 2012; Song 2005).

Hypothesis 2 (H2). There is a positive relationship between tangibility and debt ratio (Chaklader and Chawla
2016; Cortez and Susanto 2012; Song 2005).

45
JRFM 2019, 12, 163

Hypothesis 3 (H3). There is a negative relationship between growth opportunity and debt ratio (Alipour et al.
2015; Cortez and Susanto 2012; Psillaki and Daskalakis 2009).

Hypothesis 4 (H4). There is a negative relationship between liquidity and debt ratio (Alipour et al. 2015;
Chaklader and Chawla 2016).

Hypothesis 5 (H5). There is a positive relationship between the tax rate and debt ratio (Alipour et al. 2015).

Hypothesis 6 (H6). There is a negative relationship between profitability and debt ratio (Alipour et al. 2015;
Chaklader and Chawla 2016; Cortez and Susanto 2012; Nenu et al. 2018).

Hypothesis 7 (H7). There is a negative relationship between inflation rate and debt ratio (Bokpin 2009; Chadha
and Sharma 2015; Demirgüç-Kunt and Maksimovic 1999).

Hypothesis 8 (H8). There is a negative relationship between interest rate and debt ratio (Bartholdy and Mateus
2008; Chadha and Sharma 2015; Demirgüç-Kunt and Maksimovic 1999).

Hypothesis 9 (H9). There is a positive relationship between GDP and debt ratio (Demirgüç-Kunt and
Maksimovic 1996).

Hypothesis 10 (H10). There is a negative relation between board size and debt ratio (own consideration).

Hypothesis 11 (H11). There is a negative relation between presence of audit committee and debt ratio
(own consideration).

Hypothesis 12 (H12). There is a negative relation between presence of nomination committee and debt ratio
(own consideration).

Hypothesis 13 (H13). There is a negative relation between presence of remuneration committee and debt ratio
(own consideration).

Hypothesis 14 (H14). There is a negative relation between CEO Status and debt ratio (own consideration).

3.2. Econometric Framework


The influence factors were studied based on multiple regression model, using the method of least
squares, data being structured as panel type:

Financial_structurei,t = α0 + α1 × Depri,t + α2 × PBVi,t + α3 × WCi,t + α4 × Propi,t + α5 × ROEi,t


(Model 1)
+ α6 × Inf_ri,t + α7 × C_ai,t + εi,t

Financial_structurei,t = α0 + α1 × Liqi,t + α2 × Tangi,t + α3 × M_sizei,t + α4 × GDP_capi,t


(Model 2)
+ α5 × Int_ri,t + α6 × C_ni,t + α7 × S_CEOi,t + εi,t

Financial_structurei,t = α0 + α1 × Growthi,t + α2 × PERi,t + α3 × Stocki,t + α4 × Sizei,t


(Model 3)
+ α5 × Etaxi,t + α6 × C_ri,t + α7 × Boardi,t + εi,t
where Financial_structure = TD, LTD, STD; α0 = constant; α1 . . . α7 = coefficients of the parameters; ε =
error term; t = 2005 . . . 2018; i = 1, 2, . . . , 51.
The regression models are built based on the correlation matrix. The corporate governance variables
are strongly correlated with each other and they were separated in three models. This situation is
similar for the size indicator, which was calculated once as natural logarithm from total assets and
once as natural logarithm from turnover. A macroeconomic indicator was also included in each model.

46
JRFM 2019, 12, 163

4. Empirical Findings

4.1. Summary Statistics and Correlations


Table 3 presents the descriptive analysis of the variables. The indebtedness rates of the companies
are neither very small nor very high, to signal an alarming situation. The average of long-term debt is
35%, while the average of short-term debt is 21%, so the proportion of long-term debt is higher than
that of short-term debt. The maximum values, respectively the minimum, the median and the standard
deviation are presented in the table for statistical inferences.

Table 3. Descriptive statistics.

Variable Observations Mean Median Maximum Minimum Std. Dev.


TD 714 0.56 0.18 11.31 0.02 1.36
LTD 714 0.35 0.16 11.28 0.00 1.19
STD 714 0.21 0.11 2.92 0.02 0.29
Growth 714 1.22 0.10 286 −0.94 15.30
Depr 714 17,427.7 36.50 980,101 0.10 99,342.38
WC 714 200,976.9 135.40 48,789,450 −21,487,305 413,645
Liq 714 2.56 1.88 34.93 0.14 3.01
Prop 714 7.31 7.01 17.36 −2.30 2.85
Size 714 7.52 7.18 18.60 2.19 2.84
M_size 714 0.000463 0.000448 0.000847 0.000133 0.000105
Board 714 8.55 8.00 16.00 4.00 2.20
PBV 714 −9.87 2.03 526.09 −2843.21 190.92
PER 714 −155.34 15.18 5538.66 −64,217.32 3067.12
GDB_cap 714 52,104.38 51,556 62,996 44,026 5505.14
Inr_r 714 0.14 0.14 0.16 0.13 0.01
Etax 714 −0.57 0.27 6.86 −511.33 19.31
Inf_r 714 0.02 0.02 0.04 0.001 0.01
ROE 714 −221.10 0.10 2.43 −58,695 3077.75
Stock 714 61.31 55 629.70 0.70 51.03
S_Ceo 714 0.78 1.00 1.00 0.00 0.41
Tang 714 0.30 0.21 1.21 0.0022 0.27
C_a 714 0.75 1.00 1.00 0.00 0.43
C_n 714 0.64 1.00 1.00 0.00 0.48
C_r 714 0.74 1.00 1.00 0.00 0.44
Source: Author’s own work.

The rate of financial return is somewhere at 10% and is negatively correlated with all debt rates,
the strongest correlation being with the long-term debt rate. Price to earnings ratio and price to book
value are also negatively correlated with debt ratios. Debt can create artificial increases in price to book
value. Price to earnings ratio, as well as price to book value, does not help investors in comparisons
regarding companies’ debts to make certain decisions, although debt has a major impact on company
performance, illustrated by the financial leverage effect, that can be both positive or negative.
The average duration of the stock rotation is 66 days, meaning that the products stay about
2 months in stock until they are sold. According to Table 4 there is no significant association between
the working capital and the total indebtedness rate, respectively on the long term, but there is a negative
correlation between this and the short-term indebtedness rate. There is also a negative correlation
between current liquidity and debt ratios, most companies having optimal liquidity, if we look at the
median that is around 1. The technology sector requires a longer period of time to use the products,
thus a value less than 1 should not be a negative signal.

47
Table 4. Correlation of variables.
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24
Variable
TD LTD STD Growth Depr WC Liq Size Prop M_Size Board PBV PER GDP_cap Int_r Etax Inf_r ROE Stock S_CEO Tang C_a C_n C_r
1 1 0.90 0.18 0.03 −0.01 0.00 −0.07 −0.20 −0.29 0.07 −0.06 −0.64 −0.05 −0.12 0.04 0.00 0.06 −0.13 0.03 0.12 −0.03 −0.25 −0.18 −0.23
2 0.90 1 0.23 0.03 −0.02 0.00 −0.08 −0.23 −0.31 0.10 −0.04 −0.52 −0.32 −0.14 0.05 0.00 0.07 −0.25 0.04 0.12 −0.06 −0.28 −0.21 −0.26
3 0.18 0.23 1 −0.04 −0.08 −0.03 −0.31 −0.26 −0.16 0.02 −0.17 −0.12 −0.09 −0.12 0.06 0.02 0.07 −0.08 −0.11 0.02 −0.20 −0.27 −0.23 −0.26
JRFM 2019, 12, 163

4 0.03 0.03 −0.04 1 −0.01 0.00 −0.04 −0.02 −0.08 0.06 −0.02 −0.01 −0.04 −0.09 0.03 0.02 0.07 0.00 0.01 0.04 0.11 0.03 0.04 0.03
5 −0.01 −0.02 −0.08 −0.01 1 0.36 0.03 0.64 0.59 0.35 0.28 0.01 0.01 0.11 0.03 0.01 −0.03 0.01 −0.16 −0.01 −0.14 0.01 −0.16 0.01
6 0.00 0.00 −0.03 0.00 0.36 1 0.02 0.19 0.17 0.08 0.09 0.00 0.00 0.06 0.00 0.00 −0.02 0.00 −0.05 0.03 −0.04 0.03 −0.04 0.03
7 −0.07 −0.08 −0.31 −0.04 0.03 0.02 1 −0.05 −0.05 −0.09 −0.18 0.03 0.04 0.02 −0.06 −0.04 −0.05 0.04 0.01 0.11 0.23 0.13 0.14 0.12
8 −0.20 −0.23 −0.26 −0.02 0.64 0.19 −0.05 1 0.95 0.63 0.56 0.10 0.07 0.15 −0.01 0.01 −0.06 0.08 −0.16 −0.20 −0.02 0.15 0.01 0.14
9 −0.29 −0.31 −0.16 −0.08 0.59 0.17 −0.05 0.95 1 0.59 0.50 0.15 0.11 0.14 −0.02 0.02 −0.07 0.07 −0.24 −0.21 −0.05 0.17 0.03 0.16
10 0.07 0.10 0.02 0.06 0.35 0.08 −0.09 0.63 0.59 1 0.40 −0.05 −0.08 −0.38 −0.01 0.01 0.18 −0.06 −0.24 −0.21 −0.17 −0.21 −0.20 −0.25
11 −0.06 −0.04 −0.17 −0.02 0.28 0.09 −0.18 0.56 0.50 0.40 1 0.04 0.00 0.19 0.01 0.03 −0.07 −0.03 −0.13 −0.13 0.11 0.06 −0.05 0.04
12 −0.64 −0.52 −0.12 −0.01 0.01 0.00 0.03 0.10 0.15 −0.05 0.04 1 −0.14 0.07 −0.03 0.00 −0.05 −0.04 −0.01 −0.03 0.04 0.13 0.10 0.13
13 −0.05 −0.32 −0.09 −0.04 0.01 0.00 0.04 0.07 0.11 −0.08 0.00 −0.14 1 0.07 −0.04 −0.01 −0.04 0.00 −0.03 −0.03 0.05 0.09 0.07 0.09
14 −0.12 −0.14 −0.12 −0.09 0.11 0.06 0.02 0.15 0.14 −0.38 0.19 0.07 0.07 1 0.14 −0.07 −0.36 0.05 0.04 0.26 0.01 0.49 0.29 0.50
15 0.04 0.05 0.06 0.03 0.03 0.00 −0.06 −0.01 −0.02 −0.01 0.01 −0.03 −0.04 0.14 1 −0.09 0.37 0.00 −0.01 −0.04 0.05 −0.11 −0.05 −0.11
16 0.00 0.00 0.02 0.02 0.01 0.00 −0.04 0.01 0.02 0.01 0.03 0.00 −0.01 −0.07 −0.09 1 0.00 0.00 0.00 −0.02 0.04 −0.01 −0.02 −0.02
17 0.06 0.07 0.07 0.07 −0.03 −0.02 −0.05 −0.06 −0.07 0.18 −0.07 −0.05 −0.04 −0.36 0.37 0.00 1 −0.04 −0.02 −0.12 0.02 −0.23 −0.13 −0.24
18 −0.13 −0.25 −0.08 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.04 0.08 0.07 −0.06 −0.03 −0.04 0.00 0.05 0.00 0.00 −0.04 1 −0.04 −0.04 0.06 0.08 0.06 0.08
19 0.03 0.04 −0.11 0.01 −0.16 −0.05 0.01 −0.16 −0.24 −0.24 −0.13 −0.01 −0.03 0.04 −0.01 0.00 −0.02 −0.04 1 0.10 0.16 0.03 0.02 0.06
20 0.12 0.12 0.02 0.04 −0.01 0.03 0.11 −0.20 −0.21 −0.21 −0.13 −0.03 −0.03 0.26 −0.04 −0.02 −0.12 −0.04 0.10 1 0.03 0.49 0.42 0.47
21 −0.03 −0.06 −0.20 0.11 −0.14 −0.04 0.23 −0.02 −0.05 −0.17 0.11 0.04 0.05 0.01 0.05 0.04 0.02 0.06 0.16 0.03 1 0.18 0.27 0.19
22 −0.25 −0.28 −0.27 0.03 0.01 0.03 0.13 0.15 0.17 −0.21 0.06 0.13 0.09 0.49 −0.11 −0.01 −0.23 0.08 0.03 0.49 0.18 1 0.78 0.97
23 −0.18 −0.21 −0.23 0.04 −0.16 −0.04 0.14 0.01 0.03 −0.20 −0.05 0.10 0.07 0.29 −0.05 −0.02 −0.13 0.06 0.02 0.42 0.27 0.78 1 0.74
24 −0.23 −0.26 −0.26 0.03 0.01 0.03 0.12 0.14 0.16 −0.25 0.04 0.13 0.09 0.50 −0.11 −0.02 −0.24 0.08 0.06 0.47 0.19 0.97 0.74 1

48
Source: Author’s own computation.
JRFM 2019, 12, 163

The size of the company is negatively correlated with the indebtedness rates, as well as the
tangibility, which from a statistical point of view, shows that the companies have fixed assets with an
average proportion of 30%. The sales growth rate is positively correlated with the total indebtedness
rate, respectively on the long term and negative with the short term one. Although the technology
sector is a sector in continuous development, registering very high growths, the median shows that the
growth rate is at the level of 10%. The median of the variable working capital fund suggests that most
companies have a financial balance, managing to finance their fixed assets from permanent capital.
The corporate governance dummy variables have the median 1, regarding the duality of the CEO
it can be said that the CEO is not the chairman of the board of directors, regarding the presence of the
three committees, remuneration, audit and nomination, we can also affirm in this is the case that most
companies have these committees in their structure, with the average number of board members being
around 8. These are negatively correlated with debt ratios.
Macroeconomic indicators such as interest rate, inflation rate and market size are positively
correlated with debt ratios, only the gross domestic product per capita is negatively correlated
with them.

4.2. The Outcomes of Panel Data Regression Models


After analyzing the influence of the variables, placed in different models, on the three dependent
variables, we can say whether we accept or reject the hypotheses that have been initially formulated.
Based on the outcomes out of Table 5, the working capital and the inflation rate variables have a
statistically negative but insignificant relationship with the dependent variables. The first hypothesis
states that there is a positive relationship between the size of the company and the indebtedness rates,
the results of the regressions showed that there is a negative relation, so we can conclude that we reject
H1. The second hypothesis states that there is a positive relationship between tangibility of assets
and indebtedness rates, the results of the regressions showed that there is a positive relation with the
total indebtedness rate and with the long-term indebtedness rate, and negative with the long-term
indebtedness rate in short, so we can accept H2.
The third hypothesis argues that there is a negative relationship between growth opportunity
and debt, results of regressions showing that growth opportunity is in a positive relationship with the
total and long-term debt ratio, and a negative relationship with the short-term one. In short, we can
reject H3. The fourth hypothesis states that there is a negative relationship between liquidity and debt
while the results of the regressions have shown that there is a negative relationship with all three rates,
thus H4 is accepted. Hypothesis 5 states that there is a positive relationship between the effective tax
rate and indebtedness, the results of the regressions showed that there is a negative relationship, thus,
H5 is rejected. Theoretically, a company that has a high effective tax rate will benefit, by contracting
debts, from maximizing the tax deduction. In our case, the negative relationship can be explained by
the fact that companies with long-term debt have a reduced effective rate.
The sixth hypothesis argues that there is a negative relationship between financial return and
debt, the coefficient came out negative in relation to all debt rates, so H6 can be accepted. The negative
coefficient of ROE underlines that the debt rate decreases as profitability increases, so companies follow
the theory of hierarchical financing sources, using profit first to finance operations, and then debt.
The following hypothesis states that there is a negative relationship between the rate of inflation and
debt. The coefficient came out negative in relation to the total and long-term debt rate, and positive to
the short-term debt rate, so we can accept H7. Hypothesis 8 states that there is a negative relationship
between the annual interest rate and debt, the results of the regressions showed a positive relationship,
so H8 is rejected.

49
JRFM 2019, 12, 163

Table 5. Estimated coefficients for all three models.

(1) (2) (3)


Variable
TD LTD STD TD LTD STD TD LTD STD
0.002 0.002 −0.0006
Growth
(1.05) (0.78) (−1.02)
1.77 × 2.29 × −4.71 ×
Depr 10−6 *** 10−6 *** 10−8
(4.17) (4.44) (−0.33)
−1.47 × −1.80 × 2.16 ×
WC 10−9 10−9 10−10
(−0.17) (−0.17) (−0.07)
−0.027 * −0.03 ** −0.02 ***
Liq
(−2.50) (−2.18) (−7.72)
−0.10 *** −0.14 *** −0.009 *
Prop
(−7.49) (−8.23) (−2.05)
−0.08 *** −0.10 *** −0.02 ***
Size
(−4.62) (−5.44) (−4.98)
381.07 *** 713.10 210.07 *
M_size
(4.04) (1.41) (−1.98)
0.03 0.05 * 0.008
Board
(1.43) (2.26) (−1.43)
−0.0033 −0.000121
−0.003 ***
PBV *** *
(−21.56)
(−15.99) (−2.14)
−0.000141 −0.000127 −6.42 ×
PER *** *** 10−6 *
(−12.46) (−8.40) (−1.90)
−2.24 × −2.19 × −6.31 ×
GDP_cap 10−5 * 10−5 ** 10−6 **
(−2.54) (−2.92) (−3.00)
−6.31 ×
6.51 9.50 *
Int_r 10−6 **
(1.28) (1.65)
(−3.00)
−1.95 ×
−0.0003 −0.003
Etax 10−5
(−0.14) (−0.62)
(−0.008)
−2.16 −1.82 0.11
Inf_r
(−0.70) (−0.48) (0.10)
−5.09 × −0.000103 −5.30 ×
ROE 10−5 *** *** 10−6
(−4.89) (−8.15) (−1.53)
−0.0008
0.0003 0.0006
Stock ***
(0.35) (0.71)
(−4.05)
0.76 *** 0.94 *** 0.09 ***
S_Ceo
(6.62) (7.22) (3.62)
0.37 ** 0.33 * −0.10 *
Tang
(2.85) (2.32) (−2.49)
−0.32 *** −0.46 *** −0.15 ***
C_a
(−4.28) (−4.98) (−6.02)
0.63 *** −0.77 *** −0.11 ***
C_n
(−6.15) (−6.54) (−4.78)
0.03 0.05 * 0.008
C_r
(1.43) (2.26) (−1.43)
R2 0.49 0.43 0.089 0.099 0.12 0.16 0.08 0.199 0.14
F-statistic 98.71 *** 76.05 *** 9.96 *** 11.17 *** 13.86 *** 19.80 *** 9.69 *** 24.67 *** 16.74 ***
Source: Author’s own computation. ***, **, * denotes statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% significance
level, respectively.

50
JRFM 2019, 12, 163

Hypothesis 9 argues that there is a positive relationship between the gross domestic product per
capita and debt, the results of the regressions showed a negative relation with all the three rates of
debt, so H9 is rejected. The latter hypothesis argues that there is a negative relationship between
governance and debt indicators. The audit, remuneration and nomination committees are in a negative
relationship with all three indebtedness rates, so H11, H12 and H13 are accepted. The status of the
CEO is in a positive relationship, so Hypothesis 14 is rejected. Between board size and debt ratio is a
positive relationship, H10 is rejected. The presence of the audit committee in the company structure
signifies an efficient control of internal processes and activities, as well as combating information
asymmetry, resulting in the reduction of agency costs. The presence of the nomination committee in
the organizational structure of the company helps to nominate capable people in the management
structure, who take decisions that do not lead to increasing debt when looking for alternative funding
sources. The presence of the remuneration committee can lead to effective decisions to motivate and
ambition the board directors so that they can run the company efficiently without suffocating it in debt.
The CEO’s status is in a positive relationship with the dependent variable, the fact that the CEO is or is
not the president, has an impact on the debt.
The Prop variable which measures the size of the company and is calculated as a natural logarithm
of the turnover, is in a significantly negative relation with the indebtedness rates and respects the
principles of pecking order theory. Thus, with the increase in size, the company will use in the
first phase, as a source of financing, its own earnings. Depreciation is in a positive and significant
relationship with the long-term and total indebtedness rate and in an insignificant relationship with
the short-term indebtedness rate. Price to book value has a significant negative impact on indebtedness
rates, so when this indicator increases, it means that the value of the market shares compared to
the book value increases, and the investments will be financed by the shareholders, which leads to
the reduction of bank loans. The size of the market, a variable calculated as a ratio between market
capitalization and gross domestic product, is in a positive and significant relationship with the total
indebtedness rate, respectively with the short term rate, suggesting that easy access on the market
to financial sources, information, etc., allows companies to access new sources of external financing,
such as the issue of shares or bank loans. The more developed the market, in our case, the technology
services and information industry, the more the companies are inclined to turn to external sources to
support their short-term operations. In relation to the long-term debt ratio, a statistically insignificant
relationship resulted. Price to earnings ratio is in a statistically negative and significant relationship
with all three debt ratios. Thus, when a company borrows from banks, for example, it will have to pay
interests, and this will lead to a decrease in the net result of the firm, and implicitly of the PER. It is
also true that depending on what purpose the debt is made, if it is done with the purpose of making a
strategic investment, acquiring another company for example, this will have a positive influence on
the PER. The duration of the stock rotation has a positive coefficient, but it is insignificant, except for
the short-term debt ratio, in relation to which it is in a significant relationship. A positive relationship
between this and the dependent variable can be explained by the fact that a longer duration of stock exit
means that the sales are not very high and the company has to borrow in order to support its expenses.

5. Concluding Remarks
The purpose of this paper was to investigate the main factors which have an influence on financial
structure at the enterprise level, using a sample of 51 American companies listed on the New York
Stock Exchange. The relationships that were analyzed between debt and the most important factors,
promoted by the traditional theories of capital structure, are similar to those which were observed and
analyzed in other research papers from previous years. The dependent variables chosen, namely the
total indebtedness rate, the long-term indebtedness rate and the short-term indebtedness rate were
chosen because they are factors that influence more or less each of the three. The factors were grouped
into three categories, company specific factors, macroeconomic factors and corporate governance
factors. These factors have an impact that can be more or less significant. It was demonstrated once

51
JRFM 2019, 12, 163

again that factors such as tangibility, growth, size, liquidity etc. have an important influence on the
financial structure. In conclusion, the results of the analysis show that the principles of the pecking
order theory apply in this case, because the tendency of firms is to be financed internally rather than
externally. External finance is also a possibility, but as soon as the internal funds become available,
the companies prefer to use them.
This work is limited because the database consists of 51 companies and for a relatively short
period of time. The companies were taken from only one sector of activity and only from one country,
and this limits the applicability. Future research that includes more countries and a larger sample of
companies would better explain the determinants, as, as we have seen, there are also country-specific
factors that influence decisions in choosing the optimal financial structure.

Author Contributions: Conceptualization, G.V., Ş.C.G. and D.A.T.; Data curation, G.V., Ş.C.G. and D.A.T.; Formal
analysis, G.V., Ş.C.G. and D.A.T.; Funding acquisition, G.V., Ş.C.G. and D.A.T.; Investigation, G.V., Ş.C.G. and
D.A.T.; Methodology, G.V., Ş.C.G. and D.A.T.; Project administration, G.V., Ş.C.G. and D.A.T.; Resources, G.V.,
Ş.C.G. and D.A.T.; Software, G.V., Ş.C.G. and D.A.T.; Supervision, G.V., Ş.C.G. and D.A.T.; Validation, G.V., Ş.C.G.
and D.A.T.; Visualization, G.V., Ş.C.G. and D.A.T.; Writing—original draft, G.V., Ş.C.G. and D.A.T.; Writing—review
& editing, G.V., Ş.C.G. and D.A.T.
Funding: This research received no external funding.
Conflicts of Interest: The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References
Alipour, Mohammad, Mir Farhad Seddigh Mohammadi, and Hojjatollah Derakhshan. 2015. Determinants of
capital structure: An empirical study of firms in Iran. International Journal of Law and Management 57: 53–83.
[CrossRef]
Amidu, Mohammed. 2007. Determinants of capital structure of banks in Ghana: An empirical approach. Baltic
Journal of Management 2: 67–79. [CrossRef]
Ang, James S., Jess H. Chua, and John J. McConnell. 1982. The Administrative Costs of Corporate Bankruptcy: A
Note. The Journal of Finance 37: 219–226. [CrossRef]
Auerbach, Alan J. 1985. Real Determinants of Corporate Leverage. In Corporate Capital Structures in the United
States. Edited by Benjamin M. Friedman. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 301–24.
Baker, Malcolm, and Jeffrey Wurgler. 2002. Market timing and capital structure. Journal of Finance 57: 1–32.
[CrossRef]
Bartholdy, Jan, and Cesario Mateus. 2008. Taxes and Corporate Debt Policy: Evidence for Unlisted Firms of
Sixteen European Countries. SSRN. [CrossRef]
Barton, Sidney L., Ned C. Hill, and Srinivasan Sundaram. 1989. An Empirical-Test of Stakeholder Theory
Predictions of Capital Structure. Financial Management 18: 36–44. [CrossRef]
Bas, Tugba, Gulnur Muradoglu, and Kate Phylaktis. 2010. Determinants of capital structure in developing
countries. Paper presented at the European Financial Management Symposium 2010, Beijing, China,
April 22–24.
Bokpin, Godfred Alufar. 2009. Macroeconomic development and capital structure decisions of firms: Evidence
from emerging market economies. Studies in Economics and Finance 26: 129–42. [CrossRef]
Buvanendra, Shantharuby, P. Sridharan, and S. Thiyagarajan. 2017. Firm characteristics, corporate governance and
capital structure adjustments: A comparative study of listed firms in Sri Lanka and India. IIMB Management
Review 29: 245–58. [CrossRef]
Chadha, Saurabh, and Anil K. Sharma. 2015. Determinants of capital structure: An empirical evaluation from
India. Journal of Advances in Management Research 12: 3–14. [CrossRef]
Chaklader, Barnali, and Deepak Chawla. 2016. A Study of Determinants of Capital Structure through Panel Data
Analysis of Firms Listed in NSE CNX 500. Vision: The Journal of Business Perspective 20: 267–77. [CrossRef]
Chittenden, Francis, Graham Hall, and Patrick Hutchinson. 1996. Small firm growth, access to capital markets
and financial structure: Review of issues and an empirical investigation. Small Business Economics 8: 59–67.
[CrossRef]

52
JRFM 2019, 12, 163

Cortez, Michael Angelo, and Stevie Susanto. 2012. The Determinants of Corporate Captal Structure: Evidence
from Japanese Manufacturing Companies. Journal of International Business Research 11: 121–34.
Demirgüç-Kunt, Asli, and Vojislav Maksimovic. 1996. Stock market development and financing choices of firms.
World Bank Economic Review 10: 341–69. [CrossRef]
Demirgüç-Kunt, Asli, and Vojislav Maksimovic. 1999. Institutions, financial markets, and firm debt maturity.
Journal of Financial Economics 54: 295–336. [CrossRef]
Eldomiaty, Tarek I., and Mohamed H. Azim. 2008. The dynamics of capital structure and heterogeneous systematic
risk classes in Egypt. International Journal of Emerging Markets 3: 7–37. [CrossRef]
Eriotis, Nikolaos, Dimitrios Vasiliou, and Zoe Ventoura-Neokosmidi. 2007. How firm characteristics affect capital
structure: An empirical study. Managerial Finance 33: 321–31. [CrossRef]
Ezeoha, Abel Ebel. 2008. Firm size and corporate financial-leverage choice in a developing economy: Evidence
from Nigeria. Journal of Risk Finance 9: 351–64. [CrossRef]
Graham, John R. 1996. Debt and the marginal tax rate. Journal of Financial Economics 41: 41–73. [CrossRef]
Hall, Graham C., Patrick J. Hutchinson, and Nicos Michaelas. 2004. Determinants of the Capital Structures of
European SMEs. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting 31: 711–28. [CrossRef]
Iwaki, Hiromichi. 2019. The effect of debt market imperfection on capital structure and investment: Evidence
from the 2008 global financial crisis in Japan. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance. [CrossRef]
Jensen, Michael C., and William H. Meckling. 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and
ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3: 305–60. [CrossRef]
Jordan, Judith, Julian Lowe, and Peter Taylor. 1997. Strategy, financial policy and technology assets in UK small
firms. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting 25: 55–70.
Karadeniz, Erdinc, Serkan Yilmaz Kandir, Mehmet Balcilar, and Yildirim Beyazit Onal. 2009. Determinants of
capital structure: Evidence from Turkish lodging companies. International Journal of Contemporary Hospitality
Management 21: 594–609. [CrossRef]
Kraus, Alan, and Robert H. Litzenberger. 1973. A State-Preference Model of Optimal Financial Leverage. The
Journal of Finance 28: 911–22. [CrossRef]
Krishnan, V. Sivarama, and R. Charles Moyer. 1996. Determinants of Capital Structure: An Empirical Analysis of
Firms in Industrialized Countries. Managerial Finance 22: 39–55. [CrossRef]
Li, Larry, and Silvia Z. Islam. 2019. Firm and industry specific determinants of capital structure: Evidence from
the Australian market. International Review of Economics & Finance 59: 425–37. [CrossRef]
Marsh, Paul. 1982. The Choice between Equity and Debt: An Empirical-Study. Journal of Finance 37: 121–44.
[CrossRef]
Michaelas, Nicos, Francis Chittenden, and Panikkos Poutziouris. 1999. Financial policy and capital structure
choice in UK SMEs: Empirical evidence from company panel data. Small Business Economics 12: 113–30.
[CrossRef]
Modigliani, Franco, and Merton H. Miller. 1958. The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory of
Investment. The American Economic Review 48: 261–97.
Modigliani, Franco, and Merton H. Miller. 1963. Corporate Income Taxes and the Cost of Capital: A Correction.
The American Economic Review 53: 433–43.
Moradi, Amir, and Elisabeth Paulet. 2019. The firm-specific determinants of capital structure—An empirical
analysis of firms before and during the Euro Crisis. Research in International Business and Finance 47: 150–61.
[CrossRef]
Myers, Stewart C. 1977. Determinants of Corporate Borrowing. Journal of Financial Economics 5: 147–75. [CrossRef]
Myers, Stewart C., and Nicholas S. Majluf. 1984. Corporate Financing and Investment Decisions When Firms
Have Information That Investors Do Not Have. Journal of Financial Economics 13: 187–221. [CrossRef]
Nenu, Elena Alexandra, Georgeta Vintilă, and Ştefan Cristian Gherghina. 2018. The Impact of Capital Structure
on Risk and Firm Performance: Empirical Evidence for the Bucharest Stock Exchange Listed Companies.
International Journal of Financial Studies 6: 41. [CrossRef]
Ooi, Joseph. 1999. The determinants of capital structure Evidence on UK property companies. Journal of Property
Investment & Finance 17: 464–80. [CrossRef]
Öztekin, Özde, and Mark J. Flannery. 2012. Institutional determinants of capital structure adjustment speeds.
Journal of Financial Economics 103: 88–112. [CrossRef]

53
JRFM 2019, 12, 163

Psillaki, Maria, and Nikolaos Daskalakis. 2009. Are the determinants of capital structure country or firm specific?
Small Business Economics 33: 319–33. [CrossRef]
Rajan, Raghuram G., and Luigi Zingales. 1995. What do We Know about Capital Structure—Some Evidence from
International Data. Journal of Finance 50: 1421–60. [CrossRef]
Ramli, Nur Ainna, Hengky Latan, and Grace T. Solovida. 2019. Determinants of capital structure and firm financial
performance-A PLS-SEM approach: Evidence from Malaysia and Indonesia. Quarterly Review of Economics
and Finance 71: 148–60. [CrossRef]
Ross, Stephen A. 1977. The Determination of Financial Structure: The Incentive-Signalling Approach. The Bell
Journal of Economics 8: 23–40. [CrossRef]
Sheikh, Nadeem Ahmed, and Zongjun Wang. 2012. Effects of corporate governance on capital structure: Empirical
evidence from Pakistan. Corporate Governance 12: 629–41. [CrossRef]
Smith, Clifford W., Jr., and Jerold B. Warner. 1979. Bankruptcy, Secured Debt, and Optimal Capital Structure:
Comment. The Journal of Finance 34: 247–51. [CrossRef]
Song, Han-Suck. 2005. Capital Structure Determinants. An Empirical Study of Swedish Companies. Electronic Working
Paper Series; CESIS, Stockholm, Sweden: The Royal Institute of Technology.
Stulz, René M., and Herb Johnson. 1985. An Analysis of Secured Debt. Journal of Financial Economics 14: 501–21.
[CrossRef]
Su, Larry D. 2010. Ownership structure, corporate diversification and capital structure Evidence from China’s
publicly listed firms. Management Decision 48: 314–39. [CrossRef]
Titman, Sheridan, and Roberto Wessels. 1988. The Determinants of Capital Structure Choice. Journal of Finance 43:
1–19. [CrossRef]
van der Wijst, Nico, and Roy Thurik. 1993. Determinants of Small Firm Debt Ratios—An Analysis of Retail Panel
Data. Small Business Economics 5: 55–65. [CrossRef]
Vintilă, Georgeta, and Stefan Cristian Gherghina. 2012. An Empirical Investigation of the Relationship between
Corporate Governance Mechanisms, CEO Characteristics and Listed Companies’ Performance. International
Business Research 5: 175–91. [CrossRef]
Viviani, Jean-Laurent. 2008. Capital structure determinants: An empirical study of French companies in the wine
industry. International Journal of Wine Business Research 20: 171–94. [CrossRef]

© 2019 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access
article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution
(CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).

54
Journal of
Risk and Financial
Management

Article
How Long Does It Last to Systematically Make Bad
Decisions? An Agent-Based Application for
Dividend Policy
Victor Dragotă 1 and Camelia Delcea 2, *
1 Department of Finance and CEFIMO, Faculty of Finance and Banking, Bucharest University of Economic
Studies, 010374 Bucharest, Romania; victor.dragota@fin.ase.ro
2 Department of Economic Informatics and Cybernetics, Faculty of Economic Cybernetics, Statistics and
Informatics, Bucharest University of Economic Studies, 010552 Bucharest, Romania
* Correspondence: camelia.delcea@csie.ase.ro; Tel.: +40-769-652-813

Received: 4 October 2019; Accepted: 3 November 2019; Published: 5 November 2019

Abstract: Bad decisions have harmful effects on the quality of human life and an increase of their
duration expands these undesirable effects. Systematic bad decisions related to dividend policy
can affect the investors’ quality of life in the long-term. We propose an agent-based model for the
estimation of the duration of systematically making bad decisions, with an application on dividend
policy. We propose an algorithm that can be used in modelling the interaction between different
classes of shareholders and for predicting this duration. We perform numerical simulations based on
this model using NetLogo 6.0.4. We prove that, as a result of agents’ interaction, in some conditions,
the duration of systematically making bad decisions can be very long: some numerical simulations
suggest that, in some circumstances, this duration can significantly exceed the human lifetime.
Additionally, in some conditions, the company can fail before the power is switched. This duration
can increase dramatically if the shareholders have a great level of trust in the management’s decisions.
As an implication, a greater concern for the quality of financial education, and more performant
instruments for controlling the power’s decisions are required.

Keywords: agent-based models; decision-making; systematically making bad decisions; dividend


policy; investors’ behavior; simulation

1. Introduction
At least for some persons, it seems very easy to define a decision as being good or bad. For instance,
a religious, racist, or nationalistic individual can have no doubt that all he or she does in the name
of his or her faith is a good decision, and what is contrary to the accepted dogma is a bad decision.
On the other hand, other persons would consider, without any doubt, that the decisions made in the
name of the same values are bad decisions, which affect the life and its quality of many innocent
people (e.g., children, victims of different kinds of discrimination), science, education, etc. Finally,
all the parties can produce different arguments for supporting their values and can refuse the others’
arguments. In other cases, even the negative effects can be identified by everyone, the parties involved
in making decisions support one decision as being the only one acceptable. For instance, for some
persons it is difficult to support measures for protecting the environment and reduce emissions, since
the GDP/capita is too small and not enough railways and factories are present in the region. For others,
sustainable development is a necessity (e.g., Lele 1991; Doyle and Stiglitz 2014; Armeanu et al. 2018).
Unfortunately, the incapacity to provide a unanimous final answer for the best decision, and if one
decision is definitely bad (at least for some people) it does not mean that the problem is not important.
Even more, even if consensus between parties is not achieved, it does not mean that the problem does
not exist.

JRFM 2019, 12, 167; doi:10.3390/jrfm12040167 55 www.mdpi.com/journal/jrfm


JRFM 2019, 12, 167

For some reasons, finance can be a safer place for defining a bad decision. One main advantage is
that finance has a clear ideology (e.g., the search for maximizing the shareholders’ wealth) (Ross et al.
2010; Belghitar et al. 2019), and also clear instruments for monitoring the deviations from it. If one
decision determines a loss (e.g., a decrease in shareholders’ wealth), it is a bad decision. Additionally,
if a decision determines a lower return than another, it can be reasonably considered that selecting this
one was worse. Probably for this reason the presence of making bad decisions is well documented in
economics and finance in different contexts (e.g., De Bondt and Thaler 1995; Rubinstein 2001; Ariely
2009; Campbell et al. 2009; Taleb et al. 2009; Gennaioli et al. 2015, etc.). However, all these conclusions
can be formulated only after these decisions produce their outcomes (ex post) (Campbell et al. 2009).
Initially, most of them are decisions in a risk-context, which can be better or worse than the others.
For instance, making decisions based on the assumed knowledge at one moment, using the classical
model, based on Gaussian distribution for modelling return distribution and, thus, neglecting the
extreme values, determined losses which were unexpected initially (Taleb 2007; Taleb et al. 2009). It was
a bad decision to use the Gaussian distribution but, for the most part, the deciders were convinced that
using the Gaussian distribution for modelling returns is a good, normal, one.
In some cases, these decisions can become systematic. Human history provides many examples
of making systematically bad decisions, sometimes after a long time of making good decisions (Gilbert
2011; Lucero et al. 2011; Harari 2015). In this paper, we analyze the duration of systematically making
bad decisions, defined as the length in time of making erroneous mistakes, based on the same mental
algorithm. The end of making bad decisions can be decided by other parties; from this perspective,
the end of making bad decisions can be the end of the decider’s position.
In corporate finance theory, based on the principle of maximizing the shareholders’ wealth
(Ross et al. 2010; Belghitar et al. 2019), the impact of the existence of one decider that make systematic
bad decisions is only marginally considered. However, in some cases, the quality of different decisions
can be disputable (Morgan and Hansen 2006). Moreover, this issue becomes more complicated if
multi-objective optimization is considered (Lovric et al. 2010). In the same line, different cultural
(not financial) values can have an impact on financial decisions (Fidrmuc and Jacob 2010; Ucar 2016).
These different values can result in contrary decisions, which can be considered “good” or “bad”,
depending on each culture’s perspective.
In certain cases, some agents can make good decisions, but they have to accept the viewpoint
imposed by some other agents, which make bad decisions. For instance, at the corporate level,
dividend policy is decided by vote, democratically. Some bad decisions made by the dominating
group of voters can affect the rational shareholders’ wealth. People are different, thus, different
features (e.g., overconfidence, pattern recognition, etc.) of some agents can affect the wealth of other
shareholders (Campbell et al. 2009). Bad decisions, but, even more, systematic bad decisions, can affect
the investors’ quality of life in the long-term (and sometimes, probably irreversible; for instance, in the
case of retired employees, regarding their pension plans).
Shareholders’ wealth can be affected by dividend policy. Dividend policy is discussed in many
papers and is approached from different perspectives (Graham and Dodd 1951; Lintner 1964; Miller
and Modigliani 1961; Miller and Scholes 1978; Easterbrook 1984; La Porta et al. 2000a, 2000b; Fidrmuc
and Jacob 2010; Shao et al. 2010; Ucar 2016; Jiang et al. 2017, etc.). The discussions regarding an optimal
dividend policy still continue. Contrary viewpoints can be considered good or bad, depending on
each side’s perspective. Thus, the dividend payout decision is a possible fruitful field for analyzing the
duration of systematically making bad decisions.
In this paper, we propose a model in which shareholders are not aware instantly about a bad
decision made by the shareholders that dominate annual general meetings of shareholders (hereafter,
AGM; in Table 1 are provided all the abbreviations and notations). In our paper, we consider a
non-homogenous behavior of the shareholders implied in setting a dividend policy at an AGM
(and supporting or not the power) through agent-based models (Zambrano and Olaya 2017; Negahban
and Smith 2018; McGroarty et al. 2019, etc.). Especially, due to the diversity of the conclusions

56
JRFM 2019, 12, 167

regarding dividend policy, this is a good field for analysis of the impact of systematically making
bad decisions. It is very difficult to state a priori that a decision is bad or not, because each dividend
policy can be considered right for some reasons, and wrong for others. For this reason, considering
a non-homogenous behavior for the shareholders can be a contribution to the existent literature.
Some studies consider, in other contexts, different classes of shareholders, for instance, controlling
shareholders versus minority shareholders (La Porta et al. 2000a), each one having specific interests.
In our paper, we consider a more general case, in which shareholders can follow the same objective,
but having different opinions about the manner of action, or having different perceptions about the
company’s perspectives. Moreover, we consider that the option of different shareholders for supporting
one of another policy can be reversible in time.
Bad decisions have an impact on the company’s performance. However, their impact is not
instant. One issue that complicate even more the problem in some cases is the long period between
the moment of making the decision and the moment when the outputs can be checked (see Figure 1).
A bad decision is difficult to be identified in earliest stages, but only after a long period. In general,
decisions regarding dividend payout (DPRt ) are made considering exclusively expected levels for
indicators, for example comparing the expected internal rate of return of the proposed investment
project (Et (IRRt+1 )) with the expected required rate of return (Et (kD,t+1 )).
In this paper, we propose a model, which can be used in simulations, regarding the impact
of systematically making bad decisions. We use this model for the estimation of the duration of
systematically making bad decisions (hereafter, DSMBD). Some of the issues considered in our study
can be found in Dragotă (2016). However, comparative to Dragotă (2016), this study proposes an
application for financial management. This application concerns the dividend policy.

0 1 ........ n–1 n

Io
EA0(CFt)
ࡱ࡮ ࡭
૙ ሺ‫ܨܥ‬௧ ሻ ൌ ࣐ࡱ૙ ሺ‫ܨܥ‬௧ ሻ ‫ܨܥ‬௧ ൌ ࣐ࡱ࡭૙ ሺ‫ܨܥ‬௧ ሻ
࣐ ‫ א‬ሺ૙ǡ ૚ሻ
The project is analyzed, The manager’s results can be
assuming the expected checked. Class A agents understand
outcomes, based on a criterion that their expectations made at the
(e.g., NPV or IRR), which use moment 0 were incorrect.
estimated future level of cash
flows.
The decisions (for example, using net present values (NPV) or internal rate of return (IRR)
criterions) are made the moment 0, based on some considerations, including the expected level of cash
flows generated in the future (at the moment t). In this figure, we consider two classes of agents—A
and B, which expect at the present moment (0), future levels (at moment t) for the cash flow
determined by the project—EA0(CFt), EB0(CFt). Class B makes good predictions for these cash flows.
The class of agents make a bad prediction (biased, modelled by us through a coefficient Π, with Π
∈(0,1)) which conducts to wrong decisions. Agents from class A will be convinced that their decision
was bad only at the moment n, comparing the realized level of cash flow (CFt) with the anticipated
level for this cash flow—EA0(CFt). Thus, only after some financial exercises, the decisions can be
validated as good or wrong.

Figure 1. The long period between the decision-making process and the control of its result.

57
Table 1. Notations used in the text.

Indicator Notation Relation or Definition Observations


Annual general meeting of shareholders AGMt
Average ROE calculated for the past five t−1

JRFM 2019, 12, 167

APROEt 1 Used in ROE* estimations


years APROEt = 5 ROEt
t=t−5
Difference between cash in-flows and cash
Cash flow CF
out-flows.
It can take values between 0 (this means
Coefficient of impact of bad decisions bd the forecast is optimal) and 1 (this means
that the forecast is totally inadequate).
Coefficient of intolerance for the manager’s τ ∈ [0, 1]. If this tolerance is maximal, τ
τ
performance = 0. Input in the model.
Cost of investment I0
Decision made by the management DECt
Discount rate k The shareholders’ required rate of return.
DIVt

58
Dividend payout ratio DPRt DPRt = NEt
Dividends paid to shareholders DIVt
Duration of systematically making bad
DSMBD Output of the model.
decisions
Internal rate of return for the investment It is the discount rate (k) (solution of the
IRRt
projects equation) for NPV = 0 (k = IRR).
Magnitude of interest to change the power M M ∈ [0, 1]. Input in the model.
Net earnings NEt
n

Net present value NPV CFt RVn


NPV = −I0 + t + (1+k )n
t=1 (1+k )
In this paper, we consider n = 4 classes
Percentage of shareholders per Class of
xi t of shareholders (i = A,

B, C, D), defined
shareholders
in Section 3.2. ni=1 xit = 1.
The cash flow resulted at the end-life of the
Residual value RV
investment project
Table 1. Cont.

Indicator Notation Relation or Definition Observations


Random variable, normal distributed, with a
Realized capital market return kMt mean [Et−1 (kMt )] and a finite standard
JRFM 2019, 12, 167

deviation
Random variable, normal distributed, with a
Realized internal rate of return IRRt mean [Et−1 (IRRt )·(1 − bd)] and a finite
standard deviation
Realized rate of return on assets ROAt In this paper, ROA = ROE
NEt
Realized rate of return on equity ROEt ROEt = TAt−1
In this paper, ROA = ROE
Required rate of return on equity ROE*t ROE∗t = τ·max(APROEt ; Et−1 (IRRt ); kMt )
In this paper, TA = TE. Input in the
Total assets TAt
model.
In this paper, TA = TE. Input in the
Total equity TEt
model.
Shareholders’ wealth Wm

59
JRFM 2019, 12, 167

We propose an agent-based model for the estimation of DSMBD. We use NetLogo 6.0.4 (https:
//ccl.northwestern.edu/netlogo/), which offers an easy-to-understand programming language and a
graphical interface, where the changes in the simulated environment can be observed in real-time.
In the proposed model, we consider four classes of shareholders, each of them with a specific
behavior (Dragotă 2016). We propose an algorithm that can be used in modelling their interaction
and for predicting DSMBD, considering variables used in the practice of making decisions regarding
dividend policy. Thus, the changes in voting structure can be followed in real-time.
We perform some simulations based on the proposed model. We prove that, as a result of
agents’ interaction, in some conditions, DSMBD can be very long. Thus, some numerical simulations
suggest that, in some circumstances, this duration can significantly exceed the human lifetime.
Additionally, in some conditions, the company can fail before the power is switched. DSMBD can
increase dramatically if the shareholders have a great level of trust in the management’s decisions.
The democratic voting process and the good intentions are not sufficient conditions for making good
decisions. As an implication, a greater concern for the quality of financial education, and more
performant instruments for controlling the power’s decisions, are required.
Considering its implications, this paper can be useful both for academics and for practitioners.
A better understanding of the process of systematically making bad decisions can be beneficial for the
academic literature. Highlighting the determining factors that can determine an increase of DSMBD
and performing simulations for finding their impact can be a contribution in understanding a less
studied process. As far as we know, this approach is new in analyzing dividend policy. For practitioners
(e.g., investors in capital markets, other shareholders), it provides a decisional tool for anticipating
some possible problems in the decision-making process, for a better control at the corporations’ level.
A systematic bad decision can affect the investor’s wealth, with potentially disastrous effects in the
long-term. For instance, a person can find that his or her pension funds are negatively affected when it
is too late to make adjustments in portfolios.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. The next section presents the theoretical
background. For our purpose, we have proposed a model for the estimation of DSMBD. Section 3
provides the model design and describes its implementation in NetLogo 6.0.4. Some numerical results
are presented and discussed in Section 4. Section 5 concludes this paper.

2. Theoretical Background
Our study is concerned with analyzing the impact of making a systematic bad decision (for the
estimation of DSMBD) in AGM, when deciding if the financial resources are directed through dividends
or for investments in the company. We propose an agent-based model, which is implemented in
NetLogo 6.0.4. Below, the theoretical background related to this issue is presented.
The literature regarding bad decisions made by individuals is vast (e.g., Shefrin and Statman
1985; De Bondt and Thaler 1995; Odean 1998; Rubinstein 2001; Hirshleifer 2001; Campbell et al. 2009;
Gennaioli et al. 2015; Morgan and Hansen 2006; Dragotă 2016; Pikulina et al. 2017). In this paper,
we consider the impact of making systematically bad decisions in connection to setting a dividend
policy. Dividend policy, respectively fixing the portion of the net earnings paid to shareholders, can be
an interesting application for analyzing DSMBD. A dividend policy can be considered as optimal
from some perspectives, but non-optimal from others. For instance, paying dividends can be a sign
of the companies’ interest of protecting the shareholders’ rights (La Porta et al. 2000b), but can also
be interpreted as a smaller amount of financial resources for adopting profitable investment projects.
For this reason, the discussions in AGM can determine different solutions, which can be optimal,
or, to the contrary, wrong, even if they are made with very good intentions and based on rational
arguments (sometimes, with sound foundations in financial literature). The harmonization between
these contradictory viewpoints can be impossible. For this reason, some agents can be convinced that
their decisions are good and can persist in making bad decisions.
At the AGM, shareholders decide the amount that will be paid as dividend. The decision regarding
dividend payment consists in fixing a percent p from the net earnings (dividend payout ratio, DPR)

60
JRFM 2019, 12, 167

to be paid as dividend (a percent equal to (1 − p) is allocated for investments)1 . Shareholders are


different from many perspectives. A large amount of financial literature analyzes the relations between
large (controlling) shareholders and minority shareholders (Shleifer and Vishny 1986; Holderness
2003). Many papers analyze the controlling shareholders’ behavior in connection with dividend
policy, mainly related to agency problems (Easterbrook 1984; La Porta et al. 2000b; Fidrmuc and Jacob
2010). Additionally, in their decision, shareholders are (or at least, can be) influenced by the managers
proposals regarding the dividend proposed to be paid. Usually, they approve (or not) DPR proposed by
management. This can determine also agency costs (Jensen and Meckling 1976). Another segmentation
of shareholders in different groups can be made considering some socio-cultural factors. Some papers
provide evidence between dividend policies across the world, considering different socio-cultural as
determinants of dividend policy (Fidrmuc and Jacob 2010; Shao et al. 2010; Ucar 2016). As an effect, a
segmentation in different groups (dominant or not) can be useful in modelling shareholders’ behavior.
Many papers are concerned about dividend policy. Dividend policy is approached from many
perspectives (Graham and Dodd 1951; Walter 1956; Miller and Modigliani 1961; Miller and Scholes
1978; Bhattacharya 1979; Kalay 1980; Easterbrook 1984; La Porta et al. 2000a, 2000b; Fidrmuc and
Jacob 2010; Shao et al. 2010; Ucar 2016; Jiang et al. 2017, etc.). Some classical papers propose rules in
recommending an optimal dividend payout (Graham and Dodd 1951; Walter 1956). Other studies
identify the factors that influence the dividend payment (Lintner 1964; La Porta et al. 2000a; Fidrmuc and
Jacob 2010; Jiang et al. 2017). Miller and Modigliani (1961) prove, under some restrictive assumptions,
the irrelevance of dividend payout on shareholders’ wealth. Different real-life factors challenge the
implications of Miller and Modigliani theorem: agency problems (Easterbrook 1984; La Porta et al.
2000a), behavioral and cultural influences (Shao et al. 2010; Ucar 2016), imperfect information and
signaling effects (Bhattacharya 1979; Kalay 1980), taxation (Miller and Scholes 1978; Hanlon and
Hoopes 2014), etc.
Many papers provide recommendations regarding an optimal dividend policy, contrary to the
irrelevance theorem of Miller and Modigliani (1961). For instance, Walter (1956) proposes that dividends
should be paid only in the case in which the company can’t offer to its shareholders a rate of return
higher than the required rate of capital. Other papers suggest that dividends should be paid if the
company is interested by the minority shareholders’ interests (Graham and Dodd 1951; La Porta et al.
2000b). The list of papers providing more or less advices regarding an optimal dividend policy also
provide a multitude of divergent advice: pay, do not pay, or it does not matter. Thus, the literature on
dividend policy does not produce a consensus for an optimal dividend policy. For this reason, we
can reasonably assume that, even if they are convinced that their arguments have sound theoretical
foundations, some agents will make, depending by case, a bad decision, and they would not be able
to consider their decision is bad. Practically, they will not be able to characterize their decisions as
being bad. This situation will conduce to making systematically bad decisions. It is very possible (and
reasonably plausible) to appear a segmentation between two classes of agents, respectively the ones
that are making good decisions (being convinced that they are making a good decision) and the ones
that are making a bad decision (but being also convinced that they are making a good decision).
Over the last years, applications using agent-based modelling have been successfully used in
various research fields such as: supply chain management (Walsh and Wellman 2000; Pan and Choi
2016), strategic simulation (Bunn and Oliveira 2003; Wang et al. 2016; Negahban and Smith 2018),
operational risk and organizational networks (Frels et al. 2006), decision-making (Rai and Allada 2006;

1 De facto, a dividend is defined as apart from net income, and the dividend payout decision is conditioned by the available
cash flows, and not by net earnings. If one company records net earnings, but do not record a higher (or equal) amount of
cash flows, as long as both dividends and financing investment projects require cash payments, the dividend policy is only a
matter of (theoretical) accounting (Dragotă et al. 2019). In this study, we will consider a simplified case, respectively, profit ≡
cash flow. Signaling theories on dividends (e.g., Bhattacharya 1979; Kalay 1980) state that companies that pay dividends
signal that they have sufficient cash for paying them, while non-payers can be suspected as not having it.

61
JRFM 2019, 12, 167

Dougherty et al. 2017; Zambrano and Olaya 2017), customers flows (Tan et al. 2008), algorithmic trading
strategies (McGroarty et al. 2019), transport systems (Delcea et al. 2018a, 2018b; Monteiro et al. 2014),
etc. The main advantage of agent-based models is their ability to take into account the heterogeneity of
agents (McGroarty et al. 2019), meaning that each agent can have his or her own characteristics and can
make decisions in accordance with them. Additionally, one agent can observe the environment and the
actions/decisions made by other agents and he or she can decide which course of the action will be taken
in the following. The adaptability and the responsiveness capacities of the agents make them actively
observe and interact with the environment and with other agents. Moreover, the bounded-rationality
property that the agents possess make them act as human beings while facing a decision situation,
namely, they are just partially and not completely rational (Wilensky and Rand 2015). The abilities and
the properties of the agents make the agent-based modelling proper to human-behavior modelling.
Strictly related to the AGM situation, the agent-based modelling can be very useful for modelling the
shareholders’ behavior if we consider they do not share the same opinion in the context of a democratic
vote. In this particular context, the agent-based modelling approach enables us to define several
categories (named “classes” in our paper) to which the decision persons might belong to. Depending
on one’s class, several properties are enabled, which ensure that the agent is acting according to the
assumed behavior of its class. From the interaction among the agents, different emerging behaviors
and decisions can be observed and analyzed in depth.
Regarding the usage of the agent based modelling in the research area through the use of NetLogo
platform, between 2003–2018, 512 papers using NetLogo have been published in ISI Web-of-Science in
areas such as: operations research and management, business economics, finance, computer science,
engineering, education and educational research, social sciences, mathematics, environmental sciences
and ecology, etc. Thus, we have decided to use NetLogo for conducting the simulations as it offers
a friendly user interface and an easy-to-write and understand syntax (Wilensky and Rand 2015).
Among the characteristics of NetLogo, which differentiate it from other agent-based modelling
software, one can underline that it is a free software, easy to use, and easy to understand even by
persons outside the programming area, with a visual interface which allows one to see the changes in
agents’ properties in real-time, while the program is running, and which provides an extensive and
up-to-date documentation.
The next section presents our model.

3. The Model
This section presents a model for the estimation of DSMBD. We structured this section in six
sub-sections. The problem is defined in Section 3.1. We considered four classes of shareholders.
Their behavior is described in Section 3.2. In Section 3.3 we discuss the evolution of the company’s
performance when making bad decisions persists. The agents’ behavior is strongly influenced by the
differences between the realized rate of return and their required rate of return. The manner of the
estimation of the required rate of return is discussed in Section 3.4. We discuss the model inputs in
Section 3.5. Section 3.6 presents the implementation in NetLogo. The decision-making process can be
followed sequentially in Table 2.
We have chosen the agent-based modelling for representing, analyzing and simulation of this
situation as in this type of modelling, each agent, representing a shareholder, can be endowed with a
series of properties that makes it unique comparative to the other agents. Even more, as each different
groups of shareholders have different expectations and points of view related to the company’s efficient
management, the inter-group properties of these agents are easy to model and represent. Even more,
the NetLogo software offers a specific tool which enables one to conduct several experiments under
different conditions and to observe, in real-time, the agents’ behavior, as individuals and as a part of a
particular group.

62
Table 2. The sequence of the decision-making process.

Financial Exercise (Year) Phase Content


0
1 1.1 The company records output results: ROE1 and NE1 .
JRFM 2019, 12, 167

If NE1 ≤ 0, DIV1 = 0.
1.2
Otherwise, the management (the controlling shareholder) anticipates Et−1 (IRRt ), respectively E1 (IRR2 )
AGM: The management (the controlling shareholder) proposes a dividend policy:
1.3 If E1 (IRR2 ) ≥ E1 (kM2 ), then: DIV1 = 0
If E1 (IRR2 ) < E1 (kM2 ), then: DIV1 = NE1
AGM: shareholders analyze the performance of the company at the present moment, as a proxy for the quality of the management’s
1.4–1.5
decisions. We consider that, at this moment, the power remains in function.
2 2.1 The company records output results: ROE2 and NE2 .
If NE2 ≤ 0, DIV2 = 0.
2.2
Otherwise, the management (the controlling shareholder) anticipates Et−1 (IRRt ), respectively E2 (IRR3 )
AGM: The management (the controlling shareholder) proposes a dividend policy:
2.3

63
If E2 (IRR3 ) ≥ E2 (kM3 ), then: DIV2 = 0
If E2 (IRR3 ) < E2 (kM3 ), then: DIV2 = NE2
AGM: shareholders analyze the performance of the company at the present moment, as a proxy for the quality of the management’s
 decisions:
ROE2 ≥ ROE∗2 , then : xC 2
≤ xC1
2.4 if
ROE2 < ROE∗2 , then : xC 2
≥ xC
1
Notes: ROE∗t = (1 − τ)·max(ROE0 ; Et−1 (IRRt ); kMt )
xt C = xt−1 C + αt ·Mt (1 − xA − xB − xt−1 C ) = xt−1 C (1 − αt ·Mt ) + (1 − xA − xB )αt ·Mt
AGM: vote:
2.5 x2 B + x2 C ≤ 0.5, the management remains in power
If x2 B + x2 C > 0.5, then the power is switched (the end of the discussion)
3 3.1 The company records output results: ROE3 and NE3 .
If NE3 ≤ 0, DIV3 = 0.
3.2
Otherwise, the management (the controlling shareholder) anticipates Et−1 (IRRt ), respectively, E3 (IRR4 )
... ...
Table 2. Cont.

Financial Exercise (Year) Phase Content


t t.1 The company records output results: ROEt and NEt .
If NEt ≤ 0, DIVt = 0.
JRFM 2019, 12, 167

t.2
Otherwise, the management (the controlling shareholder) anticipates Et−1 (IRRt ), respectively, Et (IRRt+1 )
AGM: The management (the controlling shareholder) proposes a dividend policy:
t.3 If Et (IRRt+1 ) ≥ Et (kMt+1 ), then: DIVt = 0
If Et (IRRt+1 ) < Et (kMt+1 ), then: DIVt = NEt
AGM: shareholders analyze the performance of the company at the present moment, as a proxy for the quality of the management’s
 decisions:
ROEt ≥ ROE∗t , then : xC C
if t ≤ xt−1
t.4 ROEt < ROE∗t , then : xC ≥ x C
t t−1
Notes: ROE∗t = (1 − τ)·max(ROE0 ; Et−1 (IRRt ); kMt )
C C A B C C
xt = xt−1 + αt · Mt (1 − x − x − xt–1 ) = xt−1 (1 − αt · Mt ) + (1 − xA − xB )αt · Mt
AGM: vote:
t.5 xt B + xt C ≤ 0.5, the management remains in power
If xt B + xt C > 0.5, then the power is switched (the end of the discussion; DSMBD is determined)

64
... ... ...
... ... ...
JRFM 2019, 12, 167

3.1. The Problem


Shareholders, and also managers, analyze the company’s performance from different viewpoints
and use different indicators to measure it. This performance is the result of many different decisions,
so the extraction of a single, unique, bad one, for analyzing its impact can be difficult. We have chosen
the moment of the AGM for shareholders to simultaneously consider two issues: (1) deciding if the
manager is maintained in function; and (2) deciding the amount paid as dividend.
We can present sequentially the series of decisions as:

DEC−t , DEC−t+1 , DEC−t+2 , . . . , DEC0 , DEC1 , DEC2 , DEC3 , . . . , DECn

The decisions made by the management (DECt ) are right for the period [−t, 0]:

DEC−t , DEC−t+1 , DEC−t+2 , . . . , DEC0 ,

In the period [1, n], decisions are systematically wrong:

DEC1 , DEC2 , DEC3 , . . . , DECn

The problem is to find n (the moment in which the manager is switched). In other words,
we estimate the duration of making systematically bad decisions (DSMBD) in setting one dividend policy.
This duration expresses the length in time of making an inappropriate decision regarding dividend
policy. This decision is supported by some agents (some shareholders which sustain this decision)
even it is wrong. The supporters of the good decision are in minority (they do not reach more than
50% from the votes even they are right). The switch in sustaining the bad decision can be considered
synonymous with a switch in power (Dragotă 2016). The manager is switched when the percent of
shareholders that support them is lower than 50%. We consider four classes of shareholders, described
in Section 3.2.
Dividend policy (respectively, the percent of the net earnings paid as dividend, or, alternatively,
the percent invested in the company) is decided in AGM (at the moment t + 1), usually based on the
manager’s recommendation, only if NEt > 0. If NEt ≤ 0, we cannot discuss about a dividend policy.
The manager (supported by the controlling shareholders) (Class A agents in our model,
see Section 3.2) proposes a dividend policy based on her or his expectations regarding the internal rate
of return for the investment projects proposed to be financed from the retained earnings—Et−1 (IRRt )
and on their expectation regarding the evolution of the market—Et−1 (kMt ) (this is the market return
for projects with a similar risk2 ):
If E1 (IRR2 ) ≥ E1 (kM2 ), then: DIV 1 = 0
If E1 (IRR2 ) < E1 (kM2 ), then: DIV 1 = NE1
In other words, the dividend payout ratio (DPR) is:

0% i f Et−1 (IRRt ) > Et−1 (kMt )
DPRt = (1)
100% i f Et−1 (IRRt ) ≤ Et−1 (kMt )

In our paper, this decision-making process is based on Walter (1956), sometimes defined as the
“residual” dividend policy. This policy is widely recognized by practitioners, but also in the financial
literature (Aivazian et al. 2006; Kim and Kim 2019).
In practice, the dividend payout ratio follows a Tweedie distribution (Dragotă et al. 2019). This
distribution is characterized by a modal value of 0%. This modal value of 0% is confirmed by other

2 It can be noted that this rate of return is not a realized one. Investors expect to record this promised rate of return, so an
adequate notation is still Et−1 (kMt ).

65
JRFM 2019, 12, 167

studies (Denis and Osobov 2008; Fama and French 2001; von Eije and Megginson 2008; Fatemi and
Bildik 2012; Kuo et al. 2013). In our paper, the option between 0% and 100% DPR is considered only for
simplifications reasons. It is not the purpose of our paper to justify an optimal dividend policy, but to
analyze the impact of a bad decision.
As long as the supporters of the power are dominant (respectively, more than 50% votes), the
decision proposed by the management will be adopted.
The decisions made by the management (DECt ) are right for the period [−t, 0]. They are determining
a stock of wealth for shareholders, which can induce in shareholders a status of safety and also a state
of trust for the manager’s performance. A company’s return is, to a large extent, the effect of some
decisions made in the past. As an effect, investors can judge one manager’s performance (the return
in one year, source for dividend payments) even if this is the effect of the choices made in the past.
Moreover, even the results of some projects are not desirable from a financial viewpoint, in real life
their effects are combined with the other projects’ effects, finally, the shareholders having access only
to some synthetic indicators at the company’s level (like cash flows, net earnings or return on equity).
The initial stock of wealth allows the management to make some wrong decisions because their impact
is not fatal for the company.
For simplification, in our paper, we assume that no agency problems occur in making the
dividend payment decisions, even if they are documented in financial literature (Easterbrook 1984;
La Porta et al. 2000a; Kim and Kim 2019) and they can be an interesting field of study. We also assumed
that information is symmetrical (Dragotă 2016) and we ignored the impact of taxation3 .
We assume, as in Dragotă (2016), that the decisions regarding dividend payments are made
democratically, in AGM. The decisions are based on the principle one share, one vote4 . The ownership
structure is assumed to be dispersed. We consider that all the shareholders are exercising their vote.
The dividend payout decision requires a simple majority (respectively, more than 50% votes). In our
study, we consider that the decisions are made in each financial exercise and we consider in each
financial exercise only one round of votes (we consider the final vote for each AGM).
For modelling reasons, we consider that the shareholders do not sell their shares in the considered
period and, also, no new shares are issued in this period5 . As an effect, the total number of shares and
the initial number of shareholders remain constant.

3.2. Shareholders’ Typology and Behavior


We consider four classes of shareholders (agent types) (Dragotă 2016) (denoted A, B, C, and D),
with xt i is the percent in total shares (which correspond to the voting power), with xt A + xt B + xt C +
xt D = 1. Each of classes of shareholders (agents) is characterized by some features, described below.
Class A represents the decider (the power). In our study, they are the group of shareholders
that make systematically bad decisions, until the power is switched. Agents from this class are
overconfident in their decisions (De Bondt and Thaler 1995; Hirshleifer 2001), even if they are wrong.
Due to the outputs produced, the behavior of this class of shareholders can be suspected by agency
problems, even if they are not real. Additionally, it seems reasonable to anticipate that Class A will
suggest that the other shareholders should support their decisions, probably insisting on arguments
like trust the expertise of the management which is acting in the benefits of the other shareholders.
Class B represents the opposition, respectively, the group of shareholders that understand that
the decisions of the Class A are bad, but are not in power. Their rationality is useless for convincing

3 Taxation can have an impact on dividend payments (Dragotă et al. 2009). Walter (1956) analyzes the impact of taxation, too.
4 The model can be easily generalized for the case of multiple classes of shares, with different voting power, according to the
company’s statute (see, for instance, (Nenova 2003), for the case of dual classes of shares).
5 A similar result occurs if the new shareholders (the buyers) replicate the behavior of the former shareholders (the sellers).

66
JRFM 2019, 12, 167

agents from Class A, and even Class B can be associated with keywords like financial rationality, abilities,
or literacy6 .
As an observation, each rational agent probably knows that that the expected level of one indicator
can be different from its realized level (see Figure 2). As an effect, it can be very difficult to argue that
one forecast is, indeed, wrong.

3 1 2 (VWLPDWHGFDVKIORZ

3 1 2 (VWLPDWHGFDVKIORZ

Figure 2. Two forecasts for future level of cash flows–for each class of agents—A (with green) and
B (with blue). The two classes estimate the level of indicator (the estimated cash flow) through its
probability distribution. The forecast made by one class of agents (B—in the left, with blue) is better
than the second one (A—in the right, with green). In (a), if the realized cash flow is N (from normal,
very plausible for the first class of agents’ forecast), it can be interpreted by the second class of agents
as an unfavorable scenario of evolution (but still plausible, according to their forecast). A realized cash
flow equal to O (from optimistic) should confirm the good forecast made by class A (even it is only a
relatively unusual good performance based on the forecast made by class B). (b) depicts an even greater
dissonance between the two forecasts. In this case, if the realized cash flow is N, class A can realize that
the forecast was indeed wrong, but, also, they can consider that an extreme event occurred.

6 As observation, when the impact of factors like financial literacy or education is discussed, it has to be interpreted cautiously.
For instance, Mare et al. (2019) found that insurance literacy has an impact on financial decisions, but education (in general)
does not.

67
JRFM 2019, 12, 167

Class C includes the shareholders that can change their decision. They can learn from past errors
(for them, evolution is the keyword). Initially, xt C = 0. Firstly, they support the power (they are in Class
D), but they change their vote.
Class D is a residual in this model: xt D = 1 − xA − xB − xt C . Initially, we assume that they support
the power, but they can migrate to Class C.
According to these assumptions, xA and xB are fixed (constant in time), with xA ∈ (0, 0.5) and xB ∈
(0, 0.5), and xC and xD are variable. Initially, x0 C = 0.
The power is switched democratically when the number of voters against the power is higher
than 50% (respectively: xB + xt C > 50%). As in Dragotă (2016), the switch in power in AGM is
determined exclusively by the changes in the voting preferences of Class C. Shareholders from Class C
analyze the quality of decisions based on the results recorded by the company. As such, they do not
evaluate the quality of the decision regarding the dividend payments made at the present moment (t)
(see Section 3.1), but the quality of the decisions made in the past moments, as a proxy for the quality
of the present decision (see also Table 2). The decision’s quality is quantified comparing the recorded
performance with the required one. We considered that the performance is proxied by the realized
return of equity (ROEt ). Similarly, the required level of performance is quantified through a required
rate of return (ROEt * ). The evolution of ROE is described in Section 3.3. In Section 3.4 we discuss how
they estimate their required rate of return.
At each moment t (the annual shareholders’ meeting), Class C agents: (a) analyze if the realized
return of equity ROEt has an acceptable level (is higher or, at least, equal to the required rate of
return, ROEt * ), deciding if they support the power; and (b) if they support the power, they vote for the
recommended dividend policy. Additionally, the AGM is the moment when the agents from Class
C can change their voting preference: (i) if ROEt ≥ ROEt * , they are satisfied and keep their voting
preference (they will continue to support the power); (ii) if ROEt < ROEt * , they change their voting
preferences, voting against the power. As a result, shareholders from Class A are imposing their
viewpoint until: xt B + xt C > 0.5.
The changing preferences for Class C agents can be modelled through many different rules
(Dragotă 2016). In this paper, we consider two cases. First, we assume that once an agent from
Class D pass to Class C, his or her decision is irreversible (situation 1, S1). Secondly (situation 2, S2),
we assume that: 
ROEt ≥ ROE∗t , then : xC t ≤ xt−1
C
if ∗
ROEt < ROEt , then : xt ≥ xt−1
C C

We consider that xt C is determined based on the rule defined in Dragotă (2016):

xt C = xt−1 C + αt ·Mt ·xt−1 D (2)

In this relation, the percent of shareholders which vote against the power (xt C ) increase from
financial exercise to financial exercise if they are unsatisfied by the level of the rate of return;
however, they can change their opinion if the results are satisfying them, becoming more trustful in
management’s decision.
As such: 
1, if ROEt < ROE∗t
αt = . (3)
−1, if ROEt ≥ ROE∗t

Additionally, by definition, xt C should be at least equal cu 0: xt C ≥ 0.


Mt is a random variable uniformly distributed on [0,1], which can be interpreted as a magnitude of
the interest to change the power (Dragotă 2016). If Mt = 0, this can be interpreted as a total indifference
to the level of return, but also as a conservative attitude (Hirshleifer 2001). If Mt = 1, the entire
population of agents from class D will change their voting preference, joining the class C of agents,

68
JRFM 2019, 12, 167

immediately after the level of realized return is below the required rate of return. Mt is dependent of
different factors that can have an impact on wealth and for this reason is not constant in time7 .
xt C can be written as:

xt C = xt−1 C + αt ·Mt (1 − xA − xB − xt−1 C ) = xt−1 C (1 − αt ·Mt ) + (1 − xA − xB )αt ·Mt (4)

As an observation, shareholders from Class D can migrate to Class C even in the case in which the
company records a low performance, even if the dividend policy was correct.

3.3. Evolution of Return on Equity


In our model, shareholders use the return on equity (ROE) recorded by the company in their
analyses regarding the quality of the management’s decision (decisions supported by Classes A and D
of shareholders) (see Section 3.2). We consider that the company is 100% equity-financed, so assets
= equity. Retained earnings are the sole source for financing the investment projects (Walter 1956).
ROE, as a proxy for the company’s level of performance, is determined by different factors, more or
less anticipable. In an over-simplified model (but useful for our application), we can consider ROE as
a cumulative effect of: (i) the normal (usual, unaffected by the decider’s bad decision) ROE; (ii) the
decrease in ROE determined by making the bad decision; and (iii) the impact of other factors, which are
acting independently by the first two components. In other words, ROE is affected by bad decisions,
but also by bad forecasts.
The initial level of ROE0 can be considered as a benchmark. It is determined by the ratio between
net earnings recorded in the year 0 (NE0 ) and the level of equity in the previous year:

NE0 NE0
ROE0 = = (5)
TE−1 TA−1

We consider the period [−t, 0] as being one characterized by making good decisions. As such, in
this study, these historical levels of performance are important only for comparing the actual results
with them. Moreover, we can assume that all the quantity of information is incorporated in this initial
level of ROE, ROE0 . The level of total assets at the moment 0, TA0 is considered as an initial stock of
shareholders’ wealth and is another input in the model.
However, ROE0 is only a punctual benchmark. Some aleatory factors can influence even this
normal ROE. Even if the company maintains constant its level of assets, most probably ROE1 will be
different than ROE0 . Even if it is considered that no bad decisions are made, it can be assumed that
ROEt is a random variable. Each year, NEt is determined by the ROEt (the return at which the capital is
invested) and the stock of capital in the previous year, by the accounting identity:

NEt = ROEt ·TAt−1 (6)

The level of total assets on one moment t (TAt ) can be determined as a function by the level of the
total assets in the previous year (TAt−1 ), net earnings (NEt ) and dividend payments (DIVt ):

TAt = TAt−1 + NEt − DIVt (7)

In another form:
TAt = TAt−1 (1 + ROEt ) − DIVt (8)

7 Individuals prefer in many situations the status quo (the “anchoring” effect) (Samuelson and Zeckhauser 1988). As an effect,
in this paper, we considered that Class C agents do no change their voting preference instantly. In a different context, Harari
(2015, pp. 264–67) provides historical evidence regarding this “anchoring” effect and explains it by a necessity of human
beings to make sense of their decisions. If they should accept the fact that their past decision was wrong, they should accept
that their past “sacrifices” were unuseful.

69
JRFM 2019, 12, 167

As an effect, NEt has t components: (1) a component resulted as the return of equity at which
initial stock of assets is invested; (2) the result of the investments made in the first financial exercise
(t = 1); and (3) the result of the investments made in the second financial exercise (t = 2), . . . , (t) the
result of the investments made in the last financial exercise (t = t − 1). The components (2), (3), . . .
(t) are a function of the internal rates of returns (IRR) corresponding to the invested capital in each
financial exercise.
In our model, shareholders decide to invest in the company if the invested capital will determine
an increase of their wealth higher than investing on the financial market in projects of similar risk
(Walter 1956; Ross et al. 2010)8 . In this study, we assume that the decisions at the AGM are made
comparing the expected IRR, respectively, Et−1 (IRRt ), with the expectations regarding the capital
market return, Et−1 (kMt ).
It can be noticed that IRRt  Et−1 (IRRt ). IRRt = Et−1 (IRRt ) only in the case of a perfect forecast.
Since management is making a bad decision, IRRt can be considered as a random variable, normally
distributed, with a mean [Et−1 (IRRt )·(1 − bd)] and a finite standard deviation9,10 .
As an observation, in this equation, Et−1 (IRRt ) is the expectation made by the Class A agents, and
it is not optimal (it can be assumed by Class B shareholders make a better prediction).
The bad decision is modelled through a coefficient, bd, which is applied to the estimated rate of
internal return of the new projects. For instance, 0.1 means that the expected internal rate of return is
over-valuated by 10% by the deciders.
Similarly, market return can be considered as a random variable, normal distributed, with a mean
[Et−1 (kMt )] and a finite standard deviation11 .
Table 3 presents TA, NE, and ROE in some financial exercises and their rules of evolution12 . It can
be noted that the bad decisions have impact only if the net earnings are invested in the company. For a
numerical simulation of the financial indicators, see Table 4.

3.4. Required Rates of Return


In our paper, we consider in the same model two of the investor’s statuses. On the one hand,
investors are making their analysis from a portfolio management’s perspective, being interested about
characteristics like return13 and risk of their portfolio, making their judgments in estimating a required
rate of return, etc. (Markowitz 1952). On the other hand, they are shareholders and they participate in
AGM, being implied in making decisions at the corporate level, like adopting the dividend payout ratio.
In our model, two required rates of return appear as benchmarks, respectively, Et−1 (kMt ) and ROEt * .
The first indicator is related to the expectations regarding the capital market. We assume that this
indicator is estimated by the shareholders. In our study, we consider that, when proposing a dividend
policy, the management compares the expected IRR with Et−1 (kMt ) and decides to pay dividends only
if Et−1 (kMt ) > Et−1 (IRRt ).

8 This statement is formalized in the corporate finance literature through classical selection criteria, like the net present value
(NPV) > 0 and IRR > the required rate of return (Ross et al. 2010; Dragotă et al. 2013).
9 Theoretically, the realized IRR can take values in the (−∞, ∞) interval.
10 Some readers can have objections to this manner of formulation, considering that the expected rate of return is a function of
the realized rate of return, and not vice versa. In our simple formulation, if we consider Et−1 (IRRt ) as function of IRRt , IRRt
should be generated randomly.
11 Similar to the formulation of IRRt, if we consider Et−1 (kMt ) as function of kMt , kMt should be generated randomly.
12 Shareholders’ wealth at moment t (Wt ) is structured in two components: the initial capital invested in company and the
capitalized dividends.
13 In the entire paper we consider the real rates of returns, even it is not specified expressly. In a more general context, we can
assume that it is not important if we prefer real or nominal rates of returns as long as all the comparisons and considerations
regarding these rates are consider the coherence between rates (e.g., compare real rates of returns with real rates of return,
and nominal rates of returns with nominal rates of returns).

70
Table 3. Evolution of financial indicators.

Financial Exercise Total Assets at the


Net Earnings Return of Equity
(Year) Beginning of the Period
0 TA−1 NE0 ROE0
JRFM 2019, 12, 167

ROE1 =
1 TA0 NE1 = ROE1 ·TA0 = NE0 ·ROE0 ·(1 + εROE )
ROE0 (1 + εROE )
TA1 = NE2
2 NE2 = NE0 (1 + εROE ) + (NE1 − DIV1 )[E1 (IRR2 )(1 − bd)](1 + εIRR2 ) ROE2 = TA1
TA0 + NE1 − DIV1
TA2 = NE3 = NE0 (1 + εROE ) + (NE1 − DIV1 )[E1 (IRR2 )(1 − bd)](1 + εIRR2 )
3 ...
TA1 + NE2 − DIV2 +(NE2 − DIV2 )[E2 (IRR3 )(1 − bd)](1 + εIRR3 )
... ... ... ...
TAn−2 =
n−1 ... ...
TAn−3 + NEn−2 − DIVn−2

TAn−1 = NEn = NE0 (1 + εROE ) +


NEn
n n−1

  ROEn =
TAn−2 + NEn−1 − DIVn−1 TAn−1
(NEt − DIVt )[Et (IRRt+1 )(1 − bd)] 1 + εIRR,t+1

71
t=1

Table 4. Numerical simulation for the financial indicators (example).

Financial 1−
TAt NEt ROEt Et–1 (IRRt ) Et–1 (kMt ) DIVt xA t xB t xC t xD t APROEt IRRt kMt bd ROEt * Mt
Exercise τ
(m.u.) (m.u.) (%) (%) (%) (m.u.) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%)
0 1000 25.00 2.50 25.00 1.00 1.00 0.00 98.00 2.50
1 1000 38.50 3.85 2.64 2.90 38.50 1.00 1.00 0.00 98.00 2.77
2 1000 56.00 5.60 9.32 0.65 0.00 1.00 1.00 0.00 98.00 3.17 2.38 2.90 10.00 90.00 2.86 20.00
3 1056 −13.90 −1.32 4.48 3.14 0.00 1.00 1.00 19.60 78.40 1.82 8.39 0.65 10.00 90.00 7.55 20.00

... ... ... ... ... ... ... ... ... ... ... ... ... ... ... ... ...
...
JRFM 2019, 12, 167

Regarding the second indicator, the required ROE (ROEt * ), investors can consider different
benchmarks (Dragotă et al. 2013). However, basically, all of these benchmarks can be reduced to two
fundamental approaches. On the one hand, they expect a rate of return, related to the characteristic
of the project (for instance, in CAPM they require a rate of return higher than risk-free rate and they
claim also a risk premium—otherwise they will reject the project) (Ross et al. 2010). On the other hand,
investors analyze the alternatives available on the capital market (if they do not invest in the proposed
project, what alternatives are available?).
First (but not necessary in this order), they require an acceptable rate of return14 . It can be
considered that they consider as normal to record (at least) a level for return equal to a benchmark
assumed to be normal (this can be considered as an “anchor”). It can be considered that the rate of
equity return recorded in the past can be considered as a proxy for future performance. As such, in
this study, we assumed, conventionally, that investors consider an average for the past five financial
exercises as a first proxy for the required rate of return (noted APROE).
Secondly, shareholders require a rate of return related to IRR (a function of the risk of the
investment project). Finally, they accept renouncing dividends in exchange for an acceptable estimated
IRR for the projects adopted.
Thirdly, investors analyze the capital market conditions. They compare their return with the
returns recorded by other investors, for other investment projects. In our model, we consider that they
compare their performance with the capital market return (kMt ).
Finally, we can assume that all these benchmarks can be adjusted for some extraordinary events.
Shareholders can have a relative tolerance before dismissing their management15 . We introduce a
coefficient of intolerance for the manager’s performance—τ, with τ ∈ [0, 1]. If this tolerance is maximal,
that means that τ = 0. In other words, shareholders do not require a rate of return (however, they
require that their wealth to be maintained at the same level, so min (ROEt * ) = 0). If shareholders decide
to maintain the management in function only if the company records a level of ROE higher than ROEt * ,
we can state τ = 1 (they are totally intolerant in the case of a lack of performance). This coefficient can
be related to some socio-cultural factors (e.g., Schwartz 2006).
Thus:
ROE∗t = τ·max(APROEt ; Et−1 (IRRt ); kMt ) (9)

3.5. Model Inputs


Table 5 presents the model inputs. Many discussions can be made regarding the level of the
numerical values included in simulations. The purpose of this article is not to provide levels for these
indicators based on empirical data or theoretical literature. The choice of these parameters should be
adapted, case by case, function of the analyzed company. For some input variables we have preferred
to use round values (e.g., TA0 ).

14 Most of the papers in finance stipulate that this required rate of return is related to the assumed risk.
15 This variable can be also connected to the aversion to loss (Shefrin and Statman 1985; Odean 1998).

72
Table 5. Model inputs.

Distribution of the
Input Notation Level Numerical Simulation Remarks
Variable
Initial stock of total assets
JRFM 2019, 12, 167

(equal to total equity) This level is configurable in slider


TA0 Fixed 1000 Constant
(initial wealth in our “Initial-Total-Assets”.
program)
In the case of APROE calculations for the
first periods (before the period of bad
Initial return on equity ROE0 Fixed 2.5% Constant
decisions), we have assumed also that ROE
was equal to this level.
Normally distributed,
Range between 0% and with a mean of 2.5 and At the beginning of each iteration, its value
Expected market return Et–1 (kMt ) Random
5% a standard deviation of is changing.
2.5.
Normally distributed
Expected internal rate of Range between 0% and with a mean of 2.5 and
Et−1 (IRRt ), ∀ t Random eIRR in NetLogo

73
return for the new projects 5% a standard deviation of
0.8
It can take values between 0 (this means the
forecast is optimal) and 1 (this means that
The impact of making bad
bd Fixed 0.1 Constant the forecast is totally inadequate). It can be
decision
set from the interface and ranges between
0%–100%.
50% (but it can be set
The tolerance for the from the interface and It can be considered also as a resilience for
τ Fixed Constant
manager’s performance ranges between changing the power.
0%–100%)
Random (multi-values,
The magnitude of interest
M Random 0.2 each agent has its own Range between 0% and 100%
to change the power
value of this variable)
JRFM 2019, 12, 167

Other variables are intensely studied in different contexts. For instance, if the investors in our
simulations should consider the past records of market return as proxies for expected market return,
the variability of these expectations should be somehow exaggerated. For instance, the Standard and
Poor Composite Index rose 85% (between 1927 and 1929) and 69% (between 1954 and 1957), but fell
56% (between 1973 and 1975) and 52% (between 1929 and 1933) (the standard deviation of the market
return was 17%) (Shiller 1987). In our simulations, we have preferred a more prudent approach and we
have considered Et−1 (kMt ) to be normally distributed16 , with a mean of 2.5 and a standard deviation of
2.5. Of course, the program allows for considering a larger range.

3.6. Implementation in NetLogo


Four types of agents (see Section 3.2) have been created in NetLogo 6.0.4, belonging to either
class A (in red), B (in green), C (in cyan), or D (in orange), as presented in Figure 3. Additionally, four
monitors are available for each type of members, where one can easily observe how the number of
the members in each category is changing in real-time. Additionally, we have offered the agents the
possibility to return to group D, by setting the switch “Group-C-Can-Return-To-Group-D” to “on”.
The agents passing from group C to group D will be highlighted by coloring them in yellow, while their
number, in real-time, will be counted in the “Group-D-Returned-Members” monitor. The NetLogo
code is provided in Appendix A.

Figure 3. The types of agents created in NetLogo 6.0.4.

A series of variables have been considered in accordance with the model description presented
above. The visual interface created in NetLogo 6.0.4. offers the possibility of setting some of these

16 We have considered a normal distribution, and not a fat-tail one (e.g., McGroarty et al. 2019) for this variable due to the
NetLogo limitations.

74
JRFM 2019, 12, 167

variables’ values at the beginning of the simulation, while the presence of monitors and graphs depicts
their evolution in real-time (see Figure 4).

Figure 4. A snapshot of the NetLogo 6.0.4. model’s interface at t = 20 ticks.

The simulation is stopping when the total number of members in groups A and D is smaller or
equal than 50%. The “time interval” monitor depicts the number of ticks needed in order to change the
power, where the tick is the time unit in NetLogo.

4. Numerical Results: Discussion


We have considered two main situations, described in Section 3.2, respectively: (i) Situation S1:
group D members cannot return to their initial status (once they decide to enter in group C, they remain
in this one); (ii) Situation S2: group D members can change their group (becoming member of group C
if the performance of the company is changing in worse, but also re-becoming a member of D group if
the performance of the company is changing in better). The first situation can be considered more
optimistic (as it is easier to be followed), but the second one seems to be more connected to reality. For
this reason, the DSMBD estimated in Situation S2 is the indicator which should be taken into account
when a prudent approach is required.
For S1, different levels for “the tolerance for the manager’s performance” (τ) and “the impact of
making bad decisions” (bd) have been considered (see Tables 6 and 7). For each situation (S1-1 to S1-13)
the model has been run 400 times and the average DSMBD in ticks has been extracted.

Table 6. Simulation’s results for S1 when bd = 0.1.

S1 S1-1 S1-2 S1-3 S1-4 S1-5 S1-6 S1-7


The tolerance for the
manager’s 0 0.1 0.3 0.5 0.7 0.9 1
Parameters
performance (τ)
The impact of making
0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1
bad decision (bd)
Average DSMBD (ticks) 12.29 12.54 14.73 19.17 24.28 31.43 43.52
DSMBD interval (min, max) [10, 14] [10, 16] [11, 23] [12, 27] [15, 38] [16, 39] [24, 54]

75
JRFM 2019, 12, 167

Table 7. Simulation’s results for S1 when τ = 0.5.

S1 S1-8 S1-9 S1-10 S1-11 S1-12 S1-13


The tolerance for the
0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5
Parameters manager’s performance (τ)
The impact of making bad
0 0.3 0.5 0.7 0.9 1
decision (bd)
Average DSMBD (ticks) 20.26 19.05 17.73 16.92 16.31 16.04
DSMBD interval (min, max) [14, 27] [12, 27] [12, 26] [12, 25] [12, 24] [12, 20]

For the (S1-1)–(S1-7) situations, we have kept the value of bd constant at the level of 0.1 and we
have changed the tolerance for the manager’s performance from 0 to 1. A level of bd = 0.1 can be
interpreted as a systematic bad decision, but having a minor impact on financial performance. As a
result, it has been observed that the average time (years) needed in order to stop the process of making
bad decisions ranges between [12.29, 43.52], depending on the various values of the tolerance for the
manager’s decision variable (see Figure 5). Obviously, a systematic bad decision with minor impact
can remain unobserved for a longer period.

ϰϳ ϰϯ͘ϱϮ
ϰϮ
ǀĞƌĂŐĞ^D;ƚŝĐŬƐͿ

ϯϳ
ϯϭ͘ϰϯ
ϯϮ

Ϯϳ Ϯϰ͘Ϯϴ

ϮϮ ϭϵ͘ϭϳ

ϭϳ ϭϮ͘Ϯϵ ϭϰ͘ϳϯ
ϭϮ͘ϱϰ
ϭϮ
Ϭ Ϭ͘Ϯ Ϭ͘ϰ Ϭ͘ϲ Ϭ͘ϴ ϭ
ďĚсϬ͘ϭ dŚĞƚŽůĞƌĂŶĐĞĨŽƌŵĂŶĂŐĞƌΖƐƉĞƌĨŽƌŵĂŶĐĞ

Figure 5. Average DSMBD versus the tolerance for manager’s performance, when bd = 0.1 and S1
is considered.

As observation, even in the case of τ = 0, DSMBD can reach 10–14 years (iterations). Looking closer
to the S1-1 situation in which we encounter zero tolerance for the manager’s performance, an average
DSMBD of 12.29 years results. Comparing this to the case in which 10% tolerance is considered, the
average DSMBD of 12.54 years is recorded. Considering the individual values obtained from the
simulations, it can be observed that the most frequent recorded value is 11 years (in 26% of the cases),
the amount of time needed for making bad decisions being in [10, 16] (see Figure 6).
Additionally, from simulations, 32.75% of the cases in S1-2 have reached a DSMBD of 13 units,
being also the most frequent value. On the other hand, no particular distribution can be determined
for S1-3 average time, as there were a series of most frequent values encountered through simulations,
such as: 13, 18, 22, and 26. This situation also occurs for all the other cases starting with S1-4 until S1-7.
Now, considering the two extreme cases: no tolerance (S1-1) and total tolerance for the manager’s
performance (S1-7), the average DSMBD difference is of 31.23 years, almost three and a half times
more than in the no tolerance case. As expected, for the intermediate situations (S1-2 until S1-6), as the
tolerance for manager’s performance is increasing, while the impact of making bad decisions is not
changing, the average DSMBD increases.
76
JRFM 2019, 12, 167

dŝŵĞŶĞĞĚĞĚ
ϯϬ͘Ϭй
Ϯϲ͘Ϭй
Ϯϱ͘Ϭй

ϮϬ͘Ϭй ϭϴ͘Ϭй ϭϴ͘Ϭй

ϭϱ͘Ϭй
ϭϬ͘Ϭй ϭϬ͘Ϭй ϭϬ͘Ϭй WĞƌĐĞŶƚĂŐĞ
ϭϬ͘Ϭй ϴ͘Ϭй

ϱ͘Ϭй

Ϭ͘Ϭй
ϭϬ ϭϭ ϭϮ ϭϯ ϭϰ ϭϱ ϭϲ
WĞƌĐĞŶƚĂŐĞ ϭϬ͘Ϭй Ϯϲ͘Ϭй ϭϴ͘Ϭй ϭϴ͘Ϭй ϭϬ͘Ϭй ϭϬ͘Ϭй ϴ͘Ϭй

Figure 6. DSMBD—situation S1-1.

Considering the S1-4, S1-8 until S1-13 cases, it can be observed that when the deciders have
over-confidence in the values of the expected IRR, DSMBD is longer, even though the time difference
among the situations with the smallest and the largest average time amount is of only 4.22 time units
(see Table 7). All the other average DSMBD values range smoothly among the values recorded for the
extreme cases (see Figure 7).

ϮϬ͘Ϯϲ
ϮϬ͘ϱ
ϮϬ
ϭϵ͘ϱ ϭϵ͘ϭϳ
ǀĞƌĂŐĞ^D;ƚŝĐŬƐͿ

ϭϵ͘Ϭϱ
ϭϵ
ϭϴ͘ϱ
ϭϴ ϭϳ͘ϳϯ

ϭϳ͘ϱ
ϭϲ͘ϵϮ
ϭϳ
ϭϲ͘ϯϭ
ϭϲ͘ϱ ϭϲ͘Ϭϰ
ϭϲ
Ϭ Ϭ͘Ϯ Ϭ͘ϰ Ϭ͘ϲ Ϭ͘ϴ ϭ
ʏсϬ͘ϱ dŚĞŝŵƉĂĐƚŽĨŵĂŬŝŶŐďĂĚĚĞĐŝƐŝŽŶƐ

Figure 7. Average DSMBD versus the impact of making bad decisions, when τ = 0.5 and S1 is considered.

Thus, among the two considered variables (the tolerance for the manager’s performance and the
impact of making bad decisions), the tolerance for manager’s decisions has a greater impact, recording
an average of 31.23 years (time units) when comparing the extreme cases with zero and total tolerance,
while for the impact of making bad decisions considering the extreme cases, a time difference of
only 4.22 years (time units) have been recorded. This result can suggest the important role of good
monitoring processes, in accordance with Campbell et al. (2009).

77
JRFM 2019, 12, 167

We have made the same measurements for the S2 situation, in which the deciders can decide to
return to group D. The results are summarized in Tables 8 and 9 below.

Table 8. Simulation’s results for S2 when bd = 0.1.

S2 S2-1 S2-2 S2-3 S2-4 S2-5 S2-6 S2-7


The tolerance for the
manager’s 0 0.1 0.3 0.5 0.7 0.9 1
Parameters
performance (τ)
The impact of making
0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1
bad decision (bd)
Average DSMBD (ticks) 12.72 17.92 24.97 59.14 260.57 1203.71 4555.86
[12, [49, [263, [933,
DSMBD interval (min, max) [10, 15] [10, 43] [11, 85]
166] 741] 2252] 12489]

Table 9. Simulation’s results for S2 when τ = 0.5.

S2 S2-8 S2-9 S2-10 S2-11 S2-12 S2-13


The tolerance for the
0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5
Parameters manager’s performance (τ)
The impact of making bad
0 0.3 0.5 0.7 0.9 1
decision (bd)
Average DSMBD (ticks) 65.62 54.23 50.71 50.32 49.18 48.13
[20, [12, [12, [12, [12,
DSMBD interval (min, max) [12, 116]
171] 164] 144] 141] 138]

Obviously, the greater the tolerance for the manager’s performance, the longer the average
DSMBD is. However, it can be observed that, as the tolerance is higher, DSMBD can take extremely
long periods of time until a normal situation is reached (see the S2-7 situation). This length (in years)
substantially exceeds the normal life of companies which are in existence at this moment17 .
Figure 8 depicts the evolution of the average DSMBD when considering different values for the
tolerance for manager’s decision, ranging between zero tolerance (S2-1) and full tolerance (S2-7). It can
easily be observed that a tolerance greater than 0.5 can have dramatic results on the DSMBD value.
In the extreme case of total tolerance (S2-7), the negative effects can perpetuate as much as possible,
as people are continually changing their mind and switching groups, making DSMBD very long
(supposing that the company can function in these conditions for such a long period).
Considering a low-tolerance situation (case S2-1), which can be plausible in some real-life situations,
the average of such bad decisions’ time is 17.92 years, which can be characterized as a double time
for not creating major problems within the analyzed economic entity. Moreover, as the tolerance for
manager’s performance increases, DSMBD continues to increase, and it can be observed that, after a
0.5 tolerance, it is critically high, reaching, on average, more than 59.14 years (time units).
Comparing (S1-1)–(S1-7) with (S2-1)–(S2-7), it can be observed that for small values of tolerance
for the manager’s decisions (τ), DSMBD has comparable values. For example, the time difference
between S1-1 and S2-1 is of only 0.43 (practically, 0) years (time units), while for 0.1 tolerance is 5.38
years (cases S1-2 and S2-2), and for 0.3 tolerance is of 10.24 years (cases S1-3 and S2-3). Starting with
0.5 tolerance, differences for DSMBD become notable: 39.97 years for τ = 0.5, 236.29 for τ = 0.7. Higher

17 According to Wikipedia (https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/List_of_oldest_companies, accessed on 23 July 2019), the oldest


company still in function is Nishiyama Onsen Keiunkan (founded in 705 AD, so with an age less than 1400 years). Of course,
such a long period of existence can be explained by making good decisions. From this perspective, it is implausible that, for
a company to function for so many years, making systematically bad decisions, large levels of DSMBD can be interpreted as
a failure before the change of the decider.

78
JRFM 2019, 12, 167

levels of tolerance make the difference extremely high: 1172.28 years (time units) for 0.9 tolerance and
4512.34 years for total tolerance (τ = 1). Once more, the significant effect the degree of tolerance has on
the average DSMBD can be underlined.

ϱϬϬϬ ϰϱϱϱ͘ϴϲ
ϰϱϬϬ
ϰϬϬϬ
ǀĞƌĂŐĞ^D;ƚŝĐŬƐͿ

ϯϱϬϬ
ϯϬϬϬ
ϮϱϬϬ
ϮϬϬϬ
ϭϱϬϬ ϭϮϬϯ͘ϳϭ
ϭϬϬϬ
ϭϮ͘ϳϮ ϮϲϬ͘ϱϳ
ϱϬϬ ϭϳ͘ϵϮ Ϯϰ͘ϵϳ ϱϵ͘ϭϰ
Ϭ
Ϭ Ϭ͘Ϯ Ϭ͘ϰ Ϭ͘ϲ Ϭ͘ϴ ϭ
ďĚсϬ͘ϭ dŚĞƚŽůĞƌĂŶĐĞĨŽƌŵĂŶĂŐĞƌΖƐƉĞƌĨŽƌŵĂŶĐĞ

Figure 8. Average DSMBD versus the tolerance for manager’s performance, when bd = 0.1 and S2
is considered.

As for the impact of making bad decisions, the data in Table 9, shows, as in the previous cases
(S2-8 until S2-13), that bd has only a reduced influence over the overall average bad decisions time,
making only a 17.49-time units (years) difference.
Figure 9 presents the evolution of DSMBD for various values of the impact of making bad decisions.
It can be observed that the decrease of the average DSMBD values is smooth as it was also in Figure 7.
The only difference is that in this case the values of DSMBD are higher than in the (S1-8)–(S1-13)
situations and the difference among the extreme values is higher in this case.

ϲϱ͘ϲϮ
ϲϳ
ϲϱ
ϲϯ
ǀĞƌĂŐĞ^D;ƚŝĐŬƐͿ

ϲϭ ϱϵ͘ϭϰ
ϱϵ
ϱϳ
ϱϰ͘Ϯϯ
ϱϱ
ϱϯ
ϱϬ͘ϳϭ ϱϬ͘ϯϮ
ϱϭ ϰϵ͘ϭϴ
ϰϵ ϰϴ͘ϭϯ

ϰϳ
Ϭ Ϭ͘Ϯ Ϭ͘ϰ Ϭ͘ϲ Ϭ͘ϴ ϭ
ʏсϬ͘ϱ dŚĞŝŵƉĂĐƚŽĨŵĂŬŝŶŐďĂĚĚĞĐŝƐŝŽŶƐ

Figure 9. Average DSMBD versus the impact of making bad decisions, when τ = 0.5 and S2 is considered.

79
JRFM 2019, 12, 167

Comparing the two situations (S1 and S2), it can be seen that in both of them, the deciders’
tolerance to manager’s bad decisions can make a difference, having a significant contribution to the
overall average decision-making time.
Based on these simulations, we can conclude that the length of the DSMBD can be very long,
probably exceeding the lifetime of the company. In some cases, the dominant group (class A in
our model) can impose their viewpoint until the end of the company, while the group of rational
shareholders (class B in our model) cannot impose theirs. Thus, in the absence of the improving the
quality of making judgments and making better decisions, the existence of informed and rational
investors is useless.

5. Conclusions
Bad decisions have an impact on the company’s performance. However, their impact is not
instant. For this reason, the process of making bad decisions can be very persistent, especially if no
agreement about the best solution is existent. In this paper, we propose a model in which shareholders
are not instantly aware about a bad decision made by the shareholders that dominate the annual
general meeting of shareholders (AGM). This paper analyzes the case in which, for different reasons,
the deciders systematically make bad decisions regarding dividend payout. We use this model for the
estimation of the DSMBD in setting one dividend policy. We have started from Dragotă (2016), as a
general case, and we have made some adjustments in order to adapt this model for the case of financial
management, respectively, for dividend policy. We use NetLogo 6.0.4 for modelling, which offers a
graphical interface, where the changes in the simulated environment can be observed in real-time.
This paper considers the case in which, in voting one dividend policy or another, individuals
are following different objectives based on different values. Unfortunately, the democratic vote and
the good intentions are not sufficient for guaranteeing the avoidance of systematically making bad
decisions (Dragotă 2016). Since the deciders are convinced that their decisions are right, they have
no reason to change them until the results of their actions significantly affect themselves. However,
as long as their wealth is determined by other factors, too, they can hardly differentiate between the
effect of their decisions and the impact of these other factors. As an effect, they can still be convinced
that they are making good decisions. Moreover, even if the outputs are not acceptable, these results
can be explained not as the effect of some bad decisions, but as the effect of some nonsystematic,
external effects.
Our paper analyzes the conditions in which making bad decisions can become a systematic
phenomenon and proposes a model presented both mathematically and numerically on a small
example in order to increase its understanding and readability. Using the advantages provided by
the agent-based modelling and NetLogo 6.0.4, a model is created and numerically simulated in order
to make a proper estimation of DSMBD. In our model, we consider four classes of shareholders,
each of them with a specific behavior. We propose an algorithm that can be used in modelling their
interaction and for predicting this duration. Thus, the changes in voting structure can be followed in
real-time. As far as we know, this approach has not been used in the financial literature concerning
dividend policy.
Some cases have been considered, depending on whether hat the deciders can change their groups
or not. Additionally, different values for the involved variables have been considered and simulated
400 times each. It has been observed that the deciders’ tolerance to a manager’s bad decisions can
make a difference in terms of time.
We prove that, in some circumstances, DSMBD can be very long. Its length can reach a very large
number of years, exceeding in some conditions a human lifetime and the maximal age of existing
companies on Earth at this moment. Moreover, it can be possible for DSMBD to increase dramatically
if the shareholders have a great level of trust in the management’s decisions. Practically, in some
conditions, the dominant group (controlling shareholders) can impose their viewpoint until the end of
the company, while the group of rational shareholders cannot impose theirs. As a principal implication,

80
JRFM 2019, 12, 167

an increase of the quality of financial education for top-management and shareholders, and, from
here, more performant instruments for controlling the power’s decisions are required. After all,
Campbell et al. (2009) warn that “Given the way the brain works, we can’t rely on leaders to spot
and safeguard against their own errors in judgment. [ . . . ] So rather than rely on the wisdom of
experienced chairmen, the humility of CEOs, or the standard organizational checks and balances,
we urge all involved in important decisions to explicitly consider whether red flags exist and, if they
do, to lobby for appropriate safeguards.”
Of course, simulations provide only an artificial environment and our study and their findings
can be easily attacked from this perspective. New directions for study can be related to two proposed
inputs—the coefficient of impact of bad decisions (bd) and the coefficient of intolerance for the manager’s
performance (τ). However, most of the parameters required in our model can be relatively easily
imported in real-life, company level context.
Further, one interesting development of the study is to consider the agency problems which
occur in dividend payment decision (Dragotă et al. 2009). In this case, multiple objective functions
(Lovric et al. 2010), adaptable for different classes of shareholders, could be used. The manner in which
the dividend payout is fixed can be a fruitful field of study, especially if the asymmetrical information,
the power in negotiation, and the skills required for persuading other individuals to vote somehow
are considered. In the same context, valuation the impact of combining financial and non-financial
(e.g., ethical objectives) (Ballestero et al. 2012; Mallin 2016) can be another direction for study.

Author Contributions: Conceptualization: V.D.; formal analysis: V.D. and C.D.; investigation: V.D. and C.D.;
methodology: V.D. and C.D.; software: C.D.; supervision: V.D.; validation: V.D. and C.D.; visualization: V.D. and
C.D.; writing—original draft: V.D. and C.D.; writing—review and editing: V.D. and C.D.
Funding: This research received no external funding.
Acknowledgments: We wish to thank the participants of the 29th European Conference on Operational Research
(Valencia, 8–11 July 2018) for their remarks. The remaining errors are ours.
Conflicts of Interest: The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A. The NetLogo Code


breed [ groupAmembers groupAmember ]
breed [ groupBmembers groupBmember ]
breed [ groupCmembers groupCmember ]
breed [ groupDmembers groupDmember ]
globals [
Previous-DIV
Previous-TA
Previous-NE
Previous-eIRR
All-Previous-ROE
]
to setup
clear-all
reset-ticks
set-default-shape turtles “person”
setup-people
end
to setup-people
create-groupAmembers Percent-of-Group-A-Members * Members/100 [
setxy random-xcor random-ycor
set color red
]

81
JRFM 2019, 12, 167

create-groupBmembers Percent-of-Group-B-Members * Members/100 [


setxy random-xcor random-ycor
set color green
]
create-groupCmembers 0 [
setxy random-xcor random-ycor
set color cyan
]
create-groupDmembers Members - count groupAmembers - count groupBmembers - count
groupCmembers [
setxy random-xcor random-ycor
set color orange
end
to go
if count groupAmembers + count groupDmembers <= 0.5 * Members [
stop
]
if ticks = 0 [
go-0
]
if ticks = 1 or ticks = 2 [
go-12
]
if ticks > 2 [
go-3n
]
tick
end
to go-0
let TA Initial-Total-Assets
let ROE 0.025
let NE TA * ROE
let DIV 0
ifelse NE <= 0
[
set DIV 0
]
[
let eIRR (random-normal 2.5 0.8)/100
let eKm (random-normal 2.5 2.5)/100
ifelse eIRR >= eKm
[
set DIV 0
]
[
set DIV NE
]
]
set Previous-DIV DIV
set Previous-TA TA

82
JRFM 2019, 12, 167

set Previous-NE NE
set All-Previous-ROE (list ROE)
end
to go-12
let TA Previous-TA + Previous-NE - Previous-DIV
let ROE (random-normal 2.5 2.5)/100
let NE TA * ROE
let DIV 0
let eIRR 0
ifelse NE <= 0
[
set DIV 0
]
[
set eIRR (random-normal 2.5 0.8)/100
let eKm (random-normal 2.5 2.5)/100
ifelse eIRR >= eKm
[
set DIV 0
]
[
set DIV NE
]
]
set Previous-DIV DIV
set Previous-TA TA
set Previous-NE NE
set Previous-eIRR eIRR
set All-Previous-ROE fput ROE All-Previous-ROE
end
to go-3n
print word “#” ticks
let TA Previous-TA + Previous-NE - Previous-DIV
let ROE (random-normal 2.5 2.5)/100
let IRR (1.1 - random-float 0.2) * Previous-eIRR * (1 - bd/100)
let NE Previous-TA * ROE + Previous-NE * IRR;
print word “NE:” NE
let DIV 0
let eIRR 0
let eKm 0
ifelse NE <= 0
[
set DIV 0
]
[
set eIRR (random-normal 2.5 0.8)/100
set eKm (random-normal 2.5 2.5)/100
print word “eIRR:” eIRR
print word “eKm:” eKm
ifelse eIRR >= eKm

83
JRFM 2019, 12, 167

[
set DIV 0
]
[
set DIV NE
]
]
let CompanyROE NE/TA
print word “CompanyROE:” precision CompanyROE 3
let kM (1.1 - random-float 0.2) * eKm
let aproe compute-aproe
print word “aproe:” aproe
let ROE* bad-decisions-intolerance/100 * max (list kM IRR aproe)
print word “ROE*:” precision ROE* 3
ifelse CompanyROE < ROE*
[
ask n-of (0.2 * count groupDmembers) groupDmembers
[
set breed groupCmembers
set color cyan
]
]
[
print word “Scade C cu “ (0.2 * count groupCmembers)
; scade numarul de agenti din grupul C
if Group-C-Can-Return-To-Group-D
[
ask n-of (0.2 * count groupCmembers) groupCmembers
[
set breed groupDmembers
set color yellow
]
]
]
set Previous-DIV DIV
set Previous-TA TA
set Previous-NE NE
set Previous-eIRR eIRR
set All-Previous-ROE fput ROE All-Previous-ROE
end
to-report compute-aproe
let i 0;
let roe-sum 0
while [i < 5]
[
ifelse i < length All-Previous-ROE
[
set roe-sum roe-sum + item i All-Previous-ROE
]
[

84
JRFM 2019, 12, 167

let index length All-Previous-ROE - 1


set roe-sum roe-sum + item index All-Previous-ROE
]
set i i + 1
]
report roe-sum/5
end

References
Aivazian, Varouj A., Laurence Booth, and Sean Cleary. 2006. Dividend Smoothing and Debt Ratings. Journal
Financial and Quantitative Analysis 41: 439–53. [CrossRef]
Ariely, Dan. 2009. The End of Rational Economics. Harvard Business Review 87: 78–84.
Armeanu, Daniel Ştefan, Georgeta Vintilă, and S, tefan Cristian Gherghina. 2018. Empirical Study towards the
Drivers of Sustainable Economic Growth in EU-28 Countries. Sustainability 10: 4. [CrossRef]
Ballestero, Enrique, Mila Bravo, Blanca Perez-Gladish, Mar Arenas-Parra, and David Pla-Santamaria. 2012.
Socially Responsible Investment: A multicriteria approach to portfolio selection combining ethical and
financial objectives. European Journal of Operational Resrearch 216: 487–94. [CrossRef]
Belghitar, Yacine, Ephraim Clark, and Konstantino Kassimatis. 2019. A measure of total firm performance:
New insights for the corporate objective. Annals of Operations Research 281: 121–41. [CrossRef]
Bhattacharya, Sudipto. 1979. Imperfect Information, Dividend Policy, and “The Bird in the Hand” Fallacy.
Bell Journal of Economics 10: 259–70. [CrossRef]
Bunn, Derek W., and Fernando S. Oliveira. 2003. Evaluating Individual Market Power in Electricity Markets via
Agent-Based Simulation. Annals of Operations Research 121: 57–77. [CrossRef]
Campbell, Andrew, Jo Whitehead, and Sydney Finkelstein. 2009. Why Good Leaders Make Bad Decisions. Harvard
Business Review 87: 60–66.
De Bondt, Werner F. M., and Richard H. Thaler. 1995. Chapter 13 Financial decision-making in markets and firms:
A behavioral perspective. In Handbooks in Operations Research and Management Science. Edited by Robert
Alan Jarrow, Vojislav Maksimovic and William T. Ziemba. Amsterdam: Elsevier, pp. 385–410. [CrossRef]
Delcea, Camelia, Liviu-Adrian Cotfas, Nora Chirit, ă, and Ionut, Nica. 2018a. A Two-Door Airplane Boarding
Approach When Using Apron Buses. Sustainability 10: 3619. [CrossRef]
Delcea, Camelia, Liviu-Adrian Cotfas, and Ramona Păun. 2018b. Agent-Based Evaluation of the Airplane
Boarding Strategies’ Efficiency and Sustainability. Sustainability 10: 1879. [CrossRef]
Denis, David J., and Igor Osobov. 2008. Why do firms pay dividends? International evidence on the determinants
of dividend policy. Journal of Financial Economics 89: 62–82. [CrossRef]
Dougherty, Francis L., Nathaniel P. Ambler, and Konstantinos P. Triantis. 2017. A complex adaptive systems
approach for productive efficiency analysis: Building blocks and associative inferences. Annals of Operations
Research 250: 45–63. [CrossRef]
Doyle, Michael W., and Joseph E. Stiglitz. 2014. Eliminating Extreme Inequality: A Sustainable Development
Goal, 2015–2030. Ethics and International Affairs 28: 5–13. [CrossRef]
Dragotă, Victor. 2016. When Making Bad Decisions Becomes Habit: Modelling the Duration of Making
Systematically Bad Decisions. Economic Computation and Economic Cybernetics Studies and Research 50: 123–40.
Dragotă, Mihaela, Victor Dragotă, Lucian T, ât, u, and Delia T, ât, u. 2009. Income Taxation Regulation and Companies’
Behaviour: Is the Romanian Companies’ Dividend Policy Influenced by the Changes in Income Taxation?
Romanian Journal of Economic Forecasting 10: 76–93.
Dragotă, Victor, Nicoleta Vintilă, and Ingrid-Mihaela Dragotă. 2013. Rights and Wrongs in the Estimation of the
Cost of Equity: Theoretical and Practical Issues. Paper presented at the 8th International Conference AMIS
IAAER 2013, Bucharest, Romania, June 12–13; pp. 484–504.
Dragotă, Victor, Daniel Traian Pele, and Hanaan Yaseen. 2019. Dividend Payout Ratio follows a Tweedie
Distribution: International evidence. Economics: The Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal 13: 1–34.
Available online: http://www.economics-ejournal.org/economics/journalarticles/2019-45 (accessed on 4
November 2019).

85
JRFM 2019, 12, 167

Easterbrook, Frank H. 1984. Two Agency-Cost Explanations of Dividends. American Economic Review 74: 650–59.
Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French. 2001. Disappearing Dividends: Changing Firm Characteristics or Lower
Propensity to Pay? Journal of Financial Economics 60: 3–43. [CrossRef]
Fatemi, Ali, and Recep Bildik. 2012. Yes, dividends are disappearing: Worldwide evidence. Journal of Banking and
Finance 36: 662–77. [CrossRef]
Fidrmuc, Jana P., and Marcus Jacob. 2010. Culture, agency costs and dividends. Journal of Comparative Economics
38: 321–39. [CrossRef]
Frels, Judy, Debra Heisler, James Reggia, and Hans-Joachim Schuetze. 2006. Modeling the Impact of Consumer
Interactions in Technology Markets. Journal of Cellular Automata 2: 91–103.
Gennaioli, Nicola, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishny. 2015. Neglected Risks: The Psychology of Financial Crises.
American Economic Review 105: 310–14. [CrossRef]
Gilbert, Daniel. 2011. Buried by bad decisions. Nature 474: 275–77. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
Graham, Benjamin, and David L. Dodd. 1951. Security Analysis, 3rd ed. New York: McGraw-Hill, Book Company.
Hanlon, Michelle, and Jeffrey L. Hoopes. 2014. What do firms do when dividend tax rates change? An examination
of alternative payout responses. Journal of Financial Economics 114: 105–24. [CrossRef]
Harari, Yuval Noah. 2015. Sapiens: A Brief History of Humankind. London: Vintage Books.
Hirshleifer, David. 2001. Investor Psychology and Asset Pricing. Journal of Finance 56: 1533–97. [CrossRef]
Holderness, Clifford G. 2003. A Survey of Blockholders and Corporate Control. Economic Policy Review 9: 51–64.
[CrossRef]
Jensen, Michael C., and William H. Meckling. 1976. Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and
Ownership Structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3: 305–60. [CrossRef]
Jiang, Fuxiu, Yunbiao Ma, and Beibei Shi. 2017. Stock liquidity and dividend payouts. Journal of Corporate Finance
42: 295–314. [CrossRef]
Kalay, Avner. 1980. Signaling, Information Content, and the Reluctance to Cut Dividends. Journal of Financial and
Quantitative Analysis 15: 855–69. [CrossRef]
Kim, Hyunseok, and Ju Hyun Kim. 2019. Voluntary zero-dividend paying firms: characteristics and performance.
Applied Economics 51: 5420–446. [CrossRef]
Kuo, Jing-Ming, Dennis Philip, and Qingjing Zhang. 2013. What drives the disappearing dividends phenomenon?
Journal of Banking and Finance 37: 3499–514. [CrossRef]
La Porta, Robert, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny. 2000a. Agency Problems and
Dividend Policies around the World. Journal of Finance 55: 1–33. [CrossRef]
La Porta, Robert, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny. 2000b. Investor Protection
and Corporate Governance. Journal of Financial Economics 58: 3–27. [CrossRef]
Lele, Sharachchandra M. 1991. Sustainable Development: A Critical Review. World Development 19: 607–21.
[CrossRef]
Lintner, John. 1964. Optimal Dividends and Corporate Growth under Uncertainty. Quarterly Journal of Economics
78: 49–95. [CrossRef]
Lovric, Milan, Uzay Kaymak, and Jaap Spronk. 2010. A conceptual model of investor behavior. In Advances
in Cognitive Systems (IET Control Engineering Series, 71). Edited by Samia Nefti-Meziani and John O. Grey.
London: Institution of Engineering and Technology, pp. 369–94.
Lucero, Lisa J., Joel D. Gunn, and Vernon L. Scarborough. 2011. Climate Change and Classic Maya Water
Management. Water 3: 479–94. [CrossRef]
Mallin, Christine A. 2016. Corporate Governance, 5th ed. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Mare, Codrut, a, Simona Laura Dragos, , Ingrid-Mihaela Dragotă, and Cristian Dragos, . 2019. Insurance Literacy
and Spatial Diffusion in the Life Insurance Market: A Subnational Approach in Romania. Eastern European
Economics 57: 375–96. [CrossRef]
Markowitz, Harry. 1952. Portfolio Selection. Journal of Finance 7: 77–91. [CrossRef]
McGroarty, Frank, Ash Booth, Enrico Gerding, and V.L. Raju Chinthalapati. 2019. High frequency trading
strategies, market fragility and price spikes: An agent based model perspective. Annals of Operations Research
282: 217–44. [CrossRef]

86
JRFM 2019, 12, 167

Miller, Merton H., and Franco Modigliani. 1961. Dividend Policy, Growth, and the Valuation of Shares. Journal of
Business 34: 411–33. [CrossRef]
Miller, Merton H., and Myron S. Scholes. 1978. Dividends and taxes. Journal of Financial Economics 6: 333–64.
[CrossRef]
Monteiro, Nuno, Rosaldo Rossetti, Pedro Campos, and Zafeiris Kokkinogenis. 2014. A Framework for a
Multimodal Transportation Network: An Agent-based Model Approach. Transportation Research Procedia 4:
213–27. [CrossRef]
Morgan, John, and James Hansen. 2006. Escalating Commitment to Failing Financial Decisions: Why Does It
Occur? Journal of Business & Leadership: Research, Practice, and Teaching (2005–2012) 2: 37–45. Available online:
http://scholars.fhsu.edu/jbl/vol2/iss1/6 (accessed on 4 November 2019).
Negahban, Ashkan, and Jefrey S. Smith. 2018. A joint analysis of production and seeding strategies for new
products: An agent-based simulation approach. Annals of Operations Research 268: 41–62. [CrossRef]
Nenova, Tatiana. 2003. The value of corporate voting rights and control: A cross-country analysis. Journal of
Financial Economics 68: 325–51. [CrossRef]
Odean, Terrance. 1998. Are Investors Reluctant to Realize Their Losses? Journal of Finance 53: 1775–98. [CrossRef]
Pan, An, and Tsan-Min Choi. 2016. An agent-based negotiation model on price and delivery date in a fashion
supply chain. Annals of Operations Research 242: 529–57. [CrossRef]
Pikulina, Elena, Luc Renneboog, and Philippe Tobler. 2017. Overconfidence and investment: An experimental
approach. Journal of Corporate Finance 43: 175–92. [CrossRef]
Rai, Rahul, and Venkat Allada. 2006. Agent-based optimization for product family design. Annals of Operations
Research 143: 147–56. [CrossRef]
Ross, Stephen A., Randolph W. Westerfield, and Jeffrey Jaffe. 2010. Corporate Finance, 9th ed. New York:
McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
Rubinstein, Mark. 2001. Rational Markets: Yes or No? The Affirmative Case. Financial Analysts Journal 57: 15–29.
[CrossRef]
Samuelson, W., and R. J. Zeckhauser. 1988. Status Quo Bias in Decision Making. Journal of Risk & Uncertainty 1:
7–59.
Schwartz, Shalom H. 2006. A Theory of Cultural Value Orientations: Explication and Applications. Comparative
Sociology 5: 137–82. [CrossRef]
Shao, Liang, Chuck C.Y. Kwok, and Omrane Guedhami. 2010. National culture and dividend policy. Journal of
International Business Studies 41: 1391–414. [CrossRef]
Shefrin, Hersh, and Meir Statman. 1985. The Disposition to Sell Winners Too Early and Ride Losers Too Long:
Theory and Evidence. Journal of Finance 40: 777–90. [CrossRef]
Shiller, Robert J. 1987. The Volatility of Stock Market Prices. Science 235: 33–37. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
Shleifer, Andrei, and Robert W. Vishny. 1986. Large Shareholders and Corporate Control. Journal of Political
Economy 94: 461–88. [CrossRef]
Taleb, Nassim N. 2007. The Black Swan: The Impact of Highly Improbable. New York: Random House.
Taleb, Nassim N., Daniel G. Goldstein, and Mark W. Spitznagel. 2009. The Six Mistakes Executives Make in Risk
Management. Harvard Business Review 87: 78–81.
Tan, WenAn, Weiming Shen, Lida Xu, Bosheng Zhou, and Li Ling. 2008. A Business Process Intelligence System
for Enterprise Process Performance Management. IEEE Transactions on Systems Man and Cybernetics Part
C—Applications and Reviews 38: 745–56. [CrossRef]
Ucar, Erdem. 2016. Local Culture and Dividends: Local Culture and Dividends. Financial Management 45: 105–40.
[CrossRef]
von Eije, Henk, and William L. Megginson. 2008. Dividends and share repurchases in the European Union. Journal
of Financial Economics 89: 347–74. [CrossRef]
Walsh, William E., and Michael P. Wellman. 2000. Modeling Supply Chain Formation in Multiagent Systems.
In Agent Mediated Electronic Commerce II. Edited by Moukas Alexandros, Ygge Fredrik and Sierra Carles.
Berlin/Heidelberg: Springer, pp. 94–101. [CrossRef]
Walter, James E. 1956. Dividend Policies and Common Stock Prices. Journal of Finance 11: 29–41. [CrossRef]
Wang, Haizhong, Alireza Mostafizi, Lori A. Cramer, Dan Cox, and Hyoungsu Park. 2016. An agent-based model
of a multimodal near-field tsunami evacuation: Decision-making and life safety. Transportation Research Part
C—Emerging Technology 64: 86–100. [CrossRef]

87
JRFM 2019, 12, 167

Wilensky, Uri, and William Rand. 2015. An Introduction to Agent-Based Modeling: Modeling Natural, Social, and
Engineered Complex Systems with NetLogo. Cambridge: The MIT Press.
Zambrano, Cristian, and Yris Olaya. 2017. An agent-based simulation approach to congestion management for
the Colombian electricity market. Annals of Operations Research 258: 217–36. [CrossRef]

© 2019 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access
article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution
(CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).

88
Journal of
Risk and Financial
Management

Article
Are Family Firms Financially Healthier Than
Non-Family Firm?
Lious Agbor Tabot Ntoung 1, *, Helena Maria Santos de Oliveira 2, *,
Benjamim Manuel Ferreira de Sousa 2 , Liliana Marques Pimentel 3 and
Susana Adelina Moreira Carvalho Bastos 2
1 Department of Economics, University of Buea, Buea 00237, Cameroon
2 School of Accounting and Administration of Porto (ISCAP), Polytechnic Institute of Porto (IPP),
4200-465 Porto, Portugal; helenabenjamimsousa@bensou.pt (B.M.F.d.S.);
susanamoreirabastos@gmail.com (S.A.M.C.B.)
3 Department of Economic, University of Coimbra, 3004-531 Coimbra, Portugal; liliana.pimentel@fe.uc.pt
* Correspondence: lious2010@gmail.com (L.A.T.N.); hmoliveira@sapo.pt (H.M.S.d.O.)

Received: 19 October 2019; Accepted: 23 December 2019; Published: 29 December 2019

Abstract: This study examines the whether or not family firms are financially healthier than non-family
in terms of capital structure and leverage. It therefore takes into consideration the existence of any
significant differences between the leverage and risk choices of family and non-family firms. Using a
panel data set of 888 firms and 7104 firm-year observations of unlisted small and medium size firms
over the period 2007–2014, we present that family owned businesses have lower financial structure
than those of non-family owned businesses. This indicates that most family firms use less debt
financing than non-family firms, and as such maintain a lower level of debt. Secondly, family firms
demonstrate lower risk as illustrated by the Altman Z-score. The Altman Z-score scale illustrates a
contrary relationship of significance with respect to family firms and their counterparts in terms of
the operation aspect of the business’s risk factors. Family firms managed their business operations
with lower risk and are generally healthier financially than their counterpart firms. Lastly, findings
from the robust tests for the hypotheses using a sample of bankrupt firms in Iberian Balance sheet
Analysis System (SABI) reveal that the proportion of failure of family firms as opposed to their
counterpart firms is relatively low. Analyzing the bankruptcy files of firms from 2002 to 2014 shows
a considerably low ratio of family firms at the 5% significant level. This affirms that the low risk
illustrated in the Altman Z-score regression is consistent to the lower ratio of family firms that were
declared bankrupted over the study period, which makes Spain an important case in this study.

Keywords: capital structure; family firms; leverage; non-family firms; risk

JEL Classification: G1; G32; G38

1. Introduction and Literature Review


Following the evidence cited by several researchers over the years (such as Shleifer and Vishny
1986; DeAngelo and DeAngelo 2000; Anderson and Reeb 2003), one principal characteristic to influence
the management of firms is that of its risk profile. Even though very little empirical research has shown
light on this topic, the small amount of existing empirical research suggests that the characteristics of
family owned companies could be a possible reason for family business risk aversion and the choice of
capital structure.
Anderson and Reeb (2003) argue that the agency problems that exist between management and
stakeholders is reduced when the structure of a family firm is adopted by a company. They suggest
however that the risk averse nature of the controlling families is disintegrated through monitoring.

JRFM 2020, 13, 5; doi:10.3390/jrfm13010005 89 www.mdpi.com/journal/jrfm


JRFM 2020, 13, 5

DeAngelo and DeAngelo (2000) add that the risk nature of family firms achieved through engaging in
lower risky activities that promote net present value by large and undiversified shareholders might
impose costs to well-diversified shareholders with minority power. Following the illustration in
(Miller et al. 2007; Villalonga and Amit 2006; Pison et al. 2014), 65%–80% of firms around the world
are managed by one or more families, and generate approximately 70%–90% of the gross domestic
product. Neubauer and Lank (2016) add that family owned businesses create approximately 70%–80%
of jobs on a yearly basis. Meanwhile, evidence from the European Family Businesses (2012) present
that over the globe, 85% of business startups are family orientated.
The fundament reason for the said study using Spain as the case is due to the peculiarities of the
Spanish system being made up of approximately 90% family orientedbusinesses contributing to 60%
of the country’s GDP. In (Pérez and Lluch 2015; Pison et al. 2014; European Family Businesses 2012),
family-oriented businesses generate over two-thirds of the total employment, and often these firms are
thought to be small and medium size enterprises. Yet little attention has been provided to the financial
health of the business in terms of capital structure and leverage.
A review of both management and finance empirical evidence regarding the risk profile of family
businesses suggests the main hypothesis that family-oriented businesses have lower leverage and
lower risk, which could actually benefit the company during times of economic downturn. Thus,
from a financial standpoint, this paper presents indicators that are specific to family-orientedbusiness
with long-time horizon, family orientation, and generational continuity as potential reasons for family
business risk aversion and the choice of capital structure for medium and small oriented family
companies in Spain.
In order to answer the hypothesis, we first examine the characteristics of family firms in term of
the operation aspect of the business’s risk factors and whether family firms managed their business
operations with lower risk and are generally healthier financially than their counterpart firms. Next,
we examine a series of bankruptcy filings in Spain from 2002 to 2014 and evaluate the proportion of
family businesses in the sample.
Accordingly, March and Shapira (1987) consider decision investment as the deal between expected
return and risk per the conventional theory. Masulis (1988, pp. 14−16) suggests that “managers in both
family and non-family businesses will prefer having less leverage than shareholders in order to reduce
the risk of their undiversified investment in the company”. Consistent with this view, Grossman and
Hart (1986) argue that increased leverage reduces the agency cost of type I associated with managerial
discretion and managers’ discretion over corporate decisions. In Bangladesh, Dey et al. (2018) present
findings of financial risk disclosure indices in annual reports of 48 manufacturing companies over
six-year period (2011–2015) using 30 disclosure identifiers. Their results show that there is a positive
and significant relationship between the level of financial risk disclosure and firm size, financial
performance, and auditor type.
A more recent study suggests “that risk is an unavoidable part of life, including business life
and therefore, it exists in the content of uncertainty” (Garland 2003, p. 4). Furthermore, “it is no
surprise that predicting the future is an uncertain task, involving, at best, probabilities, and inferences
since the memory of the past is sometimes flawed and our knowledge of the present is incomplete”
(Garland 2003, pp. 4–5). Hollenbeck et al. (1994) find that individuals treat risk as a dynamic factor,
because the future carries its opportunities as well as it risks. They add that the “perspective of change
in value rather than total value to evaluate a decision and to separate gains but not losses from initial
outlay” is preferred by most risk analysis treating risk as a dynamic factor.
Furthermore, Bernstein and Bernstein (1996) add that the nature of risk has been sharp by the time
horizon. May (1995) posits that the reason behind managers using only approximate time frames in
their planning rather than the accurate time forecast is due to the personal risk when making decisions
regarding firms risk. De Vries (1993) add that family businesses have a longer-term perspective
than non-family businesses, (Oswald and Jahera 1991; Ntoung et al. 2016a), which may “improve
decision-making resulting in higher earnings and dividends. After controlling for a variety of factors

90
JRFM 2020, 13, 5

that affect cross-sectional debt levels among all firms”, Mishra and McConaughy (1999) conclude that
family-controlled firms using less debt. This is indeed true because the use of less debt creates the
founding family’s aversion to the risk of loss of control.

2. Family Control and Firm Value


Family control businesses have been debated over century by prior research that it enhances
family firm value. Some classical research argues that the ownership structures in widely held firms
create opportunities for conflicts of interest between managers and shareholders. This can reduce the
value of the firm since managers of such firms are more concerned about the maximization of private
benefits at the expense of the owner of the firms (Agency Cost of Type I). Other school of thought claim
that the most suitable instrument to correct the action of such sulphurous management behaviour is
through concentrated ownership, (Ntoung et al. 2017, p. 127). For instance, in (Ntoung et al. 2016a)
(Jensen and Meckling 1976; Sraer and Thesmar 2007) claim that separation between ownership and
control can involveimportant costs and problems forshareholders. Their classical agency problem
suggests that one way to resolve the conflict of interest between shareholders and managers is to
increase the proportion of shares in the hands of the controlling shareholder.
“In light of the above, minority shareholders are victimised as ownership becomes more
concentrated, while controlling shareholders tend to engage in undesirable behaviours. In a similar way,
Schulze et al. (2001) examine the consequences of altruism concept and pay of incentives by controlling
shareholder, and their influence in the level family firm’s performance. They affirm that family firms
with concentrated ownership are more exposed to agency danger. Chrisman et al. (2004) conclude that
agency cost affects the performance of family business. Researches in Austria, Italy, and Spain show a
positive and signification relationship between incentive and performance”, (Ntoung et al. 2016b).
Furthermore, Asghar Butt et al. (2018) add that most family owners are less likely to use derivatives
for hedging purposes as compared to non-family owners. Examining corporate derivatives and the
ownership concentration of 101 Pakistani non-financial firms over the period 2012–2016, they concluded
that non-family firm are more likely to use derivativemeasures to increase the value of their stocks.
Meanwhile, Yang et al. (2018) conclude by attesting that in order to perform risk management
practices in a way that will guarantee competitive position in the market, the top management need
to have enough financial skills. Finally, “their findings suggest that these characteristics of family
firms do influence their performance. In Europe, Barontini and Caprio (2006) provide similar evidence
to those of Villalonga and Amit. According to them, family firms with a founder or descendants as
CEO or Chairman outperform other firms. However, family firms with a founder as CEO outperform
family firms with descendants as CEO. Also, if no member of the family is involved in the management
(passive), then the firms perform worse” (Ntoung et al. 2017, p. 125).

Hypotheses
With respect to the mixed empirical evidence from prior research, one can clearly argue that
financial and capital structure choices by family businesses are motivated by the level of risk assumed.
Anderson and Reeb (2003) argue that “the principal-agent cost and the asymmetric information
between shareholders and managers” is reduced when a structure of family firm is adopted in a
company. They suggest however that the risk averse nature of the controlling families is disintegrated
through monitoring. DeAngelo and DeAngelo (2000) add that the risk aversion of family companies is
achieved through avoiding high risk projects even when they have positive net present value as large
and undiversified shareholders might impose costs to well-diversified shareholders with minority
power. Thus, our first hypothesis:

Hypothesis 1 (H1). Family firms have lower leverage than non-family peers.

Hypothesis 2 (H2). Family owned companies are less risky than non-family firms.

91
JRFM 2020, 13, 5

These hypotheses suggest that family owned firms possess some characteristics, such as family
legacy, generational succession, and longer-term horizons, which might potentially be responsible for
the capital structure choice and make family business more risk averse and conservative.

3. The Hypothesis, Methods and Data

3.1. Empirical Model


This study examines if family firms are financially healthier than their counterpart firms. This led
us to two specific factors that determine the financial health of the firm as shown in Sections 3.1.1
and 3.1.2 below.

3.1.1. Leverage
“We use a panel regression analysis to evaluate whether a family owned company has a different
level of leverage to a similar non-family” (Ntoung et al. 2017) to examine the level of a firm’s leverage
(debt/EBITDA ratio and interest coverage ratio). One reason for excluding the usual ratio of debt/capital
is because it is influenced not only by the choice of debt level the company makes, but also by the level
of equity the company has. Also, the debt/capital ratio induced the market perception of the firm into
the equation, thus it wouldn’t provide aclean estimate of the leverage choices made by the firm.
We run five regression equations regarding our two dependent variables for leverage.
The regression equation is illustrated as follows:

Leverage = α1 × (Family dummy) + α2 × Age + α3 × Size measure + α4 × Industry Dummy


(1)
+ α5 × Profitability measure + α6 × Interactive Variables

where,

Leverage: Debt/EBITDA and Interest Coverage Ratio.


Family firm takes: dummy equals 1 when a firm is a family firm or zero otherwise
Profitability measure: refers to return of equity, return on assets, EBITDA margin, netincome margin
Size measure: refers to number of employees, total revenues, total assets
Age: calculate based on the company date of establishment.
Industry dummy: equaling 1 as dummy for each IAC classification code,
Year dummy: equals 1 for each year considered in the analysis.

Furthermore, to correct the presence of heteroskedasticity and serial correlation in the data, we
employ the Huber–White sandwich estimator for variance (Ntoung et al. 2017).

3.1.2. Risk Exposure


“To critically analyze the risk profile of family businesses as opposed to their non-family peers, it
is vital to examine beyond leverage, factors that reflect overall risk. We further evaluate these factors
by employing the Altman Z-score, a predictive model developed to determine acompany’s probability
of filing for bankruptcy in the next subsequence of years and to measure the overall financial health of
a company” (Ntoung et al. 2016b).
Altman Z-score: We consider the Altman Z-score as a dependent variable. “The choice of variable
regarding a company risk’s of survival was based on four balance sheet and income statement variables,
namely profitability, leverage, solvency, liquidity, and activity. The result of the combination of ratios
gives rise to a discriminantscore, otherwise called the Z-Score. The ratios are X1 = working capital/total
assets, X2 = retained earnings/total assets, X3 = earnings before interest and taxes/total assets, X4 =
market value of equity/book value of total debt, and X5 = sales/total assets. In 1998, Altman redefined

92
JRFM 2020, 13, 5

his model by excluding X5 (sales/total assets) to forecast the corporate risk of survival for manufacturing
firms in Mexico. The weighted coefficients thus have different values” (Ntoung et al. 2017).

Z” = 6.5X1 + 3.2X2 + 6.72X3 + 1.0X4 (2)

Source: Altman et al. (1998, p. 3).


The analysis of family business risk characteristics using Altman Z-score provides information
about risk exposure the company is willing to take on, hypothesizing that family firms would have a
tendency to be more risk averse, if all things being equal.
We run five regression equations regarding our two dependent variables for leverage.
The regression equation is illustrated as follows:

Altman Z-Score = α1 × (Family dummy) + α2 × Age + α3 × Size measure + α4 × Industry


(3)
Dummy + α5 × Profitability measure + α6 × Interactive Variables

where,

Altman Z-Score: 6.5X1 + 3.2X2 + 6.72X3 + 1.0X4


Family firm takes: dummy equals 1 when a firm is a family firm or zero otherwise
Profitability measure: refers to return of equity, return on assets, EBITDA margin, netincome margin
Size measure: refers to number of employees, total revenues, total assets
Age: calculated based on the company date of establishment.
Industry dummy: equaling 1 as dummy for each IAC classification code,
Year dummy: equals 1 for each year considered in the analysis.

Furthermore, to correct the presence of heteroskedasticity and serial correlation in the data,
we employ the Huber–White Sandwich estimator for variance (Ntoung et al. 2017).

3.2. Data
In this section we examine the hypothesis that family owned companies have lower leverage and
lower risk than non-family peersof unlisted small and medium size sing data constructed based on the
Iberian Balance sheet Analysis System (SABI) of the Bureau Van Dijk, containing detailed financial
information on more than 2,000,000 Spanish businesses. Next, we employ the IAC2015 classification
code excludingall financial and utilities firms using the industry classification. The reason for the
exclusion of firms in these industries is due to the fact that firms are strongly regulated and influenced
by the government. We also excluded all firms with incomplete accounting information. Our final
sample consists of 888 firms and 7104 firm-year observations of unlisted small and medium size firms
over the period 2007–2014. The study is based on Spain because Spain was one of the European
countries that suffered greatly duringthe 2008 financial crisis. Many small and medium size businesses
experienced bankruptcy and, as a result of this, it reveals an important case to study. We were interested
to investigate whether the businesses failure was due to a high leverage or risk profile.

3.3. Variables Measurement

3.3.1. Dependent Variables


Leverage is measured using the debt/EBITDA and interest coverage ratio and Altman Z-score. This
is consistent with (Shleifer and Vishny 1986; DeAngelo and DeAngelo 2000; Anderson and Reeb 2003).

3.3.2. Independent Variables—Ownership structure


The criteria used for the ownership structure of firms in Spain are based on the Iberian balance
sheet analysis system (SABI). These criteria focus on the holding of a shareholder’s ultimate voting

93
JRFM 2020, 13, 5

rights across these firms, which differ from the ultimate cash flow rights. In cases where information
was available about the ownership structure of a company, we search this property directly on the
company websites. Firms in Spain were classified through the aid of the BvD independence indicator
available in SABI. The BvD independence indicator has five levels, namely “A”, “B”, “C”, “D”, and
“U”. According to SABI, independent indicator “A” denotes that a company is said to be independent
if the shareholder must be independent by itself (i.e., no shareholder with more than 25% of ownership
of ultimate voting rights), whereas independent indicator “B” is when no shareholders with more
than 50% exist but one shareholder with voting rights between 25.1% to 50%. For a company to be
classified with independent indicator “C”, the company must have a recorded shareholder with a
total or calculated ownership of 50.1% or higher, whereas a company is classified as “D” when a
recorded shareholder demonstrates direct ownership of over 50% with branches and foreign companies
(Ntoung et al. 2017).
Independent indicator “U” is applied when a company does not fall into the categories “A”, “B”,
“C” or “D”. Based on the above features and prior studies, a company with a shareholder having
more than 25% is classified as family-run firm, while firms with no shareholder with more than
25% areclassified as widely held firms. This threshold of 25% allows shareholder to have significant
influence on the firm. Therefore, firms categorized as “A” are widely held firms while firms in “B”,
“C”, and “D” are family firms. Our next criteria for family is that, in a family firm, an individual or
a family must be the largest shareholder and be categorized in “B”, “C”, and “D”. The individual
must be part of the founding family. If this is not the case, the controlling shareholder must have
had the largest percentage of ultimate voting right over a long time period.For each firm, we identify
founding family presence using information provided by SABI about corporate proxy statements on
board structure and characteristics, ECO attributes, equity ownership structure, and founding-family
attribute” (Ntoung et al. 2017). In case where there weremissing data, we directly search the company
website for extra detail.

3.3.3. Other Independent Variables


Profitability measure refers to the return of equity, return on assets, EBITDA margin, and net
income margin. Size measure refers to number of employees, total revenues, and total assets. Age is
calculated based on the company’s date of establishment. Table 1 provides a detailed definition of the
variable used.

3.4. Descriptive Statistics


Table 2 shows a simple t-test analysis and itssignificance of the difference between family and
non-family firms on each of the independent variables used in this study. With respect to the dependent
variables, from our t-test presented in Table 2, both family and non-family firms exhibit the same
risk profiles, even though family firms seem to be less risky than non-family firms. However, further
examination is needed for the relationship between the variables in the form of regression estimates
while controlling for other possible explanations for the outcome, as revealed in the t-test.
Also, the outcomes of the different t-tests indicate that most of the controlling variables are
different for both family and non-family firms. With respect toprofitability measures, non-family firms
appear to be more profitable than their peers. The proxy of age reveals that family firms have a longer
time-horizon than non-family firms.
Lastly, across the different industrial sectors, the outcome from the t-test shows that, for
construction, other services, and restaurant and lodging trades, family firms significantly dominate
their non-family counterparts. However, for transport, communication, management and insurance
activities, as well as energy, water, and metal transforming industries, non-family firms significantly
dominate family firms (See Table 2).

94
Table 1. Definition of variable.

Dependent Variables Debt/Earnings before interest, tax, depreciation and amortization (EBITDA), Interest Coverage Ratio and Altman Z-Score.
Independent Variables
JRFM 2020, 13, 5

“A” “Indicates a dummy equaling 1 if no shareholder with more than 25% of ownership of ultimate voting rights);”
“B” “Indicates a dummy equaling 1 if no shareholder with more than 50% but exist one shareholder with voting rights between 25.1% and 50%.”
“C” “Indicates a dummy equaling 1 if a recorded shareholder with a total or a calculated ownership of 50.1% or higher”
“D” “Indicates a dummy equaling 1 if a recorded shareholder with a direct ownership of over 50% with branches and foreign companies”
Family Firms “B”, “C” and “D”
Non-family firms “A”
“A family member is CEO, Chairman, CEO and Chairman, respectively in a family firm; the family only holds shares in the company
Family characteristics
without taking an active position; and the founder or a descendant is actively managing the company as Chairman or CEO.”
Widely held
“Denote a dummy variable 1 if the largest ultimate shareholder owns more than 25% of the shares in one of the categories.”
corporation
Profitability measure ROA, ROE, EBITDA margin, and Net income margin.
Size measure Number of employees, total revenues, and total assets.
Firm age “Defined the logarithm of the date of establishment”

95
Industry “Defined according IAC classification code”
Table 2. Descriptive Statistics.

All Sample Non-Family Firms Family Firms Difference in mean


Descriptive Statistics t-Test
(Non-Family-Family Firms)
Mean Std. Mean Std. Mean Std.
JRFM 2020, 13, 5

Independent Variables
Number of Employees 110.79 96.77 123.63 221.34 112.78 73.17 10.85 1.41
Total Assets 20,108.90 14,480.30 18,331.50 9231.54 26,191.18 27,523.31 −7859.66 −8.248 *
Total Revenue 20,206.30 13,224.60 19,062.50 9356.42 22,025.11 23,499.49 −2962.58 −3.514
Age 24.44 11.41 25.50 11.21 28.61 11.82 3.11 7.05 **
Return on Assets 2.84 8.05 2.57 6.45 2.60 7.60 −0.03 −0.10 **
Return on Equity 7.79 48.41 6.96 14.23 7.28 21.60 −0.32 −0.38 *
Net Income Margin −19.22 1812.36 2.33 6.79 2.14 9.67 0.19 −0.50 *
Industry dummy
−55.338
Cattle raising 0.82 0.39 0.11 0.31 0.19 0.31 −0.08
***
Energy and water 1.00 0.00 1.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
Extraction, transformation of
0.10 0.47 0.15 0.36 0.06 0.36 0.09 25.974 ***
non-energetic minerals
Metal transforming industries 0.09 0.50 0.12 0.33 0.08 0.33 0.04 39.118 *
Other manufacturing industries 0.43 0.50 0.17 0.30 0.10 0.30 0.07 58.663 **
−17.507

96
Construction 0.85 0.36 0.15 0.36 0.85 0.36 −0.70
***
−38.056
Restaurant and lodging trade 0.00 0.06 0.17 0.38 0.83 0.38 −0.65
***
Transport and Communication 0.47 0.31 0.66 0.23 0.34 0.23 0.32 44.443 **
Management and insurance activities 0.35 0.42 0.54 0.69 0.39 0.31 0.13 14.924 **
−18.331
Other services 0.86 0.34 0.14 0.34 0.86 0.34 −0.73
**
Dependent Variables
Z-Score 2.91 1.41 2.75 1.46 3.04 1.41 −0.30 −4.502 *
−4.678
Debt/Capital 71.92 319.88 36.67 60.27 68.61 197.29 −31.95
***
EBIT/Interest Expense 5.78 1.33 4.17 1.32 9.05 51.21 −4.88 2.875 **
Debt/EBITDA 3.09 0.45 −1.45 184.97 3.11 210.59 −4.56 0.49 **
***, **, * significant at 1%, 5% and 10% levels.
JRFM 2020, 13, 5

4. Empirical Analysis

4.1. Leverage
Tables 3 and 4 summarize the panel regression outcomes for the leverage variable used in the
study. We executed five regressions for each of the two dependent variables (debts/EBITDA and
interest coverage ratio). This analysis helps us to prove whether a family firm has a different level
of leverage than a similar non-family firm. For both analyses, we controlled for other possible proxy
variables such as profitability measure (return of equity, return on assets, EBITDA margin, and net
income margin), size measure (number of employees, total revenues, and logarithm of total assets),
and age of firm based on the date of establishment

Table 3. Debt/EBITDA Regression.

1 2 3 4 5
Intercept −6.37 ** −1.82 5.74 ** −9.88 * −8.65 *
(−0.843) (−0.04) (0.015) (−0.13) (0.61)
Family Dummy −6.78 *** −2.89 ** −4.72 ** −3.34 ** −8.32 **
(−0.366) (−0.12) (−0.23) (−0.01) (0.46)
Return on Assets −1.53 * −2.30 * −5.74 ** −5.44
(0.547) (0.55) (0.04) (−0.11)
Return on Equity −0.033 * −4.63 * −1.39 ** −0.01 * −5.55 **
(0.01) (0.039) (−0.10) (0.00) (0.07)
Total Revenue −0.037 * −0.04 −0.034 −0.00
(−1.32) (−1.40) (−1.25) (−0.09)
Age of Firm 0.64 * 0.03 * −3.30 ** 3.41
(−0.24) (0.01) (0.06) (0.05)
Number of Employees 1.66 *** 4.80 −3.11 ** −5.23 *
(0.518) (−0.50) (−0.33) (−0.55)
Size (log of Total Assets) 5.26 * 7.715 ** 3.58 ** 1.40 9.89 *
(1.042) (0.06) (0.01) (0.26) (1.25)
EBITDA Margin −0.55 * −0.37 ** 0.22 * −1.38 ** −2.78 **
(0.02) (−0.02) (0.14) (−0.06) (4.32)
Net Income Margin −0.22 * −5.14 ** −2.34 ** −6.36 *
(−0.143) (0.21) (−0.59) (0.137)
Return on Assets*Family −2.74 **
(−2.17)
Return on Equity*Family −1.68 ** −5.72 ** 0.02 * −7.74 **
(−0.03) (0.10) (−0.12) (−0.07)
Total Revenue*Family −5.35 *
(−1.18)
Age of Firm*Family 2.16 ** −7.86 −4.80 **
(−0.12) (0.92) (−0.11)
Number of Employees*Family 5.04 3.00 5.35
(0.72) (0.44) (0.76)
Size (log of Total Assets)*Family 5.28 ** −1.23 * −0.35 **
(0.12) (2.19) (−0.22)
EBITDA Margin*Family −0.26 −0.85 **
(0.17) (−0.77)
Net Income Margin*Family −0.02 −0.02
(−0.02) (−2.19)
Adjusted R2 23.2 *** 23.2 *** 21.5 *** 28.7 *** 29.4 ***
Industry Dummy included Yes Yes No No No
“The variables for the analyzed sample of 888 firms and 7104 firm-year observations of unlisted small and medium
size firms over the period 2007 to 2014, includes leverage is measured using the Debt/EBITDA and Interest Coverage
Ratio. Profitability measure refers to return of equity, return on assets, EBITDA margin, and net income margin.
Size measure refers to number of employees, total revenues, and total assets. Age calculate based on the company
date of establishment. Also, family firm denotes a dummy taking the value 1 if the firm has a family or individual
with 25% or more voting rights, and zero otherwise (SABI of the Bureau Van Dijk).***, **, * illustrate the significance
at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level respectively”. Source: Authors elaboration.

97
JRFM 2020, 13, 5

Table 4. Interest Coverage Ratio Regression.

1 2 3 4 5
Intercept −7.27 ** 5.88 −6.44 ** −15.35 ** −19.62
(−4.44) (0.90) (1.94) (2.69) (0.39)
Family Dummy −1.72 ** −30.23 −0.52 −4.50 *** −3.04 **
(−1.98) (−0.93) (−0.32) (−3.70) (−2.44)
Return on Assets −1.95 *** −1.98 *** 1.20
(30.34) (30.28) (0.18)
Return on Equity −0.016 −0.77 *** −0.69 *** −0.74 *** −0.64 *
(−1.48) (3.75) (−3.54) (3.61) (−1.75)
Total Revenue −0.00 −0.00 *** −0.00 −0.00
(1.48) (−0.00) (−0.06) (−0.50)
Age of Firm −9.64 11.59 ** −11.79 * −10.88
(−0.24) (−5.73) (−1.77) (−1.73)
Number of Employees −2.64 * −0.00 0.01 ** −0.01 **
(−2.89) (−0.18) (0.52) (−0.33)
Size (log of Total Assets) −3.125 1.78 ** 0.64 ** 2.79 ** 2.53 *
(2.72) (−0.29) (0.32) (2.21) (2.09)
EBITDA Margin −0.01 −1.69 −0.063 −1.16
(−0.28) (−1.20) (−1.34) (−0.00)
Net Income Margin −2.35 * −0.00 −7.20 *** −5.27 ***
(1.65) (−0.34) (−4.66) (−1.18)
Return on Assets*Family −0.05 **
(0.91)
Return on Equity*Family −1.68 ** −0.33 ** −0.31 **
(−0.03) (−3.22) (−1.71)
Total Revenue*Family −4.45 ***
(−4.46)
Age of Firm*Family 5.23 5.46 ** −4.96 **
(1.49) (1.57) (1.51)
Number of Employees*Family 0.00 −0.11 0.00
(0.16) (−0.89) (0.35)
Size (log of Total Assets)*Family 1.88 ** −2.53 **
(0.58) (2.09)
EBITDA Margin*Family −2.98
(−2.18)
Net Income Margin*Family −7.46
(−4.85)
Adjusted R2 23.3 *** 23.2 *** 24.5 *** 27.4 *** 31.3 ***
Industry Dummy included Yes Yes Yes No No
“The variables for the analyzed sample of 888 firms and 7104 firm-year observations of unlisted small and medium
size firms over the period 2007 to 2014, includes leverage is measured using the Debt/EBITDA and Interest Coverage
Ratio. Profitability measure refers to return of equity, return on assets, EBITDA margin, and net income margin.
Size measure refers to number of employees, total revenues, and total assets. Age calculated based on the company’s
date of establishment. Also, family firm denotes a dummy taking the value 1 if the firm has a family or individual
with 25% or more voting rights and zero otherwise (SABI of the Bureau Van Dijk). ***, **, * illustrate the significance
at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level respectively”. Source: Authors elaboration.

With respect to debts/EBITDA as a dependent variable for leverage, our results from Table 3 show
negative significance at the debt level for the first regression. This indicates that most family firms use
less debt financing than non-family firms, and as such maintain a lower level of debt.Regarding the
profitability measure, the result from regression 1 illustrates a negative and statistically significant
relationship between level of debt and profitability at the 5% level. These results suggest that most
families tend to increase their reserves during the profitable circle of their firms and later reinvest this
surplus profit when there is a need for expansion. They employ equity finance rather than debt finance
for investment.
Further, to examine the cross-influence of family business age and size on debt, we execute
regression 2 with interactive terms of two controlling variables and the family dummy. Specifically, the
cross-influence of family business age and size on debt is positive and statistically significantly at the
5% level. The average age of most family examined in this study is 28, indicating that most of the firms
are first generation. This result suggests that most family firms in their earlier developmentdepend
on equity finance;however, as years go by, they more fully depend on debt finance for their activities.
This is consistent with a positive and statistically significant correlation with the interactive term of

98
JRFM 2020, 13, 5

family and size. Early in their development, most family firms depend on equity finance, but as they
grow bigger, huge debt finance is needed to finance their activities.
In addition, regressions 3, 4, and 5 exclude some of the controlling variables and include some
combination of interaction variables between size and family, profitability and family, and age and
family, and are negative and statistically significant at the 5% level. These regressions using different
combinations of variables indicate positive coefficients for the family dummy on debt. The results of
these regressions illustrate that family firms actually have lower levels of debt than non-family firms.
This result is consistent with several prior research papers which have examined the characteristics of
family-controlled business. One possible reason for this could be that family ownership and control
is responsible for most family businesses adopting a more risk averse structure and the tendency to
avoid high risk activities. These results support the hypothesis that family owned companies have
lower leverage than non-family firms (See Table 3).
With respect to the interest coverage ratio as a dependent variable for leverage, our results from
Table 4 show a similar result in Table 3, with negative significance at the debt level for the first regression.
This indicates that most family firms use less of debt financing than non-family firms, as such maintain
a lower level of debt. Regarding the profitability measure, the result from regression 1 illustrates a
negative and statistically significant relationship between the level of debt and profitability at the 5%
level. These results suggest that most family firms tend to increase their reserves during the profitable
cycle of their firms and later reinvest this profit when there is a need for expansion. They employ
equity finance rather than debt finance for investment.
Further, to examine the cross-influence of family business age and size on debt, we execute
regression 2 with interactive terms of two controlling variables and the family dummy. Specifically,
the cross-influence of family business age and size on debt is positive and statistically significantly
at the 5% level. The average age of most family firms examined in this study is 28, indicating that
most of the firms are first generation. This result suggests that most family firms in their earlier
developmentdepend on equity finance, however, as years go by, they come to fully depend on debt
finance for their activities. This is consistent with a positive and statistically significant correlation for
the interactive terms of family and size. During their earlier development, most family firms depend
on equity finance, but as they grow bigger, huge debt finance is needed to finance their activities.
In addition, regressions 3, 4, and 5 exclude some of the controlling variables and include some
combination of interaction variables between size and family, profitability and family, and age and
family, and are negative and statistically significant at the 5% level. These regressions, using different
combinations of variables, indicate positive coefficients for the family dummy in the case of debt.
The results of these regressions illustrate that family firms actually have lower levels of debt than
non-family firms. This result is consistent with several prior research papers that examined the
characteristics of family-controlled businesses. One possible reason for this could be that family
ownership and control is responsible for most family business adopting a more risks adverse structure
and the tendency to avoid high risk activities. These results support the hypothesis that family owned
companies have lower leverage than non-family firms (see Table 4).

4.2. Risk Exposure


In this section of our study, we prove the risk exposure of family businesses by applying the
Altman Z-score, a predictive model developed to evaluate the possibility of a firm going bankrupt in
the subsequent years and to measure the overall financial health of companies (Altman et al. 2013;
Altman and Hotchkiss 2006). We run five regressions for the leverage analysis in Tables 3 and 4.
Table 5 shows the positive significance of family orientated businesses as independent variables
of the Z-score at the 5% level. These results suggest that a family-oriented business is actually healthier
than its counterpart.

99
JRFM 2020, 13, 5

Table 5. Altman Z-Score Regression.

1 2 3 4 5
Intercept −0.16 1.13 −1.92 ** 1.52 *** 1.28 ***
(−0.48) (3.36) (2.82) (9.80) (8.21)
Family Dummy 0.13 ** 0.06 0.31 3.16 *** 0.58 **
(2.89) (0.74) (0.88) (11.05) (3.15)
Return on Assets 0.07 *** 0.25 *** 0.00 **
(38.28) (2.81) (0.00)
Return on Equity 0.00 ** 0.01 *** 0.01 *** 0.02 *** 0.05 *
(2.41) (14.15) (13.90) (3.69) (4.62)
Total Revenue 0.00 *** 0.04 *** 0.00 0.00 ***
(11.59) (0.52) (0.28) (13.38)
Age of Firm 9.64 0.07 0.09 ** 0.07 **
(0.24) (0.34) (2.69) (2.16)
Number of Employees 1.34 * 0.00 ** 0.00 *** 0.00 **
(4.21) (3.56) (0.52) (6.15)
Size (log of Total Assets) 0.23 ** 0.36 *** 0.18 ** 6.30 *** 0.37 ***
(6.5) (10.88) (0.56) (2.21) (4.19)
EBITDA Margin 0.00 0.00 ** 36.11 *** 0.00 ***
(2.05) (2.30) (−3.54) (2.13)
Net Income Margin 16.62 *** 0.00 * 17.27 *** 3.21 ***
(12.59) (0.00) (13.06) (5.38)
Return on Assets*Family 0.04 **
(3.37)
Return on Equity*Family 0.00 0.33 ** 0.03 ***
(0.21) (3.22) (4.56)
Total Revenue*Family 4.45 ***
(4.46)
Age of Firm*Family 0.32 *** 0.09 ** 0.07 **
(1.68) (2.11) (2.39)
Number of Employees*Family 0.00 ** 0.00 0.00 **
(0.00) (−7.01) (6.97)
Size (log of Total Assets)*Family 0.00 ** 0.11 **
(0.00) (5.92)
EBITDA Margin*Family −37.70
(−3.73)
Net Income Margin*Family −23.34 ***
(−17.37)
Adjusted R2 23.6 *** 23.2 *** 23.8 *** 30.1 31.3
Industry Dummy included Yes Yes Yes No No
“The variables for the analyzed sample of 888 firms and 7104 firm-year observations of unlisted small and medium
size firms over the period 2007–2014 includes risk exposure and is measured using the Altman Z-score. Profitability
measure refers to the return of equity, return on assets, EBITDA margin, and net income margin. Size measure
refers to number of employees, total revenues, and total assets. Age is calculated based on the company’s date of
establishment. Also, family firm denotes a dummy taking the value 1 if the firm has a family or individual with 25%
or more voting rights and zero otherwise (SABI of the Bureau Van Dijk). ***, **, * illustrate significance at the 1%, 5%,
and 10% level respectively”. Source: Authors elaboration.

We further examine the cross-influence of family business age and size on risk exposure. Specifically,
the cross-influence of family business age and size on risk exposure is positive and statistically
significantly at the 5% level. The positive sign shows the relationship between age and size to risk
exposure. Following the Altman Z-Score, “to check the bankruptcy situation of these firms, Altman
and Hotchkiss (2006) and Ntoung et al. (2016b) matched a correspondencebetween the Standard and
Poor’s rating and the score, which makes the model reliable and consistent” (Ntoung et al. 2017).
Therefore, the higher the Z-Score, the lowerthe possibility ofa firm being categorized in the distress
zone, and this suggests that, at any size and age, family firms are less risky than their counterpart firms.
In addition, regressions 3, 4 and 5 “exclude some of the controlling variables and include some
combination of interaction variables between size and family, profitability and family, and age and
family” and are positive and statistically significant at the 5% level. This result confirms the results
obtained in the first and second regressions.These regressions using different combinations of variables
indicate positive coefficients for the family dummy on debt. The results of these regressions illustrate
that family firms are actually less risky than their counterpart firms. This result is consistent with
several prior research papers which examined the characteristics of family-controlled businesses.

100
JRFM 2020, 13, 5

One possible reason for this could be that family ownership and control is the responsible for most
family businesses adopting a more risk averse structure and the tendency to avoid high risk activities.
These results support the hypothesis 2 that family owned companies are less risky than non-family
firms (see Table 5).

4.3. Robustness Test


“The endogeneity of ownership structures of firmsbe theyfamily or non-family, post an important
concern regarding the validity of the result obtained. Several authors fail to consider ownership
as endogenous, and have reported a positive, negative, insignificant, nonlinear reverse relationship
between ownership and firm performance. No study so far has provided evidence for the risk profile
of Spanish family firms. Meanwhile, other authors have tested ownership as endogenous to obtain
theconclusion of there being no significant relationship using either a panel-fixed effect or instrumental
variables” (Ntoung et al. 2016a).
In this study, we argue that family ownership and control can be motivated by the lower leverage
and risk aversion of family businesses as opposed to the school of thought that says thatfamily
ownership and control is responsible for most family businesses adopting a more risk averse structure
and the tendency to avoid high risk activities. This is indeed true because the use of less debt and lower
risk strategies makes the founding family’s aversion to the risk of loss of control. Also, imagine that
high leverage and high risk are associated with family ownership, this will either result to bankruptcy
or disintegration of the family ownership and control. As usual, every business is characterized
byboth ups and downs. To see if high leverage and high risk is the sole cause of family firms changing
to non-family firms or to be categorised as bankrupt, or the reason why family businesses in Spain
don’t attain the second and third generation, we sampled a series of bankruptcy filings of small and
medium size firms in SABI from 2002 to 2014, evaluating the ratio of family to non-family companies
in the sample. We selected a longer horizon time because these years represent the financial crisis of
2008–2014, as well as 2005 to 2007, and stable (2002–2004) markets in the Spanish economy. These
different cycles in the economy will have a huge effect on family firm’s bankruptcies, due to the high
inherent risk. The sample includes 534 companies that have been declared bankrupt in SABI. We collect
information over the period 2002–2014. Big and listed firms were eliminated from the list. Only small
and medium size firms are considered, giving us a total 526 small and medium firms that filed for
bankruptcy from 2002 to 2014. We collected data on bankruptcy date, industry, year founded, number
of employees, debt level at bankruptcy, a list of large shareholders at bankruptcy, as well as information
about ownership and control. The ownership and control information helped us to categorize which
firm is a family firm or non-family firm.
In Ntoung et al. 2017, “according to SABI, the shareholder ultimate voting rights across these
firms differs from the ultimate cash flow rights. In cases where information was available about the
ownership structure of a company, we search this property directly on the company websites. Family
firms in Spain were classified through the aid of the BvD independence indicator available in SABI.”
“The BvD independence indicator has five levels, namely “A”, “B”, “C”, “D”, and “U”. According to
SABI, independent indicator “A”, denotes that a company independent if the shareholder must be
independent by itself (i.e., no shareholder with more than 25% of ownership of ultimate voting rights),
whereas independent indicator “B” is when no shareholder with more than 50% but one shareholder
with voting rights between 25.1% to 50% exist. For a company to be classified with independent
indicator “C”, the company must have a recorded shareholder with a total or a calculated ownership
of 50.1% or higher, whereas a company is classified with “D” when a recorded shareholder has direct
ownership of over 50% with branches and foreign companies”.
“Independent indicator “U” is applied when a company does not fall into the categories “A”, “B”,
“C” or “D”. Based on the above features and prior studies, a company with a shareholder having
more than 25% is classified as a family firm while firms with no shareholder with more than 25%
areclassified as widely held firms. This threshold of 25% allows shareholders to have a significant

101
JRFM 2020, 13, 5

influence on the firm. Therefore, firms categorized with “A” are widely held firms while firms in “B”,
“C”, “D” are family firms. Our next criterion for a family firm is that an individual or a family must
be the largest shareholder, and be categorized in “B”, “C”, and “D”. The individual must be part
of the founding family. If this is not the case, the controlling shareholder must have had the largest
percentage of ultimate voting rights over a long time period. After building a database by classifying
which firm is family or non-family firm, Figure 1 shows the filingsforbankruptcy over 2002 to 2014”.

ϰϬϬ
ϯϱϬ
ϯϬϬ
ϮϱϬ
ϮϬϬ
ϭϱϬ
ϭϬϬ
ϱϬ
Ϭ

EŽŽĨĨŝƌŵƐ &ĂŵŝůLJĨŝƌŵƐ EŽŶͲĨĂŵŝůLJĨŝƌŵƐ

Figure 1. Number of Bankrupt firms over the period 2002–2014. Source: Authors’ elaboration.

Analysing Figure 1 shows that family firms are less likely to file for bankruptcy in the years of
difficult financial pressure and economic downturn, as opposed to the years of growth or stagnation.
This is because family firms are characterised with lower debt and are less risky. The proportion of
firms that filed for bankruptcy during the financial crisis 2008 to 2013 is relatively lower than those
that filed in for bankruptcy during 2003–2004 for family firms. Also, the proportion of family firms
that filed for bankruptcy isrelatively lower than their counterpart firms. Thus, high leverage and high
risk cannot be the sole cause of family firms changing to non-family, or to be categorised as bankrupt,
or the reason why family businesses in Spain don’t attain the second orthird generation.Therefore,
the hypothesis that family firms have lower debt and manage their operations in a less risky manner
is true.
We also back up the analysis in Figure 1 by running a t-test. The t-test evaluates whether there are
significant differences between family and non-family firms with respectto four variables, namely the
number of employees, age of firms, debt level, andratio of amortization over cash flow.The number of
employees is a proxy for company size, while age distinguishes between younger and older firms,
as well as being a proxy of generational succession.The ratio of amortization and cash flow is a proxy
for the risk ofbankruptcy, while debt levels show the level of debt at bankruptcy.
Table 6 shows that the ratios of family/non-family firms in the sample in each year are 0.00 for 2012,
0.29 for 2008, 0.32 for 2004, and 0.44 for 2002, and statistically significant at the 5% level.This initial
observation rejects the hypothesis that high debt and high risk cause family firms to file for bankruptcy,
or causes family ownership to dissolve. Family firms have lower debt and are less risky thantheir
counterpart firms. The ratio of family firms filing for bankruptcy is higher for 2004 (32.2%) and 2002
(44.2%) and lower for 2014 (0.0%), 2012 (0.0%), and 2008 (29.4%). This shows that family ownership
involvement, in the management or ownership ofa significant holding, in the firms reveals a unique
characteristic of the firms and thus maintains a lower percentage of bankruptcy cases. Comparing
thisproportion of bankruptcy cases, we conclude that family firmshave lower debts and are less risky
than non-family firms.

102
JRFM 2020, 13, 5

Table 6. Bankrupt Firms over the period 2014–2002.

Family Ownership
Family Family Both Insiders &
Number of Family Firms
Year Insiders Blockholders Blockholders
Firms %
% % %
2014 0 0% 0% 0% 0%
2013 6 50% 50% 50% 0%
2012 4 0% 0% 0% 0%
2011 4 33.3% 100% 0% 0%
2010 6 20% 0% 100% 0%
2009 15 50% 80% 20% 0%
2008 22 29.4% 60% 40% 0%
2007 22 29.4% 60% 40% 0%
2006 78 27.9% 65% 35% 0%
2005 137 31.7% 67% 33% 0%
2004 189 32.2% 76% 24% 0%
2003 126 21.2% 91% 9% 0%
2002 75 44.2% 65% 35% 0%

According to the difference between family and non-family with regards to number of employees,
the age of firm, debt at bankruptcy, and the ratio of amortization/cash flows, our findings are significant
at 5% and 10% levels. However, when evaluating the age of the firms that file for bankruptcy, it is
apparent that family firms are younger on average. A potential explanation for this significant
difference is that many of the firms categorized as family firms following the definition are start-ups or
in their early stage in their life cycle. Such young firms are at greater risk to fail as compared to more
established firms as in Table 7.

Table 7. Bankrupt Firms over the period 2014 to 2002.

Mean Age Mean Age Difference


Mean Age All
Year (Non-Family (Family) (Non-Family-Family t-Test p-Value
Bankrupt Firms
Firms) Firms Firms)
2014 13.441 16.267 0.000 16.267 67.673 0.000 ***
2013 23.280 26.850 12.330 14.530 1.360 0.268
2012 44.000 22.500 0.00 −7.250 −0.298 0.816
2011 16.500 26.700 23.900 2.800 0.000 0.000 ***
2010 19.843 26.900 8.467 18.433 1.307 0.321
2009 19.096 23.900 2.600 21.230 3.597 0.023 **
2008 17.755 7.380 14.240 −6.860 −2.568 0.062 *
2007 19.382 0.000 17.540 −17.540 −4.236 0.013 **
2006 14.691 0.000 18.760 −18.760 −3.028 0.039 **
2005 14.738 0.000 13.429 −13.429 −7.551 0.000 ***
2004 12.192 18.013 12.392 5.621 1.989 0.054 *
2003 10.274 14.246 4.015 10.229 7.902 0.000 ***
2002 9.046 12.059 2.152 9.908 10.118 0.000 ***
Note: ***, **, *, significance levels1%, 5%, and 10% of the difference of family and non-family bankrupted firms.
Number of employees refers to the latest number of employees available at bankruptcy date.

Younger firms tend to have founders present due to their phase in the cycle and therefore are
categorized as family companies in this sample. However, these firms do not necessarily share the
characteristics associated with family firms, such as long-term time horizon, succession planning
considerations, and risk aversion. To eliminate this bias, we re-runa t-test for firms that filed for
bankruptcy with the age of 10 years and above. Table 8 shows a duplicated version of Table 7, but only
includes firms with an age above 10 years before declaring bankruptcy. As expected, the sample of
family firms decreases in each of the years except for 2004. Specifically, in the year of financial crisis
(2008–2013), the ratio of family firms filing for bankruptcy waslower than in the years of economic
prosperity (2004–2007). This confirmed the fact that family businesses filing for bankruptcy is not due

103
JRFM 2020, 13, 5

to the high debt and riskiness of the business. Using this sample, we can validate our hypothesis that
family firms have lower leverage and are less risky than their counterpart firms.

Table 8. Firms older than 10 years.

Family Ownership
Number of Family Family Both Insiders &
Family Firms
Year Firms Insiders Blockholders Blockholders
%
% % % %
2014 0 0 0 0
2013 4 17% 17% 0% 0
2012 0 0% 0% 0% 0
2011 4 25% 25% 0% 0
2010 3 0% 0% 0% 0
2009 7 0% 0% 0% 0
2008 13 18% 14% 5% 0
2007 13 18% 14% 5% 0
2006 16 21% 19% 1% 0
2005 18 24% 18% 7% 0
2004 21 22% 16% 6% 0
2003 0 0% 0% 0% 0
2002 0 0% 0% 0% 0

5. Conclusions
Numerous scholars have debated the uniqueness of the characteristics of family firms in terms
of performance as opposed to their counterpart firms. The perception that families possess a more
conservative attitude towards the management of the business makes family firms less risky. The risk
profile of family business has been argued to be one of the characteristics significantly impacting the
management of family business. In the light of the above, this paper has as its main objective to predict
if family firms have lower leverage and manage their operations in a less risky manner as compared to
their counterpart firms. The analysis conducted in this study yields some interesting results regarding
the risk profile of the family firm.
Firstly, family firms have a lower financial structure than non-family firms. This indicates that
most family firms use less debt financing than non-family firms, and as such maintain a lower level
of debt. Regarding the profitability measure, this result suggests that most families tend to increase
their reserves during the profitable cycle of their firms and later reinvest this reserved profit during
economic downturn, rather than using debt finance. In other words, they employ their equity finance
rather than debt finance for investment.
Secondly, family firms demonstrate lower risk as illustrated by the Altman Z-score. The Altman
Z-score captures the financial risk inherent in a firm by examining four financial ratios (such as working
capital/total assets, retained earnings/total assets, EBITDA/total assets, and market value of equity/book
value of total debt). The significant difference between family firms and non-family firms on the Altman
Z-score scale indicates that the lower inherent risk of family firms arises from the operation aspect
of the business. Family firms managed their business operation with lower risk and are generally
healthier financially than their counterpart firms. This explains the uniqueness of the capital structure
of family businesses.
Lastly, the robust tests for the hypotheses using a sample of bankrupt firms in SABI reveal that the
proportion of failure of family firms as opposed to theircounterpart firms is relatively low. Analyzing
the bankruptcy files of firms from 2002 to 2014 shows a considerably low ratio of family firms at the
5% significance level. This affirms that the low risk illustrated in the Altman Z-score regression is
consistent withthe lower ratio of family firms that were declared bankrupt over the study period. Lastly,
the average debt at bankruptcy was lower and statistically significant for family firms as opposed to

104
JRFM 2020, 13, 5

non-family firms. Therefore, the findings herein confirm the hypothesis that family firms have a lower
capital structure and maintain more financially healthy operations than non-family firms.

Author Contributions: Conceptualization, methodology, software, and formal analysis, L.A.T.N.; validation,
visualization, supervision and project administration, H.M.S.d.O.; formal writing, software and funding acquisition,
B.M.F.d.S.; investigation and data curation and methodology, L.M.P.; visualization, formal analysis and resources,
S.A.M.C.B. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.
Funding: This research was funded by Center for Studies in Business and Legal Sciences (CECEJ) and Research
Centre for the Study of Population, Economics and Society (CEPESE).
Acknowledgments: We will like to give special thanks to the reviewers for their valuable comments. More thanks
to Professor Paul Ntungwe Ndue for his remarkable review and assistance. Lastly, thanks to the Center for Studies
in Business and Legal Sciences (CECEJ) and Research Centre for the Study of Population, Economics and Society
(CEPESE) for all the financial funding and support provided by its members during this research.
Conflicts of Interest: The authors declared no potential conflict of interest with respect to the research, authorship,
and publication of this article.

References
Altman, Edward I., John Hartzell, and Matthew Peck. 1998. Emerging market corporate bonds a scoring system.
In Emerging Market Capital Flows. Boston: Springer, pp. 391–400.
Altman, Edward I., Alessandro Danovi, and Alberto Falini. 2013. ‘Z-Score Models’ Application to Italian
Companies Subject to Extraordinary Administration’. Journal of Applied Finance 23: 128–37.
Altman, Edward I., and Edith Hotchkiss. 2006. Corporate Financial Distress & Bankruptcy, 3rd ed. Hoboken: John
Wiley & Sons.
Anderson, Ronald C., and David M. Reeb. 2003. Founding-family ownership and firm performance: Evidence
from the S&P 500. The Journal of Finance 58: 1301–28.
Asghar Butt, Affaf, Main SajidNazir, Hamera Arshad, and Aamer Shahzad. 2018. Corporate Derivatives and
Ownership Concentration: Empirical Evidence of Non-Financial Firms Listed on Pakistan Stock Exchange.
Journal of Risk and Financial Management 11: 33. [CrossRef]
Barontini, Roberto, and Lorenzo Caprio. 2006. The effect of family control on firm value and performance:
Evidence from continental Europe. European Financial Management 12: 689–723. [CrossRef]
Bernstein, Peter L., and Peter L. Bernstein. 1996. Against the Gods: The Remarkable Story of Risk. New York: Wiley,
pp. 1269–75.
Chrisman, James J., Jess H. Chua, and Reginald A. Litz. 2004. Comparing the agency costs of family and non-family
firms: Conceptual issues and exploratory evidence. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 28: 335–54.
DeAngelo, Harry, and Linda DeAngelo. 2000. Controlling stockholders and the disciplinary role of corporate
payout policy: A study of the Times Mirror Company. Journal of Financial Economics 56: 153–207. [CrossRef]
De Vries, Manfred FR Kets. 1993. The dynamics of family controlled firms: The good and the bad news.
Organizational Dynamics 21: 59–71.
Dey, Ripon, Syed Hossain, and Zabihollah Rezaee. 2018. Financial risk disclosure and financial attributes
among publicly traded manufacturing companies: Evidence from Bangladesh. Journal of Risk and Financial
Management 11: 50. [CrossRef]
European Family Businesses. 2012. Family Business Statistics. Available online: http://www.
europeanfamilybusinesses.eu/uploads/Modules/Publications/family-business-statistics.pdf (accessed on
30 September 2018).
Garland, David. 2003. The rise of risk. In Risk and Morality. Toronto: University of Toronto Press, pp. 48–86.
Grossman, Sanford J., and Oliver D. Hart. 1986. The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and
Lateral Integration. Journal of Political Economy 94: 691–719. [CrossRef]
Hollenbeck, John R., Daniel R. Ilgen, Jean M. Phillips, and Jennifer Hedlund. 1994. Decision risk in dynamic
two-stage contexts: Beyond the status quo. Journal of Applied Psychology 79: 592. [CrossRef]
Jensen, Michael C., and William H. Meckling. 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and
ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3: 305–60. [CrossRef]
March, James G., and Zur Shapira. 1987. Managerial perspectives on risk and risk taking. Management Science 33:
1404–18. [CrossRef]

105
JRFM 2020, 13, 5

Masulis, Ronald W. 1988. The Debt/Equity Choice. Tampa: Financial Management Assoc, pp. 14–16.
May, Don O. 1995. Do managerial motives influence firm risk reduction strategies? The Journal of Finance 50:
1291–308. [CrossRef]
Miller, Danny, Isabelle Le Breton-Miller, Richard H. Lester, and Albert A. Canella Jr. 2007. Are family firm’s really
superior performers? The Journal of Corporate Finance 13: 829–58. [CrossRef]
Mishra, Chandra S., and Daniel L. McConaughy. 1999. Founding family control and capital structure: The risk of
loss of control and the aversion to debt. Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice 23: 53. [CrossRef]
Neubauer, Fred, and Alden G. Lank. 2016. The Family Business: ItsGovernance for Sustainability. Berlin/Heidelberg:
Springer.
Ntoung, Agbor Tabot Lious, Helena Maria Santos De Oliveira, Cláudia M. F. Pereira, Benjamim Mamuel Ferreira De
Sousa, Susana A. M. C. Bastos, and Cacilia Kome. 2017. Family Involvement in Ownership, Management and
Firm Performance in Spain. Revista Contabilidade e Gestão, 21/Novembro. Lisboa: Ordem dos Contabilistas
Certificados, pp. 123–53.
Ntoung, Agbor Tabot Lious, Carlos Ferro Soto, and Ben C. Outman. 2016a. Ownership Structure and Financial
Performance of Small Firms in Spain. Corporate Ownership & Control 13. [CrossRef]
Ntoung, Agbor Tabot Lious, Puime Guillén Felix, and Miguel Angel Crespos Cibrán. 2016b. The Effectiveness of
Spanish Banking Reforms: Application of Altman’s Z-Score. Risk Governance & Control: Financial Markets &
Institution 6: 40–47.
Oswald, Sharon L., and John S. Jahera. 1991. The influence of ownership on performance: An empirical study.
Strategic Management Journal 12: 321–26. [CrossRef]
Pérez, Paloma Fernández, and Andrea Lluch, eds. 2015. Familias Empresarias y Grande Sempresas Familiares en
América Latina y España: Una Visión de Largo Plazo. Madrid: Fundacion BBVA.
Pison, F. Irene, Cibrán F. Pilar, and Ntoung A. T. Lious. 2014. Cash flow fixing: A new approach to Economic
Downturn (Small and Medium Size Enterprise). International Journal of Current Research and Academic Review
2: 271–90.
Schulze, Willam S., Michael H. Lubatkin, Richard N. Dino, and Ann K. Buchholtz. 2001. Agency relationships in
family firms: theory and evidence. Organization Science 12: 99–116. [CrossRef]
Shleifer, Andrei, and Robert W. Vishny. 1986. Large shareholders and corporate control. The Journal of Political
Economy 94: 461–88. [CrossRef]
Sraer, Dvid, and David Thesmar. 2007. Performance and behavior of family firms: Evidence from the French stock
market. Journal of the European Economic Association 5: 709–51. [CrossRef]
Villalonga, Belen, and Raphael Amit. 2006. How do family ownership, control and management affect firm value?
Journal of Financial Economics 80: 385–417. [CrossRef]
Yang, Songling, Muhammad Ishtiaq, and Muhammad Anwar. 2018. Enterprise risk management practices and
firm performance, the mediating role of competitive advantage and the moderating role of financial literacy.
Journal of Risk and Financial Management 11: 35.

© 2019 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access
article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution
(CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).

106
Journal of
Risk and Financial
Management

Article
Optimal Contracting of Pension Incentive: Evidence
of Currency Risk Management in
Multinational Companies
Jeffrey (Jun) Chen 1, *, Yun Guan 2 and Ivy Tang 3
1 Department of Transportation, Logistics, & Finance, College of Business, North Dakota State University,
1340 Administration Ave, Fargo, ND 58105, USA
2 College of Business, Clemson University, 105 Sikes Hall, Clemson, SC 29634, USA; yguan@clemson.edu
3 Luxembourg School of Finance, Université du Luxembourg, 2, avenue de l’Université, 4365 Esch-sur-Alzette,
Luxembourg; ivytang22@hotmail.com
* Correspondence: jun.chen1@ndsu.edu

Received: 17 December 2019; Accepted: 27 January 2020; Published: 3 February 2020

Abstract: Using a large sample of multinational companies (MNCs), this paper intends to explore
whether executives’ pension incentives will function as a mechanism of optimal contracting in
motivating firm risk management. We find that granting more pension to executives is significantly
related to the higher likelihood and intensity of currency hedging strategies in MNCs. This suggests
that pension incentive should promote executives to more actively manage firms’ risk. Such a positive
relationship is robust to endogeneity and is more prominent in firms with strong shareholder power.
We further explore the contribution of currency hedging induced by pension incentives to shareholder
value. Supporting the hypothesis of optimal contracting, our results indicate that pension incentives
play an important role in reconciling managerial risk preference and shareholder value creation.

Keywords: pension incentive; currency hedging; multinational companies; firm value

1. Introduction
How to financially motivate executives has attracted a great deal of attention in literature. This is
not surprising, as self-interested managers—along with their substantial influence on firm policies—are
found to extract private benefits at the expense of shareholders, and therefore a well-designed
compensation contract is critically important for shareholders who seek to maximize their value.
However, the dominant theme of existing literature in executive compensation only focuses on
traditional components, such as a base salary, bonus, and equity compensation (stocks or options),
but overlooks another important piece, pension benefits, which mainly include retirement plans and
deferred compensation. As emphasized by Jensen and Meckling (1976), the ingredients of an ideal
compensation package for managers should include both equity-based and liability-based instruments.
The binding claim in liability-like benefits is expected to influence managerial risk-preference, mitigate
the agency cost, and hence affect possible value reallocation among stakeholders.
Compared to the widespread practice of pension plans or retirement benefits, studies regarding
to the role of such liability-based compensation are generally scant. Edmans and Liu (2011) and
Sundaram and Yermack (2007) are the earlier studies that explore liability-based instruments in
compensation from theoretical and empirical perspectives. Particularly, Edmans and Liu (2011)
propose that pension compensation outperforms cash compensation and helps solve the agency
conflicts between shareholders and debtholders. Sundaram and Yermack (2007) document that
liability-based compensation accounts for an important portion of executives’ total wealth, motivating
them to invest conservatively and therefore reducing default risk. Recent studies suggest that executives’

JRFM 2020, 13, 24; doi:10.3390/jrfm13020024 107 www.mdpi.com/journal/jrfm


JRFM 2020, 13, 24

pension benefits are associated with lower CDS spreads (Wei and Yermack 2011), lower R&D investment
and financial leverage (Cassell et al. 2012), lower cost of private loan financing and fewer restrictive
covenants (Anantharaman et al. 2014), cash holding (Liu et al. 2014), and managerial risk-taking
(Anantharaman and Lee 2014).
The research on incentive design is important not only because it, per se, targets a fundamental
business contract, but also yields instructive and practical insights into how an agent’s risk attitude is
financially effected and how the stakeholders are exposed to the related consequence. As noted above,
there is a paucity of research on the nature of pension incentive and its impacts on the risk management
of firms. For example, Anantharaman et al. (2014) found that firms with more pension incentive are
charged with lower cost of debt financing and fewer restricting covenants. Cassell et al. (2012) and
Liu et al. (2014) observe that the use of pension incentive is associated with lower R&D investment and
more cash holding. However, none of them provide an explicit link between pension incentive and
corporate risk management, particularly with the interplay of shareholder governance. By utilizing the
data of currency hedging strategy used by the MNCs, this paper aims to investigate a direct impact of
pension incentive on the managerial decisions. Additionally, the unique and hand-collected hedging
data across the industries offer us a chance to have an unambiguous view of active risk management.
Corporate risk management, particularly hedging strategy, has become a critical dimension
of financial policy and also attracted a lot of research interest. The study based on the Wharton
survey of derivative usage shows that a growing number of CEOs view financial derivatives as
indispensable tools in managing firms’ risk (Géczy et al. 2007). The academic research also documents
that hedging increases firm value by overcoming the market imperfections, such as deadweight costs
related with bankruptcy risk, aggressive tax region, the underinvestment problem, and high cost of
capital (Smith and Stulz 1985; Froot et al. 1993; Rogers 2002; Campello et al. 2011). More importantly,
the literature suggests that executives’ compensation incentives are an important determinant of
corporate hedging. The traditional view of financial incentives focusing on equity compensation
predicts that granting stocks or stock options will motivate managers to overcome risk aversion.
In contrast, Sundaram and Yermack (2007) argue that executives’ pension benefits would generate
different incentives. The nature of unsecured and unfunded pension liabilities may expose managers
to firm risk due to a lack of diversification and may result in a devastating loss of personal wealth
in the case of firm bankruptcy. Since hedging reduces a firm’s cash flow volatility and consequently
lowers the likelihood of bankruptcy, it is plausible that CEOs who hold a larger amount of wealth in
pension will be more actively involved in managing firm risk through hedging.
This study focuses on currency risk management by using foreign exchange derivatives, because
Géczy et al. (1997) investigated the use of derivatives for a sample of Fortune 500 non-financial firms and
found that currency derivatives are used most frequently by corporations. Foreign currency exposure
is also considered as a major source of risk by the US firms (Bodnar et al. 1998; Krapl and White 2016).
It is arguable that a firm may have little need to use foreign currency hedging if it has no relevant foreign
currency risk. Therefore, in the spirit of the literature (Graham and Rogers 2002; Campello et al. 2011),
we identify the multinational firms with ex ante exposure to foreign currency risk in this study.
However, we also followed Doukas and Pantzalis (2003), to consider the case that a firm might be
subject to foreign currency risk due to the competitive environment. To do so, we included keywords
related to foreign currency and foreign exchange market risk in our textual searching program to read
if firms explicitly state their foreign currency exposures in 10-K filings.
In this paper, we first examine the relationship between pension incentive and hedging
propensity. Based on the sample retrieved from the COMPUSTA Segment database and matched with
EXECUCOMP executive pension database, our investigation covers 1625 US firms from 2006 through
2015. Hedging data are collected from 10-K filings compiled in the SEC EDGAR database. We find
that a higher level of pension incentive is associated with a higher probability of adopting currency
hedging strategy. A one-standard-deviation increase in the pension benefits in dollar amount leads
to an increase of 2.2% in hedging probability. Meanwhile, a one-standard-deviation increase in the

108
JRFM 2020, 13, 24

pension proportion in CEO total compensation increases hedging probability by 6.5%. In addition, by
using the notional amount of hedging position, we find that a higher level of pension incentive also
brings about a larger position of hedging. For one percent increase in CEO pension relative leverage,
the hedging position rises by 40 basis points of total assets (0.4%), an equivalence of USD 35.95 million
investment in foreign currency derivatives.
As with most studies in business research, the endogenously determined incentive might be a
potential concern in our research. However, the significant and positive relation between hedging
activity and pension incentive remains consistent when we perform robustness checks, instrumental
variables (IV) model to control for endogeneity. The results from the robust models suggest that
endogeneity cannot explain away the positive impact of pension incentive on hedging activity, and the
inference from the baseline models is unaffected when correcting for endogeneity.
Given a positive relation between pension incentive and hedging activity, a natural question
to further explore is whether this relation is contingent on governance mechanism. To answer this
question, we propose the optimal contracting hypothesis. Our analysis suggests a more prominent
influence of pension incentive on hedging for the firms with strong shareholder power than those
with weak shareholder power. Furthermore, we employ the model of Faulkender and Wang (2006)
to quantify the impact of hedging on firm value, augmented with pension incentive and governance
mechanisms. The empirical evidence shows that one dollar of investment in existing hedging position
generates USD 0.374 to shareholders and one dollar increase in hedging position creates an additional
value of USD 0.204. More importantly, we find that the marginal impact of pension incentive on the
value of hedging is higher for the firms with strong shareholder power, which supports the optimal
contracting hypothesis.
In the extant research, the influence of pension incentive on active risk management (e.g., hedging)
has not been given enough attention. Belkhir and Boubaker (2013) and Krapl and White (2016) are
the two of few studies that have explored this area. Belkhir and Boubaker (2013) examined pension
paid to CEOs in the US bank holding companies and find that higher CEO pension holdings relate
to higher use of derivatives to hedge against banks’ interest rate risk. They explain that pension
compensation binds the banks’ default risk with the executives’ interest and curbs their excessive
risk-taking activities. Krapl and White (2016) document a negative relation between foreign exchange
exposure and pension-based compensation paid to executives including CEOs, CFOs, and other top
managers. These results imply that pension compensation encourages executives to reduce cash flow
volatility and hence lowers firms’ exposure to foreign exchange risk.
Our findings are consistent with Belkhir and Boubaker (2013) and Krapl and White (2016),
but this study differs from them. First, we build a large sample of companies that span across
a wide array of industries, rather than only financial institutions. This large sample recognizes
the possible heterogeneity and produces more applicable conclusions. Moreover, as suggested by
Krapl and White (2016) foreign exchange exposure is a major source of risk to most of the US firms.
Our focus on currency risk management reflects such an urgent demand in the age of globalization.
In addition, our hedging data allow a direct look at the financial derivatives used in risk management.
This study supplements the literature with the supportive evidence and further casts new light on the
long-debated contracting theory of executive compensation.
In this paper, we fill the void in the literature by empirically examining the impact of pension
incentive on firm risk management and how such influence is contingent on governance environment.
Our study contributes to the literature in the following ways. First, we document a significantly positive
impact of pension incentive on foreign currency hedging implemented by the multinational firms.
Second, this paper complements the literature of compensation design by providing new evidence to
support the optimal contracting hypothesis. Our analysis suggests that pension, the liability-based
instrument adopted in the environment of strong shareholder power has a more pronounced impact
on executives’ hedging decisions. In addition, this study also enriches the existing hedging literature.
After controlling for other well-documented determinants, we find pension incentive plays a remarkable

109
JRFM 2020, 13, 24

role, which is different from the equity-like compensation, in determining managerial risk attitude
gauged through the hedging strategy. Finally, this research relates to the literature of risk management
and we add the new insight to understand the active currency hedging strategy used by the multinational
companies in creating shareholder value.
The remainder of this paper is structured as follows: Section 2 will review the literature and
develop the testable hypotheses. Section 3 describes the sample, the variable constructions, and the
summary statistics are also provided. Section 4 discusses the model specification and reports our main
empirical results. In Section 5, we present an extended analysis on the value of hedging, interacted
with pension incentive and governance. Section 6 concludes the paper.

2. Relevant Literature and Testable Hypotheses

2.1. Equity-Based Incentive and Managerial Risk Preference


There is a large and growing literature on executive compensation and its influence on managerial
incentives, corporate financing, investment, and firm value (Peng and Roell 2014; Gormley et al. 2013;
Bereskin and Cicero 2013; Liu and Mauer 2011; Billett et al. 2010; Coles et al. 2006; Carpenter 2000).
Practically, an executive compensation package consists of the short-term and long-term components.
The former mainly includes salary and bonus, whereas the latter refers to restricted stock grants, grants
of stock options, long-term incentive payouts, and other compensation. Although the annual salary can
be partially decided by the past performance, and the bonus component is based on various metrics of
accounting information (i.e., return on assets, return on equity, sales growth or other according measures
relative to the industry or competitors), these two components are not the primary solutions for the
shareholders, intuitively, to maximize the their value since neither of them are directly linked to stock
returns, which is presumably concerned most by shareholders. As Jensen and Murphy (1990) point out,
the present value of current and future increases in salary and bonus represents a small fraction of total
financial incentives. Meanwhile, under the framework of principal-agent theory, incentive contract is
designed to reduce the agency conflicts between risk-neutral shareholders and risk-averse managers.
For this reason, compensation packages containing long-term incentives, particularly equity-based
instruments, attract more interests and explorations.
Unlike well-diversified shareholders, managers cannot diversify their human capital. As a result,
they tend to forgo positive NPV but highly risky projects when their benefits from an increase in
firm value are lower than their costs associated with greater firm risk. Equity-like compensation is
viewed as a mechanism to reduce this underinvestment problem through aligning the interests of
managers and shareholders (Jensen and Meckling 1976). Smith and Stulz (1985) and Guay (1999) also
suggest that equity compensation motivates managers to overcome risk aversion and hence induce
optimal risk-taking behaviors. In particular, Smith and Stulz (1985) show that the risk-related incentive
problem can be controlled by rewarding managers with stock options or common stocks to structure
their wealth as a convex function of firm value, therefore leading to risk-seeking managers.

2.2. Liability-Based Incentive


Although there has been a rigorous examination of executives’ equity compensation in
the literature, the exploration of liability-based compensation remains relatively limited after
Jensen and Meckling (1976) first formulated a concept of debt-like compensation. Until recently,
Bebchuk and Fried (2004) state that pension and other retirement benefits are considerably large in
relation to executives’ actual compensation. Sundaram and Yermack (2007) implement one of the
first empirical research on debt-like compensations of large U.S. companies’ CEOs. They find that
when a CEO’s incentive leverage (a ratio of liability-based compensation relative to equity-based
compensation) exceeds the firm’s leverage ratio, CEOs tend to manage firms more conservatively, such
as investing on less risky projects, lowering the use of debt capital or choosing long-maturity debt,
and trimming dividends payout. An event study by Wei and Yermack (2011) indicates that a wealth

110
JRFM 2020, 13, 24

transfer from stockholders to debtholders is associated with the announcements of granting pension
and deferred compensation to CEOs. Additional examinations of the impact of CEO pension on firm
policies include White (2012), Anantharaman et al. (2014), and Cassell et al. (2012). In particular
Cassell et al. (2012) find a negative relationship between pension compensation and the volatility
of equity returns, financial leverage or R&D expenditures, but a positive relation between debt
compensation and firm diversification or asset liquidity. Anantharaman et al. (2014) find that CEOs’
pension incentive is associated with a lower cost of debt financing and fewer restrictive covenants.
Moreover, White (2012) examines how pension incentive affects the dividend policy. Overall, studies
suggest that pension incentives have a significant influence on discouraging risk taking behavior.

2.3. Hypothesis Development


As suggested by Sundaram and Yermack (2007), the nature of unsecured and unfunded pension
liabilities held by CEOs makes them in line with outside creditors. In other words, CEOs with
greater pension benefits are expected to display lower levels of risk-seeking behavior since they are
exposed to similar default risk. From risk management literature a well-known benefit of hedging is
that hedging smooths firm performance, resulting in lower volatility of net income and cash flows
(Smith and Stulz 1985). The probability of bankruptcy or financial distress is considerably higher when
a firm’s earnings or cash flows are more volatile. As hedging smooths cash flows or/and net incomes,
bankruptcy risk will be reduced. Smith and Stulz (1985) suggest that hedging reduces a firm’s cash
flow volatility and consequently lowers the likelihood of bankruptcy. As a result, we conjecture that
firms granting the higher level of pension incentive to CEOs are more likely to engage in hedging
activities. Our first hypothesis is formulated as:

Hypothesis 1 (H1). Pension incentive has a positive impact on corporate hedging activity.

Given that our first hypothesis reveals an important relationship between pension incentive and
hedging behavior, there is another question that remains unclear, namely the interplay of pension
incentive and governance on this relation. To disentangle the relation between corporate hedging
and CEO pension incentive in the different context of governance, we propose our second hypothesis:
Pension incentive is a part of the optimal contract that is designed to mitigate agency costs of debt (e.g.,
risk-shifting) and agency costs of equity (effort-shirking). Under this logic, we would expect CEOs
with a larger amount of debt-like compensation relative to equity compensation (i.e., a higher CEO
pension relative leverage) to be more active hedgers of the “priced” risk. Since corporate hedging is
an outcome of an optimal compensation contract for CEOs, we anticipate that the predicted positive
relation between hedging and executives’ pension incentive should be observed in firms with strong
corporate governance. Thus, our second hypothesis can be offered as:

Hypothesis 2 (H2). The positive relation between pension incentive and the hedging activity should be more
pronounced for the firms with strong governance than those with poor governance.

To summarize, both hypotheses predict a positive relation between pension incentive and hedging.
The theory of optimal contracting further suggests that a positive relation should be more significant
for firms with strong corporate governance than for firms with weak governance. In contrast, however,
an opposite view would predict that the positive relation between hedging and pension incentive
should only hold for poorly governed firms where managers face fewer consequences from pursuing
corporate policies that are mainly motivated for self-interests. In the empirical tests below, we first
examine how pension incentive influences hedging, and further condition the relation on corporate
governance to verify the h of optimal contracting.

111
JRFM 2020, 13, 24

3. Sample Selection and Variable Construction

3.1. Sample Selection


The information of executive pension is collected from the Standard and Poors’ EXEUCOMP
database. In 2006, the SEC issued a new rule on the proxy disclosure of executive compensation,
requiring a detailed disclosure of pension and deferred compensation that are granted as a part
of executive compensation. Accordingly, EXEUCOMP extends the coverage on this disclosure,
which allows us to obtain top managers’ pension compensation from 2006 and afterwards. Therefore,
our initial sample includes all US firms whose CEOs are listed in EXEUCOMP from 2006 through
2015. Financial firms (with a SIC code of 6000 through 6999) and utility firms (with a SIC code of 4900
through 4999) are excluded as these firms are heavily regulated. We also eliminate observations with
missing or negative total assets or negative common equity. Such criteria generate the initial sample of
1936 firms with 16,936 firm-years.
Following the literature (Doukas and Pantzalis 2003; Graham and Rogers 2002; Campello et al. 2011),
we identify the multinational firms with ex ante exposure to currency risk if they report foreign assets,
foreign sales, or foreign income in the COMPUSTAT Geographic Segment databases, or they disclose
positive amounts of foreign currency adjustment, exchange rate effect, foreign income taxes, or deferred
foreign taxes in the annual COMPUSTAT database. We identify an MNC sample of 49,557 firm-year
observation associated with 8642 firms that have foreign operation activities from 2006 to 2015.1 Given the
fact of the different coverage between COMPUSTAT and EXECUCOMP (EXECUCOMP mainly covers the
large-cap firms), after merging two databases we obtain the final sample of 11,718 firm-year observations
associated with 1625 firms that have foreign operation activities from 2006 to 2015.
We retrieved the information of firm hedging activities through conducing a textual search in
10-K filings compiled in the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) EDGAR database. Specifically,
we performed the search based on a set of keywords including: currency derivative, currency swaps,
currency forwards, currency futures, currency options, currency contract, currency forward contract, exchange
forward, exchange future, exchange swap, exchange option, exchange contract, or forward exchange contract.
For each keyword found, we review the context in which the keyword appears in the report to confirm
the use of derivatives for hedging. We match the 10-K filing information with the financial data from
COMPUSTAT by the identifier of Central Index Key (CIK).

3.2. Measure of Active Management of Currency Risk


Based on the above sample, we examine the firms’ foreign currency risk management by examining
their hedging strategy against the currency risk. To retrieve hedging data, we perform a keyword
search for financial derivatives uses in 10-K filings compiled in the SEC EDGAR database. In this study,
we focus on foreign currency derivatives. The foreign currency derivatives are most commonly used
for hedging strategy by non-financial U.S. firms. Géczy et al. (1997) investigate the use of derivatives
for a sample of Fortune 500 non-financial firms in 1993 and find that currency derivatives are used
most frequently by corporation (52.1%). For each type of derivative, we use a set of relevant key words
as specified above for the corresponding currency derivative instruments. When a keyword is found,
we review the context in which the keyword appears in the report to confirm the use of derivatives for
hedging and to collect hedging information. We use two proxies from literature to describe corporate

1 We also follow Doukas and Pantzalis (2003) to consider the case that a firm might be subject to foreign currency risk due
to the competitive environment. To do so, we include the keywords related to foreign currency risk and market risk in
our textual searching program to read if firms explicitly state their foreign currency exposures in 10-K filings. We also
perform the additional check by identifying MNCs by setting the ratios of foreign assets, foreign sales or foreign income
greater than 10%. This classification is based on the requirements of the Statement of Financial Accounting Standard No. 14
(Financial Accounting Standards Board 1976), which defines a firm as a multinational company if it reports foreign assets and
foreign sales ratios of 10% or more. Both ways show the qualitatively consistent results.

112
JRFM 2020, 13, 24

hedging activities. Following Nance et al. (1993), Géczy et al. (1997), and Chen and King (2014) we
first use a dummy variable of hedging to represent if a firm implements hedging in a given year.
The hedging dummy variable takes the value of one if a firm holds a hedging position using any
types of foreign currency derivatives at the end of the fiscal year or has transactions involving one or
more foreign currency derivatives for the purpose of hedging during that year, and zero otherwise.
In addition, we use the notional amount of foreign currency derivatives in a given year to quantitatively
capture the intensity of hedging activity.

3.3. Measures of Pension Incentive


As one of the main variables of interest for our study, we follow the literature to construct the
measures of executive pension incentive. Sundaram and Yermack (2007) point out that retirement
compensation and deferred compensation are two primary benefits generating CEO pension incentives.
In the Execucomp database, the value of retirement compensation is defined to be the aggregate present
(actuarial) value of the executive’s accumulated benefits under the firm’s pension plans, and deferred
compensation is computed as the aggregate balance under the non-tax-qualified deferred compensation
plan. Pension incentive motivates the executives to stand with the creditors to claim residual value
during firm liquidations. Deferred compensation refers to the part of compensation which is deferred
under the voluntary act of the executives to pay at pre-specified dates in the future. Such two types
of compensation arrangements may work as the liability-like security to align CEO incentives with
creditors and to induce less risky firm policies. Consequently, we expect a positive relation between
hedging activity and executive pension incentive.
Although the equity-based components of CEO compensation have been documented in extant
literature to cause risk-taking behavior, liability-based compensation is expected to lead to managerial
risk aversion. Particularly, Jensen and Meckling (1976) conjecture that a compensation package with
equal-weighted equity and debt instruments is superior to 100% equity compensation. In contrast,
Edmans and Liu (2011) suggest granting executives equally weighted liability and equity compensation
is typically inefficient. With the component of pension, the executives’ wealth is aligned with
both the incidence of bankruptcy and firm liquidation value, which makes them less incentive to
transfer wealth from debtholders to stockholders and attenuates the stockholder-bondholder conflicts.
However, on the other hand, executives paid with excessive pension compensation might engage
in unnecessarily conservative policies and reallocate wealth from stockholders to debtholders. As a
result, to quantitatively capture the incentive of liability-based compensation relative to equity-based
compensation and also to consider the external influence of firm capital structure exposed on the
executives, we form the two main proxies to gauge the relative magnitude of pension incentive.
The first is relative pension leverage, which is defined as CEO pension leverage divided by firm
leverage. We also adopt a dummy variable, which takes the value of one if the relative pension
leverage is greater than one and zero otherwise, as a way to capture the possible non-linear relation
between dominant liability-based incentives and managerial risk attitude. These measures are also
suggested by Edmans and Liu (2011) and Wei and Yermack (2011). We speculate that firms with a
higher relative pension leverage have a higher likelihood of hedging and a larger notional amount of
hedging derivatives.

3.4. Control Variables


The motivations of corporate hedging have been well examined in the literature; thus, we follow
the previous studies to incorporate those important drivers of hedging as control variables. Below we
briefly discuss the motivation of including those control variables. We first control for CEO equity-based
compensation, which is based on stocks and options granted to the executives: One is the change in
stock price, which affects the value of stock holding and value of options, and the other is the volatility
of stock return, which mainly affects the value of options. Guay (1999) highlights the difference between
these two measures, with the former notated by delta and the latter by vega. More incentives from

113
JRFM 2020, 13, 24

delta expose more firm risk to managers and cause them risk averse, while compensation with vega
incentive helps offset the problem of underinvestment due to the risk aversion that arises from delta
incentive. In addition, Rogers (2002) argues that it has more explicitly economic sense to measure the
CEO risk-taking incentive per dollar of value-increasing incentives, namely, the ratio of vega to delta
(vega/delta). We expect a negative relation between the ratio of vega/delta and hedging since a stronger
risk-taking incentive from compensation makes executive more aggressive and are consequently less
likely to hedge.
Smith and Stulz (1985) suggest that hedging reduces the volatility of corporate performance,
resulting in a lower bankruptcy risk. The probability of bankruptcy or financial distress is considerably
higher when a firm’s leverage is higher, or when interest coverage or percentage of tangible assets
is lower. Therefore, there is a negative relation between interest coverage or tangible assets and
hedging, and a positive relation between leverage and hedging. Froot et al. (1993) theorize that
hedging can curtail the underinvestment problem (Myers 1977) when a firm faces potential growth
opportunities but suffers a high cost of external financing. Following Gay and Nam (1998), we use
the correlation between cash flow and firm investment to gauge the underinvestment problem and
expect a positive relation between this measure and hedging, indicating that firms with a severe
underinvestment problem tend to hedge. In the case of a progressive (convex) tax schedule, marginal
tax rate increases with taxable income. Hedging reduces the expected tax liability by smoothing taxable
income. Therefore, a positive relation between tax benefit and hedging is predicted. We adopt two
measures of tax benefit: a dummy variable indicating positive tax credit and a continuous variable of
tax convexity, which measures the expected tax savings from a 5% reduction in the volatility of taxable
income (Graham and Smith 1999). Cash holdings are regarded as a natural mechanism to alleviate the
negative impact of uncertainty. In addition, convertible bonds can be also used to reduce the agency
cost of debt. As both are potential alternatives of hedging, we include them and expect a negative
relation between these substitutes and hedging.

3.5. Descriptive Statistics


Our final sample contains 1625 firms and 11,718 firm-year observations. Table 1 provides the
summary statistics of hedging behavior, pension incentive, equity incentive and control variables for
this final sample. We find that in general hedging appears in 52% of the firm-years and the notional
amount of hedging position is on average USD 19.51 million, an equivalent of about 8.2% of total
assets for the full sample of firm-year observations, and rises to USD 260.7 million. These results are
consistent with the literature. For example, Campello et al. (2011) report that 50% of their sample firms
use foreign currency derivative to hedge and the positions of derivatives account for about 7.5% of
firm assets, respectively. As to the pension incentive variables, on average, CEOs are paid with USD
2.63 million of pension benefits. Such liability-based compensation constitutes 36% of CEOs’ total
compensation or 54% of equity-based compensation.
The variable of CEO pension relative leverage has a mean (median) value of 4.72 (0.30) in our
final sample. Less than half (39%) of the firm-year observations have this variable greater than
one. For equity incentive, the mean values of Delta incentive and Vega incentive are 0.14 and 0.01,
respectively. We also note that the ratio of Vega/Delta has an average value of 0.24, suggesting that
risk-taking incentive tied to stock volatility represents about a quarter of the value-increasing incentives
driven by stock price. Our sample firms on average have a moderate leverage ratio of 0.18 and a healthy
interest coverage ratio of 24.61. On average market-to-book ratio is 1.66 and the tangible assets ratio is
76%. The correlation between cash flow and firm investments has a mean (median) value of 0.41 (0.48).
In addition, the sample firms hold 18% assets in cash and 3% assets in convertible bond contracts.
We also find that 56% sample firm-year observations have a positive tax credit and the average tax
convexity is USD 2.13 million, both suggesting that the tax benefits associated with smoothing incomes
are considerably attractive. Finally, about 71% of the board members are from out of the firms to serve
as independent directors and 33% firm stakes are held by the institutional blockholders.

114
JRFM 2020, 13, 24

Table 1. Summary statistics.

N Mean Median SD P25 P75


Pension Incentive
CEO Pension (USD M) 11,718 2.63 0.00 7.59 0.00 0.80
CEO Pension/Total Compensation 11,718 0.36 0.00 0.84 0.00 0.17
CEO Pension/Equity Compensation 11,221 0.54 0.03 1.36 0.00 0.46
CEO Pension Relative Leverage 9488 7.72 0.30 31.69 0.00 2.76
Dummy (CEO Pension Relative Leverage >1) 9488 0.39 0.00 0.49 0.00 1.00
Hedging Variables
Currency Hedging Propensity (Dummy) 11,718 0.52 1.00 0.52 0.00 1.00
Currency Hedging Intensity (Notional Amount, USD M) 11,718 19.51 0.00 187.98 0.00 0.00
Currency Hedging Intensity (USD M, For Hedgers) 6128 260.70 71.31 639.91 21.55 197.73
CEO-Equity Incentive
Delta Incentive 11,718 0.14 0.06 0.23 0.03 0.18
Vega Incentive 11,718 0.01 0.01 0.02 0.00 0.02
Vega Incentive/Delta Incentive 11,718 0.24 0.11 0.31 0.01 0.37
Firm-related Characteristics
Total Assets (USD M) 11,718 8987.72 1739.99 33078.54 612.05 5512.01
Leverage 11,718 0.18 0.15 0.14 0.06 0.27
Market-to-book Ratio 11,718 1.66 1.38 0.75 1.11 1.94
Interest Coverage 11,718 24.61 8.43 42.74 3.84 20.51
Tangible Assets Ratio 11,718 0.76 0.80 0.21 0.54 0.96
Corr(Cash Flow, Investment) 11,718 0.41 0.48 0.42 0.15 0.76
Cash Holding 11,718 0.18 0.10 0.21 0.03 0.24
Convertible Bonds Ratio 11,718 0.03 0.00 0.06 0.00 0.00
Positive Tax Credit (Dummy) 11,718 0.56 1.00 0.50 0.00 1.00
Tax Convexity (MUSD) 11,718 2.13 1.72 1.67 0.70 3.40
Board Independence 11,718 0.71 0.80 0.14 0.43 0.93
Institutional Blockholder Ownership 11,718 0.33 0.30 0.08 0.15 0.57
This table shows summary statistics of pension incentive variables, hedging variables, equity incentive variables,
and firm-related variables for the sample of 11,718 firm-year observations from 2006 through 2015 with winsorization
at the 1th and 99th percentiles. All variable definitions are reported in Appendix A.

Moreover, we present the Pearson correlation matrix of hedging activity and incentive variables
in Table 2, which indicates a positive relation between hedging activity and CEO pension incentives.
For example, CEO Pension Relative Leverage is significantly positive correlated with both of hedging
measures, including hedging propensity (0.36) and hedging intensity (0.35). These relations suggest
that greater pension incentives may lead to more hedging activities. In addition, Delta incentive and
Vega incentive—these two equity-based incentives—are found to have a different correlation with
hedging activity. Note that Delta incentive has an insignificant correlation with hedging, while Vega
incentive has a significantly negative correlation with hedging, which is consistent with the literature
of equity compensation that granting equity, particularly stock options to managers should, ceteris
paribus, generate incentives to take more risks, or consequently hedge less.

Table 2. Correlations matrix between hedging and pension incentive.

Variables [1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6] [7] [8] [9] [10]
Foreign Currency Hedging Propensity [1] 1
Foreign Currency Hedging Intensity [2] 0.60 * 1
CEO Pension (USD M) [3] 0.32 * 0.26 * 1
CEO Pension/Total Compensation [4] 0.31 * 0.26 * 0.34 * 1
CEO Pension/Equity Compensation [5] 0.37 * 0.31 * 0.84 * 0.75 * 1
Ln (CEO Pension Relative Leverage) [6] 0.36 * 0.35 * 0.64 * 0.65 * 0.80 * 1
Dummy (Pension Relative Leverage > 1) [7] 0.36 * 0.35 * 0.67 * 0.66 * 0.82 * 0.88 * 1
Delta Incentive [8] 0.04 0.03 0.20 * 0.19 * 0.26 * 0.16 * 0.18 * 1
Vega Incentive [9] −0.07 * −0.07 * −0.11 −0.05 * −0.10 * −0.05 −0.06 * −0.06 * 1
Vega Incentive/Delta Incentive [10] −0.07 * −0.05 * −0.20 * −0.11 * −0.22 * −0.09 * −0.10 * −0.33 * −0.54 * 1
This table presents the Pearson correlation coefficients between hedging variables and CEO pension incentive for
the final sample from 2006 through 2015. * denotes statistical significance under 5% level. All variable definitions
are reported in Appendix A.

115
JRFM 2020, 13, 24

4. Model Specification and Empirical Results

4.1. Baseline Model


The primary purpose of this research is to investigate the influence of executive pension incentive
on firms’ active management of risk. Utilizing the final sample of multinational firms that are exposed
to foreign currency risk, we first implement the baseline model regressions of hedging activity on
a series of regressors, which contain the measures of pension incentives as the main independent
variables, equity incentive variables, the proxies for other hedging drivers discussed in Section 3.4,
and control for heterogeneity across industries and time. The baseline model is specified as follows:

Hedgei,t = α + β ∗ PensionIncentivei,t−1 + γ1 EquityIncentivei,t−1 + γ2 Leveragei,t−1 + γ3 InterestCovi,t−1


+γ4 Tangiblei,t−1 + γ5 Market/booki,t−1 + γ6 Corr(CF, Investment)i,t−1 + γ7 TaxDummyi,t−1
+γ8 TaxCovexityi,t−1 + γ9 CashHoldingi,t−1 + γ10 CovertibleBondi,t−1 + γ11 Ln(TotalAssets)i,t−1 (1)

47

10
+ Industryk + Yeart + εi,t
k =1 t=1

where hedging, the dependent variable, is measured by the dummy variable of hedging or the
continuous variable of hedging intensity. The measures of pension incentives include the logarithm of
CEO pension benefits in dollar amount, the ratio of CEO pension benefits to CEO total compensation,
the ratio of CEO pension benefits to CEO equity compensation. Additionally, following the literature,
the continuous variable of CEO pension relative leverage and the dummy variable of CEO pension
relative leverage greater than one are constructed.2 As to CEO equity-based compensation, the incentives
of stock and option compensation are gauged by Delta incentive, Vega incentive, and a ratio of Vega
incentive to Delta incentive.
To analyze the impact of pension incentives on the hedging adoption, we first perform a Probit
model analysis by regressing the dummy variable of hedging on the explanatory variables specified in
Equation (1). The results are reported in Panel A of Table 3. To facilitate the interpretation of regression
results, we report the incremental effects on the probability of implementing hedging strategy for
a one standard deviation change in continuous explanatory variables. However, the incremental
effects for the logarithmic variables (i.e., the logarithm of CEO pension relative leverage) or the
incremental effects for the dichotomous variables (i.e., the dummy variable of CEO pension relative
leverage greater than 1 or the dummy variable of positive tax credit) follow the traditional pattern.3
Z-values based on robust standard errors are reported in parentheses to test whether the coefficients
are equal to zero. Consistent with the theoretical predictions provided on the sign column, we first
observe strong evidence across models that CEO pension incentives have a significantly positive
influence on the decision of currency hedging. From Model 1 through Model 3, we look at the
effect of pension incentives by directly examining the dollar amount of CEO pension incentive,
the proportion of pension benefits to total compensation, and the proportion of pension benefits to
equity-based compensation. The coefficients of pension incentive in these models all show significant
and positive relations with corporate hedging decision. For example, a one-standard-deviation increase
in the overall pension benefits in dollar amount leads to an increase of 2.2% in hedging probability.
Similarly, a one-standard-deviation increase in pension proportion in CEO total compensation (equity

2 We also test the alternative measures, such as the CEO pension relative leverage and the squared CEO pension relative
leverage, and we find general consistent results. However, considering the potential skewness in the variable of CEO
pension relative leverage, we adopt the logarithm form of CEO pension relative leverage or use the conversion to a dummy
indicator of CEO pension relative leverage.
3 Specifically, for each of continuous explanatory variables we multiply the coefficients of the regressions by the standard
deviations of each independent variable, while for the logarithmic variables and the dichotomous variables we directly
report the coefficient of estimation.

116
JRFM 2020, 13, 24

compensation) increases the hedging probability by 6.5% (4.8%). More importantly, the effect of CEO
pension incentives on hedging probability is economically meaningful. In Model 4 the continuous
measure of CEO pension relative leverage has a positive and significant coefficient (0.006), suggesting
that a percentage increase in CEO pension relative leverage leads to about 1.6% increase in the likelihood
of hedging. In Model 5, we find when the CEO pension relative leverage is greater than one, that is,
when CEO’s wealth “leverage” is greater than firm’s capital “leverage”, the probability of corporate
hedging is higher by 20.9%.

Table 3. Baseline Models of Impact of Pension Incentive on Hedging.

Panel A: Probit Model of Hedging Propensity


Sign [1] [2] [3] [4] [5]
CEO Pension (USD M)) + 0.022 **
(2.545)
CEO Pension/Total Compensation + 0.065 ***
(2.628)
CEO Pension/Equity Compensation + 0.048 ***
(3.064)
Ln (CEO Pension Relative Leverage) + 0.016 **
(2.313)
Dummy (CEO Pension Relative Leverage >1) + 0.209 ***
(3.352)
Delta Incentive + 1.241 0.477 0.865 0.834 0.731
(0.891) (0.341) (0.620) (0.596) (0.523)
Vega Incentive − −0.273 ** −0.195 −0.376 *** −0.216 * −0.228 *
(−2.259) (−1.602) (−3.133) (−1.762) (−1.862)
Leverage + 1.066 *** 0.949 *** 0.908 *** 1.359 *** 1.336 ***
(4.947) (4.417) (4.242) (6.180) (6.092)
Interest Coverage − −0.002 *** −0.002 *** −0.002 *** −0.002 *** −0.002 ***
(−3.455) (−3.283) (−3.567) (−4.149) (−3.756)
Tangible Assets Ratio − −0.362 *** −0.388 *** −0.310 ** −0.353 ** −0.367 ***
(−2.630) (−2.808) (−2.260) (−2.567) (−2.666)
Market to Book + 0.029 0.035 0.037 0.011 0.013
(0.757) (0.922) (0.986) (0.297) (0.353)
Corr (CF, Investment) − −0.134 ** −0.132 ** −0.127 ** −0.133 ** −0.130 **
(−2.413) (−2.379) (−2.308) (−2.394) (−2.350)
Positive Tax Credit (Dummy) + 0.130 *** 0.137 *** 0.139 *** 0.129 *** 0.128 ***
(3.150) (3.307) (3.382) (3.123) (3.091)
Tax Convexity + −0.033 ** −0.028 ** −0.030 ** −0.029 ** −0.030 **
(−2.447) (−2.114) (−2.232) (−2.177) (−2.213)
Cash Holding − −0.456 *** −0.442 *** −0.509 *** −0.463 *** −0.424 ***
(−3.292) (−3.205) (−3.713) (−3.346) (−3.062)
Convertibles Bonds − −1.790 *** −1.504 *** −1.502 *** −1.516 *** −1.520 ***
(−4.433) (−3.728) (−3.739) (−3.767) (−3.775)
Log (Total Assets) + 0.348 *** 0.334 *** 0.358 *** 0.346 *** 0.345 ***
(20.278) (19.159) (20.733) (20.102) (19.973)
Intercept −2.508 *** −2.506 *** −2.676 *** −2.632 *** −2.635 ***
(−7.130) (−7.072) (−7.570) (−7.484) (−7.450)
Industry and Year Fixed Effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Number of Observations 11,718 11,718 11,221 9488 9488
Pseudo R2 0.369 0.369 0.371 0.393 0.391
Panel B: Tobit Model of Hedging Intensity
Sign [1] [2] [3] [4] [5]
CEO Pension (USD M) + 0.009 **
(2.238)
CEO Pension/Total Compensation + 0.035 *
(1.695)
CEO Pension/Equity Compensation + 0.027 **
(2.501)
Ln (CEO Pension Relative Leverage) + 0.004 *
(1.690)
Dummy (CEO Pension Relative Leverage >1) + 0.018 ***
(2.919)

117
JRFM 2020, 13, 24

Table 3. Cont.

Panel B: Tobit Model of Hedging Intensity


Sign [1] [2] [3] [4] [5]
Delta Incentive + 0.109 0.089 0.109 0.096 0.093
(1.412) (1.139) (1.393) (1.234) (1.203)
Vega Incentive − −0.011 −0.010 −0.018 ** −0.009 −0.010
(−1.500) (−1.364) (−2.350) (−1.213) (−1.255)
Leverage + 0.097 *** 0.090 *** 0.090 *** 0.110 *** 0.110 ***
(7.520) (7.033) (7.001) (8.328) (8.300)
Interest Coverage − −0.000 *** −0.000 *** −0.000 *** −0.000 *** −0.000 ***
(−5.631) (−5.521) (−5.721) (−6.133) (−5.858)
Tangible Assets Ratio − −0.024 *** −0.024 *** −0.022 *** −0.024 *** −0.024 ***
(−2.990) (−3.037) (−2.749) (−2.939) (−2.983)
Market to Book + 0.014 *** 0.014 *** 0.014 *** 0.013 *** 0.013 ***
(6.314) (6.498) (6.643) (5.911) (6.088)
Corr (CF, Investment) − −0.005 −0.004 −0.004 −0.004 −0.004
(−1.417) (−1.352) (−1.345) (−1.366) (−1.332)
Positive Tax Credit (Dummy) + 0.003 0.004 0.004 * 0.004 0.004
(1.403) (1.643) (1.771) (1.507) (1.482)
Tax Convexity + −0.001 * −0.001 −0.001 −0.001 −0.001
(−1.678) (−1.462) (−1.606) (−1.431) (−1.424)
Cash Holding − −0.058 *** −0.059 *** −0.062 *** −0.059 *** −0.058 ***
(−6.852) (−6.908) (−7.252) (−6.974) (−6.790)
Convertibles Bonds − −0.141 *** −0.130 *** −0.130 *** −0.128 *** −0.129 ***
(−5.589) (−5.126) (−5.118) (−5.068) (−5.062)
Log (Total Assets) + 0.016 *** 0.016 *** 0.017 *** 0.016 *** 0.016 ***
(17.086) (16.344) (17.511) (16.817) (16.638)
Intercept −0.192 *** −0.195 *** −0.201 *** −0.197 *** −0.198 ***
(−10.040) (−10.342) (−10.758) (−10.446) (−10.735)
/sigma 0.070 *** 0.070 *** 0.070 *** 0.070 *** 0.070 ***
(79.666) (79.860) (80.000) (79.687) (79.861)
Industry and Year Fixed Effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Number of Observations 6128 6128 5869 4962 4962
Pseudo R2 0.105 0.099 0.117 0.104 0.104
This table shows the results of baseline model regressions of hedging activity for the sample of 3492 firm-years from
2006 through 2010. Panel A reports the effects on the probability of hedging from Probit model for a one standard
deviation change in continuous explanatory variables (or for a change from zero to one in dummy explanatory
variable). In Panel B we apply Tobit model to regress the total notional amount of hedging positions scaled by book
value of total assets on the set of explanatory variables. We control for industry effects by using the Fama-French
48-industry classification and control for time effects by using year dummies. The robust standard errors are used to
calculate Z-Statistics (Probit model) or T-Statistics (Tobit model) that are reported in parentheses below estimates.
*, ** and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively.

For firm-related variables, the results are generally consistent with the literature. Leverage has
the positive impact on hedging, and both interest coverage and tangible assets are negatively related
with hedging. We also find a significantly negative association between hedging and the correlation
of cash flow and investments, suggesting that firms with a lower degree of matching between cash
flows and investment needs tend to hedge more. Furthermore, we find evidence to support the
potential tax benefits of hedging. For example, the dummy variable of positive tax credit has positive
and significant effect on hedging. Lastly, we find that cash holding and convertible bonds are both
negatively associated with hedging, indicating that they may serve as possible substitutes for hedging.
Liability-based incentive urges executives’ inclination to take risk-reduced investment, i.e., more
likely to hedge and increase the magnitude of hedging activity. To detect how pension incentive affects
the intensity of hedging, we turn to an investigation by applying the continuous measure of hedging
activity. Specifically, we replace hedging dummy variable in Equation (1) with the notional amount
of hedging positions scaled by the book value of total assets. We keep the same set of explanatory
variables. Given the nature of non-negative notional amount of hedging position, we adopt Tobit
regressions for our baseline models. The results are shown in Panel B of Table 3. Across the models,
we find a significantly positive relation between the notional amount of hedging and all measures of
pension incentives. The positive relations between pension incentive and hedging notional amount to
total assets ratio are detected from Models 1 through 4. For example, we observe from Model 1 that

118
JRFM 2020, 13, 24

firms increase about USD 81 million (=0.009 *USD 8987 million) when pension compensation increases
one-standard-derivation or equivalently USD 7.59 million. In addition, the coefficient (0.004) in Model
4 shows that for a one percent increase in CEO pension relative leverage, the hedging position rises
by 40 basis points of total assets (0.4%), and in other words, firms on average increase their hedging
positions by USD 35.95 million (=0.04%*USD 8987 million). Finally, this significant and positive
relation also holds in Models 5, when CEOs’ wealth leverage is greater than firms’ leverage, the ratio
of hedging position to total assets is higher by 1.8%. Considering that the average hedging notional
amount to total assets ratio is 2.9% (=USD 260.70/USD 8987), the change of the CEO pension relative
leverage from less than or equal to one to greater than one boosts the hedging intensity by more than
60% (1.8%/2.9% = 62%). Overall, the results of baseline models provide supportive evidence to our
first hypothesis.

4.2. Alternative Models to Control for Equity-Based Incentives


While the focus of this research is not about equity-based incentive, it may be arguable that
equity-based incentive is designed differently for the sample firms that are more/less likely to do
currency risk management. From our baseline models, we find that Vega incentive is negatively
associated with hedging decision, but an insignificant impact of Delta incentive on hedging decision is
also observed. Although the results of equity incentives seem mixed from the theoretical predictions,
these discordant results are also reported in the literature. For instance, Guay (1999) illustrates that
shareholders should consider the slope and convexity of the relation between executives’ compensation
and firm performance, where slope (Delta) refers to the sensitivity of executives’ compensation to
stock price and convexity (Vega) refers to the sensitivity of executives’ compensation to stock return
volatility. As a result, granting equity compensation to executives should, ceteris paribus, generate
incentives to take more risks, or equivalently hedge less. Knopf et al. (2002) provide the evidence to
support the positive association between hedging and the sensitivity of a manager’s equity wealth to
stock price and the negative association between hedging and the sensitivity of a manager’s equity
wealth to stock return volatility. Rajgopal and Shevlin (2002) report a significantly negative relation
between risk-taking incentives (Vega) and commodity hedging for a sample of gas and oil firms.
But in a similar setting, Rogers (2002) only find weak evidence of Delta and Vega incentives
which affect the hedging decision. Accordingly, Rogers (2002) proposes economic interpretation
of the ratio of Vega to delta should be more intuitive because it measures the CEO risk-taking
incentive per dollar of value-increasing incentives from option and stock holdings that delta and Vega
measure managerial motivation from “value-creating” and “risk-taking” incentives, respectively. On
the other hand, Lewellen (2006) demonstrates that the “moneyness” of stock options has different
impacts on managerial risk attitude. In particular, those in-the-money options discourage risk-taking.
Meanwhile, as emphasized by Carpenter (2000) equity compensation does not necessarily result in more
risk-taking behavior because it makes executives’ wealth more vulnerable to stock price fluctuation.
Hirshleifer and Suh (1992) also discuss the side effect of equity compensation, which encourages
executives to work hard but also affects their attitude toward project risks, ending up with less
risk-taking. Gerakos (2010) provides some evidence that executives granted with more pension benefits
are paid less on other dimensions of compensation.
To ensure that the results of the baseline model are not vulnerable to the potential inconsistent
impact of equity-based incentive, we perform the alternative models to recognize the evidence from
Carpenter (2000). The results of the alternative models are shown in Table 4 and report the regressions
by adopting the ratio of Vega incentive to Delta incentive. As expected, we find the significant and
negative coefficients of this variable across the models. For example, the ratio of Vega incentive to
Delta incentive are negatively associated with both hedging propensity in Model 3 of Panel A (−0.226)
and hedging intensity in Model 3 of Panel B (−0.028). With this new control variable in Table 4,
the coefficients of pension incentive measures keep positive. Notably, the effect of pension incentive
on hedging propensity and on hedging intensity are also statistically significant, consistent with the

119
JRFM 2020, 13, 24

finding in Table 3. To this end, the alternative models help confirm that hedging activity is plausibly
affected by the executive pension incentive.

Table 4. Alternative Models of Impact of Pension Incentive on Hedging.

Panel A: Probit Model of Hedging Propensity


Sign [1] [2] [3] [4] [5]
CEO Pension (USD M) + 0.024 **
(2.533)
CEO Pension/Total Compensation (%) + 0.066 **
(2.612)
CEO Pension/Equity Compensation (%) + 0.047 ***
(3.012)
Ln (CEO Pension Relative Leverage) + 0.017 **
(2.256)
Dummy (CEO Pension Relative Leverage >1) + 0.204 ***
(3.218)
Vega Incentive/Delta Incentive − −0.154 ** −0.135 ** −0.226 *** −0.156 ** −0.157 **
(−2.256) (−1.975) (−2.809) (−2.278) (−2.291)
Firm-related Characteristics Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Industry and Year Fixed Effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Number of Observations 11,718 11,718 11,221 9488 9488
Pseudo R2 0.368 0.368 0.370 0.392 0.391
Panel B: Tobit Model of Hedging Intensity
Sign [1] [2] [3] [4] [5]
CEO Pension (USD M) + 0.009 **
(2.401)
CEO Pension/Total Compensation (%) + 0.038 *
(1.732)
CEO Pension/Equity Compensation (%) + 0.030 **
(2.503)
Ln (CEO Pension Relative Leverage) + 0.005 *
(1.740)
Dummy (CEO Pension Relative Leverage >1) + 0.019 ***
(3.172)
Vega Incentive/Delta Incentive − −0.021 −0.020 −0.028 ** −0.026 ** −0.030 **
(−1.496) (−1.618) (−2.222) (−2.061) (−2.395)
Firm-related Characteristics Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Industry and Year Fixed Effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Number of Observations 6128 6128 5869 4962 4962
Pseudo R2 0.099 0.102 0.105 0.099 0.117
This table shows the results of the alternative models of pension incentive on hedging activity by recognizing a
different measure of equity incentives (the ratio of Vega incentive relative to Delta incentive). Panel A reports
the effects on the probability of hedging from Probit model for a one standard deviation change in continuous
explanatory variables (or for a change from zero to one in dummy explanatory variable). In Panel B we apply
Tobit model to regress the total notional amount of hedging positions scaled by book value of total assets on the
set of explanatory variables. We control for industry effects by using the Fama-French 48-industry classification
and control for time effects by using year dummies. The robust standard errors are used to calculate Z-Statistics
(Probit model) or T-Statistics (Tobit model) that are reported in parentheses below estimates. *, ** and *** denote
significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively.

4.3. Robustness Checks for Endogeneity


In this section, we tend to identify the causal drive of the pension incentive to the hedging
activity. As in most research in business, endogeneity may cause a concern in this study. While, by
and large, the relation between pension incentive and hedging is well supported by theoretical work,
it is relatively challenging to capture the causal effect because compensation contracts and hedging
practices can be determined by unobservable firm-related and other factors.

120
JRFM 2020, 13, 24

We employ the approach of instrumental variables (IV) regression, where two instruments (firm age
and CEO age) are used for each of the pension incentive measures in regressions.4 In particular, treated
as endogenous variable, pension incentive is regressed on a set of all other explanatory variables
plus firm age and CEO age as instruments in the first stage. Predicted values of pension incentive
are computed from the first-stage regression and used in the second-stage regression as specified in
Equation (1).
We report the results in Table 5. In Model 5 of Panel A, as the dependent variable (hedging
dummy) and the endogenous independent variable (the dummy variable of CEO pension relative
leverage greater than one) are both dichotomous variables, we apply the Bivariate Probit model.
Specifically, we simultaneously estimate a system in which the first and second stage regressions are
both Probit models (Greene 2004). For other models of the hedging dummy regressions, we apply the
IV-Probit model in which the first stage is an OLS (Ordinary Least Squares) model and the second
stage is a Probit model. For the models in Panel B where the dependent variable is hedging notional
amount scaled by the firm size (a continuous nonnegative variable), we apply IV-Tobit model as a
regular IV regressions with truncated continuous dependent variable, namely, the first stage is an
OLS model and the second stage is a Tobit model. Panel B of Table 5 reports the second stage results
of IV regressions on hedging dummy and hedging notional amount, respectively. Consistent with
our conjecture, the positive relation between hedging and pension incentive remain robust after
controlling for potential endogeneity. Meanwhile, we find that the impact of equity-based incentives
also shows evidence consistent with theoretical predications. For example, in Model 5 of Panel A
(the hedging dummy regression), the coefficient of Vega incentive relative to Delta incentive is negative
and significant the 5% level. In the regressions of hedging notional amount, the coefficient of this
variable is found negative and significant at the 1% level in Models 5 of Panel B.

Table 5. Instrumental variables regressions.

Panel A: Instrumental Variable Regression of Debt Incentives on Hedging Propensity


Sign [1] [2] [3] [4] [5]
CEO Pension (USD M) + 1.410 ***
(3.463)
CEO Pension/Total Compensation (%) + 2.386 ***
(3.951)
CEO Pension/Equity Compensation (%) + 3.015 ***
(3.984)
Ln (CEO Pension Relative Leverage) + 0.251 ***
(3.224)
Dummy (CEO Pension Relative Leverage >1) + 0.959 ***
(3.542)
Vega Incentive/Delta Incentive − −1.028 ** −0.201 −0.083 ** −0.225 −0.142 **
(−2.233) (−0.954) (−2.086) (−0.895) (−2.067)
Leverage + 1.843 *** 0.940 *** 0.828 *** 2.093 *** 1.939 ***
(4.911) (4.296) (3.768) (4.884) (5.366)
Interest Coverage − −0.001 −0.001 ** −0.002 *** −0.002 *** −0.002 ***
(−0.728) (−2.422) (−2.921) (−4.239) (−3.374)
Tangible Assets Ratio − −0.833 *** −0.521 *** −0.388 *** −0.478 *** −0.484 ***
(−3.553) (−3.431) (−2.727) (−3.110) (−3.215)
Market to Book + −0.039 0.028 0.038 −0.031 −0.017
(−0.750) (0.715) (0.999) (−0.701) (−0.415)
Corr (CF, Investment) − −0.130 * −0.127 ** −0.110 * −0.129 ** −0.125 **
(−1.875) (−2.255) (−1.954) (−2.272) (−2.215)
Positive Tax Credit (Dummy) + 0.071 0.139 *** 0.164 *** 0.123 *** 0.120 ***
(1.282) (3.308) (3.830) (2.906) (2.857)

4 We recheck the results by trying the lagged variable approach, with which the endogenous variable of pension incentive is
lagged to help in mitigating the potential bias of endogeneity. We observe the positive relation between hedging activity and
pension incentive unchanged.

121
JRFM 2020, 13, 24

Table 5. Cont.

Panel A: Instrumental Variable Regression of Debt Incentives on Hedging Propensity


Sign [1] [2] [3] [4] [5]
Tax Convexity + −0.013 −0.017 −0.016 −0.017 −0.019
(−0.740) (−1.206) (−1.098) (−1.132) (−1.344)
Cash Holding − 0.155 −0.306 ** −0.420 *** −0.307 * −0.247
(0.579) (−2.010) (−2.943) (−1.903) (−1.512)
Convertibles Bonds − −2.086 *** −1.162 *** −0.938 ** −1.209 *** −1.241 ***
(−4.007) (−2.662) (−2.070) (−2.757) (−2.888)
Log (Total Assets) + 0.152 ** 0.270 *** 0.304 *** 0.288 *** 0.292 ***
(2.209) (8.314) (12.000) (8.540) (9.623)
Intercept −0.948 −2.173 *** −2.534 *** −2.391 *** −2.454 ***
(−1.380) (−5.587) (−6.949) (−6.296) (−6.620)
p-value of Smith-Blundell Test of Exogeneity 0.114 0.189 0.237 0.012 0.236
p-value of Amemiya-Lee-Newey Over-identification Test 0.523 0.512 0.469 0.305 0.363
Industry and Year Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Number of Observations 11,718 11,718 11,221 9488 9488
Panel B: Instrumental Variable Regression of Debt Incentives on Hedging Intensity
Sign [6] [7] [8] [9] [10]
CEO Pension (USD M) + 0.025 **
(2.545)
CEO Pension/Total Compensation (%) + 0.052 ***
(2.826)
CEO Pension/Equity Compensation (%) + 0.048 **
(2.231)
Ln (CEO Pension Relative Leverage) + 0.005 **
(2.158)
Dummy (CEO Pension Relative Leverage >1) + 0.021 **
(2.449)
Vega Incentive/Delta Incentive − −0.002 * −0.005 −0.003 ** −0.003 * −0.004 ***
(−1.681) (−0.713) (−1.963) (−1.924) (−2.772)
Leverage + 0.070 *** 0.053 *** 0.052 *** 0.078 *** 0.076 ***
(7.093) (7.571) (7.349) (5.833) (6.673)
Interest Coverage − −0.000 *** −0.000 *** −0.000 *** −0.000 *** −0.000 ***
(−4.693) (−5.891) (−6.457) (−7.211) (−6.646)
Tangible Assets Ratio − −0.028 *** −0.024 *** −0.020 *** −0.022 *** −0.022 ***
(−4.563) (−4.888) (−4.502) (−4.579) (−4.675)
Market to Book + 0.006 *** 0.008 *** 0.008 *** 0.006 *** 0.007 ***
(4.413) (5.983) (6.306) (4.389) (4.981)
Corr (CF, Investment) − −0.002 −0.002 −0.002 −0.002 −0.002
(−1.198) (−1.190) (−1.085) (−1.224) (−1.171)
Positive Tax Credit (Dummy) + 0.001 0.002 0.003 * 0.002 0.002
(0.475) (1.576) (1.926) (1.296) (1.254)
Tax Convexity + −0.001 ** −0.001 ** −0.001 *** −0.001 ** −0.001 ***
(−2.377) (−2.528) (−2.784) (−2.493) (−2.633)
Cash Holding − −0.019 *** −0.027 *** −0.030 *** −0.027 *** −0.026 ***
(−2.617) (−5.005) (−5.926) (−4.931) (−4.610)
Convertibles Bonds − −0.092 *** −0.072 *** −0.072 *** −0.074 *** −0.074 ***
(−6.063) (−4.868) (−4.725) (−4.968) (−5.082)
Log (Total Assets) + 0.006 *** 0.007 *** 0.008 *** 0.008 *** 0.008 ***
(3.266) (7.220) (11.051) (7.407) (8.252)
Intercept −0.072 *** −0.092 *** −0.101 *** −0.096 *** −0.098 ***
(−3.970) (−7.216) (−8.481) (−7.750) (−8.093)
p-value of Smith-Blundell Test of Exogeneity 0.243 0.365 0.328 0.068 0.202
p-value of Amemiya-Lee-Newey Over-identification test 0.322 0.317 0.125 0.242 0.387
Industry and Year Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Number of Observations 6128 6128 5869 4962 4962
This table reports the results of the robustness checks based instrumental variables (IV) models. The dependent
variables are hedging dummy in Panel A and are hedging intensity (the ratio of total notional amount of hedging
positions scaled by the book value of total assets) in Panel B. The two-stage regressions with a Probit model in
the second stage are applied on Panel A and the two-stage regressions with a Tobit model in the second stage are
applied on Panel B, respectively. We control for industry effects by using the Fama-French 48-industry classification
and control for time effects by using year dummies. The robust standard errors are used in all models in Panel A to
calculate Z-Statistics or T-Statistics that are reported in parentheses below estimates. *, ** and *** denote significance
at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively.

122
JRFM 2020, 13, 24

Roberts and Whited (2013) suggest that the IV regression model is only as good as the choice
of instrumental variables. We select the instruments by considering both its relevance with pension
incentives and irrelevance with hedging. More specifically, the relevance rule requires a non-zero
correlation between an instrument and the endogenous variable of pension incentive, and the irrelevance
rule indicates that the selected instrument must not be correlated with the unobserved determinants of
hedging. Existing literature on pension benefits suggests that CEO age and firm age are closely related
to the granting of retirement plans (Liu et al. 2014; Cassell et al. 2012; Sundaram and Yermack 2007).
The firm age is used as one of instrumental variables due to the business life-cycle reason. Firms usually
do not offer pension or other fringe benefit plans when they start in business, and gradually adopt them
afterwards. Brown and Medoff (2003) document that the firms that have been in business longer are
more likely to implement pension plans. With the consideration of little conclusive theory in classical
economics for the connection between hedging activity and biological age, CEO age is used as another
variable in the set of instruments. However, we are aware of some evidence in the recent literature
that reports the impact of executives’ age on corporate polices. For example, Serfling (2014) suggests
that younger CEOs generally have a more aggressive leadership style. Jenter and Lewellen (2015) and
Yim (2013) show that younger CEOs are more likely to engage in risky acquisitions. Croci et al. (2017)
find a high likelihood of being a hedger from senior CEOs. When biological age connects to executives’
psychological or physiological situation, the CEOs’ age may not be able to introduce exogenous
variations to capture the causal impact of pension incentive on firms’ hedging policy.5
But to be more prudent, we use the econometric methods to test the verification of IV model and
instruments. We employ the Smith-Blundell test of exogeneity to test the null hypothesis that there is
no serious endogeneity in the model, and the Amemiya-Lee-Newey over-identification test to test the
null hypothesis that there is no over-identification problem. Across the models, we find that the null
hypothesis of Smith-Blundell test of exogeneity cannot be rejected in all Models except Model 4 for the
hedging propensity and hedging intensity, indicating that a problem of endogeneity is not extensively
present. Meanwhile, from models 1 through 4 for both the hedging propensity and hedging intensity
regressions, the p-value in the Amemiya–Lee–Newey over-identification test is much greater than 10%,
indicating that the instruments are chosen appropriately and there is no over-identification problem in
our models. To summarize, the robustness checks confirm that the positive impact of pension incentive
on hedging activities detected in baseline models is unlikely to be driven by the endogeneity issue.

4.4. The Role of Pension Incentive in Different Governance Environment


From the above empirical analyses a significant and positive relation between hedging and pension
incentive has been documented in baseline and robustness models, but another important question,
which relates to a considerable debate regarding the nature of incentive design as aforementioned, is
how this positive relation varies in the different situations of corporate governance. As a component
of compensation contract, pension incentive itself is closely associated with governance mechanism.
Lee and Tang (2011) document that CEO pension benefits are associated with corporate governance.
They find that entrenched managers, proxied by a small board, CEO duality, and protection
from anti-takeover provisions, are more likely to obtain higher compensation of pension benefits.
Halford and Qiu (2012) test whether firms that are likely to face more severe agency problems of debt

5 With this caveat in mind, we seek the alternative instruments by trying the federal and state personal tax rates
(Anantharaman et al. 2014; Kim and Lu 2011), as one can reasonably assume that those highest-paid CEOs would
have different preference towards the compensation packages when they are subject to the different personal income tax
brackets. In addition, we also utilize a regulatory reform, Pension Protection Act in 2006, which attempts to strengthen
the pension system, protects retirement accounts and makes pension benefits more attractive. As the legislation provides
greater incentives to firms and employees in investing in pension plans, this exogenous change of law should have no
implicit impacts on the hedging decision. Although the tests by using the above alternative sets of instruments show the
qualitatively consistent results, we acknowledge that the potential issue of endogeneity cannot be entirely resolved given the
lack of perfect instruments, and therefore the causality results based on the IV models should be interpreted with caution.

123
JRFM 2020, 13, 24

provide more debt incentives. Inconsistent with the agency theory’s prediction they find evidence that
firms with lower default risk use more pension plans, and little evidence to support the hypothesis
that pension incentive is used to alleviate the agency costs of debt.
In Section 2, our second hypothesis (H2) predicts the different relations between corporate
hedging and CEO liability-based compensation which are conditional upon the strength of corporate
governance. Recall that our first hypothesis proposes a positive relation between hedging and pension
incentive. However, the optimal contracting hypothesis predicts that the positive relation should be
more significant for firms with strong corporate governance than for firms with weak governance.
Thus, in this section we test how the influence of pension incentive on hedging is contingent on the
mechanism of corporate governance. In Table 6, we present the regressions of three baseline models
but in the subsamples categorized by the median value of board independence.
Following the same steps, we report the incremental effect on the probability of hedging for a
one-standard-deviation change in the continuous explanatory variables (or for a change from zero
to one for the dummy explanatory variables). Furthermore, we apply the Chow test to examine the
difference in coefficients between the two subsamples. Panel A reports the results for the hedging
propensity regressions. In particular, the influence of pension incentive on hedging is more pronounced
for the firms in the above-median group than in the below-median group (0.069 vs. 0.04 in Model 1 and
Model 2). In other words, the effect of pension incentives on hedging is more prominent for firms with
strong shareholder power. The differences are also economically significant based on the predicted
probabilities. Specifically, Model 5 and Model 3 show that when CEOs’ wealth leverage is greater than
firms’ leverage, it will cause a 44% (=0.287/0.650) rise in predicated probability of hedging for the firms
in the above-median group of independent board directors, but only a 16% (=0.124/0.783) rise for the
firms in the below-median group of independent board directors. Panel B of Table 6 reports the results
based on the notional value of hedging, further confirming the finding.
Similarly, we conduct the subsample comparison by splitting firms into groups with the median
value of blockholder ownership and report the results in Table 7. In Models 1 and 2 of Panel A, we
find that a one-standard-deviation increase in pension incentive in firms with higher blockholder
ownership will increase 7.3% of hedging probability, more than double the increase (2.8%) in the
subsample with lower blockholder ownership. A similar difference with statistical significance is also
found in Panel B of Table 7. For example, the coefficient of the dummy variable of CEO pension relative
leverage greater than 1 is substantially larger in the subsample with low blockholder ownership than
that in the subsample with high blockholder ownership (0.028 vs. 0.016 in Model 5 and Model 6)
with significance at the 5% level. As a result, the above evidence lends strong support for the optimal
contracting hypothesis (our second hypothesis). The pension incentive is governed to expose more
influence on executives’ decisions, and this risk-reducing function is induced more when firms have
strong governance, but does not fully perform in the case of weak governance.

124
Table 6. The influence of pension incentive on hedging by board independence.

Panel A: The Influence of Pensive Incentive on Hedging Propensity by Board Independence


(> (< (> (< (> (<
Sign Diff Diff Diff
Median) Median) Median) Median) Median) Median)
JRFM 2020, 13, 24

Chow Chow Chow


[1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6]
test test test
CEO Pension/Equity Compensation (%) + 0.069 *** 0.040 0.029 ***
(5.249) (1.048) (2.907)
Ln (CEO Pension Relative Leverage) + 0.018 ** 0.008 * 0.009 *
(2.440) (1.893) (1.736)
Dummy (CEO Pension Relative Leverage >1) + 0.287 *** 0.124 0.163 **
(3.700) (1.303) (2.302)
Firm-related Characteristics Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Industry and Year Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Number of Observations 5455 5455 2216 2217 2216 2217
Pseudo R2 0.435 0.422 0.472 0.465 0.433 0.439
Panel B: The Influence of Pensive Incentive on Hedging Intensity by Board Independence
(> (< (> (< (> (<
Sign Diff Diff Diff
Median) Median) Median) Median) Median) Median)
Chow Chow Chow

125
[1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6]
test test test
CEO Pension/Equity Compensation (%) + 0.039 *** 0.019 0.020 ***
(3.187) (0.716) (3.661)
Ln (CEO Pension Relative Leverage) + 0.005 *** 0.003 0.002 ***
(3.875) (1.218) (2.586)
Dummy (CEO Pension Relative Leverage >1) + 0.020 *** 0.015 * 0.005 ***
(5.644) (1.918) (3.266)
Firm-related Characteristics Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Industry and Year Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Number of Observations 2867 2867 2413 2414 2413 2414
Pseudo R2 0.186 0.181 0.135 0.133 0.138 0.138
This table reports the regressions for the subsamples categorized by board independence. The Probit Model is applied in Panel A where the dependent variable is hedging dummy,
and Tobit models are used in Panel B where the dependent variable is the ratio of total notional amount of hedging positions scaled by the book value of total assets. We control for
industry effects by using the Fama-French 48-industry and control for time effects by using year dummies. The robust standard errors are to calculate Z-Statistics or T-Statistics reported
in parentheses below estimates. *, ** and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively.
Table 7. The influence of pension incentive on hedging by blockholder ownership.

Panel A: The Influence of Pensive Incentive on Hedging Propensity by Blockholder Ownership.


(> (< (> (< (> (<
Sign Diff Diff Diff
Median) Median) Median) Median) Median) Median)
JRFM 2020, 13, 24

Chow Chow Chow


[1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6]
test test test
CEO Pension/Equity Compensation (%) + 0.073 *** 0.028 0.045 ***
(4.875) (1.568) (2.788)
Ln (CEO Pension Relative Leverage) + 0.020 ** 0.014 * 0.006
(2.495) (1.949) (1.614)
Dummy (CEO Pension Relative Leverage >1) + 0.251 *** 0.132 0.119 *
(2.202) (1.072) (1.893)
Firm-related Characteristics Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Industry and Year Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Number of Observations 5455 5455 2216 2217 2216 2217
Pseudo R2 0.431 0.430 0.464 0.468 0.419 0.418
Panel B: The Influence of Pensive Incentive on Hedging Intensity by Blockholder Ownership
(> (< (> (< (> (<
Sign Diff Diff Diff
Median) Median) Median) Median) Median) Median)

126
Chow Chow Chow
[1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6]
test test test
CEO Pension/Equity Compensation (%) + 0.043 *** 0.021 0.021 **
(2.667) (0.762) (2.348)
Ln (CEO Pension Relative Leverage) + 0.007 *** 0.002 * 0.004 **
(2.605) (1.690) (2.351)
Dummy (CEO Pension Relative Leverage >1) + 0.028 *** 0.016 * 0.012 **
(2.143) (1.729) (2.003)
Firm-related Characteristics Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Industry and Year Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Number of Observations 2867 2867 2414 2413 2414 2413
Pseudo R2 0.187 0.181 0.134 0.134 0.138 0.137
This table reports the regressions for the subsamples categorized by blockholder ownership. The Probit Model is applied in Panel A where the dependent variable is hedging dummy,
and Tobit models are used in Panel B where the dependent variable is the ratio of total notional amount of hedging positions scaled by the book value of total assets. We control for
industry effects by using the Fama-French 48-industry and control for time effects by using year dummies. The robust standard errors are to calculate Z-Statistics or T-Statistics reported
in parentheses below estimates. *, ** and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively.
JRFM 2020, 13, 24

5. The Influence of Pension Incentive on Value of Corporate Hedging


Tan and Young (2016) show that executives motivated by the long-term incentive pay, such as
retirement plans may engage in behaviors unfavorable to shareholders. To provide a novel insight
into the role of pension incentive in terms of value creation, we adopt Faulkender and Wang’s (2006)
methodology to assess the marginal value of hedging as a function of CEO pension incentives. We first
treat hedging motivated by pension incentive as a beneficial driver to shareholders. Therefore, in
addition to the firm characteristics specified in Faulkender and Wang (2006), we include the change of
hedging activity in the regression model to quantify the value of hedging:

ΔCi,t ΔE ΔNA ΔRD ΔI


ri,t − RBi,t = γ0 + β ∗ ΔHedgei,t + γ1 Li,t + γ2 M + γ3 Mi,t−1
i,t
+ γ4 Mi,t−1i,t + γ5 Mi,t−1i,t + γ6 Mi,t−1
i,t
i,t−1

10 (2)
ΔD NF
+γ7 Mi,t−1
i,t
+ γ8 Mi,t−1
i,t
+ Yeart + εi,t
t=1

where the dependent variable ri,t is the annual excess equity return calculated from a firm i’s stock
return over year t − 1 to year t, net of RBr,t , the return of Fama and French (1993) size and book-to-market
matched portfolio from year t − 1 to year t. ΔXi,t is the notation for the one-year change of variable X
for firm i over year t − 1 to year t, i.e., Xt − Xt−1 ; ΔHedge,t represents the hedging propensity (HP) or
change of hedging intensity (HI). Mi,t is market value of equity at time t; Ci,t is cash plus marketable
securities; Ei,t is earnings before extraordinary items plus interest, deferred tax credits, and investment
tax credits; NAi,t is total assets minus cash holdings; RDi,t is research and development expense (which
is set to zero if missing); Ii,t is interest expense; Di,t is common dividends; NFi,t is total equity issuances
minus repurchases plus debt issuances minus debt redemption; Li,t is the ratio of long-term debt plus
debt in current liabilities divided by the market value of assets at time t. The regression results of
Equation (2) are reported in Table 8. We use three measures of pension incentive to separate the sample.

Table 8. The impact of pension incentives on the value of hedging.

Panel A: The Value of Hedging Propensity by Pension Incentive


CEO Pension/Equity CEO Pension Relative CEO Pension Relative
Compensation (%) Leverage Leverage
Full (High (Low (High (Low
Sample >1 <1
Group) Group) Group) Group)
[1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6]
HPi,t 1.015 * 1.039 ** 1.007 1.022 * 1.018 1.025 ** 1.017
1.682 (1.973) (0.390) (1.724) (1.018) (2.367) (0.953)
Li,t −0.796 *** −0.661 *** −0.765 *** −0.841 *** −0.607 *** −0.726 *** −0.746 ***
(−10.227) (−7.162) (−10.165) (−10.503) (−7.618) (−8.798) (−9.344)
ΔCi,t /Mi,t−1 0.949 *** 1.052 *** 0.847 *** 0.974 *** 0.900 *** 1.026 *** 0.850 ***
(6.106) (7.064) (6.827) (7.270) (6.725) (7.523) (6.470)
ΔEi,t /Mi,t−1 0.865 *** 0.904 *** 0.935 *** 0.904 *** 0.961 *** 0.802 *** 1.106 ***
(9.872) (8.540) (11.097) (10.382) (9.746) (9.098) (11.430)
ΔNAi,t /Mi,t−1 −0.001 0.007 −0.081 * −0.076 −0.018 −0.026 −0.110 **
(−0.023) (0.105) (−1.758) (−1.566) (−0.329) (−0.526) (−2.029)
ΔRDi,t /Mi,t−1 0.301 3.247 −2.040 3.161 −2.744 2.641 −1.847
(0.184) (1.416) (−1.102) (1.502) (−1.385) (1.219) (−0.952)
ΔIi,t /Mi,t−1 −0.019 −1.087 −0.920 1.937 −3.842 *** −1.291 −0.849
(−0.994) (−0.612) (−0.755) (1.436) (−2.666) (−0.926) (−0.606)
ΔDi,t /Mi,t−1 3.053 * 2.649 4.122 −0.013 9.081 * −0.058 7.085
(1.787) (0.611) (0.877) (−0.003) (1.811) (−0.014) (1.402)
NFi,t /Mi,t−1 0.135 *** 0.098 *** 0.129 *** 0.137 *** 0.092 *** 0.094 *** 0.137 ***
(4.719) (3.678) (6.575) (6.319) (4.150) (4.270) (6.257)
Intercept 0.169 ** 0.316 ** 0.224 0.046 0.037 0.336 * 0.149
(2.373) (2.072) (0.783) (0.245) (0.129) (1.765) (0.523)
Year Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
N of Obs. 11,718 5610 5611 4744 4744 3710 5778
Adjusted R2 0.153 0.200 0.264 0.270 0.211 0.233 0.250

127
JRFM 2020, 13, 24

Table 8. Cont.

Panel B: The Value of Hedging Intensity by Pension Incentive


CEO Pension/Equity CEO Pension Relative CEO Pension Relative
Compensation (%) Leverage Leverage
Full (High (Low (High (Low
Sample >1 <1
Group) Group) Group) Group)
[1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6]
HIi,t−1 /Mi,t−1 0.312 0.374 * 0.291 * 0.286 * 0.370 0.326 * 0.289 *
1.518 (1.921) (1.789) (1.852) (0.932) (1.936) (1.831)
ΔHIi,t /Mi,t−1 −0.033 0.694 −0.169 −0.234 0.730 −0.092 0.065
(−1.343) (0.924) (−0.216) (−0.337) (0.841) (−0.137) (0.072)
(HIi,t−1 /Mi,t−1 )*(ΔHii,t /Mi,t−1 ) 0.114 * 0.204 ** 0.059 * 0.143 ** −0.013 0.141 *** 0.129
(1.873) (2.328) (1.934) (2.413) (−0.079) (2.890) (0.750)
Li,t −0.811 *** −0.764 *** −0.850 *** −0.939 *** −0.684 *** −0.834 *** −0.800 ***
(−9.091) (−8.200) (−11.313) (−11.503) (−8.602) (−9.984) (−9.983)
ΔCi,t /Mi,t−1 1.126 *** 1.045 *** 0.822 *** 0.962 *** 0.889 *** 1.018 *** 0.836 ***
(7.253) (7.087) (6.676) (7.248) (6.698) (7.558) (6.393)
ΔEi,t /Mi,t−1 0.937 *** 0.877 *** 0.899 *** 0.861 *** 0.942 *** 0.770 *** 1.071 ***
(8.303) (8.368) (10.697) (9.906) (9.647) (8.827) (11.058)
ΔNAi,t /Mi,t−1 −0.043 0.024 −0.067 −0.048 −0.017 0.008 −0.108 **
(−1.174) (0.392) (−1.473) (−0.984) (−0.307) (0.172) (−2.013)
ΔRDi,t /Mi,t−1 1.602 3.403 −1.694 2.871 −1.966 2.781 −1.371
(1.518) (1.501) (−0.923) (1.377) (−1.000) (1.301) (−0.710)
ΔIi,t /Mi,t−1 −0.658 −0.395 −0.511 2.607 * −3.293 ** −0.954 −0.275
(−0.593) (−0.224) (−0.422) (1.942) (−2.301) (−0.692) (−0.196)
ΔDi,t /Mi,t−1 0.165 ** 4.493 6.099 2.232 9.893 ** 1.866 8.906 *
(2.059) (1.051) (1.305) (0.547) (1.996) (0.465) (1.770)
NFi,t /Mi,t−1 2.353 ** 0.069 ** 0.111 *** 0.114 *** 0.076 *** 0.073 *** 0.118 ***
(2.324) (2.557) (5.599) (5.194) (3.425) (3.297) (5.282)
Intercept 0.278 0.388 ** 0.183 0.188 0.062 0.218 0.172
(0.497) (2.571) (0.645) (0.989) (0.219) (1.151) (0.610)
Year Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
N of Obs. 6128 2935 2934 2481 2481 1940 3022
Adjusted R2 0.175 0.201 0.255 0.260 0.210 0.234 0.237
This table presents the OLS regressions of excess stock returns on CEO pension incentive and the changes in firm
characteristics, including the explanatory variables from Faulkender and Wang (2006) specification augmented with
the measures of pension incentive, hedging variables, and governance variable. Panel A examines the propensity of
hedging (HP) and Panel B examines the intensity of hedging (HI). In all panels the dependent variable is the annual
excess equity return calculated from a firm i’s stock return over year t − 1 to year t, ri,t , net of RBr,t , the return of
Fama and French (1993) size and book-to-market matched portfolio from year t − 1 to year t. ΔXi,t is the notation for
the one-year change of variable X for firm i over year t − 1 to year t, i.e., Xt − Xt−1 ; HIi,t is hedging principal (dollar
amount of total notional value of derivatives) at time t, and ΔHIi,t = HIi,t − HIi,t−1 ; Mi,t is market value of equity at
time t; Ci,t is cash plus marketable securities; Ei,t is earnings before extraordinary items plus interest, deferred tax
credits, and investment tax credits; NAi,t is total assets minus cash holdings; RDi,t is research and development
expense; Ii,t is interest expense; Di,t is common dividends; NFi,t is total equity issuances minus repurchases plus
debt issuances minus debt redemption; Li,t is the ratio of long-term debt plus debt in current liabilities divided by
the market value of assets at time t. The robust standard errors are to calculate T-Statistics reported in parentheses
below estimates. *, ** and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively.

Across the groups, we observe that the coefficients on the variables used in
Faulkender and Wang (2006) are generally consistent with the literature. For example, cash and
earnings are positively related to excess shareholder return, while leverage is negatively related to
excess equity return. Considering that the dependent variable is excess equity return, the coefficient
of explanatory variables measures the additional value accrued to the equity holder for one unit
change of the explanatory variables. The coefficients of hedging propensity (HPi,t ) and hedging
intensity (HIi,t ) mean the additional value flowing to shareholder per one dollar investment in hedging
position. Particularly, Panel A shows the incremental value contributed by hedging adoption to
the shareholders. We find the value creation of hedging is more significant when pension incentive
is higher. This indicates that pension incentive functions an effective mechanism in motivating
executives to implement active risk management to create firm value. In Panel B, the existing hedging
position (NIi,t−1 /Mi,t−1 ), incremental hedging amount (ΔNIi,t /Mi,t−1 ), and the interaction term of them

128
JRFM 2020, 13, 24

are included. We find that the interaction term has a significant and positive impact on firm value.
For example, the result in Model 1 shows that one dollar investment in existing hedging position
brings USD 0.374 to shareholders and one dollar increase in hedging position creates an additional
value of USD 0.204. In contrast, when pension incentive is in the lower level (Model 2), the additional
value created by the hedging investment is only USD 0.059 per dollar of investment. This distinct
difference suggests that the pension incentive promotes a firm’s hedging strategy and also strengthens
the value creation of hedging for shareholders.
Given the above finding as to how hedging creates value for shareholders, we advance further to
consider the interplay of pension incentives and governance mechanisms. In particular, we augment the
model specified in Equation (2) by adding measures of pension incentive and governance. For pension
incentives, we construct a dummy variable, PI, for each of the pension incentive measures. Specifically,
PI takes the value of one when CEO Pension/Equity is greater than the median value of this variable,
and takes the value of one when CEO Pension Relative Leverage is above the median value or greater than
one, respectively. In addition, we construct the indictors of strong governance, a dummy variable that
takes the value of one when Board Independence is greater than the median value, and zero otherwise.6
The regression model to examine the value of hedging with the consideration of pension incentive and
governance is specified below in Equation (3):

ri,t − RBi,t = β1 ∗ Hedgei,t + β2 ∗ PIi,t + β3 ∗ Gov>p50,i,t ∗ PIi,t ∗ Hedgei,t + β4 ∗ Gov<p50,i,t ∗ PIi,t ∗ Hedgei,t
ΔC ΔE ΔNA ΔRD ΔI ΔD NF
+γ1 Li,t + γ2 Mi,t−1
i,t
+ γ3 Mi,t−1
i,t
+ γ4 Mi,t−1i,t + γ5 Mi,t−1i,t + γ6 Mi,t−1
i,t
+ γ7 Mi,t−1
i,t
+ γ8 Mi,t−1
i,t
(3)

10
+ Yeart + εi,t
t=1

The optimal contracting hypothesis suggests the more pronounced effect of pension incentive on
the equity value of hedging to well-governed firms. Intuitively, since pension incentive is intended
to dampen CEO incentives to pursue active risk management that largely benefits equity holders,
the optimal contracting hypothesis predicts that pension benefit has a positive influence on the marginal
relation between equity value and hedging in firms with stronger shareholder power. We report the
result of above specification in Table 9. Remarkably, among the coefficients on the triple interaction terms
for each of three pension incentive measures, we find that those that interacted with the above-median
governance dummies are statistically significant, but those that interacted with the below-median
governance dummies are not significant. For example (in Panel A), a significant coefficient of the triple
interaction term (0.068) is found in the column of CEO Pension/Equity Compensation for the firms with
governance measure above the median. From the column using the dummy variable of (CEO pension
relative leverage greater than one) we also observe that the triple interaction term with the governance
(>Median) has a significant coefficient of 0.068. These results indicate that the marginal impact of
pension incentive on value of hedging is higher for the firms with good governance structure or strong
shareholder power. This finding is consistent with the optimal contracting hypothesis that the contract
of liability-based incentive is an outcome of optimal governance structure, and the additional hedging
amount promoted by such effective incentive creates more value for shareholders.

6 We also examine the results by using institutional blockholder ownership and observe the consistent results. These results
are not reported for brevity.

129
JRFM 2020, 13, 24

Table 9. The Value Creation of Pension Incentive through Hedging Interacted with Governance.

Panel A: Value of Hedging Adoption Interacted with Governance


CEO Pension/Equity CEO Pension Relative Dummy (CEO Pension
Compensation (%) Leverage Relative Leverage >1)
Coef T-stat Coef T-stat Coef T-stat
HPi,t 1.301 ** (1.993) 1.306 ** (1.989) 1.322 ** (1.991)
PIi,t (=1 if CEO Pension/Equity >Median) 0.023 (1.220)
PIi,t (=1 if CEO Pension Relative Leverage > Median) 0.022 (1.242)
PIi,t (=1 if CEO Pension Relative Leverage >1) 0.049 (1.085)
Governance (>Median)*PIi,t *HPi,t 0.068 *** (3.607)
Governance (<Median)*PIi,t *HPi,t 0.010 (0.096)
Governance (>Median)*PIi,t *HPi,t 0.060 * (1.921)
Governance (<Median)*PIi,t *HPi,t 0.053 (0.634)
Governance (>Median)*PIi,t *HPi,t 0.074 ** (2.304)
Governance (<Median)*PIi,t *HPi,t 0.051 (0.361)
Li,t −0.638 *** (−11.789) −0.632 *** (−10.543) −0.644 *** (−10.779)
ΔCi,t /Mi,t−1 0.881 *** (8.459) 0.863 *** (7.512) 0.859 *** (7.506)
ΔEi,t /Mi,t−1 0.799 *** (10.243) 0.769 *** (9.013) 0.766 *** (8.968)
ΔNAi,t /Mi,t−1 −0.044 (−1.030) −0.039 (−0.825) −0.039 (−0.838)
ΔRDi,t /Mi,t−1 −0.019 (−0.012) −0.336 (−0.194) −0.309 (−0.178)
ΔIi,t /Mi,t−1 −1.039 (−0.876) −1.795 (−1.372) −1.774 (−1.359)
ΔDi,t /Mi,t−1 5.351 * (1.752) 5.331 (1.566) 5.423 (1.592)
NFi,t /Mi,t−1 0.110 *** (6.244) 0.116 *** (6.008) 0.116 *** (5.968)
Year Controls Yes Yes Yes
N of Obs. 11,221 9488 9488
Adjusted R2 0.184 0.182 0.188
Panel B: Regression of Pension Incentives on the Value of Hedging Intensity with Governance
CEO Pension/Equity CEO Pension Relative Dummy (CEO Pension
Compensation (%) Leverage Relative Leverage >1)
Coef T-stat Coef T-stat Coef T-stat
HIi,t−1 /Mi,t−1 0.276 * (1.908) 0.283 * (1.855) 0.224 (1.483)
ΔHIi,t /Mi,t−1 0.037 (0.506) 0.025 (0.205) 0.059 (0.788)
PIi,t (=1 if CEO Pension/Equity > Median) −0.018 (−0.278)
PIi,t (=1 if CEO Pension Relative Leverage > Median) 0.024 (0.519)
PIi,t (=1 if CEO Pension Relative Leverage >1) 0.055 (1.508)
Governance (>Median)*PIi,t *(ΔHIi,t /Mi,t−1 ) 0.009 *** (2.594)
Governance (<Median)*PIi,t *(ΔHIi,t /Mi,t−1 ) 0.010 (0.096)
Governance (>Median)*PIi,t *(ΔHIi,t /Mi,t−1 ) 1.213 ** (2.436)
Governance (<Median)*PIi,t *(ΔHIi,t /Mi,t−1 ) 0.853 (0.634)
Governance (>Median)*PIi,t *(ΔHIi,t /Mi,t−1 ) 1.297 *** (2.578)
Governance (<Median)*PIi,t *(ΔHIi,t /Mi,t−1 ) 1.051 (0.361)
Li,t −0.467 *** (−11.463) −0.486 *** (−11.746) −0.492 *** (−12.114)
ΔCi,t /Mi,t−1 0.656 *** (8.468) 0.668 *** (8.460) 0.656 *** (8.364)
ΔEi,t /Mi,t−1 0.594 *** (10.241) 0.608 *** (10.263) 0.606 *** (10.309)
ΔNAi,t /Mi,t−1 −0.033 (−1.034) −0.034 (−1.058) −0.036 (−1.120)
ΔRDi,t /Mi,t−1 −0.002 (−0.002) −0.026 (−0.022) −0.021 (−0.018)
ΔIi,t /Mi,t−1 −0.767 (−0.876) −0.782 (−0.874) −0.676 (−0.763)
ΔDi,t /Mi,t−1 3.801 * (1.667) 3.962 * (1.703) 3.252 (1.409)
NFi,t /Mi,t−1 0.081 *** (6.165) 0.082 *** (6.080) 0.083 *** (6.262)
Year Controls Yes Yes Yes
N of Obs. 5869 4962 4962
Adjusted R2 0.155 0.146 0.142
This table presents the OLS regressions of excess stock returns on CEO pension incentive and the changes in firm
characteristics, including the explanatory variables from Faulkender and Wang (2006) specification augmented with
the measures of pension incentive, hedging variables, and governance variable. Panel A examines the propensity of
hedging (HP) and Panel B examines the intensity of hedging (HI). In all panels the dependent variable is the annual
excess equity return calculated from a firm i’s stock return over year t − 1 to year t, ri,t , net of RBr,t , the return of
Fama and French (1993) size and book-to-market matched portfolio from year t − 1 to year t. ΔXi,t is the notation for
the one-year change of variable X for firm i over year t − 1 to year t, i.e., Xt − Xt−1 ; HIi,t is hedging principal (dollar
amount of total notional value of derivatives) at time t, and ΔHIi,t = HIi,t − HIi,t−1 ; Mi,t is market value of equity at
time t; Ci,t is cash plus marketable securities; Ei,t is earnings before extraordinary items plus interest, deferred tax
credits, and investment tax credits; NAi,t is total assets minus cash holdings; RDi,t is research and development
expense; Ii,t is interest expense; Di,t is common dividends; NFi,t is total equity issuances minus repurchases plus
debt issuances minus debt redemption; Li,t is the ratio of long-term debt plus debt in current liabilities divided by
the market value of assets at time t; PI denotes one of three dummy proxies of pension incentive in each regression,
namely, PI takes the value of one when CEO Pension/Equity is greater than the median value of this variable, and takes
the value of one when CEO Pension Relative Leverage is above the median value or greater than one, respectively.
Governance is a dummy variable that takes the value of one when Board Independence is greater than the median
value, and zero otherwise. T-Statistics in the column next to the estimates are computed using robust standard
errors. *, ** and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively.

130
JRFM 2020, 13, 24

Apparently, the tests based on hedging intensity in Panel B also report the consistent results
of significantly strengthening influence of pension incentive on the value of hedging. For instance,
when we use the dummy measure of CEO pension relative leverage, pension incentive significantly
increases the value of hedging by USD 1.297 for the firms with strong governance but no significant
value creation is found for the peers with weak governance. This result justifies our optimal contract
hypothesis and, also, confirms our findings in Tables 6 and 7. With more influence of pension incentive,
the marginal value creation of hedging attributed to such liability-based incentives is higher for firms
with strong shareholder power.

6. Conclusions
In this paper, we empirically examine the influence of CEO pension incentive on corporate risk
management activity by employing a sample of multinational firms over the period of 2006 to 2015 and
across a wide array of industries. The results show a significantly positive impact of pension incentive
on hedging activity. More liability-based incentives encourage managers to adopt hedging or/and
increase hedging position. We also verify that such a positive relationship cannot be attributed to the
endogenous issue of compensation design.
Furthermore, we find that the influence of pension incentive on hedging is more pronounced for
the firms with good governance than those with poor governance. The results help untangle the role
of compensation in the mechanism of governance by providing the evidence to support the optimal
contracting hypothesis. Lastly, we further investigate the value of extra investment in hedging position
by following Faulkender and Wang’s (2006) methodology, especially in the context of pension incentive
and corporate governance. We detect that a higher level of pension incentive is associated with the
higher value of hedging, particularly for the firms with strong shareholder power. This result echoes
the theory of optimal contracting.
Taken together, this research contributes to the extant literature on the role of pension incentive by
providing new evidence about its economic influence on corporate risk management. Although the
existing literature reports mixed results pertaining to equity-based incentives, the findings documented
in this research clearly show that liability-based compensation creates a valuable incentive and has a
material impact on firms’ active risk management. Our results warrant further attention to the design
of pension incentive and its interplay with corporate governance.

Author Contributions: Conceptualization, J.J.C., and I.T.; Methodology, J.J.C.; Software, J.J.C., and Y.G.;
Investigation, J.J.C., and Y.G.; Data collection and preparation, J.J.C., Y.G., and I.T.; Review and validation,
J.J.C. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.
Funding: This research received no external funding.
Conflicts of Interest: The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A
Table A1. Detailed definition of primary variables used in this study.

Variable Names Variable Definitions


Pension Incentive
The sum of the aggregate actuarial present value of the CEO’s accumulated benefits of
CEO Pension (USD M) pension and the aggregate balance in non-tax-qualified deferred compensation plans at the
end of the fiscal year.
The value of CEO pension divided by CEO total compensation. Total CEO compensation
CEO Pension/Total
includes CEO pension, equity compensation, salary, bonus, long-term Incentive payouts,
Compensation (%)
and all other total.
Value of CEO pension divided by CEO equity compensation. Equity compensation is the
CEO Pension/Equity
sum of the value of the CEO’s common stock holdings plus the value of options based on
Compensation (%)
Black-Scholes, all measured at the fiscal year end.

131
JRFM 2020, 13, 24

Table A1. Cont.

Variable Names Variable Definitions


= (CEO pension/ CEO equity Compensation)/(firm debt/firm equity). CEO pension and
CEO Pension Relative equity compensation are defined as above. Firm debt is sum of long term debt plus debt in
Leverage current Liabilities. Firm equity is common shares outstanding*stock price at the end of
fiscal year.
Dummy (CEO Pension A dummy variable which takes value of one if CEO-firm D/E ratio is greater than one.
Relative Leverage >1) Otherwise zero.
Hedging Variables
Currency Hedging The dummy variable that takes a value of one when a firm holds or trades foreign currency
Propensity derivatives for hedging in a given year, and zero otherwise.
Currency Hedging Total notional value of foreign currency derivatives for hedging in scaled by the book value
Intensity of total assets.
CEO-Equity Incentive
=[∂ (option value)/ ∂ (stock price)]*(price/100) = exp(−d*T)*N(Z)*(price/100). Particularly,
Delta Incentive
it’s defined as the change in option portfolio value for a 1% change in the stock price.
=[∂ (option value)/∂ (stock volatility)]*0.01 = exp(−d*T) N‘(Z)*S*T*(1/2)*(0.01). Particularly,
Vega Incentive it’s defined as the change in option portfolio value for a 0.01 change in the annualized
standard deviation of stock return.
Rogers (2002) proposes that delta and Vega measure managerial motivation from
“value-creating” and “risk-taking” incentives, respectively. However, economic
Vega Incentive/Delta interpretation of the ratio of Vega to delta should be more intuitive because it measures the
Incentive CEO risk-taking incentive per dollar of value-increasing incentives from option and stock
holdings. Rogers (2002) demonstrates this ratio has more explanatory power than either
Delta or Vega.
Firm-related
Characteristics
Log (Total Assets) The logarithm of firm total assets adjusted with 2015 CPI.
= (long term debt + debt in current liability)/market value of total assets, where market
Leverage
value of assets is the sum of total debt and market value of equity.
= market value of Total assets/book value of total assets. market value of assets is the sum
Market-to-book Ratio
of Total debt and market value of equity.
Interest Coverage = EBITDA/Interest paid
Tangible Assets Ratio A ratio of tangible assets relative to firm total assets
The correlation coefficient between cash flow and investment expense. The calculation of
cash flow is following Lang et al. (1991) as: Operating income before depreciation-interest
Corr(Cash Flow,
expense-(income taxes-deferred tax change)-common dividends-preferred dividends.
Investment)
The investment expense is following Gay and Nam (1998) to define as the sum of capital
expenditure, R&D expense and net PP&E.
Cash Holding The value of cash and short term security scaled by firm total assets
Convertible Bonds Ratio The value of convertible bond scaled by firm total assets
Positive Tax Credit
The dummy variable of one if the firm has non-zero tax loss carry-forwards.
(Dummy)
= 4.88 + 7.15*(indicator variable of small negative taxable income) + 1.6*(indicator variable
of small positive taxable income) + 0.019 *(absolute coefficient of variation of pervious
taxable income) − 5.5 *(first-order serial correlation of taxable income) − 1.28*(indicator
variable of investment tax credit) + (indicator variable of net operating loss
Tax Convexity (MUSD) carry-forward)*(3.29 − 4.77*(indicator variable of small negative taxable income)) − 1.93
*(indicator variable of small positive taxable income). It measures expected percentage tax
savings from a 5% reduction in the volatility of taxable income. Graham and Smith (1999)
use simulation to illustrate that this proxy is more precise to capture the shape of tax
function than tax loss carry-forward.
Board Independence The proportion of directors who are classified as outside directors serving on the board.
Institutional Blockholder Defined as the sum of all ownership positions greater than or equal to 5% held by
Ownership institutional investors.

132
JRFM 2020, 13, 24

References
Anantharaman, Divya, and Yong Gyu Lee. 2014. Managerial risk taking incentives and corporate pension policy.
Journal of Financial Economics 111: 328–51. [CrossRef]
Anantharaman, Divya, Vivian. W. Fang, and Guojin Guong. 2014. Inside debt and the design of corporate debt
contracts. Management Science 60: 1260–80. [CrossRef]
Bebchuk, Lucian A., and Jesse M. Fried. 2004. Pay without Performance. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Belkhir, Mohamed, and Sabri Boubaker. 2013. CEO inside debt and hedging decisions: Lessons from the US
banking industry. Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money 24: 223–46. [CrossRef]
Bereskin, Frederick L., and David C. Cicero. 2013. CEO compensation contagion: Evidence from an exogenous
shock. Journal of Financial Economics 107: 477–93. [CrossRef]
Billett, Matthew T., David C. Mauer, and Yilei Zhang. 2010. Stockholder and bondholder wealth effects of CEO
incentive grants. Financial Management 39: 463–87. [CrossRef]
Bodnar, Gordon M., Gregory S. Hayt, and Richard C. Marston. 1998. Wharton survey of financial risk management
by US non-financial firms. Financial Management 27: 70–91. [CrossRef]
Brown, Charles, and James L. Medoff. 2003. Firm age and wages. Journal of Labor Economics 21: 677–97. [CrossRef]
Campello, Murillo, Chen Lin, Yue Ma, and Hong Zou. 2011. The real and financial implications of corporate
hedging. Journal of Finance 66: 1615–47. [CrossRef]
Carpenter, Jennifer N. 2000. Does option compensation increase managerial risk appetite? Journal of Finance 55:
2311–31. [CrossRef]
Cassell, Cory A., Shawn X. Huang, Juan Manuel Sanchez, and Michael D. Stuart. 2012. Seeking safety: The relation
between CEO inside debt holdings and the riskiness of firm investment and financial policies. Journal of
Financial Economics 103: 588–610. [CrossRef]
Chen, Jun, and Tao-Hsien Dolly King. 2014. Corporate hedging and the cost of debt. Journal of Corporate Finance
29: 221–45. [CrossRef]
Coles, Jeffrey L., Naveen D. Daniel, and Lalitha Naveen. 2006. Managerial incentives and risk-taking. Journal of
Financial Economics 79: 431–68. [CrossRef]
Croci, Ettore, Alfonso Del Giudice, and Håkan Jankensgård. 2017. CEO age, risk incentives, and hedging strategy.
Financial Management 46: 687–716. [CrossRef]
Doukas, John A., and Christos Pantzalis. 2003. Geographic diversification and agency costs of debt of multinational
firms. Journal of Corporate Finance 9: 59–92. [CrossRef]
Edmans, Alex, and Qi Liu. 2011. Inside Debt. Review of Finance 15: 75–102. [CrossRef]
Fama, Eugene F., and Kenenth R. French. 1993. Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds. Journal of
Financial Economics 33: 3–56. [CrossRef]
Faulkender, Michael, and Rong Wang. 2006. Corporate financial policy and the value of cash. Journal of Finance 61:
1957–90. [CrossRef]
Financial Accounting Standards Board. 1976. Reasonable Estimation of the Amount of a Loss: An Interpretation of FASB
Statement No. 5. Norwalk: Financial Accounting Standards Board.
Froot, Kenneth, David S. Scharfstein, and Jeremy C. Stein. 1993. Risk management: Coordinating investment and
financing policies. Journal of Finance 48: 1629–58. [CrossRef]
Gay, Gerald D., and Jouahn Nam. 1998. The underinvestment problem and corporate derivatives use. Financial
Management 27: 53–69. [CrossRef]
Géczy, Christopher, Bernadette A. Minton, and Catherine Schrand. 1997. Why firms use currency derivatives?
Journal of Finance 52: 1323–54.
Géczy, Christopher, Bernadette A. Minton, and Catherine Schrand. 2007. Taking a view: Corporate speculation,
governance and Compensation. Journal of Finance 52: 2405–43. [CrossRef]
Gerakos, Joseph. 2010. Chief executive officer and the pay-pension tradeoff. Journal of Pension Economics and
Finance 9: 303–19. [CrossRef]
Gormley, Todd A., David A. Matsa, and Todd Milbourn. 2013. CEO compensation and corporate risk: Evidence
from a natural experiment. Journal of Accounting and Economics 56: 79–101. [CrossRef]
Graham, John R., and Daniel A. Rogers. 2002. Do firms hedge in response to tax incentives? Journal of Finance 57:
815–39. [CrossRef]

133
JRFM 2020, 13, 24

Graham, John R., and Clifford W. Smith Jr. 1999. Tax incentives to hedge. Journal of Finance 54: 2241–62. [CrossRef]
Greene, William H. 2004. Econometric Analysis. Upper Saddle River: Prentice Hall.
Guay, W. 1999. The sensitivity of CEO wealth to equity risk: An analysis of the magnitude and determinants.
Journal of Financial Economics 53: 43–71. [CrossRef]
Halford, Joseph T., and Mingming Qiu. 2012. Inside Debt and Debt Incentives: Evidence from the 2008 Financial
Crisis. Working Paper. Milwaukee, WI, USA: University of Wisconsin Milwaukee.
Hirshleifer, David, and Yoon Suh. 1992. Risk, managerial effort, and project choice. Journal of Financial Intermediation
2: 308–45. [CrossRef]
Jensen, Michael C., and Kevin J. Murphy. 1990. Performance pay and top management incentives. Journal of
Political Economy 98: 225–64. [CrossRef]
Jensen, Michael C., and William H. Meckling. 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and
ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3: 305–60. [CrossRef]
Jenter, Dirk, and Katharina Lewellen. 2015. CEO preferences and acquisitions. Journal of Finance 70: 2813–52.
[CrossRef]
Kim, E. Han, and Yao Lu. 2011. CEO ownership, external governance, and risk-taking. Journal of Financial Economics
102: 272–92. [CrossRef]
Knopf, John D., Jouahn Nam, and John H. Thornton Jr. 2002. The volatility and price sensitivities of managerial
stock option portfolios and corporate hedging. Journal of Finance 57: 801–13. [CrossRef]
Krapl, Alain A., and Reilly S. White. 2016. Executive pensions, risk-shifting, and foreign exchange exposure.
Research in International Business and Finance 38: 376–92. [CrossRef]
Lang, Larry H. P., René M. Stulz, and Ralph A. Walkling. 1991. A test of the free cash flow hypothesis: The case of
bidder returns. Journal of Financial Economics 29: 315–35. [CrossRef]
Lee, Gemma, and Hongfei Tang. 2011. CEO Pension and Deferred Compensation. Working Paper. South Orange,
NJ, USA: Seton Hall University.
Lewellen, Katharina. 2006. Financing decisions when managers are risk-averse. Journal of Financial Economics 82:
551–89. [CrossRef]
Liu, Yixin, and David C. Mauer. 2011. Corporate cash holdings and CEO compensation incentives. Journal of
Financial Economics 102: 183–98. [CrossRef]
Liu, Yixin, David C. Mauer, and Yilei Zhang. 2014. Firm cash holdings and CEO inside debt. Journal of Banking and
Finance 42: 83–100. [CrossRef]
Myers, Stewart. 1977. Determinants of corporate borrowing. Journal of Financial Economics 5: 147–75. [CrossRef]
Nance, Deana R., Clifford W. Smith Jr., and Charles W. Smithson. 1993. On the determinants of corporate hedging.
Journal of Finance 48: 267–84. [CrossRef]
Peng, Lin, and Alisa Roell. 2014. Managerial Incentives and Stock Price Manipulation. Journal of Finance 69:
487–526. [CrossRef]
Rajgopal, Shivaram, and Terry Shevlin. 2002. Empirical evidence on the relation between stock option compensation
and risk taking. Journal of Accounting and Economics 33: 145–71. [CrossRef]
Roberts, Michael R., and Toni M. Whited. 2013. Endogeneity in empirical corporate finance. Handbook of the
Economics of Finance 2: 493–572. [CrossRef]
Rogers, Daniel A. 2002. Does executive portfolio structure affect risk management? CEO risk-taking incentives
and corporate derivatives usage. Journal of Banking and Finance 80: 271–95. [CrossRef]
Serfling, Matthew A. 2014. CEO age and the riskiness of corporate policies. Journal of Corporate Finance 25: 251–73.
[CrossRef]
Smith, Clifford W., and Rene M. Stulz. 1985. The determinants of firms’ hedging policies. Journal of Financial and
Quantitative Analysis 28: 391–405. [CrossRef]
Sundaram, Rangarajan K., and David L. Yermack. 2007. Pay me later: Inside debt and its role in managerial
compensation. Journal of Finance 62: 1551–88. [CrossRef]
Tan, Christine E. L., and Susan M. Young. 2016. Share repurchase choice and executive pension compensation.
Journal of Management Accounting Research 28: 127–49. [CrossRef]

134
JRFM 2020, 13, 24

Wei, Chenyang, and David L. Yermack. 2011. Investor reactions to CEOs’ inside debt incentives. Review of
Financial Studies 24: 3813–40. [CrossRef]
White, Reilly S. 2012. Three essays on inside debt. Working Paper. Storrs, CT, USA: University of Connecticut.
Yim, Soojin. 2013. The acquisitiveness of youth: CEO age and acquisition behavior. Journal of Financial Economics
108: 250–73. [CrossRef]

© 2020 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access
article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution
(CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).

135
Journal of
Risk and Financial
Management

Article
CEO Diversity, Political Influences, and CEO
Turnover in Unstable Environments:
The Romanian Case
Ingrid-Mihaela Dragotă *, Andreea Curmei-Semenescu and Raluca Moscu
Department of Finance, Faculty of Finance and Banking, Bucharest University of Economic Studies,
010374 Bucharest, Romania; andreea.semenescu@fin.ase.ro (A.C.-S.); moscu.raluca@yahoo.com (R.M.)
* Correspondence: mihaela.dragota@fin.ase.ro

Received: 19 February 2020; Accepted: 17 March 2020; Published: 18 March 2020

Abstract: This work expands the literature on a less studied topic, the Chief Executive Officer (CEO)
turnover in post-communist economies, analyzed during an unstable and ambiguous economic
and financial environment. For the period 2005–2010, the results indicate the political inference in
CEO turnover decision for the Romanian listed companies. In this period, with great turmoil in the
economy determined by the financial crisis of 2008, we also find that CEO gender helps to explain
the probability of changing the CEO. Moreover, this paper empirically tests if the financial and
corporate governance determinants that are validated in the existing literature work for the Romanian
listed companies. We reinforce that CEO turnover decision is negatively related to accounting-based
performance. We find evidence of the “voting with their feet” behavior of institutional investors,
and of the lack of Board of Directors monitoring. The CEO–Chairman duality and the controlling
power of the largest shareholder act as entrenchment mechanisms.

Keywords: CEO turnover; foreign CEO; female CEO; ownership structure; Romania

1. Introduction
A substantial literature base devoted to the causes and consequences of CEO succession has
been developed in the last decades. Due to the key economic role played by top-executive managers,
CEO turnover has become a subject of widespread attention. The decision of managerial succession
stands at the crossroads of corporate finance, management, corporate governance, psychology,
and sociology (Campbell et al. 2011). It can be considered a strategic decision, which helps to preserve
the shareholders’/stakeholders’ interest whenever major objectives of the firm are not achieved,
or whenever resources of the company are not used according to a mutually agreed plan.
Although there is a large amount of literature on CEO turnover in developed countries (e.g.,
Parrino 1997; Kato and Long 2006; Hazarika et al. 2012), not much has been written about the difficulties
in implementing the letter and spirit of corporate governance rules in this area for a transition economy.
To the best of our knowledge, this is the first study considering a wide range of financial, social,
political, and corporate governance determinants on CEO turnover in Romania. Little research has
been conducted for Central and Eastern European (CEE) post-communist countries (Muravyev 2003
for Russia; Claessens and Djankov 1999, 2000; Muravyev et al. 2010 for Ukraine; Eriksson 2005 for
Slovakia and Fidrmuc and Fidrmuc 2007 for Czech Republic). The above-mentioned studies are not
entirely applicable to the Romanian case for several reasons. For example, these studies focus mainly
oxn the enterprise restructuring process and its consequences from a corporate governance perspective.
Moreover, even if Eastern and Central European countries have some economic and recent political
similarities, important differences in terms of cultural and pre-communist political backgrounds can

JRFM 2020, 13, 59; doi:10.3390/jrfm13030059 137 www.mdpi.com/journal/jrfm


JRFM 2020, 13, 59

be found (Filip and Raffournier 2010). In the last decades, these countries have become, to a certain
extent, different in terms of the degree of economic1 and stock market development.2
This paper contributes to CEO turnover research by taking into account three new variables,
namely, the foreign origin of the CEO, the CEO’s gender, and also the role of government ownership in
connection with political changes. We find a positive correlation between the CEO foreign origin and
the likelihood of CEO turnover. CEO gender helps explain both forced and voluntary CEO turnover:
women chief executives are replaced more often than men. With regards to the specific corporate
governance mechanisms in companies with governmental participation, we find that government
ownership interaction with political changes is positively correlated with CEO turnover. The financial
crisis also has a role in explaining the CEO turnover likelihood during the analyzed period, but only
for the period of sharp downturn (the year 2009).
In addition, we analyzed the influence of “classical” corporate governance characteristics on
CEO turnover in Romania. We partially validated the hypotheses usually proposed by the literature.
Whenever it was necessary, we adapted them to better fit to the characteristics of the Romanian financial
system and regulations.
The conclusions from this paper can be interesting for researchers, analysts, practitioners,
and supervision authorities, also from the perspective of the analyzed period. This paper concentrates
on a period of economic turmoil, namely, the period 2005–2010. Our choice has scientific but also
practical reasons. From a scientific point of view, this paper covers the Romanian listed companies,
the only relevant sample in terms of corporate governance implementation and data availability.
Starting from 2011, the listing criteria and, consequently, the sample of listed companies suffered
numerous changes, thus it is difficult to insure the homogeneity of the database.
In terms of practical interest for the study, our analyzed period, characterized by different
researchers and analysts as turbulent in terms of economic and financial evolution, requires specific
interest for corporate decisions. For example, Caruso et al. (2019) performed a model-based
counterfactual exercise by estimating the model for the period 1983–2007 (pre-crisis sample) and by
computing forecasts for 2008–2013 based on the pre-crisis parameters. They confirmed that households’
and financial corporations’ debts and house prices are weakly associated with the economic cycle
in the pre-crisis sample. Additionally, an abnormal deep downfall in private investment and an
increase in households’ savings beyond historical regularities were registered. Finally, the major
changes in the fiscal deficit–GDP and debt–GDP ratios in 2008–2009 were exceptional, similar to the
fiscal consolidation that followed. Furthermore, international, but also national analysts, agree in
declaring that during the year 2019, there was—and in the following years, there will be—a clear
deceleration of the macroeconomic indicators. On 1 October 2019, when Ms. Kristalina Georgieva was
appointed Managing Director and Chairman of the Executive Board of the International Monetary
Fund, her discourse was focused on Europe being on the verge of a new financial crisis. One month
later, the same institution released a warning for European countries to put in place emergency
plans, ready to be implemented, in the eventuality of what seems to be an imminent crisis. Also,
some European countries entered into technical recession according to different financial institutions:

1 The Gross Domestic Product (GDP) per capita (constant 2010 US$) varied between 5735 US$ for Serbia and 23437 US$ for
Slovenia in the year 2010, in a comparision which included nine CEE countries (World Bank statistics). Romania had, in 2010,
a GDP per capita of 8210 US$. Using the same CEE countries and the same database, Romania had, in 2008, the highest
GDP growth rate (11.14%), but a decrease of −4.74% in 2009 (however, better than the case of the Czech Republic (−5.34%),
Hungary (−6.46%), Croatia (−7.19%), and Slovenia (−8.63%)). In 2010, Romania had the slowest recovery in terms of GDP
growth rate (−3.32%) out of all nine of the analyzed CEE countries.
2 Romania had, in 2005, almost the least developed capital market out of all nine of the analyzed CEE countries, with a market
capitalization of listed domestic companies (% of GDP) of 16.11%, whereas Poland, Hungary, and Croatia had market
capitalization around 30% from GDP. Romania had an even weaker position in 2010 (8.54%), after the fall from 2008, and
the gap with countries such as Poland (39.79%) and Croatia (42.76%) increased. At the same time, it can be noticed that
Romania was not among the most affected countries by the crisis from the analyzed CEE countries (a decrease of market
capitalization as % from GDP around 59% in 2008), while the CEE countries with the most developed capital markets had
the highest drop rates (65% and above) (using the World Bank indicators).

138
JRFM 2020, 13, 59

Germany in September 2019 according to the Central Bank, and Italy according to the European
Central Bank. Romania is a special case, because for the previous few years, the government led a
pro-cyclical policy that is likely to increase the risk of a potential recession. Several analysts warned of
the unsustainability of public policies, but also of the economic growth, with the National Bank of
Romania Governor Mugur Isarescu and his counselors, as well as Nouriel Roubini in a press analysis in
November 2019, being among them. At the beginning of 2020, the worst-case scenario was confirmed
with the spread of the Covid-19 epidemy, that caused a big fall in most important financial markets,
as well as in the Romanian one. Thus, the conclusions of the present study can be very relevant to
better understand and anticipate the future period (for 2020 and beyond), that Europe, in particular,
will go through.
The emerging and/or frontier markets can be of great interest for both national and foreign
investors, looking for new investment opportunities and for diversified portfolios based on shares
issued by companies, other than those listed on mature capital markets. Therefore, we believe that our
conclusions may be of great interest for scientists, but also for analysts and other finance practitioners.
The remainder of the study is organized as follows. Section 2 provides a short description of
the Romanian environment in terms of corporate governance and investors’ protection. In Section 3,
we present previous research on the determinants of CEO turnover and we develop the tested
hypotheses, focusing on CEO diversity and on political influences. Section 4 describes the research
methodology and the data set. The empirical results and discussion are then presented in Section 5,
while Section 6 concludes the study.

2. A Short Description of the Romanian Environment in Terms of Corporate Governance and


Investors’ Protection
In 2009, the Romanian Corporate Governance Code was adopted on a comply-or-explain basis.
It proposed principles harmonized to those of the European Union. For the most liquid listed companies
in Romania, Dobroţeanu et al. (2010) provided empirical evidence of a corporate governance disclosure
gap. Indeed, Romanian listed companies still have a hesitant evolution regarding the implementation
of the corporate governance standards.
Romania has a small capital market, even in comparison with different CEE countries, with 73
listed companies in 2010 (compared with 240 in Croatia, 390 in Bulgaria, and 570 in Poland in the same
year) and with low trading volumes (1% for stock traded value, as % of GDP, compared with 15% for
Poland and 11% for Czech Republic in 2010) (World Bank indicators) and relatively few disclosure
requirements (including those for corporate governance). Moreover, the development of the Romanian
capital market, including the corporate governance domain, took place in a peculiar political and
economic context, different from other CEE countries. Due to the fact that the Romanian governments
focused more on political issues than on important and necessary economic decisions for the healthy
development of an ex-communist country, the economic gap of CEE countries such as the Czech
Republic, Poland, and Hungary increased, and Romania joined the European Union only in 2007 (Filip
and Raffournier 2010).
Because we use market-based performance variables (alongside accounting-based performances),
additional explanations are necessary for the Romanian capital market. Previous studies regarding
the efficient market hypothesis (EMH) either reject it or provide evidence only for a relatively low
degree of informational efficiency (Dragotă and Mitrică 2004). The most recent studies have both
interesting and intricate conclusions. Dragotă and Ţilică (2014) reject the weak form of informational
efficiency, but reveal that for some assets and indexes, it is hard to reach systematic abnormal earnings.
In this context, we expect some questionable results for market-based performance in relation to
CEO turnover.
Institutional investors’ ownership is far less important in Romania than in developed capital
markets. For the period 2005–2010, the average institutional investors’ holdings for the companies listed
on the Bucharest Stock Exchange (BSE) varied between 24% in 2005 and 30% in 2010, comparatively

139
JRFM 2020, 13, 59

to almost 50% for the US in 2006 (Helwege et al. 2012). Also, our sample confirms the high level
of ownership concentration, with an average percentage of the voting rights owned by the largest
shareholder of around 47% and a median value of 52%. Thus, more than half of the listed companies
have a major shareholder, controlling at least 52% of the voting rights.
Regarding the minority shareholders’ rights protection index, Romania stands slightly above the
average of the transition countries (41 compared with the average value of 35.4), but with a lower
index value than the average of the developed countries included in the study (the average value
for the developed countries is 46.9). Claessens and Yurtoglu (2013) also emphasize a weak creditors’
protection in Romania and a low efficiency of debt enforcement. Weak investor protection obstructs
the function of corporate governance systems. Consequently, CEO turnover will most likely be less
sensitive to firm performance when the strength of investor protection decreases (Hu and Kim 2019).

3. Literature Review and the Tested Hypotheses


We structured this section in two main parts. First, we review the existing literature on CEO
turnover, firm performance (Section 3.1), corporate governance (Section 3.2), and also in connection
with various financial indicators for leverage, dividend policy, and sector homogeneity (Section 3.3).
There is a large body of empirical literature examining the impact of a wide range of economic,
social, financial, and corporate governance determinants for CEO turnover. Then, in the second step,
we propose three new determinants with corresponding hypotheses for foreign CEO, female CEO,
and political influences on CEO turnover (Section 3.4).

3.1. CEO Turnover and Firm Performance


Many research studies put performance among the most important causes of CEO departure (see,
among others, Weisbach 1988; Parrino 1997; Eisfeldt and Kuhnen 2013). A large body of evidence
shows that CEO turnover (particularly forced replacements) is inversely related to firm and industry
performances (Parrino 1997; Leker and Salomo 2000; Huson et al. 2001; Brunello et al. 2003; Kato and
Long 2006; Jenter and Kanaan 2015; Muravyev et al. 2010; Hu and Leung 2012, among others).
Both market-based and accounting-based performance indicators are widely discussed in the
literature and, in some cases, the conclusions are not similar. Market-based performance indicators are
related to firm accounting performance, and also to investors’ expectations regarding the perspectives
of the firm, to their culture and optimism, and also to the degree of market efficiency. Weisbach
(1988), Murphy and Zimmerman (1993), and Blackwell et al. (1994) claim that companies with low
performance can use accounting manipulations to change investors’ expectations. Altogether, Blackwell
et al. (1994) affirm that accounting-based performance seems to be more important than market-based
performance to explain CEO turnover, while Murphy and Zimmerman (1993) conclude that CEO
replacement is inversely related to firm performance for both measures used.
Bushman et al. (2010), Kaplan and Minton (2012), Eisfeldt and Kuhnen (2013), and Jenter and
Kanaan (2015) underline also the importance of industry and market performance. Eisfeldt and Kuhnen
(2013) emphasize that the weight-skills industry shocks determine CEO turnover, while idiosyncratic
shocks do not strongly influence this phenomenon. Their model provides a broad explanation to better
understand CEO turnovers for both performing and under-performing companies that experience
voluntary CEO departures. Another result is that companies with low industry-adjusted return are
more likely to have forced CEO turnovers, and also that industry performance is negatively correlated
with the probability of forced turnovers.
We tested a wide range of accounting- and market-based performance indicators to obtain a better
understanding of the main performance objectives considered by shareholders when they decide to
change the CEO and, at the same time, to better fit this study to the Romanian economic environment.
We used the return on equity (ROE) as an alternative to the stock return to overcome the effects of weak
market informational efficiency (see, for example, the study of Dragotă and T, ilică 2014, regarding the
market efficiency in Romania). We also analyzed if long-term return monitoring is more important

140
JRFM 2020, 13, 59

than short-term returns, to decide forced CEO turnover using a 3-year average return on assets (ROA),
a 3-year average return on equity (ROE), and a 3-year average operating margin.

3.2. CEO Turnover and Corporate Governance


Country and firm characteristics in terms of corporate governance, ultimately resulting in a
specific level of control of the managerial activity, are also expected to influence forced CEO turnover
decisions. The existing literature proved that the CEO–Chairman duality is associated with a lower
probability of forced turnovers (Kato and Long 2006; Helwege et al. 2012; Hu and Leung 2012; Hazarika
et al. 2012). This correlation can be explained through a higher influence of the CEO on the Board of
Directors and higher opportunities for the CEO to maintain informational asymmetries. On the other
hand, the separation between CEO and Chairman leads to more efficient board control and improves
firm performance.
CEO turnover occurrence is also related to the board’s characteristics—such as size and
independence. It is expected that a higher number of board members is associated with a higher level
of managerial control, especially when independent directors prevail in the board. On the other hand,
when the Board of Directors has numerous members, it could be more difficult to make changes in the
company. Brunello et al. (2003) found a direct link between board size and the probability of forced
CEO turnover. However, for Ukraine, a post-communist country, Muravyev et al. (2010) found that
board size had no statistically or economically significant effects on the probability of CEO turnover.
To protect the interests of minority shareholders, the BSE Corporate Governance Code (2015)
recommends that “the Board and its committees should have the appropriate balance of skills,
experience, gender diversity, knowledge and independence to enable them to effectively perform their
respective duties and responsibilities. It is recommended for the majority of non-executive members of
the Board of Directors or Supervisory Board to be independent.” Additionally, the same Corporate
Governance Code (2015) recommends that “the majority of the members of the Board of Directors
should be non-executive.” Even though the Code does not establish an exact number or a proportion
of independent directors, the Romanian listed companies have chosen to follow this recommendation.
Helwege et al. (2012) provide weak evidence on board independence being associated with higher
probability of CEO turnover. On the other hand, there are studies showing that companies with an
independent board experience higher of forced CEO turnover to performance (Guo and Masulis 2015).
Ownership concentration is important to determine a forced CEO turnover. Many empirical
studies show that listed companies in Western Europe, but also in East Asia, the Middle East, or Latin
America have large shareholders (see, among others, Claessens and Djankov 2000; Barca and Becht
2001; Faccio and Lang 2002). The presence of large shareholders is also typical for Romania and other
post-communist Eastern European countries. For the companies listed on the first and second tiers on
the BSE, the average first shareholder ownership is 47.42%.
Concentrated ownership is considered by some authors more favorable for good corporate
governance (Shleifer and Vishny 1997), based on the agency problem arising from the separation
of ownership and control. On the contrary, when using asymmetric information models, different
authors prove that a higher ownership concentration affects firm performance or dividend policy (see
Holmström and Tirole 1983; Aghion and Tirole 1997; Bolton and Von Thadden 1998, or studies for CEE
countries such as Hanousek et al. 2007; Bena and Hanousek 2008; Dragotă et al. 2013, among others).
The high stake owned by the largest shareholder can also lead to a decrease in the interest of the
companies in promoting firm-level corporate governance measures, as the controlling shareholder has
additional and more effective instruments to monitor the firm (Bollaert and Dilé 2009).
The literature predicts a lower probability of forced CEO turnover associated with a concentrated
ownership (see, for example, Parrino 1997; Brunello et al. 2003), while Kato and Long (2006) recognize the
usefulness of ownership concentration as a control variable in order to eliminate endogeneity problems.
Institutional ownership is also important to explain CEO turnover occurrence, especially due to
the commonly known activism, doubled by the advanced financial skills of the institutional investors.

141
JRFM 2020, 13, 59

It is expected that these “highly skilled and well-resourced professional shareholders would make
informed use of their rights, promoting good corporate governance in companies in which they invest”
(OECD 2011). Kaplan and Minton (2012), following the methodology applied by Cremers and Nair
(2005), used the cumulative percentage of shares held in each firm by the large institutional shareholders
(who own more than 5% ownership of the firm’s outstanding shares). They found that the institutional
investors’ activism increases the probability of CEO turnover. Similar results can be found in the work
of Brav et al. (2008) and Del Guercio et al. (2008). Parrino et al. (2003) found decreases of the share
owned by institutional investors prior to forced turnovers, which can be considered as proof of the
“voting with their feet” phenomenon.
The studies on agency models in connection with CEO ownership can be divided into at least
two distinct groups. First, it is considered that CEO ownership can reduce the agency conflicts
between managers and shareholders (especially with minority shareholders), because an executive
with stocks (and stock options) is “in the same boat” as the rest of the owners. Contrary to this view,
the second set of studies argues that an owner–manager can distort the main performance objectives
of the company for private benefits, affecting the market prices and/or using his/her close ties with
the controlling shareholders (Isakov and Weisskopf 2014). This could certainly be the case of the
Romanian listed companies, controlled by major shareholders. In this context, minority shareholders
can still be protected if managers (or controlling shareholders) develop a reputation for treating outside
shareholders well (Gomes 2000; Maury and Pajuste 2002).
The results of previous studies confirm the negative correlation between CEO ownership
and the probability of forced turnover (see, among others, Brunello et al. 2003; and Campbell
et al. 2011). Muravyev et al. (2010) also found evidence of managerial ownership supporting
entrenchment. CEO ownership, like board ownership (Helwege et al. 2012), becomes a mechanism of
alleviating shareholder–manager agency conflicts and is expected to be negatively correlated to CEO
forced turnover.
Particularly when CEOs are significant shareholders, it is possible that they mainly represent the
interests of the controlling shareholders, more so than those of the firms. When the CEO is appointed
directly by the controlling shareholder, the criteria for measuring the CEO’s performance may possibly
be connected more to the effectiveness in protecting the interests of the controlling shareholder, rather
than those of the firm. In our models, we took into account the simple presence of the CEO as a
shareholder and then we considered his/her presence as a significant shareholder (owning 5% or more
of the voting rights).

3.3. CEO Turnover, Capital Structure, Dividend Policy, and Sector Homogeneity
The agency conflict between CEO and shareholders can also be mitigated using capital structure
and dividend policy. The creditors have the concern and appropriate skills to monitor the firms,
and the shareholders benefit from their financial expertise (Ross 1977). In the meantime, the CEO is
less willing to undertake excessive risks and is more disciplined, which eventually leads to a lower
probability of being forced to quit his/her position. On the other hand, capital structure is considered
in the literature as a reflection of the financial risk undertaken by the company (Hazarika et al. 2012;
Hu and Leung 2012; Cronqvist et al. 2012). Hence, the leverage is expected to be positively associated
with CEO turnover (forced or voluntary), especially in economies based on capital markets. Hazarika
et al. (2012) for the US, and Hu and Leung (2012) for China provide weak evidence of a positive
correlation between leverage and CEO turnover (forced and voluntary). On the other hand, Lin and
Liu (2004) found a negative relation between leverage and forced CEO turnover in Taiwan.
In recent decades, financial theory has offered several explanations for dividend policy, based on
signaling theories, or taking into consideration the agency conflicts between corporate insiders and
outside shareholders. The dividend signaling hypothesis predicts that dividends convey information
to shareholders/investors regarding the firm’s future prospects, and only good-quality firms can use
it (Bhattacharya 1979). Even when managers are not sure whether their company has the ability

142
JRFM 2020, 13, 59

to generate cash flows in the future, they may keep dividends constant, or even gradually increase
payments in order to avoid sending a negative signal to the market (Zwiebel 1996). Myers (2000)
created a link between maintaining leading positions in the companies and the trustworthy perspective
of dividend payments. Moreover, other studies argue that top-executive managers protect minority
shareholders through dividend policy to create a reputation for treating outside shareholders well
(Gomes 2000). Parrino et al. (2003) provide evidence that firms experience dividend cuts prior to
forced CEO turnover.
Based on these arguments, we expect a company that pays dividends to have a lower probability
of forced CEO turnover. High dividend yields increase the demand for the company’s shares, which is
expected to mitigate the potential conflict between managers and shareholders.
Parrino (1997) introduced sector homogeneity as a determinant of CEO turnover. He measured
sector homogeneity through a volatility indicator of the company’s stock return related to industry
return. The intuition behind this assumption refers to the fact that in more homogeneous industries,
the managerial skills required are similar, and managers can be easily replaced by others from the
same industry. The low liquidity of the Romanian capital market did not allow us to follow the same
methodology, but we indirectly studied the role of sector homogeneity on CEO turnover.

3.4. CEO Diversity, Political Influences, and CEO Turnover in Unstable Environments

3.4.1. Particularities of the Romanian Economic Environment


Due to the fact that Romania still has a poor corporate governance culture and a relatively high
perceived level of corruption (Claessens and Yurtoglu 2013), we analyzed the possibility of political
influences on CEO turnover decisions.
State ownership, and sometimes the state as the controlling shareholder, can significantly influence
the decision to change the CEO or other board members. If the CEOs of privately controlled firms are
politically connected, those companies could have increasing access to credit, as well as to regulatory
favors and government financial assistance. In these cases, the likelihood of CEO turnover is lower.
Also, if the CEOs are politically connected, this fact causes weaker turnover -performance sensitivity
(Cao et al. 2016) and the criteria for executive evaluations may be different. State-owned companies are
more likely to apply government-oriented executive evaluations that focus on political performance
rather than on their economic performance (Liu and Zhang 2018).
Taking into account several references of CEO appointments based on political criteria in different
Romanian listed companies where the state is a significant or controlling shareholder, we expect a
greater likelihood for CEO turnover after political parties (coalitions) change in parliamentary elections.
If the political forces in power change, more frequent CEO turnover could follow if political pressure is
exercised in the economic environment. Based on these considerations, our first tested hypothesis is:

Hypothesis 1 (H1). Forced CEO turnover probability is higher, subsequent to political changes in companies
with governmental ownership, especially when the government is an important shareholder.

3.4.2. Particularities Related to Post-Communist Economies


We also tested for potential inefficiencies in the labor market. A general practice of post-communist
countries is to reproduce the mechanisms from developed market economies, usually without adapting
them to their socio-cultural values (see, in this context, the complex analysis of King and Szelenyi 2005).
The problem can be even more stringent when it is cumulated to the propensity toward the conservatism
of experienced people. In this case, a foreign manager can bring an advantage in terms of experience
in a highly competitive environment and knowledge regarding the newly implemented systems.
On the other hand, the appointment of foreign CEOs is not without risk, because they are not
accustomed to the local economic environment. Due to the scarcity of the labor market, a bigger effort
may be made to appoint a foreign manager, and therefore we can expect a lower probability for a

143
JRFM 2020, 13, 59

forced turnover. However, difficulties to adapt to the new environment may worsen the performance
of the company and eventually lead to a forced CEO turnover. A correlation between a CEO’s origin
and CEO turnover points to a possible gap in the managerial skills between domestic and foreign
CEOs. The second tested hypothesis is:

Hypothesis 2 (H2). The foreign origin of a CEO is correlated with the likelihood of CEO turnover.

Some previous empirical evidence shows that women have behavioral and attitudinal differences
compared to males (Beck et al. 2018). Female CEOs/directors tend to be less overconfident in their
decision making than men, and are more likely to express their independent views than male directors.
Furthermore, Srinidhi et al. (2020) show that female CEOs/directors from US companies manage
to overcome the obstacles of being in the minority and not having the reputational advantages of
long-serving male directors, by acting as norm change catalysts to achieve substantial governance
changes. In this context, the boardroom dynamics could be changed in the presence of a female
CEO/director and, consequently, the intensity of discussions around difficult (financial) decision
problems could be different (Kim and Starks 2016; Chen et al. 2019). In an unstable economic and
financial environment resulting from a deep financial crisis, such as the one started in 2008, removing a
female CEO may (or may not) be more likely, depending on the goals that the company management
proposes in such a turbulent period.
Moreover, Johnson and Powell (1994), Bajtelsmit and VanDerhei (1997), and also Francis et al.
(2015), Zigraiova (2015), and Skała and Weill (2018) proved that women tend to have a stronger
risk aversion than men. Especially in the macroeconomic context of the analyzed period, a positive
correlation between CEO gender (i.e., female CEO) and the likelihood of turnover can be related to
women’s risk aversion, but a discrimination hypothesis cannot be rejected. However, the evidence on
gender differences in risk aversion is mixed. Croson and Gneezy (2009) conclude that the difference in
risk aversion between men and women becomes less significant for managers and professionals in
finance. The hypothesis of gender discrimination inside the company can be disputable, because they
have already been appointed as CEOs. However, the hypothesis of more subtle gender discrimination
from outside the company cannot be rejected. An example of such a form of discrimination is evidenced
in the work of Muravyev et al. (2009). It occurs through the more financial constraints imposed on
companies managed by female CEOs and, respectively, a lower number of approved loans or higher
credit costs relative to male managers. These differences are more important in weakly competitive
financial systems and in emergent countries and tend to diminish in developed countries. Consequently,
our third tested hypothesis is:

Hypothesis 3 (H3). Forced CEO turnover probability is higher when the CEO is a woman.

These hypotheses were tested in an economic environment that can be considered as ambiguous
and unstable, with a first sub-period of exceptional economic growth, followed by a severe financial
crisis. The financial crisis, which started in 2008, brought a general deterioration of the economic
conditions and we could thus expect an increase in the probability of forced CEO turnover (Kaplan
and Minton 2012). At the same time, financial difficulties augment the occupational stress of CEOs and
may lead to more frequent occurrences of CEO turnover. In times of crisis, companies are confronted
with a great deal of ambiguity in the strategic planning process and in their business environment,
and so should try to rely more on intuition and creativity in many parts of the management process,
including in decisions regarding their top managers and whether to change them (e.g., CEO turnover).
Based on the extensive literature in the field, Ogilvie (1998) showed that imagination and creativity
become more suitable to manage unstructured, random, and contradictory data from the environment.
In this context, we analyzed how the Romanian listed companies decide to manage a very turbulent
period, with this study focusing on the criteria for CEO turnover (gender, nationality, and/or the level
of political intrusion into a company’s life).

144
JRFM 2020, 13, 59

4. Methodology and Data


To test our hypotheses, we used two different methodological approaches, which were also
applied in the previous literature. First, similar to Brunello et al. (2003) and Hu and Leung (2012),
among others, we applied a balanced panel data analysis. The (forced) CEO turnover dummy variable
is equal to 1 if the firm had at least one (forced) CEO replacement during the year, and 0 otherwise.
Second, we considered each CEO departure separately, and we applied an unbalanced panel data
analysis (as a robustness check procedure), due to the fact that there are companies in our sample that
registered more than one CEO turnover during the same year.
First, we identified and classified the reasons for CEO turnover using the methodology also applied
by Warner et al. (1988) and Dherment-Ferere and Renneboog (2002), with necessary adjustments for the
Romanian case, described below. Additionally, we considered the reasons for CEO turnover motivated
by political manipulations and the battle for power as in Cannella and Shen (2001). We identified 12
reasons for CEO turnover (including both forced and voluntary CEO departures): retirement, health
problems, political reasons, promotion, persona non-grata, change of ownership, common succession,
pressure from shareholders, separation of the positions of CEO and Chairman of the Board, CEO
resignation, other reasons, and no public reasons. A more detailed presentation for these reasons for
our sample of Romanian listed companies can be found in the Appendix A.
Second, we divided these turnovers into two classes: forced and voluntary. However, identification
of forced departures can sometimes be very difficult when press releases are the main source of
documentation, because they rarely describe them as such. To isolate most likely forced departures,
firstly we followed Fee and Hadlock’s (2004) methodology for classifying turnover as forced. If an
article in the business press indicates that the CEO was banished, forced, or equivalent, then turnover
was defined as forced. Secondly, similar to Conyon and Florou (2002), we considered the turnover
as forced if the CEO was replaced for reasons such as political misunderstandings, conflicts with the
Board of Directors, weak performance, personality differences, and scandals. Thirdly, we followed
Dahya et al.’s (2002) methodology, considering dismissal and resignation as forced turnover. Thus,
we considered the following reasons as forced turnovers: persona non-grata, change of ownership,
pressure from shareholders, political reasons (except for the CEO of Oil Terminal who was elected in
the Romanian Parliament, due to incompatibility reasons), CEO resignation (due to conflicts with the
Board of Directors), as well as the cases in which no reason was given for CEO replacement, in case of
weak pre-succession performances.
The sample contained 58 CEO turnover events that occurred in 36 companies. In the balanced panel
data approach, they represent 53 company year CEO turnover observations out of the 426 observations
collected between 2005 and 2010 for the whole sample of 71 companies. Hence, CEO turnover occurred
in 12.47% of the cases and forced CEO turnover in 6.81% of the observations.
In the balanced panel analysis, we considered both accounting-based and market-based returns,
computed at the end of the year previous to that when the CEO turnover occurred. In subsidiary,
we also took into account in our models the annual returns of the year when the CEO was changed.
We presumed that effects of the dismissed CEO’s activity might also occur after the CEO was changed,
due to his/her strategic position in the company. In the unbalanced panel analysis, the performance
indicators were determined for 12 months before the date of the succession announcement and, because
we did not exclude observations for CEOs who served less than a year, we computed the return for the
period when they held the position and annualized the result.
To compute industry annual return, we used all of the Romanian companies listed on the BSE
and on the over-the-counter market (former RASDAQ) that had the same first two industry code
digits. It has been proven that this classification offers a higher homogeneity of returns than statistical
clustering or three- or four-digit classification (Chan et al. 2007; Clarke 1989). To minimize the
possibility of biases in our results due to outliers, the performance variables, the price/book value,
and the leverage ratios were winsorized at 1% and 99%. We did not include the same regression
variables that had a correlation coefficient equal to or greater than 0.4. Following the literature and the

145
JRFM 2020, 13, 59

hypotheses presented in Section 2, we applied a binary logit model to estimate the forced CEO turnover
equation. Logit regressions are commonly used in management turnover studies in order to show that
the likelihood of turnover is sensitive to changes in firm performance (see Powers 2005 for an extensive
literature in this field). Consistent with previous literature, we included as independent variables
several accounting-based and market-based performance indicators, various corporate governance
indicators, variables related to the financial features of the firm, and industry dummies. Additionally,
we included new variables for foreign CEOs and female CEOs, for the financial crisis that started in
2008, as well as an interactional variable for government ownership and political changes.
The use of composite variables in logit regressions was proved to be problematic by Powers (2005)
due to the non-linearity of the model employed. However, in our analysis, the composite variable acts
as a stand-alone variable, as its components were not used separately in the regression. Consequently,
it can be interpreted as such, the sign of its coefficient being statistically significant.
Our sample included all firms listed, during the 2005–2010 period, on the first and second tiers of
the BSE, except for the BSE itself (a listed company which became public in June 2010). We studied
public companies because, for small and/or unlisted Romanian companies, it would be very difficult
to collect these data, and the corporate governance mechanisms are expected to not be properly
implemented. The sample cannot be extended due to the small dimension of the Romanian capital
market. The 36 companies that experienced CEO turnovers represent one half of all listed firms on the
first and second tiers of the BSE in 2010, with average sales of 904 million RON, an average number
of employees of 1728, and an average stock market capitalization of 985 million RON. The analyzed
time span includes a period of exceptional development of the Romanian capital market (2005–2008),
but also one of economic recession (2009–2010). Besides, this period is particularly interesting due
to the ongoing corporate governance reforms and the adoption of the Romanian Code of Corporate
Governance in 2009.
Most of the data regarding the CEO’s identity, CEO ownership, board independence, the reasons
for CEO turnover, the succession type (voluntary/forced), and the exact date when the CEO was
changed were hand-collected through corporate websites. Additionally, different Romanian business
newspapers (Ziarul Financiar, Capital, Săptămâna Financiară, and Business Magazin) and news
agencies (Mediafax and Daily Business) were accessed. Data for corporate governance variables and
the accounting and financial data were from quarterly and annual company reports provided by the
BSE. The explanatory variables are described in Table 1.

Table 1. Description of explanatory variables used in the model.

Variable Description
Panel A: Variables related to the characteristics of the economic environment
The variable ‘political change’ equals 1 for the years with
Political change
governmental changes and 0 otherwise
Crisis dummy 1 1 for the years 2009 and 2010 and 0 otherwise
Crisis dummy 2 1 for the year 2009 and 0 otherwise
Industry dummies
Panel B: Variables related to peculiarities of post-communist countries
Foreign CEO 1 if the CEO is a foreign citizen and 0 otherwise
Female CEO 1 if the CEO is a woman and 0 otherwise
Firm and industry performance variables
Panel C: Accounting-based performance variables
Return on assets (ROA) Operating profit/(total equity + long term debt)
Operating margin Operating profit/net sales
Return on equity (ROE) Net income/Shareholders’ equity
Industry-adjusted ROA ROA – Industry average ROA
Industry-adjusted operating margin Operating margin-Industry average operating margin

146
JRFM 2020, 13, 59

Table 1. Cont.

Variable Description
Panel D: Market-based performance variables
Total stock return Dividend yield + capital gains yield
Price to book value Stock price/book value per share
Panel E: Other firm specific variables
Firm size Ln (net sales)
Leverage Long term debt/Equity
1 if the company paid dividends during the year and 0
Dividend dummy
otherwise
Corporate governance variables
Panel F: Ownership structure
Proportion of votes/cash flow rights held by the largest
First shareholder ownership
shareholder when the CEO was changed
1 if the largest shareholder’s ownership exceeds 50% and
First shareholder ownership dummy
0 otherwise
Government ownership Proportion of votes held by the state
CEO ownership dummy 1, if current CEO is also shareholder and 0 otherwise
Significant CEO ownership dummy 1, if CEO’s ownership exceeds 5% and 0 otherwise
The sum of votes held by all institutional investors, each
Institutional cumulative ownership
of them holding more than 5% of the votes
1 if the cumulative ownership of the institutional
Institutional cumulative ownership dummy over 33%
shareholders exceeds 33% of the votes and 0 otherwise
1 if the cumulative ownership of the institutional
Institutional cumulative ownership dummy over 50%
shareholders exceeds 50% of the votes and 0 otherwise
Change in institutional investors ownership
Panel G: Board characteristics
Board size Number of Directors of the Board
Number of independent directors divided by the number
Board independence
of the non-independent ones
1 if the number of independent directors is half or more
Board independence dummy
of the board size and 0 otherwise
1 for a CEO who simultaneously holds the positions of
CEO-Chairman duality
Chairman of the Board and CEO and 0 otherwise
Notes: Furthermore, we constructed two variables for the second largest shareholder ownership, as a percentage of
common shares, and respectively as a dummy variable equal to 1, if the second shareholder’s ownership equals or
exceeds 10% of the total voting rights and 0 otherwise. We found no empirical evidence of a correlation between
these variables and the CEO turnover occurrence.

Some descriptive statistics for the variables used in the model are presented in Table 2. These data
emphasize that the average values for the firm’s performance ratios are low, reflecting a negative
influence of the global financial crisis starting in late 2008. The same trend is sustained by the price
to book median value of 0.95, suggesting that, for more than half of the companies in the sample,
the market value of the company is lower than the book value of shareholders’ equity. This finding
may also be related to the low liquidity and low degree of informational efficiency of the Romanian
capital market.
Table 2 shows that 11% of the listed companies have foreign CEOs. We found evidence that the
foreign origin of a manager is associated with the fact that the company is part of a foreign group.
Almost 12% of the managers in our sample were women. This is not a high figure, but compared to
other statistics, we can expect a relative significance of the manager’s gender on the likelihood of CEO
turnover occurrence. For instance, Kato and Long (2006) emphasize that in 2002, the proportion of
female CEOs was only 4% in China.
The average first shareholder’s ownership was around 47%, with a median value slightly above
50%. This result is important to characterize the corporate governance context of the Romanian market.
It is presumably associated with important agency problems, especially between controlling and

147
JRFM 2020, 13, 59

minority shareholders, and with high opportunities of extracting private benefits from control on a
capital market with high control premiums.3

Table 2. Summary statistics on CEO turnover for the Romanian listed companies during the
2005–2010 period.

Average Median Minimum Maximum Standard


Indicator
Value Value Value Value Deviation
Variables related to the characteristics of the economic environment
Crisis dummy 1 0.500 0.500 0 1 0.500
Crisis dummy 2 0.167 0 0 1 0.373
Political change 0.333 0 0 1 0.471
Variables related to peculiarities of post-communist countries
Foreign CEO 0.113 0 0 1 0.317
Female CEO 0.116 0 0 1 0.320
Firm and industry performance variables (values in coefficients)
Return on assets 0.038 0.047 −1.152 0.458 0.165
Operating margin 0.032 0.009 −0.334 0.581 0.135
Return on equity 0.056 0.058 −0.785 0.446 0.148
Industry-adjusted ROA 0.001 0.003 −0.624 0.576 0.122
Industry adjusted operating margin 0.099 0.072 −0.456 0.715 0.165
3-years average ROA 0.069 0.066 −0.542 0.387 0.117
3-years average ROE 0.065 0.069 −0.408 0.402 0.119
3-years average operating margin 0.105 0.072 −0.228 0.688 0.153
Total stock return 0.343 0.180 −0.935 4.976 0.779
Price to Book value 1.543 0.950 0.080 8.560 1.688
Other firm specific variables
(ln) Firm size 18.558 18.322 14.996 23.670 1.604
Leverage (coefficients) 0.172 0.045 0 1.992 0.314
Dividend dummy 0.324 0 0 1 0.468
Corporate governance variables
CEO Turnover 0.125 0 0 1 0.331
CEO forced turnover 0.068 0 0 1 0.252
First shareholder ownership (%) 47.418 52.000 0.0001 98.000 25.864
First shareholder ownership dummy 0.542 1 0 1 0.499
Government ownership (%) 3.816 0 0 79 14.475
CEO ownership dummy 0.399 0 0 1 0.491
Significant CEO ownership dummy 0.241 0 0 1 0.429
Institutional cumulative ownership (%) 26.070 11 0 93 30.771
Institutional cumulative ownership over 33% 0.340 0 0 1 0.475
Institutional cumulative ownership over 50% 0.298 0 0 1 0.458
Change in institutional investors’ ownership (%) 0.980 0 −58.000 93.000 10.182
Board size 5.556 5 2 11 2.233
Board independence 2.369 2 0 6 1.713
Board independence dummy 0.817 1 0 1 0.388
CEO-Chairman duality 0.373 0 0 1 0.485
Source: Authors’ calculation based on data provided by Bucharest Stock Exchange and the annual reports of the
companies in the sample.

The average percentage of votes held by all institutional investors, each of them holding more
than 5% of the votes, was 26.07%, but in half of the cases, it was below 11%. The average ownership
of institutional investors was around half of the average institutional ownership for US firms in the
work by Helwege et al. (2012). The standard deviations for all the variables regarding institutional
ownership recorded high values, showing significant differences between the listed companies in
our sample. Only 29% of the companies had institutional investors who own more than 50% of the
equity. This may lower the incentives of institutional investors to be actively involved in controlling

3 Dragotă et al. (2013) documented an average value of control premium around 115% and a median one of 25% for 173
tender offers carried through the BSE and RASDAQ for the period 2000–2011.

148
JRFM 2020, 13, 59

the companies efficiently. Due to the fact that, in the existing literature, it was shown that the role and
involvement of institutional investors in the decision to change CEOs (forced) is even greater as they
hold more shares (Kang et al. 2018), the results for this independent variable in the case of Romania are
somewhat uncertain.
The average board size is around five members, with a maximum value of eleven members.
These values are somewhat similar to the size in other one-tier board systems, such as in the US
(Yermack 1996; Denis et al. 1997; Denis and Sarin 1999), Belgium (Renneboog 2000), Italy (Brunello et
al. 2003), and China (Kato and Long 2006). We can bring into the discussion the arguments of Yermack
(1996) for smaller and more efficient boards that monitor the executive managers more effectively. Thus,
smaller board size can emphasize the negative relation between firm performance and CEO turnover.

5. Results and Discussion


Table 3 presents evidence on the relation between firm performance, CEO characteristics, political
influence, industry sector, or financial crisis and CEO turnover likelihood. In accordance with
H1, the interactional variable for political change and governmental ownership is positively and
significantly correlated with forced CEO turnover. This relation is proof of the political influence on
the Board of Directors’ decisions, especially when the Romanian government owns an important share
of total equity.
Consistent with H2, the foreign origin of the CEO for the Romanian listed companies is positively
and significantly correlated with the likelihood of forced CEO turnover (see Table 3). The probability
of forced turnover was higher (i.e., 15–20%) if the CEO was of foreign origin. This result is in line
with Boenisch and Schneider (2013), who found that one of the communist legacies is the formation of
strong closed informal connections, difficult to breach, and it can also be a clue for explaining foreign
managers’ difficulties to adapt to the Romanian environment.
We found a positive and significant correlation between the female CEO dummy and CEO forced
turnover likelihood (similar to the results from Kato and Long 2006). The probability of forced turnover
was higher (i.e., 7–8%) when the CEO was a woman.
We also found evidence that the crisis dummy is positively and significantly correlated with forced
CEO turnover. The probability of forced CEO turnover was around 7% higher in 2009, amidst the crisis,
than in other years from the database. This result is in accordance with Kaplan and Minton (2012),
concluding that the expectations regarding the industry and market performances (decreasing during
an economic crisis) negatively influence the probability of forced CEO turnover. An unstable economic
and financial environment also puts pressure on the Romanian listed companies’ management, and,
consequently, the probability of forced CEO turnover is higher than in more stable economic times.
Our results are in line with the results from the existing literature and show that CEO turnover
(particularly forced replacements) is inversely related to firm and industry performances (Hu and
Leung 2012; Kato and Long 2006; Muravyev et al. 2010, among others). We also found that companies
with low industry-adjusted return are more likely to have forced CEO turnovers (see Eisfeldt and
Kuhnen 2013). Due to the anomalies of the Romanian capital market, we expected the accounting-based
performance indicators to be more reliable than the market-based returns. We used similar models for
forced CEO turnover and the three different market-based performance measures (price to book value,
total stock return, and capital gains return), but we found no significant relation with the probability of
forced CEO turnover4 .
The average marginal effects explain how sensitive the probability of CEO forced turnover is
to independent variables. Some differences can be noticed in the amplitude of the average marginal
effects, depending on the performance measures used. A 1% decrease in the return was correlated
with an increase of the probability of CEO forced turnover of around 0.3% if we measured firm

4 These results are available upon request.

149
JRFM 2020, 13, 59

performance using ROE, 0.5% if the performance indicator was ROA, and 0.54% for the operating
margin. These results suggest that the Romanian listed companies put less emphasis on shareholders’
interests than on the whole capital invested by creditors and shareholders for CEO turnover decisions.
A 1% decrease of the three-year average return was correlated, with slightly lower increases in the
likelihood of forced CEO turnover than in the case of the performance indicators computed for the
previous year. This result could be an argument for the assumption that for the Board of Directors,
the short-term perspective of the performance is prevalent before the long-term perspective in their
forced CEO replacement decisions. Our results are similar to Kaplan and Minton (2012), but with lower
magnitude than those of Eisfeldt and Kuhnen (2013). One possible explanation for the difference in the
magnitude of the changes can be the occurrence of the financial crisis during the analyzed period.
We found almost similar results for the likelihood of forced CEO turnover when we used
contemporary firm performance measures. When we used three-year average ROA and ROE, the results
were no longer statistically significant.
Regarding the scarcity of the managerial labor market, we found evidence that the utilities,
energy, and pharmaceutics sectors are more likely to force CEOs to leave their positions. Our result
is in accordance with Parrino (1997), who found that the utilities and energy sectors are among the
most homogeneous.
With regards to the relation between CEO turnover and different corporate governance
characteristics, first we found that the CEO–Chairman duality is inversely related to the likelihood of
forced CEO turnover (Hazarika et al. 2012; Helwege et al. 2012; Hu and Leung 2012). This correlation can
be explained through a higher influence of the CEO on the Board of Directors and higher opportunities
for the CEO to maintain informational asymmetries. For our sample, the probability of forced CEO
turnover was lower, by around 10%, for companies where CEOs held a dual position, compared to the
rest of the sample.
Second, the presence of the controlling shareholder was associated with a lower probability of
forced CEO turnover (see Brunello et al. 2003; Parrino 1997), which is consistent with a greater probability
of type II agency conflicts. All other variables related to ownership had no statistical significance.
Third, similar to Parrino et al. (2003), the “voting with their feet” behavior can be validated for
the Romanian listed companies. By some means, this result is expected for a transitional country with
an enforced Corporate Governance Code only from 2009. Moreover, the results may be due to the
lower holdings of the institutional investors compared to developed countries. For US companies,
Helwege et al. (2012) showed that although the net change in institutional ownership prior to forced
CEO turnover is negative and significant in the first sub-period of their analysis, the extent of “voting
with their feet” is small and declines over time, and so becomes irrelevant in the second sub-period.
The authors signal that the role of institutional investors in forced CEO turnover tends to diminish and
that research must move toward other determinants. Such empirical evidence could also explain a lower
statistical significance for this variable, registered for our Romanian sample for the period 2005–2010.
Fourth, we found no influence of board size and independence (as in Muravyev et al. 2010).
This result can be explained by a limited effectiveness of corporate governance mechanisms, or through
the activism of the first large shareholders, who put in place other mechanisms to control the managers.
Additionally, we cannot exclude the assumption of a passive attitude of the outside directors. The results
are somewhat similar to Miyajima et al. (2018), where the independent outside directors have no
significant effect of enhancing CEO turnover sensitivity to ROE. The CEO turnover sensitivity to ROA
is higher when boards have three or more independent outside directors than when boards have only
one outside director.
Leverage is negative and statistically significantly correlated with the likelihood of forced CEO
turnover (see Table 3). This link shows the existence of agency conflicts between managers and
shareholders, which can be alleviated using the supplementary monitoring realized by the creditors.
The creditors have the concern and appropriate skills to monitor the firms, and the shareholders benefit
from their financial expertise.

150
Table 3. Estimates of binary logit models on forced CEO turnover using the accounting-based returns.

Expected Equation Equation Equation Equation Equation Equation Equation Equation


Variables
Sign (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
−9.1228
JRFM 2020, 13, 59

Industry-adjusted return on assets - [0.00]


−0.493
−4.54623
Return on assets (ROA) - [0.00]
−0.469
−5.72032
Return on equity (ROE) - [0.00]
−0.323
−5.94133
Industry-adjusted operating margin - [0.00]
−0.351
−9.01518
Operating margin - [0.00]
−0.542
−5.2662

151
3 years average return on assets - [0.01]
−0.312
−5.18364
3 years average return on equity - [0.00]
−0.302
−7.0803
3 years average operating margin - [0.02]
−0.432
2.034089 1.259163 1.866373 2.31829 2.197453 2.40688 2.12277 1.98776
Foreign CEO +/− [0.02] [0.00] [0.02] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.01]
0.152 0.161 0.15 0.202 0.183 0.219 0.187 0.177
1.292348 0.645056 0.951188 1.072577 1.069988 0.896042 0.815577 0.82362
Crisis dummy 2 + [0.02] [0.06] [0.09] [0.05] [0.05] [0.07] [0.097] [0.02]
0.083 0.073 0.061 0.075 0.075 0.061 0.055 0.058
1.279092 0.537237 1.122408 0.869574 1.096683 1.13084
Female CEO + [0.08] [0.15] [0.098] [0.23] [0.09] [0.08]
0.081 0.075 0.078 0.084
Table 3. Cont.

Expected Equation Equation Equation Equation Equation Equation Equation Equation


Variables
Sign (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
0.040583 0.025951 0.040694 0.035569 0.040903 0.035542 0.034834 0.03583
Government ownership × Political change +
JRFM 2020, 13, 59

[0.01] [0.00] [0.00] [0.07] [0.01] [0.07] [0.07] [0.045]


−3.3509 −1.60233 −2.57295 −2.57654 −2.33399 −2.65378 −2.48547 −1.9570
CEO−Chairman duality − [0.08] [0.00] [0.02] [0.00] [0.01] [0.00] [0.00] [0.02]
−0.104 −0.136 −0.100 −0.109 −0.100 −0.110 −0.106 −0.091
−0.03460
Change in institutional investors ownership Insignificant/− [0.08]
−0.002
−1.45821 −1.05737 −1.84211 −2.06363 −1.50065 −1.74685 −1.77616 −1.4832
First shareholder dummy − [0.05] [0.00] [0.02] [0.00] [0.03] [0.00] [0.00] [0.03]
−0.084 −0.113 −0.115 −0.135 −0.096 −0.115 −0.116 −0.099
−0.35245 −0.26063 −0.42307 −0.53417 −0.35748 −0.4673 −0.43460 −0.3281
Ln (net sales) − [0.09] [0.02] [0.08] [0.01] [0.099] [0.01] [0.03] [0.08]
−0.019 −0.027 −0.024 −0.032 −0.022 −0.028 −0.025 −0.020
−4.08264 −2.21574 −4.10193 −4.60895 −4.34411 −4.22106 −3.76608 −3.8271
Leverage − [0.06] [0.01] [0.09] [0.02] [0.09] [0.01] [0.02] [0.05]

152
−0.220 −0.229 −0.232 −0.272 −0.262 −0.250 −0.220 −0.234
6.210834 4.110076 6.852578 8.024094 6.278387 6.748419 6.545332 6.68263
Utilities dummy [0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00]
0.646 0.636 0.764 0.824 0.724 0.757 0.759 0.8
2.572995 2.218322 2.87868 4.258439 2.697677 3.908447 3.332632 2.8089
Energy dummy [0.08] [0.00] [0.08] [0.00] [0.06] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00]
0.21 0.321 0.278 0.465 0.256 0.426 0.358 0.299
1.524418 2.459127 2.255324 2.281926
Pharmaceutics dummy [0.00] [0.00] [0.01] [0.00]
0.206 0.23 0.208 0.213
3.636597 3.432823 5.683193 7.762265 4.091619 6.629814 6.062318 4.13335
Constant C
[0.98] [0.08] [0.19] [0.03] [0.30] [0.05] [0.095] [0.22]
Prob (LR Statistic) 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
Pseudo R2 0.37 0.4 0.33 0.3 0.3 0.29 0.3 0.27
Notes: The estimated coefficients for board independence, board size, institutional investors’ ownership, CEO ownership and second largest shareholder’s ownership are not
statistically significant and are not reported. We report p-value in brackets. Marginal effects of independent variables on likelihood of forced CEO turnover are shown in bold. Source:
authors’ estimation.
JRFM 2020, 13, 59

Due to a relatively high homogeneity in our sample regarding the size of the Romanian listed
companies, firm size becomes less important, but remains significant in explaining the CEO turnover
decisions. The results for average marginal effects show that a 1% increase of the logarithm of net sales
was associated with a decrease of around 2.5% of the likelihood of forced CEO departure.
Additionally, we analyzed separately voluntary and forced CEO turnovers. For voluntary CEO
turnover, we found similar results as for all CEO turnovers in regard to the foreign origin of CEOs and
ownership, supporting the explanations mentioned above. We found no statistically significant relation
between firm performance and the likelihood of voluntary CEO turnovers, neither for accounting-based
nor market-based returns. This result is consistent with mainstream literature, concluding that forced
CEO turnovers are related to firm and industry performances, whereas other forms of managerial
turnover are not linked to firm performance (see Eisfeldt and Kuhnen 2013).
The unreported results for the pooled data analysis were similar for CEO turnover, and also
for forced and voluntary CEO turnovers.5 Additional robustness tests were performed by gradually
introducing into the logit models the explanatory variables for both specifications (balanced and
unbalanced panel data). The results confirm the significance of all variables.

6. Conclusions
We revisited a widely studied topic in the literature—the determinants for the likelihood of CEO
turnover. To the best of our knowledge, this is the first paper to focus on CEO turnover in Romania
using a detailed and comprehensive analysis and considering financial, social, political, and corporate
governance determinants, applied to an intricate period of time, with both exceptional development
and economic recession.
For the Romanian case, our study took into consideration, for the first time, explanatory variables
for the foreign origin of a CEO, CEO gender, and the incidence of political intrusions in corporate
decisions in companies with governmental ownership. Thus, the occurrence of CEO turnover was
positively correlated with the foreign origin of the manager, supporting the hypothesis that foreign
managers experience difficulties in adapting to the Romanian economic environment. The political
influence on the CEO turnover decision was revealed when firms had large state ownership. We found
evidence that female CEOs were more likely to leave their positions than male CEOs. We also showed
that the financial crisis boosted the probability of CEO forced turnover.
We examined, as well, the role of other important corporate governance variables in the CEO
turnover process, and the results are mixed. The empirical evidence confirmed that some reforms
have been implemented. Two particular entrenchment mechanisms were emphasized, namely,
the CEO–Chairman duality and the controlling power of the largest shareholder. Additionally,
we emphasized the “voting with their feet” behavior of the institutional investors. The CEO ownership
is not significant as an entrenchment mechanism for forced CEO turnovers, but we found some
intriguing evidence of its direct relation to the likelihood of voluntary CEO turnover occurrence.
Other well-known corporate governance mechanisms, such as the second largest shareholder and the
institutional investors’ activism, seem ineffective in the sample considered.
As for the relation to several performance indicators, our results were similar to those identified
in the previous financial literature for other countries. The CEO turnover decision was strongly
and negatively related only to accounting-based performance ratios. Whatever model applied,
the market-based performance variables did not have a significant influence, and a possible explanation
could relate to the features of the Romanian capital market.
As per many empirical studies, this one has some limitations. The most important limitation
concerns the sample, which was relatively small (426 observations, with 58 CEO turnover events)
compared to similar studies in this field. This limit can usually be found in empirical studies that

5 The results are available upon request.

153
JRFM 2020, 13, 59

analyze emerging economies, especially those of Eastern and Central Europe. Due to the fact that their
capital markets are newly created or recently reopened, in many cases, the whole number of listed
companies is small and thus it is not possible to collect data sets as large as those of studies conducted
in highly developed countries (Filip and Raffournier 2010). In our study, this criticism should be
mitigated, given that the sample includes all of the Romanian listed companies (except the BSE).
Our results can be useful for practitioners, as well as for academics. The conclusions are
important for investors, and especially for foreign investors not accustomed to the Romanian economic
environment. Additionally, our findings provide a better understanding of the managerial labor market
in a transitional Eastern European country and evidence that it is still subject to political interference in
corporate decisions of state-owned companies subsequent to a change of the political party in power.
We expect the development of post-communist economies to determine substantial improvements
in corporate governance mechanisms and practices, and the CEO turnover phenomenon to follow the
trends revealed in the literature for developed countries. It would be interesting for future analysis to
mainly capture this evolution for a better understanding of the causes that trigger it.

Author Contributions: All authors contributed to the design, introduction, literature review, results, and discussion.
The database and methodology section was mostly written by A.C.-S. and R.M. The original draft preparation,
the review and editing processes, and the funding acquisition were mostly done by I.-M.D. and A.C.-S. All authors
have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.
Funding: This work was supported by the Center of Financial and Monetary Research (CEFIMO). All opinions
expressed are those of the authors and have not been endorsed by CEFIMO.
Acknowledgments: The authors would like to express their gratitude to the Bucharest Stock Exchange (BSE) and
Tradeville representatives, who provided part of the preliminary database. The results and conclusions of the
paper are entirely the authors’ responsibility and the BSE cannot be held liable for any of the opinions stated in
this research paper. The authors also wish to thank Victor Dragotă, Elena Dumitrescu, Elena Ţilică, Radu Ciobanu,
the participants of the SSEM-2013 Conference in Famagusta on 10–14 May 2013, the participants of the research
seminar of the Center of Financial and Monetary Research (CEFIMO) on 19 June 2013, and participants of the
GEBA-2019 Conference in Ias, i for their useful comments. Lastly, the authors also thank the anonymous reviewers
for their useful comments and suggestions. The remaining errors are ours.
Conflicts of Interest: The authors declare no conflicts of interest. The funders had no role in the design of the
study; in the collection, analyses, or interpretation of data; in the writing of the manuscript; to publish the results.

Appendix A. The Main Reasons for CEO Turnover for the Romanian Listed Companies 2005–2010
1. Retirement (4 cases). We consider retirement before the age of 63 as forced retirement.
2. Health problems (2 cases). We consider these cases as unforced reasons.
3. Political reasons (4 cases). Hu and Leung (2012) define three types of government intervention:
(1) the government can play the role of “invisible hand” and senior executives of state-owned
companies are political appointments; (2) the government has no control over the selection and
appointment processes; or (3) the appointment is “just window dressing, as politically affiliated
directors are puppets of management.” In Romania, the first case is the most common practice
for state-owned companies. In our sample are two state-owned companies, Transelectrica and
Transgaz, with CEO replacement in 2009. The replacement was made in both cases by the Ministry
of Economy in the first months after the new political party won the general election. Additionally,
in both cases, there was an exchange between the position of the CEO and the deputy director.
It can be noticed that the deputy directors were previously former CEOs in the same companies.
The new senior executives appointed are controversial people, influential politicians with strong
connections to the political party who won the general election.
4. Promotion (3 cases). This refers to a CEO who was promoted and made “a step forward” to take
a new position within the company. From our sample, the most relevant example is the CEO
from OMV, who resigned following the decision of the OMV group to become senior counsellor
of the Chairman of the OMV group.
5. Persona non-grata (4 cases). Multiple reasons can be considered to justify the decision to replace
the former CEO, from prolonged conflict with the board to conflict of interests or fraud; all of

154
JRFM 2020, 13, 59

them are seen as forced and illegal decisions by the CEO who was changed. Often, the real reason
for CEO replacement is not publicly announced, and thus the mass-media becomes the main
source to learn about the internal conflicts within the company.
6. Change of ownership (4 cases). If the ownership changes, CEO turnover is inevitable. In this
study, we consider these replacements as involuntary.
7. Common succession (4 cases). In our sample, these CEOs just finished their four-year mandate
and took other functions after their contract expired.
8. Pressure from the shareholders (16 cases). This is the most common reason for CEO replacements
for the Romanian listed companies for the period 2005–2010. These cases are as follows: CEO
dismissal due to low performance, change of jobs to improve firm performance, and a new
approach of the company or CEO turnover decided by the majority shareholder(s).
9. Separation of the Positions of CEO and Chairman of the Board (5). The BSE Corporate Governance
Code recommends avoiding CEO duality, as per many other similar Codes, in an international
context. On the contrary, the Romanian listed companies can be considered as following the
CEO–Chairman duality pattern.
10. CEO resignation (3). Only one case can be considered a CEO resignation, due to prolonged
conflicts with the Board concerning the company’s future direction. For the other two cases,
the public announcement mentioned only that it was the decision of those CEOs to resign from
their current positions.
11. Other reasons (2). We include two cases of CEOs who decided to remain only shareholders in
their companies and to be actively involved in other businesses.
12. No reason (8). From 59 cases of CEO turnover, in 8 cases, the companies did not give any public
motivations for these decisions.

References
Aghion, Philippe, and Jean Tirole. 1997. Formal and real authority in organizations. Journal of Political Economy
105: 1–29. [CrossRef]
Bajtelsmit, Vickie L., and Jack L. VanDerhei. 1997. Risk aversion and pension investment choices. In Positioning
Pensions for the Twenty-First Century. Edited by Michael Gordon, Olivia S. Mitchell and Marc Twinney.
Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press, pp. 45–66.
Barca, Fabrizio, and Marco Becht. 2001. The Control of Corporate Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Bhattacharya, Sudipto. 1979. Imperfect information, dividend policy, and “the bird in the hand” fallacy. The Bell
Journal of Economics 10: 259–70. [CrossRef]
Beck, Thorsten, Patrick Behr, and A. Andreas Madestam. 2018. Sex and credit: Do gender interactions matter for
credit market outcomes? Journal of Banking & Finance 87: 380–96.
Bena, Jan, and Jan Hanousek. 2008. Rent extraction by large shareholders: Evidence using dividend policy in
Czech Republic. Czech Journal of Economics and Finance (Finance a Uver) 58: 106–30.
Blackwell, David W., James A. Brickley, and Michael S. Weisbach. 1994. Accounting information and internal
performance evaluation: Evidence from Texas banks. Journal of Accounting and Economics 17: 331–58.
[CrossRef]
Boenisch, Peter, and Lutz Schneider. 2013. The social capital european legacy of communism—Results from the
Berlin wall experiment. Journal of Political Economy 32: 391–411. [CrossRef]
Bollaert, Helen, and Antoine Dilé. 2009. Changes in corporate governance quality in Estonia between 1999 and
2007. Post-Communist Economies 21: 65–84. [CrossRef]
Bolton, Patrick, and Ernst-Ludwig Von Thadden. 1998. Blocks, liquidity, and corporate control. Journal of Finance
53: 1–25. [CrossRef]
Brav, Alon, Wei Jiang, Frank Partnoy, and Randall Thomas. 2008. Hedge fund activism, corporate governance,
and firm performance. Journal of Finance 63: 1729–75. [CrossRef]
Brunello, Giorgio, Clara Graziano, and Bruno Parigi. 2003. CEO turnover in insider-dominated boards: The Italian
case. Journal of Banking & Finance 27: 1027–51.

155
JRFM 2020, 13, 59

Bushman, Robert, Zhonglan Dai, and Xue Wang. 2010. Risk and CEO turnover. Journal of Financial Economics 96:
381–98. [CrossRef]
Campbell, Colin T., Michael Gallmeyer, Shane Johnson, Jessica Rutherford, and Brooke W. Stanley. 2011.
CEO optimism and forced turnover. Journal of Financial Economics 101: 695–712. [CrossRef]
Cannella, Albert A., and Wei Shen. 2001. So close and yet so far: Promotion versus exit for CEO heirs apparent.
The Academy of Management Journal 44: 252–70.
Cao, Xiaping, Xiaofei Pan, Meijun Qian, and Gary Gang Tian. 2016. Political capital and CEO entrenchment:
Evidence from CEO turnover in Chinese non SOEs. Journal of Corporate Finance 42: 1–14. [CrossRef]
Caruso, Alberto, Lucrezia Reichlin, and Giovanni Ricco. 2019. Financial and fiscal interaction in the Euro Area
crisis: This time was different. European Economic Review 119: 333–55. [CrossRef]
Chan, Louis K.C., Josef Lakonishok, and Bhaskaran Swaminathan. 2007. Industry classification and return co
movement. Financial Analysts Journal 63: 56–70. [CrossRef]
Chen, Jie, Woon Sau Leung, Wei Song, and Marc Goergen. 2019. Why female board representation matters:
The role of female directors in reducing male CEO overconfidence. Journal of Empirical Finance 53: 70–90.
[CrossRef]
Claessens, Stijn, and Simeon Djankov. 1999. Enterprise performance and management turnover in the Czech
Republic. European Economic Review 43: 1115–24. [CrossRef]
Claessens, Stijn, and Simeon Djankov. 2000. Manager incentives and turnover of managers: Evidence from the Czech
Republic. New York/London: St. Martin’s/Macmillan Press.
Claessens, Stijn, and Burcin B. Yurtoglu. 2013. Corporate governance in emerging markets: A survey. Emerging
Markets Review 15: 1–33. [CrossRef]
Clarke, Richard N. 1989. SICs as delineators of economic markets. Journal of Business 62: 17–31. [CrossRef]
Conyon, Martin J., and Annita Florou. 2002. Top executive dismissal, ownership and corporate performance.
Journal Accounting and Business Research 32: 209–25. [CrossRef]
Cremers, K.J. Martijn, and Vinay B. Nair. 2005. Governance mechanisms and equity prices. Journal of Finance 60:
2859–94. [CrossRef]
Cronqvist, Henrik, Anil K. Makhija, and Scott E. Yonker. 2012. Behavioral consistency in corporate finance:
CEO personal and corporate leverage. Journal of Financial Economics 103: 20–40. [CrossRef]
Croson, Rachel, and Uri Gneezy. 2009. Gender differences in preferences. Journal of Economic Literature 47: 448–74.
[CrossRef]
Dahya, Jay, Jojn J. McConnell, and Nickolaos G. Travlos. 2002. The Cadbury Committee, corporate performance
and top management turnover. Journal of Finance 57: 461–83. [CrossRef]
Del Guercio, Diane, Laura Wallis, and Tracie Woidtke. 2008. Do Boards pay attention when institutional investors
‘just vote no’? Journal of Financial Economics 90: 84–103. [CrossRef]
Denis, David J., Diane K. Denis, and Atulya Sarin. 1997. Ownership structure and top executive turnover. Journal
of Financial Economics 45: 193–221. [CrossRef]
Denis, David J., and Atulya Sarin. 1999. Ownership and Board structures in publicly traded corporations. Journal
of Financial Economics 52: 187–223. [CrossRef]
Dherment-Ferere, Isabelle, and Luc D.R. Renneboog. 2002. Share price reactions to CEO resignations and large
shareholder monitoring in listed French companies. In Convergence and Diversity of Corporate Governance
Regimes and Capital Markets. Edited by Joseph A. McCahery, Piet Moerland, Theo Raaijmakers and
Luc Renneboog. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 297–324.
Dobroţeanu, Camelia L., Laurent, iu Dobroţeanu, and Adriana S. Răileanu. 2010. Reporting on corporate
governance—A case study on Romanian companies. Transformations in Business & Economics 9: 273–88.
Dragotă, Victor, and Eugen Mitrică. 2004. Emergent capital markets’ efficiency: The case of Romania. European
Journal of Operational Research 155: 353–60. [CrossRef]
Dragotă, Victor, Carmen Lipară, and Radu Ciobanu. 2013. Agency problems and synergistic effects in Romania:
The determinants of the control premium. Finance a úvěr-Czech Journal of Economics and Finance 63: 197–219.
Dragotă, Victor, and Elena V. Ţilică. 2014. Market efficiency of the post communist East European stock markets.
Central European Journal of Operations Research 22: 307–37. [CrossRef]
Eisfeldt, Andrea, and Camelia Kuhnen. 2013. CEO turnover in a competitive assignment framework. Journal of
Financial Economics 109: 351–72. [CrossRef]

156
JRFM 2020, 13, 59

Eriksson, Tor. 2005. Managerial pay and executive turnover in the Czech and Slovak Republics. Economics of
Transition 13: 659–77. [CrossRef]
Faccio, Mara, and Larry H.P. Lang. 2002. The ultimate ownership of western European corporations. Journal of
Financial Economics 65: 365–95. [CrossRef]
Fee, Edward C., and Charles J. Hadlock. 2004. Management turnover across the corporate hierarchy. Journal of
Accounting and Economics 37: 3–38. [CrossRef]
Fidrmuc, Jana P., and Jan Fidrmuc. 2007. Fire the manager to improve performance? Managerial turnover and
incentives after privatization in the Czech Republic. Economics of Transition 15: 505–33. [CrossRef]
Filip, Andrei, and Bernard Raffournier. 2010. The value relevance of earnings in a transition economy: The case of
Romania. The International Journal of Accounting 45: 77–103. [CrossRef]
Francis, Bill, Iftekhar Hasan, Jong Chool Park, and Qiang Wu. 2015. Gender differences in financial reporting
decision making: Evidence from accounting conservatism. Contemporary Accounting Research 32: 1285–318.
[CrossRef]
Gomes, Armando. 2000. Going public without governance: Managerial reputation effects. Journal of Finance 52:
615–46. [CrossRef]
Guo, Lixiong, and Ronald W. Masulis. 2015. Board structure and monitoring: New evidence from CEO turnovers.
The Review of Financial Studies 28: 2770–811. [CrossRef]
Hanousek, Jan, Evzen Kocenda, and Jan Svejnar. 2007. Origin and concentration. corporate ownership, control
and performance in firms after privatization. The Economics of Transition 15: 1–31. [CrossRef]
Hazarika, Sonali, Lonathan Karpoff, and Rajarishi Nahata. 2012. Internal corporate governance, CEO turnover,
and earnings management. Journal of Financial Economics 104: 44–69. [CrossRef]
Helwege, Jean, Vincent J. Intintoli, and Andrew Zhang. 2012. Voting with their feet or activism? Institutional
investors’ impact on CEO turnover. Journal of Corporate Finance 18: 22–37. [CrossRef]
Holmström, Bengt, and Jean Tirole. 1983. Market liquidity and performance monitoring. Journal of Political
Economy 101: 678–709. [CrossRef]
Hu, Jinshuai, and Jeong-Bon Kim. 2019. The relative usefulness of cash flows versus accrual earnings for CEO
turnover decisions across countries: The role of investor protection. Journal of International Accounting,
Auditing and Taxation 34: 91–107. [CrossRef]
Hu, Fang, and Sidney Leung. 2012. Top management turnover, firm performance and government control:
Evidence from China’s listed state-owned enterprises. The International Journal of Accounting 47: 235–62.
[CrossRef]
Huson, Mark R., Robert Parrino, and Laura T. Starks. 2001. Internal monitoring mechanisms and CEO turnover:
A long-term perspective. Journal of Finance 56: 2265–97. [CrossRef]
Isakov, Dusan, and Jean-Philippe Weisskopf. 2014. Are founding family’s special blockholders? An investigation
of controlling shareholder influence on firm performance. Journal of Banking & Finance 41: 1–16.
Jenter, Dirk, and Fadi Kanaan. 2015. CEO turnover and relative performance evaluation. The Journal of Finance 70:
2155–84. [CrossRef]
Johnson, Johnnie E.V., and Philip L. Powell. 1994. Decision making, risk and gender: Are managers different?
British Journal of Management 5: 123–38. [CrossRef]
Kaplan, Seven N., and Bernadette A. Minton. 2012. How has CEO turnover changed? International Review of
Finance 12: 57–87. [CrossRef]
Kato, Takao, and Cheryl Long. 2006. CEO turnover, firm performance, and enterprise reform in China: Evidence
from micro data. Journal of Comparative Economics 34: 796–817. [CrossRef]
Kang, Jun-Koo, Juan Luo, and Na Hyun Seung. 2018. Are institutional investors with multiple blockholdings
effective monitors? Journal of Financial Economics 128: 576–602. [CrossRef]
Kim, Daehyun, and Laura T. Starks. 2016. Gender diversity on corporate Boards: Do women contribute unique
skills? American Economic Review 106: 267–71. [CrossRef]
King, Lawrence P., and Ivan Szelenyi. 2005. The new capitalism in Eastern Europe: Towards a comparative
political economy of post-communism. In Handbook of economic sociology. Edited by Neil Smelser and
Richard Swedberg. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Leker, Jens, and Soren Salomo. 2000. CEO turnover and corporate performance. Scandinavian Journal of Management
16: 287–303. [CrossRef]

157
JRFM 2020, 13, 59

Lin, Ying-Fen, and Victor Wei-Chi Liu. 2004. Firm performance, corporate governance, compensation, and CEO
turnover in Taiwan. Asia Pacific Management Journal 9: 603–19.
Liu, Feng, and Linlin Zhang. 2018. Executive turnover in China’s state-owned enterprises: Government-oriented
or market-oriented? China Journal of Accounting Research 11: 129–49. [CrossRef]
Maury, Benjamin, and Anete Pajuste. 2002. Controlling shareholders, agency problems and dividend policy in
Finland. Finnish Journal of Business Economics 1: 15–45.
Miyajima, Hideaki, Ryo Ogawa, and Takuji Saito. 2018. Changes in corporate governance and top executive
turnover: The evidence from Japan. Journal of the Japanese and International Economies 47: 17–31. [CrossRef]
Muravyev, Alexander. 2003. Turnover of senior managers in Russian privatized firms. Comparative Economic
Studies 45: 148–72. [CrossRef]
Muravyev, Alexander, Oleksandr Talavera, Olga Bilyk, and Bogdana Grechaniuk. 2010. Is corporate governance
effective in Ukraine? A crude test using chief executive officer turnover data. Eastern European Economics 48:
5–24. [CrossRef]
Muravyev, Alexander, Oleksandr Talavera, and Dorothea Schäfer. 2009. Entrepreneurs’ gender and financial
constraints: Evidence from international data. Journal of Comparative Economics 37: 270–86. [CrossRef]
Murphy, Kevin J., and Jerold L. Zimmerman. 1993. Financial Performance Surrounding CEO Turnover. Journal of
Accounting and Economics 16: 273–315. [CrossRef]
Myers, Stewart C. 2000. Outside equity. Journal of Finance 55: 1005–37. [CrossRef]
Ogilvie, Dt. 1998. Creative action as a dynamic strategy: Using imagination to improve strategic solutions in
unstable environments. Journal of Business Research 41: 49–56. [CrossRef]
Parrino, Robert. 1997. CEO turnover and outside succession: A cross-sectional analysis. Journal of Financial
Economics 46: 165–97. [CrossRef]
Parrino, Robert, Richard W. Sias, and Laura T. Starks. 2003. Voting with their feet: Institutional ownership changes
around forced CEO turnover. Journal of Financial Economics 68: 3–46. [CrossRef]
Powers, Eric. 2005. Interpreting logit regressions with interaction terms: An application to the management
turnover literature. Journal of Corporate Finance 11: 504–22. [CrossRef]
Renneboog, Luc. 2000. Ownership, managerial control and the governance of companies Brussels Stock Exchange.
Journal of Banking & Finance 24: 1959–95.
Ross, Stephen A. 1977. The determination of financial structure: The incentive—Signalling approach. Bell Journal
of Economics and Management Science 8: 23–40. [CrossRef]
Shleifer, Andrei, and Robert W. Vishny. 1997. A survey of corporate governance. Journal of Finance 52: 737–83.
[CrossRef]
Skała, Dorota, and Laurent Weill. 2018. Does CEO gender matter for bank risk? Economic Systems 42: 64–74.
[CrossRef]
Srinidhi, Bin, Yie Sun, Hao Zhang, and Shiqiang Chen. 2020. How do female directors improve board governance?
A mechanism based on norm changes, Journal of Contemporary Accounting & Economics 16: 100–18.
Warner, Jerold B., Ross L. Watts, and Karen H. Wruck. 1988. Stock prices and top management changes. Journal of
Financial Economics 20: 461–92. [CrossRef]
Weisbach, Michael S. 1988. Outside directors and CEO turnover. Journal of Financial Economics 20: 431–60.
[CrossRef]
Yermack, David. 1996. Higher market valuation of companies with a small Board of directors. Journal of Financial
Economics 40: 185–211. [CrossRef]
Zigraiova, Diana. 2015. Management Board Composition of Banking Institutions and Bank Risk-Taking: The Case of the
Czech Republic. Working Papers 2015/14. Prague: Czech National Bank.
Zwiebel, Jeffrey. 1996. Dynamic capital structure under managerial entrenchment. American Economic Review 86:
1197–215.

© 2020 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access
article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution
(CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).

158
Journal of
Risk and Financial
Management

Article
The Impact of Brand Relationships on Corporate
Brand Identity and Reputation—An
Integrative Model
Teresa Barros 1 , Paula Rodrigues 2 , Nelson Duarte 1 , Xue-Feng Shao 3 , F. V. Martins 4 ,
H. Barandas-Karl 4 and Xiao-Guang Yue 1,5,6,7, *
1 CIICESI-ESTG, Politécnico do Porto, 4610-156 Felgueiras, Portugal; tbarros@estg.ipp.pt (T.B.);
nduarte@estg.ipp.pt (N.D.)
2 Faculty of Economics and Management, Universidade Lusíada Norte, 4369-006 Porto, Portugal;
paula_rodrigues@por.ulusiada.pt
3 Business School, University of Sydney, Sydney 2006, Australia; xuefeng.shao@sydney.edu.au
4 Faculty of Economics, University of Porto, 4099-002 Porto, Portugal; vmartins@fep.up.pt (F.V.M.);
barandas@fep.up.pt (H.B.-K.)
5 Department of Computer Science and Engineering, School of Sciences, European University Cyprus,
Nicosia 1516, Cyprus
6 Rattanakosin International College of Creative Entrepreneurship, Rajamangala University of Technology
Rattanakosin, Nakhon Pathom 73170, Thailand
7 School of Domestic and International Business, Banking and Finance, Romanian-American University,
012101 Bucharest, Romania
* Correspondence: x.yue@external.euc.ac.cy

Received: 9 May 2020; Accepted: 15 June 2020; Published: 22 June 2020

Abstract: The current literature focuses on the cocreation of brands in dynamic contexts, but the
impact of the relationships among brands on branding is poorly documented. To address this
gap a concept is proposed concerning the relationships between brands and a model is developed,
showing the influence of the latter on the identity and reputation of brands. Therefore, the goal
of this study is to develop a brand relationships concept and to build a framework relating it with
corporate brand identity and reputation, in a higher consumer involvement context like higher
education. Structural equation modelling (SEM) was used for this purpose. In line with this,
interviews, cooperatively developed by higher education lecturers and brand managers, were carried
out with focus groups of higher education students, and questionnaires conducted, with 216 complete
surveys obtained. Data are analyzed using confirmatory factor analysis and structural equation
modelling. Results demonstrate that the concept of brand relationships comprises three dimensions:
trust, commitment, and motivation. The structural model reveals robustness regarding the selected
fit indicators, demonstrating that the relationships between brands influence brand identity and
reputation. This suggests that managers must choose and promote brand relationships that gel with
the identity and reputation of the primary brand they manage, to develop an integrated balanced
product range.

Keywords: brand interrelationships; corporate identity; brand reputation; higher education;


students’ perceptions

1. Introduction
Consumer brand knowledge is multidimensional and needs to be understood and accounted
for, in order to provide the right perspective and background for research on branding as it relates to
consumers (Keller 2003). This research aims at developing a concept that defines the relationships

JRFM 2020, 13, 133; doi:10.3390/jrfm13060133 159 www.mdpi.com/journal/jrfm


JRFM 2020, 13, 133

among brands and analyzes the influences on brand identity and the reputation of corporate brands.
The context under study is higher education. We propose a model for higher education institutions
which integrates the particularities of brand relationships in the management of corporate brand
identity and reputation. Academics and professionals value reputation as a precious asset, as it
reduces stakeholders’ uncertainty about the future and increases the value of goods and services.
Where branding is concerned, the strength of reputation lies in the corporate brand’s promise, therefore
companies should keep it as a means of managing corporate reputation (Argenti and Druckenmiller 2004).
The scientific community believe that brand reputation depends on brand identity, so a good brand
reputation is the result of a good management of that identity.
While brand relationships are known to have impacts on brand identity, the literature on
this subject is scarce. Relationships have been traditionally positioned in the theory of networks
among companies (Ford et al. 2003; Hakansson and Ford 2002; Hakansson and Snehota 1989, 1995).
Although previous studies may acknowledge the influence of brand relationships on the identity of
organizations (Hakansson and Snehota 1989, 1995), no empirical studies have supported this.
In the current context, where the environment is increasingly dynamic and transformations
are difficult to predict, the development of technology results in increasing interactions among
corporate brands, as well as between corporate brands and their consumers. These end-users are
now, more than ever, considered as cocreators of brands (Hatch and Schultz 2010; Madden et al. 2006;
Payne et al. 2009; Prahalad and Ramaswamy 2004; Da Silveira et al. 2013). Similarly, we argue that the
identity of a corporate brand is developed as it adapts to consumers’ demands. It develops alongside
other recognized brands to build an identity with a desirable reputation among all stakeholders,
especially consumers.
In line with the development of the proposed model regarding branding, a number of researchers,
Kapferer (1986, 2008), Fombrum (1996, 2006) and Vidaver-Cohen (2007), focus on reputation. Other recent
studies on reputation in higher education (Priporas and Kamenidou 2011; Suomi 2014) were based on the
reputation of researchers and consultants, so that the model could provide insights from academics
with responsibilities in the field. The current study is intended to constitute policy advice to general
managers and to those in positions of responsibility for higher education brands. This study is
distinctive because it:

- helps fill a gap in the literature by supplying a concept of brand relationships


- introduces the concept of brand relationships in the management of brand identity and reputation
in higher education;
- relates the concept of corporate brand reputation with the management of corporate brand identity;
- leads brand managers into new perspectives for building a new dynamic construct under a brand
relationship approach.

This paper is organized as follows. Section 2 highlights the relevant literature and describes
the structure of the proposed framework for managing corporate brand identity under a relational
approach. Section 3 provides an explanation of methods used to assess the concept of corporate brand
relationships and the structural model, together with a brief description of the sample. The hypotheses
and definitions of the measures used are provided in this section. Section 4 reports our findings and
summarizes the model validity and applicability. Section 5 offers a brief discussion of the results and
draws the conclusion together with recommendations for future research.

2. Literature Review
This review provides detailed information about the conceptualization of the constructs and
measures used in the developed model, to manage corporate brand identity under a relational approach.
The methodology used to assess the references was search and analysis of the databases at our disposal,
like B-ON, Science Direct, JSTOR, ISI Web of knowledge, Scopus, Springer Link, and others.

160
JRFM 2020, 13, 133

2.1. Brand Relationships


The concept of brand relationships needs clarification in order to investigate the influence of
relationships on corporate brand identity, since relationships are vital for the interactions between
consumers and brands. Consumer–brand interactions extend beyond mere utilitarian benefits
(Aggarwal 2004). According to Fournier (1998), relationships constitute a series of repeated exchanges
between two parties known to each other, who also evolve in response to these exchanges and to
fluctuations in the contextual environment. Fournier (1998) and Muniz and Muniz and O’Guinn (2001)
argue that people form relationships with brands in the same way that they form relationships with
each other in social contexts. We can extend this approach to the relationships between brands and
state that brands tend to relate to each other in a social context and that this association can be used
to attract specific members of the public. This is not the same thing as a brand alliance, because
such alliances involve all joint marketing activities in which two or more brands are simultaneously
presented to consumers (Rao et al. 1999; Simonin and Ruth 1998). In this study, brand relationships are
mutually oriented interactions among corporate brands whose target is education (universities and
other higher education institutions) and other reputed brands which may attract students to create
a commitment. The definition of relationships between companies (Hakansson and Snehota 1995)
supports this perspective. A relationship is a mutually oriented interaction between two reciprocally
committed parties (p. 25). The parties agree that the notion of a relationship is defined by concepts of
mutual orientation and commitment over time, which are common in interactions between brands.
The specific characteristics of corporate brands make them different from other brands: Their bases
are brand promise, multidisciplinary roots, and medium to long-term gestation. Their focus is external
focused, but they are largely supported by internal stakeholders, who value highly communication
and visual identity (Balmer and Gray 2003); these facts make it necessary to adapt the dimensions of
brand relationships to these notions. This required that we review the literature on services focused on
the theory of relational networks and branding and search for characteristics that suited the concept of
the relationships among brands connected to education services.
Five different but related dimensions were used to assess the quality of the relationships in
the context of services in the B2B markets: recognized quality of the service, trust, commitment,
satisfaction, and service quality (Rauyruen and Miller 2007), but there is little empirical investigation
on the subject. However, the empirical studies of Dwyer et al. (1987) and Moorman et al. (1992)
concluded that the quality of relationships is characterized by three dimensions: trust, commitment,
and satisfaction. Berry (1995) emphasizes the relationships that customers have with service companies.
Beatty et al. (1988) are in favor of trust and commitment to explain the mechanisms underlying stable
preferences. Other researchers examined the roles of trust and commitment in the relationships that
customers develop with service companies (Garbarino and Johnson 1999; Sirieix and Dubois 1999).
Chaudhuri and Holbrook (2001) and Kennedy et al. (2000) found a positive relationship between
trust and commitment to consumer products. Most recently, Alkhawaldeh et al. (2020) accessed the
effect of brand familiarity and perceived service quality on brand image as and explored the position
of brand image on student´s satisfaction. The findings showed that familiarity with the brand and
perceived quality of service had an important and beneficial connection with the image of the brand
and there was an important and positive connection between brand image and students´ satisfaction.
Yet, these results were tested in the private field, and ours is focused on public institutions.
Next to trust we take commitment, recently described as an important major aspect of strategic
partnerships (Søderberg et al. 2013). We followed the definition of Hardwick and Ford (1986) and
Wilson (1995). Commitment influences or benefits internal and external stakeholders’ perceptions of
future value. Failing to find a scale characterizing the commitment among brands, we developed a
scale procedure to select items for this dimension.
Motivation has to do with the internal and external variables stakeholders consider when choosing
an educational institution. It is also based on the relationships that the university/institution is able to
provide. The scale procedure that we followed had to be adapted, so we decided to develop a scale

161
JRFM 2020, 13, 133

procedure to select items for this dimension as well, because we could not find a suitable scale in
the literature.

2.2. Corporate Brand Identity


The past few years have witnessed a burgeoning interest—among both practitioners and
academics—in consumers’ “love” for brands (Batra and Bagozzi 2012). Brands are frequently
represented in the minds of consumers as a set of humanlike characteristics (van der Lans et al. 2014).
In this context, recognized higher education institutions tend to evoke feelings and emotions like
“love” in students and prospective students. Most of the recognized faculties in the country in which
this research was conducted behave like corporate brands by demonstrating specific characteristics
that distinguish them from their peers. Legally, they are part of a university that aggregates them,
but brand images of faculties are so strong and distinctive from one another that they can be considered
as corporate brands. According to Muniz and O’Guinn (2001) there are brand communities of faculties.
These authors define a community as a core construct in social thought and a brand community
is a specialized, nongeographically-bound community, based on a structured set of social relations
among admirers. We readily become aware of these faculty brand communities when students choose
one in which to study after finishing high school. Balmer et al. (2010) used business schools as
a model to investigate corporate brand management and identification. In addition, according to
Han et al. (2018), the establishment of good interpersonal relationships among community members
will enable members to have a sense of belonging and social identity, thereby enhancing customer
satisfaction within the community.
Kapferer (1986, 2008) refers to the prism of brand identity as consisting of an internal part-
brand “culture,” “personality,” and “self-image”, as well as an external part—“physical dimension,”
“relation,” and “reflected consumer.” He considers the external part of the identity prism highly
important, especially in the case of corporate brands, since it is exposed to constant interactions with
the public. “Reflected consumer” is an external and intangible dimension which reflects the way the
consumer wishes to be regarded for “using” a certain brand (Kapferer 1986, 2008). This dimension
is characterized by the following features: being better prepared for the labor market; being more
capable of creating/innovating as successful professionals; and professionals with high credibility.
The relation dimension has tangible and intangible aspects. It defines the behavior that identifies the
brand and the way it interacts with its consumers (Kapferer 1986, 2008). It is characterized by the
following: friendliness, respect, trust, motherly and close. Finally, the “physical” dimension of brand
identity is defined by Kapferer (2008), as an exterior dimension that communicates the physical traits,
colors, forms, and qualities of the brand. This dimension has features such as: the physical traits of the
university/institution; modernity, sophistication, functional, and adequate.

2.3. Brand Reputation


Reputation is considered the most valuable asset of an organization, for the following reasons:
its positive effects on reducing stakeholder uncertainty about future performance; the trust it creates
in the public; the expectation of being rewarded for the excellence of goods and services. Fortune
Magazine published a list of The World´s Most Admired Companies, which reveals that a 5 percent
increase in reputation of an entity corresponds to a 3 percent increase in its market value. According
to Fombrum (1996), such an organization attracts qualified employees and external investors; so,
the defense of reputation is the cause of the growing interest in corporate brands. Vidaver-Cohen (2007)
based her concept of reputation on the Rep Trak model (Fombrum 2006), which was successfully
adapted to a business school. Suomi (2014) and Priporas and Kamenidou (2011) followed the same
model in their studies of branding and reputation in higher education. The prime objectives of this
study are: to measure and define the concept of brand relationships (relationships among brands) and
demonstrate the validity and reliability of its dimensions; to integrate the concept of brand relationships
in the management of corporate brand identity as an antecedent of the external part of identity; and to

162
JRFM 2020, 13, 133

integrate the concept of brand reputation in the management of corporate brand identity, showing that
it is a result of the management of the external part of identity under a relational approach.

3. Methodology
Service brands act in dynamic contexts, where brand building is developed with the help of
consumers. In higher education, this is particularly visible, as students are consumers (they pay to
attend university) and staff are part of the university´s identity. We thought it would be appropriate to
interview a sample of engineering students, as engineering faculties are recognized for developing
highly salient brand identities based on their societal interventions (e.g. building bridges and private
infrastructure, developing innovative artifacts, processes, and technologies for industries that are
frequently funded by national/international research centers).

3.1. Research Stages


We developed this research into the two stages explained below.

1. Exploratory research used a case study methodology developed in two engineering faculties to
find items to characterize the dimensions proposed in the model; and
2. Confirmatory research was pursued by developing a questionnaire for higher education
engineering students. A total of 216 complete surveys were obtained.

In the first stage, we followed King (1991), Balmer (2001), and Aaker (2004), who stated that
senior management members must be selected as informants because they are important in terms
of corporate brand management. Further, informants who had day-to-day strategic management
responsibilities were also selected. We conducted in-depth interviews with lecturers/researchers
and focus groups with students. Interviews were developed for senior management and staff,
and focus groups were created for students at undergraduate, master, and doctoral levels. Before
the interviews were conducted, several preparatory procedures were undertaken. These included
discussions with academics and practitioners national and internationally recognized in higher
education (Barros et al. 2011). These discussions indicated the necessity of having a protocol in the
interviews and focus groups. This initial study marshaled insights from thirteen in-depth interviews
(seven in one faculty and six in the other), following a predesigned interview protocol. Each interview
lasted for about two hours, and some informants were interviewed more than once. All interviews
were recorded with the permission of interviewees. Four focus groups of students were created, two in
each institution. Each focus group had six to eight students. To ensure the accuracy of interview data,
we conducted member checks (Lincoln and Guba 1985). In addition to interviews, desk research was
conducted by consulting faculties’ websites and media news.
Data were coded first by hand, because we thought this would bring us closer to the data.
Both stages were coded separately. In accordance with the general protocol for a previously designed
qualitative study, data collection, analysis, and interpretation were undertaken simultaneously,
generating tables of synthesized data. Simultaneously, several long meetings were held between the
authors to obtain an in-depth understanding of the phenomena under study.
This exploratory research suggested that, in contexts of high consumer involvement, the
relationships of a corporate brand with highly recognized brands have a definite impact on the
identity and reputation of the corporate brand, by influencing the perceptions of the stakeholders and
the educational services being offered.
This initial research suggested that corporate brand relationships with recognized brands have
impacts on identity and reputation. To confirm this conclusion, a second stage was designed, in which
the proposed model (with the selected dimensions and items previously selected in the first stage)
was tested. See Figure 1. A questionnaire was developed for higher education engineering students;
216 complete surveys were obtained. The data permitted us to validate a new concept defining the
relationships among brands from the students’ point of view. The investigated relationships were the

163
JRFM 2020, 13, 133

ones among corporate brands whose mission was education; these included universities and other
higher education institutions and strategic partnerships with national reputed research centers or
international reputed universities such as MIT, Harvard, and Oxford, with which these brands interact
in the context of conjoint degrees, international mobility, or other forms of interaction. To define
each dimension, we adopted a holistic perspective for reviewing the literature on several fields of
study, including B2B marketing, psychology, and organizational studies. We developed a procedure to
determine the pool of items to use in this research; these are shown in Table 1.

Figure 1. Proposed Model (developed by the authors).

Table 1. Summary of Procedures to Develop New Multi-Item Scales.

Procedure to Develop Multi-Item Scales Techniques and Indicators


1—Develop a theory Literature review and discussion with experts
Theory, secondary data, and thirteen interviews with
2—Generate an initial pool of items for each
lecturers and university managers, four focus groups of
dimension/scale
students (bachelor, master, and doctoral)
3—Select a reduced set of items based on qualitative Panel of ten experts (national and international, academics,
judgment and practitioners)
4—Collect data from a large pretest sample Pretest on a sample of eighty higher education Students
5—Perform statistical analysis Reliability; factor analysis
Analysis of the results of the pretest sample and discussion
6—Purify the measures
with experts
7—Collect data Survey of higher education students (216 complete surveys)

164
JRFM 2020, 13, 133

Table 1. Cont.

Procedure to Develop Multi-Item Scales Techniques and Indicators


8—Assess reliability and unidimensionality Cronbach’s alpha and factor analysis
Construct (AVE and CR), discriminant (comparison
between the squared root of AVE and the simple
9—Assess validity
correlations), and nomological validity (significant simple
correlations examination)
Confirmatory factor analysis (CFA)
10—Perform statistical analysis
Structural equation modelling (SEM)
Sources: Adapted from Churchill (1979) and Malhotra (1981, 2004). AVE—Average Variance Extracted;
CR—Construct Validity.

3.2. Proposed Model and Testing


Regarding the first construct—brand relationships—we found that it is formed by three dimensions:
trust, commitment, and motivation. Trust was adapted from existing scales in the literature,
but motivation and commitment (although based on the concepts of Hardwick and Ford (1986)
and Wilson (1995)) were developed in this research, by using confirmatory factor analysis (CFA).
The scales used to define the brand relationships construct were found to be valid and reliable.
To test the structural model, we used corporate brand identity (external part), which was developed
in a previous study. The items used to characterize the physical dimension, the relation and the
reflected consumer dimension were the result of previous research pursued by Barros et al. (2016).
The authors used the external part of the brand identity prism to argue that the relationships among
brands (brand relationships) influence the external part of corporate brand identity and reputation.
The result of a well-managed corporate brand identity is a positive reputation. Therefore, brand
reputation is the expected result of an active corporate brand identity management under a relational
approach. It is widely suggested in the literature that identity precedes reputation (Burmann et al. 2009;
de Chernatony 1999; Kapferer 1986, 2008). Corporate brands should actively choose and select
recognized brands with which to develop relationships, to bridge the gap between brand identity and
reputation. The result of this management should be an increase in brand reputation.
We also used the reputation concept unidimensionality, developed by Vidaver-Cohen (2007),
to connect with this research. Data were analyzed using CFA and structural equation modeling
(SEM). A structural equation model was developed to test the brand relationships concept as an
antecedent to corporate brand identity and reputation. According to Nachtigall et al. (2001), SEM
represents the relationship between latent variables (brand relationships, corporate brand identity,
and brand reputation in our model) and their manifest or observable indicators (the items that
characterize the latent variables). The most prominent feature of SEM is the capability to deal
with latent variables. These variables are connected to observable ones by a measurement model
(Edwards and Bagozzi 2000).

3.3. Research Hypotheses


Authors like de Chernatony (1999) and Kapferer (1986, 2008) state that brand identity precedes
brand reputation. It is our aim to confirm this hypothesis, in order to be able to argue that the
management of corporate brand identity is developed under a relational approach. It follows that the
choice and selection of recognized brands to develop should be carried out by the brand management
team, taking into account the fact that brand identity develops and interacts with the external dynamic
environment. We propose three research hypotheses:

Hypothesis 1 (H1). The constructs trust, commitment, and motivation are a part of a higher dimension
construct named brand relationships;

165
JRFM 2020, 13, 133

Hypothesis 2 (H2). The brand relationships construct influences the external part of corporate brand
identity; and

Hypothesis 3 (H3). The external part of corporate brand identity influences brand reputation.

We conducted CFA with the three second-order constructs: brand relationships, corporate brand
identity, and brand reputation, using a total of 34 measures, detailed as follows:

(a) A list of eighteen items was obtained from qualitative research to measure the constructs that
define the brand relationships concept: trust (7 items), motivation (7 items), and commitment
(four items);
(b) Eight items were considered before testing the validity of the measurement model. The guidelines
followed by the literature regarding SEM suggested a drop of T4. In line with this, the trust
dimension was characterized by seven items;
(c) A list of thirteen items was derived from previous research by Barros et al. (2016), regarding
corporate brand identity (external part) and its measures: physical (four items); relation (five
items); reflected consumer (four items);
(d) A list of four items was adapted from the brand reputation scale developed by Vidaver-Cohen (2007).
Previously, ten items had been selected from the framework, but we found that this concept was
bidimensional, so, we selected one dimension that we considered to be more connected with this
research. After analyzing the measurement model, we decided to maintain three of the four items.

We began by developing measures for the concepts we intended to connect: brand relationships,
corporate brand identity (external part), and brand reputation. First, we tested construct reliability
and unidimensionality for the proposed measures for brand relationships: trust, commitment,
and motivation. The same procedure was followed for brand reputation. The measures that formed
corporate brand identity have been analyzed previously, and the construct has been found to be reliable
and unidimensional. Next, we developed the measurement model for the brand relationships concept
(using CFA). The results regarding the selected fit indices were considered acceptable. After dropping
one item from the trust dimension, we developed the second-order model. The results revealed
robustness regarding the selected criteria. Finally, we tested the structural model, using brand
relationships as the cause of the salience of the external part of corporate brand identity and brand
reputation as the result of the management of corporate brand identity (external part), using a
relational approach.

4. Results

4.1. Unidimensionality and Reliability of Scales for Measuring Brand Relationships, Reputation and
Corporate Identity
The first-order model had three factors (trust, commitment, and motivation) and nineteen
corresponding reflective indicators, as listed in Tables 2 and 3. The goal of most research projects
is not just to develop unidimensional and reliable measurement scales, but to build and test
theory. To summarize the data in terms of a set of underlying constructs, a factor analysis was
conducted. We measured the unidimensionality and reliability of the proposed scales. To measure
unidimensionality, we conducted principal component analysis with varimax rotation and Kaiser
normalization to each scale. The scale items that did not show factorial stability were candidates for
elimination. To measure reliability, we selected Cronbach’s alpha.

166
Table 2. Initial and final research constructs and measures.

Construct Initial Full Measured Items * Source


The connections between my university/institution and the recognized brands (INESC,
INEGI, ISISE, CCT, CALG, ALGORITMI; MIT, Harvard, Oxford . . . ) with whom it relates
T1—make me feel safe
JRFM 2020, 13, 133

T2—are trustable
T3—are a guarantee
Adapted from Morgan and Hunt (1994) and
Trust T4—are transparent (honest)—deleted while testing the measurement model of brand
Gurviez and Korchia (2002)
relationships for the sake of discriminant validity between trust and commitment
T5—are sincere
T6—are interesting
T7—influence the curricula offer of my university/institution
T8—contribute to improving the answers to students’ needs
Attending this university/institution allows me
Concept based on Hardwick and Ford (1986) and
C1—to achieve (have access to) important relationship networks
Wilson (1995), but the scales are new in the
Commitment C2—to be able to play a major professional and social role
literature; Sources of influence: informants + focus
C3—to be influential
groups + experts + desk research
C4—to reach technical and scientific excellence
The connections between my university/institution and the recognized brands (INESC,
INEGI, ISISE, CCT, CALG, ALGORITMI; MIT, Harvard, Oxford . . . ) with whom it relates
M1—give credibility to the lecturing process

167
M2—facilitate access to research
New scale in literature; sources of influence:
Motivation M3—facilitate access to the labor market
informants + focus groups + experts + desk research
M4—facilitate access to a top career
M5—give credibility to the university/institution in the eyes of the labor market
M6—facilitate access to an international career
M7—foster entrepreneurship
I believe that society in general considers graduates of my university/institution
RC1—better prepared for the labor market
Reflected consumer RC2—more capable of creating/innovating Developed in previous research
RC3—successful professionals
RC4—professionals with high credibility
I feel that the relationship between my university/institution and me is
R1—friendly
R2—respectful
Relation Developed in previous research
R3—trustable
R4—motherly
R5—close
F1—the facilities of my university/institution are modern
F2—the facilities of my university/institution are sophisticated
Physical Developed in previous research
F3—the facilities of my university/institution are functional
F4—the facilities of my university/institution are adequate
Table 2. Cont.

Construct Initial Full Measured Items * Source


Please classify the items below from 1—poor to 5—high:
Rep2.1—intellectual performance (retain/recruit prestigious lecturers/investigators; high
levels of scientific publications . . . )
JRFM 2020, 13, 133

Rep2.2—network performance (attracts first-class students; high employment rate; strong


links between students and the industry . . . )
Rep2.3—products (prestigious degrees; competent graduates . . . )
Rep2.4—innovation (innovative methodologies; rapid adaptation to changes; innovating
curricula . . . ) deleted after analyzing the measurement model (standardized residual
values)
Rep2.5—provided services (strong relations with the exterior; specialized tasks; high level
of instruction by lecturers and staff . . . )
Reputation Rep2.6—leadership (strong and charismatic leaders; organized and competent Adapted from Vidaver-Cohen (2007)
management; vision for future . . . )
Rep2.7—corporate governance (open and transparent management; ethical behavior; fair
in transactions with stakeholders . . . )
Rep2.8—work environment (equal opportunities; reward systems; care for the welfare of
the staff and students . . . )
Rep2.9—citizenship (promotes services to society; supports good causes; acts positively in
society; open to the industry and to society . . . )
Rep2.10—financial performance (fees and value-added programs.)

168
From Rep2.5 to Rep2.10 all deleted after analyzing the dimensionality of the construct,
because SEM demands unidimentionality of the scales as previously mentioned—see
Table 3
* Items measured on a five-point Likert scale, ranging from (1) strongly disagree to (5) strongly agree.
JRFM 2020, 13, 133

Table 3. Analysis of the dimensionality of reputation.

Factor Loadings
Reputation
Factor 1 Factor 2
Rep2.1—intellectual performance (retain/recruit prestigious
0.800
lecturers/investigators; high levels of scientific publications . . . )
Rep2.2—network performance (attracts first-class students; high employment
0.813
rate; strong links between the students and industry . . . )
Rep2.3—products (prestigious degrees; competent graduates . . . ) 0.736
Rep2.4—innovation (innovative methodologies; rapid adaptation to changes;
0.685
innovative curricula . . . )
Rep2.5—provided services (strong relations with the exterior; specialized tasks;
0.591 0.449
high level of instruction by lecturers and staff . . . )
Rep2.6—leadership (strong and charismatic leaders; organized and competent
0.616
management; vision for future . . . )
Rep2.7—corporate governance (open and transparent management; ethical
0.822
behavior; fair in transactions with stakeholders . . . )
Rep2.8—work environment (equal opportunities; reward systems; care for
0.821
welfare of staff and students . . . )
Rep2.9—citizenship (promotes services to society; supports good causes; acts
0.709
positively in society; open to the industry and to society . . . )
Extraction Method: Principal Component Analysis

Next, we analyze the measures of the brand relationships construct. We start by analyzing
Trust, commitment and Motivation. Then we define guidelines and criteria to assess a model for
Brand Relationships.

4.1.1. Trust
This scale was adapted from Morgan and Hunt (1994) and Gurviez and Korchia (2002) and
had eight reflexive items. We measured the reliability of the scale defined by the selected items.
Cronbach’s alpha was 0.898 (higher than the 0.8 suggested by Nunnally (1978)). Dekovic et al. (1991)
and Holden et al. (1991) characterized reliabilities of 0.60 or 0.70 as good or adequate. However,
Ping (2004) stated that higher reliability measures tend to avoid low average variance extracted (AVE)
when running the CFA. Regarding dimensionality, the scale was shown to be unidimensional, with an
explained variance of 59.213 percent extracted by that component.

4.1.2. Commitment
This was a new scale proposed for this research and consisted of four reflexive items. Regarding
the reliability of the scale, Cronbach’s alpha was high (0.819). We then analyzed the dimensionality of
the scale and found that the scale was unidimensional, with an explained variance of 64.898 percent by
that component.

4.1.3. Motivation
This was also a new scale proposed for this research and consisted of seven reflexive items.
Assessing the reliability, the Cronbach’s alpha was high (0.886). Analyzing the dimensionality,
we found that the scale was unidimensional, with an explained variance of 60.417 percent.
Results regarding the other constructs (external brand identity and brand reputation), the initial
measures, the analysis of the dimensionality of reputation, and the final research measures are
summarized in Tables 2 and 3. More information regarding the technical procedures can be provided
on request.

169
JRFM 2020, 13, 133

4.2. Guidelines and Criteria to Assess Model for Brand Relationships


We used the following guidelines:

- CMIN/DF < 2.00 (Byrne 1989, 2010);


- CFI > 0.90 (Bentler 1990; Browne and Cudeck 1993; Hu and Bentler 1999; Marsh et al. 1996);
- RMSEA < 0.08 (Bentler 1990; Browne and Cudeck 1993; Hair et al. 2006; Hu and Bentler 1999;
Marsh et al. 1996). where CMIN/DF = Chi-square value/degrees of freedom, CFI = comparative
fit index, RMSEA = root mean square error of approximation.

Following these guidelines, we applied the first-order measurement model to the brand
relationships concept. A summary of the psychometric properties for the first-order constructs
is provided in Table 4. Discriminant validity was tested, and after dropping item T4, no problems were
reported, as can be seen in Table 5. Taking these results into account, we tested the second-order model
for the brand relationships construct. The results showed robustness regarding the selected indicators
(see Table 6).
We assessed the reliability and validity of the second-order factor for the brand relationships
construct. Construct validity is demonstrated by plausible correlations of the second-order construct
with first-order indicators, whereas convergent validity can be suggested by an AVE for the second-order
construct that is greater than 0.5 (Bagozzi et al. 1991; Ping 2004).
The values of CR = 0.87 and AVE = 0.68 are greater than the recommended values, suggesting
higher reliabilities and convergent validity for the second-order construct. In line with this, we
can conclude that the results support the first hypothesis (H1) and state that the constructs of trust,
commitment, and motivation are a part of a higher dimension construct of brand relationships.

Table 4. Psychometric properties for first-order constructs for brand relationships.

Measured Items Factor Loadings λ


a Delta b AVE CR Cronbach’s α
Trust (T) 0.53 0.89 0.885
T1 0.713 0.492
T2 0.816 0.334
T3 0.713 0.492
T5 0.657 0.568
T6 0.733 0.463
T7 0.759 0.424
T8 0.683 5.074 0.534
Commitment (C) 0.77 0.82 0.819
C1 0.705 0.308
C2 0.716 0.487
C3 0.653 0.574
C4 0.717 2.791 0.316
Motivation (M) 0.52 0.89 0.886
M1 0.647 0.581
M2 0.723 0.477
M3 0.696 0.516
M4 0.761 0.421
M5 0.735 0.460
M6 0.771 0.406
M7 0.731 5.064 0.466
a Sum of the factor loadings; b Delta is a measure that is used to calculate CR (construct reliability), and the formula
to obtain it is 1 − λ2 .

170
JRFM 2020, 13, 133

Table 5. Construct and discriminant validity for brand relationships.

Construct validity (before drop T4)


Motivation Trust Commitment
AVE 0.52 0.51 0.77
CR 0.89 0.89 0.82
Discriminant validity (before drop T4)
Motivation 0.72
Trust 0.67 0.72
Commitment 0.65 0.73 0.88
Construct validity (after drop T4)
Motivation Trust Commitment
AVE 0.52 0.53 0.77
CR 0.89 0.89 0.82
Discriminant validity (after drop T4)
Motivation 0.72
Trust 0.67 0.73
Commitment 0.65 0.72 0.88
Notes: Squared root of AVE on the diagonal; correlation estimates below the diagonal.

Table 6. Summary of second-order factors for brand relationships.

Model χ2 DF p CMIN/DF CFI RMSEA


Brand relationships
219.023 129 0.000 1.698 0.955 0.057 [0.044; 0.070]
(three factors)
The theoretical propositions justifying the second-order model were assumed to directly estimate the empirical.
Model; no further tests were used.

4.3. Model Evaluation


The first analysis of the proposed measurement model suggested that the item Rep2.4 (innovation)
be dropped. We re-calculated the reliability and unidimensionality of the scale and found the following
for the new three items. The brand reputation scale had a Cronbach’s α of 0.777 (higher than the
threshold of 0.7 defined by Bland and Altman 1997; DeVellis 2003; Nunnally 1978; Nunnally and
Bernstein 1994) and a percentage of explained variance of 68.481 percent, which is highly acceptable.
In line with these findings, we re-specified the model and conducted CFA again. The results are
summarized in Table 7.

Table 7. Summary of the indices of fit of the measurement model.

Model χ2 DF p CMIN/DF CFI RMSEA


Measurement model
(Brand relationships;
726.149 503 0.000 1.444 0.944 0.045 [0.038; 0.053]
corporate brand identity
(external) and reputation)

These fit indices were satisfactory according to the selected guidelines. This means that the
second-order construct named brand relationships was related to the second-order corporate brand
identity construct (external part) and to the brand construct reputation formed by three measures.
An analysis of all loadings showed that all except one were higher than the threshold of 0.5.
The “physical” dimension was the exception; it contributed poorly to the external part of the corporate
brand identity construct (0.420 < 0.5). Even so, the model fit was satisfactory. We can conclude that, in
contrast to what Kapferer (1986, 2008) suggests, the used sample did not greatly value the physical

171
JRFM 2020, 13, 133

dimension of corporate brand identity (external part). This is consistent with the sample, which was
composed of goal-oriented engineering students. They demonstrated that they assign more value
to the dimensions reflecting consumer (loading: 0.784) and relation (loading: 0.750), because they
believe that these dimensions are more connected with their lives as students and future professionals.
The reflected consumer dimension (the one with the highest loading) was strictly connected with
the aspirations of students. However, this finding should be further investigated in other contexts,
using other samples. The following standardized residual values also deserve further attention: 2.629
between F4 and Rep2.2; 2.731 between R5 and C3; and 2.716 between R5 and C2.
Rep2.4 (innovation), that was immediately deleted because it had a high standardized residual.
Rep2.2 (network performance) also had a relatively high standardized residual, yet we had to maintain
one of them because CFA demands at least three items to run an analysis. We considered Rep2.2 more
in line with the theoretical background and the factor loadings gave us the same cue (Rep2.2 0.813 vs.
Rep2.4 0.685). All the other standardized residuals were below the cut-off point of 2.58, as suggested by
Jöreskog and Sörbom (2001). The other items were a part of other second-order constructs, which were
previously analyzed and evaluated and revealed as valid (convergent, discriminant, and nomological).
Therefore, considering that the mentioned values were far from the cut-off point of 4.0 (Hair et al. 2006)
and required no further considerations and that the model fit was satisfactory, we decided to keep
these items and test the structural model.
Regarding the modification indices, the one between R5 and C3 had a value of 11.588 (>11).
This was expected, given the standardized residual value between both items. However, as mentioned
above, the difference was very small, and it was decided to keep both items. All other modification
indexes (Mis) had values below 11. No problems regarding multicollinearity were found, and no other
indices required our attention; with these findings, we tested the structural model.

4.4. Final Structural Model Estimation and Testing


By developing this causal model, we aimed to demonstrate that universities/institutes of higher
education need to invest in and select recognized brands for developing relationships, as well as
manage the corporate brand identity in the part that is more exposed to interaction with the public.
In the proposed model, the brand relationships construct was an antecedent of the corporate
brand identity construct (external part), and the brand identity (external part) was an antecedent of
the brand reputation construct. Corporate brand identity (external part) and reputation were latent
variables. Consistent with Hair et al. (2006), Marôco (2010), and James et al. (1982), we added a
parsimony fit index (PCFI) to the analysis. We selected PCFI because it represents the result of applying
James et al. (1982) parsimony adjustment to the CFI:

PCFI = CFI × d/db

where d is the degree of freedom for the model being evaluated, and db is the degree of freedom for the
baseline model. Values are between [0–1], and better fits are closer to 1. Table 8 summarizes the indices
of fit of the structural model:

Table 8. Summary of the indices of fit of the measurement model.

Model χ2 DF p CMIN/DF CFI RMSEA PCFI


Structural model (Brand
relationships; corporate
727.239 504 0.000 1.443 0.944 0.045 [0.038; 0.053] 0.847
brand identity (external)
and reputation)

As expected, the χ2 was higher than the one calculated with the measurement model, because a
recursive structural model cannot fit better (to have a lower χ2 ) than the overall CFA. The difference
between both χ2 was quite small (727.239 − 726.149 = 1.09), demonstrating that the model was strongly

172
JRFM 2020, 13, 133

suggestive of adequate fit (Hair et al. 2006). The loadings, standardized residuals, and modification
indices maintained approximately the same values. Regarding the standardized residuals: 2.704
between F4 and Rep2.2; 2.805 between R5 and C3; and 2.787 between R5 and C2.
The problematic items relating to the modification indices are:

−R5 and C3 = 11.752

These small differences did not require further analysis, because, at this stage, the focus was on
diagnosing the relationships among constructs. A good model fit alone is insufficient to support a
structural theory. It is also necessary to examine the individual parameter estimates that represent
each specific hypothesis (Hair et al. 2006). Table 9 summarizes the main indicators and conclusions.

Table 9. Structural equation model results.

Relationships between the Regression Estimates Statistics


Constructs Unstandardized S.E. Standardized C.R. p-Value Decision
External
Brand H2
Corporate <— 0.652 0.135 0.876 4.830 <0.001
relationships supported
Brand ID
External
Physical <— Corporate 1.000 0.421
Brand ID
External
Relation <— Corporate 1.419 0.302 0.762 4.695 <0.001
Brand ID
External
Reflected
<— Corporate 1.185 0.242 0.797 4.890 <0.001
consumer
Brand ID
Brand
Trust <— 1.000 0.801
relationships
Brand
Motivation <— 0.625 0.093 0.771 6.698 <0.001
relationships
Brand
Commitment <— 1.031 0.144 0.937 7.156 <0.001
relationships
External
H3
Reputation <— Corporate 1.302 0.260 0.824 5.012 <0.001
supported
Brand ID
Notes: S.E.—standard error; CR—Critical ratio.

Examining the paths among constructs showed that they were all statistically significant in the
predicted direction. The path that represented the weight between brand relationships and external
corporate brand identity was characterized by βBR.ECBI = 0.652; S.E. = 0.135; βBR.ECBI = 0.876;
p < 0.001. This means that the regression weight for brand relationships in the prediction of external
corporate brand identity was significantly different from zero at the 0.001 level (two-tailed). The path
that represented the weight between external corporate brand identity and reputation was characterized
by βECBI.Rep = 1.302; S.E. = 0.260; βECBI.Rep = 0.824; p < 0.001, meaning that the regression weight
for external corporate brand identity in the prediction of reputation was significantly different from
zero at the 0.001 level (two-tailed).
We analyzed the variance explained estimates for the endogenous constructs in Table 10 and
found that the predictors of the physical construct explained 17.7 percent of variance. This means that
the error variance of the physical dimension was approximately 82.3 percent of the variance of this
dimension itself. As for the other constructs, no problems were found. We can conclude that our model
supported both Hypotheses 2 and 3. Therefore, the relationships among brands (brand relationships)
influenced external corporate brand identity, and later, the brand reputation.

173
JRFM 2020, 13, 133

Table 10. Squared correlations (R2 ).

Endogenous Construct R2
External Corporate Brand ID 0.768
Physical 0.177
Relation 0.581
Reflected consumer 0.636
Trust 0.641
Motivation 0.595
Commitment 0.878
Reputation 0.680

Because theory has become essential in assessing the validity of a structural model, we examined
an equivalent model, with the purpose of testing an alternative theory. For the previous model,
we dropped the physical dimension, for comparison purposes. In line with these findings, we accepted
the second and third hypotheses and concluded that the brand relationships construct influences the
external part of corporate brand identity (H2) and that the brand identity influences brand reputation
(H3). Therefore, the management of corporate brand identity depends on the investment and selection
of strong relationships with reputed brands, to attract students and increase brand reputation.

5. Discussion and Conclusions


This study presents empirical findings in the field of higher education branding, where studies are
mainly limited to business schools (Balmer and Liao 2007; Priporas and Kamenidou 2011; Suomi 2014;
Vidaver-Cohen 2007). It contributes to filling a gap in the literature regarding the relationships
among brands, as well as their influence on brand identity management and reputation. Students’
perceptions of relationships among their higher education institutions indicate that the concept of
brand relationships is formed by three dimensions: trust, commitment, and motivation. Trust and
commitment are also considered relevant variables in the car industry (Morgan and Hunt 1994), as well
as in a branding context: development of a scale to brand confidence (Gurviez and Korchia 2002).
The relationships concept has been traditionally positioned in the theory of networks among
companies (Ford et al. 2003; Hakansson and Ford 2002; Hakansson and Snehota 1989, 1995); however,
although the literature may acknowledge corporate brand identity’s influence on the organizational
identity (Hakansson and Snehota 1989, 1995), empirical research on this topic is scarce. An initial step
is to further examine the relationships and clients’ experience (Keller and Lehmann 2006). This study
empirically supports the statements of Hakansson and Snehota (1989, 1995), by connecting brand
relationships with the corporate brand identity construct.
This finding empirically proves that brand identity can also be managed by issues considered
external to identity.
Previous researchers have established links between corporate brand and reputation
(de Chernatony 1999), as well as between brand identity and reputation (de Chernatony and Harris 2000);
and between reputation, satisfaction, and loyalty (Helm 2007). But few authors have examined the
links among brand relationships and the impact of those relationships on corporate brands’ identity
or reputation. Our research establishes these missing links by empirically testing this impact. It is
important to analyze brands in the services sector, because of its particular characteristics, especially
the intangibility of the relationships that allow services to materialize. We particularly selected higher
education because of its higher consumer involvement. In the higher education context, students
are internal stakeholders and consumers at the same time. It is our own view that students’ base
part of their appreciation of the university/institution they attend on the relationships it has with
other recognized brands, by means of trust, commitment and motivation. Such features improve the
visibility of the reflected consumer and their image in society.
We measured the external corporate brand identity in line with the proposed definition of external
brand identity by Kapferer (1986, 2008). We concluded quantitatively that the three dimensions:

174
JRFM 2020, 13, 133

relation, reflected consumer and tangible physical, make sense together and that there is a higher
external dimension formed by these three factors. This a very important input for academics and
also for brand managers in order to adapt the external dimensions of the corporate brand identity
to their publics. Moreover, the use of quantitative methods allowed us to find a higher dimension
called corporate brand identity, formed by five of the six factors proposed by Kapferer (1986, 2008):
self-image, personality, relation, reflected consumer and tangible physical. The brand identity prism
of the mentioned author also includes the culture dimension. We also included it in this research by
using the findings revealed by Deshpande et al. (1993). We were able to identify the perceived culture
by each student regarding their university/institution. In line with this, we demonstrated that cultures
perceived as being performance oriented develop more salient corporate brand identities (measured
by the model fit). We divided the sample into two groups in accordance with Deshpande et al. (1993)
and verified that the sample compound by the students that perceived their university/institution as
being performance oriented revealed better identity salience than the other sample. We consider this
of great importance to the management of brand identity in universities/higher education institutions.
It reveals the power of the students’ perceptions and its influence in the corporate brand identity
dimensions. The perceptions regarding brand culture must be managed by the brand managers so as to
create the desired perceptions in the students making the desired corporate brand identity coincident
with the existing one. This finding also reveals the influence of the culture dimension in the other
dimensions of the corporate brand identity, something that we have not found in previous studies.
This research also revealed the importance of joining qualitative and quantitative methodologies
and proved that the latter is also applicable to a field of studies where quantitative studies are scarce.
As far as our knowledge is concerned, it is the first time that the brand identity prism developed
by Kapferer (1986, 2008) is measured in the mentioned context.

6. Limitations of the Research, Future Directions and Contributions


Even though the sample of engineering students was adequate for the purposes of this research,
it would be extremely useful to compare these findings with those of other samples, consisting
of students with other characteristics. Such studies would confirm our findings and improve
generalizability. A new perspective of the physical dimension in the brand identity prism was revealed.
We named it “Intangible Physical”. This dimension is present in the physical dimension defined by
Kapferer (1986, 2008). Yet, taking in account the used sample, the research revealed that this dimension,
although valid and reliable, did not show enough discriminant validity to be considered a single
differentiated factor. Therefore, we consider that other samples with different characteristics should be
studied. Furthermore, other services with high levels of consumer involvement should be tested for
generalization purposes, such as insurance or medical services.
Regarding the contributions to the literature and to brand management, the conclusions of this
research highlight the importance of designing, choosing, and investing in relationships with brands.
These relationships should be coherent with the desired brand identity and reputation, in such a way
that they cocreate value for stakeholders. The brand managers of higher education corporate brands
should pay more attention to the process of engaging with other brands that are perceived by students
and stakeholders as providing value to their institution.

Author Contributions: Conceptualization and methodology, T.B., P.R., and N.D.; writing—original draft
preparation, T.B., P.R., and N.D.; writing—review and editing, F.V.M., H.B.-K., X.-G.Y. and X.-F.S.; funding
acquisition, X.-F.S. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.
Funding: This research received no external funding.
Acknowledgments: The authors are grateful to anonymous MDPI referees and editors.
Conflicts of Interest: The authors declare no conflict of interest.

175
JRFM 2020, 13, 133

References
Aaker, David Allen. 2004. Leveraging the Corporate Brand. California Management Review 46: 6–18. [CrossRef]
Aggarwal, Pankaj. 2004. The Effects of Brand Relationship Norms on Consumer Attitudes and Behavior. Journal of
Consumer Research 31: 87–101. [CrossRef]
Alkhawaldeh, Abdelbaset, Abdallah Alsaad, Abdallah Taamneh, and Hussein Alhawamdeh. 2020. Examining
Antecedents and Consequences of University Brand Image. Management Science Letters 10: 953–60. [CrossRef]
Argenti, Paul, and Bob Druckenmiller. 2004. Reputation and the Corporate Brand. Corporate Reputation Review 7:
368–74. [CrossRef]
Bagozzi, Richard, Youjae Yi, and Lynn Philips. 1991. Assessing Construct Validity in Organizational Research.
Administrative Science Quarterly 36: 421–58. [CrossRef]
Balmer, John M. T. 2001. From the Pentagon: A new identity framework. Corporate Reputation Review 4: 11–22.
[CrossRef]
Balmer, John, and Edmund Gray. 2003. Corporate Brands: What Are They? What of Them? European Journal
of Marketing 37: 972–97. [CrossRef]
Balmer, John, and Mei-Na Liao. 2007. Student Corporate Brand Identification: An Exploratory Case Study.
Corporate Communications: An International Journal 12: 356–75. [CrossRef]
Balmer, John, Mei-Na Liao, and Wei-Yue Wang. 2010. Corporate Brand Identification and Corporate Brand
Management: How Top Business Schools Do It. Journal of General Management 35: 77–102. [CrossRef]
Barros, Teresa, Francisco Vitorino Martins, and Hortênsia Gouveia Barandas. 2011. Corporate Brand Identity
Management—Proposal of a New Framework. In 7th International Conference of: The AM’s Brand and Corporate
Reputation SIG. Oxford: Academy of Marketing.
Barros, Teresa, Francisco Vitorino Martins, and Hortênsia Gouveia Barandas. 2016. Corporate Brand Identity
Measurement—An Application to the Services Sector. International Journal of Innovation and Learning 20: 214–31.
[CrossRef]
Batra, Rajeev, and Richard Bagozzi. 2012. Brand Love. Journal of Marketing 76: 1–16. [CrossRef]
Beatty, Sharon, Pamela Homer, and Lynn Kahle. 1988. The Involvement—Commitment Model: Theory and
Implications. Journal of Business Research 16: 149–67. [CrossRef]
Bentler, Peter. 1990. Comparative Fit Indexes in Structural Models. Psychological Bulletin 107: 238–46. [CrossRef]
Berry, Leonard. 1995. Relationship Marketing of Service: Growing Interest, Emerging Perspectives. Journal of the
Academy of Marketing Science 23: 236–45. [CrossRef]
Bland, J. Martin, and Douglas Altman. 1997. Statistics Notes: Cronbach’s Alpha. British Management Journal
314: 572. [CrossRef]
Browne, Michael, and Robert Cudeck. 1993. Alternative Ways of Assessing Model Fit. Sage Focus Editions 154: 136.
[CrossRef]
Burmann, Christoph, Marc Jost-Benz, and Nicola Riley. 2009. Towards an Identity-based Brand Equity Model.
Journal of Business Research 62: 390–97. [CrossRef]
Byrne, Barbara. 1989. A Primer of LISREL: Basic Applications and Programming for Confirmatory Factor Analytic Models.
New York: Springer.
Byrne, Barbara. 2010. Structural Equation Modeling with AMOS: Basic Concepts, Applications, and Programming.
Abingdon-on-Thames: Routledge, Taylor and Francis Group.
Chaudhuri, Arjun, and Morris Holbrook. 2001. The Chain of Effects from Brand Trust and Brand Affect to Brand
Performance: The Role of Brand Loyalty. Journal of Marketing 65: 81–93. [CrossRef]
Churchill, Gilbert. 1979. A Paradigm for Developing Better Measures of Marketing Constructs. Journal of
Marketing Research 16: 64–73. [CrossRef]
Da Silveira, Catherine, Carmen Lages, and Cláudia Simões. 2013. Reconceptualizing Brand Identity in a Dynamic
Environment. Journal of Business Research 66: 28–36. [CrossRef]
de Chernatony, Leslie. 1999. Brand Management through Narrowing the Gap between Brand Identity and Brand
Reputation. Journal of Marketing Management 15: 157–79. [CrossRef]
de Chernatony, Leslie, and Fiona Harris. 2000. Developing Corporate Brands through Considering Internal and
External Stakeholders. Corporate Reputation Review 3: 268–74. [CrossRef]

176
JRFM 2020, 13, 133

Dekovic, Maja, Jan M. Janssens, and Jan R. Gerris. 1991. Factor Structure and Construct Validity of the Block Child
Rearing Practices Report (CRPR). Psychological Assessment: A Journal of Consulting and Clinical Psychology
3: 182–87. [CrossRef]
Deshpande, Rohit, Farley John, and Webster Frederick Jr. 1993. Corporate Culture, Customer Orientation, and
Innovativeness in Japanese Firms: A Quadrad Analysis. Journal of Marketing 57: 23–37. [CrossRef]
DeVellis, Robert. 2003. Scale Development: Theory and Applications. Chapel Hill: Sage, University of North Carolina.
Dwyer, Robert, Paul Schurr, and Sejo Oh. 1987. Developing Buyer-Seller Relationships. Journal of Marketing
51: 11–27. [CrossRef]
Edwards, Jeffrey, and Richard Bagozzi. 2000. On the Nature and Direction of the Relationship between Constructs
and Measures. Psychological Methods 5: 155–74. [CrossRef]
Fombrum, Charles. 1996. Reputation: Realizing Value from the Corporate Image. Boston: Harvard Business School
Press.
Fombrum, Charles. 2006. The Rep Track System. Paper presented at the 10th Anniversary Conference on
Reputation, Image, Identity and Competitiveness, New York, NY, USA, May 25–28.
Ford, David, Lars-Erik Gadde, Hakan Hakansson, and Ivan Snehota. 2003. Managing Business Relationships.
Chichester: John Wiley and Sons.
Fournier, Susan. 1998. Consumers and Their Brands: Developing Relationship Theory in Consumer Research.
Journal of Consumer Research 24: 343–73. [CrossRef]
Garbarino, Ellen, and Mark S. Johnson. 1999. The Different Roles of Satisfaction, Trust, and Commitment in
Customer Relationships. Journal of Marketing 63: 70–87. [CrossRef]
Gurviez, Patricia, and Michael Korchia. 2002. Proposition d’Une Échelle de Mesure Multidimensionnelle de la
Confiance dans la Marque. Recherche et Applications en Marketing 17: 41–61. [CrossRef]
Hair, Joseph, William Black, Barry Babin, Rolph Anderson, and Ronald Tatham. 2006. Multivariate Data Analysis.
Upper Saddle River: Prentice-Hall.
Hakansson, Hakan, and David Ford. 2002. How should Companies Interact in Business Networks? Journal of
Business Research 55: 133–39. [CrossRef]
Hakansson, Hakan, and Ivan Snehota. 1989. No Business is an Island: The Network Concept of Business Strategy.
Scandinavian Journal of Management 5: 187–200. [CrossRef]
Hakansson, Hakan, and Ivan Snehota, eds. 1995. Developing Relationships in Business Networks. London: Routledge.
Han, Min, Jiacong Wu, Yu Wang, and Mingying Hong. 2018. A Model and Empirical Study on the User’s
Continuance Intention in Online China Brand Communities Based on Customer-Perceived Benefits. Journal of
Open Innovation: Technology, Market, and Complexity 4: 46. [CrossRef]
Hardwick, Bob, and David Ford. 1986. Industrial Buyer Resources and Responsibilities and the Buyer–Seller
Relationships. Industrial Marketing and Purchasing 1: 3–26.
Hatch, Mary Jo, and Majken Schultz. 2010. Brand Management Vol. 17, 8, 590–604. 1350-23IX. New York: Macmillan
Publishers Ltd.
Helm, Sabrina. 2007. The Role of Corporate Reputation in Determining Investor Satisfaction and Loyalty.
Corporate Reputation Review 10: 22–37. [CrossRef]
Holden, Ronald, Cynthia Fekken, and Dorothy Cotton. 1991. Assessing Psychopathology Using Structured
Test-Item Response Latencies. Psychological Assessment 3: 111–18. [CrossRef]
Hu, Li-Tze, and Peter M. Bentler. 1999. Cutoff Criteria for Fit Indexes in Covariance Structure Analysis:
Conventional Criteria versus New Alternatives. Structural Equation Modeling 6: 1–55. [CrossRef]
James, Lawrence R., Stanley A. Mulaik, and Jeanne M. Brett. 1982. Causal Analysis: Assumptions, Models and Data.
Beverly Hills: Sage.
Jöreskog, Karl, and Dag Sörbom. 2001. LISREL 8: User’s Reference Guide, 2nd ed. Chicago: Scientific Software
International.
Kapferer, Jean-Noel. 1986. Beyond Positioning, Retailer’s Identity. Brussels: Esomar Seminar Proceedings, pp. 167–76.
Kapferer, Jean-Noel. 2008. The New Strategic Brand Management—Creating and Sustaining Brand Equity Long Term,
4th ed. London: Kogan Page Publishers.
Keller, Kevin Lane. 2003. Brand Synthesis: The Multidimensionality of Brand Knowledge. Journal of
Consumer Research 29: 595–600. [CrossRef]
Keller, Kevin Lane, and Donald R. Lehmann. 2006. Brands and Branding: Research Findings and Future Priorities.
Marketing Science 25: 740–59. [CrossRef]

177
JRFM 2020, 13, 133

Kennedy, Mary Susan, Linda Ferrel, and Debbie Thorne LeClair. 2000. Consumers’ Trust of Salesperson and
Manufacturer: An Empirical Study. Journal of Business Research 51: 73–86. [CrossRef]
King, Stephen. 1991. Brand building in the 1990s. Journal of Marketing Management 7: 3–13. [CrossRef]
Lincoln, Yvonna S, and Egon G. Guba. 1985. Naturalistic Inquiry. Newbury Park: Sage Publications.
Madden, Thomasrank J., Frank Fehle, and Susan Fournier. 2006. Brands Matter: An Empirical Demonstration of
the Creation of Shareholder Value through Branding. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science 34: 224–35.
[CrossRef]
Malhotra, Naresh K. 1981. A Scale to Measure Self-concepts, Person Concepts, and Product Concepts. Journal of
Marketing Research 18: 456–64. [CrossRef]
Malhotra, Naresh K. 2004. Marketing Research, 4th ed. Upper Saddle River: Pearson-Prentice Hall.
Marôco, João. 2010. Análise de Equações Estruturais, Fundamentos Teóricos, Software & Aplicações. Pêro Pinheiro:
ReportNumber, Lda, ISBN 9789899676336.
Marsh, Herbert, John Balla, and Kit-Tai Hau. 1996. An Evaluation of Incremental Fit Indices: A Clarification
of Mathematical and Empirical Properties. In Advanced Structural Equation Modeling: Issues and Techniques.
Edited by George A. Marcoulides and Randall E. Schumacker. Mahwah: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates,
pp. 315–53.
Moorman, Christine, Gerald Zaltman, and Rohit Deshpande. 1992. Relationships between Providers and Users of
Market Research: The Dynamics of Trust. Journal of Marketing Research 29: 314–28. [CrossRef]
Morgan, Robert M., and Shelby D. Hunt. 1994. The Commitment–Trust Theory of Relationship Marketing.
Journal of Marketing 58: 20–38. [CrossRef]
Muniz, Albert Muñiz, Jr., and Thomas C. O’Guinn. 2001. Brand Community. Journal of Consumer Research
27: 412–32. [CrossRef]
Nachtigall, Christof, Rolf Steyer, and Wuthich-Martone. 2001. Causal Effects in Empirical Research.
In Interdisciplinary Perspectives on Causality: Bern Studies in the History and Philosophy of Science. Edited by
Michael May and Uwe Ostermeier. Norderstedt: Libri Books, pp. S1–S100.
Nunnally, Jum. 1978. Psychometric Theory, 2nd ed. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Nunnally, Jum, and Ira Bernstein. 1994. Psychometric Theory. New York: McGraw-Hill Higher.
Payne, Adrian, Kaj Storbacka, Pennie Frow, and Simon Knox. 2009. Co-creating Brands: Diagnosing and Designing
the Relationship Experience. Journal of Business Research 62: 379–89. [CrossRef]
Ping, Robert A. 2004. On Assuring Valid Measures for Theoretical Models Using Survey Data. Journal of Business
Research 57: 125–41. [CrossRef]
Prahalad, Coimbatore Krishnarao, and Venkat Ramaswamy. 2004. Co-creation Experiences: The Next Practice in
Value Creation. Journal of Interactive Marketing 18: 5–14. [CrossRef]
Priporas, Constantinos Vasilios, and Irene Kamenidou. 2011. Perceptions of Potential Postgraduate Greek Business
Students towards UK Universities Brand and Brand Reputation. Journal of Brand Management 18: 264–73.
[CrossRef]
Rao, Akshay R., Lu Qu, and Robert W. Rueker. 1999. Signaling Unobservable Product Quality through a Brand
Ally. Journal of Marketing Research 36: 258–68. [CrossRef]
Rauyruen, Papassapa, and Keneth E. Miller. 2007. Relationship Quality as a Predictor of B2B Customer Loyalty.
Journal of Business Research 60: 21–31. [CrossRef]
Simonin, Bernard, and Julie Ruth. 1998. Is a Company Known by the Company It Keeps? Assessing the Spillover
Effects of Brand Alliances on Consumer Brand Attitudes. Journal of Marketing Research 35: 30–42. [CrossRef]
Sirieix, Lucien, and Pierre-Louis Dubois. 1999. Vers un Modèle Qualité-satisfaction Intégrant la Confiance?
Recherche et Applications en Marketing 14: 1–22. [CrossRef]
Søderberg, Anne-Marie, Sundar Krishna, and Pernille Bjørn. 2013. Global Software Development: Commitment,
Trust and Cultural Sensitivity in Strategic Partnerships. Journal of International Management 19: 347–61.
[CrossRef]
Suomi, Kati. 2014. Exploring the Dimensions of Brand Reputation in Higher Education—A Case Study of a Finnish
Master’s Degree Programme. Journal of Higher Education Policy and Management 36: 646–60. [CrossRef]
van der Lans, Ralf, Bram van den Bergh, and Evelien Dieleman. 2014. Partner Selection in Brand Alliances: An
Empirical Investigation of the Drivers of Brand Fit. Marketing Science 33: 551–66. [CrossRef]

178
JRFM 2020, 13, 133

Vidaver-Cohen, Deborah. 2007. Reputation beyond the Rankings: A Conceptual Framework for Business School
Research. Corporate Reputation Review 10: 278–304. [CrossRef]
Wilson, David T. 1995. An Integrated Model of Buyer–Seller Relationships. Journal of the Academy of Marketing
Science 23: 335–45. [CrossRef]

© 2020 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access
article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution
(CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).

179
Journal of
Risk and Financial
Management

Article
Corporate Governance Quality, Ownership Structure,
Agency Costs and Firm Performance. Evidence from
an Emerging Economy
Haroon ur Rashid Khan 1 , Waqas Bin Khidmat 2, *, Osama Al Hares 1 , Naeem Muhammad 1 and
Kashif Saleem 1
1 Faculty of Business, University of Wollongong in Dubai, Knowledge Park, Dubai P.O. Box 20183, UAE;
HaroonKhan@uowdubai.ac.ae (H.u.R.K.); osamaalhares@uowdubai.ac.ae (O.A.H.);
NaeemMuhammad@uowdubai.ac.ae (N.M.); KashifSaleem@uowdubai.ac.ae (K.S.)
2 Department of Business Administration, Air University, Aerospace and Aviation Campus,
Kamra P.O. Box 43600, Pakistan
* Correspondence: waqas.khidmat@aack.au.edu.pk

Received: 16 June 2020; Accepted: 9 July 2020; Published: 15 July 2020

Abstract: The purpose of this paper is to investigate the effect of corporate governance quality
and ownership structure on the relationship between the agency cost and firm performance.
Both the fixed-effects model and a more robust dynamic panel generalized method of moment
estimation are applied to Chinese A-listed firms for the years 2008 to 2016. The results show that
the agency–performance relationship is positively moderated by (1) corporate governance quality,
(2) ownership concentration, and (3) non-state ownership. State ownership has a negative effect
on the agency–performance relationship. Various robust tests of an alternative measure of agency
cost confirm our main conclusions. The analysis adds to the empirical literature on agency theory
by providing useful insights into how corporate governance and ownership concentration can help
mitigate agency–performance relationship. It also highlights the impact of ownership type on the
relationship between agency cost and firm performance. Our study supports the literature that
agency cost and firm performance are negatively related to the Chinese listed firms. The investors
should keep in mind the proxies of agency cost while choosing a specific stock. Secondly; the abuse of
managerial appropriation is higher in state-held firms as compared to non-state firms. Policymakers
can use these results to devise the investor protection rules so that managerial appropriation can
be minimized.

Keywords: corporate governance; ownership concentration; agency cost; firm performance; dynamic
panel model

1. Introduction
Opportunistic managers, rather than maximizing the shareholder’s wealth, tend to misuse the
organizational resources for their own benefit. A good set of governance practices and ownership
structures can mitigate the conflict of interest between the principles and the agents, hence enhancing
the firm value. The purpose of this paper is to investigate the effect of corporate governance quality
and ownership structure on the relationship between agency cost and firm performance. This is
one of the few studies to explore the relationship between agency costs and firm performance in a
dynamic modeling approach. Specifically, this study aims to address the following research questions:
(1) Does corporate governance quality mitigates the relationship between agency cost and firm
performance? (2) How do ownership concentrations affect the relationship between agency cost and
firm performance? (3) How do state and non-state companies moderate the relationship between
agency cost and firm performance?

JRFM 2020, 13, 154; doi:10.3390/jrfm13070154 181 www.mdpi.com/journal/jrfm


JRFM 2020, 13, 154

Data is extracted of 2248 Chinese A-listed companies for the period 2008–2016. Using both
fixed effects and dynamic panel generalized methods of moment estimation, the results show that
agency cost is negatively related to firm performance. At the same time, corporate governance and
ownership concentration enhances firm performance. When corporate governance and ownership
concentration are taken as a moderating variable, we find a positive impact on the agency–performance
relationship. We also studied the effect of ownership type on the association between agency cost and
firm performance. Non-state ownership positively moderates the relationship between agency cost
and firm performance. In contrast, the agency cost keeps its negative sign when the state ownership
is taken as a moderating variable. Our conclusions are supported by taking alternative measures of
independent variables for robustness.

2. Background of the Study


The motivations for this study can be broken down into the following aspects: (1) Why China
should be used as the test case to conduct this research. (2) Why corporate governance quality matters
in an emerging economy like China. (3) Why dynamic panel modeling approach was used in this
study. The following Sections 2.1–2.3 briefly discuss these questions.

2.1. Why China?


Emerging markets are prone to managerial discretion to a greater extent compared to in
Anglo-American countries. Managers in these economies tend to manage funds inefficiently, which directly
affects firm performance. Compared to developed economies, the extent of agency cost is different in
emerging economies, specifically in China. Many researchers have used the proxy of agency cost based
on either the managerial discretion or ineffective use of shareholder’s funds.
We chose Chinese listed firms for this study because China’s market for corporate control and
the stock market mechanism is unique. Established in the early 1990s, the Chinese stock market
was used as a vehicle to transform the “planned economy” to a “market economy.” The Chinese
Securities Regulatory Commission (CSRC hereafter) under the umbrella of the Chinese government
made these reforms possible. Chinese listed firms rely heavily on internal financing, such as retained
earnings, rather than external funding. The reliance on internal financing gives managers discretion to
manipulate funds for self-empire building or investing inefficiently.
During the wave of recent privatization, about 60% of the Chinese market is still under the direct
or indirect control of the state. The word corporatization is used instead of privatization by Lin (2001).
He suggested that although the market for corporatization falls in the hands of the state, the firm’s
governance will be improved. The corporatization process has made it difficult for stakeholders
to distinguish between state-held and non-state-held companies (Milhaupt and Zheng 2015). State
control leads to more market power and easy access to external financing, which ultimately leads to a
considerable amount of funds at the disposal of managers. Firms with concentrated state ownership
behave differently when compared to non-state firms. For this purpose, the agency cost in state-owned
institutions is much higher than in privately held firms. Clarke (2003) suggested that state-owned
enterprises lack any clearly defined principles, which incites managers to fulfill their interest rather
than the interest of the shareholders. Additionally, these managers have strong political backing,
which makes them unaccountable for their actions. Therefore, as described by Ding et al. (2007),
the performance of state-held firms falls well short of that of privately owned firms. Based on the
argument above, we try to answer the research question, whether the ownership type affects the
agency–performance relationship or not?

2.2. Why Governance Quality Matters in China


In 2001, China became a member of the World Trade Organization (WTO) and adopted the
Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) principles of corporate governance
and started improving the corporate governance of its listed companies. CSRC, in cooperation with

182
JRFM 2020, 13, 154

National Trade and Economic Commission, issued the code of corporate governance in 2002. The laws
were based on the principles of investor protection and the code of conduct of the directors and
managers. A continuous improvement took place that led the listed companies to shift the reporting
from Chinese Accounting Standards to the International Accounting Standards in 2006. A two-tier
board system is a unique aspect of the Chinese corporate governance mechanism. A one-tiered system
such as that of USA has all the directors (executives and non-executives) being part of one Board,
known as the Board of directors. In the two-tier board system, there is an executive board (consisting of
all executive directors) and a supervisory board (consisting of all non-executive directors). The CSRC
has taken many steps for the good of corporate governance in listed companies and to protect minority
shareholders. Now companies are being encouraged to have at least one third independent directors
on Board, the information disclosure act (2007) was explicitly introduced during IPO, and rules relating
to shareholder meetings (2006) related to the convening of shareholder meetings and their resolution
were introduced. Most of the state and legal person companies were either fully or partially privatized
during this transition period.
The steps taken by CSRC to improve the corporate governance mechanism in China are remarkable.
They can be used as one of the tools to curtail the opportunistic behavior of the managers. As an emerging
economy, the Chinese market is still in the earliest steps of adopting good corporate governance practices.

2.3. Why Dynamic Panel Data?


The traditional agency framework was reexamined outside the jurisdiction of the Anglo-Saxon
market, especially in the emerging markets. The development in the corporate governance literature
has suggested that the governance variables plays an important part (endogenously) in the value
maximization process of the shareholders (Nguyen et al. 2015). The agency cost can affect firm
performance. Still, due to the link between the agency cost and firm governance variables, we cannot
be sure about the relationship, e.g., studies have shown that state ownership is positively related to
the presence of agency cost (Wei et al. 2005). Therefore, a dynamic model is required to cater to the
endogeneity problem, specifically in the case of China, where investor protection is weak. Additionally,
the motivation for using a dynamic panel model in the corporate governance literature is derived from
the recent calls by Zhou et al. (2014) and Nguyen et al. (2015).

3. Literature Review

3.1. Theoretical Literature Review


Two sets of approaches in literature have been distinguished by the researchers to mitigate the
agency problem. The first approach is the refraining approach, which proposes that the manager’s
interest could be aligned with that of the shareholders only if they are forced to refrain from opportunistic
behavior. The refraining approach consists of leverage (Emanuel et al. 2003; Malmquist 1990; Siregar
and Utama 2008), dividend payment (Easterbrook 1984; Lang and Litzenberger 1989), the risk of
corporate takeover (Bethel and Liebeskind 1993; Shleifer and Vishny 1991), a strong board structure
(Bathala et al. 2017; Jackling and Johl 2009; Miller 2002), independent audit committees (Collier and
Gregory 1999; Islam 2010), well-reputed external auditors (Eshleman and Guo 2014; Hope et al. 2012),
and oversight by institutional shareholders (Singh and Davidson 2003).
The second approach is known as the encouraging approach, and motivates the managers
to do desirable actions. This approach includes performance-based remuneration (Abowd 1990)
and employee stock ownership programs (Fox and Marcus 1992; Nikoskelainen and Wright 2007;
Singh and Davidson 2003). Agrawal and Knoeber (1996) suggested a different agency-mitigating
mechanism and concluded that a single measure could be misleading. Shan (2015) prepared a corporate
governance index for eight different corporate governance measures and explored their effect on
earnings management and value relevance. Our study also focusses on the design of the corporate
governance index, consisting of agency-mitigating variables, and investigates the impact of corporate

183
JRFM 2020, 13, 154

governance in moderating the relationship between agency cost and firm performance. The result
shows that an effective monitoring mechanism (corporate governance quality) can align the interests
of shareholders and managers.
Studies on ownership concentration and firm performance follow two contradicting theories.
The monitoring argument implies that in the presence of weak governance mechanism, the majority
shareholders helps in reducing the agency cost and increasing the overall firm value (Porta et al. 1999;
Shleifer and Vishny 1986; Bhagat et al. 2017; Su et al. 2008; Li et al. 2008). The principal–principal
theory states that the minority shareholders are exploited when the control of the ownership lies with
the majority shareholders. They are the key decision-makers and appoint the management based
on personal preferences. The management works to maximize value for the majority shareholders,
while the minority shareholders are continuously overlooked (Denis and McConnell 2003; Hu and
Izumida 2009). China is regarded as an emerging economy with corporate governance procedures still
at an evolving stage. Shareholders are subject to managerial expropriations, and hence concentrated
ownership may help mitigate the agency problem.

3.2. Empirical Literature Review and Hypothesis Development

3.2.1. Agency Cost and Firm Performance


Emerging markets are prone to managerial discretion to a greater extent compared to
Anglo-American countries. The managers in these economies tend to manage the funds inefficiently
that directly effects the firm performance. Compared to developed economies, the extent of agency cost
is different in emerging economies, specifically in China. Many researchers have used a proxy of agency
cost based either on managerial discretion or effective use of shareholder funds. The proxies for agency
cost mostly used in China are discretionary accruals as a mean to earnings management (Wang et al. 2015;
Wang and Campbell 2012; Guo and Ma 2015), free cash flow coupled with low growth opportunities
(Chung et al. 2005b; Chen et al. 2016; Chiou et al. 2010), research and development expenditure (Shust 2015;
Dinh et al. 2016; Ruiqi et al. 2017), and administrative expense ratio, which usually includes executives’
salaries, travelling allowances, conference levies, etc. (Li et al. 2008; Huang et al. 2011; Zhang et al. 2016).
Most of the literature cited on the relationship between the agency cost and firm performance has
established a negative relationship. For example, management earnings lead to the negative market
performance of firms listed in Hong Kong (Ching et al. 2006). Higher levels of leverage in terms of
short-term debt and long-term debt also have a negative effect on firm performance (Yazdanfar and
Öhman 2015). A study conducted by Lang et al. (1995) showed that managers’ discretion in selling
assets led to lower firm performance. Khidmat and Rehman (2014) empirically tested the relationship
between agency cost and firm performance in the emerging economy of Pakistan. They found a
negative association between the selling and administrative expense ratio and firm performance.
The Chinese market is prone to agency cost, and we expect a negative effect of agency cost on Chinese
listed firm performance.
H1. Agency costs have a negative effect on the firm performance.

3.2.2. Corporate Governance, Agency Cost, and Firm Performance


Managers’ opportunistic behavior increases their wealth, which leads to a decrease in firm
performance. This opportunistic behavior of managers can be curtailed through a good set of
internal and external corporate governance principles. Leverage is considered to be an agency
mitigating mechanism, as outsiders monitor the actions of managers with respect to efficient contracting
(Jensen 1986; Lang et al. 1995; Malmquist 1990). Debt covenants are considered an essential part of
efficient contracting that, in addition to active monitoring, prevents specific risk-taking activities by
management. All these efforts reduce the agency cost on one hand, while the value of the firm is
increased on the other.

184
JRFM 2020, 13, 154

Dividend policy is also considered to be an agency mitigating variable, as elaborated by


Ghosh et al. (2000). Two ways in which shareholder wealth can be maximized, either by increasing the
share price by investing in value-enhancing projects or by distributing the excess cash in the form of
dividends if managers fail to identify value-maximizing projects. Managers try to gain hold of the
firm’s resources when they have no positive NPV projects; hence, the agency cost of free cash flow
occurs. In this case, dividends play an essential role in alleviating the agency problem (Jensen 1986).
Porta et al. (2000) claimed that with the country having low investor protection, dividend policy
becomes a robust governance mechanism for alleviating agency cost.
Studies have shown the effects of different board characteristics on firm performance in emerging
economies (Borlea et al. 2017). A strong and independent board structure aligns the interest of managers
and shareholders. Jackling and Johl (2009), in their study, concluded that from the perspective of agency
theory, having independent directors on the Board enhances firm performance. Independent directors
not only the have experience and the knowledge required to scrutinize the opportunistic behavior
of the managers, but can also dissent from the other board members if they find any irregularities
(Marchetti et al. 2017). The literature has shown mixed results regarding the size of the board, e.g.,
Mappadang et al. (2018) found that larger board size led to tax avoidance. Some studies have suggested
that the optimal board size is either very small or very large (U-shaped), when assessed with respect to
performance (Coles et al. 2008). However, a study conducted by Beiner et al. (2004) shows that the choice
of the board size is dependent on environmental factors. Pearce and Zahra (1992) suggested that large
boards were characterized by efficient monitoring and had a larger impact on corporate performance
than small boards. Similarly, in advanced economies, studies have shown a positive association between
board size and firm performance (Guest 2009). In the context of the Chinese market, board size has a
negative impact on risk taking (Huang and Wang 2015; Haider and Fang 2016). Since board size leads
to less risk taking in Chinese listed firms, we can propose that managerial appropriations can be
curtailed through having a larger board size, thus boosting firm performance. CEO duality is taken as
an important component of board characteristics, and generally, empirical research has shown that
the separation of the CEO and the chairman results in an alleviation of the agency cost (Goyal and
Park 2002; Kula 2005; Lei et al. 2013). Board diversity is also considered an important element of
corporate governance. Research has shown that the representation of females on the board reduces
the agency cost and enhance the firm value. For example, the relationship between gender diversity
and firm performance in Chinese listed firms was investigated by Sial et al. (2018a). They concluded
that board diversity influences firm performance, and that corporate social responsibility mediates
the relationship. Similarly, research conducted by Sial et al. (2019) highlighted the importance of
gender diversity in moderating the relationship between corporate social responsibility and earnings
management. Board activity has a significant negative effect on agency costs. Frequent meetings of the
Board of directors mean that they are actively involved in the matters of the company, and managers
refrain from self-empire building (Ma and Tian 2009; Sahu and Manna 2013).
Some other corporate governance variables, in addition to board structure, also help in
mitigating agency cost. The presence of an audit committee with independent members can proactively
identify misappropriations in the financial records and can play a significant role in mitigating the
agency problem. The agency cost is reduced when an independent committee is devised voluntarily
(Collier and Gregory 1999). Additionally, it enhances firm value (Chan and Li 2008). A well-reputed
and experienced external auditor can carefully scrutinize the financial statements. They have the
required expertise, as well as having market knowledge of harmful financial practices. A Big Four
auditor can mitigate the agency cost, as well as help in enhancing the firm value (Eshleman and
Guo 2014; Hope et al. 2012). Some researchers have shown a profound effect of corporate social
responsibility (CSR) on firm performance. The study conducted by Sial et al. (2018b) suggested
CSR to be an important determinant of corporate governance in enhancing the firm performance.
However, the earnings management had the negative impact on the relationship between CSR and
firm performance.

185
JRFM 2020, 13, 154

The encouraging approach to agency cost states that managers can be motivated to carry out
specific desirable behavior. Jensen and Meckling (1976) proposed the convergence of interest hypothesis,
in which managers who were given stock ownership have a better effect on firm performance. Brander
and Poitevin (1992) explained that the terms offered in the compensation contract reduced the agency
cost. In China, the same results were established by Zhang et al. (2016), who concluded that the
perks of senior executives were negatively related to the agency cost. Managerial ownership is one
of the ways to align the interest of the shareholders and managers. By having an ownership stake
in the company, the managers would now take ownership of the company and would do their best
to increase its value. However, in the literature, this relationship has not been not found to be linear.
Still, there is a monotonic relationship, which suggests that at a lower level of managerial ownership,
the agency cost is reduced, but the agency cost increases when a certain level of managerial ownership
is reached (Jensen and Meckling 1976; McConnell and Servaes 1990).
Many recent studies have examined a combination of agency mitigating governance variables
instead of focusing on the effect of an individual variable. Agrawal and Knoeber (1996) suggested
a different agency mitigating mechanism and concluded that a single measure could be misleading.
Shan (2015) prepared a corporate governance index for eight various corporate governance measures
and explored their effect on earnings management and value relevance. Achim et al. (2016) investigated
the effect of overall corporate governance quality in the performance of Romanian firms. They found
a positive association between the governance quality and business performance in the emerging
economy. This study focuses on the design of the corporate governance index comprising agency
mitigating variables, and examines the impact of corporate governance in moderating the relationship
between agency cost and firm performance. Dey (2008) used seven different proxies of agency conflict
and generated seven principal factors from 22 individual governance variables. She concluded that
the existence and role of governance mechanism is a function of the level of agency conflict in the
firm. The link between corporate governance, agency cost and the firm performance is elaborated in
Table A1, Appendix A.
From the literature above, we establish the link between corporate governance variables, agency
cost and firm performance. The corporate governance quality mitigates the corporate expropriation
through efficient monitoring. The corporate governance is also linked with better performance
specifically in emerging markets (Klapper and Love 2004). With effective corporate governance
mechanisms, the agency cost can be curtailed, while higher firm performance can simultaneously
be achieved. Based on the link between corporate governance attributes and agency cost reduction,
as well as the positive association between the corporate governance dimensions and firm performance,
we can devise our hypothesis:
H2. Corporate governance quality moderates the agency–performance relationship.

3.2.3. Ownership Concentration, Agency Cost, and Firm Performance


The literature on ownership provides two contradicting theories with respect to ownership
concentration and the agency problem. The first theory is based on efficient monitoring. The theory
postulates that the majority shareholders have more stake in the firm. They are more vigilant than
the minority shareholders. Their monitoring skills make them distinct from the rest of the minority
shareholders. Due to efficient monitoring, they are able to reduce managerial expropriation. The second
theory, known as principle–principle agency theory, postulates that the majority shareholders
exert undue power on management to obtain their own benefits. The minority shareholders are
hence exploited by the managers as well as the majority shareholders (Denis and McConnell 2003;
Hu and Izumida 2009). In countries where the corporate governance mechanism is weak, ownership
concentration works as a substitute for corporate governance (Porta et al. 1999). An increase in
ownership concentration leads to shareholder activism. Therefore, agency costs can be reduced
(Kroll et al. 1993; Li et al. 2008; Su et al. 2008). As the percentage of individual ownership increases in
the firm, more individuals are inclined to incur monitoring costs (Porta et al. 1997).

186
JRFM 2020, 13, 154

Ma et al. (2010) studied the effect of ownership concentration and firm performance in Chinese
listed companies. They found a positive impact of ownership concentration and firm performance,
irrespective of who the majority shareholder was. Heugens et al. (2009) performed a meta-analysis
of the relationship between ownership concentration and firm performance in Asian countries.
They concluded a positive association between the two variables. They further elaborated that
ownership concentration was an active corporate governance mechanism for protecting the minority
shareholders from managerial appropriation.
In summary, concentrated ownership is linked with better firm performance in emerging economies
(Heugens et al. 2009). The concentrated ownership structure helps in the protection of the minority
shareholders from the managerial expropriation. Based on the alignment of interest argument,
the concentrated ownership mitigates the agency cost in the emerging economies, resulting in
improved performance (Chen 2001). The link between ownership concentration, agency cost, and firm
performance is stated in the following hypothesis:
H3. Ownership concentration moderates the agency–performance relationship.

3.2.4. Ownership Type, Agency Cost, and Firm Performance


Although ownership concentration has a significant effect on alleviating the agency problem,
different studies have shown that it depends upon the type of majority shareholder. The objective
of the government is to provide employment and social solidity in the economy. In this way, a
conflict of interest arises between state-owned enterprises and shareholders (Chong-En et al. 2002).
As illustrated by Gunasekarage et al. (2007), the performance of firms decreases if the ultimate
shareholder is the state. State-owned companies have substantial market power, easy access to finance,
and less monitoring, which makes them difficult to default (Li et al. 2008). Keeping in view the agency
perspective, many researchers have found a negative relationship between state ownership and firm
performance (Chen 2001; Jia et al. 2005; Wei and Varela 2003; Xu and Wang 1999).
Clarke (2003), in his article “Corporate Governance in China: An Overview”, demarcated the
objectives of state-owned firms as the generation of employment, direct control over strategic industries,
and politically motivating employment. This results in state-owned firms having a suboptimal level of
performance and higher agency costs. According to Xu and Wang (1999), the ownership concentration
in Chinese listed companies is positively related to firm performance. Additionally, state-owned firms
have an adverse effect on firm performance and labor productivity. Similarly, Chen et al. (2016), in their
study, investigated the impact of free cash flows and corporate governance characteristics on a firm’s
investment decisions, using data from 865 Chinese listed firms. The results showed that state ownership
concentration boosted over-/underinvestment, while firms with good governance attributes mitigated
the over-/underinvestment. On a similar note, Huang et al. (2011) examined the effect of agency
cost on the relationship between top executives’ overconfidence and investment–cash flow sensitivity.
Their results showed that investment–cashflow sensitivity was higher in state-owned companies.
Furthermore, they constructed an agency cost proxy and concluded that the agency cost was
higher in state-owned companies. A comparative study between state and non-state firms and their
effect on earnings management was carried out by Ding et al. (2007). They analyzed 273 privately
owned and state-owned companies. They concluded that the privately owned companies tended to
maximize their earnings more than the state-owned companies, despite the reported discretionary
accruals reported in non-state companies exceeding those of the state-owned companies.
In summary, state-owned firms in China are characterized by having higher agency costs. Hiring
in Chinese firms is based on political connections (Jonge 2014). The performance of non-state firms is
better than that of state-owned firms (Hess et al. 2010). The effect of state ownership on agency cost
and firm performance will be different from that of non-state ownership.
Accordingly, our next hypothesis would be as follows:
H4. State (non-state) ownership negatively (positively) moderates the agency–performance relationship.

187
JRFM 2020, 13, 154

4. Research Design

4.1. Data Collection


The data collection started by taking all the Chinese A-listed firms over the period 2008 to 2016.
However, we dropped firms based on the following criteria: (i) Firms belonging to financial sector.
These firms have different accounting mechanisms and are not subject to current data collection process.
(ii) Firms with ST (special treatment) and PT (particular treatment) status. These firms are financially
distressed and may give spurious results. (iii) Firms with missing values for dependent, independent
or control variables. (iv) We winsorized 1% of the data from upper and lower values to control for
outliers. After all the adjustments, the final sample comprised 2248 firms. The data was extracted from
the Chinese Stock Market and Research (CSMAR) database.

4.2. Model Specification and Estimation Techniques


The fixed-effects model and system GMM proposed by Blundell and Bond (1998) were used to
test our hypothesis and cater to the un-observed endogeneity problem (Nakano and Nguyen 2013;
Nguyen et al. 2014).
In the first equation, we want to explore the effect of agency cost and corporate governance on
firm performance.
FPit = αo + α1 ACit + α2 CGQit + αn CTR + μo (1)

where FP represents firm performance and has more than one measure, AC is the measure of agency
cost, while CGQ is the corporate governance quality index. CTR represents the control variables used
in the equations.
We added the interaction term in Equation (1) to capture the impact of corporate governance
quality and ownership structure on the relationship between agency cost and firm performance.

FPit = αo + α1 ACit + α2 CGQit + α2 (AC × Moderators it ) + αn CTR + μo (2)

where the moderators are corporate governance quality, ownership concentration, and ownership type,
respectively.
The financial performance of the firm is time-dependent, i.e., the current performance of the firm
is affected by the past performance and testing the effect of two-year lagged performance on current
performance does not give us a significant impact. This leads us to conclude that the AR (1) dynamic
panel model is sufficient. The literature on corporate governance suggests that corporate governance,
as well as ownership structure, are endogenously determined (Nguyen et al. 2015). Therefore, this
study first uses the fixed effect model to control the governance variables when estimating the
agency–performance relationship. However, the use of a fixed-effect estimator does not eliminate the
endogeneity lag performance measures. Following Nguyen et al. (2015), this study uses the system
GMM recommended by Blundell and Bond (1998). The major advantage of constructing the system
GMM estimator is that it enhances the power of estimation (Hoechle et al. 2012).

4.3. Dependent Variables


Following Le and Buck (2011), we incorporated two measures of performance return on assets
(ROA) and earnings per share (EPS) as dependent variables. We decided to include only the book
measures of performance as the market measure of performance lacks accuracy and precision of
valuation (Le and Buck 2011; Park and Luo 2001; Wan and Yuce 2007).

188
JRFM 2020, 13, 154

4.4. Independent Variables

Agency Cost
Our first independent variable is the proxy for different agency cost measures. We measured
the agency cost as the ratio of administrative expense to sales. The administrative expense includes
the majority of the costs that have been incurred by the management, such as salaries, executive
travel allowances, entertainment expenses, conferences and tour expenses, welfare payments, utilities,
and other expenses that fall under this category. According to Li et al. (2008), Chinese managers misuse
administrative expenses in automobiles, lavish office designs, recreational activities, and traveling.
Therefore, administrative overhead can be regarded as a close proxy of agency costs.
Free cash flow is also considered to be a determinant of agency costs (Jensen and Meckling 1976).
Still, the financial flexibility view suggests that managers intentionally keep a higher proportion of
cash to meet future needs (Arslan-Ayaydin et al. 2014). An alternative definition of free cash flow as a
measure of agency cost was used by Rahman and Mohd-Saleh (2008). First, we calculated free cash
flow and growth opportunities following Chung et al. (2005a). Then, we created a dummy variable for
agency cost that took the value of 1 if the firm in a particular industry in a specific year had free cash
flow in excess of the industry median and a price-to-book ratio less than the industry median.
Three additional variables for measuring the extent of agency cost were provided as a robust
check of our results. Earnings management, measured by absolute discretionary accruals following
Dechow et al. (1995), is considered to be a proxy of agency cost. Research has determined that firms
having high agency costs tend to manage their accruals (Christie and Zimmerman 1994; Teoh et al. 1998;
Cormier and Martinez 2006). Next, we measured research and development expenditure (R&D-AC).
R&D-AC is a dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the firm ‘i’ in the year t has a price-to-book
ratio less than the industry median and research and development expenditures higher than the
industry median. Finally, we constructed an agency cost index through principal component analysis.
We took the first principle component as the measure of agency cost.

4.5. Corporate Governance Quality


The second independent variable used in this study was the corporate governance quality index.
Due to the adoption since 2007 of the new accounting standards and the availability of data under
the compliance and explanation statement, we constructed the index with different agency mitigating
governance variables. The variables used in the construction of the index were dividend payment,
board size, board independence, board diversity, board meeting, CEO duality, Big Four auditor,
managerial ownership, managerial compensation, institutional investors, number of commissions
established, and separation of control rights and cashflow rights. The collection of corporate governance
variables data was based on the study conducted by Shan (2015), who developed a governance index
for Chinese listed firms. The detailed measurement of these variables is given in Table 1 below.
Following Achim et al. (2016), we used the compliance and explanation statement for the measurement
of corporate governance index.

Table 1. Constructing the Corporate Governance Index.

Corporate Governance
Description Measurement with Supporting Literature
Mechanism
When CEO is also the board Assigned value 1 to firm i in year t if CEO Duality does not exist,
CEO Duality
chairman. 0 for otherwise (Dey 2008; Gaio 2010; Lei et al. 2013).
The number of independent Award 1 mark if Board Independence of firm i in fiscal year t is
Independent Directors directors on the Board of greater than the median value of the sample in fiscal year t,
directors 0 mark otherwise (Shan 2013; Shan and Xu 2012).
Award 1 mark if Board Size of firm i in fiscal year t is greater
The number of directors on the
Board size than the median value of the sample in fiscal year t, 0 mark
Board of directors
otherwise (Pearce and Zahra 1992; Berghe and Levrau 2004).

189
JRFM 2020, 13, 154

Table 1. Cont.

Corporate Governance
Description Measurement with Supporting Literature
Mechanism
Award 1 mark if Board Meeting held in the firm i in year t is
Number of board meetings Total number of board
greater than the median value of the sample in fiscal year t,
held meetings held.
0 mark otherwise (Dey 2008; Vafeas 1999).
Award 1 mark if firm i in fiscal year t has a female director on
If the Board has female
Female Director the Board, 0 mark otherwise (Ararat et al. 2010; Carter et al. 2003;
representation or not.
Erhardt et al. 2003).
Total compensation awarded Award 1 mark if managerial compensation paid in the firm i in
Managerial Compensation to the top three highest-paid year t is greater than the median value of the sample in fiscal
managers in the same industry. year t, 0 mark otherwise (Lei et al. 2013).
Award 1 mark if managerial ownership held in the firm i in year
It is the shareholding
t is greater than the median value of the sample in a specific
Managerial Ownership percentage of top three officials
industry, 0 marks otherwise (Chong-En et al. 2002; Agrawal and
of the firm.
Knoeber 1996).
Award 1 mark if Dividend paid in the firm i in year t is greater
Measured by the dividend
Dividend Payment than the median value of the sample in a specific industry,
per share.
0 marks otherwise (Easterbrook 1984; Porta et al. 2000).
Award 1 mark if institutional ownership held in the firm i in
Measured as the ownership
Institutional Ownership year t is greater than the median value of the sample in a specific
held by institutions in the firm
industry, 0 marks otherwise (Tang and Chang 2015).
Award 1 mark if firm i in fiscal year t hires a Big Four auditor,
Big Four auditor Hiring a Big Four auditor
0 marks otherwise (Gao and Kling 2008; Lei et al. 2013).
Award 1 mark if separation between the control right and cash
Degree of separation between
Separation of control rights flow right in the firm i in year t is less than the median value of
the control right and cash
and cash flow rights the sample in a specific industry, 0 marks otherwise (Lei et al.
flow right
2013).
Award 1 mark if the Committee established in the firm i in year t
Number of committees Total number of committees a
is greater than the median value of the sample in a specific
established firm has.
industry, 0 marks otherwise.
Note: The corporate governance index is made under the compliance and explanation statement rule.

4.6. Ownership Concentration


Large shareholders have a lot of stake in the company and can actively monitor the activities of the
managers. The greater the degree of ownership, the more active the shareholders are (Kroll et al. 1993;
Su et al. 2008; Li et al. 2008). Therefore, we measured ownership concentration as the percentage of
shares held by the largest shareholder.

4.7. Ownership Type


We divided ownership type into two categories depending upon whether it was held by the state or
by a non-state entity. State ownership was measured as the percentage share held by the state. Non-state
ownership was defined as the percentage of shares held by non-state entities (Ding et al. 2007).

4.8. Control Variables


In this study, we controlled the firm size by taking the natural logarithm of total assets
(Nguyen et al. 2014; Richardson et al. 2003). The second control variable was leverage, which was
measured as the ratio of total debt to total assets (Arthurs et al. 2008). Growth opportunities also affect
the firm value, so their effect was also controlled. This was calculated as the difference between current
year sales and previous sales divided by the previous sales (Gill and Biger 2013). We also controlled
the firm age, which was calculated as the number of years for which the firms had been listed in the
stock exchange (Shan 2015). The summary of all the variables is given below in Table 2.

190
JRFM 2020, 13, 154

Table 2. Summary of the variables.

Variables Symbol Measurement with Supported Literature


ROA is measured as the ratio of earnings before interest and taxes scaled by
Return on Assets ROA
total assets (Le and Buck 2011; Zahra 2007; Zahra et al. 2000)
EPS is calculated as the net income scaled by several shares outstanding
Earnings per share EPS
(Zhang et al. 2014).
Independent Variables
Administrative Expense Ratio AC1 AC1 is measured as the ratio of administrative expenses to sales (Lei et al. 2013).
FCFE_AC is a dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the firm ‘i’ in year t
Free Cash Flows FCFE_AC has a price-to-book ratio less than the industry median and free cash flows
greater than the industry median (Rahman and Mohd-Saleh 2008).
The absolute value of EM is the measure of earnings management. The discretionary accruals are
EM
discretionary accruals calculated through a modified Jones model (Dechow et al. 1995).
R&D-AC is a dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the firm ‘i’ in year t
Research and Development
R&D-AC has a price-to-book ratio less than the industry median and R&D greater than
expenditures
the industry median.
PC_AC is the first principle component generated through principal
The first principle component
PC-AC component analysis of four agency cost proxies i-e AC1, FCF_AC, EM,
of agency cost variables
and R&D-AC (An et al. 2016).
CGQ represents the corporate governance index comprising of twelve
Corporate Governance index CGQ individual corporate governance measures. The detailed calculation is
discussed in Table 1 (Shan 2015; Lei et al. 2013).
Top1 is measured as the shareholding percentage of the largest shareholder.
Ownership Concentration Top1
(Su et al. 2008; Lei et al. 2013)
State SOE Percentage of shares held by state.
Non-state NSOE Percentage of shares held by non-state entity (Ding et al. 2007).
Control Variables:
Firm Size SIZE The natural logarithm of total assets (Nguyen et al. 2014; Richardson et al. 2003).
Following (Arthurs et al. 2008), we measure leverage as the book value of total
Leverage Lev
debt over the book value of debt plus the book value of equity.
(Current year sales less previous year sales)/previous year sales
Growth in Sales Growth
(Gill and Biger 2013).
Firm’s age measures the age of the firm from the first year of listing
Firm Age AGE
(Shan and Xu 2012).
Industry dummy shows the effect of each company listed in a particular the
Industry Dummy INDUSTRY industry according to CSRC coding
(Arora and Dharwadkar 2011; Filatotchev et al. 2007).
Year Dummies YEAR The year dummies represent the year effect from the year 2008 to 2016.

5. Empirical Results and Discussion

5.1. Descriptive Statistics and Multicollinearity Diagnostic


Table 3, Panel A reports the descriptive statistics of all the variables used in our methodology.
The overall descriptive statistics show the mean value of performance measures used in our analysis at
4.3 percent, 6.49 percent, and 0.39 per share for ROA, ROE, and EPS, respectively. The average value of
the administrative expense ratio is 9.8 percent, while the free cash flows to total assets have a negative
average value of −18.7 percent of total assets. The absolute value of discretionary accruals denoted
by EM has a mean value of 5.43 percent of total assets. The mean value of the corporate governance
quality index represented by CGQ is 5.79. The maximum amount of the shareholding percentage of
the largest shareholder (top 1) is 89.99 percent.

191
Table 3. Summary statistics.

Overall Sample State Owned Non-State Owned


Variables Obs. Mean SD Min Med Max Obs. Mean SD Min Median Max Obs. Mean SD Min Median Max
ROA 15,075 0.0430 0.0619 −1.097 0.045 2.632 8791 0.0496 0.063 −1.097 0.051 2.632 5761 0.035 0.057 −0.688 0.033 0.373
JRFM 2020, 13, 154

ROE 15,349 0.0649 1.646 −176.4 0.066 100.7 8925 0.0866 1.073 −1.881 0.088 100.7 5795 0.0327 2.322 −176.4 0.037 4.126
EPS 15,349 0.397 0.592 −4.828 0.399 17.82 8925 0.401 0.473 −2.880 0.42 17.82 5795 0.402 0.742 −4.828 0.421 15.38
AC1 15,349 0.0988 0.0819 0.00976 0.10 0.791 8925 0.081 0.086 0.0097 0.079 0.791 5795 0.102 0.066 0.0097 0.114 0.791
FCF/TA 14,292 −0.187 0.239 −4.333 −0.17 1.091 8006 −0.170 0.230 −2.717 −0.161 1.091 5677 −0.212 0.237 −3.615 −0.192 0.500
R&D/TA 13,591 0.0023 0.0102 0 0.0025 0.277 7870 0.0027 0.0110 0 0.0024 0.277 5187 0.0017 0.007 0 0.0019 0.170
EM 12,218 0.0543 0.0554 0.00041 0.056 0.794 7106 0.06 0.057 0.0001 0.05 0.794 4607 0.07 0.052 0.0004 0.043 0.461
CGQ 15,075 5.792 1.565 0 5.81 11 8791 6.074 1.523 1 6.061 11 5761 5.354 1.525 0 5.82 11
TOP1 15,349 35.63 15.09 2.197 35.67 89.99 8925 33.66 14.24 2.197 34.63 89.99 5795 39.42 15.49 4.159 39.25 89.09
SIZE 15,075 21.86 1.244 17.64 21.79 28.04 8791 21.49 0.981 17.64 21.41 25.86 5761 22.46 1.371 17.67 22.34 28.04
Lev 14,897 0.413 0.203 0.0460 0.42 0.903 8925 0.353 0.192 0.0460 0.38 0.903 5795 0.505 0.185 0.0460 0.53 0.903
Growth 12,219 0.173 0.362 −0.484 0.154 2.077 7065 0.198 0.372 −0.484 0.22 2.077 4635 0.136 0.338 −0.484 0.146 2.077
Firm Age 15,075 8.071 6.252 0 8.20 26 8791 5.748 5.573 0 5.712 26 5761 11.50 5.564 0 11.58 26
Governance Variables
Board Size 14,623 8.809 1.773 0 8.82 18 5632 9.468 1.941 0 9.78 18 8816 8.387 1.505 3 8.42 16
Board Independence 14,625 3.229 0.635 0 3.23 8 5632 3.444 0.760 0 3.47 8 8818 3.090 0.491 1 3.19 6
CEO Duality 14,681 0.263 0.440 0 0.252 1 5671 0.105 0.307 0 0.18 1 8835 0.364 0.481 0 0.352 1
Female Directors Ratio 15,075 0.167 0.106 0 0.168 0.647 5761 0.135 0.0933 0 0.11 0.600 8791 0.187 0.109 0 0.194 0.647

192
Board Meetings 15,064 9.526 3.727 1 9.61 46 5759 9.330 3.688 2 9.46 46 8782 9.626 3.745 1 9.66 38
Top 3 Compensation 14,877 14.15 0.726 10.71 14.18 17.45 5779 14.14 0.752 10.71 15.41 17.45 8921 14.14 0.698 11.13 14.05 17.35
Managerial ownership 14,558 14.98 3.735 3.045 14.94 21.93 5757 11.57 2.767 4.605 11.51 20.82 8646 16.63 2.945 3.045 15.93 21.93
Commission established 14,869 3.884 0.556 0 3.93 8 5780 3.889 0.620 0 3.95 7 8912 3.882 0.511 0 3.04 8
Dividend payments 15,349 0.121 0.209 0 0.132 6.787 5795 0.111 0.248 0 0.12 6.787 8925 0.131 0.183 0 0.141 3
Big 4 Auditor 14,897 0.0498 0.218 0 0.051 1 5795 0.0871 0.282 0 0.045 1 8925 0.0245 0.155 0 0.0296 1
Separation of two rights 14,825 5.543 8.070 0 5.55 53.42 5566 4.388 7.665 0 4.334 39.43 8852 6.266 8.246 0 7.07 53.42
Institutional shareholders 13,337 7.092 9.497 0 7.10 87.89 5244 8.810 12.33 0 8.91 85.77 7542 5.885 6.658 0.0020 5.72 87.89
Note: Table 3 reports the summary statistics of the variables used in Equations (1) and (2). Additionally, the Table reports the summary statistics for the state and non-state enterprises.
The detailed calculations are presented in Table 1. The detailed measurements of governance variables are presented in Table 2.
JRFM 2020, 13, 154

We divided the descriptive statistics into two more panels based on state ownership and non-state
ownership. The mean values of ROA, ROE, and EPS in Non-SOE (4.9 percent, 8.6 percent, and 4.01
respectively) are higher than those of the SOE (3.5 percent, 3.27 percent, 4.02 per share respectively).
State-owned enterprises have a higher level of absolute discretionary accruals (0.07 > 0.06), as well as a
higher administrative expense ratio (0.102 > 0.081) compared to non-SOE. The non-state companies
have a better corporate governance score of 6.07 compared to state companies, which have a score of
5.35. The state-owned companies are larger (22.46 > 21.49), as well as having a higher average leverage
(0.505 > 0.353), than non-state-owned companies.
Panel B presents the descriptive statistics of the corporate governance variables used in this study
divided into three groups: Overall, State, and Non-State. The A-listed companies from the period 2008
to 2016 have an average independent director of 3.29, reported CEO duality of 26.27 percent of the total
sample, average board size of 8.8, while 16.7 percent on average present female representation on the
board. On average, non-state firms pay a higher level of dividends (0.13 > 0.11), have a higher female
ratio on the board (0.18 > 0.13), have higher managerial ownership (16.63 percent > 11.57 percent), and a
higher degree of separation between control rights and cash flow rights (6.26 percent > 4.38 percent)
as compared to state-owned companies. All these governance attributes lead to a better governance
environment, resulting in less managerial expropriation. State-owned companies have a greater board
size (9.46 > 8.38), more institutional ownership (8.8 > 5.8), more access to getting audited by Big Four
auditors (0.087 > 0.02) and more independent directors on the board (3.44 > 3.09).
Table 4 shows the results for pairwise correlation analysis. Looking at all of the independent
variables, we find no sign of multicollinearity, as the values of the coefficients are less than 0.8.
Additionally, we performed individual VIF analysis and found all the values to be less than the critical
level of 10 in every case (Shan 2015). When performing the regression analysis for the moderating
effect, the interaction term usually gives a value for VIF greater than 10. Following Allison (2010),
we mean-centered the interaction terms (agency cost variables and their interaction with CGQ, Top1,
SOE, and NSOE). The use of mean centering does not affect the probability values, and at the same
time, the multicollinearity is reduced, as seen from Table 5. All the dependent variables are positively
correlated with corporate governance quality. On the other hand, the agency cost proxies are negatively
related to the performance measures. Ownership concentrations also have a positive association with
the firm performance.

5.2. Moderating Effects of Corporate Governance Quality


Table 6 shows the effect of corporate governance and agency cost on firm performance by using
the fixed-effect model and system dynamic panel data estimation. ROA and EPS were the dependent
variables, while agency cost and corporate governance were the independent variables. Four variables,
namely, Size, Leverage, Growth, and Firm age, were used as control variables. The asset size used
has a positive effect on firm performance while, on the contrary, a higher level of leverage hampers
performance. These results are similar to the study conducted by Vithessonthi and Tongurai (2015).

193
Table 4. Correlation analysis.

ROA EPS AC1 FCF-AC R&D-AC EM F1 CGQ Top1 SOE NSOE SIZE LEVERAGE GROWTH FIRM AGE
ROA 1
EPS 0.5956 * 1
AC1 −0.1460 * −0.1453 * 1
JRFM 2020, 13, 154

FCF-AC −0.0344 * −0.0495 * −0.0610 * 1


R&D-AC −0.0605 * −0.0245 * −0.0011 0.1738 * 1
EM −0.0302 * −0.008 0.0036 −0.0556 * −0.0258 * 1
F1 −0.0728 * 0.0118 0.017 0.5568 * 0.4603 * −0.0604 * 1
CGQ 0.0653 * 0.0915 * −0.0564 * −0.0072 −0.0801 * −0.0219 * −0.0414 * 1
Top1 0.0889 * 0.1191 * −0.1935 * 0.0168 * −0.0594 * −0.0024 * −0.0367 * −0.0332 * 1
SOE −0.1214 * −0.0003 −0.1703 * −0.0937 * −0.0241 * −0.0323 * 0.0624 * −0.2252 * 0.1873 * 1
NSOE 0.1248 * 0.0085 0.1402 * 0.0733 * 0.0175 * 0.0299 * −0.0451 * 0.2129 * −0.1643 * 0.21 1
SIZE −0.0176 * 0.2028 * −0.3230 * 0.1898 * 0.1876 * −0.0555 * 0.2388 * 0.1495 * 0.2321 * 0.3825 * −0.3600 * 1
LEVERAGE −0.3121 * −0.1126 * −0.3177 * 0.0646 * 0.0861 * 0.0715 * 0.0608 * 0.1547 * 0.0681 * 0.3665 * −0.3513 * 0.5097 * 1
GROWTH 0.2309 * 0.1920 * −0.1004 * −0.0277 * 0.0157 * 0.141 * −0.0193 * 0.1110 * 0.0132 −0.0850 * 0.0818 * 0.0423 * 0.0193 * 1
FIRM AGE −0.1682 * −0.0814 * −0.0530 * 0.0715 * 0.0974 * 0.025 * 0.0931 * −0.0372 * −0.0585 * 0.4509 * −0.4395 * 0.4068 * 0.4176 * −0.0854 * 1
Note: Table 4 reports the correlation coefficients of the variables used in Equations (1) and (2); the detailed calculation is presented in Table 1. * signify p-values of 1 percent.

Table 5. VIF diagnostic.

Variables VIF SQRT VIF Tolerance

194
AC1 1.01 1.005 0.810474
FCF-AC 1.24 1.114 0.994244
CGQ 1.12 1.058 0.444664
CGQ × AC 4.38 2.093 0.614631
CGQ × FCF-AC 4.51 2.124 1.257379
TOP1 1.26 1.122 0.436769
TOP1 × AC1 3.57 1.889 0.549014
TOP1 × FCF-AC 4.92 2.218 1.2473
SOE 1.37 1.170 0.481675
SOE × AC1 3.43 1.852 0.526637
SOE × FCF-AC 3.96 1.990 1.670354
NSOE 1.03 1.015 0.415938
NSO × AC1 3.44 1.855 0.41766
NSOE*FCF-AC 3.74 1.934 1.681659
Size 1.15 1.072 0.864823
Leverage 1.24 1.114 0.959959
Growth 1.16 1.077 1.045663
Firm age 1.03 1.015 0.69513
Note: Table 5 reports the VIF diagnostics with tolerance values; the detailed calculation is presented in Table 1.
Table 6. Moderating effect of CGQ on agency costs and firm performance.

Return on Assets (ROA) Earnings per Share (EPS)


Variables
Fixed Effects System GMM Fixed Effects System GMM Fixed Effects System GMM Fixed Effects System GMM
AC1 −0.282 *** −0.386 *** −0.301 *** −0.315 ** −1.299 *** −1.527 *** −1.187 *** −1.691 ***
JRFM 2020, 13, 154

(0.011) (0.057) (0.027) (0.13) (0.088) (0.508) (0.216) (0.640)


FCF-AC −0.004 *** −0.002 −0.009 * 0.001 −0.032 *** −0.008 * −0.113 *** −0.055
(0.001) (0.003) (0.005) (0.006) (0.019) (0.013) (0.041) (0.052)
Top1 0.005 *** 0.00287 *** 0.00316 *** 0.00418 ** 0.0330 *** 0.0193 *** 0.0350 *** 0.0163 *
(0.002) (0.004) (0.006) (0.001) (0.003) (0.004) (0.004) (0.008)
AC1 × Top1 0.004 ** 0.013 * 0.021 ** 0.029 *
(0.044) (0.017) (0.035) (0.075)
FCF-AC × Top1 0.009 *** .007 * 0.014 ** 0.079 *
(0.082) (0.088) (0.006) (0.008)
Size 0.008 *** 0.047 0.086 *** 0.045 0.180 *** 0.129 *** 0.18 *** 0.13 ***
(0.001) (0.003) (0.001) (0.003) (0.011) (0.04) (0.011) (0.04)
Growth 0.002 *** 0.023 ** 0.002 *** 0.003 ** 0.004 *** 0.088 * 0.003 *** 0.088 *
(0.0006) (0.001) (0.000) (0.001) (0.005) (0.004) (0.0005) (0.04)
Leverage −0.118 *** −0.135 *** −0.119 *** −0.134 *** −0.725 *** −0.535 *** −0.724 *** −0.537 ***
(0.005) (0.012) (0.005) (0.012) (0.043) (0.089) (0.043) (0.089)
Firm Age −0.003 *** −0.002 *** −0.003 *** −0.002 *** −0.038 *** −0.006 −0.038 *** −0.006

195
(0.000) (0.001) (0.000) (0.006) (0.002) (0.011) (0.002) (0.011)
L.ROA 0.102 ** 0.105 ** 0.522 *** 0.508 ***
(0.047) (0.044) (0.071) (0.07)
Constant −0.062 ** 0.026 −0.061 ** 0.021 −3.008 *** −2.387 *** −3.017 *** −2.379 ***
(0.0285) (0.0718) (0.0286) (0.0727) (0.230) (0.793) (0.231) (0.796)

Observations 13,178 11,930 13,178 11,930 13,178 11,983 13,178 11,983


R-squared 0.129 0.129 0.088 0.088
Number of Firms 2404 2248 2404 2248 2404 2252 2404 2252
Wald test (Prob > Chi2 ) (0.00) *** (0.00) *** (0.00) *** (0.00) ***
- 0.145 - 0.149 - 0.55 - 0.58
Hansen-J test (p-value)

Note: Table 6 reports the regression results from estimating Equations (1) and (2) respectively. Variable definitions are provided in Table 2. *, **, *** signify p-values at 1 percent, 5 percent,
and 10 percent, respectively.
JRFM 2020, 13, 154

Looking at the primary results, agency cost (administrative expense ratio and free cash flow) has
a significant adverse effect on firm performance measured by ROA and EPS. Corporate governance
has a positive impact on both returns on ROA (FE: β = 0.003, p < 0.01; GMM: β = 0.002, p < 0.01) as
well as EPS (FE: β = 0.003, p < 0.01; GMM: β = 0.004, p < 0.01). The objective of the study was to
investigate the moderating effect of corporate governance quality on the relationship between agency
cost and firm performance. To do so, we incorporated the interactions terms of corporate governance
quality with agency cost proxies. The results are depicted in Table 6 with ROA and EPS as dependent
variables. Corporate governance quality significantly positively moderates the relationship between
agency cost and firm performance. When interaction terms are introduced, the coefficient of agency
cost has changed the sign from negative to positive for both AC1 × CGQ (ROA—FE: β = 0.004, p < 0.01;
GMM: β = 0.012, p < 0.01 and EPS—FE: β = 0.002, p < 0.05; GMM: β = 0.03, p < 0.1) and FCF-AC
× CG (ROA—FE: β = 0.009, p < 0.01ta; GMM: β = 0.007, p < 0.1 and EPS—FE: β = 0.002, p < 0.05;
GMM: β = 0.007, p < 0.1). These results indicate that the objectives of the principles and agents are
aligned if the firms have the adopted good corporate governance practices reported by Jensen and
Meckling (1976). Looking at the control variables, the size of the firm has a positive effect on the firm
performance in all cases, which is in agreement with what we found in the literature. Leverage is
negatively related to the performance, as can be seen by the signs of the negative coefficients in the
table. Based on these results, we can accept our alternative hypothesis that corporate governance
positively moderates the agency–performance relationship.

5.3. Moderating Effects of Ownership Concentration


Table 7 indicates the effect of ownership concentration measured by the shareholding percentage
of the top shareholder on the relationship between agency cost and firm performance. The results
show a positive impact of ownership concentration on the ROA and EPS for both the fixed-effect
model and GMM. These results are in line with those of Shleifer and Vishny (1986) and Li et al. (2008).
We introduced two interaction terms to measure the moderating effect of ownership concentration on
the relationship between firm performance and agency cost. As shown in the results, the interactions
terms possess a positive coefficient value, with ROA (TOP_1 × AC1 β = 0.002, p < 0.01 and TOP_1
× FCF-AC β = 0.0014, p < 0.1) and EPS (TOP_1 × AC1 β = 0.002 and TOP_1 × AC2 β = 0.006) in the
fixed effect model. Similarly, the GMM model also exhibits a positive moderating effect of ownership
concentration on the relationship between agency cost and firm performance. At higher levels of
ownership concentration (for the largest shareholder), the shareholders are highly vigilant, and this
helps facilitate the alignment of interests among the agents and the principles. The results show
that as the ownership concentration is increased, the firm performance increases on the one hand,
while the agency cost is decreased on the other side. These results support the second hypothesis
that the ownership concentration positively moderates the relationship between agency cost and
firm performance.

5.4. Moderating Effects of Ownership Types


The effect of ownership type on the relationship between agency cost and firm performance is
reported in Table 8 State ownership is taken as a primary independent variable. A firm is described as
state-owned if more than 50 percent of shares are held by the government and its affiliates. The results
of the table report the adverse effect of state ownership on firm performance for both the fixed-effect
model and GMM. These two sets of results are in line with the studies conducted in the Chinese
context by Wei and Varela (2003) and Wei et al. (2005). According to these authors, the agency cost
in state enterprises is higher, and this negatively affects the firm value. To test our third hypothesis,
we introduced two interaction terms for agency costs with the state ownership variable to measure
the effect on firm performance. All the interaction terms (SO × AC1, SO × FCF-AC) report negative
coefficients, showing that state enterprises are significantly motivated by political motives; therefore,
they focus less on performance.

196
Table 7. Moderating effect of ownership concentration on agency costs and firm performance.

Return on Assets (ROA) Earnings per Share (EPS)


Variables
Fixed
Fixed Effects System GMM Fixed Effects System GMM System GMM Fixed Effects System GMM
EFFECTS
JRFM 2020, 13, 154

AC1 −0.28 *** −0.387 *** −0.206 *** −0.258 ** −1.274 *** −1.529 *** −0.136 0.303
(0.011) (0.057) (0.021) (0.105) (0.088) (0.507) (0.173) (0.764)
FCF-AC −0.004 *** −0.004 0.007 0.005 −0.035 *** −0.009 −0.033 −0.004
(0.002) (0.001) (0.003) (0.004) (0.019) (0.013) (0.027) (0.0349)
Top1 0.003 *** 0.019 0.006 *** 0.006 ** 0.004 *** 0.003 * 0.008 *** 0.009 ***
(0.004) (0.007) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.001) (0.000) (0.002)
AC1 × Top1 0.002 *** 0.004 * 0.042 *** 0.064 ***
(0.000) (0.002) (0.005) (0.019)
FCF-AC × Top1 0.00143 ** 0.00155 * 0.005 0.014
(.000) (.000) (0.007) (0.008)
Size 0.009 *** 0.005 * 0.00949 *** 0.00593 * 0.189 *** 0.136 *** 0.188 *** 0.131 ***
(0.001) (0.003) (0.002) (0.003) (0.011) (0.040) (0.011) (0.039)
Growth 0.001 ** 0.002 ** 0.001 *** 0.002 ** 0.003 *** 0.088 * 0.003 *** 0.089 *
(0.002) (0.001) (0.000) (0.001) (0.000) (0.049) (0.000) (0.049)
Leverage −0.114 *** −0.133 *** −0.114 *** −0.133 *** −0.682 *** −0.527 *** −0.688 *** −0.548 ***

197
(0.005) (0.011) (0.005) (0.012) (0.043) (0.09) (0.042) (0.089)
Firm Age −0.002 *** −0.001 ** −0.002 *** −0.001 ** −0.032 *** −0.004 −0.034 *** −0.003
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.002) (0.011) (0.002) (0.011)
L.ROA 0.105 ** 0.109 ** 0.505 *** 0.496 ***
(0.047) (0.045) (0.067) (0.068)
Constant −0.0814 *** 0.00856 −0.0873 *** −0.00594 −3.220 *** −2.549 *** −3.309 *** −2.624 ***
(0.0288) (0.0733) (0.0289) (0.0741) (0.233) (0.825) (0.233) (0.812)

Observations 13,178 11,930 13,178 11,930 13,178 11,983 13,178 11,983


R-squared 0.125 0.126 0.084 0.089
Number of Firms 2404 2248 2404 2248 2404 2252 2404 2252
Wald test (Prob > Chi2 ) (0.00) *** (0.00) *** (0.00) *** (0.00) ***
Hansen-J test (p-value) 0.25 0.23 0.31 0.33
Note: Table 7 reports the regression results from estimating Equations (1) and (2), respectively. Variable definitions are provided in Table 2. *, **, *** signify p-values at 1 percent, 5
percent, and 10 percent, respectively.
Table 8. Moderating effect of ownership type (SOE) on agency costs and firm performance.

Return on Assets (ROA) Earnings per Share (EPS)


Variables
Fixed Effects System GMM Fixed Effects System GMM Fixed Effects System GMM Fixed Effects System GMM
JRFM 2020, 13, 154

AC1 −0.304 *** −0.414 *** −0.314 *** −0.436 *** −1.405 *** −1.665 *** −1.233 *** −1.239 *
(0.011) (0.066) (0.012) (0.095) (0.093) (0.582) (0.107) (0.658)
FCF-AC −0.004 *** −0.002 −0.005 *** −0.001 −0.036 *** −0.014 −0.063 *** −0.022
(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.011) (0.013) (0.015) (0.014)
SOE −0.019 *** −0.014 −0.023 *** −0.023 0.144 *** 0.327 ** −0.074 * 0.475 ***
(0.004) (0.011) (0.005) (0.02) (0.038) (0.143) (0.043) (0.172)
AC1 × SOE −0.034 *** −0.069 −0.576 *** −1.276 *
(0.021) (0.251) (0.176) (0.773)
FCF-AC × SOE −0.002 ** −0.002 −0.057 *** −0.025
(0.002) (0.002) (0.022) (0.027)
Size 0.009 *** 0.008 ** 0.009 *** 0.008 ** 0.197 *** 0.140 *** 0.197 *** 0.142 ***
(0.001) (0.004) (0.001) (0.004) (0.011) (0.043) (0.011) (0.042)
Growth 0.001 *** 0.001 * 0.001 *** 0.002 * 0.003 *** 0.089 * 0.003 *** 0.091 *
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.059) (0.000) (0.055)
Leverage −0.115 *** −0.135 *** −0.115 *** −0.135 *** −0.700 *** −0.582 *** −0.698 *** −0.579 ***
(0.005) (0.013) (0.005) (0.012) (0.044) (0.096) (0.044) (0.094)

198
Firm Age −0.003 *** −0.002 *** −0.003 *** −0.002 *** −0.039 *** −0.008 −0.039 *** −0.008
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.002) (0.011) (0.002) (0.011)
L.ROA 0.103 ** 0.104 ** 0.475 *** 0.474 ***
(0.051) (0.047) (0.065) (0.064)
Constant −0.052 * −0.028 −0.04 * −0.023 −3.12 *** −2.575 *** −3.149 *** −2.667 ***
(0.0287) (0.0838) (0.0287) (0.0930) (0.240) (0.848) (0.240) (0.841)
Observations 12,700 11,518 12,700 11,518 12,700 11,552 12,700 11,552
R-squared 0.136 0.137 0.085 0.086
Number of Firms 2381 2224 2381 2224 2381 2227 2381 2227
Wald test (Prob > Chi2 ) (0.00) *** (0.00) *** (0.00) *** (0.00) ***
Hansen-J test (p-value) 0.17 0.22 0.24 0.22
Note: Table 8 reports the regression results from estimating Equations (1) and (2), respectively. Variable definitions are provided in Table 2. *, **, *** signify p-values of 1 percent, 5
percent, and 10 percent, respectively.
JRFM 2020, 13, 154

The effect of non-state ownership on the relationship between agency cost and firm performance
is shown in Table 9. Non-state ownership has a positive impact on both performance measures,
as depicted in the fixed-effect model and GMM. We introduced two interaction terms to specifically
explore the effect of non-state ownership on agency–performance relationships. The interaction terms
show a positive and significant moderating effect on firm performance in the fixed effect model as
well as GMM. Looking at the ROA model, NSO × AC1 and NSO × AC2 have coefficients of 0.0381
and 0.0027 in the fixed-effect model, and of 0.068 and 0.0026 in GMM. The EPS model also shows
positive coefficients with both fixed-effect models (FE: β = 0.019, p < 0.01; GMM: β = 0.005, p < 0.01)
and GMM (FE: β = 0.597, p < 0.05; GMM: β = 0.028, p < 0.1). These results are in alignment with the
study conducted by Ding et al. (2007), who found better performance by non-state enterprises as
compared to state-owned ones. Based on the above analysis, we support our third hypothesis, that
state ownership has an adverse effect on the agency–performance relationship. In contrast, non-state
ownership positively moderates the agency–performance relationship.

5.5. Additional Analyses

Alternative Measures of Agency Costs


Tables 10 and 11 display the alternative measures of agency cost incorporated into our analysis.
We have taken three variables, namely, earnings management using the absolute value of discretionary
accruals as a proxy denoted by EM; research and development expenditures, denoted by R&D-AC;
and the first principle component, obtained through principal component analysis using four agency
cost proxies used in this paper, denoted by PC-AC. The results show the positive moderating effect
of alternative measures of agency cost and corporate governance (R&D-AC × CGQ, EM × CGQ,
and PCA-AC × CGQ) on ROA and EPS for both the fixed-effect model and the system GMM approach.
These results again strengthen our hypothesis that corporate governance positively moderates the
agency–performance relationship.
Tables 10 and 11 also explore the moderating effect of ownership concentration on the agency–
performance relationship. Again, from the results, we can accept our alternative hypothesis that the
ownership concentration has a positive influence on the agency–performance relationship. Ownership
structure has a negative moderating effect on the agency–performance association when the firms are
state-owned. On the contrary, we witness a positive moderating effect when the ownership rests in the
hand of non-state entities. These results support our third hypothesis that SOE has a negative impact
on the agency–performance relationship, while NSOE has a positive moderating effect.

199
Table 9. Moderating effect of ownership type (NSOE) on agency costs and firm performance.

Return on Assets (ROA) Earnings per Share (EPS)


Variables
Fixed Effects System GMM Fixed Effects System GMM Fixed Effects System GMM Fixed Effects System GMM
JRFM 2020, 13, 154

AC1 −0.283 *** −0.388 *** −0.259 *** −0.344 *** −1.310 *** −1.547 *** −1.429 *** −1.925 ***
(0.011) (0.057) (0.015) (0.119) (0.088) (0.509) (0.126) (0.509)
FCF-AC −0.004 *** −0.004 −0.003 0.007 −0.035 *** −0.007 * −0.005 −0.008
(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.002) (0.019) (0.013) (0.015) (0.022)
NSOE 0.008 *** 0.003 0.013 *** 0.015 0.061 *** 0.059 * 0.037 −0.137 **
(0.002) (0.004) (0.003) (0.018) (0.021) (0.035) (0.027) (0.068)
AC1 × NSOE 0.0381 *** 0.0689 * 0.190 *** 0.597 **
(0.017) (0.148) (0.143) (0.444)
FCF-AC × NSOE 0.002 *** 0.002 *** 0.058 *** 0.028 *
(0.002) (0.002) (0.021) (0.026)
Size 0.009 *** 0.005 0.009 *** 0.005 0.187 *** 0.134 *** 0.187 *** 0.135 ***
(0.001) (0.003) (0.0014) (0.003) (0.011) (0.04) (0.011) (0.039)
Growth 0.001 *** 0.002 ** 0.001 *** 0.002 ** 0.003 *** 0.088 * 0.003 *** 0.089 *
(0.000) (0.001) (0.000) (0.001) (0.000) (0.049) (0.000) (0.044)
Leverage −0.113 *** −0.131 *** −0.113 *** −0.132 *** −0.679 *** −0.520 *** −0.679 *** −0.519 ***
(0.005) (0.011) (0.005) (0.012) (0.043) (0.089) (0.043) (0.088)

200
Firm Age −0.003 *** −0.002 *** −0.003 *** −0.001 ** −0.037 *** −0.006 −0.037 *** −0.007
(0.000) (0.000) (0.001) (0.000) (0.003) (0.016) (0.002) (0.016)
L.ROA 0.106 ** 0.108 ** 0.506 *** 0.504 ***
(0.047) (0.044) (0.068) (0.068)
Constant −0.066 ** 0.022 −0.068 ** 0.019 −3.037 *** −2.348 *** −3.024 *** −2.321 ***
(0.028) (0.072) (0.028) (0.073) (0.231) (0.794) (0.232) (0.787)
Observations 13,178 11,930 13,178 11,930 13,178 11,983 13,178 11,983
R-squared 0.124 0.124 0.081 0.081
Number of firms 2404 2248 2404 2248 2404 2252 2404 2252
Wald test (Prob>Chi2 ) (0.00) *** (0.00) *** (0.00) *** (0.00) ***
Hansen-J test (p-value) 0.19 0.24 0.25 0.27
Note: Table 9 reports the regression results from estimating Equations (1) and (2), respectively. Variable definitions are provided in Table 2. *, **, *** signify p-values of 1 percent, 5
percent, and 10 percent, respectively.
Table 10. Baseline models with alternative measure of agency costs.

Dependent Variable: Return on Assets (ROA)


Variables
Fixed Effects System GMM Fixed Effects System GMM Fixed Effects System GMM Fixed Effects System GMM
EM −0.126 *** −0.291 *** −0.108 *** −0.234 *** −0.0112 −0.0723 * 0.0255 −0.0656 **
JRFM 2020, 13, 154

(0.038) (0.094) (0.025) (0.087) (0.012) (0.039) (0.015) (0.033)


R&D-AC 0.018 0.002 −0.004 −0.011 0.005 0.002 0.002 0.001
(0.012) (0.013) (0.007) (0.008) (0.003) (0.003) (0.004) (0.004)
F1-PCA −0.165 −0.007 −0.003 0.002 −0.004 *** −0.003 *** −0.003 ** −0.002
(0.217) (0.003) (0.002) (0.003) (0.001) (0.000) (0.002) (0.002)
CGQ 0.015 0.002 *
(0.022) (0.002)
EM × CGQ 0.021 *** 0.036 ***
(0.006) (0.012)
R&D-AC × CGQ 0.002 *** 0.003 *
(0.001) (0.002)
F1 × CGQ 0.005 ** 0.009
(0.002) (0.004)
TOP1 0.003 *** 0.008
(0.000) (0.002)
EM × TOP1 0.003 *** 0.003 *

201
(0.000) (0.000)
R&D-AC × TOP1 0.002 * 0.004 **
(0.000) (0.001)
F1-PCA × TOP1 0.003 −0.008
(0.000) (0.001)
SOE 0.023 *** 0.011
(0.005) (0.013)
EM*SOE −0.012 *** −0.002
(0.021) (0.005)
R&D-AC × SOE −0.003 *** −0.024 *
(0.005) (0.053)
F1-PCA × SOE 0.002 0.003
(0.001) (0.001)
NSOE 0.012 *** 0.002
(0.003) (0.004)
EM × NSOE 0.036 * 0.001
(0.021) (0.005)
Table 10. Cont.

Dependent Variable: Return on Assets (ROA)


Variables
Fixed Effects System GMM Fixed Effects System GMM Fixed Effects System GMM Fixed Effects System GMM
R&D-AC × NSOE 0.002 * −0.022
JRFM 2020, 13, 154

(0.005) (0.055)
F1-PCA × NSOE 0.021 *** 0.022 *
(0.001) (0.001)
Size 0.015 *** 0.011 ** 0.015 *** 0.012 *** 0.016 *** 0.015 *** 0.015 *** 0.012 ***
(0.002) (0.004) (0.002) (0.004) (0.001) (0.004) (0.002) (0.004)
Growth 0.002 *** 0.005 ** 0.002 *** 0.005 ** 0.002 *** 0.005 ** 0.002 *** 0.005 **
(0.000) (0.002) (0.000) (0.002) (0.000) (0.002) (0.000) (0.002)
Leverage −0.122 *** −0.138 *** −0.117 *** −0.135 *** −0.117 *** −0.138 *** −0.116 *** −0.134 ***
(0.005) (0.013) (0.005) (0.013) (0.005) (0.014) (0.005) (0.013)
Firm Age −0.047 *** −0.003 *** −0.004 *** −0.003 *** −0.004 *** −0.004 *** −0.004 *** −0.003 ***
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.000)
L.ROA 0.147 *** 0.153 *** 0.151 *** 0.153 ***
(0.052) (0.053) (0.054) (0.052)
Constant −0.340 ** −0.113 −0.232 *** −0.157 * −0.210 *** −0.198 ** −0.224 *** −0.152 *
(0.165) (0.082) (0.031) (0.086) (0.031) (0.099) (0.031) (0.085)
Observations 11,964 10,833 11,964 10,833 11,557 10,487 11,964 10,833

202
R-squared 0.073 0.070 0.072 0.067
Number of firms 2210 2066 2210 2066 2191 2045 2210 2066
Wald test (Prob > Chi2 ) (0.00) *** (0.00) *** (0.00) *** (0.00) ***
Hansen-J test (p-value) 0.14 0.12 0.13 0.17
Note: Table 10 reports the regression results from estimating Equations (1) and (2), respectively. Variable definitions are provided in Table 2. *, **, *** signify p-values at 1 percent, 5
percent, and 10 percent, respectively.
Table 11. Results of baseline models with alternative measure of agency costs.

Dependent Variable: Earnings Per Share (EPS)


Variables
Fixed Effects System GMM Fixed Effects System GMM Fixed Effects System GMM Fixed Effects System GMM
EM −0.176 −0.400 0.0792 −0.555 0.284 *** −0.116 0.326 *** −0.311
JRFM 2020, 13, 154

(0.275) (0.469) (0.181) (0.344) (0.0904) (0.192) (0.114) (0.244)


R&D-AC 0.077 0.082 −0.061 −0.06 −0.002 0.012 −0.004 0.027
(0.082) (0.121) (0.050) (0.076) (0.022) (0.031) (0.019) (0.041)
F1-PCA −1.275 −0.017 −0.014 0.0184 −0.036 *** −0.021 ** −0.011 −0.003
(1.560) (0.031) (0.015) (0.022) (0.008) (0.009) (0.008) (0.013)
CGQ 0.097 0.02 ***
(0.160) (0.005)
EM × CGQ 0.077 *** 0.011 ***
(0.04) (0.018)
R&D-AC × CGQ 0.014 0.026
(0.013) (0.068)
F1 × CGQ 0.001 0.008
(0.000) (0.005)
TOP1 0.004 *** 0.004 **
(0.000) (0.001)
EM × TOP1 0.005 ** 0.002

203
(0.004) (0.001)
R&D-AC × TOP1 0.001 0.009
(0.001) (0.008)
F1-PCA × TOP1 0.002 0.004
(0.039) (0.000)
SOE −0.164 *** 0.302 **
(0.037) (0.130)
EM × SOE −0.083 0.018
(0.150) (0.057)
R&D-AC × SOE 0.007 −0.082 *
(0.042) (0.324)
F1-PCA × SOE 0.026 ** 0.016
(0.012) (0.015)
Table 11. Cont.

Dependent Variable: Earnings Per Share (EPS)


Variables
Fixed Effects System GMM Fixed Effects System GMM Fixed Effects System GMM Fixed Effects System GMM
NSOE 0.087 *** −0.063 *
JRFM 2020, 13, 154

(0.022) (0.036)
EM × NSOE 0.043 0.006
(0.145) (0.055)
R&D-AC × NSOE 0.005 *** 0.117 ***
(0.042) (0.306)
F1-PCA × NSOE 0.025 ** 0.017
(0.011) (0.015)
Size 0.191 *** 0.193 *** 0.200 *** 0.200 *** 0.209 *** 0.203 *** 0.201 *** 0.200 ***
(0.011) (0.032) (0.011) (0.033) (0.011) (0.036) (0.011) (0.032)
Growth 0.015 *** 0.047 ** 0.014 *** 0.045 ** 0.014 *** 0.047 ** 0.014 *** 0.047 **
(0.000) (0.022) (0.000) (0.021) (0.000) (0.023) (0.000) (0.022)
Leverage −0.793 *** −0.555 *** −0.751 *** −0.557 *** −0.770 *** −0.616 *** −0.744 *** −0.539 ***
(0.042) (0.106) (0.042) (0.106) (0.043) (0.112) (0.042) (0.105)
Firm Age −0.041 *** −0.016 −0.03 *** −0.012 −0.042 *** −0.017 −0.041 *** −0.017
(0.002) (0.011) (0.002) (0.011) (0.002) (0.011) (0.002) (0.017)
L.EPS 0.568 *** 0.562 *** 0.536 *** 0.567 ***

204
(0.082) (0.079) (0.077) (0.080)
Constant −4.256 *** −3.855 *** −3.547 *** −4.053 *** −3.480 *** −4.021 *** −3.441 *** −3.843 ***
(1.184) (0.624) (0.226) a (0.632) (0.232) (0.680) (0.226) (0.630)
Observations 11,964 10,886 11,964 10,886 11,557 10,521 11,964 10,886
R-squared 0.080 0.073 0.074 0.070
Number of Firms 2210 2070 2210 2070 2191 2048 2the, 210 2070
Wald test (Prob > Chi2 ) (0.000) *** (0.000) *** (0.000) *** (0.000) ***
Hansen-J test (p-value) 0.19 0.34 0.27 0.31
Note: Table 11 reports the regression results from estimating Equations (1) and (2), respectively. Variable definitions are provided in Table 2. *, **, *** signify p-values at 1 percent, 5
percent, and 10 percent, respectively.
JRFM 2020, 13, 154

6. Summary and Conclusions


Emerging markets with weak investor protection have much-execrated agency problems as
compared to developed markets. The sources and types of agency cost differ in emerging economies.
The purpose of this study was to investigate the effect of corporate governance quality and ownership
concentration on the relationship between agency cost and firm performance. A-share listed firms in China
were taken as a sample. Both the fixed-effect model and dynamic panel generalized method of moment
estimation were employed in order to cater for the unobserved endogeneity problem. The results show
that agency cost is negatively related to firm performance, while corporate governance and ownership
concentration enhance firm performance. When corporate governance and ownership concentration were
taken as moderating variables, we found a positive impact on the agency–performance relationship.
We also studied the effect of ownership type on the association between agency cost and firm
performance. Non-state ownership positively moderated the relationship between agency cost and
firm performance, while the agency cost kept its negative sign when the state ownership was taken as
a moderating variable. Alternative measures of independent variables were also considered for the
robustness of our results, such as the absolute value of discretionary accruals, denoted as (EM), research
and development expenditures (R&D-AC), and first principle component (PCA-AC) generated through
the principal component analysis of agency cost.
This study adds to the literature on corporate governance, specifically with respect to emerging
economies. China is one of the largest emerging economies, and possesses a unique corporate governance
system. Most of the companies are state owned, and are characterized by political influence and
corporate expropriation. By incorporating effective corporate governance mechanisms, Chinese listed
firms can enhance their financial performance. The theoretical evidence on ownership structures
postulates that concentrated ownership can help firms to reduce agency problems. The results of this
study show that concentrated ownership aligns the interests of managers and shareholders, hence
increasing the overall performance of firms. Our study divides the ownership structure of Chinese
listed firms into state and non-state. Studies on emerging economies have shown that non-state firms
can effectively curtail agency costs (Ding et al. 2007). The results of this study show that the performance
of Chinese listed firms is enhanced when they are owned by non-state entities. State ownership has a
negative impact on the agency–performance relationship.
This study supports the literature in concluding that agency cost and firm performance are
negatively related in Chinese listed firms. Investors should keep in mind the proxies of agency cost
when choosing a specific stock. Secondly, the abuse of managerial appropriation is higher in state-held
firms compared to non-state firms. Policymakers can use these results to devise the investor protection
rules so that managerial appropriation can be minimized.
In summary, our results support all of our hypotheses, indicating a positive moderating effect of
corporate governance quality (H1) and ownership concentration (H2) on the relationship between
agency cost and firm performance. Additionally, non-state (state) ownership of companies positively
(negatively) moderates the agency–performance relationship (H3).
Our study does have certain limitations. First, in constructing the corporate governance index,
we tried to take account of all of the agency-mitigating governance variables. However, due to data
unavailability, we dropped several governance variables, such as CEO compensation (instead, we used
top three compensation), stock options, independent director dissent report (although this data is
present on CSMAR, it lacks the data of financial statements), and audit committee (CSMAR contains
the total committee data, but does not further elaborate), to name several.
Author Contributions: Conceptualization and data curation, H.u.R.K.; formal analysis and original draft, W.B.K.;
validation, O.A.H.; writing—review and editing, N.M. and K.S. All authors have read and agreed to the published
version of the manuscript.
Funding: This research received no external funding.
Acknowledgments: The authors are grateful to anonymous MDPI referees and editors.
Conflicts of Interest: The authors declare no conflict of interest.

205
Appendix A

Table A1. Correlation between agency cost, corporate governance and the firm performance.
Authors Sample Time Period Performance Measures CG Measure Agency Cost Measure Findings
JRFM 2020, 13, 154

The mix and concentration of stock ownership do


indeed significantly affect a company’s
performance. First, there is a positive and
1. Ownership concentration significant correlation between ownership
1. The market-to-book
ratios measured by proportion concentration and profitability. Second, the firm’s
Chinese Firms listed on Shanghai value ratio (MBR)
Xu & Wang (1999) 1993–1995 of shares held by the top 10 profitability is positively correlated with the fraction
and Shenzhen stock exchange 2. Return on equity (ROE),
shareholders of legal person shares, but it is either negatively
3. Return on asset (ROA)
2. Ownership Mix correlated or uncorrelated with the fractions of state
shares and tradable A-shares held mostly by
individuals. Third, labor productivity tends to
decline as the proportion of state shares increases
Firms with good corporate governance tend to
The CLSA report includes
conduct less earnings management.
corporate governance (CG) 1. Amount of external
1. Earnings smoothing Firms with higher growth (lower earnings yield) are
Shen & Chih (2007) rankings on 495 companies in 25 1991–2000 financing
2. Earnings discretion prone to engage in earnings smoothing and
emerging countries in April 2001 2. Governance index
earnings aggressiveness, but good corporate
and February 2002.
governance can mitigate the effect.
The results reveal that the capital structure
characteristics of firms, namely bank debt and debt

206
maturity, constitute important corporate
governance devices for UK companies. Also,
1. Managerial ownership 1. Sales to total assets
Florackis, managerial ownership, managerial compensation
1672 UK listed firms 1999–2003 2. Managerial compensation 2. Selling, general and administrative
Chrisostomos (2008) and ownership concentration are strongly
3. Ownership concentration expenses to total sales
associated with agency costs. Finally, the results
suggest that the impact exerted by specific internal
governance mechanisms on agency costs varies
with firms’ growth opportunities.
In high protection countries, investors are able to
use their legal powers to extract cash from firms but
their ability to do so can be substantially hindered
Bartram, Brown, 1. Dividend/Earnings
1. corporate governance index when agency costs at the firm level are high. In poor
How, & Verhoeven, 29,610 firms in 43 countries 2001–2006 2. Dividend/Cash Flow
constructed from ISS data protection countries, investors can seek refuge in
(2009) 3. Dividend/Sales
firm level governance mechanisms to curb agency
conflicts, suggesting a substitution between country
and firm level investor protection.
The study finds evidence to support the agency
theory, meaning AC has a significantly negative
1. Free Cash Flows
505 companies publicly listed 1. ROA impact on firm performance and stock return.
2. Assets Turnover
Wang (2010) companies on Taiwan Stock 2002 to 2007 2. ROE In contrast, the study finds a significantly positive
3. Operating expense ratio
Exchange. 3. Tobin’s Q relation between FCF and firm performance
4. Advertising and R & D expense ratio
measures, indicating lack of evidence supporting
the free cash flow hypothesis.
Table A1. Cont.
Authors Sample Time Period Performance Measures CG Measure Agency Cost Measure Findings
On average firm value is lower in family firms than
non-family firms, while board size, independent
1. Board size director and duality have a significant impact on
474 companies listed on the main 1. Tobin’s Q 1. Asset utilization ratio
Ibrahim (2011) 1999–2005 2. Independent director firm performance in family firms as compared to
JRFM 2020, 13, 154

board of the Bursa Malaysia. 2. ROA 2. Expense ratio


3. Duality non-family firms. We also find that these
governance mechanisms have significant impact on
agency costs for both family and non-family firms.
The study finds that firms with a greater percentage
of female officer’s present lower agency costs but
that the negative relation is not robust when
1. Number of female officers considering the endogeneity of diversity.
Jurkus, Park, & Fortune 500 firm 668 firms and 2. Gender-diversity dummy 1. FCFs with poor growth The study also finds that external governance
1995–2005
Woodard (2011) 3172 firm-year observations. 3. Product Market 2. Dividend payout ratio influences the relationship. Although increasing
Competition diversity does not reduce agency costs for all firms,
the evidence shows that diversity is significantly
negatively related to agency costs in firms in less
competitive markets
The finding of the study is that board independence
can reduce the firm agency cost only under ‘asset
utilization ratio’ measure of agency cost.
Furthermore, the non-linearity tests suggest that the
1. Board Independence
1. Expense ratio’ benefit of outside independent directors is generally
118 non-financial firms listed on 2. Board Size
Rashid (2015) 2006–2011 2. The ‘Q-free cash flow interaction’ plausible as a factor controlling agency costs in the
the Dhaka Stock Exchange 3. Frequency of Board Meeting

207
3. The ‘asset utilization ratio’ case of a medium level of board independence.
4. CEO Duality
Overall, these findings do not reject the validity of
agency theory, supporting the Anglo-American
orthodoxy promoting outside independent
directors as good monitors.
1. Market capitalization
1. Corporate governance index
1600 companies listed on major 2. Price to book ratio (ratio The results document a positive correlation between
Achim, Borlea, & 2. Corporate social responsibility
stock exchanges around the 2001–2011 between market value and corporate governance quality and market value of
Mare (2016) activities adopted by the company
world book value) companies, such it is reflected by Tobin’s Q.
(CSR).
3. Tobin’s Q
JRFM 2020, 13, 154

References
Abowd, John M. 1990. Does Performance-Based Managerial Compensation Affect Corporate Performance?
Industrial & Labor Relations Review 43: 52-S–73-S. [CrossRef]
Achim, Monica Violeta, Sorin Nicolae Borlea, and Codruţa Mare. 2016. Corporate Governance and Business
Performance: Evidence for the Romanian Economy. Journal of Business Economics and Management. [CrossRef]
Agrawal, Anup, and Charles R. Knoeber. 1996. Firm Performance and Mechanisms to Control Agency Problems
between Managers and Shareholders. The Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 31: 377. [CrossRef]
Allison, Paul. 2010. When Can You Safely Ignore Multicollinearity? Statistical Horizons 5: 1–2.
An, Zhe, Donghui Li, and Jin Yu. 2016. Earnings Management, Capital Structure, and the Role of Institutional
Environments. Journal of Banking & Finance 68: 131–52. [CrossRef]
Ararat, Melsa, Mine Aksu, and Ayse Tansel Cetin. 2010. The Impact of Board Diversity on Boards’ Monitoring
Intensity and Firm Performance: Evidence from the Istanbul Stock Exchange. SSRN Electronic Journal 90: 1–33.
[CrossRef]
Arora, Punit, and Ravi Dharwadkar. 2011. Corporate Governance and Corporate Social Responsibility (CSR):
The Moderating Roles of Attainment Discrepancy and Organization Slack. Corporate Governance 19: 136–52.
[CrossRef]
Arslan-Ayaydin, Özgür, Chris Florackis, and Aydin Ozkan. 2014. Financial Flexibility, Corporate Investment
and Performance: Evidence from Financial Crises. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting 42: 211–50.
[CrossRef]
Arthurs, Jonathan D., Robert E. Hoskisson, Lowell W. Busenitz, and Richard A. Johnson. 2008. Managerial
agents watching other agents: Multiple agency conflicts regarding underpricing in IPO firms. Academy of
Management Journal 51: 277–94. [CrossRef]
Bathala, Chenchuramaiah T., Ramesh P. Rao, Source Managerial, Decision Economics, No Jan Feb, Chenchuramaiah
T. Bathala, and Ramesh P. Rao. 2017. The Determinants of Board Composition: An Agency Theory Perspective
the Determinants of Board Composition: An Agency Theory Perspective. Managerial and Decision Economics
16: 59–69. [CrossRef]
Beiner, Stefan, D. Wolfgang Drobetz, Frank Schmid, and Heinz Zimmermann. 2004. Is board size an independent
corporate governance mechanism? Kyklos. [CrossRef]
Berghe, L.a.a. Van den, and Abigail Levrau. 2004. Evaluating Boards of Directors: What Constitutes a Good
Corporate Board? Corporate Governance: An International Review 12: 461–78. [CrossRef]
Bethel, Jennifer E., and Julia Liebeskind. 1993. The effects of ownership structure on corporate restructuring.
Strategic Management Journal 14: 15–31. [CrossRef]
Bhagat, Sanjai, Brian Bolton, and Ajay Subramanian. 2017. Investor Protection and Corporate Governance. Journal
of Accounting Research 14: 471–517. [CrossRef]
Blundell, Richard, and Stephen Bond. 1998. Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data
models. Journal of Econometrics 87: 115–43. [CrossRef]
Borlea, Sorin Nicolae, Monica Violeta Achim, and Codrut, a Mare. 2017. Board characteristics and firm performances
in emerging economies. Lessons from Romania. Economic Research-Ekonomska Istrazivanja. [CrossRef]
Brander, James A., and Michel Poitevin. 1992. Managerial compensation and the agency costs of debt finance.
Managerial and Decision Economics 13: 55–64. [CrossRef]
Carter, David A., Betty J. Simkins, and W. Gary Simpson. 2003. Corporate Governance, Board Diversity, and Firm
Value. The Financial Review 38: 33–53. [CrossRef]
Chan, Kam C., and Joanne Li. 2008. Audit committee and firm value: Evidence on outside top executives as
expert-independent directors. Corporate Governance 16: 16–31. [CrossRef]
Chen, Jian. 2001. Ownership Structure as Corporate Governance Mechanism: Evidence from Chinese Listed
Companies. Economics of Planning 34: 53–72. [CrossRef]
Chen, Xin, Yong Sun, and Xiaodong Xu. 2016. Free cash flow, over-investment and corporate governance in China.
Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 37: 81–103. [CrossRef]
Ching, Ken M.L., Michael Firth, and Oliver M. Rui. 2006. Earnings Management, Corporate Governance and
the Market Performance of Seasoned Equity Offerings in Hong Kong. Journal of Contemporary Accounting &
Economics. [CrossRef]

208
JRFM 2020, 13, 154

Chiou, Jeng-Ren, Yenn-Ru Chen, and Ting-Chiao Huang. 2010. Assets Expropriation via Cash Dividends? Free
Cash Flow or Tunneling. China Journal of Accounting Research. [CrossRef]
Chong-En, Bai, Liu Qiao, Lu Joe, M. Song Frank, and Zhang Junxi. 2002. Corporate Governance and Firm
Valuations in China. SSRN Electronic Journal. [CrossRef]
Christie, Andrew A., and Jerold L. Zimmerman. 1994. Efficient and Opportunistic Choices of Accounting
Procedures: Corporate Control Contests. Accounting Review 69: 539–66. [CrossRef]
Chung, Richard, Michael Firth, and Jeong Bon Kim. 2005a. Earnings management, surplus free cash flow,
and external monitoring. Journal of Business Research 58: 766–76. [CrossRef]
Chung, Richard, Michael Firth, and Jeong Bon Kim. 2005b. FCF agency costs, earnings management, and investor
monitoring. Corporate Ownership and Control 2: 51–61. [CrossRef]
Clarke, Donald C. 2003. Corporate governance in China: An overview. China Economic Review 14: 494–507.
[CrossRef]
Coles, Jeffrey L., Naveen D. Daniel, and Lalitha Naveen. 2008. Boards: Does one size fit all? Journal of Financial
Economics. [CrossRef]
Collier, Paul, and Alan Gregory. 1999. Audit committee activity and agency costs. Journal of Accounting and Public
Policy 18: 311–32. [CrossRef]
Cormier, Denis, and Isabelle Martinez. 2006. The association between management earnings forecasts, earnings
management, and stock market valuation: Evidence from French IPOs. International Journal of Accounting
41: 209–36. [CrossRef]
Dechow, Patricia M., Richard G. Sloan, and Amy P. Sweeney. 1995. Detecting Earnings Management. The Accounting
Review 70: 193–225. [CrossRef]
Denis, Diane K., and John J. McConnell. 2003. International Corporate Governance. The Journal of Financial and
Quantitative Analysis. [CrossRef]
Dey, Aiyesha. 2008. Corporate governance and agency conflicts. Journal of Accounting Research 46: 1143–81.
[CrossRef]
Ding, Yuan, Hua Zhang, and Junxi Zhang. 2007. Private vs. State Ownership and Earnings Management: Evidence
from Chinese listed companies. Corporate Governance: An International Review 15: 223–38. [CrossRef]
Dinh, Tami, Helen Kang, and Wolfgang Schultze. 2016. Capitalizing Research & Development: Signaling or
Earnings Management? European Accounting Review. [CrossRef]
Easterbrook, Frank H. 1984. Two Agency-Cost Explanations of Dividends. The American Economic Review 74: 650–59.
[CrossRef]
Emanuel, David, Jilnaught Wong, and Norman Wong. 2003. Efficient contracting and accounting. Accounting and
Finance 43: 149–66. [CrossRef]
Erhardt, Niclas L., James D. Werbel, and Charles B. Shrader. 2003. Board of Director Diversity and Firm Financial
Performance. Corporate Governance 11: 102–11. [CrossRef]
Eshleman, John Daniel, and Peng Guo. 2014. Do big 4 auditors provide higher audit quality after controlling for
the endogenous choice of auditor? Auditing 33: 197–220. [CrossRef]
Filatotchev, Igor, Natalia Isachenkova, and Tomasz Mickiewicz. 2007. Corporate Governance, Managers’
Independence, Exporting, and Performance of Firms in Transition Economies. Emerging Markets Finance and
Trade 43: 62–77. [CrossRef]
Fox, Isaac, and Alfred Marcus. 1992. The Causes and Consequences of Leveraged Management Buyouts. Academy
of Management Review 17: 62–85. [CrossRef]
Gaio, Cristina. 2010. The relative importance of firm and country characteristics for earnings quality around the
world. European Accounting Review 19: 693–738. [CrossRef]
Gao, Lei, and Gerhard Kling. 2008. Corporate governance and tunneling: Empirical evidence from China.
Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 16: 591–605. [CrossRef]
Ghosh, Chinmoy, Raja Nag, and C. F. Sirmans. 2000. The Pricing of Seasoned Equity Offerings: Evidence from
REITs. Real Estate Economics 28: 363–84. [CrossRef]
Gill, Amarjit S., and Nahum Biger. 2013. The impact of corporate governance on working capital management
efficiency of American manufacturing firms. Managerial Finance 39: 116–32. [CrossRef]
Goyal, Vidhan K., and Chul W. Park. 2002. Board leadership structure and CEO turnover. Journal of Corporate
Finance 8: 49–66. [CrossRef]

209
JRFM 2020, 13, 154

Guest, Paul M. 2009. The impact of board size on firm performance: Evidence from the UK. European Journal of
Finance. [CrossRef]
Gunasekarage, Abeyratna, Kurt Hess, and Amity (Jie) Hu. 2007. The influence of the degree of state ownership
and the ownership concentration on the performance of listed Chinese companies. Research in International
Business and Finance 21: 379–95. [CrossRef]
Guo, Fei, and Shiguang Ma. 2015. Ownership Characteristics and Earnings Management in China. Chinese Economy.
[CrossRef]
Haider, Junaid, and Hong Xing Fang. 2016. Board size, ownership concentration and future firm risk. Chinese
Management Studies. [CrossRef]
Hess, Kurt, Abeyratna Gunasekarage, and Martin Hovey. 2010. State-dominant and non-state-dominant
ownership concentration and firm performance: Evidence from China. International Journal of Managerial
Finance 6: 264–89. [CrossRef]
Heugens, Pursey P.M.A.R., Marc van Essen, and J. van Oosterhout. 2009. Meta-analyzing ownership concentration
and firm performance in Asia: Towards a more fine-grained understanding. Asia Pacific Journal of Management
26: 481–512. [CrossRef]
Hoechle, Daniel, Markus Schmid, Ingo Walter, and David Yermack. 2012. How much of the diversification
discount can be explained by poor corporate governance? Journal of Financial Economics. [CrossRef]
Hope, Ole Kristian, John Christian Langli, and Wayne B. Thomas. 2012. Agency conflicts and auditing in private
firms. Accounting, Organizations and Society 37: 500–17. [CrossRef]
Hu, Yabei, and Shigemi Izumida. 2009. The Relationship between Ownership and Performance: A Review of
Theory and Evidence. International Business Research. [CrossRef]
Huang, Wei, Fuxiu Jiang, Zhibiao Liu, and Min Zhang. 2011. Agency cost, top executives’ overconfidence,
and investment-cash flow sensitivity—Evidence from listed companies in China. Pacific Basin Finance Journal.
[CrossRef]
Huang, Ying Sophie, and Chia Jane Wang. 2015. Corporate governance and risk-taking of Chinese firms: The role
of board size. International Review of Economics and Finance. [CrossRef]
Islam, Muhammad Zahirul. 2010. Agency Problem and the Role of Audit Committee: Implications for Corporate
Sector in Bangladesh. Journal of Economics and Finance 2: 177–89. [CrossRef]
Jackling, Beverley, and Shireenjit Johl. 2009. Board structure and firm performance: Evidence from India’s top
companies. Corporate Governance 17: 492–509. [CrossRef]
Jensen, M., and W. Meckling. 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure.
Journal of Financial Economics 3: 305–360. [CrossRef]
Jensen, Michael. 1986. American Economic Association Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance,
and Takeovers. American Economic Review.
Jia, Jin, Qian Sun, and Wilson H.S. Tong. 2005. Privatization through an overseas listing: Evidence from China’s
H-share firms. Financial Management 34: 5–30. [CrossRef]
Jonge, Alice de. 2014. The Glass Ceiling That Refuses to Break: Women Directors on the Boards of Listed Firms in
China and India. Women’s Studies International Forum 47: 326–38. [CrossRef]
Khidmat, Waqas Bin, and Mobeen Ur Rehman. 2014. The impact of free cash flows and agency costs on firm
performance—An empirical analysis of KSE listed companies of Pakistan. Journal of Financial Engineering.
[CrossRef]
Klapper, Leora F., and Inessa Love. 2004. Corporate governance, investor protection, and performance in emerging
markets. Journal of Corporate Finance. [CrossRef]
Kroll, Mark, Peter Wright, and Pochera Theerathorn. 1993. Whose interests do hired top managers pursue?
An examination of select mutual and stock life insurers. Journal of Business Research 26: 133–48. [CrossRef]
Kula, Veysel. 2005. The impact of the roles, structure and process of boards on firm performance: Evidence from
Turkey. Corporate Governance 13: 265–76. [CrossRef]
Lang, Larry H.P., and Robert H. Litzenberger. 1989. Dividend Announcements. Cash Flow Signalling vs. Free
Cash Flow Hypothesis? Journal of Financial Economics 24: 181–91. [CrossRef]
Lang, Larry, Annette Poulsen, and René Stulz. 1995. Asset sales, firm performance, and the agency costs of
managerial discretion. Journal of Financial Economics 37: 3–37. [CrossRef]
Le, Trien Vinh, and Trevor Buck. 2011. State ownership and listed firm performance: A universally negative
governance relationship? Journal of Management and Governance 15: 227–48. [CrossRef]

210
JRFM 2020, 13, 154

Lei, Qianhua, Bingxuan Lin, and Minghai Wei. 2013. Types of agency cost, corporate governance and liquidity.
Journal of Accounting and Public Policy 32: 147–72. [CrossRef]
Li, Hong-xia, Zong-jun Wang, and Xiao-lan Deng. 2008. Ownership, independent directors, agency costs and
financial distress: Evidence from Chinese listed companies. Corporate Governance 8: 622–36. [CrossRef]
Lin, Cyril. 2001. Corporatisation and Corporate Governance in China’s Economic Transition. Economics of Planning.
[CrossRef]
Ma, Shiguang, Tony Naughton, and Gary Tian. 2010. Ownership and ownership concentration: Which is important
in determining the performance of China’s listed firms? Accounting and Finance 50: 871–97. [CrossRef]
Ma, Shiguang, and Gary Tian. 2009. Board composition, board activity and ownership concentration, the impact
on firm performance. Problems and Perspectives in Management 7: 42–61. [CrossRef]
Malmquist, David H. 1990. Efficient contracting and the choice of accounting method in the oil and gas industry.
Journal of Accounting and Economics 12: 173–205. [CrossRef]
Mappadang, Agustina, T. Widyastuti, and A. M. Wijaya. 2018. The Effect of Corporate Governance Mechanism
on Tax Avoidance: Evidence from Manufacturing Industries Listed in the Indonesian Stock Exchange.
The International Journal of Social Sciences and Humanities Invention. [CrossRef]
Marchetti, Piergaetano, Gianfranco Siciliano, and Marco Ventoruzzo. 2017. Dissenting Directors. European Business
Organization Law Review 18: 659–700. [CrossRef]
McConnell, John J., and Henri Servaes. 1990. Additional evidence on equity ownership and corporate value.
Journal of Financial Economics 27: 595–612. [CrossRef]
Milhaupt, Curtis J., and Wentong Zheng. 2015. Beyond ownership: State capitalism and the Chinese firm.
Georgetown Law Journal. [CrossRef]
Miller, Judith L. 2002. The board as a monitor of organizational activity: The applicability of agency theory to
nonprofit boards. Nonprofit Management and Leadership 12: 429–50. [CrossRef]
Nakano, Makoto, and Pascal Nguyen. 2013. Foreign ownership and firm performance: Evidence from Japan’s
electronics industry. Applied Financial Economics 23: 41–50. [CrossRef]
Nguyen, Tuan, Stuart Locke, and Krishna Reddy. 2014. A dynamic estimation of governance structures and
financial performance for Singaporean companies. Economic Modelling 40: 1–11. [CrossRef]
Nguyen, Tuan, Stuart Locke, and Krishna Reddy. 2015. Ownership concentration and corporate performance from
a dynamic perspective: Does national governance quality matter? International Review of Financial Analysis.
[CrossRef]
Nikoskelainen, Erkki, and Mike Wright. 2007. The impact of corporate governance mechanisms on value increase
in leveraged buyouts. Journal of Corporate Finance 13: 511–37. [CrossRef]
Park, Seung Ho, and Yadong Luo. 2001. Guanxi and organizational dynamics: Organizational networking in
Chinese firms. Strategic Management Journal 22: 455–77. [CrossRef]
Pearce, John A., and Shaker A. Zahra. 1992. BOARD COMPOSITION FROM A STRATEGIC CONTINGENCY
PERSPECTIVE. Journal of Management Studies 29: 411–38. [CrossRef]
Porta, Rafael La, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, and Andrei Shleifer. 1999. Corporate Ownership around the World.
Journal of Finance 54: 471–517. [CrossRef]
Porta, Rafael La, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishny. 1997. Investor Protection and
Corporate Governance. Journal of Finance 52: 737–83. [CrossRef]
Porta, Rafael La, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishny. 2000. Investor Protection and
Corporate Governance. Journal of Financial Economics 58: 3–27. [CrossRef]
Rahman, Aulia Fuad, and Norman Mohd-Saleh. 2008. The Effect of Free Cash Flow Agency Problem on the Value
Relevance of Earnings and Book Value. Journal of Financial Reporting and Accounting 6: 75–90. [CrossRef]
Richardson, Scott A., A. Irem Tuna, and Min Wu. 2003. Predicting Earnings Management: The Case of Earnings
Restatements. SSRN Electronic Journal. [CrossRef]
Ruiqi, Wang, Fangjun Wang, Luying Xu, and Changhong Yuan. 2017. R&D expenditures, ultimate ownership and
future performance: Evidence from China. Journal of Business Research. [CrossRef]
Sahu, Tarak N., and Apu Manna. 2013. Impact of board composition and board meeting on firms’ performance:
A study of selected Indian companies. Vilakshan: The XIMB Journal of Management 10: 99–112.
Shan, Yuan George. 2013. Can internal governance mechanisms prevent asset appropriation? Examination of type
I tunneling in China. Corporate Governance (Oxford) 21: 225–41. [CrossRef]

211
JRFM 2020, 13, 154

Shan, Yuan George. 2015. Value relevance, earnings management and corporate governance in China. Emerging
Markets Review 23: 186–207. [CrossRef]
Shan, Yuan George, and Lei Xu. 2012. Bad debt provisions of financial institutions. International Journal of
Managerial Finance 8: 344–64. [CrossRef]
Shleifer, Andrei, and Robert W. Vishny. 1986. Large Shareholders and Corporate Control. Journal of Political
Economy 94: 461–88. [CrossRef]
Shleifer, Andrei, and Robert W. Vishny. 1991. Takeovers in the ’60s and the ’80s: Evidence and implications.
Strategic Management Journal 12: 51–59. [CrossRef]
Shust, Efrat. 2015. Does Research and Development Activity Increase Accrual-Based Earnings Management?
Journal of Accounting, Auditing & Finance. [CrossRef]
Sial, Muhammad Safdar, Chunmei Zheng, Tehmina Khan, and Vinh Khuong Nguyen. 2018a. Corporate social
responsibility, firm performance and the moderating effect of earnings management in Chinese firms.
Asia-Pacific Journal of Business Administration. [CrossRef]
Sial, Muhammad Safdar, Zheng Chunmei, and Nguyen Vinh Khuong. 2019. Do female and independent directors
explain the two-way relationship between corporate social responsibility and earnings management of
Chinese listed firms? International Journal of Accounting and Information Management. [CrossRef]
Sial, Muhammad Safdar, Chunmei Zheng, Jacob Cherian, M. A. Gulzar, Phung Anh Thu, Tehmina Khan,
and Nguyen Vinh Khuong. 2018b. Does corporate social responsibility mediate the relation between
boardroom gender diversity and firm performance of Chinese listed companies? Sustainability (Switzerland)
10: 3591. [CrossRef]
Singh, Manohar, and Wallace N. Davidson III. 2003. Agency costs, ownership structure and corporate governance
mechanisms. Journal of Banking & Finance 27: 793–816. [CrossRef]
Siregar, Sylvia Veronica, and Sidharta Utama. 2008. Type of earnings management and the effect of ownership
structure, firm size, and corporate-governance practices: Evidence from Indonesia. International Journal of
Accounting 43: 1–27. [CrossRef]
Su, Yiyi, Dean Xu, and Phillip H. Phan. 2008. Principal—Principal Conflict in the Governance of the Chinese
Public Corporation. Management and organization review 4: 17–38. [CrossRef]
Tang, Hui Wen, and Chong Chuo Chang. 2015. Does corporate governance affect the relationship between earnings
management and firm performance? An endogenous switching regression model. Review of Quantitative
Finance and Accounting 45: 33–58. [CrossRef]
Teoh, Siew Hong, T. J. Wong, and Gita R. Rao. 1998. Are accruals during initial public offerings opportunistic?
Review of Accounting Studies 3: 175–208. [CrossRef]
Vafeas, Nikos. 1999. Board meeting frequency and firm performance. Journal of Financial Economics 53: 113–42.
[CrossRef]
Vithessonthi, Chaiporn, and Jittima Tongurai. 2015. The effect of leverage on performance: Domestically-oriented
versus internationally-oriented firms. Research in International Business and Finance 34: 265–80. [CrossRef]
Wan, Jiayong, and Ayse Yuce. 2007. Listing regulations in China and their effect on the performance of IPOs and
SOEs. Research in International Business and Finance 21: 366–78. [CrossRef]
Wang, Ying, and Michael Campbell. 2012. Corporate governance, earnings management, and IFRS: Empirical
evidence from Chinese domestically listed companies. Advances in Accounting. [CrossRef]
Wang, Yishu, Xue Jiang, ZhenJia Liu, and Weixing Wang. 2015. Effect of Earnings Management on Economic
Value Added: A China Study. Accounting and Finance Research. [CrossRef]
Wei, Zuobao, and Oscar Varela. 2003. State equity ownership and firm market performance: Evidence from
China’s newly privatized firms. Global Finance Journal 14: 65–82. [CrossRef]
Wei, Zuobao, Feixue Xie, and Shaorong Zhang. 2005. Ownership Structure and Firm Value in China’s Privatized
Firms: 1991–2001. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 40: 87. [CrossRef]
Xu, X., and Y. Wang. 1999. Ownership structure and corporate governance in Chinese stock companies.
China Economic Review 10: 75–98. [CrossRef]
Yazdanfar, Darush, and Peter Öhman. 2015. Debt financing and firm performance: An empirical study based on
Swedish data. Journal of Risk Finance. [CrossRef]
Zahra, Shaker A. 2007. An embeddedness framing of governance and opportunism: Towards a cross-nationally
accommodating theory of agency—Critique and extension. Journal of Organizational Behavior 28: 69–73.
[CrossRef]

212
JRFM 2020, 13, 154

Zahra, Shaker A., R. Duane Ireland, and Michael A. Hitt. 2000. International expansion by new venture
firms: International diversity, mode of market entry, technological learning, and performance. Academy of
Management Journal 43: 925–50. [CrossRef]
Zhang, Qing, Lilin Chen, and Tianjun Feng. 2014. Mediation or Moderation? The Role of R&D Investment in the
Relationship between Corporate Governance and Firm Performance: Empirical Evidence from the Chinese
IT Industry. Corporate Governance: An International Review 22: 501–17. [CrossRef]
Zhang, Xiaohong, Gaowen Tang, and Zhaohong Lin. 2016. Managerial power, agency cost and executive
compensation—An empirical study from China. Chinese Management Studies. [CrossRef]
Zhou, Qing, Robert Faff, and Karen Alpert. 2014. Bias correction in the estimation of dynamic panel models in
corporate finance. Journal of Corporate Finance. [CrossRef]

© 2020 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access
article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution
(CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).

213
Journal of
Risk and Financial
Management

Article
Transition to the Revised OHADA Law on
Accounting and Financial Reporting: Corporate
Perceptions of Costs and Benefits
Micheal Forzeh Fossung 1 , Lious Agbor Tabot Ntoung 1, *, Helena Maria Santos de Oliveira 2 ,
Cláudia Maria Ferreira Pereira 2 , Susana Adelina Moreira Carvalho Bastos 2 and
Liliana Marques Pimentel 3
1 Fomic Polytechnic & University of Buea, Department of Accounting, Faculty of Social and Management
Sciences, P. O. Box 65 Buea, Cameroon; michael.fossung@fomicgroup.cm
2 School of Accounting and Administration of Porto (ISCAP), Polytechnic Institute of Porto (IPP), Center for
Organisational and Social Studies of P. Porto (CEOS.PP), Research Centre for the Study of Population,
Economics and Society (CEPESE), Oporto, 4465-004 S. Mamede de Infesta, Portugal;
hmoliveira@sapo.pt (H.M.S.d.O.); cmfpereira.pt@gmail.com (C.M.F.P.);
susanamoreirabastos@gmail.com (S.A.M.C.B.)
3 Faculty of Economics, University of Coimbra, and Centre for Business and Economics Research (CeBER),
Coimbra, 3004-512 Coimbra, Portugal; liliana.pimentel@fe.uc.pt
* Correspondence: agbor.tabot@fomicgroup.cm; Tel.: + 237-670954991

Received: 25 June 2020; Accepted: 22 July 2020; Published: 3 August 2020

Abstract: This paper examines the ongoing transition to the revised Organisation for the Harmonisation
of Business Law in Africa Act on Accounting and Financial Reporting for companies in general and
to the International Financial Reporting Standards for listed and group companies with a particular
focus on recent institutional developments and corporate concerns. The study used 80 professional
accountants, most of whom were members of the Institute of Chartered Accountants of Cameroon
and academics. Using the descriptive statistics, the study shows that the transition to the revised
OHADA brings about a high level of comparability and transparency of the financial statements, that
the International Financial Reporting Standards can be implemented in Cameroon (but not fully),
and that the benefit of the transition exceeds the cost.

Keywords: perception; OHADA accounting; transition; IFRS; comparability

XIX ENCUENTRO INTERNACIONAL AECA


THEMATIC AREAS
A) Financial Information and Accounting Standardisation

1. Introduction
The global wind of economic integration is at the doorstep of the accounting profession with
intense pressure on nations and states to apply unified accounting standards. This effort could be
seen as a century reform to the profession. The reform agenda was perceived as the way forward
towards harmonising the accounting practice within the Organisation for the Harmonisation of
Business Law in Africa (OHADA) Generally Accepted Accounting Principles with that of the rest of
the world (The International Financial Reporting Standards), which for a long time experts had been
advocating on the belief that financial accounting practises should be harmonised for ease of comparison
(Dicko and Fortin 2014; Fossung 2016; Mayegle 2014; OHADA Uniform Acts 2016; AICPA 2019).
The effects of globalisation have posed the need for comparable, consistent and quality financial
statements. The general expectations and advantages of the International Financial Reporting Standards

JRFM 2020, 13, 172; doi:10.3390/jrfm13080172 215 www.mdpi.com/journal/jrfm


JRFM 2020, 13, 172

(IFRS) are widely known, but due to the scarcity in the various economic resources, there is always
a primary issue of implementation of the law, and then there is the question of whether the country
would also benefit from the proclaimed advantages of the IFRS while considering the cost involved.
It is therefore important to examine the perception of accounting practitioners on the transition to
the revised OHADA Uniform Acts on Accounting and Financial Reporting, and particularly of the
transition of both listed companies and group companies to IFRS as inscribed in the revised OHADA
Uniform Acts. Hence, the study sets out to investigate the perceptions of Accountants in Cameroon on
the transition to the International Financial Reporting Standards, since the clients who fall within this
group were required to implement IFRS as of January 2019 (OHADA Uniform Acts 2016; AICPA 2019).
Therefore, the main research question is: what is the perception of Cameroon accounting
practitioners on the transition to the Revised OHADA Act on Accounting and Financial Reporting?
The following specific research questions will be answered:

1. Would the implementation of the IFRS enhance comparability and transparency of financial
statements produced by the concerned companies?
2. To what extent can IFRS be fully implemented in Cameroon?
3. Does the cost involved in transitioning to International Financial Reporting Standards supersede
the benefits?

The recent transition to IFRS has been welcomed by many, while others still have lukewarm feelings
on the decision to transit to the IFRS. As such, this study is aimed at investigating the perception of
Cameroon accounting practitioners on the transition to the International Financial Reporting Standards.
The specific objectives of the study are: (1) to investigate the extent to which the transition to IFRS
would improve the transparency and comparability of financial statements; (2) to understand the
extent to which the International Financial Reporting Standards can be completely implemented in
Cameroon; (3) to assess the costs and benefits involved in transitioning from the previous (OHADA)
Accounting System to IFRS.
Studies like Barth et al. (2012) analysed the difference between IFRS and US GAAP-based accounting.
Exploring information from US companies with IFRS-based accounting and US-based accounting from
1995 and 2006 showed that IFRS firms’ accounting amounts had greater comparability with those of US
firms when IFRS firms applied IFRS than when they applied non-domestic standards. They add that
there was greater comparability for firms that adopted IFRS mandatory, common law firms and firms
in countries with high enforcement. Furthermore, Armstrong et al. (2010) reported 16 events associated
with the IFRS as a result of the European stock market reactions. Their study showed that there existed
an incremental positive reaction for European firms with higher pre-adoption information quality
and lower pre-adoption information asymmetry. Meanwhile, the study of Jeanjean and Stolowy (2008)
revealed that the European Commission, the International Accounting Standard Board and the Security
and Exchange Commission (SEC) should put more effort to promote institutional factors and incentives
rather than harmonising accounting standards.

2. Literature Review

2.1. Background
In the early 60s, antecedent to the acquisition of independence by most African countries,
accounting practices where still those inherited from colonial masters. The companies in the areas
of the Economic and Monetary Union of West Africa (WAEMU) and the Customs and Economic
Union of Central Africa (CACEU) continued to use the French accounting systems in 1947 and 1957
(Dicko and Fortin 2014; Fossung 2016; Mayegle 2014; AICPA 2019). It was only until the Africans
conceived their unity in 1963 and decided to create the Common African and Mauritian Organisation
(OCAM) accounting plan in 1965. This was before the convergence of the WAEMU and CACEU.
OCAM lived for 15 years, but during those years there still existed many accounting standards;

216
JRFM 2020, 13, 172

the legal framework was confused and as such it resulted in a very unfavourable business climate
and sub-standard financial reporting. The effects of this on some sectors were inconsistent financial
records and the mismatch of some accounting works. This led the African States and certain groups to
develop new accounting information systems and specific accounting plans for the credit institutions
(Central Africa Banking Commission (COBAC) chart of accounts and the insurance companies
(Dicko and Fortin 2014; Riasi 2015; Riasi and Aghdaie 2013; Fossung 2016)).
In response to these challenges, the Organisation for the Harmonisation of Business Laws in
Africa (OHADA) was established in Port Louis, Mauritius, on 17 October 1993. The fledgling entity
was launched under the treaty for the Harmonisation of Business Law in Africa, a document signed
by 16 African countries (and later became 17). The objective of OHADA was to develop modern
business laws relevant to conditions in Africa, promote better economic integration across the continent
and encourage its harmonious development. Before the adoption of OHADA, investors had to deal
with different and sometimes confusing laws in each country (Fossung 2016; Dicko and Fortin 2014).
Although OHADA was initially designed for countries in the Franc zone, it now welcomes any
African state, irrespective of whether it is a Francophone African countries. OHADA’s primary goal
is to improve the investment climate. Its Uniform Acts, including the Act on about accounting,
are directly applied in all member states and supersede any existing legislation with conflicting
provisions (Paillusseau 2004). Amongst the different OHADA Uniform Acts was the UNIFORM ACT
of 24 MARCH 2000 on the harmonisation of the accounts of enterprises. After being in use for more
than seventeen years, this Act was revised to converge with the IFRS in response to the global pressure
of international accounting harmonisation.

2.2. Conceptual Framework


The concept of perception (generally referred to as social perception by most scholars) like
many others in the social science disciplines has been defined in a variety of ways since it was
first used. A lay man can see perception as “a particular way of viewing things that depends
on one’s experience and personality.” Perception (from the Latin perception) is the organisation,
identification, and interpretation of sensory information in order to represent and understand the
presented information, or the environment (Schacter 2012). The perceived quality construct developed
with its service quality instruments, is defined as the difference between perceptions and expectations.
Perception is the “process by which an individual receives, selects and interprets stimuli to form a
meaningful and coherent picture of the world”. In customer satisfaction and service quality dimensions,
perceptions are defined as the consumer’s judgement of the services and an organisation’s performance.
Many social psychologists have tended to develop the concept around one of its most essential
characteristics: that the world around us is not psychologically uniform to all individuals. This is the
fact, in all probability, that accounts for the difference in the opinions and actions of individuals/groups
that are exposed to the same social phenomenon.
According to Jandt (1995), perception is unique to each person; it begins with a three-step process
of selection, organisation and interpretation. It has also been found that perceptions differ with respect
to the physical environment of the service settings, cultural background and differences in gender
(Ndhlovu and Senguder 2002). These indicate that a clear understanding of how perceptions are formed
is critical to any service business as it facilitates the formulation of strategies to manage customer
perceptions of service performance. Rao and Narayana (1998) define perception as “the process
whereby people select, organise, and interpret sensory stimulations into meaningful information
about their work environment.” To Rao and Narayana, perception is the most critical determinant
of human behaviour, which leads them to imply further that there can be no behaviour without
perception. Though focusing on managers in work settings, they draw attention to the fact that since
there are no specific strategies for understanding the perception of others, everyone appears to be
“left with his inventiveness, innovative ability, sensitiveness and introspective skills to deal with
perception.” Rao and Narayana (1998) share the main characteristics of the above definition. However,

217
JRFM 2020, 13, 172

they emphasise that perception ranks among the “important cognitive factors of human behaviour”
or psychological mechanisms that enable people to understand their environment. The details of
the mental and environmental nature of perception are not of primordial important to this study.
However, these literary definitions help to shed more light on the variances in perception and what
may cause them.

2.3. Theoretical Framework


An objective of perception is to gauge genuine properties of the world. An objective of
categorisation is to characterise its structure. Ages of development have formed our faculties to
this end. These three presumptions inspire much work on human discernment. The interface theory
of perception offers a system, roused by advancements, to control inquiries about in question order.
The perceptions of an organism are like a user interface between that organism and the objective world.
This theory addresses the natural question that if our perceptions are not accurate, then what good
are they? The answer becomes evident for user interfaces. The colour, for instance, of an icon on a
computer screen does not estimate or reconstruct the exact colour of the file that it represents in the
computer. The conventionalist theory that our perceptions are reconstructions is, in precisely the same
manner, equally naive. Colour is, of course, just one example among many: the shape of an icon does
not reconstruct the exact shape of the file; the position of an icon does not reconstruct the exact position
of the file in the computer. A user interface reconstructs nothing. Its predicates and the predicates
required for reconstruction can be entirely disjointed. Files, for instance, have no colour, and yet a user
interface is useful even though despite the fact that it is not a reconstruction. The conventional theory
of perception gets evolution fundamentally wrong by conflating fitness and accuracy. This leads the
conventional theory to the false claim that a primary goal of perception is a faithful depiction of the
world. The idea of understanding the perceptions of accountants on the transition to IFRS was based
on the understanding that the perception of accountants can depict the reality of the events that are
altered by the transition.

2.3.1. Hypotheses
The hypotheses below would give various users of financial information insight into the costs
involved in transitioning from the previous to the revised OHADA Accounting System (SYSCOHADA)
and to IFRS by taking into consideration the views of fifty accountants in Cameroon. The findings are
anticipated to provide useful and timely information to the Council of Ministers under the OHADA,
to assist them in making decisions affecting accounting practices which, in turn, will support social
and economic development in Cameroon and the other 16 African member countries. The evidence
provided by this study is likely to be of interest to other countries or firms considering the adoption of
the revised SYSCOHADA and the International Financial Reporting Standards.

Hypothesis 1 (H1). Comparability and transparency of financial statements are enhanced under the revised
SYSCOHADA.

Hypothesis 2 (H2). IFRS can be fully implemented in Cameroon, given the available resources and time and
within the stated time.

Hypothesis 3 (H3). The cost involved in transitioning to International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRSs)
does not supersede the benefits.

2.3.2. J.J Gibson’s Theory of Direct Perception


James Jerome Gibson (1979) believed that our cognitive apparatus was created and formed by a
long evolutionary influence of the external environment, which is apparent in its structure and abilities.
We learned to extract precisely the information which is necessary for our survival. By Darwin’s

218
JRFM 2020, 13, 172

assumption, the pressures of the environment caused our receptors to be created and formed so that
they became sensitive to relevant stimulus from the environment and they adapted to the environment.
Such interpretation of perception is called the ecological one because it attributes the determinative role
to the environment and to its influence on the whole process of perception. The basis of Gibson’s theory
is the conviction that our perception is determined by optical flows—optic arrays—which Gibson
regarded as some sort of structure or pattern of light in the environment. The visual terminology
he was using is not crucial since, analogically, it can be used for auditory or tactile components of
perception. J.J Gibson’s theory is quite relevant to this study because we believe that every individual
perceives information depending on several different factors, as discussed in the theory, which gives
us a reason to capture the opinion of a number of accountants on the recent decision to transit to the
revised OHADA law on accounting and financial reporting (revised SYSCOHADA).

2.4. Empirical Literature


Several studies have been carried out in different parts of the world on the benefits of IFRS
and on the perception of accounting practitioners on the transition and convergence to the IFRS
(Mohamed et al. 2019; Dabbicco and Mattei 2020; Albu et al. 2020; Ntoung et al. 2020; Muraina 2020;
Sharairi 2020; Joshi et al. 2008; Ionascu et al. 2014).
A study by Mohamed, Yasseen and Omarjee (Mohamed et al. 2019) on the perception of South
African accounting practitioners on the post-implementation of the IFRS for SMEs in institutionalised
environment suggests that the approval of the IFRSs was accepted by all SMEs, and significant
advantages were uniformly associated with the IFRS for SMEs. Pallavi Gupta et al. (2015) add that
accounting experts are optimistic towards the benefits associated with the implementation of the IFRS,
while at the same time they are concerned about the significant costs and challenges such as inadequate
training of staff, changes required to process, changes in information technology infrastructure and
other costs that are associated with the implementation of the IFRS. This conclusion was arrived at
using a closed-ended questionnaire to collect responses from 200 accounting experts. The objectives of
the study were to identify the perception of accounting experts regarding the benefits and challenges
of IFRS based the Kruskal–Wallis Test, and descriptive statistical tools were also used for data analysis.
Meanwhile, Dabbicco and Mattei (2020) carried out a comparative study of Italy and the UK.
These authors claim that uniformity and aliment of practices in public finance reporting systems aids in the
understanding of the relationship between financial reporting and budgeting processes. Albu et al. (2020)
examined the impact of the IFRSs in the institutional context of the Central and Eastern European (CEE)
with national or multinational regional insights both at the firm-level financial reporting benefits and
country-level benefits, together with the cost-benefits relationship involved. Their study suggests that
the accounting and auditing profession was the most valuable resource in the IFRS adoption process in
CEE. A serious adoption process at the micro-level, signalled by high levels of perceived difficulties
and regulatory impediments, along with resources available at the country-level and enforcement
initiatives, is associated with financial reporting benefits. Country-level benefits are perceived to
have materialised to a greater extent in countries with a lower quality of institutions, but with more
organisational enablers available at the micro-institutional level. Benefits are perceived to exceed costs
to a lesser extent in larger countries and those with more influential institutions.
A similar study was carried out by Muraina (2020) who examined the effects of the implementation
of the International Public Sector Accounting Standards (IPSAS) on Nigeria’s financial reporting quality.
The study employed a survey research design to determine the effects of the implementation of the
IPSAS on Nigeria’s financial reporting quality. Partial Least Square 3 (SmartPLS 3) technique of analysis
was applied to achieve the research objective. The study found that accountability positively and
significantly affects the quality of financial reporting in Nigeria. Specifically, IPSAS has improved the
level of accountability, which in turn improved Nigeria’s financial reporting quality. Sharairi (2020)
investigated the factors that influenced the current adoption of the International Financial Reporting
Standards (IFRS) by Islamic banks in the UAE. This paper examined the relationship between the

219
JRFM 2020, 13, 172

theoretical aspects and practical components. This paper revealed that factors such as religion, culture
and local investors might have limited influence on the current adoption of accounting standards in
the Islamic banks. Furthermore, this paper uncovered a concern among respondents of issues that
developed when Islamic banks commenced the adoption of IFRS.
P.L Joshi et al. (2008) studied the perception of accounting professionals on the adoption and
implementation of a single set of global accounting standards in Bahrain. The data for the study
were collected using a pre-tested survey plan containing demographic information and professional
qualifications—the study aimed at examining the perceptions of accounting professionals on adopting
a single set of global standards. The results of the study proved that the accountants were optimistic
about the harmonisation of accounting standards, and they felt that it is worth the while. Despite the
conclusion drawn, the study was limited in its number of respondents. This conclusion may have been
altered if more accountants responded.
There has been much discussion on the relationship that exists between the accounting standards
and accounting quality. A study by Barth et al. (2008) sought to examine whether the application
of International Accounting Standards is associated with higher accounting quality. The study used
accounting quality metrics for a broad sample of firms across 21 countries that adopted IAS from 1994
to 2003. The accounting quality was compared with that of the non-US firms that do not apply the IAS.
The study used inferential statistical tools and arrived at the conclusions that the firms of 21 countries
which were applying IAS showed evidence of less earnings management, more timely loss recognition
and more value relevance of accounting amounts. The author also compared the accounting quality
for IAS firms before and after they adopted the IAS and concluded that accounting quality improved
between the pre- and post-adoption periods. The period before and after they adopted IAS found that
accounting quality was enhanced between the pre- and post-adoption periods.
The perception of accountants on the implementation of IFRS is quite essential in the
implementation of the IFRS. A study by (Ionascu et al. 2014) was carried out on the adoption of IFRS
by developing countries in the case of Romania. The paper attempted to research the fundamental
proof with respect to the advantages and costs of adopting IFRS in Romania. The outcomes acquired
demonstrate that, regardless of consistency issues, the Romanian economic environment was open to
IFRS and idealistic about their potential to an extent.

3. Methodology

3.1. Research Design


In order to realise the objectives of this paper, a survey research design was chosen given the nature
of the population considered for the research as in prior studies (such as Dabbicco and Mattei 2020;
Albu et al. 2020; Muraina 2020; Sharairi 2020). It is also likely to be beneficial to accounting standard-
setting bodies like the IFRS Foundation, the International Federation of Accountants (IFAC) OHADA,
professional accounting associations and public accounting firms in their efforts to promote the
worldwide adoption of international standards. Finally, this research would be of importance to
academicians as they try to understand the strengths and limitations of the implementation of revised
SYSCOHADA and specifically the IFRS in the OHADA zone. Lastly, this study would help educate
the stakeholders of listed companies and group companies operating within the OHADA zone.

3.2. Population and Sampling


The study population consisted of the all-professional accountants across the national territory
of Cameroon. The reason for selecting Cameroon was because Cameroon is the ‘melting pot’ and a
member of the OHADA zone where all economic and financial transactions are represented.
This population comprised of males and females from different cultural, geographical and social
origins. As of 2018, there were two hundred and eight (208) chattered accountants in Cameroon.
Our total sample was eighty (80) participants drawn mostly from the Institute of Chartered Accountants

220
JRFM 2020, 13, 172

of Cameroon (ONECCA) list of chartered accountants in Cameroon. A random sampling technique was
used. The specific reason for selecting 80 accountants, most of whom were members of ONECCA was
due to the willingness and availability of participants and to provide us with specific explanation and
clarification through open extended questions when the need arose during the survey. This involved
the selection of respondents who were available and willing to participate in the study. The data for
the research were all primary data collected on the field.
Consequently, we resorted to using a structured close-ended questionnaire. The questionnaires
were made up of close-ended questions with the first part relating to demographics and the second part
relating to the variables of the study. All questionnaires were administered by mail to the respondents.
The question of the cost and benefits arising from the transition from the revised OHADA accounting
system may have shown the culture and way of life which can be echoed by the differences between
international, regional and national laws and how this affected the reporting decision of players with
the confines of these conflicting laws. For example, there is conflict between the OHADA Uniform Acts
and General Tax code regarding the deadline for filing company accounts and tax returns, and as such,
companies need to extract cost in order to be compliant to both standards. Following the institution of
the new accounting law in Cameroon, there was a need to investigate if transitioning from the revised
OHADA was beneficiary to companies.
The data obtained were reported using descriptive statistical analysis represented by tables,
graphs, charts and other tools to enable adequate interpretation for the required, resulting output.
The statistical package for social sciences (SPSS) software version 20.0 was used to facilitate the analysis.
The main portion of the questionnaire used a Likert scale where respondents were expected to respond,
ranging from strongly disagree to agree strongly.

4. Data Analysis

4.1. Background Information of the Respondents


It was essential to find out the background information of the respondents as this allows the
researcher to know the kind of respondents in terms of occupation and years of experience. This typically
has implications in terms of how different people perceive different things. For example, the way
auditors may recognise a certain IFRS element may be different from the way an accounting professional
in a company, as well as an academician, may view the same.
Percentages and frequencies were used to present data on tables classified under four respond
options: agree and strongly agree as Agree (A), Neutral (N) and Disagree and strongly disagree
as Disagree (D). A cut off 2.5 on a scale of 5 was adopted for the analysis of close-ended items.
This stipulates that items with a mean lower than 2.5 exclusively were considered to imply a negative
perception on the transition to IFRS as per the SPSS analysis on the main objective. However, to achieve
this aim, the information presented was guided by the study objectives. The first section covered the
background information such as demographic characteristics of the respondents (that is, the occupation
of the respondent and number of years of experience). The second part covered perceptions about the
comparability and transparency of the financial statements, the effect of full IFRS implementation in
Cameroon, the extent to which the transition to IFRS would improve the transparency and comparability
of the reported financial statements, relationship between the dependent variable (transition to IFRS)
and independent variables of the study and testing of the hypotheses. The last part focused on
determining the best predictor variable for influencing the implementation of IFRS. The data is
presented using tables, charts and graphs. Descriptive statistics analysis was used to analyse, interpret
and discuss the results from the data collected in line with the study objectives so as to enable the
researcher to report the results in detail.

221
JRFM 2020, 13, 172

4.2. Occupation of the Respondents


The study sought to find out the various position of responsibility or occupation of the respondents
who responded to the questionnaires. Our goal here was to look at those professionals who performed
other duties than public practice. The results are presented in Figure 1 below.
Occupation

ƵĚŝƚŽƌ
ϯϴ

ĐĐŽƵŶƚŝŶŐƉƌĂĐƚŝƚŝŽŶĞƌŝŶĂĐŽŵƉĂŶLJ
ϴ

ĐĐĂĚĞŵŝĐĂŝŶ
ϰ

Ϭ ϭϬ ϮϬ ϯϬ Number ϰϬ

Figure 1. Occupation of the respondents (Source: developed purposely for this research).

The results presented in Figure 1 above show a total of fifty respondents. According to the data
collected, 38 (76%) of the respondents were auditors, 16% (8) of the respondents were accounting
practitioners in companies, and 8% (4) were academicians. The percentages imply that for the most part
the respondents were auditors who audit clients and understand the difficulties or ease involved in their
clients’ transition. Even though 80 respondents were anticipated, only 50 thoroughly completed the
questionnaires. Those 30 respondents who did not complete the questionnaire correctly were eliminated.

4.3. Distribution of Respondents by Number of Years of Experience


The results in Table 1 indicate that the majority of the respondents (22 respondents) worked for
11–20 years which is 44.0%, and 17 respondents worked for 6–10 years, which comprises 34% of the
total number, while seven worked 0–5 years (14%). The groups working from 21–30 years and 30 years
and above had the same percentage (2%), respectively. This shows that most of the respondents were
well experienced in financial reporting and have witnessed the transition and implementation of other
financial reporting standards before the IFRS.

Table 1. Distribution of respondents by number of years of experience.

Frequency Percent %
11–20 years 22 44.0
6–10 years 17 34.0
0–5 years 7 14.0
21–30 years 2 4.0
30 years and above 2 4.0
Total 50 100.0
Source: Developed purposely for this research.

222
JRFM 2020, 13, 172

4.4. Comparability and Transparency of Finance Statement


The first objective of this study was geared towards examining comparability and transparency
of the financial statements. To effectively examine this, respondents were requested to indicate their
opinion about the comparability and transparency of the financial statements concerning the IFRS.
To reduce ambiguity, the results were collapsed from a five-point Likert scale to three-point Likert
scale options and their mean values were stipulated.
Table 2 shows the respondents’ views on comparability and transparency of the financial statements.
Of the respondents, 48 (96%) agreed that there was a higher quality of disclosure in financial statements
presented under IFRS than under the former OHADA Uniform Accounting Act. There were no neutral
views on this, while a minority of two respondents (4%) disagreed. However, the mean value of 4.61
on a scale of 5 showed there was a strong positive correlation as stipulated by the statement. Thus,
we can conclude that there was a higher quality of disclosure in financial statements presented in
accordance with IFRS than with the former OHADA Uniform Accounting Act. In terms of comparability,
a significant percentage of respondents, 46 persons (92%), agreed that the financial statements were
directly comparable to national and international companies. There was one neutral view (2%) and
three persons (6.0%) who disagreed with the statement that the financial statements were directly
comparable to national and international companies. This can be seen from the mean value of 4.35 on
a scale of 5 which shows that there was a strong positive correlation.

Table 2. Respondents’ views on comparability and transparency of financial statements.

Agree Neutral Disagree Mean


ITEMS
F % F % F %
There is a higher quality of disclosure in
financial statements presented in accordance
48 96 0 00 2 4 4.61
with IFRS than under former OHADA Uniform
Accounting Act
The financial statements are directly comparable
46 92.0 1 2.0 3 6.0 4.35
to national and international companies
IFRS are appropriate for achieving a true and
49 98 0 0.0 1 2 4.84
fair view of the financial statements
The financial statements prepared in accordance
to the IFRS are more transparent than those
47 94 1 2.0 2 4 4.39
prepared under former OHADA Uniform
Accounting Act
Implementing IFRS would increase the
49 98% 1 2.0% 0 0.0% 4.58
understand ability of financial statements
Source: Developed purposely for this research.

Similarly, out of the 50 respondents sampled, 49 of them (98%) agreed that IFRS were appropriate
for achieving a true and fair view of the financial statements. There was just one person (2%) who
disagreed to the fact that the IFRS were appropriate for achieving a true and fair view of the financial
statements. There was, therefore, a very strong indication that the IFRS were appropriate for achieving
a true and fair view of the financial statements as stipulated by the mean value of 4.84 on a scale of 5,
which shows the statement was in line. Furthermore, concerning the statement indicating that the
financial statements prepared under the IFRS were more transparent than those prepared under the
former OHADA Uniform Accounting Act, a vast majority of the respondents (47 persons) confirmed
the assertion to be true. However, three persons differed with the claim. Going from the majority, it can
be noted that the financial statements prepared following the IFRS were more transparent than those
prepared under the former OHADA Uniform Accounting Act. Furthermore, the mean value of 4.39 on
a scale of 5 tells us that there was a strong positive correlation in the statement.

223
JRFM 2020, 13, 172

Furthermore, 49 respondents agreed that the implementing of IFRS would increase the ability to
understand financial statements. As well, 48 respondents (96%) strongly agreed that there was a higher
quality of disclosure in financial statements presented in accordance with IFRS than under the former
OHADA Unfirom Accounting Act. Forty-six people (92.0%) agreed that the financial statements were
directly comparable to national and international companies, while 4 (8%) disagreed with this. In a
nutshell, the mean value of 4.58 on a scale of 5 shows there was a strong positive correlation with the
statement with the Cronbach alpha of 0.842 as shown in Table 3 below.

Table 3. Reliability Statistics.

Cronbach’s Alpha Cronbach’s Alpha Based on Standardised Items N of Items


0.842 0.810 5
Source: Results obtained from SPSS.

4.5. Examining the Possibility of Fully Implementing the International Financial Reporting Standards in Cameroon
Another aspect of the study was to examine the extent of the application of IFRS in the Cameroon
accounting system.
As seen in Table 4, more than three quarters (84.0%) of the respondents strongly agreed that
were aware of the International financial reporting standards; eight (16.0%) agreed, and none of the
participants disagreed with this. This was closely supported by an understanding of the differences
between the IFRS and SYSCOHADA. It was revealed that most of the respondents clearly knew the
differences between the accounting reporting systems, as 39 (78.0%) strongly agreed to this, 10 (20.0%)
agreed, while one person (2.0%) expressed a neutral view. However, their computed mean was greater
than 2.5 and above, which shows that both statements were positively correlated.

Table 4. Respondents’ view on the extent of the implementation of International Financial Reporting
Standards (IFRS) in Cameroon.

Agree Neutral Disagree Mean


Survey Statement
F % F % F %
I am well aware of the IFRS 50 100 0 0.0 0 0.0 4.98
I understand the key differences that exist between the
49 98.0 1 2.0 0 0.0 4.71
IFRS and SYSCOHADA
Cameroon has the structures needed to carry out a
20 40.0 4 8.0 26 52.0 2.35
revaluation of fixed assets
The nature of fixed assets in most companies are such that
38 76.0 2 4.0 10 20.0 3.94
they can be decomposed and recorded separately
The clients fully understand the IFRS and can prepare their
statements for the 2018 Financial year in accordance with 26 52.0 3 6.0 21 42.0 3.39
the IFRS
Accountants understand the distinguishing factors in the
30 60.0 5 10.0 15 30.0 4.00
IFRS for SME’s
Accountants of SME’s who report internationally have
been well trained to prepare their statements in accordance 39 78 4 8 7 14 3.61
to the revised standards
Companies have understood the changes in the statistics
11 22.0 3 6.0 36 72.0 2.77
and tax return filing
My clients would be able to prepare their tax returns in
19 38.0 11 22.0 4 8.0 3.97
accordance with the revised laws for the 2018 financial year
Source: Developed purposely for this research.

224
JRFM 2020, 13, 172

From Table 4 above, the study also found that a majority of the respondents (52%) disagreed
with the assertion that Cameroon has the structures needed to carry out a revaluation of fixed assets.
Four neutral respondents comprised 8%, and as the mean value of 2.35 on a scale of 5 shows, there was
a weak positive correlation. Furthermore, 40% of the respondents felt that Cameroon has the structures
needed to carry out the revaluation of fixed assets. This depicts clearly that many of the respondents
think that Cameroon does not have the necessary structures and infrastructures to implement the IFRS,
as well as the revaluation of fixed assets.
50 respondents agreed with the assertion that the natures of fixed assets in most companies are
such that they can be decomposed and recorded separately. Of the total respondents, 34% strongly
agreed with that assertion, 42% agreed (giving a total of 76% for those who agreed), two respondents
could not tell whether companies have fixed assets that can be decomposed and recorded separately,
and 20% disagreed that companies have fixed assets that can be decomposed. This shows that most of
the respondents hold the view that the natures of fixed assets in most companies are such that they can
be decomposed and recorded separately. The computed mean value of 3.39 shows that the statement
was in line.
Furthermore, 60% agreed that accountants understand the distinguishing factors in the IFRS for
SME’s, and only 10% and 30% were neutral and strongly disagreed, respectively. The computed mean
value of 4.00 shows there was a strong positive relationship. However, 78% agreed that accountants of
SME’s who report internationally had been well trained to prepare their statements in accordance to
the revised standards. In comparison only 8% and 14% were neutral and disagreed, respectively. In a
nutshell, the mean value of 3.61 on a scale of 5 shows that the statement was positively correlated.
In addition to that, 11 respondents (22%) strongly agreed that the clients fully understand the
IFRS and can prepare their statements for the 2018 financial year under the IFRS; 15 respondents (30%)
supported this, while 6% of the respondents were indifferent. However, 10% of the total respondents
disagreed with the assertion that their clients fully understand the IFRS and can prepare their statements
for the 2018 financial year per the IFRS. Accountants understand the distinguishing factors in the IFRS
for SMEs, and the mean value of 2.77 shows the statement was strongly correlated.
Equally, from those sampled in the study, less than half accepted that companies have understood
the changes in the statistics and tax return filling, while few were indifferent. This was opposed to
about 72% who disagreed that companies’ accountants understand the changes in tax return filing
with the introduction of IFRS. The last aspect indicates that most of the respondents disagreed that
their clients would be able to prepare their tax returns in accordance with the revised laws for the 2018
financial year. This was opposed to a few whom the study found could, and the mean value of 3.9 on a
scale of 5 shows there was a strong positive correlation with the Cronbach’s alpha of 0.818 as shown in
Table 5 below.

Table 5. Reliability Statistic.

Cronbach’s Alpha Cronbach’s Alpha Based on Standardised Items N of Items


0.818 0.770 9
Source: Results obtained from SPSS.

4.6. Perception on the Costs and Benefits Involved in Transitioning from the Former OHADA to IFRS
The last objective of this study sought an understanding of respondents’ perception on the costs
and benefits involved in transitioning from the OHADA GAAP to IFRS as shown in the Table 6 below.

225
JRFM 2020, 13, 172

Table 6. Respondents’ perceptions of the costs and benefits involved in transitioning from the
Organisation for the Harmonisation of Business Laws in Africa (OHADA) GAAP to IFRS.

Agreed Neutral Disagree Mean


Survey Statement
F % F % F %
Implementing IFRS would increase the relevance of
50 100 0 0.0 0 0.0 4.71
accounting information for decision making
Preparing financial statements in accordance with the IFRS
would increase the opportunities of Cameroon companies for 50 100 0 0.0 0 0.0 4.65
assessing global markets
Presenting Financial statements in accordance with the IFRS
would assure greater accessibility of funds for Cameroonian 46 92.0 0 0.0 4 8.0 4.65
companies
Transitioning to IFRS would lower the cost of capital 44 88.0 3 6.0 3 6.0 4.39
Transitioning to IFRS would provide professional
49 98.0 1 2.0 0 0.0 4.55
opportunities to Cameroonian professionals across the globe
Transitioning to IFRS would make the business climate more
48 96.0 1 2.0 1 2.0 4.72
welcoming to investors
IFRS is complicated in comparison to OHADA 40 80.0 1 2.0 9 18.0 4.64
Transitioning to IFRS requires the training of staff which
11 22.0 3 6.0 36 72.0 2.05
would be costly to organisations
Transitioning to the IFRS would require a change in the
35 70.0 2 4.0 13 26.0 3.94
accounting processes
Implementing IFRS would require significant changes in the
Information Technology Infrastructure of several 31 62.0 2 4.0 17 34.0 3.57
organisations
The IFRS requires too much disclosure of financial
25 50.0 0 00 25 50.0 2.50
information which is troublesome
Implementation of IFRS would require significant changes in
21 42.0 1 2.0 28 56.0 2.46
various existing laws
Source: Developed purposely for this research.

As seen in the Table 6 above, an evaluation of respondents’ opinions on the cost-benefit analysis
of the implementation of IFRS found a strong confirmation by all respondents that implementing IFRS
would increase the relevance of accounting information for decision making. About three-quarters
of the respondents agreed that preparing financial statements under the IFRS would increase the
opportunities of Cameroon companies for assessing global markets. This was supported by the
remaining one quarter 13 (26%) of respondents. However, the mean values greater than 2.5 on a scale
of 5 shows that there was a strong positive relationship in the stipulated statement.
Likewise, it was confirmed by 38 (76%) of the respondents that presenting financial statements per
the IFRS would assure greater accessibility of funds for Cameroonian companies. While eight (16%) of
the respondents supported this assertion, four (8%) significantly differed and four (5%) were indecisive.
In terms of cost of capital, the results proved that 34 (68%) of the respondents strongly agreed that
transitioning to IFRS would lower the cost of capital; this was decided upon by 10 respondents (20%)
of the respondents, while three respondents (6%) stayed neutral and three respondents (6%) disagreed.
Conversely, 11 (22%) of the respondents held that transitioning to IFRS required the training of staff,
which would be costly to organisations. Nevertheless, the majority of the respondents (72%) disagreed
with the minority. This was confirmed by the mean value of 2.05 which was less than 2.5, showing
there was a weak positive correlation.
On another dimension, 49 respondents (98%) held that transitioning to IFRS would provide
professional opportunities to accounting professionals in Cameroon across the globe. Transitioning
to IFRS would make the business climate more welcoming to investors according to 48 (96%) of the
respondents. Likewise, transitioning to the IFRS would require a change in the accounting processes

226
JRFM 2020, 13, 172

according to 35 (70%) of the respondents, although 13 (26%) of them opposed. In a nutshell, the mean
value of 3.94 shows the statement was strongly in line.
In terms of technological change, the results recorded a significant confirmation by 31 (62%)
respondents that implementing IFRS would require substantial information technology infrastructure
of several organisations. This was opposed by 17 (34%) of the respondents, while two (4%) of them
were uncertain. This was in accordance with the mean value of 3.57 which was greater than 2.5 on a
scale of 5. This shows there was a strong positive correlation with and the Cronbach alpha of 0.825 as
shown in Table 7 below.

Table 7. Reliability Statistics.

Cronbach’s Alpha Cronbach’s Alpha Based on Standardised Items N of Items


0.825 0.802 11
Source: Results obtained from SPSS.

Moreover, the IFRS requires too much disclosure of financial information, which was troublesome
according to 25 (50%) respondents, besides the fact that implementation of IFRS would require
significant changes in various existing laws. The mean value of 2.5 on a scale of 5 shows there was a
positive correlation stipulated by the statement. IFRS recommends the application of the fair value
concept, which is generally difficult to apply.
In terms of the effect on earnings, the study found that 30 (60%) of the respondents admitted that
implementing IFRS would increase volatility in the company’s earnings. This is because financial
statements presented under the IFRS are prone to manipulation since businesses can use the methods
they wish. This was according to 13 respondents (23%), while the majority disdained. However,
the result shows a weak positive correlation of 2.46 on a scale of 5 as stipulated by the statement.

4.7. Verification of Research Hypothesis


The first goal in analysing the results was to test if the findings were robust. In particular,
this examines if individuals gave broadly similar answers to roughly similar questions (an essential
test of reliability). Furthermore, the results using a 1% level of significance as our tested hypotheses
under one sample test are computed on the Table 8 below:

Table 8. Hypothesis testing results.

One-Sample Test
Test Value = 2
99% Confidence Interval of
Sig. Mean
T df the Difference
(2-Tailed) Difference
Lower Upper
The implementation of the IFRS would improve
the comparability and transparency of financial 31.976 50 0.000 4.613 4.22 5.01
statements
IFRS can be fully implemented in Cameroon given
72.058 50 0.011 2.839 4.65 5.02
the available resources and within the stated time.
The benefits involved in transitioning to IFRS
66.635 50 0.000 3.806 4.61 5.00
supersedes the cost of the transition
Source: Developed purposely for this research.

As analysed above from the presentation of results for the test of hypothesis on Table 8, it was
noticed that the p-value for comparability and transparency was 0.000, which is less than 0.01 at 1%
level of significance. We therefore reject the null hypothesis which says that the implementation
of the IFRS would not improve the comparability and transparency of financial statements and
accept the alternative hypothesis which says that the implementation of the IFRS would improve the

227
JRFM 2020, 13, 172

comparability and transparency of financial statements. Therefore, we conclude that the International
Financial Reporting Standards would have a significant effect on the comparability and transparency
of financial statements.
Furthermore, the p-Value for Cameroon’s resources was greater than 1% level of significance
(p-Value > 0.01) therefore, our study was insignificant. That is, we do not have enough evidence to reject
the null hypothesis which says IFRS cannot be fully implemented given Cameroon’s resources and
within the stated time, and conclude that the test was statistically insignificant at 1% level of significance.
Lastly, the p-Value for transitioning to IFRS was less than 1% level of significance (p-Value < 0.01)
therefore, our study was significant. That is, we then reject the null hypothesis which says that the costs
involved in transitioning to IFRS supersedes the benefits and accept the alternative which says that the
benefits involved in transitioning to IFRS supersede the cost of the transition. Therefore, we conclude
that there is likely an overall effect of benefits and costs by transitioning to IFRS.

4.7.1. Discussion of Results on the Comparability and Transparency of the Financial Statements under
the IFRS
The first objective of this study was geared towards examining comparability and transparency
of the financial statements under the IFRS. Aspects of perception examined showed that majority
of the respondents agreed that with the introduction of IFRS in the Cameroon accounting reporting
system, there is a higher quality of disclosure in financial statements presented as per the IFRS than
under OHADA. This means that the respondents perceive that IFRS enables greater transparency,
as such disclosure in financial statements filed in accordance with IFRS can reveal more information
about the financial situation of the business, which makes analysis easier. Furthermore, a significant
percentage of respondents also agreed that the financial statements prepared in accordance with the
IFRS would be more comparable to national and international companies than those prepared following
the OHADA GAAP. Greater comparability lowers the cost of acquiring information and increases
the overall quantity and quality of information available to analysts about the firm. In addition to
that, the respondents were positive about the idea that reporting in accordance with the IFRS would
result in financial statements that reflect a true and fair view of the financial situation of the company.
According to some proponents of International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS), IFRS increase
financial comparability and usefulness of accounting information (Tweedie 2010).
The last aspect identified under this objective recorded great confirmation that there was more
transparency of financial statements prepared in line with IFRS than those prepared in accordance with
the OHADA GAAP. These findings align to an extent with those of Rachel Byers (2017), who found that
a transition to IFRS would have significant effects on those accounting information sources, as this has
been already adopted by over 100 countries because of its levels of transparency and comparability in
international business environments spur by globalisation. Furthermore, P.L. Joshi et al. (2008), on the
perception of accounting professionals on the adoption and implementation of a single set of global
accounting standards in Bahrain, proved that the accountants were optimistic about the harmonisation
of accounting standards and they feel that it is worth the while.

4.7.2. Discussion on the Findings of the Full Implementation of IFRS in Cameroon


The findings with respect to Cameroon’s ability to implement the IFRS revealed that accounting
practitioners are actually positive about the IFRS implementation irrespective of the limited time for
the law to take effect. However, the results were insignificant, indicating that most of those interviewed
believe that Cameroon does not have the necessary infrastructure as well as proper accounting
knowledge of IFRS to implement IIFSR in the system fully. This is unlike Barth et al. (2008), who found
that the application of International Accounting standards was associated with higher accounting
quality in 21 countries that adopted IAS from 1994 to 2003. The author also compared the accounting
quality for IAS firms before and after they adopted the IAS and concluded that accounting quality has

228
JRFM 2020, 13, 172

improved between the pre- and post-adoption periods. The period before and after they adopted IAS
showed that accounting quality was enhanced between the pre- and post-adoption periods.

4.7.3. Discussion of Cost/Benefits of the Transition to IFRS


In line with Gupta et al. (2015), the conclusion generated from the descriptive and empirical analysis
was that accounting experts are optimistic towards the benefits associated with the implementation of
the IFRS, while at the same time they are concerned about the significant costs and challenges, such
as inadequate training of staff, changes required in the process, changes in information technology
infrastructure and other costs that are associated with the implementation of the IFRS. The low response
rate below 50% makes the study limited. The number of responses used to arrive at the conclusion was
quite small with respect to their target population. Perhaps if the response rate was higher, the results
would have been different.
This, however, contradicted the works of others in the Swiss accounting system who found
that a high percentage of firms voluntarily chose IAS in the 1990s, and switching to IAS was likely
to be more costly for Swiss firms than for firms from countries with higher reporting standards;
as such, voluntary adopters in Swiss firms should expect more advantages from IAS adoption
(Dumontier and Raffournier 1998; Murphy 1999). While proponents of IFRS claim that IFRS increases
financial comparability and usefulness of accounting information concord with the findings of this
study, others believe worldwide adoption of IFRS by all firms is costly, complex and does not necessarily
improve the quality of accounting reports. These study findings did not agree as there was significant
evidence that the benefits of the transition to IFRS supersede cost.

5. Conclusions
This study aimed at investigating the perception of accounting practitioners on the transition from
the former OHADA Uniform Accounting Act to the revised (now) OHADA Act on Accounting and
Financial Reporting and to IFRS, taking into account their opinion on the extent to which the transition
to IFRS would improve the transparency and comparability of the reported financial statements.
Also, it looked at the extent to which the International Financial Reporting Standards can be completely
implemented fully in the economy of Cameroon as a whole given its level of resources and within
the stated time. Lastly an understanding of the costs and benefits involved in transitioning from
SYCOHADA to IFRS was explored. The findings of this study are summarised as follows: with respect
to the transparency and comparability of the financial statement, the results indicated that there would
be a higher quality of disclosure in financial statements prepared following the International Financial
Reporting Standards than under the previous OHADA Accounting Act. This is supported by the
fact that the respondents believe that when reporting following the IFRS, financial statements of a
company can be directly comparable with a similar company in the same industry both within and out
of the country.
The study proved that financial statements prepared in accordance with the IFRS are more
appropriate in presenting a true and fair view. This implies that the Cameroon accountants perceive
IFRS to be a better reporting standard than the previous OHADA Uniform Accounting Act because
financial statements are expected to present a true and fair picture of the company’s financial
situation and be free from material misstatements. In addition to that, the study also proved that the
understandability of the financial statements would be greatly improved when reporting under IFRS
because a greater majority understands these standards as they are used in several countries already
and they present a higher quality of disclosures than OHADA. All these prove that the accountants
have a positive perception about the comparability, transparency and understandability of the financial
statements. The investigation on the perception of practitioners regarding the complete implementation
of International Financial Reporting Standards in the economy of Cameroon proved that Cameroon
does not have the structures required to carry out the revaluation of fixed assets. Hence there is a need

229
JRFM 2020, 13, 172

for an independent valuation body in Cameroon. However, the respondents attested to the fact that the
nature of fixed assets in some companies is such that it can be decomposed and recorded separately.
The study also found out that the accountants in Cameroon understand the distinguishing factors
in the IFRS for small and medium-size enterprises, and they would be able to prepare their financial
statements for the year ending in December 2018 in accordance with the IFRS. However, though the
accountants believe that they can prepare the financial reports in accordance with the International
Financial Reporting Standards, there is still insufficient evidence to attest to the fact that companies in
Cameroon have understood the changes in the statistics and tax return filling and that many clients
would be able to prepare their tax returns in accordance with the laws for the 2018 financial year.
It should be dully noted that Cameroon implemented just part of the IFRS, which is the reporting
standards for publicly listed companies and group companies that report internationally. The IFRS for
SME’s is still under review. The advantages and disadvantages of implementing IFRS are peculiar
to respective countries based on the availability of resources. Cost and complex nature have been a
cause of concern for implementing and adopting IFRS. There are of course positive gains regarding the
implementation of IFRS. However, there are serious concerns about the cost and benefits associated with
IFRS. All the respondents agreed that implementing IFRS would increase the relevance of accounting
information for decision making and it would increase the opportunities of Cameroon companies for
assessing global markets.
They also attested to the fact that presenting financial statements in accordance with the IFRS
would assure greater accessibility of funds for Cameroonian companies, lower the cost of capital,
provide professional opportunities to Cameroonian professionals and of course make the business
climate more welcoming to investors. However, there are major concerns attributed to the transition,
as the respondents supported the fact that the IFRS is a more complicated statute to adhere to than the
OHADA. The transition does not come with previous knowledge, and as such, every company would
have to train its staff on the new standards and these trainings and workshops are usually very costly
and time-consuming. The transition would also require a change in the accounting process which may
be attributed to the higher quality of disclosures when reporting under IFRS. It was also uncovered in
the course of the study that the increase in the disclosure may tend to be troublesome because when too
much information is made available, deciphering may become difficult for shareholders. In addition to
that, the findings of the study also included the fact that implementing IFRS would require significant
changes in the information technology infrastructure of several organisations and would also require
significant changes in various existing laws.
In sum, this study on the perception of accounting practitioners on the transition from OHADA
General Accepted Accounting Principles to IFRS in Cameroon sought specifically the respondents’
views pertaining to transparency and comparability of IFRS, the extent to which the IFRS can be
implemented in the economy of Cameroon and the costs and benefits involved in transitioning from
OHADA to IFRS. Data were collected using questionnaires administered to a sample of 50 respondents
constituting accountants in Cameroon businesses. Accounting practitioners have a positive perception
of the cost/benefits of IFRS transition in Cameroon. It was concluded that full IFRS could not be
completely implemented in Cameroon given Cameroon’s resources, especially within the slated time.
However, there is need for further research to be done in this area. Further studies should focus on
investigating whether the perception of accountants is independent of their individual attributes like
age, education, experience and qualification to bring about uniformity in the reporting structures.
It is necessary to investigate the extent to which the IFRS was actually implemented in Cameroon
and understand the challenges and opportunities that actually arose after the implementation of the
new reporting standards. One of the limitations is that it is specific to Cameroon. We had as one
of our principal objectives to widen the scope, but due to limited information we were restricted
only to Cameroon. Further research will include other African countries that had adopted the
OHADA Accounting System. Consistently, Tawiah and Boolaky (2019) shows that in most African
Countries there is a very slow implementation process of the IFRS. His study suggests that amongst the

230
JRFM 2020, 13, 172

African countries examined, 18 African nations required their companies to report financial statements
according to IFRS, meanwhile, 23 did not permit their companies to report according to the IFRS. Thus,
the above discussion shows that Cameroon needs the local institutional capacity and professional
training to smoothen the path towards the transition of IFRS.

6. Recommendations of the Study


The first priority of the International Accounting Standards Board (IASB) is to improve financial
reporting for the benefit of investors and other users of financial information. It is done by striving to
set the highest-quality standards, which collectively are known as Generally Accepted Accounting
Principles (GAAP). The IASB is a key participant in the development of the IFRS. The benefits of
having internationally comparable financial statements are abound. However, the results from the
study reveal that the respondents were not aware of whether the financial statements prepared in
accordance with IFRS were comparable or not. This shows that their knowledge on IFRS was limited,
hence seminars and focus group discussions should be organised to educate the experts on all the
benefits of this transition.
It is necessary to revalue fixed assets to bring them to their proper fair value when reporting under
the IFRS. However, the results from the study reveal that there are no proper structures in Cameroon
to carry out the revaluation of fixed assets. Hence the ministry of finance and the government at large
should ensure that such structures are put in place in order to reduce the level of material misstatement
in fixed assets.
More so, results showed that clients do not fully understand the IFRS and were not certain if their
clients would be able to prepare their financial statements in accordance with the IFRS. It is worth
noting that the IFRS provides momentous changes to the manner of reporting financial transactions.
Hence, there is an inexorable need to train the auditors and accountants on these changes. In view
of this, it is worth proposing that the accounting body in Cameroon (ONECCA) should strive to
ensure that all accountants have a proper understanding of the IFRS that guides the preparation of
their financial statements in their sector of business. In line with the cost-benefit analysis of IFRS
implementation, the findings showed that transitioning to IFRS requires the training of staff which
is costly to organisations, and it also requires too much disclosure of financial information which is
troublesome to businesses. Likewise, implementation of IFRS would require significant changes in
various existing laws. To address these issues, it was recommended that businesses should evaluate
the overwhelming benefits that IFRS have on their businesses such that the accompanying cost can be
undermined. Considering that the trainings would have a ripple effect on several parties, the organisers
should see into it that these trainings are very affordable for all and the both languages should be
represented. The fundamental reason for utilising this research method was due to the fact that a
qualitative survey is holistic, and it allowed us to develop an initial understanding of how people
think and feel. It equally permitted a primary study of a large and diversified population with the
possibility of adequately studying a sample while still maintaining the validity and reliability.

7. Limitation of Study
Our study is limited to the sociability of the respondents. This might be bias. However, this is
because we were more concerned with examining the perceptions of professional accountants which
might impose some incomplete information to the study.

Author Contributions: Data curation, M.F.F. and L.A.T.N.; Formal analysis, H.M.S.d.O. and C.M.F.P.; Methodology,
S.A.M.C.B.; Writing—review & editing, L.M.P. All authors have read and agree to the published version of
the manuscript.
Funding: The authors received no external funding for the research, authorship, and publication of this article.
Conflicts of Interest: The authors declared no potential conflicts of interest with respect to the research, authorship,
and publication of this article.

231
JRFM 2020, 13, 172

References
AICPA. 2019. American Institute of Certified Public Accountants. New York, NY 10036-8775. Available online:
www.IFRS.com (accessed on 20 July 2019).
Albu, Nadia, Cătălin N. Albu, and Sidney J. Gray. 2020. Institutional factors and the impact of international
financial reporting standards: The Central and Eastern European experience. Accounting Forum, 1–31.
[CrossRef]
Armstrong, Christopher S., Mary E. Barth, Alan D. Jagolinzer, and Edward J. Riedl. 2010. Market reaction to the
adoption of IFRS in Europe. The Accounting Review 85: 31–61. [CrossRef]
Barth, Mary. E., Wayne R. Landsman, and Mark H. Lang. 2008. International Accounting Standards and
Accounting Quality. Journal of Accounting and Research 46: 467–98. [CrossRef]
Barth, Mary E., Wayne R. Landsman, Mark Lang, and Christopher Williams. 2012. Are IFRS-based and US
GAAP-based accounting amounts comparable? Journal of Accounting and Economics 54: 68–93. [CrossRef]
Byers, R. 2017. Implications of Transitioning to IFRS on Key Financial Indicators in the Oil and Gas Production
Industry. Journal of Accounting and Finance 17.
Dabbicco, Giovanna, and Giorgia Mattei. 2020. The reconciliation of budgeting with financial reporting:
A comparative study of Italy and the UK. Public Money & Management, 1–11. [CrossRef]
Dicko, Saidatou, and Anne Fortin. 2014. IFRS adoption and the opinion of OHADA accountants. Afro-Asian
Journal of Finance and Accounting 4: 141–62. [CrossRef]
Dumontier, Pascal, and Bernard Raffournier. 1998. Why firms comply voluntarily with IAS: An empirical analysis
with Swiss data. Journal of International Financial Management & Accounting 9: 216–45.
Fossung, Michael Forzeh. 2016. Assessment of Compliance with OHADA Uniform Accounting Act by Public
Limited Companies. Journal of Accounting and Finance Research 5. [CrossRef]
Gibson, James J. 1979. The Ecological Approach to Visual Perception. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.
Gupta, Pallavi, Javaid Akhter, and Barnali Chaklader. 2015. An Empirical Study of Accounting Expert’s Perception
for Implementation of International Financial Reporting Standards in India. Nitte Management Review 9: 35–53.
[CrossRef]
Ionascu, Mihaela, Ion Ionascu, Marian Sacarin, and Mihaela Minu. 2014. IFRS adoption in developing countries:
The case of Romania. Accounting and Management Information Systems 13: 311.
Jandt, F. E. 1995. Effective Interviewing for Paralegals. New York: Anderson Publishing Company.
Jeanjean, Thomas, and Hervé Stolowy. 2008. Do accounting standards matter? An exploratory analysis of earnings
management before and after IFRS adoption. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy 27: 480–94. [CrossRef]
Joshi, P. L., Wayne G. Bremser, and Jasim Al-Ajmi. 2008. Perceptions of accounting professionals in the adoption
and implementation of a single set of global accounting standards: Evidence from Bahrain. Advances in
Accounting 24: 41–48. [CrossRef]
Mayegle, François-Xavier. 2014. OHADA accounting system and sharmonisation of accounting practice in
francophone sub-saharan africa. International Journal of Business and Social Science 5: 233–40.
Mohamed, W., Y. Yasseen, and F. Z. Omarjee. 2019. The perceptions of South African accounting practitioners
on the post-implementation of IFRS for SMEs in an institutionalised environment. Journal of Economic and
Financial Sciences 12: 1–11. [CrossRef]
Muraina, Saheed Adekunle. 2020. Effects of implementation of International Public Sector Accounting Standards
on Nigeria’s financial reporting quality. International Journal of Public Sector Management 33: 323–38.
Murphy, Kevin J. 1999. Executive compensation. In Handbook of Labor Economics. Amsterdam: Elsevier, vol. 3,
pp. 2485–2563.
Ndhlovu, J., and T. Senguder. 2002. Gender and perception of service quality in the hotel industry. Journal of
American Academy of Business 1: 301–7.
Ntoung, Lious Agbor Tabot, Helena Maria Santos de Oliveira, Benjamim Manuel Ferreira de Sousa,
Liliana Marques Pimentel, and Susana Adelina Moreira Carvalho Bastos. 2020. Are Family Firms Financially
Healthier Than Non-Family Firm? Journal of Risk and Financial Management 13: 5. [CrossRef]
OHADA Uniform Acts. 2016. Organisation for the Harmonisation of Business Law in Africa, Official Bulletin, Special
Edition Permanent Secretariat of P. Box: 10071 Yaounde Cameroon. Available online: https://www.ohada.org/
attachments/article/1847/jo-ohada-se-nov2016-official-translation.pdf (accessed on 18 July 2019).

232
JRFM 2020, 13, 172

Paillusseau, J. 2004. Le droit de l’OHADA; Un droit très important et original. Available online: https://www.ohada.
org/attachments/article/1847/jo-ohada-se-nov2016-official-translation.pdf (accessed on 18 July 2019).
Rao, V. S. P., and Pemmasani Sankara Narayana. 1998. Organisation Theory and Behaviour. Delhi: Konark Publishing
Company, pp. 329–30.
Riasi, Arash. 2015. Competitive Advantages of Shadow Banking Industry: An Analysis Using Porter Diamond
Model. Business Management and Strategy 6: 15–27. [CrossRef]
Riasi, Arash, and Seyed Fathollah Amiri Aghdaie. 2013. Effects of a Hypothetical Iranian Accession to the World
Trade Organization on Iran’s Flower Industry. Consilience 10: 99–110. [CrossRef]
Schacter, D. L. 2012. Adaptive constructive processes and the future of memory. American Psychologist 67: 603.
[CrossRef]
Sharairi, Mohammad Haroun. 2020. Factors that influenced the adoption of IFRS by Islamic banks in the UAE.
Accounting Research Journal 33. [CrossRef]
Tawiah, V., and P. Boolaky. 2019. Determinants of IFRS compliance in Africa: Analysis of stakeholder attributes.
International Journal of Accounting & Information Management.
Tweedie, D. 2010. IFRS in 2011 and beyond. Paper Presented at 2010 International Financial Reporting Standards
(IF—RSs) Conference, Tokyo, Japan, July 28.

© 2020 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access
article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution
(CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).

233
Journal of
Risk and Financial
Management

Article
What Drives the Declining Wealth Effect of
Subsequent Share Repurchase Announcements?
David K. Ding 1,2 , Hardjo Koerniadi 3, * and Chandrasekhar Krishnamurti 4
1 Lee Kong Chian School of Business, Singapore Management University, Singapore 178899, Singapore;
davidding@smu.edu.sg or d.ding@massey.ac.nz
2 School of Economics and Finance, Massey University, Auckland 0745, New Zealand
3 Department of Finance, Faculty of Business, Economics and Law, Auckland University of Technology,
Private Bag 92006, Auckland 1142, New Zealand
4 UniSA Business, University of South Australia, Adelaide 5001, Australia;
Chandra.krishnamurti@unisa.edu.au
* Correspondence: hkoernia@aut.ac.nz; Tel.: +64-9-921-9999 (ext. 5042)

Received: 16 July 2020; Accepted: 5 August 2020; Published: 7 August 2020

Abstract: Recent academic studies document that open market share repurchase announcements
in the United States generate significantly lower returns than those reported in earlier studies.
We find that the lower announcement return is associated with an increasing number of subsequent
announcements in the more recent periods. Although the announcement period return from the
initial announcement is positive, subsequent announcement returns are significantly decreasing.
Further, we find that the decreasing returns of subsequent announcements are attributed to firms
with negative past repurchase announcement returns. Our multivariate regression test results are
consistent with the notion that the decreasing subsequent repurchase announcement returns are
driven by hubris-endowed managers.

Keywords: open market share repurchase; hubris; cumulative announcement returns; endowed

1. Introduction
SEC Rule 10b-18 of the United States’ Securities and Exchange Commission, introduced in 1982,
allows a company to announce its intention to repurchase its shares at the going market price.
Market reactions to open market share repurchase announcements in the 1980s were very positive
with average cumulative announcement returns recorded of more than 3 percent (see, for example,
(Vermaelen 1981; Ikenberry et al. 1995)).1 Since then, however, the cumulative abnormal announcement
returns are reported to decline over the years with average cumulative announcement returns of
around 1% in 2004 (Bonaimé 2012; Yook and Gangopadhyay 2011). The goal of this paper is to explain
why some firms, in light of the evidence of declining average announcement period returns, continue
to repeat their open market share repurchases.
What has caused the depletion of open market repurchase announcement returns? One possible
explanation is that it could be related to the increasing number of frequent repurchase announcements.2

1 The main motive for open market share repurchases is mainly either to buy back undervalued stocks (Lakonishok and
Vermaelen 1990; Peyer and Vermaelen 2009), or to distribute temporary free cash flows, in lieu of dividends, to shareholders
(Stephens and Weisbach 1998; Dittmar 2000; Skinner 2008). Other theories used to explain repurchases are: (1) to improve
their leverage ratios (Bagwell and Shoven 1988); (2) to discourage takeover attempts (Bagwell 1991); and (3) to counter the
dilution effect of stock option plans (Fenn and Liang 2001; Kahle 2002).
2 Another possible explanation could be due to lower past repurchase completion rates. (Bonaimé 2012; Mishra et al. 2011;
Chang et al. 2010) argue that when a firm launches an open market share repurchase program but does not follow it through

JRFM 2020, 13, 176; doi:10.3390/jrfm13080176 235 www.mdpi.com/journal/jrfm


JRFM 2020, 13, 176

Jagannathan and Stephens (2003) find that the market reacts less positively to announcements made
by frequent repurchasers than to those made by non-frequent repurchasers. The number of frequent
repurchase announcements in their sample, during the period from 1986 to 1996, accounts for about
half of their total sample. Since 2003, however, the frequency of announcing subsequent open market
repurchase programs is reported to have been increased substantially (Fu and Huang 2016).3
Busch and Obernberger (2017) document that share repurchases help to maintain accurate stock
prices by providing price support at fundamental values. They find no evidence of managers using
share repurchases to manipulate stock prices when selling their equity holdings or exercising stock
options. Similarly, Liu and Swanson (2016) provide evidence that a key motive for increasing share
repurchases is to provide price support.
If the market reacts less favorably to subsequent repurchase program announcements, why would
some firms keep repeating such a program? Ben-David et al. (2007) argue that hubristic managers
are not only responsive to excess cash flows, but also prone to believe that their firms’ stock prices
are less than what they should be and are likely to communicate their (biased) belief to the market by
launching open market repurchase programs.4 Ben-David et al. (2007) argument is consistent with
Jagannathan and Stephens (2003) findings that repeat repurchasing firms have large excess cash flows
and high growth opportunities. As empirical evidence in the literature suggests that hubristic bias
is pervasive among managers,5 this paper examines whether managerial hubris bias can explain the
decreasing magnitude of open market repurchase announcement period returns. The empirical results
are consistent with this conjecture.
It should be pointed out that the term hubris has been used in the context of takeovers by Roll (1986)
to describe the managerial motive behind takeovers. Managerial hubris refers to overconfident managers
who attribute their success to their individual superior abilities. There is no direct instrument available
to measure CEO/managerial hubris. Prior work has used the following indicators to infer managerial
hubris: recent organizational success (Meindl et al. 1985; Hayward and Hambrick 1997), recent media
praise (Chen and Meindl 1991; Salancik and Meindl 1984), CEO’s self-importance (Manfred et al. 1984;
Miller and Droge 1986; Finkelstein 1992), and the moneyness of CEO’s option (Kim et al. 2016).
Following these works, particularly Hayward and Hambrick (1997), we infer about managerial hubris
based on a firm’s prior performance.
This paper finds that, during the sample period from 1996 to 2014, the number of repeat or
subsequent open market repurchase announcements has been increasing over the years. On average,
the number of repeat announcements in a year accounts for about 68% of total open market repurchase

or repurchase less than the number of shares announced in the program, the market considers the firm as having a bad
reputation. Consequently, the market will react less favourably when the firm announces a subsequent open market share
repurchase program. Low past completion rates, however, cannot explain why some firms keep repeating open market
repurchase programs. If the motivation to repurchase is related to stock undervaluation, which is one of the most common
motives to launch an open market repurchase program, a positive market reaction to the repurchase announcement may be
sufficient for the announcing firm to not fully follow through on its announced repurchase plan, and therefore may explain
its lower repurchase completion rate. Similarly, if a firm’s subsequent open market repurchase program is motivated by
distributing excess cash flows or stock options, it should not have a low repurchase completion rate.
3 A similar pattern has also been observed in the Swedish stock market. De Ridder and Rasbrandt (2014) find that repeat
repurchasers make two out of three Swedish share repurchase announcements.
4 For the purposes of the current research work, we refer to hubris as an individual’s personal attribute of self- or over-confidence.
We define the term managerial hubris as the over-confident behavior of corporate managers.
5 The finance literature documents that some managers are prone to self-attribution bias, which leads them to be hubristic.
Ben-David et al. (2007) find that among other corporate actions, these managers are more likely to be associated with less
efficient investments. Hayward and Hambrick (1997) find that CEO’s hubris (or exaggerated self-confidence) is strongly
positively associated with the size of premiums paid for acquisitions. Malmendier and Tate (2008) find evidence consistent
with the view that hubristic CEOs overestimate their ability to generate returns. Hence, they overpay for target companies
and undertake value-destroying mergers. Another managerial trait—CEO narcissism—has also been shown to be positively
related to the number and size of acquisitions. (Chatterjee and Hambrick 2007; Billett and Qian 2008; Karolyi et al. 2015) find
evidence consistent with hubristic managers explaining the declining returns of serial acquirers. Recent work by Aktas et al.
(2016) show that both acquirer and target CEO narcissism affect the characteristics of the takeover process. No prior studies
have studied stock repurchases using the lens of managerial hubris.

236
JRFM 2020, 13, 176

announcements.6 Consistent with prior studies, compared with firms that do not repeat share
repurchase announcements, firms that repeat their share repurchase programs have higher growth
opportunities, have more free cash flows, are more profitable, less undervalued, larger, and have
significantly lower cumulative abnormal announcement period returns (3.56% vs. 1.83%, respectively).
It is, therefore, an empirical question why such firms, having high growth opportunities and large cash
flows, would keep investing in their own stocks rather than investing in the real sector.
This paper documents firms that repeat open market share repurchase programs experience an
average cumulative announcement period abnormal return of 2.51% from their initial announcement.
However, when these firms repeat their repurchase programs, the market reacts less favorably to the
second announcement, that the cumulative announcement period return drops significantly to 1.77%.
The cumulative announcement period return continues to drop further to only 0.89% when firms make
five or more open market repurchase announcements. In a further analysis, this study finds that firms
with negative past announcement returns experience decreasing subsequent announcement returns,
which is consistent with the notion that managers endowed with hubris are associated with decreasing
subsequent announcement returns.
This study sheds light in explaining the declining open market share repurchase announcement
returns and attempts to contribute to the literature in several aspects. First, this study employs a
more recent sample period (from 1996 to 2014) and documents that the number of repeat open market
share repurchase announcements has significantly increased over the years, suggesting that there is
a systematic change in repurchasing behavior during the sample period. Second, the present study
is the first to document that, not only the announcement returns of repeat announcements are lower
than those of non-repeat announcements, but also that the magnitude of subsequent announcement
returns is decreasing significantly. Third, this paper proposes a managerial motivation bias to explain
the increasing number of repeat open market share repurchase programs. The empirical results are
consistent with the hubris bias hypothesis that firms with managers endowed with hubris bias and
equipped with excessive cash flows, are more likely to repeat their open market share repurchase
programs even though their decisions generate lower subsequent announcement returns.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 develops and discusses the hypotheses.
Section 3 describes the sample and data collection processes. The empirical results are reported in
Sections 4 and 5 concludes.

2. Hypothesis Development
The literature documents that firms that repeat their repurchase programs have higher growth
opportunities, have more free cash flows, are less undervalued and are larger than those with infrequent
repurchases (Jagannathan and Stephens 2003). Firms with such characteristics provide an ideal research
setting for examining the managerial hubris hypothesis in subsequent share repurchase programs as
hubristic managers are significantly more responsive to the generation of excess cash flows by their
firms and tend to over-invest by repurchasing their firms’ shares (Ben-David et al. 2007; Malmendier
and Tate 2005; Campbell et al. 2011).7 Supported with large amounts of free cash flows, managers
may feel confident in their ability to meet the firm’s obligations and may also be over-confident in
using the excess free cash flows on a subsequent open market repurchase program when they believe
their firms’ equity value is underpriced, regardless of firms’ high growth opportunities and could have

6 Drops only in 1998 and 1999 to less than half of the total announcements in a year (48% and 45%, respectively).
7 Lehn and Poulsen (1989) find that firms with undistributed free cash flows tend to pay a significant premium for stock
repurchases related to going private transactions. Howe et al. (1992) investigate whether Jensen (1986) free cash flow
theory explains the market reaction to tender offer share repurchases and specially designated dividends where the cash
distribution is not expected to be repeated. They find that free cash flows do not explain the announcement returns
very well and conclude that their results are inconsistent with Jensen’s free cash flow hypothesis but consistent with the
information-signaling hypothesis. They offer the entrenchment hypothesis as a possible explanation for their conflicting
findings with those of Jensen’s.

237
JRFM 2020, 13, 176

invested in real capital projects instead. If a repeat repurchase program is not in the best interest of
shareholders, the market will react less favorably to a firm’s subsequent announcement. As such, we
test the following hypothesis:
Hypotheses 1 (H1). Subsequent open market repurchase announcements by hubristic managers will experience
lower announcement period returns due to their overpayment for the shares.
Managers may develop a hubris bias when their previous open market repurchase program is
successful (learning hubris) and, therefore, may overestimate their ability to repeat their previous
success by launching a subsequent repurchase program. On the other hand, managers can also be
hubristic if they are already endowed with it. Prior studies in the psychology literature document that
people endowed with hubris are likely to ignore negative feedback of their behavior (Snyder et al. 1977;
Swann and Read 1981; Taylor and Gollwitzer 1995). Thus, managers endowed with hubris are likely to
ignore negative feedback from the market (Roll 1986; Billett and Qian 2008). Because they are biasedly
optimistic about their ability to succeed, even though their firm’s past announcement return from the
previous program is negative, if they believe that their current stock price is undervalued, they would
likely attempt to correct the stock price by repeating a repurchase program. Therefore, we expect that
the subsequent announcement returns of such firms to be lower, or even negative. Thus, the second
hypothesis is:
Hypotheses 2 (H2). If repeat repurchase announcements are attributed to endowed hubris, then firms with
negative past announcement period returns will experience even lower subsequent announcement returns.
Managers with endowed hubris bias may likely repeat a subsequent share repurchase
announcement within a shorter period, as they would like to repeat their previous success. The shorter
the number of days between a previous and a current announcement, the lower is the expected current
announcement period return. Consequently, the third hypothesis is:
Hypotheses 3 (H3). The time between two subsequent announcements is positively related to the announcement
period return.

3. Sample
This study collects open market share repurchase announcement dates of non-financial and
non-utility firms in the U.S. from January 1996 to September 2014 from Thomson Reuters SDC Platinum.
Price and accounting variable data of these firms were obtained from Thomson Reuters Datastream.
Market-adjusted announcement period abnormal returns were computed with market value-weighted
returns obtained from Kenneth French’s website8 as the benchmark. This study does not use the
market model to estimate abnormal announcement returns as several firms in the sample repeat their
announcements in less than a year period, and thus would bias the measurement of normal period
return.9 Merging the data obtained from SDC Platinum and Thomson Reuters Datastream reduces the
sample size to 3122 announcement-year observations. To mitigate the effects of outliers, these variables
are winsorized at the 1% and 99% levels.
Table 1 shows the number of non-repeat and repeat announcements from 1996 to 2014,
their corresponding announcement period returns, and the associated size programs during the
sample period. In Panel A of Table 1, the total number of open market share repurchase announcements
increases from 227 in 1996 to 405 in 2008 and then declines to 82 in 2014. The lowest (highest)
total number of announcements is in 2012 (1998) with 36 (405) announcements. The percentage of
announcements made by repeat repurchasers decreases from 59% in 1996 to less than half in 1999.
Since then, it has increased to, on average, around three-fourths of all repurchase announcements

8 http://mba.tuck.dartmouth.edu/pages/faculty/ken.french/data_library.html#HistBenchmarks.
9 This methodology is also used in studies on repeat acquisitions, such as (Karolyi et al. 2015; Billett and Qian 2008).

238
JRFM 2020, 13, 176

every year in the sample period. Panel B shows that the lowest (highest) 2-day cumulative abnormal
returns or CARs (days 0, +1) is 0.4% (4.7%) in year 2006 (1999). The average 2-day CARs since year
2000 is 1.78% per year, which is much lower than those reported in earlier studies in the open market
repurchase literature. The average cumulative announcement abnormal return for the whole sample
period is 2.4%. We observe that the size of repurchase programs increases over time with the average
smallest (largest) program launched in 2004 (2012). On average, repurchasing firms plan to buy
back around 7.56% of their outstanding stocks. The (untabulated) correlation coefficient between the
percentage of repeat announcements and announcement returns is negative. These statistics clearly
show that open market share repurchase announcements in more recent periods are dominated by
repeat repurchase announcements with significantly lower announcement period returns.

Table 1. Sample distribution and market adjusted returns.

Panel A. Number of Repurchases


YEAR ONLY ONE REPEAT TOTAL % REPEAT
1996 94 133 227 59%
1997 122 128 250 51%
1998 211 194 405 48%
1999 147 122 269 45%
2000 96 112 208 54%
2001 43 82 125 66%
2002 57 109 166 66%
2003 23 79 102 77%
2004 25 132 157 84%
2005 47 156 203 77%
2006 47 1474 194 76%
2007 41 142 183 78%
2008 32 92 124 74%
2009 12 59 71 83%
2010 30 97 127 76%
2011 28 106 134 79%
2012 12 24 36 67%
2013 16 43 59 73%
2014 36 46 82 56%
Panel B. Cumulative Abnormal Announcement Returns
2-day Cumulative Abnormal SIZE OF PROGRAM (%)
YEAR
Returns [CAR (0, +1)] (SIZEPROG)
1996 0.024 6.656
1997 0.020 6.538
1998 0.030 7.358
1999 0.047 7.917
2000 0.045 7.631
2001 0.023 7.413
2002 0.040 6.617
2003 0.016 6.826
2004 0.013 6.465
2005 0.019 7.010
2006 0.004 7.459
2007 0.022 8.649
2008 0.025 8.025

239
JRFM 2020, 13, 176

Table 1. Cont.

2-day Cumulative Abnormal SIZE OF PROGRAM (%)


YEAR
Returns [CAR (0, +1)] (SIZEPROG)
2009 0.020 7.441
2010 0.015 8.753
2011 0.010 8.201
2012 0.020 9.407
2013 0.008 8.177
2014 0.014 7.055
ONLY ONE refers to firms that announce only one repurchase during the sample period. REPEAT is firms that
announce to repurchase the first time and will repeat during the sample period. SIZEPROG is percent of shares
authorized at initial authorization date.

4. Methods and Results


Fu and Huang (2016) report the disappearance of long run abnormal returns following stock
repurchase programs from 2003 to 2012. They argue that the U.S. stock markets have become more
efficient since 2003 due to several regulatory changes, such as the decimalization of stock prices and
the enactment of the Sarbanes–Oxley Act of 2002 (SOX). These are expected to affect not only market
and regulatory environments, but also reduce managers’ incentives to manipulate earnings. Thus,
to examine whether the lower cumulative announcement period return is attributed to increased
efficiency of the U.S. stock market since 2003, this study splits per year announcement period returns
based on whether they are the first or subsequent announcements made by the repurchasing firms.
The results, as reported in Table 2, show that, on average, subsequent announcement returns
are significantly lower than those of initial announcements at the 95% confidence level. These results
remain consistent when the sample is sorted based on pre- and post-2003 periods. Hence, the findings
suggest that the increased efficiency of the U.S. stock market alone cannot explain the decline in open
market repurchase announcement period returns, but that subsequent announcements may also explain
the lower repurchase announcement period returns. We also find that the average announcement
returns in the 2003–2014 period (post-SOX) are significantly lower than those in the 1996–2002 period
for both the first and subsequent repurchase announcements.

Table 2. First and subsequent market-adjusted announcement returns.

PERIOD First Announcement Subsequent Announcements Difference


Average Total period 0.026 *** 0.016 *** 0.010 **
Average 1996–2002 0.037 *** 0.022 *** 0.015 **
Average 2003–2014 0.020 *** 0.013 *** 0.007 **
Difference 0.017 *** 0.009 **
This table displays the cumulative market-adjusted returns (0, +1) from first and subsequent open market share
repurchase announcements and the difference between the two. It also shows the difference of the average
announcement returns between the two sub-periods. *** and ** denote statistical significance at the 1% and
5% respectively.

Panel A of Table 3 shows the differences of announcement returns sorted by firms that announce
only one repurchase during the sample period versus firms that repeat their repurchase announcements.
The cumulative abnormal return of open market repurchase programs announced by firms that do
not repeat their open market repurchase programs is 3.56% and significantly higher than that of
firms that repeat their announcements (1.83%), which is consistent with the findings of Jagannathan
and Stephens (2003). In Panel B, announcement returns are sorted based on the order of repeat
announcements. On average, repeat repurchasers earn 2.51% from their initial announcements.
The average cumulative abnormal return in the second announcements, however, drops significantly
to 1.77%. Third announcements experience a further decline in cumulative announcement return to

240
JRFM 2020, 13, 176

1.25%. The cumulative announcement return continues to decline when firms announce more open
market repurchase programs (0.89%).

Table 3. Cumulative abnormal announcement returns (0, +1).

Panel A. Only One Repurchase vs. Repeat Repurchases


ONLY ONE REPEAT Difference
3.56% *** 1.83% *** −1.73% ***
Panel B. Cumulative announcement abnormal returns of repeat repurchasers
Initial announcement Second announcement Difference
2.51% *** 1.77% *** −0.73% **
Second announcement Third announcement Difference
1.77% *** 1.25% *** −0.53% *
Third announcement ≥5 announcements Difference
1.25% *** 0.89% *** −0.36%
Abnormal returns are measured as market-adjusted returns. ONLY ONE is firms that announce one repurchase
during the sample period. REPEAT is firms that announce to repurchase the first time and will repeat during the
sample period. Initial announcement is the first announcement made by repeat repurchasers. Second announcement
is the second announcement made by repeat repurchasers. Third announcement is the third announcement made
by repeat repurchasers. *, **, *** denote statistical significance at the 10%, 5% and 1%, respectively.

To examine if the declining subsequent announcement returns are attributed to hubristic bias,
this study sorts the announcement returns based on the sign of past announcement returns. Panel A of
Table 4 shows that the mean (median) return of the second repurchase announcements of firms that
experience a negative announcement return from their initial announcements is 1.59% (1.29%) during
the two-day announcement window period. When firms make subsequent announcements, their mean
(median) announcement return drops significantly to 0.16% (−0.16%) during the two-day window
period. However, there is no evidence of decreasing subsequent announcement returns for firms with
positive past announcement returns (Panel B). These results suggest that the decreasing subsequent
announcement returns can be attributed to firms experiencing negative past announcement returns
that keep repeating their repurchase programs.

Table 4. Announcement returns sorted by past announcement returns.

Panel A. Negative Past Announcement Returns


CAR (0, +1)
2nd Announcement >2 Announcements Difference
Mean 1.59% 0.16% −1.43% ***
Median 1.29% −0.16% −1.45% †
Panel B. Positive past announcement returns
CAR (0, +1)
2nd announcement >2 announcements Difference
Mean 1.39% 2.12% 0.74% **
Median 0.90% 1.50% 0.60% †
*** and ** denote statistical significance at the 1% and 5% levels, respectively. † denotes significance at the 1% level,
based on Wilcoxon p-values for the median.

Table 5 shows the descriptive statistics of the sample sorted by the frequency of announcements
made by repurchasing firms. Consistent with prior studies, repeat repurchasing firms are bigger,
more profitable, have more free cash flows, have higher growth opportunities, and are less underpriced
than those of non-repeat repurchasing firms (the mean of RUNUP is −7.3% vs. −9.2%, respectively).

241
JRFM 2020, 13, 176

The less underpricing of repeat repurchasing firms suggests that the motivation of firms that frequently
announce open market share repurchase programs may be less attributable to undervaluation but
seems to be more consistent with the distribution of excess cash flows. According to the free cash flows
hypothesis, when there are no growth opportunities available, managers distribute excess cash to the
firm’s shareholders to maximize their firm value. These firms, however, have higher and increasing
growth opportunities than non-repeat repurchasing firms as indicated by their book-to-market ratios.
Thus, instead of investing in the real sectors, these firms choose to invest in the firms’ stocks by
announcing subsequent repurchase programs, which is inconsistent with the free cash flow hypothesis
but is more consistent with the hubris bias hypothesis.

Table 5. Descriptive statistics.

Repeat Repurchasers
Initial ≥2 ≥3
Mean Values Total ONLY ONE
Announcement Announcements Announcements
CASHFLOW 0.120 0.092 0.133 0.137 0.140
B/M 0.561 0.671 0.519 0.492 0.436
DIVYIELD 0.008 0.005 0.007 0.009 0.011
LEVERAGE 0.178 0.180 0.172 0.179 0.183
SIZE ($000) 741,760 273,773 770,361 1,654,712 2,770,892
ΔSALES 0.022 0.018 0.035 0.019 0.023
ROA 0.049 0.016 0.064 0.068 0.079
ROA+1 0.048 0.009 0.068 0.069 0.076
RUNUP −0.063 −0.092 −0.073 −0.035 −0.024
STDEV 0.028 0.034 0.028 0.023 0.020
SIZEPROG 7.420 7.702 6.780 7.496 7.689
ONLY ONE refers to firms that announce only one repurchase during the sample period. Initial announcement is
the first announcement made by repeat repurchasers. Second announcement is the second announcement made by
repeat repurchasers. Third announcement is the third announcement made by repeat repurchasers. CASHFLOW is
measured as cashflows/total assets. B/M is book-to-market ratio. DIVYIELD is dividend/market value of equity at
time t − 1. LEVERAGE is total debt/total assets. SIZE is the natural logarithm of market value of equity in the quarter
prior to announcement quarter. ΔSALES is change in sales/total assets. ROA is return on assets. All accounting
variables are measured in the quarter prior to the announcement quarter. RUNUP is cumulative market-adjusted
return measured from −46 to −6. STDEV is the standard deviation of market-adjusted return measured from
day −100 to −46. SIZEPROG is the size of the repurchase program, measured as percentage of shares authorized
at announcement.

Table 5 also shows that the stock performance of repeat repurchasers prior to subsequent
announcements (RUNUP) is negative. The hubris bias hypothesis predicts that when hubristic
managers believe their firms’ shares are undervalued, they are likely to repurchase shares by repeating
their repurchase program. Furthermore, due to their illusory belief that they can repeat their past
success of announcing such programs, these managers may also increase the size of their repurchase
programs in subsequent announcements. The size of the repurchase program (SIZEPROG) reported in
Table 5 is consistent with this conjecture. The size of the programs announced by repeat repurchasers
from the initial announcement to subsequent announcements increases from 6.78% of the total
outstanding shares to 7.50% in subsequent announcements, and further up to 7.69% for more than
three subsequent announcements.
The results displayed in Table 5 suggest that firm characteristics of repeat repurchasers are different
from those of non-repeat repurchasers and that they have the propensity to repeat open market share
repurchase programs. Hence, this study conducts a logit analysis to examine the determinants or the
likelihood of these firms to announce a share repurchase program:

REPEAT REPURCHASE = α + β1 RUNUP + β2 SIZE + β3 B/M + β4 SIZEPROG +


(1)
β5 LEVERAGE + β6 STDEV + β7 ROA + β8 OPTION + Industry and Year Control + ε

where REPEAT REPURCHASE is a dummy of 1 for announcements made by repeat repurchasers.

242
JRFM 2020, 13, 176

The results reported in Table 6 are consistent with the firm characteristics reported in Table 5.
RUNUP is positively related to the likelihood to a repeat repurchase, suggesting that repeat repurchasers
are not motivated by under-performance. Large firms with large cash flows are more likely to repeat
share repurchase programs. Firms repeating repurchase announcements are also likely to increase
their program size.

Table 6. The determinants of repeat repurchases.

Coeff. (p-Values)
RUNUP 0.600 *** (0.001)
CASHFLOW 3.629 *** (0.000)
SIZE 0.287 *** (0.000)
B/M 0.226 * (0.061)
ΔSIZEPROG 0.038 *** (0.006)
LEVERAGE −0.123 (0.670)
STDEV −7.744 ** (0.026)
ROA −0.014 (0.959)
OPTION 0.492 (0.614)
INTERCEPT −3.168 ** (0.029)
Year effect Y
Industry effect Y
LR chi2 616.11
Pseudo R2 0.1599
Number of obs. 2981
Logit analysis of the determinants of repurchasing made by repeat repurchasers. The dependent variable is one for
repurchases made by repeat repurchasers. RUNUP is cumulative market-adjusted return measured from −46 to −6.
CASHFLOW is measured as cashflows/total assets. SIZE is the natural logarithm of market value of equity in the
quarter prior to announcement quarter. B/M is book-to-market ratio. ΔSIZEPROG is the change in program size.
LEVERAGE is total debt/total assets. STDEV is the standard deviation of market-adjusted return measured from
day −100 to −46. ROA is return on assets. OPTION is a dummy variable of one if the motivation to conduct a share
repurchase program is related to stock options. p-values are in parentheses. ***, **, * denote statistical significance at
the 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively.

To examine whether hubris explains the lower subsequent repurchase announcement returns,
this study controls for the probability of repeating a repurchase program measured by the fitted value
from the logistic regression reported in Table 6. If the market is able to anticipate that a subsequent
repurchase program would be launched by a repeat repurchaser, then the coefficient of this variable
should be significantly related to the announcement period return and that the market should not react
significantly to subsequent or repeat share repurchase announcements.
The results of cross-sectional regressions of share repurchasers’ announcement abnormal returns on
hubris and control variables are reported in Table 7. Consistent with the second hypothesis, the results
show that the decreasing subsequent announcement period returns are attributed to hubris-endowed
managers. The coefficients of the probability of repeating a repurchase are not statistically significant,
suggesting that the market may fail to anticipate subsequent repurchase announcements. The last
column in Table 7 shows that firms that repeat their repurchase announcements within a shorter period
experience significantly lower returns, which is consistent with the third hypothesis.

243
JRFM 2020, 13, 176

Table 7. Regressions of repeat repurchasers’ abnormal returns.

(1) (p-Values) (3) (p-Values)


ENDWHUBRIS −0.008 ** (0.037)
TBD (×10,000) 0.0288 * (0.083)
RUNUP −0.031 *** (0.000) −0.01768 (0.125)
SIZE −0.002 (0.306) −0.00173 (0.393)
B/M 0.003 (0.394) 0.002276 (0.672)
LEVERAGE −0.018 (0.042) −0.00916 (0.399)
STDEV 0.627 *** (0.000) 0.485303 *** (0.003)
ΔSIZEPROG 0.001 * (0.055) 0.000679 * (0.066)
OPTION −0.026 (0.421) −0.08596 (0.111)
CASHFLOW 0.029 (0.280) 0.054924 * (0.091)
Pr(Repeat repurchase) −0.026 (0.420) 0.002167 (0.954)
INTERCEPT 0.033 (0.462) −0.13531 ** (0.022)
Year effect Y Y
Industry effect Y Y
Adj. R2 0.0679 0.0214
Number of obs. 2972 1311
The dependent variable is cumulative abnormal return (0, +1). ENDWHUBRIS is one if a past repurchase
announcement return is negative. TBD is the number of days between two announcements. RUNUP is cumulative
market-adjusted return measured from −46 to −6. SIZE is the natural logarithm of market value of equity in
the quarter prior to announcement quarter. B/M is book-to-market ratio. LEVERAGE is total debt/total assets.
STDEV is the standard deviation of market-adjusted return measured from day −100 to −46. ΔSIZEPROG is the
change in program size. OPTION is a dummy variable of one if the motivation to conduct a share repurchase
program is related to stock options. CASHFLOW is measured as cashflows/total assets. Pr (repeat repurchase) is
the estimated probability of a repeat repurchase based on the logit results presented in Table 6. *, **, *** denote
statistical significance at 10%, 5%, and 1%, respectively.

Robustness Tests
The sample period starts from the beginning of 1996. However, there could be a concern that
this might not be representative of the start of an initial open market repurchase program. For added
robustness, this study follows (Song and Walkling 2000; Cai et al. 2011; Aktas et al. 2013) by imposing
an initial time lag of two years (1996 and 1997) during which time the repurchasing firms are not active.
Only those firms that have not undertaken any transactions during the initial dormant period (1996
and 1997) are included in the sample. The results are similar to those reported in the main analysis.
Additionally, this study redefines the measure for repeat repurchasers as firms that announce
subsequent open market share repurchase programs within five years of their initial issue. Although this
alternative measure may suffer from a sample selection bias due to the restriction, this study finds that
the results are also similar to those already reported. This study also considers the average abnormal
returns on the announcement day (day 0) and three (−1, +1), four (−2, +2), and ten (−5, +5) days of
return window periods in the analysis and finds that the results remain the same.
The present study examines managerial hubris at the firm level for several reasons. First, the most
popular proxy for hubris at the CEO level is the option-related measure developed by Malmendier and
Tate (2005). However, according to Malmendier and Tate (2015), Execucomp data prior to 2006 cannot
be used to calculate this measure, while noting that our sample period runs from 1996 to 2014. Second,
a recent study by Bayat et al. (2016) suggests that this option-based measure does not accurately
measure hubris at the CEO level; rather, it measures firm characteristics. They find that CEOs who are
considered hubristic according to the option-based measure are not considered as hubristic when they
change their affiliation.
As prior studies suggest that hubristic managers with large cash flows tend to over-invest,
therefore, we consider hubristic managers as those in firms that have the highest investments.
Following Campbell et al. (2011), we measure a firm’s industry-adjusted investments as the difference
between the firm’s capital expenditures scaled by its beginning of year gross property, plant,
and equipment (PPE), and the average industry investment based on 2-digit Standard Industrial

244
JRFM 2020, 13, 176

Classification (SIC) codes. These variables were downloaded from the Research Insight database
and matched the variables to the final sample. This study then creates quintiles based on the
industry-adjusted investments and examine only those firms that belong to the highest quintile
(the largest investments) as they are considered to have hubris bias. The matching procedure and
examining only the highest quintile, however, reduce the number of observations quite significantly.
After re-running the regression models, we find similar results. The endowed hubris variable is
significantly and negatively associated with the announcement period cumulative returns.
The other two proxies are a dummy variable of 1 for subsequent announcements as hubristic
managers are expected to repeat a repurchase program and the number of previous repurchase
announcements. A manager who has experience in launching more than one share repurchase
program can develop hubris bias and feel more confident in repeating a program but result in negative
announcement returns. The results are like those reported earlier. Both proxy variables are negatively
related to the announcement period returns; however, only the coefficient of the dummy variable is
statistically significant.
For added robustness, we include a time trend (TREND) in place of year effects in Table 7.
The results shown in Table 8 are consistent with the earlier findings, albeit with a slight reduction of
significance (p-value of 0.053) for ENDWHUBRIS.

Table 8. Regressions of repeat repurchasers’ abnormal returns with time trend.

Coeff. p-Value Coeff. p-Value


ENDWHUBRIS −0.007 * (0.053)
TBD (×10,000) 0.031 * (0.061)
RUNUP −0.033 *** (0.000) −0.018 * (0.099)
SIZE −0.002 (0.080) −0.001 (0.504)
B/M 0.004 (0.281) 0.005 (0.291)
LEVERAGE −0.016 * (0.065) −0.008 (0.429)
STDEV 0.700 *** (0.000) 0.530 *** (0.000)
ΔSIZEPROG 0.001 ** (0.045) 0.001 ** (0.012)
OPTION −0.028 (0.384) −0.091 * (0.087)
CASHFLOW 0.028 (0.133) 0.072 *** (0.004)
Pr(Repeat repurchase) −0.020 (0.181) −0.012 (0.489)
TREND 0.000 (0.298) 0.000 (0.445)
INTERCEPT 0.020 (0.648) −0.155 *** (0.006)
Industry effect Y Y
Adj. R2 0.0681 0.0279
Number of obs. 2972 1311
*, **, *** denote statistical significance at 10%, 5%, and 1%, respectively.

5. Conclusions
This paper examines open market share repurchase announcements from January 1996 to
September 2014. This paper documents that repeat announcements, which generate decreasing
announcement returns, dominate the number of open market share repurchase announcements in the
later period. Large firms with large cash flows are more likely to repeat share repurchase programs.
Firms repeating repurchase announcements are also likely to increase their program size. This paper
also finds that the decreasing announcement returns are attributable to subsequent announcements
made by firms experiencing negative past repurchase announcement returns.
Our results are robust to alternative definitions of repeat purchases and are consistent with the
notion that managers endowed with hubris or self-confidence drive the declining wealth of repeat
repurchasing firms’ shareholders. A word of caution is in order. Corporate board members should
be more mindful of the adverse impact of repeat share repurchases made by their over-confident
managers to shareholders before approving such offers.

245
JRFM 2020, 13, 176

We acknowledge the limitation in the sampling period of our study and recommended future
research to include data from more recent years. It would also be interesting to compare the results
of this study to those in other countries that may have a similar regulatory framework to see if the
conclusions are similar.

Author Contributions: Data curation, D.K.D.; formal analysis, D.K.D., H.K. and C.K.; methodology, H.K. and
C.K. All authors have read and agree to the published version of the manuscript.
Funding: This research received no external funding.
Conflicts of Interest: The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References
Aktas, Nihat, Eric de Bodt, and Richard Roll. 2013. Learning from repetitive acquisitions: Evidence from the time
between deals. Journal of Financial Economics 108: 99–117. [CrossRef]
Aktas, Nihat, Eric De Bodt, Hellen Bollaert, and Richard Roll. 2016. CEO narcissism and the takeover process:
From private initiation to deal completion. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 51: 113–37. [CrossRef]
Bagwell, Laurie Simon. 1991. Share repurchase and takeover deterrence. Rand Journal of Economics 22: 72–88.
[CrossRef]
Bagwell, Laurie Simon, and John B. Shoven. 1988. Share repurchase and acquisitions: An analysis of which firms
participate. In Corporate Takeovers: Causes and Consequences. Edited by A. J. Auerbach. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.
Bayat, Ali, Reza Salehnejad, and Peter Kawalek. 2016. Does CEO’s Holding of Vested Options Measure Overconfidence?
Working Paper. Manchester: Alliance Manchester Business School.
Ben-David, Itzhak, John R. Graham, and Campbell R. Harvey. 2007. Managerial Overconfidence and Corporate Policies
No. w13711. Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Billett, Matthew T., and Yiming Qian. 2008. Are overconfident CEOs born or made? Evidence of self-attribution
bias from frequent acquirers. Management Science 54: 1037–51. [CrossRef]
Bonaimé, Alice A. 2012. Repurchases, reputation and returns. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis
47: 469–91. [CrossRef]
Busch, Pascal, and Stefan Obernberger. 2017. Actual share repurchases, price efficiency, and the information
content of stock prices. The Review of Financial Studies 30: 324–32. [CrossRef]
Cai, Jie, Moon H. Song, and Ralph A. Walkling. 2011. Anticipation, acquisitions, and bidder returns: Industry
shocks and the transfer of information across rivals. Review of Financial Studies 24: 2242–85. [CrossRef]
Campbell, T. Colin, Michael Gallmeyer, Shane A. Johnson, Jessica Rutherford, and Brooke W. Stanley. 2011.
CEO optimism and forced turnover. Journal of Financial Economics 101: 695–712. [CrossRef]
Chang, Shao-Chi, Sheng-Syan Chen, and Li-Yu Chen. 2010. Does prior record matter in the wealth effect of
open market share repurchase announcements? International Review of Economics and Finance 19: 427–35.
[CrossRef]
Chatterjee, Arijit, and Donald C. Hambrick. 2007. It’s all about me: Narcissistic chief executive officers and their
effects on company strategy and performance. Administrative Science Quarterly 52: 351–86. [CrossRef]
Chen, Chao C., and James R. Meindl. 1991. The construction of leadership images in the popular press: The case
of Donald Burr and People Express. Administrative Science Quarterly 36: 521–55. [CrossRef]
De Ridder, Adri, and Jonas Rasbrandt. 2014. Share repurchases: Does frequency matter? Studies in Economics and
Finance 31: 88–105. [CrossRef]
Dittmar, Amy. K. 2000. Why do firms repurchase stock? Journal of Business 73: 331–55. [CrossRef]
Fenn, George W., and Nellie Liang. 2001. Corporate payout policy and managerial stock incentives. Journal of
Financial Economics 60: 1–44. [CrossRef]
Finkelstein, Sydney. 1992. Power in top management teams: Dimensions, measurement and validation. Academy of
Management Journal 3: 505–38.
Fu, Fangjian, and Sheng Huang. 2016. The persistence of long-run abnormal reruns following stock repurchases
and offerings. Management Science 62: 964–84. [CrossRef]
Hayward, Matthew L. A., and Donald C. Hambrick. 1997. Explaining the premiums paid for large acquisitions:
Evidence of CEO hubris. Administrative Science Quarterly 42: 103–27. [CrossRef]

246
JRFM 2020, 13, 176

Howe, Keith M., Jia He, and G. Wenchi Kao. 1992. One-Time Cash Flow Announcements and Free Cash-Flow
Theory: Share Repurchases and Special Dividends. Journal of Finance 47: 1963–75. [CrossRef]
Ikenberry, David, Josef Lakonishok, and Theo Vermaelen. 1995. Market underreaction to open market share
repurchases. Journal of Financial Economics 39: 181–208. [CrossRef]
Jagannathan, Murali, and Clifford P. Stephens. 2003. Motives for multiple open market repurchase programs.
Financial Management 32: 71–91. [CrossRef]
Jensen, Michael C. 1986. Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance and takeover. American Economic Review
76: 323–29.
Kahle, Kathleen M. 2002. When a buyback isn’t a buyback: Open market repurchases and employee options.
Journal of Financial Economics 63: 235–61. [CrossRef]
Karolyi, G. Andrew, Rose C. Liao, and Gilberto Loureiro. 2015. The Decreasing Returns of Serial Acquirers
around the World. Working Paper. Ithaca: Cornell University, New Brunswick: Rutgers University, Braga:
University of Minho.
Kim, Jeong-Bon, Zheng Wang, and Liandong Zhang. 2016. CEO overconfidence and stock price crash risk.
Contemporary Accounting Research 33: 1720–49. [CrossRef]
Lakonishok, Josef, and Theo Vermaelen. 1990. Anomalous price behavior around repurchase tender offers.
Journal of Finance 45: 455–77. [CrossRef]
Lehn, Kenneth, and Annette Poulsen. 1989. Free Cash Flow and Stockholder Gains in Going Private Transactions.
Journal of Finance 44: 771–87. [CrossRef]
Liu, Harrison, and Edward P. Swanson. 2016. Is price support a motive for increasing share repurchases? Journal of
Corporate Finance 38: 77–91. [CrossRef]
Malmendier, Ulrike, and Geoffrey Tate. 2005. CEO overconfidence and corporate investment. Journal of Finance
60: 2661–700. [CrossRef]
Malmendier, Ulrike, and Geoffrey Tate. 2008. Who makes acquisitions? CEO overconfidence and the market’s
reaction. Journal of Financial Economics 89: 20–43. [CrossRef]
Malmendier, Ulrike, and Geoffrey Tate. 2015. Behavioral CEOs: The role of managerial overconfidence. Journal of
Economic Perspectives 29: 37–60. [CrossRef]
Manfred, F. R., Kets de Vries, and Danny Miller. 1984. Neurotic style and organizational pathology. Strategic
Management Journal 5: 35–55.
Meindl, James R., Sanford B. Ehrlich, and Janet M. Dukerich. 1985. The romance of leadership. Administrative
Science Ouarterly 30: 78–102. [CrossRef]
Miller, Danny, and Cornelia Droge. 1986. Psychological and traditional determinants of structure. Administrative
Science Quarterly 31: 539–60. [CrossRef]
Mishra, Dev, Marie D. Racine, and Luke Schmidt. 2011. Credibility of Corporate Announcements and Market
Reaction: Evidence from Canadian Share Repurchase Programs. Canadian Journal of Administrative Sciences
28: 83–100. [CrossRef]
Peyer, Urs, and Theo Vermaelen. 2009. The Nature and Persistence of Buyback Anomalies. Review of Financial
Studies 22: 1693–745. [CrossRef]
Roll, Richard. 1986. The hubris hypothesis of corporate takeovers. Journal of Business 59: 197–216. [CrossRef]
Salancik, Gerald R., and James R. Meindl. 1984. Corporate attributions as strategic illusions of management
control. Administrative Science Quarterly 29: 238–54. [CrossRef]
Skinner, Douglas J. 2008. The evolving relation between earnings, dividends, and stock repurchases. Journal of
Financial Economics 87: 582–609. [CrossRef]
Snyder, C. R., Randee Jae Shenkel, and Carol R. Lowery. 1977. Acceptance of personality interpretations:
The “Barnum effect” and beyond. Journal of Consulting and Clinical Psychology 45: 104–14. [CrossRef]
Song, Moon H., and Ralph A. Walkling. 2000. Abnormal Returns to Rivals of Acquisition Targets: A Test of the
“Acquisition Probability Hypothesis”. Journal of Financial Economics 55: 143–72. [CrossRef]
Stephens, Clifford P., and Michael S. Weisbach. 1998. Actual share reacquisition in open market repurchase
programs. Journal of Finance 53: 313–33. [CrossRef]
Swann, William B., and Stephen J. Read. 1981. Acquiring self-knowledge: The search for feedback that fits.
Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 41: 1119–28. [CrossRef]
Taylor, Shelley E., and Peter M. Gollwitzer. 1995. Effects of mindset on positive illusions. Journal of Personality and
Social Psychology 69: 213–26. [CrossRef] [PubMed]

247
JRFM 2020, 13, 176

Vermaelen, Theo. 1981. Common stock repurchases and market signaling. Journal of Financial Economics 9: 139–83.
[CrossRef]
Yook, Ken C., and Partha Gangopadhyay. 2011. A comprehensive examination of the wealth effects of recent stock
repurchase announcements. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting 37: 509–29. [CrossRef]

© 2020 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access
article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution
(CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).

248
Journal of
Risk and Financial
Management

Article
Innovation in SMEs and Financing Mix
Joanna Błach *, Monika Wieczorek-Kosmala and Joanna Trz˛esiok
College of Finance, University of Economics in Katowice, ul. 1 Maja 50, 40-287 Katowice, Poland;
m.wieczorek-kosmala@ue.katowice.pl (M.W.-K.); joanna.trzesiok@ue.katowice.pl (J.T.)
* Correspondence: jblach@ue.katowice.pl

Received: 12 August 2020; Accepted: 8 September 2020; Published: 10 September 2020

Abstract: This study addresses the types of innovation activity of SMEs (Small and medium-sized
enterprises) in the European Union and its association with financing decisions. The main objective
is to capture the cross-country differences in the types of innovation in SMEs and then investigate
the relationship between the types of innovations and relevance of a given type of funding. In the
empirical examinations, we use the non-parametric methods, due to the nature of the data. We have
found out that there are differences in the types of innovation activity of SMEs in the cross-country
dimension. We have also confirmed the contingencies between the types of innovations undertaken
by SMEs in each cluster of the European countries, which suggests that various types of innovations
co-exist. However, we have not found any unified pattern of correlations between the relevance of
a given source of financing and a given type of innovation. Our study contributes to the ongoing
debate on the different intensity of innovation activity of SMEs, as linked to the problem of the SMEs
financing gap as one of the fundamental drivers of innovation.

Keywords: SMEs financing; financing gap; innovative activity; innovation; capital structure decisions

1. Introduction
Small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) are regarded as the dominant vector of economic
progress, as their successful activity determines regional and country development, creates new jobs,
supports market competition, and enhances innovation (Beck et al. 2005; Kersten et al. 2017; Savlovschi
and Robu 2011). High flexibility and entrepreneurial spirit are the key attributes of SMEs (Thurik and
Wennekers 2004). Thus, SMEs remain the crucial players in the knowledge-based economy, as they can
respond flexibly to new opportunities, diversify their activities, and create new products, processes,
and organization forms. Innovative activity of SMEs results in multiple applications, and their gains
may be shared through knowledge and information spill-overs with other firms (Organisation for
Economic Co-operation and Development, OECD 2013). In this respect, SMEs are regarded as the
main driving force of innovation.
However, SMEs are quite heterogeneous (e.g., sector, size, age, profitability) and they operate in
different business environments (e.g., macroeconomic factors, institutional system, financial market,
banking sector). Thus, the level of their innovative activity may vary across countries, which was
confirmed in prior research (e.g., Pełka 2018).
It is empirically confirmed that innovation activity of SMEs is limited by the accessibility of
sufficient funds (Goujard and Guérin 2018; Hall 2010). In this respect, this study contributes to the
ongoing debate on SMEs financing decisions and the existence of financing (capital) gap (Angilella
and Mazzù 2015; De Moor et al. 2016; Hottenrott and Peters 2012). However, the existing body of
the literature in this field remains focused on the public support for innovative SMEs, as it has been
confirmed that firms may face difficulties in finding external market-based finance for intangible
(knowledge-based) assets (Lee et al. 2015; Vasilescu 2014). Numerous studies have also examined the
relevance of venture capital funding and recently—crowdfunding, in the context of innovative SMEs

JRFM 2020, 13, 206; doi:10.3390/jrfm13090206 249 www.mdpi.com/journal/jrfm


JRFM 2020, 13, 206

(Anwar 2018; Baldock and Mason 2015; Kijkasiwat and Phuensane 2020; Schenk 2015). The relevance
of debt finance and internal funding (determined by the efficient performance) in enhancing innovation
in SMEs remains relatively less explored (Kerr and Nanda 2015; Sau 2007).
Facing this research gap, the main objective of this study is to capture the cross-country differences
in the innovation activity of European SMEs and then to investigate the relationship between the types
of innovation and relevance of a given type of funding. In this respect, there are two main contributions
of our study to the existing body of the literature. First, it contributes to the debate on the cross-country
differences in SMEs innovation activity. Second, it contributes to the debate on the SMEs’ financing
gap as one of the fundamental drivers of their innovative activity.
In the empirical examinations, this study relies on the data provided in the Survey of Access to
Finance of Enterprises (SAFE) reports (SAFE 2018). SAFE regularly analyzes numerous aspects of the
European SMEs performance and thus enables to study the differences and similarities in the firms’
behaviors. In this study, we use the data that reflect the types of SMEs innovation (within product,
market, process, and sales) and the relevance of various types of financing to detect the similarities and
the differences of SMEs performing in different European countries.
The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. In the second section, we briefly review
the related literature to highlight the conceptual framework of the study. In the third section, we
explain the research design and methodology. The fourth section presents and discusses the results of
empirical investigations. In the final section, we conclude.

2. Literature Review
In the conceptual dimension, this study is merging two streams of literature: innovation activity
of SMEs and financial management. The first part derives from the premises of the innovation theory
formulated originally by J. Schumpeter, developed further by numerous researchers in the field. Within
the second part, the study refers primarily to the discussion on SMEs financing decisions and the
persistence of the phenomenon known as financing (capital) gap.

2.1. SMEs and Innovations


In the 1930s, J. Schumpeter defined innovation as the introduction of new or qualitative change
in existing products, processes, markets, sources of supply of inputs, and organizations. Innovation
encompasses a creative activity, the element of novelty, as well as the disruptive change and is often
described as a complex, multi-actor process, determined by numerous factors (Assink 2006; Boer and
During 2001).
In economic literature, various classifications of innovation have been applied. However, the most
common approach is based on the OECD methodology and distinguishes between product, process,
organization, and market innovation (Oslo 2018).
Product innovation is defined as any goods, service, or idea that is perceived by its users as new.
Process innovation includes the adaptation of existing production lines and the installation of entirely
new infrastructure and the implementation of new technologies. Any changes in marketing, purchases
and sales, administration, management, and staff policy are classified as organization innovation. In
addition, market innovation encompasses the exploitation of new territorial markets or the penetration
of new market segments in the existing markets. This approach is widely applied e.g., in the studies by:
(Baregheh et al. 2012; Boer and During 2001; Tavassoli and Karlsson 2015 or Varis and Littunen 2010).
J. Schumpeter discussed the importance of SMEs in the context of the innovation process in one of
his pioneer works (Schumpeter Mark 1 presented in Schumpeter 1934). He insisted that new, small,
entrepreneurial firms are likely to be the source of most innovations, searching creatively for the new
market opportunities. However, later, he focused on capital market imperfections and claimed that
large, mature firms have better access to finance and extensive resources required for R&D projects.
Thus, he proposed subsequently that small firms tend rather to imitate than to innovate themselves due
to high costs of R&D activity (Schumpeter Mark 2 presented in Schumpeter 1942). Both hypotheses

250
JRFM 2020, 13, 206

formulated by Schumpeter were tested in numerous studies, for various sectors and economies with
contradictory results (Freel 2007; Santarelli and Sterlacchini 1990; Van Dijk et al. 1997; Vaona and Pianta
2008). Recent studies, however, point out that small firms are quite heterogeneous, ranging from highly
innovative firms to traditional ones for which the innovation process is irrelevant. As a consequence,
the main determinants of innovation in SMEs are proposed to be: sector belonging, the particular
nature of innovation and the characteristics of the firm itself, such as size and age (Avermaete et al.
2003; Bhattacharya and Bloch 2004; Ortega-Argilés et al. 2009). Another stream of studies examined
the effects of innovation on firm performance (Anwar 2018; Kijkasiwat and Phuensane 2020; Wolff and
Pett 2006). Most of the works focus on innovative activity in particular countries (e.g., Hall et al. 2009;
Lecerf and Omrani 2019 in Germany; Oke et al. 2007 in the UK; Varis and Littunen 2010 in Finland).
However, in this stream of literature, the cross-country studies are relatively rare. Skuras et al. (2008)
analyzed product innovation in SMEs from six European countries, while Anwar (2018) identified
four clusters of European countries based on the level of intensity of innovative activity. Facing this
gap, this study remains focused on the cross-country analysis, by referring to four types of innovation:
product, process, management, and sales (organization). In this context, the study aims at answering
the first research question:

RQ1: Are there any contingencies between the types of innovations undertaken by SMEs in
the cross-country dimension?

2.2. SMEs and Financing Gap


Another stream of studies focused on the barriers to innovation, which may be analyzed with
regard to: the stages of the innovation process (such as: knowledge, invention, implementation,
diffusion, and adaptation), the levels of innovation (microeconomic and macroeconomic barriers),
and the nature of factors (financial, personal and organizational, socio-cultural, and legal factors).
The variety of barriers to innovation were recently discussed in (Assink 2006; Hueske and Guenther
2015; Madeira et al. 2017). In particular, the access to external financing and the existence of capital
constraints that may negatively affect the firms’ innovative activity was underlined by Angilella and
Mazzù (2015); Colombo and Grilli (2007). Accordingly, the existing empirical evidence shows that the
key determinant of the SMEs development is access to sufficient funds. As proved by Kersten et al.
(2017), SMEs finance has a positive significant impact on firm performance, capital investment, and
employment. However, SMEs often face various problems while searching for new sources of funds.
Kumar and Rao (2015) identified the main problems of insufficient funds for SMEs: (1) demand gap,
due to the effect of various capital structure determinants, (2) supply gap (limited availability of funds
for SMEs), (3) knowledge gap (lack of knowledge on the accessibility of funds, and (4) benevolence gap
(unwillingness of financial institutions to provide funds to SMEs). Various financing patterns of SMEs
addressing the problem of financing gap were identified and analyzed by Moritz et al. (2016); Ou and
Haynes (2006); Whittam and Wyper (2007). Some studies refered exclusively to the debt financing
gap (Colombo and Grilli 2007; De Moor et al. 2016; Neely and Auken 2012), while others focused
on the equity financing gap (Deffains-Crapsky and Sudolska 2014; Durvy 2007; Papadimitriou and
Mourdoukoutas 2002).
Capital structure decisions have been the focus of research attention since the seminal works of
Modigliani and Miller (1958). The main theoretical explanation for the capital structure determinants
was provided by the pecking order theory (POT). As suggested by Donaldson (1961) and further
developed by Myers and Majluf (1984), the observed capital structures reflect the relationship between
internally available funds and investment requirements. The POT suggests that companies have
a hierarchy of preferences concerning sources of funds. That is the consequence of asymmetric
information between management and potential capital providers. This issue may cause firms to
avoid raising external equity by issuing new shares. At the same time, while the access to debt may be
limited, firms may be forced to postpone or to cancel valuable investment opportunities, including
innovative ones. In these circumstances, firms prefer internal finance; they try to avoid new equity

251
JRFM 2020, 13, 206

issues, and their borrowings are a residual between desired investment and the supply of retained
earnings. Colombo and Grilli (2007) explained the modified pecking order financing for innovative
firms, including private equity financing (from Angel investors and Private Equity/Venture Capital
funds) before debt capital. The importance of venture capital for innovative firms is widely discussed
in the literature (Da Rin and Penas 2007; Wadhwa et al. 2016; Wu et al. 2019).
Our study, however, addresses the relevance of internal finance, external equity, and debt financing
for SMEs, which is consistent with the modified or ‘bridged pecking order theory’ (BPOT). The BPOT
assumes that SMEs move directly from self-funding (internal equity) to external equity (provided by
private equity investors) in preference to, or instead of bank finance, as suggested by Whittam and
Wyper (2007). The importance of internal finance as the primary source of funds for smaller firms is
discussed by Ou and Haynes (2006), who declared that the significance of external equity for SMEs
seems to be overstated. Therefore, based on the BPOT findings and the financing gap facing by SMEs,
we may assume that the SMEs’ innovative activity is financed first with the internal finance. As a result,
the types of innovations undertaken by SMEs may be limited due to the external capital constraints
(both in terms of debt and external equity). In this respect, the second question addressed in this study
is as follows:

RQ2: Is there any association between the type of innovations in SMEs and the relevance of
a given type of financing?

3. Materials and Methods


Driven by the relevance of innovation activity of SMEs and the literature evidence on the existence
of SMEs financing gap, this study is designed to shed some light on types of innovations of SMEs
that perform in the European Union and its relationship with the relevance of a given type of fund.
The differences in the implementation of given types of innovation are captured on the cross-country
level (RQ1). Further, we investigate the relationships between the types of innovation and the relevance
of internal funds, external equity, and debt finance (RQ2).
In the empirical investigations, we rely on the data provided on a regular basis as SAFE (Survey
of Access to Finance of Enterprises) reports by the European Commission and European Central Bank.
The SAFE dataset consists of aggregated survey results obtained for each of the European Union (EU)
member states. In this study, we have focused on SAFE results obtained for five consecutive years
in a 5-year time span (2014–2018). Since 2013, the results of the SAFE survey are published annually,
but since 2014 in a unified format that allows time comparisons. At the moment of the research
investigation, the latest results were available for 2018. The SAFE survey sample includes randomly
selected SMEs from each EU member state, from various sectors and of various size (micro, small, and
medium-sized enterprises). In 2018, there were over 17,000 survey respondents (SAFE 2018).
For this study, we cluster the EU members states to construct the research sample. First, we
grouped the countries following the prevailing classification scheme by distinguishing between the
“old” and “new” EU members states, as explained in Table 1. This distinction is guided by the fact
that “old” EU member states have a long history of performance as a union and are regarded as better
developed, in comparison to the new member states. On the other hand, the “new” member states (in
this, the SMEs sector in these countries) have benefited from numerous programs that were aimed at
enhancing the removal of disparities (before and shortly after the EU accession).

252
JRFM 2020, 13, 206

Table 1. The clusters of the examined European Union (EU) member states.

Clusters Sub-Clusters
Countries Reasoning
1st Demarcation 2nd Demarcation
Belgium
France
Germany Founders of the EU
INNER_C
Italy and UK as the largest
OLD_EU (inner core)
Luxembourg net contributor
The Netherlands
UK
Austria
Denmark
Finland
OUTER_C Greece The remainder ‘old’
(outer core) Ireland EU member states
Portugal
Spain
Sweden
Cyprus
Estonia
Latvia ‘New’ EU member states
INNER_P
Lithuania (since 2004 or later),
NEW_EU (inner peripheral)
Malta in the Eurozone
Slovakia
Slovenia
Bulgaria
Croatia
‘New’ EU member states
OUTER_P Czech Republic
(since 2004 or later),
(outer peripheral) Hungary
outside the Eurozone
Poland
Romania

Secondly, guided by the studies of Bartlett and Prica (2017) and Bruha and Kocenda (2018), we
clustered the EU countries into four groups that consider the existence of core and peripheral EU
member states. In particular, consistently with Bartlett and Prica (2017), in the cluster of “old” and
“new” EU countries, we further distinguished between the inner core, outer core, inner peripheral,
and outer peripheral countries. In the cluster of the “old” EU member states, we identified 7 “inner
core” countries: the founders of the EU and the UK, as one of the largest net contributors to the EU
budget (Kovacevic 2019). In the cluster of the “new” EU countries, we identified 7 “inner peripheral”
countries: the members of Eurozone (see the reasoning explained in Table 1). The adopted scheme of
clustering the EU countries is justified by the results of prior works related to innovation activity and
capital-structure related issues. The Anwar (2018) study confirmed that the majority of the old EU
countries are typically innovation leaders, whereas the post-communist countries (that are a majority
in outer and inner peripheral EU countries) are low-moderate innovators. Anwar (2018) also addressed
the types of innovations (product and process), including SMEs. The K˛edzior (2012) study confirmed
that there are significant differences in capital structure-related issues between the old and new EU
member states.
The list of the examined variables is provided in Table 2. However, it is substantial to explain
the methodology behind the SAFE survey and the presentation of its results, as it remains relevant
for the design of the empirical investigations performed in this study. The SAFE database presents
the percentage structure of SMEs (the respondents) answers for a given question. Moreover, the
percentage structure of answers remains aggregated on country level (in other words—it is provided
separately for each of the EU member states). In our empirical investigations, we merge two aspects
(problems) that were subject to the SAFE study: innovation and sources of funds in SMEs. Within

253
JRFM 2020, 13, 206

the first aspect (innovation), the survey incorporates the set of questions that refer to four areas of
improvements implemented by firms in the past year. In this respect, we are able to identify the
percentage of companies which declared the implementation of product, process, management, and
sales innovations, as explained in Table 2. The second aspect (financing mix) refers to the relevance of
a given source of funds. The SAFE survey provides information on the percentage of respondents
(SMEs) who declared that a given source of funds was relevant in their activity in the past six months.
In this respect, in statistical examinations, we refer to the percentage of firms (SMEs) which declared
the relevance of internal funding, external equity, and debt financing, as explained in Table 2.
In the empirical investigations, we use the non-parametric methods, due to the nature of the
available data. In particular, to examine the differences on country-level (in accordance with the
defined clusters), the non-parametric ANOVA is used (Kruskal–Wallis test). The relationships of SMEs
innovation and the use of particular sources of funds are captured by the Rho–Spearman correlations.

Table 2. The definitions of the examined variables.

Variable Definition
Types of SMEs innovation
The percentage of companies which declared that they introduced
Product
significant improvements in products or services within the past year.
The percentage of companies which declared that they introduced
Process significant improvements of production process or methods within the
past year.
The percentage of companies which declared that they introduced a new
Management
organization of management within the past year.
The percentage of companies which declared that they introduced a new
Sales
way of selling goods or services.
Relevance of SMEs financing
The percentage of surveyed companies which declared the relevance of
INTERNAL FINANCING internal sources of financing (retained earnings and sales of assets were
used over the past 6 months or are considered to be used in the future).
The percentage of surveyed companies which declared the relevance of
EXTERNAL EQUITY external sources of equity (equity capital was used over the past 6 months
or is considered to be used in the future).
The percentage of surveyed companies which declared the relevance of
DEBT debt (debt was used over the past 6 months or is considered to be used in
the future).

4. Results and Discussion

4.1. SMEs Innovations across the EU


In Appendix A, we present the figures with data on the percentage share of SMEs, which
declared the implementation of a given type of innovation between 2014 and 2018 (product, process,
management, or sales), in accordance with the assumed clusters of the EU member states. The data
indicate that in the case of the implementation of product, process, and sales innovations, the situation
could be judged as comparable. The percentage of SMEs which declared the implementation of
product, process, and sales innovations was slightly lower in inner core EU countries, in comparison to
the remaining core countries. In the group of the old EU countries, Finland is clearly in the leading
position. Moreover, in the cluster of the old EU countries in the majority of the countries, peak levels of
product and process innovations were observable until 2017, with a visible drop in 2018. A similar
pattern of changes was observable in the cluster of new EU countries (2014–2017), however with a slight
improvement in 2018. In the inner peripheral countries, the lowest percentage of SMEs that declared

254
JRFM 2020, 13, 206

the implementation of the product, or process innovations was in Estonia, whereas in the cluster of
outer peripheral countries—in Hungary. In the remaining new EU countries, the percentage of SMEs
that declared the implementation of product or process innovations could be judged as comparable,
with the most dynamic changes in Cyprus, Latvia, and Malta (only for process innovations). Similar
conclusions could be drawn concerning sales innovations, with a leading position in Cyprus and
Romania. Cyprus and Romania are also leading in the implementation of management innovations
(Figure A3). However, in the case of old EU countries, the situation is different as compared to product,
process, and sales innovations. First, a slightly higher percentage of innovative SMEs operating in
the cluster of inner core EU countries is observable, as compared to the outer core ones. In the old
EU countries, Greece was in a leading position in the implementation of management innovations,
as declared by SMEs. The data also indicate that in the majority of countries, the declared level of
management innovations remained unchanged between 2017 and 2018.
The initial observations on the overall trends and differences between the declared level of the
implementation of innovation in European SMEs (Appendix A) justify the examination of the statistical
relevance of these differences, within the defined clusters of countries and consistently with the
first research question (RQ1). In Table 3, we present the results of non-parametric tests that have
confirmed that there are statistically significant differences between the defined clusters of countries,
concerning the percentage of SMEs that declared the implementation of the product, management,
and sales innovation, but not the process innovations. Within the comparisons between new and old
EU countries, the mean ranks of the U Mann–Whitney test (Figure 1) indicate that in the cluster of new
EU countries, a higher percentage of SMEs declared the implementation of product innovations, as
compared to the old EU countries. However, we observe a contrary situation in the case of management
and sales innovations. The percentage of SMEs, which declared the implementation of management
and sales innovations was significantly higher in the old EU countries, as compared to the new ones.

Eth K>h
K>h
ϴϲ͘ϵϯ K>h Eth ϴϳ͘ϱϰ
K>h ϳϰ͘Ϭϳ Eth ϳϳ͘ϭϭ Eth
ϲϳ͘ϰϭ ϲϮ͘ϴϴ
ϱϲ͘Ϯϲ ϱϬ͘ϴϰ

WZKhdΎΎ WZK^^ DE'DEdΎΎ ^>^ΎΎ



Figure 1. Mean ranks of U Mann–Whitney test for differences in the declared implementation of
innovation between the clusters of old and new EU member states. Notes: statistically significant
differences at ** α = 0.05.

The Kruskal–Wallis test indicates the overall differences between the four clusters of EU countries.
Thus, to detects which specific groups of countries differ significantly, the post hoc tests were performed
(see Table 3). In the case of product innovations, the post hoc tests have confirmed that there are
statistically significant differences between the inner core EU countries, as compared to the remainder
clusters. The analysis of mean ranks of the Kruskal–Wallis test, illustrated in Figure 2 indicates that
the percentage of SMEs that declared the implementation of product innovation was significantly
lower in inner core countries, as compared to the remainder clusters. In the case of management
innovation, statistically significant differences were observed in several dimensions. First of all, the
post hoc tests and the ranks of the Kruskal–Wallis test indicate that the percentage of SMEs which
declared the implementation of management innovation was significantly higher in the cluster of

255
JRFM 2020, 13, 206

outer core EU countries, in comparison to the clusters of the outer and inner peripheral. Moreover, the
percentage of SMEs which declared the implementation of innovation in management was significantly
higher in the cluster of inner core countries, in comparison to the clusters of inner and outer peripheral
(Figure 2). Finally, in the case of sales innovation, the statistically significant differences were confirmed
only between the cluster of the outer core EU countries and the cluster of outer peripheral countries
(significantly higher percentage of SMEs declared the implementation of innovations in sales in the
cluster of the outer core, as compared to the cluster of outer peripheral EU countries).

Table 3. The differences between the clusters of countries concerning innovation in SMEs.

Data Type of Innovations


Product Process Manag. Sales
Clusters—1st demarcation (old/new EU)
p-value
0.000 ** 0.332 0.000 ** 0.038 **
U Mann–Whitney test
Sub-clusters—2nd demarcation (IC/OC/IP/OP)
p-value
0.000 ** 0.186 0.000 ** 0.002 **
H Kruskal–Wallis test
IC/IP 0.000 ** 0.012 ** 1.000
IC/OP 0.000 ** 0.001 ** 1.000
Post-hoc tests IC/OC 0.004 ** 1.000 0.610
pairwise comparisons OC/IP 0.182 0.001 ** 0.475
OC/OP 1.000 0.000 ** 0.001 **
OP/IP 1.000 1.000 0.318
Notes: statistically significant at ** α = 0.05; symbols: IC—inner core, OC—outer core, IP—inner peripheral,
OP—outer peripheral.
KƵƚĞƌWĞƌŝƉŚ ϴϭ͘ϲϬ

KƵƚĞƌWĞƌŝƉŚ ϲϯ͘ϱϴ

KƵƚĞƌWĞƌŝƉŚ ϰϱ͘ϴϯ

KƵƚĞƌWĞƌŝƉŚ ϱϮ͘ϯϳ
/ŶŶĞƌWĞƌŝƉŚ ϵϭ͘ϱϬ

/ŶŶĞƌWĞƌŝƉŚ ϴϯ͘Ϭϲ

/ŶŶĞƌWĞƌŝƉŚ ϱϱ͘ϭϯ

/ŶŶĞƌWĞƌŝƉŚ ϳϭ͘ϴϵ
KƵƚĞƌŽƌĞ ϳϭ͘ϭϴ

KƵƚĞƌŽƌĞ ϲϵ͘ϭϭ

KƵƚĞƌŽƌĞ ϴϵ͘ϲϲ

KƵƚĞƌŽƌĞ ϴϴ͘ϯϲ
/ŶŶĞƌŽƌĞ ϯϵ͘Ϯϭ

/ŶŶĞƌŽƌĞ ϲϱ͘ϰϲ

/ŶŶĞƌŽƌĞ ϴϱ͘ϭϭ

/ŶŶĞƌŽƌĞ ϲϰ͘Ϯϰ

WZKhdΎΎ WZK^^ DE'DEdΎΎ ^>^ΎΎ




Figure 2. Mean ranks of the Kruskal–Wallis test for differences in the declared implementation of
innovation between the sub-clusters of the EU countries. Notes: statistically significant differences at
** α = 0.05.

We additionally examined the possible co-existence between the types of innovations most
frequently undertaken by the SMEs. In Table 4, we present the Rho–Spearman correlation coefficients
to capture the associations between the percentage of the European SMEs, which declared the
implementation of various types of innovations, broken by the clusters of analyzed countries.

256
JRFM 2020, 13, 206

Table 4. Correlations between a percentages of the European SMEs which declared the implementation
of innovations.

Declared Types of Innovations


Product Process Management Sales
Old EU
Product 1
Process 0.676 ** 1
Management 0.077 0.282 * 1
Sales 0.653 ** 0.714 ** 0.356 ** 1
New EU
Product 1
Process 0.675 ** 1
Management 0.460 ** 0.529 ** 1
Sales 0.464 ** 0.455 ** 0.744 ** 1
Inner Core
Product 1
Process 0.432 ** 1
Management 0.206 0.744 ** 1
Sales 0.395 * 0.648 ** 0.425 * 1
Outer Core
Product 1
Process 0.839 ** 1
Management −0.033 −0.011 1
Sales 0.667 ** 0.773 ** 0.351 * 1
Inner Peripheral
Product 1
Process 0.616 ** 1
Management 0.363 * 0.323 1
Sales 0.310 0.100 0.628 ** 1
Outer Peripheral
Product 1
Process 0.761 ** 1
Management 0.579 ** 0.849 ** 1
Sales 0.609 ** 0.821 ** 0.887 ** 1
Notes: statistically significant at ** α = 0.01; * α = 0.05.

The data presented in Table 4 indicate that in general, in the cluster of the old EU countries,
there were statistically significant correlations between all types of innovations, except for product
and management. It suggests that the undertakings of various types of innovations co-existed in
the surveyed SMEs that perform in the old EU member states. This pattern of interdependencies is
repeated in the sub-clusters of inner and outer core countries. However, in the case of the cluster of
inner core countries, the correlation coefficients between product innovation and process and sales
innovations are visibly lower, as compared to the cluster of outer core countries. In the cluster of new
EU countries, there are statistically significant correlations between the implementation of all types
of innovations, and this pattern is also observable in the sub-cluster of outer peripheral countries,
with visibly higher correlation coefficients. In the case of inner peripheral countries, the statistically
significant correlations are observable only between the following pairs of innovations: process and
product, management and sales, as well as management and product. These observations clearly
indicate that the co-existence of the implementation of various innovations was higher in the cluster of
outer peripheral countries (for statistically significant correlation coefficients). That can be explained
by the ‘spiral of innovation’ phenomenon, which describes the relationship between different types
of innovations: one successful innovation (e.g., product innovation) begets the other (e.g., process

257
JRFM 2020, 13, 206

innovation). One type of innovation generates demand on the other, as well as it provides solutions
that can be used to create new developments.

4.2. Types of SMEs Innovations and Sources of Funds


The second aspect of the empirical investigations was concerned with the analysis of the
associations between the percentage of SMEs that declared the implementation of a given type of
innovation and the percentage of SMEs that declared the relevance of a given source of financing (RQ2).
In this respect, we may track the possible relevance of a given type of financing to the implementation
of innovations. In Table 5, we present the Rho–Spearman correlation matrix, broken by the analyzed
clusters of the EU countries.

Table 5. Correlations between declared type of innovation and relevance of a given source of funds.

Product Process Management Sales


Old EU
Internal 0.252 * 0.112 −0.277 * 0.019
External Equity 0.042 −0.072 −0.220 −0.055
Debt 0.200 0.451 ** 0.328 ** 0.464 **
New EU
Internal 0.194 0.255 * 0.216 0.184
External Equity 0.218 0.482 ** 0.261 * 0.241
Debt 0.396 ** 0.431 ** 0.458 ** 0.363 **
Inner Core
Internal 0.321 0.220 0.185 0.139
External Equity −0.148 −0.016 −0.080 0.081
Debt −0.145 0.364 * 0.373 * 0.290
Outer Core
Internal 0.205 0.046 −0.591 ** 0.205
External Equity −0.023 −0.120 −0.314 * −0.023
Debt 0.462 ** 0.511 ** 0.304 0.462 **
Inner Peripheral
Internal 0.257 0.156 0.097 0.238
External Equity 0.150 0.366 * 0.078 0.027
Debt 0.331 0.326 0.551 ** 0.526 **
Outer Peripheral
Internal 0.057 0.338 0.339 0.100
External Equity 0.219 0.573 ** 0.534 ** 0.417 *
Debt 0.465 ** 0.518 ** 0.212 0.152
Notes: statistically significant at ** α = 0.01; * α = 0.05.

In the cluster of the old EU countries, there are statistically significant correlations between the
percentage of SMEs that declared the implementation of process, management, and sales innovations
and the relevance of debt financing. It suggests that debt finance remains a prime source of funds
for these types of innovations in the SMEs performing in the old EU countries. However, if we
consider the sub-clusters of the old EU countries (inner and outer core countries), the statistically
significant correlations were observed only in the case of debt financing and management and process
innovation (inner core), as well as between debt financing and the product, process, and sales innovation
(outer core).
In the cluster of new EU countries, the statistically significant correlations are observable
between debt financing and the implementation of all types of innovations. In addition, the
declaration on the relevance of external equity financing was correlated with the declarations on the
implementation of process and management innovations, while internal financing was correlated with
the process innovations.

258
JRFM 2020, 13, 206

In general, if we consider the correlations in the sub-clusters of new EU countries (inner and
outer peripheral), the statistically significant correlations were obtained only for debt financing and
management and sales innovations (inner peripheral), as well as for debt financing and product and
process innovations (outer peripheral). Interestingly, the relevance of equity financing was correlated
with the declaration on the implementation of process innovations (both in inner and outer peripheral)
as well as management and sales innovations (outer peripheral).
The obtained results clearly indicate that on the level of sub-clusters of the EU countries, there is
no unified pattern of correlations between the relevance of a given source of financing and a given type
of innovation. Nevertheless, debt financing seems to be a primary source of financing innovation in all
clusters of countries, and external equity remains relevant only in the case of new EU countries. This
may lead to the conclusion that different financing mechanisms were developed in different countries.
In some countries, the main source of finance for innovative SMEs comes from the banking sector, in
others—from the private equity capital providers. Possibly, our observations are related to the financial
support and arrangements offered within the equity-related programs directed to SMEs operating in
the new European member states.

5. Conclusions
This study was designed to capture the cross-country differences in the types of innovations
undertaken by European SMEs (RQ1) and the relationship between the types of innovations and
relevance of given types of funding (RQ2). The empirical investigation has found out that there
are significant differences in SMEs innovations if we consider the product, management, and sales
innovations. However, the directions of these differences are heterogeneous. The larger scale of product
innovations was observed in the new EU member states, while the larger scale of management and sales
innovations was identified in the old EU member states. If we consider the sub-clusters of EU countries
(inner/outer core and inner/outer peripheral), a similar pattern was confirmed. The SMEs from the
inner core of the old EU member states are significantly least involved in the product innovations,
at the same time, the SMEs form the inner core and outer core EU countries are the leaders in the
management innovations. Simultaneously, the SMEs from outer and inner peripheral countries are
less involved in management innovations.
This evidence suggests that the types of innovations undertaken by the SMEs may be linked to the
general level of economic development and innovative activity in particular countries. The SMEs from
the new member states try to catch up with SMEs from countries with a higher level of development,
focusing on product innovations. On the other hand, more developed economies create a favorable
environment for further improvements beyond product innovations. The importance of the regional
factors in the innovation process was underlined by Varis and Littunen (2010). In addition, the different
scale of innovative activity in different European countries was noticed by Anwar (2018). In this respect,
further inquiries should be placed to detect the drivers of SMEs innovativeness, on the cross-country
level. In particular, the relevance of dynamic development of IT technology shall be addressed, in this,
the open access to knowledge and the increasing popularity of the open innovation concept.
This study has also confirmed the contingencies between the types of innovations undertaken by
SMEs in each cluster of the European countries. These contingencies are most visible in the case of the
cluster of the old EU countries, as well as in the outer peripheral cluster. It was found that various
types of investment are accompanying undertaken innovations, thus various types of innovations
co-exist, although they require different inputs and strategies as suggested by Vaona and Pianta (2008)
and are characterized by different degrees of persistency as noticed by Tavassoli and Karlsson (2015).
That relationship is explained by ‘the spiral of innovation’ phenomenon, according to which, one
successful innovation provides the opportunity to create another one.
The second aspect subject to this study and addressed in the second research question (RQ2—the
analysis of the associations between the type of innovation and a given type of financing) provided
mixed results. Although debt capital was identified as the prime source of financing innovations in

259
JRFM 2020, 13, 206

several sub-clusters of countries, there is no unified pattern of correlations between the relevance of
a given source of financing and given type of innovation. These results are inconsistent with our
earlier assumption about the importance of internal finance, as suggested by the BPOT. They are also
in contrast to the earlier findings that innovative firms are more likely to be financed by equity than
debt (Hall 2010). On the other hand, Kerr and Nanda (2015) noticed the growing importance of debt
financing related to innovation. It suggests that different financing mechanisms were developed in
different countries to facilitate SMEs access to finance for innovative activity, which was addressed by
Moritz et al. (2016). However, further studies are needed to confirm this supposition. In particular,
further studies shall revise the relevance of debt financing, with reference to the domination of banking
sector in the financial system, which is typical in numerous European countries. On the other hand,
in the case of SMEs, the external equity comes mostly from the private equity market, of which
development is one of the priorities of the European Union strategy, focusing on the sustainable growth
and innovation.
The results of this study contribute to the ongoing debate on the SMEs financing gap, as linked
to their innovative activities (Hottenrott and Peters 2012; Lee et al. 2015; Vasilescu 2014). From an
applicative point of view, these results may support the design of system intervention mechanisms that
are implemented to reduce the existence of the SME financing gap. As the SMEs operating in various
countries remain focused on various types of innovations, the country settings seem to be relevant
for the directions of innovations undertaken by the SMEs. In finance-oriented contexts, the system
intervention mechanisms should be multivariate and allow flexible design of SMEs financing mix.
Moreover, it seems that the system interventions mechanisms should not pursue a defined financing
mix for the implementation of a given type of innovation. The core element of these mechanisms
should be based on the alternative market-based financing instruments, which are crucial for access to
the long-term sources of funds, as noted by Goujard and Guérin (2018).
The main limitation of this study is the nature of the SAFE survey data. Surveys data are always
exposed to the risk of bias. In this case, the conclusions are finally driven concerning the SMEs’
self-reported (and thus subjective) information. However, as the SAFE survey is repeated continuously
(the EU initiative), the risk of bias seems limited. Nevertheless, this study signals a need to perform
further investigations that could potentially enrich the evidence on innovative activity of SMEs and
financing (capital structure) considerations. In particular, by referring to other possible proxies of
innovation in SMEs, the direct associations with the existing SMEs capital structures could be addressed.
Such an approach, however, needs a detailed study related to balance sheet entries and annual reports.
Further inquiries shall also be placed to better explain the possible reasons behind the differences in
types of undertaken innovation in the country-oriented contexts.

Author Contributions: The contribution of co-authors is 40% for J.B.; 40% for M.W.-K.; and 20% for J.T.
Conceptualization J.B. and M.W.-K.; literature review section J.B.; results and discussion section; statistical
calculations M.W.-K. and J.T.; material and methods section M.W.-K.; writing and editing J.B. and M.W.-K. All
authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.
Funding: This research received no external funding.
Acknowledgments: We gratefully acknowledge the insightful comments provided by three anonymous Reviewers
of our paper.
Conflicts of Interest: The authors declare no conflict of interest.

260
JRFM 2020, 13, 206

Appendix A

WE>͘/EEZKZ ϮϬϭϰ ϮϬϭϱ ϮϬϭϲ ϮϬϭϳ ϮϬϭϴ

ϲϬй

ϯϵй

ϯϵй
ϯϴй
ϱϬй

ϯϳй
ϯϳй

ϯϳй
ϯϱй

ϯϰй
ϯϯй

ϯϮй
ϯϮй
ϯϭй

ϯϭй

ϯϬй
ϯϬй
Ϯϵй

Ϯϵй
Ϯϵй

Ϯϴй
Ϯϴй

Ϯϳй
ϰϬй
Ϯϳй

Ϯϳй
Ϯϳй
Ϯϳй
Ϯϲй

Ϯϲй

Ϯϲй
Ϯϱй
Ϯϰй

Ϯϰй
Ϯϯй
Ϯϯй

Ϯϭй
ϭϵй

ϯϬй
ϮϬй
ϭϬй
Ϭй
ĞůŐŝƵŵ &ƌĂŶĐĞ 'ĞƌŵĂŶLJ /ƚĂůLJ >ƵdžĞŵďŽƵƌŐ EĞƚŚĞƌůĂŶĚƐ hŶŝƚĞĚ
<ŝŶŐĚŽŵ

WE>͘KhdZKZ ϮϬϭϰ ϮϬϭϱ ϮϬϭϲ ϮϬϭϳ ϮϬϭϴ


ϱϮй
ϱϭй
ϱϭй
ϰϴй

ϲϬй

ϰϲй
ϰϮй
ϰϬй
ϰϬй

ϰϬй
ϱϬй
ϯϴй

ϯϳй
ϯϳй

ϯϲй
ϯϲй
ϯϲй

ϯϲй
ϯϱй

ϯϱй
ϯϰй
ϯϰй
ϯϰй

ϯϰй
ϯϯй
ϯϯй
ϯϮй
ϯϭй
ϯϭй

ϯϭй

ϯϭй
ϯϬй
ϯϬй
ϯϬй

ϯϬй
Ϯϵй
Ϯϴй

Ϯϴй
ϰϬй
Ϯϳй

Ϯϳй
Ϯϳй
Ϯϲй

ϯϬй
ϮϬй
ϭϬй
Ϭй
ͲϭϬй ƵƐƚƌŝĂ ĞŶŵĂƌŬ &ŝŶůĂŶĚ 'ƌĞĞĐĞ /ƌĞůĂŶĚ WŽƌƚƵŐĂů ^ƉĂŝŶ ^ǁĞĚĞŶ

WE>͘/EEZWZ/W,Z> ϮϬϭϰ ϮϬϭϱ ϮϬϭϲ ϮϬϭϳ ϮϬϭϴ

ϲϬй
ϰϵй

ϰϲй

ϰϱй
ϰϱй

ϰϱй
ϰϰй

ϰϯй
ϰϮй
ϰϮй
ϰϮй
ϰϮй
ϰϮй
ϰϭй

ϰϬй

ϰϬй

ϱϬй ϯϵй
ϯϵй
ϯϴй

ϯϴй
ϯϳй

ϯϳй
ϯϳй
ϯϱй
ϯϱй

ϯϱй
ϯϰй

ϯϯй

ϯϮй
ϯϮй

ϯϮй
ϯϮй

ϯϮй
Ϯϵй

ϰϬй
Ϯϳй

ϯϬй
ϭϴй

ϮϬй
ϭϬй
Ϭй
LJƉƌƵƐ ƐƚŽŶŝĂ >ĂƚǀŝĂ >ŝƚŚƵĂŶŝĂ DĂůƚĂ ^ůŽǀĂŬŝĂ ^ůŽǀĞŶŝĂ
ͲϭϬй

WE>͘KhdZWZ/W,Z> ϮϬϭϰ ϮϬϭϱ ϮϬϭϲ ϮϬϭϳ ϮϬϭϴ

ϲϬй
ϰϲй

ϰϱй

ϰϯй
ϰϮй

ϰϮй
ϰϬй
ϰϬй

ϰϬй

ϰϬй
ϰϬй

ϱϬй
ϯϳй

ϯϳй
ϯϳй
ϯϳй

ϯϲй
ϯϲй

ϯϱй
ϯϱй
ϯϱй

ϯϰй
ϯϰй

ϯϯй
ϯϯй

ϯϮй
ϯϮй

ϯϭй

ϰϬй
Ϯϵй
Ϯϳй
Ϯϲй
Ϯϰй

ϯϬй
ϮϬй
ϭϬй
Ϭй
ͲϭϬй ƵůŐĂƌŝĂ ƌŽĂƚŝĂ njĞĐŚZĞƉƵďůŝĐ ,ƵŶŐĂƌLJ WŽůĂŶĚ ZŽŵĂŶŝĂ

Figure A1. Percentage share of SMEs which declared the implementation of product innovations by
country. Source: Own study.

261
JRFM 2020, 13, 206

WE>͘/EEZKZ ϮϬϭϰ ϮϬϭϱ ϮϬϭϲ ϮϬϭϳ ϮϬϭϴ

ϱϬй

ϯϰй
ϯϯй
ϯϮй
ϯϭй
ϯϬй
ϰϬй

ϯϬй
Ϯϵй

Ϯϵй
Ϯϳй

Ϯϳй
Ϯϳй

Ϯϲй

Ϯϲй
Ϯϲй

Ϯϱй
Ϯϯй

ϮϮй
Ϯϭй

Ϯϭй

Ϯϭй
ϮϬй
ϮϬй
ϯϬй

ϮϬй

ϮϬй
ϭϵй
ϭϵй
ϭϵй

ϭϴй
ϭϴй
ϭϴй
ϭϴй
ϭϳй

ϭϳй

ϭϳй
ϭϲй
ϮϬй
ϭϬй
Ϭй
ĞůŐŝƵŵ &ƌĂŶĐĞ 'ĞƌŵĂŶLJ /ƚĂůLJ >ƵdžĞŵďŽƵƌŐ EĞƚŚĞƌůĂŶĚƐ hŶŝƚĞĚ
<ŝŶŐĚŽŵ

WE>͘KhdZKZ ϮϬϭϰ ϮϬϭϱ ϮϬϭϲ ϮϬϭϳ ϮϬϭϴ


ϰϱй
ϰϭй

ϱϬй
ϰϬй
ϯϴй

ϯϲй
ϯϯй

ϯϮй
ϰϬй

ϯϭй
ϯϬй

Ϯϳй
Ϯϲй

Ϯϰй
Ϯϯй

Ϯϯй

Ϯϯй
Ϯϯй
ϮϮй

ϮϮй

ϮϮй
ϮϮй
ϮϮй

ϮϮй
Ϯϭй
Ϯϭй

Ϯϭй
Ϯϭй

Ϯϭй
ϯϬй

Ϯϭй
ϮϬй

ϮϬй
ϮϬй

ϮϬй
ϭϵй

ϭϵй
ϭϵй
ϭϵй
ϭϴй

ϭϴй
ϭϴй

ϭϳй

ϮϬй

ϭϬй

Ϭй
ƵƐƚƌŝĂ ĞŶŵĂƌŬ &ŝŶůĂŶĚ 'ƌĞĞĐĞ /ƌĞůĂŶĚ WŽƌƚƵŐĂů ^ƉĂŝŶ ^ǁĞĚĞŶ

WE>͘/EEZWZ/W,Z> ϮϬϭϰ ϮϬϭϱ ϮϬϭϲ ϮϬϭϳ ϮϬϭϴ


ϰϬй

ϱϬй
ϯϵй

ϯϲй
ϯϲй

ϯϱй
ϯϱй

ϯϯй

ϯϯй
ϯϭй
ϯϬй
ϯϬй

ϰϬй
Ϯϴй

Ϯϴй
Ϯϳй
Ϯϳй
Ϯϲй

Ϯϲй
Ϯϱй

Ϯϱй
Ϯϰй

Ϯϰй
Ϯϰй

Ϯϯй
Ϯϯй

Ϯϯй
ϮϮй

Ϯϭй
Ϯϭй
Ϯϭй

ϯϬй
ϭϴй

ϭϳй
ϭϳй
ϭϰй

ϭϮй
ϭϭй

ϮϬй
ϭϬй
Ϭй
LJƉƌƵƐ ƐƚŽŶŝĂ >ĂƚǀŝĂ >ŝƚŚƵĂŶŝĂ DĂůƚĂ ^ůŽǀĂŬŝĂ ^ůŽǀĞŶŝĂ

WE>͘KhdZWZ/W,Z> ϮϬϭϰ ϮϬϭϱ ϮϬϭϲ ϮϬϭϳ ϮϬϭϴ

ϱϬй
ϯϯй

ϯϭй

ϰϬй
Ϯϵй
Ϯϵй

Ϯϵй
Ϯϴй

Ϯϳй

Ϯϲй
Ϯϲй

Ϯϱй
Ϯϱй

Ϯϱй
Ϯϰй

Ϯϰй
Ϯϯй
Ϯϯй
Ϯϯй
ϮϮй

Ϯϭй
Ϯϭй

ϯϬй
ϭϵй

ϭϵй

ϭϴй

ϭϴй
ϭϳй
ϭϱй

ϭϰй
ϭϰй
ϭϯй

ϭϭй

ϮϬй

ϭϬй

Ϭй
ƵůŐĂƌŝĂ ƌŽĂƚŝĂ njĞĐŚZĞƉƵďůŝĐ ,ƵŶŐĂƌLJ WŽůĂŶĚ ZŽŵĂŶŝĂ

Figure A2. Percentage share of SMEs which declared the implementation of process innovations by
country. Source: Own study.

262
JRFM 2020, 13, 206

WE>͘/EEZKZ ϮϬϭϰ ϮϬϭϱ ϮϬϭϲ ϮϬϭϳ ϮϬϭϴ

ϲϬй

ϰϯй
ϯϵй

ϯϵй
ϱϬй

ϯϴй
ϯϳй

ϯϳй
ϯϳй
ϯϲй

ϯϲй
ϯϲй

ϯϱй
ϯϱй
ϯϱй
ϯϭй
ϯϭй

Ϯϵй
ϰϬй

Ϯϳй
Ϯϳй
Ϯϲй

Ϯϲй
Ϯϱй
Ϯϱй

Ϯϰй
Ϯϰй
Ϯϰй
Ϯϰй

Ϯϰй

Ϯϯй
Ϯϯй
Ϯϯй

ϮϮй

ϮϮй
ϮϮй

ϮϮй
Ϯϭй
ϯϬй
ϮϬй
ϭϬй
Ϭй
ĞůŐŝƵŵ &ƌĂŶĐĞ 'ĞƌŵĂŶLJ /ƚĂůLJ >ƵdžĞŵďŽƵƌŐ EĞƚŚĞƌůĂŶĚƐ hŶŝƚĞĚ
<ŝŶŐĚŽŵ

WE>͘KhdZKZ ϮϬϭϰ ϮϬϭϱ ϮϬϭϲ ϮϬϭϳ ϮϬϭϴ

ϲϬй
ϰϴй
ϰϰй
ϰϮй
ϯϵй
ϱϬй
ϯϵй

ϯϴй
ϯϳй
ϯϳй

ϯϱй
ϯϰй
ϯϯй

ϯϯй

ϯϯй
ϯϮй
ϯϮй

ϯϭй
ϯϭй
ϯϬй

ϯϬй

ϰϬй
Ϯϴй

Ϯϴй

Ϯϴй
Ϯϳй

Ϯϳй
Ϯϳй
Ϯϲй

Ϯϲй
Ϯϲй

Ϯϲй
Ϯϲй
Ϯϲй
Ϯϱй

Ϯϱй

Ϯϰй

Ϯϰй

ϮϮй

ϮϮй
Ϯϭй

ϮϬй

ϯϬй

ϭϴй
ϮϬй
ϭϬй
Ϭй
ͲϭϬй ƵƐƚƌŝĂ ĞŶŵĂƌŬ &ŝŶůĂŶĚ 'ƌĞĞĐĞ /ƌĞůĂŶĚ WŽƌƚƵŐĂů ^ƉĂŝŶ ^ǁĞĚĞŶ

WE>͘/EEZWZ/W,Z> ϮϬϭϰ ϮϬϭϱ ϮϬϭϲ ϮϬϭϳ ϮϬϭϴ


ϱϰй

ϲϬй
ϰϳй

ϰϱй
ϰϰй
ϰϭй

ϱϬй
ϯϮй
ϯϮй

Ϯϵй

Ϯϵй
ϰϬй
Ϯϳй

Ϯϲй
Ϯϰй

Ϯϰй
Ϯϰй
Ϯϯй

Ϯϭй

Ϯϭй
Ϯϭй
ϮϬй

ϭϵй
ϭϵй

ϯϬй
ϭϴй
ϭϴй

ϭϴй
ϭϴй
ϭϴй
ϭϳй

ϭϳй
ϭϳй
ϭϳй

ϭϲй

ϭϲй
ϭϲй
ϭϲй
ϭϯй

ϮϬй
ϭϬй
Ϭй
ͲϭϬй LJƉƌƵƐ ƐƚŽŶŝĂ >ĂƚǀŝĂ >ŝƚŚƵĂŶŝĂ DĂůƚĂ ^ůŽǀĂŬŝĂ ^ůŽǀĞŶŝĂ

WE>͘KhdZWZ/W,Z> ϮϬϭϰ ϮϬϭϱ ϮϬϭϲ ϮϬϭϳ ϮϬϭϴ

ϲϬй
ϰϮй

ϱϬй
ϯϳй
ϯϳй
ϯϲй
ϯϯй

ϰϬй
Ϯϴй
Ϯϳй

Ϯϳй
Ϯϲй
Ϯϯй

ϮϮй
Ϯϭй

Ϯϭй

ϮϬй
ϮϬй
ϭϵй

ϭϵй

ϯϬй
ϭϴй
ϭϴй

ϭϴй
ϭϴй

ϭϱй

ϭϰй
ϭϰй
ϭϰй

ϭϯй
ϭϮй
ϭϭй

ϮϬй
ϵй
ϵй

ϭϬй
Ϭй
ͲϭϬй ƵůŐĂƌŝĂ ƌŽĂƚŝĂ njĞĐŚZĞƉƵďůŝĐ ,ƵŶŐĂƌLJ WŽůĂŶĚ ZŽŵĂŶŝĂ

Figure A3. Percentage share of SMEs which declared the implementation of management innovations
by country. Source: Own study.

263
JRFM 2020, 13, 206

WE>͘/EEZKZ ϮϬϭϰ ϮϬϭϱ ϮϬϭϲ ϮϬϭϳ ϮϬϭϴ

ϱϬй

ϯϮй

ϯϮй
ϯϭй
ϯϬй
Ϯϵй

Ϯϵй

Ϯϵй
ϰϬй

Ϯϴй
Ϯϳй

Ϯϳй
Ϯϳй
Ϯϲй
Ϯϲй

Ϯϲй

Ϯϲй

Ϯϲй
Ϯϱй

Ϯϱй
Ϯϱй
Ϯϱй

Ϯϱй
Ϯϰй
Ϯϰй

Ϯϰй
Ϯϯй
Ϯϯй
ϮϮй
Ϯϭй

ϭϵй

ϭϵй
ϭϵй
ϯϬй

ϭϴй
ϭϴй
ϭϲй

ϭϰй
ϮϬй
ϭϬй
Ϭй
ĞůŐŝƵŵ &ƌĂŶĐĞ 'ĞƌŵĂŶLJ /ƚĂůLJ >ƵdžĞŵďŽƵƌŐ EĞƚŚĞƌůĂŶĚƐ hŶŝƚĞĚ
<ŝŶŐĚŽŵ

WE>͘KhdZKZ ϮϬϭϰ ϮϬϭϱ ϮϬϭϲ ϮϬϭϳ ϮϬϭϴ


ϰϳй
ϰϲй
ϰϲй
ϰϰй
ϰϭй

ϱϬй
ϯϲй

ϯϲй
ϯϲй

ϯϲй

ϯϱй
ϯϱй
ϯϱй

ϯϰй
ϯϰй

ϯϰй

ϯϰй
ϯϮй

ϯϭй
ϰϬй
ϯϬй

ϯϬй

Ϯϴй
Ϯϴй
Ϯϳй
Ϯϲй

Ϯϲй
Ϯϱй

Ϯϱй

Ϯϰй
Ϯϰй
Ϯϰй
Ϯϯй

Ϯϯй
Ϯϯй
Ϯϭй
Ϯϭй

ϯϬй
ϭϵй

ϭϵй
ϭϴй

ϭϴй
ϭϴй

ϮϬй

ϭϬй

Ϭй
ƵƐƚƌŝĂ ĞŶŵĂƌŬ &ŝŶůĂŶĚ 'ƌĞĞĐĞ /ƌĞůĂŶĚ WŽƌƚƵŐĂů ^ƉĂŝŶ ^ǁĞĚĞŶ

WE>͘/EEZWZ/W,Z> ϮϬϭϰ ϮϬϭϱ ϮϬϭϲ ϮϬϭϳ ϮϬϭϴ

ϱϬй
ϯϵй

ϯϯй

ϯϯй
ϯϭй

ϰϬй
ϯϭй

ϯϬй

ϯϬй

ϯϬй
ϯϬй

Ϯϴй
Ϯϴй

Ϯϳй
Ϯϳй
Ϯϳй
Ϯϲй

Ϯϲй
Ϯϲй

Ϯϲй

Ϯϲй
Ϯϲй
Ϯϱй
Ϯϱй

Ϯϱй

Ϯϰй
Ϯϰй

ϮϮй
ϮϮй

ϯϬй ϮϮй
ϮϬй
ϮϬй

ϮϬй

ϮϬй
ϮϬй

ϭϵй
ϭϵй

ϮϬй

ϭϬй

Ϭй
LJƉƌƵƐ ƐƚŽŶŝĂ >ĂƚǀŝĂ >ŝƚŚƵĂŶŝĂ DĂůƚĂ ^ůŽǀĂŬŝĂ ^ůŽǀĞŶŝĂ

WE>͘KhdZWZ/W,Z> ϮϬϭϰ ϮϬϭϱ ϮϬϭϲ ϮϬϭϳ ϮϬϭϴ

ϱϬй
ϯϴй
ϯϴй
ϯϲй

ϯϲй
ϯϰй
ϯϭй

ϰϬй
Ϯϳй
Ϯϲй

Ϯϰй
Ϯϰй
Ϯϰй

Ϯϰй

Ϯϯй
Ϯϯй
Ϯϯй

ϮϮй
ϮϮй

Ϯϭй

Ϯϭй

Ϯϭй
ϮϬй

ϯϬй
ϮϬй
ϭϵй

ϭϴй

ϭϴй
ϭϳй
ϭϲй

ϭϲй

ϭϲй
ϭϱй

ϮϬй
ϭϬй
Ϭй
ƵůŐĂƌŝĂ ƌŽĂƚŝĂ njĞĐŚZĞƉƵďůŝĐ ,ƵŶŐĂƌLJ WŽůĂŶĚ ZŽŵĂŶŝĂ

Figure A4. Percentage share of SMEs which declared the implementation of sales innovations by
country. Source: Own study.

264
JRFM 2020, 13, 206

References
Angilella, Silvia, and Sebastiano Mazzù. 2015. The financing of innovative SMEs: A multicriteria credit rating
model. European Journal of Operational Research 244: 540–54. [CrossRef]
Anwar, Muhammad. 2018. Business model innovation and SMEs performance: Does competitive advantage
mediate? International Journal of Innovation Management 22: 1–31. [CrossRef]
Assink, Marnix. 2006. Inhibitors of disruptive innovation capability: A conceptual model. European Journal of
Innovation Management 9: 215–33. [CrossRef]
Avermaete, Tessa, Jacques Viaene, Eleanor J. Morgan, and Nick Crawford. 2003. Determinants of innovation in
small food firms. European Journal of Innovation Management 6: 8–17. [CrossRef]
Baldock, Robert, and Colin Mason. 2015. Establishing a new UK finance escalator for innovative SMEs: The roles
of the Enterprise Capital Funds and Angel Co-Investment Fund. Venture Capital 17: 59–86. [CrossRef]
Baregheh, Anahita, Jennifer Rowley, Sally Sambrook, and Dafydd Davies. 2012. Food sector SMEs and innovation
types. British Food Journal 114: 1640–53. [CrossRef]
Bartlett, William, and Ivana Prica. 2017. Interdependence between Core and Peripheries of the European Economy:
Secular Stagnation and Growth in the Western Balkans. European Journal of Comparative Economics 14: 123–39.
[CrossRef]
Bhattacharya, Mita, and Harry Bloch. 2004. Determinants of innovation. Small Business Economics 22: 155–62.
[CrossRef]
Beck, Thorsten, Asli Demirguc-Kunt, and Ross Levine. 2005. SMEs, growth, and poverty: Cross-country evidence.
Journal of Economic Growth 10: 199–229. [CrossRef]
Boer, Harry, and Willem E. During. 2001. Innovation, what innovation? A comparison between product, process
and organizational innovation. International Journal of Technology Management 22: 83–107. [CrossRef]
Bruha, Jan, and Evžen Kocenda. 2018. Financial stability in Europe. Banking and sovereign risk. Journal of
Financial Stability 36: 305–21. [CrossRef]
Colombo, Massimo G., and Luca Grilli. 2007. Funding gaps? Access to bank loans by high-tech start-ups. Small
Business Economics 29: 25–46. [CrossRef]
Da Rin, Marco, and MarÃ-a Fabiana Penas. 2007. The effect of venture capital on innovation strategies (No.
w13636). National Bureau of Economic Research. [CrossRef]
Deffains-Crapsky, Catherine, and Agata Sudolska. 2014. Radical innovation and early stage financing gaps:
Equity-based crowdfunding challenges. Journal of Positive Management 5: 3–19. [CrossRef]
De Moor, Lieven, M. Wieczorek-Kosmala, and Joanna Błach. 2016. SME Debt Financing Gap: The Case of Poland.
Transformations in Business Economics 15: 274–91.
Donaldson, Gordon. 1961. Corporate Debt Capacity: A Study of Corporate Debt Policy and Determination of Corporate
Debt Capacity. Working Paper. Boston: Harvard Graduate School of Management.
Durvy, Mr Jean-Noel. 2007. Equity Financing for SMEs: The Nature of the Market Failure. In The SME Financing
Gap, Proceedings of the Brasilia Conference, Brasilia, 27–30 March 2006. Paris: OECD Publishing, vol. II.
Goujard, Antoine, and Pierre Guérin. 2018. Financing Innovative Business Investment in Poland. OECD Economics
Department Working Papers, No. 1480. Paris: OECD Publishing. [CrossRef]
Hall, Bronwyn H. 2010. The financing of innovative firms. Review of Economics and Institutions 1: 1–30. [CrossRef]
Hall, Bronwyn H., Francesca Lotti, and Jacque Mairesse. 2009. Innovation and productivity in SMEs: Empirical
evidence for Italy. Small Business Economics 33: 13–33. [CrossRef]
Hottenrott, Hanna, and Bettina Peters. 2012. Innovative capability and financing constraints for innovation: More
money, more innovation? Review of Economics and Statistics 94: 1126–42. [CrossRef]
Hueske, Anne-Karen, and Edeltraud Guenther. 2015. What hampers innovation? External stakeholders, the
organization, groups and individuals: A systematic review of empirical barrier research. Management Review
Quarterly 65: 113–48. [CrossRef]
Freel, Mark S. 2007. Are small innovators credit rationed? Small Business Economics 28: 23–35. [CrossRef]
Lecerf, Marjorie, and Nessrine Omrani. 2019. SME Internationalization: The Impact of Information Technology
and Innovation. Journal of Knowledge Economy, 1–20. [CrossRef]
Lee, Neil, Hiba Sameen, and Marc Cowling. 2015. Access to finance for innovative SMEs since the financial crisis.
Research Policy 44: 370–80. [CrossRef]

265
JRFM 2020, 13, 206

Kerr, William R., and Ramanda Nanda. 2015. Financing innovation. Annual Review of Financial Economics 7: 445–62.
[CrossRef]
Kersten, Renate, Job Harms, Kellie Liket, and Karen Maas. 2017. Small Firms, large Impact? A systematic review
of the SME Finance Literature. World Development 97: 330–48. [CrossRef]
K˛edzior, Marcin. 2012. Capital structure in EU selected countries—Micro and macro determinants. Argumenta
Oeconomica 28: 69–117.
Kijkasiwat, Ploypailin, and Pongsutti Phuensane. 2020. Innovation and Firm Performance: The Moderating
and Mediating Roles of Firm Size and Small and Medium Enterprise Finance. Journal of Risk and Financial
Management 13: 97. [CrossRef]
Kovacevic, Tamara. 2019. EU Budget: Who Pays most in and Who Gets most back? BBC News. May 28. Available
online: https://www.bbc.com/news/uk-politics-48256318 (accessed on 11 November 2019).
Kumar, Satish, and Purnima Rao. 2015. A conceptual framework for identifying financing preferences of SMEs.
Small Enterprise Research 22: 99–112. [CrossRef]
Madeira, Maria José, João Carvalho, Jacinta Raquel Miguel Moreira, Filipe AP Duarte, and Flávio de São Pedro Filho.
2017. Barriers to innovation and the innovative performance of Portuguese firms. Journal of Business 9.
[CrossRef]
Modigliani, Franco, and Merton H. Miller. 1958. The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of
investment. The American Economic Review 48: 261–97.
Moritz, Alexandra, Block Joern H., and Heinz Andreas. 2016. Financing patterns of European SMEs—An empirical
taxonomy. An International Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance 16: 115–48. [CrossRef]
Myers, Stewart C., and Nicholas S. Majluf. 1984. Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms have
information that investors do not have. Journal of Financial Economics 13: 187–221. [CrossRef]
Neely, Lynn, and Howard Van Auken. 2012. An examination of small firm bootstrap financing and use of debt.
Journal of Developmental Entrepreneurship 17: 1250002. [CrossRef]
OECD. 2013. Supporting Investment in Knowledge Capital, Growth and Innovation. Paris: OECD Publishing.
Oke, Adegoke, Gerard Burke, and Andrew Myers. 2007. Innovation types and performance in growing UK SMEs.
International Journal of Operations Production Management 27: 735–53. [CrossRef]
Ortega-Argilés, Raquel, Macro Vivarelli, and Peter Voigt. 2009. R&D in SMEs: A paradox? Small Business Economics
33: 3–11. [CrossRef]
Oslo, Manual. 2018. Oslo Manual 2018: Guidelines for Collecting, Reporting and Using Data on Innovation. Paris:
OECD Publishing.
Ou, Charles, and Geogre W. Haynes. 2006. Acquisition of Additional Equity Capital by Small Firms—Findings
from the National Survey of Small Business Finances. Small Business Economics 27: 157–68. [CrossRef]
Papadimitriou, Stratos, and Panos Mourdoukoutas. 2002. Bridging the start-up equity financing gap: Three policy
models. European Business Review 14: 104–10. [CrossRef]
Pełka, Marcin. 2018. Analysis of innovations in the European Union via ensemble symbolic density clustering.
Econometrics 22: 84–98. [CrossRef]
SAFE. 2018. Available online: https://ec.europa.eu/growth/access-to-finance/data-surveys (accessed on 30
September 2019).
Santarelli, Enrico, and Alessandro Sterlacchini. 1990. Innovation, formal vs. informal R&D, and firm size: Some
evidence from Italian manufacturing firms. Small Business Economics 2: 223–28. [CrossRef]
Sau, Lino. 2007. New Pecking Order Financing for Innovative Firms: An Overview. Working Paper Series. Torino:
Universita di Torino, Available online: https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/3659/ (accessed on 25 March 2020).
Savlovschi, Ludovica Ioana, and Nicoleta Raluca Robu. 2011. The role of SMEs in modern economy. Economia,
Seria Management 14: 277–81.
Schenk, Andreas. 2015. Crowdfunding in the context of traditional financing for innovative SMEs. In European
Conference on Innovation and Entrepreneurship. Reading: Academic Conferences International Limited,
pp. 636–43.
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1942. Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. New York: Harper.
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1934. The Theory of Economic Development. Cambridge: Harvard Economic Studies.
Skuras, Dimitris, Kyriaki Tsegenidi, and Kostas Tsekouras. 2008. Product innovation and the decision to invest in
fixed capital assets: Evidence from an SME survey in six European Union member states. Research Policy 37:
1778–89. [CrossRef]

266
JRFM 2020, 13, 206

Tavassoli, Sam, and Charlie Karlsson. 2015. Persistence of various types of innovation analyzed and explained.
Research Policy 44: 1887–901. [CrossRef]
Thurik, Roy, and Sander Wennekers. 2004. Entrepreneurship, small business and economic growth. Journal of
Small Business and Enterprise Development 11: 140–49. [CrossRef]
Van Dijk, Bob, René Den Hertog, Bert Menkveld, and Roy Thurik. 1997. Some new evidence on the determinants
of large-and small-firm innovation. Small Business Economics 9: 335–43. [CrossRef]
Vaona, Andrea, and Mario Pianta. 2008. Firm size and innovation in European manufacturing. Small Business
Economics 30: 283–99. [CrossRef]
Varis, Miika, and Hannu Littunen. 2010. Types of innovation, sources of information and performance in
entrepreneurial SMEs. European Journal of Innovation Management 13: 128–54. [CrossRef]
Vasilescu, Laura. 2014. Accessing Finance for Innovative EU SMEs Key Drivers and Challenges. Economic Review
Journal of Economics and Business 12: 35–47.
Wadhwa, Anu, Corey Phelps, and Suresh Kotha. 2016. Corporate venture capital portfolios and firm innovation.
Journal of Business Venturing 31: 95–112. [CrossRef]
Wu, Chuanrong, Xiaoming Yang, Veronika Lee, and Mark E. McMurtrey. 2019. Influence of Venture Capital and
Knowledge Transfer on Innovation Performance in the Big Data Environment. Journal of Risk and Financial
Management 12: 188. [CrossRef]
Whittam, Geoff Paul Stuart, and Janette Wyper. 2007. The pecking order hypothesis: Does it apply to start-up
firms? Journal of Small Business and Enterprise Development 14: 8–21. [CrossRef]
Wolff, James A., and Timothy L. Pett. 2006. Small-firm performance: Modeling the role of product and process
improvements. Journal of Small Business Management 44: 268–84. [CrossRef]

© 2020 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access
article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution
(CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).

267
Journal of
Risk and Financial
Management

Article
Bankruptcy Prediction with the Use of Data
Envelopment Analysis: An Empirical Study of
Slovak Businesses
Róbert Štefko, Jarmila Horváthová and Martina Mokrišová *
Faculty of Management, University of Prešov, Konštantínova 16, 080 01 Prešov, Slovakia;
robert.stefko@unipo.sk (R.Š.); jarmila.horvathova@unipo.sk (J.H.)
* Correspondence: martina.mokrisova@unipo.sk

Received: 24 August 2020; Accepted: 13 September 2020; Published: 16 September 2020

Abstract: The paper deals with methods of predicting bankruptcy of a business with the aim of
choosing a prediction method which will have exact results. Existing bankruptcy prediction models
are a suitable tool for predicting the financial difficulties of businesses. However, such tools are based
on strictly defined financial indicators. Therefore, the Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA) method has
been applied, as it allows for the free choice of financial indicators. The research sample consisted of
343 businesses active in the heating industry in Slovakia. Analysed businesses have a significant
relatively stable position in the given industry. The research was based on several studies which also
used the DEA method to predict future financial difficulties and bankruptcies of studied businesses.
The estimation accuracy of the Additive DEA model (ADD model) was compared with the Logit
model to determine the reliability of the DEA method. Also, an optimal cut-off point for the ADD
model and Logit model was determined. The main conclusion is that the DEA method is a suitable
alternative for predicting the failure of the analysed sample of businesses. In contrast to the Logit
model, its results are independent of any assumptions. The paper identified the key indicators of the
future success of businesses in the analysed sample. These results can help businesses to improve
their financial health and competitiveness.

Keywords: bankruptcy; data envelopment analysis; logit; model

1. Introduction
Determining the probability of bankruptcy is becoming one of the most important risk management
tasks. We pay close attention to predictions of bankruptcy due to the fact that it is important from
the point of view of creditors, employees, and other entities around the affected company that would
feel the effect the bankruptcy brings (Štefko et al. 2012). Bankruptcy prediction methods can, with a
certain degree of probability, alert a company to a negative situation. By taking early remedy measures,
businesses can prevent future bankruptcy events (Gundová 2015). To date, empirical studies have found
that inefficiency, high corporate indebtedness, and solvency problems are a prerequisite for bankruptcy
(Altman 1968). According to Achim et al. (2012) the risk of bankruptcy of an enterprise is closely linked
to economic and financial risks. The financial risk is determined by the level of indebtedness, while the
economic risk depends on the ratio of fixed and variable costs. In general, knowing these risks allows us
to quantify the risk of bankruptcy. Although there is no uniform definition of the concept of bankruptcy,
it is advisable to follow the definition of Dimitras et al. (1996), according to whom bankruptcy is a
situation where an enterprise is unable to repay its creditors’ obligations and meet obligations towards
shareholders or suppliers, or where bankruptcy proceedings were commenced under applicable
law. Ding et al. (2008) described bankruptcy in a similar way: Bankruptcy is a situation where a
firm could not pay lenders, preferred stock shareholders, suppliers, etc., or a bill was overdrawn,

JRFM 2020, 13, 212; doi:10.3390/jrfm13090212 269 www.mdpi.com/journal/jrfm


JRFM 2020, 13, 212

or a firm was bankrupt. Trahms et al. (2013) have contributed the most to the current research on
finding the causes of bankruptcy. They state that more complex indicators of business performance
decline should be identified in any research on bankruptcy. Scarlat and Delcea (2011) introduced a
new concept, a bankruptcy syndrome, which they define as a summary of related symptoms that
characterise a particular situation that can lead to bankruptcy. Many authors devote their attention
to financial symptoms of bankruptcy, which are expressed by financial indicators. These authors
include, among others, Beaver (1966), Altman (1968), Altman et al. (1977), Geng et al. (2014), and Ding
et al. (2008) who attributed the risk of bankruptcy to reduced company profitability. One of the most
common aspects involved in assessing the cause of bankruptcy is either financial or non-financial causes.
Chen et al. (2009) determined that non-financial causes of corporate bankruptcy include: customer
relationship levels, IT infrastructure, innovation potential, employee professionalism, and other factors.
Martin et al. (2012) referred to other parameters of bankruptcy such as operational risk, competitiveness,
credibility analysis, training of employees, quality, etc. The loss of competitiveness as a cause of
bankruptcy was also examined by Suhányi and Suhányiová (2017). In addition to the previous
classifications, research studies often classify the causes of bankruptcy based on the environment they
come from through external and internal causes (Blazy et al. 2008). Despite the existence of various
other causes of bankruptcy, our empirical study prioritises the financial causes of bankruptcy.
The next part of the text is structured as follows: The second chapter outlines the theoretical basis
of the studied problem. This part of the paper lists various methods and models used for predicting the
risk of bankruptcy. A special part is devoted to the summary of the theoretical knowledge about the
Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA) method. At the end of the theoretical part, a research problem and
goal are formulated. The aim of the paper is to find out whether businesses from the analysed sample
have been faced the threat of bankruptcy due to financial difficulties. The third chapter describes the
data, the analysed sample of companies, and the processing methods. When addressing the research
problem, we made use of selected financial indicators, a correlation matrix, the Additive DEA model
(ADD model) model, and the Logit model. We formulated the ADD non-oriented model with variable
returns to scale that were solved with the use of Efficiency Measurement Systems (EMS) software.
The fourth chapter includes results and discussion of the results achieved. This chapter lists and
compares the results of bankruptcy prediction with the use of the DEA and Logit models. The final part
of the paper is the conclusion in which the essential conclusions resulting from the research problem
are addressed.

2. Theoretical Background
At present, we can observe several tendencies regarding the application of prediction models
in predicting bankruptcy. Sun et al. (2014) specifically point to three trends: the transition from
one-dimensional analysis of variables to multidimensional prediction, a shift from classical statistical
methods to machine learning methods based on artificial intelligence, and more intensive involvement
of hybrid and ensemble classifiers. Aziz and Dar (2006) divided prediction models into statistical
prediction models, models that use artificial intelligence, and theoretical models. Individually, the use
of multiple discriminant analysis (MDA) and Logit models dominates the research (Altman and
Saunders 1997; In: Csikosova et al. 2019).
Fitzpatrick (1931) was the first to deal with bankruptcy prediction in his study of solvent and
insolvent businesses. In the following years, research on this topic has been carried out by Merwin (1942),
Chudson (1945), Jackendoff (1962), and Beaver (1966) (In: Delina and Packová 2013). Beaver (1966)
demonstrated that financial ratios can be useful in the prediction of an individual firm’s failure. He has
proven that not all financial indicators can be used to predict business difficulties. However, the use of
simple financial indicators was questioned in practice because of their possible mismanagement by
managers. Univariate analysis was later followed by authors who used multivariate analysis. In the
beginning of multivariate prediction models, discriminant analysis (DA) was applied. In 1968 Altman
developed a multiple discriminant analysis model (MDA) called the Z-Score Model. Since Altman’s

270
JRFM 2020, 13, 212

study, the number and complexity of these models has increased dramatically. DA was explored
by Blum (1974), Elam (1975), Altman et al. (1977), Norton and Smith (1979), and Taffler (1983).
Altman’s original model required the fulfilment of multinormality, homoskedasticity, and linearity
assumptions. These prerequisites for financial indicators were often not met. The main drawback
of DA, however, is that although it is able to identify businesses that are likely to go bankrupt, it is
not able to estimate the likelihood of this situation occurring. Based on these shortcomings, the next
step in the theory of bankruptcy prediction was to develop methods and models that would be able
to provide such information (Mihalovič 2015). That was the reason why logistic regression began to
be preferred, as this method does not have to meet these conditions. Compared to methods based
on multi-dimensional discriminant analysis, logistic regression has several advantages. It has a
higher predictive ability and its application does not require compliance with assumptions that could
limit its usability. The method was first used to predict the bankruptcy of banks by Martin (1977).
Ohlson (1980) was the first to use it to assess companies. Ohlson, as a pioneer in the application of
Logit analysis, did not agree with the application of discriminant analysis to predict bankruptcy due to
its requirement for a variance-covariance matrix (Klieštik et al. 2014). However, even Logit models
have their weakness—their sensitivity to remote observation.
Another method used in the area of bankruptcy prediction is DEA (Horváthová and
Mokrišová 2018). Compared to statistical methods, DEA is a relatively new, non-parametric method,
which represents one of the main possible approaches to assessing the financial health of a business
and its risk of bankruptcy (Štefko et al. 2018). This method was first applied in Charnes et al. (1978).
It is based on the idea mentioned in the article “Measuring efficiency of decision making units“,
published by Farrell in 1957. His work was based on the works of Debreu (1951) and Koopmans
(1951). Farrell (1957) proposed a new approach to efficiency measuring based on a linear convex
envelopment curve and the use of distance measurement functions between the enterprise of interest
and the projected point on the efficiency frontier. In this way, he proposed a new level of efficiency
based on the calculation of two components of the overall business efficiency: technical efficiency
and resource allocation efficiency. Farrell’s approach measures the ability of the business to transform
inputs into outputs. Therefore, it is also called the input-oriented approach. Charnes et al. (1978) have
applied a multiplicative input-output model to measure business efficiency. The approach of these
authors represents a two-stage efficiency calculation. The first step is to identify the production frontier,
while businesses that lie on this line are among the best businesses. In the second step, the efficiency
score is calculated for the analysed enterprises and their distance from the production frontier is
determined. From the point of view of their input, DEA models can be divided into DEA CCR (Charnes
et al. 1978) and DEA BCC (Banker et al. 1984). This method was further developed by Färe et al. (1985).
The DEA method was also used by the following authors: Tone (2001); Wang et al. (2007); Kao and
Hwang (2008); Sadjadi and Omrani (2008); Zhu (2015); Oanh and Ngoc (2016); Ghomi et al. (2019);
Dumitrescu et al. (2020); and many others.
The first idea to use the DEA method to predict bankruptcy was recorded by Simak (1997),
who was the first to compare its results with the results of Altman’s Z-score. Other authors dealing
with the DEA bankruptcy prediction included Cielen et al. (2004). The authors used the DEA radial
model to predict bankruptcy and compared the results with DA results. In the same year Paradi et al.
(2004) applied an additive and radial model along with the peeling technique. The model achieved
100% success in predicting the bankruptcy of businesses. In 2009, Premachandra et al. used an ADD
model and compared its results with the results of logistic regression. The result of this research was
a satisfactory level of correct prediction of business bankruptcy. The prediction rate for financially
sound businesses was less accurate. Sueyoshi and Goto (2009) applied an ADD model to create a line
under which businesses go bankrupt. The results were then compared with the DEA-DA approach.
In 2011, Premachandra et al. combined the radial and ADD model and created the DEA ranking index.
Shetty et al. (2012) applied the DEA model in 2012 to determine the bankruptcy likelihood for their

271
JRFM 2020, 13, 212

analysed business sample. The result of their study was the designing of indicators that should be
applied as predictors of bankruptcy.
Other methods that are suitable for the application in the field of bankruptcy prediction include
neural networks. In this context, it is possible to mention the authors Odom and Sharda (1990),
who developed a neural network to investigate business bankruptcy using selected financial indicators.
Gherghina (2015) made a significant contribution to the application of neural networks in this
area. The neural network in the field of bankruptcy prediction was also applied by Altman et al.
(1994). Other methods include decision trees (Breiman et al. 1984; Frydman et al. 1985). However,
in conclusion, it should be noted that the most commonly used methods today are discriminant analysis
and logistic regression.
In line with the above-mentioned text, we identified the following research problem: Is the DEA
method a suitable alternative in predicting failure of businesses from the analysed sample? In relation
to the research problem, the aim of the paper was formulated: To predict business failure with the use
of the ADD model and to compare its results with the results of the Logit model. The aim was also
to analyse classification and estimation accuracy of the ADD DEA model and to compare it with the
classification and estimation accuracy of the Logit model.

3. Methodology and Data


DEA models are designed to assess the technical efficiency of production units based on the size
of inputs and outputs. There are two possible approaches to creating DEA models: multiplicative and
dual. The dual model is an additional task to the multiplicative one. A significant problem of the
DEA analysis are production externalities (negative outputs) and desirable inputs. Generally, in DEA
models, the basic prerequisite is data positivity. However, situations in which negative inputs and
outputs occur are not uncommon. In the case of the sample of companies analysed, negative outputs
occurred in the case of profitability. The ways to deal with this problem are different. Some software
programmes attach zero weight to negative inputs and outputs. Another frequently used option is to
treat the negative outputs as inputs (thus minimising them) and the desired inputs as outputs (thus
maximising them). However, this procedure is not universally applicable. One of the simpler options
is to use an additive model in which the positive and negative inputs and outputs are evaluated
separately (Premachandra et al. 2009; Mendelová and Stachová 2016).
The ADD model is one of the non-oriented models. This model was formulated by Charnes et al.
(1985). A Decision Making Unit (DMU) was introduced as a unit for which efficiency was solved and
which describes any entity for which the process of transforming inputs into outputs is in progress.
Determining DMU efficiency with an additive model for variable returns to scale means solving the
following linear programming model:
 
max Ao = eTm sx + eTs s y

λ,s s
x y

s.t. nj=1 x j λ j + sx = xo , sx ≥ 0,

n (1)
j=1 y j λ j − s = yo , s y ≥ 0,
y

n
1 λ j = 1, λ j ≥0,

where em , es , are unit vectors of appropriate length and sx , s y are additional variables-slacks. DMUo o
= {1, . . . , n}, is efficient when sx = 0, s y = 0, in other words, when the objective function and all slacks
equal zero. Otherwise, the DMUo is inefficient.
Since our paper does not address the efficiency of the analysed sample, but rather covers
bankruptcy, the input vectors xo , were replaced by output vectors yo . The efficiency condition
in this case served as a condition for the assumed bankruptcy of the company. In our research,
we used 9 financial indicators. We selected this group of indicators in such a way that it contains
indicators from all areas of financial health evaluation (liquidity, profitability, activity, indebtedness)
and there is not a strong correlation between indicators. As output variables, we applied indicator

272
JRFM 2020, 13, 212

LLTA—long-term liabilities/total assets used as a leverage measure which indicates long-term financial
obligation, and indicator CLTA—current liabilities/total assets which indicates a lack of cash flow to
fund business operations. As input variables, we applied 7 indicators: TRTA—total revenue/total assets,
CR (Current ratio)—(financial assets + short-term receivables)/current liabilities, WCTA—working
capital/total assets, CATA—current assets/total assets, EBTA—earnings before interest and taxes/total
assets, EBIE—earnings before interest and taxes/interest expense, and ETD—equity/total debt. For the
creation of the ADD model, we used the Efficiency Measurement System (EMS) software. We divided
the results of the DEA model into 6 zones (businesses in financial distress—3 zones and financially
healthy businesses—3 zones) according to Mendelová and Bieliková (2017).

3.1. Logit Model


The Logit regression model was applied to compare the results obtained with the DEA model.
The Logit model is a widespread model that has been used by several authors to predict the default/no
default probability of a company (Premachandra et al. 2009; Kováčová and Klieštik 2017; Mendelová
and Stachová 2016). This model is a type of multivariate statistical model. It captures the relationship
between the dependent variable Y and the independent variable X.
Logistic regression works very similar to linear regression, but with a binomial response variable
(Sperandei 2014). The dependent variable yi can only take two values: yi = 1 if the probability of
bankruptcy occurs and yi = 0 if the probability of bankruptcy does not occur. Therefore, we can
assume that probability yi =1 is given by Pi ; probability yi = 0 is given by 1 − Pi. By using logistic
transformation, we could specify the probability Pi using the following model: Pi = f (α + βxi ), where xi
are the chosen financial indicators while α and β are estimated parameters. Pi is then calculated using
the logistic function:
exp(α + βxi) 1
Pi = = . (2)
1 + exp(α + βxi) 1 + exp(−α − βxi)
A logistic regression models the chance of an outcome based on individual characteristics
(Sperandei 2014). According to Kováčová and Klieštik (2017), the Logit can be defined as:

Pi
Logit = ln( ) = f (α + βxi ). (3)
1 − Pi

The above represents the logarithm of the odds ratio of the two possible alternatives (Pi , 1 − Pi ).
P
It is called the Logit. The goal of logistic regression is to calculate the odds ratio ( 1−Pi ); ln in this
i
relationship represents the Logit transformation.
For the creation of Logit model, it was necessary to divide businesses into bankrupt and
non-bankrupt. When choosing the appropriate conditions for bankruptcy occurrence evaluation,
we studied the papers of various authors. Some of them assume that a company goes bankrupt if it does
not make a profit (Beaver 1966; Altman 1968; Altman et al. 1977; Geng et al. 2014) or reaches negative
cash flow (Ding et al. 2008). Based on the bankruptcy definition stated in the Introduction, we chose
the value of indebtedness as the bankruptcy condition. We then detected 50 bankrupt businesses.
When creating the Logit model, we started with the same 9 indicators which we used for the ADD
model. However, there was a strong correlation between ETD and the indicator of indebtedness which
we used as a bankruptcy criterion. Therefore, we did not use the indicator ETD in the Logit model.
We also excluded the indicator CATA because when applying it, the Logit model did not process any
coefficients. We assumed that the indicators CATA and WCTA are related indicators which evaluate
the same financial area of evaluation and express the same reality. For the creation of the Logit model,
we used software Statistica 13.1.
Using the results of the Logit model, it is possible to determine whether a company is about
to go bankrupt or not. This classification may use a cut-off score (usually 0.5), with businesses
above this value facing a probability of going bankrupt and businesses below this value facing lower
(or no) probability of going bankrupt. Two types of misclassification can occur when evaluating

273
JRFM 2020, 13, 212

business failure. The type I error (false negative rate) arises when a bankrupt company is classified
as non-bankrupt, and the type II error (false positive rate) arises when the non-bankrupt company is
classified as bankrupt (Kováčová and Klieštik 2017).
The prediction ability of the Logit model can be verified by using the Area Under Curve (AUC)
method, which measures the area under the Receiver Operating Characteristic curve (ROC curve).
This analysis represents a statistical procedure for evaluating correct and false positives as well as
correct and false negatives. ROC curve analysis describes the relationship of sensitivity and specificity
at different discriminatory levels. AUC measures overall performance of the model. It can take on
any value between 0 and 1. The closer AUC is to 1, the better is the overall performance of the model
(Park et al. 2004).
One of the important tests that can be mentioned in verifying the Logit model is the Wald test,
which confirms the significance of variables in the model. Based on the results of Likelihood ratio test,
the model includes those variables, which increases its maximum credibility. This test is suitable not
only to assess the significance of the model, but also to assess the contribution of individual predictors
to the model. The higher the Chi-square test statistic, the better the model reflects the situation of a
business. In addition to the above tests, the results of the Hosmer–Lemeshow test should be mentioned.
This test indicates the compliance of the model with the applied data. Nagelkerke’s R Square explains
the percentage of variance, while we could also find out how successful the model is in explaining the
“variability” of a dependent variable.

3.2. Description of the Sample of Companies


The input database of this empirical study was created from data obtained for 497 companies
operating in Slovakia in the heat supply industry. The database of the data from financial statements of
these companies for the year 2016 was obtained from the Slovak analytical agency CRIF—Slovak Credit
Bureau, s.r.o. According to SK NACE Rev. 2, the sample of enterprises analysed falls under section D:
“Supply of electricity, gas, steam and cold air“. Sources and distribution of heat of these businesses
were built along with the development of urban agglomerations. Their systems allow the effective
use of various sources of energy generated in a city, including renewable sources, waste heat, and so
on. These systems are an energy infrastructure integrator which can efficiently link production and
consumption and enable the storing of energy (in the form of heat) at the time of its surplus. As part
of independent heat production, today about 54% of the heat is produced in combined production
(Janiš 2018). The European Commission’s winter energy package sets new targets for energy efficiency.
These goals and new trends in energy bring new opportunities and challenges for the heating industry.
These facts are a precondition for the occurrence of risk factors which affect the performance and
competitiveness of analysed businesses from outside. A more detailed analysis of this sample excluded
154 companies due to a negative value of equity or deficiencies in the database. The resulting analysed
sample consisted of 343 companies. In terms of each business’s legal status, 15% of the companies are
joint stock companies and the remaining 85% are limited liability companies. The results of the financial
analysis show that the analysed companies do not have a liquidity problem. The average value of
current ratio found is 3.92. However, we also obtained a median of current ratio of 0.951. This was also
reflected in the negative value of net working capital. The analysed sample of companies reported a
high creditors payment period, which results in a negative value of cash conversion cycle. The assets
of these companies change on average once a year. The average value of the return on assets is 5%.
The capital structure of these companies is 35:65 in favour of equity. The performance of companies
active in the heating industry was not found to reach the required value to avoid bankruptcy.
The Table 1 shows the descriptive statistics of indicators, which represent indicators applied in
the DEA model. The values of the indicators are divided into two groups. The first group consists
of bankrupt businesses and the second group consists of non-bankrupt businesses. Of these values,
the negative values for WCTA, EBTA, ETD, and EBIE should be pointed out, as these negative values
are one of the signs of bankruptcy. Analysed businesses also have high indebtedness.

274
JRFM 2020, 13, 212

Table 1. Descriptive statistics for bankrupt and non-bankrupt businesses.

Financial Indicators TRTA CR WCTA CATA EBTA EBIE ETD LLTA CLTA
Bankrupt businesses (50)
Mean 0.336 3.925 −0.239 0.185 −0.026 −1.1120 −0.217 0.499 0.424
Median 0.205 0.473 −0.067 0.138 −0.000 0.014 −0.200 0.615 0.227
Standard deviation 0.875 12.190 0.590 0.173 0.129 5.244 0.150 0.384 0.600
Skewness 6.752 4.433 −3.273 2.239 1.181 −4.877 −0.909 −0.150 3.450
Non-bankrupt businesses (293)
Mean 0.854 3.644 −0.036 0.300 0.070 830.989 0.838 0.330 0.332
Median 0.286 0.813 −0.018 0.192 0.055 2.243 0.241 0.300 0.240
Standard deviation 1.460 12.43 0.270 0.270 0.160 11,531.54 3.5800 0.300 0.300
Skewness 3.461 6.075 −0.541 1.416 6.669 16.550 13.889 0.167 0.893

4. Results and Discussion


During the research process presented in the paper, we created two models. One was developed
based on DEA as an ADD model. As the outcome of the ADD model is an extensive set of data,
we present selected data as an example in Table 2. In the case of businesses that have a score of zero
and all their slacks equal to zero, it can be said that they are likely to go bankrupt. From the Table 3,
it can be seen that such a situation applies to e.g., company number 122 and company number 126.

Table 2. Selected results of the Additive DEA model (ADD model).

DMU Score TRTA CR WCTA CATA EBTA


TP121 2.48 0 0 0 0.52 0.15
TP122 0 0 0.01 −0.27 0.09 0
TP123 2.21 0 0 0 0 0.16
TP124 2.54 0.43 0 0 0 0.19
TP125 2.62 0.47 0 0 0 0.27
TP126 0 0.05 0 −0.45 0.45 0.01
TP127 1.77 0 0 0 0 −0.17
TP128 1.2 0.6 0 0 0 0
TP129 0.1 0.45 0 0 0 −0.18

Table 3. Results of a multi-zones ADD model.

DEA Zones 1 2 3 4 5 6
Number of businesses 17 15 23 56 81 151

The classification of businesses into individual DEA zones is shown in Table 3. In case of three
financial distress zones, the risk of going bankrupt affects 55 companies. With regard to the first zone
of the DEA model, it turned out that 17 companies face risk of bankruptcy. With regard to the second
zone, 15 companies face such risk, and in case of the third zone, the risk is being faced by another
23 companies.
To determine a model’s estimation accuracy, a cut-off point of 0.5 is usually used. However,
this cut-off is not appropriate for every given model. Therefore, we were looking for the optimal cut
off corresponding to a point in which the sum of sensitivity and specificity is the highest. The optimal
cut-off was found at the level of 0.63. The results are shown in Table 4. In this case, 82% estimation
accuracy for bankrupt businesses and 56% estimation accuracy for non-bankrupt businesses could be
achieved. We can consider this to be an adequate estimation accuracy rate.

275
JRFM 2020, 13, 212

Table 4. Classification accuracy of the ADD model corresponding to a cut-off point of 0.63.

Predicted: Yes Predicted: No % Correct Error %


82
Observed: yes 41 9 18 (I)
188
Observed: no 131 163 56 44 (II)

We also constructed a ROC curve for the ADD model (see Figure 1), where the AUC is at the level
of 0.82.

52&&XUYH
$UHD







6HQVLWLYLW\








       
6SHFLILFLW\

Figure 1. ROC curve for ADD model.

We then formulated Logit model to identify businesses that are likely to go bankrupt. We selected
7 financial indicators for the Logit model. They are indicators TRTA, CR, WCTA, EBTA, LLTA, EBIE and
CLTA. Table 5 shows the results of Logit model.

Table 5. Logit function coefficients.

Bankrupt-Parameter Estimates
Effect Standard Lower CL Upper CL
Column Estimate Wald Stat. P
Error 95.0% 95.0%
Intercept 1 −2.15434 0.443236 23.62436 −3.0231 −1.28562 0.000001
TRTA 2 −0.48536 0.415575 1.36406 −1.2999 0.32915 0.242835
CR 3 0.01264 0.011864 1.13604 −0.0106 0.03590 0.286491
WCTA 4 −1.58510 1.136295 1.94594 −3.8122 0.64200 0.163025
EBTA 5 −8.52758 1.987190 18.41503 −12.4224 −4.63276 0.000018
LLTA 6 1.31126 0.591269 4.91819 0.1524 2.47012 0.026575
EBIE 7 −0.00026 0.002247 0.01353 −0.0047 0.00414 0.907416
CLTA 8 0.19154 1.156441 0.02743 −2.0750 2.45812 0.868449
Scale 1.00000 0.000000 1.0000 1.00000

Based on the Wald confidence intervals, it can be stated, with 95% confidence, that the coefficients
of the variables EBTA, LLTA are within the specified limits of the interval and none of the intervals
contains a value of 0, which would exclude the variable from the model. Since no Wald statistics

276
JRFM 2020, 13, 212

parameter is equal to zero, it can be assumed that all explanatory variables can be included in the model.
It follows that the tested variables are suitable for the Logit model. At the same time, Wald statistics
determines which of the independent variables is more important than the others. A statistically
significant relationship determining probability of bankruptcy was confirmed for the indicators EBTA
and LLTA. The above results show that the probability of bankruptcy is determined by profit and
indebtedness. The resulting Logit function providing the probability of business bankruptcy is:

1
P1 = , (4)
1 + e−(−2.150.49×TRTA + 0.01×CR −1.59×WCTA8.53×EBTA + 1.31×LLTA − 0.0003×EBIE + 0.19×CLTA)

To assess the estimation accuracy of the model, we constructed a Receiver Operating Characteristic
(ROC) curve (see Figure 2). In our case, the AUC accounts for 79.65%, which we evaluated positively.
Therefore, we can state that our model has good estimation accuracy.

52&&XUYH
$UHD







6HQVLWLYLW\








       

6SHFLILFLW\

Figure 2. Receiver Operating Characteristic (ROC) curve for the Logit model.

The Hosmer–Lemeshow test signalized good conformity of the final model with given data.
The p-value of the test was 0.71. This value is higher than the significance level, so we accepted
the null hypothesis—the distribution of predicted and achieved results is the same across all groups
of businesses. According to Nagelkerke’s R Square, the model explains 26.73% variability of the
binary dependent variable. Total estimation accuracy of the Logit model was found to be 86.6%,
for non-bankrupt businesses the result was 96%, and estimation accuracy for bankrupt businesses was
30% (see Table 6). The error type I was 70% and error type II was 4%. The model was found to have
higher classification accuracy for businesses that are financially sound.

Table 6. Classification accuracy of the Logit model corresponding to the same cut-off as the ADD model.

Classification of Cases
Predicted: Yes Predicted: No Percent Correct
Observed: yes 15 35 30%
Observed: no 11 282 96%

277
JRFM 2020, 13, 212

A comparison of the classification ability of the models is given in Table 7 (corresponding to a


cut-off point of 0.63). Several researchers compared the results of the ADD model and the Logit model.
We already described the research of Premachandra et al. (2009) in the Introduction. The comparison of
these two models was also performed by the Slovak researchers Mendelová and Stachová (2016, p. 103)
who based on their research concluded that, in general, they cannot say that one method is better
than the other one, because the accuracy and suitability of each method depends on the particular
data used, its size, and its proportions. The results of the ADD model and Logit model were also
compared by Araghi and Makvandi (2012). They found out that DEA is an effective tool for predicting
business bankruptcy, but it is not as efficient as the Logit model—DEA achieved a weak performance
in identifying bankrupt and non-bankrupt companies.

Table 7. Comparison of the estimation accuracy of the ADD and Logit models corresponding to optimal
cut-off for the DEA model.

Model Error Type I Error Type II Overall Estimation Accuracy Sensitivity Specificity
Logit 70% 4% 87% 30% 96%
DEA 18% 44% 59% 82% 56%

The ADD model was found to have a lower classification accuracy for non-bankrupt businesses
corresponding to a cut-off of 0.63 and the Logit model has lower classification accuracy for bankrupt
businesses at this cut-off (see Table 7). Therefore, it is necessary to state the optimal cut off for the
Logit model, which is 0.16. At this point, the Logit model achieves a higher classification accuracy for
bankrupt businesses.
Figure 3 shows the estimation accuracy for bankrupt and non-bankrupt businesses, as well as the
percentage of total correct predictions for the DEA model. In the case of non-bankrupt businesses,
the highest estimation accuracy was found at a cut-off of 1. Then the estimation accuracy decreases.
In the case of bankrupt businesses, the estimation accuracy gradually increases up to 100% at a cut-off
point of 0.5 and lower. The overall estimation accuracy decreases with a decreasing cut-off.











%5
 1%5
           2

Figure 3. Percentage of correct predictions using the DEA model. Legend: BR—Estimation Accuracy
for Bankrupt Businesses. NBR—Estimation Accuracy for Non-Bankrupt Businesses, O—Overall
Estimation Accuracy.

278
JRFM 2020, 13, 212

Figure 4 illustrates the estimation accuracy for bankrupt and non-bankrupt businesses, as well as
the percentage of total correct predictions for the Logit model.











%5
 1%5
           2

Figure 4. Percentage of correct predictions using the Logit model.

Figure 4 shows that estimation accuracy in the case of the Logit model is different in comparison
with the results of the DEA model. In the case of non-bankrupt businesses, the highest estimation
accuracy is from a cut-off point of 1 to cut-off point of 0.4; from a cut-off of 0.3, the estimation accuracy
decreases rapidly. In the case of bankrupt businesses, the estimation accuracy gradually increases up
to 100% at a cut-off point of 0. The overall estimation accuracy slightly increases up to a cut-off of 0.3
and then rapidly decreases. At the end of this discussion, it is necessary to point out the fact that each
of the models has its optimal cut-off and the estimation accuracy of the models is given by the selected
value of each cut-off.

5. Conclusions
In this paper, we created specific bankruptcy prediction models for the analysed sample of
businesses with the use of the DEA method and Logit model. Inspired by authors who dealt with
the causes of bankruptcy and based on the correlation matrix, we selected financial indicators as
inputs and outputs for the constructed models. Based on the scientific literature, we also identified the
bankruptcy condition of indebtedness, which was necessary to classify businesses into bankrupt and
non-bankrupt businesses. This condition was applied in the case of the Logit model and together with
the profit, it was verified by this model as a symptom of bankruptcy. Based on the results outlined in
the Results and Discussion section, we can say that the ADD model achieved an estimation accuracy
for bankrupt businesses of 82%. A similar estimation accuracy rate for businesses threatened with
bankruptcy was presented in the work of Premachandra et al. (2009) of 84.89%; Mendelová and
Stachová’s (2016) accuracy rate was 10–42.86% and Cielen et al.’s (2004) accuracy rate was 74.4–75.7%.
We obtained an estimation accuracy of the ADD model for non-bankrupt businesses of 56%, and an
overall estimation accuracy of DEA model of 59%. We can compare this result with the outcomes of
the above-mentioned authors: Premachandra et al. (2009) obtained 75–77%, Mendelová and Stachová
(2016) obtained 88–95%, and Cielen et al. (2004) obtained 85.1–86.4%. The error type I for the ADD
model was 18% and the error type II was 44%.

279
JRFM 2020, 13, 212

Several studies (Premachandra et al. 2011; Paradi et al. 2014) confirm that the traditional cut-off
point of 0.5 may not be appropriate for assessing bankruptcy models’ estimation accuracy. This was
also confirmed in our research. The optimal cut off for DEA model was found to be 0.63, and we
compared the results of the DEA model with the results of theLogit model at this cut-off. Overall
estimation accuracy and estimation accuracy for non-bankrupt businesses was higher in the case of
the Logit model. On the other hand, DEA has a higher estimation accuracy for bankrupt businesses.
Also error type I was lower in the case of the DEA model. The optimal cut-off for Logit model
was different, corresponding to 0.16. It should be noted that estimation accuracy of the models
depends on their cut-off values. Both models have different optimal cut-offs, so the results cannot be
clearly compared. DEA identifies fewer businesses at risk of bankruptcy, but at a higher probability
of achieving bankruptcy. Logit identifies more businesses at risk of bankruptcy, but with a lower
probability of the identified businesses achieving bankruptcy. This fact may also speak in favour of the
application of DEA model in predicting the financial distress of businesses. In this paper, the optimal
cut-off was set as the value at which the sum of sensitivity and specificity is the highest. Another way
of determining an optimal cut-off is to calculate an index based on two DEA models, one representing
the financial health frontier and the other representing the financial distress frontier.
Results of the constructed models can be a starting point to improve financial health, prosperity,
and competitiveness of analysed businesses. Based on the achieved results, we can conclude that
within our research sample, DEA identifies bankrupt businesses at a higher probability of bankruptcy
than the Logit model. The DEA method does not take into account initial bankruptcy conditions
but its results are based on the achieved values of financial indicators, so they are independent of
any assumptions. A significant benefit of this method is that it allows us to accept the specifics of
companies and industry. In contrast to the Logit model, it offers us goal values of indicators, which the
Logit model does not offer. Based on the above-mentioned factors, we can conclude that the DEA
method is a suitable alternative for predicting the failure of businesses from the analysed sample.
In order to increase estimation accuracy of the DEA model and decrease type I and II errors for this
model, in our further research we will focus on selecting explanatory variables from a wider range of
financial and even non-financial indicators.
A limitation of our research is the sample of businesses used, which consisted of a limited number
of companies and insufficient data; therefore, we will improve our sample and data to overcome these
shortcomings in the future. However, it is important to note that the research sample consisted of real
businesses and it took into account all businesses in the Slovak heat sector. Therefore, we can say that
results will be beneficial for that industry.

Author Contributions: All authors contributed to all aspects of this work. All authors have read and agreed to
the published version of the manuscript.
Funding: This research received no external funding.
Acknowledgments: This paper was prepared within the grant scheme VEGA No. 1/0741/20 (The application
of variant methods in detecting symptoms of possible bankruptcy of Slovak businesses in order to ensure their
sustainable development).
Conflicts of Interest: The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References
Achim, Monica Violeta, Codruta Mare, and Sorin Nicolae Borlea. 2012. A statistical model of financial risk
bankruptcy applied for Romanian manufacturing industry. Procedia Economics and Finance 3: 132–7. [CrossRef]
Altman, Edward I. 1968. Financial Ratios, Discriminant Analysis and the Prediction of Corporate Bankruptcy.
Journal of Finance 23: 589–609. [CrossRef]
Altman, Edward I., and Anthony Saunders. 1997. Credit risk measurement: Development over the last 20 years.
Journal of Banking & Finance 21: 1721–42. [CrossRef]
Altman, Edward I., Robert G. Haldeman, and Paul Narayanan. 1977. ZETA ANALYSIS, a new model to identify
bankruptcy risk of corporations. Journal of Banking and Finance 1: 29–54. [CrossRef]

280
JRFM 2020, 13, 212

Altman, Edward I., Giancarlo Marco, and Franco Varetto. 1994. Corporate distress diagnosis: Comparisons using
linear discriminant analysis and neural networks (the Italian experience). Journal of Banking and Finance 18:
505–29. [CrossRef]
Araghi, Khalili, and Sara Makvandi. 2012. Evaluating Predictive power of Data Envelopment Analysis Technique
Compared with Logit and Probit Models in Predicting Corporate Bankruptcy. Australian Journal of Business
and Management Research 2: 38–46.
Aziz, Adnan M., and Humayon A. Dar. 2006. Predicting corporate bankruptcy: Where we stand? Corporate
Governance 6: 18–33. [CrossRef]
Banker, Rajiv D., Abraham Charnes, and William W. Cooper. 1984. Some models for estimating technical and
scale inefficiencies in data envelopment analysis. Management Science 30: 1078–92. [CrossRef]
Beaver, William H. 1966. Financial ratios as predictors of failure. Journal of Accounting Research 4: 71–111. [CrossRef]
Blazy, Régis, Bertrand Chopard, and Agnès Fimayer. 2008. Bankruptcy law: A mechanism of governance for
financially distressed firms. European Journal of Law and Economics 25: 253–67. [CrossRef]
Blum, Marc. 1974. Failing company discriminant analysis. Journal of Accounting Research 12: 1–25. [CrossRef]
Breiman, Leo, Jerome Friedman, Richard Olshen, and Charles J. Stone. 1984. Classification and Regression Trees.
New York: Taylor & Francis.
Charnes, Abraham, William W. Cooper, and Edwardo L. Rhodes. 1978. Measuring the efficiency of decision
making units. European Journal of Operation Research 2: 429–44. [CrossRef]
Charnes, Abraham, William W. Cooper, Boaz Golany, Lawrence M. Seiford, and Joel D. Stutz. 1985. Foundations
of Data Envelopment Analysis for Pareto-Koopmans Efficient Empirical Production Functions. Journal of
Econometrics 30: 91–127. [CrossRef]
Chen, Hsueh-Ju, Shaio Yan Huang, and Chin-Shien Lin. 2009. Alternative diagnosis of corporate bankruptcy:
A neuro fuzzy approach. Expert Systems with Applications 36: 7710–20. [CrossRef]
Cielen, Anja, Ludo Peeters, and Koen Vanhoof. 2004. Bankruptcy prediction using a data envelopment analysis.
European Journal of Operational Research 154: 526–32. [CrossRef]
Csikosova, Adriana, Maria Janoskova, and Katarina Culkova. 2019. Limitation of Financial Health Prediction in
Companies from Post-Communist Countries. Journal of Risk and Financial Management 12: 15. [CrossRef]
Debreu, Gerard. 1951. The coefficient of resource utilization. Econometrica 19: 273–92. [CrossRef]
Delina, Radoslav, and Miroslava Packová. 2013. Validácia predikčných bankrotových modelov v podmienkach
SR. Ekonomie a Management 16: 101–12.
Dimitras, Augustinos I., Stelios H. Zanakis, and Constantin Zopounidis. 1996. A survey of business failures with
an emphasis on prediction methods and industrial applications. European Journal of Operational Research
90: 487–513. [CrossRef]
Ding, Yongsheng, Xinping Song, and Yueming Zen. 2008. Forecasting Financial Condition of Chinese Listed
Companies Based on Support Vector Machine. Expert Systems with Applications 34: 3081–9. [CrossRef]
Dumitrescu, Dalina, Ionela Costică, Liliana Nicoleta Simionescu, and Stefan Cristian Gherghina. 2020.
DEA Approach Towards Exploring the Sustainability of Funding in Higher Education. Empirical Evidence
from Romanian Public Universities. The Amfiteatru Economic journal 22: 593–607. [CrossRef]
Elam, Rick. 1975. The effect of lease data on the predictive ability of financial ratios. The Accounting Review
50: 25–43.
Färe, Rolf, Shawna Grosskopf, and C.A. Knox Lovell. 1985. Measurement of Efficiency of Production. Boston:
Kluwer-Nijhoff Publishing Co.
Farrell, Michael James. 1957. The Measurement of Productive Efficiency. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society,
Series A 120: 253–90. [CrossRef]
Fitzpatrick, Paul Joseph. 1931. A comparison of the ratios of successful industrial enterprises with those of failed
companies. Certified Public Accountant 6: 727–31.
Frydman, Halina, Edward I. Altman, and Duen-Li Kao. 1985. Introducing recursive partitioning for financial
classification: The case of financial distress. Journal of Finance 40: 269–91. [CrossRef]
Geng, Ruibin, Indranil Bose, and Xi Chen. 2014. Prediction of financial distress: An empirical study of listed
Chinese companies using data mining. European Journal of Operational Research 241: 236–47. [CrossRef]
Gherghina, Stefan Cristian. 2015. An Artificial Intelligence Approach towards Investigating Corporate Bankruptcy.
Review of European Studies 7: 5–22. [CrossRef]

281
JRFM 2020, 13, 212

Ghomi, Hamidreza, Morteza Rahmani, and Morteza Khakzar Bafruei. 2019. A two-stage method for assessing the
efficiency of the three-stage series network data envelopment analysis model with two feedback. Decision
Science Letters 8: 339–352. [CrossRef]
Gundová, Petra. 2015. Verification of the selected prediction methods in Slovak companies. Acta Academica
Karviniensia 14: 26–38. [CrossRef]
Horváthová, Jarmila, and Martina Mokrišová. 2018. Risk of Bankruptcy, its Determinants and Models. Risks 6:
117. [CrossRef]
Janiš, Stanislav. 2018. Slovak Heating Companies are Preparing for the Fourth Generation of Heating. In Slovak
Enetgy Annual 2018. Bratislava: RE-PUBLIC, pp. 76–79.
Kao, Chiang, and Shiuh-Nan Hwang. 2008. Efficiency decomposition in twostage data envelopment analysis: An
application to non-life insurance companies in Taiwan. European Journal of Operational Research 185: 418–29.
[CrossRef]
Klieštik, Tomáš, Alexander N. Lyakin, and Katarína Valašková. 2014. Stochastic calculus and modelling in
economics and finance. Paper Presented at 2nd International Conference on Economics and Social Science
ICESS 2014, Shenzhen, China, July 29–30; pp. 161–7.
Koopmans, Tjalling Charles. 1951. Analysis of production as an efficient combination of activities. In Activity
Analysis of Production and Allocation. New York: J. Wiley and Sons, London: Chapman and Hall, pp. 33–97.
Kováčová, Mária, and Tomáš Klieštik. 2017. Logit and Probit application for the prediction of bankruptcy in
Slovak companies. Equilibrium. Quarterly Journal of Economics and Economic Policy 12: 775–91. [CrossRef]
Martin, Daniel. 1977. Early warning of bank failure. A logit regression approach. Journal of Banking and Finance
1: 249–76. [CrossRef]
Martin, Aaron Hillsboro, V. Aswathy, Sundarraman Balaji, T. Muthu Lakshmi, and V. Prasanna Venkatesan. 2012.
An Analysis on Qualitative Bankruptcy Prediction Using Fuzzy ID3 and Ant Colony Optimization Algorithm.
Paper Presented at International Conference on Pattern Recognition, Informatics and Medical Engineering
PRIME 2012, Periyar University, Salem, Tamilnadu, India, March 21–23.
Mendelová, Viera, and Tatiana Bieliková. 2017. Diagnostikovanie finančného zdravia podnikov pomocou metódy
DEA: Aplikácia na podniky v Slovenskej republike. Politická Ekonomie 65: 26–44. [CrossRef]
Mendelová, Viera, and Mária Stachová. 2016. Comparing DEA and logistic regression in corporate financial
distress prediction. Paper Presented at International Scientific Conference FERNSTAT 2016, Banská Bystrica,
Slovakia, September 22–23; pp. 95–104.
Mihalovič, Matúš. 2015. The Assessment of Corporate Financial Performance via Discriminant Analysis.
Acta Oeconomica Cassoviensia: Scientific Journal 8: 57–69. [CrossRef]
Norton, Curtis. L., and Ralph. E. Smith. 1979. A comparison of general price level and historical cost financial
statements in the prediction of bankruptcy. The Accounting Review 54: 72–87.
Oanh, Nguyen Hoang, and Nguyen Hong Ngoc. 2016. An Application of the Data Envelopment Analysis Method
to Evaluate the Performance of Academic Departments within a Higher Education Institution. Journal of
Economics & Development 18: 71–87. [CrossRef]
Odom, Marcus D., and Ramesh Sharda. 1990. A neural network model for bankruptcy prediction. Paper Presented
at 1990 IJCNN International Joint Conference on Neural Networks, San Diego, CA, USA, June 17–21; vol. 2,
pp. 163–68. [CrossRef]
Ohlson, James A. 1980. Financial ratios and the probabilistic prediction of bankruptcy. Journal of Accounting
Research 18: 109–31. [CrossRef]
Paradi, Joseph C., Mette Asmild, and Paul C. Simak. 2004. Using DEA and worst practice DEA in credit risk
evaluation. Journal of Productivity Analysis 21: 153–65. [CrossRef]
Paradi, Joseph C., D’Andre Wilson, and Xiaopeng Yang. 2014. Data Envelopment Analysis of Corporate Failure for
Non-Manufacturing Firms Using a Slack-Based Measure. Journal of Service Science and Management 7: 277–90.
[CrossRef]
Park, Seong Ho, Jin Mo Goo, and Chan-Hee Jo. 2004. Receiver Operating Characteristic (ROC) Curve: Practical
Review for Radiologists. Korean Journal of Radiology 5: 11–8. [CrossRef] [PubMed]
Premachandra, Inguruwatt M., Gurmeet Singh Bhabra, and Toshiyuki Sueyoshi. 2009. DEA as a tool for bankruptcy
assessment: A comparative study with logistic regression technique. European Journal of Operational Research
193: 412–24. [CrossRef]

282
JRFM 2020, 13, 212

Premachandra, Inguruwatt M., Yao Chen, and John Watson. 2011. DEA as a Tool for Predicting Corporate Failure
and Success: A Case of Bankruptcy Assessment. Omega 3: 620–6. [CrossRef]
Sadjadi, Seyed Jafar, and Hashem Omrani. 2008. Data envelopment analysis with uncertain data: An application
for Iranian electricity distribution companies. Energy Policy 36: 4247–54. [CrossRef]
Scarlat, Emil, and Camelia Delcea. 2011. Complete analysis of bankruptcy syndrome using grey systems theory.
Grey Systems: Theory and Application 1: 19–32. [CrossRef]
Shetty, Udaya, TPM Pakkala, and Thathaiah Mallikarjunappa. 2012. A modified directional distance formulation
of DEA to assess bankruptcy: An application to IT/ITES companies in India. Expert Systems with Applications
9: 1988–97. [CrossRef]
Simak, Paul C. 1997. DEA Based Analysis of Coporate Failure. Master’s thesis, Faculty of Applied Sciences and
Engineering, University of Toronto, Toronto, ON, Canada.
Sperandei, Sandro. 2014. Understanding logistic regression analysis. Biochemia Medica 24: 12–18. [CrossRef]
Štefko, Róbert, Beata Slusarczyk, Sebastian Kot, and Cezary Kolmasiak. 2012. Transformation on steel products
distribution in Poland and Slovakia. Metalurgija 51: 133–6.
Štefko, Róbert, Beáta Gavurová, and Kristína Kočišová. 2018. Healthcare efficiency assessment using DEA analysis
in the Slovak Republic. Health Economics Review 8: 1–12. [CrossRef]
Sueyoshi, Toshiyuki, and Mika Goto. 2009. Methodological comparison between DEA and DEA-DA from the
perspective of bankruptcy assessment. European Journal of Operational Research 188: 561–75. [CrossRef]
Suhányi, Ladislav, and Alžbeta Suhányiová. 2017. Competitiveness of Slovak spa facilities. Paper Presented at
4th International Multidisciplinary Scientific Conference on Social Sciences and Arts SGEM 2017, Albena,
Bulgaria, August 24–30; vol. 4, pp. 153–60.
Sun, Jie, Hui Li, Qing-Hua Huang, and Kai-Yu He. 2014. Predicting Financial Distress and Corporate
Failure: A Review from the State-of-the-art Definitions, Modeling, Sampling, and Featuring Approaches.
Knowledge-Based Systems 57: 41–56. [CrossRef]
Taffler, Richard J. 1983. The assessment of company solvency and performance using a statistical model. Accounting
and Business Research 13: 295–308. [CrossRef]
Tone, Kaoru. 2001. A slacks-based measure of efficiency in data envelopment analysis. European Journal of
Operational Research 130: 498–509. [CrossRef]
Trahms, Cheryl A., Hermann Achidi Ndofor, and David G. Sirmon. 2013. Organizational decline and
turnaround—A review and agenda for future research. Journal of Management 39: 1277–307. [CrossRef]
Wang, Ying-Ming, Kwai-Sang Chin, and Jian-Bo Yang. 2007. Measuring the performances of decision-making
units using geometric average efficiency. Journal of the Operational Research Society 58: 929–37. [CrossRef]
Zhu, Joe, ed. 2015. DEA Based Benchmarking Models. In Data Envelopment Analysis. International Series in
Operations Research & Management Science. Boston: Springer, vol. 221. [CrossRef]

© 2020 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access
article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution
(CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).

283
Journal of
Risk and Financial
Management

Article
Corporate Governance and Firm Performance:
A Comparative Analysis between Listed Family
and Non-Family Firms in Japan
Kojima Koji 1 , Bishnu Kumar Adhikary 2, * and Le Tram 3
1 School of International Studies, Kwansei Gakuin University, Nishinomiya 662-8501, Japan;
kojima@kwansei.ac.jp
2 Doshisha Business School, Doshisha University, Kyoto 6028580, Japan
3 Zurich Insurance Company Ltd, Tokyo 1640003, Japan; thibichtram.le@zurich.co.jp
* Correspondence: biadhika@mail.doshisha.ac.jp

Received: 19 August 2020; Accepted: 15 September 2020; Published: 18 September 2020

Abstract: This study aims to explore the relationship between corporate governance and financial
performance of publicly listed family and non-family firms in the Japanese manufacturing industry.
The study obtains data from Bloomberg over the period 2014–2018 and covers 1412 firms comprising
of 861 non-family and 551 family firms. Our results show that family firms outperform non-family
counterparts in terms of return on assets (ROA) and Tobin’s Q when a univariate analysis is invoked.
On multivariate analysis, family firms show superior performance to non-family firms with Tobin’s Q.
However, family ownership negates firm performance when ROA is taken into account. Regarding
the impact of governance elements on Tobin’s Q, institutional shareholding appears to be a significant
and positive factor for promoting the performance of both family and non-family firms. Furthermore,
board size encourages the performance of non-family firms, while such influence is not observed
for family firms. In terms of ROA, foreign ownership inspires the performance of both family and
non-family firms. Moreover, government ownership stimulates the performance of family firms,
while board independence significantly negates the same. Besides, we find that the performance of
family firms run by the founder’s descendants is superior to that of family firms run by the founder.
These findings have critical policy implications for family firms in Japan.

Keywords: family firm; non-family firm; corporate governance; corporate performance; Japan

JEL Classification: G32; M13

1. Introduction
In recent times, the performance difference between family and non-family firms has received
a new impetus to study because many studies claim that family firms outperform the non-family
firms (Anderson and Reeb 2003; Sharma 2004; Allouche et al. 2008; Saito 2008; Chu 2011; Hansen and
Block 2020; Srivastava and Bhatia 2020), while some others do not document the existence of such a
relationship (Filatotchev et al. 2005; McConaughy and Phillips 1999; Miller et al. 2007; Yoshikawa and
Rasheed 2010). Prior studies also note that the performance difference between family and non-family
firms arises due to the governance system and corporate cultures across countries (Allouche et al. 2008;
Srivastava and Bhatia 2020).
Given the above inconclusive results, we study and compare the financial performance of family
and non-family firms in Japan from the governance perspective to add value. We consider Japan as a
case for two reasons. First, family firms constitute over 40% of the listed firms in Japan (Saito 2008),
implying the importance of such firms on stock market development and economic growth. However,

JRFM 2020, 13, 215; doi:10.3390/jrfm13090215 285 www.mdpi.com/journal/jrfm


JRFM 2020, 13, 215

not many researchers have deep-dived to investigate the factors contributing to the performance
difference between family and non-family firms in Japan. Furthermore, the limited empirical works on
the performance of family firms in Japan offer mixed results. For example, Allouche et al. (2008) and
Saito (2008) revealed that family firms perform better than non-family firms in Japan. Dazai et al. (2016)
claimed that Japanese family firms outperform their counterparts, particularly after the economic
bubble in 1991. However, Morikawa (2013) discovered that the annual productivity growth rate (one of
the indicators of a firm’s performance) of non-family firms in Japan was about 2% higher than that of
family firms. Saito (2008) noted that the performance of founder-run firms was worse than non-family
firms, but the performance of family firms owned by the founder’s successors was better than the
non-family firms. Moreover, Yoshikawa and Rasheed (2010) did not trace a significant relationship
between family ownership and return on assets (ROA) in Japanese Over-The-Counter (“OTC”) market
listed firms in the manufacturing industry. Since most of the studies on family firms in Japan were
conducted a fairly long time before, updated evidence on the performance difference between Japanese
family and non-family firms is instrumental for policy implications.
Secondly, the Japanese governance structure is found to be somewhat different from that of
US-style governance. The distinct Japanese governance system, such as the Japanese integrated
monitoring system practiced by main banks, life-time employment system, and cross-shareholdings
which contributed to the post-World War II economic growth rates of Japan, were substantially changed
after the “big bang financial and accounting reform in 1997” in favor of the US-style governance. Even
though the impact of the reform program helped the increase of independent directors, encouraged
foreign shareholding, and reduced shareholding by main banks, Japanese firms are still found to
be characterized by the board of directors promoted from within the firms (Arikawa et al. 2017),
relatively less numbers of independent directors (two or more as per Corporate Governance Code,
2015), insider CEOs, and a higher percentage of family ownership. Thus, it is essential to know
whether the current financial setup impacts the performance of family firms in Japan. Clearly, do the
governance mainsprings such as board structure and ownership patterns impact on the performance
difference between Japanese family and non-family firms?
We explain the above question by studying all the manufacturing firms listed in Tokyo, Nagoya,
and Osaka stock markets covering the period 2014–2018. We consider manufacturing firms because this
sector accounts for nearly half of the total number of corporations existing in Japan while contributing
approximately 20% of Japan’s GDP. The Japanese manufacturing industry is still very sizeable and
significantly crucial to the Japanese economy. Furthermore, we exclude the financial and service sectors
because they have a different asset structure from the manufacturing firms.
Our results show that family firms outperform the non-family counterparts on both accounting
and market-based measures of firm performance, such as ROA and Tobin’s Q, when univariate
analysis is invoked. On multivariate analysis, family ownership reduces firm performance, indexed
by ROA, but promotes the same with Tobin’s Q. Among the governance elements, we find that
institutional shareholding is a significant and positive factor for boosting the performance of both
family and non-family firms. Moreover, board size inspires the performance of non-family firms, while
such influence is not observed for family firms. In terms of ROA, foreign ownership stimulates the
performance of both family and non-family firms. Furthermore, government ownership positively
influences the performance of family firms, while board independence significantly negates the same.
Besides, we find that the performance of family firms run by the founder’s descendants are superior to
that of family firms run by the founder.
The rest of the paper is structured as follows: Section 2 develops hypotheses, and Section 3
presents the research methods. Section 4 discusses regression results, while Section 5 concludes
the paper.

286
JRFM 2020, 13, 215

2. Hypotheses

2.1. Family Ownership and Firm Performance


Agency theory can be put into place to discuss the performance difference between family and
non-family firms. Agency theory states that executives do not have an interest in the firm’s long-term
performance (Jensen and Meckling 1976; Dalton et al. 1998), and they tend to make a decision based on
their preferences, looking for short-term gain while ignoring shareholders’ interests (Kallmuenzer 2015).
Thus, from the agency theory perspective, family firms tend to perform better than non-family firms
because the involvement of family members in both ownership and management can minimize this
particular conflict of interest between managers and owners. Moreover, family firms are likely to
have longer investment horizons, resulting in higher investment efficiency (Muttakin et al. 2014),
as they want to preserve firm value for successive generations (Achleitner et al. 2014; Hasso and
Duncan 2013). Moreover, empirical works by Razzaque et al. (2020) and Muttakin et al. (2014)
reveal that family ownership has a positive impact on the performance of Bangladeshi manufacturing
firms. Herrera-Echeverri et al. (2016) concluded that the family’s involvement in the ownership and
management often led to a more stable directorship for Columbian family firms. Blanco-Mazagatos et al.
(2018) reported that family ownership has a positive influence on the performance of Spanish second-
and later-generation firms. The more robust performance of family firms is also reported for companies
in the S&P 500 (Anderson and Reeb 2003).
In the Japanese context, Chen et al. (2005) found evidence that supports the positive effect of
family ownership on firm performance. Saito (2008) concluded that family control has a link to higher
Tobin’s Q. Similarly, Chen and Yu (2017) contend that Japanese and Taiwanese firms run by founders
are traded at a higher value in the stock market.
Notably, there could be a Type II agency problem (principal–principal conflict) in family firms
because the interest of family members may not necessarily be in line with the interest of minority
shareholders (Muttakin et al. 2014). Besides, family firms usually hire executives from close relatives
ignoring outside talents, resulting in suboptimal financial performance (Anderson and Reeb 2003).
Accordingly, some empirical studies found a negative link between family ownership and firm
performance (Yoshikawa and Rasheed 2010, for Japan).
Nonetheless, we argue that founders or family members who own and control the firms have
stronger motivation to create wealth for successors. Thus, they tend to adopt long-run views in their
investment horizons, which discourage them from taking higher risks, leading to generate stable
returns for shareholders. Furthermore, higher family ownership reduces agency costs by reducing
managerial myopia, moral hazards, and the agency problem. On this basis, we formulate Hypothesis 1.

Hypothesis 1 (H1). Family ownership encourages the performance of family firms.

2.2. Institutional Ownership and Firm Performance


Institutional ownership is considered to be a useful tool to reduce the Type II agency problem,
where family firms may expropriate profits at the expense of minority shareholders. Dau et al. (2018)
report that institutional ownership improves the ROA of family firms in India. A study on 134 listed
firms in Kuwait reveals that institutional investors encourage firm performance, indexed by ROA
and Tobin’s Q (Alfaraid et al. 2012). By contrast, Ahmad et al. (2019) found a significant negative
relationship between institutional investors and ROA for non-financial firms in Pakistan. Charfeddine
and Elmarzougui (2011) traced that institutional ownership has a significant negative impact on Tobin’s
Q for French firms. However, Alnajjar (2015) found no substantial effect of institutional ownership on
both ROA and Return on Equity (ROE) for firms in Jordan. Regarding the Japanese firms, Mizuno
and Shimizu (2015) found that firms with a higher level of institutional ownership tended to perform
better than firms having less or no institutional ownership. Moreover, Yasuhiro et al. (2016) and

287
JRFM 2020, 13, 215

Arikawa et al. (2017) found a significant positive association between institutional ownership and
Tobin’s Q. However, they did not see any relationship between institutional ownership and ROA.
We argue that institutional investors can mitigate much of the agency problem associated with
family firms as they hold a significant equity stake in the firm (Charfeddine and Elmarzougui 2011).
Institutional investors are seen to be more powerful than non-institutional investors in exercising
voting rights and selling shares when management actions are not aligned with shareholders’ interests
(Arikawa et al. 2017). Furthermore, institutional shareholders can protect the interest of minority
shareholders and reduce the Type II agency problem by monitoring the firm’s management. Therefore,
following previous empirical findings and agency theory, we take the following hypothesis.

Hypothesis 2 (H2). Institutional ownership encourages the performance of family firms.

2.3. Government Ownership and Firm Performance


Few pieces of research have studied the impact of government ownership on firm performance.
Fukuda et al. (2018) argued that the government, as a shareholder, can reduce companies’ financing
costs. A study on Vietnamese firms from 2004–2012 provides evidence that an increase of government
ownership in large firms improves firms’ ROA and ROE, while for middle and small firms, it hurts
the same (Ngo et al. 2014). Similarly, a study on listed firms in Shanghai and Shenzhen Stock
Exchange reveals a positive relationship between government shareholdings and firm performance
(Sun et al. 2002). Ahmad et al. (2008) obtained similar positive results for the link between government
ownership and firm performance, measured by both Tobin’s Q and ROA, in Malaysian firms.
In the case of Japan, Fukuda et al. (2018) noted that the effect of government ownership on firm
performance varies depending on the state of the company, such as good, normal, or bad (performance
is measured based on operating profit ratios in previous years). Their study revealed that a negative
relationship runs between government ownership and Tobin’s Q for good and normal Japanese firms,
while a positive association exists for the same for bad performing companies. Notably, unlike the
private sector, the government neither pursues aggressive growth nor puts too much pressure on
the management to improve their financial performance (Fukuda et al. 2018). With that being said,
the higher the government’s shareholding inside the firm, the less well-performed the firm is. Thus,
we take the following hypothesis.

Hypothesis 3 (H3). Government ownership inhibits the performance of family firms.

2.4. Foreign Ownership and Firm Performance


Many studies have been conducted to examine the relationship between foreign ownership and
the firms’ profitability. Firms with foreign ownerships are found to have better ROA than firms with
higher domestic ownerships in Turkey (Aydin et al. 2007). A positive relationship between foreign
ownership and profitability is also observed in a study of Tunisian firms (Moez et al. 2015). Likewise,
a study on 663 non-financial listed firms on the Korea Stock Exchange from 2001 to 2017 revealed
that foreign ownership enhances firms’ long-term growth rate, thus increasing firm value, indexed
by Tobin’s Q (Choi and Park 2019). Moreover, foreign ownership can reduce agency costs because
foreigners can use their expertise in monitoring management, thereby improving firms’ profitability
(Choi and Park 2019).
As for Japanese firms, Fukuda et al. (2018) found a positive relationship between foreign shareholding
and Tobin’s Q. Although Sueyoshi et al. (2010) found a similar result, they note that the influence of
foreign shareholding on firm performance diminishes when the ratio of foreign shareholders increases to
19.49%. Yoshikawa and Rasheed (2010) considered the interaction effect of foreign ownership and ROE for
the OTC market listed Japanese firms in the manufacturing industry and revealed that foreign investors
influence family owners to improve firm performance. Hideaki et al. (2015) unearthed a significant
positive association between foreign shareholding and Tobin’s Q for Japanese firms even after controlling

288
JRFM 2020, 13, 215

the effect of various factors that may affect firm performance. By contrast, Kojima et al. (2017) found a
negative relationship between foreign shareholdings and earnings quality.
We note that foreign investors can improve the performance of family firms in the following ways.
First, foreign ownership does not just simply mean financial contribution but the transfer of knowledge,
technology, innovations, and management expertise from foreign firms, which are essential to the
growth of family firms. Second, foreign shareholders are often perceived as a catalyst for growth and
change. If the domestic firm’s performance goes downhill, foreign firms can layout necessary efforts to
adopt various strategies to improve the firm’s value. Third, foreign investors can play an essential role
in disciplining managers of family firms, which are mostly recruited from family members without
considering market talents.
However, foreign shareholders may easily ruin firm value if they leave firms during an economic
slowdown. Another negative point is that foreigners may be biased in making investment decisions
by choosing the firms based on their preferences, not by looking and carefully examining the firm’s
performance. In that case, the higher stock returns or more top market-based indicators do not reflect the
firm’s true performance. Instead, it only shows the investors’ biased preferences (Hideaki et al. 2015).
Nonetheless, foreign investors are generally reported to have a positive effect on firm performance in
previous literature. Thus, we take the following hypothesis.

Hypothesis 4 (H4). Foreign ownership encourages the performance of family firms.

2.5. Board Size and Firm Performance


Extant literature shows inconclusive results for the link between board size and firm performance.
Lorsch and Maclver (1989) point out that a larger board size hurts firm performance because it impedes
faster decision-making. Besides, a large board size incurs higher coordination costs because of the
arduous process of trying to reach a consensus amongst all board members. Empirical works also trace
a significant negative relationship between large board size and firm performance in many countries
(Eisenberg et al. 1998, for Finland; Mak and Kusnadi 2005, for Malaysia and Singapore; Naushad and
Malik 2015, for Bangladesh; Aljifri and Moustafa 2007, for the United Arab Emirates). In the context of
Japan, Hu and Izumida (2008) and Sueyoshi et al. (2010) found no significant relationship between
board size and firm performance. Nonetheless, some scholars argue that a large board size can enhance
board independence and diversity, thereby increasing firm performance (Ciftci et al. 2019, for Turkish
firms; Jackling and Johl 2009, for Indian firms).
We argue that, for family firms, most of the board members are selected from family members
who are expected to be free riders. Thus, the coordination problem arising from a larger board size
would not be a severe issue for family firms. Instead, a larger board of directors could bring in more
opinions from members of diverse backgrounds and enhance firm performance by improving strategic
decision-making. Thus, we take the following hypothesis.

Hypothesis 5 (H5). Board size encourages the performance of family firms.

2.6. Board Meeting and Firm Performance


A limited number of studies have been conducted so far to examine the relationship between
board meetings and firm performance. Vafeas (1999) found a negative correlation between board
meetings and firm value. He concluded that frequent board meetings can play an important role
in enhancing firm performance because it helps to reduce the informational gap among the board
members. Furthermore, Chou et al. (2013) traced a positive link between the frequency of board
meetings and firm profitability for Taiwanese firms. They further noted that outside directors are
less likely to attend board meetings for companies with a higher percentage of family ownership.
However, a study on Columbian firms revealed no significant relationship between the number of
board meetings and ROA or ROE (Gomez et al. 2017).

289
JRFM 2020, 13, 215

In the Japanese context, the board of directors in family firms usually consists of directors selected
from their relatives or employees who have been with the company under the life-time employment
scheme, implying that there is little to no fresh ideas and perspectives in the board. Therefore, for family
firms, the traditional group thinking may dominate the entire discussion process, while innovation and
breakthrough ideas would often be given away for conservatism. Nevertheless, the board meeting is
considered to be an essential factor for promoting firm performance because frequent board meetings
make everyone aligned about various issues faced by companies and resolve them smoothly and
timely. Huse (2007) noted that a higher number of board meetings provide effective monitoring on
the board and quickly reach a consensus in resolving corporate issues. On this basis, we take the
following hypothesis.

Hypothesis 6 (H6). Frequency in board meetings encourages the performance of family firms.

2.7. Board Independence and Firm Performance


Previous studies suggest that independent directors can improve a firm’s decision making by
providing effective monitoring on the board (Jensen and Meckling 1976). Huson et al. (2001) revealed
a positive relationship between independent directors and firm performance. Yasuhiro et al. (2016)
found that boards dominated by insiders have a significant effect on low profitability and market
valuation of Japanese firms. They noted that independent directors could guarantee and promote
risk-taking action, thereby creating a significant positive impact on firm performance (both ROA and
Tobin’s Q). Arikawa et al. (2017) unearthed that ROA and Tobin’s Q increase by 0.6% and 0.26%,
respectively when outside directors increase by 29%. In addition, in examining 144 companies that
appointed their first outside directors, Saito (2009) reported that the stock prices of these companies
responded significantly positively, rising approximately 1.2% on average, and 1% at the median.
We note that family firms can receive valuable advice if they encourage more independent
directors on the board. In Japan, many independent directors are found to be life-long employees who
were hired to serve on the company’s board upon retirement. With such a long-term commitment,
these independent directors are likely to direct the firm towards sustainable growth, not just for a
short-term profit (Bauer et al. 2008). Therefore, we take the following hypothesis.

Hypothesis 7 (H7). Board independence encourages the performance of family firms.

3. Research Methods

3.1. Definition of Family Firms


We classified a company as a family firm if it satisfied any of the five criteria: (a) run by a founder;
(b) run by family members who hold important positions inside the company (such as Chairman,
Vice Chairman, Chief Executive Officer); (c) controlled by family members who are on the top 10
shareholder list; (d) controlled by family members who account for 50% of the number of board members;
and (e) owned by a privately held company. We adopted these criteria following previous studies on
Japanese family firms (Yoshikawa and Rasheed 2010; Saito 2008; Morikawa 2013; Arikawa et al. 2017;
Hideaki et al. 2018).

3.2. Sample Description


We applied the archival research method in which data was collected from various secondary
sources. General and financial data were collected from OSIRIS (software version 213, a database
managed by Bureau van Dijk, BvD). The search strategy was customized to look for all of the listed
companies in the manufacturing industry in Japan. First of all, companies that were in operation in
Japan were selected. Then, all companies in the manufacturing industry were chosen based on the
North American Industry Classification System (NAICS). After the initial search, 1601 companies

290
JRFM 2020, 13, 215

were identified as publicly listed Japanese companies in the manufacturing industry. Companies
were grouped into 21 different sub-industry codes, depending on the nature of their business. These
companies were then screened to see if they had sufficient data for analysis. We omitted 163 companies
that lacked 5-year financial data and 26 companies that changed their industries during the study period
2014–2108. Accordingly, our sample firms reduced to 1412 publicly listed firms in the manufacturing
industry, giving a sample size of 1412 × 5 = 7060 observations (n × T). We collected corporate governance
data from Bloomberg. Table 1 lists out the number and percentage of family and non-family firms in
each industry grouping.

Table 1. Family and non-family manufacturing firms by North American Industry Classification
System (NAICS) 2017 Code.

Non-Family Family Percentage of


Industry Total
Firms Firms Family Firms
311: Food manufacturing 59 39 98 39.80
312: Beverage and tobacco product manufacturing 11 3 14 21.43
313: Textile mills 22 4 26 15.38
314: Textile product mills 7 2 9 22.22
315: Apparel manufacturing 17 11 28 39.29
316: Leather and allied product manufacturing 3 0 3 0.00
321: Wood product manufacturing 9 7 16 43.75
322: Paper manufacturing 20 16 36 44.44
323: Printing and related support activities 11 14 25 56.00
324: Petroleum and coal product manufacturing 9 1 10 10.00
325: Chemical manufacturing 135 77 212 36.32
326: Plastics and rubber product manufacturing 24 20 44 45.45
327: Nonmetallic mineral product manufacturing 31 20 51 39.22
331: Primary metal manufacturing 54 16 70 22.86
332: Fabricated metal product manufacturing 57 28 85 32.94
333: Machinery manufacturing 126 82 208 39.42
334: Computer and electronic product manufacturing 138 105 243 43.21
335: Electronic equipment, appliance, and component manufacturing 33 30 63 47.62
336: Transportation equipment manufacturing 72 34 106 32.08
337: Furniture and related product manufacturing 2 10 12 83.33
339: Miscellaneous manufacturing 21 32 53 60.38
Total 861 551 1412 39.02
Note: This table shows the number and the percentage of family firms and non-family firms in the manufacturing
industry in Japan. The industry classification is based on the North American Industry Classification System 2017,
extracted from the OSIRIS database. The sample comprises of listed firms on the Stock Exchange of Tokyo, Osaka,
and Nagoya.

Table 1 reveals that family firms account for 39% of the manufacturing firms in Japan. The distribution
in the number of family firms in the top five segments, such as computer and electronics (43%), chemicals
(36%), machinery (40%), transportation equipment (32%), and food manufacturing (40%), is found to be
relatively closer. For other segments, the distribution between family and non-family firms is found to
be skewed. For example, ten firms out of twelve firms in furniture and related product manufacturing
are found to be family firms. Likewise, only 10% of firms are seen to be family firms in petroleum and
coal product manufacturing. Finally, the statistical data indicates that the presence of family firms in
the Japanese manufacturing industry is strong, except for some variations. This also supports previous
academic research that family ownership is an essential characteristic of Japanese firms.

3.3. Description of Variables


For dependent variables, we used both accounting (ROA) and market-based (Tobin’s Q) methods
to measure firm performance. For test variables, we considered some ownership and board structure
data available on Bloomberg. Moreover, we controlled several firm-specific variables to get robust
estimates. Table 2 summarizes the list of variables together with their definitions and formulas.

291
JRFM 2020, 13, 215

Table 2. List of variables.

Variables Abbreviation Definition Formula


Performance Characteristics—Dependent Variables
The percentage of net income after
Return on assets ROA paying preferred dividends divided by (Net income/Total assets) × 100
average total assets for the year
The market value of a firm divided by
Tobin’s Q Tobin’s Q (Market capitalization/Total assets) × 100
its value of total assets
Firm-Specific Characteristics—Control Variables
Natural logarithm of market
Firm size SIZE Ln (Outstanding shares × share price)
capitalization
Firm age AGE Natural logarithm of the firm’s age Ln (financial year–year of incorporation)
Cash flow over The percentage of cash generated from
CFOP Cash flow/operating revenue
operating revenue carrying out its operating activities
The percentage of total liability to
Debt to equity ratio LEV Total liability/Shareholders’ equity
shareholder equity
Ownership Characteristics—Independent Variables
The percentage of equity owned by the
Sum of the percentage of shares (founder, family
Family ownership FAM firm’s founder and/or family members
members, privately held firms)
and/or privately held firms
Sum of the percentage of shares (investment
advisor, bank, corporation, insurance company,
Institutional The percentage of equity owned by stock ownership plan, holding company,
INS
ownership different institutions sovereign wealth fund, pension fund, hedge fund
managers, venture capital, brokerage, hedge
fund, trust, foundation, private equity fund)
The percentage of equity owned by
Foreign ownership FOR foreigners (other than Japanese) The percentage of equity owned by foreigners
individual/institution
Government The percentage of equity owned by the The percentage of equity owned by the
GOV
ownership Japanese government Japanese government
Board Characteristics—Independent Variables
Board size BO_SIZE Number of board members Number of board members
Board meeting Number of the board of director’s Number of the board of director’s meetings
BO_MEET
frequency meetings in one year in one year
Board Percentage of independent directors,
BO_IND (Independent directors on board/board size) × 100
independence defined as outside directors

3.4. Data Diagnosis


To ensure linearity and to avoid the outlier problem, we ran primary regression on the independent
variables to obtain residuals and estimated values for dependent variables. We then plotted the residual
and estimated values on the residual-versus-fitted graph to detect linearity. Then, we corrected the
outlier problem by winsorizing data at 1% and 99% tails. After winsorizing, we had 7055 observations.
Figure 1 confirms linearity after data winsorizing.






5HVLGXDOV
5HVLGXDOV







         
)LWWHGYDOXHV )LWWHGYDOXHV

ȱ
MultipleȱRegressionȱonȱROAȱ MultipleȱRegressionȱonȱTobin’sȱQȱ

Figure 1. Residual-versus-fitted plot after data winsorizing. Source: authors’ construction.

292
JRFM 2020, 13, 215

3.5. Econometric Model


We conducted a Hausman test to see whether the fixed effect or random effect model was
suitable for regression. The test result yields a Chi-squared value of 391.42 with a 1% significance
level and supports the use of the fixed-effect model. Accordingly, we ran the following fixed effect
regression model.

PERFORMANCE = β0 + β1 SIZE + β2 AGE + β3 CFOP + β4 LEV + β5 FAM + β6 INS +


β7 GOV + β8 FOR + β9 BO_SIZE + β10 BO_MEET + β11 BO_IND + β12 FAM*INS + (1)
β13 FAM*GOV + β14 FAM* FOR + β15 BO_SIZESQ + β16 BO_MEETSQ + ε

where PERFORMANCE represents the dependent variables: ROA and Tobin’s Q. Variables such as
SIZE, AGE, CFOP, and LEV are control variables defined in Table 2. Similarly, variables such as
FAM, INS, GOV, FOR, BO-SIZE, BO_MEET, and BO_IND are the test variables defined in Table 2.
We also include INS, GOV, and FOR as interaction with FAM to see their moderating effects on firm
performance. Further, we square BO-SIZE and BO_MEET to see the non-linear relationship. β0 is the
unknown intercept for each firm, and ε is the between-entity error.
To ensure the consistency of our estimates, we also invoked the following random effect
regression model.

PERFORMANCE = β0 + β1 SIZE + β2 AGE + β3 CFOP + β4 LEV + β5 FAM + β6 INS +


β7 GOV + β8 FOR + β9 BO_SIZE + β10 BO_MEET + β11 BO_IND + β12 FAM*INS + (2)
β13 FAM*GOV + β14 FAM* FOR + β15 BO_SIZESQ + β16 BO_MEETSQ + u + ε

where u is the between-entity error, and ε is the within-entity error. All other variables are the same as
defined in Equation (1).

4. Results and Discussion

4.1. Descriptive Statistics


Tables 3 and 4 provide descriptive statistics and mean comparison tests of the variables used in the
study, respectively. As is observed in Table 3, family firms are found to perform better than the non-family
firms in terms of Tobin’s Q and ROA. The mean values of family firms’ ROA (net income/total assets*100)
and Tobin’s Q (market capitalization/total assets*100) are 5.092 and 0.774, respectively, as compared to
5.045 and 0.646 mean values of non-family firms, as shown in Table 3. Similarly, the median value of
ROA (5.100) and Tobin’s Q (0.503) for family firms is higher than that of non-family firms, as shown in
Table 4. However, the mean and median comparison tests (t-test and z-test) yield a significant difference
between family and non-family firms in terms of Tobin’s Q, as shown in Table 4. The above results
are consistent with previous literature, which points out that family firms tend to perform better than
non-family firms (Chen et al. 2005; Saito 2008; Morikawa 2013; Dazai et al. 2016; Chen and Yu 2017).
Regarding the test variables, family firms have higher family ownership concentration than
non-family firms because they are owned by founders or controlled by founding family members.
On the other hand, family firms have a lower level of institution, government, and foreign ownership
than non-family firms. The presence of institutional investors in family firms is around 15%, while it
is about 17% in non-family firms. The government owns approximately a 1% share in family firms
as opposed to nearly a 0.8% share in non-family firms. Besides, foreign owners tend to invest less in
family firms with an average of a 2% equity stake compared to non-family firms with an average of a
3% share, as shown in Table 3.

293
JRFM 2020, 13, 215

Table 3. Descriptive statistics.

All Firms Non-Family Firms Family Firms


Variable (n = 7055 Observations) (n = 4305 Observations) (n = 2750 Observations)
Mean Std. dev Min Max Mean Std. dev Min Max Mean Std. dev Min Max
Performance Characteristics
ROA 5.064 5.433 −18.440 19.680 5.045 4.976 −18.440 19.680 5.092 6.080 −18.440 19.680
Tobin_Q 0.696 0.704 0.000 4.502 0.646 0.622 0.000 4.502 0.774 0.811 0.000 4.502
Firm-Specific Characteristics
SIZE 2.986 1.508 0.000 6.992 3.118 1.491 0.000 6.992 2.779 1.512 0.000 6.992
AGE 1.745 0.254 0.778 2.117 1.782 0.247 0.778 2.117 1.688 0.255 0.778 2.117
CFOP 8.499 5.260 0.000 27.460 8.581 5.108 0.000 27.460 8.369 5.487 0.000 27.460
LEV 43.711 18.536 8.080 85.440 45.067 18.183 8.080 85.440 41.592 18.885 8.080 85.440
Ownership Characteristics
FAM 0.625 3.029 0.000 22.370 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 1.602 4.685 0.000 22.370
INS 16.283 33.597 0.000 97.610 17.285 35.298 0.000 97.610 14.718 30.693 0.000 97.610
GOV 0.962 2.694 0.000 12.110 1.110 2.911 0.000 12.110 0.731 2.296 0.000 12.110
FOR 2.563 7.529 0.000 39.810 2.921 8.144 0.000 39.810 2.004 6.414 0.000 39.810
Board Characteristics
BO_SIZE 5.761 4.713 0.000 16.000 6.523 4.556 0.000 16.000 4.570 4.707 0.000 16.000
BO_MEET 8.917 7.520 0.000 24.000 9.974 7.219 0.000 24.000 7.262 7.683 0.000 24.000
BO_IND 13.504 14.375 0.000 57.143 15.142 14.155 0.000 57.143 10.941 14.344 0.000 57.143

Table 4. Mean and median comparison between family and non-family firms.

Mean Median
Variable
Non-Family (a) Family (b) (a)–(b) t-Value Non-Family (c) Family (d) (c)–(d) z-Value
Performance Characteristics
ROA 4.976 5.092 −0.047 −0.338 4.900 5.100 −0.200 −1.359
Tobin_Q 0.622 0.774 −0.128 −7.074 ** 0.476 0.503 −0.027 −4.123 **
Firm-specific Characteristics
SIZE 3.118 2.779 0.339 9.237 ** 2.741 2.383 0.358 11.364 **
AGE 1.782 1.688 0.093 15.157 ** 1.833 1.763 0.070 20.843 **
CFOP 8.581 8.369 0.212 1.626 7.870 7.600 0.270 2.843 **
LEV 45.067 41.592 3.475 7.651 ** 44.590 40.490 4.100 7.723 **
Ownership Characteristics
FAM 0.000 1.602 −1.602 −17.947 ** 0.000 0.000 0.000 −28.217 **
INS 17.285 14.718 2.567 3.230 ** 0.000 0.000 0.000 1.882
GOV 1.110 0.731 0.379 6.088 ** 0.000 0.000 0.000 4.092 **
FOR 2.921 2.004 0.917 5.263 ** 0.000 0.000 0.000 1.178
Board Characteristics
BO_SIZE 6.523 4.570 1.953 17.223 ** 8.000 5.000 3.000 16.992 **
BO_MEET 9.974 7.262 2.712 14.802 ** 13.000 5.000 8.000 13.797 **
BO_IND 15.142 10.941 4.200 12.057 ** 14.286 0.000 14.286 13.748 **
Note: ** meaning p-value is less than 0.01; t-value is the result from t-student test comparing the mean of two groups
with unequal variances at confidence level of 95%; z-value is the result from two-samples Wilcoxon rank-sum
(or Mann–Whitney U) test comparing the median of two groups. The null hypothesis is the two groups are equal
versus the alternative hypothesis that the two groups are not equal.

As for board structure, family firms are found to have smaller board size, fewer board meetings,
and fewer independent directors on the board than those of non-family firms. On average, board
members in family firms consist of five persons, as compared to seven persons in non-family firms.
For board meetings, family firms conduct about 7 sessions in a year, while it is 10 for their counterparts.
For board independence, independent directors are found to be fewer in family firms with an average
of 10 people against 15 people in non-family firms.
Concerning firm characteristics (control variables), non-family firms show higher market
capitalization, a higher longevity level, better cash flow over operating revenue, and higher debt to
equity ratio than family firms. The lower leverage ratio for family firms indicates fewer financial risks

294
JRFM 2020, 13, 215

for them as compared to non-family firms. However, lower cash flow over operating revenue ratio for
family firms suggests that they may encounter financial difficulties in expanding businesses. Overall,
the univariate analysis presented in Tables 3 and 4 indicates that there is a significant performance
difference between Japanese family and non-family firms in terms of firm-specific characteristics,
ownership structure, and board composition.

4.2. Correlation Matrix


Table 5 reports the results of the correlation between variables. The correlation coefficient between
variables shows no multicollinearity problem except for BO_MEET with BO_SIZE (0.776), and GOV
with FOR (0.761). While perfect multicollinearity is considered a serious problem, often signaling a
logical error, imperfect multicollinearity (correlation coefficient nearly equals 1) may not be an error
but just a feature or characteristic of data. Therefore, we do not drop these two variables for running
the final regression.

Table 5. Correlation matrix.

Variables ROA Tobin_Q SIZE AGE CFOP LEV FAM INS GOV FOR BO_SIZE BO_MEET BO_IND NON_EXE
ROA 1.000
Tobin_Q 0.279 1.000
SIZE 0.172 0.251 1.000
AGE 0.052 −0.239 0.109 1.000
CFOP 0.639 0.368 0.242 0.015 1.000
LEV −0.267 −0.366 −0.085 0.075 −0.398 1.000
FAM −0.011 0.075 −0.108 −0.074 −0.016 −0.018 1.000
INS 0.034 0.064 −0.136 0.060 0.051 −0.022 0.301 1.000
GOV 0.071 0.078 −0.004 0.090 0.089 −0.017 0.138 0.732 1.000
FOR 0.101 0.136 0.014 0.056 0.134 −0.053 0.163 0.705 0.761 1.000
BO_SIZE 0.168 0.079 0.350 0.212 0.174 −0.024 −0.069 0.043 0.213 0.142 1.000
BO_MEET 0.135 0.091 0.284 0.136 0.164 −0.027 −0.047 0.040 0.203 0.124 0.773 1.000
BO_IND 0.134 0.159 0.356 0.128 0.197 −0.046 −0.015 0.161 0.312 0.240 0.570 0.616 1.000

4.3. Regression Results

4.3.1. Family Ownership and Firm Performance


Table 6 reports the results of the fixed effect regression model for all firms, family firms,
and non-family firms separately. In the case of all firms, Table 6 reveals that family ownership
has a positive effect on Tobin’s Q at the 5% significance level. However, it shows a negative relationship
with ROA. For family firms, family ownership tends to have a positive impact on Tobin’s Q, which is
consistent with previous literature (Saito 2008, for Japan; Isakov and Weisskopf 2014, for Switzerland;
Muttakin et al. 2015, for Bangladesh). However, we found that family ownership hurts ROA. Plausibly,
this happens because family firms do not heavily focus on short-term profitability, which is reflected
by ROA (Kapopoulos and Lazaretou 2007), to please third-party shareholders. Instead, they strive
for long-term and sustainable growth, as opposed to non-family firms, to pass their wealth to future
generations. It is worth noting that ROA and Tobin’s Q are different measures of firm performance. ROA
is an accounting-based measure reflecting short-term performance, while Tobin’s Q is a market-based
measure focusing on long-term growth. Thus, we may not always have consistent estimates. As for
non-family firms, family ownership concentration does not exist, so no relationship is recorded. As a
whole, we conclude that a significant positive connection runs between family ownership and firm
performance, measured by Tobin’s Q (H1). For ROA, the hypothesis H1is rejected.

295
JRFM 2020, 13, 215

Table 6. Fixed effect regression result.

All Firms Non-Family Firms Family Firms


Variable
ROA Tobin’s Q ROA Tobin’s Q ROA Tobin’s Q
Firm-Specific Characteristics
SIZE −0.015 0.049 ** −0.042 0.044 ** 0.039 0.058 **
AGE −9.835 *** −0.062 * −6.320 * −0.990 * −34.701 ** −0.320
CFOP 0.709 *** 0.015 ** 0.597 ** 0.008 ** 0.918 ** 0.027 **
LEV −0.192 *** −0.012 ** −0.162 ** −0.016 ** −0.225 ** −0.008 **
Ownership Characteristics
FAM −0.184 ** 0.009 * Omitted Omitted −0.166 ** 0.009 *
INS 0.0003 0.001 ** 0.000 0.001 ** 0.006 0.001 **
FAM*INS 0.003 ** 0.0001 * Omitted Omitted 0.003 ** 0.000 *
GOV 0.015 −0.002 −0.018 −0.002 0.241 ** −0.006
FAM*GOV −0.006 ** 0.0002 Omitted Omitted −0.013 ** 0.000
FOR 0.011 0.001 0.025 * 0.001 0.051 * 0.004
FAM*FOR 0.006 ** 0.003 Omitted Omitted 0.003 * 0.000 *
Board Characteristics
BO_SIZE 0.182 0.047 ** 0.006 0.052 * 0.382 0.014
BO_SIZESQ −0.000 −0.001 * 0.000 −0.002 −0.016 −0.000
BO_MEET 0.008 0.005 −0.021 0.002 0.031 0.011
BO_MEETSQ −0.001 −0.000 0.000 −0.000 −0.000 −0.000
BO_IND 0.007 0.0009 −0.033 ** −0.001 −0.064 * 0.000
constant 41.55 ** 1.873 ** 19.080 ** 2.724 ** 63.97 ** 1.12 **
N 7055 7055 4305 4305 2750 2750
R-square 0.096 0.169 0.229 0.143 0.038 0.179
Note: *** meaning p-value is less than 0.001; ** meaning p-value is less than 0.01; * meaning p-value is less than 0.05.

4.3.2. Institutional Ownership and Firm Performance


We found a significant positive relationship between institutional ownership and firm performance,
indexed by Tobin’s Q, for each group such as all firms, family firms, and non-family firms. This
relationship becomes stronger and significant with ROA and Tobin’s Q when institutional ownership
interacts with family ownership, implying that institutional shareholders can augment firm performance
in family firms. There could be two possible explanations in this respect. First, family firms are likely
to require more financial and technical knowledge from outside parties to manage the firms better.
In that matter, institutional investors can advise and monitor family firms on various issues to foster
performance in the short term (indicated by ROA). Non-family firms can take similar advantages from
institutional investors to enhance profits temporarily. However, non-family firms are usually run and
managed by managers coming from diverse backgrounds with strong business know-how. Thus, they
are less likely to rely on advice from institutional shareholders to promote short-term profits. Instead,
they seek consultation from institutional investors on strategic management, which has more impact
on firms’ long-term performance (Tobin’s Q).
Second, institutional investors, such as banks and pension funds, demand more transparency
in the board of management in disbursing funds. Unfortunately, family firms may not be perceived
well by institutional investors to achieve the same level of transparency as non-family firms have.
Thus, institutional investors can provide necessary advice and monitoring to the family firms to foster
profits in the short term. As a whole, we found that a significant positive relationship exists between
institutional ownership and firm performance, and family firms can enhance financial performance
both in the short term and long term by increasing institutional ownership (H2).

296
JRFM 2020, 13, 215

4.3.3. Government Ownership and Firm Performance


We found that a significant and positive relationship runs between government ownership and
performance of family firms, measured by ROA. For all firms, government ownership shows a positive
impact on ROA, and a negative effect on Tobin’s Q, although none of them is significant. By contrast,
a negative relationship is found to run between government ownership and firm performance in both
measures of firm performance for non-family firms, but the effect is not significant. Notably, government
ownership turns out to be negative for family firms when it interacts with family ownership, indicating
that family firms can reap the benefits of government stakes up to a certain threshold level. In this
tune, Fukuda et al. (2018) concluded that the effect of government ownership on firm performance
varies depending on the state of the company. Good and normal companies are likely to possess a
negative relationship between government ownership on firm performance, while bad companies have
a positive association between the same (Fukuda et al. 2018). As the p-value of government ownership
is found to be significant with ROA for family firms, we accept H3. However, we note that government
ownership contributes to firm performance up to a certain threshold level.

4.3.4. Foreign Ownership and Firm Performance


We found a significant and positive connection between foreign ownership and the performance
of family firms with ROA. A similar substantial and positive relationship was observed between
foreign ownership and Tobin’s Q for non-family firms. This result is consistent with the findings of
Yoshikawa and Rasheed (2010), Sueyoshi et al. (2010), and Fukuda et al. (2018), which reveal that
foreign ownership improves Tobin’s Q for Japanese firms. Notably, we found that foreign ownership
significantly enhances the performance of family firms (both ROA and Tobin’s Q) when it interacts
with family ownership. This means that foreign investors, because of their expertise in overseas
market operations, can monitor the company’s performance closely and provide necessary advice to
improve the firm’s profit in the short term (ROA). Furthermore, family firms can take advantage of
new knowledge, innovation, and management expertise brought by foreign shareholders to enhance
profits in the long term (Tobin’s Q). In conclusion, there is evidence of a significant positive relationship
between foreign ownership both for family and non-family firms (H4).

4.3.5. Board Size and Firm Performance


We did not find any significant relationship between board size and firm performance for family
firms, although it has been significant and positive for non-family firms. The result corresponds to
previous studies by Hu and Izumida (2008) and Sueyoshi et al. (2010) for Japan. Looking at the
case of all firms, we found that a non-linear negative relationship exists between board size and firm
performance, indicating that the increase in board members can hurt firm performance. However, we
note that it depends on the complexity of companies’ structure, nature of the business, and economic
goals. Finally, we do not accept H5 that a significant positive relationship exists between board size
and performance of family firms (H5). However, H5 is accepted for non-family firms.

4.3.6. Board Meeting and Firm Performance


We did not find any significant relationship between board meetings and firm performance either
for family or for non-family firms. This could lie in the fact that the board of directors in Japanese
firms usually consists of directors selected from employees who have been with the company under
the life-time employment scheme, implying that there are little to no fresh ideas and perspectives
on the board. Therefore, the traditional group thinking may dominate the entire discussion process,
while innovation and breakthrough ideas may be sacrificed against conservatism. Our result does not
approve the findings by Huse (2007), which document that frequency of board meetings enhances
firm performance by improving monitoring activities and resolving corporate issues. Moreover, we
did not find that a non-linear relationship runs between the frequency of board meetings and firm

297
JRFM 2020, 13, 215

performance. In conclusion, we reject H6 that a significant positive relationship runs between the
number of board meetings and Tobin’s Q for family firms in Japan.

4.3.7. Board Independence and Firm Performance


As a whole, a negative relationship was traced between independent directors and firm performance.
However, this negative effect was evidenced only with ROA for the case of family firms, and Tobin’s
Q with non-family firms. This contradicts previous studies of Yasuhiro et al. (2016) and Arikawa et al.
(2017) that report a positive relationship between independent directors and firm performance for
Japanese firms. In our study, the average number of independent directors is 15.142 for non-family
firms, and 10.941 for family firms. Possibly, too many independent directors may have a side effect on
firm performance, as they kill time for communication and making decisions. Thus, the hypothesis
(H7) is not approved. We also note that the optimal size of independent directors on the board is still a
complicated matter, depending on various factors and firm characteristics, and requires further study.
As for control variables, factors such as firm size and cash flows from operating activities were
found to be positively and significantly associated with Tobin’s Q of both family and non-family
firms. By contrast, leverage tends to inhibit the performance of family and non-family firms in both
the accounting-based (ROA) and market-based (Tobin’s Q) measures of firm performance. Table 7
summarizes our regression results for predefined hypotheses.

Table 7. Summary of findings with hypotheses.

Expected All Firms Non-Family Firms Family Firms


Variable
Sign ROA Tobin’s Q ROA Tobin’s Q ROA Tobin’s Q
Family ownership + − ** +* Omit Omit − ** +*
Institution ownership + + +* + + ** + + **
Government ownership − + − − − + ** −
Foreign ownership + + + +* + +* +
Board size + + + ** + +* + +
Board meeting + + + − + − −
Board independence + + + + − −* +
Note: ** meaning p-value is less than 0.01; * meaning p-value is less than 0.05. + represents a positive but insignificant
relationship, while − indicates a negative and insignificant relationship.

4.4. Robustness Test


Table 8 presents regression results from the random effect model after controlling for time and
industry effects. The regression results on ROA and Tobin’s Q yield relatively consistent estimates
with the regression results reported in the fixed-effect model. However, there are a few exceptions.
For family firms, board independence that showed a significantly negative effect on ROA in the
fixed-effect model disappears. Furthermore, foreign ownership appears to be a significant variable
to improve the performance of all firms. In addition, institutional ownership, which showed no
relationship with ROA in the fixed-effect model for family firms, turns out to be a significant and
positive factor for the same.

4.5. Additional Analysis


To check the performance difference between different types of family firms, we did further
analysis following the Saito (2008) approach. Accordingly, we separated the family firms into two
groups: family firms run by founders and founding family members. The results are shown in
Table 9. As Table 9 portrays, family firms run by the founder’s family members outperform the family
firms run by founders concerning Tobin’s Q. This result is in line with the findings of Saito (2008).
However, we found that family ownership reduces the performance of founder run family firms as far
as the ROA is concerned, but Tobin’s Q does not evidence the same. By contrast, family ownership
significantly improves the performance of family firms run by the founder’s descendants when Tobin’s

298
JRFM 2020, 13, 215

Q is taken into account. However, such evidence is not pronounced with ROA. Similarly, factors such
as institutional ownership and government shareholding encourage the performance of both types of
family firms (founders and founders’ descendants).

Table 8. Random effect regression results in controlling for time and industry effects.

All Firms Non-Family Firms Family Firms


Variable
ROA Tobin’s Q ROA Tobin’s Q ROA Tobin’s Q
Firm-Specific Characteristics
SIZE −0.084 * 0.058 ** −0.014 0.051 ** −0.162 * 0.068 **
AGE 1.454 ** −0.814 * 0.372 −0.539 * 3.027 ** −1.142 **
CFOP 0.672 * 0.020 ** 0.557 ** 0.016 ** 0.858 ** 0.028 **
LEV −0.042 ** −0.011 ** −0.045 ** −0.012 ** −0.038 ** −0.009 **
Ownership Characteristics
FAM −0.187 ** 0.012 ** Omitted Omitted −0.189 ** 0.012 **
INS 0.004 * 0.001 ** −0.000 0.001 ** 0.016 ** 0.001 **
FAM*INS 0.003 ** 0.0001 * Omitted Omitted 0.003 ** 0.000 **
GOV 0.015 −0.004 −0.031 −0.003 0.243 ** −0.007
FAM*GOV −0.007 ** 0.000 Omitted Omitted −0.014 ** 0.000
FOR 0.016 0.002 * 0.031 * 0.002 0.057 * 0.005 *
FAM*FOR 0.007 ** 0.000 * Omitted Omitted 0.004 * 0.000
Board Characteristics
BO_SIZE 0.229 ** 0.002 0.211 ** 0.000 0.123 0.010
BO_SIZESQ −0.008 * −0.000 0.007 −0.000 −0.004 0.000
BO_MEET −0.014 0.003 −0.009 0.001 −0.000 0.007
BO_MEETSQ 0.000 −0.000 0.000 −0.000 −0.000 −0.000
BO_IND 0.006 −0.002 −0.028 ** 0.000 −0.016 0.002
constant 1.51 * 2.212 ** 1.22 ** 1.814 ** −5.47 2.57 **
N 7055 7055 4305 4305 2750 2750
R-square 0.298 0.169 0.3241 0.1726 0.3027 0.2373
Note: ** meaning p-value is less than 0.01; * meaning p-value is less than 0.05.

Table 9. Regression results for family firms run by founder and founding family members (fixed-effect model).

Founder Run Family Members’ Run


Variable
ROA Tobin’s Q ROA Tobin’s Q
Firm-Specific Characteristics
SIZE 0.408 0.198 ** 0.036 0.038 *
AGE −38.48 ** −0.4.26 * −11.972 ** 0.829
CFOP 1.325 ** 0.038 ** 0.743 ** 0.021 **
LEV −0.331 ** −0.005 −0.095 ** −0.008 **
Ownership Characteristics
FAM −0.254 ** 0.014 −0.040 0.007 *
INS 0.088 * 0.007 −0.003 0.001 **
FAM*INS 0.013 ** 0.0001 0.000 0.000
GOV 1.264 * −0.029 0.126 * −0.005
FAM*GOV −0.039 * 0.000 −0.008 0.000
FOR 0.077 0.017 0.005 * 0.002
FAM*FOR 0.027 * 0.000 0.003 * 0.0004 *
Board Characteristics
BO_SIZE 0.559 0.118 0.241 −0.025
BO_SIZESQ −0.015 −0.004 −0.002 0.00
BO_MEET −0.040 0.003 0.025 −0.000
BO_MEETSQ −0.000 −0.000 −0.002 −0.000 *
BO_IND 0.719 0.004 −0.025 * −0.0003
constant 109.54 * 6.57 ** 24.06 ** 1.780 *
N 355 355 2045 2045
R-square 0.198 0.209 0.2954 0.1381
Note: ** meaning p-value is less than 0.01; * meaning p-value is less than 0.05.

299
JRFM 2020, 13, 215

However, as opposed to the firms run by founders’ family members, foreign ownership is not
found to be a significant factor for firms run by founders. This means that firms run by founders’
descendants can utilize foreign shareholdings to boost firm performance following Japan’s recent
financial policy that encourages foreign ownership. Besides, we found that factors such as board
independence and board meetings appear to be the significant factors for inhibiting the performance
of firms run by founders’ descendants. In contrast, such evidence is not pronounced for family firms
run by founders. Moreover, we did not find any significant performance differences between these
two types of family firms for the remaining cases.
Finally, we note that family firms run by founding family members tend to perform better over the
family firms run by founders. Furthermore, foreign ownership encourages the performance of firms
run by the founders’ descendants. However, we note that further studies incorporating management
strategies are required to reveal the performance difference between these two groups of family firms.
Moreover, more studies with longer time and multiple angles are warranted to generalize our findings.

5. Conclusions
In this paper, we sought to compare the performance difference between family and non-family
firms in the Japanese manufacturing industry from the perspective of corporate governance utilizing
data of 1412 companies over the period 2014–2018. The sample size consisted of 861 non-family firms
and 551 family firms. We investigated how the two mainsprings of corporate governance, namely
ownership structure and board structure, influence the firm performance measured by ROA and
Tobin’s Q.
Our univariate analysis indicated that both family and non-family firms differ significantly in
terms of ownership structure, board structure, and firm performance. We found that family firms
outperformed non-family firms in terms of the mean values of ROA and Tobin’s Q when the univariate
analysis was invoked. Furthermore, the mean and median comparison tests (t-test and z-test) yield
that family firms have higher performance than non-family firms with Tobin’s Q, in particular. We note
that this may happen because family firms’ top priority is to seek sustainable growth as they want to
pass their wealth to future generations, not on pleasing their shareholders in the short term (ROA).
For ownership structure, family firms are found to be less diversified than non-family firms,
indicated by the lower percentage of the institution, government, and foreign shareholding, and less
transparent in terms of having higher family ownership concentration. In terms of board structure,
family firms have a small board size, fewer board meetings, and fewer independent directors on the
board than non-family firms. The lower value of board-related characteristics does not necessarily
indicate that the board of family firms is worse than that of non-family firms. It is likely due to the
difference in size, the company’s organizational structure, and the complexity of the firm’s business.
Our multivariate analysis shows that family ownership has a significant positive impact on Tobin’s
Q. However, family ownership negates firm performance when ROA is taken into account. We note
that this may happen because the management of family firms is more interested in improving the
long-term growth of the firm, not to increase the short-term gain to please their shareholders.
Regarding the effects of governance elements on firm performance, we found that institutional
shareholding appears to be a significant and positive factor for promoting the performance of both
family and non-family firms as far as Tobin’s Q is concerned. Moreover, board size encourages the
performance of non-family firms, while such influence was not observed for family firms. In terms
of ROA, foreign ownership inspires the performance of both family and non-family firms. However,
the effect of foreign ownership was more noticeable for family firms, indicating that family firms can
benefit more from foreign investors as they can bring in more radical changes to the firms. Furthermore,
government ownership stimulates the performance of family firms up to a certain threshold level,
while board independence significantly negates the same. Besides, we found that the performance of
family firms run by the founder’s descendants is superior to that of family firms run by the founder.
As a whole, the study confirms previous findings that family firms outperform non-family firms in

300
JRFM 2020, 13, 215

the Japanese context using Tobin’s Q and ROA measures. Simultaneously, the study outlines some
governance factors that are instrumental in improving firm performance and policymaking as well.
However, this study is not free from certain limitations. We only studied governance variables
available with Bloomberg. The inclusion of more governance factors with a longer time may hurt our
results. Moreover, we did not investigate the management strategies adopted by different types of
family firms, which might have an impact on the performance difference between firms. Moreover,
a study on the link between corporate social responsibility and performance of different types of family
firms in Japan may add value to the literature of family firms.

Author Contributions: Data curation, L.T.; Funding acquisition, K.K.; Investigation, L.T.; Methodology, B.K.A.;
Project administration, K.K.; Writing—original draft, B.K.A.; Writing—review & editing, K.K. All authors have
read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.
Funding: This research received no external funding.
Acknowledgments: This study is the outcome of JSPS Grant-in-Aid No. 18H00901, Type B, received from the
Ministry of Education, Culture, Sports, Science and Technology, Japan for the financial year 2018–2020 to research
“Governance and Performance of Family Firms and Non-Family Firms in Japan-A Comparative Study”.
Conflicts of Interest: The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References
Achleitner, Ann-Kristin, Nina Günther, Christoph Kaserer, and Gianfranco Siciliano. 2014. Real Earnings
Management and Accrual-based Earnings Management in Family Firms. European Accounting Review
23: 431–61. [CrossRef]
Ahmad, Rubi, Huson Aliahmed, and Nazrul Razak. 2008. Government Ownership and Performance: An Analysis
of Listed Companies in Malaysia. Corporate Ownership and Control 6: 434–42. [CrossRef]
Ahmad, Maqbool, Nam Baek, Wan Dae, and Abbas Shah. 2019. The Impact of Institutional Ownership on Firm’s
Performance Evidence from Pakistan. The Journal of Asian Studies 22: 27–48. [CrossRef]
Alfaraid, Mishari, Faisal Alanezi, and Hesham Almujamed. 2012. The Influence of Institutional and Government
Ownership on Firm Performance: Evidence from Kuwait. International Business Research 5: 192–200.
Aljifri, Khaled, and Mohamed Moustafa. 2007. The Impact of Corporate Governance Mechanisms on the
Performance of UAE Firms: An Empirical Analysis. Journal of Economic and Administrative Sciences 23: 71–93.
[CrossRef]
Allouche, Jose, Bruno Amann, Jacques Jaussaud, and Toshiki Kurashina. 2008. The Impact of Family Control on the
Performance and Financial Characteristics of Family Versus Nonfamily Businesses in Japan: A Matched-pair
Investigation. Family Business Review 21: 315–29. [CrossRef]
Alnajjar, Dana. 2015. The Effect of Institutional Ownership on Firm Performance: Evidence from Jordanian Listed
Firms. International Journal of Economics and Finance 7: 97–105. [CrossRef]
Anderson, Ronald, and David Reeb. 2003. Founding-family ownership and firm performance: Evidence from the
S&P 500. Journal of Finance 58: 1301–28.
Arikawa, Yasuhiro, Inoue Kotaro, and Saito Takuji. 2017. Corporate Governance, Employment Laws,
and Corporate Performance in Japan: An international perspective. Tokyo Institute of Technology 9: 1–34.
Aydin, Nurhan, Mustafa Sayim, and Abdullah Yalama. 2007. Foreign Ownership and Firm Performance: Evidence
from Turkey. International Research Journal of Finance and Economics 11: 102–110.
Bauer, Rob, Bart Frijns, Roger Otten, and Alireza Tourani-Rad. 2008. The impact of corporate governance on
corporate performance: Evidence from Japan. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 16: 236–51. [CrossRef]
Blanco-Mazagatos, Virginia, Esther Quevedo-Puente, and Juan Delgado-García. 2018. Human resource practices
and organizational human capital in the family firm: The effect of generational stage. Journal of Business
Research 84: 337–48. [CrossRef]
Charfeddine, Lanouar, and Abdelaziz Elmarzougui. 2011. Institutional Ownership and Firm Performance:
Evidence from France. The IUP Journal of Behavioral Finance 7: 36–46.
Chen, L.-Wen, and Hsin-Yi Yu. 2017. Corporate governance, political involvement, and internationalization:
An empirical investigation in Japan and Taiwan. Research in International Business and Finance 39: 640–55.
[CrossRef]

301
JRFM 2020, 13, 215

Chen, Zhilan, Yan-Leung Cheung, Aris Stouraitis, and Anita Wong. 2005. Ownership concentration, firm
performance, and dividend policy in Hong Kong. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 13: 431–49. [CrossRef]
Choi, Young, and Kunsu Park. 2019. Foreign Ownership, Agency Costs, and Long-Term Firm Growth: Evidence
from Korea. Journal of Sustainability 11: 1–17.
Chou, Hsin-I., Huimin Chung, and Xiangkang Yin. 2013. Attendance of Board Meetings and Company
Performance: Evidence from Taiwan. Journal of Banking and Finance 37: 4157–71. [CrossRef]
Chu, Wenyi. 2011. Family ownership and firm performance: Influence of family management, family control,
and firm size. Asia Pacific Journal of Management 28: 833–51. [CrossRef]
Ciftci, IIhan, Ekrem Tatoglu, Geoffrey Wood, Mehmet Demirbag, and Selim Zaim. 2019. Corporate governance
and firm performance in emerging markets: Evidence from Turkey. International Business Review 28: 90–103.
[CrossRef]
Dalton, Dan, Catherine Daily, Alan Ellstrand, and Jonathan Johnson. 1998. Meta-analytic reviews of board
composition, leadership structure, and financial performance. Strategic Management Journal 19: 269–90.
[CrossRef]
Dau, Luis Alfanso, Saptarshi Purkayastha, and Kimberly Eddleston. 2018. Who does it best? Family and non-family
owners and leaders navigating institutional development in emerging markets. Journal of Business Research.
[CrossRef]
Dazai, Hokuto, Takuji Saito, Zenichi Shishido, and Noriyuki Yanagawa. 2016. Japanese Corporate Governance
from the Perspective of Family Firms. SSRN Electronic Journal. Available online: https://papers.ssrn.com/
sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2811069 (accessed on 11 January 2020).
Eisenberg, Theodore, Stefan Sundgren, and Martin Wells. 1998. Larger board size and decreasing firm value in
small firms. Journal of Financial Economics 48: 35–54. [CrossRef]
Filatotchev, Igor, Yung-Chih Lien, and Jenifer Piesse. 2005. Corporate governance and performance in publicly
listed, familycontrolled firms: Evidence from Taiwan. Asia Pacific Journal of Management 22: 257–83. [CrossRef]
Fukuda, Shin-Ichi, Munehisa Kasuya, and Jouchi Nakajima. 2018. The role of corporate governance in Japanese
unlisted companies. Japan and the World Economy 47: 27–39. [CrossRef]
Gomez, Jorge, Diogenes Lagos, and Gonzalo Betancourt. 2017. Effect of the Board of Directors on Firm
Performance. International Journal of Economic Research 14: 349–61.
Hansen, Christopher, and Joern Block. 2020. Exploring the relation between family involvement and firms
financial performance: A replication and extension analysis. Journal of Business Venturing Insights 13: 1–21.
[CrossRef]
Hasso, Tim, and Keith Duncan. 2013. Valuation of Family Firms: The Limitations of Accounting Information.
Australian Accounting Review 23: 135–50. [CrossRef]
Herrera-Echeverri, Hernan, Josse Geleilate, Sandra Gaitan-Riano, Jerry Haar, and Nidia Soto-Echeverry. 2016.
Export behavior and board independence in Colombian family firms: The reverse causality relationship.
Journal of Business Research 69: 2018–29. [CrossRef]
Hideaki, Miyajima, Hoda Takaaki, and Ogawa Ryo. 2015. Does Ownership Really Matter? The Role of Foreign
Investors in Corporate Governance in Japan. The Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry Discussion
Paper Series 15: 1–41.
Hideaki, Miyajima, Ryo Ogawa, and Takuji Saito. 2018. Changes in corporate governance and top executive
turnover: The evidence from Japan. Journal of the Japanese and International Economies 47: 17–31.
Hu, Yabei, and Shigemi Izumida. 2008. Ownership Concentration and Corporate Performance: A Causal Analysis
with Japanese Panel Data. Corporate Governance 16: 342–58. [CrossRef]
Huse, Morten. 2007. Boards, Governance and Value Creation: The Human Side of Corporate Governance. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Huson, Mark, Robert Parrino, and Laura Starks. 2001. Internal Monitoring Mechanisms and CEO Turnover:
A Long-Term Perspective. The Journal of Finance 56: 2265–97. [CrossRef]
Isakov, Dusan, and Jean-Philippe Weisskopf. 2014. Are Founding Families Special Block-holders?—An Investigation
of Controlling Shareholder Influence on Firm Performance. Journal of Banking and Finance 41: 1–16. [CrossRef]
Jackling, Beverley, and Shireenjit Johl. 2009. Board structure and firm performance: Evidence from India’s top
companies. Corporate Governance: International Review 17: 492–509. [CrossRef]
Jensen, Michael, and William Meckling. 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and
ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3: 305–60. [CrossRef]

302
JRFM 2020, 13, 215

Kallmuenzer, Andreas. 2015. Agency Theory and the Family Business. In Theoretical Perspectives on Family
Businesses. Edited by Mattias Nordqvist, Leif Melin, Matthias Waldkirch and Gershon Kumeto. Cheltenham:
Edward Elgar Publishing, pp. 58–77.
Kapopoulos, Panayotis, and Sophia Lazaretou. 2007. Corporate Ownership Structure and Firm Performance:
Evidence from Greek firms. Corporate Governance: An International Review 15: 144–58. [CrossRef]
Kojima, Koji, Bishnu Kumar Adhikary, and Ranjan Kumar Mitra. 2017. Does equity holding by main banks
affect the earnings quality of client firms? Empirical Evidence from Japan. Journal of Multinational Financial
Management 42–43: 56–73. [CrossRef]
Lorsch, Jay, and Elizabeth Maclver. 1989. Pawns or Potentates: The Reality of America’s Corporate Boards. Boston:
Harvard University Press.
Mak, Yuen Teen, and Yuanto Kusnadi. 2005. Size really matters: Further evidence on the negative relationship
between board size and firm value. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 13: 301–18. [CrossRef]
McConaughy, Daniel, and Michael Phillips. 1999. Founders versus descendants: The profitability, efficiency,
growth characteristics and financing in large, public, founding-family-controlled firms. Family Business
Review 12: 123–31. [CrossRef]
Miller, Danny, Isabelle Le Breton-Miller, Richard Lester, and Albert Cannella. 2007. Are family firms really
superior performers? Journal of Corporate Finance 13: 829–58. [CrossRef]
Mizuno, Mitsuru, and Hajime Shimizu. 2015. The Influence of Institutional Investors on Corporate Governance
and Firm Performance: Evidence from Japan. Kindai Management Review 3: 75–89.
Moez, Dabboussi, Kouki Marouan, and Rajhi Mohammad Tahar. 2015. Does Foreign Ownership Influence Firm
Profitability? Evidence from the Tunisian Context. International Journal of Economics and Finance 7: 159–67.
[CrossRef]
Morikawa, Masayuki. 2013. Productivity and survival of family firms in Japan. Journal of Economics and Business
70: 111–25. [CrossRef]
Muttakin, Mohammad Badrul, Arifur Khan, and Nava Subramaniam. 2014. Family firms, Family generation
and firm performance: Evidence from an emerging economy. Journal of Accounting in Emerging Economics
4: 197–219. [CrossRef]
Muttakin, Mohammad Badrul, Reza Monem, Arifur Khan, and Nava Subramaniam. 2015. Family firms, firm
performance and political connections: Evidence from Bangladesh. Journal of Contemporary Accounting and
Economics 11: 215–30. [CrossRef]
Naushad, Mohammad, and Syed Abdul Malik. 2015. Corporate governance and bank performance: A study of
selected banks in GCC Region. Asian Social Science 11: 226–34. [CrossRef]
Ngo, My Tram, Walter Nonneman, and Ann Jorisen. 2014. Government Ownership and Firm Performance:
The Case of Vietnam. International Journal of Economics and Financial Issues 4: 628–50.
Razzaque, Rushdi, Muhammad Jahangir Ali, and Paul Mather. 2020. Corporate governance reform and family
firms: Evidence from an emerging economy. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 59: 1–21. [CrossRef]
Saito, Takuji. 2008. Family Firms and Firm Performance: Evidence from Japan. Waseda Institute for Advanced Study
Discussion Paper 2007: 1–46. [CrossRef]
Saito, Takuji. 2009. Why Outside Directors in Japan are not Prevalent. Research Institute of Economy Trade and
Industry. Available online: https://www.rieti.go.jp/jp/projects/cgp/16.html (accessed on 11 January 2020).
Sharma, Pramodita. 2004. An overview of the field of family business studies: Current status and directions for
the future. Family Business Review 17: 1–36. [CrossRef]
Srivastava, Aman, and Shikha Bhatia. 2020. Influence of family ownership and governance on performance:
Evidence from India. Global Business Review, 1–19. [CrossRef]
Sueyoshi, Toshiyuki, Mika Goto, and Yusuke Omi. 2010. Corporate governance and firm performance: Evidence
from Japanese manufacturing industries after the lost decade. European Journal of Operational Research 203:
724–36. [CrossRef]
Sun, Qian, Wilson Tong, and Jing Tong. 2002. How Does Government Ownership Affect Firm Performance? Evidence
from China’s Privatization Experience. Journal of Business Finance and Accounting 29: 1–27. [CrossRef]
Vafeas, Nikos. 1999. Board Meeting Frequency and Firm Performance. Journal of Financial Economics 53: 113–42.
[CrossRef]

303
JRFM 2020, 13, 215

Yasuhiro, Arikawa, Inoue Kotaro, and Saito Takuji. 2016. Corporate Governance, Employment Laws, and Corporate
Performance in Japan: An International Perspective. Tokyo Institute of Technology Working Paper No. 2016-9.
Tokyo: Tokyo Institute of Technology.
Yoshikawa, Toru, and Abdul Rasheed. 2010. Family control and ownership monitoring in family-control firms in
Japan. Journal of Management Studies 47: 274–95. [CrossRef]

© 2020 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access
article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution
(CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).

304
Journal of
Risk and Financial
Management

Article
Women on Boards and Firm Performance:
A Microeconometric Search for a Connection
Marek Gruszczyński
Institute of Econometrics, SGH Warsaw School of Economics, 02-554 Warszawa, Poland;
marek.gruszczynski@sgh.waw.pl

Received: 28 July 2020; Accepted: 13 September 2020; Published: 19 September 2020

Abstract: This paper discusses questions of the gender diversity of corporate boards vis-à-vis
firm performance. Typically, researchers have asked if a female presence is associated with improved
performance and more transparent governance. The paper’s first part reports on several econometric
attempts in the quest to prove the existence of such an association. The primary outcome is that
the results vary over geographical, cultural, and time settings. The study presented in the second
part examines European firms’ annual reports from 2015. Binomial models, multiple regression,
and quantile regression are applied resulting in the finding that female presence on a board is not
significantly related to firm performance for this sample. Together with the picture that emerged from
the paper’s first part, this result leads to the possibility that the search for an association between
women on boards and company performance is not fundamental. Nevertheless, modern business
societies worldwide may need to boost the female presence on managerial bodies. Current econometric
evidence indicates that this is not harmful to corporate results.

Keywords: corporate governance; board of directors; women in corporations; financial microeconometrics;


multiple regression; quantile regression; diff-in-diff

1. Introduction: Corporate Boards Vis-à-Vis Gender Diversity


Topics in corporate finance and corporate governance research include the examination of
such aspects of corporate board structure as the presence of independent directors, the formation
of committees, and recently the presence of women. This paper discusses research attempts concerning
the possible relationship between gender structure and the financial results of companies.
Research in empirical corporate finance is developing in many directions. Some studies have
a sound theoretical setting, while some still need to be properly rooted in theory. Specific theories
have proved to be unstable over time and space—as shown by empirics—and there is, perhaps, no
need to strive for a unified theory of corporate finance. Instead, there is a growing demand for
more “operational” results based on statistical data on companies (Gruszczyński 2020). This paper
contemplates an area that is in the developmental phase, apparently without solid theory, and, perhaps,
that is an advantage.
Empirical studies on women and the corporation have emerged in recent decades in vast numbers,
along with changes in societies’ views on gender issues. The new subject of the corporate presence
of women has naturally become a topic for research in corporate governance, corporate finance,
corporate law, and other areas. Researchers have concentrated on various aspects of women’s
presence in corporations, including the relationship between women on boards of directors (BoDs) and
financial results.
The presence of women on corporate boards is no longer questioned, with major efforts being
constantly directed towards increasing the proportion of women on boards. This has become a political
issue since the “natural” process of board evolution into bodies reflecting the gender structure of

JRFM 2020, 13, 218; doi:10.3390/jrfm13090218 305 www.mdpi.com/journal/jrfm


JRFM 2020, 13, 218

their respective societies seems to be rather lengthy. The result is that, in some countries, gender
board quotas have been imposed, such as 40% in Norway, Spain, Iceland, and France, 33% in Belgium,
and 30% in the Netherlands and Italy (Ahern and Dittmar 2012).
The European Commission in 2012 adopted a proposal for a directive “setting a minimum
objective of having 40% of the under-represented sex in non-executive board-member positions in listed
companies in Europe by 2020, or 2018 for listed public undertakings” (European Commission 2012).
While the European Parliament voted in 2013 to back this law, until now, EU countries have not
adopted the directive. In 2019, the Commission reported on “data confirming the positive impact of
gender diversity in management on business performance, but also data indicating that the EU still
scores low when it comes to equality in decision-making, and that the gap between Member States is
widening” (European Commission 2019).
In Section 2, we propose an overview of this paper’s subject, beginning with a brief account of
theories regarding the female presence in organizational leadership, theories rooted in political science,
sociology, psychology, economics, and finance. Furthermore, we comment on two meta-analyses
summing up research devoted specifically to the association between women’s presence on boards
and company performance.
Section 3 presents a short survey of microeconometric methodologies applied in exploring
gender vs. performance. The examples include studies that rely on techniques of multiple linear
regression, panel data linear modelling, quantile regression, the diff-in-diff technique, and other
methods. In Section 4, we show how econometric approaches may compete in discussing the direction
of association between firm performance and women on BoDs for a sample of companies in Norway.
The study presented in Section 5 examines European firms’ financial reports from the year 2015
and the association between women’s presence on boards and their respective companies’ performance.
Applying binomial models, multiple regression, and quantile regression, we find that, for this sample,
female presence on BoDs is not significantly related to firm performance.
Section 6 concludes.

2. Women on Boards and Financial Results—Theoretical Underpinnings and Meta-Analyses


There are multiple theories directed towards showing the necessity of female participation in all
corporate structures, reflective of their presence in greater society. Aluchna and Krejner-Nowecka (2016)
propose a list of such theories, including:

- the non-discrimination approach: “women represent 50% of the society and should be given
rights to have the respective participation in corporate boards”;
- the social/gender/feminist theory: “women’s presence can help to change stereotypes embedded
in others’ expectations”;
- the resource dependency theory: “women having adequate experience and education improve
the board work quality”;
- the diversity management perspective: “women enrich corporate boards contributing to
communication, leadership style, different risk attitude and term orientation”;
- the stakeholder theory: “women reveal stronger stakeholder representation and largest social and
environmental concerns”.

None of these theories tackle the question of the “impact” of female presence on corporate
financial results. It seems that this issue is not theoretically solid and remains a “political” or
“sociological” question rather than an economic or financial one. Eckbo et al. (2019) point out that
“in principle, restricting shareholders’ free choice of directors can reduce board effectiveness”. There
are studies pointing out that new female directors may lead to a reduction in firm value, that new
and less experienced female directors may be “overly focused on monitoring and exhibit excessive
risk aversion”. On the other hand, ”it is in principle possible for shareholders to benefit from the

306
JRFM 2020, 13, 218

diversity and broader skill set resulting from adding female directors”. As can be seen from this paper,
the evidence in each direction of reasoning is mixed.
Editors of the book “Women in corporate boards. An international perspective” (Aluchna and Aras 2018)
state that “Female presence and involvement on boards improves firm performance, transforms
corporate governance and leads to the transition towards more responsible business”. This general
observation should be limited, at least in regard to the aspect that can be statistically/econometrically
examined—i.e., relating women’s presence on boards and firm performance. As in many instances of
research in corporate finance and corporate governance, this relationship may differ across countries,
regions, time spans, samples, etc. Explaining those differences without a unified theory is a task outside
the scope of economics and finance.
To this end, we reference the comprehensive meta-analysis provided by Halliday et al. (2020) that
addresses gender diversity questions in the framework of psychology. They “integrate psychological
theory related to implicit biases and agency theory, with institutional theory, to propose that the
national context for gender equality moderates the extent to which characteristics of organizational
leadership relate to female board representation”. This comprehensive analysis begins with 1604
studies published in or before 2018. The final set examined in the authors’ paper consists of 158 studies,
mostly journal articles, from the period 2004–2018. The “sample” contains 60,648 organizations
from 36 countries. Their final conclusion stresses the “importance of the national context for gender
equality as a boundary condition for understanding the relationship between organizational leadership
characteristics and female board representation”. The national context is important, but this observation
is, in fact, the only solid result from so comprehensive a meta-analysis.
There are attempts, however, to place the question of gender into the theoretical framework of
economics/finance. For example, Taghizadeh-Hesary et al. (2019) show the disparity in the lending
behavior of banks to small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) based on their owners’ gender.
They use the production function approach, distinguishing the capital of male- and female-owned
companies. The major assumption is that “the loan default risk of female-owned companies is greater
than the default risk of male-owned companies”, placed in the context of Asia, where customarily
female entrepreneurs face greater credit constraints than their male counterparts. Along with this
assumption, it is shown that, indeed, there is gender-based inequity in bank lending. To mitigate
this issue, the authors propose a governmental credit guarantee for female-owned enterprises and,
subsequently, demonstrate that this would increase GDP growth. The elegant mathematical structure
is then followed by a statistical–econometric analysis on a sample of 1492 Iranian SMEs in which it is
shown that, actually, “female-owned SMEs perform lower relative to male counterparts as they have a
higher default ratio and lower profitability, liquidity, and coverage”. To sum up, what we really have
here is a theoretical dispute, but it has no relevance to the empirical exercise that is the substance of
this paper.
What remains as a major research possibility in examining gender edge vis-à-vis corporate
categories is the application of a statistical–econometric methodology. Such research attempts typically
use microdata on large numbers of companies and may be placed under the label of “financial
microeconometrics” (Gruszczyński 2020).
There are at least two meta-analyses in this direction. Post and Byron (2015) use results from
140 studies (92 published, 48 unpublished) and examine “whether results vary by firms’ legal/regulatory
and socio-cultural contexts”. The conclusion is mixed. On one side “female board representation is
positively related to accounting returns” (r = 0.047; significantly higher than zero), and on the other
“the relationship between female board representation and market performance is near-zero” (r = 0.014;
not significantly different from zero). The authors indicate that much depends on the countries in

307
JRFM 2020, 13, 218

question: the relationships are stronger in countries with greater gender parity. In a sense, this appears
to be a similar conclusion to the analysis by Halliday et al. (2020)1 .
Pletzer et al. (2015) present a meta-analysis of 20 studies from peer-reviewed journals that examine
the possible relationship of female presence on corporate boards and firm financial performance.
The primary conclusion is that the “mere representation of females on corporate boards is not
related to firm performance”. The authors explain that their analysis, unlike that of Post and
Byron (2015), follows “a more rigorous and controlled methodological approach by investigating
the relationship between percentage of females on corporate boards and firm financial performance,
operationalized as return on assets, return on equity, and Tobin’s Q”. The primary hypothesis here
is “that female representation on corporate boards is either positively or negatively related to firm
financial performance, but that the magnitude of such a relationship is likely to be small”.
Thus, the empirical research, as evidenced in three meta-analyses, does not convey the message of
a significant relationship between women’s presence on boards and firm performance. The primary
outcome is that the mere representation of females in the governing bodies substantially relates to the
“national context”. A similar conclusion may also be attributed to research by Carrasco et al. (2015).
The authors use Hofstede cultural dimensions methodology and apply it to a comprehensive data set
from 32 countries from 2010. It turns out that two of the four Hofstede dimensions are related to the
level of female representation on BoDs. These are power distance and masculinity. Companies in the
countries where unequal distribution of power in institutions is accepted have relatively fewer women
on BoDs. It is also the case in countries where values associated with the masculine role dominate.
Thus, the national context seems to be an important determinant of female presence on boards.
Before embarking on specific issues of methodology, we point to the paper by Ferreira (2015) who
clearly subscribes to the view of this paper. He states that research does not show a clear “business
case for gender quotas”, nor does it support the contrary: that female participation on BoDs reduces
firm profitability.
However, there is always the question of the methodological quality of the research. This is
discussed in the next section.

3. Financial Microeconometrics: Selected Empirical Studies on Gender vs. Performance

3.1. Methodological Considerations


In this section, we concentrate on specific studies, as well as on financial microeconometrics
methodologies. Indications remain that the inconclusive outcomes might be embedded in the research
question itself, as shown in Section 2, and may also be the result of an improper methodological setup.
Our argument, in some way, coincides with the line taken by Adams (2016) in her important paper
published in the special issue of The Leadership Quarterly on strategic questions of female participation
on boards vis-a-vis challenges faced by the research2 . She argues that “more research needs to be
done to understand the benefits of board diversity”. The principal problems are data limitations,
selection, and causal inference. This is in line with the reasoning presented by the same author in the
paper Adams (2017) on possible flaws in corporate governance research. Gruszczyński (2018) indicates
similar questions in the paper on good practices in corporate governance and accounting research.
For example, a significant correlation between the measure of female presence on boards and the
measure of firm performance should not be interpreted as a causal relationship if the endogeneity
problem is not taken into account. This is a situation in which the gender variable, being exogenous in
the linear regression model explaining the performance variable, is also correlated with an error term. It

1 These authors present another meta-analysis on how the female presence on boards relates to corporate social performance
(Byron and Post 2016). Based on 87 studies from more than 20 countries, the authors find that this relationship is positive
and is stronger in countries with higher stakeholder protection and gender parity.
2 I thank an anonymous reviewer for referring this paper to me.

308
JRFM 2020, 13, 218

means the gender variable is correlated with another explanatory variable that has not been included in
the model. Such a variable may be, for example, firm size: it is more likely that women are appointed to
the boards of larger companies. Company size may also be a determinant of its performance. There are
various types of remedies for endogeneity. One group includes techniques that aim at the source of
the variability of the exogenous variable: the instrumental variables approach, or such methods as
diff-in-diff or regression discontinuity design. An example of diff-in-diff is given later in this section.
The second group comprises techniques that use panel data or matching estimation (Roberts and
Whited 2013).
The techniques mentioned above belong to what are referred to as new microeconometrics or
‘metrics’ and are presented in the seminal books of Angrist and Pischke (2009, 2015), among other
sources. The primary issue is how to “prove” causality between the variables. Thi appears to offer a
way of solving the primary question here: what is the impact of female directors on firm performance?
However, most techniques advocate the use of experiments or natural experiments. Adams (2016)
points out that an experiment is impossible: “To experimentally identify the causal effect of gender
diversity on firm performance, one would have to randomly assign female directors to firms and then
measure subsequent firm performance”. The same view is held by Ferreira (2015): “Causal effects
will always be too hard to estimate, unless governments unintentionally help us with badly designed
policies that randomly assign quotas to some firms and not to others”.
The question is whether regression analyses may suffice without searching for causality. Obviously,
regression tools are valuable, as evidenced in corporate finance and corporate governance research.
Regression outcomes may even be close to ascertaining causality, especially when we use
panel techniques (Gruszczyński 2018). On the other hand, to properly design and execute
research with endogeneity in mind is sometimes hard, as pointed out in the survey paper of
Atanasov and Black (2016).
Another concern should be raised here: the question of the statistical significance of the explanatory
variables in the regression-type model. It is often the case in empirical corporate finance that some
insignificant variables are not removed from the model due to their merit in research. Such practice
is admissible and correct. Putting too much weight on statistical significance may not be correct
(for more, see Gruszczyński 2020, section 2.8). Today, this is the subject of worldwide discussion
among researchers who, in their hundreds, recently endorsed the call to “retire statistical significance”
(Amrhein et al. 2019).

3.2. Selected Empirical Studies


From the plethora of studies on the topic, we choose a few, one of which specifically represents the
“new microeconometrics” methodology. All belong methodologically to financial microeconometrics
(Gruszczyński 2020).
Ionascu et al. (2018) examine Romanian companies listed on the Bucharest Stock Exchange
2012–2016 (343 firm-year observations). Their results indicate that, on average, the diversity of BoDs
has no significant impact on firm performance. In the authors’ words: “although firm performance
seems to be positively correlated with gender diversity of the boards, the association is not robust
and ceases to be significant after endogeneity is controlled for”. The method employed is panel data
linear regression with a dependent variable representing performance. There are three such variables
attempted: return on assets (ROA), Market-To-Book ratio, and Tobin’s Q. Such a setup is typical for
most studies. The gender diversity variable is one of the explanatory variables in the regression.
The authors consider three such variables: the proportion of female members on a board, a dummy
variable indicating a woman as president of the board, and an interaction variable being the product
of the first two variables. A major problem is always the selection of other predictors (explanatory
variables, controls). The authors also try to perform the same analysis for profitable companies with a

309
JRFM 2020, 13, 218

marginally better result: for profitable companies, the relationship between female presence and firm
performance is then marginally positive3 .
Gordini and Rancati (2017) use panel data analysis to establish the relationship between female
presence (gender diversity) on boards and firm performance for 918 listed companies in Italy between
2011 and 2014. The authors use Tobin’s Q as the measure of firm performance. The “female” variables
are four (sequentially): a dummy representing at least one woman on the BoD, the percentage of
female directors, the Blau index, and the Shannon index. The last two indices measure the gender
diversity of the BoD with limits of zero (no diversity) and 0.5 or 0.69—perfect diversity or 50:50,
respectively. According to Italian law from 2011, it is mandatory that there be at least one woman on
a BoD. Nevertheless, only 73% of boards in the sample fulfilled this law. This variable specifically
turns out to be insignificant in the models explaining Tobin’s Q with other typical control variables.
Other “female” variables are significantly positively related to Tobin’s Q. Strangely enough, the authors
placed ROA as one of the performance measures among the controls. The authors maintain that their
study shows a “positive and significant effect” on Tobin’s Q of the three variables measuring the
presence of women on BoDs in Italy.
Examples of studies using the simple methodologies are as follows:

- Rossi et al. (2017) use a cross-section of Italian listed companies from 2016. The result is a
significantly positive relationship between financial performance and the composition of the BoD.
The methodology used is linear regression where price/book value is related to the percentage of
women on the BoD.
- Kompa and Witkowska (2017) consider listed companies in Poland in 2010–2015. They study the
correlation between changes in the feminization ratio of BoDs and changes in ROE as a measure
of company performance. No significant correlation was observed.

Another study referenced here uses the more sophisticated approach of quantile regression.
Conyon and He (2017) investigate 3000 US companies for the period 2007–2014 (over 18,000 firm-year
observations). With two dependent variables, ROA and Tobin’s Q, and a number of typical controls,
the authors examine the association between the percentage of women on BoDs and firm performance.
Firstly, they report OLS and fixed-effects OLS estimation results. The OLS gives a mixed message:
a significant and positive association between women on boards and Tobin’s Q, and a significant
and negative association between women on boards and ROA. After controlling for firm-level fixed
effects, the board gender diversity variable becomes insignificant in both cases. Now, the authors
claim that the assumption (in OLS regressions) that “the board gender effect is constant across the
performance distribution is not valid”. Alongside such reasoning, a quantile regression is employed,
which provides very promising results supporting the authors’ main hypothesis: “Board gender
diversity has a significantly larger positive impact on firm performance in high-performing firms than
in low-performing firms”. The paper shows that searching for a relationship between female presence
on BoDs and performance requires sometimes more than simple techniques of multiple regression.
The new microeconometrics (as coined in Section 3.1) are represented in this survey by Sila et al. (2016),
who investigate 1960 US firms with 13,581 firm-year observations for the period 1996–2010.
The authors examine the gender diversity of corporate boards and its possible effect on company risk.
The methodology employed applies linear regression, binomial probit, and diff-in-diff with matching.
In stage (1), the authors use the binomial probit to explain the probability that at least one female director
is appointed in a company in a given year. The major predictor is the risk variable defined (in one
variant) as the variability of daily stock returns in the preceding year. The number of firm years with the
appointment of at least one director is 7101. It is shown that risk may well predict a female appointment.

3 Interestingly, an earlier study examining companies listed on the Bucharest Stock Exchange (2007–2011) by Vintilă et al.
(2014) showed a mostly significant relationship between female representation on BoDs and firm value.

310
JRFM 2020, 13, 218

In stage (2), the authors estimate linear regression, with risk being explained by the proportion of
women on the board and other control variables. The method used for estimation is GMM for a
dynamic panel system. In effect, the authors find no evidence of a relationship between equity risk and
a female appointment. In stage (3), an alternative strategy for identifying this relationship is applied
with the use of diff-in-diff and matching. This amounts, here, to estimating the following model:

Riskit = α0 + α1 Female Appointmentit ∗ Post Periodit + α2 Female Appointmentit



+α3 Post Periodit + CONTROLit γ + εit

The variable Female Appointmentit = 1 for firms in treatment group, =0 otherwise. Firms comprising
the treatment group appoint exactly one female director in year t to replace a departing male director
(must be older than 60). The variable Post Periodit = 1 in the post-treatment period, =0 in the
before-treatment period.
The firms from the treatment group are matched to similar control firms that represent a group with
a male director appointed to replace another male director (there are 153 matches possible). Matching is
made with the propensity score and nearest-neighbor techniques. The model is estimated for both sets
of data: for propensity score and for nearest-neighbor. The authors find that the Female Appointmentit ∗
Post Periodit variable is not significant in either version of the model. In other words, this is the causal
evidence that appointments of female directors and male directors do not result in different risks.
The final conclusion is that a board with a higher proportion of female directors is no more or less
risk-taking than a more male-dominated board.
The research by Sila et al. (2016) is an example of how to use techniques of identifying the
causal relationship between the gender structure of the board and the firm performance (in this case:
equity risk).
Examples presented in this subsection are intended to show the diversity of possible methodological
approaches that are available in the microeconometric toolbox and that may be used in regard to
corporate governance questions like the one considered in this paper. The major hypothesis here
remains as before: there is no solid evidence for a significant association between female presence on
BoDs and firm performance across countries, regions, time spans, and samples.

4. The Case of Norway: Competing Econometric Studies


One interesting case concerns Norway, where gender quotas were imposed on listed companies
a relatively long time ago—a 40% quota was imposed in 2003, becoming compulsory from 2008.
A number of studies of Norway’s gender balancing of corporate boards conclude that the gender
quota law imposed large costs on the shareholders of firms. Eckbo et al. (2019) especially identify one
paper by Ahern and Dittmar (2012) (AD), who state that their research reveals a causal effect of the
imposition of the quota on (1) stock prices and on (2) companies’ financial performance. Effect (1)
occurred immediately after the announcement of the new law, while effect (2) was reflected in a
significant decline in Tobin’s Q in the following years. AD also maintain that the quota led to
“younger and less experienced boards, increases in leverage and acquisitions, and deterioration in
operating performance”.
The AD study is strongly rooted in good econometric methodology, applied to a panel of 248
publicly listed companies in Norway for the period 2001–2009. The tools used include the event study
on the stock price reaction to the initial announcement of the quota, the instrumental variable approach
to investigate the “impact of the quota on Tobin’s Q”, the “effect of the quota on board characteristics”,
and the “effect of quota on firm policies”, as well as the binomial logit for explaining companies’
decisions to delist any time during the period 2003–2009. The AD paper appeared in the Quarterly
Journal of Economics and has been widely cited and followed by other research in the area.
In the study by Eckbo et al. (2019), the authors use the AD data and perform a comprehensive
new econometric analysis. In effect, the authors state that AD’s results are not sustained when “simple

311
JRFM 2020, 13, 218

econometric adjustments” are applied. Eckbo et al. (2019) use the same methodology as AD with
refinements that (the authors claim) are necessary. For example, the event study has been repeated
but with the use of a portfolio approach—which yielded insignificant abnormal returns to major
quota-related news events—and also with adjustment for cross-correlation, resulting in insignificant
abnormal returns as well. In addition, the instrumental variable approach to panel Tobin’s Q regression
resulted in an insignificant effect of the quota on Q. Finally, by using the diff-in-diff regression, the
authors prove that, unlike AD, there is no significant change in CEO experience following the quota.
The discussion reported here is an example of results that differ even when using the same sample.
Such a message is not very encouraging. Perhaps, wider use of good practices and extending the
reasoning foundation into areas outside economics and finance may be an appropriate solution when
conducting such research in the future.

5. European Data: Microeconometric Exercise


The final part of this paper presents another study within the search for a relationship between
female presence on BoDs and firm performance, this time for European companies in 2015. The data
used in this study were collected by Olesiejuk4 (2017) from the Amadeus (Orbis) database. There are
1194 observations selected on an availability basis (non-random sample), representing the same number
of European companies and their financial statements for the year 2015.
The companies represent 18 countries, primarily Italy (49% of observations) and Spain (23%),
followed by the UK (7%), Sweden (7%), and Norway (4%). The average number of BoD members is 3.57
and all the BoD members are male in 57% of the cases. Due to the large proportion of Italian companies
in the full sample, we also consider a “no Italy” (limited) sample with 614 observations (companies).
In line with the research results presented in this paper, our search starts with finding
predictors/correlates of the dummy variable WomaninBoD (=1 when there is at least one woman
on the board, =0 otherwise). For the full sample, the WomaninBoD variable has the mean 0.4263—i.e.,
in 509 cases out of 1194, WomaninBoD = 1. In the limited sample, the WomaninBoD variable has the
mean 0.4495—i.e., in 276 cases out of 614, WomaninBoD = 1.
The list of potential predictors for the variable WomaninBoD in the dataset includes more than
50 variables5 ; however, WomaninBoD is significantly correlated with only a few.
Tables 1 and 2 present the linear correlation coefficients of WomaninBoD with other variables that
are significantly different than zero. Most correlations are low. Our plan now is:

(1) First, we try to find how the relationship between WomaninBoD and the other variables holds
in the binomial regression model where WomaninBoD is the dependent variable. This is
because we have here a cross-section situation and the attempted binomial model is just
representing how in a given year (2015) the presence of women on the boards is associated
with selected company characteristics/financials for that year. The novel approach is showing
the connection in reverse: from the predictors to the dummy variable representing women on
the BoD. When the performance variable appears as a predictor, this is the reverse causality
setup—e.g., the better-performing companies may choose to appoint more (or fewer) female
directors (Adams 2016). This interpretation is possible for our limited sample where the predictors
include ROCE or ROA.
(2) Secondly, we attempt to repeat the typical linear regressions where, on the left-hand side,
the ”performance” variable is explained by WomaninBoD and other selected predictors.

4 The Olesiejuk (2017) study is not used here.


5 Since not all companies in the sample are listed, no market-based variables are available for the sample.

312
JRFM 2020, 13, 218

Table 1. Correlation of WomaninBoD with selected explanatory variables. Full sample.

Full Sample
WomaninBoD ROCE Logassets BoDsize Gearing
n = 1194
WomaninBoD 1
ROCE −0.0693 * 1
logassets 0.2174 * −0.1430 * 1
BoDsize 0.3468 * −0.0874 * 0.5309 * 1
gearing −0.0738 * −0.0713 * −0.0231 −0.0620 * 1
solvency 0.1058 * −0.1019 * 0.1636 * 0.1081 * −0.6000 *

Table 2. Correlation of WomaninBoD with selected explanatory variables. Limited sample.

Limited Sample
WomaninBoD ROCE ROA Logassets BoDsize Solvency
n = 614
WomaninBoD 1
ROCE −0.0996 * 1
ROA −0.0792 * 0.7518 * 1
logassets 0.2755 * −0.1410 * −0.1620 * 1
BoDsize 0.4948 * −0.0798 * −0.0710 0.5736 * 1
solvency 0.1011 * −0.0595 0.1476 * 0.1094 * 0.0730 1
net_assets_ turnover −0.0851 * 0.2065 * 0.0044 −0.1707 * −0.0654 −0.3666 *
* indicates p < 0.05; Explanation of terms: gearing ratio = (non-current liabilities + current loans)/(shareholder
funds) × 100; solvency ratio = (shareholder funds)/(total assets); ROCE = return on capital employed = (P/L before
tax + extr. items + interest paid)/(shareholder funds + non-current liabilities); ROA = return on total assets = P/L
before tax + extr. items/total assets; net assets turnover = (operating revenue)/(shareholder funds + non-current
liabilities); non-current liabilities = long term debt + other non-current liabilities.
Tables 3 and 4 present the results of the first stage: estimating the logistic regression of WomaninBoD
against some variables, but not more than two at a time. This is because of the high multicollinearity
among the prospective correlates of WomaninBoD.

Table 3. Estimation results of binomial logit (logistic regression) for WomaninBoD as the outcome
variable. Full sample (n = 1194) with WomaninBoD = 1 for 509 observations.

WomaninBoD Coeff. Std. Err. z P > |z|


solvency ratio 0.0048353 0.0029843 1.62 0.105
logBoD 1.418742 0.101768 13.94 0.000
constant −1.773889 0.1514283 −11.71 0.000
LR chi2(2) = 264.85 Prob > chi2 = 0.0000 Pseudo R2 = 0.1626
Count R2 (Cramer) = 0.701 Area under ROC = 0.757

Table 4. Estimation results of binomial logit (logistic regression) for WomaninBoD as the outcome
variable. Limited sample (n = 614) with WomaninBoD = 1 for 276 observations.

WomaninBoD Coeff. Std. Err. z P > |z|


ROCE −0.005823 0.003341 −1.74 0.081
logBoD 1.598067 0.1472888 10.85 0.000
constant −1.793394 0.1870708 −9.59 0.000
LR chi2(2) = 170.86 Prob > chi2 = 0.0000 Pseudo R2 = 0.2022
Count R2 (Cramer) = 0.700 Area under ROC = 0.789

The classification tables for logistic regressions are formed on the basis of Cramer’s rule
(Cramer 1999). This possibility is often neglected. When samples are unbalanced, Cramer (1999)
advocates the use of a cut-off point α equal to the proportion of ones in the sample. In effect, the success
rates for yi = 1 and yi = 0 are better spread than for the typical cut-off point of 0.5 (Gruszczyński 2019).
The interpretation effect of logistic regressions lies in showing that—despite poor correlation with
prospective covariates—the variable WomaninBoD may formally be “explained” with such models.
Classification results are rather weak but sensible—the fit measure of around 0.7 is common in
microeconometric applications in corporate finance.

313
JRFM 2020, 13, 218

Now we place WomaninBoD among the regressors in the typical model considered in previous
sections of this paper where the outcome variable is firm performance. After the correlation check,
one should expect that WomaninBoD is insignificant in any model attempted in the classical way—i.e.,
as multiple regression, and, in fact, that is the case here. As an example, Tables 5 and 6 present the
estimation results of two regressions: one for the full sample and one for the limited sample.

Table 5. Estimation results of multiple regressions with WomaninBoD as the predictor variable and
ROCE as the dependent variable. Full sample (n = 1194).

ROCE Model I Model II Model III


−2.330915 −2.656997 −3.00803 *
WomaninBoD
(1.704436) (1.704133) (1.6794)
−2.429104 ** −2.439499 ** −1.875371 **
logassets
(0.5311289) (0.5297278) (0.5293145)
−0.0122183 **
gearing ——– ——–
(0.0045002)
−0.0027405 **
solvency × gearing ——– ——-
(0.000425)
52.8078 ** 54.85445 51.90963
constant
(7.753808) (7.769805) (7.626242)
Adjusted R2 0.0203 0.0256 0.0526
Standard errors in brackets; * indicates p < 0.1; ** indicates p < 0.05.

Table 6. Estimation results of multiple regressions with WomaninBoD as the predictor variable and
ROA as the dependent variable. Limited sample (n = 614).

ROA Model I Model II


−0.7753716 −1.047199
WomaninBoD
(0.8596029) (0.8498533)
−0.8995534 ** −0.9889818 **
logassets
(0.2461068) (0.2435302)
0.0805369 **
solvency ——–
(0.0186925)
19.54126 ** 17.76706 **
constant
(3.615013) (3.587858)
Adjusted R2 0.0244 0.0516
Standard errors in brackets; ** indicates p < 0.05.

As shown in Tables 5 and 6 multiple regressions for performance against WomaninBoD reveal no
significance of this variable, even in a typical setup for controlling the endogeneity—i.e., with the control
variable being the size of the company, here represented by the logassets variable (see Adams 2016,
Table 1).
The next step would be searching for relationships between WomaninBoD and firm performance
along the distribution of the performance variable. In other words, we may try to employ quantile
regressions as in the paper of Conyon and He (2017), mentioned in Section 3. Tables 7 and 8 present the
results of the quantile regressions estimation for the full sample and for the limited sample. We used
the setup from the multiple regression:

(1) the full sample performance variable is ROCE and the regressors are WomaninBoD, logassets,
and the interaction variable solvency × gearing.
(2) the limited sample performance variable is ROA and the regressors are WomaninBoD, logassets,
and solvency.

314
JRFM 2020, 13, 218

Table 7. Estimation results of quantile regressions with WomaninBoD as the predictor variable and
ROCE as the dependent variables. Full sample (n = 1194).

Quantile 25 50 75
−0.7275284 −0.2503224 −2.570621
WomaninBoD
(0.7895722) (1.07899) (2.047829)
−0.2003255 −1.055661 ** −2.281304 **
logassets
(0.2488579) (0.3400768) (0.6454362)
−0.0003952 ** −0.0014783 ** −0.0032773 **
solvency × gearing
(0.0001998) (0.000273) (0.0005182)
8.399047 ** 31.20172 ** 68.13485 **
constant
(3.585488) (4.899749) (9.299297)
Pseudo R2 0.0041 0.0331 0.0727
Standard errors in brackets; ** indicates p < 0.05.

Table 8. Estimation results of quantile regressions with WomaninBoD as the predictor variable and ROA
as the dependent variables. Limited sample (n = 614).

Quantile 25 50 75
−0.5104711 −0.5208956 −1.315783
WomaninBoD
(0.5368787) (0.7291287) (1.300562)
−0.03384130 −0.2523032 −1.294657 **
logassets
(0.1538456) (0.2089359) (0.3726834)
0.0177385 0.0572204 ** 0.0822441 **
solvency
(0.0118086) (0.0160371) (0.0286058)
0.9480991 5.532674 * 27.01107 **
constant
(2.266561) (3.078191) (5.490634)
Pseudo R2 0.0052 0.0162 0.0422
Standard errors in brackets; * indicates p < 0.1; ** indicates p < 0.05.

Quantile regressions were performed for centiles 25, 50, and 75. Tables 7 and 8 show that, along the
full distribution of the performance variables, we do not see any connection between female presence
on the boards and firm performance. This evidence is, to some extent, stronger than that resulting
from multiple regressions.
Again, for this particular dataset, the association of women on boards and performance of
companies seems not to be present.
The study presented in this section may be the starting point for a more thorough investigation.
Firstly, the dataset could be improved by taking into consideration the time dimension and
applying panel econometric techniques. Secondly, the differences between countries could be better
examined—e.g., by considering further controls. Those may be governance-specific variables like
country shareholder protection strength (Byron and Post 2016) and Hofstede dimension variables
(Carrasco et al. 2015).

6. Conclusions
The results of research on the association of female presence on boards and firm performance
worldwide are not consistent. This might be due to a lack of solid theories on this particular issue.
The general reasoning points in all three possible directions: female presence and performance are
(1) related negatively, (2) related positively, and (3) not related. Outcome (3) is advocated in this paper.
We present examples of research showing all three types of associations. On the basis of selected works,
we also show the variety of microeconometric methodologies that might be applied in the search for
the relationship between female presence on boards and firm performance.

315
JRFM 2020, 13, 218

In the empirical part of the paper, we present a study of this association for a sample of European
companies in 2015. With the use of binomial modelling, multiple regression, and quantile regression,
we find that female presence on BoDs is not significantly related to firm performance for the sample of
European companies.
This, together with the picture emerging from the paper’s first part, leads to us stating that, perhaps,
searching for an association between women on boards and performance is not fundamental. However,
modern business societies worldwide may need to boost the female presence within managerial bodies.
Current econometric research provides evidence that this is not harmful to corporate results.

Funding: This research received no external funding.


Acknowledgments: The author thanks Agnieszka Olesiejuk for the permission to use data collected by her.
Conflicts of Interest: The author declares no conflict of interest.

References
Adams, Renée B. 2016. Women on boards: The superheroes of tomorrow? The Leadership Quarterly 27: 371–386.
[CrossRef]
Adams, Renée B. 2017. The ABCs of empirical corporate (governance) research. Corporate Governance International
Review 25: 461–464. [CrossRef]
Ahern, Kenneth R., and Amy K. Dittmar. 2012. The Changing of the Boards: The Impact on Firm Valuation of
Mandated Female Board Representation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 127: 137–197. [CrossRef]
Aluchna, Maria, and Güler Aras, eds. 2018. Women on Corporate Boards. An International Perspective. Abingdon:
Routledge.
Aluchna, Maria, and Anna Krejner-Nowecka. 2016. Why do we need women on boards? A synthesis of theories.
Przeglad˛ Organizacji 10: 72–80. [CrossRef]
Amrhein, Valentin, Sander Greenland, and Blake McShane. 2019. Retire statistical significance. Nature 567:
305–307. [CrossRef]
Angrist, Joshua D., and Jörn-Steffen Pischke. 2009. Mostly Harmless Econometrics. Princeton: Princeton University
Press.
Angrist, Joshua D., and Jörn-Steffen Pischke. 2015. Mastering ‘Metrics: The Path from Cause to Effect. Princeton:
Princeton University Press.
Atanasov, Vladimir A., and Bernard S. Black. 2016. Shock-based causal inference in corporate finance and
accounting research. Critical Finance Review 5: 207–304. [CrossRef]
Byron, Kris, and Corinne Post. 2016. Women on Boards of Directors and Corporate Social Performance:
A Meta-Analysis. Corporate Governance: An International Review 24: 428–442. [CrossRef]
Carrasco, Amalia, Claude Francoeur, Réal Labelle, Joaquina Laffarga, and Emiliano Ruiz-Barbadillo. 2015.
Appointing women to boards: Is there a cultural bias? Journal of Business Ethics 129: 429–444. [CrossRef]
Conyon, Martin, and Lerong He. 2017. Firm Performance and Boardroom Gender Diversity: A Quantile
Regression Approach. Journal of Business Research. [CrossRef]
Cramer, Jan S. 1999. Predictive performance of the binary logit model in unbalanced samples. Journal of the Royal
Statistical Society 48: 85–94. [CrossRef]
Eckbo, B. Espen, Knut Nygaard, and Karin S. Thorburn. 2019. Board Gender-Balancing and Firm Value. Finance
Working Paper No. 463/2016. Brussels, Belgium: European Corporate Governance Institute (ECGI).
[CrossRef]
European Commission. 2012. Women on Boards: Commission Proposes 40% Objective. Available online:
https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/IP_12_1205 (accessed on 9 July 2020).
European Commission. 2019. Gender Balance on Company Boards—Information from the Commission. Available
online: https://data.consilium.europa.eu/doc/document/ST-9823-2019-INIT/en/pdf (accessed on 9 July 2020).
Ferreira, Daniel. 2015. Board diversity: Should we trust research to inform policy? Corporate Governance
International Review 23: 108–111. [CrossRef]
Gordini, Niccolò, and Elisa Rancati. 2017. Gender diversity in the Italian boardroom and firm financial performance.
Management Research Review 40: 75–94. [CrossRef]

316
JRFM 2020, 13, 218

Gruszczyński, Marek. 2018. Good Practices in Empirical Corporate Finance and Accounting Research. Journal of
Banking and Financial Economics 2: 45–51. [CrossRef]
Gruszczyński, Marek. 2019. On Unbalanced Sampling in Bankruptcy Prediction. International Journal of Financial
Studies 7: 28. [CrossRef]
Gruszczyński, Marek. 2020. Financial Microeconometrics. A Research Methodology in Corporate Finance and Accounting.
Cham, Switzerland: Springer.
Halliday, Cynthia Saldanha, Samantha C. Paustian-Underdahl, and Stav Fainshmidt. 2020. Women on Boards of
Directors: A Meta-Analytic Examination of the Roles of Organizational Leadership and National Context for
Gender Equality. Journal of Business and Psychology. [CrossRef]
Ionascu, Mihaela, Ionascu Ion, Marian Sacarin, and Mihaela Minu. 2018. Women on Boards and Financial
Performance: Evidence from a European Emerging Market. Sustainability 10: 1644. [CrossRef]
Kompa, Krzysztof, and Dorota Witkowska. 2017. Wpływ zmian frakcji kobiet w managemencie na zmiany
ROE spółek publicznych (Relations between changes of women share in management and ROE of public
companies). Metody ilościowe w badaniach ekonomicznych (Quantitative Methods in Economic Research) XVIII/4:
614–623. [CrossRef]
Olesiejuk, Agnieszka. 2017. Kobiety w organach zarzadzaj ˛ acych
˛ przedsi˛ebiorstw a wyniki finansowe. Analiza
ekonometryczna (Women in Corporate Boards and Companies’ Financial Results. Econometric Analysis).
Master’s Dissertation, SGH Warsaw School of Economics, Warsaw, Poland.
Pletzer, Jan Luca, Romina Nikolova, Karina Karolina Kedzior, and Sven Constantin Voelpel. 2015. Does gender
matter? Female representation on corporate boards and firm financial performance—A meta-analysis.
PLoS ONE 10: e0130005. [CrossRef]
Post, Corinne, and Kris Byron. 2015. Women on boards and firm financial performance: A meta-analysis.
Academy of Management Journal 58: 1546–1571. [CrossRef]
Roberts, Michael R., and Toni Whited. 2013. Endogeneity in Empirical Corporate Finance. In Handbook of the
Economics of Finance. Edited by Constantinides George M., Milton Harris and Rene M. Stulz. Amsterdam:
Elsevier, vol. 2.
Rossi, Matteo, Serena Galasso, and Arturo Capasso. 2017. Women Do it Better: An Investigation on the Association
between Gender Diversity in Board of Directors and the Financial Performance. International Journal of
Economics and Financial Issues 7: 41–50.
Sila, Vathunyoo, Angelica Gonzalez, and Jens Hagendorff. 2016. Women on board: Does boardroom gender
diversity affect firm risk. Journal of Corporate Finance 36: 26–53. [CrossRef]
Taghizadeh-Hesary, Farhad, Naoyuki Yoshino, and Lisa Fukuda. 2019. Gender and Corporate Success: An Empirical
Analysis of Gender-Based Corporate Performance on a Sample of Asian Small and Medium-Sized Enterprises.
ADBI Working Paper 937. Tokyo, Japan: Asian Development Bank Institute, Available online: https:
//www.adb.org/publications/gender-and-corporate-success-asian-sme (accessed on 17 September 2020).
Vintilă, Georgeta, Mihaela Onofrei, and Ştefan C. Gherghina. 2014. Corporate Governance Context on Women’s
Representation in Top Management Positions and Listed Companies Value. Revista de Cercetare şi Intervenţie
Socială 44: 229–252.

© 2020 by the author. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access
article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution
(CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).

317
Journal of
Risk and Financial
Management

Article
Capital Structure Choices in Technology Firms:
Empirical Results from Polish Listed Companies
Marcin Kedzior 1, *, Barbara Grabinska 2 , Konrad Grabinski 1 and Dorota Kedzior 3
1 Financial Accounting Department, College of Economics, Finance and Law, Cracow University
of Economics, Rakowicka 27, 31-510 Cracow, Poland; kg@uek.krakow.pl
2 Finance and Financial Policy Department, College of Economics, Finance and Law, Cracow University
of Economics, Rakowicka 27, 31-510 Cracow, Poland; grabinsb@uek.krakow.pl
3 Corporate Finance Department, College of Economics, Cracow, Finance and Law, University of Economics,
Rakowicka 27, 31-510 Cracow, Poland; kedziord@uek.krakow.pl
* Correspondence: kedziorm@uek.krakow.pl; Tel.: +48-12-293-56-94

Received: 31 August 2020; Accepted: 17 September 2020; Published: 22 September 2020

Abstract: The main aim of the paper is the identification of capital structure determinants, with a
special emphasis on investments in the innovativeness of Polish New Technology-Based Firms
(NTBFs). Poland is a unique country in that it is an emerging market that was also promoted in 2018
to the status of a developed country. The study sample consisted of 31 companies listed in the Warsaw
Stock Exchange that are classified as high-tech firms and covers the period 2014–2018. The following
factors influencing the capital structure were analyzed: internal and external innovativeness and
the firm’s size, liquidity, intangibility, age, profitability, and growth opportunities. The results of the
research provide empirical evidence that liquidity, age, and investments in innovativeness determine
capital structure, which provides an additional argument supporting the trade-off theory and the
modified version of the pecking order theory. More specifically, the results suggest that companies
whose process of investment in innovativeness is based on the external acquisition of technology are
able to attract external financing, while the process based on internally generated innovativeness (R&D
activity) deters external capital. The results are interesting for policymakers in emerging markets.

Keywords: capital structure; New Technology-Based Firms (NTBFs); internal and external
innovativeness; intangibility

1. Introduction
Over one hundred years ago, entrepreneurial activity undertaken in technologically advanced
sectors was considered to be a primary source of innovation and economic growth (Schumpeter 1911).
Nowadays, economic growth and competitive power are ascribed to the innovativeness of the economy
to an even greater degree (Gherghina et al. 2020). From a policymaking perspective, special attention is
devoted to high-tech companies and tools supporting innovative activity. Anecdotal evidence implies
that the high-tech sector is a crucial driver of economic development. Furthermore, the endogenous
growth theory assumes that the long-run growth rate has an endogenous character, and that the human
factor plays a vital role (Kopf 2007). The decision of whether to invest more in R&D or to increase
public spending on education is crucial in this context. The problem is especially important for EU
countries, where, over the last decade, the lower level of investments in R&D and innovativeness
has created a gap as compared to the main economic partners like the U.S. or China (Gil et al. 2019).
Furthermore, investments in innovativeness create a knowledge-based society, produce intellectual
capital, and finally, as (Popescu 2019) suggests, become an integral part of national wealth.
According to the results of the McKinsey Global Survey of Business Executives, on the
corporate level, executives believe that innovation is the most required element of growth

JRFM 2020, 13, 221; doi:10.3390/jrfm13090221 319 www.mdpi.com/journal/jrfm


JRFM 2020, 13, 221

(Carden et al. 2005, p. 25). (Hay and Kamshad 1994), at the beginning of the 1990s, designed and
performed a questionnaire based on Small and medium—sized enterprises located in the U.K.
The results of the study imply that investment in product innovation was, at that time, perceived as
the single most crucial strategy, followed by the policy of broadening the product range and
geographic expansion.
In recent years small, medium, and young companies active in high tech sectors have attracted
special attention in economic literature, as they are deemed to be a major source of innovation and
development for the economy. Some authors claim that these firms have a specific business model.
(Giraudo et al. 2019), Aghion and Howitt (2005), Hall (2002) stress that these firms are characterized by
a specific attitude toward grasping technological innovation. Still, they also suffer from inefficient
mechanisms of capital allocations, which are very severe, especially for young firms which lack track
record, stable cash flows, and collaterals. (Giraudo et al. 2019) indicate that financial constraints can be
especially severe for so-called bank-based economies, like Europe. Howell (2016), who investigates
barriers in financing innovative firms in China, stresses that the problem of financial constraints for
innovative firms can be especially severe in transitioning economies with a less developed system of
financial intermediaries.
From the policymaking point of view, special attention is devoted to so-called New
Technology-Based Firms (NTBFs). The term was supposedly coined by Arthur D. Little (Little 1977),
who defined NTBFs as an independent venture less than 25 years old that supplies a product or service
based on the exploitation of an invention or technological innovation. The issue invoked by many
researchers is financial constraints, which are encountered by NTBFs at the early stage of development.
So far, most studies have been focused on developed countries like the US, UK, Germany, France,
or Ireland, where the institutional market environment is well established and at the same time most
developed in terms of technology and science. These countries also represent a long history and have
extensive experience in supporting the development of innovative activity. The high-technology firms
in these countries have access to the best research centers, the best universities, and are subject to a very
competitive market, and therefore their activity is based mostly on internally generated innovation.
However, scant research is devoted to the other emerging or less developed countries whose
economies are trying to catch up with the leading innovators. This is especially apparent,
as (Vintilă et al. 2017, p. 38) note, for countries from Eastern Europe, which endeavor to line up
with Western Europe. The specific NTBFs located in these countries have other distinctive attributes.
Firstly, since they are usually in emerging economies, there is no equivalent to the best research centers
and access to the best universities. Secondly, there are almost no headquarters and/or research centers
of multinational companies, which are usually located in the most developed countries. Thirdly, it is
much more difficult for high-tech companies to compete for leading researchers with multinational
companies. Fourthly, it is much more challenging to compete with high-tech companies from leading
countries due to scarce resources in terms of finance, marketing, patent protection, etc.
As a result, high-tech companies in developing countries often adopt a different strategy in which
innovative activity is based in substantial part on the acquisition of external technology and to a minor
degree on internally generated innovation. The purchase and implementation of new technology is the
preferred and less risky strategy in comparison to the development of in-house produced innovative
processes. Therefore, the specificity of the high-tech companies in emerging and developing markets is
slightly different in comparison to NTBFs from leading countries. The problem is especially visible
within the EU, where the concept of “Two-Speed Europe” is apparent in the economic press. Therefore,
as (Vintilă et al. 2018, p. 571) point out, the disparities between the West and East require a deeper
understanding of proper public policy.
The main aim of the paper is the identification of determinants of the capital structure of
NTBFs in a country that has an emerging economy. The focus of this study is on technological
firms (NTBFs) headquartered in Poland, which is a very unique and specific case. Poland was
the first CEE economy promoted by FTSE Russel’s index provider with the Emerging Market to

320
JRFM 2020, 13, 221

Developed Market status. Since 2018, Poland has been classified as one of the 25 most advanced global
economies, including the U.S., U.K., Germany, France, Japan, etc. Therefore, Poland is considered a
success story in terms of economic development, but at the same time is a country with one of the
lowest levels of corporate R&D expenditures within EU countries. This contradiction urges us to
investigate deeper the determinants of the capital structure of Polish NTBFs with special attention
given to investments in innovativeness. We select companies at a certain stage of development that
are listed on the stock exchange, mostly because of the higher quality of accounting information
reported in the financial statements as compared to the non-listed companies. We hypothesize that
investment in innovation has an inconclusive influence on financial leverage. Therefore, we separated
it into two categories: innovation generated internally (R&D projects) and innovation acquired
externally. These two types of investments have significant and distinct attributes, which we posit
have a differential impact on financial leverage. We provide empirical evidence that the former kind
of investment has negative, while the latter one a positive impact on financial leverage. The other
hypotheses conjecture the impact of the other firm’s attributes like a firm’s size, liquidity, intangibility,
age, profitability, and growth opportunities.
As far as we know, there is no study related to emerging economies in which investments
in innovativeness are separated into externally acquired and internally generated and treated as a
potential determinant of capital structure. Our hypotheses are tested on a sample of 102 firm-year
observations (34 companies). The study period (2014–2018) ends at the moment when Poland was
promoted to a group of countries with Developed Market status, so it can be regarded as a study of a
country with the Emerging Market status.
The first section presents a literature review of the most important studies related to the problem of
the financial structure of high-tech companies, the theories, and hypothesis development. The second
section presents the sample characteristics, research design, and empirical results. The last section
concludes with the most important issues resulting from empirical research.

2. Theories of Capital Structure


Over the past several decades a number of capital structure theories have been developed which
attempt to explain the creation of structures of economic entities’ financing. The classical capital
structure theories include Net Income Theory, Net Operating Income Theory, and Traditional Theory.
Net Income Theory is based on the assumption that a firm’s value is proportionate to its share of debt
in capital structure, so a firm’s maximum value is reached in the situation of its maximum indebtedness.
Net Operating Income Theory assumes the dependence of a firm’s value on the value of operating
income; in the situation of determined conditions capital structure does not affect a firm’s value.
According to Traditional Theory, a proper balance should be maintained between internal and external
sources of financing. Therefore, a reasonable level of debt increases a firm’s value (Durand 1952).
However, the best known classical theories are those created by F. Modigliani and M. Miller (MM).
In their famous paper MM argue that a firm’s value is not dependent on the capital structure but rather
owners’ expectations with regard to cash flows (Modigliani and Miller 1958). The conclusions based
on the assumption of perfect capital markets were partly rejected in MM’s next work, which took into
account the issue of taxation (Modigliani and Miller 1963). MM finally admitted that indebtedness
has a positive impact on a firm’s value thanks to possible tax burden reductions. In the context of
determining the capital structures of high-tech companies, MM and the remaining classical theories
are of limited practical application (Coleman and Robb 2012; Ullah et al. 2010). High-tech firms, due to
high-risk levels, do not heavily rely on debt financing; however, high debt levels have a negative
impact on the value of high-tech companies.
The capital structure of high-tech firms can be more affected by the agency costs theory. Its basics
were developed by Fama and Miller (1972), and initially by Jensen and Meckling (1976). It assumes the
existence of conflicts of interest between owners, lenders, and managers. Managers do not always act
with the intention of protecting owners’ interests—they often pursue their own interests, which can

321
JRFM 2020, 13, 221

be different (Novaes and Zingales 1995). In such a situation owners are forced to exercise additional
control over the management’s activities, which generates additional costs—agency costs. One of
the ways of linking the interests of the above groups is relating the management’s compensation to
the company’s shares. Another situation can occur in which managers implement risky investment
projects, generating additional risk for lenders, while only owners benefit from higher profits. Debt can
then act as a factor that disciplines the management, enforcing more active operating policies, and more
effective investment policies (Kenourgios et al. 2019). In this situation, debt decreases agency costs
(Novaes and Zingales 1995). Agency costs tend to be very high in companies with high unique value
(Colombo et al. 2014; Sau 2007). The higher the agency costs, the lower the firm’s value (Lins 2003).
A possibly significant role in high-tech firms is played by trade-off theory. Its creators
are Kraus and Litzenberger (1973). All financing methods have both advantages and drawbacks.
Higher debt levels provide an opportunity to deduct interest from taxable income. However,
it should be noted that there are other methods of reducing tax burden with the use of non-interest
tax shields including effective depreciation policies, or, in a broader sense, tax optimization
(DeAngelo and Masulis 1980). It should be stressed that a company can benefit considerably from
relatively high tax rates. A company’s heavy reliance on indebtedness in its capital structure increases
business risk and results in the costs of bankruptcy (Baxter 1967). The higher the bankruptcy costs,
the lower a firm’s value. Higher debt levels in the balance sheet total originally increase a firm’s value,
but at a certain point, a firm’s value decreases (Adrienn 2014). The costs of bankruptcy are then higher
than tax shield positive effects. A practical confirmation of the trade-off theory is the occurrence of
the so-called industry effect. The functioning of an enterprise within one industry is dependent on
similar factors—economic entities are characterized by similar operating cycles, risk levels, and agency
costs, hence their similar share of debt in overall financing. The companies whose share of debt in the
structure of financing is below industry average tend to increase it, unlike entities that have a large share
of debt in their financing structure and try to lower its level (K˛edzior 2012). The industry effect is not
identical in all industries. In industries characterized by stiff competition and diversified agency costs,
debt levels can vary. Unequal access to advanced technologies has a similar impact on indebtedness
(Michaelas et al. 1999). The above factors result in the existence of an optimal industry capital structure,
which economic entities seek to achieve in their long-term operations (M’ng et al. 2017).
In the case of innovative companies, it is difficult to estimate the risk of the sources of financing
within the framework of trade-off theory. Many threats should be regarded as potential, and their
materialization is conditional and not easy to estimate (Sau 2007), hence difficulties in choosing
adequate sources of financing. Choices made by high-tech firms with regard to financing are affected
by a rapidly changing business environment and the complexity of applied technologies (Li et al. 2006).
These entities do not have the ability to offer adequate guarantees to mitigate lenders’ risk (Sau 2007).
Innovative firms have higher bankruptcy costs (Aghion et al. 2004; Sau 2007), so the share of liabilities
in the balance sheet total cannot be dominant. High-tech companies with a relatively high volume of
intangible assets are less inclined to borrow funds. On the other hand, high growth companies rely
on debt financing to a smaller degree (Castro et al. 2015). Transaction costs in such entities are also
high due to risk factors and, generally, limited volumes (Revest and Sapio 2012). Their market value
is subject to large fluctuations, especially as their financial standing deteriorates. It results from the
fact that their valuation is based on specialized assets as well as large growth potential. Therefore,
valuation changes on stock exchanges play a crucial role in high-tech firms (Revest and Sapio 2012).
The financial conditions and capital requirements of high-tech firms depend on the stage of their
development (Sau 2007). At the initial stage of development economic entities’ cash flows are often
negative, so they are not able to repay their debts, and the acquisition of funds is difficult. In their early
stages, high-tech firms’ biggest problem in product commercialization based on the use of familiar
technologies is the acquisition of funds for operating activities (Minola et al. 2013).
The creation of capital structure is greatly affected by the pecking order theory. The theory
was created by Donaldson (1961), and then elaborated and modified by Myers and Majluf (1984).

322
JRFM 2020, 13, 221

The authors divide sources of financing into external and internal sources. The choice of the sources
of financing is mainly determined by their cost which is lower for internal capital. Therefore,
companies should finance their operations by relying on retained earnings, followed by debt and,
finally, the issue of shares (Stulz 1990). This order is justified by information asymmetry in relationships
between companies, banks and external investors. Banks and external investors have more difficulty
accessing information about companies than people operating within company structures, so in
light of the higher risk of transferring capital, they require higher interest on loans and higher
rates of return. Information asymmetry leads to moral hazard and adverse selection. The adverse
selection indicates that banks find it difficult to distinguish between effective and ineffective investment
projects, which generates additional costs and increases risk. A high level of adverse selection also
results from great uncertainty with regard to future return on investment rates as compared with
traditionally implemented projects (Carpenter and Petersen 2002). Moral hazard indicates that owners
benefit more from implementing risky investment projects than debtors (Aoun and Heshmati 2006).
High information asymmetry results, to a considerable degree, from the large development potential of
high-tech firms (Castro et al. 2015). High information asymmetry in the technology sector mainly applies
to small companies. Therefore, such companies can often be undervalued (Coleman and Robb 2012).
Pecking order theory assumes that the accessibility of information about a high-tech firm has
an impact on the choice of capital structure. To avoid problems resulting from the disclosure of
internal information to a larger group of stakeholders, high-tech firms give preference to internal
sources of financing (Hogan et al. 2017; Scherr et al. 1993). Due to such factors as uncertainty with
regard to the ultimate results of innovative investment projects, possible cases of underinvesting
and overtrading, difficulties in monitoring R&D activities, and the frequent lack of comprehensive
knowledge about technology among investors and banks, access to external financing can be limited
(Revest and Sapio 2012). Generally, high reinvestment rates in technology firms force them to seek
external sources of financing in the absence of their own funds (Berggren et al. 2000).
The acquisition of external capital implies the necessity of disclosing additional information about
planned operating or investment activities. Small and medium-sized high-tech firms are not inclined
to disclose such information. Similar opinions are held by Revest and Sapio (2012). Technology firms
are unwilling to disclose detailed information about R&D programs due to a very competitive market
and the fear of losing competitive advantage. Aoun and Heshmati (2006) also claim that because of the
confidential character of business operations high-tech firms have difficulty disclosing comprehensive
financial data, and hence face problems with acquiring funds for business activities. As a result,
markets do not possess full information, and lenders have limited knowledge about the current
operations of high-tech firms (Ullah et al. 2010). Transaction costs and greater flexibility of operations
justify reliance on retained earnings as a source of financing (Grinblatt and Titman 2002). A number
of empirical research studies point to a negative correlation between profitability and indebtedness
(Bhayani 2010a; Korkmaz and Karaca 2014). Therefore, profitable firms rely on debt financing on a
limited scale.
Technology firms tend to choose financing through the issue of shares rather than indebtedness.
This mainly refers to young firms at an early stage of development (Minola et al. 2013).
Innovative firms are characterized by attractive investment possibilities as compared with other
business entities, but the costs of the issue of shares should be regarded as high (Aghion et al. 2004;
Castro et al. 2015). Larger technology firms have a greater ability to raise funds through the issue of
shares (Mac an Bhaird and Lucey 2010). Frequently, young firms without a long credit history and
relationships with banks are left with no other option but to issue shares (Carpenter and Petersen 2002).
Because of the lack of collateral in the form of tangible assets, innovative companies tend to rely more
frequently on share capital. The issue of shares does not have to be secured by tangible assets and does
not increase the threat of bankruptcy. High-tech firms can successfully implement R&D programmes if
they are able to convince investors to purchase issued shares (Carpenter and Petersen 2002). The idea

323
JRFM 2020, 13, 221

of the issue of shares is also justified by technology firms’ tendency to implement high returns but also
risky investments (Carpenter and Petersen 2002).
Because of the risk of share dilution and takeovers, innovative companies tend to rely on debt
financing (Aghion et al. 2004). If the lack of transparency of disclosures is acceptable, high-tech firms
can also resort to bank loans (Berggren et al. 2000). As firms grow and gain more experience, the range
of information asymmetry reduces, the value of assets (especially tangible assets) increases, and access
to bank loans becomes easier (Hogan et al. 2017). High-risk firms may not be granted loans, but they
are still able to successfully implement the process of issuing shares.
It seems, however, that pecking order theory turns out to be more useful in large economic
entities, which rarely issue shares because of the high values of retained earnings and the possibility
of acquiring corporate bonds (Akgül and Sigali 2018). Nevertheless, within a short time horizon,
enterprises are likely to create their capital structure based on the pecking order theory. On the other
hand, in longer periods of time in which the changeability of cash flows and economic conditions is
less severe, companies are likely to rely on trade-off theory (Bontempi 2002). Pecking order theory
(POT) is probably more effective in describing the choice of sources of financing in mature companies
as compared with high growth entities.
The signaling theory, created by Ross (1977), has a different impact on capital structure creation.
Due to information asymmetry, people operating inside and outside of an organization have unequal
access to information about a company’s financial standing. External stakeholders make intensive
efforts to obtain information about a company’s future financial condition and future share valuations.
Therefore, they seek additional signals concerning an economic entity’s actual financial condition.
The most reliable signals and those that cannot be easily imitated refer to dividend policies and capital
structure decisions (Frankfurter and Wood 2002; Deesomsak et al. 2004). Increased indebtedness
should be regarded as a positive signal—it indicates a bank’s favorable assessment of an entity’s
creditworthiness and stable projected financial results and cash flows. It can be assumed that current and
projected financial results will not be diluted. On the other hand, the issue of shares is sometimes treated
by financial markets as a negative signal. Companies with less optimistic financial result predictions
tend to finance their operations through the issue of shares (Leland and Pyle 1977). Managers choose
the issue of shares if their current valuation is excessively high. The market’s negative response to
the issue of shares can be even more severe if investors perceive a company as being characterized by
great information asymmetry (Minola et al. 2013). The range of information asymmetry is very high
for new investment projects, new areas of activity and new strategies. Over time asymmetry tends
to decrease (Harris and Raviv 1988). Information asymmetry relates to new areas and issues—past
events of key significance are reflected in the price of shares (Harris and Raviv 1988).
Last but not least important is the financial life cycle theory, which assumes that a firm’s capital
structure preferences vary with their life cycle (Butzbach and Sarno 2018). The life cycle determined
the availability of financial resources and the cost of capital. The theory implies that smaller and
younger companies exhibit higher information asymmetry, which in turn increases the cost of capital.
We expect that in the case of NTBFs the financial life cycle theory may be of use due to the fact that
R&D activity increases information asymmetry and the fact that NTBFs are typically young companies
with low or no reputation, and have almost no (or very low) carrying amount of tangible assets.

3. Literature Review and Hypothesis Development


Determinants of capital structure have been at the heart of finance theory for many decades. Still,
as Dobusch and Kapeller (2018) indicate, innovation advancements and digital technologies have a big
influence on changes in firms’ strategic choices, so there is a need to reconsider factors influencing
corporate financing decisions, especially in high-tech sectors. The sector is expected to be a crucial
factor affecting access to finance, in part because firms in different industries will be seeking to access
finance for diverse reasons. High–tech firms very often look for sources of financing for innovative or

324
JRFM 2020, 13, 221

R&D activity. Hall (2010) addresses the extent to which innovative firms are fundamentally different
from established companies and how it is reflected in their financing.
In terms of methodology, the critical problem concerns the identification and measuring of
financial constraints. In other words, the operationalization of this problem may be expressed by the
identification determinants of financial leverage, and there is vast literature concerning that problem.
However, papers related to the determinants of high-tech companies or NTBFs represent a much
narrower field of study. There are at least several significant factors whose impact on financial leverage
was empirically investigated and documented. These factors include, among others, the intangibility of
assets, R&D intensity, the firm’s size, age, liquidity, profitability, intangibility, and institutional setting.
Several researchers identified and documented the fact that access to finance for high-tech
companies is constrained. Lee et al. (2015), based on the study of 10,000 UK small and medium-sized
companies1 , found that access to finance is much more difficult for innovative firms and that this problem
has worsened since the 2008 financial crisis. They investigated the relationship between innovation
and access to funding while controlling for firm characteristics (size, age, sector, several personal
features of the management), and the likelihood of applying. Their focus was on the change in access
to capital for innovative firms caused by the 2008 economic crises. It is important to note that their
definition of innovative firms is much broader than in other studies, and extends beyond R&D intensive,
high technology industries. The results suggest that there are barriers to obtaining external finance
for innovative projects, even controlling for several factors that might have influenced more difficult
access to funds. They indicate that there are two kinds of problems in financial systems. The first one
is related to structural problems connected with financial constraints for innovative firms. The second
problem concerns cyclical issues caused by the financial crisis, which, surprisingly, has had a more
severe effect on non-innovative firms’ access to finance. They find that innovative firms in the UK
show higher demand for external capital but encounter more significant barriers to obtaining financing
(restricted supply). In their case, there is a much higher imbalance between demand and supply
compared with non-innovative firms.
Brown and Lee (2019) challenged the assumption of innovative firms having problems with access
to credit. They concluded, based on the survey of 8000 UK SMEs in the period following the financial
crisis of 2008, that there is no difference in access to external finance for high growth SMEs and other
companies. The authors focus on the high growth of SME firms but admit that those are particularly
likely to be innovative firms, and R&D activity is especially seen as growth-inducing. They find that
a vast majority of high growth companies (achieving rapid growth in turnover and employment)
rely strongly on debt, not equity finance for investment purposes (the situation is different in the
case of working capital purposes). Based on these findings, the authors question the rationale for UK
government policy aimed at increasing credit availability for high growth innovative companies.
An important strand of literature concerning the financing of innovative firms is focused on
venture capital and other forms of equity financing tailored to financing risky, innovative projects.
Economic literature shows that innovative firms are more dependent on equity than debt financing
(Brown et al. 2009; Brown et al. 2013; Falato et al. 2018). Still, there is also a growing interest in access
to bank financing (the more standard, traditional form of funding).

3.1. Intangibility
Studies exploring the relationship between intangible assets and capital structure are still relatively
rare. In the economic literature, tangible assets are widely recognized as an important determinant
of financial leverage because of their potential to be treated as collateral. However, investigating the
influence of intangibles on the corporate capital structure is of vital importance because in today’s
economy a large and still increasing part of companies’ assets is represented by intangibles. For obvious

1 SMEs are defined as those with fewer than 250 employees, but excluding those without employees—so SME Employers.

325
JRFM 2020, 13, 221

reasons, it should be assumed that this phenomenon is especially evident in the case of high tech
companies, where innovation activity is crucial. For that reason, intangible assets account for a
substantial part of total assets. However, the situation is more complicated because of the phenomena
of underreporting of R&D outlays, which is a visible problem in today’s financial reporting on
emerging economies.
As Lim et al. (2020) indicate, internally generated intangible assets are reported in balance sheets
and other companies’ reports. For that reason, it is very difficult to evaluate the impact of intangibles
on financial leverage (under accounting rules, most of the internally generated intangible assets are not
recognized on the balance sheet).
Peters and Taylor (2017), based on a sample of U.S. firms, estimated that an average firm acquires
externally only 19% of intangible capital. Therefore, the vast majority of intangible assets are missing
from the balance sheet, so they construct a proxy to measure the value of internally acquired assets
by accumulating past intangible investments reported on firms’ income statements. They define the
stock of international intangible capital as the sum of knowledge capital and organizational capital.
Knowledge capital is created in the process of R&D activity, and to measure it, Peters and Taylor (2017)
use the perpetual inventory method. The accounting approach is different from externally acquired
intangible assets that are capitalized.
Lim et al. (2020) also point out that intangible assets may discourage debt financing because of
poor collateralizibility and high valuation risk. However, they come to the conclusions that identifiable
intangible assets have the same positive influence on financial leverage as tangible assets, and that
they support debt. The study is based on a sample of 469 US public companies between 2002 to
2014. The dataset consists of targets of acquisitions, and in such transactions, there is a disclosure
requirement for the acquiring firms to allocate the purchase price paid for the target to two main
subsets of tangible and intangible assets. Authors in their research use fair value estimates (not the
usually used book value) of both tangible and intangible assets. They divide intangible assets into two
categories: identifiable intangible assets (among them technology-related as patents and in-process
R&D, marketing-related as trademarks, trade names, customer contracts, customer relationships,
and others as non-compete agreements, unproven mineral or gas properties) and unidentifiable
intangible assets—goodwill.
Hall (2010) indicates that in the case of high-tech companies, not only are a significant part of
results intangible, but “much of it is in the form of human capital embedded in the heads of the
employees.” It has low salvage value and is also idiosyncratic, which means that when a company
goes out of business, it is a signal that its value is low. As Hall stresses, except for certain types of
patents, there is little market for distressed intangible assets. This is one more reason for debt financing
being poorly suited to the financing of R&D intensive sectors.
Some studies in the economic literature investigate the relationship between one subset of
intangible assets—patent counts—and financial leverage. The main limitation of these studies is that
there are no objective methods in the valuation of patents.
Mann (2018) calculated that in 2013, 38% of US patenting firms used patent portfolios as collateral
for secured debt, so this type of intangible assets contributes significantly to the financing of innovation.
Mann (2018) also stressed that 16% of patents produced by American firms have been pledged as
collateral at some point. The pledgeability of patents depends on their high level of citation counts and
generality. Brown et al. (2009) points out that companies using patents as collateral mainly belong to
the high-tech sector and feature low tangibility. Therefore, we posit the following hypothesis:

Hypothesis 1 (H1). Intangibility has a significant and negative impact on the financial leverage of NTBFs.

326
JRFM 2020, 13, 221

3.2. Investment in Innovativeness


There is ample empirical evidence suggesting that the capital structure of R&D intensive firms
exhibits significantly less debt than in the case of other firms. The problem of financial constraints in
financing R&D intensive or innovative firms is well pronounced in economic literature. These problems
are also referred to in economic literature as structural problems of the financial system in financing
R&D or, more broadly, innovations. The reasons for that include higher risk, information asymmetry
between financing providers and companies themselves (the main theoretical premise for the difficulties
SMEs face when accessing external capital, which are due to the context-specific nature of R&D projects,
which makes them very difficult for valuation), and the lack of collateral in the case of firms based
mainly on intangible assets (denied finance due to their lack of collateral). Studies typically suggest
that all these reasons cause innovative firms to encounter severe obstacles when it comes to acquiring
debt financing. Internal finance is usually insufficient to finance rapid growth.
A study by Alderson and Betker (1996) provides evidence that there is a positive relation between
liquidation costs and R&D in the corporate sector. Therefore, R&D activity is associated with higher
sunk costs than other types of investments.
Guiso (1998) finds evidence for a representative sample of about 1000 Italian manufacturing
firms with 50 or more employees. Those which belong to the high-tech sector are more likely to be
credit-constrained than low-tech companies. Measurement problems in the proxies for high-tech firms
make it difficult to provide a precise estimate of the size of the effect. The author also points out that
credit constraints have a highly counter-cyclical pattern with the proportion of firms, with limited
access to financing increasing during the downturn.
A very important issue is the relation between intangibility and investment in innovativeness.
We distinguish two types of investments in innovativeness, which are measurable in the accounting
system: external and internal. The internal one refers to R&D outlays expended in a given period
(usually one year) on the firm’s own invention. The external one refers to the expenditures
on other intangible assets acquired externally, having mainly an innovative character. The last
concept—intangibility—refers to the attribute of total assets, which has a cumulative and resource
character. Usually, high intangibility is caused by heavy investments in innovativeness over a longer
period. However, in some instances, it can be triggered by a low carrying amount of tangible assets.
Therefore, from the perspective of a given reporting period, the mutual correlation between intangibility
and investments in innovativeness is not necessary. Both concepts: intangibility and investments in
innovativeness refer to similar but different concepts.
Firstly, we conjecture that, in a country that is at the stage of development classified as an
emerging market, the more a firm invests in an innovative in-house project, the less the bank sector is
willing to provide external capital. We argue that in the case of emerging markets, the informational
asymmetry gap caused by the R&D project is even higher than in the case of developed markets.
Secondly, we hypothesize that the external acquisition of innovation (i.e., technology) does not create
informational asymmetry. Therefore, it does not increase the cost of external capital. Quite the
opposite, it makes a company a more attractive client for the bank sector, with better prospects for
the future. Therefore, we posit that the more a company invests in externally acquired innovation,
the more leveraged it will be. Based on the above-mentioned chain of reasoning, we posit the
following hypotheses:

Hypothesis 2 (H2). Internal investments in innovativeness in NTBFs from emerging countries have a
significant and negative impact on financial leverage.

Hypothesis 3 (H3). External investments in innovativeness in NTBFs from emerging countries have a
significant and positive impact on financial leverage.

327
JRFM 2020, 13, 221

3.3. Liquidity
Liquidity is another determinant that has an impact on capital structure and is usually understood
as a measure of a firm’s capability of debt repayment. High liquidity implies that a company has the
potential to pay back debt or shareholders (Ozkan 2001). Low risk of insolvency allows acquiring debt
at a lower cost (Morellec 2001). More liquid companies are more prone to undertake riskier projects
and finance them via bank loans thanks to a lower risk of solvency problems (Ramli et al. 2019).
According to the pecking order theory, more liquid companies tend to finance their activity
mainly by their funds (retained earnings). By doing that, companies avoid taking more costly debt
and disclosing confidential information to financial institutions (banks) or investors. Therefore,
many researchers hypothesize an inverse relationship between liquidity and financial leverage
(Kara and Erdur 2015; Karacaer et al. 2016). Internal financing is preferred over debt, and the surplus of
cash flows allows the financing of investment projects. Higher liquidity translates to financial flexibility
and opens up possibilities of acquiring debt at a lower cost. Based on our experience, we suppose that
in the case of emerging markets liquidity may play an important factor in shaping the capital structure
of high-tech companies. Therefore, we conjecture the following hypothesis:

Hypothesis 4 (H4). The liquidity of NTBFs located in emerging markets has a significant and negative impact
on financial leverage.

3.4. Size
One of the most studied firm parameters is company size. Firm size is likely to influence capital
structure in several ways. Larger firms are usually treated as less risky and believed to have fewer
constraints in obtaining a bank loan. Risk is higher in the case of small firms, which, due to the lack of
scale, cannot diversify the risk and invest in multiple projects (Freel 2007). The financial constraints
in financing are well pronounced, especially in the case of small and medium-sized innovative firms
(Schneider and Veugelers 2010; Hutton and Lee 2012; Mina et al. 2013; Lee et al. 2015).
At least several important characteristics of a firm’s size are invoked in the literature.
Bigger companies are able to operationalize more debt in their balance sheets due to more collateral on
the asset side (Karacaer et al. 2016; Cai and Ghosh 2003). The size of a company is correlated with its
age. In other words, bigger companies are usually the older ones, which means that they are already
established in the market, have a deeper knowledge of the market and customer preferences, and have
higher credibility, which results in lower operational risk. The financial situation of bigger companies is
usually more stable, and the variability of their cash flows and financial risk is lower. Bigger companies
may utilize the economies of scale and transfer the cost of short-term financing to their suppliers or
clients. Bigger companies tend to engage in international activities, therefore they are more able to
diversify their operations and raise funds in foreign capital markets. The cost of external capital is
typically lower for bigger companies in comparison to smaller ones. Additionally, bankruptcy costs
are lower for bigger companies, and as a result, they are more flexible in terms of managing their
liabilities (Demir 2009). Informational asymmetry is lower for bigger companies, which corresponds to
a higher quality of financial reporting. Finally, transaction costs necessary to obtain bank loans are
usually lower for bigger companies (Hall et al. 2004). All the above factors supposedly make the cost
of attracting external capital lower and may imply that the bigger a company, the higher its financial
leverage. The study conducted by Nenu et al. (2018), based on the sample of Romanian companies
provides empirical evidence supporting this statement. The authors of that study point out that the
trade-off theory may explain the research outcome.
In the literature, one can also find the opposite arguments. Bigger companies often accumulated
retained earnings for many years, and external capital was not necessary (Kara and Erdur 2015).
Bigger companies are also more prone to the problem of moral hazard (Frank and Goyal 2008).
Many cases from the past show that bigger companies tend to accept excessive growth, which translates

328
JRFM 2020, 13, 221

to lower operational efficiency and, finally, an increased cost of external capital (Ammar et al. 2003).
Agency costs are usually higher for bigger companies, which means that monitoring and auditing are
more costly (Yildirim et al. 2018). However, higher long-term debt may provide additional incentives
to managers for the creation of shareholder value (Izdihar 2019).
External finance is vital for innovative SMEs, as they usually lack the internal sources of
financing needed for the commercialization of their innovations (Beck and Demirguc-Kunt 2006;
Schneider and Veugelers 2010). The business model of innovative firms is riskier, and the intangible
assets account for a bigger part than physical property in their balance sheets, which creates a problem
in bank valuation. Intangibles are context-specific, which creates a problem for banks who value
them and use them as collateral for lending. Also, Canepa and Stoneman (2008), Czarnitzki (2006),
and Freel (2007) suggest that all these structural problems with innovative financing firms are amplified
in the case of SMEs. Finally, as Kijkasiwat and Phuensane (2020) documented, bigger companies are
more able to benefit from external and internal innovative projects, while the smaller ones only benefit
from internal projects.
In the case of NTBFs, an increase in size should result in a decrease in operational and investment
risk. However, it is probably at a higher level compared to other firms. Likewise, bankruptcy costs
should be lower, yet substantial. The scope of information asymmetry will decrease, agency costs may
be lower, but not low. It can be expected that NTBFs’ willingness to attract external capital will increase
with its size (Berggren et al. 2000). Therefore, we conjecture the following hypothesis:

Hypothesis 5 (H5). The size of NTBFs located in emerging markets has a significant and positive impact on
financial leverage.

3.5. Age
The next important determinant of capital structure—a firm’s age—is especially important in
the case of the high-tech sector. Some authors take into account the age of the firm as a determinant
in obtaining a bank loan. According to Cowling et al. (2012), the size of the company and its track
record influence bankers’ decisions to credit an entity, putting small and young firms at a disadvantage.
Older companies also have more fixed assets, which can serve as collateral for the long-term credit
loan, which also makes the debt more accessible and less costly. The results of empirical studies suggest
that the firm’s age allows it to curtail limits typical for high-tech companies, especially higher risk.
Older firms have lower bankruptcy costs, lower costs of external capital, a broader customer base,
more stable financial results over time, and more profitable companies (Malik 2011; Bhayani 2010b).
The firm’s age, or the period counted since the IPO on the stock market, is positively correlated
with the quality of corporate governance, and, consequently, lowers the agency costs and the cost of
the bank loan (Kieschnick and Moussawi 2018). On the other hand, older firms usually accumulated
retained earnings from the previous periods and may not strive for capital offered by the bank sector
(Mac an Bhaird and Lucey 2010). Younger firms suffer more from agency problems, and this is the
reason why access to external capital is hampered (Mac an Bhaird and Lucey 2010). As the firm gains
experience and records a more extended credit history, the risk of moral hazard becomes lower.
Younger firms usually suffer from lack of capital, and for this reason, they often apply for external
capital to finance their investment projects (Bhayani 2010b; Hall et al. 2004). At the same time, due to the
problem of moral hazard, which is a very distinctive feature of young, technological firms, applying for
and getting a bank loan is the way through torment (Hogan et al. 2017). Easier access to external
capital for NTBFs is possible and can be observed in countries where the financial system is based on a
well-developed banking sector. Therefore, we posit the following hypothesis:

Hypothesis 6 (H6). The age of NTBFs located in emerging markets has a significant and positive impact on
financial leverage.

329
JRFM 2020, 13, 221

3.6. Profitability
The next important characteristic of the company—profitability—is an important determinant
of capital structure. According to the pecking order theory, a firm first instances its activity from
retained earnings. If this source is not sufficient, a company tries to obtain external sources of capital
(Myers and Majluf 1984). From this perspective, higher financial leverage does not always imply or
correlate with higher profitability.
Another implication may be derived from the trade-off theory, which assumes a state of balance
between equity and debt capital, while the cost of debt capital is lower. More profitable companies
usually have sufficient financial resources necessary to pursue their investment plans. However,
more profitable companies may find a tax shield to be a decisive argument for increasing financial
leverage (Bouallegui 2006), which is especially important for companies from countries where the tax
rate is high. The theory of free cash flows also posits that more profitable companies should indebt
themselves because it provides a self-control mechanism. It forces management to transfer free cash
flows as dividends to their shareholders instead of investing in less profitable investment projects
(Izdihar 2019).
Highly profitable companies have much easier access to external financing at a much lower
cost (Cassar and Holmes 2003). This is also supported by the substitutive theory, which posits that
less risky and more profitable companies are much more able to finance their activity from external
sources, especially debt. High profitability also minimizes the risk of bankruptcy, and for this reason,
the capacity of indebtedness is increased (Ramli et al. 2019). Highly profitable companies, which finance
their activity from internal sources, are not required to disclose detailed information on their operations
(Li and Islam 2019). Internal sources of finance (retained earnings) and increased indebtedness may be
attractive for investors since a firm’s shareholding is not diluted (Karacaer et al. 2016). On the basis of
the above discussion, it may seem that the impact of profitability on capital structure is ambiguous
(Degryse et al. 2012). However, from the perspective of NTBFs, we can suppose that more profitable
companies would have much better credit standing and better access to debt. Therefore, we treat the
firm’s profitability parameter as a control variable.

3.7. Growth Opportunities


Growth opportunities are an important firm characteristic influencing capital structure in the
high-tech sector. Most often, high-tech companies tend to use their own equity funds because of
innate higher risk and the necessity of more costly supervision of this type of company (Myers 1977).
High growth opportunities, on the one hand, create the chance of development, but on the other
hand, pave the way for new risk. Usually, enormous growth opportunities accompany low equity
values which are necessary to finance important investment projects. Fortunately, these companies,
even when dealing with severe financial problems, don’t have problems with raising equity capital.
Indebtedness may put pressure and discipline on the management and enforce a more efficient
decision-making process. The valuation process of high-tech companies is based on their future
potential (option), which is heavily burdened with risk. Therefore, the market valuation is under the
threat of impairment. This is especially important considering that the asset is in substantial part
intangible and, as a result, cannot serve as collateral (Karacaer et al. 2016). Thus, some researchers
(Rajan and Zingales 1995) hypothesize an inverse relationship between growth opportunities and
financial leverage. This relationship is also implied by the pecking order theory, which posits that a
firm tends to finance its activity by internal funds and, afterward, look for external ones. Agency costs
theory provides similar implications for high-tech companies. Additional monitoring costs related
to management supervision may be substantial, especially when growth opportunities do exist,
which supposedly will lead to an increased cost of debt. High-tech companies will be discouraged
from taking on more debt in their balance sheet in order to minimize potential conflict between
shareholders and creditors (Ramli et al. 2019). The implication of the substitution theory also confirms

330
JRFM 2020, 13, 221

that relationship, because high-tech companies are more prone to the risk of financial situation
deterioration. Therefore, we treat the firm’s growth opportunities as a control variable.

4. Sample Characteristics, Research Design, and Results


The study sample consisted of 31 companies listed on the Warsaw Stock Exchange classified as
high-tech firms in sectors like biotechnology, R&D in physics, natural sciences, engineering, biology,
medical laboratories, computer software, e-commerce, marketing analysis, etc. We decided to use
data derived from firms listed on the stock exchange because of a higher quality of accounting data.
These companies, under the scrutiny of stock market institutions and the public, are obliged to meet
higher standards of transparency and are audited. Companies may also be classified as NTBFs because
the oldest firm in the study period is 17 years old, and the average age is around six years. The initial
sample consists of 155 firm-year observations covering the period of 2014–2018. The final sample is
limited to only 102 firm-year observations due to the missing data.
Our main object of interest is capital structure, and as a dependent variable, we use the leverage
ratio calculated as total liabilities to total assets. As a proxy for the innovation generated internally,
we use a ratio of the sum of R&D expenses recorded in the P&L statement and year-to-year change in
R&D outlays recorded in the balance sheet, deflated by the total assets. In our opinion, this is the only
possible way to measure R&D outlays based on information derived from a financial statement. As the
proxy for the innovation acquired externally, we use a year-to-year change of intangibles extracted
from the balance sheet, excluding R&D expenses recognized. We also use a set of control variables such
as profitability (ROE) and growth opportunities. In order to avoid the influence of outliers, all data
were winsorized. Table 1 presents the characteristics of the main variables used in the model.

Table 1. Sample statistics.

Variable No. of Obs. Min. Max. Mean Median St. Dev. Variance Skewness Kurtosis
LEV 155 0.004 1.000 0.448 0.375 0.298 0.089 0.392 2.029
INTANGIBILITY 155 0.000 0.939 0.216 0.121 0.238 0.057 1.125 3.438
INNOV_INT 155 0.000 0.543 0.067 0.003 0.099 0.010 1.795 6.650
INNOV_EXT 155 0.000 1.000 0.091 0.003 0.168 0.028 3.443 3.260
CUR_RATIO 155 0.007 10.000 2.737 1.592 2.862 8.193 1.552 4.329
SIZE 155 4.143 14.952 9.793 9.818 2.093 4.380 −0.131 3.443
AGE 155 0.000 17.000 6.072 6.000 3.934 15.475 0.655 2.957
ROE 155 −1.000 1.000 −0.140 −0.043 0.484 0.234 −0.123 3.026
SALES_TR 117 −1.000 1.000 0.111 0.091 0.656 0.431 −0.177 2.010
Source: our own elaboration based on the data from financial statements.

In order to avoid intercorrelated variables in the model, we performed a correlation analysis,


the results of which are presented in Table 2. The highest correlations, however moderate, are between
a firm’s age and profitability (ROE), financial leverage, and size. The results are logical and correspond
to the conclusions of the literature review section. The older a company is, the higher its profitability.
Similarly, the older the firm is, the more able it is to indebt itself. Finally, bigger companies tend
to be more profitable. The results show that variables INNOV_INT and INNOV_EXT are weakly
correlated. The rest of the correlation coefficients of independent variables are at a low or moderate
level, so including them in the model is not controversial.

331
JRFM 2020, 13, 221

Table 2. Correlation between variables.

Variable Lev Size Age Roe CUR_RATIO SALES_TR Intangibility INNOV_INT INNOV_EXT
LEV 1.000
INTANGIBILITY 0.134 1.000
INNOV_INT −0.254 −0.018 1.000
INNOV_EXT 0.029 0.071 0.200 1.000
CUR_RATIO −0.632 −0.201 0.207 0.022 1.000
SIZE −0.119 −0.011 0.333 0.090 0.136 1.000
AGE 0.388 −0.224 −0.053 −0.107 −0.286 0.291 1.000
ROE −0.082 −0.185 0.087 −0.028 0.132 0.384 0.410 1.000
SALES_TR 0.011 −0.082 0.069 0.213 0.032 0.084 0.028 0.064 1.000
Source: our own elaboration based on the data from financial statements.

To test the hypotheses formulated in the previous section, we used the following model:

LEVi,t = INTANGIBILITYi,t + INNOV_INTi,t + INNOV_EXTi,t + CUR_RATIOi,t + SIZEi,t + AGEi,t + ROEi,t + SALES_TRi, (1)

where:
LEVi,t —financial leverage (total liabilities/total assets) of the i-company in t-year
INTANGIBILITYi,t —the ratio of intangibles to total assets of the i-company in t-year
INNOV_INT1i,t —the ratio of internally generated intangibles to total assets of the i-company in t-year
INNOV_EXT2i,t —the ratio of externally acquired intangibles to total assets of the i-company in t-year
CUR_RATIOi,t —liquidity of the company measured as a current ratio (current asset/current liabilities)
SIZEi,t —the size of the i-company in t-year as a logarithm of total assets
AGEi,t —age of the i-company in t-year
ROEi,t —profitability of the i-company in t-year measured as a return on equity
SALES_TRi,t —sales trend of the i-company in t-year calculated as year-to-year change of sales (sales
from the t-year minus sales from the t−1 year, and deflated by the sales from t−1 year)
We ran a regression with a robust option in order to obtain robust coefficients. It allows us to
avoid many problems with the specification of the model.
We performed an extensive post-estimation diagnosis to test our model. We tested the model
for multicollinearity using the variance inflation factor and detected none. We ran a Shapiro-Wilk
test for residuals, and we couldn’t reject the null hypothesis which states that they are normally
distributed. Finally, we used the Ramsey RESET to test for the specification of the model; results (0.048)
are in the borderline and may suggest that there are some problems with the specification of the
model. The model is better at detecting influence on the dependent variable and should not be treated
as a predictive model. The model detects some critical links between variables and has acceptable
predicting power (adj. R = 0.54). First of all, we found a strong influence of the firm’s age on financial
leverage, which suggests that the older the firm is, the more leveraged it is. The results fit the theory
and results of other studies. The second important conclusion is that the more liquid the company
is, the less leveraged it is. The implication of that result may be that younger companies that are
usually less leveraged tend to maintain a safe cash position and hold more cash within the company.
Bigger companies may allow themselves to keep a relatively lower level of liquidity because they are
able to raise cash faster if needed through the bank system. Therefore, we provide empirical evidence
supporting our fourth and sixth hypotheses.
From our perspective, the most crucial results refer to the variables INNOV_INT and INNOVE_EXT.
The p-value of those variables is at a low (10%), yet still statistically significant (see Table 3). Firstly,
INNOV_INT has a negative coefficient, which suggests that the more a company invests in an
innovative in-house project, the less willing a bank sector is to finance it with debt. This provides
empirical evidence supporting our second hypothesis and may be explained by the higher informational
asymmetry generated by the R&D project, which probably translates to a higher cost of debt. Secondly,
INNOV_EXT has a positive coefficient, which implies that the bank sector is willing to provide more
external funds to companies acquiring innovation externally. We ascribe that result to the fact that

332
JRFM 2020, 13, 221

external acquisition of technology/invention is perceived to be less risky and the final output more
predictable. Again, we provide an argument supporting the third hypothesis. The results must be
interpreted with caution, and the hypotheses need to be tested on high-tech companies from other
emerging markets.

Table 3. Regression analysis.

Independent Variables Coefficient p-Value


INTANGIBILITY 0.126 0.256
INNOV_INT −0.334 0.095 *
INNOV_EXT 0.138 0.091 *
CUR_RATIO −0.045 0.000 ***
SIZE −0.012 0.328
AGE 0.024 0.000 ***
ROE −0.062 0.361
SALES_TR 0.011 0.758
Constant 0.504 0.000
A number of obs. 102
R2 0.55
Adjusted R2 0.54
* significance at 10% level; ** significance at 5% level; *** significance at 1% level. Source: our own elaboration based
on the data from financial statements.

Unfortunately, we find no empirical evidence supporting the first and the fifth hypothesis.
With regard to the firm’s size, this may be explained by the fact that the majority of companies are
of moderate size. In the case of the intangibility parameter, we suppose that this parameter would
be more important for companies in sectors other than high-tech. In our opinion, this matter needs
further investigation.

5. Concluding Remarks
High-tech firms play an increasingly important role in the contemporary economy. Their growth is
more dynamic than classical industries. Employment in high-tech industries has increased considerably,
while other industries often record reductions in the number of employees. High-tech firms,
especially NTBFs, are characterized by high risk, great information asymmetry, high agency and
bankruptcy costs, and a great likelihood of deterioration in their financial standing, which makes
access to external financing and, in particular, debt financing, more difficult.
The results of empirical studies allow for the verification of the second hypothesis which states that
internal investments in innovativeness have a negative impact on the level of indebtedness in NTBFs,
while external investments in innovativeness have a positive impact on the level of debt. These results
can undoubtedly be attributed to higher information asymmetry and risk in financing new technologies
generated internally as compared with innovations purchased on the market, the usefulness of which
is well known and proven. It should be noted that internal investments in innovativeness are not
always bound to succeed, and their output is very risky. Financial liquidity has an adverse effect on the
level of indebtedness in the structure of financing, so companies with high liquidity and availability of
their own funds rely on their own resources and, possibly, on debt financing (Hypothesis 4). Due to big
market changes and changes in technologies, highly liquid NTBFs give preference to financing based on
their own funds. Age has a positive impact on the share of debt in the capital structure (Hypothesis 6).
Those NTBFs which are well established on the market and have long credit history and high reliability
tend to rely on debt financing. This effect can be limited in NTBFs with excess liquidity. The impact of
intangibility turns out to be statistically insignificant. This may result from the fact that the possession
of intangible assets is not a necessary, sufficient or decisive factor in determining a decrease in debt
financing. The size of NTBFs does not have a positive impact on indebtedness probably due to the fact

333
JRFM 2020, 13, 221

that the analyzed sample comprises moderate-sized entities. The impact of profitability and growth
potential is also limited. The impact of these factors on debt levels in NTBFs is probably diversified.
Polish NTBFs create their capital structure, which to a certain degree can be explained by the
trade-off theory. This view can be justified by the positive impact of age and liquidity on the level
of indebtedness, resulting in lower bankruptcy costs. The analyzed NTBF’s population also fits
the agency theory because of the limited scale of business operations and relatively limited market
experience. Pecking order theory applies to the analysis to a smaller degree—an impact of profitability,
size, and risk on indebtedness is not visible. Polish NTBFs apply the following order of financing:
retained earnings followed by share capital and debt financing.
The obtained results can be useful for high-tech firms, stock market investors, banks and standard
setters. Without support offered by the government and various public institutions the development
of NTBFs, especially in countries with a low level of innovativeness, can be hindered due to difficulties
in acquiring necessary funds for expansion.
This paper attempts to narrow a theoretical gap in the area of capital structure creation and
explore the impact of capital structure theory on the level of indebtedness in NTBFs in an emerging
economy. We believe that the empirical verification of the impact of internally and externally generated
investment in innovativeness, and the verification of the impact of other capital structure factors on
NTFBs in emerging markets characterized by low innovativeness, can be regarded as a significant
contribution to the research of the determinants of capital structure in NTBFs. In our opinion, there are
not many research studies on emerging markets which empirically verify the determinants of NTBF
capital structure, hence the need for further analyses.
The major limitations of this work include a relatively short period of research and a small number
of analyzed NTBFs. Further analyses should comprise a larger number of countries and observations,
as well as a longer period of study. Possibly significant determinants of NTFB capital structure include
various corporate governance characteristics and macroeconomic and country-level factors.

Author Contributions: Conceptualization M.K., B.G., K.G. and D.K.; methodology M.K., B.G., K.G. and D.K.;
software, K.G.; validation M.K., B.G., K.G. and D.K.; formal analysis M.K., B.G., K.G. and D.K.; investigation M.K.,
B.G., K.G. and D.K.; resources B.G. and D.K.; data curation B.G. and D.K.; writing—original draft preparation
M.K., B.G., K.G. and D.K.; writing—review and editing, M.K., B.G., K.G. and D.K.; visualization, M.K., B.G., K.G.
and D.K.; supervision, M.K., B.G., K.G. and D.K.; project administration, M.K.; funding acquisition, M.K. and K.G.
All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.
Funding: This research was funded by the Ministry of Science and Higher Education within the “Regional
Initiative of Excellence” Programme for 2019–2022. Project no.: 021/RID/2018/19.
Conflicts of Interest: The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References
Adrienn, Herczeg. 2014. Summary of theories in capital structure decisions. Annals of the University of Oradea,
Economic Science Series 23: 912–18.
Aghion, Philippe, and Peter Howitt. 2005. Growth with quality-improving innovations: An integrated framework.
Handbook of Economic Growth 1: 67–110.
Aghion, Philippe, Stephen Bond, Alexander Klemm, and Ioana Marinescu. 2004. Technology and financial
structure: Are innovative firms different? Journal of the European Economic Association 2: 277–88. [CrossRef]
Akgül, Ersin Fırat, and Seçil Sigali. 2018. Determinants of Capital Structure: An Application on BIST Transportation
Index. Journal of Accounting & Finance 77: 193–215.
Alderson, Michael J., and Brian L. Betker. 1996. Liquidation costs and accounting data. Financial Management 25:
25–36. [CrossRef]
Ammar, Abdurahman, S. Hanna Awad, Erik V. Nordheim, and Jeffrey S. Russell. 2003. Indicator variables model
of firm’s size-profitability relationship of electrical contractors using financial and economic data. Journal of
Construction Engineering and Management 129: 192–97. [CrossRef]
Aoun, Dany, and Almas Heshmati. 2006. The causal relationship between capital structure and cost of capital:
Evidence from ict companies listed at nasdaq. Stockholm School of Economics 1–26.

334
JRFM 2020, 13, 221

Baxter, Nevins D. 1967. Leverage, risk of ruin and the cost of capital. The Journal of Finance 22: 395–403.
Beck, Thorsten, and Asli Demirguc-Kunt. 2006. Small and medium-size enterprises: Access to finance as a growth
constraint. Journal of Banking & Finance 30: 2931–43.
Berggren, Björn, Christer Olofsson, and Lars Silver. 2000. Control aversion and the search for external financing in
Swedish SMEs. Small Business Economics 15: 233–42. [CrossRef]
Bhayani, Sanjay J. 2010a. Determinant of Profitability in Indian Cement Industry: An Economic Analysis.
South Asian Journal of Management 17: 6–20.
Bhayani, Sanjay J. 2010b. Intangible assets, research and development expenditure, knowledge capital and capital
structure: A study of Indian pharmaceutical firms. Indian Journal of Accounting 40: 41–52.
Bontempi, Maria Elena. 2002. The dynamic specification of the modified pecking order theory: Its relevance to
Italy. Empirical Economics 27: 1–22. [CrossRef]
Bouallegui, Imen. 2006. Capital structure determinants and the new High-Tech firms: The critical distinction
between fixed and random effects through a static panel data investigation. MPRA Paper 22477: 1–24.
Brown, Ross, and Neil Lee. 2019. Strapped for cash? Funding for UK high growth SMEs since the global financial
crisis. Journal of Business Research 99: 37–45. [CrossRef]
Brown, James R., Steven M. Fazzari, and Bruce C. Petersen. 2009. Financing innovation and growth: Cash flow,
external equity, and the 1990s R&D boom. The Journal of Finance 64: 151–85.
Brown, James R., Gustav Martinsson, and Bruce C. Petersen. 2013. Law, stock markets, and innovation. The Journal
of Finance 68: 1517–49. [CrossRef]
Butzbach, Olivier, and Domenico Sarno. 2018. To What Extent Do Regional Effects Influence Firms’ Capital
Structure? The Case of Southern Italian SMEs’. International Journal of Financial Studies 7: 3. [CrossRef]
Cai, Francis, and Arvin Ghosh. 2003. Tests of capital structure theory: A binomial approach. The Journal of Business
and Economic Studies 9: 20–32.
Canepa, Alessandra, and Paul Stoneman. 2008. Financial constraints to innovation in the UK: Evidence from CIS2
and CIS3. Oxford Economic Papers 60: 711–30. [CrossRef]
Carden, Steven D., Lenny T. Mendonca, and Tim Shavers. 2005. What global executives think about growth and
risk. McKinsey Quarterly 2: 16–25.
Carpenter, Robert E., and Bruce C. Petersen. 2002. Capital market imperfections, high-tech investment, and new
equity financing. The Economic Journal 112: F54–F72. [CrossRef]
Cassar, Gavin, and Scott Holmes. 2003. Capital structure and financing of SMEs: Australian evidence.
Accounting & Finance 43: 123–47.
Castro, Paula, María T. Tascón, and Borja Amor-Tapia. 2015. Dynamic analysis of the capital structure in
technological firms based on their life cycle stages. Spanish Journal of Finance and Accounting/Revista Española
de Financiación y Contabilidad 44: 458–86. [CrossRef]
Coleman, Susan, and Alicia Robb. 2012. Capital structure theory and new technology firms: Is there a match?
Management Research Review 35: 106–20. [CrossRef]
Colombo, Massimo G., Annalisa Croce, and Samuele Murtinu. 2014. Ownership structure, horizontal agency costs
and the performance of high-tech entrepreneurial firms. Small Business Economics 42: 265–82. [CrossRef]
Cowling, Marc, Weixi Liu, and Andrew Ledger. 2012. Small business financing in the UK before and during the
current financial crisis. International Small Business Journal 30: 778–800. [CrossRef]
Czarnitzki, Dirk. 2006. Research and development in small and medium-sized enterprises: The role of financial
constraints and public funding. Scottish Journal of Political Economy 53: 335–57. [CrossRef]
DeAngelo, Harry, and Ronald W. Masulis. 1980. Optimal capital structure under corporate and personal taxation.
Journal of Financial Economics 8: 3–29. [CrossRef]
Deesomsak, Rataporn, Krishna Paudyal, and Gioia Pescetto. 2004. The determinants of capital structure:
Evidence from the Asia Pacific region. Journal of Multinational Financial Management 14: 387–405. [CrossRef]
Degryse, Hans, Peter de Goeij, and Peter Kappert. 2012. The impact of firm and industry characteristics on small
firms’ capital structure. Small Business Economics 38: 431–47. [CrossRef]
Demir, Firat. 2009. Financialization and manufacturing firm profitability under uncertainty and macroeconomic
volatility: Evidence from an Emerging Market. Review of Development Economics 13: 592–609. [CrossRef]
Dobusch, Leonhard, and Jakob Kapeller. 2018. Open strategy-making with crowds and communities:
Comparing Wikimedia and Creative Commons. Long Range Planning 51: 561–79. [CrossRef]

335
JRFM 2020, 13, 221

Donaldson, Gordon. 1961. Corporate Debt Capacity: A Study of Corporate Debt Policy and the Determination of Corporate
Debt Capacity. Boston: Division of Research, Harvard School of Business Administration.
Durand, David. 1952. Cost of Debt and Equity Funds for Business. Trends and Problems of Measurement.
In Conference on Research in Business Finance. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, pp. 215–61.
Falato, Antonio, Dalida Kadyrzhanova, and Jae W. Sim. 2018. Rising intangible capital, shrinking debt capacity,
and the US corporate savings glut. Shrinking Debt Capacity, and the US Corporate Savings Glut 1–59. [CrossRef]
Fama, Eugene F., and Merton H. Miller. 1972. The Theory of Finance. New York: Holt Rinehart & Winston.
Frank, Murray Z., and Vidhan K. Goyal. 2008. Trade-off and pecking order theories of debt. In Handbook of
Empirical Corporate Finance. Amsterdam: Elsevier, pp. 135–202.
Frankfurter, George M., and Bob G. Wood Jr. 2002. Dividend policy theories and their empirical tests.
International Review of Financial Analysis 11: 111–38. [CrossRef]
Freel, Mark. 2007. Are small innovators credit rationed? Small Business Economics 28: 23–35. [CrossRef]
Gherghina, S, tefan Cristian, Mihai Alexandru Botezatu, Alexandra Hosszu, and Liliana Nicoleta Simionescu. 2020.
Small and Medium-Sized Enterprises (SMEs): The Engine of Economic Growth through Investments and
Innovation. Sustainability 12: 347. [CrossRef]
Gil, Pedro Mazeda, Oscar Afonso, and Paulo Brito. 2019. Economic growth, the high-tech sector, and the
high skilled: Theory and quantitative implications. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 51: 89–105.
[CrossRef]
Giraudo, Emanuele, Giancarlo Giudici, and Luca Grilli. 2019. Entrepreneurship policy and the financing of young
innovative companies: Evidence from the Italian Startup Act. Research Policy 48: 103801. [CrossRef]
Grinblatt, Mark, and Sheridan Titman. 2002. Financial Markets and Corporate Strategy. New York:
MCGraw Hill Irwin.
Guiso, Luigi. 1998. High-tech firms and credit rationing. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 35: 39–59.
Hall, Bronwyn H. 2002. The financing of Research and Development. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 18: 35–51.
[CrossRef]
Hall, Bronwyn H. 2010. The financing of innovative firms. Review of Economics and Institutions 1: 1–30. [CrossRef]
Hall, Graham C., Patrick J. Hutchinson, and Nicos Michaelas. 2004. Determinants of the capital structures of
European SMEs. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting 31: 711–28.
Harris, Milton, and Artur Raviv. 1988. Corporate control contests and capital structure. Journal of
Financial Economics 20: 55–86. [CrossRef]
Hay, Michael, and Kimya Kamshad. 1994. Small firm growth: Intentions, implementation and impediments.
Business Strategy Review 5: 49–68. [CrossRef]
Hogan, Teresa, Elaine Hutson, and Paul Drnevich. 2017. Drivers of external equity funding in small high-tech
ventures. Journal of Small Business Management 55: 236–53. [CrossRef]
Howell, Anthony. 2016. Firm R&D, innovation and easing financial constraints in China: Does corporate tax
reform matter? Research Policy 45: 1996–2007.
Hutton, Will, and Neil Lee. 2012. The city and the cities: Ownership, finance and the geography of recovery.
Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society 5: 325–337. [CrossRef]
Izdihar, Baharin. 2019. Capital Structure Determinants of Financially Distressed Firms at the Bursa Malaysia.
Kuala Lumpur: Asia e University.
Jensen, Michael C., and William H. Meckling. 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and
ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3: 305–60. [CrossRef]
Kara, Esen, and Duygu Acar Erdur. 2015. Determinants of Capital Structure: A Research on Sectors That
Contribute to Exports in Turkey. Istanbul University Journal of the School of Business Administration 44: 27–38.
Karacaer, Semra, Hüseyin Temiz, and Omer Faruk Gulec. 2016. Determinants of capital structure: An application on
manufacturing firms in Borsa Istanbul. International Academic Journal of Accounting and Financial Management
3: 47–59.
K˛edzior, Marcin. 2012. Capital structure in EU selected countries–micro and macro determinants.
Argumenta Oeconomica 28: 69–117.
Kenourgios, Dimitris, Georgios A. Savvakis, and Theofanis Papageorgiou. 2019. The capital structure dynamics of
European listed SMEs. Journal of Small Business & Entrepreneurship 1–18. [CrossRef]
Kieschnick, Robert, and Rabih Moussawi. 2018. Firm age, corporate governance, and capital structure choices.
Journal of Corporate Finance 48: 597–614. [CrossRef]

336
JRFM 2020, 13, 221

Kijkasiwat, Ploypailin, and Pongsutti Phuensane. 2020. Innovation and Firm Performance: The Moderating
and Mediating Roles of Firm Size and Small and Medium Enterprise Finance. Journal of Risk and
Financial Management 13: 97. [CrossRef]
Kopf, Dennis A. 2007. Endogenous growth theory applied: Strategies for university R&D. Journal of
Business Research 60: 975–78.
Korkmaz, Özge, and Süleyman Serdar Karaca. 2014. Financial Determinants of Firm Profitability in Manufacturing
Firms and an Application on BIST Manifacturing Firms. Ege Akademik Bakış Dergisi 14: 21–29.
Kraus, Alan, and Robert H. Litzenberger. 1973. A state-preference model of optimal financial leverage. The Journal
of Finance 28: 911–22. [CrossRef]
Lee, Neil, Hiba Sameen, and Marc Cowling. 2015. Access to finance for innovative SMEs since the financial crisis.
Research Policy 44: 370–80. [CrossRef]
Leland, Hayne E., and David H. Pyle. 1977. Informational asymmetries, financial structure, and financial
intermediation. The Journal of Finance 32: 371–87. [CrossRef]
Li, Larry, and Silvia Z. Islam. 2019. Firm and industry specific determinants of capital structure: Evidence from
the Australian market. International Review of Economics & Finance 59: 425–37.
Li, Yan-xi, Shi-ze Bao, and Xian-jing Kong. 2006. Environment risk, capital structure, growth and high-tech firm’s
performance. Science Research Management 6: 40–46.
Lim, Steve C., Antonio J. Macias, and Thomas Moeller. 2020. Intangible assets and capital structure. Journal of
Banking & Finance 118: 1–59.
Lins, Karl V. 2003. Equity ownership and firm value in emerging markets. Journal of Financial and
Quantitative Analysis 38: 159–84. [CrossRef]
Little, Arthur D. 1977. New Technology-Based Firms in the United Kingdom and the Federal Republic of German. London:
Wilton House.
M’ng, Jacinta Chan Phooi, Mahfuzur Rahman, and Selvam Sannacy. 2017. The determinants of capital structure:
Evidence from public listed companies in Malaysia, Singapore and Thailand. Cogent Economics & Finance 5:
1–34.
Mac an Bhaird, Ciarán, and Brian Lucey. 2010. Determinants of capital structure in Irish SMEs.
Small Business Economics 35: 357–75. [CrossRef]
Malik, Hifza. 2011. Determinants of insurance companies profitability: An analysis of insurance sector of Pakistan.
Academic Research International 1: 315–21.
Mann, William. 2018. Creditor rights and innovation: Evidence from patent collateral. Journal of Financial
Economics 130: 25–47. [CrossRef]
Michaelas, Nicos, Francis Chittenden, and Panikkos Poutziouris. 1999. Financial policy and capital structure
choice in UK SMEs: Empirical evidence from company panel data. Small Business Economics 12: 113–30.
[CrossRef]
Mina, Andrea, Henry Lahr, and Alan Hughes. 2013. The demand and supply of external finance for innovative
firms. Industrial and Corporate Change 22: 869–901. [CrossRef]
Minola, Tommaso, Lucio Cassia, and Giuseppe Criaco. 2013. Financing patterns in new technology-based firms:
An extension of the pecking order theory. International Journal of Entrepreneurship and Small Business 25:
212–33. [CrossRef]
Modigliani, Franco, and Merton H. Miller. 1958. The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of
investment. The American Economic Review 48: 261–97.
Modigliani, Franco, and Merton H. Miller. 1963. Corporate income taxes and the cost of capital: A correction.
The American Economic Review 53: 433–43.
Morellec, Erwan. 2001. Asset liquidity, capital structure, and secured debt. Journal of Financial Economics 61:
173–206. [CrossRef]
Myers, Stewart C. 1977. Determinants of corporate borrowing. Journal of Financial Economics 5: 147–75. [CrossRef]
Myers, Stewart C., and Nicholas S. Majluf. 1984. Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms have
information that investors do not have. National Bureau of Economic Research 1396: 1–61. [CrossRef]
Nenu, Elena A., Georgeta Vintila, and Stefan C. Gherghina. 2018. The Impact of Capital Structure on Risk and Firm
Performance: Empirical Evidence for the Bucharest Stock Exchange Listed Companies. International Journal
of Financial Studies 6: 41. [CrossRef]

337
JRFM 2020, 13, 221

Novaes, Walter, and Luigi Zingales. 1995. Capital structure choice when managers are in control:
Entrenchment versus efficiency. National Bureau of Economic Research 5384: 1–42.
Ozkan, Aydin. 2001. Determinants of capital structure and adjustment to long run target: Evidence from UK
company panel data. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting 28: 175–98.
Peters, Ryan H., and Lucian A. Taylor. 2017. Intangible capital and the investment-q relation. Journal of
Financial Economics 123: 251–72. [CrossRef]
Popescu, Cristina R. 2019. Intellectual Capital: Major Role, Key Importance and Decisive Influences on
Orgamizations’ Performance. Journal of Human Resources Management Research 2019: 1–17.
Rajan, Raghuram G., and Luigi Zingales. 1995. What do we know about capital structure? Some evidence from
international data. The Journal of Finance 50: 1421–60. [CrossRef]
Ramli, Nur Ainna, Hengky Latan, and Grace T. Solovida. 2019. Determinants of capital structure and firm
financial performance—A PLS-SEM approach: Evidence from Malaysia and Indonesia. The Quarterly Review
of Economics and Finance 71: 148–60. [CrossRef]
Revest, Valérie, and Alessandro Sapio. 2012. Financing technology-based small firms in Europe: What do we
know? Small Business Economics 39: 179–205. [CrossRef]
Ross, Stephen A. 1977. The Determination of Financial Structure: The Incentive-Signalling Approach. The Bell
Journal of Economics 8: 23–40. [CrossRef]
Sau, Lino. 2007. New pecking order financing for innovative firms: An overview. MPRA Paper 3659: 1–28.
Scherr, Frederick C., Timothy F. Sugrue, and Janice B. Ward. 1993. Financing the small firm start-up:
Determinants of debt use. The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance 3: 17–36.
Schneider, Cédric, and Reinhilde Veugelers. 2010. On young highly innovative companies: Why they matter and
how (not) to policy support them. Industrial and Corporate Change 19: 969–1007. [CrossRef]
Schumpeter, Joseph Alois. 1911. The Theory of Economic Development. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Stulz, René M. 1990. Managerial discretion and optimal financing policies. Journal of Financial Economics 26: 3–27.
[CrossRef]
Ullah, Farid, Qaisar Abbas, and Saeed Akbar. 2010. The relevance of pecking order hypothesis for the financing of
computer software and biotechnology small firms: Some UK evidence. International Entrepreneurship and
Management Journal 6: 301–15. [CrossRef]
Vintilă, Georgeta, Radu Alin Păunescu, and Ştefan Cristian Gherghina. 2017. Determinants of effective corporate
tax rate. Empirical evidence from listed companies in Eastern European Stock Exchanges. Theoretical &
Applied Economics 24: 39–46.
Vintilă, Georgeta, Ştefan Cristian Gherghina, and Radu Alin Păunescu. 2018. Study of effective corporate tax rate
and its influential factors: Empirical evidence from emerging european markets. Emerging Markets Finance
and Trade 54: 571–90. [CrossRef]
Yildirim, Ramazan, Mansur Masih, and Obiyathulla Ismath Bacha. 2018. Determinants of capital structure:
Evidence from Shari’ah compliant and non-compliant firms. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 51: 198–219.
[CrossRef]

© 2020 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access
article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution
(CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).

338
Journal of
Risk and Financial
Management

Article
Corporate Governance Characteristics of Private
SMEs’ Annual Report Submission Violations
Oliver Lukason 1, * and María-del-Mar Camacho-Miñano 2
1 School of Economics and Business Administration, University of Tartu, 51009 Tartu, Estonia
2 Accounting and Finance Department, Complutense University of Madrid, 28223 Madrid, Spain;
mmcamach@ucm.es
* Correspondence: oliver.lukason@ut.ee

Received: 23 August 2020; Accepted: 25 September 2020; Published: 28 September 2020

Abstract: Managers are, by law, responsible for the timely disclosure of financial information through
annual reports, but despite that, it is usual that they are engaged in the unethical behaviour of not
meeting the submission deadlines set in law. This paper sheds light on the afore-given issue by aiming
to find out how corporate governance characteristics are associated with annual report deadline
violations in private micro-, small- and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs). We use the population
of SMEs from Estonia, in total 77,212 unique firms, in logistic regression analysis with the delay
of presenting an annual report over the legal deadline as the dependent and relevant corporate
governance characteristics as the independent variables. Our results indicate that the presence of
woman on the board, higher manager’s age, longer tenure and a larger proportion of stock owned
by board members lead to less likely violation of the annual report submission deadline, but in
turn, the presence of more business ties and existence of a majority owner behave in the opposite
way. The likelihood of violation does not depend on board size. We also check the robustness of the
obtained results with respect to the severity of delay, firm age and size, which all indicate a varying
importance of the explanatory corporate governance characteristics.

Keywords: corporate governance; information disclosure; timeliness of financial reporting;


law violation; private firms

1. Introduction
The aim of this paper is to analyse the interconnection between corporate governance
characteristics and the violation of the annual report submission deadline in private micro-,
small- and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs). According to the theory of upper echelons,
managers’ experiences, values and responsibilities condition firms’ decisions, strategy and even
their performance (Hambrick and Mason 1984). One responsibility of the board of directors is
the timely submission of firms’ compulsory accounting information in order to make it public
and accessible for the decision-making of firms’ stakeholders. It has been established that board
composition is associated with the transparency, correctness and timeliness of financial reporting
(Beasley 1996; Abdelsalam and Street 2007; Hermalin and Weisbach 2012).
Prior studies suggest that high levels of corporate governance may reduce managers’
earnings manipulations and the tendency to commit fraud, and help to achieve higher levels
of information transparency or even condition credit ratings (Ashbaugh-Skaife et al. 2006;
Prior et al. 2008; Scholtens and Kang 2013; Liu et al. 2017). However, most of the literature is focused
on corporate governance and financial reporting disclosure practices in public and large firms
(Carslaw and Kaplan 1991; Abernathy et al. 2014; Lim et al. 2014; Efobi and Okougbo 2014; Spiers 2018;
Bae et al. 2018), which could be conditioned by agency problems and disagreeing objectives
among shareholders in such firms. Still, reporting disclosure is also relevant for private SMEs

JRFM 2020, 13, 230; doi:10.3390/jrfm13100230 339 www.mdpi.com/journal/jrfm


JRFM 2020, 13, 230

(Clatworthy and Peel 2016). Much of this concern stems from the recognition that small firms serve as
an engine of economic growth and innovation around the world (Cowling et al. 2015).
Corporate governance and accounting information disclosure violation, but also their
interconnections, are different between public and private firms. In SMEs, board and owners
often overlap, and thus, different functions of these two corporate governance levels are consolidated
(Gabrielsson and Huse 2005; Brunninge et al. 2007). The incentives to disclose information vary across
stakeholders (Berglöf and Pajuste 2005), and even across shareholders. Consequently, the concept of
corporate governance of SMEs differs from listed firms (Uhlaner et al. 2007; Voordeckers et al. 2014).
Large companies are more concerned about market behaviour than private ones, which in turn
are more tax-oriented (Brunninge et al. 2007) and have lower scrutiny as many of them are not
audited (Höglund and Sundvik 2019). In this sense, Östberg (2006) posits that disclosure is a form of
minority protection that decreases the scope of extracting private benefits by controlling shareholders.
Non-audited private SMEs also need to have the information ready for creditors (Collis 2008;
Peek et al. 2010). Indeed, small firms may face difficulties in accessing formal financing due to their
informational opacity (Ortiz-Molina and Penas 2008). Managers of SMEs can choose, which information
to divulge and which to contain, whether to present it timely or not and if it is accurate or biased
information (Hoskisson et al. 1994). Thus, opportunistic information disclosure behaviours could
appear more likely in SMEs.
The context of this research is Estonia, which is considered to be one of the most advanced digital
societies in the world, and consequently, permits full access to SMEs’ information. The Estonian
legislative system and institutions are harmonized with EU regulations, which increases the
comparability of Estonian SMEs with firms with similar sizes from other EU countries. Our dataset is
composed of 77,212 Estonian private SMEs, using data procured from the Estonian Business Register
(EBR), which contains firms’ annual reports (compulsory once per year) and up to date information
about firms’ boards and owners. With logistic regression analysis, we show which corporate governance
characteristics, representing three distinct corporate governance dimensions, increase or decrease the
likelihood of violating the legal deadline set for annual report submission.
The paper contributes to the literature by presenting an original conceptual framework for the
corporate governance dimensions affecting SMEs’ risk behaviour, specifically timely annual report
submission violation. Only a few previous studies explore corporate governance variables in the SME
context (Spiers 2017). In addition, violation of annual report submission deadlines is a rarely studied
topic in the case of SMEs (Lukason and Camacho-Miñano 2019).
We show that corporate governance can be used to explain annual report submission deadline
violations in the SME context. Thus, this paper fills the major gap in prior research with respect to
how corporate governance can affect firms’ behaviour in the SME context (Li et al. 2020). For private
SMEs, earlier studies have used a limited number of corporate governance factors (e.g., the number of
board members), partly due to the difficulty of accessing such data. In this study, the factual corporate
governance information was obtained directly from the business register, not from questionnaires as in
most of the studies. Concerning annual reports, the bulk of the literature concentrates on the time of
disclosure, not on the violation (Luypaert et al. 2016; Lukason and Camacho-Miñano 2019), which is
the approach of this study. In addition, the institutional context has been suggested as an important
issue due to the necessity of cross-cultural governance research (Uhlaner et al. 2007). According to
La Porta et al. (1999), governance issues differ from one context to another, and Estonia’s context is
different from the Anglo-Saxon countries, based on which most of the studies have been composed
so far.
The paper is structured as follows. First, the literature review section outlines corporate governance
dimensions being potentially associated with timely annual report submission violation and outlines
the literature-based expectations concerning the interconnections between the latter and specific
corporate governance variables. Then, the study’s sample, variables and method sections are presented.
This is followed by empirical results, robustness tests, and discussion. Finally, the study concludes

340
JRFM 2020, 13, 230

this research arguing its main implications and limitations, while suggestions for future research are
also provided.

2. Corporate Governance Characteristics and Timely Accounting Information Disclosure


Violations in Private SMEs: Development of Research Propositions and Hypotheses

2.1. Conceptual Framework of the Study


The violations of law occur in a firm when its managers do not comply with the legal requirements
for either content, forms or time. Information on time is essential to align all firm stakeholders’ interests
(Singhvi and Desai 1971); generally, the older the information, the less useful it is. In addition, the timely
disclosure of information is a way to reduce the information asymmetry between firms’ stakeholders
(Owusu-Ansah and Leventis 2006; Donnelly and Mulcahy 2008). The latter is possible through
transparency, one of the important qualities of governance according to Hermalin and Weisbach (2007).
According to the upper echelons theory, the organization is a reflection of its top managers
(Hiebl 2014). Based on the seminal paper by Hambrick and Mason (1984), the characteristics of firm’s
top managers and their strategic choices help to explain the organization’s performance. Consequently,
organizational outcomes such as firms’ disclosure practices are influenced by the board’s characteristics
due to the monitoring role of corporate governance. Broadly, corporate governance is the setup
of direction and control in companies (Huse 2007), given the separation of these two functions.
The regulation of corporate governance originates from the time when ownership and management
of businesses first became separated in accordance with the agency theory (Fama and Jensen 1983).
Thousands of papers have been published about corporate governance related to multiple aspects of
firms from that seminal paper. However, the extant evidence does not provide a clear answer if better
corporate governance has a positive influence on information disclosures (Beekes et al. 2016).
As provided in the introduction, most of the studies about corporate governance are focused
on large and listed firms but not on SMEs and private companies (Abor and Adjasi 2007; Spiers 2018).
For instance, Durst and Henschel (2014, p. 18) even propose a different definition of corporate
governance in small companies, where the focus is set on the interplay with relevant stakeholders
to achieve a strategic change, rather than focusing only on the routine control function.
Corporate governance in privately held firms includes many factors and variables that condition
decision-making as to violate or not the disclosure of compulsory information, such as different
organizational and/or institutional contexts (Uhlaner et al. 2007).
Clarke and Klettner (2009) and Uhlaner et al. (2007) suggest that directors of small firms
are more worried about survival than planning and control as corporate governance imperatives.
In this line, Crossan et al. (2015) emphasize that the lack of governance within small companies is a
conditioning factor for business failure, while similar opinions are shared by Saxena and Jagota (2015)
and Spiers (2017). Thus, an organic interconnection exists between corporate governance and risk
behaviour of managers, one example of which is the timely accounting information disclosure violation
(later also referred to as TADV).
We posit a theoretical concept in which corporate governance characteristics could condition risk
behaviour in firms (see Figure 1). Our central standpoint states that based on the upper echelons’ theory,
firms’ risk behaviour is conditioned by their management. In detail, we rely on three main theoretical
streams of corporate governance (see Nicholson and Kiel 2007), that is, agency, stewardship and resource
dependence theories, to outline the dimensions relevant to study the interconnection between corporate
governance and risk behaviour. First, we rely on agency theory, the central question of which are the
nonaligned interests of managers and owners in corporate governance (e.g., Jensen and Meckling 1976).
Thus, our first dimension of interest considers the convergence of decision-making in a firm, which we
name in the further text as “power concentration”. Second, we rely on the resource dependence
theory, which postulates that corporate governance channels firms’ internal and external resources
into performance (e.g., Pfeffer and Salancik 2003). In light of this theory, we focus on a specific type of
internal resource, that is, the managers’ “experience” dimension. Third, we rely on the stewardship

341
JRFM 2020, 13, 230

theory, which considers managers having aligned interests with owners, and thus, behaviour differences
of firms are subject to inherent characteristics of managers (e.g., Donaldson and Davis 1991). The third
dimension is named the “demographic diversity” of managers. These three dimensions are discussed
further as follows, coming to the postulation of research propositions for each of the dimensions.
Under each research proposition, specific testable hypotheses are developed. The same approach of
using research propositions and specific testable hypotheses has been frequently used in management
research (see e.g., Zajac and Westphal 1996). The postulated hypotheses rely on the (most) usual
corporate governance characteristics applied to depict these dimensions in the literature.

Figure 1. Conceptual framework of the study. Source: Own elaboration.

2.2. Power Concentration and TADV


Although much attention has been paid to the role of boards (Daily et al. 2003), many small
firms do not have formal boards but only a unique manager who concentrates on all the functions
of the board, while managers and owners are often overlapping. Occasionally, in addition to the
founder or owner-manager, there may also be one or two family members on the board, with a unique
way of making decisions (Gabrielsson 2007). The varying power concentration among private firms
grounds the first dimension that could condition SMEs’ decisions concerning timely information
disclosure violations. This dimension is relevant, as the agency theory posits that adequate monitoring
or control mechanisms need to be established to protect stakeholders from conflicts of interests
(Kiel and Nicholson 2003; Parsa et al. 2007), therefore avoiding information asymmetry. In general,
more power concentration in a firm’s board suggests less pressure for disclosing information as there is
less demand for transparency (Carney 2005; Beuselinck and Manigart 2007). Thus, the first proposition
(P1) about corporate governance dimensions states that:
P1: Larger power concentration will increase the likelihood of TADV.
In relation to the need for concrete information disclosure policy by firms’ decision-makers, there
are two corporate governance characteristics that measure the power concentration of decision-making,
namely ownership concentration and managerial ownership. The former means whether firms have a
high concentration of ownership in one or a few large shareholders that own the majority of shares in
the firm. High levels of ownership concentration foster risk-taking (Nguyen 2011). The concentration
of ownership and the unification of ownership and control may lead to managers being subjected
to less pressure from outside investors who demand accountability and transparency (Carney 2005).
In private firms, concentrated ownership means that large shareholders tend to have less interest in
disclosing information because they are well informed of what is happening in the firm. In the same

342
JRFM 2020, 13, 230

line, Beuselinck and Manigart (2007) argue that private equity firms with majority shareholders are
likely to have lower-quality financial reporting systems compared to those with minority shareholders
only. Additionally, if decision-making is concentrated, firm risk behaviour can be assimilated with that
of the owner. Taking the prior reasoning into account, the first hypothesis (H1a) related to the power
concentration proposition is as follows:

Hypothesis 1a. Ownership concentration will increase the likelihood of TADV.

The second corporate governance variable to capture power concentration is managerial ownership,
focused on the shares owned by their own managers, that is, the involvement of owners in running
a firm. Most SMEs are closely held, and owner-managed (Brunninge et al. 2007), and consequently,
they do not disclose much information, because they do not need to make it public. Moreover,
managers of those firms have much information “in the head” (Uhlaner et al. 2007). Accordingly,
we posit the second hypothesis (H1b) concerning the power concentration proposition:

Hypothesis 1b. Managerial ownership will increase the likelihood of TADV.

2.3. Demographic Diversity and TADV


As boards of directors monitor the disclosure of business information, their characteristics may
condition the policy of business information disclosure (Hambrick 2007; Hiebl 2014). As outlined
earlier, the theory of upper echelons is based on the idea that managerial characteristics could
affect their choices and that the choices of managers are influenced by their cognitive base and
values (Hambrick and Mason 1984). However, psychological factors of managers are very difficult to
measure, and thus, demographic variables are considered as good proxies (Hambrick and Mason 1984;
Nielsen 2010). In this sense, “managers’ unique disclosure styles are associated with observable
demographic characteristics of their personal backgrounds” (Bamber et al. 2010, p. 1131).
Bamber et al. (2010) note that managers must comply with legal deadlines for submission, in addition
to deciding what type of voluntary information may be disclosed.
One of the corporate governance characteristics considered by prior literature to affect the quality
of the corporate board’s monitoring, and thus, firm’s financial performance, is the board’s demographic
diversity (Campbell and Minguez-Vera 2008; Carter et al. 2010; Shehata et al. 2017) as a way to portray
the influence of personal and psychological characteristics of managers. In this sense, greater diversity
is beneficial because that variety may influence what information is brought into decision-making
processes (Post and Byron 2015), although there is a trade-off between the benefits and costs of diversity
on board effectiveness (Bennouri et al. 2018). We argue that certain demographic profiles reduce
risk-taking, and thus, are more likely to lead to law-abiding actions. In this line, the second proposition
(P2) in relation to the board’s demographic diversity is posited as:
P2: Certain demographic characteristics will reduce the likelihood of TADV.
One specific characteristic of demographic diversity in the board is the age of a manager,
which reflects well the attitude towards risk and actual risk-taking behaviour (Plöckinger et al. 2016).
Thus, the manager’s age is related to risk aversion (Jianakoplos and Bernasek 1998) and even to
the acceptance of financial fraud (Troy et al. 2011). Younger managers are more inclined towards
risky strategies such as law violations. On the contrary, more mature managers are more risk-averse
(MacCrimmon and Wehrung 1990). Older CEOs are less involved in dishonest actions (Troy et al. 2011)
because maturity has also been associated with higher levels of moral development and stricter
interpretations of firm’s ethical standards of conduct (Serwinek 1992), therefore resulting in a lower
likelihood of engaging in or facilitating unethical behaviours (Ortiz-de-Mandojana et al. 2018).
Consequently, for the demographic diversity proposition, the first hypothesis (H2a) is stated as follows:

Hypothesis 2a. Managerial age will reduce the likelihood of TADV.

343
JRFM 2020, 13, 230

A common measure of demographic diversity is gender. According to prior literature, risk aversion
also differs by gender (e.g., Jianakoplos and Bernasek 1998; Ho et al. 2015). The specific corporate
governance variable usually applied is the existence of women on the board. From an informational
perspective, female directors may contribute to decision-making processes because of their different
knowledge, experience, and values (Kanadli et al. 2018). In addition, even in majority male
boards, women isolation and minorities have the potential to influence the board’s decision-making
(Kanadli et al. 2018). Some authors argue that female directors are more likely to be objective and
independent (Fondas 2000), and thus, they could follow legal requirements better than male directors
because women directors reduce the level of conflicts (Nielsen and Huse 2010). Indeed, their presence
enhances board information, perspectives, debate and decision-making (Burke 2000). For example, an
equilibrated board tends to mitigate earnings management practices, reinforcing obedience to the law
(Saona et al. 2018). Other studies in this line support the idea that women are more ethical than men
(Glover et al. 2002; Larkin 2000; Wahn 2003). In this way, earnings quality and voluntary disclosure
levels increase when gender diversity exists in boards (Krishnan and Parsons 2008; Liao et al. 2015).
Some authors argue that having women in boards influences not only what information is used in
decision-making but also how, because females do have different organizational skills than males
(Adams and Funk 2012; Post and Byron 2015). Additionally, Ho et al. (2015) found that companies
with female CEOs report information more conservatively when companies face high litigation or
risks. Relying on the afore-given argumentation, we posit the following hypothesis (H2b) for the
demographic diversity proposition:

Hypothesis 2b. The presence of women on the board will reduce the likelihood of TADV.

2.4. Experience and TADV


One of the most usual attributes of executives in the risk-taking literature is their experience
(May 1995; Hoskisson et al. 2017), as experienced managers are reluctant to make changes and
consequently take fewer risks (Hambrick and Fukutomi 1991; Miller and Shamsie 2001). Thus,
experienced managers are more risk-averse and violate laws less. They have life and business
experiences and perhaps past violation consequences such as prior penalties, which make them not to
violate laws. The more experience managers have, the more business problems and more solutions
they have had to deal with. Accordingly, the third proposition (P3) can be posited as follows:
P3: More entrepreneurial experience will reduce the likelihood of TADV.
The experience dimension could be measured as the combination of tenure (the board’s inside
experience) and business ties (the board’s outside experience). Board tenure is the time spent on the
board of a specific firm and it is expected to increase the director’s knowledge of the firm and its business
environment (Vafeas 2003) as well as commitment towards the company (Buchanan 1974). The tenure
of directors on the same board captures the knowledge of the company’s strategy and functioning
(Harris and Shimizu 2004). As the boards of SMEs have fewer members, each board member should
be fairly well informed on all aspects of the firm. Longer serving CEOs have greater temporal depth,
as greater exposure to various events in the past helps to design more effective decisions impacting
future outcomes (Ortiz-de-Mandojana et al. 2018). Related to the timely information disclosure
violation, a longer board tenure could reduce the occurrence of it, because the longer CEOs have been
in the firm, the more experienced they can be on the consequences of a law violation. Concerning
other legal requirements, Baatwah et al. (2015) found that longer-tenured CEOs are linked with a
timelier completion of the audit report. Similarly, Schrand and Zechman (2012) posit that managers of
misreporting and fraudulent firms generally have shorter tenures. Thus, the first hypothesis (H3a) for
the experience proposition states as follows:

Hypothesis 3a. Board tenure will reduce the likelihood of TADV.

344
JRFM 2020, 13, 230

Another proxy of managers’ experience is multiple directorships or ties, a corporate governance


variable that measures whether board members hold director positions in several firms at the same
time. Managers with multiple directorships may be perceived positively since they facilitate the
exchange of vital information for firms (Connelly and Slyke 2012) and because they are more likely to
understand the business environment of the company (Hillman et al. 2007). Additionally, working in
several firms may be conditioned by board members having uncommon skills and strong abilities in
both monitoring and advising subordinates (Falato et al. 2014). In addition, the past penalties because
of violating the law the board members with many ties have experienced in other firms could also
reduce the risk of a new law violation. Thus, relying on the afore-given motivation, we posit the
following hypothesis (H3b) for the proposition about experience:

Hypothesis 3b. Multiple directorships will reduce the likelihood of TADV.

2.5. Board Size and TADV


Finally, as one of the main characteristics frequently used in the literature of corporate governance
from large and/or listed firms is board size (Huse 2000), we assume that it is also relevant in SMEs,
although less than in large and/or listed firms. Normally, the board size of SMEs is small, but still,
there could be difficulties or conflicts in what information disclosure policy the company should have
due to opposite opinions. According to the literature of public firms, the presence of a large number
of directors implies a reduction of the board’s effectiveness in management control (Yermack 1996;
Eisenberg et al. 1998; De Andres et al. 2005; Cheng 2008) and an effective board can also be engaged in
better disclosure practices (Willekens et al. 2005).
From another angle, a larger board will bring together a greater depth of intellectual knowledge,
and therefore, could improve the quality of strategic decisions. An additional director could bring
more human capital to the company, therefore increasing the board’s information and specific
knowledge about the business and its environment. The latter will increase the firm’s efficiency
(Adams and Ferreira 2007; De Andres and Vallelado 2008; Linck et al. 2008); and as mentioned before,
efficiency in boards conditions its disclosure practices. Consequently, there could be a link between
board size and information disclosure, while there are contradictory explanations with respect to
whether it will increase or decrease the likelihood of TADV. Thus, we include board size in the analysis
as a control variable to shed light on the controversy about its role in association with TADV.

3. Data, Variables and Method

3.1. Study’s Data


In this study, we apply firm-level data from Estonia and the population includes 77,212 unique
private SMEs, accounting for roughly 50% of all Estonian private SMEs registered at the end of 2014.
While we did not include large and/or listed firms in the analysis, some additional contractions were
made to the whole population of firms. Namely, we do not include firms having (at least some)
corporate owners or foreign individuals as managers/owners, as in case of them we are not able to
calculate (all) the variables documented in Section 3.3. In addition, we are not including firms lacking
an annual report because of not being obliged to submit it for different reasons (e.g., a firm is too young
or in the liquidation procedure). All information obtained is factual and originates from the Estonian
Business Register (see also Sections 3.2 and 3.3). The median firm in the analysis is 7.3 years old and a
micro firm by size (i.e., total assets 22 thousand euros). Thus, the median firm in the population refers
to an older micro firm, which dominates the firms’ population in other countries as well. In the case
of all firms, we consider the annual report submission delay for the fiscal year of 2014 and corporate
governance variables are calculated from the last day firms had to present the annual report (for the
vast majority of cases that date is 30 June 2015). The boards and owners of SMEs change infrequently,

345
JRFM 2020, 13, 230

thus the usage of a single year is justified. Despite the latter, the TADV behaviour can vary through
reporting years, and thus, in order to guarantee the robustness of the results with respect to the year
chosen for the analysis (i.e., 2014), we check the results for another fiscal year (i.e., 2015) as well.

3.2. Dependent Variable


The dependent variable is TADV as our aim is to analyse what specific corporate governance
factors are associated with this behaviour. For portraying TADV, we code a binary dependent
variable (BINARYDELAY), which equals 1 if the company does not present the annual report on time
(i.e., exceeding the legal deadline at least by one day) and 0 otherwise.
All Estonian SMEs have to disclose their financial statements (i.e., balance sheet, income statements
and explanatory notes) once per year and online. This presentation of the annual report has a legal
deadline of six months from the fiscal year end. For the vast majority of firms, the fiscal year end is
also the calendar year end, that is, the 31st of December every year. Thus, in the latter circumstance,
the deadline for uploading the annual report is the 30th of June the following year.
In order to enhance the context of the violation further, we distinguish between mild and severe
delayers in further analysis. Namely, as a mild delay, we consider a delay of up to 365 days (i.e., one year)
and a severe delay is over 365 days. Such coding is based on the Estonian legal considerations. Namely,
according to the Estonian Commercial Code, this is the minimal date after which the Estonian Business
Register can start the deletion procedure of a firm because of not submitting the annual report. We base
the severity of the submission delay on this legal consideration to avoid a subjective selection of the
relevant break-even time. The usage of two types of violators enables us to study, how non-violators
differ from either modest or severe violators, but also, how modest and severe violators differ from
each other. It is not rational to distinguish between different types of non-violators, as firms can freely
choose when to submit their annual report during the legally allowed half-year period after the end of
the fiscal year, and usually, they do it in June.

3.3. Independent Variables


Based on the motivation in the literature review section, we use three dimensions, further splitting
them into six independent variables portraying corporate governance characteristics of a firm
(see Table 1). The independent variables were calculated mostly based on their formulas in
previous studies.
For capturing the ownership concentration, variable MAJORITY is used, which indicates in a
binary form, whether there is a majority owner (i.e., having more than 50% of the shares) present.
According to the Estonian regulation, an owner having more than 50% has the power to decide upon
most of the actions in a firm, thus the usage of that threshold is well-motivated with legislation.
Another variable for the concentration dimension is managerial ownership. To portray managerial
ownership, the variable BOARDOWNER is used, which is a ratio of shares owned by the board
members to the total shares. Thus, this variable directly portrays the overlap between the two levels of
corporate governance (i.e., owners and board members). It must be emphasized, that the Estonian
SMEs are subject to a two-level corporate governance system, in which the board is subordinate to
owners directly, while the board members are legally responsible for all firm’s activities.
For the demographic diversity dimension, the manager’s age is portrayed with MANAGERAGE,
which is calculated as the biological age of the oldest board member. Although in previous studies
the mean age of board members has been used as well, it does not suit herewith, as we intend to
capture the life experience available on the board, not the average experience. Furthermore, as a large
proportion of firms have single-person boards, the usage of mean age would not be a suitable option.
The context of gender is captured with the presence of a woman on the board (reflected with a binary
variable WOMAN obtaining 1 on that occasion and 0 otherwise). In studies focusing on larger firms,
a gender proportion has been used, but that option is not suitable in the case of SMEs, of which the
overwhelming majority have only one or two individuals on the board.

346
JRFM 2020, 13, 230

Table 1. Variables in the analysis.

Dimension Variable Coding Variable Content Expected Sign


Dependent variable
Whether a firm violated the annual
TADV dependent
BINARYDELAY report submission date at least by 1 day
variable
(coded as 1) or not (coded as 0)
Independent variables
Whether there is a single majority
Concentration MAJORITY (for H1a) owner (i.e., >50%) in the +
dimension’s firm (coded as 1) or not (coded as 0)
independent variables Share of the stock the board members
BOARDOWNER (for H1b) +
hold divided by total stock
Biological age of the oldest
Diversity dimension’s MANAGERAGE (for H2a) -
board member
independent variables Whether there is a woman on the board
WOMAN (for H2b) -
(coded as 1) or not (coded as 0)
Tenure length of the longest serving
Experience dimension’s TENURE (for H3a) -
board member in years
independent variables Number of other board memberships
TIES (for H3b) -
the board members hold
Control variable BOARDSIZE Number of board members
Source: own elaboration. Note: for robustness tests, BINARYDELAY is recoded to account for mild and severe
violators (see also Sections 3.2 and 3.4).

For the experience dimension, business ties are portrayed with the variable TIES, which reflects
the number of board memberships in other firms the board members of the firms under question
hold. Thus, this variable reflects the scope of ongoing business experience outside the firm under
question. Managerial tenure is captured with the variable TENURE, which reflects the time in years the
longest-serving board member has been on their position. TENURE could also be used as a ratio of the
time the longest-serving board member has been on their position to the firm’s age. Still, such a ratio
would easily lead to overestimating firm-specific experience in the case of (very) young firms. Finally,
the control variable reflecting board size is captured by BOARDSIZE, which reflects the number of
board members in the firm.

3.4. Statistical Method


In the case of the base model, binary logistic regression (BLR) will be used with BINARYDELAY
as the dependent variable and seven corporate governance variables listed in Table 1 as independent
or control variables. The model tested with BLR is as follows:

BINARYDELAY = β0 + β1 MAJORITY + β2 BOARDOWNER + β3 MANAGERAGE + β4 WOMAN


+ β5 TENURE + β6 TIES + β7 BOARDSIZE

We will also run three additional BLRs to check how: (a) non-violators differ from mild violators,
(b) non-violators differ from severe violators, (c) mild violators differ from severe violators. The latter
BLRs help to disclose, how the results vary when the severity of the violation is incorporated into
the analysis.
Moreover, in further analysis, we divide the firm population into two subpopulations based on
either the median size or median age, in order to check the robustness of the base results with respect to
firm size and age differences. Additional BLRs are run in the subpopulations, which enable us to outline
how smaller/larger or younger/older firms differ from the base results. The usage of more categories
(e.g., breaking the firm population based on size or age quartiles) is not reasoned, as the ranges of size
and age variables are not wide enough to justify the usage of a large number of subpopulations. We do
not apply size and/or age as control variables due to (serious) multicollinearity issues, which can emerge
from applying them with the chosen independent variables (e.g., with variables MANAGERAGE
or TENURE).

347
JRFM 2020, 13, 230

It is not rational to use different types of logistic regressions (e.g., multinomial or ordered)
herewith, as by keeping BLR as the only method, we can exactly compare the coefficients in different
models, and by doing that, outline whether the independent variables behave differently when
various contexts (i.e., the severity of delay, firm size or age) are altered. Finally, we run bootstrapping
with 100 subsamples in order to study, how the coefficients of independent variables vary in the
subpopulations of the whole population.

4. Results and Discussion


In the case of using BINARYDELAY as a factor, Welch robust ANOVA indicates (see the descriptive
statistics in Table 2) that the means are different for all six independent variables at p < 0.001.
Thus, all independent variables could potentially exhibit significance in discriminating between
(non-)violators in BLR.
The conducted BLR analysis (see Table 3) testing the model specified in Section 3.4 indicates that
at p < 0.05 level all six independent variables discriminate between (non-)violators, while the control
variable BOARDSIZE is significant only at the p < 0.1 level. When the presence of a majority owner
(MAJORITY) and board memberships in other firms (TIES) lead to a higher likelihood of violation,
then in turn older managers (MANAGERAGE), women on the board (WOMAN), longer tenure
(TENURE) and a larger amount of shares owned by the board members (BOARDOWNER) all reduce
the likelihood of violation. Thus, H1a, H2a, H2b and H3a are supported in BLR, while H1b and H3b
are rejected. Although larger boards could to a certain extent exhibit a lower likelihood of delay,
the significance level of that variable does not enable to draw any ultimate conclusions, especially
when considering the population size used in this study.

Table 2. Descriptive statistics of corporate governance variables.

Firm Type Statistic MAJORITY BOARDOWNER MANAGERAGE WOMAN TENURE TIES BOARDSIZE
N 54,081 54,081 54,081 54,081 54,081 54,081 54,081
Mean 0.81 0.88 47.30 0.38 8.01 1.41 1.31
Std. Dev. 0.39 0.28 11.84 0.48 5.22 2.10 0.57
Non-violators
Median 1.00 1.00 46.44 0.00 6.79 1.00 1.00
Min. 0.00 0.00 18.73 0.00 0.50 0.00 1.00
Max. 1.00 1.00 92.56 1.00 20.28 10.00 7.00
N 23,131 23,131 23,131 23,131 23,131 23,131 23,131
Mean 0.84 0.87 44.25 0.35 6.88 1.67 1.28
Std. Dev. 0.37 0.30 11.29 0.48 4.74 2.36 0.54
Violators
Median 1.00 1.00 42.94 0.00 5.59 1.00 1.00
Min. 0.00 0.00 19.32 0.00 0.50 0.00 1.00
Max. 1.00 1.00 93.60 1.00 20.24 10.00 7.00
N 77,212 77,212 77,212 77,212 77,212 77,212 77,212
Mean 0.82 0.88 46.39 0.37 7.67 1.49 1.30
Std. Dev. 0.39 0.28 11.76 0.48 5.11 2.18 0.56
Total
Median 1.00 1.00 45.38 0.00 6.34 1.00 1.00
Min. 0.00 0.00 18.73 0.00 0.50 0.00 1.00
Max. 1.00 1.00 93.60 1.00 20.28 10.00 7.00
Source: Own elaboration.

According to our expectation, P1 assumes a positive relationship between both variables of


the board’s power concentration dimension and TADV. However, our results are inconclusive.
The ownership concentration variable enables the support of P1, as high levels of ownership
concentration can foster risk-taking, in line with Nguyen (2011). Moreover, minority shareholders
might not make much pressure as outside investors who demand more transparency (Carney 2005).
Conversely, when managers hold a larger proportion of the shares, they are less likely to be engaged
in TADV. As the manager-owners of the firm, they are more engaged/committed to decision-making
processes, and in this case, they also have a direct responsibility to face law violations. It can be
assumed, that although manager-owners have much information “in the head” (Uhlaner et al. 2007),
and thus, are not in need to publish annual reports quickly, they are still more worried about the
personal reputation loss and legal consequences of violations.

348
JRFM 2020, 13, 230

Table 3. Logistic regression model for BINARYDELAY (0—non-violator, 1—violator).

Variable B S.E. Wald Sig. Exp(B) VIF


MAJORITY 0.222 0.025 77.912 0.000 1.249 1.45
BOARDOWNER −0.160 0.029 31.356 0.000 0.852 1.09
MANAGERAGE −0.018 0.001 490.339 0.000 0.982 1.36
WOMAN −0.079 0.017 20.514 0.000 0.924 1.10
TENURE −0.028 0.002 224.590 0.000 0.973 1.33
TIES 0.064 0.004 295.859 0.000 1.066 1.13
BOARDSIZE 0.035 0.018 3.551 0.060 1.035 1.63
Constant 0.009 0.050 0.033 0.855 1.009
Source: Own elaboration. Notes: Average variance inflation factor (VIF) 1.30. See the model’s general form in
Section 3.4.

Related to the proposition P2, certain demographic characteristics should have a negative
relationship with TADV, which found proof with the two variables employed. When members of the
board are less risk-prone as women, have more life-experience measured as being biologically older,
then the probability of TADV is lower. According to prior studies, age and gender are two relevant
conditions against risk, that is, older managers and women are more risk-averse than young ones and
men (Jianakoplos and Bernasek 1998; Troy et al. 2011; Ho et al. 2015). In addition, female directors
are more likely to be objective and independent (Fondas 2000), therefore decreasing risk-taking
(Elsaid and Ursel 2011), and thus, also following rules and official requirements to disclose financial
information on time. Older managers with experience are less involved in dishonest and unethical
behaviours than young ones (Troy et al. 2011; Ortiz-de-Mandojana et al. 2018). This could be due to
the fact that old managers have experienced other law violations in their business life, which could
have had negative consequences, for instance in the form of fees, penalties, reputation reduction,
or decreases of credit ratings. Thus, they do not want to conduct more misbehaviours.
Regarding the third proposition P3 reflecting board experience, firms are supposedly less
risk-taking when their managers have more experience, but proof for this was found only by using the
TENURE variable. Being engaged in a firm for a longer period makes the managers more capable
of consolidating financial information quicker, but also, they might have witnessed the negative
consequences of TADV already before. In turn, being a board member in other firms acts in the
opposite way. While multiple directorships are related to uncommon skills and strong abilities in
both monitoring and advising (Falato et al. 2014; Harris and Shimizu 2004), such individuals could be
busy directors who may lack the time needed to execute their monitoring well (Johnson et al. 2013;
Jiraporn et al. 2009). However, some empirical research has concluded that “criticisms levelled against
these directors may be unfounded” (Harris and Shimizu 2004, p. 791), and perhaps, there are other
potential explanations related to this variable.
Our results show that board size is not associated with TADV. This might be because the board
size in private firms is very small and many times is made up of the unique owner who is also the
unique manager. In addition, when there are more members in private firms’ boards, they could also
be from the same family, therefore making the same decisions as they are defending the same interests
(Zona 2015).
Table 4 extends the base BLR analysis by introducing different types of violators. When violators
are broken into two types, that is, mild violators (up to 365 days delay) and severe violators (more than
365 days delay), an interesting feature is that the significances and effect directions of independent
variables are not altered, although the magnitude of the effect of specific variables can (largely) vary. It is
possible to generalize that when comparing non-violators with a specific type of violator (either mild or
severe), in case of all independent variables, the effect is always stronger in the case of severe violators.
Many independent variables are not significant when distinguishing between mild and severe violators,
namely only two variables (i.e., MANAGERAGE and TENURE) are significant at p < 0.01. Thus,
violators differ more from non-violators than different violators differ between themselves.

349
JRFM 2020, 13, 230

As the effects in the case of mild violators are not as strong, we can suggest that perhaps the
decision to follow or not the disclosure regulation in the case of mild violators could be the case of
“carelessness”. Such managers do not really want to violate the regulation, but for instance, when the
composition of the annual report is left “to the last minute”, it cannot be prepared on time and perhaps
not all board members can accept and sign the report enough quickly. The latter “carelessness” logic is
corroborated by prior studies such as Cheng (2008) or Arosa et al. (2013).

Table 4. Additional logistic regression models for the subpopulations of BINARYDELAY in comparison
with the base model.

All Firms Subpopulation 1 Subpopulation 2 Subpopulation 3


(0 Non-Violator; (0 Non-Violator; (0 Non-Violator; (0 Mild Violator;
1 Violator) 1 Mild Violator) 1 Severe Violator) 1 Severe Violator)
Variable B Sig. B Sig. B Sig. B Sig.
MAJORITY 0.222 0.000 0.214 0.000 0.232 0.000 0.053 0.254
BOARDOWNER −0.160 0.000 −0.121 0.000 −0.223 0.000 −0.114 0.020
MANAGERAGE −0.018 0.000 −0.017 0.000 −0.020 0.000 −0.004 0.002
WOMAN −0.079 0.000 −0.063 0.002 −0.111 0.000 −0.059 0.063
TENURE −0.028 0.000 −0.010 0.000 −0.072 0.000 −0.064 0.000
TIES 0.064 0.000 0.064 0.000 0.066 0.000 0.005 0.456
BOARDSIZE 0.035 0.060 0.053 0.011 −0.025 0.425 −0.068 0.048
Constant 0.009 0.855 −0.593 0.000 −0.636 0.000 −0.023 0.795
Source: Own elaboration. Note: All firms, 54,081 non-violators and 23,131 violators, SP1 54,081 non-violators and
15,917 mild violators, SP2 54,081 non-violators and 7214 severe violators, SP3 15,917 mild violators and 7214 severe
violators. See the model’s general form in Section 3.4.

Table 5 provides additional BLR models in case the applied population of firms is broken in two
based on either median size or age of firms. Likewise, with the violation context, the BLRs focusing
on different size or age groups indicate that the variables are significant and the effects are in the
same direction, but the magnitudes of the effects vary. Still, unlike with the violation context, there is
more variation with respect to whether smaller/larger size or younger/older age of firms leads to the
independent variable having a weaker/stronger effect in distinguishing between (non-)violators.

Table 5. Additional logistic regression models of BINARYDELAY for smaller/larger and younger/older
firms in comparison with the base model.

All Firms Smaller Firms Larger Firms Younger Firms Older Firms
Variable
B Sig. B Sig. B Sig. B Sig. B Sig.
MAJORITY 0.222 0.000 0.209 0.000 0.250 0.000 0.115 0.001 0.338 0.000
BOARDOWNER −0.160 0.000 −0.196 0.000 −0.154 0.000 −0.238 0.000 −0.121 0.004
MANAGERAGE −0.018 0.000 −0.017 0.000 −0.018 0.000 −0.015 0.000 −0.020 0.000
WOMAN −0.079 0.000 −0.122 0.000 −0.070 0.010 −0.058 0.013 −0.110 0.000
TENURE −0.028 0.000 −0.027 0.000 −0.021 0.000 −0.028 0.000 −0.016 0.000
TIES 0.064 0.000 0.057 0.000 0.078 0.000 0.055 0.000 0.071 0.000
BOARDSIZE 0.035 0.060 0.113 0.000 −0.021 0.406 0.019 0.481 0.049 0.051
Constant 0.009 0.855 0.026 0.712 −0.114 0.113 0.109 0.130 −0.196 0.009
Source: Own elaboration. Note: For the distinction of smaller/larger and younger/older firms, the population is
broken in two based on median size (natural logarithm of total assets) 9.98 or median age (firm age in years at 30
June 2015) 7.34. See the model’s general form in Section 3.4.

When the BLR is run with another fiscal year (i.e., 2015), the results are not altered (see Table A1).
Namely, the only variable clearly not significant, likewise with the base model calculated by using
the fiscal year 2014, is the control variable BOARDSIZE. In turn, in the case of independent variables,
the signs of the coefficients remain the same and absolute values of the coefficients are very similar,
like for the base model documented in Table 3. Thus, the results are robust with respect to the year
chosen for analysis. Table A1 also shows the bootstrapping results for the year 2014. In a 100-sample
bootstrapping, the signs of independent variables’ coefficients do not change for the lower and upper
95% confidence intervals, thus the subpopulations of firms are quite similar to the findings obtained

350
JRFM 2020, 13, 230

with the base regression model on the whole population documented in Table 3. The bootstrapping
result is an expected scenario based on the age and size contexts in Table 5, which also do not indicate
the change in variables’ signs.
The results of the study are consolidated into Table 6, which in future research can be used as a
benchmark for the association of timely accounting disclosure violation and corporate governance
attributes in SMEs. As a contribution to the literature, we found that certain demographic attributes
in the board make them less likely to be violators of the accounting regulation, while the power
concentration and experience on the board can lead to varying violation behaviour, depending on
what variable of the specific dimension is considered. In addition, corporate governance characteristics
have more pronounced effects on the violation probability when the violation becomes more severe.

Table 6. Summary of the associations found in this study.

Corporate Governance Base Effect Context of


Variable Context of Size Context of Age
Dimension on Violation Violation Length
MAJORITY Effect stronger Effect stronger in Effect stronger for
Power Increases
(H1a accepted) in larger firms older firms severe violators
Concentration (Proposition
1 inconclusive) BOARDOWNER Effect stronger Effect stronger in Effect stronger for
Decreases
(H1b rejected) in smaller firms younger firms severe violators
MANAGERAGE Effect stronger Effect stronger in Effect stronger for
Decreases
Demographic Diversity (H2a accepted) in larger firms older firms severe violators
(Proposition 2 true) WOMAN Effect stronger Effect stronger in Effect stronger for
Decreases
(H2b accepted) in smaller firms older firms severe violators
TENURE Effect stronger Effect stronger in Effect stronger for
Decreases
Entrepreneurial Experience (H3a accepted) in smaller firms younger firms severe violators
(Proposition 3 inconclusive) TIES Effect stronger Effect stronger in Effect stronger for
Increases
(H3b rejected) in larger firms older firms severe violators
Source: Own elaboration. Note: The first column includes the result for the three research propositions (either true,
inconclusive or false; inconclusive means one true and one false evidence), while the second column includes the
result for the acceptance/rejection of postulated six hypotheses.

5. Conclusions and Future Research


The objective of this research was to analyse the association between corporate governance
characteristics and timely accounting information disclosure violations in private SMEs. Relying on an
SME population in a developed European economy, namely Estonia, a set of theoretically motivated
corporate governance (independent) variables was studied with annual report submission delays
(as the dependent variable) in different logistic regression analyses. Evidence was found that certain
demographic diversity in the board (as portrayed by women on the board and managers’ older
age) reduces the likelihood of violation, while variables portraying power concentration (managerial
ownership and ownership concentration) and board experience (tenure length and business ties)
provided mixed results.
Varying stakeholders can benefit from the results of this study. First, as non-timely disclosure
has been proven to be associated with either financial distress or bankruptcy (Altman et al. 2010;
Lukason 2013; Luypaert et al. 2016; Lukason and Camacho-Miñano 2019), creditors can account
specific corporate governance characteristics in case of lengthy delays. In the latter circumstance,
financial information from the past can already be obsolete, and thus, non-financial variables could be
of remarkable value to predict distress or bankruptcy. Second, based on the results, state institutions
monitoring timely submission have a better understanding, which corporate governance characteristics
in association with firm size and age can lead to a law violation with a higher likelihood. The latter
enables, for instance, the targeting of likely lengthy violators earlier to guarantee better transparency in
the business environment. Last but not least, as the general foundation of this study was risk behaviour
more broadly, the findings can provide valuable hints, which corporate governance characteristics
could potentially be triggers for other risk behaviour types.

351
JRFM 2020, 13, 230

Finally, this paper is not free from limitations, being fully related to future research proposals.
First, our paper is focused on one country, Estonia, and thus, our findings could be altered by
the peculiarities of this country, for example, the accounting disclosure (violation) legal framework
and its implementation. Future research could be conducted in other countries in order to check
whether cultural or legal settings have an impact on how corporate governance is linked to accounting
disclosure violations. Second, our approach to corporate governance is limited to a certain set of
dimensions and variables portraying them, and thus, future research could be enhanced to account
more for psychological or personal characteristics such as ethical level, past violation behaviour or
past training/education of managers. Third, although the results were validated with another fiscal
year, the violations could be studied in a longer time frame, to either detect certain disclosure pattern
changes or even consider corporate governance changes, should these occur.

Author Contributions: Both authors contributed to all parts. Both authors have read and agreed to the published
version of the manuscript.
Funding: The first author acknowledges financial support from the University of Tartu Foundation’s Ernst Jaakson
Commemorative Scholarship, the Estonian Research Council’s grant PRG791 “Innovation Complementarities and
Productivity Growth” and the Estonian Research Infrastructures Roadmap project “Infotechnological Mobility
Observatory (IMO)”.
Acknowledgments: Authors thank the Estonian Centre of Registers and Information Systems for the data.
Conflicts of Interest: The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Table A1. Model composed with another fiscal year 2015 and bootstrapping results for the year 2014.

Variable B-2014 Sig.-2014 B-2015 Sig.-2015 BS 95% CI Lower BS 95% CI Higher


MAJORITY 0.222 0.000 0.189 0.000 0.165 0.277
BOARDOWNER −0.160 0.000 −0.169 0.000 −0.219 −0.089
MANAGERAGE −0.018 0.000 −0.014 0.000 −0.019 −0.016
WOMAN −0.079 0.000 −0.066 0.000 −0.124 −0.049
TENURE −0.028 0.000 −0.014 0.000 −0.032 −0.024
TIES 0.064 0.000 0.053 0.000 0.057 0.074
BOARDSIZE 0.035 0.060 0.010 0.593 −0.001 0.066
Constant 0.009 0.855 −0.337 0.000 −0.069 0.095
Source: Own elaboration. Notes: BS—bootstrapping, CI—confidence interval. BS results were obtained with 100
bootstrap samples for the year 2014 population. B and Sig.—coefficient and p-value either for the whole populations
from 2014 or 2015.

References
Abdelsalam, Omneya H., and Donna L. Street. 2007. Corporate governance and the timeliness of corporate internet
reporting by U.K. listed companies. Journal of International Accounting, Auditing and Taxation 16: 111–30.
[CrossRef]
Abernathy, John L., Brooke Beyer, Adi Masli, and Chad Stefaniak. 2014. The association between characteristics
of audit committee accounting experts, audit committee chairs, and financial reporting timeliness.
Advances in Accounting 30: 283–97. [CrossRef]
Abor, Joshua, and Charles K. D. Adjasi. 2007. Corporate governance and the small and medium enterprises
sector: Theory and implications. Corporate Governance: The International Journal of Business in Society 7: 11–122.
[CrossRef]
Adams, Renee B., and Daniel Ferreira. 2007. A theory of friendly boards. Journal of Finance 62: 217–50. [CrossRef]
Adams, Renee B., and Patricia Funk. 2012. Beyond the glass ceiling: Does gender matter? Management Science
58: 219–35. [CrossRef]
Altman, Edward I., Gabriele Sabato, and Nick Wilson. 2010. The value of non-financial information in small and
medium-sized enterprise risk management. The Journal of Credit Risk 6: 1–33. [CrossRef]
Arosa, Blanca, Txomin Iturralde, and Amaia Maseda. 2013. The board structure and firm performance in SMEs:
Evidence from Spain. Investigaciones Europeas de Dirección y Economía de la Empresa 19: 127–35. [CrossRef]

352
JRFM 2020, 13, 230

Ashbaugh-Skaife, Hollis, Daniel Collins, and Ryan LaFond. 2006. The effects of corporate governance on firms’
credit ratings. Journal of Accounting and Economics 42: 203–43. [CrossRef]
Baatwah, Saeed R., Zalailah Salleh, and Norsiah Ahmad. 2015. CEO characteristics and audit report timeliness:
Do CEO tenure and financial expertise matter? Managerial Auditing Journal 30: 998–1022. [CrossRef]
Bae, Seong M., Md. A. K. Masud, and Jong D. Kim. 2018. A cross-country investigation of corporate governance
and corporate sustainability disclosure: A signaling theory perspective. Sustainability 10: 2611. [CrossRef]
Bamber, Linda S., John Jiang, and Isabel Y. Wang. 2010. What’s my style? The influence of top managers on
voluntary corporate financial disclosure. The Accounting Review 85: 1131–62. [CrossRef]
Beasley, Mark S. 1996. An empirical analysis of the relation between the board of director composition and
financial statement fraud. The Accounting Review 71: 443–65.
Beekes, Wendy, Philip Brown, Wewen Zhan, and Qiyu Zhang. 2016. Corporate governance, companies’ disclosure
practices, and market transparency: A cross country study. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting 43: 263–97.
Bennouri, Moez, Tawhid Chtioui, Haithem Nagati, and Mehdi Nekhili. 2018. Female board directorship and firm
performance: What really matters? Journal of Banking & Finance 88: 267–91.
Berglöf, Erik, and Anete Pajuste. 2005. What do firms disclose and why? Enforcing corporate governance and
transparency in Central and Eastern Europe. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 21: 178–97.
Beuselinck, Christof, and Sophie Manigart. 2007. Financial reporting quality in private equity backed companies:
The impact of ownership concentration. Small Business Economics 29: 261–74. [CrossRef]
Brunninge, Olof, Mattias Nordqvist, and Johan Wiklund. 2007. Corporate governance and strategic change in
SMEs: The effects of ownership, board composition and top management teams. Small Business Economics
29: 295–308. [CrossRef]
Buchanan, Bruce. 1974. Government managers, business executives, and organizational commitment.
Public Administration Review 34: 339–47. [CrossRef]
Burke, Ronald J. 2000. Women on corporate boards of directors: Understanding the context. In Women on corporate
boards of directors: International Challenges and Opportunities. Edited by Ronald J. Burke and Mary C. Mattis.
Berlin: Springer, pp. 179–96.
Campbell, Kevin, and Antonio Minguez-Vera. 2008. Gender diversity in the boardroom and firm financial
performance. Journal of Business Ethics 83: 435–51. [CrossRef]
Carney, Michael. 2005. Corporate Governance and Competitive Advantage in Family-Controlled Firms.
Entrepreneurship Theory & Practice 29: 249–65.
Carslaw, Charles A. P. N., and Steven E. Kaplan. 1991. An examination of audit delay: Further evidence from
New Zealand. Accounting and Business Research 22: 21–32. [CrossRef]
Carter, David A., Frank D’Souza, Betty J. Simkins, and W. Gary Simpson. 2010. The gender and ethics diversity of US
boards and board committees and firm financial performance. Corporate Governance: An International Review
18: 396–414. [CrossRef]
Cheng, Shijun. 2008. Board size and the variability of corporate performance. Journal of Financial Economics
87: 157–76. [CrossRef]
Clarke, Thomas, and Alice Klettner. 2009. Governance issues for SMEs. Journal of Business Systems, Governance
and Ethics 4: 23–40. [CrossRef]
Clatworthy, Mark A., and Michael J. Peel. 2016. The timeliness of UK private company financial reporting:
Regulatory and economic influences. The British Accounting Review 48: 297–315. [CrossRef]
Collis, Jill. 2008. Views of the Directors of SMEs in the UK on Financial Reporting Requirements in a
Changing Regulatory Environment. Paper presented at the 4th Annual Workshop on Accounting in
Europe, Lund University, Lund, Sweden, September 10–11; Available online: https://eprints.kingston.ac.uk/
5516/3/Collis-J-5516.pdf (accessed on 1 September 2020).
Connelly, Brian L., and Erik J. Van Slyke. 2012. The power and peril of board interlocks. Business Horizons 55: 403–8.
[CrossRef]
Cowling, Marc, Weixi Liu, Andrew Ledger, and Ning Zhang. 2015. What really happens to small and medium-sized
enterprises in a global economic recession? UK evidence on sales and job dynamics. International Small
Business Journal 33: 488–513. [CrossRef]
Crossan, Kenny, Elena Pershina, and Thomas Henschel. 2015. A model analysis of internal governance for SMEs.
Interdisciplinary Journal of Economics and Business Law 4: 1–26.

353
JRFM 2020, 13, 230

Daily, Catherine M., Dan R. Dalton, and Albert A. Cannella. 2003. Corporate governance: Decades of dialogue
and data. Academy of Management Review 28: 371–82. [CrossRef]
De Andres, Pablo, and Eleuterio Vallelado. 2008. Corporate governance in banking: The role of the board of
directors. Journal of Banking & Finance 32: 2570–80.
De Andres, Pablo, Valentin Azofra, and Felix López. 2005. Corporate boards in OECD countries: Size, composition,
functioning and effectiveness. Corporate Governance: An International Review 13: 197–210. [CrossRef]
Donaldson, Lex, and James H. Davis. 1991. Stewardship theory or agency theory: CEO governance and
shareholder returns. Australian Journal of Management 16: 49–64. [CrossRef]
Donnelly, Ray, and Mark Mulcahy. 2008. Board structure, ownership, and voluntary disclosure in Ireland.
Corporate Governance: An International Review 16: 416–29. [CrossRef]
Durst, Susanne, and Thomas Henschel. 2014. Governance in small firms—A country comparison of current
practices. International Journal of Entrepreneurship and Small Business 21: 16–32.
Efobi, Uchenna, and Peace Okougbo. 2014. Timeliness of financial reporting in Nigeria. South African Journal of
Accounting Research 28: 65–77. [CrossRef]
Eisenberg, Theodore, Stefan Sundgren, and Martin T. Wells. 1998. Larger Board Size and Decreasing Firm Value in
Small Firms. Journal of Financial Economics 48: 35–54. [CrossRef]
Elsaid, Eahab, and Nancy D. Ursel. 2011. CEO succession, gender and risk taking. Gender in Management:
An International Journal 26: 499–512.
Falato, Antonio, Dalida Kadyrzhanova, and Ugur Lel. 2014. Distracted directors: Does board busyness hurt
shareholder value? Journal of Financial Economics 113: 404–26.
Fama, Eugene F., and Michael C. Jensen. 1983. Agency Problems and Residual Claims. Journal of Law and Economics
26: 327–49. [CrossRef]
Fondas, Nanette. 2000. Women on boards of directors: Gender bias or power threat. In Women on Corporate Boards
of Directors: International Challenges and Opportunities. Edited by Ronald J. Burke and Mary C. Mattis. Berlin:
Springer, pp. 171–77.
Gabrielsson, Jonas. 2007. Correlates of board empowerment in small companies. Entrepreneurship Theory
and Practice 31: 687–711.
Gabrielsson, Jonas, and Morten Huse. 2005. Outside directors in SME boards: A call for theoretical reflections.
Corporate Board: Role, Duties and Composition 1: 28–37.
Glover, Saundra H., Minnette A. Bumpus, Glynda F. Sharp, and George A. Munchus. 2002. Gender differences in
ethical decision making. Women in Management Review 17: 217–27.
Hambrick, Donald C. 2007. Upper echelons theory: An update. Academy of Management Review 32: 334–43.
[CrossRef]
Hambrick, Donald C., and Gregory D. S. Fukutomi. 1991. The seasons of a CEO’s tenure. Academy of
Management Review 16: 719–42.
Hambrick, Donald C., and Phyllis A. Mason. 1984. Upper echelons: The organization as a reflection of its top
managers. Academy of Management Review 9: 193–206.
Harris, Ira C., and Katsuhiko Shimizu. 2004. Too busy to serve? An examination of the influence of overboarded
directors. Journal of Management Studies 41: 775–98. [CrossRef]
Hermalin, Benjamin E., and Michael S. Weisbach. 2007. Transparency and Corporate Governance. NBER Working
Paper Series, #12875; Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Hermalin, Benjamin E., and Michael S. Weisbach. 2012. Information disclosure and corporate governance.
Journal of Finance 67: 195–233. [CrossRef]
Hiebl, Martin R. W. 2014. Upper echelons theory in management accounting and control research. Journal of
Management Control 24: 223–40. [CrossRef]
Hillman, Amy J., Christine Shropshire, and Albert A. Cannella, Jr. 2007. Organizational predictors of women on
corporate boards. Academy of Management Journal 50: 941–52. [CrossRef]
Ho, Simon S.M., Annie Y. Li, Kinsun Tam, and Feida Zhang. 2015. CEO gender, ethical leadership, and accounting
conservatism. Journal of Business Ethics 127: 351–70. [CrossRef]
Höglund, Henrik, and Dennis Sundvik. 2019. Do auditors constrain intertemporal income shifting in private
companies? Accounting and Business Research 49: 245–70. [CrossRef]

354
JRFM 2020, 13, 230

Hoskisson, Robert E., Richard A. Johnson, and Douglas D. Moesel. 1994. Corporate Divestiture Intensity in
Restructuring Firms: Effects of Governance, Strategy, and Performance. Academy of Management Journal
37: 1207–52.
Hoskisson, Robert E., Francesco Chirico, Jinyong Zyung, and Eni Gambeta. 2017. Managerial risk taking:
A multitheoretical review and future research agenda. Journal of Management 43: 137–69. [CrossRef]
Huse, Morten. 2000. Boards of directors in SMEs: A review and research agenda. Entrepreneurship and Regional
Development 12: 271–90. [CrossRef]
Huse, Morten. 2007. Boards, Governance and Value Creation: The Human Side of Corporate Governance. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Jensen, Michael C., and William H. Meckling. 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial behaviour, agency costs and
ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3: 305–60.
Jianakoplos, Nancy A., and Alexandra Bernasek. 1998. Are women more risk averse? Economic Inquiry 36: 620–30.
[CrossRef]
Jiraporn, Pornsit, Manohar Singh, and Chun I. Lee. 2009. Ineffective corporate governance: Director busyness and
board committee memberships. Journal of Banking & Finance 33: 819–28.
Johnson, Scott G., Karen Schnatterly, and Aaron D. Hill. 2013. Board composition beyond independence:
Social capital, human capital, and demographics. Journal of Management 39: 232–62. [CrossRef]
Kanadli, Sadi B., Mariateresa Torchia, and Patricia Gabaldon. 2018. Increasing women’s contribution
on board decision making: The importance of chairperson leadership efficacy and board openness.
European Management Journal 36: 91–104. [CrossRef]
Kiel, Geoffrey C., and Gavin J. Nicholson. 2003. Board composition and corporate performance: How the Australian
experience informs contrasting theories of corporate governance. Corporate Governance: An International
Review 11: 189–205. [CrossRef]
Krishnan, Gopal V., and Linda M. Parsons. 2008. Getting to the bottom line: An exploration of gender and
earnings quality. Journal of Business Ethics 78: 65–76. [CrossRef]
La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny. 1999. The quality of
government. The Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 15: 222–79. [CrossRef]
Larkin, Joseph M. 2000. The ability of internal auditors to identify ethical dilemmas. Journal of Business Ethics
23: 401–9. [CrossRef]
Li, Hezun, Siri Terjesen, and Timurs Umans. 2020. Corporate governance in entrepreneurial firms: A systematic
review and research agenda. Small Business Economics 54: 43–74. [CrossRef]
Liao, Lin, Le Luo, and Qingliang Tang. 2015. Gender diversity, board independence, environmental committee
and greenhouse gas disclosure. The British Accounting Review 47: 409–24. [CrossRef]
Lim, Mable, Janice How, and Peter Verhoeven. 2014. Corporate ownership, corporate governance reform and
timeliness of earnings: Malaysian evidence. Journal of Contemporary Accounting & Economics 10: 32–45.
Linck, James S., Jeffry M. Netter, and Tina Yang. 2008. The determinants of board structure. Journal of Financial
Economics 87: 308–28. [CrossRef]
Liu, Mingzhi, Yulin Shi, Craig Wilson, and Zhenyu Wu. 2017. Does family involvement explain why corporate
social responsibility affects earnings management? Journal of Business Research 75: 8–16. [CrossRef]
Lukason, Oliver. 2013. Firm bankruptcies and violations of law: An analysis of different offences. In Dishonesty
in Management: Manifestations and Consequences. Edited by Tiia Vissak and Maaja Vadi. Bingley: Emerald,
pp. 127–46.
Lukason, Oliver, and Maria-del-Mar Camacho-Miñano. 2019. Bankruptcy risk, its financial determinants and
reporting delays: Do managers have anything to hide? Risks 7: 77. [CrossRef]
Luypaert, Mathieu, Tom Van Caneghem, and Steve Van Uytbergen. 2016. Financial statement filing lags:
An empirical analysis among small firms. International Small Business Journal 34: 506–31. [CrossRef]
MacCrimmon, Kenneth R., and Donald A. Wehrung. 1990. Characteristics of risk taking executives.
Management Science 36: 422–35. [CrossRef]
May, Don O. 1995. Do managerial motives influence firm risk reduction strategies? Journal of Finance 50: 1291–308.
[CrossRef]
Miller, Danny, and Jamal Shamsie. 2001. Learning across the life cycle: Experimentation and performance among
the Hollywood studio heads. Strategic Management Journal 22: 725–45. [CrossRef]

355
JRFM 2020, 13, 230

Nguyen, Pascal. 2011. Corporate governance and risk-taking: Evidence from Japanese firms. Pacific-Basin
Finance Journal 19: 278–97. [CrossRef]
Nicholson, Gavin J., and Geoffrey C. Kiel. 2007. Can directors impact performance? A case-based test of three
theories of corporate governance. Corporate Governance: An International Review 15: 585–608. [CrossRef]
Nielsen, Sabina. 2010. Top management team diversity: A review of theories and methodologies.
International Journal of Management Reviews 12: 301–16. [CrossRef]
Nielsen, Sabina, and Morten Huse. 2010. Women directors’ contribution to board decision-making and strategic
involvement: The role of equality perception. European Management Review 7: 16–29. [CrossRef]
Ortiz-de-Mandojana, Natalia, Pratima Bansal, and J. Alberto Aragón-Correa. 2018. Older and Wiser: How
CEOs’ Time Perspective Influences Long-Term Investments in Environmentally Responsible Technologies.
British Journal of Management 30: 134–50. [CrossRef]
Ortiz-Molina, Hernan, and Maria F. Penas. 2008. Lending to small businesses: The role of loan maturity in
addressing information problems. Small Business Economics 30: 361–83. [CrossRef]
Östberg, Per. 2006. Disclosure, investment and regulation. Journal of Financial Intermediation 15: 285–306. [CrossRef]
Owusu-Ansah, Stephen, and Stergios Leventis. 2006. Timeliness of corporate annual financial reporting in Greece.
European Accounting Review 15: 273–87. [CrossRef]
Parsa, Sepideh, Gin Chong, and Ewere Isimoya. 2007. Disclosure of governance information by small and
medium-sized companies. Corporate Governance: The International Journal of Business in Society 7: 635–48.
[CrossRef]
Peek, Erik, Rick Cuijpers, and Willem Buijink. 2010. Creditors’ and shareholders’ reporting demands in public
versus private firms: Evidence from Europe. Contemporary Accounting Research 27: 49–91. [CrossRef]
Pfeffer, Jeffrey, and Gerald R. Salancik. 2003. The External Control of Organizations: A Resource Dependence Perspective.
Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Plöckinger, Martin, Ewald Aschauer, Martin R.W. Hiebl, and Roman Rohatschek. 2016. The influence of individual
executives on corporate financial reporting: A review and outlook from the perspective of upper echelons
theory. Journal of Accounting Literature 37: 55–75. [CrossRef]
Post, Corinne, and Kris Byron. 2015. Women on boards and firm financial performance: A meta-analysis.
Academy of Management Journal 58: 1546–71. [CrossRef]
Prior, Diego, Jordi Surroca, and Josep A. Tribó. 2008. Are socially responsible managers really ethical? Exploring
the relationship between earnings management and corporate social responsibility. Corporate Governance:
An International Review 16: 160–77. [CrossRef]
Saona, Paolo, Laura Muro, Pablo San Martín, and Hugo Baier-Fuentes. 2018. Board of Director Gender
Diversity and Its Impact on Earnings Management: An Empirical Analysis for Selected European Firms.
Technological and Economic Development of Economy 25: 634–63. [CrossRef]
Saxena, Anand, and Rajni Jagota. 2015. Should SMEs be governed the corporate governance way? Indian Journal
of Corporate Governance 8: 54–67. [CrossRef]
Scholtens, Bert, and Feng-Ching Kang. 2013. Corporate social responsibility and earnings management: Evidence
from Asian economies. Corporate Social Responsibility and Environmental Management 20: 95–112. [CrossRef]
Schrand, Catherine M., and Sarah L.C. Zechman. 2012. Executive overconfidence and the slippery slope to
financial misreporting. Journal of Accounting and Economics 53: 311–29. [CrossRef]
Serwinek, Paul J. 1992. Demographic and Related Differences in Ethical Views among Small Businesses. Journal of
Business Ethics 11: 555–66. [CrossRef]
Shehata, Nermeen, Ahmed Salhin, and Moataz El-Helaly. 2017. Board diversity and firm performance:
Evidence from the U.K. SMEs. Applied Economics 49: 4817–32. [CrossRef]
Singhvi, Surendra S., and Harsha B. Desai. 1971. An empirical analysis of the quality of corporate financial
disclosure. The Accounting Review 46: 129–38.
Spiers, Leslie. 2017. Corporate Governance, Risk and Crises in Small Companies: Shedding light from inside the
boardroom black box. Economics and Business Review 3: 112–26. [CrossRef]
Spiers, Leslie. 2018. Corporate Governance and Its Contribution to Risk and Crisis Management in Small
Companies. Ph.D. dissertation, Bournemouth University, Bournemouth, UK.
Troy, Carmelita, Ken G. Smith, and Madeline A. Domino. 2011. CEO demographics and accounting fraud: Who is
more likely to rationalize illegal acts? Strategic Organization 9: 259–82. [CrossRef]

356
JRFM 2020, 13, 230

Uhlaner, Lorraine, Mike Wright, and Morten Huse. 2007. Private firms and corporate governance: An integrated
economic and management perspective. Small Business Economics 29: 225–41. [CrossRef]
Vafeas, Nikos. 2003. Length of board tenure and outside director independence. Journal of Business Finance &
Accounting 30: 1043–64.
Voordeckers, Wim, Anita Van Gils, Jonas Gabrielsson, Diamanto Politis, and Morten Huse. 2014. Board structures
and board behaviour: A cross-country comparison of privately held SMEs in Belgium, the Netherlands and
Norway. International Journal of Business Governance and Ethics 9: 197–219. [CrossRef]
Wahn, Judy. 2003. Sex differences in competitive and compliant unethical work behavior. Journal of Business
and Psychology 18: 121–28. [CrossRef]
Willekens, Marleen, Heidi V. Bauwhede, Ann Gaeremynck, and Linda van de Gucht. 2005. The Impact of
Internal and External Governance Mechanisms on the Voluntary Disclosure of Financial and Non-Financial
Performance. In BAA Auditing Research Conference. Birmingham: Aston Business School.
Yermack, David. 1996. Higher market valuation of companies with a small board of directors. Journal of
Financial Economics 40: 185–211. [CrossRef]
Zajac, Edward J., and James D. Westphal. 1996. Director reputation, CEO-board power, and the dynamics of board
interlocks. Administrative Science Quarterly 41: 507–29. [CrossRef]
Zona, Fabio. 2015. Board ownership and processes in family firms. Small Business Economics 44: 105–22. [CrossRef]

© 2020 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access
article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution
(CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).

357
Journal of
Risk and Financial
Management

Article
Does Corporate Governance Compliance Increase
Company Value? Evidence from the Best Practice
of the Board
Maria Aluchna 1, * and Tomasz Kuszewski 2
1 Department of Management Theory, Warsaw School of Economics, aleja Niepodleglosci 162,
02-554 Warsaw, Poland
2 College of Economic Analysis, University of Economics and Human Sciences in Warsaw, ul. Okopowa 59,
01-043 Warsaw, Poland; t.kuszewski@vizja.pl
* Correspondence: maria.aluchna@sgh.waw.pl; Tel.: +48-22-564-86-20

Received: 20 August 2020; Accepted: 11 October 2020; Published: 15 October 2020

Abstract: Drawing upon agency theory, we address the limitations of best practice code in the
context of emerging governance, emphasizing the role of concentrated ownership. While the code
provisions were formulated in developed countries, the transfer of one-size-fits-all guidelines may
not address the characteristics and challenges of emerging and post-transition economies. Specifically,
we emphasize that provisions of corporate governance codes are aimed at solving the principal–agent
conflict between shareholders and managers. These guidelines may remain limited in addressing
principal–principal conflicts between majority and minority shareholders and have either a lesser
effect on valuation or none at all. Using a unique sample of 155 companies listed on the Warsaw Stock
Exchange during the period 2006–2015, with hand-collected data from declarations of conformity,
we tested the hypotheses on the link between corporate governance compliance (with board) practice
and company value. The period of 2006–2015 was chosen deliberately, due to the relative stability of
corporate governance code recommendations over this time. The results of our panel model reveal a
negative and statistically significant relation between corporate governance compliance and company
value. We contribute to the existing literature providing new evidence on compliance practice in the
context of concentrated ownership, and the limited effect of code provisions in addressing structural
challenges of corporate governance in emerging post-transition economies and hierarchy-based
control systems.

Keywords: corporate governance best practice; corporate governance compliance; company value;
Warsaw Stock Exchange

1. Introduction
The adoption of best practice codes has been one of the most influential trends in corporate
governance in the last 20 years (Aguilera and Cuervo-Cazura 2004; Zattoni and Cuomo 2008;
Cuomo et al. 2016), being noted in both developed and emerging economies. Conceptually, codes of
best practice offer self-regulation for companies (Hooghiemstra and van Ees 2011) and aim to resolve the
inherent principal–agent conflict, strengthen monitoring tools over management and limit the power
of corporate officials (Pritchett 1983). As a result, corporate governance guidelines reduce information
asymmetry, empower shareholders, and lower agency costs (Chang 2018). Despite institutional
differences across corporate governance regimes, the code provisions remain similar (Cicon et al. 2012;
OECD 2015). In practice, the set of recommendations on board work, and the structure of executive
remuneration and standards of transparency have been viewed as a systemic response to corporate
governance inefficiencies identified during disruptive corporate scandals (Aguilera et al. 2009; Krenn 2015).

JRFM 2020, 13, 242; doi:10.3390/jrfm13100242 359 www.mdpi.com/journal/jrfm


JRFM 2020, 13, 242

Prior studies identify the value added by the adoption of best practice. The positive effects for those
companies complying with corporate governance principles relate to increased investor trust and lower
risk (Durnev and Kim 2005). With greater transparency, investors are more interested in allocating their
funds in company stocks. Compliance also leads to enhanced company reputation, lower cost of capital,
better performance, higher return on investment, and higher market valuation (Mazotta and Veltri 2014;
Kaspereit et al. 2017). Nevertheless, despite the belief in the positive effect of higher compliance,
scholars have addressed limitations in the transfer of Anglo-Saxon corporate governance guidelines to
countries having different institutional environments and company characteristics (Chen et al. 2011).
The criticism of the one-size fits-all approach indicates the structural differences in ownership structure,
cultural norms, and socializing patterns, which may result in problems of code implementation, such as an
instrumental approach to adoption (Fotaki et al. 2019), manipulation (Okhmatovskiy and David 2012),
and decoupling (Martin 2010; Sobhan 2016). These issues may reduce compliance benefits and limit
the effect of higher valuations.
In countries characterized by concentrated ownership and wedge between control and cash-flow
rights, the conflicts between majority and minority shareholders become the prime concern of
corporate governance (La Porta et al. 1999; Bennedsen and Nielsen 2010; Hamadi and Heinen 2015;
Huu Nguyen et al. 2020). While the flexibility of the codes and the universalism of best practice enable
the adoption of code guidelines for a concentrated ownership environment, in compliance terms,
it remains the decision of powerful blockholders as to whether they constrain themselves in exerting their
power over the company and their willingness to share “control of control” (Perezts and Picard 2015).
The gap between “formal adoption of structures and their actual daily use” (Perezts and Picard 2015,
p. 833) or the lack of congruence between enacted values and espoused values (Fotaki et al. 2019)
are more likely to occur in countries with insufficient investor protection, inadequate transparency
standards, and weak institutions. These conditions, accompanied with ownership concentration,
happen to materialize in developing countries, as well as emerging and post-transition economies
(Huu Nguyen et al. 2020). Implementing codes of best practice in the context of what is termed
“emerging governance” reveals a different logic, since “arrangements adapt and evolve over time”, as a
result of “the co-habitation of different institutional, regal and ownership tradition and assumptions
from more established governance models” (Mahadeo and Soobaroyen 2016, pp. 739–40).
In this paper, we aim to add to the existing literature on corporate governance compliance in
developing and emerging markets (Outa and Waweru 2016; Sarhan and Ntim 2018), in addition to
smaller economies (Chang 2018), and to deliver insights on the implementation of best practice codes in a
post-transition and post-communist economy (Okhmatovskiy and David 2012; Albu and Girbina 2015).
In this light, we pose a question concerning the market valuation effect for the implementation of best
practice codes. Drawing upon agency theory, we address the limitations of best practice codes in an
emerging governance context, emphasizing the role of concentrated ownership. While the existing
literature emphasizes that the prime objective of best practice implementation lies in creating conditions
to attract investors to invest funds (Chang 2018), the reality of operating in the context of concentrated
ownership may offer different incentives for blockholders (Chen et al. 2011). Compliance per se may
be seen in terms of a cost, a loss of power, or a threat from the exposure of internal structure to the
scrutiny of the general public. We study the link between compliance practice and company value in
relation to ownership concentration and ownership by distinct shareholder types, including financial,
individual, industry, CEO, and state.
The contribution of the paper is twofold. Firstly, we provide much-needed evidence on longitudinal
compliance practice in an unfavorable environment of insufficient investor protection, concentrated
ownership, and a hierarchy-based corporate governance system under a post-communist legacy.
We study the scope and dynamics of compliance with best practice in the context of reemerging
trust and civic society, yet where institutions and the legal system are still insufficiently effective.
Secondly, developing further the approach proposed by Chen et al. (2011) on the limitations of best

360
JRFM 2020, 13, 242

practice adoption in emerging markets, we analyze the relations between compliance practices and
company value.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. First, we outline the concept of corporate
governance best practice by recourse to agency theory, which explains the motivation for compliance.
We explain practices by listed companies in the context of emerging governance, concentrated
ownership, and a hierarchy-based control system. Then, we present prior studies on the relations
between corporate governance compliance and company value and performance. This is followed
by a presentation of our research design, presenting our study sample, data collection, descriptive
statistics, and econometric models. Our analysis is based on a sample of 155 companies listed on the
Warsaw Stock Exchange in the years 2006–2015. The period of 2006–2015 was chosen deliberately, due
to the relative stability of corporate governance code recommendations. Our findings suggest that
implementing new corporate governance practice is an incremental process. Descriptive statistics are
consistent with prior studies on emerging and post-transition countries and demonstrate a slow but
steady increase in the number of complying companies, though still lagging behind well-established
economies (Albu and Girbina 2015; Chang 2018). The results of the constructed models reveal a
statistically significant and negative relationship between all three constructed measures of compliance
and firm value as measured by Tobin’s Q. We discuss implications for theory and practice and formulate
suggestions for further research in the final sections.

2. Corporate Governance Best Practice

2.1. Corporate Governance Code in the View of Theory


The existing literature analyzes corporate governance from the perspective of inherent conflicts
which exist in the organization context and are explained by agency theory (Fama and Jensen 1983;
Shleifer and Vishny 1997). According to agency theory, the conflict between shareholders and
managers arises from the separation of ownership and control (Jensen and Meckling 1976),
observed predominantly in the context of dispersed ownership structure. The principal–agent conflict,
known as the agency conflict of type I, refers to information asymmetry and differences in time horizon
and risk diversification opportunities, which characterize the relation between shareholders and managers
(Jensen and Meckling 1976). The theory explains that managers may have the tendency of maximizing
their own wealth, acting at the cost of shareholders (Fama and Jensen 1983; Shleifer and Vishny 1997).
Given that dispersed ownership, which offers an ideal environment for the emergence of
principal–agent conflict, remains in a global context more the exception than the rule (La Porta et al. 1999)
more interest in corporate governance studies has been devoted to concentrated ownership
(Su et al. 2008; Loyola and Portila 2019). While concentrated ownership provides a natural mechanism
for mitigating principal–agent conflict (Coffee 1999; Berglöf and Claessens 2006), it leads to the
emergence of the agency conflict type II, which refers to the relations between majority and minority
shareholders (Wang and Shailer 2015; Edmans 2014; Khan et al. 2020). Principal–principal conflicts
materialize in the majority shareholders’ actions related to investment and dividend policy, in order
to enjoy private benefits (Gilson and Schwartz 2013) and to extract value from the company at the
expense of minority investors (Krivogorsky and Burton 2012; Wang and Shailer 2015). In addition,
majority investors tend to appoint their own representatives to the board to limit the access to
information and decision-making for minority investors (Shleifer and Vishny 1997).
Agency conflicts are inherent in organizations and remain naturally linked to more complex ownership
structures characterized by the presence of shareholders who differ in terms of their type (industry, family,
and financial), as well as the size and the time horizon of their investment (Hamadi and Heinen 2015).
In reaction to these conflicts, corporate governance offers a set of mechanisms and institutions for
reducing potential problems by aligning the interests of managers with the interests of shareholders
and by aligning interests of majority and minority shareholders. This alignment can be exerted with
monitoring and incentive schemes. Monitoring exercised by internal forces, such as ownership, board

361
JRFM 2020, 13, 242

composition, and structure, and by external mechanisms, including markets for corporate control,
competitive labor markets, shareholder activism, rating agencies, and media (Aguilera et al. 2015;
Elgharbawy and Abdel-Kader 2016) is expected to reduce agency conflicts. Despite ongoing efforts to
formulate and enforce principles, “effective corporate governance still remains a puzzle for practice
and research” (Fotaki et al. 2019, p. 1).
Best practice codes offer corporate governance principles on oversight and control over the firm
(Cuervo 2002; Aguilera and Cuervo-Cazura 2004; Chizema 2008; Tricker 2012). The best practice
concept assumes voluntary adoption according to the comply or explain rule, providing flexibility in
terms of scope and pace for implementing code recommendations (Tan 2018). It is viewed an example
of self-regulation of listed companies (Hooghiemstra and van Ees 2011). The codes address selected
dimensions of corporate governance, such as functioning of the board, shareholder rights, transparency,
auditing, and remuneration (OECD 2015), and they are designed to provide principles and norms for
creating shareholder value (Mallin 2004). The codes offer widely recognized and accepted guidelines
for addressing governance inefficiencies (Lipman 2007; Arcot et al. 2010; Tricker 2012) and are often
inspired by international organizations, such as the OECD, or regulatory and supervision authorities,
such as the European Commission (e.g., the European Commission Communication 284 to the European
Council and the European Parliament) or the US Securities and Exchange Commission.
In the conceptual framework of agency theory, the adoption of code provisions is expected to mitigate
information asymmetry and reduce conflicts between shareholders and managers. Increasing disclosure
and addressing the problems of hidden action, hidden information, and hidden intention compliance
lower investment risk and enhance investor trust (Durnev and Kim 2005; (Mazotta and Veltri 2014;
Kaspereit et al. 2017). In the context of ownership concentration, majority shareholders may be
motivated for compliance by the assumption that their interests are “interchangeably merged with the
interests of the corporate entity and whatever is good for the society must be good for the corporation
in the long run” (Pritchett 1983, p. 997). This resonates in the commitment to adopt the rules of
fairness, an ethical stance which is in the best interests of the company. Blockholders may decide to
voluntarily constrain themselves in exerting their power over the company and by their willingness
to share “control of control” (Perezts and Picard 2015), driven by the notion that “corporate actions
are related to long run corporate benefit and there is no taint of self-dealing or conflict of interests”
(Pritchett 1983, p. 997).
Implementing the code is driven by numerous reasons. Firstly, the idea of self-regulation and “soft
law” provided by the code assumes that the market monitors compliance. This means that investors
express their acceptance of conformity with the code via increasing their holdings of a company’s shares,
leading to an increase of company value (Gompers et al. 2003; Black et al. 2006; Goncharov et al. 2006;
Renders et al. 2010). Consequently, investors penalize non-complying companies through selling their
shares (Easterbrook and Fischel 1996).
Secondly, the code principles are formulated according to the needs and interests of institutional
investors, for whom high conformity translates into high trust towards the company management
(Arcot et al. 2010). Compliance with internationally recognized and easily comparable standards
increases transparency and lowers the risk associated with firm operation (Bistrowa and Lace 2012).
In a sense, greater compliance is understood as higher protection of shareholder interest.
Thirdly, corporate governance conformity not only aims to develop efficient monitoring and
oversight to protect shareholder value, but also aims to legitimize the presence of the firm on the stock
market. Competition between companies to attract investors and raise funds for growth generates
coercive or normative imitation (Guler et al. 2002). According to the legitimization perspective,
companies implement new practices in order to enjoy the benefits of meeting social expectations.
“If practices become institutionalized, their adoption brings legitimization to the adopting organization
or social system” (Aguilera and Cuervo-Cazura 2004, p. 422). Firms are differently motivated to comply
with best practice, and such conformity does not necessarily result in greater efficiency or effectiveness.
The declaration of conformity issued by listed companies may either fail to lead to better performance or

362
JRFM 2020, 13, 242

higher firm value, or else it may not necessarily be motivated by the strategy of increasing shareholder
value. Instead, compliance may be a product of the endogenously determined structure of internal
firm governance or result from isomorphic dynamics driven by the firm’s legitimization policy
(Hermalin and Weisbach 2003).
In sum, according to agency theory, firms operate in an economically rational way and search
for practices and organizational solutions that improve performance with respect to resources utilized
and effectiveness (Williamson 1981). Thus, the decisions on corporate governance compliance and
the implementation of best practice are undertaken for the purpose of obtaining efficiency gains
(Aguilera and Cuervo-Cazura 2004). The process of innovation diffusion introduces new solutions,
improves company performance, and is driven by technical and rational needs (Zattoni and Cuomo 2008).
It is motivated by rational arguments and is expected to improve company efficiency. Thus,
well-performing companies which previously met shareholder expectations with respect to financial
results, share price, and company value are more responsive to formal requirements and shareholder
expectations with respect to the board’s functioning, structure, and composition, as well as transparency
standards and remuneration policy. Compliance with the code recommendations constitutes a signal
for investors that the firm, its executives, and board directors aim at protecting shareholder interests
and endeavor to enhance shareholder value (Hermes et al. 2007).

2.2. Corporate Governance Code and Company Value


Studies on corporate governance compliance offer a wide range of qualitative and quantitative analyses
revealing the degree, scope, and dynamics of compliance (Seidl et al. 2013; Shrives and Brennan 2015;
Okhmatovskiy 2017), in addition to its relation to company performance and value (Stiglbauer and Velte
2014; Rose 2016; Roy and Pay 2017). Conceptually, studies are based on the assumption that companies
with poor corporate governance should have lower valuations in comparison to companies with effective
corporate governance, since investors do not tolerate higher risk of expropriation without receiving a
premium for such investments (Gompers et al. 2003; Goncharov et al. 2006). A positive link between
the quality of governance and performance is observed in studies on European (Drobetz et al. 2003;
Gompers et al. 2003; Bauer et al. 2004; Goncharov et al. 2006; Renders et al. 2010; Bistrowa and Lace
2012), Japanese (Aman and Nguyen 2007), and American (Bhagat and Bolton 2008) companies.
Specifically, a series of studies analyze the dynamics of compliance with corporate governance codes
and the link between the compliance and firm performance. Goncharov et al. (2006) examine the declared
degree of compliance for a sample of German DAX30 and MDAX listed firms and find that “the compliance
with the Code is value-relevant after controlling for endogeneity bias” (Goncharov et al. 2006, p. 432).
Research on a sample of 140 German companies reveals that companies with a higher value of Tobin’s
Q are more likely to comply with the recommendation on disclosing the remuneration schemes of
individual directors (Andres and Theissen 2008). A study on a large sample of 1199 observations on
FTSE companies and 33,667 observations of Worldscope firms (Renders et al. 2010) shows that—when
controlling for endogeneity by introducing instrumental variables and eliminating the sample selection
bias—there is a positive link between the quality of corporate governance (measured by the rating
variable) and company performance. The strength of this relationship depends on the quality of the
institutional environment, while “improvements in corporate governance ratings over time result
in decreasing marginal benefits in terms of performance” (Renders et al. 2010, p. 87). A positive
link between company performance measured by return of equity (ROE) and return on assets (ROA)
indicators and total corporate governance comply or explain disclosure scores is noted in a sample of
Danish firms (Rose 2016). This study indicates a positive effect for two categories: board composition
and remuneration policy, while no impact on performance is reported for increasing compliance with
the recommendations on risk management and internal controls.
Similar results are shown in a study on the impact of corporate governance quality on stock
performance in a sample of 116 firms from 10 Central and Eastern European countries for the period of
2008–2010 (Bistrowa and Lace 2012). Based on the model rating, the firms characterized by the highest

363
JRFM 2020, 13, 242

corporate governance quality (top 25%) outperformed companies with the worst corporate governance
quality (bottom 25%) by 0.98% on a monthly basis.
Although studies document a positive association between corporate governance compliance
and firm value and performance (Goncharov et al. 2006; Renders et al. 2010; Rose 2016), the opposite
may also be true (Bhagat and Black 2002). The assumed effect referring to higher company valuation,
increased legitimization towards constituencies, and positive ethical spillovers may be constrained by
a number of reasons. Firstly, the pricing effect takes place when investors believe in the reliability of
information provided by firms to the market. This may not necessarily be the case, as the declaration of
conformity is neither verified nor audited. Moreover, companies may choose to comply with provisions
which are either relatively easy to follow or which appear useless from an investor standpoint
(Goncharov et al. 2006; Sobhan 2016).
Secondly, the voluntary approach to compliance and the absence of enforcement mechanisms
may lower the credibility of the conformity statement and may weaken the positive economic
consequences (Healy and Palepu 2001; Goncharov et al. 2006). With the given institutional
and ownership characteristics in emerging and post-transition economies, codes of best practice
aim to resolve the inherent principal–principal conflict and add to the protection of minority
investors (Mahadeo and Soobaroyen 2016). In spite of this, “publicly mandated commitment to
corporate governance, business ethics and legal compliance” (Adelstein and Clegg 2016) is significantly
constrained. Insufficient enforcement mechanisms, combined with institutional skepticism, increases
“the declarative and instrumental use of corporate governance structures and their actual daily use”
(Perezts and Picard 2015, p. 833). This can lead, as shown in a study on Hungary, to a “disjuncture
between formal commitment to code adoption and its effective implementation” (Martin 2010, p. 145).
Therefore, the effective implementation of codes of best practice depends on the perceived benefits and
costs by majority shareholders.
Thirdly, compliance with the code guidelines may be viewed as explicit information on
the corporate governance structure and standards for board functioning and investor protection.
The declaration of conformity issued by listed companies may either not lead to better performance or
higher firm value or not necessarily be motivated by a strategy of increasing shareholder value. Instead,
compliance may be a product of the endogenously determined structure of internal firm governance or
result from the isomorphic dynamics driven by company legitimization policy. Research reveals the
impact of endogeneity in the process of board formation and monitoring (Hermalin and Weisbach 2003).
The legitimacy driven effect should be particularly strong for poorly performing companies, which,
by publishing a declaration of corporate governance conformity, intend to compensate shareholders
reacting to unsatisfying financial results.
Fourthly, while we acknowledge the contribution of agency theory, we also consider the limitations
of the rationale approach to corporate governance compliance. Since legitimacy is crucial for
organization survival, as it provides access to resources from the environment (Deephouse 1996;
Mizruchi and Fein 1999), companies may be “prone to construct stories about their actions that
correspond to socially prescribed dictates about what organization should do” (Mizruchi and Fein 1999,
p. 656). In addition, companies may tend to declare adherence with corporate governance principles
without any substantive compliance.
Fifthly, legitimacy motivation is observed in many companies, regardless of the country of origin
or operation. However, in the context of weaker institutions and insufficient investor protection, this
declarative character (Okhmatovskiy 2017), overstatement (Sobhan 2016) or instrumental approach
(Fotaki et al. 2019) to compliance may result in no effect on market valuation (Gherghina 2015).
We follow the approach proposed by Chen et al. (2011), who argue that the provisions of corporate
governance codes are designed around companies in developed economies. They suggest that best
practice “cannot mitigate the negative effect of controlling-shareholder expropriation on corporate
performance” (Chen et al. 2011, p. 115). This is caused by two main limitations. Firstly, code provisions
are designed to solve type I principal–agent problems between shareholders and managers, while they

364
JRFM 2020, 13, 242

do not address conflicts between majority and minority shareholders. Secondly, the core of best practice
code lies in the guidelines on board structure and operation, which structurally will not be implemented
in a concentrated ownership context since majority shareholders appoint their own representatives
to the board (Shleifer and Vishny 1997; Ferrarini and Filippelli 2013; Gaur et al. 2015). Put differently,
not only are the code provisions not substantively implemented by boards, but they also fail to respond
to the structural problems and challenges of corporate governance in emerging economies. Investors
do not observe positive effects with regard to lower asymmetry, lower risk, or more efficient oversight;
thus, there is no resulting higher valuation. In sum, recognizing the limitations of corporate governance
codes in the context of concentrated ownership, we formulate the following hypotheses:

Hypothesis 1a (H1a). Formal compliance with board best practice is negatively associated with firm value.

Hypothesis 1b (H1b). Minimum compliance with board best practice is negatively associated with firm value.

Hypothesis 1c (H1c). Substantive compliance with board best practice is negatively associated with firm value.

3. Research Design

3.1. Sample and Data Collection


We intended to test the hypothesis regarding the link between compliance with best practice
and company value on a unique sample of companies listed on the Warsaw Stock Exchange over
a long period, during which corporate governance conformity evolves and gradually becomes
institutionalized. We purposefully choose sample companies listed over a 10-year period (2006–2015)
that are characterized by their relative stability of corporate governance code recommendations.
We constructed a balanced panel to investigate companies which were listed over the whole period
of our analysis and reveal similar attributes with regard to corporate governance practice. Over the
analyzed period, the numbers of companies listed on the Warsaw Stock Exchange varied due to initial
public offerings (POs) and delisting, as reported in Table 1.

Table 1. Number of companies listed on the Warsaw Stock Exchange.

Years 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015
Listed companies 284 351 374 379 400 426 438 450 471 487
Initial public offerings (IPOs) 38 81 33 13 34 38 19 23 28 30
Delisted firms 9 14 10 8 13 12 7 11 8 13
Source: GPW, www.gpw.pl/statystyki.

We start with 284 firms quoted on the Warsaw Stock Exchange in 2006. We eliminate companies
operating in the insurance sector, real estate firms, companies with missing observations and those delisted
over the analyzed period. Our final sample consists of a balanced panel with 155 companies and 1550
observations. We collect data on company financial characteristics and performance, company value,
and ownership structure from the IQ Capital data base. Prior research emphasizes the essential
role of the board for mitigating agency costs, for attaining sufficient quality in corporate governance
(Khan et al. 2020). Data on compliance include the conformity—or the lack thereof—of a given
company with best practice on the following: the presence of two independent directors, information
concerning the identification of independent board members, the presence of an independent board
chairman, and the formation of an audit committee and remuneration committee on the supervisory
board. Due to the absence of such data in any available database, all information on compliance is
collected by hand directly from annual reports of the companies in the sample. The analyses were
performed, using STATA16 software.

365
JRFM 2020, 13, 242

3.2. Variables
We operationalize our variables, following the research procedures adopted in prior studies. We
employ Tobin’s Q, defined as market value to book value, as our explained variable (Kim et al. 2015).
Compliance with board best practice is our explanatory variable. Due to the essential role of corporate
governance, we focus on compliance with recommendation on the supervisory board (Seidl et al. 2013;
Huu Nguyen et al. 2020). Specifically, we include information on the presence of independent directors
on the board, chairman status, the formation of an audit committee and other committees within
the supervisory board, and publication of the compliance statement included in the annual report
and its size (length). In order to test for the relationship between conformity to best practices and
company value, we introduce three compliance variables: formal compliance (FORMALCOMPL),
minimum compliance (MINCOMPL), and substantive compliance (SUBSTCOMPL). FORMALCOMPL
is constructed as an arithmetic sum of compliance with the best practice on the presence of two
independent directors and the formation of an audit committee and remuneration committee on
the supervisory board. MINCOMPL is defined as the minimum level of compliance and is the
arithmetic sum of compliance with the best practice on the presence of two independent directors
and the formation of audit committee on the supervisory board. SUBSTCOMPL refers to substantive,
pragmatic compliance and is the arithmetic sum of compliance with the best practice on the presence of
two independent directors with the information of board directors who are independent, the presence
of an independent board chairman, and the formation of a separate audit committee and remuneration
committee on the supervisory board. SUBSTCOMPL is a measure which depicts compliance in
substance, rather than its declarative character. Formally, the amendments of the Accounting Act
imposed the obligation to form an audit committee within the supervisory board. According to the
act, in the case of supervisory board with the minimum legal size of 5 directors, the whole board
can function as the committee. We include additional variables which depict (1) whether a company
reports the existence of an audit committee within the board, (2) whether the whole board performs
the function of the audit committee, and (3) whether a separate committee within the board is formed.
Finally, we use control variables on ownership structure, company size, and financial performance. We
operationalize the variables on ownership structure, following prior studies (Thomsen and Pedersen 2000;
Krivogorsky and Burton 2012). Specifically, we use ownership variables on concentration (the largest
shareholder), in addition to the shareholders’ stakes by selected types (financial, foreign, CEO,
and government), to control for the impact of ownership on firm value. In both cases, we measure the
potential effect of ownership concentration and shareholder identity, using the variable of the size of
the stake owned (Krivogorsky and Burton 2012; Florackis et al. 2015). Finally, we use standard control
variables covering the company size (assets and debt) and performance (ROA). The list of variables
used in the analysis is provided in Table 2.

Table 2. Summary of variables.

Variable Description Type


Regressand
ln_Q Natural logarithm of value of Tobin’s Q (market value/book value) Quantitative, real
Regressors
Formal compliance with best practice on the presence of two independent
FORMALCOMPL directors, and the formation of an audit committee and remuneration Quantitative, real
committee on the supervisory board
Minimal compliance with best practice on the presence of two independent
MINCOMPL Quantitative, real
directors, and the formation of an audit committee on the supervisory board

366
JRFM 2020, 13, 242

Table 2. Cont.

Variable Description Type


Substantive compliance with best practice on the presence of two
independent directors with the information who of board directors are
SUBSTCOMPL independent the presence of an independent board chairman, and the Quantitative, real
formation of a separate audit committee and remuneration committee on
the supervisory board
Square root of percentage of company’s shares held by the
FILASHA_sq Quantitative, real
largest shareholder
INSTINV_sq Square root of percentage of company’s shares held by financial investors Quantitative, real
INDUSTINV_sq Square root of percentage of company’s shares held by industry investors Quantitative, real
CEOSHA Percentage of company’s shares held by the CEO Quantitative, real
GOVSHA Percentage of company’s shares held by the government Quantitative, real
ln_ASSETS Natural logarithm of the value of assets (current prices, million PLN) Quantitative, real
ADJ_ROA Sector-adjusted and time-adjusted return of assets ratio (see note below) Quantitative, real
DEBT Debt (current prices, million PLN) Quantitative, real
DEBT_ON_ASSETS Debt versus assets Quantitative, real
Note: The value of return of assets (ROA) variable is the value of the return of assets measure of a company,
adjusted by the year of observation and the sector it operates in (Vintila et al. 2014). This measure is
calculated with the use of the median value of ROA for each sector and year, as follows: ADJ ROAit =


sign(ROAit − median ROASE,t )· ROAit − median ROASE,t , i = 1, . . . , 155; t = 2006, . . . , 2015, where i—number
of the company, SE ∈ {Industry, Services, Construction, Financial}.

3.3. Descriptive Statistics


We transform some variables (as shown in Table 2) into square root or natural logarithm measures
for the purpose of constructing econometric models which allow for economic interpretation. Below we
report the process of variables transformation, presenting natural values of our variables (Tables 3–8).
Table 3 reveals the distribution of our explained variable, Tobin’s Q.

Table 3. Distribution of Tobin’s Q—number of companies and untransformed variables.

Value 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015
(0;1) 13 24 106 57 49 103 96 75 83 83
(1;2) 48 50 29 67 73 42 47 56 46 37
(2;3) 35 29 11 21 25 6 5 14 17 15
(3;4) 24 24 6 5 3 3 2 4 5 9
>4 35 28 3 5 5 1 5 6 4 11

As reported in Table 3, the distributions of Q are one-modal, yet since 2008, they reveal strong
positive asymmetry, which means that, over the analyzed period, there are more years characterized
with a low value of Q than a high one. A more balanced distribution of Q is revealed in the first year
of the analyzed period, while since 2008, we depict the effects of the financial crisis peaking in 2011.
Due to the asymmetric distribution, we analyze the median value of Q, as shown in Table 4.

Table 4. Mean value of Tobin’s Q by sector and year, and untransformed variables.

Sector 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015
Median for industrial companies 2.1 2.0 0.7 1.1 1.4 0.7 0.8 1.2 0.9 0.85
Median for services companies 2.35 1.8 0.8 1.1 1.15 0.75 0.7 0.9 0.9 1.00
Median for construction companies 3.05 2.9 1.45 1.65 1.65 0.7 0.8 0.95 0.9 0.8
Median for financial companies 3.8 4.0 1.3 1.65 1.85 1.35 1.45 1.8 1.7 1.25
Median for all companies 2.5 2.0 0.7 1.2 1.4 0.7 0.8 1.0 0.9 0.9
Arithmetic mean for all companies 3.005 2.597 1.048 1.423 1.546 0.974 1.107 1.369 1.228 1.467

367
JRFM 2020, 13, 242

Table 4 reveals variations of Q in the specified sectors of operation. The maximum values of Q
were noted in the initial years of the analyzed period, with a strong drop in 2008 and some recovery in
2010–2011, followed by a subsequent decline. The recovery of the median Q value in 2013 is mostly
evident for industrial companies. Stagnation is observed for service and construction sectors until
the end of the analyzed period. A similar trend is noted for companies operating in the financial
sector, yet the values of Tobin’s Q remain at the higher level. The differences between the median and
arithmetic mean confirm the expectation of the positive asymmetry of Q.
Next, we investigate the variability of Tobin’s Q over the analyzed period and across the years
under consideration, using the standard deviation and average mean, as presented in Table 5.

Table 5. Variability of Tobin’s Q, and untransformed variables.

Standard Deviation 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015
Overall 1.450
Between 1.976 1.776 0.913 0.916 1.019 0.803 1.063 1.232 1.167 1.597
Between variation coefficient 0.658 0.684 0.871 0.644 0.659 0.824 0.960 0.900 0.950 1.089
Within 1.131
Within variation coefficient 0.376 0.436 1.079 0.795 0.732 1.161 1.022 0.826 0.921 0.771

The between variation coefficient, which measures the variability of Tobin’s Q, has risen since
2009, suggesting the variability of adaptability and capability to survive amongst listed companies.
The within variation coefficient is calculated as the quotient within standard deviation, which remains
stable across time, and the arithmetic mean of Tobin’s Q for the given years (Table 4).
We test the variables used in the econometric analysis, employing the Shapiro–Wilk normality
test (null hypothesis assumes normal distribution of variable) and the Harris–Tzavalis stationarity
test for a balanced panel (null hypothesis assumes the variable has unit root). Tests are run for the
untransformed variables. The results are given in Table 6.

Table 6. Shapiro–Wilk normality test and Harris–Tzavalis stationarity test for variables, and
untransformed variables.

Shapiro–Wilk Test Harris–Tzavalis Test


Variable
Critical Value Prob > z Critical Value p-Value
Q 13.584 0 −17.101 0
FORMALCOMPL 8.449 0 −7.050 0
MINCOMPL 6.352 0 −6.482 0
SUBSTCOMPL 9.784 0 −7.448 0
FILASHA 9.294 0 −13.845 0
INSTINV 9.907 0 −8.602 0
INDUSTINV 9.685 0 −14.422 0
CEOSHA 14.573 0 −8.548 0
GOVSHA 13.670 0 −8.515 0
ASSETS 16.367 0 −9.385 0
ADJ_ROA 7.998 0 −21.974 0
DEBT_ON_ASSETS 12.692 0 −14.598 0

None of variables have normal distribution and reveal a stationary distribution over the analyzed
period at every level of significance. While the absence of a normal distribution of variables may
constitute challenges for econometric modeling, the stationary distribution does not hinder further
analysis. Thus, using the logarithm or square root of selected variables before employing them as
regressand or regressors means recognizing the non-linearity in the analyzed link between Tobin’s
Q and selected company attributes. It does not serve as a solution to eliminating non-stationarity of
variables. Table 7 presents descriptive statistics of variables used in econometric modeling.

368
JRFM 2020, 13, 242

Table 7. Descriptive statistics of variables, and untransformed variables.

Variable Mean Median SD Min Max Skewness Kurtosis


Q 1.576 1.1 1.449 0 9.5 2.294 9.333
FORMALCOMPL 1.526 1.0 1.348 0 8 0.896 4.280
MINCOMPL 1.154 1.0 0.889 0 3 −0.052 1.730
SUBSTCOMPL 1.449 1.0 1.572 0 9 1.302 4.678
FILASHA 35.706 31.570 21.938 0 99.0 0.413 2.211
INSTINV 26.803 22.760 22.019 0 98.870 0.808 3.089
INDUSTINV 22.984 0 28.894 0 99.8 0.778 2.111
CEOSHA 4.426 0 11.213 0 77.500 3.303 14.826
GOVSHA 2.841 0 11.899 0 84.750 4.740 25.902
ASSETS 1997.9 138.4 7148.6 1.51 70,198.9 5.561 38.663
ADJ_ROA −0.010 0 0.245 −1.220 0.890 −0.519 4.222
DEBT_ON_ASSETS 0.208 0.177 0.190 0 1.999 2.420 15.894

As shown in Table 7, variables are characterized by asymmetry and kurtosis. Only the
distributions of MINCOMPL, FILASHA, INDUSTINV, and ADJ_ROA remain moderately asymmetric,
while distributions of other variables are strongly asymmetric (FORMALCOMPL, SUBSTCOMPL,
and INSTINV) or extremely asymmetric (Q, CEOSHA, GOVSHA, ASSETS, and DEBT_ON_ASSETS).
The strong asymmetry present in the majority of variables may lead to lesser explanatory power of the
estimated econometric models and may limit the ability to interpret kurtosis. In addition, the minimal
value of Tobin’s Q is zero, which was not transformed into a logarithm. However, a value of zero is
present in only eight cases from 1550 observations, making it an acceptable number.
We analyze the distribution of compliance variables, specifically formal compliance, minimum
compliance, and substantive compliance, as shown in Table 8.

Table 8. Distribution of compliance variables (formal, minimum, and substantive).

FORMALCOMPL MINCOMPL SUBSTCOMPL


Year
0 1–3 4–8 0 1 2 3 0 1–3 4–8
2006 134 21 0 134 14 6 1 133 18 4
2007 101 54 0 102 34 18 1 101 46 8
2008 63 90 2 64 51 37 3 71 70 14
2009 35 114 6 36 54 61 4 47 89 19
2010 25 122 8 27 51 72 5 36 100 19
2011 19 129 7 21 49 79 6 35 101 19
2012 18 130 7 21 46 82 6 32 103 20
2013 18 134 3 21 39 88 7 32 102 21
2014 17 131 7 20 45 84 6 32 103 30
2015 16 132 7 19 44 85 7 27 107 21

The data presented in Table 8 are indicative of a constant improvement in compliance by the
sample companies in all the measured categories over the analyzed period. For each identified variable,
the number of companies which do not comply with any code provisions drops significantly—from
133 or 134 firms in 2006 to 16–27 firms in 2015. Interestingly, the highest improvement is noted for the
medium value of compliance—formal compliance between 1 and 3 increases from 21 companies in
2006 to 132 companies in 2015. The growth for the high value of compliance end is marginal—formal
compliance between 4 and 8 is noted in 0 companies in 2006 and increases to 7 companies in 2015.
Using a Pearson linear correlation coefficient, we report the correlation coefficients of regressand
and regressors in Table 9.

369
JRFM 2020, 13, 242

Table 9. Correlation coefficients of variables, regressand and regressors.

Variables ln_Q (1) (2)) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)
Q (1) 1.00
FORMALCOMPL (2) −0.11 −0.13 1.00
MINCOMPL (3) −0.09 −0.10 0.71 1.00
SUBSTCOMPL (4) −0.06 −0.08 0.87 0.50 1.00
FILASHA (5) −0.09 0.13 0.19 0.16
1.00
FILASHA_sq −0.11 −0.12 0.16 0.21 0.18
INSTINV (6) 0.02 0.03 0.10 0.03 −0.12
1.00
INSTINV_sq 0.10 0.04 0.04 0.10 0.03 −0.12
INDUSTINV (7) −0.04 0.12 0.09 0.16 0.54 −0.16
1.00
INDUSTINV_sq −0.04 −0.06 0.12 0.09 0.16 0.46 −0.10
CEOSHA (8) −0.17 −0.09 0.11 0.05 0.07 0.04 −0.02 −0.21 1.00
GOVSHA (9) −0.04 −0.07 −0.01 0.01 0.03 0.19 −0.05 −0.04 −0.09 1.00
ASSETS (10) 0.04 0.18 0.19 0.26 0.24 0.24 0.17 −0.09 0.26
1.00
ln_ASSETS −0.13 0.03 0.17 0.26 0.26 0.40 0.27 0.18 −0.13 0.37
ADJ_ROA (11) 0.35 0.28 0.04 0.05 0.01 0.03 0.17 0.03 −0.03 0.03 0.13 1.00
DEBT_ON_ASSETS (12) −0.06 −0.05 0.06 0.01 0.05 0.08 −0.01 0.03 0.08 −0.05 0.04 −0.24 1.00

Table 9 presents the correlation matrix for both untransformed and transformed variables (with the
use of logarithm and square root measures). In rows with two lines, the upper line represents the
value of the untransformed variable, while the bottom line shows the value of transformed variables.
The column “ln_Q” presents the coefficient of linear correlation between regressand and regressors.
The correlation matrix illustrates the strength and directions of the analyzed relations between variables,
similar to linear correlation. It shows the relations in which the value of a given variable increases or
decreases by a stable unit in line with the value change of another variable within a given time (year).
With the non-linear relations, the Pearson linear correlation coefficient may incorrectly suggest
a magnitude which may be stronger than initially anticipated. The statistical test indicates that all
correlation coefficients higher than 0.04 may be viewed as statistically different from zero. As reported in
Table 8, changes in ln_Q are correlated with ROA, assets, CEO ownership and ownership concentration.
A weaker link is noted for compliance measures. With low correlation coefficients, we do not identify
the multicollinearity problem.

3.4. Econometric Modeling


We test our hypotheses on the links between firm value and compliance with board best practice,
with the use of the following econometric model:
 
Q = f Compliance, FILASHASQ , INSTINSQ , INDUSTINSQ , CEOSHA, GOVSHA, ln _ASSETS, ADJ_ROA, DEBT_ON_ASSETS

where Compliance is FORMALCOMPL, MINCOMPL, and SUBSTCOMPL.


We test the formulated hypotheses with the use of panel analysis (Cameron and Trivedi 2005, 2010).
Constructing the econometric models, we address three main issues. Firstly, we consider the problem
of heteroskedasticity with the parallel variability of random variables between units and time period,
which requires the adoption of a method for estimating parameters robust enough for standard
estimates errors. We acknowledge heteroskedasticity and calculate the values of robust errors with
the use of a Wald test in all models. Secondly, we run a Hausman test to determine the type of the
model to be constructed. For each model, the significance level equals zero, indicating a rejection of the
null hypothesis and acceptance of the alternative hypothesis to choose the fixed effects model. Thus,
we decide to run fixed effects for all A–C models, meaning that the individual effects which differentiate
the reactions of the companies under analysis are represented by an intercept, which remains stable
over time.

370
JRFM 2020, 13, 242

Considering the heteroskedasticity of the random variable we use a dedicated version of the
Hausman test (rhausman test). Next, for A–C models, we employ an F-test to determine the statistical
significance of the entire set of regressors. In each of the models, we reject the null hypothesis,
suggesting that there is no variable that impacts the changes in the value of the regressand in the
models. We also run the Shapiro–Wilk test, which assumes a normal distribution of the random
variable. This hypothesis is rejected. Finally, to test for multicollinearity of regressors, we determine
the variance inflation factor (VIF) for each regressor in a given model. A VIF below 2, as is revealed in
the A–C models, eliminates multicollinearity. The VIF coefficients, overall and between, are close to
zero, signifying that the A–C models only explain the time changes of Tobin’s Q value. These tests
support the supposition that the changes of each explanatory variable have a statistically significant
impact on the value of explained variable.
The results of the tests and models under discussion are reported in Table 10.

Table 10. Estimation results for dependent ln_Q.

Model AS Model BS Model Model CS


Regressors Model A Model B Model C
(Std.) (Std.) BC (Std.)
−0.089
−0.147
FORMALCOMPL [L1] (0.025)
[1.349]
***
−0.082
−0.159
SUBSTCOMPL [L1] (0.025)
[1.572]
***
−0.035
dec_SUBSTCOMPL [L1]
(0.026)
−0.157
−0.171
MINCOMPL [L1] (0.033)
[0.889]
***
−0.129
INDNED [L1] (0.025)
***
−0.061 −0.063 −0.060 −0.060
−0.149 −0.153 −0.146
FILASHA_sq (0.024) (0.024) (0.025) (0.024)
[1.980] [1.980] [1.980]
** ** ** **
−0.031 −0.031 −0.028
−0.091 −0.096 −0.031 −0.087
INSTINV_sq (0.017) (0.016) (0.014)
[2.467] [2.467] (0.020) [2.467]
* * *
−0.035 −0.037 −0.036 −0.036
−0.156 −0.163 −0.161
INDUSTINV_sq (0.012) (0.012) (0.011) (0.011)
[3.614] [3.614] [3.614]
*** *** *** ***
−0.014 −0.014 −0.014 0.013
−0.189 −0.197 −0.183
CEOSHA (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004)
[11.213] [11.213] [11.213]
*** *** *** ***
−0.007 −0.007 −0.007 −0.008
−0.101 −0.100 −0.112
GOVSHA (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003)
[11.899] [11.899] [11.899]
** ** ** **
−0.210 −0.209 −0.203 −0.207
−0.514 −0.512 −0.506
ln_ASSETS (0.096) (0.097) (0.098) (0.096)
[1.991] [1.991] [1.991]
** ** ** **
0.759 0.751 0.742 0.759
0.229 0.226 0.228
ADJ_ROA (0.105) (0.104) (0.104) (0.105)
[0.245] [0.245] [0.245]
*** *** *** ***
0.350 0.332 0.341 0.335
0.082 0.077 0.083
DEBT_ON_ASSETS (0.205) (0.204) (0.203) (0.202)
[0.190] [0.190] [0.190]
* * * *
1.898 1.908 1.908 1.916
INTERCEPT (0.567) (0.574) (0.583) (0.563)
*** *** *** ***
N (observations) 1387 1387 1387 1387

371
JRFM 2020, 13, 242

Table 10. Cont.

Model AS Model BS Model Model CS


Regressors Model A Model B Model C
(Std.) (Std.) BC (Std.)
n (companies) 155 155 155 155
Max VIF 1.61 1.67 1.95 1.65
R_sq within 0.172 0.170 0.181 0.183
R_sq between 0.003 0.003 0.007 0.005
R_sq overall 0.006 0.005 0.004 0.003
F test 13.19 13.08 15.68 16.37
Prob > F 0 0 0 0
Shapiro–Wilk test z 11.81 11.84 5.16 11.80
Prob > z 0 0 0 0
Hausman chi2 test 78.26 62.17 116.35 67.04
Prob > chi2 0 0 0 0
Notes: The symbol of L1 by the regressor name indicates the variable value lagged by 1 year. The robust standard
error for each coefficient in models A, B, and C is reported in parentheses; *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, and * p < 0.1, where
the p-value is called the observed level of significance. The significance test for the coefficients is the t-statistics test.
Models AS, BS, and CS are models estimated for standardized variables, with standard deviations for values of
non-standardized variables presented in parentheses.

As shown in Table 10, for each A–C model, a given set of regressors differs only by one variable
on compliance. We use a compliance variable lagged by 1 period (year) to examine the effect on the
company market valuation after the publication of the conformity declaration and the information
on compliance practice. The results indicate a negative correlation between compliance with board
best practice and Tobin’s Q. The negative association is noted for all three measures of compliance,
i.e., formal compliance (FORMALCOMPL), minimum compliance (MINCOMPL), and substantive
compliance (SUBSTCOMPL). This means that from the perspective of our hypotheses we find support
for H1, which assumes a negative association between compliance with best practice code and firm
value. We also find support for H2, as we observe a negative and statistically significant relation
between the minimum level of compliance with code provisions and Q. Finally, for H3, our results
reveal a negative relation between company value and SUBSTCOMPL, which measures the most
substantive scope of compliance. Hence, we find support for H3, as well.
In addition, we tested A–C models for endogeneity. Based on prior studies, we identify ln_ASSETS
as the potential endogeneity driver and we proceed as follows. We estimate fixed-effect models with
the same set of regressors, using two approaches: the least-squares method (LS) and instrumental
variables method (IV). In the latter model, we use the lagged value of ln_ASSETS as the instrument.
We estimate both models for 2007–2015, in order to ensure full comparability. We use a Hausman
test, comparing LS model (null hypothesis) with the IV model. The rejection of the null hypothesis
would suggest selection of the IV model and would indicate that the ln_ASSETS variable may cause
endogeneity problems. We find no reason to reject the null hypothesis, which implies that we should
choose the LS model and that we do not note endogeneity issues. For models A–C, we do not reject the
null hypothesis, so fixed effect models estimated with the use of the least squared method offer the
most appropriate approach. Thus, there is no need to adopt instrumental variables, and the variable of
ln_ASSETS does not cause an endogeneity problem. As a consequence, it follows that the use of other
estimation methods is not appropriate.
We address the question concerning the changes in the values of regressors that have the strongest
impact on changes in the regressand. For this purpose, we estimate the equivalents for the A–C
models with standardized variables. The coefficients in models with standardized variables show
how the regressand changes within its own standard deviation if the regressor values change by one
standard deviation. Table 10 shows the values of standardized coefficients and values of standard
deviation of regressors for models AS, BS, and CS in dedicated columns. Models estimated with
standardized variables reveal that the signs of the regression parameters and the values of t-statistics
of regression parameters do not change, so the statistical significance of the relations does not change

372
JRFM 2020, 13, 242

either. Other values of the statistical verification for our models remain stable, as well. The value
of ln_Q ranges between −2.303 and 2.251, with the standard deviation equal to 0.815. It shows that
ln_ASSETS and ADJ_ROAs have the strongest impact on a change in the regressand value, followed by
CEOSHA, FILASHA, and compliance. DEBT_ON_ASSETS reveals the lowest impact on the change of
ln_Q.
Finally, we run an additional BC model with the measure of decomposed substantive compliance
(dec_SUBSTCOMPL). We observe that, in the A–C models, the variable for independent directors is the
main explanatory component, since WSE-listed companies do not report numerous aspects included in
the substantive compliance measure (e.g., independent chair, the identification of independent directors,
and the formation of a separate audit committee). Thus, in the BC model for decomposed substantive
compliance (dec_SUBSTCOMPL) we exclude the variable of INDNED from compliance. As presented
in Table 10, for the BC model, the decomposed substantive compliance (dec_SUBSTCOMPL) remains
statistically insignificant, while INDNED is statistically significant. While this approach offers a deeper
insight into compliance practice, it has two limitations: Firstly, dec_UBSTCOMPL and INDNED
are strongly correlated; secondly, neither are more strongly correlated with the variable ln_Q than
SUBSTCOMPL. This means that introducing two variables instead of one measure, being the sum of
the two variables, may increase parameter estimation error and consequently render the regressors
statistically insignificant. Importantly, the decomposition of SUBSTCOMPL into INDNED and
dec_UBSTCOMPL changed neither the signs of the estimated parameters of other regressors nor
the statistical characteristics of the estimated models reported with the F test, Shapiro–Wilk test,
and Hausman test.

3.5. Robustness Tests


We run robustness tests to check the stability of our models. For this purpose, we construct
models with an additional control variable—board size (BOARDSIZE)—which represents the number
of non-executive directors on the supervisory board. The results for the three models, AR, BR, and CR,
are presented in Table 11.

Table 11. Estimation results of robustness tests.

Regressors Model AR Model BR Model CR


−0.089
FORMALCOMPL [L1] (0.025)
***
−0.083
SUBSTCOMPL [L1] (0.025)
***
−0.157
MINCOMPL [L1] (0.033)
***
−0.060 −0.062 −0.060
FILASHA_sq (0.024) (0.024) (0.024)
** ** **
−0.032 −0.029
−0.031
INSTINV_sq (0.020) (0.020)
(0.020)
* *
−0.036 −0.037 −0.036
INDUSTINV_sq (0.012) (0.012) (0.011)
*** *** ***
−0.013 −0.014 0.013
CEOSHA (0.003) (0.003) (0.004)
*** *** ***

373
JRFM 2020, 13, 242

Table 11. Cont.

Regressors Model AR Model BR Model CR


−0.007 −0.007 −0.008
GOVSHA (0.003) (0.003) (0.003)
** ** **
−0.211 −0.210 −0.208
ln_ASSETS (0.096) (0.097) (0.096)
** ** **
0.350 0.333 0.3569
DEBT_ON_ASSETS (0.205) (0.206) (0.202)
* ** **
0.761 0.753 0.761
ADJ_ROA (0.106) (0.104) (0.104)
*** * *
0.015 0.014 0.017
BOARDSIZE
(0.025) (0.025) (0.025)
1.808 1.821 1.815
INTERCEPT (0.554) (0.562) (0.552)
*** *** ***
N (observations) 1387 1387 1387
n (companies) 155 155 155
Max VIF 2.49 2.51 2.53
R_sq within 0.172 0.171 0.183
R_sq between 0.002 0.003 0.005
R_sq overall 0.007 0.006 0.006
F test 11.96 11.85 14.76
Prob > F 0 0 0
Shapiro–Wilk test z 5.120 5.060 5.220
Prob > z 0 0 0
Hausman chi2 test 106.390 97.790 79.090
Prob > chi2 0 0 0
Notes: *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, and * p < 0.1.

As shown in Table 11, the variable of board size does not change the stability of our models.
All parameter signs and statistical significances remain stable.

4. Discussion
The objective of this article was to provide an empirical verification of the relationship between
corporate governance compliance and company value. With the application of the framework
offered by agency theory (Jensen and Meckling 1976; Fama and Jensen 1983), the study tests the
main assumption that greater compliance has a positive effect on the market valuation of complying
companies. Codes of corporate governance best practice are based on fundamental principles of justice,
fairness, and equality (Zattoni and Cuomo 2008) and recommend conformity with a set of provisions
of board work, practices of executive compensation, policies of risk management, and standards
of transparency (Aguilera et al. 2015). Along with the criticism of a one-size-fits-all approach with
national adjustments, codes of best practice reveal conditions in which participants of a community
reach a mutual understanding. The concept of flexibility and a voluntary approach to codes of best
practice provide space for a dialog to reach consent, in which certain norms and behavior are seen as
right or wrong. According to the comply-or-explain rule (Tan 2018), companies are obliged to report

374
JRFM 2020, 13, 242

their scope of conformity, which facilitates understanding of both the determinants and performance
effects of compliance.
Prior studies indicate the positive effect of compliance related to enhanced investor trust, lower
capital cost, and reduced information asymmetry, and they reveal a positive relation between corporate
governance conformity and company performance and value (Mazotta and Veltri 2014; Rose 2016;
Kaspereit et al. 2017). However, some researchers argue that the impact of corporate governance codes and
compliance may be limited in different institutional settings, in particular in the context of concentrated
ownership, insufficient investor protection, and emerging governance (Sobhan 2016; Okhmatovskiy 2017).
The main focus of corporate governance codes is devoted to solving principal–agent conflicts between
shareholders and managers, rather than giving sufficient attention to principal–principal conflicts
between majority and minority shareholders (Chen et al. 2011). Thus, in countries of concentrated
ownership and emerging governance, the code provisions and compliance with best practice may not
result in a higher performance effect (Gherghina 2015) or may even be detrimental to company value
(when regarded merely as an extra cost) or fail to elicit investor trust.
We tested the hypotheses of the relationship between compliance and company value compliance,
using a unique sample of conformity with board best practice by 155 companies listed on the Warsaw
Stock Exchange over a 10-year period. Specifically, we assume that formal compliance with board best
practice is negatively associated with firm value (H1) and a that minimum compliance with board best
practice is negatively associated with firm value (H2). We hypothesize that investors do not appreciate
substantive compliance either and that conformity with board best practice is negatively associated
with firm value (H3).
The results of the panel analysis provide support for hypotheses H1 and H2, showing a negative
association between formal compliance and firm value and minimum compliance and firm value.
In line with our assumption in H3, we obtain partial support for the negative association between
substantive compliance and Q. The negative correlation between company value and compliance
remains statistically significant for the general measure of substantive compliance (SUBSTCOMPL)
and statistically insignificant for decomposed substantive compliance (dec_SUBSTCOMPL), for which
we exclude the variable on independent directors (INDNED). We interpret these findings as
evidence for a mismatch between code provisions and corporate governance challenges, relating to
concentrated ownership and principal–principal conflicts (Chen et al. 2011). Consistent with findings by
Bhagat and Black (2002), we do not observe a positive market valuation effect for complying companies.
Investors appear not to find compliance with board best practice a convincing solution to possible
tensions between majority and minority shareholders (Healy and Palepu 2001; Goncharov et al. 2006),
questioning the efficient implementation of board guidelines (Martin 2010).

5. Conclusions
The goal of this study was to test for the link between compliance and company value in a specific
context of concentrated ownership and post-transition corporate governance. The results show a
negative correlation between compliance with the code provisions on board practice and company
value, as measured by Tobin’s Q, suggesting that investors do not find the adoption of board practice a
plausible solution for the principal–principal conflict in an environment of concentrated ownership.
The study adds to the debate on corporate governance compliance, in general, and its effects
on market valuation in emerging and post-transition countries, in particular. For practitioners and
policymakers, the results of our analysis deliver important insights into the limitations of code
provisions, which are transmitted across countries with differing institutional environments and
ownership structures, and results in different agency problems.
We acknowledge the limitations of our research—we focused on board best practice and in one
country. Further research should address a wide scope of code provisions and cover a larger sample of
companies from different economies. Adding variables to cover the institutional environment, such as

375
JRFM 2020, 13, 242

measures of investor protection or rule of law, would aid in understanding the effect of the regulatory
context on the efficiency of corporate governance provisions.

Author Contributions: Formal analysis, writing T.K.; Writing—original draft, concept, discussion, M.A. All authors
have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.
Funding: This research received no external funding.
Conflicts of Interest: The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References
Adelstein, Jennifer, and Steward Clegg. 2016. Code of ethics: A stratified vehicle for compliance. Journal of
Business Ethics 138: 53–66. [CrossRef]
Aguilera, Ruth, and Alvaro Cuervo-Cazura. 2004. Codes of good governance worldwide: What is the trigger?
Organization Studies 25: 415–43. [CrossRef]
Aguilera, Ruth, Alvaro Cuervo-Cazura, and Soyoung Kim. 2009. Taking stock of research on codes of good
governance. In Codes of Good Governance Worldwide. Edited by Felix J. Lopez Iturriaga. New York: Nova Science
Publishers Inc., pp. 3–32.
Aguilera, Ruth, Kurt Desender, Michael Bednar, and Jun Ho Lee. 2015. Connecting the dots—Bringing external
corporate governance into the corporate governance puzzle. The Academy of Management Annals 9: 483–573.
[CrossRef]
Albu, Cătălin, and Maria Girbina. 2015. Compliance with corporate governance codes in emerging economies.
How do Romanian listed companies “comply-or-explain”. Corporate Governance 15: 85–107. [CrossRef]
Aman, Hiroyuki, and Pascal Nguyen. 2007. Do stock prices reflect the corporate governance quality of Japanese
firms? Journal of the Japanese and International Economies 22: 647–62. [CrossRef]
Andres, Christian, and Erik Theissen. 2008. Setting a Fox to keep the geese—Does the comply-or-explain principle
work? Journal of Corporate Finance 14: 289–301. [CrossRef]
Arcot, Sridhar, Valentina Bruno, and Antoine Faure-Grimaud. 2010. Corporate governance in the UK: Is the
comply or explain approach working. International Review of Law and Economics 30: 193–201. [CrossRef]
Bauer, Rob, Nadja Gunster, and Rogér Otten. 2004. Empirical evidence on corporate governance in Europe:
The effect on stock returns, firm value and performance. Journal of Asset Management 5: 91–104. [CrossRef]
Bennedsen, Morten, and Kasper Nielsen. 2010. Incentive and entrenchment effects in European ownership.
Journal of Banking and Finance 34: 2212–29. [CrossRef]
Berglöf, Erik, and Stijn Claessens. 2006. Enforcement and good corporate governance in developing countries and
transition economies. World Bank Research Observer 21: 123–50. [CrossRef]
Bhagat, Sanjai, and Bernard Black. 2002. The non-correlation between board independence and long term firm
performance. Journal of Corporation Law 27: 231–74. [CrossRef]
Bhagat, Sanjai, and Brian Bolton. 2008. Corporate governance and firm performance. Journal of Corporate Finance
14: 257–73. [CrossRef]
Bistrowa, Julia, and Natalja Lace. 2012. Corporate governance best practice and stock performance: Case of CEE
Companies. Systemics, Cybernetics and Informatics 10: 63–69.
Black, Bernard, Hasung Jang, and Woochan Kim. 2006. Does corporate governance predict firms’ market value.
Evidence from Korea. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 22: 366–413. [CrossRef]
Cameron, A. Collin, and Pravin Trivedi. 2005. Microeconometrics. Methods and Applications. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Cameron, A. Collin, and Pravin Trivedi. 2010. Microeconometrics Using STATA. Revised Edition. College Station:
Stata Press.
Chang, Allan. 2018. Analysis on corporate governance compliance standards in New Zealand—A qualitative
study on disclosures using content analysis and interviews. Journal of Financial Regulation and Compliance
26: 505–25. [CrossRef]
Chen, Victor Zitian, Jing Li, and Daniel Shapiro. 2011. Are OECD-prescribed “good corporate governance
practices” really good in an emerging economy? Asia Pacific Journal of Management 28: 115–38. [CrossRef]
Chizema, Amon. 2008. Institutions and voluntary compliance: The disclosure of individual executive pay in
Germany. Corporate Governance 16: 359–74. [CrossRef]

376
JRFM 2020, 13, 242

Cicon, James, Stephen Ferris, Armin Kammel, and Gregory Noronha. 2012. European corporate governance:
A thematic analysis of national codes of governance. European Financial Management 18: 620–48. [CrossRef]
Coffee, John. 1999. Privatization and corporate governance: The lessons from securities market failure. Journal of
Corporation Law 25: 1–39. [CrossRef]
Cuervo, Alvaro. 2002. Corporate governance mechanisms: A plea for less code of good governance and more
market control. Corporate Governance 10: 84–93. [CrossRef]
Cuomo, Francesca, Christine Mallin, and Alessandro Zattoni. 2016. Corporate governance codes: A review and
research agenda. Corporate Governance: An International Review 24: 222–41. [CrossRef]
Deephouse, David. 1996. Does isomorphism legitimate? Academy of Management Journal 39: 1024–39. [CrossRef]
Drobetz, Wolfgand, Andreas Shillhofer, and Heinz Zimmermann. 2003. Corporate governance and expected stock
returns: Evidence from Germany. European Financial Management 10: 267–93. [CrossRef]
Durnev, Artyom, and E. Han Kim. 2005. To steal or not to steal: Firm attributes, legal environment and valuation.
Journal of Finance 60: 1461–93. [CrossRef]
Easterbrook, Frank, and Daniel Fischel. 1996. The Economic Structure of Corporate Law. Cambridge: Harvard
University Press.
Edmans, Alex. 2014. Blockholders and corporate governance. Annual Review of Financial Economics 6: 23–50.
[CrossRef]
Elgharbawy, Adel, and Magdy Abdel-Kader. 2016. Does compliance with corporate governance hinder corporate
entrepreneurship? Corporate Governance 16: 765–84. [CrossRef]
Fama, Eugene, and Michael Jensen. 1983. Separation of ownership and control. Journal of Law and Economics
26: 301–25. [CrossRef]
Ferrarini, Guido, and Marilena Filippelli. 2013. Independent directors and controlling shareholders around
the world. Orizzonti del Diritto Commerciale. Rivista Telematica, 1–31. Available online: http:
//orizzontideldirittocommerciale.it/media/24835/ferrarini_-_filippelli_independent_directors.pdf (accessed
on 13 October 2020).
Florackis, Chris, Angelos Kanas, and Alexandros Kostakis. 2015. Dividend policy, managerial ownership and debt
financing: A non-parametric perspective. European Journal of Operational Research 214: 783–95. [CrossRef]
Fotaki, Maria, Spyros Lioukas, and Irini Voudouris. 2019. Ethics is destiny: Organizational values and compliance
in corporate governance. Journal of Business Ethics. [CrossRef]
Gaur, Sanjaya, Hanoku Bathula, and Deeksha Singh. 2015. Ownership concentration, board characteristics and
firm performance: A contingency framework. Management Decision 53: 911–31. [CrossRef]
Gherghina, Ştefan. 2015. Corporate Governance Ratings and Firm Value: Empirical Evidence from the Bucharest
Stock Exchange. International Journal of Economics and Financial Issues 5: 97–110.
Gilson, Ronald J., and Alan Schwartz. 2013. Contracting about Private Benefits of Control. Columbia Law and
Economics Research Paper No. 436. Available online: https://law.stanford.edu/wp-content/uploads/sites/
default/files/publication/359494/doc/slspublic/ssrn-id2182781.pdf (accessed on 13 October 2020).
Gompers, Paul, Ishii Joy, and Andrew Metrick. 2003. Corporate governance and equity prices. Quarterly Journal of
Financial Economics 118: 107–55.
Goncharov, Igor, Joerg Werner, and Jochen Zimmermann. 2006. Does compliance with the German corporate
governance code have an impact on stock valuation? An empirical analysis. Corporate Governance 14: 432–45.
[CrossRef]
Guler, Isin, Mark Guillén, and John MacPherson. 2002. Global competition, institutions and the diffusion of
organizational practices: The international spread of ISO quality certificates. Administrative Science Quarterly
47: 207–32. [CrossRef]
Hamadi, Malika, and Andréas Heinen. 2015. Firm performance when ownership is very concentrated: Evidence
from a semiparametric panel. Journal of Empirical Finance 34: 172–94. [CrossRef]
Healy, Paul, and Krishna Palepu. 2001. Information asymmetry, corporate disclosure and the capital markets:
A review of the empirical disclosure literature. Journal of Accounting and Economics 31: 405–40. [CrossRef]
Hermalin, Benjamin, and Michael Weisbach. 2003. Boards of directors as an endogenously determined institutions:
A Survey of economic literature. Economic Policy Review 9: 7–26.
Hermes, Niels, Theo Postma, and Orestis Zivkov. 2007. Corporate governance codes and their contents: An analysis
of Eastern European codes. Journal for East European Management Studies 12: 53–74. [CrossRef]

377
JRFM 2020, 13, 242

Hooghiemstra, Reggy, and Hans van Ees. 2011. Uniformity as response to soft law: Evidenced from compliance
and non-compliance with the Dutch corporate governance code. Regulation and Governance 5: 480–98.
[CrossRef]
Huu Nguyen, Anh, Duong Thuy Doan, and Linh Ha Nguyen. 2020. Corporate governance and agency cost:
Empirical evidence from Vietnam. Journal of Risk and Financial Management 13: 103. [CrossRef]
Jensen, Michael, and William Meckling. 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and
ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3: 305–60. [CrossRef]
Kaspereit, Thomas, Kerstin Lopatta, and Dennis Onnen. 2017. Shareholder value implications of compliance with
the German corporate governance code. Managerial and Decision Economics 38: 166–77. [CrossRef]
Khan, Haroon ur Rashid, Waqas Bin Khidmat, Osama Al Hares, Naeem Muhammad, and Kashif Saleem. 2020.
Corporate governance quality, ownership structure, agency costs and firm performance. Evidence from an
emerging economy. Journal of Risk and Financial Management 13: 154. [CrossRef]
Kim, Ji Youn, Jooyoung Kwak, and Keun Lee. 2015. Estimating Tobin’s Q for listed firms in Korea (1980–2005):
Comparing alternative approaches and an experiment with investment functions. Seoul Journal of Economics
28: 1–30.
Krenn, Mario. 2015. Understanding decoupling in response to corporate governance reform pressures. The case
of codes of good governance. Journal of Financial Regulation 23: 369–82. [CrossRef]
Krivogorsky, Victoria, and Greg Burton. 2012. Dominant owners and performance of continental European firms.
Journal of International Accounting Research 11: 191–221. [CrossRef]
La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, and Andrei Shleifer. 1999. Corporate ownership around the world.
Journal of Finance 54: 471–517. [CrossRef]
Lipman, Frederick. 2007. Summary of major corporate governance principles and best practices. International
Journal of Disclosure and Governance 4: 309–19. [CrossRef]
Loyola, Gino, and Yolanda Portila. 2019. Optimal ownership structure and monitoring in entrepreneurial firms.
Finance Research Letters. [CrossRef]
Mahadeo, Jyoti Devi, and Teerooven Soobaroyen. 2016. A longitudinal study of the implementation of the
corporate governance code in a developing country: The case of Mauritius. Business and Society 55: 738–77.
[CrossRef]
Mallin, Christine. 2004. Corporate Governance. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Martin, Roderick. 2010. Transferring corporate governance: Form or substance? Corporate governance in
Hungary. Europe-Asia Studies 62: 145–71. [CrossRef]
Mazotta, Romilda, and Stefania Veltri. 2014. The relationship between corporate governance and the cost of
equity capital. Evidence from the Italian stock exchange. Journal of Management and Governance 18: 418–48.
[CrossRef]
Mizruchi, Mark, and Lisa Fein. 1999. The Social construct of organizational knowledge: A study of the uses of
coercive, mimetic and normative isomorphism. Administrative Science Quarterly 44: 653–83. [CrossRef]
OECD. 2015. G20/OECD Principles of Corporate Governance. Available online: http://www.oecd.org/daf/ca/
Corporate-Governance-Principles-ENG.pdf (accessed on 9 January 2019).
Okhmatovskiy, Ilya, and Robert David. 2012. Setting your own standards: Internal corporate governance codes as
a response to institutional pressure. Organization Science 23: 155–76. [CrossRef]
Okhmatovskiy, Ilya. 2017. Self-regulation of corporate governance in Russian firms: Translating the national
standard into internal policies. Journal of Management and Governance 21: 499–532. [CrossRef]
Outa, Erik, and Nelson Waweru. 2016. Corporate governance guidelines compliance and firm financial
performance. Kenya listed companies. Managerial Auditing Journal 31: 891–914. [CrossRef]
Perezts, Mar, and Sébastien Picard. 2015. Compliance or comfort zone? The work of embedded ethics in
performing regulation. Journal of Business Ethics 131: 833–52. [CrossRef]
Pritchett, Marshal. 1983. Corporate ethics and corporate governance: A critique of the ALI Statement on corporate
governance section 2.01(b). California Law Review 71: 994–1011. [CrossRef]
Renders, Annelies, Ann Gaeremynck, and Piet Sercu. 2010. Corporate-governance ratings and company
performance: A cross-European study. Corporate Governance: An International Review 18: 87–106. [CrossRef]
Rose, Casper. 2016. Firm performance and comply or explain disclosure in corporate governance. European
Management Journal 34: 202–22. [CrossRef]

378
JRFM 2020, 13, 242

Roy, Amitava, and Ananda M. Pay. 2017. Corporate governance compliance, governance structures and firm
performance. Indian Accounting Review 21: 31–50. [CrossRef]
Sarhan, Ahmed, and Collins Ntim. 2018. Firm- and country-level antecedents of corporate governance compliance
and disclosure in MENA countries. Managerial Auditing Journal 33: 558–85. [CrossRef]
Seidl, David, Paul Sanderson, and John Roberts. 2013. Applying the ‘comply-or-explain’ principle: Discursive
legitimacy tactics with regards to codes of governance. Journal of Management and Governance 17: 791–826.
[CrossRef]
Shleifer, Andrei, and Robert Vishny. 1997. A survey of corporate governance. Journal of Finance 52: 737–83.
[CrossRef]
Shrives, Philip J., and Niamh M. Brennan. 2015. A typology for exploring the quality of explanations for
non-compliance with UK corporate governance regulations. The British Accounting Review 47: 85–99.
[CrossRef]
Sobhan, Abdus. 2016. Where institutional logics of corporate governance collide: Overstatement of compliance in
a developing country, Bangladesh. Corporate Governance: An International Review 24: 599–618. [CrossRef]
Stiglbauer, Markus, and Patrick Velte. 2014. Impact of soft law regulation by corporate governance code on firm
valuation: The case of Germany. Corporate Governance 14: 395–406. [CrossRef]
Su, Yiyi, Dean Xu, and Phillip Phan. 2008. Principal-principal conflict in the governance of the Chinese public
corporation. Management and Organization Review 4: 17–38. [CrossRef]
Tan, Zhiyuan. 2018. Textual construction of comparative space: How analyst corporate governance reports
redefine and create “best practice”. Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal 31: 1794–827.
Thomsen, Steen, and Torben Pedersen. 2000. Ownership structure and economic performance in the largest
European companies. Strategic Management Journal 21: 689–705. [CrossRef]
Tricker, Bob. 2012. Corporate Governance. Principles, Policies and Practices. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Vintila, Goergeta, Ştefan Gherghina, and Mihai Nedelescu. 2014. The effects of ownership concentration and
origin on listed firms’ value. Empirical evidence from Romania. Romanian Journal of Economic Forecasting
17: 51–71.
Wang, Kun, and Greg Shailer. 2015. Ownership concentration and firm performance in emerging markets:
A meta-analysis. Journal of Economic Surveys 29: 199–229. [CrossRef]
Williamson, Oliver. 1981. The economics of organization: The transaction cost approach. American Journal of
Sociology 87: 548–77. [CrossRef]
Zattoni, Alessandro, and Francesca Cuomo. 2008. Why adopt codes of good governance? A comparison of
institutional and efficiency perspective. Corporate Governance 16: 1–15. [CrossRef]

Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional
affiliations.

© 2020 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access
article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution
(CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).

379
Journal of
Risk and Financial
Management

Article
Corporate Governance and Earnings Management in
a Nordic Perspective: Evidence from the Oslo
Stock Exchange
Frode Kjærland *, Ane Tolnes Haugdal, Anna Søndergaard and Anne Vågslid
NTNU Business School, Norwegian University of Science and Technology, NO-7491 Trondheim, Norway;
ane.haugdal@ntnu.no (A.T.H.); anna.soendergaard@gmail.com (A.S.); annevaagslid@hotmail.com (A.V.)
* Correspondence: frode.kjarland@ntnu.no

Received: 11 September 2020; Accepted: 26 October 2020; Published: 29 October 2020

Abstract: The purpose of the study is to examine the relation between Nordic corporate governance
practices and earnings management. We find that the presence of employee representation on the
board and the presence of an audit committee are both practices that reduce the occurrence of earnings
management. Moreover, we find that both board independence and share ownership by directors
positively affect earnings management, while board activity and directors as majority shareholders
show an insignificant relation to earnings management. We contribute to the existing literature
on corporate governance and earnings management by providing valuable insight into the Nordic
corporate governance approach and its potential in mitigating earnings management.

Keywords: accrual earnings management; corporate governance; Nordic model

1. Introduction
In response to recent accounting scandals in both the US and Europe there has been an increased
concern regarding the effectiveness of corporate governance practices. Undoubtedly, the concerns
are justified. The case of Enron Corporation in 2001 is a well-known example of the destroying
consequences of weak corporate governance. The scandal created an international attention on how to
systematically implement improved corporate governance practices to prevent fraud and questionable
managing of earnings. Immediate responses were proposed reforms of corporate governance through
legislation and improved listing standards (Coffee 2002). This included the US Sarbanes Oxley Act
(SOX) in 2002 and the UK Higgs Report and the Smith Report in 20031 . The motivation behind our
study is thus the implicit assertion that earnings management and weak corporate governance practices
are positively related.
The concept of corporate governance is not new. Its need aroused with the separation
of ownership and control in public companies (Berle and Means 1932), which, according to
Jensen and Meckling (1976), resulted in agency problems. Consequently, the responsibility to present
credible financial information and protect shareholders’ interests fell on the corporate governance
system (Fama and Jensen 1983). As information asymmetry between preparers and users of financial
information makes opportunism possible (Beatty and Harris 1999), the guardian role of the board
become obvious.
The extent of earnings management could implicate how well the corporate governance practices
are in protecting shareholder’s interests, since corporate governance has the potential to reduce
or even eliminate fraudulent behavior (Man and Wong 2013). This study addresses the triangular

1 Regarding Norway; the result was the establishment of the Norwegian Corporate Governance Board (NUES) in 2004.

JRFM 2020, 13, 256; doi:10.3390/jrfm13110256 381 www.mdpi.com/journal/jrfm


JRFM 2020, 13, 256

interaction between a company’s shareholders, board of directors and management in a Nordic setting.
Many prior studies on corporate governance and earnings management have come from countries
within a two-tier or one-tier model of corporate governance, such as the US, the UK, Italy. Egypt,
Malaysia and China (Al-Jaifi 2017; Beasley 1996; Campa and Donnelly 2014; Karmel and Elbanna 2012;
Klein 2002; Liu and Lu 2007; Marchini et al. 2018; Peasnell et al. 2000; Xie et al. 2003) which differentiate
from the Nordic corporate governance model in several ways. Lekvall et al. (2014) claim that two
key distinctive features of Nordic corporate governance are the powers vested with a shareholder
majority to effectively control the company and the entirely nonexecutive board. Norwegian boards
are characterized by a high shareholder concentration. Accordingly, instead of turning to the market
for corporate control, major owners generally take an active part in the governance of the company.
The system thus provides dominating shareholders the motivation to take long-term responsibility
for the company. Moreover, Norwegian Public Limited Companies (ASA) are comprised exclusively
of nonexecutive officers, except for employee representatives. An important implication of this is
the distinction the duties and responsibilities of a strategically and monitoring board and a mere
executive management function. Lekvall et al. (2014) argues that although these features may not
seem individually unique, together they make a comprehensive system. Its success is shown by the
competitiveness of Nordic companies on international markets. In 2013, The Economist described
the Nordic corporate governance model as “The next supermodel”, pointing to Nordic countries
clustering at the top of global league tables of everything from economic competitiveness to happiness
(The Economist 2013; Lourenco et al. 2018).
Although Nordic countries have been declared role models for their corporate governance systems
(The Economist 2013), there have been limited studies exploring the relationship between corporate
governance and earnings management in countries within the Nordic model of corporate governance.
The aim of this paper is to fill these gaps and provide valuable insight for users of financial statements
beyond the Nordic countries. We do find as a contribution that the presence of employee representation
on the board reduce earnings management. Moreover, board independence seem positively related
to earnings management, contradictory to the findings of other well-known studies (Beasley 1996;
Dechow et al. 1996; Peasnell et al. 2000; Klein 2002). We also find the same regarding share ownership
by directors, thus indicating that large proportions of minority shareholders on the board could give
the directors incentives to pursue higher-risk strategies to generate larger financial returns.
The findings will be of interest for countries following the same triangular interaction between
a company’s shareholders, board of directors and management. In addition, the study aims to
provide increased attention to the potential benefits the Nordic corporate governance approach has on
improving earnings quality by mitigating earnings management.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 provides a review of previous
literature and the hypothesis development. The data and methodology are presented in Section 3,
while Section 4 presents the empirical results. Finally, Section 5 conclude the paper’s findings, included
the limitations of the study.

2. Review of Literature and Hypothesis Development


Earnings are the summary measure of firm performance produced under the accrual basis
of accounting (Dechow 1994). Healy and Wahlen (1999) provides a commonly cited definition of
earnings management:
Earnings management occurs when managers intentionally use judgements in financial reporting
and in structuring financial transactions to alter financial reports to mislead some stakeholders about
the underlying economic performance of the firm or to influence contractual outcomes that depend on
reported accounting numbers.
As the definition points out, firms have two options to manage earnings. First, earnings
can be managed through deviations from normal business activities (Xu et al. 2007). The firm
could, for example, boost reported profit by cutting down on research and development, selling

382
JRFM 2020, 13, 256

assets it would otherwise keep and cutting down on employee development. Deviating from
normal business practices to manipulate reported income is defined as real earnings management
(Roychowdhury 2006). Second, a firm can alter the level of accruals to obtain the desired level of
earnings. Using management judgements in financial reporting is defined as accrual-based earnings
management (Healy and Wahlen 1999). Real changes in investment and operating activities are costlier
than mere accounting manipulation. It is therefore reasonable to assume that firms have a lower
threshold to manipulate earnings through accruals rather than real activities. This study focuses on
accrual earnings management only.
Many motivations for earnings management have been examined in the literature. The managerial
motives are mixed and include motivations such as maximizing firm value (Beneish 2001), management
buyouts (DeAngelo 1986), initial public offerings (IPO’s) (Teoh et al. 1998) and meeting the expectations
of financial analysts, management, investors and social and political pressure (Payne and Robb 2000;
Kasznik 1999; Li and Thibodeau 2019). The essence of earnings manipulation is derived from the
flexibility given to management in disclosing their reported earnings (Busirin et al. 2015).
Accounting information is traditionally considered to have a dual role as both informer and
steward (Ronen and Yaari 2008). The informative role arises because of investors’ need to predict
future cash flows and assess the risk of investments. This study will focus on the stewardship role
of accounting. The stewardship role of accounting comes from the separation of ownership and
management in public firms, resulting in agency problems that could lead to divergence between
the interest of shareholders and managers (Jensen and Meckling 1976; Gjesdal 1981). A following
control difficulty is information asymmetry. Information asymmetry exists when managers have a
more complete set of information about the company than the shareholders, leading to agency costs
as the managers have opportunities to promote their own self-interest at the shareholders’ expense
(Beatty and Harris 1999). Prior studies have found a positive relationship between agency costs and the
latitude of earnings management (Beatty and Harris 1999; Man 2019). Corporate governance is thus
necessary to align and coordinate the interest of the upper management with those of the shareholders
to mitigate the occurrence of earnings management. Fama and Jensen (1983) argue that the board
of directors is the highest internal control mechanism responsible for monitoring the actions of top
management. Monks and Minow (2008) underline that as the body who governs the firm, it is the
board of directors’ duty to ensure that the company is run in the long-term interests of the shareholders.
While there is no generally accepted definition of corporate governance, it may be defined as a system
“consisting of all the people, processes and activities to help ensure stewardship over a company’s
assets” (Messier et al. 2008).
There is mixed evidence on the effect corporate governance practices has on earnings management.
Board characteristics that have been frequently investigated in earnings management literature, such as
board independence, board activity and the presence of an audit committee will be included in this
study (see Table 1). In addition, directors’ share ownership, majority shareholding by directors and
the presence of employee representatives will be examined as key elements of the Nordic corporate
governance model (see Table 1). Following are some prominent studies reviewed in this regard.

2.1. Board Independence


NUES (2018) recommend that most of the shareholder-elected members of the board should
be independent of the company’s executive personnel and material business contacts, while at least
two of the shareholder-elected members should be independent of the company’s main shareholders.
Independent directors are chosen in the interest of shareholders, adding value due to their impartial
monitoring of business ethics (Rosenstein and Wyatt 1990). Independent board members are associated
with effective monitoring (Fama 1980), while nonindependent board members are considered an
obstacle to efficient monitoring (Ronen and Yaari 2008). It is assumed that effective monitoring
controls earnings management, as suggested in studies investigating board independence and earnings
management (Dechow et al. 1996; Beasley 1996; Klein 2002; Peasnell et al. 2005). Haldar et al. (2018)

383
JRFM 2020, 13, 256

and Van den Berghe and Baelden (2005) do however point to other important aspects of directors’
independence. They argue that the quality of independent directors depends on other factors specific to
the directors’ character, the firm and its environment. In accordance with prior earnings management
literature, the following hypothesis is tested:

Hypothesis 1 (H1). There is a negative relation between board independence and earnings management.

2.2. Employee Representatives


As stated in the Public Companies Act, the main rule regarding employee representation in
Norway is that one third of the directors can be elected by and among the employees. NUES (2018)
do not mention any specific recommendations regarding employee representatives since they are
considered ordinary members of the board with the same authority and responsibility as the
shareholder-elected board members. Literature and prior studies on employee representatives
and earnings management is however rare. In Fauver and Fuerst (2006) study on German companies,
they argue that employee representatives contribute as informed monitors with detailed operational
knowledge that is valuable in board decision-making and supervising. They further conclude that
the presence of employee representatives on the board is negatively and significantly related to
earnings management. Other studies on monitoring and earnings management have found that
better monitoring quality by directors could ultimately help to reduce agency costs induced by either
managers or large shareholders (Gul et al. 2002; Peasnell et al. 2005). The importance of operational
knowledge is supported in a Chinese study conducted by Chen et al. (2015). They found that the
quality of managerial oversight by directors depends significantly on the quality and completeness of
the information they receive, stating that directors’ monitoring is more effective in a richer information
environment. Accordingly, the second hypothesis is:

Hypothesis 2 (H2). There is a negative relation between the presence of employee representatives and earnings
management.

2.3. Share Ownership by Directors


It is difficult to state a clear theoretical prediction about the effect of share ownership by
directors on earnings management. From an opportunistic point of view, share ownership by
directors could weaken their independence and their effectiveness in monitoring financial reporting
(Lin and Hwang 2010). On the other hand, managers of firms with low director ownership are expected
to exploit the latitude of accounting standards to ease financial constraints, indicating that higher
share ownership by directors will reduce the occurrence of earnings management (Gul et al. 2002).
It is also found that directors’ shareholdings are associated with smaller increases in information
asymmetry (Kanagaretnam et al. 2007), which in turn could reduce agency costs and better prevent the
occurrence of earnings management (Beatty and Harris 1999; Man 2019). The theoretical assumptions
will also vary depending on the ownership structure. According to NUES (2018), long-term share
ownership by directors contributes to create an increased common financial interest between the
shareholders and the members of the board. With a majority shareholding in the company, and thus a
longer-term ownership perspective, an investor is incentivized to prioritize the company’s strategic
growth. Further, NUES (2018) emphasize that a short-term ownership perspective may work against
the best interest of the company and its shareholders. Prior studies on share ownership by directors
and earnings management reflects the inconsistent assumptions. Peasnell et al. (2005) found a positive,
though not significant, relation between share ownership by directors and earnings management,
while Gul et al. (2002) reported a significantly negative relation. In their meta-analysis, Lin and Hwang
(2010) documented no significant relationship. Based on the theoretical predictions and the existing
literature, the following two hypotheses have been made:

384
JRFM 2020, 13, 256

Hypothesis 3 (H3). There is a relation between share ownership by directors and earnings management.

Hypothesis 4 (H4). There is a negative relation between the percentage of directors as majority shareholders
and earnings management.

2.4. Board Activity


The board activity is measured by the board meeting frequency and is often considered an
indicator of the effort put in by the directors. It is generally believed that an active board is more
effective in monitoring the management (Ronen and Yaari 2008). Lipton and Lorsch (1992) stress
that a widely shared problem among directors is too little time to carry out their duties, pointing out
that more frequent board meetings will make directors more willing to perform their duties in line
with shareholders’ interests. The literature on board activity and earnings management consists of
contradictory conclusions. Vafeas (1999) and Xie et al. (2003) find that more frequent board meetings
lower the degree of earnings management, while other studies show either a positive relation between
board meeting frequency and earnings management (Daghsni et al. 2016) or no relation between them
at all (Ahmed 2007). Based on the contradictory literature, the fifth hypothesis is:

Hypothesis 5 (H5). There is a relation between board meeting frequency and earnings management.

Table 1. Presentation and description of the corporate governance variables along with the expected
impact on earnings management.

Variable Predicted Sign Definition


The percentage of independent
Board Independence −
shareholder-elected board members
dummy variable assigned the value 1 if the
Employee representatives: − board has employee representatives,
0 otherwise
Share ownership by Number of directors who directly or
+/−
directors indirectly holds shares in the company.
Directors as majority The percentage of directors as majority

shareholders shareholders
The number of board meetings held during
Board activity +/−
the period
Dummy variable that equal 1 if the company
Audit committee −
has an audit committee, 0 otherwise

2.5. Audit Committee


The Public Companies Act and the Stock Exchange Regulations stipulates whether Norwegian
public companies are required to establish an audit committee or not. The members of the audit
committee are elected by and among the board members and at least one of the members of the
committee must be independent with regards to NUES’ (2018) recommendations (Lekvall et al. 2014).
According to the Public Companies Act, the audit committee’s primary mission is to prepare the
supervision of the financial reporting process and monitor the systems for internal control and
risk management. The committee should further meet regularly with the firm’s external auditor
and internal financial managers to produce balanced and accurate reports. Accordingly, audit
committees complement existing internal governance practices by improving the monitoring function
and reduce agency conflicts (Cai et al. 2015). Prior studies have found a significant relation between
earnings management and audit committee practices (Bedard et al. 2004; Wan Mohammad et al. 2016).
Klein (2002) found that the existence of an audit committee will reduce earnings management. Similarly,

385
JRFM 2020, 13, 256

Dechow et al. (1996) and Purat Nelson and Devi (2013) found that firms manipulating earnings were
less likely to have an audit committee. The last hypothesis is formulated as follows:

Hypothesis 6 (H6). There is a negative relation between the presence of an audit committee and earnings
management.

3. Data and Methodology

3.1. Data And Sample Selection


Our initial dataset consisted of quarterly financial statements from 168 companies listed on the
Oslo Stock Exchange in the period 2014 to 2017. Due to difficulties in defining abnormal accruals in
the financial service industry, 16 bank and insurance companies were eliminated from the sample.
In addition, there is an exclusion of 18 companies that had not been listed for the entire period, 83 firms
due to lack of data and 2 firms due to mergers and acquisitions in the period (see Table 2). The financial
data was collected through the Thomson Reuters Eikon database, while the corporate governance data
was collected from companies’ annual reports. If the reports lacked data, it was retrieved directly from
the companies through e-mails and phone calls.
Table 2. Sample selection of the companies in the study.

Sample Selection
Companies listed on the Oslo Stock Exchange 12.31.17 168
− Companies in the financial service industry 16
− Not-continuously listed companies in the period 18
− Companies lost due to lack of data 83
− Companies lost due to mergers and acquisitions 2
= Companies included in the sample 49
Initial firm-quarter observations for 2014 to 2017 2688
− Companies in the financial service industry 256
− Not-continuously listed companies in the period 288
− Companies lost due to lack of data 1328
− Companies lost due to mergers and acquisitions 32
= Final sample 784

In Das et al.’s (2009) study on quarterly earnings patterns and earnings management, they find
that firms performing poorly in interim quarters may attempt to increase earnings in the fourth quarter
to achieve a desired annual earnings target. Accordingly, this study used data from quarterly reports in
the analyses to catch more of the fluctuations in earnings. Further, interim reports are often unaudited,
which allows greater managerial discretion and require less detailed disclosure than annual financial
statements (Jeter and Shivakumar 1999). Using quarterly financial data in the analysis could thus
increase the likelihood of detecting earnings management.

3.2. Measurement of Earnings Management


In the existing earnings management literature, a commonly used approach for detecting earnings
management is by examining accruals. The literature distinguishes between two widely used
approaches in defining total accruals: the balance sheet-based approach (Healy 1985; Jones 1991) and
the cash flow-based approach (Vinten et al. 2005). The cash flow approach measures accruals directly
from the statement of cash flows which mitigate the danger of measurement errors. Consequently,
this study used the cash flow approach to define total accruals. The cash flow approach measures total
accruals as the difference between the earnings of an entity and its cash flow generated from operating
activities. Thus, to calculate total accruals using the cash flow approach the following formula has
been used:
TAit = NIit − CFOit

386
JRFM 2020, 13, 256

where TAit = total accruals for company i in quarter t, NIit = net income for company i in quarter t and
CFOit = cash flow from operating activities for company i in quarter t.
Total accruals consist of a discretionary component and a nondiscretionary component.
Nondiscretionary accruals represent changes in a company’s underlying performance,
while discretionary accruals represent changes due to management’s accounting decisions
(Ronen and Yaari 2008). When estimating earnings management, it is the discretionary accruals that
are of interest. A fundamental issue is however the challenge of separating the discretionary and
nondiscretionary components of earnings (Elgers et al. 2003), since they cannot be directly observed.
Several methods have been developed to estimate the discretionary component of accruals. A widely
used approach is to benefit regression techniques, where total accruals are regressed on variables
that are proxies for normal accruals. Discretionary accruals were thus the unexplained component of
total accruals.
Several widely used regression techniques have their origin in the original Jones model
from 1991. This study used 2 modified versions of the original model; the Modified Jones model
proposed by Dechow et al. (1995) and a performance-matched model introduced by Kothari et al.
(2005). The Modified Jones model was designed to eliminate the assumed tendency of the Jones
model to measure discretionary accruals with error when discretion was exercised over revenues
(Dechow et al. 1995). The modification made from the original Jones model is that changes in revenues
are adjusted for the changes in receivables in the event period. When applying the Modified Jones
model, the nondiscretionary and the discretionary components of total accruals can be calculated by
the following equation (Dechow et al. 1995):

TAit 1 ΔREVit − ΔRECit PPEit


= β0 + β1 + β2 + β3 + εit . (1)
Ait−1 Ait−1 Ait−1 Ait−1

where

TAit = total accruals deflated by lagged total assets for company i in quarter t
Ait−1 = lagged total assets for company i in quarter t
ΔREVit = changes in total sales deflated by lagged total assets for company i in quarter t
ΔRECit = changes in account receivables deflated by total assets for company i in quarter t
PPEit = net value of property, plant and equipment deflated by lagged total assets for company i in
quarter t

Kothari et al.’s (2005) performance matched model is an extended version of the Modified Jones
model, where return on assets (ROA) is added as an additional variable. The following equation
is used:
TAit 1 ΔREVit − ΔRECit PPEit ROAit
= β0 + β1 + β2 + β3 + β4 + εit (2)
Ait−1 Ait−1 Ait−1 Ait−1 Ait−1
where

ROAit = net income after tax deflated by lagged total assets for company i in quarter t

Kothari et al. (2005) claim that economic intuition, empirical evidence and extant models of
accruals suggest that accruals are correlated with a firm’s present and past performance. Hence,
to control for performance on discretionary accruals, ROA is added as a control variable. Further,
because of the nonlinear relationship between accruals and performance, Kothari et al. (2005) argue
that a performance matched approach is better specified to test discretionary accruals than by using a
linear regression-based approach.
In both models the variables are deflated by lagged total assets to control for firm size effect
(Healy 1985; DeAngelo 1986) and to mitigate heteroscedasticity in the residuals (White 1980). Further,
nondiscretionary accruals are estimated using ordinary least squares (OLS). The prediction from the

387
JRFM 2020, 13, 256

OLS estimation in model (1) and model (2) represents nondiscretionary accruals while the residuals
represents discretionary accruals. Discretionary accruals can be both positive and negative. In the
analysis, the study used the absolute value of discretionary accruals as a proxy for earnings management
(as a normal procedure—see Hribar and Nichols (2007) for elaboration). Higher levels of discretionary
accruals indicate greater levels of earnings management.
The Modified Jones model (1) showed an explanatory power of 0.1139 (Table A1), while the Kothari
model (2) showed an explanatory power of 0.4334 (Table A2). The higher the explanatory power, the
closer the estimated regression equation fits the sample data (Brooks 2019). Hence, the measure of
discretionary accruals following the Kothari model (2) was used as the dependent variable for the
further corporate governance analysis.

3.3. Corporate Governance


After estimating the extent of discretionary accruals, the relation between earnings management
and the corporate governance practices was investigated. In the regression, the corporate governance
practices represented the following independent variables:
Board independence: referred to the percentage of shareholder-elected directors that were
evaluated as independent with respect to the company’s executive management, material business
contacts and main shareholders.
Employee representatives: referred to the presence of employee representatives or not. The variable
was calculated as a dummy variable assigned the value 1 if the board has employee representatives,
0 otherwise.
Share ownership by directors: referred to the percentage of directors who directly or indirectly
holds shares in the company. The variable was calculated by scaling the total number of directors who
holds shares by total board size.
Directors as majority shareholders: referred to the percentage of directors who directly or indirectly
is listed amongst the company’s 20 largest shareholders. The variable was calculated by scaling the
total number of directors who are majority shareholders by total board size.
Board activity: referred to the total number of meetings held during a year, scaled by quarter.
The variable was calculated using the natural logarithm of total board meetings2 .
Audit committee: referred to the presence of an audit committee or not. The variable was
calculated as a dummy variable assigned the value 1 if the firm has an audit committee, 0 otherwise.
Earnings management decisions can also be influenced by factors other than the explanatory
variables included in this analysis. To control for this and for any spurious relations between board
characteristics and earnings management, the control variables firm size, return on assets and return
on equity were included.
Firm size: the natural logarithm of total assets was used as a proxy for firm size.
Return on assets: net income divided by total assets was used as a measure for firm performance.
Return on equity: total equity divided by total assets was used as a measure for firm profitability.
To test the hypotheses’, the following equation was used:

absDAit = β0 + β1 (BISEit ) + β2 (DERit ) + β3 (SODit ) + β4 (MJSit ) + β5 (BAit )


(3)
+β6 (ACit ) + β7 (FSit ) + β8 (ROAit ) + β9 (ROEit ) + εit

absDAit = absolute value of discretionary accruals for company i in quarter t


BISEit = board independence for company i in quarter t
DERit = dummy variable that equal 1 if the company has employee representatives on the board,
0 otherwise

2 The natural logarithm is used to correct for heteroscedasticity (Benoit 2011).

388
JRFM 2020, 13, 256

SODit = share ownership by directors for company i in quarter t


MJSit = directors as majority shareholders for company i in quarter t
BAit = board activity for company i in quarter t
ACit = dummy variable that equal 1 if the company has an audit committee, 0 otherwise
FSit = firm size for company i in quarter t
ROAit = return on assets for company i in quarter t
ROEit = return on equity for company i in quarter t

Our study used panel data, featured by exploring the cross-section and time-series data
simultaneously. A Hausman test (Table A3), showed that fixed effects estimator was a better fit
for the model than the random effects estimator3 . Moreover, Equation (3) using OLS was estimated.
Additional analysis of the residuals from this estimation displayed significant heteroscedasticity.
Consequently, the regression using robust standard errors was estimated. In regression estimates,
multicollinearity due to a significant linear relationship between the explanatory variables can affect
the estimation of the coefficients of the variables, leading to imprecise results. To test the severity of
multicollinearity in the data, a correlation matrix and the Variance Inflation Factor (VIF) method was
used. According to Brooks (2019), severe multicollinearity is indicated if the correlation between 2
variables exceeds 0.80 and the VIF index exceed 5. The VIF for each explanatory variable was under 5,
with a total mean of 1.6. Supported by the correlation matrix, multicollinearity was not a problem
to the model. The correlation matrix and VIF index for the variables are reported in the Appendix A
(Tables A4 and A5).

4. Empirical Results

4.1. Descriptive Statistics


Table 3 reports descriptive statistics for the sample firms. The absolute value of discretionary
accruals has a small mean of 0.03 with a standard deviation of 0.04. The percentage of board
independence spans from 0.00 to 1.00, indicating that the sample consists of firms with both 100 percent
independent boards and zero percent independent boards. On average the presence of independent
shareholder-elected board members is 70 percent. The number of board meetings held by the board of
directors is on average 0.95 per quarter4 , while the minimum and maximum number of meetings per
quarter is respectively 0.00 and 2.205 . Further, the descriptive statistics show that the sample consists
of firms with both 100 percent share ownership by directors and zero percent share ownership by
directors. The mean of share ownership by directors is 63 percent. With respect to the percentage of
directors as majority shareholders, the average is 22 percent. The mean of the dummy variable for
employee representatives on the board is 0.46, indicating that 46 percent of the sample firms have
boards with presence of employee representatives. The dummy variable referring to the presence
of an audit committee shows that 92 percent of the sample firms have an audit committee. Finally,
the remaining variables included in the model were control variables for different firm characteristics
and were not central to our study.

3 The dummy variables concerning employee representation and audit committee are not considered time-invariant explanatory
variables. They will therefore not be absorbed by the intercept in the fixed effects model.
4 This is equivalent to an average e0.95 ≈ 2.59 per quarter.
5 This is equivalent to a minimum value of e0.00 ≈ 1 per quarter and a maximum value of e2.20 ≈ 9 per quarter.

389
JRFM 2020, 13, 256

Table 3. Descriptive statistics for the sample firms.

- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - Quantiles - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
n Mean S.D. Min 0.25 Mdn 0.75 Max
Discretionary accruals 784 0.03 0.04 0.00 0.01 0.02 0.04 0.44
Board independence 784 0.70 0.20 0.00 0.60 0.71 0.80 1.00
Employee representatives 784 0.46 0.50 0.00 0.00 0.00 1.00 1.00
Share ownership by directors 784 0.63 0.22 0.00 0.50 0.63 0.80 1.00
Directors as majority
784 0.22 0.21 0.00 0.00 0.20 0.33 1.00
shareholders
Board activity 784 0.95 0.37 0.00 0.69 0.92 1.18 2.20
Audit Committee 784 0.92 0.27 0.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00

4.2. Regression Results


Table 4 reports the results of the multivariate regression analysis on the panel data. The R-square
is the coefficient of determination, and the value of 0.204 indicates that 20.4 percent of the variation in
discretionary accruals is explained by the regression equation.
If we exclude the corporate governance variables (see Table A6 in the Appendix A), the results
vary little to nothing compared to the results in Table 4. The difference between the two models
is seen in the quality of the model, where Table 4 shows an r-squared of 0.204 compared to 0.148
in Table A6. This implies that model (3), as shown in Table 4 with the corporate governance
variables, has a substantially bigger r-squared, and thus explains more of the variation in the absolute
discretionary accruals.

4.2.1. Results Hypothesis 1—Board Independence


The panel regression analysis provides a significantly positive relation between the proportion of
independent board members and earnings management, providing evidence that the occurrence of
earnings management increases in line with the percentage of board independence. Thus, the results do
not coincide with the hypothesis, nor the results of Beasley (1996), Dechow et al. (1996), Peasnell et al.
(2005) and Klein (2002). Nevertheless, the result is of interest. The previously mentioned studies are all
recognized and well-established in the earnings management literature, yet one could argue that firms,
legislations and codes of best practices have changed since the studies were conducted. However, our
finding is not strong, so our following comments could be related to the mere absence of a significant
result of the hypothesis. Recent changes may imply that the current recommendations regarding
independence could benefit from a reconsideration considering today’s business environment and the
experiences made during the recent decades. Moreover, looking beyond the earnings management
literature, the findings may support Van den Berghe and Baelden (2005) argument that it may not
be sufficient for good corporate governance to implement a formal standard on board independence
alone. They argue that “soft” elements like character, attitude and independence of mind are equally
important elements to the concept of independence6 . Accordingly, as stated in the report of the
Conference Board on Corporate Governance Best Practices, “directors must not only be independent
according to evolving legislative and stock exchange listing standards, but also independent in thought
and action—qualitative independent” (Brancato and Plath 2003).

6 This argument was also brought to concern by Åse Aulie Michelet on NUES’ 2017 annual debate for good corporate
governance practices, arguing that for directors to truly be independent they must be able to promote and defend their own
opinions (Bjørklund 2017).

390
JRFM 2020, 13, 256

4.2.2. Results Hypothesis 2—Employee Representatives


The regression results indicate that employee representation has a direct negative effect on
earnings management, as expected in the hypothesis. The finding may be due to several causes. In line
with Fauver and Fuerst (2006) analysis on German companies, the result could imply that employee
representation provides a credible channel for information to the board of directors. Supported by
the findings of Chen et al. (2015), this could improve the quality of managerial monitoring and board
decision-making since employee representation provides a richer information environment. Moreover,
one could argue that the operational information provided by the employee representatives helps to
decrease the control issue of information asymmetry. In line with the findings of Gul et al. (2002),
Peasnell et al. (2005) and Beatty and Harris (1999), the assumed increased monitoring quality and
decreased information asymmetry brought to the board by employee representation is seemingly
effective in mitigating agency costs and earnings management.
Table 4. Regression results of model (3).

Variables Dependent Variable: Discretionary Accruals (absDA)


Board Independence (BISE) 0.025 *
(0.014)
Employee Representatives (DER) −0.011 **
(0.004)
Share ownership by directors (SOD) 0.020 *
(0.012)
Directors as majority shareholders (MJS) −0.012
(0.020)
Board Activity (BA) 0.016
(0.009)
Audit Committee (AC) −0.071 *
(0.038)
Firm Size (FS) −0.014 **
(0.006)
Return on assets (ROA) −0.100 ***
(0.037)
Return on equity (ROE) −0.015 ***
(0.002)
Constant 0.178 ***
(0.043)
Observations 784
Number of Identifications 49
R-squared 0.204
Notes: The equation used to test the hypotheses’: absDAit = β0 + β1 (BISEit ) + β2 (DERit ) + β3 (SODit ) +
β4 (MJSit ) + β5 (BAit ) + β6 (ACit ) + β7 (FSit ) + β8 (ROAit ) + β9 (ROEit ) + εit (3). ***, ** and * indicate the significance
level at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively (two-tailed). All numbers reported in NOK million. Robust standard errors in
parentheses, *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1.

4.2.3. Results Hypothesis 3 and 4—Share Ownership by Directors


The regression analysis shows a significantly positive relationship between share ownership
by directors and earnings management, suggesting a direct positive effect between increasing the
percentage of directors who owns shares in the company and the latitude of earnings management.
The finding is not in line with the hypothesis, nor the results of Gul et al. (2002). As suggested
by Kanagaretnam et al. (2007), directors’ shareholdings are associated with smaller increases in
information asymmetry, which in turn has the potential to reduce agency costs and thus mitigate
the occurrence of earnings management. With respect to the finding, one could therefore argue that
there may be other elements of importance when evaluating the effect of directors’ shareholdings
on earnings management. Supported by Lin and Hwang (2010), the result may provide evidence
that directors who own shares in the company are subject to weakened independence and weakened

391
JRFM 2020, 13, 256

effectiveness in impartial monitoring, leading to increased agency problems and earnings management.
The result is fairly congruent with the findings of Peasnell et al. (2005), who found a positive, though
not significant relationship between directors’ shareholding and earnings management. It would
also be of importance to include the fourth hypothesis in this analysis to more thoroughly assess the
assumption. For the fourth hypothesis, the analysis finds a negative, though not significant relation
between majority shareholding by directors and earnings management. Even though the result does
not support a direct negative effect on earnings management, its implications are of interest. It could
imply that majority share ownership gives directors an incentive to prioritize the company’s strategic
growth. If so, this would help to reduce agency problems related to dissimilar financial interests
between the shareholders and the members of the board. The sample data shows that the mean of
share ownership by directors and the mean of majority shareholding by directors are respectively 63
percent and 22 percent of the total board size. This implicates that on average 65 percent of the directors
who own shares in the company are considered minority share owners with a greater likelihood of
a short-term ownership perspective. Given a short-term ownership perspective, they have greater
incentives to pursue higher-risk strategies to generate larger financial returns. Combined, these
assumptions could implicate that companies with large proportions of minority shareholders on the
board manage earnings more frequently. Given these findings, the results corroborate NUES (2018)
recommendations regarding directors’ long-term and short-term shareholdings.

4.2.4. Results Hypothesis 5—Board Activity


The results of the panel regression suggest a positive, though insignificant relation between board
activity and earnings management. This implies that board meeting frequency does not seem to have a
direct effect on earnings management, in contradiction to what was expected in the hypothesis and the
results of Vafeas (1999), Xie et al. (2003) and Daghsni et al. (2016). The result is however in line with
previous studies conducted by Ahmed (2007) and Ahmed (2007). It is worth noticing that the p-value
of 0.103 is close to a 10 percent significant level.

4.2.5. Results Hypothesis 6—Audit Committee


Further, the regression analysis points out that an audit committee who supervises the financial
reporting and disclosure negatively affects the occurrence of earnings management. This is in line
with the hypothesis and the studies conducted by Klein (2002) and Dechow et al. (1996). The finding
implies that the audit committee’s role in board matters contributes to create trust by securing internal
control of financial reporting and that the firm complies with laws and regulations. In addition, one
could argue that the regular contact they have with the firm’s external auditor could be effective in
reducing agency conflicts as they weigh divergent views to produce a more balanced and accurate
financial report.
Finally, the control variables behave as expected and are consistent with other earnings
management studies (Iqbal et al. 2015; Daghsni et al. 2016). Firm size is found to be negatively related
with earnings management, indicating that the occurrence of earnings management is decreasing in
line with the size of the firm. The results further show that ROA and ROE negatively affects earnings
management, suggesting that earnings management decreases as firm performance and profitability
increases. In addition, all control variables are significant.

4.3. More Discussion


We do acknowledge the potential of endogeneity issues in our analysis, as e. g. omitted variables.
We are also aware of the important role of firm size in this kind of research, and thus can affect the
independent and dependent variables simultaneously—see Coles and Li (2020) for a comprehensive
discussion. Moreover, we observe that robustness tests can weaken our findings to some degree,
however our main message of the analysis remains.

392
JRFM 2020, 13, 256

5. Conclusions
Cited as the next supermodel for corporate governance (The Economist 2013), it is of interest to
examine corporate governance practices within the Nordic model of corporate governance. The purpose
of this study was to provide insight to better assess the relation between Nordic corporate governance
practices and earnings management, and potentially highlight the benefits of the model. The robust
multivariate regression analysis under the fixed effect estimator has been used for estimation,
while the absolute value of discretionary accruals is used as a proxy for earnings management
(Hribar and Nichols 2007).
The presence of employee representation on the board and the presence of an audit committee
are both practices that seem to reduce the occurrence of earnings management. The negative relation
between the presence of an audit committee and earnings management is already well-established in
the earnings management literature (Klein 2002; Dechow et al. 1996), while the findings of employee
representation is to some extent new insight. Our findings may suggest that employee representatives
provide a credible channel for information, contributing to a richer information environment. This can
mitigate agency costs and earnings management and could imply that there are other important aspects
of independence that should be taken into consideration to improve the quality of the directors. As for
the results regarding share ownership by directors, the findings indicate that large proportions of
minority shareholders on the board could give the directors incentives to pursue higher-risk strategies
to generate larger financial returns. Finally, board activity and directors as majority shareholders
both presented insignificant relations to earnings management. Still, their implications on earnings
management may be of interest.
The contribution of this study is not without limitations. First, by using discretionary accruals as a
measurement for earnings management one relies solely on proxy measures. Hence, one cannot exclude
the possibility that the findings are subject to more natural accounting explanations than earnings
management. Second, the relatively small sample size could affect the accuracy of the estimations.
Third, our model is not without econometric challenges, and, finally, the corporate governance model
may not be enough in capturing the omission of other corporate governance variables. These limitations
may constrain the validity of the findings.

Author Contributions: Conceptualization, F.K., A.S. and A.V.; methodology, A.T.H.; software, A.T.H.; formal
analysis, A.S. and A.V.; investigation, A.S. and A.V.; data curation, A.S. and A.V.; writing—original draft
preparation, A.S. and A.V.; writing—review and editing, F.K.; supervision, F.K.; project administration, F.K.
All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.
Funding: This research received no external funding.
Acknowledgments: We appreciate the thoughtful comments and constructive suggestions from two
anonymous reviewers.
Conflicts of Interest: The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A
Table A1. The Modified Jones model (1).

Variable Dependent Variable: Total Accruals


1/Ait−1 −4.014 ***(0.398)
ΔREVit − ΔRECit −0.07(0.037)
PPEit −0.021 ***(0.07)
Constant −0.013 ***(0.003)
Observations 784
R-squared 0.117
TAit
Notes: The equation for the Modified Jones model developed by Dechow et al. (1995): Ait−1 = β0 + β1 A 1 +
it−1
ΔREVit −ΔRECit PPEit
β2 Ait−1 + β3 A + εit (1). Standard errors in parentheses, *** p < 0.01.
it−1

393
JRFM 2020, 13, 256

Table A2. The performance matched model (2).

Variables Dependent Variable: Total Accruals


1/Ait−1 −0.213
(0.366)
ΔREVit − ΔRECit −0.123 ***
(0.030)
PPEit −0.012 **
(0.006)
ROAit 0.615 ***
(0.029)
Constant −0.016 ***
(0.003)
Observations 784
R-squared 0.436
TAit
Notes: The equation for the performance matched model by Kothari et al. (2005): Ait−1 = β0 + β1 A 1 +
it−1
ΔREVit −ΔRECit PPEit ROAit
β2 Ait−1 + β3 A + β4 Ait−1 + εit (2). Standard errors in parentheses, *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05.
it−1

Table A3. Hausman test model (3).

Test Summary Chi-sq. Statistic Chi-Sq. d.f. p-Value


143.00 9 0.0000
Notes: Test of H0 : difference in coefficients is not systematic. The random effects estimator is chosen if the p-value is
> 0.05, and the fixed effect estimator is chosen otherwise.

Table A4. Correlation matrix.

Abs_DA BISE DER SOD MJS BA AC FS ROA ROE


Abs_DA 1.00
BISE −0.02 1.00
DER −0.19 0.30 1.00
SOD 0.03 −0.09 −0.09 1.00
MJS −0.01 −0.65 −0.46 0.33 1.00
BA −0.04 0.01 0.08 0.08 0.07 1.00
AC −0.39 0.11 0.28 −0.28 −0.17 0.11 1.00
FS −0.42 0.20 0.41 −0.01 −0.21 0.10 0.51 1.00
ROA −0.44 −0.03 0.21 −0.17 −0.08 −0.01 0.36 0.30 1.00
ROE −0.21 0.02 0.14 −0.11 −0.10 −0.07 0.10 0.13 0.49 1.00
Notes: According to Brooks (2019) a correlation between two variables that exceeds 0.80 indicates severe multicollinearity.
The variables are defined as: abs_DA = absolute value of discretionary accruals, BISE = board independence, DER =
employee representatives, SOD = share ownership by directors, MJS = directors as majority shareholders, BA = board
activity, AC = audit committee, FS = firm size, ROA = return on assets, ROE = return on equity.

Table A5. Variation inflation factors (VIF).

Variable VIF 1/VIF


abs_DA 1.47 0.6792
BISE 1.84 0.5438
DER 1.50 0.6686
SOD 1.33 0.7507
MJS 2.42 0.4127
BA 1.07 0.9389
AC 1.65 0.6060
FS 1.70 0.5885
ROA 1.70 0.5870
ROE 1.35 0.7424
Mean VIF 1.60
Notes: According to Brooks (2019) a VIF index over five indicates severe multicollinearity. The variables are defined
as: abs_DA = absolute value of discretionary accruals, BISE = board independence, DER = employee representatives,
SOD = share ownership by directors, MJS = directors as majority shareholders, BA = board activity, AC = audit
committee, FS = firm size, ROA = return on assets, ROE = return on equity.

394
JRFM 2020, 13, 256

Table A6. Regression results of model (3) without corporate governance variables.

Variables Dependent Variable: Discretionary Accruals (absDA)


Firm size (FS) −0.02 ***
(0.003)
Return on assets (ROA) −0.111 ***
(0.021)
Return on equity (ROE) −0.011 *
(0.006)
Constant 0.206 ***
(0.030)
Observations 784
Number of Identifications 49
R-squared 0.148
Notes: The equation used to test the robustness: absDAit = β0 + β1 (FSit ) + β2 (ROAit ) + β3 (ROEit ) + εit (3).
*** and * indicate the significance level at 1% and 10%, respectively (two-tailed). All numbers reported in NOK
million. Robust standard errors in parentheses, *** p < 0.01, * p < 0.1

References
Ahmed, Ebrahim. 2007. Earnings management and board activity: An additional evidence. Review of Accounting
& Finance 6: 42. [CrossRef]
Ahmed, Sohail. 2007. Board of director characteristics and earnings management in Malaysia. Journal on Business
Review 2. Available online: http://dl6.globalstf.org/index.php/gbr/article/viewFile/183/181 (accessed on
5 February 2020).
Al-Jaifi, Hamdan Amer. 2017. Ownership concentration, earnings management and stock martket liquidity:
Evidence from Malaysia. Corporate Governance 17: 490–510. [CrossRef]
Beasley, Mark S. 1996. An Empirical Analysis of the Relation between the Board of Director Composition and
Financial Statement Fraud. The Accounting Review 71: 443–65. [CrossRef]
Beatty, Anne, and David G. Harris. 1999. The Effects of Taxes, Agency Costs and Information Asymmetry on
Earnings Management: A Comparison of Public and Private Firms. Review of Accounting Studies 4: 299–326.
[CrossRef]
Bedard, Jean, Sonda M. Chtourou, and Lucie Courteau. 2004. The effect of audit committee expertise, independence,
and activity on aggressive earnings management. Auditing: A Journal of Practice & Theory 23: 13. [CrossRef]
Beneish, Messod D. 2001. Earnings management: A perspective. Managerial Finance 27: 3–17. [CrossRef]
Benoit, Kenneth J. 2011. Linear regression models with logarithmic transformations. London School of Economics 22:
23–36.
Berle, Adolf A., and Gardener C. Means. 1932. The Modern Corporation and Private Property. New York: Transaction
Publishers.
Bjørklund, Ingrid. 2017. Det hjelper ikke å være kompetent hvis man ikke tør å si noe. Dagens Næringsliv 10: 13.
Available online: https://www.dn.no/arbeidsliv/-det-hjelper-ikke-a-vare-kompetent-hvis-man-ikke-tor-a-si-
noe/2-1-186667 (accessed on 5 February 2020). (In Norwegian).
Brancato, Carolyn K., and Christine Plath. 2003. Corporate Governance Best Practices: A Blueprint for the Post-Enron
Era. New York: Conference Board.
Brooks, Chris. 2019. Introductory Econometrics for Finance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Busirin, Mohd F., Nurul A. Azmi, and Nor B. Zakaria. 2015. How Effective is Board Independence to the
Monitoring of Earnings Manipulation? Procedia Economics and Finance 31: 462–69. [CrossRef]
Cai, Charlie X., David Hiller, Gaoliang Tian, and Quinghua Wu. 2015. Do audit committees reduce the agency
costs of ownership structure? Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 35: 225–40. [CrossRef]
Campa, Domenico, and Ray Donnelly. 2014. An assessment of corporate govenance reforms in Italy based on a
comparative analysis of earnings management. Corporate Governance 14: 407–23. [CrossRef]
Chen, Xia, Quiang Cheng, and Xin Wang. 2015. Does increased board independence reduce earnings management?
Evidence from recent regulatory reforms. Review of Accounting Studies 20: 899–933. [CrossRef]
Coffee, John C., Jr. 2002. Understanding Enron: “It’s about the gatekeepers, stupid”. Business Lawyer 57: 1403–20.
[CrossRef]

395
JRFM 2020, 13, 256

Coles, Jeffrey L., and Zhichuan Li. 2020. Managerial Attributes, Incentives and Performance. The Review of
Corporate Finance Studies 9: 256–301. [CrossRef]
Daghsni, Olfa, Mighri Zouhayer, and Karim B. H. Mbarek. 2016. Earnings management and board characteristics:
Evidence from French listed firms. Arabian Journal of Buisness and Management Review 1: 92–110.
Das, Somnath, Pervin K. Shroff, and Haiwen Zhang. 2009. Quarterly earnings patterns and earnings management.
Contemporary Accounting Research 26: 797–831. [CrossRef]
DeAngelo, Linda E. 1986. Accounting Numbers as Market Valuation Substitutes: A Study of Management Buyouts
of Public Stockholders. The Accounting Review 61: 400–20.
Dechow, Patricia M. 1994. Accounting earnings and cash flows as measures of firm performance: The role of
accounting accruals. Journal of Accounting and Economics 18: 3–42. [CrossRef]
Dechow, Patricia M., Richard G. Sloan, and Amy P. Sweeney. 1995. Detecting earnings management. Accounting
Review 70: 193–225.
Dechow, Patricia M., Richard G. Sloan, and Amy P. Sweeney. 1996. Causes and consequences of earnings
manipulation: An analysis of firms subject to enforcement actions by the SEC. Contemporary Accounting
Research 13: 1–36. [CrossRef]
Elgers, Pieter T., Ray J. Pfeiffer Jr., and Susan L. Porter. 2003. Anticipatory income smoothing: A re-examination.
Journal of Accounting Economics 35: 405–22. [CrossRef]
Fama, Eugene F. 1980. Agency Problems and the Theory of the Firm. Journal of Political Economy 88: 288–307.
[CrossRef]
Fama, Eugene F., and Michael C. Jensen. 1983. Separation of Ownership and Control. The Journal of Law and
Economics 26: 301–25. [CrossRef]
Fauver, Larry, and Michael E. Fuerst. 2006. Does good corporate governance include employee representation?
Evidence from German corporate boards. Journal of Financial Economics 82: 673–710. [CrossRef]
Gjesdal, Frøystein. 1981. Accounting for Stewardship. Journal of Accounting Research 19: 208–31. [CrossRef]
Gul, Ferdinand A., Stephen G. Lynn, and Judy S. L. Tsui. 2002. Audit Quality, Management Ownership, and the
Informativeness of Accounting Earnings. Journal of Accounting, Auditing & Finance 17: 25–49. [CrossRef]
Haldar, Arunima, Reeta Shah, Nagaeswara Rao, Peter Stokes, Dilek Demirbas, and Ali Dardour. 2018. Corporate
performance: Does board independence matter?—Indian evidence. International Journal of Organizational
Analysis 26: 185–200. [CrossRef]
Healy, Paul M., and James M. Wahlen. 1999. A review of the earnings management literature and its implications
for standard setting. Accounting Horizons 13: 365–83. [CrossRef]
Healy, Paul M. 1985. The effect of bonus schemes on accounting decisions. Journal of Accounting Economics 7:
85–107. [CrossRef]
Hribar, Paul, and Craig Nichols. 2007. The Use of Unsigned Earnings Quality Measures in Tests of Earnings
Management. Journal of Accounting Research 45: 1017–53. [CrossRef]
Iqbal, Amjad, Xianzhi Zhang, and Khalil Jebran. 2015. Corporate Governance and Earnings Management: A Case
of Karachi Stock Exchange Listed Companies. Indian Journal of Corporate Governance 8: 103–18. [CrossRef]
Jensen, Michael C., and William H. Meckling. 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and
ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3: 305–60. [CrossRef]
Jeter, Debra C., and Lakshamanan Shivakumar. 1999. Cross-sectional estimation of abnormal accruals using
quarterly and annual data: Effectiveness in detecting event-specific earnings management. Accounting
Business Research 29: 299–319. [CrossRef]
Jones, Jennifer J. 1991. Earnings management during import relief investigations. Journal of Accounting Research 29:
193–228. [CrossRef]
Kanagaretnam, Kiridaran, Gerald J. Lobo, and Dennis J. Whalen. 2007. Does good corporate governance reduce
information asymmetry around quarterly earnings announcements? Journal of Accounting Public Policy 26:
497–522. [CrossRef]
Karmel, Hany, and Said Elbanna. 2012. Investigating the phenomenon of earnings management in the Egyptian
stock market. Corporate Governance 12: 337–52. [CrossRef]
Kasznik, Ron. 1999. On the association between voluntary disclosure and earnings management. Journal of
Accounting Research 37: 57–81. [CrossRef]
Klein, April. 2002. Audit committee, board of director characteristics, and earnings management. Journal of
Accounting and Economics 33: 375–400. [CrossRef]

396
JRFM 2020, 13, 256

Kothari, S. P., Andrew J. Leone, and Charles E. Wasley. 2005. Performance matched discretionary accrual measures.
Journal of Accounting and Economics 39: 163–97. [CrossRef]
Lekvall, Per, Ronald J. Gilson, Jesper L. Hansen, Carsten Lønfeldt, Manne Airaksinen, Tom Berglund, Tom
von Weymarn, Harald Norvik, Rolf Skog, and Erik Sjöman. 2014. The Nordic Corporate Governance Model.
Edited by Per Lekvall. Stockholm: SNS Förlag, December, Nordic & European Company Law Working
Paper No. 14-12. Available online: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2534331 (accessed on 5 February 2020).
Li, Zhichuan F., and Caleb Thibodeau. 2019. CSR-Contingent Executive Compensation Incentive and Earnings
Management. Sustainability 11: 3421. [CrossRef]
Lin, Jerry W., and Mark I. Hwang. 2010. Audit Quality, Corporate Governance, and Earnings Management:
A Meta-Analysis. International Journal of Auditing 14: 57–77. [CrossRef]
Lipton, Martin, and Jay W. Lorsch. 1992. A Modest Proposal for Improved Corporate Governance. The Business
Lawyer 48: 59.
Liu, Qiao, and Zhou Lu. 2007. Corporate governance and earnings management in the Chinese listed companies:
A tunneling perspective. Journal of Corporate Finance 13: 881–906. [CrossRef]
Lourenco, Isabel C., Alex Rathke, Veronika Santana, and Manuel C. Branco. 2018. Corruption and earnings
management in developed and emerging countries. Corporate Governace 18: 35–41.
Man, Chi-Keung, and Brossa Wong. 2013. Corporate governance and earnings management: A survey of literature.
Journal of Applied Business Research 29: 301–418. [CrossRef]
Man, Yimei. 2019. Earnings Management and Agency Costs: Evidence from China. Ph.D. thesis, The University
of Waikato, Hamilton, New Zealand.
Marchini, Pier L., Tatiana Mazza, and Alice Medioli. 2018. Related party transactions, corporate governance and
earnings management. Corporate Governace 18: 1124–46.
Messier, William F., Steven M. Glover, and Douglas F. Prawitt. 2008. Auditing & Assurance Services: A Systematic
Approach. Boston: McGraw-Hill Irwin.
Monks, Robert A. G., and Neil Minow. 2008. International Governance. West Sussex: John Wiley & Sons Ltd.
NUES. 2018. The Norwegian Code of Practice for Corporate Governance. Available online: http://nues.no/eierstyring-
og-selskapsledelse/ (accessed on 5 February 2020).
Payne, Jeff L., and Sean W. G. Robb. 2000. Earnings Management: The Effect of Ex Ante Earnings Expectations.
Journal of Accounting, Auditing & Finance 15: 371–92. [CrossRef]
Peasnell, Ken V., Peter F. Pope, and Steven Young. 2000. Accrual Management to Meet Earnings Targets: UK
Evidence Pre- and Post-Cadbury. The British Accounting Review 32: 415–45. [CrossRef]
Peasnell, K. V., Peter F. Pope, and Steven Young. 2005. Board Monitoring and Earnings Management: Do Outside
Directors Influence Abnormal Accruals? Journal of Business Finance & Accounting 32: 1311–46. [CrossRef]
Purat Nelson, S., and S. Devi. 2013. Audit committee experts and audit quality. Corporate Governace: The
International Journal of Business in Society 13: 335–51.
Ronen, Joshua, and Varda Yaari. 2008. Earnings Management: Emerging Insights in Theory, Practice, and Research.
Boston: Springer US.
Rosenstein, Stuart, and Jeffrey G. Wyatt. 1990. Outside directors, board independence, and shareholder wealth.
Journal of Financial Economics 26: 175–91. [CrossRef]
Roychowdhury, Sugata. 2006. Earnings management through real activities manipulation. Journal of Accounting
and Economics 42: 335–70. [CrossRef]
Teoh, Siew H., Iwo Welch, and T. J. Wong. 1998. Earnings Management and the Long-Run Market Performance of
Initial Public Offerings. Journal of Finance 53: 1935–74. [CrossRef]
The Economist. 2013. The Nordic Countries: The Next Supermodel. Available online: https://www.economist.com/
leaders/2013/02/02/the-next-supermodel (accessed on 4 January 2020).
Vafeas, Nikos. 1999. Board meeting frequency and firm performance. Journal of Financial Economics 53: 113–42.
[CrossRef]
Van den Berghe, L. A. A., and Tom Baelden. 2005. The complex relation between director independence and board
effectiveness. Corporate Governance 5: 58–83. [CrossRef]

397
JRFM 2020, 13, 256

Vinten, Gerald, Ken Y. Chen, Kuen-Lin Lin, and Jian Zhou. 2005. Audit quality and earnings management for
Taiwan IPO firms. Managerial Auditing Journal 20: 86–104.
Wan Mohammad, Wan M., Shaista Wasiuzzaman, and Mohamad Z. Nik Salleh. 2016. Board and audit committee
effectiveness, ethnic diversification and earnings management: A study of the Malaysian manufacturing
sector. Corporate Governance 16: 726–46. [CrossRef]
White, Halbert. 1980. A heteroskedasticity-consistent covariance matrix estimator and a direct test for
heteroskedasticity. Econometrica 48: 817–38. [CrossRef]
Xie, Biao, Wallace N. Davidson, and Peter J. Dadalt. 2003. Earnings management and corporate governance:
The role of the board and the audit committee. Journal of Corporate Finance 9: 295–316. [CrossRef]
Xu, Randall Z., Gary K. Taylor, and Michael T. Dugan. 2007. Review of Real Earnings Management Literature.
Journal of Accounting Literature 26: 195–228.

Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional
affiliations.

© 2020 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access
article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution
(CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).

398
MDPI
St. Alban-Anlage 66
4052 Basel
Switzerland
Tel. +41 61 683 77 34
Fax +41 61 302 89 18
www.mdpi.com

Journal of Risk and Financial Management Editorial Office


E-mail: jrfm@mdpi.com
www.mdpi.com/journal/jrfm
MDPI
St. Alban-Anlage 66
4052 Basel
Switzerland
Tel: +41 61 683 77 34
Fax: +41 61 302 89 18
www.mdpi.com ISBN 978-3-0365-0571-8

You might also like