Economic and Political Weekly Economic and Political Weekly

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 7

Crisis of Increasing Costs in Agriculture: Is There a Way Out?

Authors(s): M. V. Nadkarni
Source: Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 23, No. 39 (Sep. 24, 1988), pp. A114-A119
Published by: Economic and Political Weekly
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/4379085
Accessed: 30-03-2016 10:37 UTC

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
http://about.jstor.org/terms

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted
digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about
JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Economic and Political Weekly is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to
Economic and Political Weekly

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 150.216.68.200 on Wed, 30 Mar 2016 10:37:13 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Crisis of Increasing Costs in Agriculture
Is There a Way Out?
M V Nadkarni

The increasing costs, in the manufacturing sector have received considerable attention in recent years. But the
situation in agriculture is no less serious. The output-input ratios are declining and costs per unit of output are
increasing rapidly. The rate of growth in inputs per hectare has been more than double that of output. Clearly,
we are increasing the productivity of our land through a strategy which is proving to be increasingly costly, reflecting
the inherently unsustainable character of the increase in productivity.
BEING a pioneer in evolving national in- input ratio declined at an average rate of 0.05 affairs in agriculture is the choice of develop-
come accounting for India, it was only point per year between 1960-61 and 1979-80 meint strategy in agriculture, which relies
natural that V K R V Rao provided many in terms of Rao's calculation, it declined at principally on high-cost industrial inputs like
valuable insights into the working of the the higher rate of 0.07 point per year fertiliser, pesticides, mnachinery and diesel.
Indian economy when he came back to his between 1970-71 and 1984-85. The cause for Since local varieties had a low yield and since
pet field again in the eaily eighties. One of cooncern, therefore, continues to exist in High Yielding Varieties (HYVs) were ferti-
these insights based on his analysis of agriculture. liser responsive, it looked evident that
National Accounting Statistics (NAS) since The increasing costs in the manutacturinig reliance on these inputs was indispensable
1950 is contained in his observation on how sector have received considerable attention for self-reliance in foodgrains. These inputs
"India is developing into a high cost in recent years. It is true that there is cause cannot be produced on farms and have to
economy in spite of its comparatively low for concern in this sector too since the be purchased from the markets, making
level of employee compensation. No doubt, output-input ratio, already the lowest amiion*g them more vulnerable to the market, a con-
there has been economic growth and a all sectors, continues to fall. With the pro- sequence of which is reflected in the terms
substantial increase in national output, but portion of value added in the total output ot trade discussed in the next section. But
this is being achieved by increasing costs" beiiig reduced to marginal levels, growth and even apart trom this question of terms of
[Rao, 1983, p 179]. employimeint prospects in the sector caninot trade, it has rcached a situation which shifts
Using the disaggregated data from the be bright unless technological breakthroughs the generation of value added from agri-
NAS about inputs and outputs in three take place to lower per unit costs significant- culture to industry, which is supposed to be
sectors, Rao observed that output-input ly. But the situation in agriculture is no less advantageous to agriculture. Inherently, it
ratios at constant (1960-61) prices declined serious, since the ratios are declining and has beeni a shift from low cost self-produced
between 1960-61 and 1979-80 from 4.63 to costs per umnit of output are increasing most inputs to high cost capital intensive market
3.59 (by 22.5 per cent) in agriculture, from rapidly among major economic sectors. The inputs.
6.24 to 4.33 (by 30.6 per cent) in mining, and gravity of the situation in agriculture can be Tlhe new strategy has been acclaimed as
from 1.40 to 1.29 (by 8.1 per cent) in the better appreciated if it is realised that, on a technological breakthrough by agricultural
registered manufacturing sectpr. Rao the whole, an expenditure of Rs 272 on scientists and economists alike. Strictly
observes here: "The amazing fact. . . is the inputs (including capital consumption) was speaking, a technological breakthrough, as
steady fall in the output-input ratio in the incurred in 1970-71 to obtain Rs 1,250 as understood in economics, shifts the produc-
case of all three industrial sectors listed, output per hectare of gross cropped area. In tion function upwards, which means that a
though the fall has been considerably less 1984-85, on the other hand, an expenditure greater production is achieved at a given
in the case of registered manufacturing. The of Rs 460 was incurred (69 per cent more) input level, and thus at a lower per unit cost.
steep fall in the case of agriculture and to obtain Rs 1,665 as output (only 33 per Our experience of technological break-
animal husbandry and mining is particularly cent more), both at 1970-71 prices. The rate through in Indian agriculture so. far defies
disquieting because of the cost-push effect of growth in inputs per hectare has been this definition. Greater production was no
they could have on the economy, as their more than double that of output. Though doubt achieved per unit of land, but at much
output consists of either food or raw we can still take some consolation from the greater costs per unit of output. Even gran-
materials which enter into the cost of labour fact that even in this process, the value added ting that the adoption of a new technology
maintenance and industrial production" per hectare increased from Rs 986 to would require greater investment and inputs
[Rao, 1983, p 179]. It may be added that it Rs 1,256 (27 per cent more) during the than before to reach new heights in produc-
is disquieting also because of the effect it period at constant prices, justifying increas- tion which were considered infeasible in old
has on the income of millions of growers, ed expenditure, it should be clear neverthe- technology, it is expected that such a break-
as the value added by them shrinks relatively less that we are increasing the productivity through is accompanied by lower costs.
to inputs invested. It should be noted here of our land through a strategy which is Unfortunately such was not the case in
that the cost increases observed here are in proving to be increasingly costly, reflecting practice.
real terms, independent of inflation rates the inherently unsustainable character of the The role of industrial inputs and the new
and terms of trade of agriculture. increase in productivity. technology behind this phenomenon is
We may now look into the latest data becoming more and more obvious. Going
available to see if the trend observed by Rao back to Rao's calculations, they show that
ROLE OF NEW TECHNOLOGY AND
has continued or reversed in recent years. output-input ratio in agriculture declined
INDUSTRIAL INPUTS
Table 1 presents here output-input ratios at only marginally from 4.63 in 1960-61 to only
constant (1970-71) prices for seven major Rao had indicated that the main tactor 4.49 in 1970-71, during the period when both
sectors for the years 1970-71, 1975-76, behind the increasing costs in the Indiain the area under HYVs and the consumption
1980-81, and 1984-85, based on NAS data.' economy was the 'management factor', im- of inidustrial inputs in agriculture were also
Among these sectors, only two-construction plying that while we have been earnestly margiinal. It was only during the subsequent
and communications-show an improve- pushing up inputs and investments our period that most ot the decline in output-
ment in the ratios (that is, reduction in costs) attempt in raising their productivity is much iniput ratio was concentrated, which also
though marginal. All the remaining sectors less serious [Rao, 1983, pp 179-80]. While witnessed unprecedented expansion both in
showed a decline,2 which was particularly accepting this as a general explanation rea unlder H YVs and industrial inputs.
significant in agriculture and allied activities, applicable to the economy as a whole Fakinig together the five major crops affected
and mining ,nd quarrying. Agriculture including agriculture, the author wishes to by HYVs viz, rice, wheat, maize, jowar and
shows the maiimum decline now, and at a be more specific and assert that the main bajra, the proportion of area under HYVs
faster rate than before. Whereas the output- factor which has contributed to this state of to total cropped area under themn, was only

A-114 Economic and Political Weekly September 24, 1988

This content downloaded from 150.216.68.200 on Wed, 30 Mar 2016 10:37:13 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
16.7 per cenit in 1970-71 anld rose to 44.9 per indicated by private costs to farmers. ing prices. The decline in the terms oi iuduL
cenit in 1980-81 aIind 55.8 per cenit in 1984-85. The goal of maxinlising production during the seventies has received con-
Of the total increase in all inputs (valued at irrespective of costs comiies out even more siderable attention both by farmers' lobbies
1970-71 prices) between 1970-71 and 1984-85, clearly durinig droughts. Even normally, and academics, but it has tended to be attri-
tthe increase in three inajor industrial iniputs when production is lower in the face of btuted more to the so called urban bias rather
(fertilisers, pesticides, and diesel) Conlstituted failure of raint'all, costs per unit of output than to the adoption of the new technology.
64.6 per cenit. While these three inputs go up. Farmers normiially try to adjust to It is neccssary to note in this regard that
acou.nted for a imere 14.9 per cent of total droughts either by not sowing or even where relative agricultural prices were continuously
input.s in 1970-71, their- share increased to they sow, by miniilmising their purchase of and sharply--moving upward (in favour of
35.1 per cenlt in 1984-85 at conistanit prices market inputs so that risk of loss is thereby agricLulture) throughout the period preceding
indicating a iiore than dLoubled role. The minimiiised. But the of'ficial machinery seeks the Green Revolution from 1948-49 to
consumnptioni ot chemical tertilisers increas- to Counter this by pushilg up fertiliser con- 1966-67, except for a year in 1954-55. After
ed fromii a miiere 2.9 lakh tonnes of nutrients sumIptioni through easy crop loans so as to staggering somewhat between 1966-67 and
in 1960-61 in the country to 21.8 lakh tonnes comiipenlsate for t'ailLure of rainfall and 1971-72, they rose to an unprecedented
in 1970-71, 55.2 lakh tonnes in 1980-81, 82.1 prevenit a steep decline in production. height in 1973-74, only after which there was
lakh tonnles in 1984-85, and 87.4 lakh tonnes T'he process cani be observed in Table 2. a sharp decline in 1975-76. After a slight
in 1986-87 [India, 1988, p S-26]. The increase It should be noted that the table is at an improvement the decline continued, but has
in agricultural production or yields bears no aggregate level and blunts the sharpness of been reversed since 1982-83. The terms of
comparison with this phenomiienal rise in actual adjustments in different regions. Even trade, however, have not regained their
fertiliser consumption. thein, the table is revealing eniough. In the earlier heights prevailing in 1973-74 [See
The paradox ot the new techniology in the face of impending decline in output, farmiers Nadkarni, 1987-a, pp 169-170 for a long-
case of' wheat comlies out from the con- were induced to increase the application of term view]. The reversal in the long-term
trastirng cases ot Punjab and Madhya industrial inputs, which was accompanied trend in 1973-74 coincided with the hike in
Pradesh, known respectively as progressive with either a decrease in other inputs or only petroleum prices. This was no mere coinci-
and backward in technological advance. a marginal increase in them. The outcome dence, since, as noted earlier, the proportion
Fromn the suLmmInary presenitation of the is a far greater increase in costs per unit of of industrial inputs-fertilisers, pesticides
studies on Cost ot cultivation for 1983-84, output thani could have occurred in the and diesel-had sharply increased since the
it is secen that Punjab obtained an average absence of such official emphasis on market mid-sixties, and when the hike in petroleum
yield ot 40.7 quintals per hectare, and MP inputs. prices came in 1974, the Indian agriculture
only 34.0 quintals per hectare; but a wheat had already become sensitive to it.
TERMS O01 TRADE ANt) INDUSTRIAL
grower in PuLnjab spent Rs 3,169 on inputs Focusing on the movements in the terms
IN PUt1S
(cash and kind expenses) and obtained a net of trade of agriculture after 1970-71, we can
return of Rs 3,908 per hectare, compared to Pressed by the increasing costs, it is only easily observe the role of industrial inputs
a grower- in MNP who spent only Rs 2,227 and natural that farmers would demand increas- vis-a-vis the remaining inputs in contributing
obtained a net return of Rs 4,360 per hectare
over operating costs. While the progressive TABLE 1: OUTPUT-INPUT RATIOS AT CONSTANT (1970-71) PRICES IN MAJOR ECONOMIC
farm-er of Plunjab used 138 kgs of nitrogen SECTORS IN THE INDIAN ECONOMY
anid 58 kgs of P,O,, the backward grower Output-Input Ratios at Constant Prices by Sectors
ot MP used only 74 kgs of niLrogetn and 48
Year Agri and Fishing Mining Registered Construc- Railways Communi-
kgs of pzO, per hectalre and yet obtainied
more protit 0 l [ndia, 1987, p 305]. Allied and Quar- Manufac- tion cations
We have a siiilmiar contrast between rying turing*
Pondicherry arid B3ihar in the case of paddy.
1970-71 4.59 7.74 3.31 1.27 1.64 2.08 4.69
The paddy growers in the tormer applied on
1975-76 4.32 7.41 3.15 1.25 1.64 2.21 4.88
an average 125 kgs ot Nitrogen, 75 kgs of
1980-81 3.81 7.70 3.04 1.22 1.66 1.98 4.94
P,O^; and 50 kgs of K,O per hectare in
1984-85 3.62 7.39 2.75 1.21 1.71 1.89 4.90
1583-84. Their operatinig cost of production
Change (per
per hectare was Rs 5,546 and they obtained
cent) bet-
Rs 4,862 as net return per hectare over
ween 1970-71
operating cost. In contrast, paddy growers
and 1984-85 --21.10 -4.50 -16.90 -4.70 +4.30 -9.10 +4.50
in Bihar applied much lower doses of ferti-
lisers, viz, 69 kgs of nitrogen, 42 kgs of Notes: * Since value of output was available only at current prices in the published data in the
P,O, and 28 kgs of K,O per hectare, in- NAS, the Implicit Price Index for GDP in Manufacturing (Registered) was used to
curred a much lower cost of production of obtain output at constant prices.
Rs 2,888, but obtained a higher net return Inputs are inclusive of consumption of fixed capital, but not remuneration to labour,
of Rs 5,303 per hectare than their more pro- rent and interest.
gressive Pondicherry colleagues. Indeed, the Source: Derived from Disaggregated tables in various issues of National Accounts Statistics,
average yield per 'hectare was higher in CSO, Government of India (see note 1).
Pondicherry at 73 quintals compared to only
TABLE 2: CHANGE (AT CONSTANT PRICES) IN OUTPUT AND INPUTS IN INDIAN ACRICULTURE
40 quintals in Bihar [Inidia, 1987, p 305].
There is no dearth of similar paradoxes. IN DROUGHT YEARS OVER PRECEDING YEARS (AT THE AGGREGATE NATIONAL LEVEL)

This is not to suggest that there is


Change in Output Total Industrial Inputs other
necessarily or unavoidably a strong and Inputs Inputs* than (3)
negative correlation betweeni yields and net
(1) (2) (3) (4)
return. But such paradoxes as have beeni
noted above are more likely to depict the 1972-73 over 1971-72 a: -1108 - 26 + 8 5 -111
normal patterni in the wears to come and b: (5.3) (0.6) (11.0) (3.2)
retlect oni objective ot maxin sing yields per 1979-80 over 1978-79 a: -2472 +192 +200 -8
hectare irrespective of costs to farnmers. Of b: (9.8) (3.5) (13.4) (0.2)
courrse, the cost to the farmer is tried to be 1982-83 over 1981-82 a: -579 +90 +63 +27
-eduLced thlough huge subsidies on irrigia- b: (2.2) (1.5) (3.3) (0.6)
tion, electricitv and tertili.sers aLndic hi kes in
procuremenlt pries. T he real co.st of thi.s Notes: a: Change in terms of Rs crore; b: Percentage change (in brackets).
a*griculttiurl deCveltopmenclt sAtrateg,y inlustlive' * Chemical fertilisers, pesticides, and diesel oil.
of subsidy, the^reftore, is higher thanlr what is Source: National Accounts Statistics, CSO, Government of India (see note 1).

Economic and Politica Weekly Sept.ember 24, 1988 A-I 15

This content downloaded from 150.216.68.200 on Wed, 30 Mar 2016 10:37:13 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
to the decline in them. This can be seen from if yields are low, input use is lower still. The fertiliser-s canl also adversely affect trne
Table 3 which presents the terms of trade in situation can be worse in areas with miiodern nitrogen fixinlg organiisnms in the soil anld
three series: prices of agricultural output agriculture. Besides, cost expr-essed in rela- reduce natur al nitrogeni absor-ption
relative to prices of all inputs, the three tion to value of output (both at currenlt Similarly, pesticides, besides killing
major industrial inputs and other inputs prices) is deflated by the implicit price index unwanited pests, insects and birds or snall
respectively. The relative prices with respect of output. The increase in actual monetary animiials cani citer- the humi atn systemll '
to all inputs together declined during the costs per unit of output in physical terms [Nag Chaudhuri, 1983, pp 15-16]. Lest we
period at the rate of 1.3 per cent per annum can be far m ore sharp, as it is not so should take conlsolationl froim our relatively
(linear trend as per cent at mean), while the deflated. Both the leading cereals-wheat low per capita consumilption of these inlputs,
relative prices with respect to the three and paddy-provide eloquent illustrations we may take note of a OXFAM report in
industrial inputs declined by 3.4 per cent per of such an increase. The cost of cultivation 1981 that there wvere 7,50,000 cases otf
annum. Both these trends were statistically data published in the Agricultural Prices accidenltal pesticide poisoniing a year, anld
significant at 1 per cent level. The relative Commission Reports and Indian Agriculture that the third world couLltries, accounitilig
prices with respect to other inputs on the in Brief together show that the total cost for less than 1 5 per cenit of world pesticide
other hand showed a very moderate decline (Cost 'C') per quintal at currenit prices consumilption, suffered 50 per cenit ot poisoni-
at the rate of 0.37 per cent at mean, which increased by 105 per cent in the case of ings and 75 per cent of the resulting deaths
was statistically not quite significant (being wheat (from Rs 61 to Rs 125) between [quoted in Myers, 1985, p 123]. We have a
significant only at 10 per cent level). One 1970-71 and 1980-81 in Punjab, and in the further warning agaiinst carelvss promliotioni
could say that terms of trade of agriculture case of paddy by 121 per cent in Tamil Nadu of these inputs in the Brunldtlanld Repor-t too
with respect to inputs other than the three (from Rs 53.5 to Rs 118.5) between 1971-72 [WCED, 1987, p 127].
major industrial inputs remained stable, in and 1981-82. There is no case for com- The danger of erosion of genietic diver-
spite of cost pressures on them. We see thus placency on the cost fronlt. sity of our plant life which is ilihercnlt in the
that not only have the industrial inputs con- adoption of the HYV strategy hlas nlot
tributed directly to increasing the real costs received adequate attention. Gene baniks in
HUGE COSTS, LrTTLE GAIN
(at constant prices) per unit of output, they artificial laboratory conditionis have hardly
have also significantly contributed to in- We have considered here only direct provided a dependable solutionl to this
creasing the monetary costs and turning the economic costs. There is no need to go into problem [Mooney, 1983, p 76]. Even if this
terms of trade against agriculture. the debate over the distributional con- is done more satisfactorily in advanced
The share of increase in real costs is more sequences of this development strategy, since countries, it makes us dependent onl them
significant than the share on account of the there is a large degree of consensus that in a very critical field. On-farm conserva-
worsening of terms of trade. This can be seen though the new inputs are divisible and can, tion of genetic diversity could be a cheaper
From the fact that as per the calculations in theory, be applied even on tiny holdings, and possibly a more dependable alternative,
derived from NAS data, the cost of material the access to capital and skills needed for though it does not mean that all farmers
inputs including consumption of capital (but this technology is not neutral to scale. This have to give up HYVs and grow local
excluding wages, rent and interest) has in- was inherent in their being capital intensive varieties. A few farmers could be selected on
creased by 31 per cent from Rs 21.1 to in nature. The strategy has not stopped at a planned basis in different regions where
Rs 27.6 per Rs 100 worth of output at con- promoting the use of divisible inputs like local varieties can be protected under scien-
stant prices between 1970-71 and 1984-85. fertiliser. It has also stimulated considerable tific supervision. Unfortunately this is not
At current prices, the same cost increased extent of mechanisation. The whole strategy done, and consequently, it is feared that
by 39 per cent from Rs 21.1 to Rs 29.4 during has been to use more of costly inputs and India has already lost many of its precious
this period. This indicates that difficulties economise on labour, a cheaper input. The rice varieties.
on the cost front have to do more with the distributional impact of such a strategy If the strategy of heavy reliance on indus-
basic fact of deterioration of the natural cannot but be adverse. trial inputs is considered justified in spite of
resource base of agriculture and with the The environmental costs of the strategy its higher costs, it cain be only on the ground
choice of an inherently costly strategy of are also becoming obvious. In the course of that it held the promise of significantly
development, than with relative prices. zealous extension of these new inputs, increasing yields per hectare and thus
Rich farmers generally complain about farmers were hardly made familiar with production. Almost pushed to the wall by
high cost of labour and try to minimise the hazards associated with them, thanks to the droughts during the mid-sixties and by the
same, though they are not so calculating low value imputed to human health and life humiliation of having to depend on imports
about material costs. The labour costs per in India. On the other hand, there is a of foodgrains, self-reliance at any cost in a
unit of output, however, appear to have tendency to minimise the severity of the critical situation like this did seem to be a
actually declined at current prices in absolute problem by comparing per capita consump- justifiable goal. The new strategy promised
terms, let alone as a proportion. The NAS tion of these inputs in lndia with that in quick results. The self-reliance we have
data on factor incomes by industrial origin advaced countries. Such comparisons hide attained today in foodgrains, except for
give estimates of compensation of employees excessive uses in several regions, the damage marginal imports to maintain stocks during
at current prices. Calculating this cost on per done by which is not arithmetically cancelled severe droughts, has been attributed mainly
unit basis, we find that in agriculture, the by lower use in other regions. Moreover, to the success of the new technology. It is
compensation of employees (excluding other regions are also fast catching up. It is certaini that schemiies of increasing food-
mixed income of the self-employed) per relatively easier to control industrial pol- grains productioni in the niext Plan would rely
Rs 100 worth of output, declined from lution by enforcing treatment of effluents on a significant expansion in the use ot
Rs 16.9 in 1970-71 to Rs 15.1 in 1984-85 at from factories, but practically impossible in fertilisers, pesticides and diesel, in addition
current prices. This would clearly show it is the case of hundreds and thousands of to irrigation.
the rise in material costs which is responsible farmers releasing pesticides and fertilisers But how far is this premise really
for the cost escalation in agriculture, and into the environment. justified? Has it, for example, been proved
that labour costs have actually exercised a It is now known for quite sometime that beyond doubt that the new strategy produced
dampening influence. 'excessive use of fertilisers and pesticides a major upward shift in the growth' rates as
Though the increase in the cost of contributes substantially to ecological distur- compared to growth rates experienced
material inputs per unit value of output, in 'bances... Excessive use of nitrogen terti- before? Indications are that at best the new
real terms by 31 per cent and in money terms lisers, for example, can lead to leaching of growth ratBs were not much higher than the
by 39 per cent between 1970-71 and 1984-85, these excess fertilisers into water bodies. old, and that probably they have actually
may not look very alarming, it is necessary These can be transformned by micro- been lower than the old rates. Rao has
to caution here that this calculation is at the organisms into nitrites and carciniogenis. .. himself shown how the annual compound
aggregate national level and includes many which can find their way back to men anid rate of growth of production successively
areas with traditional agriculture where, even animals through the food chlain. Excessive declined in the case of cereals, from 3.7 per

A-116 Economic and Political Weekly September 24, 1988

This content downloaded from 150.216.68.200 on Wed, 30 Mar 2016 10:37:13 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
cent during the nineteen fifties to 2.8 per cent inig cover- crops. Once these practices were firmly grounded in industrial inputs, they
during the sixties, and further to 2.3 per cent neglected anid fast-acting chemical fertiliser would not be enthusiastic about improving
during the seventies. And yet, cereals are the was used instead, the humus was depleted the natural resource base of their farms. The
show bov of the Green Revolution! Rao has in a single gcilen-ation. The structure of the first requisite is to reorient them to improve
also shown that while the production of soil deteriorated; crops became weak anid their natural resource base which can reduce
pulses increased at the rate of 3 per cenit per depenldenlt oil chemical nutrients. To make their costs and also improve yields on a long-
annum during the fifties, they recorded an up for- redLuced human and animal labour, term basis.
absolute decline both in the sixties and the thenew systeml Mined thefertility reserves Korn's introduction distinguishes between
seventies. If this backlash effect of the new of the soif [em phasis added, Fukuoka, 1984, three types of farming-traditional, chemical
technology on pulses is consider-ed, it adds p xxiv]. A basically renewable resource was and natural-in their effect on soil. While
turther to its debit side [Rao, 1983, p 56]. tulrn-ed into ani exhausted resource in the in the traditional method, the condition of
Growthl rates would, of course, differ process-a phenomenon much more evident soil remains about the same, it becomes
depending on the choice of initial and ter- in Ildia even before reaching Japanese liteless and depleted in a short time under
mlinal years. But even calculations based on heights of fertiliser consumption! the chemical method. Under Fukuoka's
carefully choseni end-points do not indicate Accunmulationi of fertiliser stocks in India natural method, however, fields improve
a conlspicuous success story. For example, a has often been attributed to unfavourable with each season [Fukuoka, 1984, p xxii].
study by Rao and Deshpande [1986, p 92] relative prices, on the basis of which the fer- In Indian conditions, even traditional
shioN-s that foodgrains recorded an output tiliser industry has been asking for more SUb- farming had not necessarily taken care of
growth of 2.55 per cent per annum during sidies. But this coulld well have been due to soil erosioni. A lot of organic matter was
the pre-Green Resolution period (1952-53 to diminiishinig returns to tertiliser application burnt or wasted. A blind reversal to such
1964-65), and 2.77 per cent during the Green or their unsuitability in a variety of condi- methods is not what is needed. A fuller
Revolution period (1967-68 to 1978-79). The tions. Farmers seem to have already realised ulnderstanding of how to improve soil ferti-
new growth rate was only marginally higher this, though extension agencies are yet to lity through methods vwhich depend mainly
and did not represent a major breakthrough understand this. Where yield advantages are on farmers' skills and labour and nature's
conmpared to the difterence in the growth not conspicuous, price manipulations do not own free gifts, can alone reverse the degrada-
rates between the pre-independence and the necessarily make such an input attractive. tion of land and meet human needs on a sus-
post-independeince periods. No doubt, in- Even if the new technology did contribute tainable basis.
crease in yields played a more important role to significantly stepping up food production There is of course a lot to learn from
in the post-Green Revolution period; but in India initially, its potential to continue to traditional practices which were developed
even the growth rate in yields was not do so in future seems to be nearing the point to achieve high levels of productivity in
significantly higher. The same study shows of exhaustion. We have no choice but to find China, even before the talk about organic
that it was 1.51 per cent per annum in the an ecologically and economically viable or natural farming had started in the west.
earliei- period, and 1.84 per cent during the alternative. It was mainly because of this that even with
latter-by no means a remarkable higher less arable and irrigated land than in India,
figure. Compared to the negative growth in China could obtain about 2 1/2 times more
IOWARDS A SUSTAINABLE ALTERNATIVE
yields recorded prior to indepenidernce, the food production. Nair has observed that
achievement even up to 1964-65 was a major Such an alternative has to be less costly, though in 1976-77 both countries were
breakthrough. W!hat little incremiient to the more productive-not merely in the short applying practically identical doses of
growth rate was achieved by the new techno- run-but in the long run too, environmen- chemical fertiliser per hectare (18.4 kgs in
logy in its first decadie was at a tremendously tally sound, and equitable. The alternatives China and 18.8 kgs in India), the Chinese
higher cost. Wher all crops, including non- available need not be posed in simplistic were applying an additional 23 million
food crops, were considered, growth rates terms like modern vs traditional, or indus- tonnes (in nutritional content) and 2081
actually showed a decliie, and not a rise, in trial vs completely farm based. That is, the million tonnes in gross weight of organic
the Green Revolution period, in spite of all alternative need not consist in simply going
the extra investment. back to pre-Green Revolution agrarian prac-
TABLE 3: INDEX-NUMBERS OF TERMS OF TRADE
A more recent study by Rao, Ray and tices and shunning the use of the HYVs and
OF AGRICULTURE IN INDIA, WITH RESPECT TO
Subbarao [1988, p 7] covering subsequent all industrial inputs. The alternative could
INDUSTRIAL INPUTS VIS-A-VIS OTHER INPUTS,
years shows that the period, 1968-85, record- be even more scientific in the sense that it
BASED ON IMPLICIT PRICES IN NATIONAL
ed lower growth rates in crop production would be based on a fuller understanding
ACCOUNTS STATISTICS (1970-71 = 100)
compared to the earlier period of 1950-65, of nature, and farmers' own innovativeness.
wheat being the only exception.3 Their Though drawing on the experience of Year Relative Price of Output,
calculatioins separate the drought during the organic farming in the west and Fukuoka's with Respect of Price of
mid-sixties whein the new technology was natural farming in Japan, the alternative
Total Industrial Other
also introduced. They also make adjust- need not be a copy of these models and has
Inputs Inputs* Inputs
ments for annual fluctuations in crop to be adapted to Indian conditions. There
output. Their study shows not only a decline need not also be a sudden transition to this 1971-72 99.1 103.1 98.3
in growth rates but also an increase in alternative but a gradual one so that one can 1972-73 102.7 113.8 100.2
instability-a clear indication of unsustain- continuously learn and adjust. 1973-74 106.7 134.5 101.4
able character of our agricultural develop- To correct the lopsided emphasis on short- 1974-75 98.7 79.3 105.9
ment under the new technology. Thus the term gain in yields inherent in the strategy 1975-76 90.7 68.8 99.8
challenge that India is facing in agriculture pursued since the mid-sixties and to balance 1976-77 92.2 76.4 98.8
is not merely one of increasing costs, but it with the goal of securing long-term 1977-78 91.3 82.1 95.1
also of declining growth rates and increasing improvement in soil fertility, there has been 1978-79 91.0 81.1 95.3
instability. Fast diminishing returns to this a growing emphasis in recent years on 1979-80 93.1 92.7 93.2
technology are inherent in its very nature. schemes of soil and water conservation, 1980-81 87.5 73.2 95.1
Its strategy is to maximise short-term gain water shed development and afforestation. 1981-82 81.9 63.3 94.1
at the expense of sustainability. Introducing These schemes do not in any way alter the 1982-83 83.9 66.1 95.7
Fukuoka's method of natural farming to strategy of agricultural development based 1983-84 89.6 73.6 99.8
readers, Larry Korn observes how the on industrial inputs but supplement it. 1984-85 90.0 77.8 98.2
fertiliser-intensive technology affected Necessary though they are, such marginal
Japanese agriculture. 'For centuries correctives, however, do not go far enough, Note: * Chemical fertilisers, pesticides, aIid
Japanese farmers had maintained organic for they do not change the character of diesel oil.
matter in the soil by rotating crops, by farming particularly its cost intensity. Source: Derived from disaggregated tables in
adding compost and manure, and by grow- Moreover, as long as farmers' orientation is National Accoulnts Statistics (seenote 1).

Economic and Political Weekly September 24, 1988 A-1 17

This content downloaded from 150.216.68.200 on Wed, 30 Mar 2016 10:37:13 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
fertilisers from night soil (19 per cent), hog earned state award for best yields using difference would have been greater still if he
manlure (24 per cent), draft animal maniure heavy doses of these inputs. He was using was using only fertiliser and no organic
(37 per cent), green manure (8 per cent), this technology with all enthusiasm till manure in 1978. Even at that time, he was
comiipost (5 pev- cenit) and river and pond silt 1978-79. It was at the end of seventies that combining a lot of organic matter with
anid muLd (7 pcr cent), ignoring other sources by coincidence he came in contact with an fertiliser.
like manure f'rom dluck or chicken droppings, American devotee of an Indian saint who This approach of natural farming enabled
and weeds which too were used [Nair, 1983, introduced him to organic farming-its con- him to view not at one crop in isolation but
p 19]. While in China fertiliser use came on cepts, principles and practice. He did not, at his farm as a whole, the total productivity
top ot' a highly advanced state of traditional however, switch over suddenly, because, as of which has increased very significantly, as
soil and plant care, it tended in India to he believed, once soils are depleted of their a result. This author could personally see for
substitute whatever little soil and land care natural reserves by fertiliser, they get himself what this meant. Surrounding his
was taken within traditiorial agriculture. addicted to it and de-addiction has to be holding, Reddy has grown honge (pongemia)
Fukuoka's method goes ahead of tradi- gradual. He progressively increased the for green manure, subabul for fodder and
tional methods, learning from them and organic matter, correspondingly reducing several other trees without keeping a single
avoiding its mistakes. While it eschews chemical inputs, at the approximate rate of square foot bare. He does not purchase any
modern inputs, it also tries to economise on 100 kg, of NPK being replaced by 5 tonnes fodder or oil cake for his 17 cattle heads
labour input, without reducing yields. It (10 cartloads) of the former. When he found which are stall-fed and are in excellent
requires no machinery, no chemicals, and that organic matter produced on his own health. Their needs are met from the farm
very little weeding. He does not even plough farm was insufficient, he went with his wife itself. Apart from straw and subabul leaves,
the field or use compost. He puts agri- and children to collect roadside leaf litter. they feast on excess banana shoots. Not even
cultural wastes after harvest back into In 6 to 7 years, he stopped using any an ounce of cow dung or leaf or straw is
fields.4 The humid conditions in Japan can chemical input; though he suffered a little burnt or wasted, but is used either as manure
take care of the soil under this method decline in yields in the first two years, later in compost or is put directly into field as
without ploughing. But a shallow single continued to get the same high yields as mulch.
ploughing may be all that is needed even in before and-what is important-at a much To get the maximum out of organic
Indian conditions. Narayan Reddy, a farmer lower cost. His lands are much more fertile manure, he takes care to see that it matures,
near Bangalore, who has been practising now, in spite of intensive cultivation. It is but neither dries nor rots through excess
natural farming adapted to local conditions, possible, he observes, to reduce the depen- water. Excess water in compost pits results
believes that tractor ploughing is a waste and dence on even the prepared compost, if in the leaching of nutrients. Similarly, when
even harmful to the soil, as deep ploughing agricultural wastes and other organic matter manure is put in small heaps (before
can cause unnecessary soil erosion. Even the are put back into the soil. spreading) on fields, it has to be covered
shallow and single ploughing has to be When he had received a state award for immediately with about 2 inches of soil so
across the slope of the land and never along the highest yield in ragi in 1978, he was as to prevent its drying. He observes that
it. If a farmer can also use all the organic cultivating it on three acres, all rainfed and most farmers are careless in this matter and
matter produced on farm and put it back got 23 quintals per acre. He was cultivating as such cannot get the full benefit of
into soil, the resultant increase in microbial it even at that time in rotation with cow pea, manure.
activity can work wonders with the soil, he which yielded 2 quintals per acre. He used Natural farming does not need pesticides
asserts. Apart from increasing fertility, it 200 kgs of fertilisers and about 20 cartloads or weedicides. Pests are a menace only when
would promote stability too since it improves (10 tonnes) of organic manure per acre then, a whole farm is devoted to a single crop. One
moisture conservation and use of water can but uses about 40 cartloads of organic can carefully choose pest resistant varieties
also be reduced. Reddy feels that agricultural manure per acre and no fertiliser today and and proper inter-crops. Tl,e inter-crops can
scientists often give wrong advice without gets the same yield as before in the case of not only prevent the spread of pests, but can
knowing full facts. He had once the shock ragi, and a higher yield of 3 quintals per acre also supply nutrients if prrcperly selected.
of his life while listening to a scientist on in the case of cow pea. It should be noted Reddy says that inter-cropping cabbage with
radio who advised the use of a chemical to that he cultivates a high yield variety as marigold, or carrot with onion can take care
destroy earthworms, wvhich he believed, before, and asserts that the belief about of more than 25 per cent of pests. Cheap,
disturbed the root system of plants! The HYVs being responsive only to fertilisers is natural and harmless pesticides can be pro-
scientist obviously had no knowledge of the a myth, a superstition. While the value of duced on farm itself; for example, soap
beneficial role that earthworms play free of his total produce in a year from this field water, neem decoction5 and ash dusting can
cost to the farmers. Reddy ridicules scien- in 1978 amounted to Rs 4,800 per acre control pests significantly if not eliminate
tists' claims that the nutrient quality in (including ragi, cow pea and fodder), he was them altogether. But a total elimination of
organic matter like cowdung is inadequate spending Rs 1,800 per acre on inputs in- pests through chemicals is neither possible
and that fertilisers are indispensable. cluding imputed cost of organic manure and nor profitable. As for weeds, they are
Cowdung alone may be inadequate, but family labour (but excluding imputed in- automatically controlled if the field is
fertilisers are certainly not indispensable. terest and rent). This gave him a net return covered with agricultural wastes and leaf
Agricultural wastes, inter-crops and crop- of Rs 3,000 per acre, i e, 167 per cent over litter. Even if some weeds emerge, they
rotations can take care of inadequacy in any inputs. Today (1988) his total inputs even at should be plucked by hand and put there
particular organic matter. The farm has to current prices amount to Rs 1,900 per acre, instead of heaping and burning them, he
be viewed as a whole system where each part including imputed cost of farm produced advises.
and activity complements the other. If inter- organic manure and family labour. The Reddy also feels that though natural
relationships and complementarities within value of his farm produce per acre from ragi farming means a lot of attention and plan-
the farm are taken advantage of, farming and cow pea is Rs 5,710 (including fodder), ning, it does not necessarily mean back
can be both cheap and more productive on giving him a net return of Rs 3,810 per acre, breaking and tedious labour. It is certainly
a sustainable basis. Reddy compares a farm- i e, 201 per cent over inputs. more labour intensive than chemical
holding with an earthen pot and the leaks The real gain, Reddy claims, is much more farming, but the extra labour needed is no
of purchasing power on industrial inputs to than what is indicated by net return per acre more than about 20 or 25 per cent on the
holes in the pot. Plug these holes and as indicated above. The substitution of whole. But this extra labour is much more
produce your own inputs on farm to increase chemical inputs by farm produced manure enjoyable than under chemical farming,
profits, he says. means the creation of extra value added on since it is living and working with nature and
His own experience has given him the con- farm, which is a net gain to the family, deriving satisfaction from one's own creati-
fidence for such assertions. He began as a though organic manure is normally counted vity and innovativeness. He also believes that
small farmer with only about two acres as as a cost in crop production. If imputed cost natural farming is as practicable for small
his inherited share, but has by now increased of organic mnanure is not counted, the net farmers as for the big, and on rainfed farms
his holding to 30 acre.s. His formal education return amounted to 534 per cent over inputs as on the irrigated. Certain adjustments and
is only up to SSC. He learnt the new techno- in 1988, compared to only 200 per cent in variations are necessary but farmers can be
logy based on chemical inputs quickly and 1978 when he was relying on fertilisers. The educated to learn and devetop these skills.

A-1 18 Economic and Political Weekly September 24, 1988

This content downloaded from 150.216.68.200 on Wed, 30 Mar 2016 10:37:13 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Reddy feels that the emphasis of extension own innovativeness and k nowledge. To 4 f'our principles of natural t'atiting, atccording
service should be more on imparting the stimulate this and to enable farmiier-s to to IfUk uoka, Cre: 1o cuLIltiVation, no chemilical
knowledge of nature and skills than on discover their- own creativity and inniate tfer-tiliser or- prepared compost, no weeding
providing chemical inputs. He also believes preference for imlproving their natural by tillage or hcrbicides, anid no depenidence
that a small farmer can overcome the con- resource base, a beginniinlg has to be made on1 chemllicals 1includingL pesticides. "For
straint of his small holding by collecting by fixing the prices of chernicals at a level t'ci-tiliser, f Ukuoka gr1oss s leguLilr ilnouLs gr-ouind
organic wastes lying all around, as he that reflects their real environmrienttal costs. cover of' white clovcr, r-Ctuirnis tth thr-eshed
himself did. But this would also require It also means that ter-tiliser imports and strass to tlie t'ieldls, and adds a little poultry
increasing the common property resources subsidies have to be stopped. It is only then mlaLlnure. Vie uses 110 pcr_sistcn1t or broad spec-
and improve their bio-mass productivity so that emphasis of extenision agencies would trulll poisotis, artd has no pesticide pro-
that supply of fuel, fodder and green manure be more on helping tarnmers to increase the uramtme... Oni sot ic oi-rchard t rees he occa-
for small farmers and the landless can be productivity of their inputs and reduce costs, siottallv uises a mir,ZCteila oil Cemu.1lsioti fot the
assured on a sustained basis. instead of inducing them merely to apply col'tttol of, inisect Scales'' 1f-Iukuoka, 1984,
Such farming may not, however, be more and more industrial inputs with the pp 33-341. Reddy, howescr, uses prepared
suitable for large capitalist farms run mainly temptation of cheap loais. It is also only comp11)0ost, bLut hle a1lso ciriphasises spreaditig
on hired labour and hired supervision. It is then that we can avoid getting inito a of aItzriculttiral wastcs, anid growitng horse-
ideal for peasant farms run mainly on family ridiCulous mnix-up ot ends and means, under graim to be cut atid spread at the stage of
labour and supervision, though it does not which otftake of accuLmlulated tertiliser tlo\\critnc 5 htien its nitrogen implatiting is
eschew hired labour. A policy thrust in stocks is the end and agricultLural develop- op[t Iitt11ttii.

favour of natural farming, therefore, would ment becomes the means. 5 Neerni decoct ion is not to be prepared by
be instrumental in promoting equity in the boilingv, buLt otil by putting out neetm leaves
iNotves
agricultural sector and providing fuller itt a pot of \s atler in t le open sui t'oir tso or
employment because of its being labour Rhis paper is suLbmitted ait thc seminilar, inc/in : thiece days. as o per Rcddv.
intensive. It would be more equitable than The Emerging Challenges, in felicitatioin of'
'industrial' or chemical farming spatially too V K R V Rao at Iistitute t'or Social anid Referetnees
since it does not depend on intensive irriga- Economic Chanige, Bangalore in October 1988.
Though grown out of the author's earlier work
Lukuoka, Masanobu (1984): One-Straw,
tion and can be practised in semi-arid areas
Rev-oltiiott .4i Ituroduetiort o .oVatural
under rainfed conditions. Because of its [Nadkarni, 1987a and 1987bT, the paper owes
also to the stinmulatinig interaction he had at the faroting, lndiati edition (origitial edition,
potential for wider spread both across
1978), Rasulia (Hoshangabad, NIP, 461001),
farmers and regions, natural farming can meeting of the group "Scierntists for Peace and
F-iends Rural Cetitre.
raise the overall productivity of agriculture Development" at the Indian Institute of Scienice
India, Goerttmeitit ot (1987): Indian
much more than chemical farming. The in June 1988, and particularly to the opportuni-
.Agriculture it Brief 21st edition, New Delhi.
potential for greater spread is obvious from tv he had of learnlinig from the experience of
- (1988): Economic Surv eY; 1987-88, New
its cost advantage over the so-called pro- Narayan Reddy, a farm-ler near Battgalore, wnho
Delhi.
gressive farming dependent on costly inputs. believes in natural farminiig and has made a suc-
Mlootiev, Pat Roy (1983): 'The Law of the
Yields on an ideally natural farm like that cess of it. Thanks are due also to V K R V Rao,
Seed-Another Development and Plant
of Fukuoka may not be higher than the V 1I Rao and T R Satish Chandran for com-
Genetic ResoLurces', Development Dialogue,
yields from equally ideal demonstration ments and suggestiotts. Usual disclaimiiers
Nos I and 2.
plots practising chemical farming. The claim apply.
NMyers, Normatn (ed) (1985): The GAIA Atlas
for higher productivity of natural farming I Disaggregated tables f'rom the \National oJ Planet .M1antagement, London and Sydney,
is not derived from such comparisons. On Accounts Statistics (NAS), CSO, Govern- Pati Books.
the other hand, it rests on much lower costs ment of India, have been used here takling Nag Chaudhuri, B D (1983): Introduction to
to farmers even in less endowed regions the latest revised figures available. For the En iron,ne,ttal Managetnent, New Delhi,
under this farming and on the fact that by years 1970-71 and from 1978-79 to 1984-85, Interprint.
ensuring a continuous improvement in the NAS published in 1987 has been used; anid Nair, Kusum (1983): Transforming Tradi-
natural resource base such a farming also
for other years, as follows: 1971/72: NAS tional/t. Land and Labour Use in Agriculture
ensures a sustained increase in productivity. 1980; 1972/73: NAS 1981; 1973/74: NAS in Asia attd Africa, New Delhi, Allied.
There are not many like Reddy today-at
1982; 1974/75: NAS 1983; 1975/76: NAS Nadkarni, N1 V (1987a): Farmsners' Movements
least to this author's knowledge -who prac- 1984; 1976/77: NAS 1985; 1977/78: NAS in India, New Delhi, Allied.
tise natural farming. No sample survey to 1986. These series have 1970-71 as the base - (1987b): 'Agricultural Development and
derive 'statistically significant' conclusions year. Ecology: An Ecotioniist's View' (keynote
was feasible. Not even a physical verification 2 Though similar data are available for forestry paper), Indian Journal of Agricultural
of his claims regarding inputs used and and logging as well, we have excluded this Econotnics, Vol 42(3), July-September.
yields obtained could be made by the author. sector from our consideration here since the Rao, C H Hanumantha, Ray, S K and
But his reasoning sounded logical and con-
comparability of input data over the vears Subbarao, K (1988): Unstable Agriculture
vincing particularly after visiting his farm was doubtful. There is a sudden jump under and Droughts, New Delhi, Vikas.
and it indicated that there is definitely a way the item repairs and maintenance from Rao, V K R V (1 983): Indil's ,National Incom7e,
out of the crisis of increasing costs facing 1974-75 onwards, which is unexplained. As 1950-80, New Delhi, Sage Publications.
Indian agriculture. Certainly, more research a result, this sector shows a steep decline in Rao, V Mi atid Deshpande, R S (1986):
is needed to evolve suitable practices and to output-input ratio from 20.2 in 1973-74 to 'Agricultural Production-Pace and Pattern
demonstrate the potential of natural farming 9.17 in 1974-75. The ratios are almost con- of Growth' in MI L Dantwala and others,
in a variety of conditions. There is need for
stant between 1970-71 and 1973-74, and then Indian Agric ultural Developtnent since
a shift of emphasis from business oriented again at a lower level between 1974-75 and Independence. A Collec tion of EssaYs, New
research with an eye only on commercial 1984-85. Delhi, Oxford and IBH.
exploitation to people oriented research. 3 Growth rates in production, adjusted for WCED (World Commission on Environment
Research breakthroughs in bio-fertilisers and annual fluctuations, calculated by Rao, Ray and Development, chairman: Gro Harlem
bio-pesticides can be of help provided, as far and Subbarao [1988, p 7] are shown in Brundtland) (1987): Our Cotnmon Future,
as possible, such inputs can be raised on Table A (in per cent per annum). New Delhi, Oxford University Press.
farms by farmers themselves instead of
making them dependent on bio-factories TABLE A

and provided also that the ecological impact


Wheat Rice All Cereals Pulses All All Crops
of these inputs is well within the control of
farmers. But there is no need for waiting for Foodgrai ns
further research breakthroughs, because, the
1950-65 4.0 3.3 3.2 1.2 2.9 3.0
technology of natural farming is basically
1968-85 5.5 2.4 2.9 0.7 2.6 2 6
developed by farmers themselves using their

Economic and Political Weekly September 24, 1988 A-lI9

This content downloaded from 150.216.68.200 on Wed, 30 Mar 2016 10:37:13 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

You might also like