1990 - DeMelo Tarr - WelfareCostsOfUSQuotasInTextilesSteelAndAutos

You might also like

Download as docx, pdf, or txt
Download as docx, pdf, or txt
You are on page 1of 10

WELFARE COSTS OF U.S.

OUOTAS IN TEXTILES,
STEEL AND AUTOS
Jaime de Melo and David Tarr*
AbsIruct—this paper quantifies the welfare effects and re-
source shifts that would occur if U.S. quantitative restrictions for so that, unlike in the PE analysis, capturing
(QRs) in textiles, steel and autos were removed. Estimates are quota rents affects resource allocation. Third,
derived from a static ten-sector general equilibrium model of
the U.S. economy. The welfare loss from the ORs is estimated
economy-wide resource constraints and in-
at approximately U.S. $20 billion (1984 dollars) Due to the terindustry linkages provide a more accurate esti-
high rent transfer component of ORs (about 75Wo), the aver- mate of welfare and sectoral employment effects.
age across-the-board tariff equivalent of QRs (in terms of
welfare costs) is estimated at about 209c, a rate which pre-
This paper deals with the problems of PE analysis
date,s the early days of multilateral tariff reduction. by presenting estimates from a static ten-sector
computable general equilibrium (CGE) model of
I. Introduction the U.S. economy calibrated to the year 1984 when
quantitative restrictions (QRs) in tex- tiles and

R ECENTLY, several studies have estimated


the costs of U.S. special protection arrange-
ments.’ All these studies, using a partial equilib-
autos were in effect, and those on steel were in
negotiation. To our knowledge, the treat- ment of
OR-associated effects here is more satis- factory
rium (PE) framework, provide a useful range of than in previous CGE applications. While the
estimates of the costs of non-tariff protection. U.S.-negotiated voluntary export restraint (VER)
These studies are especially valuable when taken on automobiles has expired, demand in the
individually because then the assumptions of PE United States for protection through non- tariff
analysis provide an adequate approximation of barriers (NTBs) remains strong and may be on the
reality. But, as we quantify below, when the costs rise. A new round of estimates of the costs
of all restrictions are taken together, the underly- of protection is therefore all the more welcome.
ing assumptions are much less tenable. In partic- The remainder of the paper is organized as
ular, the general equilibrium (GE) approach used follows. Section II outlines the model. Section III
here accounts for three effects omitted by PE details the sources of estimates of premia on
estimates. First, the inclusion of a balance of preexisting QRs in 1984 and the sources for the
trade constraint (expressed in world prices) re- parameters describing demand and supply elastic-
moves an upward bias present in PE analysis. ities. Estimates of the welfare and employment
Second, the effects of income transfers to and effects of QR removal are presented by industry
from the rest of the world are properly accounted and in the aggregate in sections IV and V. Con-
clusions follow in section VI.
Received for publication January 12, 1989. Revision ac-
cepted for publication November 16, 1989.
* T he World Bank, University of Geneva, and CEPR; and Il. Model Outline°
the World Bank, respectively.
This is a revised and shortened version of de Melo and Tarr The simulation model is a static CGE model
(1985) which extends an earlier study by Tarr (1989). We with assumptions that correspond closely to those
thank Morris Morkre and two referees for comments. The followed by the partial equilibrium estimates cited
views are those of the authors, not those of the World Bank.
We thank Julie Stanton for extremely valuable research assis- above, namely, a neoclassical perfect-competition
tance, Maria Ameal for logistic support and Soren Nielsen for Walrasian model in which a representative con-
computer support.
Among the most widely known studies that provide esti-
sumer maximizes utility subject to a budget con-
mates of the welfare costs of non-tariff barriers (NTBs) in the straint, a:omistic producers minimize costs, and
United States are individual sector studies for textiles IMorkre the government redistributes tax revenues from
(1984); Tarr and Morkre (1984); Cline (1987); Keesing and
Wolf (1980); for automobiles (Winston and Associates (1987);
trade policy in a lump sum. The economy has a
Tarr and Morkre (1984); Feenstra (1984, 1985, 1958); fixed endowment of labor and capital and faces
Dinopoulos and Kreinin (1988)); and for steel (Tarr and
Morkre (1984)). Perhaps the most comprehensive recent esti-
mates come from the 31 case studies of special protection by A full description of the model is contained in the ap-
Hufbauer, Berliner and Elliott (1986). pendix to de Melo and Tarr (1988) and is available from the
authors upon request.

Copyright fi 1990 [ 489 )

CoDvriaht 2001 All Riohts Remen on


490 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

an exogenous balance of trade constraint ex-


each sector, intermediate demand is a CES func-
pressed in world prices. Because we are inter-
tion between the domestically produced interme-
ested in the static welfare costs of protection, we
diate and the competing foreign intermediate. To
abstract from investment, thereby simplifying the
give an example, no substitution is allowed be-
welfare analysis. The components of demand,
tween purchases of steel and other manufactur-
therefore, include only consumer and intermedi-
ing intermediates, but substitution in purchases is
ate demand.
allowed between domestically produced and for-
Under these assumptions, it is clear that the
eign produced steel when their relative prices
welfare changes due to a change in trade policy
change as a result of a change in trade policy.
are the usual production and consumption costs
Likewise, in consumption demand, the demand
of protection referred to in the literature on the
system derived from the Stone-Geary utility indi-
costs of protection. Our measure of the welfare
cator allows for non-unitary income elasticities of
change due to a policy change is given by the
demand and non-zero cross-price elasticities of
equivalent variation (EV) measure associated
demand between domestically produced and for-
with the Stone-Geary utility function describing
eign produced consumer goods.
the representative consumer’s preferences, i.e., Finally, we note that in previous single-country
EV —— C JR(p', y'), po — C yU(po yo) pop partial equilibrium estimates, authors have invari-
ably assumed that the United States is a small
where C is the cost function, IU is indirect utility supplier and demander in world markets. In our
which depends on prices and income, p is the preferred estimates, we retain this assumption
vector of final goods prices, and superscripts 0 except for the supply of auto imports and the
and 1 refer to the equilibrium before and after demand for agricultural exports. However, be-
the counterfactual trade policy experiment. If EV cause of the controversy about the importance of
is positive, the consumer is better off as a result terms of trade effects reported in multi-country
of the policy shift. models (e.g., Whalley (1985), Deardorfl and Stern
The structure of the ten-sector model is as (1986)), we report separately results under the
follows.' Commodities supplied (or purchased) assumption that the United States possesses gen-
abroad and domestic commodities sold on the eralized monopoly and monopsony power.
domestic market are imperfect substitutes. This The description of the model is complete ex-
assumption of product differentiation is com- cept for our treatment of QRs. In the United
monly used in applied general equilibrium analy- States, for the sectors considered here, there are
sis and is also adopted in most of the PE studies no government controls or direct quota alloca-
alluded to above. On the export side, the assump- tions with resale prohibition. Hence, unlike the
tion of product differentiation is reflected in the case of many QR allocation schemes in develop-
constant elasticity of transformation (CET) func- ing countries, the U.S. system of ORs allows for
tion between domestic and foreign sales. 4 A market-clearing prices. Since in 1984 quotas were
symmetric functional form is specified for inter- already in place in autos and textiles, we assume
mediate demand by sector (see below). The as- that observed purchases were at the premia-
sumption of product differentiation allows for the inclusive prices in that year. (The estimation of
cross-hauling observed in trade statistics. premia is discussed in section III.)’
Production possibilities are parametrized by as-
suming constant elasticity of substitution (CES) III. Elasticity and Premia Estimates
functions for value-added and Leontief functions Considerable eflort was devoted to a “parame-
between intermediates (as a whole) and value-
ter search” for elasticities of demand and supply
added and across intermediates. However, within
and to constructing premia estimates for existing
The ten sectors are agriculture (1), food (2), mining (3),
textiles and apparel (4), autos (5), steel (6), consumer goods Our calibration procedure assumes that the prices and
(7), other manufacturing (8), traded services (9), and non- quantities observed in 1984 correspond to an equilibrium of
traded services (10). All sectors are traded with the exception the U.S. economy with normal capacity utilization and in
of sector 10. See Tarr (1988) for details on aggregation. which the only distortions are the ORs and tariff on imports.
The CET was first introduced by Powell and Gruen (1967). This may be viewed as a strong assumption but it is implicit as
well in most other estimates of the costs of protection.

WELFARE COSTS OF 491


QUOTAS

TABLE 1. —E s ici
S
rECI FICATION
Sector (CENTRAL CASE)

Copyright O 2001 All Rights


Transformation
Column Notes Substitution Substitution Domestic/Export
lasticity of Intermediates Capital/Labor Sales
Elasticity (1) (2) (3) (4) t5) (1) (2) (3) Price Elasticities
of Final Demand Premia
Elasticity Domestic Imports Rates
(4) (5) (6)
Agriculture a c e k f 1.4 0.6 4.0 0.75 0.8
Food a c e f f 0.3 0.8 3.0 0.90 1.1
Mining b b e j f 0.5 0.8 3.0 0.50 1.0
Iron and Steel a d e i f 3.0 1.0 3.0 1.0 1.4
Motor Vehicles a c e h h 2.0 0.8 3.0 1.2 1.1 31.9Wo
Textiles and Apparel a c e I f 2.6 1.0 3.0 0.4 3.9 40.5Wo
Other Manufactures a c e f f 3.6 0.8 3.0 1.5 1.8
OtherConsumer a c e f f 3.2 0.8 3.0 1.9 2.4
TradedServices b c e g g 2.0 0.8 0.7 0.5 0.6
Non-traded Services b g 0.8 0.5
Note CES and CET functions imply that the corresponding elasticities of substitution (transformation) correspond to compensated import dema n‹l
(export supply) elasticities
All price elasticities of demand are defined as positive numbers -or premia estimates, see text. Column notes correspond to the sources from which
estimates are interpolated. For interpolation deta ils see Tarr (1988)
(a) Shiells, Stern and Deardorfl (1986); (b) Dixon ct al. (1982); fc) Caddy (1976); (d) Hekman (1978), (e) own estimates, (f) Stern, Francis and Schumacher
(1976), tg) Hout hakker and Taylor (1970); (h) cevinsohn (1988); (i) Cr andall (198 I ), fy) Bohi and Russell (1978), (k) USDA (1984), (1) Hufbauer, Berliner and
Elliott ( 1986)

QRs in textiles and autos. We discuss these briefly that our welfare estimates are quite insensitive to
below. (Tarr (1989, chaps. 5 and 6) is devoted to a considerable changes in their values.7
detailed discussion of how these estimates were For the premia rate estimates for apparel (ex-
derived.) pressed as a percentage of landed U.S. import
Table 1 presents all elasticities and our con- price inclusive of tariffs), we have relied on
structed estimates of pre-existing premia. These Hamilton (1988). Hamilton’s data are based on
elasticities correspond to the “central” elastici- the sale of rights to export apparel products to
ties. (When we report in table 3 the likely range the United States. His data give an estimate of
of the welfare effects of removing all trade re- the quota rents captured by Hong Kong. In order
strictions, we are reporting results from the “low” to understand the problem of premia rate estima-
and “high” elasticities that are derived from the tion, it is crucial to recognize that the existing
“central” elasticities in table 1 by subtracting and Multifiber Arrangement (MFA) allows a number
adding, respectively, a standard deviation. 6 ) Be- of marginally inefficient foreign suppliers to sell
cause much econometric work has been done to in the United States. If the MFA were abolished,
estimate the capital/labor substitution elastici- many of them would be squeezed out of the U.S.
ties, we are fairly confident about the accuracy of market by competition. The quota premium rate
these elasticities. We are also fairly confident of earned by these inefhcient suppliers is less than
the import demand elasticities, for which a num- the quota premium rate paid by U.S. consumers
ber of estimates are available. Less confidence as a result of the MFA. Thus, we had to deter-
can be placed on export supply elasticities. How- mine the marginal supplier to the United States if
ever, because these latter elasticities enter only the MFA were abolished. Data in Hamilton
indirectly into our estimations, we have found (1988) allow us to determine that Hong Kong,
which had a quota premium rate of 479c for
apparel sold to the United States in 1984, or a
As the sources for table 1 detail, the estimates were
obtained from many studies. These studies generally provide supplier more
standard errors of estimates. For those elasticities taken from
Stern, Francis and Schumacher, the high and low estimates
are generally the high and low estimates from their survey,
7
which are not based on standard deviations. In a few cases the For example, doubling (halving) the elasticity estimates in
high and low estimates are obtained by doubling and halving column (3) increases (decreases) our estimates of the welfare
the central estimate. See Tarr f1988, ch. 5) for details. gains with the central elasticity estimates from US$22.0 billion
(with infinite foreign trade elasticities) to $22.1 ($22.9) billion,
respectively, or + 0.5 to.
492 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

efficient than Hong Kong, would be the marginal sumption of imported steel products by 159c from
supplier if quotas were removed.' the observed levels in 1984. This restriction re-
The United States is much more competitive in sults in a 7Wo premium on imported intermediate
textiles than in apparel. Consequently, for textiles steel products. The employment hgures in col-
we take 5% as the premium rate, which is much umn 2 are only for the industry subject to quota
more conservative than the 159c proposed by removal; the total economy-wide relocation of
Cline (1987, p. 167). A positive rate is indicated, workers is reported in column 3. This latter mea-
however, based on data in a study by the U.S. sure is a summary of interindustry effects (see
International Trade Commission (1987). For au- Deardorff and Stern (1986)).
tos we relied on the quality-adjusted premia esti- The figures in table 2 reveal that the largest
mates of Feenstra (1988) for Japanese car im- welfare costs are due to the ORs in textiles and
ports by the United States. For European car apparel. This may seem surprising since that sec-
imports, we relied on the quality-adjusted price tor is smaller than autos, and imports are three-
increase of European cars sold in the United fourths of auto imports in value (including pre-
States estimated by Dinopoulos and Kreinin mia). Also, the proportion of the total welfare
(1988). Our resulting premia estimates, which are costs due to distortionary costs are much higher
weighted averages, are 41% for textiles and ap- in textiles and apparel than in autos even in the
parel and 32% for autos.9 case of an infinite elasticity of import supply in
autos. This is so because the premium rate is
N. Welfare Cost Estimates higher and because the price elasticity of demand
The costs of QRs reported in tables 2 and 3 for textiles and apparel is almost four times higher
below are based on estimates of the premia that than the corresponding elasticity for autos. Fur-
accrue to the exporting countries rather than to thermore, the relative homogeneity of domestic
the United States. One can therefore distinguish and imported steel reduces the production costs
two components of the costs of the QRs: (1) the of distortion.''
income or rent transfer to foreigners and (2) the Because elasticity estimates are not precise, we
distortionary cost due to the usual consumption report in table 3 a range of welfare gains from
and production costs of protection.' 0 Table 2 removing all QRs simultaneously for the cases of
summarizes these costs for each of the three low, central, and high elasticities. Because the
industries: textiles and apparel, autos and steel. marginal benefit to the economy of an income
Since the restrictions on steel—which resulted in transfer is a decreasing function of demand and
approximately a 15% reduction in imports of supply elasticities, the welfare gains from captur-
steel starting in early 1985—were not imple- ing rents from foreigners is higher in the low
mented until 1985, we obtain the estimates for elasticity case than in the high elasticity case. Of
steel by reducing intermediate and final con- course, these estimated welfare gains due to the

8
We note that estimates of quota premia, in both textiles The United States imposes ORs in other sectors in addi-
and automobiles, vary from year to year. We obtained esti- tion to textiles, autos and steel. For example, Hufbauer,
mates of quota premia for 1984, the year for which we Berliner and Elliott (1986) reported QRs in book manufactur-
benchmarked the model. Thus, our estimates apply to the ing, motorcycles, shipbuilding and maritime industries, sugar
conditions prevailing in that year. For other years, the premia and food products containing sugar, cheese and other dairy
rates and our cost estimates may differ. products, pean uts and meat. We have simulated the effects of
If the marginal supplier is more efficient than Hong Kong, removing all the QRs in the economy by assuming a high
our premium rate estimate is conservative and the associated (low) premia rate (tariff equivalent) of the ORs (with rents
welfare gain estimate is downward-biased. There is evidence going to the foreigners) of 5to (2.5Wo) in agriculture; 3Wo
that, during the quota era, U.S. dealers of Japanese autos (1.5 to) in other manufactures, other consumer goods and
captured about $550 per vehicle in rents above those rents food; and zero in the remaining sectors. Given these premia
captured by foreigners. This would correspond to a higher rates, the welfare gain from removing all QRs, including those
premium rate on autos of 43to, of which foreigners capture in textiles, autos and steel, is $27.6 billion in the high and
80Wo of the rents. We shall provide separate estimates for this $24.0 billion in the low premia rate cases. These estimates of
scenario. the benefits of removing all QRs, however, can only be
’0 In the cases where there are terms of trade effects, the considered suggestive because, unlike the case of our esti-
estimates of the distortionary costs of protection are reduced mates of the premia rates in textiles, autos and steel, we have
because the terms of trade effects partially offset the distor- not done a careful estimate of the premia rates in the remain-
tionary cost component of the ORs. ing sectors of our model.

Copyright 2001 All Rights


WELFARE COSTS OF QUOTAS 493
TABLE 2.—WELFARE COSTS ANn Evrrovvnsi Errnc+s or ORs:
I>oIVI DUAL S ACTORS

Employment
Change in the Economy- Vide
Welfare“ Industry Losing Gain Employment
Its OR Relocation'

Textiles and Apparel


Remove ORs 11.92 — 157.2 157.2
(0.15)
Capture Rents 6.05 — 3.05 28.35
from Foreigners (0.03)
Autos
Remove QRs 7.50 —1.2 1.3
t9.10) t0.001)
Capture Rents 7.95 +1.3 37.2
from Foreigners (7.92) (0.035)
Steel
Remove ORs 0.86 — 20.7 22.3
(0.021)
Capture Rents 0.74 — 0.1 3.5
from Foreigners (0.003)
Note. Estimates based on central e las treaties, with infi nite fore ign t rade ela st deities. except for ci„„, - 5, a nd — 4, where •)„,t, is ihe
foreign elastics iy of impcirt su pply of autos and ep¿, is the foreign elasticity of demand for exports of agriculture
" Welfare is the ñ U measure expressed in billions of 1984 U S dollars Numbers in parentheses are based on infin ite foreign trade e last ilities in
all sectors
' Employment is expressed in t housa nds of work-years
One- half of the sum of the absolute val ue of the employment changes expressed in thousand work-years The nu mbers in parentheses a re the
percentage of employees in the economy who must relocate For example, IU I fi) means that fifteen-hundred ths of 1*Zc of the economy’s employees
must relocate
If I J S dealers of Japanese autos capture additional rents Iexplained in footnote 9), the welfare ga in from removing O Rs is $ ? 57 I illion with 1
nfinite tore lgn trade elasticities

T Bt E 3. —WE LFA RF COSTS OF O RS AN TA R IFr P ROT I-M ION

Strong Foreign Preferred Foreign Trade


Elasticities Trade Elasticities
Low Central High Central
Elasticity Elasticity ' Elasticity" Elasticity'

Remove QRs 20.5 20.3 21.6 15.0


(22.0)
Capture Rents from 1fi.b 14.9 14.5 15.0
Foreigners (retain ORs) (14.5)
Eliminate Remaining
Tariff Protection 0..33 0.57 0.90 — 4.3
(after QR removal) (0.94)
Note: Welfare iS the AV meazure expressed in billions of 1084 U S dollars Let c/- e la8t city cf dem And fur
exports oflecor, and = e!alt ,Sof upply ofcnpo,ts *n ›tc1or ;
The centta eIasnc1ye›nma1es dre not hehveon chs hgn aud lopola,wc›yos1‹mue,, becausepe nrae a new

- 4, e/„„, ' ñ Small country a'•8umptlon for all ct he:r export demand and lmpcrt supply e I a ,tdeities
Results in pa rent heses are the welfare estimates with infinite toreign trade e lasticit res
e'' for cxpcir ts = 3 and e,‘ of supply of imports — 4 whe re i ranges over all traded sectors.

capturing of rents from foreigners are overesti- Insofar as removing QRs leads to increases in mates to the extent that
rent-seeking activities agricultural exports and auto imports, the U.S. dissipate them. For this reason, an auction quota terms
of trade will decline and hence the welfare mechanism is superior to a direct allocation of gain will be less. For the
central elasticity case, quota rights to imports. Thus our estimate of the the welfare gain is $20.3 billion, of which $5.4
annual cost of ORs in these three industries for billion is the distortionary cost component of 1955 protection levels
is between $20 billion and QRs. Obtaining the quota rents is a pure income
$22 billion. transfer from the rest of the world to the United
494 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

States, and its effect is a real appreciation of the


hence an endogenous trade balance. This would
dollar (about 1%) which is accompanied by a
correspond to what is typically done in PE esti-
small improvement in the terms of trade.
mates, which implicitly assume that the real ex-
It is conceivable that the United States would
change rate is unchanged as a result of QR
have monopoly and monopsony power in all sec-
removal and that resulting import increases need
tors in which it trades. Although this seems un-
not be compensated by increased exports (or re-
likely because the U.S. market share is usually
duced imports from other sectors). For the cen-
small in its main import and export markets, we
tral elasticity case, removing all ORs would lead
have experimented with generalized terms of
to a trade balance deterioration of $12.1 billion and
trade effects across all sectors for the central
an EV estimate of $33.9 billion. This esti- mate is
elasticity case. In column 4 of table 3, we assume
about one and two-thirds times the estimate
constant import supply elasticities of 4 and con-
obtained when the balance of trade con- straint is
stant export demand elasticities of 3 for all traded
properly taken into account. Economy- wide
sectors. The gains from QR removal are smaller,
welfare costs estimates derived by adding up
but still substantial ($15.0 billion). However, in
individual industry PE estimates are likely to be
this case the terms of trade effects (from ex-
significantly upward-biased.
panded trade volume at higher import prices and
Our welfare cost estimates are significantly
lower export prices) exactly offset the distor-
higher than previous GE estimates.' 2 This is so
tionary costs in total OR costs. Finally, adding
for several reasons. First we properly account for
unilateral tariff reduction now results in a welfare
the $14.9 billion transfer associated with the U.S.
loss of $4.3 billion because of the dominating
system of QRs." Thus, even with generalized
terms of trade effect, a result similar to those
terms of trade effects which are stronger than we
found in the global simulations mentioned above.
believe reasonable,’4 the QRs cost the U.S. econ-
Evidence of pure profits in autos and of
omy $15 billion. Second, in comparison with most
economies of scale in autos and, to a lesser ex-
previous PE and GE estimates, we have benefited
tent, in steel raises the question of the extent to
from the detailed work on premia estimates by
which our estimates would be affected by imper-
Feenstra (1988), Hamilton (1988) and Dinopoulos
fect competition and economies of scale in autos
and Kreinin (1988), which are higher than previ-
and steel. We view the empirical effects of imper-
ous estimates.
fect competition and economies of scale as off-
setting. Due to the fact that costs will increase,
OR removal will result in lower benefits than we V. Employment
have estimated to the extent that there are unre- Table 4 gives estimates of the employment
alized economies of scale in autos and steel. effects of simultaneous removal of ORs in tex-
Following Krishna (1983), however, ORs should tiles, autos and steel for the central elasticity
be viewed as a practice facilitating pricing above case. The simultaneous removal of ORs also
competitive levels. QR removal, therefore, will points out the conflicting worker interests across
induce a reduction in oligopolistic pricing prac- the three industries subject to QRs. While the
tices and lead to greater benefits (relative to our steel and textiles and apparel sectors would lose
estimates) from a reduction in the distortion costs almost as many jobs when all QRs are removed
of these pricing practices. Thus, we do not know,
a priori, the direction of the bias in our estimates ' 2 For example, Whalley (1985, table 10.2) estimates welfare
due to imperfect competition and economies of losses from unilateral U.S. removal of non-tariff barriers and
scale. The issue, however, is clearly worthy of tariffs. Deardorff and Stern (1986, table 4.6) obtain small
welfare gains.
further investigation.
'" Most previous GE studies of the costs of protection (e.g.,
In the introduction, we said that PE estimates Deardorff and Stern (1986) and Whalley (1985)) that have
are upwardly biased because they fail to include dealt with ORs have done so in the context of global models
the balance of trade constraint. An order of mag- that treat QRs by their tariff equivalents without including the
associated rent transfer that occurs with the U.S. ORs.
nitude of the diflerence between PE and GE " In addition, Brown (1987) has shown that the structure of
estimates due to this effect is obtained by solving many previous GE models has required excessive estimates of
the model with a fixed real exchange rate and terms of trade effects. See also de Melo 11986) and Deardorff
and Stern (1986, p. 41).

WELFARE COSTS OF 495


OUOTAS

as when they are removed in their sector alone, currently with the VER on autos. This is so because
the auto sector gains 1,700 jobs when ORs on steel, an important input into auto pro- duction,
steel and textiles and apparel are removed con- becomes cheaper and because the in- come
Copyright O 2001 All Rights
elasticity of demand for autos is high. Both effects TABLe 4. —Eurcovunsi Errors or Reuovi o
benefit the domestic auto industry which expands ORs
even when QR protection is removed. in Autos, STEEL AND Tex+ires
(CENTRAL ELASTI CITv CASE)‘
Given that QR protection is obtained through (thousand jobs)
the political process, one can argue that the U.S.
Agriculture 6.4
Congress has decided to value a job in the pro- Food 0.8
tected sectors more highly than a job in other Mining 4.5
sectors. In our experiment, 172,000 jobs in tex- Textiles and Apparel — 156.4
Autos 1.7
tiles and steel were protected by the QRs on the Steel — 13.5
three sectors at a cost of $20.3 billion. Hence, the Consumer Goods 17.5
annual cost per protected job is about $118,000, Other Manufacturing 87. I
Traded Services 35.4
approximately 8 (3) times the average annual Non-Traded Services 18.fi
total compensation of workers in the textile (steel) Foreign trade e lasticitieS defined in table 3
industry.
If QRs are removed, displaced workers will
incur search, relocation, and retraining costs (see
Mussa (1978)). Net benefits from QR removal are That is, for every dollar of earnings losses saved,
obtained by subtracting these costs. A proxy for the economy loses $65.
these costs is the discounted value of a displaced
worker’s earnings losses over a lifetime." This
measure allows us to estimate how much gainers VI. CORCIUSIO¥IS
will have left after compensating displaced work- Perhaps the most striking result is the high cost
ers for their earnings losses. Earnings losses for of protection from NTBs relative to that from
displaced workers last approximately six years." tariffs. While this is repeatedly mentioned in pol-
A conservative estimate of net benefits, NB, is icy discussions, few relative estimates are avail-
obtained as able. The figures in table 3 suggest that the
welfare cost of tariff protection is between 2%
(low elasticity case) and 4% (high elasticity case)
of the welfare cost of QRs in textiles, autos and
steel. Since there are other QRs in the United
States beyond those examined here, this estimate
is a lower bound.
An alternative way to evaluate the costs of
ORs is to ask what tariff structure would give the
5 EV — C, 1 same welfare loss as existing QRs in the three
NB —— sectors. In the central elasticity estimates (with
(1 + r)’
infinite foreign trade elasticities), the total wel-
fare cost is estimated at $22.0 billion (1984 dol-
where ñK is the equivalent variation measure, lars), of which $7.2 billion is the distortionary
C,
component. For that set of elasticities, moving
is estimated earnings losses in year t, and r —— 7%
from the actual tariff structure to a uniform tariff
is the discount rate. (This estimate is conservative
structure yielding the same (import weighted) av-
since earnings losses are zero after six years,
erage protection would represent a welfare gain
while yearly benefits do not decay.) NB is $104
of $0.70 billion. (Removing tariffs altogether
billion, with an associated benefit/cost of
would give a welfare gain of $0.94 billion.) Start-
65.
ing from the existing tariff dispersion, to get the
distortionary cost element of ORs would require
'‘ We call our estimate a proxy for these adjustment costs multiplying each tariff by 3.6 times its 1984
because we have not incorporated into our model an endoge-
nous sector that moves resources, as suggested by the theoret- value, which would amount to an average (import
ical work by Mussa. weighted) nominal protection of 12.59r. Adding
" See Jacobson (1978). To be conservative, we measure the loss due to rent transfers would require multi-
total compensation losses, which exceed earnings losses by the
amount of fringe benefits. Morkre and Tarr (1980, chapter 3) plying tariffs by 7.4 times their 1984 value,
discuss the merits of this measure and the alternative unem-
ployment cost measure.

Copvriciht O 2001 All Riahts Reserved


496 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS
amounting to an average protection of 19.8Hpo 17 , “Automobile Prices and Protection: The U.S.—Japan
It is no exaggeration to say that, in terms of Trade Restraint,” Journal of Policy Modelling 7 (1985), 49
—68.
protection costs, QRs are taking us back to the Ouality Change Under Trade Restraints: Theory
early days of multilateral tariff negotiations, espe- and Evidence from Japanese Autos,” Quarterly Journal of
cially if one includes the rent transfer element. Economics 103 (1988), 131 —146.
Hamilton, C., “Restrictiveness and International Transmis-
sion of the ‘New’ Protectionism,” in R. Baldwin,
C. Hamilton, and A. Sapir leds.), Issues in US-EC
REFERENCES Trade Relations (Chicago: University of Chicago Press
Baldwin, R. E., J. Mutti, and D. Richardson, “Welfare Effects for National Bureau of Economic Research, 1988), 199—
on the United States of a Significant Multilateral Tariff 224.
Reduction,” Journal of International Economics 10 Hekman, J., “An Analysis of the Changing Pattern of Iron
(1980), 405—423. and Steel Production in the Twentieth Century,”
Bohr, D., and M. Russel I, Limiting Oil Imports: An Economic American Economic Ret’iew 68 (1978a, 123— 133.
History and Analysis (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Uni- Houthakker, H., and L. Taylor, Consumer Demand in the
versity, 1978). United Slates: Analyses and Projections (Cambridge:
Brown, D. K., “Tariffs, the Terms of Trade and National Harvard University Press, 1970).
Product Differentiation,” Journal of Policy Modelling 9 Hufbauer, G., D. Berliner, and K. Elliott, Trade Protection in
(1987), 503—526. the United States: 31 Case Studies (Washington, D.C.:
Caddy, V., “Empirical Estimation of the Elasticity of Substi- Institute for International Economics, 1986).
tution: A Review,” Preliminary Working Paper OP-09, Jacobson, L., “Earnings Losses of Workers Displaced from
IMPACT Project. IAC, Melbourne, Australia (1976). Manufacturing Industries.” in W. Dewald (ed.), The
Cline, W. The Future of World Trade in Textiles and Apparel Impact of International Trade and Inuestmeni on Em-
(Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Eco- ployment (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of La-
nomics, 1987). bor, 1978), 87—98.
Crandall, R., The U.S. Steel Industry in Recurrent Crisis Johnson, H. G., “The Cost of Protection and the Scientific
(Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1981). Tariff,” Journal of Political Economy 68 (1960), 327—
Deardorff, A., and R. Stern, The Michigan Model of World 345.
Production and Trade (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, Keesing, D., and M. Wolf, Textile Quotas Against Det’eloping
1986). Countries (London: Trade Policy Research Centre,
Dinopoulos, E., and M. Kreinin, “Effects of the U.S. -Japan 1980).
Auto VER on European Prices and U.S. Welfare,” this Krishna, K., Trade Restrictions as Facilitating Practices Discus-
sEvie 70 (1988), 484—491. sion paper Number 5S Princeton University (1983).
Dixit, A., “Optimal Trade and Industrial Policies for the U.S. Levinsohn, J., “Empirics of Taxes on Differentiated Products:
Automobile Industry,” in R. Feenstra (ed.), Empirical The Case of Tariffs in the U.S. Automobile Industry,”
Methods for International Trade (Cambridge, MA: MIT in R. E. Baldwin (ed.), Trade Policy Issues and Empin -
Press, 1988), 141—165. cal Analysis (Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
Dixon, P., B. Parmenter, J. Sutton, and D. Vincent, ORANI: 1985), 11—44.
A Multisectoral Model of the Australian Economy Melo, J. de, “A Comparison of 50Wo Multilateral Tariff Re-
(Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1982). ductions in Two Global Trade Models,” in T. N.
Elliott, K., J. Schott, and W. Takacs, Auction Quoias and U.S. Srinivasan and J. Whalley (eds.), General Equilibrium
Trade Policy (Washington, D.C.: Institute for Interna- Trade Policy Modelling (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press,
tional Economics, 1987). 1986).
Feenstra, R., “Voluntary Export Restraints in U.S. Autos, 1980 Melo, J. de, and D. Tarr, Welfare Costs of US Quotas in
—81: Ouality, Employment and Welfare Effects,” in R. Textiles, Steel and Autos, PPR Working Paper No. 83,
Baldwin and A. Krueger (eds.), The Structure and Washington D.C.: World Bank (1988).
Evolution of Recent U.S. Trade Policy (Chicago: Morkre, M., Import Quotas on Textiles: The Welfare Effects of
Univer- sity of Chicago Press for National Bureau of United States Restrictions on Hong Kong (Washington,
Economic Research, 1984). D.C.: Bureau of Economics Report to the U.S. Federal
Trade Commission, 1984).
Morkre, M., and D. Tarr, The Effects of Restnctions on U.S.
" In that experiment we are increasing the variance of Impons: Five Case Studies and Theory (Washington,
nominal protection by 3.6 and 7.4 times the variance prevail- D.C.: Bureau of Economics Report to U.S. Federal
ing in 1984. Since the distortionary cost of tariff protection is Trade Commission, 1980).
positively related to the average level of protection and to the Mussa, M., “Dynamic Adjustment in the Heckscher-Ohlin-
variance of tariffs tsee Johnson (1962)), another hypothetical Samuelson Model,” Journal of Political Economy 86
calculation would consist of computing the average tariff (5), 775—791.
under the assumption of no tariff dispersion across sectors. In Powell, A., and F. Gruen, “The Constant Elasticity of Trans-
that case, starting from a uniform tariif protection (3.59c) formation Production Frontier and Linear Supply Sys-
equivalent to the existing tariff protection in 1984, the distor- tem,” International Economic Review 8 (1967), 315—328.
tionary cost element of ORs would require an average uni- Shiells, C., R. Stern and A. Deardorff, “Estimates of the
form protection of 24Wo. Adding the rent transfer loss would Elasticities of Substitution between Imports and Home
raise the average uniform protection to 50Wo. With linear, Goods for the United States,” Weltwirtschaftliches
rather than constant elasticity demand and supply curves, Archiu 122 (3) (1986), 497-519.
welfare calculations would yield lower estimates as the corre- Stern, R. M., 1. Francis and B. Schumacher, Price Elasticities
sponding elasticities would increase as one moves up the in International Trade: An Annotated Bibliographer
demand and supply curves. (London: Macmillan Press, 1976).
WELFARE COSTS OF QUOTAS 497

Tarr, 13., A General Equilibrium Analysts of the Welfare and 1984 Farm Legislation (Washington, D.C., 1984).
Employment Ejects of US Quotas on Textiles, Autos, U.S. International Trade Commission, US Global Competitive-
and Steel (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Federal Trade Com- ness: the US Textile Infill Industry, Publication No. 2048,
mission, 1989). Dec. 1987.
Tarr, D., and M. Morkre, Aggregate Costs to the Uniied States Whalley, J., Trade Liberalization Among Major World I"rading
of Tariffs and Quotas on Imports: General Tariff Cuts Areas (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1985).
and Remot’al of Quotas on Aiuomobtles, Steel, Sugar, Winston, C., and Associates, Blind Intersection* Policy and the
und Textiles (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Federal Trade Automobile Industry (Washington, D.C.: Brookings In-
Commission, 1984). stitution, 1987).
U.S. Department of Agriculture, Dairy: Background for the

Copyright O 2001 All Rights


Copyright of Review of Economics & Statistics is the property of MIT Press and its content may not be copied
or emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv without the copyright holder's express written permission.
However, users may print, download, or email articles for individual use.

You might also like