Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 10

Economics of Education Review 23 (2004) 431–440

www.elsevier.com/locate/econedurev

Can parents choose the best schools for their children?


Joseph L. Bast a,∗, Herbert J. Walberg b
a
The Heartland Institute, 19 South LaSalle Street 903, Chicago, IL 60603, USA
b
Hoover Institution, 180 East Pearson Street 3607, Chicago, IL 60611, USA

Received 21 April 2003; accepted 22 August 2003

Abstract

One of Lewis Solmon’s research interests is whether parents can choose the best schools for their children. This
paper shows how economic principles predict parents would do a better job choosing schools for their children than
do experts in government agencies. Three types of empirical research relevant to the hypothesis are reviewed: surveys
showing parents rate schools the same as experts (showing they have sufficient information to choose correctly); surveys
showing most parents choose schools on the basis of their perceived academic quality (showing they are choosing in
the child’s best long-term interests); and data showing student academic achievement gains are higher in schools of
choice than in traditional public schools. We conclude that Solmon’s belief that parents can choose the best schools
for their children is corroborated by economic theory and empirical research.
 2003 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

JEL classification: I2-128

Keywords: Educational vouchers; School choice

1. Introduction grade” question showed an exact match for 11 of the


14 schools selected with the largest number of parents
“Critics of school choice policies,” Lewis Solmon responding to the survey.
(2003) wrote recently, “have long questioned parents’ Solmon’s test, conducted with the precision and
ability to choose the best school for their child. Do par- thoroughness that characterizes all his writing, is
ents, the argument goes, have the time, qualifications, revealing, though opponents of school choice can argue
and information to make informed decisions about the that charter school parents are more informed or mot-
quality of their child’s school?” (p. 9). Solmon tested the ivated than public school parents, the sample size is too
critics’ fears by comparing how parents and experts at small, Arizona is not a typical state, and so on. Empirical
the Arizona Department of Education rated 239 charter data from small school choice experiments can persuade
schools. people with open minds that parents can indeed choose
The results were striking. “Across the board, state schools wisely, but it cannot establish a universal prin-
officials and parents gave nearly identical grades to the ciple or theory that applies in all cases.
charter schools in question.” (p. 10) Parents and state This paper contends the hypothesis that parents can
officials agreed on the best charter school, and the aver- choose the best schools for their children conforms with
age grade point average of each school on the “overall economic theory and is not refuted by reliable empirical
data. In Section 2 we describe how friends and foes of
school choice characterize the hypothesis. In Section 3

Corresponding author. Tel.: +1-312-377-4000; fax: +1- we show how it is supported by fundamental economic
312-377-5000. theories. In Section 4 we review data from various tests
E-mail address: jbast@heartland.org (J.L. Bast). of the hypothesis and find strong (but not unanimous)

0272-7757/$ - see front matter  2003 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.econedurev.2003.08.003
432 J.L. Bast, H.J. Walberg / Economics of Education Review 23 (2004) 431–440

empirical support. Section 5 contains a brief interpret- ined by parental choice assumes that all parents are fully
ation and concluding remarks. informed of their choices and fully capable of acting in
their child’s best interests,” writes Saltman (2000). “This
has been found not to be the case.” (p. 24)
2. Can parents do a better job choosing the schools Finally, some advocates of only limited school choice
their children attend than “experts” working for trace their doubts to our hypothesis. Etzioni (1992), in
governments? the foreword to a book advocating school choice, warns:
“There are dangers in the simplistic introduction of com-
The current system of school finance, write Coons and petition into areas of human services. In these areas the
Sugarman (1978), is based on the notion that “local consumer’s knowledge is usually limited; it is more dif-
government agents make better school assignments for ficult for parents to evaluate education than, say, a can
individual children they have never met than would the of beans” (p. xi).
family, even were the family to be supported by pro- Hill, Pierce and Guthrie (1997), who support limited
fessional counseling” (p. 47). Coons and Sugarman also school choice, are similarly cautious: “In education as in
point out that “the question is not whether the judgment health care, consumers do not have as much information
of the isolated and unassisted family is superior to the as the professionals, and are therefore at a disadvantage.
professional cadre of a school or a district. It is rather, … The only way markets work effectively with asym-
when all available knowledge, personal and professional, metric information is when consumers trust that suppliers
about the particular school is assembled, to whom shall are likely to act in the consumers’ interests. There must
society commit the final choice” (p. 51). be a relationship of trust created by personal relation-
The formal statement of the hypothesis needs to assert ships and shared values.” (pp. 63–64.)
not only that parents can choose the best schools for their
children, but that they would do so more often than the
available alternative, which is student assignment by 3. What economic theory tells us about parents
public school bureaucracies. Moreover, what constitutes choosing schools
the “best school” for a child is fraught with compli-
cations, starting with the implication that there exists a The prediction that parents would do a better job
single best learning environment for every student choosing schools for their children than experts in
(doubtful) and uniform agreement on the purpose of government agencies is well grounded in economic
schooling and most valuable outcomes (definitely not). theory. First we explain why parents can be expected to
A reasonable rendering of the hypothesis, then, could be good choosers, and then why government experts are
be: Parents would do a better job choosing the schools unlikely to do as well.
their children attend than “experts” working for govern-
ments. This is only one of several hypotheses put for- 3.1. Why parents would be expected to choose
ward by advocates of school choice and does not by correctly
itself make the case for policy change.
Our formulation of the hypothesis is consistent with Parents choose schools for their children based on
how it has been characterized by friends and foes of costs and benefits (incentives), the availability of infor-
school choice. Milton and Rose Friedman (1980) write, mation, and the presence of opportunities (choices). Par-
“No doubt, some parents lack interest in their children’s ents who choose the right schools for their children bene-
schooling or the capacity and desire to choose wisely. fit in several ways. They see the skills and norms they
However, they are in a small minority. In any event, our value transferred to a loved one; their children are apt
present system unfortunately does little to help their chil- to be happier, better behaved, less prone to complaining,
dren” (p. 160). and less apt to “get in trouble”; a well-educated child is
David Harmer (1993), a coauthor of California’s 1993 more likely to become financially independent and a
Parental Choice in Education Initiative, writes, “Most happy adult; and financially independent and happy
parents love their children more than anyone and any- adults are more likely to provide aid and comfort in the
thing else. Parents in the poorest circumstances seem to parents’ old age and produce healthy grandchildren. It
have the strongest desire for their children to do better. would be easy to produce a similarly long list of costs
They want good schools and they know where good borne by parents who choose the wrong schools for
schools are” (p. xv). their children.
Opponents of school choice recognize the hypothesis “For most parents, children are a source of psychic
and believe it is false. “When parents do select another income or satisfaction, and, in the economist’s termin-
school, academic concerns often are not central to the ology, children could be considered a consumption
decision,” claims the Carnegie Foundation for the good,” Becker (1976) writes. “Children may sometimes
Advancement of Teaching (1992, p. 13). “Equity determ- provide money income and are then a production good
J.L. Bast, H.J. Walberg / Economics of Education Review 23 (2004) 431–440 433

as well” (p. 172). Parents have incentives to invest in Agenda (1999) found 55% of parents with children cur-
their children for much the same reasons as they invest rently in government schools (and 67% of inner-city
in other durable goods. Of course, children are more than parents) would choose private schools if tuition was not
appliances that can talk (see Morse, 2001), but this dif- a concern. The Harwood Group (1995) found large
ference makes parents more rather than less likely to sub- majorities of parents and upwards of 80% of African-
ordinate their own interests to those of their children. American families would choose private schools over
Do parents know enough about their children’s edu- government schools if tuition were not a consideration.
cational needs and the offerings of competing schools to School choice would not increase the total amount of
make informed decisions? Coons and Sugarman (1978) schooling demanded, but merely change the mix of pub-
write, “At the outset we concede that school pro- lic and private schooling. Resources, including facilities
fessionals know more than families about how certain and personnel, would be released from the public sector
types of education have been found to affect broadly in amounts roughly equal to their acquisition by the priv-
defined types or classes of children. Such knowledge is ate sector. The private K-12 schooling sector constitutes
useful for many purposes; however, it does not translate a very small part of a marketplace that includes public
into the kind of understanding about particular children pre-kindergarten and K-12 schools, public and private
that comes from prolonged domestic intimacy” (p. 53). technical and business training, and public and private
The distinction they make is quite similar to one Hayek higher education. Therefore, even if they were to grow
(1968) made between “knowledge of the particular cir- rapidly, private K-12 schools would probably have little
cumstances of time and place” and aggregate data avail- effect on wages or rents.
able to central planners (p. 80). It has the same impli- None of the inputs needed for K-12 schooling is
cation: decision-making authority is best put in the hands especially scarce or specialized, with the possible excep-
of those who are closest to and most familiar with a situ- tion of qualified teachers on some subjects. Schools can
ation and do operate in a variety of places, including shopping
Parents should not be presumed to be ill equipped to malls, museums, universities, and office buildings
make this decision. They are trusted, after all, to choose (Seder, 1999). If schooling were provided in a competi-
doctors and hospitals, homes, automobiles, food, and tive market, we would expect to see greater diversity in
many other complicated and expensive goods and ser- size and location as entrepreneurs tailor the traditional
vices. Imperfect and asymmetric information are the rule, school and classroom to meet the interests and needs of
not the exception, in market processes. They are rou- parents and students.
tinely overcome by advertising, experience, producer Markets harmonize the interests of people with differ-
reputations, guarantees and warranties, and other per- ent expectations and knowledge, not mythical and ident-
sonal and public sources of information (Ekelund & ical rational utility maximizers. The subjectivity of
Saurman, 1988). Without compelling proof, they cannot values means markets not only allocate scarce resources
be said to justify regulation (Beals & Muris, 1993), much among competing purposes, but also enable their parti-
less the sweeping restrictions on parental choice cipants to discover and create values, a process integral
observed in public education today. to other freedoms to act, form judgments, make choices,
In the case of K-12 schooling, the supply of infor- and think (Hayek, 1973; Gray, 1984).
mation about school quality is large and growing. Many The idea that markets are discovery processes bears
states now issue “school report cards” that are sent to distinctly on the question of what school is best for a
parents, available on Web sites, and widely reported by child. Plainly, there is no uniform right answer for all
newspapers. No Child Left Behind, the federal school children. Instead, the “best schools” are discovered by
accountability act, requires a significant increase in stud- parents and children as they learn about and try compet-
ent testing, school ranking, and reporting of results to ing alternatives, and often vicariously by observing the
parents. Standard & Poor’s has a Web site experience of others. This discovery process can only
(http://www.ses.standardandpoors.com/) that provides take place when parents are given the opportunity to
extensive information on most public schools in most of choose and schools the obligation to compete with one
the country, as do many state-level think tanks and civic another. Solmon (2003), referring once again to Ari-
organizations. Advocacy and reform groups and schools zona’s charter schools, writes, “Indeed this might be a
have all increased their advertising and promotional case where supply creates its own demand. A new char-
efforts as school choice spreads. ter school that offers a particular curriculum, is con-
If parents rather than government experts chose the veniently located, or caters to special student needs may
schools children attend, would new schools arise attract students who would not have been interested in
enabling parents to exercise their new right? Assuming a charter school if that particular charter school had not
public funding would follow children to their new opened” (p. 36).
schools via a scholarship or voucher program, there is Because their management is decentralized and par-
little doubt demand would rise. A survey by Public ents are free to choose among a variety of schools com-
434 J.L. Bast, H.J. Walberg / Economics of Education Review 23 (2004) 431–440

peting for their children, private schools can specialize the industries they are supposed to regulate because
in creating schools parents want (Merrifield, 2001). The industry representatives influence political decisions
market approach to schooling enables parents and chil- affecting the regulator’s budget, restrict access to infor-
dren to reveal their preferences by choosing schools that mation needed to implement regulations, and promise
specialize in delivering the courses and learning environ- employment after regulators leave government service
ment they want without requiring that all schools offer (Stigler, 1971). In the case of schools, this is apparent
such courses. in the influence teacher unions exercise over most school
principals, superintendents, and school boards
3.2. Why government experts do not choose wisely (Lieberman, 2000; Lieberman, Troy, & Haar, 1994). The
interests of union leaders are different from and therefore
Public choice theory offers three reasons why we compete with those of the child.
would predict government agencies would be inferior to Third, to win election, school board members focus
parents at choosing schools for children. First, the on the needs of the median or typical voter, and so they
rewards for choosing correctly and the cost of mistakes neglect interests that are not widely shared (Mueller,
are not as high for government officials as they are for 1979; Jacobs & Shapiro, 2000). Because student needs
parents. and parent preferences are so diverse, debates over
Administrators, school counselors, and principals school policies—curricula, discipline, facilities, sports
spend much less time with each child than that child’s programs, and so on—become win–lose propositions,
parents. They are less likely to be bothered by the fact rather than a market-driven discovery process that allows
that the skills and norms a child is acquiring are different all parents and children to win. As Hill (2001) writes,
from their own, do not have to listen to the child’s com- “Defining public education as a result of deliberation
plaints or pleas, do not have to explain to neighbors or whose results are binding on everyone eliminates the
police if the child becomes disorderly, do not face the possibility of a differentiated solution—where parents
prospect of providing financial support to an unskilled who object to a particular sequence of instruction would
young adult after graduation, and do not anticipate hav- not have to subject their children to it” (p. 288).
ing to rely on the graduate to provide aid and comfort In conclusion, the hypothesis that parents would do a
in their old age. better job choosing schools for their children than do
The typical government expert does not view students experts in government agencies is consistent with funda-
as Becker’s “durable goods,” worthy of investment, but mental principles of economics.
as inputs in a production process overseen by a bureauc-
racy. Bureaucrats act (as all people do) in ways intended
to increase their income, authority, prestige, or leisure 4. Testing the hypothesis: results of empirical
(Niskanen, 1971; Borcherding, 1977). The bureaucratic research
approach is to minimize discretion and routinize pro-
cedures as much as possible, usually in the name of fair- School choice is not permitted on a wide enough scale
ness and efficiency but often simply to reduce effort and in the US for any single study to provide compelling
increase leisure time. Because government bureaucrats proof that a national school choice program would work
typically operate in a realm where competition is scarce as its advocates say. Moe (1995) warns against
and accountability for results has been weak, their attempting to make such generalizations on the basis of
actions are sometimes at odds with the best interests of small and often heavily regulated experiments (p. 20).
the public (Osborne & Gaebler, 1992; Eggers & O’Le- However, the data reviewed below and summarized in
ary, 1995; Twight, 2002). Table 1 reach well beyond voucher experiments and are
Understanding the nature of bureaucracies, one could sufficient to support our more-narrow hypothesis, that
easily predict that government experts would tend to parents would do a better job choosing their children’s
assign students to large, something-for-everyone neighb- schools than do experts in government agencies. The evi-
orhood schools (to capture economies of scale) based on dence comes from three kinds of tests.
where parents live (to keep transportation costs low),
with exceptions allowed only for disruptive students or 4.1. Parents rate schools the same as experts
to achieve politically imposed racial integration goals.
With only minor variations dating to the early 1990s, Solmon (2003), quoted at the beginning of this essay,
this is in fact the system in place in most of the country compared charter school ratings given by parents with
today. While mechanistically “fair” and “efficient,” it is children enrolled in them to ratings given by government
difficult to imagine an assignment scheme less likely to experts, and found a nearly exact match. If the experts
assign students to schools suited to their particular learn- are right, it cannot be said that charter school parents in
ing styles, interests, or special needs. Arizona are unable to correctly identify good and bad
Second, government regulators are often captured by schools.
J.L. Bast, H.J. Walberg / Economics of Education Review 23 (2004) 431–440 435

Table 1
Summary of research on school choice

Nature of choice Summary of findings Sources

Public school choice Parents and experts rate schools similarly Hoxby (2001)
Small public school districts that compete for Hoxby (2001); Hoxby (2002); Belfield and Levin (2001)
students with neighboring districts achieve
higher test score growth
Public schools that compete with private, Teske and Schneider (2001); Belfield and Levin (2001)
charter, and voucher schools achieve higher
test score growth
Private schools Parents choose schools based on academic Coulson (1999)
achievement, not convenience
Catholic high schools achieve higher Alt and Peter (2003); Neal (1996); Grogger and Neal
graduation, college enrollment, and college (2000); Witte (1996)
graduation rates than public schools
Test score growth is greater in Catholic Coleman and Hoffer (1987); Chubb and Moe (1990);
schools than in public schools Patrinos and Ariasingam (1997); Peterson and Walberg
(2002)
Charter schools Parents and experts rate schools similarly; Solmon (2003)
parents choose for academic reasons
Test score growth is greater (or no worse) in Finn, Manno and Vanourek (2001); Solmon, Paark and
charter schools than in public schools Garcia (2001); Mulholland (1999)
Voucher schools Parents choose voucher schools based on Moe (1995); Witte (2000)
academic achievement, not convenience
Test score growth is greater in voucher schools Gill, Timpane, Ross and Brewer (2001); Greene (2001);
than in public schools, particularly for minority Green (2002); Howell, Wolf, Peterson and Campbell
students (2001); Peterson (2001); Rouse (2000)

Hoxby (2001) uses a national survey conducted in their children’s best interests first. Although it is pre-
1996 by the US Department of Education to compare sumptuous for researchers to assume that academic
how parents rated their public schools with the school’s achievement should be the foremost concern of all par-
value added, defined as the difference between a stud- ents or for all students, this assumption has nevertheless
ent’s tenth- and eighth-grade scores in reading and math. guided most research and commentary on this subject.
She found a strong correlation. For example, only 15% Most parents who choose independent schools do, in
of parents were “highly satisfied” with schools that were fact, choose on the basis of academics. “Topping the list
in the lowest quartile of value added, while 44% of par- of responses in virtually all polls of independent-school
ents were “highly satisfied” with schools in the highest parents is academic quality,” writes Coulson (1999, p.
quartile (p. 117). 260). According to Coulson, a 1993 National Household
Fiske and Ladd (2000), in a largely critical study of Survey conducted by the US Department of Education
New Zealand’s school choice program, nevertheless found “better academic environment” was the most com-
found that parents accurately ranked schools by their mon reason parents gave for choosing an independent
academic performance, though probably by using the school. He also cites surveys of Catholic school parents
socioeconomic mix of students as a proxy for actual test in Washington DC and nationwide with similar findings.
scores. (In New Zealand, as in the US, the two are Solmon’s 2003 study of Arizona charter schools found
closely associated.) “Such behavior is probably quite the three most common reasons given by parents for
rational and sensible,” say Fiske and Ladd, “although we choosing a charter school were “better teachers at this
hasten to add that what is rational for individuals may school” (44.8%), “unhappy with curriculum or teaching
not be rational for society as a whole” (p. 203). at prior school,” (40.0%), and “people told me this is a
better school” (34.6%) (Table 6, p. 13.). All three
4.2. Parents make choices based on academic answers indicate a concern for academic achievement.
outcomes Surveys of parents participating in voucher programs
have found even higher percentages saying their goal
Finding that parents choose schools on the basis of was higher academic achievement for their children.
location (convenience) and extracurricular activities (e.g. According to Witte (2000), 88.6% of parents participat-
sports) is thought to mean that parents are not putting ing in Milwaukee’s voucher program ranked “edu-
436 J.L. Bast, H.J. Walberg / Economics of Education Review 23 (2004) 431–440

cational quality in chosen school” very important, and Belfield and Levin (2001) reviewed more than 35
85.7% said “teaching approach or style” was very studies of the effect of competition on public schools.
important (Table 4.3, p. 63). Private voucher programs The studies typically analyzed the percentages of stu-
in Milwaukee, San Antonio, and Indianapolis all report dents enrolled in private schools and the relative scarcity
more than 80% of their participants say academic quality of public school district monopoly revealed by the pres-
was the most important reason for choosing their chil- ence of many small districts within a county. They con-
dren’s schools (Moe, 1995). clude: “A sizable majority of these studies report ben-
eficial effects of competition across all outcomes, with
4.3. Schools of choice tend to outperform traditional many reporting statistically significant coefficients” (p.
public schools 1). The positive benefits included higher test scores,
graduation rates, efficiency (outcomes per unit of per-
Higher academic achievement by students attending student spending), teacher salaries, housing prices, and
schools of choice, after controlling for family socioecon- adult wages.
omic status, could be evidence that parents are choosing Hoxby has written extensively on the effects of school
wisely. However, it could also be evidence that compe- choice on public schools and their students. In a recent
tition produces better schools by holding schools more summary of her findings (Hoxby, 2002) she reports:
accountable to parents, by encouraging more parental
involvement in children’s schooling, or both. In other ∗ Every increase of 1% in an index of inter-district
words, even if parents are not choosing wisely, the fact choice increases 8th-grade reading scores by 3.82
that producers must compete or that choice motivates national percentile points, 10th-grade math scores by
parents to be more engaged in their children’s schooling 3.06, points, and 12th-grade reading scores by 5.77
may lift their children’s academic achievement. Since points. In each case the effect is statistically signifi-
our hypothesis is silent on the mechanism that enables cant.
parents to choose better schools for their children, such ∗ Every increase of 1% in the share of students who
evidence supports our hypothesis. attend private school in the metropolitan area
increases 8th-grade reading scores by 0.27 national
4.3.1. Public school choice percentile points, 8th-grade math scores by 0.25
Approximately 13% of families with children points, 12th-grade reading scores by 0.34 points, and
attending public schools have access to some sort of 12th-grade math scores by 0.371 points. In each case
school choice program, such as a magnet school, intra- the effect is statistically significant.
or inter-district choice, or charter school, and another ∗ Student achievement improved in those public schools
39% say their choice of where to live was influenced by most exposed to competition by voucher schools in
the school their child would attend (Peterson, 2001, p. Milwaukee and by charter schools in Michigan and
250). Approximately 1.2 million students attended 2400 Arizona, relative to public schools that faced less
magnet schools in the early 1990s. Intradistrict choice competition. The improvement in Milwaukee was
programs were operating in 24.7% of school districts in “dramatic,” in Michigan it was “modest,” and in Ari-
1999–2000, and interdistrict choice programs were zona it was “similar to or just a bit larger than the
reported in 42.4% (US Department of Education, 2002, gains made by Michigan public school students” (p.
Table 29-1). 162).
Magnet school programs have been strongly criticized
for selective enrollment policies that favor students from In other research, Hoxby (2001) also found that
higher socioeconomic backgrounds and with highly mot- schools in metropolitan areas with maximum choice
ivated parents (Fuller, Elmore, & Orfield, 1996). How- among districts are 35% more likely to have a curriculum
ever, Peterson (2001) says “two studies that carefully that fulfills the New Basics criteria in English, math,
addressed this issue still found positive effects from science, social studies, and foreign language than schools
attendance at a magnet school” (p. 256). Peterson reports in areas with minimum choice (p. 113). Schools with
case studies of magnet schools in East Harlem, New more choice opportunities for parents are also likely to
York, and public school choice in Minnesota and Massa- place a greater emphasis on discipline, have more highly
chusetts also find positive outcomes, but probably cannot structured classrooms, and have principals who are
be generalized. Hoxby (1998) believes evaluations of evaluated in part based on their students’ scores on stan-
intradistrict choice programs are often “badly biased” in dardized tests (ibid).
part because “even before and after studies do not enable
us to disentangle the effects of intradistrict choice from 4.3.2. Private school choice
the effects of getting a new superintendent who is paid Private schools in the US enroll approximately 11%
more and given greater latitude than previous adminis- of K-12 students in the US. They consistently achieve
trators” (p. 150). higher graduation rates, attendance rates, levels of par-
J.L. Bast, H.J. Walberg / Economics of Education Review 23 (2004) 431–440 437

ental satisfaction, and college admission rates than public enrolled in charter schools for two consecutive years
schools (Alt & Peter, 2003). These advantages occur show an additional 2.35–2.44 extra point advantage [on
across socioeconomic groupings and are often very large. the Stanford 9 test] over students who stayed in [tra-
For example, students who attend private school are ditional public schools] for two consecutive years. Simi-
twice as likely as those who attended public school to larly, students in charter schools for three consecutive
complete a bachelor’s or higher degree by their mid-20s. years show an additional 1.31 extra point advantage over
Students from low-income families who attend private students in [traditional public schools] for three consecu-
school are three times as likely to earn a bachelor’s tive years. Both differences are statistically signifi-
degree as their public school counterparts (p. 19). cant….” (p. 23). Charter schools also did slightly better
Early attempts to find a “private school effect” after for math after 2 and 3 years, with the difference in the
controlling for parents’ socioeconomic status met with third year not statistically significant. These findings con-
only mixed success. However, more recent research finds tradict earlier research by Mulholland (1999), who had
positive and statistically significant effects (Chubb & concluded, “overall, ... charter schools are not per-
Moe, 1990; Coleman & Hoffer, 1987; Grogger & Neal, forming very differently than other regular public
2000; Neal, 1996; Patrinos & Ariasingam, 1997; Rouse, schools” ( p. 42).
2000; Sander, 1995; Witte, 1996). Peterson and Walberg Unfortunately, many states restrict charter school
(2002) recently studied elementary schools in Brooklyn, autonomy, cap the number of charters at very low levels,
Manhattan, and the Bronx. Catholic schools outscored provide less per-pupil funding than neighboring public
public schools on reading and math at every grade level. schools receive, and restrict charters to serving at-risk
Both Catholic and public schools achieved less as the students, making charter-to-public school comparisons
percentage of their enrollments represented by children difficult to interpret (Hassel, 1998). Finn et al. (2001)
in poverty increased, but rising levels of poverty had a add: “... with all the different testing and assessment
smaller negative effect on learning in Catholic than in mechanisms now in use, with many districts and states
government schools. Remarkably, the Catholic schools changing them so often, and with controversies over
achieved this while spending less than half as much as which students and schools to compare against, finding
their public school counterparts. reliable, comparable, clear, and useful data can be a Her-
culean task” (p. 32).
4.3.3. Charter school choice
Opponents of school choice dispute whether compari- 4.3.4. Voucher school choice
sons of public and private schools adequately control for Private and public voucher programs in Milwaukee,
parent motivation and other differences. During the Cleveland, Washington, DC, New York City, and else-
1990s, new data became available to better test the where provide yet another set of data with which to test
hypothesis. Charter schools—public schools freed from the hypothesis. Some 50,000 students now attend private
some government regulation in exchange for having to schools with privately financed vouchers (Children First
compete for students—started in Minnesota in 1991 and America, 1999) and another 20,000 use publicly funded
now number approximately 2000 and enroll more than vouchers. In Spring 2000 there were 150 publicly funded
half a million students. Since these schools do not charge voucher schools nationwide (Finn, Manno, & Vanourek,
tuition, admission is usually by lottery, and spending is 2001, p. 22).
limited to public school levels or less, a charter-to-pub- Although fewer students participate in voucher pro-
lic-school comparison should be instructive. grams than attend charter schools, the random assign-
According to Finn, Manno and Vanourek (2001), ment of students gives researchers access to data on the
“Definitive data on the academic performance of charter achievement of voucher recipients as well as students
schools are not yet available. Of the data at hand today, whose parents applied for vouchers but did not receive
however, much is positive” (p. 31). They cite a US them. According to Greene (2001), “There have been
Department of Education study matching a thousand seven random-assignment and three non-random-assign-
charter school students with a thousand similar students ment studies of school choice programs in the last few
that found significant improvement in reading scores and years. The authors of all ten studies find at least some
a small (not statistically significant) improvement in benefits from the programs and recommend their con-
math scores. Studies of charter schools in California and tinuation if not expansion. No study finds a significant
Colorado found evidence of higher test scores, but stud- harm to student achievement from the school choice pro-
ies in Minnesota and Arizona were inconclusive. grams” (p. 90).
Arizona’s charter school program is most notable for Howell, Wolf, Peterson and Campbell (2001) exam-
its size (416 schools in 2000–2001) and minimal regulat- ined data from private voucher programs in New York,
ory requirements. Solmon, Paark and Garcia (2001) com- Dayton, and Washington, DC. They found “no signifi-
pared reading and math scores for charter and public cant differences between the test-score performance of
school students. For reading, they found “students who non-African-American students switching from a public
438 J.L. Bast, H.J. Walberg / Economics of Education Review 23 (2004) 431–440

to a private school and the performance of students in “Education Freedom Index” weighted for the amount of
the control group—either after one or two years” (pp. charter school choice, subsidized private school choice,
144–145). However, “African American students who home schooling choice, and public school choice offered
switched from public to private schools scored, after one by each state. Controlling for median household income,
year, 3.3 [National Percentile Ranking] points higher on per-pupil spending, and the percentage of ethnic min-
the combined math and reading tests and, after two years, orities in each state, Greene found achievement test
6.3 percentile points higher than the African American scores and (value-added) score gains on the National
students in the control group. Only the impact in year Assessment of Educational Progress to be significantly
two is statistically significant” (p. 145). and positively associated with the amount of total
A 2001 report by Gill, Timpane, Ross and Brewer weighted choice in the state.
(2001), published by the RAND Corporation, concludes: Together, this research shows a positive, if modest,
“Small-scale, experimental privately funded voucher association between school choice and several measures
programs targeted to low-income students suggest a of school outcomes, including student achievement, par-
possible (but as yet uncertain) modest achievement bene- ental satisfaction, and parental involvement. The results
fit for African-American students after one to two years would probably be more dramatic if choice programs to
in voucher schools (as compared with local public date were not small, located in the nation’s poorest com-
schools)” (pp. xiv–xv). The authors also point out vouch- munities, underfunded, and heavily burdened by regu-
ers promoted racial integration and charter schools gen- lation (Peterson, 2003, p. 14). Hoxby (2002) points out
erally have similar racial-ethnic compositions as local that the positive impact of school choice on student
public schools. achievement may also be obscured by the fact that public
Goldhaber (2001), a scholar at the Urban Institute, schools “respond to competition from choice schools by
summarizes voucher school research as follows: “The raising their pupils’ achievement or raising another pupil
results of this research also showed that attending a priv- outcome valued by parents” (p. 142). That test scores
ate school was beneficial, but only for African American for students from low-income families appear to increase
students. On average African Americans who received more than scores for students from better-off families
vouchers scored 0.17 standard deviations higher on the contradicts predictions that poor parents would be parti-
combined test scores than African Americans in the con- cularly handicapped by information asymmetry or other
trol group. After two years they scored 0.33 standard problems when choosing schools.
deviations higher than their counterparts in the control
group” (p. 64). If sustained, he says, such gains would
eliminate the usual black–white achievement gap in six 5. Summary and conclusion
years.
The notion that parents would do a better job choosing
4.3.5. Overview of choice and student achievement the schools for their children than experts in government
Referring to public and private choice programs gen- agencies is well grounded in economic theory. Parents
erally, political scientists Teske and Schneider (2001) have the right incentives and access to the information
conclude: “While not all of these studies conclude that needed to make correct choices. Allowing schools to
choice enhances performance, it is significant to note that compete gives parents the opportunity to discover the
the best ones do, and that [we] did not find any study best schools for their children. Government agencies in
that documents significantly lower performance in choice the education arena, on the other hand, are burdened by
schools. ... Consensus results show that parents are more conflicts of interest, control by special interest groups,
satisfied with choice, that they report using academic and a tendency to adopt one-size-fits-all remedies to
preferences to make choices, and that they tend to be complex problems that require greater variation and spe-
more involved with their child’s education as a conse- cialization.
quence of choice” (p. 619). Empirical evidence supports the hypothesis. Parents
Greene (2001) finds a “hidden consensus” that charter and government experts tend to rank schools the same
and voucher schools produce superior academic results way, indicating parents are well informed. Parents put
and higher levels of parental satisfaction. Greene also academic achievement at the top of their list of concerns
found that students in schools of choice express greater when choosing a school, meaning they presumably are
tolerance for political and religious views other than their acting in their children’s long-term best interests.
own, and had more often engaged in such civic activities Schools of choice tend to out-perform public schools on
as public speaking and writing letters on political issues. a wide range of outcomes and for children from all soci-
Voucher schools were also less racially, ethnically, and oeconomic backgrounds, meaning the act of choosing,
socially segregated than public schools. for whatever reason, leads to children attending better
In separate research, Greene (2002) compared state schools. To the extent that confounding factors and the
average student academic achievement levels with an small scale of current voucher experiments bias the
J.L. Bast, H.J. Walberg / Economics of Education Review 23 (2004) 431–440 439

results, it would be in the direction of minimizing rather Friedman, M., & Friedman, R. (1980). Free to choose. New
than exaggerating the positive effects of choice. York, NY: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.
Lewis Solmon’s finding that parents who choose Ari- Fuller, B., Elmore, R. F., & Orfield, G. (1996). Who chooses?
zona charter schools are just as well informed about their Who loses? Culture, institutions, and the unequal effects of
school choice. New York, NY: Teachers College Press.
choices as government experts, then, is collaborated by
Gill, B. P., Timpane, P. M., Ross, K. E., & Brewer, D. J. (2001).
economic theory and empirical research. Whether this is Rhetoric versus reality: What we know and what we need
enough to persuade voucher critics is uncertain. As to know about vouchers and charter schools. Santa Monica,
Traub (2002) writes, “in the world of education, a great CA: RAND Corporation.
deal of moral power attaches to practices that are aesthet- Goldhaber, D. (2001). The interface between public and private
ically appealing; but justice is very often better served schooling. In D. H. Monk, H. J. Walberg, & M. D. Wang
by the merely effective” (p. 50). (Eds.), Improving educational productivity (pp. 47–75).
Greenwich, CT: Information Age Publishing.
Gray, J. (1984). Hayek on liberty. New York, NY: Basil
References Blackwell, Inc.
Greene, J. P. (2001). The hidden research consensus for school
Alt, M. N., & Peter, K. (2003). Private schools: A brief portrait.
choice. In P. E. Peterson, & D. E. Campbell (Eds.), Char-
In The condition of education 2002. Washington, DC: US
ters, vouchers and public education (pp. 83–101). Wash-
Department of Education.
ington, DC: Brookings Institution.
Beals, J. H., & Muris, T. J. (1993). State and federal regulation
of national advertising. Washington, DC: American Greene, J. P. (2002). 2001 education freedom index. New York,
Enterprise Institute. NY: Manhattan Institute.
Becker, G. S. (1976). The economic approach to human Grogger, J., & Neal, D. (2000). Further evidence on the effects
behavior. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. of Catholic secondary schooling. Brookings-Wharton Pap-
Belfield, C. R., & Levin, H. M. (2001). The effects of compe- ers on Urban Affairs. Washington, DC: Brookings Insti-
tition on educational outcomes: A review of US evidence. tution.
New York, NY: National Center for the Study of Privatiz- Harmer, D. J. (1993). School choice: why we need it, how we
ation in Education, Teachers College, Columbia University. get it. Salt Lake City, UT: Northwest Publishing, Inc.
Borcherding, T. E. (1977). Budgets and bureaucrats: The Harwood Group. (1995). Halfway out the door: citizens talk
sources of government growth. Durham, NC: Duke Univer- about their mandate for public schools. Dayton, OH: Ketter-
sity Press. ing Foundation.
Carnegie Foundation for the Advancement of Teaching. (1992). Hassel, B. C. (1998). Charter schools: politics and practice. In
School choice: A special report. Princeton, NJ: Carnegie P. E. Peterson, & B. C. Hassel (Eds.), Learning from school
Foundation for the Advancement of Teaching. choice (pp. 249–271). Washington, DC: Brookings Insti-
Children First America (1999). 68 private programs and coun- tution.
ting. School Reform News, 3 (10), insert, p. B. Hayek, F. A. (1973). New studies in philosophy, politics, eco-
Chubb, J. E., & Moe, T. M. (1990). Politics markets and Amer- nomics and the history of ideas. Chicago, IL: University of
ica’s schools. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution. Chicago Press.
Coleman, J. S., & Hoffer, T. (1987). Public and private high Hayek, F. A. (1968). Individualism and the economic order.
schools: the impact of communities. New York, NY: Chicago, IL: Henry Regnery Company.
Basic Books. Hill, P. T. (2001). What is public about public education? In
Coons, J. E., & Sugarman, S. D. (1978). Education by choice: T. M. Moe (Ed.), A primer on America’s schools (pp. 285–
The case for family control. Troy, NY: Educator’s Inter- 316). Stanford, CA: Hoover Institution Press.
national Press, Inc. Hill, P. T., Pierce, L. C., & Guthrie, J. W. (1997). Reinventing
Coulson, A. J. (1999). Market education: the unknown history. public education. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers. Howell, W. G., Wolf, P. J., Peterson, P. E., & Campbell, D. E.
Eggers, W. D., & O’Leary, J. (1995). Revolution at the roots: (2001). Effects of school vouchers on student test scores. In
Making our government smaller, better, and closer to home. P. E. Peterson, & D. E. Campbell (Eds.), Charters, vouch-
New York, NY: Free Press. ers, and public education (pp. 136–159). Washington, DC:
Ekelund, R. B. Jr., & Saurman, D. S. (1988). Advertising and Brookings Institution.
the market process: a modern economic view. San Franci- Hoxby, C. M. (1998). Analyzing school choice reforms that
sco, CA: Pacific Research Institute for Public Policy. use America’s traditional forms of parental choice. In P. E.
Etzioni, A. (1992). Foreword. In C. W. Cobb (Ed.), Responsive Peterson, & B. C. Hassel (Eds.), Learning from school
schools, renewed communities (pp. xi–xvi). San Francisco, choice (pp. 133–155). Washington, DC: Brookings Insti-
CA: ICS Press. tution.
Finn, C. E. Jr., Manno, B. V., & Vanourek, G. (2001). Charter Hoxby, C. M. (2001). If families matter most. In T. M. Moe
schools: Taking stock. In P. E. Peterson, & D. E. Campbell (Ed.), A primer on America’s schools (pp. 89–125). Stan-
(Eds.), Charters, vouchers and public education (pp. 19– ford, CA: Hoover Institution Press.
42). Washington, DC: Brookings Institution. Hoxby, C. M. (2002). How school choice affects the achieve-
Fiske, E. B., & Ladd, H. F. (2000). When schools compete: a ment of public school students. In P. T. Hill (Ed.), Choice
cautionary tale. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution with equity (pp. 141–178). Stanford, CA: Hoover Insti-
Press. tution Press.
440 J.L. Bast, H.J. Walberg / Economics of Education Review 23 (2004) 431–440

Jacobs, L. R., & Shapiro, R. J. (2000). Politicians don’t pander: Public Agenda. (1999). On thin ice: How advocates and
political manipulation and the loss of democratic respon- opponents could misread the public’s view on vouchers and
siveness. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. charter schools. New York, NY: Public Agenda.
Lieberman, M. (2000). Understanding the teacher union con- Rouse, C. E. (2000). School reform in the 21st century: A look
tract: a citizen’s handbook. New Brunswick, NJ: Trans- at the effect of class size and school vouchers on the aca-
action Publishers. demic achievement of minority students, Working Paper No.
Lieberman, M., Troy, L., & Haar, C. K. (1994). The NEA and 440. Princeton University.
AFT: Teacher unions in power and politics. Rockport, MA: Saltman, K. J. (2000). Collateral damage: corporatizing public
Pro⬎Active Publications. schools—a threat to democracy. Lanham, MD: Rowman &
Merrifield, J. (2001). The school choice wars. Lanham, MD: Littlefield Publishers, Inc.
Scarecrow Press Inc. Sander, W. (1995). The Catholic family: marriage, children,
Moe, T. M. (1995). Private vouchers. Stanford, CA: Hoover and human capital. San Francisco, CA: Westview Press.
Institution Press. Seder, R. C. (1999). Satellite charter schools: addressing the
Morse, J. R. (2001). Love and economics: Why the laissez-faire school-facilities crunch through public-private partnerships.
family doesn’t work. Dallas, TX: Spence Publishing Com- Los Angeles, CA: Reason Public Policy Institute.
pany. Solmon, L. C. (2003). Findings from the 2002 survey of parents
Mulholland, L. A. (1999). Arizona charter school progress with children in Arizona charter schools: how parents grade
evaluation. Phoenix, AZ: Arizona State University, Mor- their charter schools. Santa Monica, CA: Human Resources
rison Institute for Public Policy. Policy Corporation.
Mueller, D. C. (1979). Public choice. New York, NY: Cam- Solmon, L. C., Paark, K., & Garcia, D. (2001). Does charter
bridge University Press. school attendance improve test scores? The Arizona results.
Neal, D. (1996). The effects of Catholic secondary schooling Phoenix, AZ: Goldwater Institute.
on educational achievement. Chicago, IL: University of Stigler, G. S. (1971). The theory of economic regulation. Bell
Chicago, Harris School of Public Policy and National Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2, 3–21.
Bureau for Economic Research. Teske, P., & Schneider, M. (2001). What research can tell pol-
Niskanen, W. A. Jr. (1971). Bureaucracy and representative icy makers about school choice. Journal of Policy Analysis
government. Chicago, IL: Aldine-Atherton. and Management, Fall, 609–631.
Osborne, D., & Gaebler, T. (1992). Reinventing government: Traub, J. (2002). The class war over school testing. The New
how the entrepreneurial spirit is transforming the public York Times Magazine, April 7, 50.
sector. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley Publishing Com- Twight, C. A. (2002). Dependent on DC: the rise of federal
pany Inc. control over the lives of ordinary Americans. New York,
Patrinos, H. A., & Ariasingam, D. L. (1997). Decentralization NY: Palgrave.
of education: demand-side financing. Washington, DC: The US Department of Education. (2002). The condition of edu-
World Bank. cation. Washington, DC: US Department of Education.
Peterson, P. E. (2001). Choice in American education. In T. M. Witte, J. F. (1996). School choice and student performance. In
Moe (Ed.), A primer on America’s schools (pp. 249–283). H. F. Ladd (Ed.), Holding schools accountable: perform-
Stanford, CA: Hoover Institution Press. ance-based reform in education (pp. 149–176). Washington,
Peterson, P. E. (2003). Our schools and our future. Stanford, DC: Brookings Institution.
CA: Hoover Institution Press. Witte, J. F. (2000). The market approach to education: an
Peterson, P. E., & Walberg, H. J. (2002). Catholic schools analysis of America’s first voucher program. Princeton, NJ:
excel. School Reform News, 6(7), 12. Princeton University Press.

You might also like