Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 24

BSP-UP Professorial Chair Lectures

12 November 2012
Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas
Malate, Manila

Lecture No. 3

Truth in Microlending: Is Microfinance Overrated?

by

Dr. Emmanuel F. Esguerra


BSP UP Centennial Professor
of Money and Banking
TRUTH IN MICROLENDING: IS MICROFINANCE OVERRATED?

Emmanuel F. Esguerra
University of the Philippines Diliman

Abstract

The paper examines the promise of poverty-reduction-without-


subsidization that has propelled microfinance to the status of a growth
industry worldwide. It explores to what extent the vision is being realized
in the Philippines focusing on the tension between the avowed social
mission of microfinance and the goal of financial sustainability.

The data suggest that Philippine MFIs are generally able to combine
financial sustainability with serving poor borrowers, using average loan
size as an indicator of depth of outreach. The higher cost of servicing
small loans, however, implies that MFIs have to charge higher interest
rates or receive subsidies. There are indications that non-bank MFIs do
both. Regarding outreach, it is noted that where actual client poverty
status data are used instead of average loan size, it is not clear if the
relatively small proportion of the poor among loan recipients is due to
faulty targeting or the MFIs’ revealed preference. Finally, most rigorous
impact evaluations of microfinance have found no strong evidence of its
promised effects in terms of poverty reduction.

Nonetheless, the paper argues that an expansion in the scope of financial


services to include hitherto excluded segments of the population
constitutes a social welfare gain. From this standpoint, microfinance has
done well, even if it may not have directly reduced poverty. That is good
enough.

Introduction

Microfinance is widely acknowledged today as a tool for assisting people move out of
poverty. Once almost the exclusive domain of non-governmental organizations (NGOs) and
similar not-for-profit institutions, it has practically become a growth industry. The list is not
limited to philanthropic foundations and local commercial banks, thrift institutions and
finance companies, but includes as well multinationalslike Citigroup, Deutsche Bank, HSBC,
and ABN Amro (The Economist [2005]) that have also gotten into the act, inspired by the
prospect of commercial success while carrying out a noble mission. According to one
assessment (Abrams and von Stauffenberg [2007]) international private lending to various
microfinance institutions (MFIs) worldwide reached $1 billion in 2005 1. The Microcredit

1
The figure includes only direct retail lending to MFIs and excludes other forms of financing such as equity and
guarantees, lending through wholesale lending institutions, or investments in microfinance investment vehicles.
Summit Campaign places the number of MFIs worldwide at over 3,000 with a reach of close
to 155 million borrowers as of December 2007 2.

A newfound enthusiasm for using the financial market to reduce poverty thus appears to
have replaced the former disenchantment with the idea that debt can potentially help the
poor improve their situation. The view that “debt is not an effective tool for helping most
poor people enhance their condition” (Adams and Von Pischke [1992: 1468]) was especially
compelling in the 1980s in the wake of various failed attempts to alleviate poverty through
the provision of subsidized credit. Such view has become less persuasive in light of the much
heralded success of several models of “banking with the poor”, of which the Grameen Bank
and the Association for Social Advancement (ASA) of Bangladesh and BancoSol of Bolivia are
prominent examples. To true believers, these successful approaches can be attributed to
the application of sound banking principles that, by enhancing financial sustainability,
minimizes the need for government or donor support and maximizes the ability of MFIs to
reach out to poorer clients.

Not everyone who believes that access to reliable financial services benefits the poor shares
the view that full commercialization is the way forward, however. The debate sparked by
the initial public offerings (IPO) of Mexico’s CompartamosBanco in 2007 (The Economist
[2008]) and India’s SKS Microfinance in 2010 (The Economist [2010]) suggests a fissure in the
flourishing microfinance movement. To supporters, the success of the IPO is proof of the
correctness of a commercial approach to lending to the poor as it frees an MFIfrom the
supply constraint of donor money putting it in an even better position to serve more of the
poor. To critics,including Grameen Bank founder and 2006 Nobel Peace Prize winner
Muhammad Yunus, the IPO represents a departure from the original mission of
microfinance, its very success linked to policies that emphasize high interest rates and
financial profitability in order to attract private investor capital (Malkin [2008]).

Since the initial attempts at replicating the Grameen model in 1989, the Philippines has
come a long way toward promoting microfinance as a tool for poverty alleviation. A National
Strategy for Microfinance was drawn up and approved during the presidency of Fidel Ramos
(1992-1998) to provide a framework for the promotion of microfinance as a sustainable
activity. Accordingly, the government has focused its policies on enlarging the role of private
MFIs in providing financial services to low-income groups. In keeping with this objective,
Executive Order 138 (EO 138), promulgated during the term of Joseph Estrada (1998-2001),
expressly proscribed non-financial government agencies from engaging in direct lending.
The General Banking Law of 2000 opened the door to greater bank involvement in
microfinance, recognizing its specific characteristics (e.g. non-collateralized lending), and
authorizing the Monetary Board to establish rules for its practice amongst banks 3. The
country has been recognized time and again for having one of the better regulatory
environments for microfinance in the world.

This article surveys Philippine microfinance against the backdrop of competing views
regarding the potential and limits of a commercialized approach to broadening access to

2
As cited in Odell [2010].
3
There is an Inclusive Finance Advocacy Staff (IFAS) within the BangkoSentralngPilipinas (BSP) to handle
microfinance-related matters.
finance as a strategy to reduce poverty. It specifically examines the promise of poverty-
reduction-without-subsidization that has excited the growing number of microfinance
advocates in the country. It explores to what extent the vision is being realized in the
Philippines, mindful of the tension between the avowed social mission of microfinance and
the goal of financial sustainability. Are Philippine MFIs able to serve more of the poor? Are
they financially sustainable? What do we know so far about the welfare impact of
microfinance on its clients?

When the central bank declares microfinance as its “flagship program for poverty
alleviation” (Valdepeñas[2005]: v), and a President of the Republic refers to it as the
“cornerstone of this country’s fight against poverty” (Arroyo, [2001]), one can only agree
with the observation that “few recent ideas have generated as much hope for alleviating
poverty in low-income countries as the idea of microfinance” (Morduch [2000: 617]).

This paper is organized as follows: After a brief review of the evolution of organized
microfinance in the country in first section, the second section presents some stylized facts
about Philippine MFIs situating them in the broader context of the global microfinance
movement. The third section draws on insights from cross-country empirical studies on the
trade-off between financial sustainability and depth of outreach to examine how local MFIs
are responding to the challenge of the “double bottom line”. The fourth section considers
issues pertaining to outreach. The fifth section looks at some of the recent work on the
welfare impact of microfinance. The sixth section concludes. Aggregate data from industry
and government sources, as well as from published material are used throughout.

From subsidies to sustainability

As understood today microfinance refers to the provision of a range of financial services


(e.g. loans, deposits, payment services, money transfers and insurance products) 4 to
customers routinely excluded by formal financial institutions for being too costly or risky to
serve. The use of methods not normally associated with standard banking practices to reach
low income or traditionally rationed clients is its defining attribute, although practical
considerations favor a definition based on size of the transaction. The practice of
microfinance has been around for as long as rotating savings and credit associations
(ROSCAs), or paluwagans, and credit cooperatives have existed. The new element is that
private banks are becoming increasingly involved on a voluntary basis.

As a deliberate approach to promote certain economic activities or development goals in


the Philippines, however, the origins of microfinance may be traced to the period of the late
1960s to the 1970s when government implemented a policy of preferential credit allocation
to support specific sectors or activities considered critical to national development. Food
self-sufficiency, small enterprise development, and income redistribution were among the
ostensible objectives. Interest rate subsidies were a central feature of that policy.
Government financial institutions as well as privately-owned rural banks were mobilized to
extend loans for specific activities, supported by state funds in the form of special time

4
The term “microfinance” is more narrowly associated with small loans, or “microcredit”, in the popular
consciousness though. Unless stated otherwise, this is the sense in which the term is used in this paper.
deposits, and by easy access to the central bank’s rediscount facility at concessional rates.
The rural sector was a prime target of such interventions.

The subsequent failure of subsidized credit programs in the 1980s led to a shift in policy
from one inspired by a supply-leading approach to a more market-oriented one. Under the
new policy regime, the responsibility for providing loan and deposit services was entrusted
to the banks while the government was expected to concentrate on its role of providing the
policy environment hospitable to financial intermediation.

While these early reforms planted the seeds for a more stable rural financial market, credit
remained elusive for most small rural borrowers 5 , providing convenient fodder for the
lobby of politicians and other organized interest groups for a return to directed credit
programs6. Amidst the political pressure to revive credit subsidies and re-establish programs
for designated non-bankable groups, a nascent movement drawing inspiration from the
successful Grameen Bank in Bangladesh was laying the groundwork for an alternative to the
traditional approach to bank lending. The alternative lay in using technologies borrowed
from informal finance that maximized the use of social networks as collateral substitutes to
solve the information asymmetry in loan transactions. Unfamiliar and ill-prepared to work
with such technologies, banks could only yield the initiative to NGOs and similar
organizations with a grassroots orientation. The government-sponsored Grameen Bank
Replication Project in 1989 was implemented mainly with NGOs as conduits for microcredit
to non-bankable groups.

Since the initial step to replicate the Grameen model in the Philippines, various measures
have been taken to promote microfinance and put the institutions providing it on a more
solid foundation (see Alindogan [2005]). Among the early celebrated successes were the
noticeably high repayment rates of borrowers, although it is not clear to what extent this
was due to the lending technology itself or to the fact that lenders had shifted their focus
from risky agriculture to non-farm enterprises where the lending technology had a higher
chance of success.

In 1997, the National Credit Council (NCC), an inter-agency body headed by the Department
of Finance spelled out a National Strategy for Microfinance. According to the strategy, the
specific targets of microfinance are households with incomes below the poverty threshold
whose members are “engaged in some form of business but are either not served or
underserved by the formal financial sector” (NSM [1997]). The NSM provided the
framework for subsequent laws and issuances relating to finance for poverty alleviation;
among the more important ones are: the Social Reform and Poverty Alleviation Act (RA
8425, 1997), the Agriculture and Fisheries Modernization Act (RA 8435, 1999), Executive
Order 138 (1999), and the Barangay Micro Business Enterprises Act (RA 9178, 2002).

5
The reasons range from the mediocre performance of the agriculture sector to the wave of conservatism that
dominated the rural banking industry due to the negative experience with government credit programs.
(seeLlanto [2005]).
6
A good number of directed credit programs were in fact set up in the late 1980s to ease the access problem (see
Esguerra [1996], Llanto [2005]).
With a more favorable policy environment, microfinance increasingly became an attractive
proposition for the banking sector.Since the enactment of the General Banking Law of 2000
(RA 8791), around 200 7 banks have become involved in varying degrees in microfinance.

Thus the microfinance movement in the Philippines was born out of the experience with the
failed credit programs of the 1970s and as a response to the revealed inability of the
banking system, using traditional bank technologies, to extend its services to low-income
groups even in a market-friendly policy setting. For while the “new view” of rural financial
markets succeeded in convincing policy makers to liberalize interest rates to allow financial
institutions to cover their costs and remain viable, it did little to improve credit access for
classes of borrowers banks were not inclined to lend to in the first place (e.g. the
unemployed, workers in agriculture). As Stiglitz and Weiss [1981] have shown, credit
rationing is a rational response when, because of imperfect information, raising lending
rates only attracts riskier loan applicants or causes borrowers to take on riskier projects that
increase the probability of non-repayment.

Microfinance is an institutional response to the problems of adverse selection, moral


hazard, and weak contract enforcement in credit market environments where the cost of
transacting is high and the use of traditional forms of collateral is severely limited by the
level of economic development and the prevailing property relations. Through the use of
various contractual designs (e.g. group lending, regular meetings, frequent collections,
dynamic incentives), MFIs are generally able to reduce the problems associated with lending
to low-income borrowers in a way that lenders using traditional bank technologies are
unable to do.

But important issues remain. Careful to avoid the inefficiencies associated with
subsidization, key donors, such as those associated with the Consultative Group to Assist the
Poorest (CGAP), have emphasized financial sustainability, or financial self-sufficiency, as a
key performance standard for “good” microfinance. MFIs are “financially self-sufficient” if
they can continue to profitably do business without the need for subsidies. Sustainability
lies at the core of efforts of donors and leading advocates to have Philippine MFIs embrace
market-based principles in their activities. An MFI is expected to progressively move
towards becoming a for-profit, formal institution, or to operate as one, subject to prudential
regulation, where the initial step entails “adopting a more business-like approach to
administration, including the application of cost-recovery interest rates”. The process is
referred to as “commercialization” (see Charitonenko [2003]). The idea is that financially
sustainable, and thus permanent, MFIs should be in a better position to serve more of the
poor.

Although the logic in the sustainability argument seems self-evident, the path to
sustainability is not a straight one and may lead MFIs to make choices that do not
necessarily favor serving the original target – the poor – or exercising the resultant ability to
reach more of the poor after some measure of sustainability has been achieved. This
tendency describes “mission drift” or the intentional avoidance of low-income clients as
MFIs are pressured to project a good bottom line for investors (Cull, Demirgüç-Kunt and
7
The list as of June 30, 2011 includes thrift, rural, and cooperative banks engaged either fully or partially in
microfinance.
Morduch or Cull et al [2007], Ghosh and Van Tassel [2008]). The insistence on sustainability
may induce MFIs to become more innovative and competitive, but it may also encourage
conservatism and undermine the social mission if the reward for excluding a class of
borrowers is a favorable financial outcome.

Exclusionary tendencies are further reinforced by the difficulty of measuring achievement in


poverty reduction compared with that for gauging financial sustainability (Woller and
Schreiner [no date]). For instance, measures of financial success have long been well
understood and widely accepted within the industry, whereas donors and practitioners have
only belatedly become concerned with seriously measuring social performance (see
Hashemi, Foose, and Badawi [2007]) and welfare impact. Faced with multiple objectives
MFIs are bound to focus on those whose achievement can be more easily monitored or
measured and rewarded. Managing the tension between performing up to the standard of
sustainability on one hand and fulfilling the expectation of serving a greater number of low-
income households on the other thus remains a challenge for the microfinance industry.

Philippine microfinance: facts and figures

As of June 2010, about 15,000 MFIs were operating throughout the country serving an
estimated 5.1 million borrowers (MCPI [2010]). These include 25 NGOs, 200 banks and 14,700
cooperatives. The number ofNGOs engaged in microfinance is likely to be an underestimate.
Being unregulated, NGOs do not report to any single entity, although about 30 are known to
have a dominant presence in microfinance (Microfinance Information eXchange andMCPI
[2006]). It is also not known how many cooperatives have functioning microfinance
programs. For the same reason, it is difficult to say how many borrowers are being served
by the various MFIsand, except for a few, how large their respective microfinance portfolios
are. Rural banks are especially problematic as their activities are not normally confined to
microfinance and data are not disaggregated enough to show the number of microfinance
customers and the share of microfinance in total bank lending. The preceding caveats
should be kept in mind when looking at Philippine microfinance data.

Table1. Microfinance Sector Data* as of June 2010


Total Loans
No. No. of Active Average Loans
Type of MFI Oustanding (in
Reporting Borrowers Outstanding
million Pesos)
Microfinance NGOs** 25 1,768,819 10,122.40 5,722.72
Microfinance Banks*** 200 876,109 6,716.39 7,666.16
Cooperatives**** 14,711 2,459,692 n.a. n.a.
Total 14,936 5,104,620

*Data estimated from existing information from various sources


**NGO data from MCPI and MIX market data as of December. 2009 (excluding data from banks
and cooperatives
***Data from BSP, as of June 30, 2010
****Basic data from CDA, as of June 30, 2010. The estimate assumes that 80 percent of the
members of multi-purpose cooperativees have loans and savings, of which 50% have
microfinance loans. It was also assumed that 50% of the members of credit cooperatives have
microfinance loans.

Source: Microfinance Industry Report - Philippines, MCPI 2011


Data from the BSP show a total of 198 thrift, rural, and cooperative banks with various
degrees of involvement in microfinance as of June 2011. These banks had extended loans to
some 960,000 borrowers amounting to PhP 7.2 billion. They had also mobilized some
PhP3.7 million in savings deposits.

Table 2: Banks with Microfinance Exposure as of June 30, 2011


Outstanding Savings
No. of No. of
Loans Component
Banks Borrowers
(in PhP Million) (in PhP Million)
Microfinance Oriented Thrift Banks 3 195.1 28,162 99.8
Microfinance Oriented Rural Banks 6 1,812.7 314,391 1,327.7
Sub-Total 9 2,007.8 342,553 1,427.5

Microfinance Engaged Rural Banks 148 3,829.5 530,325 1,834.6


Microfinance Engaged Coop Banks 21 810.3 78,120 248.2
Microfinance Engaged Thrift Banks 20 502.0 12,719 243.4
Sub-Total 189 5,141.8 621,164 2,326.2
Grand Total 198 7,149.6 963,717 3,753.7

Source: BSP

Table 3 shows that as of 2011the top 10 Philippine MFIs based on number of active
borrowers is comprised mostly of NGOs. Moreover, 5 of the 7 NGOs in the top 10 MFIs in
terms of number of borrowers are also among the leading MFIs in terms of gross loan
portfolio. Collectively, the top 10 MFIsin either category account for more than 80 percent of
total borrowers and the aggregate value of loans of all reporting MFIs. If the MCPI’sreported
figures of 15,000MFIs serving 5.1 million borrowers in 2011 are reliable, then the preceding
would suggest that the microfinance business is a highly concentrated business with the top
10 MFIs covering more than half of all borrowers.

Table 3: Leading Microfinance Institutions, Philippines, 2010-2012


Number of Gross Loan
Active Portfolio
MFI Borrowers MFI (PhP)
CARD NGO 783,600 1st Valley Bank 103,087,502
ASA Philippines 590,053 CARD NGO 76,757,532
TSPI 290,816 CARD Bank 62,171,210
KMBI 244,356 PR Bank 48,639,582
Life Bank Foundation 236,917 ASA Philippines 48,451,134
TSKI 191,903 TSPI 43,183,581
Pagasa 161,692 G7 Bank 40,546,573
NWTF 131,002 GM Bank Luzon 36,414,510
ASKI 79,341 Green Bank 35,918,780
CCT 66,204 ASKI 28,877,468

Source: MIXmarket 2012


A benchmarking study conducted by MCPI and the Microfinance Information eXchange, Inc.
(MIX) in 2006 reveals other interesting facts about Philippine MFIs. MIX is a non-profit,
international data exchange outfit that provides information services on the microfinance
industry. It collects data from MFIs around the world, standardizes these for comparability,
and publishes the results in its semi-annual MicroBanking Bulletin. The voluntary nature of
participation in the data exchange suggests that the MFIs in MIX are likely to be from a
select group of good financial performers in their respective countries.

The benchmarking study focused on the performance 45 Philippine MFIs in 2005. The 45
MFIs included 20 NGOs, 23 rural banks, a cooperative and a thrift bank. The study compares
these MFIs with Asian MFIs and rest-of-the-world MFIs included in the MicroBanking
Bulletin. The numbers reported in Table 4 are median figures. They show, first, that local
MFIs are much older, with a median age of 19, compared with their counterparts in Asia and
elsewhere in the world 8 . Second, Philippine MFIs also tend to be smaller by comparison as
measured by the size of their loan portfolios. Third, local MFIs cover fewer borrowers. In
terms of financial structure, they are dependent on concessional fund sources for about
one-fifth of their loan portfolios, albeit less so than Asian and other MFIs. Finally, their
average loan balance per borrower, standardized by per capita GNI, is also lower relative to
those of non-Philippine MFIs. This measure indicates depth of outreach, or the ability to
reach the low-income segment of the credit market 9.

Table 4: Philippine MFIs compared with non-Philippine MFIs, 2005

Philippine A s ia n A ll M FIs
M FIs M FIs

Number reporting 45 101 446


Age 19 11 9
Active borrowers 8,858 18,487 12,432
Gross loan portfolio ($ thousand) 2,558.9 3,961.9 5,223.9
Commercial funding liabilities ratio (%) 79.0 62.9 58.6
Average loan balance per borrower/GNI per capita (%) 17.1 19.4 43.7
Return on assets (%) -0.8 -0.7 0.9
Operational self-sufficiency (%) 114.1 109.9 114.6
Financial self-sufficiency (%) 97.6 100.6 105.4
Financial revenue ratio (%) 31.6 24.1 25.8
Yield on gross portfolio (real) (%) 32.7 21.9 24.4
Total expense ratio (%) 31.0 25.6 25.0
Operating expense ratio (%) 20.1 15.1 15.7
Personnel expense ratio (%) 10.5 7.6 8.5
Administrative expense ratio (%) 9.1 7.3 7.2
Portfolio at risk > 30 days (%) 6.9 2.8 2.2
Source: MIX and MCPI [2006]

8
This is due to the inclusion in the Philippine sample of a good number of rural banks, many of which have
existed since the 1970s or 1980s.
9
This is what is commonly used to measure an MFI’s ability to penetrate the low-income market. It presumes
that the non-poor will not care to avail themselves of small loans.
Profitability-wise, Philippine MFIs are not doing well as indicated by negative return-on-
assets (Table 4). While they are operationally self-sufficient (OSS), i.e. are able to generate
sufficient operating revenue to cover operating expenses, financing costs, and provision for
loan losses, they are only nearly financial self-sufficient, as indicated by a median FSS ratio
of less than 100 percent 10 . This means that their revenues cannot adequately cover their
costs when the latter are adjusted to reflect market prices and potential loan losses based
on a uniform assessment of default risk. Since these adjustments all have the effect of
raising MFI costs, the FSS ratio is lower than the OSS ratio. Considering that many more MFIs
are not included in the MCPI-MIX study, while those in the study are supposed to be the
financially better performers among Philippine MFIs, the reported FSS ratio (see Table 4)
suggests that lack of financial sustainability is par for the course in the local microfinance
business 11. The implication is that many of these MFIs would be hard put to sustain their
activities at current levels without continuing subsidies, or charging higher interest. This
same observation was made with reference to a much larger set of MFIs around the world
(see Armendáriz deAghion and Morduch [2005]).

Table 4 further shows that local MFIs have a higher financial revenue ratio, but their costs of
delivering microfinance services are also generally higher relative to Asian and other non-
Philippine MFIs. The latter may be related to the observation that they service mostly small
loans, which involves higher transaction costs. As a result, Philippine MFIs charge interest
rates and other fees that are about a third higher than those on loans from Asian or other
MFIs based on a comparison of gross portfolio yields 12. Their portfolio-at-risk is also higher
than that reported for similar institutions in Asia or the rest of the world.

Table 5 provides a closer picture of Philippine MFIs for 2005 and 2007 according to size or
scale. It shows that financial sustainability is related to MFI size or scale and that smaller
MFIsincur higher costs overall. They are also subsidized to the extent of 50 percent of their
loanable funds. Nevertheless, small MFIs are able to attain a measure of financial
sustainability by charging the highest interest rates relative to large and medium MFIs. If
these are the same MFIs which cater to the poorest borrowers, then this implies that the
poorest borrowers pay the highest interest for their microloans.

10
Compared with OSS, which measures the extent to which revenue covers only direct costs, FSS indicates
whether enough revenue has been earned to cover both direct and indirect costs, including the adjusted cost of
capital. FSS accounts for the cost of maintaining the value of equity relative to inflation, the cost of accessing
liabilities at commercial rather than concessionary rates, and adjustments in loan loss expenses.
11
The MIX-MCPI data further reveal that local MFIs which failed to meet the standard of financial
sustainability have a median FSS ratio of 84 percent.
12
Rather than use the stated loan interest rate, MIX uses gross portfolio yield, which includes interest and other
fees as a proportion of gross loan portfolio, as a measure of interest rate. Being closer to what borrowers actually
pay it is a measure of the effective interest rate. All references to interest rate in this paper are based on the
published figure for real gross portfolio yield reported by MIX.
Table 5: Philippine MFIs by size, 2005 and 2007
2005 2007

La rge M e dium Sm a ll La rge M e dium Sm a ll

Number reporting 7 19 19 15 20 15
Age 30 25 10 21 28 12
Active borrowers 67,193 8,224 5,853 69,815 15,632 8,868
Gross loan portfolio ($ thousand) 11,365.3 3,156.6 695.6 12,995.8 4,090.7 1,057.3
Commercial funding liabilities ratio (%) 73.2 104.4 49.6 98.9 103.3 44.5
Average loan balance per borrower/GNI per capita (%) 23.6 28.6 7.1 17.0 19.7 7.4
Return on assets (%) 2.8 -0.7 -2.7 1.9 -0.6 0.1
Operational self-sufficiency (%) 126.1 113.2 112.7 114.3 112.1 104.6
Financial self-sufficiency (%) 111.0 97.6 92.6 109.8 101.3 101.8
Financial revenue ratio (%) 25.8 25.1 34.0 31.2 27.2 31.3
Yield on gross portfolio (real) (%) 24.9 20.7 40.0 35.7 29.8 50.4
Total expense ratio (%) 26.4 29.1 36.0 27.9 27.0 36.6
Operating expense ratio (%) 16.0 14.3 26.9 20.7 16.6 25.7
Personnel expense ratio (%) 5.2 7.6 13.9 11.5 10.0 14.8
Administrative expense ratio (%) 8.7 8.2 10.2 9.4 7.3 11.4
Portfolio at risk > 30 days (%) 4.2 6.5 7.0 3.3 4.8 7.2

Source: MIX and MCPI [2006] and [2008]

Sustainability-outreach tradeoffs

The problem is that raising lending rates does not always result in higher profits. Given the
already high nominal rates reported for Philippine MFIs, it may be asked by how much more
they can be increased without portfolio quality deteriorating from the effects of adverse
selection and moral hazard. Moreover, empirical evidence offers little support for the view
that poor borrowers’ demand for loans is interest inelastic (Karlan and Zinman [2008],
Briones [2009]). A higher interest rate is bound to discourage some potential debtors,
contracting outreach and reducing further the likelihood that low-income clients will receive
a loan. Of course, financial profitability can be improved by reducing operating costs; taking
advantage of recent advances in information and communications technology and
eliminating inefficiencies come to mind. Still, given the higher cost of lending to households
that are physically hard-to-reach and expensive to monitor in the absence of collateral,
would not focusing on financial sustainability result in a reduction of MFIs’ efforts to reach
more of the poor? More to the point: are not the strong advocates of sustainability ignoring
the trade-off between financial profitability and outreach? Is the trade-off more serious
than they actually believe?

While no study addressing the preceding question has been conducted for the Philippines, a
few studies using cross-country data are instructive. Woller and Schreiner [no date]
investigated the determinants of financial self-sufficiency using data from 13 village banking
institutions13in as many countries in Latin America and Africa during the years 1997-1999.
They found interest rates, administrative efficiency, loan officer productivity, and staff
salaries to be significant determinants of financial self-sufficiency. However, they found no
empirical support for the hypothesized trade-off between financial sustainability and depth

13
This MFI type, also known as village banks, employs a variant of the group lending technology to deliver
small loans to poor borrowers.
of outreach for their sample of MFIs. An analysis of 27 Asian MFIs (in India, Bangladesh, and
Myanmar) using 2002-2004 data similarly shows that extending financial services to the
poor did not necessarily adversely affect the financial sustainability of a third of the MFIs
(Sinha and Brar [2005]). These financially successful MFIs were able to reach down to the
low-end market either because of their chosen location or the extensive scale of their
operations.

An apparent tradeoff between financial sustainability and outreach is reported in a paper by


Hudon and Truca [2006], however, which examines the impact of subsidies on sustainability.
The study covering 100 MFIs in Asia, Africa, Latin America, Eastern Europe and the Middle
East over the period 2002-2005 shows that lower financial sustainability is associated with a
higher “subsidy intensity”, a major reason why MFIs ought to avoid subsidies according to
commercialization advocates. However, the authors found no evidence of moral hazard in
the form of overpaid or unproductive staff due to the subsidies. Rather the association
between lower financial sustainability and subsidy intensity derives from the MFIs’ higher
cost of loan administration as a result of a greater focus on the poor (as shown by a lower
ratio of average loan size to GDP per capita).The subsidy simply allows them to charge a
lower interest than otherwise making their loans affordable to their target customers.

Cull et al [2007] use a “high quality” data set of 124 MFIs in 49 countries to specifically
examine whether financial sustainability is associated with a lower depth of outreach, and
whether “mission drift” necessarily accompanies the effort to achieve financial
sustainability. The effect of higher lending rates on portfolio quality, i.e. whether portfolio
quality declines when lending rates rise, is also tested. Unlike earlier studies which either
looked at only one type of MFI or did not test for the effect of lending method on
performance, this study classified MFIs according to whether they practice group lending,
village banking, or individual-based lending in dealing with loan customers. According to the
authors,

Our results bring some good news for microfinance advocates. First, over
half of the institutions in the survey were profitable after accounting
adjustments were made (although average return on assets is negative
overall). Others are approaching profitability and should be able to soon
achieve financial self-sufficiency. Second, simple correlations show little
evidence of agency problems, outreach-profit trade-offs or mission drift.
The correlations thus attest to the possibility of raising interest rates
without undermining repayment rates, achieving both profit and
substantial outreach to poorer populations, and staying true to initial
social missions even when aggressively pursuing commercial goals. [F108]

When the authors explicitly consider lender type in the regressions, however, the tradeoffs
come to light underscoring the importance of institutional considerations in the relationship
between profitability and outreach to poor borrowers. The study finds support for a
negative relationship between profitability and the lending rate above some threshold level
consistent with agency theory, although such relationship exists only for MFIs practicing
individual-based lending.
The study notes further that MFIs that practice individual-based lending perform better
financially than those relying on the group-based methodology. However, the latter perform
much better with respect to depth of outreach. Although MFIs that make smaller loans are
not necessarily less profitable when other relevant factors are controlled for, the negative
association between loan sizes and average costs is suggestive of a tradeoff between
profitability and outreach given that larger loan sizes imply less outreach to the poor (F131).
Individual-based lenders are less likely to cater to low-income borrowers given the incentive
to use their ability to exploit scale economies through larger average loan sizes. The
tendency toward mission drift as they grow larger is also stronger with this lender type than
with group-based lenders.

Rural banks and microfinance NGOs in the Philippines, respectively, typify the individual-
and group-based lenders analyzed by Cull et al, although a few NGOs have started offering
individual loans to their mature customers in recent years. Established as non-profit
organizations, NGOs target low-income borrowers who have traditionally been rationed by
formal financial institutions. Their grassroots orientation makes them ideal for
implementing the group lending method, which requires tremendous social preparation, as
an approach to solving the informational problems in lending to asset poor borrowers with
small borrowing requirements. Rural banks on the other hand are organized essentially as
for-profit institutions designed to serve a much broader, more heterogeneous clientele,
which makes individualized loan transactions more suitable. As a result, bank loans are on
average larger than the typical NGO loan.

Table 6 presents data on Philippine NGOs and rural banks gathered from the same data base
used by Cull et al in their multi-country analysis ([2007] and [2008]). Without special access
to institution level information, this paper is, however, limited to examining two-way tables.
The close association between MFI organizational form, lending method, and customer
orientation should be immediately obvious from the numbers. The first two columns of
Table 6 show that rural banks have a much bigger loan portfolio than NGOs; however, their
borrowers are far fewer, indicating that non-bank, non-profit MFIs still dominate the
microlending business in the country despite vigorous donor efforts to promote
commercialization in the last few years 14. NGOs also have a much deeper outreach with an
average loan balance per borrower to per capita GNI ratio of 7.4 percent versus the rural
banks’ 34.5 percent. The joint liability feature of NGO loans tends to keep loan sizes small.

14
It should be noted that the data reported include all loans and borrowers of rural banks but exclude deposits
and depositors, which constitute an important part of rural banks’ business and clientele.
Table 6: Philippine MFIs by various classifications, 2007

NGOs R ura l ba nk Non-profit For-profit Low-end Broad

Number reporting 25 23 25 25 30 20
Age 12 33 12 32 12 33
Active borrowers 20,126 9,386 20,126 10,477 21,929 6,850
Gross loan portfolio ($ thousand) 2,617.9 6,357.5 2,617.9 5,943.4 3,117.6 5,677.1
Commercial funding liabilities ratio (%) 43.4 122.8 43.4 122.8 51.5 123.9
Average loan balance per borrower/GNI per capita (%) 7.4 34.5 7.4 30.6 7.5 46.0
Return on assets (%) 0.8 0.5 0.8 0.5 1.0 0.4
Operational self-sufficiency (%) 106.7 114.3 106.7 113.6 108.9 114.0
Financial self-sufficiency (%) 102.6 107.7 102.6 107.3 105.1 105.7
Financial revenue ratio (%) 37.2 21.6 37.2 21.6 36.9 20.6
Yield on gross portfolio (real) (%) 51.7 26.1 51.7 26.9 49.9 25.7
Total expense ratio (%) 39.2 21.9 39.2 22.1 36.0 20.4
Operating expense ratio (%) 31.2 12.2 31.1 12.5 27.2 11.0
Personnel expense ratio (%) 19.3 5.6 19.3 5.8 15.8 5.0
Administrative expense ratio (%) 11.3 6.7 11.3 6.7 11.4 5.9
Portfolio at risk > 30 days (%) 3.3 5.5 3.3 6.1 3.3 6.7
Source: MCPI and MIX [2008]

Reflecting the pattern described in Cull et al’s two papers, Table 6 further shows that the
median NGO and rural bank are both capable of operating profitably. Unlike the global
sample, however, individual-based lenders (rural banks) in the Philippines do not necessarily
show the highest profits. That NGOs pass the standard of financial sustainability suggests
that non-profit organizations geared towards the low-end market can be self-sustaining. The
last four columns of Table 6 simply confirm this. Using a different classification, they
compare MFIs by business model and market orientation; they show that non-profit MFIs
and MFIs oriented towards the low-income segment of the credit market perform just as
well on financial sustainability as those that are organized for profit and cater to a broad
clientele.

Unlike rural banks, however, a significant share of NGOs’ loan portfolios is funded at non-
commercial rates as indicated by a median commercial funding liabilities ratio of lower than
50 percent. Grants and concessional borrowings from various international and national
sources and compulsory deposits of their own loan clients typically make up NGOs’ non-
market fund sources. On the one hand, this indicates that subsidization need not be a
deterrent to sustainability, contrary to what has often been claimed by advocates of
microfinance commercialization (Figure 1). On the other hand, this state of affairs adds to
the impression held (rightly or wrongly) in some quarters that NGOs have largely retained
the benefits of subsidization instead of passing these on to their borrowers in the form of
lower interest rates.
Figure 1: Sustainability, Outreach, and
Subsidization of NGOs and Rural Banks

140.0
Commercial funding
120.0 liabilities ratio (%)
100.0
Percent (%)

80.0 Financial self-sufficiency


(%)
60.0
40.0 Average loan balance
20.0 per borrower/GNI per
capita (%)
-
NGOs Rural banks

Microfinance NGOs generally follow a high interest-rate strategy for maintaining


profitability15. The median real effective interest rate (or real gross portfolio yield) reported
by MCPI and MIX for Philippine NGOs is nearly 50 percent, compared with about 22 percent
for rural banks. The higher cost of servicing small loans is often cited as the reason for high
interest rates. Philippine MFIs specifically targeting low-income borrowers report an
operating expense ratio of 27 percent compared with only 11 percent for those serving the
broader market. The absence or lack of borrowing alternatives for low-income households
could also be a factor sustaining the high interest rates, although little is really known about
the competitiveness of markets where MFIs operate. In addition, the group lending feature
of NGO loans safeguards against agency problems that the high interest charges might set
off. This is an advantage that rural banks, which extend loans on an individual basis, possibly
do not have (Cull et al [2007]), a suspicion reinforced by the higher proportion of portfolio-
at-risk reported for such banks (Table 6). To justify their higher interest rates, NGO loans
may also be bundled with other services, such as client training, business advice, skills
enhancement, and other related services that NGOs can easily perform as multi-purpose
organizations.

15
Using a multi-country sample of 555 sustainable MFIs from the MIX data base, Rosenberg et al [2009], after
examining whether microcredit interest rates are “excessive”, conclude that “despite exceptional occasions, MFI
interest rates generally seem quite reasonable and that there is no evidence of any widespread pattern of abuse.”
[p.3].
Figure 2: Sustainable vs Non-sustainable MFIs

50 Average loan balance per


45 borrower/GNI per capita
40 (%)
35 Operating expense ratio
30 (%)
Percent

25
20 Yield on gross portfolio
15 (real) (%)
10
5 Portfolio at risk > 30 days
0 (%)
FSS ≥100 FSS<100

In the context of Cull et al’s “global analysis” of MFIs, the patterns in sustainability and
outreach observed among MFIs in the Philippines place Philippine MFIs, the NGOs in
particular, in the category of “exceptions” that have “managed to achieve profitability
together with notable outreach to the poor.” [2007: F108] This is certainly good news for
local microfinance practitioners and their supporters. However, the more successful
Philippine MFIs continue to operate with subsidies in the form of grants and low-priced
concessional funds even as their profitability ratios, adjusted for the presence of subsidies,
show that they should be able to operate without these on account of the interest rates
they charge their clients16.

Examining if subsidies encourage inefficiencies that contribute to the high operating costs of
MFIs is important because of the high microcredit interest rates that are often attributed to
the high costs of lending to the poor. Mersland and Strǿm [2010] show that average loan
size and other measures of “mission drift” are positively correlated with average costs.
Where high operating costs can be traced to inefficiencies, a case can be made whereby
subsidies cause lending rates to be high as MFIs strive to show funders a measure of
financial sustainability even as the inefficiencies are allowed to persist. In this case financial
self-sufficiency is attained at the expense of outreach through borrowers that are rationed
out by the resulting high rates in spite of an MFI showing a good measure of depth of
outreach. The coincidence of financial self-sufficiency and depth of outreach does not
necessarily imply the absence of a trade-off (Woller and Schreiner [no date]).

Reaching the poor

Depth of outreach is a gauge of how well an MFI is able to extend its services to the poor.
The usual indicator of depth of outreach is average loan size per borrower 17. The indicator
is a proxy for the socio-economic standing of an MFI’s customers, where it is assumed to

16
Cull et al [2008] observed a similar phenomenon in a sample of 346 MFIs from various countries but they
constituted a minority.
17
For purposes of cross-country comparisons, the ratio of average loan size per borrower to GDP or GNI per
capita is used.
vary directly with the income of the loan recipient. The indicator also assumes that poverty
reduction has a greater chance of happening if the loan is received by the poor person
himself instead of someone else. Thus, according to this measure, the smaller is the average
loan per borrower of an MFI, the greater is the proportion of the poor among its clientele,
and therefore the deeper is its outreach and the greater is its poverty-reducing impact.

The fact that MFIs are able to show a good measure of depth of outreach is, however,
inadequate as a basis for claiming that microfinance has improved access of the poor to
credit. Where available, it is useful to compare field-level client poverty data with the
commonly used measure of depth of outreach, as was done for 27 Asian MFIs in 2002-2004
(Sinha and Brar 2005]). The comparison showed that for average loan sizes below $100, or
where the average loan size per borrower was below 20 percent of per capita GDP (MIX’s
threshold for depth of outreach), average loan size had no correlation at all with the
proportion of the poor among the MFIs’ customers. Only beyond $100 was the presumed
negative correlation observed. These twin results indicate that while non-poor borrowers
will generally demand large loans, they are “not deterred from accessing smaller loans, if
these are available.” (Sinha and Brar: 5)

The observation above suggests the difficulty of relying on other than direct information
about the poverty status of microfinance clients for determining if MFIs are keeping to their
declared social mission.MFIs do not exclusively target their services to the poorest.
Examining the poverty targeting strategies of 25 MFIs from several countries Mathie [2002]
notes that “although microfinance programs may have the social objective of reducing
poverty, the intention of many is to achieve this not by targeting the poorest of the poor,
but by targeting the poorest of the economically active” [p. 2].

Most MFIs in the Philippines say they do not target the very poor. According to government
statements (NSM [1997] and BSP [2005]), microfinance targets the “entrepreneurial poor”
(or the “e-poor”), defined as those who are already engaged in productive activity among
the poor. This makes selection a function of where MFIs choose to locate as well as the
distribution of the attribute “entrepreneurship” among the poor population. Consumption
loans are also not generally considered microfinance even if they constitute a critical part of
the poor’s strategy in coping with uncertainties in income and consumption as well as
various emergencies.

An evaluation of the impact of an Asian Development Bank-sponsored microfinance


program on rural households in the Philippines showed that notwithstanding the program’s
stated objective to reach poor households18 , only 10 percent among the program’s actual
clients were poor, while only 4 percent were subsistence poor. Among prospective clients
and qualified non-participating households that constituted the comparison group, similar
proportions of the poor and subsistence poor were also found suggesting that either
program targeting was faulty and failed to properly identify the poor, or that the program
implementers did not consider the poor as the proper clients of the microfinance program
(Kondo et al [2008]).

18
Defined as the lowest 30 percent of the rural population in the income distribution.
Although it is not known if the finding of Kondo et al is generally true about microfinance
programs in the Philippines, reported performance indicators by and large do not include
the proportion of those below the poverty line among an MFI’s borrowers. The construction
of a poverty scorecard for the Philippines not too long ago to help MFIs direct their services
better to the poor suggests that as late as 2005 poverty targeting may have been largely ad
hoc and unsystematic 19 . Being the only attempt thus far to seriously examine outreach
among Philippine MFIs, the Kondo et al study caused some unease in the microfinance
community. After all, if direct access to credit is a key entry point to poverty reduction as
microfinance advocates hold, then with limited outreach would not the expected poverty
reducing effects of microfinance be mere chimera? Or can the poor benefit from
microfinance through less direct channels?

Accounting for impact

Assessing the state of knowledge about the impact of microfinance on poverty in 2002,
Zeller and Meyer [2002] warned about deploying public resources for microfinance
development without the benefit of “rigorous research”. Fast forward to the present and a
number of scientific papers later, Rosenberg [2010] observes that “we simply do not know
yet whether microcredit or other forms of microfinance are helping to lift millions out of
poverty.” [p.2]

The impact of microfinance, microcredit in particular, on poverty and related welfare


outcomes at different points in time has been examined by various authors. Montgomery
and Weiss [2005] list 14 studies in Asia and six in Latin America from 1996 to 2004 that try
to correct (though not always successfully or completely) for the sources of bias – sample
selection and program placement – that typically characterize impact evaluations of
microcredit. Goldberg [2005] similarly provides a review of published impact assessments
until mid-2005. More recently, Odell [2010] reviewed impact studies conducted between
2005 and 2010, grouping them under three classes: experimental (randomized), quasi-
experimental, and non-experimental. In general, impact studies have attempted to
investigate the effects of microfinance on some of measure of welfare. A non-exhaustive list
includes: (i) income, consumption and savings; (ii) financial transactions (e.g. borrowing); (iii)
microenterprise growth, employment, profitability; (iv) asset growth; and (v) human capital
investment.

In a nutshell, the more recent studies show that “microfinance is good for microbusinesses”,
but that “the overall effect on the incomes and poverty rates of microfinance clients is less
clear, as are the effects … on measures of social well-being, such as education, health, and
women’s empowerment.” (Odell [2010]: 6)

Among the studies covered in the reviews cited above are two that specifically deal with the
Philippines; only their results are briefly summarized here. The first, by Kondo et al [2008],
evaluates a rural microenterprise finance program using a quasi-experimental design. The

19
Informed by the 2002 Annual Poverty Indicators Survey (APIS), the scorecard allows field workers of MFIs to
assess the likelihood that a program participant is poor based on 10 simple indicators (Schreiner [2007]). A few
microfinance NGOs have used the scorecard also to find out if in fact the borrowers they had chosen before the
introduction of the scorecard had incomes below the poverty line.
design involved choosing existing program areas (treatment) where the microfinance
program had been ongoing for some time, and corresponding expansion areas (control)
where program clients had been identified and prepared for the program but no lending
had yet taken place. In both areas, qualified but non-participating households were also
interviewed. Kondo et al employ a difference-in difference strategy to deal with the
problems of selection bias and program placement bias. To deal with the issue of attrition
bias, the study included an appropriate number of former clients who had either graduated
or dropped out from the program.

The authors found that access to program loans resulted in a positive, albeit weakly
significant 20, effect on per capita income, per capita total consumption, and per capita food
expenditures. Moreover, these effects were regressive; positive only for the higher per
capita income quintile while either negative or insignificant for households in the lower
quintiles. Households that took out loans under the program also reduced their dependence
on other sources of financing, while a higher proportion of households with savings
accounts and balances in these accounts with participating and other MFIs was observed.
Similarly, the microfinance program had a highly significant and positive impact on the
number of microenterprises in which household members were engaged, although no
effects were found on asset accumulation, health and education.

The second impact evaluation dealing with the Philippines is a randomized study by Karlan
and Zinman [2010], which investigates how individual loans made by First Macro Bank to
microentrepreneurs have affected borrowingand other business-related decisions,
profitability, household welfare, and subjective well-being. First Macro Bank is a for-profit
institution receiving implicit subsidies from a USAID-funded program. The authors used a
credit scoring model to separate marginal loan applicants from creditworthy and non-
creditworthy ones. Borrowers were randomly selected from the pool of marginal applicants
based on a pre-assigned probability.

The study found that access to microloans did not necessarily lead to increased profits and
business scale; neither did it raise household income or consumption, on average. The
authors note that where profits increased, such effect was significant only for men and
larger for those with higher incomes. Increased borrowing was also accompanied by
reductions in the number of businesses and some labor shedding, which suggested that
program participants used the credit to “re-optimize” business investment. For male
participants, the increase in borrowing was associated with a drop in household member
employment in other businesses and a higher probability of enrolling a child in school.
Overall, a substitution of formal insurance for credit was also noted, even as access to
informal risk sharing arrangements increased. No significant improvements in several
measures of subjective well-being21were similarly found for program participants; in fact
reducing them to a summary index resulted in a small, negative, albeit “marginally
significant” welfare decrease for the entire sample.

20
Statistical significance is at the 10 percent level.
21
These included optimism, calmness, (lack of) worry, life satisfaction, work satisfaction, (lack of) job stress,
decision-making power, and socio-economic status (p.16).
Karlan and Zinman’s finding that initially better-off participants gained the most from a
microfinance program in Manila also shows up in Kondo et al’s [2008] study of a
microenterprise finance project in Philippine rural areas. In fact, the same result was
obtained by Hulme and Mosley [1996] in Indonesia and Coleman [2006] in Thailand for
similar programs they evaluated though using other measures of welfare as well as
alternative methodologies 22. However, Karlan and Zinman’s findings regarding the
participants’ use of other sources of borrowing, savings accounts, and business growth are
evidently at variance with those of Kondo et al. Moreover, the finding of positive impacts
only for males raises questions regarding the much vaunted advantages of focusing on
women and microentrepreneurs (Karlan and Zinman [2010]:18).

It is fair to say that quite a good deal of a priori expectations associated with microfinance
failed to find empirical support from these two studies conducted in the Philippines. The
same may be said in general about post-2005 microfinance evaluations which almost
invariably found no evidence of the promised effects in terms of improved household
income and consumption, much less in health, education, and women empowerment (See
Odell [2010]).

On the other hand, it may also be premature to conclude anything about the effectiveness
of microfinance as a poverty reduction instrument. For one, “it remains to be seen if
different studies arrive at different estimates due to true underlying heterogeneity across
settings, or to differences (and flaws) in some methodologies” (Karlan and Zinman
[2010]:18). On this, replication of research designs across settings seems to offer a
promising way forward as exemplified by Roodman and Morduch’s [2009] paper.

In their paper, the two authors re-examined three well-cited (and presumably influential)
papers that used survey data from Bangladesh in 1991-92 and 1999 and employed different
methodologies which produced contradictory results about the impact of microfinance (Pitt
and Khandker [1998], Morduch[1999] and Khandker [2005]). They replicated the three
studies applying the same methods to the same data used, as well as performed other
related tests, and concluded that the evidence for impact presented in all three studies is
not definitive.

Conclusion

The debate on whether a trade-off exists between sustainability and outreach is essentially
a debate about the feasibility of the microfinance promise, which holds out the potential for
poverty reduction combined with business success. Those who have been around long
enough should get a sense of déjà vu on recognizing that the same question posed some
three decades ago had managed to creep in through the back door: can credit be an
effective instrument for reducing poverty?

This paper has been essentially a reflection on that debate drawing on the existing literature
and applying the insights on Philippine microfinance data.The data suggest that Philippine
MFIs are generally able to combine financial sustainability with serving poor borrowers, using

22
Kondo et al [2008] is based on a quasi-experimental design originally implemented by Coleman in an earlier
study (Coleman [1999]) with an innovation to deal with the attrition problem.
average loan size as an indicator of depth of outreach. The higher cost of servicing small
loans, however, implies that MFIs have to charge higher interest rates or receive subsidies.
There are indications that non-bank MFIs do both. Regarding outreach, the paper has noted
that where actual client poverty status data are used instead of average loan size, it is not
clear if the relatively small proportion of the poor among loan recipients is due to faulty
targeting or the MFIs’ revealed preference. Finally, most rigorous impact evaluations of
microfinance have found no strong evidence of its promised effects in terms of poverty
reduction.

So, is microfinance overrated?

In a developing country where pervasive credit market imperfections prevent even the non-
poor micro and small entrepreneurs from exploiting productive opportunities, the loosening
of credit constraints results in a real welfare gain. This speeds up capital accumulation and
growth making it possible for the poor to benefit in the process.

Beck and Demirgüc-Kunt [2008] cite studies in both a developed and developing country
which show that finance leads to lower income inequality (and poverty) mainly via labor
market effects, i.e. by employing more of the labor force in the formal sector where wages
are higher [p.385]. That is, the poverty reducing effects of microfinance need not necessarily
depend on expanding the poor’s direct access to credit, or turning them all into
microentrepreneurs. Besides, not everyone is cut out to be an entrepreneur.

Yet the microfinance promise of delivery from poverty is built on stories of individuals
succeeding in this or that microenterprise, never mind that they would have succeeded
anyway without a loan from an MFI. It is this selective story-telling, probably by MFIs
themselves to equally enthusiastic donors who in turn passed on the anecdotes to create
still bigger stories, that has given rise to unreasonably high expectations of microfinance. If
microfinance advocates have been put on the defensive as a result of the spate of empirical
work showing that microfinance does not reduce poverty, it is only because they have
promised too much.

Microfinance will seem overrated only if we choose to assess it on the basis of its promise to
reduce poverty. A more sober analysis informed by an appreciation of the role of financial
markets should tell us that an expansion in the scope of financial services to include hitherto
excluded segments of the population constitutes a social welfare gain. From this standpoint,
microfinance has done well, even if it may not have directly reduced poverty. That is good
enough.
References

Abrams, J. and D. von Stauffenberg [2007] “Role Reversal: Are Public Development
Institutions Crowding Out Private Investment in Microfinance?” Microrate.

Adams, D. and J.D. von Pischke [1992] “Microenterprise Credit Programs: DéjàVu.” World
Development 20(10): 1463-1470.

Alindogan, A. [2005] “Microfinance: Focusing on Our Nation’s Wealth” in Valdepeñas, V.


(ed.) The Bangko Sentral and the Philippine Economy. Manila: Bangko Sentral ng
Pilipinas.

Armendáriz de Aghion, B. and J. Morduch [2005] The Economics of Microfinance Cambridge,


MA: MIT Press.

Arroyo, G. [2001] State of the Nation Address

Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas [2005] Microfinance Handbook. Manila.

Beck, T. and A. Demirgüç-Kunt [2008] “Access to Finance: An Unfinished Agenda.” World


Bank Economic Review 22(3): 383-396.

Briones, R. [2009] “Do Small Farmers Borrow Less When the Lending Rate Increases?
Interest Rate Elasticity of Rice Farmers in the Philippines.” Asian Economic Journal
23(4): 439-455.

Charitonenko, S. [2003] Commercialization of Microfinance: Philippines. Manila: Asian


Development Bank.

Coleman, B. [1999] “The Impact of Group Lending in Northeast Thailand.” Journal of


Development Economics 45( ): 105-141.

Coleman, B. [2006] “Microfinance in Northeast Thailand: Who Benefits and How Much.”
World Development 34(9): 1612-1638.

Cull, R., A. Demirgüç-Kunt and J. Morduch [2007] “Financial Performance and Outreach: A
Global Analysis of Leading Microbanks.” The Economic Journal 117(February): F107-
F133.

Cull, R., A. Demirgüç-Kunt and J. Morduch [2008] “Microfinance Meets the Market.” Policy
Research Working Paper 4630. Development Research Group, The World Bank.

Esguerra, E. F. [1996] "On the Objectives and Design of Special Credit Programs for the Rural
Sector." in R. Fabella and K. Ito (eds.) Financial Sector Issues in the Philippines.
Tokyo: Institute of Developing Economies.

Ghosh, S. and E.Van Tassel [2008] “A Model of Mission Drift in Microfinance Institutions.”
Working Paper 08003, Department of Economics, College of Business, Florida
Atlantic University (December).
File URL: http://home.fau.edu/vantasse/web/MDDec11.pdf
Goldberg, N. [2005] “Measuring the Impact of Microfinance: Taking Stock of What We
Know.” Grameen Foundation Publication Series. <www.grameenfoundation.org>.

Hashemi,S., L. Foose and S. Badawi [2007]”Beyond Good Intentions: Measuring the Social
Performance of Microfinance Institutions.” Focus Note No. 41. Consultative Group to
Assist the Poor (May).

Hudon, M. and D.Traca [2006] “Subsidies and Sustainability in Microfinance.” Working


Papers CEB 06-020. RS, Solvay Business School, Université Libre de Bruxelles.
(October).

Hulme, D. and P. Mosley [1996] Finance Against Poverty, Vols 1 and 2. London: Routledge.

Karlan, D. and J. Zinman [2008] “Credit Elasticities in Less-Developed Economies:


Implications for Microfinance.” American Economic Review 98(3): 1040-1068.

Karlan, D. and J. Zinman [2010] “Expanding Microenterprise Credit Access: Using


Randomized Supply Decisions to Estimate the Impacts in Manila.” Innovations for
Poverty Action and MIT Jameel Poverty Action Lab (May).

Kondo, T., A. Orbeta, C. Dingcong, and C. Infantado [2008] “Impact of Microfinance on Rural
Households in the Philippines.” IDS Bulletin 39 (1):51–70.

Llanto, G. [2005] Rural Finance in the Philippines. Makati: Philippine Institute for Policy
Studies and the Agricultural Credit Policy Council.

Malkin, E. [2008] “Lenders to the Poor Adopt Guidelines.” The New York Times. (September
25).

Mathie, A. [2002] “Including the Excluded: Lessons Learned from the Poverty Targeting
Strategies Used by Microfinance Providers”. Development Bulletin 57. Coady
International Institute. St. Francis Xavier University. February. File URL:
http://devnet.anu.edu.au/online%20versions%20pdfs/57/0757Mathie.pdf.

Mersland, R. and R. Strǿm [2010] “Microfinance Mission Drift?” World Development 38(1):
28-36.

Microfinance Council of the Philippines, Inc. 2010. Microfinance Industry Report –


Philippines. Pasig City.

Microfinance Information eXchange and Microfinance Council of the Philippines, Inc. [2006]
“Benchmarking Philippine Microfinance 2005.” A report from the Microfinance
Information Exchange, Inc. (November).

Microfinance Information eXchange [2006] MicroBanking Bulletin. Issue 13 (Autumn).

Montgomery, H. and J. Weiss [2005]. “Great Expectations: Microfinance and Poverty


Reduction in Asia and Latin America.” ADB Institute Research Paper Series No. 63.
Tokyo: Asian Development Bank Institute. (February).

Morduch, J. [2000] “The Microfinance Schism.” World Development 28(4): 617-629.


National Strategy for Microfinance, Department of Finance, Republic of the Philippines,
1997.

Odell, K. [2010] “Measuring the Impact of Microfinance: Taking Another Look.” Grameen
Foundation Publication Series. <www.grameenfoundation.org>

Roodman, D. and J. Morduch [2009]. “The Impact of Microcredit on the Poor in Bangladesh:
Revisiting the Evidence.” Working Paper No. 174. Washington, D.C.: Center for
Global Development.

Rosenberg, R. [2010]. “Does Microcredit Really Help Poor People?” CGAP Focus Note No. 59.
Consultative Group to Assist the Poor (January).

Rosenberg, R., A. Gonzalez and S. Narain [2009] “The New Moneylenders: Are the Poor
Being Exploited by High Microcredit Interest Rates?” CGAP Occasional Paper No. 15.
Consultative Group to Assist the Poor (February).

Schreiner, M. [2007] “A Simple Poverty Scorecard for the Philippines.” Grameen Foundation
USA (January).

Sinha, F and A. Brar [2005] “Can MFIs Achieve the Double Bottom Line? Technical Note 3,
Micro-Credit Ratings International Limited, Gurgaon, India (December).

Stiglitz, J. and A. Weiss [1981] Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfect Information.”
American Economic Review 71(3): 393-410.

The Economist [2005] “A Survey of Microfinance: The Hidden Wealth of the Poor.”
November 3.

The Economist [2008] “Poor People, Rich Returns (Is it Acceptable to Profit from the Poor)”
May 15.

The Economist [2010] “SKS Comes to Market: Microfight (Can Microlenders Serve
Shareholders and the Poor?)” July 29.

Valdepeñas, V. (ed.) [2005] The Bangko Sentral and the Philippine Economy. Manila: Bangko
Sentral ng Pilipinas.

Woller, G. and M. Schreiner [no date] “Poverty Lending, Financial Self-Sufficiency, and the
Six Aspects of Outreach.” Poverty Lending Working Group, Small Enterprise and
Education Promotion Network.

Zeller, M. and Meyer, R.L. (eds.) [2002] The Triangle of Microfinance: Financial
Sustainability, Outreach and Impact. Johns Hopkins for the International Food Policy
Research institute, Baltimore.

You might also like