Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 117

Journal of Economic Literature 2011, 49:4, 1076–1151

http:www.aeaweb.org/articles.php?doi=10.1257/jel.49.4.1076

The Fundamental Institutions of


China’s Reforms and Development
Chenggang Xu*

China’s economic reforms have resulted in spectacular growth and poverty


reduction. However, China’s institutions look ill-suited to achieve such a result, and
they indeed suffer from serious shortcomings. To solve the “China puzzle,” this paper
analyzes China’s institution—a regionally decentralized authoritarian system. The
central government has control over personnel, whereas subnational governments
run the bulk of the economy; and they initiate, negotiate, implement, divert, and
resist reforms, policies, rules, and laws. China’s reform trajectories have been
shaped by regional decentralization. Spectacular performance on the one hand and
grave problems on the other hand are all determined by this governance structure.
( JEL O17, O18, O43, P21, P25, P26)

1.  Introduction Even more impressively, the contribution


of TFP to the growth has increased from 11

C hinese economic reforms, which have


been in flux for three decades, have more
than doubled China’s economic growth, from
percent before 1978 to more than 40 percent
afterwards (Dwight H. Perkins and Thomas
G. Rawski 2008). This process has trans-
an average of 4.4 percent annually before formed the world’s largest developing coun-
1978 to an average of 9.5 percent after 1978. try from a centrally planned economy into a

* University of Hong Kong and WCU–SNU. The first


draft of this paper was written at Hong Kong University Lau, Eric Maskin, James Mirrlees, Katharina Pistor, Gerard
of Science and Technology (HKUST) when I was visiting Roland, Yumin Sheng, Joseph Stiglitz, Zhigang Tao, Daniel
there. The hospitality and generous support of HKUST are Treisman, Shaoguang Wang, Christine Wong, Jinglian Wu,
greatly appreciated. Comments from participants in confer- Dali Yang, and Lian Zhou. Special thanks go to Roger
ences and seminars at the China Europe International Busi- Gordon for his guidance and insightful comments on dif-
ness School, University of Chicago, the Chinese University ferent versions of the paper. The usual disclaimer applies.
of Hong Kong, City University of Hong Kong, IEA Round Linfeng Chen, Xiaoya Dou, Xinyu Fan, William Organek,
Tables (Beijing), IPD (Columbia/Manchester), Macau, and Jin Wang served as excellent research assistants.
Peking, Seoul National University, Singapore, Tsinghua and Financial support from the World Economy and Finance
UNU–WIDER are greatly appreciated. I am grateful for Research Program of the Economic and Social Research
helpful discussions and comments from three anonymous Council, the World Class University program through the
referees, Masahiko Aoki, Pranab Bardhan, Lauren Brandt, Korea Science and Engineering Foundation funded by the
Hongbin Cai, Chun Chang, Jiahua Che, Ronald Coase, Ministry of Education, Science, and Technology  (grant
Athar Hussain, Garry Jefferson, Yasheng Huang, Janos R32-2008-000-20055-0), HKUST, and the University of
­Kornai, James Kung, Hongbin Li, Justin Yifu Lin, Lawrence Hong Kong are sincerely acknowledged.

1076
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1077

mixed market economy, while simultaneously Daron Acemoglu and Simon Johnson 2005;
reducing poverty at a scale unparalleled in Rodrik 2006). Yet, the Chinese government
world history (World Bank 2002). During the is deeply involved in business, and there is
reform period, the Chinese per capita GDP no clear separation between government
increased by almost eight-fold, and China has and business. Using commonly applied stan-
transformed from one of the poorest countries dards, China is, in general, below average
in the world into a major economic power.1 on most measurements of the application
Today’s China is the world’s largest producer of the rule of law or for governance qual-
and largest consumer of many conventional ity (Franklin Allen, Jun Qian, and Meijun
industrial staples and high-tech products, Qian 2005) and is among the most corrupt
such as steel, cars, television sets, personal countries in the world.3 Moreover, through-
computers, cell phones, and internet usage. out most of the three-decade reform pro-
(National Statistical Bureau 2006b) and has cess, there was no constitutional protection
the world’s largest foreign reserves. The cur- of private property rights until recently (the
rent size of the Chinese economy, in terms of 2004 constitutional amendment). To sum-
GDP, is larger than the sum of eighty-three marize, China’s weak institutions are ill
countries in Eastern Europe, the CIS, and all suited to achieve economic development.
of Africa (the author’s calculation based on Thus, the Chinese reforms pose great chal-
Maddison 2003). This makes a research on lenges to standard economic theories. Can
China more imperative for understanding the economic theory explain China’s reforms?
world economy. Is the Chinese reform a miracle? This paper
However, in sharp contrast to this spectac- will tackle these challenges through a unified
ular performance, it has been reported that, conceptual framework that synthesizes exist-
from the viewpoint of standard wisdom, such ing literature.
as the Washington Consensus or the recent Recently, a growing amount of literature
empirical literature of cross-country studies, on institutions and reforms demonstrate a
Chinese institutions in government, corporate general consensus among economists and
governance, law, and finance look notoriously policymakers that a set of institutions must
weak. Moreover, Chinese reform policies are be in place to make markets function well.
often unconventional and sometimes even Therefore, a market-oriented reform should
look diametrically opposed to “standard” focus mainly on institution building to protect
policy suggestions (Martin L. Weitzman and property rights. Nevertheless, a vital chal-
Chenggang Xu 1994; Dani Rodrik 2006).2 lenge faced by all transition economies and
According to conventional wisdom, the developing economies is how to build these
government should protect private prop- requisite institutions and how to carry out the
erty rights, enforce contracts, and separate reforms. A simplistic, yet fairly popular view
itself from business (Douglas C. North 1981; is that markets will form as long as private

high levels of trade protection, lack of privatization, exten-


1 At the outset of the reform, China’s per capita GDP sive industrial policies, and lax fiscal and financial policies
was about the same as that of Zambia, which was lower through the 1990s, these two economies hardly looked like
than half of the Asian average or lower than two-thirds of exemplars of the Washington Consensus. Indeed, had they
the African average, and its size was about one half of the been dismal failures instead of the successes they turned out
Soviet Union (Angus Maddison 2003). Moreover, it had to be, they would have arguably presented stronger evidence
almost no trade with other countries. in support of Washington Consensus policies” (p. 975).
2 In comparing Chinese and Indian reforms with 3 China has a “Corruption Perception Index” level of
Washington Consensus policies, Rodrik (2006) said: 5, which is similar to Indonesia, Iraq, Myanmar, Nigeria,
“. . .  their policies remained highly unconventional. With Sudan, and Somalia (Jacob Svensson 2005).
1078 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

property is well protected through proper Based on a large body of literature, I


institutions. However, lessons drawn from argue that China’s fundamental institution
numerous historical and contemporary cases that deeply affects executives’ incentives
show that markets and economic develop- and behaviors, which in turn impact soci-
ment do not develop spontaneously, owner- ety, is what I call the regionally decentral-
ship protection is not created independent of ized authoritarian (RDA) regime (section
market development, and private ownership 2). The RDA regime is characterized as a
alone is insufficient for the market economy combination of political centralization and
to function (Ronald H. Coase 1992; Adam economic regional decentralization. On the
Smith 1763, 1776). Without government one hand, the national government’s con-
functioning beyond the protection of prop- trol is substantial in that the Chinese politi-
erty rights, markets often do not develop; cal and personnel governance structure has
even worse, disorder can destroy markets as been highly centralized. Subnational govern-
easily as dictators. Yet, failures of market-ori- ment officials are appointed from above, and
ented reforms launched by governments are the appointment and promotion of subna-
ubiquitous. This is a fundamental dilemma tional government officials serve as powerful
faced by any institution-building reform and instruments for the national government to
echoes Coase’s famous question: what is induce regional officials to follow the cen-
the boundary of the firm? (Coase 1937). As tral government’s policies. This feature fun-
I argue in this paper, the lessons of China’s damentally distinguishes the Chinese RDA
reforms suggest that an answer to this funda- regime from federalism, where governors or
mental question is ultimately determined by mayors are elected and they are supposed to
the trade-offs between costs and benefits of represent and be accountable to their con-
different forms of the government. The tra- stituents. On the other hand, the governance
jectory of China’s reforms, reform strategies, of the national economy is delegated to sub-
outcomes, achievements, and problems are national governments. Regional economies
mainly determined by China’s political and (provinces, municipalities, and counties)
economic institutions. are relatively self-contained, and subna-
Following the theoretical literature of tional governments have overall responsibil-
institutional analysis (Coase 1992; Joseph E. ity for initiating and coordinating reforms,
Stiglitz 2002; Leonid Hurwicz 2007), in this providing public services, and making and
paper the word “institution” refers to those enforcing laws within their jurisdictions.
basic and stable mechanisms that govern the This feature qualitatively differentiates the
incentives of agents and coordinate activi- Chinese economy from a typical centrally
ties in major political and economic games. planned economy.
Thus, “institutional foundations” in this China’s RDA regime evolved before and
paper refer to those basic and stable mecha- during the post-Mao reforms, and some of
nisms that determine the incentives of the its important features can be traced back to
most important players in China’s reform much earlier in China’s history. There are two
and development.4 critical historical factors that make China’s

2006). A popular definition of institution is given by North


4 These mechanisms are endogenous in that they are (1990, p. 3) that “institutions are the rules of the game in
created through the strategic interactions of agents. Thus, a s­ ociety or, more formally, are the humanly devised con-
institution may also be regarded as the equilibrium of the straints that shape human interaction.” However, this defi-
game in the economic and political world (Avner Greif nition is too abstract to be operational.
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1079

RDA regime somewhat unique. First, China to encourage them to try out reforms and
is the only country in the world that has more promote economic growth. Thus, regional
than two thousand years of imperial his- competition has been a major component
tory, which had a unique governance struc- of China’s three decades of reform (section
ture, and today’s RDA regime inherits some 3). When a region has a higher growth rate
important elements from this governance than others, the head of the region will enjoy
structure. Second, the Cultural Revolution greater power and will be more likely to be
is unique in the history of world communist promoted. One of the most important initia-
movements. The ensuing destruction of the tives taken by many subnational governments
communist institutions and society has led was the development of nonstate firms,
to disillusion with the communist ideology, a including FDI and indigenous firms (e.g.,
change of the legitimacy base of the Chinese the township–village enterprises), which has
Communist Party, and weakened resistance been the most important engine of China’s
to reforms, and has shaped the basic charac- economic growth since the mid-1980s.
teristics of the RDA regime, paving the road Chinese subnational governments not only
for the post-Mao reforms. compete against quantifiable targets, such
In the RDA regime, subnational gov- as GDP growth rate, but, they also often
ernments have influence or even direct compete in initiating or testing new reform
control rights over a substantial amount policies, i.e., regional reform experiments
of resources, such as land, firms, financial (section 4). They have been given consid-
resources, energy, raw materials, and oth- erable responsibility for regional coordina-
ers.5 Subnational governments are major tion, and such decentralized coordination
players in the bulk of the Chinese economy. has facilitated regional reform experiments;
Under the supervision of the central govern- since subnational governments are closer to
ment, they initiate, negotiate, implement, experimenting sites, they are much better
divert, and resist reforms, policies, rules, informed about local information than the
and laws. They drive, influence, or hamper central government and can therefore coor-
regional/national economic development, dinate more effectively. Regionally based
macroeconomic conditions, environmental coordination makes economywide coordi-
conservation or degradation, social stabil- nation failures less likely when there are
ity, etc. China’s reform trajectories have external shocks. This also makes it easier to
been shaped by centrally controlled regional experiment with institutional changes locally
decentralization. Spectacular performance without causing disruption to the rest of the
on the one hand and grave problems on the economy. Most importantly, by incorporat-
other hand are all created or closely associ- ing regional experiments as an essential part
ated with this governance structure. of the central decision-making process, the
At the early stages of the reforms, the political risks of advancing reforms are sub-
central government delegated more autono- stantially reduced, and political opposition to
mous power and provided stronger incen- reforms is significantly weakened (sections 2
tives to subnational governments in order and 4). Indeed, almost all successful reforms
in the past three decades were introduced
5 “In effect, it is the sub-national levels of Government through local experiments (section 5).
that implement China’s national development agenda. Nevertheless, the intrinsic deficiencies
Nearly 70 percent of total public expenditure in China takes of an authoritarian regime, such as the lack
place at the sub-national level (i.e., provincial, prefecture,
county, and township), of which more than 55 percent takes of an independent judiciary, rent-seeking
place at sub-provincial levels” (World Bank 2002). behavior, and a failure to respond to citizens’
1080 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

preferences, are important parts of the char- economic development. Nevertheless, the
acteristics of China’s RDA regime, with- overall performance of China’s reforms and
out exception (section 6). Although some of development appears not only magnificent
these problems might be mitigated when but unparalleled in world history in its gigan-
subnational governments face fierce regional tic scale and prolonged rapid growth. This
competition, regional competition may lead incredible contrast between “poor” institu-
to other problems, such as regional protec- tions and China’s spectacular performance
tion. Moreover, many problems inherent in challenges our general understanding of the
the RDA regime may be worsened when the mechanics of institutions and our under-
effectiveness of regional competition is weak- standing of “institutional quality.”
ened, e.g., when subnational governments First, there appear to be conceptual mis-
face multiple tasks, they strategically chose understandings about what exactly consti-
to ignore some tasks in the competition. Also, tutes an institution in the literature. The
regional competition may lead to “races to the so-called institution is sometimes improperly
bottom” for some tasks, which can be much defined or misinterpreted in certain popular
worse than simply being ignored. China’s empirical or policy studies. One of the most
future depends on how those problems are widespread approaches is to label a set of nar-
resolved and, given that they are deficient rowly defined measurements as the perfect
outcomes of the RDA regime, an ultimate “institution” based on some observed fea-
solution lies in a fundamental transformation tures of developed market economies, e.g.,
of the institution itself. the United States. Then, all other countries’
Although determined by its distinctive his- practices are measured against this standard
tory, China’s RDA regime is itself unique, to see the imperfections of those countries’
there are still some general lessons that can institutions. Although the empirical findings
be drawn from China’s reforms and develop- that follow from that approach could be useful
ment for other developing countries. These in a narrow scope, serious problems may arise
are discussed in the concluding section. when this approach is generalized. Without
One of the major purposes of this paper is a thorough understanding of the working
to address the so-called “China Puzzle.” It is mechanisms of institutions in developed and
undisputed among economists that the qual- developing economies, such mechanical and
ity of institutions is important for reform and narrow interpretations of institution ignore
development because they determine incen- the essence of these institutions. This kind of
tives for executives and all the players in an research, to some extent, is not only at odds
economy. China is regarded in cross-country with the theoretical literature on institutions
study literature as having poor institutions, (a la North 1990, Coase 1992, Stiglitz 2002,
such as poor legal protection of property Hurwicz 2007, etc.), but also can be mislead-
rights, poor corporate governance, lack of ing in general. 6 For instance, the concept of,
democratic accountability, and an absence of and the mechanism by which, the rule of law
the rule of law. The resulting forecast is that
Chinese officials will be corrupt, will not work
6 “The value of including such institutional factors in the
hard, and will not collect and report informa-
corpus of mainstream economics is made clear by recent
tion correctly, all of which are partly correct events in Eastern Europe. These ex-communist countries
empirically. However, much more impor- are advised to move to a market economy, and their leaders
tantly, this theory would also suggest that, wish to do so, but without the appropriate institutions no
market economy of any significance is possible. If we knew
under poor institutions, executives in China more about our own economy we would be in a better posi-
would block reforms, therefore preventing tion to advise them” (Coase 1992, p. 714).
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1081

affects economies has been the subject of may be very difficult, time-consuming, or
many debates. However, most of the popular even counterproductive under certain politi-
empirical cross-country studies apply a nar- cal conditions.
row definition of the rule of law and ignore How should a country transform a cen-
the debates on the subject, such that the trally planned economy into a market
United States is often taken as the ideal (or economy? What are the most important
almost ideal) model in those studies. Yet, if and effective reforms for economic devel-
we look at the widespread financial fraud and opment? How can a reform motivate sub-
the deep corruption from the grassroots to national governments and at the same time
the top executives on Wall Street revealed coordinate and control them? These subjects
throughout the 2008 financial crises and the have been debated by economists, political
Enron–WorldCom scandal in 2002 etc., the scientists, historians, sociologists, and others
contrast between this illusion and reality is for decades, both in general and in the con-
striking. text of China. Their viewpoints are, however,
Moreover, very often the empirical mea- scattered, and very often scholars in dif-
surements used in cross-country studies are ferent disciplines do not talk to each other.
too narrow to capture the functioning of This paper attempts to develop a coher-
institutions in developing economies, such as ent conceptual framework that synthesizes
in China. As a result, all the functioning insti- a multidisciplinary discussion on China’s
tutions that are beyond the scope of those institutions, reforms, and development. In
narrow definitions are ignored, as if they addition to improving our understanding of
did not exist. Consequently, China’s perfor- China’s reforms and economic development,
mance becomes inexplicable and it becomes by doing so, I also hope to deepen our gen-
either an outlier to be ignored or a puzzle in eral understanding of political and economic
cross-country studies. institutions, and on the evolution of these
The empirical study of the protection of institutions.
private property rights and contract enforce- This paper is not an attempt of an exhaus-
ment is a concrete example. It is true that in tive literature survey. Such a full-scale survey
China there was no formal or constitutional would require multiple volumes. Therefore,
protection of private property until 2004, many important contributions are not cov-
and commercial codes related to contracts ered due to space restrictions and my igno-
were not enacted until the late 1980s, and rance on the subject, particularly beyond the
moreover remained unimportant until the field of economics. For this reason, I have
late 1990s. However, there was semiformal only discussed some of the very serious prob-
and informal protection of private property, lems that China is facing briefly. For many
and contract enforcement mechanisms were others, I have only mentioned them without
exercised by some subnational governments elaboration, such as problems of election,
under a special social context in Chinese his- judiciary, corruption, social security, and the
tory or by social norms. Yet, these institu- environment.
tions often are unaccounted for in almost all
cross-country studies. Even worse, according
2.  The Fundamental Institution:
to some “standard” policy advice, these more
Regionally Decentralized Authoritarianism
informal institutions might be regarded as
obstacles that should be replaced by “stan- Transformation from a centralized econ-
dard” institutions as quickly as possible, even omy to a market economy requires both insti-
though setting up “standard” institutions tutional support and institutional change. In
1082 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

addition, developing from an agrarian econ- from a federal state, a unitary state, and a
omy into a modern market economy also totalitarian regime.
entails creating better institutions. However,
2.1 Decentralized Economic Governance:
reforms have never started from an insti-
Regional Decentralization
tutional vacuum. All reforms have to begin
with existing institutions, and any institutional A salient feature of the Chinese gover-
change has to be initiated and implemented nance structure is the relatively hands-off
by agents within these existing institutions approach taken by the national government
(even in the case of a revolution, existing insti- with respect to most of the national economy,
tutions still have profound long-run impacts). while subnational governments are deeply
For all of these reasons, historically inherited involved in the economies within their
institutions have far-reaching impacts on an jurisdiction, including regional firms. The
economy, sometimes long after those insti- Chinese government consists of a region-
tutions have been changed or abandoned based multilevel hierarchy. Below the central
(Richard R. Nelson and Sidney G. Winter government, there are four levels of subna-
1982; North 1990). No major distinctive fea- tional governments: the provincial level, the
tures of an economy—including reforms and municipal level (or prefecture level), the
subsequent changes—can be properly under- county level, and the township level. The
stood without understanding the fundamental central government directly controls only a
institutions that underpin the economy; more- small proportion of the Chinese economy.
over, this is especially true when considering The largest economic sector that the central
China’s spectacular and prolonged growth on government controls directly is industry, and
the one hand, and its serious socioeconomic even within this industry the central govern-
problems on the other. ment directly employed less than 4 percent
In this section, I introduce the funda- of all the industrial employees nationwide
mental institution of China, which I call (National Statistical Bureau 2006a).
the regionally decentralized authoritarian Most government functions are carried
(RDA) system.7 The RDA system is charac- out by subnational governments. Although
terized by highly centralized political and by constitution China is not a federal state,
personnel controls at the national level, and in many important economic issues Chinese
a regionally decentralized administrative and subnational governments are more powerful
economic system. Both decision making and than their counterparts in federal countries
policy implementations in the RDA regime, around the world since they are responsible
from national strategic issues to concrete for much broader regional matters than sim-
local matters, are deeply influenced by this ply fiscal issues. Unfortunately, almost all the
combination of political centralization and empirical papers in the literature of decen-
economic decentralization. These features tralization look at only fiscal decentralization
qualitatively differentiate China’s regime since there is no well-accepted methodology
to measure broadly defined regional decen-
tralization. In the context of China’s decen-
7 The concept of regionally decentralized authoritari-
tralization, although fiscal decentralization is
anism was coined to characterize China’s institution in
2006 in the first draft of this paper. In 2009, I read Pierre sometimes a reasonable proxy for decentral-
F. Landry (2008), where he uses the word decentralized ization more generally, other times regional
authoritarianism. Although looks similar on the surface, decentralization in other dimensions is more
the meaning of RDA is substantially different from the
words of Landry (2008) just like the extensive differences important than fiscal decentralization. Thus,
between this paper and his book. focusing on fiscal decentralization alone can
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1083

Table 1
Annual Growth of China’s GDP, Fixed Capital, Labor, and TFP, 1951–2005

Percentage shares of GDP


Annual growth of inputs growth attributable to
Labor input
Average Education
Fixed   Raw  Education TFP Fixed enhanced
Period GDP capital   labor   enhanced growth capital labor TFP
K L H K H

1952–2005 7.0 7.7 1.9 2.6 2.1 47.7 21.4 30.9


1952–1978 4.4 5.8 1.9 2.5 0.5 56.3 32.7 11.0
1952–1957 6.5 1.9 1.2 1.7 4.7 12.7 14.9 72.4
1957–1978 3.9 6.7 2.0 2.7 −0.5 73.7 39.7 −13.4
1957–1965 2.4 5.2 1.5 2.1 −1.0 93.1 49.5 −42.6
1965–1978 4.9 7.7 2.4 3.1 −0.2 67.7 36.7 −4.4
1978–2005 9.5 9.6 1.9 2.7 3.8 43.7 16.2 40.1
1978–1985 9.7 9.2 3.4 4.5 3.2 40.6 26.6 32.8
1985–1990 7.7 6.9 2.5 2.9 3.1 38.8 21.5 39.7
1990–1995 11.7 9.1 1.4 1.9 6.7 33.3 9.5 57.3
1995–2000 8.6 10.5 0.9 1.6 3.2 52.7 10.5 36.8
2000–2005 9.5 12.6 1.0 1.8 3.1 57.1 10.6 32.3

Source: Perkins and Rawski 2008.

be misleading (this will be elaborated in later Figure 1 depicts the governance struc-
sections). ture of the Chinese economy. The statistics
China’s governance structure does not in the figure reflect the situation in the year
fit neatly into standard conceptions of 2005, though the structure has been stable
authoritarian regimes. According to cross- throughout the reform era.8 This governance
country studies, fiscal decentralization is structure is the result of a half-century of
closely linked with democracy. However, political development (Perkins 1977, 1988;
China’s authoritarian regime is one of the Elizabeth J. Perry and Wong 1985; David
fiscally most decentralized countries in the Granick 1990; Barry J. Naughton 1995;
world. Contrasting China’s fiscal decentral- Guoguang Liu et al. 2006; Jinglian Wu
ization with its counterparts in the rest of
the world during the early 2000s, the total 8 The total number of central state-owned enterprises
expenditure of Chinese subnational govern- (SOEs) listed in figure 1 is 2,128, which is from the NSB.
ments accounted for about 70 percent of the However, according to the SASAC (State-owned Asset
Supervision and Administration Commission), the number
national total, which was far larger than that should be less than 170 in 2005 and 151 in 2007 (http://www.
of the world’s largest federal countries such as sasac.gov.cn/zyqy/qyml/default.htm). The latter is the total
the United States (46 percent), Germany (40 number of parent companies controlled directly by the cen-
tral government, which supervises a large number of sub-
percent), and Russia (38 percent) (Christine sidiary companies; whereas the former is the total number
P. W. Wong 2006). of all establishments managed by the central government.
1084 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

Central government
(Pop: 1.31 billion)
Central firms: 2,128 central SOEs
Employment: 2.75 million: Fixed assets: 1,314 billion Yuan

22 provinces and 5 autonomous regions 4 Provincial-level municipalities:


(Average pop: 45.7 million) Beijing, Shanghai, Tianjin, Chongqing
(Average pop: 17.9 million)
Regional level firms: 269,707 including local SOEs, collectives, joint, private, foreign, others.
Employment 66.21 million Fixed assets: 9,281 billion Yuan

333 Municipality-level units


(283 cities) average pop: 3.71 million

2,862 County-level units


(374 cities) average pop: 431,426

41,636 town-level units


(19,522 towns) average pop: 29,656

Figure 1. Regional Governance Structure of Chinese Economy


Source: National Statistical Bureau, 2006a, 2006b, 2006c.

2009); moreover, many important features of During the GLF campaign, central min-
it can be traced back to imperial times (to istries handed over most centrally con-
be further discussed later). Not long after a trolled SOEs to subnational governments.
full-scale transplantation of the Soviet model As a result, the subnational governments’
in the early 1950s, there were two major tax revenue increased from 20 percent of
campaigns that lead to vast waves of decen- the national total in 1958 to 76 percent in
tralizations at extremely high costs. The first 1959 and 79 percent in 1961, much higher
started in the late 1950s (the Great Leap than those in the post-Mao reform period
Forward (GLF)), and the second in the late (table 2). Central planning was replaced by
1960s (the Cultural Revolution) (Susan L. regional competition. Subnational govern-
Shirk 1993; Liu et al. 2006).9 ments were encouraged to compete with
each other to overfulfill planning targets, to
establish “communes” earlier or at a larger
9 The GLF established the People’s Commune, thus
the Commune-Brigade Enterprises (the predecessor of
the TVEs); and expanded local industries under state and of the GLF is the Great Famine (see Justin Yifu Lin 1990
collective ownership. An essential part of the human cost and Wei Li and Dennis Tao Yang 2005).
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1085

Table 2
Evolution of Chinese Fiscal Decentralization, 1953 to 2005

Subnational/ Subnational/
Year total revenue total expenditure GDP/capita GDP/capita grw Institutional changes

1953 17.0% 26.1% 554 3.2% 1st five year plan


1958 19.6% 55.7% 693 8.8%
1959 75.6% 54.1% 697 0.6% Great leap forward
1961 78.5% 55.0% 673 0.0%
1966 64.8% 36.9% 753 6.7% Cultural revolution
1975 88.2% 50.1% 874 4.5%
1978 84.5% 52.6% 979 9.4% Reform starts
1980 75.5% 45.7% 1,067 2.6% Fiscal reform starts
1984 59.5% 47.5% 1,396 10.4%
1988 67.1% 66.1% 1,816 6.4%
1993 78.0% 71.7% 2,277 8.5%
1994 44.3% 69.7% 2,475 8.7% Fiscal sharing rule
2004 45.1% 72.3%    
2005 47.7% 74.1%    

Sources: China 50 Years’ Statistics; GDP/capita: 1990 international dollars, Maddison (2003).

scale, to close down markets, etc. They were Corresponding with the second wave of
also encouraged to try out different com- decentralization in the “Cultural Revolution,”
mune organizations, different ways of orga- the subnational fiscal revenue (expenditure)
nizing production and collective life (e.g., to national fiscal revenue (expenditure) ratio
public canteen systems in communes), etc. increased from 65 percent (37 percent) in
The central government’s bureaucracy was 1966 to 88 percent (50 percent) in 1975
trimmed; supervision of most state-owned (table 2).
enterprises was delegated from the minis- As a result, China had already established
tries to provinces and cities, and subnational hundreds of relatively self-contained regional
governments’ responsibilities were substan- economies at the outset of the reforms. The
tially enlarged. Reflecting the first wave of majority of the two thousand counties had
decentralization in the late 1950s, the sub- SOEs producing agricultural machinery,
national fiscal revenue to total national fis- while 300 counties had steel plants. Small
cal revenue ratio jumped from 20 percent in regional SOEs produced 69 percent of
1958 to 76 percent in 1959 (table 2).10 China’s total fertilizer output and 59 per-
cent of its total cement. More than twenty
10 By disturbing central planning and destroying mar- provinces had SOEs producing automobiles
kets, while simultaneously removing local financial respon- or tractors (Xu and Juzhong Zhuang 1998).
sibility, these campaigns degenerated into competitions
of exaggerations and lies among subnational officials,
which ended up in chaos and eventually created one of million people died of starvation between 1959 and 1961
the worst catastrophes in world history, in which about 40 (Roderick MacFarquhar 1974, 1983, 1997).
1086 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

This is in sharp contrast to all other formally during which time the subnational fiscal rev-
centralized economies in which special- enue (expenditure) to national fiscal revenue
ization and monopoly are hallmarks. With (expenditure) ratio was 78 percent (72 per-
greatly reduced responsibilities, the Chinese cent) (table 2).
central government was much smaller than To analyze the economic incentive and
its counterparts in other centralized econo- coordination mechanisms of the Chinese
mies. When the Chinese reforms started, the RDA system, the governance structure is
number of products directly under the cen- modeled as a stylized multiregional gov-
tral plan was only 791 (the number was never ernance form (M-form) (e.g., Qian and Xu
more than one thousand in the Chinese cen- 1993; Eric Maskin, Qian, and Xu 2000; and
trally planned system) and the number of Qian, Gerard Roland, and Xu 2006, 2007).
ministries at the center was less than thirty In the M-form hierarchy, every region is
(Yingyi Qian and Xu 1993).11 controlled by the central government politi-
When the reforms took place, after the end cally, whereas each region not only enjoys
of the Cultural Revolution, subnational gov- a certain degree of autonomy but also is
ernments already de facto controlled a great self-contained in its functions.12 Figure 2
deal of resources in China. Given this inher- depicts a highly stylized Chinese regional
ited governance structure, for both political governance structure in which each region is
and economic reasons, granting more auton- self-contained (in contrast to specialization):
omous powers to subnational governments is each subnational government controls major
one of the major strategies in the post-Mao functions within its jurisdiction, such as per-
reforms, particularly during the first fifteen sonnel, finance, industry, and agriculture. As
years of the reforms (Xiaoping Deng 1980, a comparison, specialized ministries control
1986; Shirk 1993; Liu et al. 2006; Wu 2009). industrial firms and the central government
Subnational governments were given strong is responsible for coordinating the comple-
incentives and were directly involved in man- mentary tasks of various ministries in other
aging or setting up firms, forming joint ven- formally centralized economies.
tures with domestic or foreign investors, etc.
2.2 Centralized Political Governance
Many subnational governments have granted
de facto property rights to local SOEs and Although highly decentralized economi-
collectively owned firms (COEs) within their cally, China is neither a de jure nor a de facto
jurisdictions (Granick 1990), which account federal state. The backbone of China’s RDA
for most of the firms in the nation. Moreover, regime is the Chinese Communist Party
subnational governments have become more (CCP), which controls the personnel matters
important in all regional affairs, from land of subnational governments and commands
allocation, business development, infra- high economic sectors (e.g., banking, energy,
structure construction, and fiscal matters, telecommunication, railway, etc.), as well as
to law making and law enforcement. Fiscal controlling ideology and the mass media.
decentralization reached its peak in 1993, The dominant role of the CCP makes
the RDA regime of China fundamentally
11 As a comparison, in the Soviet Union the central
­ lanning system was based on the principle of functional
p 12 The term M-form was first used by Alfred D.
specialization, and the central government directly con- Chandler (1967) and Oliver E. Williamson (1975) to char-
trolled most of the SOEs. In the late 1970s, there were acterize multidivisional structure of large corporations,
sixty-two ministries under the Gosplan, which were where divisions are self-contained and are granted auton-
responsible for 48,000 plan “positions” or twelve million omous power, while division chiefs are appointed by the
products (Alec Nove 1983). headquarters.
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1087

Central government

Central adm. function Territorial control

Personnel Finance Agriculture Industry Province A Province B Province C

Personnel Finance Agriculture Industry

Figure 2. Stylized Governance Structure of China

different from a federal system. Firstly, by practice, the central government makes deci-
constitution, China is not a federal state. sions on appointment and removal of provin-
The Chinese constitution has been amended cial leaders, e.g., governors. Similarly, most
during the reforms, reflecting the changes municipal leaders, e.g., mayors, are directly
of Chinese political and economic institu- controlled by corresponding provincial gov-
tions. However, both the prereform version ernments. This nested network extends the
and the latest version of the Constitution central government’s personnel control to
stipulate that regions have no inherent officials of all levels of regions, from provin-
power, and regional power is granted by cial to municipal, then to county until the bot-
the central authorities. The central govern- tom of the hierarchy, township government
ment is empowered to delegate power to (John P. Burns 1994). Moreover, reshuffling
regions and also to rescind this power (for and cross-region rotation of regional leaders
the PRC Constitution 1975 Amendment, is a common practice to keep central control
see Chongde Xu 2005; for PRC Constitution over subnational officials. From 1978 to 2005,
Amendment, see Falv Chubanshe 2009). 80 percent of provincial regions have experi-
Secondly, China’s RDA regime is not a enced rotation of governors imposed by the
de facto federal state either. Within the central government (Xianxiang Xu, Xianbin
RDA regime, Chinese regional leaders Wang, and Yuan Shu 2007). This personnel
are appointed by upper-level governments control approach is the major instrument
through the CCP system—not by regional used to make regional officials comply with
elections—despite devolution of much the central government’s policy and also to
power over economic matters to the sub- provide incentives for regional experimenta-
national governments. While subnational tion, which I will elaborate on in a later sec-
governments obtain highly autonomous tion. Moreover, personnel control allows the
economic power, the central government central government to achieve some macro
maintains its influence on regional officials’ control, such as controlling inflation (Huang
incentives by determining their career paths 1996b). Furthermore, through this mecha-
(Yasheng Huang 1996b; Landry 2008). In nism, the central government has maintained
1088 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

considerable influence in consensus build- fast growing was not fulfilled in the last fif-
ing with subnational governments in order teen years of their reforms in former Soviet
to push through policies that are favorable Union and Central-Eastern Europe until the
to the central government (Naughton and collapse of the system (Kornai 1986, 1992).
Dali L. Yang 2004). Nevertheless, it must What makes China different is that they have
be pointed out that, although this approach transformed the system into a mixed econ-
worked sometime on high priority issues, it omy with an overwhelming private sector
frequently failed on many other important and integrated into the global economy
issues (section 6 further discusses this). However, this transformation evolved and
is not designed by anyone. On the surface,
2.2.1 Evolved Decision-Making Process of
China’s reform looks like a “pure” economic
the Central Leadership
reform without a major corresponding politi-
In this subsection, I will discuss how the cal change.14 Nevertheless, as a matter of
decision-making process of the CCP cen- fact, the post-Mao reform started from
tral leadership evolved and how it works. astonishing political changes, which resulted
In the post-Mao era, China’s central lead- in the change of the central leadership and
ership sees economic growth as a life and the change of the central decision-making
death matter for the regime. It is important process of the CCP. After three decades’
to point out that they are not unique among evolution, today’s RDA regime is fairly dif-
socialist leaders in this aspect. In discuss- ferent from the CCP regime during the Mao
ing the general features of socialist systems, era, although the political changes were
Janos Kornai (1992, pp. 160–61) explains restricted to those necessary for enabling
that the socialist leaders promise to “elimi- economic reform, with focuses on establish-
nate the backwardness very quickly.” And ing the party rules, on personnel changes to
the promise “rests on a belief that they can weaken those who might block reforms, and
catch up with the developed countries quite on the selection mechanism of leadership
fast by virtue of the socialist system’s supe- succession.
riority. This belief is a major constituent of In the prereform era, the central decision
the official ideology. The leaders insist on making of the CCP was dominated by a char-
fast growth because it will provide further ismatic figure, Mao Zedong. In the revolu-
evidence of that superiority.” There is a tionary era, the CCP was fairly decentralized
large literature on “forced growth” in for- in that many important decisions were jointly
mer socialist economies (Kornai 1971, 1992; made between central and regional lead-
Gur Ofer 1987). Indeed, many speeches by ers, or made by regional leaders. Regional
Deng (e.g., 1987) and other Chinese central power was a very strong element in the
leaders concerning the central importance
of growth echo those of Josef V. Stalin and
Nikita S. Khrushchev.13 Yet, the promise of 14 Given the nature of communist ideology and the
radical practice of the CCP in the Mao era, if there was
indeed no important political change then China’s market
reform would indeed look puzzling. Shirk (1993) notes
13 Stalin (1931 [1947, p. 356]) said “One feature of the that “ . . . the Chinese strategy of economic reform with-
history of the old Russia was the continual beatings she out political reform appeared to have worked . . .” (p. 4);
suffered . . . for her backwardness . . . We are fifty or one “The overall economic success of the Chinese economic
hundred years behind the advanced countries. We must reform experience is surprising because we usually think
make good this distance in ten years. Either we do it or of communist political institutions as rigid and hostile to
they crush us.” Khrushchev (1959, pp. 76–77) claimed that innovation” (p. 5); and “We expect communist party and
the socialist system will outcompete the Western world by government officials to defend their vested interests in the
faster growth and eventually bury them. command economy by blocking market reforms” (p. 399).
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1089

central decision-making body of the CCP.15 the central government (MacFarquhar 1974,
Soon after the CCP took power in 1949, a 1983, 1997). The personal control and cam-
dramatic political centralization took place. paigns mutually reinforced each other, and
Although a region-based organizational the influence of the campaigns was far reach-
structure was kept, the most influential ing. In addition to changing the behaviors of
regional leaders were “promoted” as central the subnational officials, it deeply affected
leaders and were physically moved to Beijing the governance structure of the party and of
in the early 1950s.16 Simultaneously, China the state.
transplanted the Soviet central planning With an extremely ambitious economic
regime and the first five year-plan of China growth plan for speeding up China’s transi-
was instituted. This centralization served to tion to a Communist society, the Great Leap
establish a centrally planned economy and Forward (GLF) and the People’s Commune
was welcomed by the CCP elites. As in the Campaigns were launched in the late 1950s.
Soviet Union, the objective of the CCP was Not only did the campaigns once again dramat-
“to build a strong socialist economy” [the ically decentralize the economy as discussed
8th National Congress of the CCP in 1956, previously, they also changed the central deci-
see Research Center of CCP History 2009]; sion-making process. Since then, the Chinese
and most SOEs were controlled centrally by economy has sharply deviated from the classi-
ministries. cal Soviet central planning model.
Through significantly weakening regional The “Cultural Revolution” (CR), launched
leadership, this centralization substantially in 1966, is much more than another wave of
strengthened Mao’s personal control over decentralization. To a large extent, it uninten-
the party, from personnel matters to the cen- tionally prepared the necessary political and
tral decision-making process.17 Mao man- institutional conditions for post-Mao reforms.
aged to strengthen the cult of his personality The CR campaign mobilized the masses and
by transforming the central decision-making CCP leaders at all subnational levels to fol-
process into a series of political games in low Mao directly to fight against party and
which his potential rivals were weakened government bureaucrats.18 There was an
through fighting with each other. Without anarchy-type of decentralization through
any rival at the subnational level, Mao which party/government organizations at the
launched campaigns that delegated substan- central and subnational levels were replaced
tial power to subnational governments, thus by mass organizations. The mobs enforced
further weakening the power of his rivals in strict censorship that any idea different from
Mao’s was absolutely not tolerated. During
15 For example, in 1949, eight out of the fifteen
this period, with the slogan “down with
Politbureau members of the 7th CCP Central Committee capitalist runners,” most of the party appa-
were regional leaders. ratuses and central government bureaucra-
16 The most prominent figures include Deng—became
cies were dismantled; most party/state/social
the CCP General Secretary and was purged in 1967,
Gao Gang—became the vice President of China and was elites were purged, including the president
purged/died in 1954, Chen Yi—became vice Premier and of the country; regional “revolutionary rebel-
was purged in 1967, Xi Zhongxun—became vice Premier lions,” with self-proclaimed loyalty to Mao
and was purged in 1962, and Deng Zihui—became vice
Premier and was purged in 1962.
17 In China’s imperial history, during the onset of each
dynasty, it was typical that a new emperor would centralize 18 Two years before launching the CR, Mao warned
power to weaken powerful regional rivals, such as warlords, subnational officials including county level officials that
for the sake of consolidating the regime. Mao discussed they should refuse to follow and should resist the revision-
this issue many times. ist central leadership (Quanxing Xu 1995).
1090 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

were supported by Mao’s lieutenants and the CR and were keen to make a radical
“seized powers (duoquan)” at all levels of change, returned to power, and propaganda
subnational governments from the CCP, campaigns were launched to change the ide-
sometimes through civil wars (MacFarquhar ology of the CCP from one of class struggles
and Michael Schoenhals 2006); and finally, to one of economic development.21 The CCP
subnational governments became the most central leaders forged a new consensus on
important level of government for manag- the following major issues: (a) the monopo-
ing the economy, given that most ministries listic political power of the CCP must not be
closed down.19 The devastation awakened challenged; (b) within the confines of, and to
the majority of the party and social elites and strengthen, condition (a), economic develop-
the legitimacy of the CCP was deeply shaken ment should be interpreted as the essence
through the CR’s overwhelming destruction. of socialism, and thus of the utmost impor-
All of these paved the road to making major tance; and (c) regarding the central decision-
changes, to changing the decision-making making process, personalistic regime should
rules and the objectives of the CCP after the be replaced by party rule, i.e., a consensus-
death of Mao.20 based collective decision-making process
The coup d’état of 1976, a few weeks after (Deng 1984; Ziyang Zhao 2009; Rui Li 2008;
the death of Mao, in which Madam Mao and Zemin Jiang 1997).22 This was a watershed
her lieutenants were arrested, eliminated period in which the CCP began to trans-
those who insisted on continuing the CR form itself from a personality-ruled party
from both the central leadership and subna- into “a system governed by rules, clear lines
tional levels. Consequently, a large number of of authority, and collective decision-making
CCP high officials, who were purged during institutions” (Shirk 1993, p. 399). Moreover,
economic development has become the
objective of the party and the state.
19 The self-contained and self-sufficient regionally
These critical personnel and ideologi-
decentralized structure was further reinforced in the
early 1970s when most of the counties in the nation were cal changes were consolidated in the Third
encouraged to setup small industrial firms in five major Plenum of the 11th CCP Central Committee
sectors (Wong 1987).
20 A failed attempt to change the central focus of the
in December 1978.23 The communiqué of
CCP before Mao’s death is more than a prelude of the this plenum became the official manifesto for
post 1978 reform. There was a belief among the top CCP political, ideological and economic change.
leaders that the CR has brought the Chinese economy to Consequently, the “Four Modernizations,”
the verge of collapse and refocusing the central task of the
CCP to the economy is a matter of life and death to the
party (in later years Deng repeated these arguments many
times, e.g., 1980, to justify the changing of the central task 21 Before Deng returned to power in late 1978, most of
of the CCP). In 1975, the premier Zhou Enlai, together the major changes were lead by Hu Yaobang, the minister
with Deng, a deputy premier after being purged for many of the CCP personnel department and the de facto head of
years, launched the so-called “Four Modernizations” (mod- the Central Party School (Jiwei Hu 2008, 2009).
ernization of agriculture, industry, science and technology, 22 The following argument of Deng (1994b) well
and defense) campaign. This campaign represented a ris- represents the goal of the CCP: “to build socialism it
ing consensus among most CCP elites. More importantly, is necessary to develop the productive forces . . . Not
they underlay a competing legitimacy for the future party until . . . we have reached the level of the moderately devel-
leadership. Challenging the revolutionary theme of the oped countries, shall we be able to say that we have really
CR, this de facto reform incited intensive political fights built socialism and to declare convincingly that it is supe-
as part of the succession of the CCP’s leadership. Although rior to capitalism. We are advancing towards that goal.”
this reform attempt was crushed politically by the left-wing 23 Although the Third Plenum of the 11th Central
faction with formidable support from Mao, this aborted Committee of the CCP officially changed the objective of
agenda became a platform for changing the CCP and it the CCP to economic development under the slogan “the
reminded the CCP reformist elites that a pure economic Four Modernizations,” reform was not in the agenda of the
reform would be blocked without political change. Plenum (Hu 2009).
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1091

the slogan of the Third Plenum of the 11th as China did in the first five-year plan? Or
Central Committee of the CCP, and later should it be developed by transforming the
“Reform and Open-up,” which replaced economy into a market system? Should the
the “Four Modernizations” after the 13th political system be reformed together with
Congress of the CCP in 1987, emerged as economic reforms? What should be the direc-
the official objective of the CCP. tion for a political reform? There were sharply
To some extent changing the foundation different views on these issues among the
of legitimacy of the CCP to one of economic CCP central leaders; more importantly, there
development does not contradict commu- were power struggles associated with these
nist ideology and is not unique to the post- differing views.25
Mao CCP, although this may be at odds with Given the inherited RDA institution, deal-
other types of dictatorships.24 Perhaps more ing with political risk and technical uncer-
important than ideology, economic develop- tainty, a general reform strategy, marked
ment is regarded as essential for the survival by a local experiment-based c­ollective
of the regime. Yet, the much more challeng- central decision making process, emerged.
ing issue is to find a way to fulfill the objective Decision-making powers for trying out
of economic development. Essential issues concrete measures were delegated to sub-
of how to reform the economy and through national governments, whereas the cen-
which approach the economy should be or tral government kept control of s­trategic
can be developed were indeed highly con- political and economic issues (Deng
tentious among the top CCP leaders (Zhao 1984). This approach makes a consensus-
2009). Should the economy be developed by building-based decision making more
restoring the Soviet central planning model, progressive.26 Therefore, most strategic
decisions on China’s market reform were
24 According to Marx, one respect in which socialism is
better than capitalism is its higher capacity for advancing in the sense of neoclassical economics. In reality, all
“productive forces.” Thus, in order to prove the validity of socialist economies have substantially smaller shares of
the communist party’s doctrine, it is necessary to deliver a consumer consumptions in their GDPs than those of mar-
higher growth rate than those of capitalist economies. For ket economies. This indicates that growth maximization
this reason, most communist leaders in Soviet Union and of socialist economies is divorced from pursuing social
Eastern Europe, even including Mao in the 1950s, tried welfare. For further analysis and more details on forced
hard to make their economies to grow faster, although growth in socialist economies, see Kornai (1980, 1992).
they all failed eventually. The following argument of Deng 25 Deng, Zhao Ziyang, and Hu Yaobang etc. shared a
(1994b) well represents the ideology of the post 1978 CCP, pro-market approach, whereas Chen Yun, Li Xiannian, Bo
“to build socialism it is necessary to develop the productive Yibo, and Hua Guofeng etc. had a strong view insisting on
forces . . . Not until . . . we have reached the level of the mod- central planning (Deng 1984; Zhao 2009; Li 2008). On
erately developed countries, shall we be able to say that we political aspects, Hu and Zhao pushed for political plural-
have really built socialism and to declare convincingly that ism within the one-party system as a part of the reform.
it is superior to capitalism. We are advancing towards that Sometimes Chen Yun also proved more amenable to other
goal.” Indeed the multiple decades’ unsuccessful reform views for maintaining the party rule rather than promoting
efforts in Soviet Union and Eastern European countries political pluralism. However, Deng, Li, Bo, and most other
were all driven by their attempts to regain growth impe- elder CCP top leaders had strong views insisting on strict
tus in those economies. The collapse of the Soviet Union ideological control combined with repression of political
and the whole Eastern Bloc made the CCP top leaders feel dissidents (Zhao 2009; Li 2008; Tong Bao 2009). Here,
that continued economic development was crucial for the ideological control is essentially about the compliance to
survival of the regime. For example, former vice premier the voice of the CCP central leadership, rather than any
Tian Jiyun attributed the collapse of Soviet Union and the particular theory or doctrine.
Eastern Bloc to their decades’ failures in improving their 26 “The Chinese government bureaucracy . . . always
productivities (Mingming Du and Qingquan Xu 2009). Yet made decisions by consensus.” “Consensus decision mak-
it should be noted that, in both communist ideology and ing institutions tend to be conservative because radical
policy, neither “advancing productive forces” nor pursu- departures from the status quo are blocked by vetoes from
ing high growth rates implies social welfare maximization groups who stand to lose” (Shirk 1993, p. 15).
1092 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

made “collectively” in the form of com- often dominated other experiments in


promises among the top CCP leaders in a regional competitions, and most of the time
trial-and-error process. “Collective” here what matters most in the decision-making
has a broad meaning in that it includes also process is performance.
subnational officials’ contributions through This local experiment-based central
their local policy experiments. decision-making process also makes reform
Political challenges and resistance to a progress more stable, since the early reforms
reform are weakened when a new reform is created strong interest groups not only
tried only in a few regions as experiments, among central leaders but also among sub-
such as the special economic zone experi- national officials, particularly those who
ments (to be further discussed in section initiated “their own experiments.” Through
4.2). More importantly, for reforms bear- the basic operating mechanisms of the RDA
ing high political risks, the reformist cen- regime, the built-in interests and pro-reform
tral leaders could be vague without making interest groups among subnational officials
an explicit decision when local experiments became a valuable stabilizer for the reform
were allowed without an official endorse- policies. Another important decision pro-
ment, which implies a central leader will cess, which establishes the continuity of
not take serious responsibility if something reform policies in the long run, is the way
goes wrong with the experiment. The pro- the future central and subnational leaders
cess of the land reform in the early 1980s are selected (I will discuss this in the next
and privatization in the late 1990s, which part when I deal with the central–regional
were major breakthroughs if we compare relationship). Economic development as the
them with the two decades’ reforms in base of legitimacy for the CCP central lead-
CEE–FSU before 1989, are illustrations of ership has been reinforced during decades of
the advantage of local experimentation (to reforms. As a result, this objective is codified
be elaborated in sections 4.2 and 5.4). It is into the amended constitutions of the Party
also pragmatic because the CCP top lead- and the state. Capitalist entrepreneurs are
ers, including those who pioneered market officially regarded as part of “advanced social
reform in China, knew little about how to productive forces” and are recruited into the
transform the Chinese economy into a mar- party (the CPC Constitution, the 16th CPC
ket economy (Zhao 2009). It was much safer Congress 2002) (see Bruce J. Dickson 2003).
for them to follow some successfully tested The Chinese constitution has also been
reform measures than to implement some amended to protect private property rights
designed programs. (Constitutional Amendment 2004).
Moreover, regional competition helps to
2.2.2 Personnel Control
contain the impact of conservative ideology,
and thus is a de facto selection mechanism Personnel control is a major channel
in local experiment-based central decision through which the central government con-
making. Indeed, not all central and subna- trols, coordinates, and motivates subnational
tional officials are pro-market reformists officials. With this instrument, the Chinese
and not all local experiments are market RDA regime implements a centrally con-
reform trials. Just as Chinese regions are trolled decentralization in which most tasks
heterogeneous, there were all kinds of of reforms and economic development are
experiments being tried, from egalitarian carried out by subnational governments.
collectives to private businesses. However, On the one hand, regional officials control
outcomes of market reform experiments huge amounts of resources and they enjoy
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1093

fairly broad autonomies within their jurisdic- targets related to economic construction
tions; on the other hand, their career paths (Tsui and Wang 2004). In general, per-
are controlled by the central government. formance criteria are broader for leading
Specifically, appointments, promotions, and officials at higher-level subnational gov-
demotions (or more severe punishments, ernments, while the targets set for leading
such as imprisonment for serious violations officials at lower level subnational govern-
of the rules) of subnational officials in China ments tend to be more precisely defined.
are ultimately determined by the central According to a handbook issued by the
government, and their career paths are tied Party, work achievement accounts for 60
to the performance of their jurisdictions. to 70 percent of the evaluation of regional
This makes Chinese economy fundamentally officials, while other aspects, such as politi-
different from a federal system.27 cal integrity, competence and diligence
This personnel control system is a nested together account for the rest, 30 to 40 per-
network in which the center directly con- cent (Maria Edin 2003).
trols the key positions at provincial level and It is also documented that county govern-
grants each tier of subnational government ments control township and village officials
the power to appoint key officials one level by linking their performance to promotion
below it. Each level of subnational govern- (Susan H. Whiting 2000). In field works at
ment oversees the appointment, evaluation, township-level governments, it has been
promotion, and dismissal of its subordinate- found that party secretaries and township
level regional leaders. heads sign performance contracts with the
A set of performance criteria for lead- county level. In these contracts, township
ing officials at subnational governments officials pledge to achieve targets estab-
is stipulated by the level of government lished by county officials, and are held
above it. Regional officials are assessed in personally responsible for attaining those
accordance with the important tasks and targets. Performance targets are ranked in
targets laid down by their superior level three categories: soft targets, hard targets,
of governments. Level by level, each level and priority targets with veto power. Hard
of subnational government negotiates with targets tend to be economic, such as an eco-
their subordinate subnational government nomic development plan and tax revenue,
for performance targets. Then, regional whereas priority targets are often politi-
officials at different levels sign target cal, such as keeping social order. Fulfilling
responsibility contracts with their superi- hard targets is important for bonuses and
ors. The targets for the tasks to be attained for political rewards, whereas completion of
as well as rewards/penalties contingent on priority targets affects personnel decisions
the fulfillment of those targets are speci- (Edin 2003).
fied in those contracts (Kai-yuen Tsui and Moreover, competition between regional
Youqiang Wang 2004). For example, in a officials among the same level, such as at the
scheme for provincial leading officials, 60 county level or township level, is an essen-
percent of these leaders were assigned to tial part of the cadre management system. As
discovered in fieldwork in one county, lead-
27 It is interesting to note that this governance structure ing cadres of the first three ranked townships
of Chinese government, i.e., a combination of a centralized in the annual evaluation were recognized as
personnel control and a decentralized operation/imple- “advanced leaders,” whereas the bottom 5
mentation, shares some similarities with the Japanese cor-
porate governance structure, particularly before the 1990s percent of officials on the list were disgraced.
(Masahiko Aoki 1990). To be a top-ranking township leader and
1094 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

to be awarded with the title of “advanced former party secretaries of Suzhou, one of
leader” enhances the chances for promo- the best-performing municipalities in China,
tion substantially, and thus it is regarded as a were promoted to become provincial gover-
“political bonus.” Indeed, some first-ranked nors of Jiangsu, Shaanxi, and Jilin. Between
township officials were promoted within the 1998 and 2002, a former mayor of Wenzhou,
county (Edin 2003). another top-performing municipality, was
To enhance the effectiveness of the per- appointed as vice-governor and then gover-
sonnel control system, rotation and cross- nor of Sichuan (Shiuh-Shen Chien and Litao
region transfer are also deployed. The Zhao 2007).
practice of rotating provincial-level offi-
2.3 The Central–Regional Relationship
cials has always existed, and it has been
further institutionalized since the 1990s. The central–regional (or central–local)
The Central Committee of the CCP has relationship has always been one of the most
issued Party decrees on the rotation system important issues when considering China’s
in 1990, 1994, 1999, and 2006. The Party governance. Although the formal structure
decrees announce that a major purpose of is hierarchical between central and regional
rotating regional officials is to promote eco- governments, the authority of the central
nomic development through diffusion or government is endogenized insofar as the
duplication of regional reform experiences power of the national leadership depends
(Xu, Wang, and Shu 2007).28 Directed by on the collective support of the regional
this policy, during the period between 1978 leaders as well. This sophisticated structure
and 2005, about 80 percent of governors plays important roles in the operation of the
were promoted or transferred from other RDA regime, such as continuing effective
provinces, i.e., many of them were not pro- national macroeconomic policies, encourag-
moted within the same province. The aver- ing regional initiatives, and balancing cen-
age duration of their tenures within a given tral–local interests.
province is close to four years, while rang- One of the most important governance
ing from as little as one year to as many as mechanisms of the RDA regime is the
ten years (Xu, Wang, and Shu 2007). selection process for the future central and
It has been documented that, during the subnational leaders. The process includes
reform era, rotation was often combined nominations and approvals. Nomination
with promotion. The rotation/promotion by top leaders is necessary for anyone to
combination was frequently used to pro- become a central leader candidate, but
mote mayors of successful municipalities to nomination alone provides no guarantee
be governors of other provinces, particularly for the future of the candidates. A nominee
underperforming provinces. This promotion must convince most of the top leaders that
path creates incentives for regional lead- he both shares their core values and prin-
ers to work hard. Moreover, this may also ciples, and he has the capability to perform.
serve as a mechanism to diffuse success- As such, excellent performance at the pro-
ful regional experimentation (I will further vincial level becomes necessary for anyone
discuss regional experiments in section 4). to be nominated and eventually promoted as
For example, between 1998 and 2004, three a top leader. Although this requirement may
not be codified formally, without a single
28 Historically, rotation was a common practice in the
exception, from 1992 to 2008 every presi-
Chinese Empire to prevent regional officials from cultivat- dent, every premier, and every newly elected
ing strong political power bases within their jurisdictions. Politbureau Standing Committee member of
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1095

the four CCP congresses29 during this period gaps in other issues—the delegation of
was promoted from a provincial position; power to regional governments is also highly
i.e., none of them were from a ministerial or incomplete (a la Katharina Pistor and Xu
other central agency position. The appoint- 2003). For most issues, as long as the central
ment of subnational level officials follows a government does not have an explicit policy,
somewhat similar consensus-based selection by default the regional governments would
process, with intensive interactions between be in the position to make decisions within
upper and lower-level governments. In addi- their jurisdiction. However, the central gov-
tion to major impacts on both the subna- ernment retains the power to intervene. The
tional officials’ career paths and the pool of incompleteness of personnel control and
future top national leader candidacy, these power delegation is partly a result of com-
procedures also act as institutions that bal- promises and partly a design for encouraging
ance national and regional interests. more local initiatives from local govern-
Supported by commonly shared col- ments, while still remaining open to central
lective interests among most national and control. At the same time, this regime also
subnational officials, the central leadership makes it possible for subnational govern-
enjoys considerable authority over poten- ments to maneuver against, rather than to
tially disobedient regional leaders. With simply comply, with policies of the central
this authority, the central government takes government.
a tough stand to make the subnational gov- To understand the distinctive feature of
ernments comply on the most important China’s RDA regime, such as the enable-
issues, such as national (or political) unity ment of local governments, it is worthwhile
and macro stability. Personnel control is to point out its origin and its robustness in
often used as the last resort for enforce- history. The basic governance structure of
ment to guarantee the implementation of China’s RDA regime originated from the
central policies.30 birth of the Chinese empire and has evolved
At the same time, as previously discussed, over two thousand years, which has sup-
the central government is often fairly hands- ported the empire to last so much longer
off on regional economic issues. Subnational than all other empires in world history,31 and
governments are granted sizable de jure has a long lasting impact on the governance
control rights and endowed with even of today’s China.32
greater de facto control rights over most Designed at the beginning of the Qin
economic issues and resources within their Dynasty (221 BC), subnational government
jurisdictions. Together with a highly incom-
plete personnel control regime—although 31 It is well known that institutions of most of the coun-
it is highly structured and effective, it is tries in the world have a European origin through their
ambiguous on many issues and there are imperial histories, e.g., the United Kingdom and France;
or colonial histories, e.g., the Americas, Africa, and South
Asia; or voluntary adoptions of the European institutions,
e.g., Russia, Japan. But it is well noticed that China has
29 A common practice of the CCP is to put the neither been colonized by Europe nor adopted European
selected next top leader(s) into the Politbureau Standing institutions systematically before the 1950s, when it
Committee. adopted an institution from the Soviet Union. This is the
30 When a few regional leaders defy the central gov- underlying reason why, on many facets, China looks incon-
ernment and challenge the power of the central govern- sistent with the regularities discovered in cross-country
ment, they are punished severely. Recent examples include studies.
the dismissal and imprisonment of the former mayor of 32 Indeed Mao frequently referred to the governance
Beijing, Chen Xitong, in 1995, and the former mayor of approach of imperial times, perhaps more than his discus-
Shanghai, Chen Liangyu, in 2006. sions on Marxism and the Soviet system.
1096 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

Emperor

Central adm. function Territorial control

Personnel Finance Justice Industry Province A Province B Province C

Personnel Finance Justice Industry

Figure 3. Stylized Governance Structure of Imperial China

officials were appointed by the Emperor (Gang Bai 1996).33 A caveat is in order that
(Qian Sima 1993 [109 BC]). This assures the during imperial times there was no political
emperor’s strategic control over the nation. party, such as the CCP, which makes today’s
Given the primitiveness in communication RDA regime historically unique.
and transportation at that time, most local The consensus-based decision-making
affairs were delegated to subnational gov- process and personal control system of
ernments, conditional on their loyalty to the the RDA regime provide mechanisms for
Emperor. To enable subnational govern- upholding a balance between economic
ments’ effective control, they are assigned decentralization and political compliance.
with self-contained functions that each of These mechanisms allow the regime to
them was able to coordinate operations evolve while keeping the central–regional
within its jurisdiction. This is true at all levels relationship basically stable.34 There were
of subnational governments. To illustrate the deep worries that delegating economic pow-
self-contained governance structure at every ers to regions undermined the capacity of
level of subnational governments, figure 3 the central power (Shaoguang Wang 1995).
depicts a stylized structure similar to that of And in the early period of the reform, the
imperial China during the Ming and Qing
dynasties (1368–1910) in which the empire 33 The six ministries at the central government are
divided the central government’s functions Ministries of Personnel (li), Finance (hu), Civil Service
into six ministries. The most important min- Exam and Foreign Affaires (li), Military (bing), Justice
(xing), and Manufacturing (gong), i.e., li-hu-li-bing-xing-
istry was Personnel (li bu), which deter- gong liu-bu. The six similar offices at each county govern-
mined the appointment and promotion of ment are li-hu-li-bing-xing-gong liu-fang. Here, bu and
central and provincial officials. This structure fang are in bold to highlight the difference between the
central government (six ministries, liu-bu) and a local gov-
extends to the bottom administrative level, ernment (six offices, liu-fang).
the county level. Just like in the central gov- 34 It has been reported that during the reform era, in

ernment and at the provincial level, a typical a period of more than two decades, the provincial share
in the Politburo of the CCP increased slightly; meanwhile,
county (xian) government controlled the six the provincial share in the Central Committee of the CCP
corresponding offices within its jurisdiction declined by a similar magnitude (Yumin Sheng 2005).
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1097

time associated with much regional decen- were compensated by other means, such as
tralization, the central government’s share of extra-budgetary and nonbudgetary revenues
national total fiscal revenue declined substan- (Wong 1997), and their losses in controlling
tially. When the economy was growing rap- bank lending were compensated by stronger
idly and some regional governments enjoyed controls over land and state assets within
high surpluses, the national government ran their jurisdictions (subsection 6.1 discusses
deficits and had to borrow from some prov- the consequences of these changes).
inces. Moreover, central power could be
2.4 General Remarks
further weakened by the enfranchisement
of regional leaders in Party institutions dur- The decision-making process of China’s
ing national-level successions (Shirk 1993).35 RDA regime relies on building consensuses
It was argued that capacity of the central among the top leaders—often including pro-
government was undermined so severely vincial leaders—and regional experiments,
during the reform era that this weakened which keeps a balance between national and
capacity threatened Chinese political unity regional interests. This mechanism generates
in a manner similar to the situation before outcomes that are somewhat similar to what
the disintegration of Yugoslavia (Wang and occurs through negotiations in a legislative
Angang Hu 2001). Responding to the wors- body. Moreover, together with the selection
ened central fiscal capacity and weakened process of national and subnational leaders,
central control over bank lending—which these mechanisms nurture interest groups
led to central government deficits, excessive of market-oriented and growth-oriented
lending, and inflation in the early 1990s—the reforms within the party, which contributes to
central government increased its political stable market reforms over several decades.
and administrative control over provincial Although China’s RDA regime is evolved
government leaders to coordinate and imple- from China’s unique history (e.g., the longest
ment national economic policies (Huang imperial history in the world and the unprec-
1996a, 1996b; Naughton and Yang 2004; edented events of the Cultural Revolution),
Landry 2008). During this time, the central which makes its policy lessons less rel-
government took away some powers from evant directly for other countries, there
subnational governments. Tax collection was are important general lessons for debates
recentralized in 1994, and control over bank on decentralization. Firstly, for developing
lending was also shifted away from subna- and transition economies, focusing on fis-
tional governments (Tsui and Wang 2004). cal decentralization can be misleading for
However, this fiscal recentralization did not both understanding and policies. Secondly,
fundamentally change the RDA regime and extreme decentralization in general may not
did not terminate regional decentralization. be optimal. If China went down a path of
These should instead be viewed as efforts extreme decentralization in which all prov-
to maintain a balance between the interests inces became completely autonomous except
of national and subnational governments. in military and foreign affairs, even assuming
Regional governments’ losses in tax revenue away potential political instability, without
an active central government all the benefits
from the combination of collective decision
35 Shirk (1993) argues that the content and sequencing making and regional experimentation would
of China’s economic reforms are determined by the ongo- disappear; negative externalities across
ing succession struggles of the Party, whereas devolution
gave central politicians the opportunity to win the gratitude regions would become prevailing; and no
and the political support of officials from the provinces. one would take care of positive externalities
1098 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

across regions. Moreover, the nature of with intrinsic motivations to reform, the only
regional competition and regional experi- incentive that needs to be devised is to give
ments would be fundamentally weakened (to them the power to initiate and to imple-
be discussed in sections 3 and 4). ment reforms. However, extra incentives,
i.e., extrinsic incentives, are necessary for
most subnational officials to take risks and
3.  Regional Competition and Subnational
to work hard for reforms. Furthermore, very
Governments’ Incentives for Reforms
often well-devised extrinsic incentives can
A distinctive feature of China’s reform is induce stronger intrinsic incentives and vice
the vital roles played by highly motivated versa, so that the two incentives often rein-
subnational governments. Governors Zhao force each other at equilibrium (a la Roland
Ziyang of Sichuan and Wan Li of Anhui Bénabou and Jean Tirole 2003). By the same
initiated land reform experiments in a few logic, poorly devised or destructive extrin-
localities within their jurisdictions in the sic incentives could weaken or even destroy
late 1970s when the national policy, includ- intrinsic motivations for reforms. In this sec-
ing the Party’s “reform” manifesto, did not tion, I will focus on the extrinsic incentives
allow any ownership change to collective provided to Chinese subnational officials.
farming. Similarly, governor Xi Zhongxun of My major argument is that interregional
Guangdong proposed the special economic competition has motivated subnational
zone reform while some top central leaders officials to push forward reforms. Chinese
were hostile to this reform plan (sections 4 regions (provinces, municipalities, counties,
will elaborate on this below). Later, when and townships) compete against each other
those locally initiated reforms were endorsed for performance rankings and regional offi-
by the central government as national poli- cials’ careers are linked to their performance
cies, the reforms were implemented by in the “tournaments.” 36
all levels of government nationwide. After As bureaucrats appointed by their upper
the initial success of the regional reforms, level governments, most Chinese subnational
these reform pioneers were all promoted to officials are very much motivated by their
national level posts. Zhao and Wan became career concerns, which are basically about
the premier and executive deputy premier climbing ladders within the government
of the state council, respectively, respon- hierarchy. Through this channel, the central
sible for national reform; Xi became a vice government affects the ultimate incentives of
Chairman of the National People’s Congress. the subnational officials. It is noteworthy that
As the pioneers and architects of regional this mechanism is fundamentally different
reform, the political risks they faced were from the well-known jurisdictional Tiebout
substantial. The key issue I will address in competition, or in general fiscal jurisdic-
this section is how subnational government tional competition in the fiscal federalism
officials are motivated to initiate and to
implement reforms. Without a solution to 36 The most popular performance indicators used in
incentive problems of government officials regional rankings are GDP (total or per capita), GDP
at all levels of government, reform would growth rate, and FDI. In addition, some other indica-
tors, such as regional competitiveness in various aspects,
not be carried out successfully or potentially are also widely reported. For example, in a recent rank-
not even be attempted. There is no question ing, Shanghai, Beijing, and Guangdong were ranked as the
that some reformists have intrinsic personal first, second, and third most competitive regions in China
in 2007, which is unchanged from those in 2006; whereas
motivations (a la Canice Prendergast 2007) inland provinces Anhui and Hubei improved their rankings
to push forward reforms. For those officials significantly (Xinhua 10/03/2008).
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1099

literature. The latter has nothing to do with incentives to regional officials for regional
the internal promotion of the local govern- economic growth, as can be seen in most
ment officials. Instead, local officials are other countries. What makes China special
driven by their fiscal motives, e.g., maximiz- in providing strong incentives to regional
ing property values within their jurisdictions officials for economic development?
by attracting additional residents (Charles Furthermore, there are serious potential
M. Tiebout 1956; Wallace E. Oates 1999) or problems associated with decentralization,
by winning votes from their constituencies such as regional protection and regional
(Dennis Epple and Allan Zelenitz 1981). environment problems. What are the con-
ditions under which regional competition
3.1 The Institutional Foundation for
leads to desirable outcomes?
Regional Tournament Competition
To address the first question, let me start
In this subsection, I elucidate how China’s with a summary of the major features of
RDA institution creates the conditions for Chinese institutions that facilitate regional
regional competition, as well as the trade- competition. First, Chinese subnational
offs of this regional competition. When the officials are subject to incentive schemes
reform era started in the late 1970s, regional managed by the central government. With
governments were encouraged to find ways centralized personnel management for sub-
to develop faster than other regions. Policies national officials, regional competition under
on special economic zones and other eco- this institutional structure is qualitatively
nomic development zones were imple- different from fiscal federalist regional com-
mented, enabling subnational governments’ petition in which local officials are elected
competition for investments. Regions com- (Epple and Zelenitz 1981). Second, the
pete for economic growth and for attracting Chinese national government not only pos-
FDI, etc. Since the mid-1980s, many better- sesses superior powers of appointment,
performing counties were upgraded to the promotion, and dismissal of subordinate
municipal level, which further enabled and government officials, but it is also strong
empowered these local governments. At the enough to eliminate collusions between
same time, this city status upgrading also lower level subnational governments. This
provides high incentives to all the county preserves tournament-like regional com-
governments to compete for the opportu- petition since collusion among subnational
nity to be promoted. Government statistics officials can make competition impossible.
and mass media regularly publish rankings Third, Chinese regions, particularly county-
of regional performance, which become an level or higher-level regions, have historically
important part of evaluations for determin- been and remain relatively self-sufficient in
ing the promotions of subnational govern- that each region contains multiple economic
ment officials. sectors. Therefore, most Chinese regions are
In contrast to the prevalence of regional alike in their economic structures, which is a
competition and initiatives taken by subna- critical condition for tournament like com-
tional governments in Chinese reforms, offi- petition to function (discussed in more detail
cials in other reforming countries or other below). Moreover, this greatly weakens
transitional economies were not given simi- interdependence among Chinese regions
lar competitive incentives and they were, in and enables subnational governments to
general, less active in taking initiatives than coordinate most of the economic activities
their Chinese counterparts. Yet, decentral- within their jurisdictions. Finally, Chinese
ization does not automatically create strong subnational governments are both enabled
1100 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

and empowered to take responsibility for the specific mechanism that makes regional
economies within their jurisdictions. They competition effective in China? And what
are granted a fairly high degree of autonomy prevented the FSU-CEE countries from
on economic activities. Enablement and deploying a similar approach?
empowerment themselves are vital sources As in any incentive theory, the outcomes
of incentives. Ultimately, incentives for offi- of the tasks are determined jointly by the
cials can play important roles only when managing efforts of the relevant officials
those officials are enabled and empowered and outside random factors. The officials’
to take reform initiatives or growth-enhanc- efforts are not observable to others and are
ing measures, etc. costly to them; therefore, when there is no
The theoretical model of Maskin, Qian, proper incentive scheme, there will be no
and Xu (2000) highlights the relationship reform efforts. It is known that when facing
between China’s RDA regime and high- unobservable efforts, tournament competi-
powered incentives associated with regional tion can motivate agents better than other
competition, which includes tournament- incentives schemes (e.g., Edward P. Lazear
like competition.37 The stylized hierarchi- and Sherwin Rosen 1981). However, an
cal organization modeled by Maskin, Qian, effective tournament competition requires
and Xu captures the feature of the RDA that the tasks of the agents should be similar
regime.38 There are two types of authori- and that the outside random factors faced by
tarian structures considered in the model: the agents should follow the same distribu-
a multiregional organizational form tion. The rigidness of these conditions makes
(M-form), such as China, in which there are these models hard to apply directly to real-
two unspecialized subnational regions, each world institutions.
of which is assigned to manage similar tasks The Maskin, Qian, and Xu model extends
such as manufacturing and agriculture; and the basic idea of tournament competition
a unitary form (U-form), such as the former to different institutions organized in differ-
Soviet Union before 1991, in which there ent ways, which determines how tasks are
are two specialized subnational units— assigned and how information is used by
ministries—each of which is assigned with each official. These in turn determine the
managing a specialized task such as manu- effectiveness of different incentive schemes
facturing or agriculture. In contrast with for the officials in the regime. Given that
China, in those economies there were no Chinese regions are alike in their economic
ministerial or regional competitions in compositions, which implies that shocks
reform measures or growth-enhancing to regions are highly correlated, by assign-
efforts, even though they started reforms ing similar tasks to regional officials and
much earlier than China. The Maskin, delegating power to them in order to carry
Qian, and Xu model focuses on incentive out regional reforms, regional competition
issues of subnational officials in order to among them can serve as an effective incen-
address the following questions: What is tive scheme. To understand the mechanism,
let us suppose a governor performs poorly
37 Interpreting the Maskin, Qian, and Xu model as a
and tries to blame the outcome on bad luck
mechanism of the RDA regime is my personal view. in his region. This excuse is unconvincing,
38 In addition to authoritarian regimes, the Maskin, however, if all other similar regions are pros-
Qian, and Xu model also applies to large corporations. This pering. Therefore, facing the comparison (or
is not coincidental as the Chinese authoritarian regime is
sometimes regarded as corporate technocrat-ship or cor- competition) with other regions should force
poratism in the literature (e.g., Jean C. Oi 1999). every governor to work hard.
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1101

On the contrary, if subnational units are industrial shocks are denoted as ε​ 1​ ​and ​ε2​ ​.
highly specialized so that they are not com- The information relevant to the incentives
parable or if tasks assigned to every official of the two ministers is summarized by the
are idiosyncratic, which implies that shocks conditional variances Var (​ε​1​|​ε2​ ​) for minister
to these tasks are not correlated, such as 1 and Var (​ε​2​|​ε1​ ​) for minister 2. For an econ-
ministries in former Soviet Union and omy organized in M-form, the middle offi-
Central-Eastern Europe before 1989, it is cials are governors responsible for regions
easy for a minister to blame a poor outcome A and B, and the corresponding regional
on bad luck in his industrial sector and it is shocks are denoted as ​εA​ ​and ε​ ​B​. The infor-
difficult to object to his excuse, given that mation relevant to the governors’ incentives
performance is imperfectly correlated with is summarized by the conditional variances
officials’ efforts. That is, ministerial tourna- Var (​ε​A​|​εB​ ​) for governor A and Var(​ε​B​|​εA​ ​) for
ment will not be efficient when tasks and governor B.
information of ministries are sufficiently dif- Therefore, if Var(​ε​1​|​ε2​ ​) > Var(​ε​A​|​εB​ ​), then
ferent from each other. Therefore, although the information quality for evaluating gov-
distributions of industry-specific shocks and ernor A in the M-form is higher than that
of region-specific shocks are exogenous, they for minister 1 in the U-form. In general, if
affect officials’ incentives differently under Var (​ε​i​|εj) > Var (​εr​​|​εs​​) (hereafter this condi-
different organizational forms. tion will be referred to as condition A), for
Two types of incentives are analyzed in the all i, j = 1, 2 and for all r, s = A, B, we will
Maskin, Qian, and Xu model: the absolute conclude that, everything else being equal,
performance incentive, which ties an offi- regional competition with relative perfor-
cial’s compensation to his own outputs, and mance evaluations under the M-form is more
the relative performance incentive, which effective than ministerial competition under
links an official’s compensation to other’s the U-form. Therefore, the M-form will be
outputs in a negative way. The absolute able to provide better incentives to their
performance incentive is inversely related governors than the U-form for ministers. Of
to the noise level of each official’s own per- course, if condition A is reversed for every
formance, while the relative performance pair-wise comparison, the conclusion will
incentive is positively related to the correla- be reversed. Therefore, ultimately, whether
tion between the performances of two offi- regional decentralization is more beneficial
cials. In summarizing the two factors, the than a centralized regime is an empirical
incentives of officials in any regime depend matter, and the Maskin, Qian, and Xu model
on the variance–covariance matrices of the provides a methodology to test it.
exogenous random shocks. Fortunately, the
3.2 Evidence
essential information of variance–covariance
matrices can be sufficiently compressed into Three forms of systematic evidences
a scalar, the conditional variation measure- on the relationship between China’s RDA
ment. A smaller conditional variation implies regime and regional competition will be pre-
a smaller variation and a larger correlation, sented in this subsection. The first evidence
i.e., a higher quality of information for incen- concerns whether or not China’s RDA regime
tive purposes. provides better conditions, in terms of con-
In a highly simplified version of the model, dition A, for jurisdictional competition than
for an economy organized in U-form, the a centralized authoritarian regime. Then, I
middle officials will be ministries responsible survey evidence that regional competition
for industries 1 and 2; and the corresponding provides incentives to regional officials. The
1102 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

last evidence suggests that China’s RDA Similarly, using data covering 344 top pro-
regime has made a significant contribution vincial leaders (187 party secretaries and 157
to China’s growth. governors) from China’s twenty-eight prov-
Using a firm-level dataset of Chinese inces for the period from 1979 to 2002, Ye
state-owned enterprises from 1986 to 1991, Chen, Hongbin Li, and Li-An Zhou (2005)
Maskin, Qian, and Xu find that Chinese find that provincial officials’ performances
regions are indeed “alike” in the sense that relative to the national average and to their
regional competition should work better immediate predecessors had significant
than ministerial competition. The dataset impacts on their promotions (columns 5 and
contains industry classification codes and 6 in table 3). The left-side variable of all the
location codes for each firm, and industry- regressions in the table 3 is turnover, i.e.,
specific shocks and region-specific shocks the probability of termination, staying at the
are estimated by running the log-linear same level, or promotion.
Cobb–Douglas production function. This Using a panel dataset covering 254 pro-
allows for calculation of regional and indus- vincial leaders (provincial party secretaries
trial conditional variations. In their sample, and governors) who served in twenty-eight
70 percent of the results satisfied condition A Chinese provincial units from 1979 to 1995,
and there is no single case that the condition Li and Zhou (2005) find that regional offi-
A is reversed. cials’ promotions are determined by the
To address the question of whether rela- performance of their jurisdiction relative to
tive performance evaluations are actually the national average. Everything else being
used in China, Maskin, Qian, and Xu investi- equal, for those provinces that surpass the
gate the relationship between the promotion average growth rate by one standard devia-
of regional officials and regional economic tion from the mean, their leader would
performance. They use regional represen- increase the probability of his promotion
tation in the CCP’s Central Committee as a by 33 percent of the average probability of
proxy for the promotion chances of officials promotion; and those that performed worse
in that region and measure the economic than the mean by one standard deviation
performance of a region by its growth rate would increase the probability of termina-
in national income. Then they investigate tion by 30 percent of the average probability
how the improvement of a region’s perfor- of termination (columns 3 and 4 in table 3).
mance relative to other regions would later In the table, the punishment for the worst
affect the promotion of this region’s officials. performers is shown as an estimated coef-
Specifically, they constructed a national rank- ficient with cut-off point 1. Overall, the
ing index of each province’s representation at marginal effects of growth performance on
the 11th Party Congress in 1977 and in the turnover are large.
13th Party Congress in 1987, and constructed By separating provincial party secretaries
a national ranking index of provincial eco- from governors, Sheng (2009) finds evidence
nomic performance lagged by one year, as that provincial GDP growth mattered for the
measured by growth rates in the year before political fortunes of governors but not those
the Party Congress, that is, in 1976 and in of party secretaries. This may capture the
1986. The evidence shows that officials from division of labor between party secretaries
relatively better-performing regions have a and governors in the RDA regime given that
better chance of being promoted, suggesting the former were responsible for party affairs,
that tournament-like regional competition is such as personnel control, whereas the latter
at work. were put in charge of running the provincial
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1103

Table 3
The Effect of Economic Performance on the Turnover of Provincial Leaders
(Ordered probit regressions)

Dependent variable: turnover (0 = termination,


1 = same level, 2 = promotion)

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Provincial annual GDP 1.615** 1.581*


  growth rate (2.05) (1.87)
Provincial average GDP 4.727*** 4.540***
  growth rate (4.34) (3.90)
Provincial average per capita 3.001**
  GDP growth rate (A) (2.10)
Provincial average per capita −3.584**
  GDP growth rate of the (2.36)
  immediate (B) predecessor (B)
(A)−(B) 3.309***
(3.41)
Age −0.026* −0.023* −0.071*** −0.070***
(−1.91) (−1.68) (6.81) (6.77)
Age 65 −0.974*** −0.976*** −0.303** −0.303**
(−5.27) (−5.25) (2.07) (2.07)
Education 0.154 0.187 0.183 0.184
(0.96) (1.17) (1.48) (1.50)
Central connection 0.384*** 0.404*** 0.082 0.085
(2.79) (2.89) (0.74) (0.77)
Tenure −0.053* −0.055* −0.062** −0.062**
(−1.74) (−1.78) (2.44) (2.45)
Lagged per capita GDP 0.080 0.010
  (million yuan) (0.43) (0.05)
Cutoff point 1 −1.320*** −3.162*** −2.850*** −2.850*** −6.992*** −6.929***
(−3.67) (−2.98) (−2.64) (−2.63) (8.42) (8.66)
Cutoff point 2 1.621*** 0.106 0.455 0.455 −3.736*** −3.662***
(4.63) (1.01) (0.43) (0.43) (4.64) (4.70)
Number of observations 864 864 864 864 1,227 1,227

Notes: The numbers in parentheses are t-ratios based on robust standard errors. The significance levels of 1 percent,
5 percent, and 10 percent are noted by ***, **, and *. All regressions include the provincial and year indicators.
Columns (1)–(4) are based on Li and Zhou (2005). Columns (5) and (6) are based on Chen, Li, and Zhou (2005).
1104 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

economy. Nevertheless, considering the fact autonomy and are treated separately from
that most provincial party secretaries served the province in which they are located. Since
previously as governors, their records on 1984, fourteen cities have obtained deputy
provincial economic performance must have provincial rank (Yupeng Shi and Zhou 2007).
already played a role in their promotion to Using a large panel data set covering all
become secretaries. counties in China from 1993 to 2004, after
Of course, the promotion of regional offi- controlling for the official upgrading require-
cials is not solely determined by their perfor- ments, such as industrialization, population,
mances in economic affairs. In most columns and fiscal strength, Li (2011) finds that,
of table 3, many of the noneconomic perfor- everything else being equal, counties with a
mance factors are controlled. One of them higher growth rate were more likely to get
is the impact of regional officials’ connec- city status. He interprets this as evidence that
tions with the central government on their upgrading is used by the central government
promotion, which is measured by their as an incentive mechanism to align regional
previous or current work experience in the interests with the national ones. Shi and Zhou
central government. The central connec- (2007) show that everything else being equal,
tion indicator has a positive and significant cities obtaining deputy provincial rank, i.e., a
impact. Comparing columns 3 and 4 with greater degree of autonomy, increased per
columns 1 and 2 of table 3 indicate that pro- capita GDP by an additional 9.3 percent, per
motion and termination appear more sensi- capita FDI by more than 50 percent, and
tive to the average growth rate than to the per capita investment by about 80 percent.
annual growth rate. They suggest that the This indicates that enabling and empower-
long-run or average measure weigh more in ing subnational governments by granting
turnover decisions than those of short-term them more autonomy power together with
shocks. high-powered incentives enhances regional
In addition to providing incentives through economic growth effectively.
appointment and promotion within the All of the above surveyed papers do not
hierarchical structure, the decentralization- pay special attention to the potential reverse
based reforms also further delegate autono- causality problem, except for applying some
mies to subnational governments through time lags. One might challenge these find-
various channels. One of those is the city ings by imagining that a governor who was
status upgrading scheme. In the city status already picked to assume important posi-
upgrading scheme, municipal governments tions in the central government in the future
are granted more administrative authority being assigned to a province with fast eco-
and the political position of a city is raised, nomic growth to show his performance.
thus more strongly incentivizing its officials. That is, instead of career concern motivating
One of these kinds of practices is to upgrade regional development, the findings may be
some county governments as city govern- interpreted as placing favorable future lead-
ments (county-to-city upgrading). From ers into easy performing regions to justify
1983 to 2001, 430 county-level cities were their later promotion.
established, mostly by upgrading (Lixing Indeed, a clear-cut econometric study
Li 2011). Another method is to upgrade that rules out a reverse causality has yet to
some prefecture level municipalities to the be done. Nevertheless, if we combine all the
deputy provincial rank city, which is offi- results from the literature, the overall pic-
cially called separately itemized cities (jihua ture should be reasonably convincing that
danlie), meaning that they enjoy substantial a reverse causality is not most likely. First,
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1105

to improve the chance of being promoted, R. Weingast 1995). China is often seen as a
a governor not only should perform better major example of market-preserving fiscal
than average (Li and Zhou result); but also federalism (Gabriella Montinola, Qian, and
should be better than his/her immediate Weingast 1995; Qian and Weingast 1997;
predecessor (Chen, Li, and Zhou results), Hehui Jin, Qian, and Weingast 2005).
which makes the reversed causality argu- At the same time, there is also a fairly siz-
ment uneasy. Second, if a governor per- able literature that challenges fiscal federal-
formed really poorly for several years, the ism on many aspects. First, interjurisdictional
likelihood of his/her losing the governorship competition for capital may lead to a “race-
is substantially increased. It is hard to imag- to-the bottom” in local tax rates or in reduced
ine that poor performance for many years is provision of some local public goods (Michael
unrelated to this governor’s own actions. Keen and Maurice Marchand 1997). It may
Finally, in the analysis and evidence dis- prompt local governments to exploit possible
cussed in sections 3.1 and 3.2, the govern- spillover to other jurisdictions, exporting taxes
ment is focused on economic growth or or pollution to their neighbors (Roger H.
growth-enhancing reforms. Under this con- Gordon 1983; Oates and Robert M. Schwab
dition, tournament-like regional competi- 1988), and central government intervention
tion creates powerful positive incentives to may be necessary to solve such problems
subnational officials. However, when the (John H. Cumberland 1981; Gordon 1983;
government’s task is expanded to many other Alice M. Rivlin 1992; David E. Wildasin
potentially conflicting tasks, such as manag- 1989). Without a strong central government,
ing inequality, protecting environment, and fiscal federalism alone will not lead to effi-
maintaining social stability, regional com- cient results and will not be market preserving
petition may create strong negative effects. (Olivier Blanchard and Andrei Shleifer 2001).
This is discussed in section 6. Second, interregional competition for capital
may encourage subnational governments to
3.3 Chinese Regional Competition and the
act in ways that corrode the capacities of the
Debate on Fiscal Federalism
central state such that fiscal federalism will
There is a large literature that debates not be market preserving (Hongbin Cai and
whether the quality of public fiscal policy Daniel Treisman 2004, 2005).
can be improved through regional compe- Evidence from cross-country studies is
tition or fiscal federalism in general. The mixed: fiscal federalism in many countries
seminal Tiebout model (1956) shows that often is found to be inefficient (Francesca
jurisdictional competition among subna- Fornasari, Steven B. Webb, and Heng-fu Zou
tional governments can make the provision 1999; Jonathan Rodden 2002; Rodden and
of public goods more efficient. Along this Susan Rose-Ackerman 1997). Furthermore,
line of thinking, a market-preserving fiscal arguments have been made and evidence
federalism develops an argument that says has been found to show that Chinese fiscal
that, under certain conditions, fiscal federal- decentralization is neither self-enforcing
ism is self-enforcing and is market preserv- nor market preserving (Wong 1991; Cai and
ing. The core mechanism is the commitment Treisman 2005; Tsui and Wang 2004).
mechanism created by certain fiscal federal- However, this kind of debate could be mis-
ism that prevents the national government leading if one ignores the fundamental differ-
from intervention, which in turn provides ence between the Chinese RDA regime and
proper incentives to government officials at a federal state. In the Tiebout branch of fis-
all levels to encourage market growth (Barry cal federalism theory, the economic gains to
1106 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

subnational officials from attracting additional basic condition of ­market-preserving fiscal


residents is central (Tiebout 1956; Oates federalism is violated is the recentralization
1999), voice or exit. In a more general version of tax-collection power after more than a
of fiscal federalism, subnational government decade of fiscal decentralization. Facing a
officials are elected and they are accountable decline on the central government’s fiscal
to their constituencies (Epple and Zelenitz revenue while the economy was growing
1981). In contrast, Chinese officials face no rapidly (Wong 1991), in 1994 a reversal of
pressure due to voice, exit, or election, sug- the fiscal decentralization took place in cen-
gesting they should perform poorly. Yet, they tral government’s attempts to overcome this
face strong incentives to meet the promotion problem (Tsui and Wang 2004). As a result,
criteria defined by higher officials. Under the share of subnational governments’ tax
certain conditions, these promotion incen- revenue in national tax revenue was reduced
tives could be strong enough to replace the substantially from 70 percent to 40 percent
incentives derived from voice, exit, or elec- (World Bank 2002). This implies there is no
tion. But this is not always the case as some commitment to limiting the central author-
later sections will discuss. ity’s power in fiscal policy.
Moreover, the condition of market-pre- In addition to the nature of the basic
serving fiscal federalism requires that “[t]he institution, there is an important technical
allocation of authority and responsibility has assumption necessary for Tiebout competi-
an institutionalized degree of durability so tion to work: factor mobility. Similarly, one of
that it cannot be altered by the national gov- the five fundamental conditions of market-
ernment” (Montinola, Qian, and Weingast preserving fiscal federalism requires that
1995, p. 55).39 This requirement “provides “[t]he national government has the authority
for credible commitment to the federal to police the common market and to ensure
system and thus for limits on the national the mobility of goods and factors across
government’s discretionary authority. Not sub-government jurisdictions” (Montinola,
only must there be decentralization, but Qian, and Weingast 1995). However, when
that decentralization must not be under the reforms started regions competed fiercely
discretionary control of the national govern- without factor mobility, and factors gradu-
ment” (Montinola, Qian, and Weingast 1995, ally became more mobile as a result of
p. 55). This is “a necessary component of the reform—not as a starting point of the
federalism’s market-preserving qualities” reform. For example, labor in China has
(Montinola, Qian, and Weingast 1995, p. 57). only become partially mobile since the mid
However, under the Chinese constitution 1990s (John Whalley and Shunming Zhang
and in line with general Chinese government 2004). Moreover, capital is even more immo-
policies—both de jure and de facto—the bile than labor, and segmentation of capital
central government preserves its discretion- markets is still a problem today (Gordon
ary power over regions, and this power has and Li 2003). Although the direction of the
been exercised during the reform era (PRC trend of trade barriers across regions and the
Constitution 1982 Amendment, see Xu direction of the trend of factor mobility are
2005; PRC Constitution 2004 Amendment, debatable subjects, the existence of severe
see Chubanshe 2009; Andrew C. Mertha factor immobility and regional trade barriers
2005). A prominent example in which this in China is indisputable (Alwyn Young 2000;
Naughton 2003; Chong-En Bai et al. 2004).
39 Kellee S. Tsai (2004) argues that China violates basic Within the theoretical framework of fis-
assumptions of market-preserving federalism. cal federalism, a violation of factor mobility
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1107

makes interjurisdictional competition among governments are responsible for much


regions impossible. Without factor mobility, broader roles in the economy, of which fiscal
citizens would not be able to “vote with their policies are only a subset. Therefore, apply-
feet,” and thus there would be no Tiebout ing fiscal federalism models that focus on fis-
competition. Similarly, in the framework of cal policy alone will miss large parts of the
market-preserving fiscal federalism, inter- reforms and will not be able to explain China’s
jurisdictional competition would fail to serve economic reform and growth. This point is
as an important incentive device without a also valid for most transition economies, at
national common market and factor mobil- least during the process of transforming the
ity (Jin, Qian, and Weingast 2005). However, economy into a market economy.
economic development and the development
of a national common market could be char-
4.  Regional Institutional Experiments
acterized as something of a chicken-or-egg
dilemma. Therefore, a recipe for economic Regional experimentation is an essential
development conditional on the existence of part of the central decision-making process
a common market or factor mobility would in China (section 2.2.1). Starting from 1978,
be difficult to apply usefully to real-world almost every major step on the path of reform
situations.40 was tried out by a few regions first before
What happened during the Chinese being launched nationwide. This is well
reforms is that when factors were highly echoed by the well-known “slogan” of the
immobile, i.e., when Tiebout conditions were Chinese reforms: “crossing a river by touch-
violated, Chinese regions started to compete ing the stones.” To some extent, the “stones”
fiercely with each other. Moreover, not only are reform measures and these “stones” are
did the RDA regime manage regional com- “touched” through regional experiments.
petition in a growth-enhancing manner, but Subnational governments play a critical
also allowed factors gradually to become role in attempting reforms due to the uncer-
more mobile, thus encouraging the evolution tainty of new reforms. One of the major
of a national common market. The key point uncertainties is related to the challenges
here is that factors became more mobile as of political resistance because reforms cre-
an outcome of the reforms, rather than as a ate winners and losers in changing institu-
precondition for them. tions. The political economy of institutional
Finally, it is important to note that fiscal changes affects paths and strategies of
federalism theory is based on the very fea- reforms. Under certain conditions, regional
ture of market economies that requires that reform experiments are used as a strategy to
the economic roles of local governments be weaken political resistance and to reduce the
restricted to fiscal policies. Thus, the key uncertainties that come from a new reform.
issues of fiscal federalism theory revolve A successful experiment outcome not only
around fiscal policies such as taxation and provides information on which reform pro-
the provision of public goods by local gov- gram works but also can be used to support
ernments. However, Chinese subnational the reform and to persuade the unconvinced.
Moreover, compared with a nationwide
full-scale reform, when a regional experi-
40 In almost all developing economies, factor mobil- ment fails the drawbacks may be contained
ity is limited and a national common market has yet to be to the experimenting region. In addition,
developed; this makes people doubt the usefulness of the
fiscal federalism model for economic development (Pranab some compromise policies or compensa-
Bardhan 2002). tion schemes aimed at opponents of a given
1108 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

policy may be attempted as a way to ease the However, this potential benefit will be
opposition toward starting a reform. That is, realized only when results can be obtained
the option value carried with regional experi- through experiments that do not disturb the
mentation may bear weight to tip the politi- rest of the economy, particularly in case of
cal balance in favor of those reforms that experiment failures. It turns out that how
may otherwise have been discarded. an experiment is coordinated determines
However, it seems that China is unique whether an experimental approach will be
in deploying regional experimentation as a fruitful and, in turn, the way experiments are
reform strategy, while it is usually agreed that coordinated is determined by the way the
Eastern Europe and the former USSR fol- economy and the government is organized.
lowed the “big bang” strategy. Moreover, this Conventional economic wisdom may lead
difference of approach is usually regarded as people to wonder why a market should not
an explanation of why China’s reforms per- be used to coordinate a reform experiment.
formed so differently than those of Eastern However, it has been argued that many
Europe (John McMillan and Naughton essential coordination tasks often have to
1992; Jeffrey D. Sachs and Wing Thye Woo be carried out through nonmarket mecha-
2000). Yet, the experimental approach was nisms, even in developed market economies
in fact utilized in the pre-1989 reforms in (Coase 1937; Weitzman 1974; Williamson
Eastern Europe and the Soviet Union, but 1975). For economies carrying out reforms
failed miserably.41 Those failures led to a aimed at transforming a centrally planned
discrediting of the experimental approach economy into a market economy, this is par-
in reforms and to the adoption of the big ticularly true since markets there have yet to
bang approach. Ironically, to a large extent, be developed. In his Nobel Lecture, Coase
China followed many of Eastern European- (1992) argued that the function of manage-
style gradual reforms with experiment as an ment in a firm “was to co-ordinate” beyond
essential ingredient in the earlier stages of the markets. He asked: “Why was it needed
its reforms. A fundamental question is: what if the pricing system provided all the co-
are the conditions that make China special in ordination necessary?” His answer was that
deploying regional experiments successfully? “[t]o have an efficient economic system it is
And, what makes the experimental approach necessary not only to have markets but also
work in China but not in Eastern Europe? areas of planning within organizations of the
The key potential benefit of experiment- appropriate size.” When an organization is
ing is to reduce the uncertainties of reforms. large, such as a multinational company or a
national government, a related key issue is
“the appropriate size” of the suborganization
41 An interesting example is Khrushchev’s “Sovnarkhoz”
reform (decentralization reform) launched in 1957 and that coordinates, or who should coordinate
1958 through a trial-and-error process, which eventually what within an organization. In the spirit of
established 105 “Sovnarkhozes” in the territory of the Coase, to some extent different ways of allo-
USSR (Howard R. Swearer 1959). The reform delegates
full authority to regional party secretaries over appoint- cating authorities within a government, or
ing SOE directors in their jurisdictions (William B. Ballis different ways of decentralization, is an insti-
1961). Regional leaders were encouraged to try reform tutional design issue that addresses the ques-
measures and strong incentives are linked to their per-
formance (Swearer 1962). But this “Sovnarkhoz” reform tion: what is the boundary of different levels
failed due to serious cross-region coordination failures of government?
(Paul R. Gregory and Robert C. Stuart 1998), which leads In reality, the success or failure of coor-
to the removal of Khrushchev in 1964. Andrei Markevich
and Ekaterina Zhuravskaya (2011) document this failed dinating reform experiments is deeply
reform. entangled with the political economy of
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1109

reforms. To make the analysis tractable, in thirty years of reform, most reform ideas did
the following subsection I simplify important not come from the central government.
political economy issues into a reduced form A closely related disadvantage of cen-
as parameters of a model. This allows me to tralized experimentation is the incentive
focus on analyzing coordination problems. problem. Without autonomous power,
Then, in subsection 4.2, I bring political unmotivated local officials would be passive
economy issues back to real cases of regional at the best and would not take initiatives to
experimentation. observe and to resolve potential problems.
Delegating the power to conduct reform
4.1 The Institutional Foundation for
experiments to local governments converts
Regional Experiments
local officials into entrepreneurs. A major fea-
Appropriately devised and implemented ture of China’s economic reforms is that local
reform experiments may reduce uncertain- officials make efforts to find market niches,
ties substantially. However, a reform experi- initiate inventive ideas, try new approaches,
ment often involves several complementary etc. Without this widespread entrepreneur-
subprograms, so a reform experiment will ship and their institutional innovations, most
fail if its related subprograms are not coor- of China’s successful reforms would not have
dinated satisfactorily.42 The role of the gov- been attempted.
ernment, particularly local governments, in However, not all governance structures are
initiating and coordinating local experiments conducive to regional reform experiments. A
is particularly vital in cases where many mar- challenging question to be addressed here
kets are missing or ill functioning. is the institutional foundation for coordi-
There are many reasons why it is important nating regional experiments. As discussed
to let local governments initiate and coordi- previously, a typical Chinese region is rela-
nate local experiments. These are best seen tively self-contained and a subnational gov-
by exploring an alternative approach, which ernment is responsible for most economic
would be to let the central government ini- activities within its jurisdiction. That is,
tiate and coordinate reforms. “Local knowl- subnational governments are assigned with
edge” and “local information” (Hayek) are the power and the resources to initiate and
the basic reasons why decentralized experi- to coordinate regional reform experiments.
mentation is superior to centralized experi- Moreover, given that interregional depen-
mentation. The central government does dence is relatively weak in China, when a
not know every thing; without information regional experiment fails, its impact on the
on local preferences, local technology, and rest of the national economy is minimal
local institutional conditions, it is hard for a (Qian and Xu 1993).43
centralized regime to come up with a con- Qian, Roland, and Xu (2006; also 1999,
crete, implementable idea that satisfies local 2007) developed a theory to explain how the
demand (preferences). Moreover, imple- Chinese RDA regime creates conditions that
menting a reform requires detailed local alleviate coordination problems in reforms
knowledge. As a matter of fact, in China’s

43 Provincial officials of Anhui and Guangdong argued


that a failed experiment in an isolated locality would not
42 Here, the central importance of complementarity affect the province’s performance when they initiated
among different reform dimensions is in odds with the regional experiments related to land reform and special
simplistic view that a single factor determines economic zone reform in the late 1970s (for more details, see sec-
development. tion 4.2).
1110 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

and that allows for flexible experimentation.44 If some attributes of the two tasks are not
In this theory, a reform program is consisted matched, many laid-off workers may not
of some complementary subprograms. Each be compensated appropriately, so they may
subprogram of the reform is characterized by strike and the ensuing social disorder will
its own individual attributes, and these com- make the reform a failure.
plementary subprograms must ultimately fit Therefore, a successful reform requires
together in order to be integrated properly. A both a good reform blueprint and proper
reform is completed successfully only if the implementation (i.e., coordination). The
characteristics of each attribute of the vari- uncertainty of the quality of a reform pro-
ous subprograms are matched successfully. A gram can be reduced to form an expression
failure in the matching of attributes implies of two factors: (a) the political support for,
a breakdown of economic order, i.e., a dras- or resistance to, a reform and (b) the tech-
tic failure. To simplify the matter, suppose a nical quality of the proposed reform. A pro-
reform program is ex ante well designed in gram with many political challenges is more
the sense that all the attributes are matched uncertain, and a reform program that incites
by those in the blueprint of the program. strong political opposition will fail in spite
However, some of the attributes may not suit of how “good” the program looks from an
local conditions ex post, and adjusting these outsider’s perspective. Therefore, a program
attributes may lead to mismatches with the without political support will be regarded as
attributes of other tasks, which will then bad regardless of how good the program is
require further adjustments. in theory or in practice in another country.
To illustrate the basic idea, let us look at In addition, a program can be technically
the following example. Suppose a reform has uncertain. For example, a mechanical trans-
two subprograms: an enterprise restructur- plantation of the case law from the United
ing program (involving a lay-off of excess States to China would be highly technically
workers) and the creation of a social safety uncertain given the linguistic, historical, and
net (involving unemployment benefits). cultural differences between the two coun-
The attributes of the enterprise restructur- tries. In a simplified theory, a bad reform
ing program include the number of laid-off program always leads to a failure, however
workers and their individual characteristics, well coordinated in the implementation. Yet,
such as: age, seniority, family composition, without a test it is not known for sure ex ante
length of residence, sex, type of contract, whether a reform program is good or not.
current wage, and history of employment. On the other hand, a good reform pro-
The attributes of the unemployment ben- gram needs to be implemented or coordi-
efits in the social safety net include the rules nated correctly. The quality of coordination
of eligibility, such as length of employment, depends on the quality of the information
special circumstances (i.e., veterans), the sta- available to decisionmakers in the organiza-
tus of enterprises, the rules of the benefits tion. Regional officials enjoy a local informa-
(such as size and length), the types of ben- tion advantage (a la F. A. Hayek 1945), in
efits (monetary or not), the technical support that they have firsthand observations on the
of computers, administration, and budget. site; whereas for others, any onsite informa-
tion would require communication, which
is subject to imperfect transmission. The
44 In the Qian, Roland, and Xu papers, Chinese econ-
Qian, Roland, and Xu framework assumes
omy is modeled as an M-form organization. All the political
economy interpretations associated with the RDA regime that information transmission is imperfect.
discussed here may or may not be shared by my coauthors. To capture the reality fully, this assumption
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1111

should be interpreted as a reduced-form a small-scale experiment, the central gov-


expression of two noises: (a) political noise ernment has to carry it out in multiple steps
and (b) technical noise. Political noise occurs involving all relevant ministries. These com-
when information is transmitted through plications in coordinating regional experi-
political skeptics or opponents, while techni- ments not only incur deadweight losses (as
cal noise arises from the fact that two officials shown rigorously in Qian, Roland, and Xu),
can have different knowledge and different but also make it easy to sabotage an experi-
interpretations of the same message, or for ment in the process.
some other technical reasons. In general, when there are more political
In China’s RDA regime, where each suspicions surrounding a reform program
region is self-contained and regional officials and when political opposition within the
are assigned the power to coordinate, reform government is stronger, therefore causing
experiments can be coordinated locally. coordination failure to occur more often,
Relying on firsthand local knowledge directly, the advantage of the RDA regime becomes
without involving upper-level officials, local more apparent. These points are illustrated
coordination will not be subject to political by case studies in the following subsection.
interference and technical noises, and will be
4.2 Regional Experiments on Land Reform
easier to accommodate. Most importantly,
and Special Economic Zones
flexibility in reform experiments makes it
possible to try a reform in one region (or a China’s land reform and special economic
few regions) first and extend the experiment zone (SEZ) reform were both made possible
to other regions later if the first experiment by the efforts of reform-oriented subnational
is a success. In the case of a failure, although governments facing stiff political resistance
the failed experimenting region’s payoff will at national level. Successful regional reform
be reduced, the payoff for the nonexperi- experiment outcomes created bases for
menting regions will remain constant. This forging consensus among the central lead-
flexibility weakens resistance to reform pro- ers, which made large-scale diffusion of the
posals and encourages attempts of many dif- reform programs possible at a later date. Ex
ferent reforms, which may otherwise not be ante the reduced uncertainties of regional
tried at all. experiments gave reformers better chances
In contrast, in an economy where spe- to try controversial programs. Ex post suc-
cialized ministries are responsible for cessful experiment outcomes—even those
implementing tasks, because ministries are that were only partially successful—could
complementary, reform experiments have be used as evidence to convince undecided
to be coordinated by the central officials. politicians and to accumulate momentum
This inevitably involves both political and and political support for the reforms.
technical noise, thereby making coordina- Chinese land reform started in the
tion failure more likely. One of the worst late 1970s and is officially known as the
features of this economy is its rigidity, which household responsibility system (HRS). It
prevents a regional experiment or a small- is regarded as “a major social experiment
scale experiment from being beneficial. A in the design of institutions in which a
fundamental institutional problem here system emphasizing social values has been
is that, because complementary tasks are replaced by a system relying on economic
grouped separately into specialized minis- incentives” (McMillan, Whalley, and Lijing
tries, coordination across ministries must Zhu 1989, p. 782). During the period of
be provided by the center. In coordinating the HRS reform between 1978 and 1984,
1112 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

output in the Chinese agricultural sector was in Xiaogang village in Fengyang county
increased by over 61 percent. Seventy-eight of Anhui. In those localities, land and output
percent of the increase in productivity in quotas were contracted out from local govern-
Chinese agriculture in this period of time ments (communes) to individual households.
was due to the changes brought about by the The experiments were carried out under high
HRS reform (McMillan, Whalley, and Zhu risks, given that people who were involved in
1989). By examining many other factors, the 1960s’ land reform were heavily penal-
Lin (1992) disentangled the contribution ized not long ago.45 At that time, land reform
to output growth of the HRS reform from was unconstitutional (as stated in the 1978
those of other reforms, as well as from that Constitution of China), and was officially
of increased input availability. He confirms banned by the Communiqué of the Third
that the dominant source of agriculture Plenum of the 11th Central Committee of the
output growth during 1978–1984 was the CCP, which is often quoted officially and in
change from the production-team system the literature as the first milestone of the post-
to HRS, which was directly responsible for Mao reform (Daniel Kelliher 1992; Naughton
49 percent of the output growth. Moreover, 1995). The State Council and the Party’s
the change in crop patterns, from grain to newspaper, the People’s Daily, issued decrees
nongrain crops, also had a positive impact. and commentaries on behalf of the central
Although it may be a bit of an exaggera- government to stop any land reform attempts
tion to call the introduction of the HRS “the with political threats based on the ban of
design of institutions,” it is pretty accurate to the Communiqué (Wu 2009). The supreme
regard this process as “a major social experi- leader Deng was quiet until some obviously
ment.” A key point I want to highlight here successful experimental results came out.
is that this major social experiment was initi- Facing the daunting challenges of car-
ated and carried out by subnational govern- rying out the land reform, in 1979 Zhao
ments without a design at the national level; Ziyang and Wan Li, then the governors of
this is the way to overcome the political resis- Sichuan and Anhui respectively, decided
tances and risks associated with land reform. to experiment with different land contract-
Similar to what happened in Central- ing schemes in a few counties within their
Eastern Europe before the 1989 reforms, jurisdictions. According to Tian Jiyun, a
or in the former Soviet Union during pere­ Vice-Premier of the State Council between
stroika, political/ideological resistance to 1983 and 1993, Dangtu county was one of
land reform were strong in China. Any the counties picked up by Wan in 1979 and
change that could lead to decollectiviza- about 17 percent of rural households there
tion was seriously challenged, and any fail- participated in the land contracting experi-
ure associated with land reform would be ment.46 All of the land reform experiments
utilized by the conservatives for political were coordinated locally.
reasons. Thus, minimizing the political and
technical uncertainties of land reform was
critically important for the survival of the 45 Land reform was tried in many Chinese regions dur-

reform, as well as the reformers themselves. ing the early 1960s but reforms were banned, and officials
and peasants involved in the experiments were punished
In the late 1970s, “proto-types” of the severely during the CR.
HRS were tried by a handful of local officials 46 Similar experiments were also carried out in

in a few provinces such as Anhui, Sichuan, Guangdong in 1978 under the leadership of governor Xi
Zhongxun at that time but were stopped due to political
and Guangdong. One of the best-known pressure from the conservatives in the central government
examples of initiative by local government (Dongshi Cai et al. 2008).
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1113

In 1980, validated by the successful allocated to separate agencies over which


regional experiment results, Wan and Zhao neither collective farms nor regional gov-
reported to the central government and ernments had any control, and thus it would
rallied for expanding reform experiments have been extremely difficult to experiment
into more regions throughout the nation. without support from all relevant ministries.
Supported by their successful experiment In 1989, Gorbachev launched his compre-
results, the central government decided to hensive agriculture reform in a manner such
allow for regional land reform experiments that all relevant ministries were included. In
to spread out nationwide in late 1980. Zhao the reform, peasants could lease land with
and Wan were promoted to be the Premier long-term contracts. Although the goal seems
and Vice-Premier of the State Council, similar to the Chinese reform, the farmers
respectively, in order to carry out the nation- encountered grave coordination problems.
wide reform experiments (Tian 2008). After As a result, there were serious problems in
this, the nationwide land reform experiment implementation, such as waste during the
propagated quickly, so that in 1981 about storage, transport, and processing stages
45 percent of rural households participated due to failures in coordination between pro-
in the reform. Subsequently participation duction units, transport, and storage (Karl-
increased to 80 percent in the next year, Eugen Wädekin 1992).
and finally, reached 99 percent in 1984 (Lin Another famous Chinese reform is the
1992). Thereafter, agricultural reforms in SEZ development and the subsequent
general and land reform in particular were meteoric rise in foreign direct invest-
consolidated through numerous further ment (FDI). Thanks to this reform, even
reform measures. Similarly, most of those though China started with virtually zero
are based on successful regional experiment FDI and almost negligible trade and for-
results.47 eign reserves in 1978, in a quarter of a
In sharp contrast, at the onset of Soviet/ century China has become one of the larg-
Russian reforms, all Soviet farming tasks est FDI recipient countries in the world,
were coordinated by the central govern- with the world’s largest foreign reserves,
ment through specialized ministries (e.g., and also one of the largest trading coun-
Ministries of Agriculture, Trade, Cereal tries in the world. Table 4 clearly shows
and Grain Production, Tractors and that FDI in China and Chinese exports
Farm Machinery, Food Industry, Rural are essentially driven by the SEZs. When
Construction, Fertilizer, Land Reclamation China first opened up and began attract-
and Water Resources, and Fruit and ing FDI and trade, 37 percent of FDI was
Vegetable Farming, etc.). The tasks of pro- located in SEZs in 1985, and 89 percent of
viding inputs to the farmers, of manag- the national exports came from the SEZs
ing their operations, storage, processing, in 1985. In 2005, when China became
transport, and road infrastructure were all the largest FDI recipient country in the
world, 93 percent of FDI was located in
SEZs, and 93 percent of China’s exports
47 Although rural households enjoy the residual income
came from the SEZs. It is not an exaggera-
and residual control rights over what they do with the land,
under the HRS the control rights of allocation and man- tion to claim that it is the SEZ that made
agement of land resources are kept with the local officials. China the country with the largest foreign
Thus, most cultivated land in rural China remains partially reserves in the world, as well as the coun-
collectively owned. Hanan G. Jacoby, Guo Li, and Scott
Rozelle (2002) show the existence of inefficiencies caused try with the largest trade surplus with the
by this partial privatization. United States and the European Union.
1114 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

Table 4
The Impacts of SEZs on National FDI and Exporting

Number Nat’l exports SEZ exports SEZ share Nat’l FDI SEZ FDI SEZ share
Year of SEZs (mil US$) (mil US$) of exports (mil US$) (mil US$) of FDI
1980 4 18,119 278 1.5% 145 51 34.9%
1985 77 27,350 24,327 89.0% 1,956 728 37.2%
1990 290 62,091 44,602 71.8% 3,487 2,551 73.2%
1995 341 148,780 124,692 83.8% 37,521 33,694 89.8%
2000 341 249,203 228,779 91.8% 40,715 38,796 95.3%
2005 342 761,953 709,373 93.1% 60,325 56,397 93.5%

Sources: China statistical yearbooks 1986-2006; China Urban Statistical yearbook 1986–2006; China Urban Forty
years; Provincial Statistical yearbooks 1996–2006; State Council documents.

Therefore, among all the Chinese reform and regional—how could China accommo-
measures, the SEZ has had the greatest date foreign and domestic firms to develop
direct impact on the global economy. trade-intensive businesses?
Although by conventional wisdom it Facing these tough constraints, the central
seems obvious to suggest SEZ reform poli- leadership was, at best, not able to build a
cies in order to improve trade and attract consensus to move forward (Cai et al. 2008;
FDI, initiating and carrying out these Zhao 2009). The idea of setting up SEZs to
reforms was a great challenge at the begin- attract FDI and to develop export-oriented
ning of the reform era. There was strong industries was initiated and experimented
political opposition to the idea of renting by subnational governments. The strategy of
land to foreign firms or multinational firms, regional experimentation played a vital role
as these kinds of practices were regarded in dealing with the ensuing difficulties and
as “selling the nation.” Indeed this kind of uncertainties. According to the archives (Cai
reform was unconstitutional at that time. et al. 2008), the idea of conducting municipal
The political risk would be too high for a experiments to attract FDI was proposed by
reformer to bear if one had to confront the officials of Guangdong province in 1979. The
convention of the planning apparatus at a proposal suggested to authorize Shenzhen
national level or to confront the constitu- and Zhuhai as experimenting municipalities,
tion head-to-head. Thus, those concerned and required that conditional on the success
with how to attract FDI to China faced tre- of the first experiment other cities will follow
mendous political and economical difficul- similar experiments in the next step. A major
ties and uncertainties. Moreover, when the part of the experiment involved trying new
constitution (including the Party’s constitu- sets of institutions, legislation, and rules for
tion) did not protect private property rights, the purpose of attracting FDI, and further-
how would one convince foreign investors more municipality governments were made
to invest? When imports/exports were all responsible for implementation. Moreover,
controlled by government agents—national the proposal asked for greater regional
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1115

autonomy, particularly for decision-making the SEZs is subdued and encouraging SEZ
power in regional experiments. development becomes a national policy. In
The skepticism toward the SEZs was 1992, SEZs comprised all the capital cities
strong at the top level of the central govern- of inland provinces and autonomous regions,
ment (Jianhui Zeng 1984). There had been fifteen free trade zones, thirty-two state-level
fierce debates in the central government and economic and technological development
within the party apparatus on the desirabil- zones, and fifty-three new- and high-tech
ity and the nature of SEZs, and on the paths industrial development zones. Currently,
of development the SEZs should take.48 As SEZs encompass more than one hundred
a compromise, approval was given by the national economic and technological devel-
State Council for small-scale experiments opment zones, fifteen national bonded areas,
in four remote cities in 1979 (The Central and fourteen border trade and cooperation
Government Circular No. 50, 1979, Zhongfa regions in the broadest sense.
(1979) 50, cited by Zeng 1984). One of the major features of the small-
Together with authorizing the experi- scale regional experiments, such as the
ments for SEZs, the central government also HRS and SEZ reforms, is that for a cer-
granted the Guangdong government, and tain period of time the nonexperimenting
particularly the experimenting municipal regions remain unchanged until diffusion
governments, more autonomy in regional commences. The coexistence of two sys-
planning, in enterprise management, and tems, experimenting versus nonexperiment-
in policies related to FDI. In August 1980, ing or reforming versus nonreforming, in
the People’s Congress approved the State the reform process is sometimes called “the
Council’s proposal of setting up four SEZs in dual track system.” The dual track system has
Guangdong and Fujian and passed the first been used to describe both small-scale and
legal rule on the SEZs: “the Regulation for full-scale reform experiments in which all
Guangdong SEZs.” This was the first kind of regions implement a reform experiment at
regional law tested, which was drafted with the same time, while keeping the nonexperi-
the help of legal experts sent from the cen- menting system for a certain period of time.
tral government (Cai et al. 2008). When the A major example of a full-scale experiment
experiment was expanded into other prov- is the dual track price system. The most
inces, they also adopted and modified this important benefit of the dual track system is
law accordingly. to reduce resistance to a reform by substan-
Supported by the initial achievements of tially reducing the number of losers through
the first group of SEZs in 1984, the central keeping the nonreforming system at earlier
government endorsed another fourteen cit- stages of the reform (Lawrence J. Lau, Qian,
ies to experiment with SEZs, and the experi- and Roland 2000). However, there are essen-
ment was further expanded to more cities tial conditions to be satisfied to make the
in 1985. In the early 1990s, the extremely dual track approach beneficial in reforms.
fast growth of export and FDI validated If the state is weak in enforcement and, as
the success of the SEZs. The opposition to a result, parties are able to siphon resources
away from low-priced existing transactions to
48 Chen Yun, a top leader of the CCP, cast deep doubts high-priced new transactions, the dual track
on the SEZs. The idea of setting up the SEZs was regarded approach may fail to function (Jiahua Che
as equivalent to a “rented territory” or “the selling of the and Giovanni Facchini 2007). Thus, the sub-
nation,” which would be a revival of the semi-colonial era.
The other objection charged that the SEZs would exacer- national governments’ enforcement capa-
bate inequalities (Zhao 2009). bility to regulate firms’ strategies is vital in
1116 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

order for the dual approach to be efficiency setting up proper incentives is essential for
improving. inducing subnational officials to conduct
In addition to locally initiated reform experiments.49
experiments, almost all important reforms It is relatively straightforward to design
sponsored by the central government in incentives for central government-sponsored
the past three decades were also tried and local experiments. Often, the central govern-
implemented through regional experiments, ment provides generous compensation to
such as the state sector reforms (Sebastian experimenting local governments (Heilmann
Heilmann 2008). The bankruptcy reform in 2008). However, for locally initiated experi-
the mid 1990s illustrates this phenomenon. ments, the incentive mechanism is subtler.
Although there was collective support from It turns out that the regional competition-
the top leaders for restructuring the state sec- based promotion system is one of the mecha-
tor drastically through enforcing the bank- nisms that create motivations for regions to
ruptcy law, there was no consensus on how be entrepreneurial in experimenting. In the
to do it. After it issued general guidelines on RDA regime, regional officials are appointed,
the basic priorities and general approaches and initiating or implementing successful
in 1994, the central government encour- regional experiments can lead to substantial
aged local governments to experiment with promotions. Thus, although experimenting
innovative solutions for debt restructuring, involves risks and externalities, experiment-
mergers, closures, and employee resettle- ing also creates chances not only to outper-
ment. Eighteen municipalities were picked form others, but also more importantly, to
up by the central government “to test new lead others, which implies getting unusual
methods for dealing with the resettlement promotion opportunities. That is, the ben-
of employees in insolvent industrial enter- efits associated with promotions will correct
prises.” Each experimenting municipality disincentives from positive externalities.
was responsible for coordinating all the rel- In addition to the costs of experiments,
evant aspects within its jurisdiction, such as another critically important issue is who
land-use rights and using the proceeds for decides what to experiment and who con-
resettling the laid-off workers (Heilmann ducts the experiment. By being granted a
2008). This reform finished in the mid 2000s. broad range of control rights over regional
economic affairs, the regionally decen-
4.3 Incentives of Experimenting
tralized structure converts many regional
Regional experimentation is a major strat- bureaucrats into entrepreneurial officials.
egy for moving a reform forward before Regional officials are active in identifying
central decisionmakers are able to build reform experiment opportunities. If, after
consensus for the reform. Experimenting someone’s initiative, other regions follow
involves high risks for regional officials who an experiment, it implies that this reform
conduct the experiments, and it also creates experiment was a success, and therefore the
large positive externalities at the costs of chance of getting a substantial promotion is
experimenting regions. Moreover, conduct- higher. Perceiving this, officials with greater
ing reform experiments often requires offi-
cials take initiatives and make extra efforts
to deal with unexpected contingencies. 49 In a Tiebout federal system, where officials are

Without the initiative to solve problems, elected from their constituencies, the value dilution due
to the positive externalities will disincentivize regional offi-
experiments would easily fail. Therefore, in cials and lead to too few experiments (Gordon 1983; Cai
addition to previously discussed conditions, and Treisman 2005).
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1117

career ambitions would initiate reform rate was significant for the period of 1990
experiments on their own, sometimes even to 2004.
taking high risks. That is, the centralized
personnel control may internalize some of
5.  Regional Competition and Regional
the externality problems of regional experi-
Experiments in Some Major Reforms
ments. The HRS and SEZ experiments dis-
cussed in the previous subsection are the This section discusses some major eco-
most visible examples of this process. In nomic reforms that have had substantial
those examples, the pioneers of the HRS impacts on China’s economic growth over
and SEZ reforms were promoted substan- the past three decades. This discussion
tially when the experiments were recognized serves two purposes: first, it is important to
by the central government as models for the understand the mechanisms by which these
nation to follow. reforms operate for their own sake and, sec-
Moreover, it is observed that a common ond, these reforms act as concrete examples
practice in reform era is to promote officials of the conceptual discussions above about
from more developed municipalities, where the mechanisms of regional competition and
many reform experiments were tried out ear- regional experimentation.
lier, to leading provincial posts, particularly
5.1 The Township–Village Enterprises
in less developed regions. Chien and Zhao
(TVEs) and the Nonstate Sector
(2007) document that, from the late 1990s
to the early 2000s, there were three former Large-scale entry and fast development of
heads of Suzhou city who were promoted to the nonstate sector is a distinctive feature of
become governors of Jiangsu, Shaanxi, and China’s reforms.50 The pace of growth of the
Jilin respectively; a former Shenzhen mayor nonstate sector is so quick that the state sec-
was appointed as the governor of Hunan, tor is unable to compete. Without a conven-
and a mayor of Wenzhou became the gover- tional form of privatization of the state sector,
nor of Sichuan. These three cities pioneered i.e., privatizing existing SOEs, the market
many reform experiments on their own and share of China’s state sector in the national
are among the best reforming municipalities economy shrunk from 78 percent in 1978
in China. to 53 percent in 1991. The most important
By using a panel data consisting of thirty nonstate sector until the mid-1990s was the
provincial regions between 1978 and 2005, TVE. By the early 1990s, TVEs accounted
through a diff-in-diff approach to control for for about four-fifths of the output of the
groups with and without transfer of gover- nonstate sector. Between 1981 and 1990,
nors and before and after transfer of gover- the total industrial output of TVEs grew at
nors, Xu, Wang, and Shu (2007) found that, an average annual rate of 28.1 percent, while
everything else being equal, cross-regional the rate for the state sector was 7.7 percent.
governor transfer increased regional GDP As a comparison, China’s average annual
growth rate by 1 percent. In the more GDP growth rate was 8.7 percent between
recent period of 1992 to 2005, the effect 1979 and 1991. Moreover, TVEs had sub-
was enlarged to 2 percent. By construct-
ing a panel data consisting of thirty provin-
cial regions between 1978 and 2004, with a
50 To some extent, Hungary, Poland, and Vietnam are
similar approach, Jun Zhang and Yuan Gao
the other transition economies that shared this feature and
(2007) find that the effect of cross regional they all enjoyed better performances than other transition
governor transfer on regional GDP growth economies.
1118 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

stantially higher TFP growth rates than the community citizens did not. Moreover, when
state sector in those years (Xu 1995). the firm is owned by the community govern-
More importantly, the TVE actually served ment, the community government faces less
as a major stepping-stone in changing China’s state expropriation because part of the rev-
institutions. A typical TVE is a collectively enue is used to finance the local provision
owned enterprise located in a township/vil- of public goods, which addresses the state’s
lage. All the people in the township/village concerns and also enhances the firm’s future
that “sets up” the TVE own the firm collec- earning potential (Che and Qian 1998).
tively. The community government of the These arguments are supported by empiri-
township/village “represents” the communal cal evidence collected from villages (Hongyi
collective owners and is the de facto execu- Chen and Rozelle 1999).
tive owner of the TVE (William A. Byrd and Another major feature of the TVEs is the
Qingsong Lin 1990). The property rights of prevailing of the informal institutions, such
the TVE are vaguely defined. From a view- as implicit contractual relationships between
point based on “conventional wisdom,” the community governments and TVEs,
governance of these firms appears deficient between TVE employees, and between
and should result in unproductive firms. TVEs. Weitzman and Xu (1994) conjectured
Therefore, the spectacular performance of that local cultural or social norms may be
the TVE sector poses major challenges to an important factor behind informal institu-
economics (Weitzman and Xu 1994). This is tions. This conjecture shares the same spirit
particularly true before the mid-1990s. of the evolutionary repeated game theory of
Several complementary explanations are social norms (Robert Axelrod 1984; Drew
proposed in the literature, and most focus on Fudenberg and Maskin 2008) and is closely
the role of the community government. The related to the literature on the evolution of
strong incentives created by regional compe- social norms, culture, and human behavior.
tition are one of the institutional reasons for Empirically, it sheds light on substantial
the rapid development of TVEs. Moreover, regional differences in TVE development,
the relatively self-contained nature of including powerful informal institutions in
regional economies gave TVEs opportunities post-TVE developments (Xu and Xiaobo
to grow. There are broad ranges of products Zhang forthcoming), which reflect the
that the TVEs can produce to meet local diverse history of China’s regional economic
demand, and there are often sufficient local development.51
semiproducts to supply to TVEs as inputs. As protection of private property rights
Close links between TVEs and local SOEs improved (Donald Clarke, Peter Murrell,
often facilitated the transfer of technology and Whiting 2006) and asset markets devel-
and management know-how (Xu and Zhuang oped, many benefits of TVEs are dimin-
1998). ished. Moreover, associated with large-scale
Concerning the relatively effective gov-
ernance of the community government 51 Most TVE employees and managers lived in the
over TVEs, most conceptual discussions same community for generations when there was almost
emphasize the second-best nature of TVEs no migration before the early 1990s. Under certain con-
ditions, close long-term interactions among community
when there is weak or no legal protection members (virtually infinitely repeated overlapping-gener-
of private property rights (Chun Chang and ation relationships) might foster a social norm within the
Yijiang Wang 1994; David D. Li 1996; Oi community that may facilitate informal institutions. In
contrast, SOEs are not organized based on natural com-
1999). That is because township–village gov- munities, such as villages; therefore, many of the informal
ernments had access to resources, whereas mechanisms found in TVEs would not function in SOEs.
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1119

migration since the mid-1990s, an increasing networks of informal arrangements, such as


number of TVE employees, including TVE implicit contracts, so that every final prod-
top managers, have become migrant work- uct is jointly produced by a collection of
ers. This also contributes to changes in the many firms. Repeated interactions among
governance of TVEs.52 A large percentage of the workshops and among the agents help
TVEs were privatized since the mid-1990s reduce the monitoring and enforcement
(James Kai-Sing Kung and Yi-Min Lin 2007; costs. The township government affects the
Albert Park and Minggao Shen 2003; Li and overall and long-run strategic direction of
Rozelle 2004). the cluster without direct involvement in the
Although TVEs have declined, the insti- daily operations of the thousands of small
tutional legacy of TVEs in China’s economic workshops.54 To a large extent, some impor-
development and corporate governance is tant features of TVE institutions, particu-
extensive. Important mechanisms that pre- larly the importance of entrepreneurial local
vailed in TVEs, e.g., the intimate involve- governments to local business development,
ment of community governments in business remain in this post-TVE development. The
and informal institutional arrangements, are clusters are strategically managed by town-
still at work today, and their impacts on the ship governments, although they have no
rise of entrepreneurship in China are far- ownership of the assets of the workshops and
reaching, such as on the fast growth of clus- are not involved in their financing, except for
ters of large numbers of small private firms most of the land and some of the buildings.
in coastal provinces. They provide infrastructure, secure property
With clustering of a vast number of small rights, regulate quality, train laborers, and
specialized firms, many Chinese townships provide favorable policies.
have become national or world “factories” All of these make the township govern-
for certain products. It is these townships ment similar to the headquarters of a con-
that made China “the world’s factory.”53 In a glomerate. Moreover, to a large extent, due
typical industrial cluster, thousands of highly to the way that they coordinate with each
specialized family-owned entrepreneurial other, the behavior of those privately owned
firms are worked together with infrastruc- specialized workshops are more like work-
tural and regulatory support of township shops within an integrated large firm than
governments. The small firms in a cluster independent small firms in a market (Xu and
are closely coordinated, similar to workshops Zhang forthcoming).
within an integrated firm, whereas they are The evolution of TVEs and the subse-
also highly competitive, as in markets. These quent clustering of modes of production are
specialized small firms are linked together by institutional responses created by entrepre-
neurs, including local entrepreneurial offi-
cials, to overcome constraints such as weak
52 In the terminology of evolutionary game theory, there
legal protections for property rights, weak
were lots of mutants that invaded the repeated games and
that would change the equilibrium strategy of the game contract enforcement, and credit and techni-
(Fudenberg and Maskin 2008). cal constraints. When the political, legal, and
53 For example, Datang township makes one-third of
the world’s socks; 40 percent of the world’s neckties are
made in Shengzhou township; more than 70 percent of 54 Take Puyuan Township (Zhejiang province), the larg-
the buttons for clothes made in China come from Qiaotou est cashmere sweater production center in the world, as
township; Songxia township produces 350 million umbrel- an example. There were six thousand family-owned highly
las every year; and Puyuan township produced 60 percent specialized workshops and three thousand private trading
of China’s cashmere sweaters, of which China is the world’s shops in the cluster coordinated strategically by the town-
largest producer (Xu and Zhang forthcoming). ship government (Xu and Zhang forthcoming).
1120 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

economic conditions improve, a firm’s orga- conglomerate in which subnational govern-


nization and organizational structure may ments functioned like the headquarters of
change as well. Less viable forms of organi- regional conglomerates (Oi 1999). This is
zational structures are eliminated through particularly true for municipalities and coun-
competitive pressures in a decentralized set- ties. The regional governments, functioning
ting, whereas it will be hard to prescribe the like the personnel department of a regional
optimal path of firm evolution beforehand. conglomerate, selected managers, made
This makes regional experiment-based deci- decisions on promotions and demotions,
sion making important. Overall, the success maintained dossiers, and tracked managerial
of TVEs and post-TVE developments is due records, etc. In response to regional com-
to the regional decentralization that allows petition, also under the encouragement of
for the full use of individual talents through the central government’s reform guidelines,
introducing various institutional and organi- subnational governments experimented with
zational innovations to cope with constrain- various “managerial responsibility systems”
ing factors. in which managers were delegated power to
make many decisions, and employees were
5.2 State Sector Reform: Centrally
given financial incentives tied to enterprise
Sponsored Local Experiments
performance.
Similar to other transition economies, the By using firm-level panel data, Groves et
Chinese economy was dominated by the al. (1994, 1995) and Li (1997) evaluated the
state sector at the onset of the reform and, outcomes of some major SOE reform experi-
therefore, state sector reform was the most ments in the 1980s. In their sample, over 80
important. Yet, as opposed to other transi- percent of the managers were appointed by
tion economies, most of the SOEs in China subnational governments, and their careers
were “owned” by subnational governments. were determined by the evaluations of
China’s state sector reforms have been very their bureaucratic superiors; the majority of
much driven by regional competition and SOEs were in the regional experiments del-
regional experiments. Two major aspects egating more authority to SOE managers,
of early SOE reforms have been discussed which allowed SOEs to keep a large propor-
in the literature. The first aspect concerns tion of their profits and to use the retained
appointment or selection of SOE managers. funds for worker bonuses, worker welfare
Before privatization (to be discussed later), facilities, and enterprise investment, etc.
subnational governments were responsible Moreover, performance responsibility con-
for selecting SOE managers within their tracts for SOE managers were experimented
jurisdictions. Under the pressure of regional with in many regions. The contracts speci-
competition and the importance of local fied performance indicators, such as profit,
SOEs to regional economies, subnational reinvestment, and compensation structure.
officials became very performance conscious Most of the SOEs’ managers in the Groves
when considering the appointment of SOE et al. sample signed the contracts. Groves et
managers (Theodore Groves et al. 1995). al. (1994) investigated how SOE managers
The second aspect of the early reforms responded to their increased autonomy and
involved managerial incentives (Groves et al. how firm productivity was affected. They
1994; Zhuang and Xu 1996). found that with more autonomy in output
As regional SOEs were owned by regional decisions and with higher marginal profit-
governments, to a certain extent, a region’s retention rates, SOEs increased their use of
state sector is like a state-run regional bonuses and hired more fixed-term contract
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1121

workers. Moreover, the strengthened incen- 1997), which is confirmed by researches


tives were positively correlated with higher based on national census data (Gary H.
productivity. Jefferson, Rawski, and Yuxin Zheng 1996).
Another important experimental SOE Nevertheless, the early SOE reforms failed
reform was the system of management selec- to solve some basic problems of the state sec-
tion by competitive auctions. About 14 per- tor. While productivity was increased, facing
cent of the managers in the Groves et al. fierce competition from the nonstate sec-
sample were selected through competitive tor and losing monopolistic position in most
auction. The usage of this reform peaked in product markets, the financial performance
the late 1980s—1987 and 1988 accounted of the state sector worsened rapidly. The
for 57.4 percent of the competitive auctions total losses in the state sector kept worsen-
in the Groves et al. sample. Auction proce- ing between 1993 and their peak in 1998,
dures varied among regional experiments. In when the state sector made a net loss of 285
general, a typical SOE was put up for auction billion RMB (table 4) and the government
by its superior municipal government. The kept pumping financial aid into this sector
most important part of a bid was the prom- for bailouts.55 The record-breaking losses
ise of profit to the municipal authority in the of the state sector led to an unprecedented
near future. In most cases, bidders also made number of nonperforming loans (NPLs) in
promises to reinvest, etc. The municipal gov- China’s banking sector. These were mani-
ernment as the owner of the SOE then chose festations of a serious soft budget constraint
the winning bidder on the basis of promised syndrome (SBC), a major moral hazard
profit delivery and the management plan, problem prevalent in all centralized econo-
etc. The top manager often signed a manage- mies and transition economies.56 The severe
ment contract and frequently was required SBC problem and the well-known conse-
to put up a security deposit, which could be quences of SBC created deep worries about
forfeited if the manager failed to meet the
promised performance.
Based on their firm level data, Groves et al. 55 Groves et al. (1994, 1995) reported no evidence that

indicated that the managerial labor market budget constraints for state-owned firms were hardened
in the 1980s. In studying the “fiscal contracting system”
was functioning in China’s state sector such operating between the central and provincial governments
that SOE managers changed jobs frequently. from 1980–93, Jin, Qian, and Weingast also found that the
They found both demotion/promotion of the central government was not able to keep its commitment
to restrain from offering ex post subsidies to subnational
previous manager and the conditions of the governments.
new manager’s appointment can be partially 56 Yet, the TVEs did not suffer much from the SBC syn-

explained by the corresponding firm’s per- drome, as millions of them went bankrupt in 1989, even
though they were supported by community governments
formance. Moreover, they found that SOE and many of them also had policy burdens for community
managers’ total compensation is positively employment and social security. This is because at the bot-
related to firm profits. In their sample, over- tom level of the hierarchy, community governments, as
well as local branches of rural credit cooperatives, have
all, SOE per worker output rose 67 percent limited financial resources available in their disposal.
(in constant prices) for the decade of the Moreover, their access to subsidies and credits from the
1980s. As a result, in that period of time TFP central government is restricted by law. These limitations
have prevented community governments from bailing out
growth contributed to 73 percent of output loss-making TVEs (Qian and Xu 1993). Moreover, given
growth; moreover, over 87 percent of the local governments’ limited financial resources, they face
TFP growth was attributable to improved high opportunity costs for bailing out failing firms. When
regional competition is tougher, the opportunity cost
incentives, intensified product market com- becomes higher and local governments would be less will-
petition, and improved factor allocation (Li ing to bailout their failing firms (Qian and Roland 1998).
1122 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

Table 5
Losses and Layoffs in the State Sector, 1991 to 2005

Losses (bil) Profits (bil) Layoffs (mil) Net profits (bil)


1991 92.6 167.1 74.5
1992 75.7 171.2 95.5
1993 47.9 214.6 166.7
1994 62.5 223.3 160.8
1995 80.2 227.2 147.0
1996 112.7 200.4 5.42 87.7
1997 142.1 196.1 6.34 54.0
1998 306.7 328.0 5.95 21.3
1999 214.5 329.1 6.53 114.6
2000 184.6 468.0 6.57 283.4
2001 199.4 480.5 5.15 281.1
2002 180.3 558.9 4.10 378.6
2003 282.0 758.9 2.60 476.9
2004 306.1 1,042.9 1.53 736.8
2005 242.6 1,200.6 0.61 958.0

Note: Losses: the total losses in the state sector; Profits: the total profits from the profitable SOEs; Layoffs: the
accumulated number of employees laid-off by the state sector.
Sources: Finance Yearbook of China, 1996–2006; China Accounting Yearbook, 1995–2006; China Labor and Social
Security Yearbook, 2006; China Labor Economic Yearbook, 1997–98.

the sustainability or even the survivability of a budget constraint is to make bankruptcy


the Chinese regime. The SBC syndrome is threats to SOEs credible.
caused by the lack of a credible commitment To a large extent, since the late-1990s, the
from the government to allow loss-making state sector bankruptcy reforms and privati-
SOEs to fail (Kornai 1980, 1992; for surveys zation (to be discussed in section 5.3) have
see Maskin and Xu 2001; Kornai, Maskin, hardened budget constraints, which turned
and Roland 2003).57 The key to hardening the state sector to profitability since the year
2000 (table 5). The effectiveness of these
reforms constitutes a big surprise for many
57 Concurrent with increased state sector losses,
experts.58 Indeed, as it is for other transition
between 1993 and 1995, inflation also worsened. A loss economies, hardening budget constraints
of control over monetary policy due to decentralization in and bankruptcy reform were some of the
credit control was blamed as the cause (Wang 1991; Huang
1996b). Sharing a similar perspective, Loren Brandt and
Xiaodong Zhu (2000) argue that facing competition from
the nonstate sector, the central government was forced to 58 Around that time, some authoritative China experts,
rely on money creation to finance the state sector, since the such as Nicolas R. Lardy (1998), worried that with a con-
central government supports the employment and invest- tinued increase of the number and value of NPLs, the
ment of the state sector. This not only softened budget Chinese financial system would collapse soon, which would
constraints of the state sector but also caused inflation. lead to economic disaster.
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1123

most difficult reforms in China. Given the creditor-friendly. Instead of being a law to
close interrelation between SOE debt and be enforced nationwide, however, this law
the state banking system, and between SOEs only served as a guideline for central-gov-
and social safety nets, radical bankruptcy ernment-sponsored local experiments. Very
reform or SOE restructuring could lead importantly, in experiments, local govern-
to massive social unrest and bankruptcy of ments deviated from the law substantially. To
state banks (Charles Booth 2004; Heilmann prevent local social problems, the administra-
2008). Moreover, state firms carry many tive practice of local governments in dealing
types of policy burdens, such as employment with insolvent enterprises favored employ-
and social security, etc. (Shleifer and Robert ees (Heilmann 2008). The early reform pro-
W. Vishny 1994; Lin, Fang Cai, and Zhou gressed fairly slowly, so that between 1989
Li 1997). With the policy burdens, the state and 1993, among tens of thousands of chron-
is accountable for the losses incurred from icle loss-making SOEs, there were only 1,150
policy burdens, and thus it has to bailout bankruptcy cases nationwide.
insolvent SOEs (Lin and Guofu Tan 1999).59 Pressured by rapidly growing SOE debts
There were intense political controver- and mounting state-bank-held NPLs, bank-
sies in drafting, updating, and finalizing the ruptcy reform emerged as a top-priority
bankruptcy law from the 1986 version to the issue in the 1990s. The central government
final 2006 version (Booth 2004).60 Facing sponsored new waves of local bankruptcy
vast difficulties and political risks, China’s experiments.61 In the peak years of restruc-
bankruptcy reform was carried out through turing and bankruptcy reforms from 1996 to
local experiments to deal with the social 2001, every year there were more than 5 or
and fiscal consequences of SOE insolven- 6 million SOE employees laid off nationwide
cies, and was used by central policymakers relatively peacefully (table 5). Summarizing
in their debates, decisions, lawmaking, etc. local experiment practices, the 2002 and
(Heilmann 2008). 2004 versions of the bankruptcy law gave
One of the most contested political and workers first priority over the rights of
legal issues in China’s bankruptcy reform was secured creditors; and the burden of pro-
about who should be assigned with priority viding compensation to the employees of
protection in the liquidation of assets. Should insolvent enterprises was put on local gov-
that be given to creditors (state banks, i.e., gov- ernments. As a result, the state sector was
ernment assets) or to employees (the source significantly transformed, total loses were
of potential social unrest) (Heilmann 2008)? reduced from 306.7 billion RMB in 1998 to
The first bankruptcy law, the “Experimental 184.6 billion RMB in 2000, net profits were
Bankruptcy Law” passed in 1986, was more increased from 21.3 billion RMB in 1998 to
958 billion RMB in 2005, when bankruptcy
and layoffs became negligible (table 5). SOE
59 In this logic, Lin and Zhiyun Li (2008) argue that
productivity in the corresponding period also
even privatization will not necessarily harden budget con-
straints. This is because bearing policy burdens, to provide
the same policy service a private enterprise will demand
more ex post subsidies from the government than an SOE 61 In 1994, the State Council issued a circular on trial
due to more agency problems between the state and pri- implementation of new insolvency procedures and spon-
vate firms. sored experiments in eighteen cities. Two years later, trial
60 Controversies revolved around safeguarding state implementations of new merger and insolvency proce-
assets in liquidations; containing the social and financial con- dures were tested in 56 cities. In the next year the State
sequences of SOE insolvencies; dealing with unemployment Council sponsored experiments in 117 cities for trial
and rearranging the social safety net function of the SOEs implementation of merger, bankruptcy, and reemployment
(pensions, health care, housing, etc.) (Heilmann 2008). procedures.
1124 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

improved significantly (Brandt, Chang-tai was pushed through by the central govern-
Hsieh, and Zhu 2008; Jefferson, Rawski, and ments as a high priority at the beginning
Yifan Zhang 2008).62 of the transition, privatization was and is a
Experimental bankruptcy reform pro- highly controversial subject in China due to
cesses helped “to conceal and manage fun- ideological and political reasons. As a result,
damental political-ideological controversies privatization has been postponed by the
that were at the heart of the delayed law Chinese government as much as possible.
making. Policy experimentation over twenty- Moreover, the Chinese privatization scheme
three years allowed recurrent adaptations in is not based on a rational design; instead, it
the application of the basic priority scheme is a result of political games given existing
and thereby helped to avoid open policy institutions. Due to this delay, at the time of
conflicts” (Heilmann 2008). When the bank- privatization, even though the state sector
ruptcy reform was carried out by local exper- was loss making and was deeply in debt, the
iments, the law was only “provisionary” and national economy was in a better shape and
formal bankruptcy proceedings in courts conditions for privatization were more ready
played a minor role. Generally, corporate than all other transition economies when
rescue measures were undertaken through they launched privatization. The nonstate
a variety of flexible, inconsistent, but less sector had already surpassed the state sector
painful policies that were experimented with in the national economy, while the market
locally (Heilmann 2008). The final version of had already replaced most of the planning
the Bankruptcy Law (2006) was not passed related to resource allocation, including the
until the reform experiments were over and product, capital, labor, and managerial labor
the number of bankruptcy cases dropped markets. Moreover, the improved productiv-
drastically. However, the final version of the ity of the state sector through earlier reforms,
law goes back to the protection of creditors as discussed in section 5.2, might also have
and did not retain those policies in favor of played an important role in making the tran-
protecting workers vis-à-vis creditors. sition smooth. Furthermore, the Chinese
privatization has been carried out by munici-
5.3 Privatization: Locally Initiated
pal governments at their discretion under
Experiments
regional competition for economic growth.
Although there is no empirical work that That is, they have opted not to privatize if
decomposes factors contributing to the turn- doing so would hurt their regional growth. As
around of the state sector from chronicle a result, China is an exceptional case among
loss-making to a profitable sector, perhaps all transition economies that did not suffer
the most effective reform was privatization, from recessions as CEE–FSU economies did
which sold most of the loss-making firms to during their privatizations (Saul Estrin et al.
private owners. In sharp contrast to other 2009). Instead, China’s privatization is asso-
transition economies, where privatization ciated with a high growth rate.
Privatization was officially banned and,
in practice, it was not encouraged by the
62 Of course, given that many reform measures were
central government until the late 1990s.
taking place in the same period of time, such as privatiza-
tion, layoffs, change of corporate governance, market com- However, given the local “ownership” of
petition, large scale FDI, and lower interest rates, it is a most of the Chinese SOEs and pressures
challenge for researchers to find out what specific reform faced by local governments, de facto privati-
measure has exactly contributed by how much to the
improvements of productivity and profitability of Chinese zation was tried quietly without official per-
firms. mission from the central government in the
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1125

process of restructuring local SOEs before contain the risks of privatization, a prevailing
the mid-1990s. Even in the late 1990s, it is privatization strategy chosen by most Chinese
still a city government’s decision whether or city governments is to sell the ownership of
not to privatize and how to privatize within SOEs and COEs to their employees. This is
their jurisdictions (Ross Garnaut et al. 2001, because employee ownership is the least con-
2005; Jie Gan, Yan Guo, and Xu 2010). troversial politically and ideologically.
Moreover, even by then, due to political Similar to the situation of the bankruptcy
and ideological constraints, privatization has reform, the most important impetus for
occurred in a camouflaged form such that privatizing SOEs was the large amount of
the term “privatization” is officially disguised debt built up by the state sector in the 1990s.
as “transforming the system” or “gaizhi” Distinctively different from the central gov-
in Chinese (Garnaut et al. 2001, 2005). ernment’s sponsorship of the bankruptcy
Nevertheless, in 2005, about two-thirds of reform, however, privatization was initiated
the Chinese SOEs and COEs with annual by city governments. The central govern-
turnover of more than 5 million RMB Yuan ment tolerated this by turning a blind eye
(about $620,000) have been privatized and to the actions of city governments. One of
the total asset value involved in the process the first regional privatization experiments
was about 11.4 trillion RMB (or 1.63 trillion was in Zhucheng, a city in Shandong prov-
USD) in 2005 (Guo, Gan, and Xu 2008). 63 ince. In that city, more than two thirds of the
Due to its recentness and the lack of data, SOEs were loss-making in 1992, with losses
the research on China’s privatization is still amounting to the city government’s total
very limited (Estrin et al.). fiscal revenue over eighteen months. The
One of the early major reforms attempted city government sold many SOEs to their
by many cities in the late 1980s, and which employees. Another representative example
lead to privatization later, was the leasing of is the municipal government of Shunde in
SOEs. The top managers of small- or medium- Guangdong. The Shunde city government
sized SOEs leased the firms by paying the sub- also encountered a serious debt problem
national government a fixed proportion of the when it privatized most of its state and col-
firms’ profits. This reform gradually led to de lective firms in 1992 (Garnaut et al. 2005).
facto privatization, since after some years of As a result of successful local experi-
leasing the share value of a manager would out- ments with privatization and the severity of
weigh that of the city government, the “state SBC problems in the state sector, privati-
owner.” The other major reform initiative, zation was gradually accepted by the cen-
which facilitated privatization later, was incor- tral government through several steps,
poration. Although officially incorporation was from an explicit “tolerance” policy to some
restricted to the exchange of shares among the proactive guidelines on privatization.64
SOEs, private shareholding was allowed in
some cities. The first reported cases were in 64 In 1993, the Third Plenum of the 14th CCP Congress
Guangzhou in the late 1980s, when employees endorsed the creation of a modern enterprise system,
of some SOEs bought a substantial amount of which approved the development of diversified forms of
shares of the firms where they worked. Under ownership including private ownership. Although much
of the political constraints on privatization were still in
severe political and ideological constraints, to place, this created a more tolerable environment for local
privatization experiments. In 1995, the central govern-
ment announced the policy of “retain the large, release
63 Based on the data collected from a nationwide ran- the small” (zhuada fangxiao), i.e., the state was to keep
dom survey of all Chinese industrial firms conducted in the largest few hundred SOEs in strategic industries and
2006. to give local governments full control rights to local SOEs.
1126 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

Finally, a green light was given by the improving firm performance.65 In contrast,
CCP’s 15th Congress, 1997 (see Research governments still kept substantial controls
Center of the CCP History 2009), which over those firms privatized through other
granted de jure ownership of local SOEs to methods, and these privatization strate-
local governments. By default, this implies gies failed to improve performance (Gan,
that the center has authorized the ‘owners,’ Guo, and Xu 2010).
mostly city governments, of smaller SOEs It is the decision of a given municipal gov-
to try everything on their own, including ernments whether to privatize and, if so,
privatization, although this has never been how to privatize. According to a nationwide
explicit. With this major change, the scale random survey, MBO was chosen mostly
of privatization gradually enlarged after by those cities that had stronger fiscal dis-
1997. cipline and/or were less concerned about
China’s regional experiments on privati- shedding labor, such as fast growing coastal
zation have adopted multiple approaches. cities like Ningbo, Wenzhou, Hangzhou,
These approaches include share issue priva- Changzhou, and Wuxi. Meanwhile, non-
tization (SIP), joint ventures with foreign MBO approaches were chosen mainly by
firms, management buyouts (MBO), and those city governments that had weak fiscal
sales to outsiders. Privatization in China discipline and a concentration of the state
has created concentrated private ownership sector, such as heavy industrial cities like
and about half of privatized firms in China Changchun, Jinzhou, Handan, and Xian
were sold to managers, i.e., through MBO, (Gan, Guo, and Xu 2010).
which has greatly changed corporate gov- The process of privatization illustrates
ernance and corporate performance (Gan, the importance of regional experiments in
Guo, and Xu 2010). advancing China’s reforms. To make this pic-
Not every privatization approach was ture sharper, it is important to point out that
effective. Based on their nationwide ran- MBO was never favored by the central gov-
dom sampling survey data, by controlling ernment. In fact, the mass media, which has
for privatized and not privatized firms; been tightly controlled by the central gov-
before privatization and after privatiza- ernment, was hostile to MBO. In contrast,
tion, based on a nationwide random sur- the central government-sponsored major
vey, Gan, Guo, and Xu (2010) found that, ownership reforms, such as share issuing
among all privatization methods, only privatization, failed to improve the perfor-
MBO had statistically significant positive mance of SOEs.66
impacts to the restructuring, corporate
governance and performance. One of the
most important changes associated with 65 Without differentiating between MBO and non-
MBO is that the state has retreated from MBO privatization, by examining formerly state-owned
firms after privatization. That is, after buy- large and medium-size enterprises for the period from
1994 to 1999 nationwide, Jefferson and Jian Su (2006)
ing out the firm, owner-managers became found that privatization increased productivity and invest-
the decisionmakers of their own firms on ments in research and development. Similarly, based on
issues like hiring, layoffs, wages, compen- firm level data collected from one city, Xiao-yuan Dong,
Louis Putterman, and Bulent Unel (2006) found that pri-
sation, production, marketing, and invest- vatization has significantly improved productivity and prof-
ments. Moreover, MBO firms substantially itability for urban firms.
66 It has been shown that China’s share issue privatiza-
restructured in a deeper way than other
tion has failed to contain costs and improve profitability
privatized firms. As a result, MBO had a (Qian Sun and Wilson H. S. Tong 2003; Jianping Deng,
statistically significant positive impact on Gan, and Jia He 2008).
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1127

5.4 The Impacts of Regional decentralization. The major focus of the


Decentralization on Growth paper is fiscal decentralization. In addition,
other reforms included in the regression
It is a major challenge to study the impact model are the HRS reform; and the share
of regional decentralization on economic of non-SOEs’ output in the total industrial
growth empirically. One of the most difficult output. As discussed in previous sections, the
issues is how to measure regional decentral- HRS reform and nonstate sector develop-
ization. The Chinese regional decentraliza- ment are all consequences of regional decen-
tion involves much more than simply fiscal tralization. Therefore, together with fiscal
decentralization. But how to measure statis- decentralization these variables capture a
tically nonfiscal elements of regional decen- large part of regional decentralization. At the
tralization is an unsettled subject. Moreover, same time, their regression models also con-
regional decentralization captures only part trol for the growth rate of per capita invest-
of the operations of China’s RDA regime. ment, the financial strength of a region, the
The effectiveness of regional experiments impacts of urbanization and the size of the
and regional competition is often conditioned population on economic growth, and price
on effectiveness of central control. That is, liberalization. All of these control variables
centralization is an essential part of the pic- have insignificant impacts to regional growth.
ture. In addition to the conceptual and theo- Lin and Liu discovered that, everything
retical problems in the literature, the lack of else being equal, the growth rate of per
statistics on broadly defined decentralization capita provincial GDP would increase by
is another major problem yet to be resolved. 3.62 percent in response to an increase of
Given the difficulties, most of the empirical the marginal retention rate of regional fiscal
literature concerning the impacts of regional revenue from 0 to 100 percent. Moreover,
decentralization on growth is restricted to the impact of the HRS on regional growth
fiscal decentralization. rates was similar to that of the fiscal decen-
Lin and Zhiqiang Liu (2000) and Jin, tralization. Furthermore, among all regional
Qian, and Weingast (2005) found that fis- decentralization variables, the one with the
cal decentralization contributed to regional largest impact was the nonstate sector devel-
growth in general, and to the development opment. Everything else being equal, the
of the regional nonstate sector in particular. regional GDP growth rate would increase by
Tao Zhang and Zou (1998) found a negative 14.2 percent if the share of the nonstate sec-
relationship between fiscal decentralization tor increased from 0 to 100 percent.
and regional economic growth in China, but Consistent with Lin and Liu, by using
Lin and Liu and Jin, Qian, and Weingast provincial data from 1980 to 1993, Jin,
suggested potential data and methodological Qian, and Weingast found that stronger
problems in Zhang and Zou. fiscal incentives are associated with faster
Lin and Liu use provincial data from 1970 development of nonstate enterprises and with
to 1993 to study the impact of fiscal decen- greater reforms in state-owned enterprises.
tralization on regional economic growth. Furthermore, Jin, Qian, and Weingast found
Their regressions are based on a Solow provincial governments in China faced
type of growth model. Economic growth stronger ex post fiscal incentives after the
is decomposed into growth of per capita reform. Specifically, they found a strong
investment and growth of total factor pro- correlation between the current provincial
ductivity. All the major reforms included in budgetary revenue and its expenditure
the regression models are related to regional for the period of 1982–91 when the “fiscal
1128 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

contracting system” was implemented. The governments’ de facto ownership over


Jin, Qian, and Weingast discovery is echoed regional SOEs has been transformed into de
by a literature that argues that the different jure or nearly de jure ownership.67 Together
fiscal federalist approaches used by China and with other major changes, this endorsement
the FSU are related to well/poorly defined paved the road for subnational governments
tax rights for subnational governments and to privatize SOEs and COEs (Garnaut et
strong/weak fiscal incentives for subnational al. 2005). Moreover, subnational govern-
governments. Some of this literature claims ments were authorized to sell land within
that these shed light on the performance gap their jurisdictions. Secondly, these changes
between China and Russia (Shleifer 1997; in turn have had impacts on fiscal matters,
Daniel Berkowitz and Li 2000; Zhuravskaya so that the revenues of subnational govern-
2000). ments in more developed regions created
However, the results of both Lin and Liu through privatization and selling land in the
and Jin, Qian, and Weingast are based on past years could sufficiently offset losses
data up to 1993. As discussed previously, of their tax revenue. Control rights over
fiscal policy was substantially recentralized land give subnational government impor-
after 1994. This makes these results vulner- tant leverage over regional development,
able to challenges (Tsui and Wang 2004; regional industrial policy, and macro control
Mertha 2005). of the region (to be further discussed in sec-
Nevertheless, the Lin and Liu–Jian, Qian, tion 6.1). To summarize, although the share
and Weingast evidence constitutes a valu- of subnational governments’ tax revenue in
able step in understanding the impacts of national tax revenue was reduced substan-
regional decentralization on regional growth. tially, subnational governments’ importance
After all, fiscal decentralization is an impor- in regional governance and in national eco-
tant part of regional decentralization, which nomic development remains essential. The
includes land reform, SEZs, and nonstate central government still relies on subna-
sector development. The period before 1994 tional governments to govern the bulk of
is one in which fiscal decentralization is fully the Chinese economy and subnational gov-
consistent with regional decentralization in ernments still dominate regional economic
general. Thus, fiscal decentralization may be affairs, including fiscal and nonfiscal matters,
a good proxy for regional decentralization in such as allocating critical resources to firms,
that period of time. However, the contribu- dealing with contract enforcement, and
tion of nonfiscal reforms to economic growth property rights protection.
is pooled together with fiscal decentraliza-
tion so that the contribution of each remains
6.  Trade-Offs of Regional Decentralization
entangled. That is, the identification prob-
lem has yet to be resolved in this literature. Rent-seeking behavior and general conser-
Last but not least, it should be pointed out vatism are inherent features of an authoritar-
that although taxation has been recentral- ian regime, therefore making them difficult
ized since the mid-1990s, it is not clear that to reform. However, under the RDA regime,
regional decentralization has been reversed
completely in general. Firstly, in the same 67 In 2005, subnational governments owned about
period of “fiscal recentralization” subna- thirty-one thousand SOEs plus control of a huge number
tional governments gained more power in of COEs (NSB 2006b) whereas the central government
owned 166 firms (the State-Owned Assets Supervision and
some nonfiscal spheres. Endorsed by the Administration Commission, or SASAC: http://www.sasac.
15th Party’s Congress in 1997, subnational gov.cn/gzwgk/gzwgk_jj.htm).
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1129

rents could be eliminated if subnational gov- SEZs, were less intrusive to rural stakehold-
ernments face fierce regional competition: ers’ interests, such as land.
given the importance of winning the compe- However, after a quarter century’s fast
tition, if losing a competition implies losing economic growth, the multitask nature of
a position, which is the necessary condition subnational governments’ duties has become
for enjoying rents. Moreover, as discussed more pronounced and the general consen-
in section 2, regional experimentation and sus on the importance of economic growth
regional competition can alleviate the prob- has broken down. Many major growth-
lem of conservatism, enabling reforms to enhancing reforms implemented since the
move forward. mid-1990s generated immediate conflicts
However, regional competition and among stakeholders. A prominent example
regional experimentation are effective only is firm restructuring and privatization, which
when subnational governments’ tasks can be started in the 1990s. In those reforms, a
summarized by a single indicator, e.g., eco- large number of SOE employees were laid
nomic growth. If subnational governments off, whereas new private owners obtained
face multiple tasks that cannot be encom- huge amounts of wealth through manage-
passed under a single objective, regional ment buy-outs. Another example is associ-
competition and regional experiments may ated with large-scale rapid urbanization,
become focused on tasks, which are more which converts arable land for nonagricul-
measurable, while less measurable tasks are tural developments and creates a great num-
ignored. In that case, high-powered incen- ber of landless peasants. This often leads to
tives created through regional competition sharp conflicts between those who lost land
may lead to undesirable consequences. Even without receiving proper compensation, and
worse than this, subnational governments property developers who profited immensely
may be induced to race to the bottom, i.e., from the transactions, and are usually closely
regions may compete in or may experiment associated with subnational governments.
on some policies that may benefit regional
6.1 Law and Regulation
officials but damage most other citizens, or
may benefit the region but damage other Under the RDA regime, Chinese subna-
regions. tional governments play significant roles in
At earlier stages of the reform, it was both law enforcement and law making. The
commonly agreed by the central govern- aforementioned provincial law on SEZs, “the
ment, subnational governments, and citizens Regulation for Guangdong SEZs,” illustrates
that economic growth was the most impor- that subnational legislation can also serve
tant objective of China’s economic reform. as the experimental basis for new national
Under that consensus, other objectives can legislation. Subnational governments were
be overlooked so long as the economy grows endowed with law-making power since the
rapidly. Thus, regional competition and PRC’s founding in 1949. Although most of
regional experiments faced easier tradeoffs. their de jure law-making power was taken
Moreover, at earlier stages of the reforms, away during the centralization movement
most growth-enhancing policies and institu- of the 1950s, subnational governments kept
tional changes avoided immediate conflicts some de facto law-making powers. At the
among stakeholders. The land reform (HRS onset of the reform, subnational governments
reform) distributed land equally among rural regained much of their law-making power
households. The TVE development and other (http://www.china.com.cn/zhuanti2005/
nonstate sector developments, including txt/2003-02/27/content_5283965.htm), and
1130 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

these gains were institutionalized by the 1982 helped avoid governance ­vacuums, as pri-
constitutional amendment. In addition, the vate businesses were at times disguised by
central government from time to time exper- subnational governments. Indeed, many of
imented with giving additional law-making the initiatives and protections provided by
powers to subnational governments, such as subnational governments to private firms
“authorized law-making power” (shouquan flew in the face of the constitution. Thus,
lifa) or “beforehand law-making power” strong incentives given to subnational gov-
(xianxing lifa). As a result, more than six thou- ernments played essential roles for them to
sands laws have enacted by subnational gov- take the risks associated with their unconsti-
ernments nationwide since 1978. Conflicts tutional actions.
that arise between regional laws and national The roles of the municipal governments of
laws are one of the major concerns of this sys- Taizhou and Wenzhou of Zhejiang province
tem, although, in principle, whenever there in developing private sectors ahead of rele-
are conflicts the national law overrules. vant legal developments illustrate this point.
However, the starting point of China’s The municipal governments offered “red
legal reform is among the weakest of all heads” to private firms within their jurisdic-
transition economies, since during the CR tion to conceal their vulnerable legal status,
China dismantled its formal legal system. thereby giving the outsiders the illusion of
As a result, China has had to build its legal official government sanction. Thanks to this
system virtually from scratch during the kind of development in many regions where
reform era. Moreover, ideological and politi- subnational governments provided similar
cal constraints delayed major legal reforms, protections, the private sector in China expe-
such as the protection of private property rienced double-digit growth for more than a
rights. Together with the lack of judiciary decade without full legal protection. To some
independence, China was in a weaker posi- extent it is this spectacular development of
tion than average transition economies in the private sector that catalyzed the legal-
terms of legal reforms. It is not surprising ization of private property rights. When the
that a lack of proper law and law enforce- constitutional protection of private property
ment can lead to serious problems, and I will rights was enacted in 2004, the private sector
discuss some of the most serious problems was already the dominant sector in Zhejiang
related to Chinese law later in this subsec- and one of the largest sectors in China.
tion. However, the coexistence of very fast- Concerning regulation, given its weakness
growing businesses, including the private in legal institutions, under the RDA regime,
sector, and a very weak formal legal sector China introduced an administration-based
is puzzling. The solution to this puzzle lies in regulatory decentralization scheme. In this
the fact that regionally decentralized admin- scheme, the central regulatory authorities
istrative measures step in as substitutes for break down the regulatory tasks and delegate
law and law enforcement (Pistor and Xu them to subnational governments. Together
2005).68 In the past, this has s­ometimes with regional competition, this system some-
times is able to implement some national
68 It is worthwhile to note that there are many cases
in which business practice preceded relevant laws in laws, such as contract law and tort law, on new business
European and American history. For example, important practices (Xu and Pistor 2006). But in Chinese reforms, a
securities laws (US 1933/34 Acts) were developed decades basic functioning legal system itself is under construction.
behind major developments in U.S. securities markets. Thus, subnational governments are essential as substitut-
However, in Europe and the United States, there were ing mechanisms to fill in the governance gap (Pistor and
functioning legal systems that effectively enforced general Xu 2005).
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1131

regulatory goals, but sometimes fails to do governments in turn would allocate quotas
so. The regulatory scheme that evolved dur- to selected SOEs for going public through
ing the last twenty years relies essentially IPOs or to listed companies seeking SEOs.
on subnational governments’ assistance and The subnational governments would collect
cooperation for enforcement of its regula- information on these firms and submit it to
tions (Julan Du and Xu 2008). In this sys- the China Securities Regulatory Commission
tem, one of the major instruments that are (CSRC), the national regulatory agent. After
deployed is the quota system. reviewing the company information, the
The bank credit quota system, which CSRC would give its approval to companies
was utilized by the People’s Bank of China to issue shares in the public equity markets.
(PBC) to control the aggregate money sup- The quota system was officially in place from
ply until 1998, is an example of one such 1993 to 2000; however, it actually governed
quota (Du and Xu 2008). The PBC formu- financial markets up until around 2003
lated the national credit plan and allocated (Pistor and Xu 2005).
credit quotas to the headquarters of all major Although the quota system was not
state banks, which in turn reallocated these designed for dealing with informational or
to their regional branches and subsidiar- incentive problems, several bodies of evi-
ies. The regional allocation of bank credit dence indicate that it has played a signifi-
quotas depends largely on regional banking cant role in creating incentives for regional
performance, measured in ways such as the competition and decentralized information
amount of deposits taken by regional banks collection in stock issuance. Based on the
in the previous year; regional economic per- data of all listed firms from 1993 to 2004,
formance; and a variety of other metrics. The after controlling for political factors, macro
bank credit quota system was a major instru- variables, etc., Du and Xu (2008) find that
ment for implementing macroeconomic firms located in regions with better perfor-
policies in general and monetary policy in mance obtained more quotas in subsequent
particular until market-based credit alloca- periods. In explaining firm-level quotas by
tion mechanisms were somewhat deployed provincial performance, this result essen-
in the late 1990s. tially rules out the possibility of reverse cau-
Another major example is the evolu- sality, since none of the firms in the sample
tion of Chinese financial market regulation. were large enough to affect provincial per-
China’s securities markets, the Shanghai and formance. In addition, the data demonstrate
Shenzhen stock exchanges, initially emerged that everything else being equal, listed firms
as self-regulated regional markets with from provinces that disclosed information
supervision from the corresponding munici- better were rewarded with more stock quo-
pal governments (Stephen Green 2003). tas in the ensuing periods. Moreover, the
The quota system of equity share issuance quality of regional information disclosure
was introduced to the Chinese equity mar- was substantially more important than other
ket in 1993, and was designed to control the factors, such as regional corporate or macro
size of financial markets to maintain balance performances, in determining how quotas
among the regions and to preserve the domi- were allocated. These findings suggest that
nant position of public ownership. The cen- provinces that performed better in various
tral government would determine the total aspects previously would be given a higher
number of shares to be issued in the nation stock issuance quota later from the central
and then would allocate stock issuance quo- government. That is, the quota allocation
tas to regions and ministries. Subnational functioned as a de facto incentive device
1132 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

that induced subnational governments to use quota for each year and regions violating
select better-performing firms for initial the land-use quota would face a deduction in
public offerings (IPOs) or seasoned equity future quota allocation, together with other
offerings (SEOs). Finally, detailed evidence penalties. Moreover, an official’s compliance
from twenty-three provincial-level regions with quotas is taken as part of the criteria for
suggests that the majority of IPO firms evaluating his work. However, because this
selected by subnational governments had quota system violates all the three aforemen-
been better-performing state-owned enter- tioned conditions, the land quota system fails
prises before they went public (Julan Du and to work.
Chenggang Xu 2009). This further indicates In fact, the land problem is one of the
that the Chinese regulatory decentralization most serious social problems in China and it
is somewhat effective at the IPO stage. can be used as an illustration of how China’s
However, administration-based regulatory RDA system makes trouble for the economy.
decentralization is not always effective, and it Deeply-flawed laws governing land owner-
is not a long-term substitute for law enforce- ship and fiscal recentralization “collectively”
ment. There are several conditions that must incentivize local governments to ignore the
be met for decentralized admin measures to quota system (Kung, Xu, and Feizhou Zhou
function well as a substitute for conventional forthcoming). Arable land in China is de jure
legal institutions. Firstly, subnational govern- collectively owned and, in this system, the
ments must have substantial control rights commune authorities before the reform, and
over the regulatory subjects; otherwise, sub- the village authorities afterwards, represent
national governments would not play a major the collectives. Although rights of use and
regulatory role (e.g., the quota system does income over land have been reassigned to
not work effectively for non-state-owned the farm households since the land reform
firms and cannot ensure adequate corporate of the early 1980s, the farmers have no right
governance of listed companies). Secondly, to alter the land’s usage or to transfer it to
subnational governments must have strong another party. The crucial right to transfer
vested interests in the subjects of regulation; these rights has remained in the hands of the
otherwise, subnational governments would state and, in part, of the village authorities.
not be motivated to participate. Finally, the Yet, the collective owners have no right to
central government must have direct control convert arable land into nonarable usages.
over the resources to be allocated by a quota Nationalization has been the only legal
system; otherwise information problems will mechanism by which farmland can be con-
disable the system. For example, the quotas verted into nonarable usages since any non-
systems used for bank credit control and for arable usage of collective farmland requires
environment protection did not work well a change from collective to state ownership
since these quotas are nominal, the financial (Articles 63 and 43 of the Land Management
resources of local banks or local branches of Law of 1999). Moreover, the law confines
national banks and pollutant emissions are farmers’ rights in land to basically an “agrar-
directly controlled by local governments, and ian” usage when land use is changed to
they can easily manipulate the information. nonagrarian and ownership converted (from
In order to prevent excessive conversion collective to state). In other words, farmers
of arable land for nonagricultural uses, the would only be compensated according to the
Chinese government has applied a land quota value of crop production after conversion,
system to regulate local governments’ land even though the land postconversion may be
conversion. Each region is allocated a land- far more valuable. Apart from the minimal
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1133

compensation that is legally protected, the bundle of rights assigned to them at the
China’s farmers are subject to the whims of outset of the reform. Opposite to the harmo-
local authorities in the process of land con- nious atmosphere at the era of land reform,
version (Kung, Xu, and Zhou forthcoming). i.e., the early 1980s, land expropriation by
As discussed previously, the fiscal recentral- local governments now becomes one of the
ization of 1994 reduced the share of local gov- worst sources of social conflicts in China
ernments’ entitlement to most tax sources. To (Xiaolin Guo 2001; Lianjiang Li and Kevin
compensate local governments for the losses, J. O’Brien 2008). This illustrates that, with-
local governments were assigned greater con- out a properly developed legal system, many
trol rights over revenues generated by land problems cannot be resolved by regional
sales within their jurisdictions. From 2002 competition, regional experimentation, per-
onwards, the central government further pro- sonnel control, and other methods deployed
posed to appropriate 50 percent of the enter- by the RDA regime.
prise profit tax, which greatly disincentivizes
6.2 Regional Protections
local governments’ efforts to improve enter-
prise efficiency. The fiscal recentralization, Regional decentralization alone may not
together with the monopoly right assigned automatically guarantee growth-enhancing
to local governments over the conversion regional competition. Without checks of the
of farmland to nonarable uses, has induced central government, subnational officials
local governments to switch from a passion may restrict cross-regional trade to protect
for industrialization to “urbanization” frenzy firms within their jurisdiction. Indeed, it is
(Kung, Xu, and Zhou forthcoming). oft-cited that subnational governments opt
Blessed with escalating land prices (espe- to put up barriers to shield local firms and
cially for commercial and real estate devel- industries from competition. It was docu-
opments in premium locations) on the one mented that, in the mid-1980s, many subna-
hand and artificially low compensations on tional governments tried to retain low priced
the other, many local governments, particu- raw materials, such as wool or silk, within
larly those in the rapidly developing coastal their jurisdictions in order to favor local man-
areas, have pocketed “windfall profits” from ufacturers (Andrew Watson, Christopher
this urbanization process. Attracted by the Findlay, and Yintang Du 1989; Thomas P.
huge “windfall profits,” land conversion has Bernstein and Xiaobo Lu 2000), and this was
accelerated after 1999. In 2003, the state also widely reported by both domestic and
became worried that China would soon international mass media coverage.69
deplete its arable land below its thresh- If there are no effective central-govern-
old required for food self-sufficiency. In ment policies to keep barriers in check, in
an attempt to slow down the conversion of addition to making factors immobile as most
farmland, since 2001 the central government often emphasized in the literature, regional
has set land conversion quotas for all prov-
inces for each year. But with seriously dis-
torted incentives, the land quota assignment 69 For example, a New York Times report illustrated

did not work. Much worse, in the process of trade barriers among Chinese regions. To protect their
local made car manufacturers, “Tianjin local officials
land conversion, local authorities have trig- barred taxi companies in the city from buying Geelys,”
gered serious conflicts with the farmers, as which are produced by a Zhejiang-based car manufacturer
a large number of farmers lost their primary (New York Times, November 17, 2006). Casual observa-
tions confirm this as a general phenomenon that most taxi
source of livelihood with minimal compensa- cabs in many major cities, e.g., Beijing, Tianjin, Shanghai,
tion. They feel that they have been robbed of Changchun, and Guangzhou, are made locally.
1134 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

protection could destroy regional compe- debated intensively in the literature. There
tition itself, one of the basic mechanisms is abundant literature about, statistical evi-
that drive China’s reform and development. dence of, and mass media coverage of the
Moreover, interregional trade barriers and fast growing interregional trade (Holz 2009).
regional protectionism can eventually lead Indeed, one of the most important early
to serious political problems, such as disinte- reforms in the early 1980s was the legal-
gration of the country. ization of cross-region trade carried out by
Recognizing the seriousness of the prob- state and nonstate merchants, including pri-
lem, the Chinese central government has vate traders. Lau, Qian, and Roland (2000)
battled against regional protectionism contend that the “dual-track system,” intro-
repeatedly during the whole reform period. duced during the reforms, promotes interre-
The central government has issued decrees gional trade because, under this system, local
in 1982, 1990, and 2001 to curb regional pro- officials can “sell” the rights to purchase a
tectionism (Carsten A. Holz 2009). A State certain percentage of raw materials and final
Council circular of 10 April 1982 states: products at lowered planned prices. Since
“regional or departmental (trade) block- opening up the market to other regions may
ages . . . are extremely harmful to China’s significantly increase the market price, this
economy in total.” The State Council clari- system is beneficial for local officials.
fied that enterprises had the authority to In an ideal situation with perfect national
sell their above-plan output anywhere in markets, all factors would be mobile, and
the country they wanted, and subnational therefore their productivities across regions
governments were not to interfere in the would be equalized; regional economies
distribution of the above-plan output. In would utilize their comparative advantages,
1990, the State Council issued a circular on their production would be specialized,
breaking interregional blockades. It requires and regional prices for the same products
that all regional trade checkpoints must be would converge. Based on this idea, taking
rectified, and differential tax rates based on the first best case as the benchmark, it has
product origin were prohibited. The State been argued that the Chinese economy has
Council issued another regulation in 2001 become fragmented regionally and that the
to deal with issues of the malfunctioning of situation was getting worse. Young (2000)
the “market order,” including regional trade reported widespread convergence in the
barriers. It contains detailed stipulations for regional structure of production during the
eliminating specific kinds of regional trade reform period, and a rise in the interre-
barriers (Holz 2009). The great efforts of the gional variation of prices during the 1980s.
central government in containing regional Moreover, there was a divergence of regional
protectionism demonstrate the stubbornness relative factor allocations and labor produc-
of the problem and the determination of the tivities. These findings were interpreted
central government to contain the problem. as evidence of industrial duplication across
It also underscores the “checks-and-bal- regions caused by regional barriers. Based
ances” between the central government and on this, he claimed that regional protection
subnational governments in the context of in China was worsening and that Chinese
regional competition. reforms resulted in a fragmented internal
Whether or not the central government’s market with fiefdoms controlled by local offi-
efforts in confining regional protectionism cials. To some extent, similarly, by studying
and whether or not regional fragmentation capital mobility across provinces, Genevieve
has worsened during the reform have been Boyreau-Debray and Shang-Jin Wei (2005)
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1135

found great discrepancies in regional mar- specialization. Echoing this finding, Fan and
ginal capital productivities and from this Wei (2006) also find the convergence trend
concluded that the Chinese financial system in China is similar to those discovered in the
was regionally fragmented. United States and Canada. In these three
However, by using more diverse and economies, many prices follow relative price
recent data than that of Young (2000), Bai convergence rather than absolute price con-
et al. (2004) found that regional specializa- vergence. Obviously, it will not be convincing
tion has increased and has become domi- to claim that market development in China is
nant over the forces of regional protection at a similar level of the United States given
in recent years. Moreover, with a data set this evidence. However, it would be even
that consists of 93 products in thirty-six cities harder to claim, based on this methodology,
over more than ten years, C. Simon Fan and that Chinese economic reforms have moved
Xiangdong Wei (2006) provided evidence the economy further away from markets.
of market integration during the reform In fact, it is quite likely that applying a
period. They found an overall price conver- similar approach, regional specialization in
gence in China that indicates that markets Russia, or more generally in the CIS and
across different cities are indeed integrated. Central–Eastern European countries, is
Furthermore, they found that the products much higher than that in China before 1990.
for which interregional trade was more likely But it would be misleading to interpret this
to be restricted by local officials for rent- as evidence for more-developed markets in
seeking purposes tended to converge to a these locations. Indeed, based on the theo-
greater degree of absolute price parity. This ries discussed in sections 3 and 4, an econ-
finding suggests that local protectionism omy with overly specialized regions would
might be a less important obstacle to inter- hamper regional competition and experi-
regional trade in China than some other fac- mentation. Of course, in those theories, the
tors, such as transportation costs. composition of regional economies is exog-
Yet, there are serious concerns regard- enous. A more complete theory has yet to be
ing the methodologies used to study trade developed to analyze dynamics of regional
barriers. Specifically, focusing on measur- competitions when both the composition of
ing regional specialization alone may not be regional economies and scale economies are
most helpful in understanding regional pro- endogenously chosen by players.
tection since it does not have the warrant of a
6.3 Regional Disparity
theoretical foundation. As Naughton (2003)
points out, without an underlying theory and In light of record-breaking rapid and
without a cross-country comparison, i.e., prolonged growth, the quickly increasing
without knowing proper benchmarks, look- disparity of wealth in China has become
ing at one country’s regional specialization a major concern. It is commonly agreed in
alone might be misleading. Indeed, state the literature that inequality in China has
manufacturing sectors in the United States, substantially worsened since the reforms,
an integrated national economy, became mainly in the past two decades. Based on
less specialized than before 1987, and they household data from nine provinces, Dwayne
became more similar than they were in Benjamin et al. (2008) find that the overall
the past (Sukkoo Kim 1995). Moreover, (combined urban–rural) Gini coefficient
by using a similar approach, Holz (2009) of China probably exceeds 0.50, which
finds that Chinese provinces are similar to is approaching that of some of the most
American states in their degree of regional unequal countries in the world, e.g., South
1136 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

America. Based on provincial level aggregate inequality can even lead to the disintegration
data, Ravi Kanbur and Zhang (2005) found of a nation (Patrick Bolton and Roland 1997).
that, associated with the increase of GDP and Concerning China’s growing inequality, it
trade, the Gini coefficient has increased from has been warned that increased regional
0.29 in 1978 to 0.37 in 2000. To what degree inequality in China may threaten economic
regional decentralization has contributed to and political stability, and national unity
this increased inequality is a hotly contested (Hu, Wang, and Xiaoguang Kang 1995).
subject in the literature. Is the Chinese duo of high growth and
The relationship between growth and increasing disparity a “normal” development
inequality is a subject of debate in the litera- path prescribed by the well-known Kuznets
ture (for a survey sees Philippe Aghion, Eve curve? Will worsening inequality hurt
Caroli, and Cecilia Garcia-Penalosa 1999). China’s economic growth? To what extent
In the classical view, inequality is regarded as is the widening disparity related to regional
necessary and transitional in the process of decentralization? These are issues still under
industrialization or growth (Simon Kuznets debate in the literature.
1955). Moreover, an increase of inequality Although empirical findings unequivo-
may not be so bad even for the poor when an cally show rapidly increasing inequality,
economy grows quickly, since the poor ben- particularly during the recent twenty years
efit more from increasing aggregate growth of reforms, findings on the relationship
than from reducing inequality through between inequality and reforms, includ-
redistribution (David Dollar and Aart Kraay ing decentralization, are divided. Based on
2001). China’s rapidly increasing per capita a Chinese household survey dataset with
income came together with rises in inequal- about one million households in the period
ity and is used as a major example to illustrate between 1980 and 2002, Martin Ravallion
the above point (Danny Quah 2003). This and Shaohua Chen (2007) found that
line of thought would argue that the reform inequality was not always related to growth-
policy in the first two decades of Chinese enhancing reforms, and that there was no
reforms enabled some people to become overall evidence of an aggregate growth-
rich first. Driven by this policy and imple- equity tradeoff in China. They found that
mented within the framework of regional higher growth in rural areas, which cor-
decentralization, arguably, in the last quarter responds well with HRS reform and TVE
century, China has experienced the largest development, brought inequality down.
scale of poverty reduction in human history. It reduced inequality within both urban
The Chinese population in absolute poverty and rural areas, as well as between them.
(defined as $1/day income) has dropped Moreover, provinces with worse dispari-
from 50 percent to 7 percent in twenty years, ties, both within rural areas and between
while the number of individuals in absolute urban and rural areas, were less able to
poverty was reduced by almost 400 million. speed up rural economic growth. However,
This number is nearly three-quarters of pov- urban economic growth was positively cor-
erty reduction in the whole developing world related with inequality. Moreover, they
(World Bank 2003). found that the increases in public spending
On the other hand, however, it is argued reduced poverty but not inequality. And,
that inequality has impacts on politics, the increases in public spending tended to
investment, etc., which in turn can harm come from subnational governments, not
stability and growth in general (e.g., Alberto the central government. Finally, they found
Alesina and Rodrik 1994); and high levels of substantial regional variations such that
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1137

provinces with a more rapid rise in inequal- Tsui 1993; Jian Chen and Belton M. Fleisher
ity usually made less progress in poverty 1996; Zhang and Kanbur 2001), they contend
reduction. that regional disparity in general, and inland–
Based on rural household-level data col- coastal disparity in particular, is a key dimen-
lected in nine provinces during 1986 to 1999, sion of increased inequality in the reform
Benjamin, Brandt, and John Giles (2005) era. From 1978 to 2000, the inland–coastal
made qualitatively similar conclusions. They GE component increased by nine times,
found that initial inequality affects growth, from 0.4 percent in 1978 to 3.8 percent in
whereas rising inequality is not related to the 2000. They argue that this rapid widening of
growth trajectory. Specifically, they found the gap between coastal and inland regions
that villages with higher inequality initially— is mainly due to FDI and trade since the two
i.e., in 1986—in their sample, grew more regions have different opportunities. On the
slowly over the next thirteen years. However, other hand, the rural–urban GE coefficient
in village fixed-effects specifications, there is component increased from 11 percent in
no statistical relationship between inequality 1978 to 13.9 percent in 2000. Although this
and growth. They believe this suggests that raise looks marginal, there was an inverse
the mechanism linking growth to inequality trend, as the number had bottomed out at
operates “in the long run.” They also found 6.4 percent in 1984 when the HRS reform
that more unequal villages had the slow- was completed.70 They argue that the wors-
est nonagricultural development. Part of ening of the rural–urban disparity was also
the explanations for the long-run impacts related to FDI and exporting.
of inequality on growth may be related to Based on provincial-level data, Lin and
their other findings. That is, low inequality Peilin Liu (2005) and Fleisher and Chen
is related to the effect of village education, (1997) also claimed that widened regional
which leads to higher income growth, espe- disparities were related to regional decen-
cially of nonfarm incomes. tralization. Lin and Liu (2005) emphasize
Yet, worries over ever-increasing inequal- different subnational governments’ strate-
ity are increasing, and the impact of regional gies and their effectiveness in economic
decentralization on inequality has been hotly development, whereas Chen and Fleisher
debated. Some scholars even argue that the (1996) attribute the widened disparity to
rapid widening of regional disparity caused the central government’s policies of favoring
by regional decentralization can lead to the the development of coastal regions, as most
disintegration of China (Hu, Wang, and important reform policies favoring coastal
Kang 1995). Kanbur and Zhang (2005) claim regions are FDI- and export-related poli-
that fiscal decentralization is responsible for cies. Similarly, Shujie Yao and Zongyi Zhang
the rise of nationwide inequality. (2001), Sylvie Demurger (2001) and Xiaolan
Based on provincial level aggregate data, Fu (2004) all claim that these reforms con-
Kanbur and Zhang (2005) use the GE (the tribute to regional inequality. They report
generalized entropy index) inequality coef- that both exports and FDI have significant
ficient, which increased from 0.14 in 1978 and positive impacts on growth in coastal
to 0.25 in 2000, and decompose Chinese regions, but not in inland regions.
inequality into three components: inland– Fiscal recentralization was proposed as a
coastal and rural–urban. They suggest that policy remedy to ease regional disparities.
regional decentralization has contributed
to about one-third of Chinese inequality. 70 Ravallion and Chen (2007) report a similar trend of
Consistent with some earlier literature (e.g., rural–urban disparity over this period of time.
1138 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

However, based on county-level data, Tsui that, during the 1990s, the difference in
(2005) and Zhang (2006) find that the average incomes between the two regions
regional fiscal disparities have worsened widened considerably. However, much of
since the 1994 fiscal recentralization. the increase in the gap appears to be the
Regional disparities in per capita fiscal result of a growing difference in incomes
expenditures (and by implication, the between rural households in the coastal and
provision of services) are extraordinarily interior provinces. By 2000, rural incomes in
large across rural governments, and they the coastal provinces were about 50 percent
were persistent since the peak reached in higher than they are in the interior, whereas
the late 1990s. Among the 2,800 county- the urban income gap between the two
level jurisdictions, in 2003 the richest spent regions did not widen much. Consistently,
forty-eight times as much as the poorest—a inequality in the coastal provinces increases
gap that is unusually large compared to that only slightly (from 0.35 to 0.39), whereas
of other countries (Wong 2007). increases are larger in the interior (from 0.39
Yet, one has to be careful about real to 0.48). The significantly larger increase
mechanisms behind the so-called fiscal in the interior is attributed to the increase
decentralization or fiscal centralization as in inequality in rural areas in the interior
most of the empirical work in the literature (increases from 0.40 to 0.49) compared to
is based on aggregate data and is carried out the coastal provinces, which remains under
in a reduced form. As we discussed previ- 0.40; and a widening rural–urban income
ously, at certain times fiscal decentralization gap in the interior (which widened from 1.58
is concurrent with regional decentralization to 1.85) compared to the coastal areas (which
such that a correlation with fiscal decentral- fell from 1.60 to 1.32).
ization in such a period could capture some Benjamin et al.’s findings suggest a strong
things other than fiscal decentralization. link between inequality and regional decen-
On the other hand, since the mid-1990s, in tralization, but due to a different mecha-
addition to fiscal recentralization there have nism than many others proposed. Instead of
been many changes in regional decentral- regional disparity, they argue that economic
ization. Thus, further research should be opportunity for citizens varies across regions,
done to study the impacts of regional decen- and this affects the development of rural
tralization and various specific reforms on areas. Thus, local institutions and differences
inequality. in the opportunities for people living in the
Based on household data from nine prov- same community explain most of the rising
inces, Benjamin et al. found that the contri- inequalities. Concretely, they contend that at
bution of regional disparities to household the outset of the reforms, the role of the state
inequality was increasing and peaked in the sector was significantly more important in the
mid-1990s, when fiscal policy was recentral- interior than in the coastal provinces. During
ized, and since then it has declined. They the reform, the growth of the nonstate sec-
find that, after the mid-1990s, most of the tor in the interior provinces has been much
inequality in China is within the villages and slower. This has handicapped the growth in
cities in which Chinese households live and rural incomes in both the urban and rural
work; that is, most of the inequality was due sectors. In contrast, growth in the nonstate
to differences of income among households sector in coastal provinces has provided
in the same province. opportunities to rural households, which
Concerning the disparity between coastal has prevented a sharp deterioration in rural
and interior regions, Benjamin et al. found inequality like that observed in the interior.
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1139

6.4 Resolving China’s Institutional However, most provincial governments who


Problems initially joined this “Green GDP” project
have withdrawn from it due to a conflict of
The lack of an independent judiciary, interests (between growth and other objec-
rent-seeking behavior, and unresponsive- tives) and disagreements on technical issues
ness to citizens’ preferences are some of related to its measurement. Indeed, this idea
the intrinsic deficiencies of an authoritar- is fundamentally flawed and the problem can
ian regime, and China’s RDA regime is no be traced back to the Lange versus Hayek
exception. As discussed previously, some of debate on the feasibility/infeasibility of cen-
those problems might be mitigated under tralized information collection. The GDP
the RDA regime when economic growth measurement is market-based and, there-
is an overwhelming objective because the fore, market transactions have already solved
multiple tasks of a regional government can a large share of the associated incentive and
be effectively converted into a single task, information problems. The difficulties in
achieving a high GDP growth rate. Under measuring nonmarket activities, i.e., beyond
this condition, regional competition can alle- GDP measurement, are notoriously difficult
viate many problems. due to incentive and technical problems. If
However, when there are many tasks that there existed a general way to measure eco-
are not well defined by quantitative targets, nomic activities without using markets or to
regional competition may lead to problems, measure nonmarket activities accurately and
such as regional protection and ignoring tasks efficiently, a centralized economy would be
that are not directly growth enhancing. It has able to resolve all incentive and informa-
been widely reported that there has been a tion problems at least as well as a market
severe deterioration of China’s environment economy.
as a result of its rapid economic growth. SO2 It is known that assigning high-powered
emissions increased from 19.9 million tons incentives, through methods such as tour-
in 2000 to 25.5 million tons in 2005, mak- nament competition, to subnational officials
ing China the largest emitter of SO2 (World can be harmful when they are responsible for
Bank 2007). Moreover, this deterioration multiple tasks (Bengt Holmstrom and Paul
was closely related with a lack of interest Milgrom 1991). However, without regional
from subnational government officials, who competition, subnational officials under the
found that enforcing environmental regula- RDA regime would not make efforts to initi-
tions detracted from their ability to provide ate reforms or undertake growth-enhancing
regional economic growth (Wanxi Li 2006). activities, which would deeply affect China’s
Theoretically, if all tasks and their outcomes future development. In the following, I
could be well measured, then by assigning a briefly discuss some principles to handle this
policy weight for each task it might be pos- dilemma.
sible to construct a comprehensive index to First, the multitask problem can be miti-
summarize an official’s achievement of all gated by redefining tasks assigned to minis-
tasks. In this way, a multitask problem could tries and provincial governments. The scope
be reduced into a single-task problem, and of tasks to be carried out by subnational
regional competition and experimentation governments should be narrowed down.
over the comprehensive index would func- For example, responsibilities for activities
tion well. The “Green GDP” proposal of with strong cross-region externalities should
the Chinese government is an endeavor in be centralized and regulated by ministries.
this direction (Elizabeth Economy 2007). Moreover, to reduce the multitask problem
1140 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

at the central level, tasks to be handled by elected officials provide better public ser-
the central government should be handled vices and are more harmonious with their
by specialized ministries, special courts, and constituencies than appointed ones (Brandt
specialized regulatory bodies. Second, many and Matthew Turner 2006; Renfu Luo et al.
monitoring and law enforcement functions, 2010). If China is unable to meet the seri-
including regulation, should be separated ous challenges of managing the institutional
from subnational governments, i.e., should transformation into a democratic federal sys-
be carried out by an independent press and tem, China’s political stability and long run
an independent judiciary. This will not only development could be put in jeopardy.
reduce the multitask problem of subnational Another closely related, fundamental,
governments effectively, but also greatly and challenging problem China has faced is
enhance neutrality, objectiveness, justice, law and law enforcement. To some extent,
and thus effectiveness in monitoring and law by deploying a regulatory decentralization
enforcement. Third—and this would further regime as a substitute, China has mitigated
entrench reforms—most market activities or postponed serious problems associated
should be carried out by firms and should with the absence of the rule of law, and has
be separated from subnational governments. therefore won itself some time to reform its
This will not only narrow the tasks of sub- law and legal institutions. However, argu-
national governments, but it would also ably, reform in this area is among the slowest
preserve strong incentives for firms for eco- and weakest, and this slow pace has caused
nomic development even when incentives of and will continue to cause severe socioeco-
subnational governments are weakened. nomic problems. As the private sector and
I must make it clear that some of the most markets become fundamentally important
serious and fundamental problems intrin- to the economy, the negative impacts of bad
sic to the RDA regime cannot possibly be laws and the absence of the rule of law will
resolved without a fundamental institutional become even more manifest. The lack of an
change. The multitask problem faced by independent judiciary is one of the most seri-
subnational governments is fundamentally ous problems; additionally, this is an intrinsic
associated with the fact that officials are problem of the RDA regime and, therefore,
accountable to their bosses, who face inher- an ultimate resolution depends on institu-
ent and difficult informational problems in tional transformation. Following success-
performance evaluation, not to mention the ful experiences in previous reforms, China
legitimacy problems of the central leader- should start to establish an independent judi-
ship (section 2). The ultimate solution to ciary system at the county level—the bottom
those problems lies in transforming the RDA subnational level—and expand the reform
regime into a democratic federal system in upwards. Without substantial legal reforms,
which subnational officials are elected and the absence of the rule of law could lead
are accountable to their constituencies, so entrenched interest groups, particularly cor-
that their multitask problem will be con- rupt officials, to block the reform, obstruct
verted into a single-task election problem. development, and even threaten the political
Arguably, to some extent this transformation stability of the nation.
is on its way, but very slowly, in a bottom-
up fashion. In the past decade, most village
7.  Concluding Remarks
heads (O’Brien and Li 2000, 2006) and some
township heads (Li 2002) in China were In this paper, I argue that the regional
elected; and systematic evidence shows that competition and experimentation governed
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1141

by China’s regionally decentralized authori- that fit with this regime could not be eas-
tarian (RDA) regime have effectively allevi- ily transplanted as a package to other coun-
ated potential incentive and informational tries. However, there are still some general
problems. By linking regional performance lessons that can be drawn from China’s
to officials’ promotion, tournament-like reforms and development for other devel-
regional competition provides high-pow- oping countries.
ered incentives to subnational officials to The first general lesson is our understand-
initiate and to implement market-oriented ing of “institutions” and their relationship
reforms, while simultaneously limiting cor- with development. During its process of tran-
ruption (section 3).71 Therefore, to some sition and development, China has changed
extent, competition among subnational its institutions at a large scale and has cre-
governments encouraged or forced them ated market-supporting institutions in an
to create implicitly the institutions essen- evolutionary way, i.e., new institutions have
tial for a well-functioning market (section gradually replaced old institutions when the
5). Furthermore, by incorporating regional new is ready. It would be mistaken to advise
experimentation into the central govern- transition economies or developing coun-
ment’s decision-making process, reforms are tries to abandon their existing institutions in
less likely to be blocked, and the political and a rush by copying stylized “best practice” or
technical risks of reforms are greatly reduced “good” institutions without a careful under-
(section 4). standing of the operation of both inherited
Nevertheless, the very same institution, and new institutions. As a matter of fact, the
the RDA regime, and the solutions created sophisticated market-supporting institutions
and implemented by the RDA regime—as observed in today’s developed world were
highly imperfect substitutes for “standard” not created overnight; instead, they histori-
solutions—also have created serious prob- cally coevolved with markets.72 Thus, for a
lems (section 6). Yet, given the political and country with many missing “good institu-
economic context of China’s reforms (section tions” like China, it is inevitable to use exist-
2), many “standard” approaches were and are ing institutions, such as the government, as
politically and institutionally infeasible, and a starting point to pave the road for institu-
it could be even worse for China’s reforms tional evolution.
if a reform fails as a result of implementing Overly simplistic, black-and-white views
an infeasible approach. In this sense, the of government are detrimental to reforms
regional competition and regional experi- and economic development. There is a
ments implemented by the RDA regime are popular view that reforms in transition and
second-best solutions. developing economies should focus on con-
To highlight the major features of the fining the government, such that the role of
RDA regime, the following table 6 compares the government should be restricted to the
the characteristics of China’s RDA regime protection of property rights and contract
with the federal state and the Soviet system.
As it evolved from a unique history,
72 Ironically, the ongoing catastrophic financial crisis
China’s RDA regime is itself somewhat
makes it crystal clear how problematic the legal (regula-
unique. Therefore, many reform policies tory) and financial institutions are in the most advanced
market economies. If we economists had a standard uni-
versal recipe on the shelf for institutional building, as
71 My prediction is if there was no fierce regional offered to transition and developing economies, why do
competition, corruption would lead to the collapse of the we not apply the recipe to fix these problems in advanced
Chinese government and Chinese economy. market economies?
1142 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

Table 6
Characteristics of China’s RDA Regime Compared with Other Regimes

China’s RDA regime Soviet system Federal State

Composition of Central, regional and Central and Federal legislature


national decision- ministerial officials ministerial officials representing regional
making body constituencies
Decision-making Central-regional bargain- Top-down; SOE-Ministry Voting in legislation;
process ing; consensus building; local bargaining federal-state bargaining
­experiments as a strategy
Subnational Promotion: absolute and Promotion: absolute To be elected; independent
officials’ incentives relative performance; performance; accountable from the federal government;
accountable to superiors; to superiors; personnel accountable to local
personnel control control constituencies

Regional Tournament-like competition; Not important Fiscal (Tiebout) competition;


competition competition affects governor’s competition affects
promotion governor’s re-election
Regional Local experiments as part of Not important States are “laboratories” for
experiment central decision-making; policy; voluntary adoption of
experimental results may experiments by states
become national policy

enforcement. However, it has been well The second general lesson is to use
argued that reform and economic develop- regional decentralization as an approach
ment involves complementary institutional to solve incentive problems imbedded in
changes to be carried out by the govern- reforms. China’s reforms illustrate that the
ment. China’s reforms in particular, and ability to reform institutions is endogenized
the experience of East Asian development as a result of the incentives of the stake-
in general (Japan, South Korea, Taiwan, holders of existing institutions; while exist-
Singapore, Hong Kong) illustrate this (Lin ing institutions are endogenized as a result
2007); the history of market development in of a country’s history, social norms, culture,
pre–Industrial Revolution Britain also illus- endowment, technology, etc. These facts
trates this (Smith 1763). The government is make institutional reform and policy design
the most important institution in any country fundamentally different from engineer-
(Stiglitz 1989) and its involvement is essen- ing design. The primary reason why many
tial for market development (Smith 1776), reforms with comprehensive plans failed was
and this has been borne out yet again dur- a lack of understanding of details of existing
ing the market reforms in China. In addi- institutions, and of stakeholders’ incentive
tion to macro and political stability, national problems with newly designed institutions,
reform strategies, a functioning national particularly when those were designed by
government also determines effectiveness outside “experts,” who are not informed on
of decentralization, which is the next point I those incentive problems. A thorough under-
want to make. standing of the details of existing institution
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1143

in general, and the incentive problems of the and regional experiments facilitate this
stakeholders of a reform program in particu- approach, thus making reform easier. A
lar, is the foremost factor in determining the large number of reforms in China were
fate of a given reform. locally initiated responses to local problems.
Although there may exist commonly The greatest benefit of this decentralized
agreed-on goals for reforms or economic approach is that it evolves within the existing
development at an abstract level, it is often institutional framework. Therefore, it is eas-
not very helpful to prescribe a universal pol- ier for a reform to be incentive-compatible,
icy recipe in detail. This is because any effec- the reform will fit better with local condi-
tive policy recipe must take into account the tions, and when new problems arise, officials
interests of stakeholders in the existing insti- will have better incentives and information
tution, which varies from country to country to find solutions.
and from context to context. When China However, what is the limitation of decen-
“ignored” standard advice, what they ignored tralization? Or what is the boundary of a
was mainly the details, particularly when national government? Pushing decentraliza-
these were not incentive-compatible with tion to the limit, if every city is completely
Chinese stakeholders and thus would not decentralized and becomes an independent
work. Sometimes they have also “ignored” country, each city-state will have substan-
basic principles of standard advice due to tial powers and responsibilities and each
political considerations, which is another will be subject to a hard budget constraint.
type of incentive compatibility problem. Is this optimal?  Applying the analytical
Most of the details of Chinese reform poli- framework of this paper (sections 2, 3, and
cies were not designed ex ante, but instead 4), I would argue that, in addition to social
evolved during the process of the reforms costs of breaking up of a nation (depend-
when incentive problems were resolved. ing on the procedure these costs may vary
The importance of decentralization is not from extremely high, e.g., anarchy or a civil
only due to heterogeneous local preferences, war, to almost zero, e.g., a peaceful refer-
(Oates 1999) but also due to heterogeneous endum and an orderly change), there are
local incentive problems and local institu- “pure” economic reasons that, under cer-
tional arrangements that can be handled tain conditions, an integrated nation with
more properly locally. Economic reforms and regional decentralization can dominate a
economic development are path-dependent, nation’s breaking up. This is because the
and this is true not only at the national level central government in an integrated nation
but also at the subnational level. A local his- is in a good position to address externali-
tory determines what interests stakeholders ties among regions, such as strong positive
have nested into the existing institution there externalities created by a few local experi-
and how those affect institutional reforms in ments in a nation.
the locality. The typical approaches deployed The last, but not the least, general lesson
in Chinese reforms evolved as a result of from China’s reform is the importance of
dealing with local incentive-compatible subnational governments. Decentralization
problems explicitly.73 Regional competition is important for reforms and economic
development in all countries except city-
states. To make decentralization work,
73 The Pareto-improving requirement (a la Lau, Qian,
subnational governments should not only
and Roland 2000) is the strongest criterion, whereas the
incentive-compatible requirement is weaker and more be empowered but also enabled. The lit-
general. erature on decentralization and federalism
1144 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

emphasizes empowering subnational gov- References


ernments but hardly discusses enabling
Acemoglu, Daron, and Simon Johnson. 2005. “Unbun-
subnational governments. Enablement dling Institutions.” Journal of Political Economy,
does not come automatically with empow- 113(5): 949–95.
erment. Without enablement, subnational Aghion, Philippe, Eve Caroli, and Cecilia Garcia-Pen-
alosa. 1999. “Inequality and Economic Growth: The
governments would not be able to take pol- Perspective of the New Growth Theories.” Journal of
icy actions and decentralization would not Economic Literature, 37(4): 1615–60.
work even when they are legally empow- Alesina, Alberto, and Dani Rodrik. 1994. “Distributive
Politics and Economic Growth.” Quarterly Journal of
ered. Moreover, enablement is a necessary Economics, 109(2): 465–90.
condition for commitment to, and institu- Allen, Franklin, Jun Qian, and Meijun Qian. 2005.
tionalization of, decentralization. This point “Law, Finance, and Economic Growth in China.”
Journal of Financial Economics, 77(1): 57–116.
illustrates again that the overly simplistic Aoki, Masahiko. 1990. “Toward an Economic Model of
view of confining government’s resources the Japanese Firm.” Journal of Economic Literature,
and functions without a careful study of the 28(1): 1–27.
Axelrod, Robert. 1984. The Evolution of Cooperation.
context can be harmful to policy. Indeed, New York: Basic Books.
in many decentralized developing econo- Bai, Chong-En, Yingjuan Du, Zhigang Tao, and Sarah
mies, subnational governments are not Y. Tong. 2004. “Local Protectionism and Regional
Specialization: Evidence from China’s Industries.”
enabled. For example, underfunding of Journal of International Economics, 63(2): 397–417.
required expenditures on local infrastruc- Bai, Gang. 1996. The General History of China’s Politi-
ture or social services has been common cal Institution (Zhongguo Zhengzhi Zhidu Tongshi),
Volume 1. Beijing: People’s Press.
in most decentralized developing countries Ballis, William B. 1961. “Political Implications of
(Bardhan 2002; Bardhan and Mookherjee Recent Soviet Economic Reorganizations.” Review
2006). In contrast, all major reforms were of Politics, 23(2): 153–71.
Bao, Tong. 2009. “On the Three Decades’ Reform
initiated and carried out by Chinese subna- (yetan gaige sanshi nian).” http://www.rfa.org/man-
tional governments since they not only had darin/yataibaodao/Baotong-12222008093954.html.
the incentives to do so, but also they have Bardhan, Pranab. 2002. “Decentralization of Gover-
nance and Development.” Journal of Economic Per-
the resources to proceed even if a given spectives, 16(4): 185–205.
reform was not fully endorsed, i.e., not Bardhan, Pranab, and Dilip Mookherjee. 2006. “The
completely empowered.74 This may explain Rise of Local Governments: An Overview.” In Decen-
tralization and Local Governance in Developing
partly why “China is the only country [in the Countries: A Comparative Perspective, ed. Pranab
world] where the local governments have Bardhan and Dilip Mookherjee, 1–52. Cambridge,
played a leading role in increasing rates of Mass. and London: MIT Press.
Bénabou, Roland, and Jean Tirole. 2003. “Intrinsic and
growth” (Bardhan and Dilip Mookherjee Extrinsic Motivation.” Review of Economic Studies,
2006, p. 48). A country’s history determines 70(3): 489–520.
to what extent subnational governments are Benjamin, Dwayne, Loren Brandt, and John Giles.
2005. “The Evolution of Income Inequality in
enabled and which government is enabled. Rural China.” Economic Development and Cultural
This implies that, except for general prin- Change, 53(4): 769–824.
ciples, standard policy recipes may not work Benjamin, Dwayne, Loren Brandt, John Giles, and San-
gui Wang. 2008. “Income Inequality during China’s
uniformly even within a country. This is Economic Transition.” In China’s Great Economic
another reason to support decentralization. Transformation, ed. Loren Brandt and Thomas G.
Rawski, 729–75. Cambridge and New York: Cam-
bridge University Press.
Berkowitz, Daniel, and Wei Li. 2000. “Tax Rights in
Transition Economies: A Tragedy of the Commons?”
74 Many Chinese local governments in less-developed Journal of Public Economics, 76(3): 369–97.
regions also suffered severe underfunding problems for Bernstein, Thomas P., and Xiaobo Lu. 2000. “Taxation
local public services, particularly after the 1994 fiscal without Representation: Peasants, the Central and
recentralization (Wong 2007). the Local States in Reform China.” China Quarterly,
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1145

163: 742–63. Chen, Jian, and Belton M. Fleisher. 1996. “Regional


Blanchard, Olivier, and Andrei Shleifer. 2001. “Fed- Income Inequality and Economic Growth in China.”
eralism with and without Political Centralization: Journal of Comparative Economics, 22(2): 141–64.
China versus Russia.” IMF Staff Papers, 48: 171–79. Chen, Ye, Hongbin Li, and Li-An Zhou. 2005. “Rela-
Bolton, Patrick, and Gerard Roland. 1997. “The tive Performance Evaluation and the Turnover of
Breakup of Nations: A Political Economy Analysis.” Provincial Leaders in China.” Economics Letters,
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(4): 1057–90. 88(3): 421–25.
Booth, Charles. 2004. “Drafting Bankruptcy Laws in Chien, Shiuh-Shen, and Litao Zhao. 2007. “Cross
Socialist Market Economies: Recent Developments Regional Cadre Transfer and Local Economic
in China and Vietnam.” Columbia Journal of Asian Development: Evidence from Jiangsu Province.”
Law, 18(1): 94–147. 2007 Annual Conference of Association of American
Boyreau-Debray, Genevieve, and Shang-Jin Wei. 2005. Geographers, San Francisco, April.
“Pitfalls of a State-Dominated Financial System: Chubanshe, Falv, ed. 2009. Constitution of the People’s
The Case of China.” National Bureau of Economic Republic of China: Amendments Compared (Zhong-
Research Working Paper 11214. hua Renmin Gongheguo Xianfa, Xinjiu Duizhaoban).
Brandt, Loren, Chang-tai Hsieh, and Xiaodong Zhu. Beijing: Law Press.
2008. “Growth and Structural Transformation in Clarke, Donald, Peter Murrell, and Susan H. Whiting.
China.” In China’s Great Economic Transformation, 2006. “The Role of Law in China’s Economic Devel-
ed. Loren Brandt and Thomas G. Rawski, 683–728. opment.” George Washington University Law School
Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Public Law and Legal Theory Working Paper 187.
Press. Coase, Ronald H. 1937. “The Nature of the Firm.” Eco-
Brandt, Loren, and Matthew Turner. 2006. “The Use- nomica, 4(16): 386–405.
fulness of Corruptible Elections.” University of Coase, Ronald H. 1992. “The Institutional Structure
Toronto Department of Economics Working Paper of Production.” American Economic Review, 82(4):
233. 713–19.
Brandt, Loren, and Xiaodong Zhu. 2000. “Redistribu- Cumberland, John H. 1981. “Efficiency and Equity in
tion in a Decentralized Economy: Growth and Infla- Interregional Environmental Management.” Review
tion in China under Reform.” Journal of Political of Regional Studies, 2: 1–9.
Economy, 108(2): 422–39. Demurger, Sylvie. 2001. “Infrastructure Development
Burns, John P. 1994. “Strengthening Central CCP Con- and Economic Growth: An Explanation for Regional
trol of Leadership Selection: The 1990 Nomenkla- Disparities in China?” Journal of Comparative Eco-
tura.” China Quarterly, 138: 458–91. nomics, 29(1): 95–117.
Byrd, William A., and Qingsong Lin, eds. 1990. Chi- Deng, Jianping, Jie Gan, and Jia He. 2008. “The Dark
na’s Rural Industry: Structure, Development, and Side of Concentrated Ownership in Privatization:
Reform. Oxford; New York; Toronto and Melbourne: Evidence from China.” Unpublished.
Oxford University Press. Deng, Xiaoping. 1984. “On the Reform of the System
Cai, Dongshi, et al., ed. 2008. Xi Zhongxun Governing of Party and State Leadership.” In Selected Works of
Guangdong (Xi Zhongxun Zhuzheng Guangdong). Deng Xiaoping, Volume 2: 1975–1982. Beijing: For-
Beijing: Chinese Communist Party History Press. eign Language Press.
Cai, Hongbin, and Daniel Treisman. 2004. “State Cor- Deng, Xiaoping. 1994a. “On Reform of the Political
roding Federalism.” Journal of Public Economics, Structure.” In Selected Works of Deng Xiaoping,
88(3–4): 819–43. Volume 3: 1982–1992, 176–80. Beijing: Foreign Lan-
Cai, Hongbin, and Daniel Treisman. 2005. “Does guage Press.
Competition for Capital Discipline Governments? Deng, Xiaoping, 1994b. “To Uphold Socialism We
Decentralization, Globalization, and Public Policy.” Must Eliminate Poverty.” In Selected Works of Deng
American Economic Review, 95(3): 817–30. Xiaoping, Volume 3: 1982–1992. Beijing: Foreign
Chandler, Alfred D. 1966. Strategy and Structure. New Language Press.
York: Doubleday. Dickson, Bruce J. 2003. Red Capitalists in China: The
Chang, Chun, and Yijiang Wang. 1994. “The Nature of Party, Private Entrepreneurs, and Prospects for
the Township–Village Enterprise.” Journal of Com- Political Change. Cambridge and New York: Cam-
parative Economics, 19(3): 434–52. bridge University Press.
Che, Jiahua, and Giovanni Facchini. 2007. “Dual Track Dollar, David, and Aart Kraay. 2001. “Growth Is Good
Reforms: With and without Losers.” Journal of Pub- for the Poor.” World Bank Policy Research Working
lic Economics, 91(11–12): 2291–2306. Paper 2587.
Che, Jiahua, and Yingyi Qian. 1998. “Insecure Property Dong, Xiao-yuan, Louis Putterman, and Bulent Unel.
Rights and Government Ownership of Firms.” Quar- 2006. “Privatization and Firm Performance: A Com-
terly Journal of Economics, 113(2): 467–96. parison between Rural and Urban Enterprises in
Chen, Hongyi, and Scott Rozelle. 1999. “Leaders, China.” Journal of Comparative Economics, 34(3):
Managers, and the Organization of Township and 608–33.
Village Enterprises in China.” Journal of Develop- Du, Julan, and Chenggang Xu. 2008. “Regional Com-
ment Economics, 60(2): 529–57. petition and Regulatory Decentralization: The Case
1146 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

of China.” Unpublished. The Case of China.” Journal of Public Economics,


Du, Julan, and Chenggang Xu. 2009. “Which Firms 87(2): 283–312.
Went Public in China? A Study of Financial Market Granick, David. 1990. Chinese State Enterprises: A
Regulation.” World Development, 37(4): 812–24. Regional Property Rights Analysis. Chicago and Lon-
Du, Mingming, and Qingquan Xu. 2009. “Tian Jiyun on don: University of Chicago Press.
the 1992 Speech at the Central Party School (Tian Green, Stephen. 2003. China’s Stockmarket: A Guide
Jiyun tan 1992 nian zhongyuang dangxiao jianghua).” to Its Progress, Players and Prospects. Hoboken,
Yanhuang Chunqiu, no. 3. N.J.: Bloomberg Press.
Economy, Elizabeth. 2007. “China from the Inside: Gregory, Paul R., and Robert C. Stuart. 1998. Russian
Shifting Nature: Opinion: Green GDP: Accounting and Soviet Economic Performance and Structure,
for the Environment in China.” http://www.pbs.org/ Sixth edition. Boston: Addison-Wesley.
kqed/chinainside/nature/greengdp.html. Greif, Avner. 2006. “Family Structure, Institutions, and
Edin, Maria. 2000. Market Forces and Communist Growth: The Origins and Implications of Western
Power: Local Political Institutions and Economic Corporations.” American Economic Review, 96(2):
Development in China. Uppsala: Uppsala University, 308–12.
Department of Government. Groves, Theodore, Yongmiao Hong, John McMillan,
Edin, Maria. 2003. “State Capacity and Local Agent and Barry J. Naughton. 1994. “Autonomy and Incen-
Control in China: CCP Cadre Management from tives in Chinese State Enterprises.” Quarterly Jour-
a Township Perspective.” China Quarterly, 173: nal of Economics, 109(1): 183–209.
35–52. Groves, Theodore, Yongmiao Hong, John McMil-
Epple, Dennis, and Allan Zelenitz. 1981. “The Impli- lan, and Barry J. Naughton. 1995. “China’s Evolv-
cations of Competition among Jurisdictions: Does ing Managerial Labor Market.” Journal of Political
Tiebout Need Politics?” Journal of Political Econ- Economy, 103(4): 873–92.
omy, 89(6): 1197–1217. Guo, Xiaolin. 2001. “Land Expropriation and Rural
Estrin, Saul, Jan Hanousek, Evžen Koc̆enda, and Jan Conflicts in China.” China Quarterly, 166: 422–39.
Svejnar. 2009. “The Effects of Privatization and Guo, Yan, Jie Gan, and Chenggang Xu. 2008. “A
Ownership in Transition Economies.” Journal of Eco- Nationwide Survey of Privatized Firms in China.”
nomic Literature, 47(3): 699–728. Seoul Journal of Economics, 21(2): 311–31.
Fan, C. Simon, and Xiangdong Wei. 2006. “The Law of Hayek, F. A. 1945. “The Use of Knowledge in Society.”
One Price: Evidence from the Transitional Economy American Economic Review, 35(4): 519–30.
of China.” Review of Economics and Statistics, 88(4): Heilmann, Sebastian. 2008. “Experimentation under
682–97. Hierarchy: Policy Experiments in the Reorganization
Fleisher, Belton M., and Jian Chen. 1997. “The Coast– of China’s State Sector, 1978–2008.” Harvard Univer-
Noncoast Income Gap, Productivity, and Regional sity Center for International Development Working
Economic Policy in China.” Journal of Comparative Paper 172.
Economics, 25(2): 220–36. Holmstrom, Bengt, and Paul Milgrom. 1991. “Multi-
Fornasari, Francesca, Steven B. Webb, and Heng-fu task Principal–Agent Analyses: Incentive Contracts,
Zou. 1999. “Decentralized Spending and Central Asset Ownership, and Job Design.” Journal of Law,
Government Deficits: International Evidence.” Economics, and Organization, 7: 24–52.
Unpublished. Holz, Carsten A. 2009. “No Razor’s Edge: Reexamining
Fu, Xiaolan. 2004. “Limited Linkages from Growth Alwyn Young’s Evidence for Increasing Interprovin-
Engines and Regional Disparities in China.” Journal cial Trade Barriers in China.” Review of Economics
of Comparative Economics, 32(1): 148–64. and Statistics, 91(3): 599–616.
Fudenberg, Drew, and Eric Maskin. 2008. “Evolution, Hu, Angang, Shaoguang Wang, and Xiaoguang Kang.
Cooperation, and Repeated Games.” Unpublished. 1995. “Regional Disparity in China.” (Zhongguo
Gan, Jie, Yan Guo, and Chenggang Xu. 2010. “Privati- Diqu Chaju Baogao). Shenyang: Liaoning People’s
zation and the Change of Control Rights: The Case Press.
of China.” Peking University School of Economics Hu, Jiwei. 2008. “Hu Yaobang Selected the Breakpoint
Working Paper E-2010-06-006. for the Reform.” Open, 4: 66–68.
Garnaut, Ross, Ligang Song, Yang Yao, and Xiaolu Hu, Jiwei. 2009. “What Is ‘Reform and Open-Up’?
Wang. 2001. China’s Private Enterprise. Canberra: When Did It Occur?” Chengming, 4: 66–70.
Asia Pacific Press. Huang, Yasheng. 1996a. “Central–Local Relations in
Garnaut, Ross, Ligang Song, Stoyan Tenev, and Yang China during the Reform Era: The Economic and
Yao. 2005. China’s Ownership Transformation: Pro- Institutional Dimensions.” World Development,
cess, Outcomes, Prospects. Washington, D.C.: World 24(4): 655–72.
Bank. Huang, Yasheng. 1996b. Inflation and Investment Con-
Gordon, Roger H. 1983. “An Optimal Taxation trols in China: The Political Economy of Central–Local
Approach to Fiscal Federalism.” Quarterly Journal Relations during the Reform Era. Cambridge; New
of Economics, 98(4): 567–86. York and Melbourne: Cambridge University Press.
Gordon, Roger H., and Wei Li. 2003. “Government as a Hurwicz, Leonid. 2007. “But Who Will Guard the
Discriminating Monopolist in the Financial Market: Guardians?” http://nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1147

economics/laureates/2007/hurwicz_lecture.pdf. Kung, James Kai-Sing, and Yi-Min Lin. 2007. “The


Jacoby, Hanan G., Guo Li, and Scott Rozelle. 2002. Decline of Township-and-Village Enterprises in
“Hazards of Expropriation: Tenure Insecurity and China’s Economic Transition.” World Development,
Investment in Rural China.” American Economic 35(4): 569–84.
Review, 92(5): 1420–47. Kung, James Kai-Sing, Chenggang Xu, and Feizhou
Jefferson, Gary H., Thomas G. Rawski, and Yuxin Zhou. Forthcoming. “From Industrialization to
Zheng. 1996. “Chinese Industrial Productivity: Urbanization: The Social Consequences of Changing
Trends, Measurement Issues, and Recent Develop- Fiscal Incentives on Local Governments’ Behavior.”
ments.” Journal of Comparative Economics, 23(2): In Institutional Design for China’s Evolving Market
146–80. Economy, ed. Joseph E. Stiglitz.
Jefferson, Gary H., Thomas G. Rawski, and Yifan Kuznets, Simon. 1955. “Economic Growth and Income
Zhang. 2008. “Productivity Growth and Convergence Inequality.” American Economic Review, 45(1): 1–28.
across China’s Industrial Economy.” Journal of Chi- Landry, Pierre F. 2008. Decentralized Authoritarianism
nese Economic and Business Studies, 6(2): 121–40. in China: The Communist Party’s Control of Local
Jefferson, Gary H., and Jian Su. 2006. “Privatization Elites in the Post-Mao Era. Cambridge and New
and Restructuring in China: Evidence from Share- York: Cambridge University Press.
holding Ownership, 1995–2001.” Journal of Com- Lardy, Nicholas R. 1998. China’s Unfinished Economic
parative Economics, 34(1): 146–66. Revolution. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution
Jiang, Zemin. 2006. “Hold High the Great Banner of Press.
Deng Xiaoping Theory for an All-round Advance- Lau, Lawrence J., Yingyi Qian, and Gerard Roland.
ment of the Cause of Building Socialism with Chi- 2000. “Reform without Losers: An Interpretation of
nese Characteristics into the 21st Century: Report at China’s Dual-Track Approach to Transition.” Journal
the 15th National Congress of the Communist Party of Political Economy, 108(1): 120–43.
of China on September 12, 1997.” In Selected Works Lazear, Edward P., and Sherwin Rosen. 1981. “Rank-
of Jiang Zemin, Volume 2, 1–49. Beijing: People’s Order Tournaments as Optimum Labor Contracts.”
Press. Journal of Political Economy, 89(5): 841–64.
Jin, Hehui, Yingyi Qian, and Barry R. Weingast. 2005. Li, David D. 1996. “A Theory of Ambiguous Property
“Regional Decentralization and Fiscal Incentives: Rights in Transition Economies: The Case of the
Federalism, Chinese Style.” Journal of Public Eco- Chinese Non-state Sector.” Journal of Comparative
nomics, 89(9–10): 1719–42. Economics, 23(1): 1–19.
Kanbur, Ravi, and Xiaobo Zhang. 2005. “Fifty Years Li, Hongbin, and Scott Rozelle. 2004. “Insider Priva-
of Regional Inequality in China: A Journey through tization with a Tail: The Screening Contract and
Central Planning, Reform, and Openness.” Review of Performance of Privatized Firms in Rural China.”
Development Economics, 9(1): 87–106. Journal of Development Economics, 75(1): 1–26.
Keen, Michael, and Maurice Marchand. 1997. “Fiscal Li, Hongbin, and Li-An Zhou. 2005. “Political Turnover
Competition and the Pattern of Public Spending.” and Economic Performance: The Incentive Role of
Journal of Public Economics, 66(1): 33–53. Personnel Control in China.” Journal of Public Eco-
Kelliher, Daniel. 1992. Peasant Power in China: The nomics, 89(9–10): 1743–62.
End of Rural Reform, 1979–1989. New Haven and Li, Lianjiang. 2002. “The Politics of Introducing Direct
London: Yale University Press. Township Elections in China.” China Quarterly, 171:
Khrushchev, Nikita S. 1959. Let Us Live in Peace and 704–23.
Friendship. Moscow: Foreign Language Press. Li, Lianjiang, and Kevin J. O’Brien. 2008. “Protest
Kim, Sukkoo. 1995. “Expansion of Markets and the Leadership in Rural China.” China Quarterly, 193:
Geographic Distribution of Economic Activities: 1–23.
The Trends in U.S. Regional Manufacturing Struc- Li, Lixing. 2011. “The Incentive Role of Creating
ture, 1860–1987.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, ‘Cities’ in China.” China Economic Review, 22(1):
110(4): 881–908. 172–81.
Kornai, Janos. 1971. Rush versus Harmonic Growth: Li, Rui. 2008. “Li Rui’s Reflections on Reform and
Meditation on the Theory and on the Policies of Eco- Open-up (Li Rui dui gaige kafang de yizhong huigu).”
nomic Growth. Amsterdam: North-Holland. Yanhuang Chunqiu, 11.
Kornai, Janos. 1980. The Economics of Shortage. Lon- Li, Wanxi. 2006. “Environmental Governance: Issues
don and New York: Elsevier Science. and Challenges.” Environmental Law Reporter,
Kornai, Janos. 1986. “The Hungarian Reform Process: 36(7): 10505–25.
Visions, Hopes, and Reality.” Journal of Economic Li, Wei. 1997. “The Impact of Economic Reform on
Literature, 24(4): 1687–1737. the Performance of Chinese State Enterprises,
Kornai, Janos. 1992. The Socialist System: The Politi- 1980–1989.” Journal of Political Economy, 105(5):
cal Economy of Communism. Princeton: Princeton 1080–1106.
University Press. Li, Wei, and Dennis Tao Yang. 2005. “The Great Leap
Kornai, Janos, Eric Maskin, and Gerard Roland. 2003. Forward: Anatomy of a Central Planning Disaster.”
“Understanding the Soft Budget Constraint.” Journal Journal of Political Economy, 113(4): 840–77.
of Economic Literature, 41(4): 1095–1136. Lin, Justin Yifu. 1990. “Collectivization and China’s
1148 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

Agricultural Crisis in 1959–1961.” Journal of Political McMillan, John, and Barry Naughton. 1992. “How to
Economy, 98(6): 1228–52. Reform a Planned Economy: Lessons from China.”
Lin, Justin Yifu. 1992. “Rural Reforms and Agricul- Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 8(1): 130–43.
tural Growth in China.” American Economic Review, McMillan, John, John Whalley, and Lijing Zhu. 1989.
82(1): 34–51. “The Impact of China’s Economic Reforms on Agri-
Lin, Justin Yifu. 2007. “Development and Transition: cultural Productivity Growth.” Journal of Political
Idea, Strategy, and Viability.” Peking University Economy, 97(4): 781–807.
China Center for Economic Research Working Mertha, Andrew C. 2005. “China’s ‘Soft’ C­ entralization:
Paper E2007007. Shifting Tiao/Kuai Authority Relations.” China
Lin, Justin Yifu, Fang Cai, and Zhou Li. 1997. The Quarterly, 184: 791–810.
China Miracle: Development Strategy and Economic Montinola, Gabriella, Yingyi Qian, and Barry R. Wein-
Reform. Beijing: Chinese University Press. gast. 1995. “Federalism, Chinese Style: The Political
Lin, Justin Yifu, and Zhiyun Li. 2008. “Policy Burden, Basis for Economic Success in China.” World Poli-
Privatization and Soft Budget Constraint.” Journal of tics, 48(1): 50–81.
Comparative Economics, 36(1): 90–102. National Statistical Bureau. 1986–2006. China Statisti-
Lin, Justin Yifu, and Peilin Liu. 2005. “Development cal Yearbooks. Beijing: China Statistics Press.
Strategies and Regional Income Disparities in National Statistical Bureau. 1986–2006. China Urban
China.” China Center for Economic Research Work- Statistical Yearbooks. Beijing: China Statistics Press.
ing Paper E2005005. National Statistical Bureau. 1990. China Urban Forty
Lin, Justin Yifu, and Zhiqiang Liu. 2000. “Fiscal Years. Beijing: China Statistics Press.
Decentralization and Economic Growth in China.” National Statistical Bureau. 1995–2006. China Account-
Economic Development and Cultural Change, 49(1): ing Yearbooks. Beijing: China Statistics Press.
1–21. National Statistical Bureau. 1996–2006. Finance Year-
Lin, Justin Yifu, and Guofu Tan. 1999. “Policy Burdens, books of China. Beijing: China Statistics Press.
Accountability, and the Soft Budget Constraint.” National Statistical Bureau. 1996–2006. Provincial Sta-
American Economic Review, 89(2): 426–31. tistical Yearbooks. Beijing: China Statistics Press.
Liu, Guoguang, Zhuyuan Zhang, Zhikai Dong, and Li National Statistical Bureau. 1997–1998. China Labor
Wu, eds. 2006. Research Report on China’s Ten Five Economic Yearbooks. Beijing: China Statistics Press.
Year Plans (Zhongguo Shige Wunian Jihua Yanjiu National Statistical Bureau. 2006a. China Industrial
Baogao). Beijing: People’s Press. Economy Statistical Yearbook 2006. Beijing: China
Luo, Renfu, Linxiu Zhang, Jikun Huang, and Scott Statistics Press.
Rozelle. 2010. “Village Elections, Public Goods National Statistical Bureau. 2006b. China Statistical
Investments and Pork Barrel Politics, Chinese-Style.” Yearbook for Regional Economy 2006. Beijing: China
Journal of Development Studies, 46(4): 662–84. Statistics Press.
MacFarquhar, Roderick. 1974. The Origins of the Cul- Naughton, Barry J. 1995. Growing Out of the Plan:
tural Revolution, Volume 1: Contradictions among Chinese Economic Reform, 1978–1993. Cambridge;
the People 1956–1957. New York: Columbia Univer- New York and Melbourne: Cambridge University
sity Press. Press.
MacFarquhar, Roderick. 1983. The Origins of the Cul- Naughton, Barry J. 2003. “How Much Can Regional
tural Revolution, Volume 2: The Great Leap Forward Integration Do to Unify China’s Markets?” In How
1958–1960. New York: Columbia University Press. Far Across the River? Chinese Policy Reform at the
MacFarquhar, Roderick. 1997. The Origins of the Cul- Millennium, ed. Nicholas C. Hope, Dennis Tao Yang,
tural Revolution, Volume 3: The Coming of the Cata- and Mu Yang Li, 204–32. Stanford: Stanford Univer-
clysm 1961–1966. New York: Columbia University sity Press.
Press. Naughton, Barry J., and Dali L. Yang, eds. 2004. Hold-
MacFarquhar, Roderick, and Michael Schoenhals. ing China Together: Diversity and National Integra-
2006. Mao’s Last Revolution. Cambridge, Mass. and tion in the Post-Deng Era. Cambridge and New York:
London: Harvard University Press, Belknap Press. Cambridge University Press.
Maddison, Angus. 2003. The World Economy: Histori- Nelson, Richard R., and Sidney G. Winter. 1982. An
cal Statistics. Paris and Washington, D.C.: Organisa- Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Cam-
tion for Economic Co-operation and Development. bridge, Mass. and London: Harvard University Press
Markevich, Andrei, and Ekaterina Zhuravskaya. 2011. North, Douglas C. 1981. Structure and Change in Eco-
“M-Form Hierarchy with Poorly-Diversified Divi- nomic History. New York: W. W. Norton & Company.
sions: A Case of Kruschev’s Reform in Soviet Russia,” North, Douglass C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional
Journal of Public Economics, 95(11–12): 1550–60. Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge;
Maskin, Eric, Yingyi Qian, and Chenggang Xu. 2000. New York and Melbourne: Cambridge University
“Incentives, Information, and Organizational Form.” Press.
Review of Economic Studies, 67(2): 359–78. Nove, Alec. 1983. The Economics of Feasible Socialism.
Maskin, Eric, and Chenggang Xu. 2001. “Soft Budget Boston: Allen & Unwin.
Constraint Theories: From Centralization to the Oates, Wallace E. 1999. “An Essay on Fiscal Federal-
Market.” Economics of Transition, 9(1): 1–27. ism.” Journal of Economic Literature, 37(3): 1120–49.
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1149

Oates, Wallace E., and Robert M. Schwab. 1988. “Eco- Roland, 518–46. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
nomic Competition among Jurisdictions: Efficiency Qian, Yingyi, and Barry R. Weingast. 1997. “Federalism
Enhancing or Distortion Inducing?” Journal of Pub- as a Commitment to Reserving Market Incentives.”
lic Economics, 35(3): 333–54. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11(4): 83–92.
O’Brien, Kevin J., and Lianjiang Li. 2000. “Accommo- Qian, Yingyi, and Chenggang Xu. 1993. “Why China’s
dating ‘Democracy’ in a One-Party State: Introduc- Economic Reforms Differ: The M-Form Hierarchy
ing Village Elections in China.” China Quarterly, and Entry/Expansion of the Non-state Sector.” Eco-
162: 465–89. nomics of Transition, 1(2): 135–70.
O’Brien, Kevin J., and Lianjiang Li. 2006. Rightful Quah, Danny. 2003. “One Third of the World’s Growth
Resistance in Rural China. Cambridge and New and Inequality.” In Inequality and Growth: Theory
York: Cambridge University Press. and Policy Implications, ed. Theo S. Eicher and Ste-
Ofer, Gur. 1987. “Soviet Economic Growth: 1928– phen J. Turnovsky, 27–58. Cambridge, Mass. and
1985.” Journal of Economic Literature, 25(4): London: MIT Press.
1767–1833. Ravallion, Martin, and Shaohua Chen. 2007. “China’s
Oi, Jean C. 1999. Rural China Takes Off: Institutional (Uneven) Progress against Poverty.” Journal of
Foundations of Economic Reform. Berkeley and Development Economics, 82(1): 1–42.
London: University of California Press. Research Center of CCP History. 2009. Major Events
Park, Albert, and Minggao Shen. 2003. “Joint Liability in People’s Republic of China 1949–2009. Beijing:
Lending and the Rise and Fall of China’s Township People’s Press.
and Village Enterprises.” Journal of Development Rivlin, Alice M. 1992. Reviving the American Dream:
Economics, 71(2): 497–531. The Economy, the States & the Federal Government.
Perkins, Dwight H. 1977. Rural Small-Scale Industry Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press.
in the People’s Republic of China. Berkeley and Los Rodden, Jonathan. 2002. “The Dilemma of Fiscal Fed-
Angeles: University of California Press. eralism: Grants and Fiscal Performance around the
Perkins, Dwight H. 1988. “Reforming China’s Eco- World.” American Journal of Political Science, 46(3):
nomic System.” Journal of Economic Literature, 670–87.
26(2): 601–45. Rodden, Jonathan, and Susan Rose-Ackerman. 1997.
Perkins, Dwight H., and Thomas G. Rawski. 2008. “Does Federalism Preserve Markets?” Virginia Law
“Forecasting China’s Economic Growth to 2025.” In Review, 83(7): 1521–72.
China’s Great Economic Transformation, ed. Loren Rodrik, Dani. 2006. “Goodbye Washington Consen-
Brandt and Thomas G. Rawski, 829–86. Cambridge sus, Hello Washington Confusion? A Review of the
and New York: Cambridge University Press. World Bank’s Economic Growth in the 1990s: Learn-
Perry, Elizabeth J., and Christine P. W. Wong, eds. ing from a Decade of Reform.” Journal of Economic
1985. The Political Economy of Reform in Post-Mao Literature, 44(4): 973–87.
China. Cambridge and London: Harvard University Sachs, Jeffrey D., and Wing Thye Woo. 2000. “Under-
Press. standing China’s Economic Performance.” Journal of
Pistor, Katharina, and Chenggang Xu. 2003. “Incom- Policy Reform, 4(1): 1–50.
plete Law.” New York University Journal of Interna- Sheng, Yumin. 2005. “Central-Provincial Relations at
tional Law and Politics, 35(4): 931–1013. the CCP Central Committees: Institutions, Mea-
Pistor, Katharina, and Chenggang Xu. 2005. “Govern- surement and Empirical Trends, 1978–2002.” China
ing Stock Markets in Transition Economies: Lessons Quarterly, 182: 338–55.
from China.” American Law and Economics Review, Sheng, Yumin. 2009. “Career Incentives and Politi-
7(1): 184–210. cal Control under Authoritarianism: Explaining the
Prendergast, Canice. 2007. “The Motivation and Bias Political Fortunes of Subnational Leaders in China.”
of Bureaucrats.” American Economic Review, 97(1): Unpublished.
180–96. Shi, Yupeng, and Li-An Zhou. 2007. “Regional Decen-
Qian, Yingyi, and Gerard Roland. 1998. “Federalism tralization and Economic Efficiency: Evidence from
and the Soft Budget Constraint.” American Eco- Separate-Planning Cities in China.” [In Chinese.
nomic Review, 88(5): 1143–62. With English summary.] Jingji Yanjiu/Economic
Qian, Yingyi, Gerard Roland, and Chenggang Xu. 1999. Research Journal, 42(1): 17–28.
“Why Is China Different from Eastern Europe? Per- Shirk, Susan L. 1993. The Political Logic of Economic
spectives from Organization Theory.” European Eco- Reform in China. Berkeley and Oxford: University of
nomic Review, 43(4–6): 1085–94. California Press.
Qian, Yingyi, Gerard Roland, and Chenggang Xu. 2006. Shleifer, Andrei. 1997. “Government in Transition.”
“Coordination and Experimentation in M-Form and European Economic Review, 41(3–5): 385–410.
U-Form Organizations.” Journal of Political Econ- Shleifer, Andrei, and Robert W. Vishny. 1994. “Politi-
omy, 114(2): 366–402. cians and Firms.” Quarterly Journal of Economics,
Qian, Yingyi, Gerard Roland, and Chenggang Xu. 2007. 109(4): 995–1025.
“Coordinating Changes in Transition Economies.” In Sima, Qian. 1993. Records of the Grand Historian:
The Economics of Transition: The Fifth Nobel Sym- Qin Dynasty. Hong Kong: Chinese University of
posium in Economics, ed. Erik Berglöf and Gérard Hong Kong; New York: Columbia University Press,
1150 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLIX (December 2011)

109 B.C. Armonk, N.Y. and London: Sharpe.


Smith, Adam, 1763. Lectures on Justice, Police, Revenue Wang, Yijiang. 1991. “Economic Reform, Fixed Capital
and Arms. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1896. Investment Expansion, and Inflation: A Behavioral
Smith, Adam. 1776. The Nature and Causes of the Model Based on the Chinese Experience.” China
Wealth of Nations, ed. R. H. Campbell, A. S. Skin- Economic Review, 2(1): 3–27.
ner, and W. B. Todd. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1976. Watson, Andrew, Christopher Findlay, and Yintang Du.
Stalin, Josef V. (1931 [1947]). Problems of Leninism. 1989. “Who Won the ‘Wool War’?: A Case Study of
Moscow: Foreign Language Press. Rural Product Marketing in China.” China Quar-
Stiglitz, Joseph E. 1989. “On the Economic Role of the terly, 118: 213–41.
State.” In The Economic Role of the State, ed. Arnold Weingast, Barry R. 1995. “The Economic Role of Polit-
Heertje, 9–85. Cambridge, Mass. and Oxford: Basil ical Institutions: Market-Preserving Federalism and
Blackwell. Economic Development.” Journal of Law, Econom-
Stiglitz, Joseph E. 2002. “Information and the Change ics, and Organization, 11(1): 1–31.
in the Paradigm in Economics.” American Economic Weitzman, Martin L. 1974. “Prices vs. Quantities.”
Review, 92(3): 460–501. Review of Economic Studies, 41(4): 477–91.
Sun, Qian, and Wilson H. S. Tong. 2003. “China Share Weitzman, Martin L., and Chenggang Xu. 1994.
Issue Privatization: The Extent of Its Success.” Jour- “Chinese Township–Village Enterprises as Vaguely
nal of Financial Economics, 70(2): 183–222. Defined Cooperatives.” Journal of Comparative Eco-
Svensson, Jakob. 2005. “Eight Questions about nomics, 18(2): 121–45.
Corruption.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Whalley, John, and Shunming Zhang. 2004. “­Inequality
19(3): 19–42. Change in China and (Hukou) Labour Mobil-
Swearer, Howard R. 1959. “Krushchev’s Revolution ity Restrictions.” National Bureau of Economic
in Industrial Management.” World Politics, 12(1): Research Working Paper 10683.
45–61. Whiting, Susan H. 2000. Power and Wealth in Rural
Swearer, Howard R. 1962. “Decentralization in Recent China: The Political Economy of Institutional
Soviet Administrative Practice.” Slavic Review, Change. Cambridge; New York and Melbourne:
21(3): 456–70. Cambridge University Press.
Tian, Jiyun. 2008. “How Economic Reforms Started Wildasin, David E. 1989. “Interjurisdictional Capital
(Jingji Gaige Shi Zenyang Gao Qilai de).” Yanhuang Mobility: Fiscal Externality and a Corrective Sub-
Chunqui, 1: 5–11, 18. sidy.” Journal of Urban Economics, 25(2): 193–212.
Tiebout, Charles M. 1956. “A Pure Theory of Local Williamson, Oliver E. 1975. Markets and Hierarchies:
Expenditures.” Journal of Political Economy, 64(5): Analysis and Antitrust Implications. New York: Free
416–24. Press.
Treisman, Daniel. 2000. “Decentralization and Infla- Wong, Christine P. W. 1987. “Between Plan and
tion: Commitment, Collective Action, or Conti- Market: The Role of the Local Sector in Post-Mao
nuity?” American Political Science Review, 94(4): China.” Journal of Comparative Economics, 11(3):
837–57. 385–98.
Tsai, Kellee S. 2004. “Off Balance: The Unintended Wong, Christine P. W. 1991. “Central–Local Relations
Consequences of Fiscal Federalism in China.” Jour- in an Era of Fiscal Decline: The Paradox of Fiscal
nal of Chinese Political Science, 9(2): 1–26. Decentralization in Post-Mao China.” China Quar-
Tsui, Kai-yuen. 1993. “Decomposition of China’s terly, 128: 691–715.
Regional Inequalities.” Journal of Comparative Eco- Wong, Christine P. W. 1992. “Fiscal Reform and Local
nomics, 17(3): 600–627. Industrialization: The Problematic Sequencing of
Tsui, Kai-yuen. 2005. “Local Tax System, Intergov- Reform in Post-Mao China.” Modern China, 18(2):
ernmental Transfers and China’s Local Fiscal Dis- 197–227.
parities.” Journal of Comparative Economics, 33(1): Wong, Christine P. W., ed. 1997. Financing Local Gov-
173–96. ernment in the People’s Republic of China. Oxford
Tsui, Kai-yuen, and Youqiang Wang. 2004. “Between and New York: Oxford University Press.
Separate Stoves and a Single Menu: Fiscal Decen- Wong, Christine P. W. 2006. “Can China Change
tralization in China.” China Quarterly, 177: 71–90. Development Paradigm for the 21st Century? Fiscal
Wädekin, Karl-Eugen. 1992. “Verlustminderung als Policy Options for Hu Jintao and Wen Jiabao after
zentrale Aufgabe der Nahrungswirtschaft in Russ- Two Decades of Muddling through.” Unpublished.
land und der GUS (SNG).” Osteuropa, 42: 938–50. Wong, Christine P. W. 2007. “Fiscal Management for
Wang, Shaoguang. 1995. “The Rise of the Regions: Fis- a Harmonious Society: Assessing the Central Gov-
cal Reform and the Decline of Central State C ­ apacity ernment’s Capacity to Implement National P ­ olicies.”
in China.” In The Waning of the Communist State: British Inter-university China Centre Working
Economic Origins of Political Decline in China and Paper 4.
Hungary, ed. Andrew G. Walder, 87–113. Berkeley Woo, Wing Thye, Hai Wen, Jin Yibiao, and Fan Gang.
and London: University of California Press. 1994. “How Successful Has Chinese Enterprise
Wang, Shaoguang, and Angang Hu. 2001. The Chinese Reform Been? Pitfalls in Opposite Biases and Focus.”
Economy in Crisis: State Capacity and Tax Reform. Journal of Comparative Economics, 18(3): 410–37.
Xu: The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development 1151

World Bank. 2002. “China: National Development & Francis, Routledge.


and Sub-national Finance: A Review of Provincial Yang, Dali L. 2006. “Economic Transformation and
Expenditures.” World Bank Poverty Reduction and Its Political Discontents in China: Authoritarian-
Economic Management Unit Report 22951-CHA. ism, Unequal Growth, and the Dilemmas of Political
World Bank. 2003. Global Economic Prospects and Development.” Annual Review of Political Science,
the Developing Countries. Washington, D.C.: World 9: 143–64.
Bank. Yao, Shujie, and Zongyi Zhang. 2001. “On Regional
World Bank. 2007. Cost of Pollution in China: Eco- Inequality and Diverging Clubs: A Case Study of
nomic Estimates of Physical Damages. Washington, Contemporary China.” Journal of Comparative
D.C.: World Bank. Economics, 29(3): 466–84.
Wu, Jinglian. 2009. Understanding and Interpret- Young, Alwyn. 2000. “The Razor’s Edge: Distortions
ing China’s Economic Reform (Dangdai Zhongguo and Incremental Reform in the People’s Rupublic
Jingji Gaige Jiaocheng). Shanghai: Shanghai Far East of China.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(4):
Press. 1091–1135.
Xu, Chenggang. 1995. A Different Transition Path: Zeng, Jianhui. 1984. “A New Step in Opening Up the
Ownership, Performance, and Influence of Chinese Economy: The Emergence of an Important Policy.”
Rural Industrial Enterprises. New York and London: Liao Wang, 24: 11–15.
Garland. Zhang, Jun, and Yuan Gao. 2007. “Term Limits and
Xu, Chenggang, and Katharina Pistor. 2006. “Enforce- Rotation of Chinese Governors: Do They Matter to
ment Failure under Incomplete Law: Theory and Economic Growth? (In Chinese. With English sum-
Evidence from Financial Market Regulation.” mary.).” Jingji Yanjiu/Economic Research Journal,
Unpublished. 42(11): 91–103.
Xu, Chenggang, and Xiaobo Zhang. Forthcoming. “The Zhang, Tao, and Heng-fu Zou. 1998. “Fiscal Decen-
Evolution of Chinese Entrepreneurial Firms: Town- tralization, Public Spending, and Economic Growth
ship–Village Enterprises Revisited.” In China’s Eco- in China.” Journal of Public Economics, 67(2):
nomic Transformation, ed. Ronald Coase. 221–40.
Xu, Chenggang, and Juzhong Zhuang. 1998. “Why Zhang, Xiaobo. 2006. “Fiscal Decentralization and
China Grew: The Role of Decentralization.” In Political Centralization in China: Implications for
Emerging from Communism: Lessons from Russia, Growth and Inequality.” Journal of Comparative
China, and Eastern Europe, ed. Peter Boone, Stani- Economics, 34(4): 713–26.
slaw Gomulka, and Richard Layard, 183–212. Cam- Zhang, Xiaobo, and Ravi Kanbur. 2001. “What Differ-
bridge and London: MIT Press. ences Do Polarisation Measures Make? An Appli-
Xu, Chongde. 2005. A History of the PRC Constitution, cation to China.” Journal of Development Studies,
Volumes 1 and 2 (Zhonghua Renmin Gongheguo 37(3): 85–98.
Xianfa Shi). Fuzhou: Fujian People’s Press. Zhao, Ziyang. 2009. Prisoner of the State: The Secret
Xu, Quanxing. 1995. Theory and Practice of Mao Journal of Zhao Ziyang. New York and London:
Zedong in His Late Years (1956–1976) (Mao Zedong Simon & Schuster.
wannian de lilun yu shijian, 1956–1976). Beijing: Zhuang, Juzhong, and Chenggang Xu. 1996. “Profit-
China Encyclopedia Press. Sharing and Financial Performance in the Chinese
Xu, Xianxiang, Xianbin Wang, and Yuan Shu. 2007. State Enterprises: Evidence from Panel Data.” Eco-
“Local Officials and Economic Growth.” Jingji nomics of Planning, 29(3): 205–22.
­Yanjiu/Economic Research Journal, 42(9): 18–31. Zhuravskaya, Ekaterina. 2000. “Incentives to Provide
Yang, Dali L. 1997. Beyond Beijing: Liberalization and Local Public Goods: Fiscal Federalism, Russian
the Regions in China. New York and London: Taylor Style.” Journal of Public Economics, 76(3): 337–68.
This article has been cited by:

1. Jing Cheng. 2021. Analysis of commercial land leasing of the district governments of Beijing in China.
Land Use Policy 100, 104881. [Crossref]
2. Shawn Xiaoguang Chen, Yong Liu, Xianxiang Xu. 2020. Dynamics of Local Cadre Appointment in
China. China Economic Review 64, 101559. [Crossref]
3. Yi Che, Rui Xiao. 2020. Import competition, fast-track authority and U.S. policy toward China.
Journal of Comparative Economics 48:4, 974-996. [Crossref]
4. Rui-fen Cao, An-lu Zhang, Yin-ying Cai, Xiang-xiang Xie. 2020. How imbalanced land development
affects local fiscal condition? A case study of Hubei Province, China. Land Use Policy 99, 105086.
[Crossref]
5. Lan Zheng, Ming Na. 2020. A pollution paradox? The political economy of environmental inspection
and air pollution in China. Energy Research & Social Science 70, 101773. [Crossref]
6. Chunhong Sheng. 2020. Not just the state: The role of entrepreneurs in China’s energy transition.
Energy Research & Social Science 70, 101814. [Crossref]
7. Xin Liu, Yongzheng Liu. 2020. Land lease revenue windfalls and local tax policy in China.
International Tax and Public Finance 89. . [Crossref]
8. Junqing Li, Qiheng Han, Pengfei Liu, Jianbo Zhang. 2020. Institutional Quality, Financial Friction,
and Sustained Economic Growth: The Case of China. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade 56:14,
3270-3293. [Crossref]
9. Sumit Kane, Hong Jiang, Yuan Tian, Maitrayee Mukhopadhyay, Xu Qian. 2020. Making effective
referrals happen: a theory-informed policy analysis. Health Policy and Planning 4. . [Crossref]
10. Guojun He, Shaoda Wang, Bing Zhang. 2020. Watering Down Environmental Regulation in China*.
The Quarterly Journal of Economics 135:4, 2135-2185. [Crossref]
11. Jiayi Wang, Ping Lei. 2020. The tournament of Chinese environmental protection: Strong or weak
competition?. Ecological Economics 106888. [Crossref]
12. Shaojian Chen, Hui Mao, Zongxian Feng. 2020. Political uncertainty and firm entry: Evidence from
Chinese manufacturing industries. Journal of Business Research 120, 16-30. [Crossref]
13. Lixing Li, Kevin Zhengcheng Liu, Zhuo Nie, Tianyang Xi. 2020. Evading by any means? VAT
enforcement and payroll tax evasion in China. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization . [Crossref]
14. Xiaoqi Sun, Xiaojia Liu. 2020. Decomposition analysis of debt’s impact on China’s energy
consumption. Energy Policy 146, 111802. [Crossref]
15. Shiyu Bo. 2020. Environmental Regulations, Political Incentives and Local Economic Activities:
Evidence from China*. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 12. . [Crossref]
16. Jianjun Zhang, Pei Sun, Kunyuan Qiao. 2020. Wining and Dining Government Officials: What Drives
Political Networking in Chinese Private Ventures?. Management and Organization Review 5, 1-30.
[Crossref]
17. Howard Liu. 2020. Elite Competition, Local Extraction, and Social Unrest: Understanding Mass
Protest in Authoritarian Regimes. Journal of Global Security Studies 44. . [Crossref]
18. Jian Wang, Mark Skidmore, Qun Wu, Shu Wang. 2020. The impact of a tax cut reform on land
finance revenue: Constrained by the binding target of construction land. Journal of Urban Affairs 26,
1-30. [Crossref]
19. Guanchun Liu, Chengsi Zhang, Yueteng Zhu. 2020. The interest group theory of banking sector
expansion in China: Evidence from a quasi-natural experiment. Journal of International Money and
Finance 107, 102225. [Crossref]
20. Liangxiong Huang, Shulin Liu, Yonghui Han, Keming Peng. 2020. The nature of state-owned
enterprises and collection of pollutant discharge fees: A study based on Chinese industrial enterprises.
Journal of Cleaner Production 271, 122420. [Crossref]
21. Jianqiang Li, Yaowen Shan, Gary Tian, Xiangchao Hao. 2020. Labor cost, government intervention,
and corporate innovation: Evidence from China. Journal of Corporate Finance 64, 101668. [Crossref]
22. Jianing Zang, Liangliang Liu. 2020. Fiscal decentralization, government environmental preference,
and regional environmental governance efficiency: evidence from China. The Annals of Regional Science
65:2, 439-457. [Crossref]
23. Meir Alkon, Audrye Wong. 2020. Authoritarian energy transitions undermined? Environmental
governance cycles in China’s power sector. Energy Research & Social Science 68, 101531. [Crossref]
24. Shilin Zheng, Zhaochen Li. 2020. Pilot governance and the rise of China's innovation. China Economic
Review 63, 101521. [Crossref]
25. Xiandeng Jiang, Dongming Kong, Chengrui Xiao. 2020. Policy certainty and heterogeneous firm
innovation: Evidence from China. China Economic Review 63, 101500. [Crossref]
26. Dayong Liu, Chunfa Xu, Yongze Yu, Kaijian Rong, Junyan Zhang. 2020. Economic growth target,
distortion of public expenditure and business cycle in China. China Economic Review 63, 101373.
[Crossref]
27. Pi‐Han Tsai, Chien‐Yu Huang, Tsun‐Feng Chiang. 2020. FISCAL EXPENDITURE AND
INDUSTRIAL LAND PRICE IN CHINA: THEORY AND EVIDENCE. Contemporary Economic
Policy 38:4, 593-606. [Crossref]
28. Jie Ouyang, Kezhong Zhang, Bo Wen, Yuanping Lu. 2020. Top-Down and Bottom-Up Approaches
to Environmental Governance in China: Evidence from the River Chief System (RCS). International
Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health 17:19, 7058. [Crossref]
29. C. Xiang, T. van Gevelt. 2020. Central inspection teams and the enforcement of environmental
regulations in China. Environmental Science & Policy 112, 431-439. [Crossref]
30. Feng Song, Zichao Yu, Weiting Zhuang, Ao Lu. 2020. The institutional logic of wind energy
integration: What can China learn from the United States to reduce wind curtailment?. Renewable
and Sustainable Energy Reviews 110440. [Crossref]
31. Guoxing Zhang, Wei Liu, Hongbo Duan. 2020. Environmental regulation policies, local government
enforcement and pollution-intensive industry transfer in China. Computers & Industrial Engineering
148, 106748. [Crossref]
32. Linchuan Yang, Xiaoling Chu, Zhonghua Gou, Hongtai Yang, Yi Lu, Wencheng Huang. 2020.
Accessibility and proximity effects of bus rapid transit on housing prices: Heterogeneity across price
quantiles and space. Journal of Transport Geography 88, 102850. [Crossref]
33. Rongyu Wang, Rong Tan. 2020. Patterns of rural collective action in contemporary China: An
archetype analysis of rural construction land consolidation. Journal of Rural Studies 79, 286-301.
[Crossref]
34. Chao Yan, Min Liu. 2020. Constitutional amendment and stock prices: evidence from China. Asia-
Pacific Journal of Accounting & Economics 27, 1-20. [Crossref]
35. Jiafu An, Seth Armitage, Wenxuan Hou, Xianda Liu. 2020. Do checks on bureaucrats improve firm
value? Evidence from a natural experiment. Accounting & Finance 21. . [Crossref]
36. Danqing Wang, Zhitao Zhu, Shuo Chen, Xiaowei Rose Luo. 2020. Running out of steam? A political
incentive perspective of FDI inflows in China. Journal of International Business Studies 39. . [Crossref]
37. Chenjian Zhang. 2020. Formal and informal institutional legacies and inward foreign direct investment
into firms: Evidence from China. Journal of International Business Studies 91. . [Crossref]
38. Eagle Zhang. 2020. Discourses on public sector accounting reforms in China: A brief history (1949–
2019). Accounting History 11, 103237322094862. [Crossref]
39. Nan Gao, Pinghan Liang, Lixin Colin Xu. 2020. Power struggle and pork barrel politics in
authoritarian countries: Evidence from China. Economics of Transition and Institutional Change 75. .
[Crossref]
40. Andrew Flynn, Linjun Xie, Nick Hacking. 2020. Governing people, governing places: advancing the
Protean environmental state in China. Journal of Environmental Policy & Planning 22:5, 724-744.
[Crossref]
41. Xin Wang, Ping Lei. 2020. Does strict environmental regulation lead to incentive contradiction? —
Evidence from China. Journal of Environmental Management 269, 110632. [Crossref]
42. Rongyu Wang, Rong Tan. 2020. Patterns of revenue distribution in rural residential land consolidation
in contemporary China: The perspective of property rights delineation. Land Use Policy 97, 104742.
[Crossref]
43. Pei Li, Yi Lu, Jin Wang. 2020. The effects of fuel standards on air pollution: Evidence from China.
Journal of Development Economics 146, 102488. [Crossref]
44. Junichi Yamasaki. 2020. Time horizon of government and public goods investment: Evidence from
Japan. Journal of Development Economics 146, 102518. [Crossref]
45. Dalia Ghanem, Shu Shen, Junjie Zhang. 2020. A Censored Maximum Likelihood Approach to
Quantifying Manipulation in China’s Air Pollution Data. Journal of the Association of Environmental
and Resource Economists 7:5, 965-1003. [Crossref]
46. Daquan Huang, Xin Tan, Tao Liu, Erxuan Chu, Fanhao Kong. 2020. Effects of Hierarchical City
Centers on the Intensity and Direction of Urban Land Expansion: A Case Study of Beijing. Land
9:9, 312. [Crossref]
47. Xiaoxia Li, Guilong Cai, Danglun Luo. 2020. GDP distortion and tax avoidance in local SOEs:
Evidence from China. International Review of Economics & Finance 69, 582-598. [Crossref]
48. Di Guo, Kun Jiang, Chenggang Xu, Xiyi Yang. 2020. Clustering, growth and inequality in China.
Journal of Economic Geography 20:5, 1207-1239. [Crossref]
49. Xia Chen, Qiang Cheng, Ying Hao, Qiang Liu. 2020. GDP growth incentives and earnings
management: evidence from China. Review of Accounting Studies 25:3, 1002-1039. [Crossref]
50. Mengling Zhou, Bing Wang, Zhongfei Chen. 2020. Has the anti-corruption campaign decreased air
pollution in China?. Energy Economics 91, 104878. [Crossref]
51. Haitao Wu, Yu Hao, Siyu Ren. 2020. How do environmental regulation and environmental
decentralization affect green total factor energy efficiency: Evidence from China. Energy Economics 91,
104880. [Crossref]
52. Zhifeng Wang, Guiying Laura Wu, Qu Feng. 2020. Productivity of core infrastructure investment in
China: An input–output approach. The World Economy 32. . [Crossref]
53. Matthew M. C. Allen, Maria L. Allen, Syed Imran Saqib, Jiajia Liu. 2020. State-Permeated Capitalism
and the Solar PV Industry in China and India. New Political Economy 33, 1-13. [Crossref]
54. LILI KANG, SAJID ANWAR, FEI PENG. 2020. OWNERSHIP STRUCTURE, ACQUISITIONS
AND EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION: EVIDENCE FROM PUBLICLY LISTED CHINESE
COMPANIES. The Singapore Economic Review 44, 1-31. [Crossref]
55. Jason Barr, Jingshu Luo. 2020. Growing Skylines: The Economic Determinants of Skyscrapers in
China. The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 38. . [Crossref]
56. Xiaohu Wang, Hanyu Xiao, Kai Chen, Xuejiao Niu. 2020. Why administrative leaders take
pro‐environmental leadership actions: Evidence from an eco‐compensation programme in China.
Environmental Policy and Governance 25. . [Crossref]
57. Shan Gao, Shuang Ling, Xiaozhou Liu, Xin Dou, Rong Wu. 2020. Understanding local government’s
information disclosure in China’s environmental project construction from the dual-pressure
perspective. Journal of Cleaner Production 263, 121311. [Crossref]
58. Qiang Liu, Ying Hao, Yong Du, Yuning Xing. 2020. GDP competition and corporate investment:
Evidence from China. Pacific Economic Review 25:3, 402-426. [Crossref]
59. Qingling Shi, Chenchen Shi, Feng Guo. 2020. Political Blue Sky: Evidence from the Local Annual
“Two Sessions” in China. Resource and Energy Economics 61, 101165. [Crossref]
60. Yanqing Ding, Fengming Lu, Xiaoyang Ye. 2020. Intergovernmental transfer under heterogeneous
accountabilities: The effects of the 2006 Chinese Education Finance Reform. Economics of Education
Review 77, 101985. [Crossref]
61. Kul B Luintel, Kent Matthews, Lucy Minford, Akos Valentinyi, Baoshun Wang. 2020. The role
of Provincial Government Spending Composition in growth and convergence in China. Economic
Modelling 90, 117-134. [Crossref]
62. Xufeng Zhu, Tianguang Meng. 2020. Geographical Leadership Mobility and Policy Isomorphism:
Narrowing the Regional Inequality of Social Spending in China. Policy Studies Journal 48:3, 806-832.
[Crossref]
63. Meina Cai, Jianyong Fan, Chunhui Ye, Qi Zhang. 2020. Government debt, land financing and
distributive justice in China. Urban Studies 5, 004209802093852. [Crossref]
64. Jiandong Chen, Sishi Rong, Malin Song, Baofeng Shi. 2020. Evaluation of the Rural Minimum Living
Standard Line in China. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade 56:9, 1971-1988. [Crossref]
65. Hazwan Haini. 2020. The evolution of China’s modern economy and its implications on future
growth. Post-Communist Economies 86, 1-25. [Crossref]
66. Shuanping Dai, Wolfram Elsner. 2020. Shrinking Trust in Growing China: A Trade-Off Between Fast
Growth, Change and Institutionalized Cooperation?. Forum for Social Economics 65, 1-19. [Crossref]
67. Tong Fu, Zhongmei Wei, Ze Jian. 2020. The persistent institutional effect of liberal colonialism:
evidence from China’s financial policies. Applied Economics 52:32, 3525-3537. [Crossref]
68. Stephen Fortescue. 2020. Russia’s civil service: professional or patrimonial? Executive-level officials
in five federal ministries. Post-Soviet Affairs 36:4, 365-388. [Crossref]
69. Xufeng Zhu, Guihua Bai. 2020. Policy Synthesis through Regional Experimentations: Comparative
Study of the New Cooperative Medical Scheme in Three Chinese Provinces. Journal of Comparative
Policy Analysis: Research and Practice 22:4, 320-343. [Crossref]
70. Zhihua Tian, Yanfang Tian. 2020. Political incentives, Party Congress, and pollution cycle: empirical
evidence from China. Environment and Development Economics 2, 1-17. [Crossref]
71. Ciqi Mei. 2020. Policy style, consistency and the effectiveness of the policy mix in China’s fight against
COVID-19. Policy and Society 39:3, 309-325. [Crossref]
72. Dic Lo. 2020. State-Owned Enterprises in Chinese Economic Transformation: Institutional
Functionality and Credibility in Alternative Perspectives. Journal of Economic Issues 54:3, 813-837.
[Crossref]
73. Linda Glawe, Helmut Wagner. 2020. The role of institutional quality and human capital for economic
growth across Chinese provinces – a dynamic panel data approach. Journal of Chinese Economic and
Business Studies 18:3, 209-227. [Crossref]
74. Qing-Ping Ma. 2020. The China Miracle in a technological and socio-political framework—The role
of institutions. Journal of Chinese Economic and Business Studies 18:3, 253-272. [Crossref]
75. Linchuan Yang, Yang Chen, Nenglai Xu, Rui Zhao, K.W. Chau, Shijian Hong. 2020. Place-varying
impacts of urban rail transit on property prices in Shenzhen, China: Insights for value capture.
Sustainable Cities and Society 58, 102140. [Crossref]
76. Jing Wu, Hao Li, Keyang Li. 2020. Local political chief turnover and economic growth: Evidence
from China. Economics of Transition and Institutional Change 28:3, 441-466. [Crossref]
77. Bingyong Zheng, Junji Xiao. 2020. Corruption and Investment: Theory and Evidence from China.
Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 175, 40-54. [Crossref]
78. Zhenbo Zhang, Taijun Jin, Xiaohua Meng. 2020. From race-to-the-bottom to strategic imitation:
how does political competition impact the environmental enforcement of local governments in China?.
Environmental Science and Pollution Research 27:20, 25675-25688. [Crossref]
79. Songtao Xu, Zhifang Zhou, Ke Liu. 2020. Multi-Evolutionary Game Research on Heavy Metal
Pollution Control in Soil: Based on a Third-Party Perspective. Sustainability 12:13, 5306. [Crossref]
80. Xu Cheng, Dongmin Kong, Junbo Wang. 2020. Political uncertainty and A-H share premium. Pacific-
Basin Finance Journal 101388. [Crossref]
81. Lin Zhang, Yanliu Lin, Pieter Hooimeijer, Stan Geertman. 2020. Heterogeneity of public
participation in urban redevelopment in Chinese cities: Beijing versus Guangzhou. Urban Studies 57:9,
1903-1919. [Crossref]
82. Jiaqi Qin, Xue Yang, Qing He, Lingxia Sun. 2020. Litigation risk and cost of capital: Evidence from
China. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 101393. [Crossref]
83. Danglun Luo, Congcong Liu, Lifan Wu. 2020. Horizontal Networks and Economic Performance:
Evidence from City Leaders in China. Social Science Quarterly 101:4, 1359-1373. [Crossref]
84. Liangliang Liu. 2020. Fiscal decentralization and the imbalance between consumption and investment
in China. The Annals of Regional Science 98. . [Crossref]
85. Yichuan Hu, Chang Li, Cong Qin. 2020. The impact of regional financial depth on outbound cross-
border mergers and acquisitions. Journal of International Money and Finance 104, 102181. [Crossref]
86. Zichao Yu. 2020. Beyond the state/market dichotomy: Institutional innovations in China's electricity
industry reform. Journal of Environmental Management 264, 110306. [Crossref]
87. Guojun He, Yang Xie, Bing Zhang. 2020. Expressways, GDP, and the environment: The case of
China. Journal of Development Economics 145, 102485. [Crossref]
88. Yongli Jiao, Yang Yu. 2020. Rising private city operators in contemporary China: A study of the
CFLD model. Cities 101, 102696. [Crossref]
89. Yunsen Chen, Jianqiao Huang, Sheng Xiao, Ziye Zhao. 2020. The “home bias” of corporate subsidiary
locations. Journal of Corporate Finance 62, 101591. [Crossref]
90. DONGHUI WU, QING YE. 2020. Public Attention and Auditor Behavior: The Case of Hurun Rich
List in China. Journal of Accounting Research 58:3, 777-825. [Crossref]
91. Gang Jin, Kunrong Shen, Jian Li. 2020. Interjurisdiction political competition and green total factor
productivity in China: An inverted-U relationship. China Economic Review 61, 101224. [Crossref]
92. Muyang Zhang, Guangsu Zhou, Gang Fan. 2020. Political Control and Economic Inequality: Evidence
from Chinese Cities. China Economic Review 61, 101272. [Crossref]
93. Pranab Bardhan. 2020. The Chinese governance system: Its strengths and weaknesses in a comparative
development perspective. China Economic Review 61, 101430. [Crossref]
94. Ying Ge, David Dollar, Xinding Yu. 2020. Institutions and participation in global value chains:
Evidence from belt and road initiative. China Economic Review 61, 101447. [Crossref]
95. Xiaoqian Zhang, Mingqiang Yu, Gaoquan Chen. 2020. Does mixed-ownership reform improve SOEs'
innovation? Evidence from state ownership. China Economic Review 61, 101450. [Crossref]
96. Kuei-min Chang. 2020. Between Spiritual Economy and Religious Commodification: Negotiating
Temple Autonomy in Contemporary China. The China Quarterly 242, 440-459. [Crossref]
97. Yunsen Chen, Chenyu Cui, Ting Yang, Xin Zhang. 2020. Political favouritism and investment
efficiency. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 61, 101058. [Crossref]
98. John Gerring, Wouter Veenendaal. Population and Politics 79, . [Crossref]
99. Yongzheng Liu, Hang Tai, Chenping Yang. 2020. Fiscal incentives and local tax competition: Evidence
from China. The World Economy 137. . [Crossref]
100. Tao Liu, Wenya Zhang, Raymond Yu Wang. 2020. How does the Chinese government improve
connectivity in water governance? A qualitative systematic review. International Journal of Water
Resources Development 8, 1-19. [Crossref]
101. Ziteng Fan, Qingguo Meng, Na Wei. 2020. Fiscal slack or environmental pressures: which matters
more for technological innovation assimilation? A configurational approach. International Public
Management Journal 23:3, 380-404. [Crossref]
102. Jiannan Wu, Richard M. Walker. 2020. Public management in China: reform, innovation and
governance. International Public Management Journal 23:3, v-ix. [Crossref]
103. Qingling Shi, Chenchen Shi, Feng Guo. 2020. National leaders’ visits and temporary improvement of
air quality: evidence from Chinese cities. Empirical Economics 58:5, 2105-2127. [Crossref]
104. Changdong Zhang. 2020. Reexamine regional models of China's economic growth: Toward an
integrated analytical framework. Sociology Compass 14:5. . [Crossref]
105. Lan Xue, Jing Zhao. 2020. Truncated Decision Making and Deliberative Implementation: A Time‐
Based Policy Process Model for Transitional China. Policy Studies Journal 48:2, 298-326. [Crossref]
106. Conghu Wang, Xiaoming Li, Wenjuan Ma, Xiaopeng Wang. 2020. Diffusion models over the life
cycle of an innovation: A bottom‐up and top‐down synthesis approach. Public Administration and
Development 40:2, 105-118. [Crossref]
107. Wen Zhang. 2020. Political incentives and local government spending multiplier: Evidence for Chinese
provinces (1978–2016). Economic Modelling 87, 59-71. [Crossref]
108. Meina Cai, Pengfei Liu, Hui Wang. 2020. Land commodification and hukou policy innovation in
China: evidence from a survey experiment. Journal of Chinese Governance 11, 1-20. [Crossref]
109. Yipeng Tang. 2020. Government spending on local higher education institutions (LHEIs) in China:
analysing the determinants of general appropriations and their contributions. Studies in Higher
Education 31, 1-14. [Crossref]
110. Kwan Nok Chan, Shiwei Fan. 2020. Friction and bureaucratic control in authoritarian regimes.
Regulation & Governance 14. . [Crossref]
111. Shu Keng, Chien‐Chiang Lee, Weiping Li, Jim Huangnan Shen. 2020. BILATERAL RENT‐
SEEKING AND GROWTH OF FDI INFLOW IN CHINA: THEORY AND EVIDENCE.
Contemporary Economic Policy 38:2, 359-379. [Crossref]
112. Meina Cai, Ilia Murtazashvili, Jennifer Murtazashvili. 2020. The politics of land property rights.
Journal of Institutional Economics 16:2, 151-167. [Crossref]
113. Matt Qvortrup, Brendan O’Leary, Ronald Wintrobe. 2020. Explaining the Paradox of Plebiscites.
Government and Opposition 55:2, 202-219. [Crossref]
114. Yu Zeng, Stan Hok-wui Wong. 2020. Time Is Power: Rethinking Meritocratic Political Selection in
China. The China Quarterly 7, 1-28. [Crossref]
115. Junxue Jia, Guangrong Ma, Cong Qin, Liyan Wang. 2020. Place-based policies, state-led
industrialisation, and regional development: Evidence from China's Great Western Development
Programme. European Economic Review 123, 103398. [Crossref]
116. Can Li, Danxue Gao, Weiguo Zhong. 2020. A Political Cycle of Regional FDI Spillovers in an
Emerging Market: Evidence from China. Management International Review 60:2, 151-176. [Crossref]
117. Hai-Anh H. Dang, Yang Huang, Harris Selod. 2020. Children Left Behind in China: The Role of
School Fees. IZA Journal of Development and Migration 11:1. . [Crossref]
118. Bo Wen. 2020. Old problems and new dilemmas: the conundrum of environmental management
reform in China. Journal of Environmental Policy & Planning 22:2, 281-299. [Crossref]
119. Jichuan Sheng, Weihai Zhou, Bangzhu Zhu. 2020. The coordination of stakeholder interests
in environmental regulation: Lessons from China’s environmental regulation policies from the
perspective of the evolutionary game theory. Journal of Cleaner Production 249, 119385. [Crossref]
120. Bin Wang, Yu Zheng. 2020. A model of tournament incentives with corruption. Journal of Comparative
Economics 48:1, 182-197. [Crossref]
121. Stan Hok‐Wui Wong, Yu Zeng. 2020. Familiarity breeds growth: The impact of factional ties on
local cadres’ economic performance in China. Economics & Politics 32:1, 143-171. [Crossref]
122. Peng Bin, Xiaolan Chen, Andrea Fracasso, Chiara Tomasi. 2020. Firm employment growth in China:
The role of marketization and regional economic factors. Growth and Change 51:1, 402-439. [Crossref]
123. Wenming Xu, Guangdong Xu. 2020. Understanding public enforcement of securities law in China: An
empirical analysis of the enforcement actions of the CSRC and its regional offices against informational
misconduct. International Review of Law and Economics 61, 105877. [Crossref]
124. Jinbo Luo, Xiaoran Ni, Gary Gang Tian. 2020. Short selling and corporate tax avoidance: Insights
from a financial constraint view. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 101323. [Crossref]
125. Wenming Xu, Shaogang Zhu, Zhicheng Wu. 2020. Building a Junior Stock Exchange: Lessons from
China. European Business Organization Law Review 21:1, 139-170. [Crossref]
126. Gaowen Kong, Tony Dongmin Kong, Ruichang Lu. 2020. Political promotion incentives and within-
firm pay gap: Evidence from China. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy 39:2, 106715. [Crossref]
127. Yunsen Chen, Limei Che, Dengjin Zheng, Hong You. 2020. Corruption culture and accounting
quality. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy 39:2, 106698. [Crossref]
128. Tong Fu, Chao Cai, Ze Jian. 2020. The illusion of “win–win” solution: Why environmental regulation
in china promotes firm performance?. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 52, 366-373.
[Crossref]
129. Jian Wang, Qun Wu, Siqi Yan, Guancheng Guo, Shangui Peng. 2020. China’s local governments
breaking the land use planning quota: A strategic interaction perspective. Land Use Policy 92, 104434.
[Crossref]
130. Zafarullah Sahito, Pertti Vaisanen. 2020. A literature review on teachers’ job satisfaction in developing
countries: Recommendations and solutions for the enhancement of the job. Review of Education 8:1,
3-34. [Crossref]
131. Xinxiang Li, Teerooven Soobaroyen. 2020. Accounting, Ideological and Political Work and Chinese
multinational operations: A neo-Gramscian perspective. Critical Perspectives on Accounting 102160.
[Crossref]
132. Qiang Gong, Chong Liu, Min Wu. 2020. Does administrative decentralization enhance economic
growth? Evidence from a quasi-natural experiment in China. Economic Modelling . [Crossref]
133. Bingyang Lv, Yongzheng Liu, Yan Li. 2020. Fiscal incentives, competition, and investment in China.
China Economic Review 59, 101371. [Crossref]
134. Chengrui Xiao. 2020. Intergovernmental revenue relations, tax enforcement and tax shifting: evidence
from China. International Tax and Public Finance 27:1, 128-152. [Crossref]
135. Jiang Yu, Rui Liu, Feng Chen. 2020. Linking institutional environment with technological change:
The rise of China's flat panel display industry. Technological Forecasting and Social Change 151, 119852.
[Crossref]
136. Shiyu Bo, Joy Chen, Yan Song, Sen Zhou. 2020. Media attention and choice of major: Evidence from
anti-doctor violence in China. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 170, 1-19. [Crossref]
137. Meina Cai, Pengfei Liu, Hui Wang. 2020. Political trust, risk preferences, and policy support: A study
of land-dispossessed villagers in China. World Development 125, 104687. [Crossref]
138. Li Ji, Wei Zhang. 2020. Fiscal Incentives and Sustainable Urbanization: Evidence from China.
Sustainability 12:1, 103. [Crossref]
139. Harry X. Wu. Losing Steam?—An industry origin analysis of China's productivity slowdown 137-167.
[Crossref]
140. Yi Lu, Mengna Luan, Tuan-Hwee Sng. 2020. Did the communists contribute to China’s rural
growth?. Explorations in Economic History 75, 101315. [Crossref]
141. Shiyu Bo. 2020. Centralization and regional development: Evidence from a political hierarchy reform
to create cities in china. Journal of Urban Economics 115, 103182. [Crossref]
142. Junxue Jia, Siying Ding, Yongzheng Liu. 2020. Decentralization, incentives, and local tax enforcement.
Journal of Urban Economics 115, 103225. [Crossref]
143. Chong-en Bai, Chang-Tai Hsieh, Zheng Song. 2020. Special Deals with Chinese Characteristics.
NBER Macroeconomics Annual 34, 341-379. [Crossref]
144. Taisu Zhang. 2020. Beyond Information Costs: Preference Formation and the Architecture of
Property Law. Journal of Legal Analysis 12, 1-78. [Crossref]
145. Po Yang, Rong Wang. 2020. Central-local relations and higher education stratification in China.
Higher Education 79:1, 111-139. [Crossref]
146. Qianmiao Chen, Qingyang Huang, Chang Liu, Peng Wang. 2020. Political Incentive is Back: The
Tradeoff between Epidemic Control and Economic Development in China’s Campaigns against SARS
and COVID-19. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
147. Yin Germaschewski, Jaroslav Horvath, Loris Rubini. 2020. Property Rights, Expropriations, and
Business Cycles in China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
148. 2020. OUP accepted manuscript. Journal Of African Economies . [Crossref]
149. Franklin Allen, Jun “QJ” Qian, Meijun Qian. 2019. A Review of China's Institutions. Annual Review
of Financial Economics 11:1, 39-64. [Crossref]
150. Danqing Wang, Xiaowei Rose Luo. 2019. Retire in Peace: Officials’ Political Incentives and Corporate
Diversification in China. Administrative Science Quarterly 64:4, 773-809. [Crossref]
151. Bo Zhang, Li Zhang, Jing Wu, Shouqing Wang. 2019. Factors Affecting Local Governments’ Public–
Private Partnership Adoption in Urban China. Sustainability 11:23, 6831. [Crossref]
152. Jinshuai Hu, Haiyan Jiang, Mark Holmes. 2019. Government subsidies and corporate investment
efficiency: Evidence from China. Emerging Markets Review 41, 100658. [Crossref]
153. Zhigao Luo, Xinyun Hu, Mingming Li, Jirui Yang, Chuanhao Wen. 2019. Centralization or
Decentralization of Environmental Governance—Evidence from China. Sustainability 11:24, 6938.
[Crossref]
154. Naubahar Sharif, Jack Linzhou Xing. 2019. Restricted generalizability of city innovation policies: The
case of E-hailing in China. Science and Public Policy 46:6, 805-819. [Crossref]
155. Julie Ann Elston, Alois Weidinger. 2019. Entrepreneurial intention and regional internationalization
in China. Small Business Economics 53:4, 1001-1015. [Crossref]
156. Vasyl Gorbachuk, Maxym Dunaievskyi, Seit-Bekir Suleimanov. Modeling of Agency Problems in
Complex Decentralized Systems Under Information Asymmetry 449-454. [Crossref]
157. Harry X. Wu. 2019. In Quest of Institutional Interpretation of TFP Change—The Case of China.
Man and the Economy 6:2. . [Crossref]
158. Shuanping Dai, Markus Taube. 2019. The long tail thesis. Chinese Management Studies 14:2, 433-454.
[Crossref]
159. Zhao Liu, Huan Zhang, Yue-Jun Zhang, Fang-E Duan, Lan-Ye Wei. 2019. Research on the effects
of market integration on carbon emissions. Management Decision ahead-of-print:ahead-of-print. .
[Crossref]
160. Ting Ren, Nan Liu, Hongyan Yang, Youzhi Xiao, Yijun Hu. 2019. Working capital management and
firm performance in China. Asian Review of Accounting ahead-of-print:ahead-of-print. . [Crossref]
161. Fangjun Wang, Junqin Sun, Yang Stephanie Liu. 2019. Institutional pressure, ultimate ownership,
and corporate carbon reduction engagement: Evidence from China. Journal of Business Research 104,
14-26. [Crossref]
162. Yun Zhong, Xiaobo Su. 2019. Spatial selectivity and intercity cooperation between Guangdong and
Hong Kong. Urban Studies 56:14, 3011-3029. [Crossref]
163. Jichuan Sheng, Michael Webber. 2019. Governance rescaling and neoliberalization of China’s water
governance: The case of China’s South–North Water Transfer Project. Environment and Planning A:
Economy and Space 51:8, 1644-1664. [Crossref]
164. Shuangrui Fan, Cong Wang. 2019. Firm age, ultimate ownership, and R&D investments. International
Review of Economics & Finance . [Crossref]
165. Kevin Lo, Vanesa Castán Broto. 2019. Co-benefits, contradictions, and multi-level governance of
low-carbon experimentation: Leveraging solar energy for sustainable development in China. Global
Environmental Change 59, 101993. [Crossref]
166. Gerhard Wegner. 2019. Entrepreneurship in autocratic regimes – how neo-patrimonialism constrains
innovation. Journal of Evolutionary Economics 29:5, 1507-1529. [Crossref]
167. Yanlei Zhang. 2019. Greasing Dirty Machines: Evidence of Pollution-Driven Bribery in China. Journal
of Business Ethics 55. . [Crossref]
168. Rong Xu, Xingmei Xu, Junyan Zhang, Conggang Li. 2019. Does legal protection affect firm value?
Evidence from China’s stock market. Accounting & Finance 77. . [Crossref]
169. Yanyu Wang, Xin Su, Huan Wang, Renyu Zou. 2019. Intellectual capital and technological dynamic
capability: evidence from Chinese enterprises. Journal of Intellectual Capital 20:4, 453-471. [Crossref]
170. Colleen Chiu-Shee, Siqi Zheng. 2019. A burden or a tool? Rationalizing public housing provision in
Chinese cities. Housing Studies 14, 1-44. [Crossref]
171. Jianhong Zhang, Shifan Quan, Jiangang Jiang. 2019. Corruption and private firms' survival in
transition economies: Evidence from China. China Economic Review 57, 101339. [Crossref]
172. Yaling Deng, Daming You, Jingjing Wang. 2019. Optimal strategy for enterprises’ green technology
innovation from the perspective of political competition. Journal of Cleaner Production 235, 930-942.
[Crossref]
173. Haifeng Zhang, Junsen Zhang, Yanfeng Zhang. 2019. Do tournament incentives matter in academics?
Evidence from personnel data in a top-tier university in China. Journal of Economic Behavior &
Organization 166, 84-106. [Crossref]
174. Xing Li, Chong Liu, Xi Weng, Li-An Zhou. 2019. Target Setting in Tournaments: Theory and
Evidence from China. The Economic Journal 129:623, 2888-2915. [Crossref]
175. Portia P.S. Sifolo, Lorraine P. Molefe, Unathi S. Henama, Pascal Tauoatsoala, Pfarelo Manavhela.
2019. Investigating the supply chain drivers and barriers in the tourism industry in Pretoria. Journal
of Transport and Supply Chain Management 13. . [Crossref]
176. Juan Carlos Suárez Serrato, Xiao Yu Wang, Shuang Zhang. 2019. The limits of meritocracy: Screening
bureaucrats under imperfect verifiability. Journal of Development Economics 140, 223-241. [Crossref]
177. Jianshuang Fan, Lin Zhou. 2019. Three-dimensional intergovernmental competition and urban
sprawl: Evidence from Chinese prefectural-level cities. Land Use Policy 87, 104035. [Crossref]
178. Ling Chen, Wenhui Yang. 2019. R&D tax credits and firm innovation: Evidence from China.
Technological Forecasting and Social Change 146, 233-241. [Crossref]
179. Xiaoran Ni. 2019. Local official turnover, ownership, and firm cash holdings: Insights from an
emerging market. European Financial Management 25:4, 1013-1046. [Crossref]
180. Junming Zhu, Marian R. Chertow. 2019. Authoritarian but responsive: L ocal regulation of industrial
energy efficiency in J iangsu, C hina. Regulation & Governance 13:3, 384-404. [Crossref]
181. GUONAN MA, JAMES LAURENCESON. 2019. CHINA’S DEBT CHALLENGE: STYLIZED
FACTS, DRIVERS AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS. The Singapore Economic Review 64:04,
815-837. [Crossref]
182. Darong Dai, Wenzheng Gao, Guoqiang Tian. 2019. Two Differential Games Between Rent-Seeking
Politicians and Capitalists: Implications for Economic Growth. International Game Theory Review
21:03, 1850011. [Crossref]
183. Cha Li, Felipe A. Csaszar. 2019. Government as Landscape Designer: A Behavioral View of Industrial
Policy. Strategy Science 4:3, 175-192. [Crossref]
184. Belay Seyoum, Juan Ramirez. 2019. Economic freedom and trade flows. Journal of Economic Studies
46:4, 985-1006. [Crossref]
185. Yin-Fang Zhang, Shengbao Ji. 2019. Infrastructure, externalities and regional industrial productivity
in China: a spatial econometric approach. Regional Studies 53:8, 1112-1124. [Crossref]
186. Yi Lu, Jin Wang, Lianming Zhu. 2019. Place-Based Policies, Creation, and Agglomeration
Economies: Evidence from China’s Economic Zone Program. American Economic Journal: Economic
Policy 11:3, 325-360. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
187. Jianhong Zhang, Xinming He, Chaohong Zhou, Désirée van Gorp. 2019. Antecedents of corporate
image: The case of Chinese multinational enterprises in the Netherlands. Journal of Business Research
101, 389-401. [Crossref]
188. Yanzhao Lai, Nicholas S Vonortas. 2019. Regional entrepreneurial ecosystems in China. Industrial and
Corporate Change 28:4, 875-897. [Crossref]
189. Giray Gozgor, Chi Keung Marco Lau, Zhou Lu. 2019. Convergence clustering in the Chinese
provinces: New evidence from several macroeconomic indicators. Review of Development Economics
23:3, 1331-1346. [Crossref]
190. Danqing Wang, Fei Du, Christopher Marquis. 2019. Defending Mao’s Dream: How Politicians’
Ideological Imprinting Affects Firms’ Political Appointment in China. Academy of Management
Journal 62:4, 1111-1136. [Crossref]
191. Carl Lin, Yana van der Meulen Rodgers. Parental Migration Decisions and Child Health Outcomes:
Evidence from China 281-310. [Crossref]
192. Roopinder Oberoi, Ian G. Cook, Jamie P. Halsall, Michael Snowden, Pete Woodock. 2019. Redefining
social enterprise in the global world: study of China and India. Social Responsibility Journal 16:7,
1001-1012. [Crossref]
193. Corinna Braun-Munzinger. 2019. Chinese CSR standards and industrial policy in GPNs. critical
perspectives on international business 16:2, 165-185. [Crossref]
194. Yutaka Suzuki. 2019. A contract theory analysis to fiscal relations between the central and local
governments in China. Economic and Political Studies 7:3, 281-313. [Crossref]
195. Hai (David) Guo. 2019. Fiscal underpinnings for sustainable development in China—rebalancing in
Guangdong. Journal of Chinese Governance 4:3, 292-294. [Crossref]
196. Weiying Zhang. 2019. The China model view is factually false. Journal of Chinese Economic and Business
Studies 17:3, 287-311. [Crossref]
197. Jiafu An, Wenxuan Hou, Yun Zhang. 2019. China’s rule of law in New Era: the rise of regulation
and formalism. Journal of Chinese Economic and Business Studies 17:3, 313-318. [Crossref]
198. Wen Zeng, Philip Rees, Lili Xiang. 2019. Do residents of Affordable Housing Communities in China
suffer from relative accessibility deprivation? A case study of Nanjing. Cities 90, 141-156. [Crossref]
199. Yu Zheng. 2019. Privatization with ‘Vested Interests’ in China. Socio-Economic Review 17:3, 767-791.
[Crossref]
200. Sarah E. Anderson, Mark T. Buntaine, Mengdi Liu, Bing Zhang. 2019. Non‐Governmental
Monitoring of Local Governments Increases Compliance with Central Mandates: A National‐Scale
Field Experiment in China. American Journal of Political Science 63:3, 626-643. [Crossref]
201. Yongjian Liu, Hong Geng. 2019. Regional Competition in China under the Price Distortion of
Construction Land: A Study Based on a Two‐regime Spatial Durbin Model. China & World Economy
27:4, 104-126. [Crossref]
202. Tianyang Xi. 2019. All the Emperor’s Men? Conflicts and Power-Sharing in Imperial China.
Comparative Political Studies 52:8, 1099-1130. [Crossref]
203. Tinglin Zhang, Bindong Sun, Yinyin Cai, Rui Wang. 2019. Government fragmentation and economic
growth in China’s cities. Urban Studies 56:9, 1850-1864. [Crossref]
204. Xinyu Fan, Feng Yang. 2019. Strategic promotion, reputation, and responsiveness in bureaucratic
hierarchies. Journal of Theoretical Politics 31:3, 286-307. [Crossref]
205. Mingzhi Hu, Jiaqi Liu, Xue Wang. Consumption Propensity and Entrepreneurship: Evidence from
China 265-286. [Crossref]
206. Junhong Bai, Jiayu Lu, Sijia Li. 2019. Fiscal Pressure, Tax Competition and Environmental Pollution.
Environmental and Resource Economics 73:2, 431-447. [Crossref]
207. Xin Yao, Ruting Huang, Kerui Du. 2019. The impacts of market power on power grid efficiency:
Evidence from China. China Economic Review 55, 99-110. [Crossref]
208. Zhengge Tu, Tianyang Hu, Renjun Shen. 2019. Evaluating public participation impact on
environmental protection and ecological efficiency in China: Evidence from PITI disclosure. China
Economic Review 55, 111-123. [Crossref]
209. Jiajing Sun, Michael Cole, Zhiyuan Huang, Shouyang Wang. 2019. Chinese leadership: Provincial
perspectives on promotion and performance. Environment and Planning C: Politics and Space 37:4,
750-772. [Crossref]
210. Zhonghua Huang, Xuejun Du, Carlos Salvador Zepeda Castillo. 2019. How does urbanization affect
farmland protection? Evidence from China. Resources, Conservation and Recycling 145, 139-147.
[Crossref]
211. 2019. Comments on Technical Change, Exports, and Employment Growth in China: A Structural
Decomposition Analysis. Asian Economic Papers 18:2, 47-48. [Crossref]
212. Margaret M. Pearson. Local Government and Firm Innovation in China’s Clean Energy Sector
96-133. [Crossref]
213. Keun Lee. The Art of Economic Catch-Up 4, . [Crossref]
214. Guangdong Xu, Binwei Gui. 2019. From financial repression to financial crisis? The case of China.
Asian-Pacific Economic Literature 33:1, 48-63. [Crossref]
215. Jianhuan Huang, Yue Hua. 2019. Eco-efficiency Convergence and Green Urban Growth in China.
International Regional Science Review 42:3-4, 307-334. [Crossref]
216. Jialin Du, Tao Bai, Stephen Chen. 2019. Integrating corporate social and corporate political strategies:
Performance implications and institutional contingencies in China. Journal of Business Research 98,
299-316. [Crossref]
217. Sai Ding, John Knight, Xiao Zhang. 2019. Does China overinvest? Evidence from a panel of Chinese
firms. The European Journal of Finance 25:6, 489-507. [Crossref]
218. Doulgas Cumming, Alessandra Guariglia, Wenxuan Hou, Zhenyu Wu. 2019. Chinese capital markets:
challenges to the China model. The European Journal of Finance 25:6, 460-464. [Crossref]
219. Yi Zhang. 2019. Institutions, Firm Characteristics, and FDI Spillovers. Emerging Markets Finance
and Trade 55:5, 1109-1136. [Crossref]
220. Chun Liu, Yi Zhang. 2019. Religiosity and Political Connections of Private Firms in China. Emerging
Markets Finance and Trade 9, 1-21. [Crossref]
221. Youlang Zhang, Xufeng Zhu. 2019. Multiple mechanisms of policy diffusion in China. Public
Management Review 21:4, 495-514. [Crossref]
222. Xuhong Su, Kelan Lu, Xiangming Hu, Yuqiong Xiang. 2019. Reforms on county-level fiscal
governance in China: impact on urban-rural income inequality. International Review of Public
Administration 24:2, 81-100. [Crossref]
223. Wei Que, Yabin Zhang, Günther Schulze. 2019. Is public spending behavior important for Chinese
official promotion? Evidence from city-level. China Economic Review 54, 403-417. [Crossref]
224. Kunlun Wang, Hongchun Yin, Yiwen Chen. 2019. The effect of environmental regulation on air
quality: A study of new ambient air quality standards in China. Journal of Cleaner Production 215,
268-279. [Crossref]
225. Yijun Zhang, Meirui Zhong, Jianbai Huang, Zhiping Wang, Yi Song. 2019. Drivers of intersectoral
metal consumption intensity in China: A combined input-output and sensitivity analysis. Journal of
Cleaner Production 217, 808-820. [Crossref]
226. Zhaotian Luo, Adam Przeworski. 2019. Why Are the Fastest Growing Countries Autocracies?. The
Journal of Politics 81:2, 663-669. [Crossref]
227. Quintin H. Beazer, Ora John Reuter. 2019. Who Is to Blame? Political Centralization and Electoral
Punishment under Authoritarianism. The Journal of Politics 81:2, 648-662. [Crossref]
228. Guy Grossman. Leadership Selection Rules and Decentralized Governance 40-60. [Crossref]
229. Edmund Malesky. Decentralization and Business Performance 144-177. [Crossref]
230. Colin D. Reddy. 2019. Cross-country start-up rates and formal incentives: a moderated mediation
model of economic development and societal legitimacy. Problems and Perspectives in Management
17:1, 297-312. [Crossref]
231. Qi Zhang, Mingxing Liu. Revolutionary Legacy, Power Structure, and Grassroots Capitalism under
the Red Flag in China 2, . [Crossref]
232. Xiao Han. 2019. Cross-field effect and institutional habitus formation: self-reinforcing inequality in
Chinese higher education system. Journal of Education Policy 34:2, 267-294. [Crossref]
233. Xiwei Zhu, Ye Liu, Ming He, Deming Luo, Yiyun Wu. 2019. Entrepreneurship and industrial
clusters: evidence from China industrial census. Small Business Economics 52:3, 595-616. [Crossref]
234. Yunsen Chen, Jianqiao Huang, Hang Liu, Weimin Wang. 2019. Regional favoritism and tax avoidance:
evidence from China. Accounting & Finance 58:5, 1413-1443. [Crossref]
235. Chenggang Xu. 2019. The pitfalls of a centralized bureaucracy. Acta Oeconomica 69:1, 1-16. [Crossref]
236. Gangqiang Yang, Hong Chen, Xia Meng. 2019. Regional Competition, Labor Force Mobility, and
the Fiscal Behaviour of Local Governments in China. Sustainability 11:6, 1776. [Crossref]
237. Martin T. Fromm. Borderland Memories 56, . [Crossref]
238. Chen Chen, Richard LeGates, Chenhao Fang. 2019. From coordinated to integrated urban and rural
development in China’s megacity regions. Journal of Urban Affairs 41:2, 150-169. [Crossref]
239. Kangkang Tong, Zhirong (Jerry) Zhao, Richard Feiock, Anu Ramaswami. 2019. Patterns of urban
infrastructure capital investment in Chinese cities and explanation through a political market lens.
Journal of Urban Affairs 41:2, 248-263. [Crossref]
240. Lin Shi, Guicheng Shi, Huanguang Qiu. 2019. General review of intelligent agriculture development
in China. China Agricultural Economic Review 11:1, 39-51. [Crossref]
241. Jean-Louis Combes, Mary-Françoise Renard, Sampawende J.-A. Tapsoba. 2019. Provincial public
expenditure in China: a tale of pro-cyclicality. Economic Change and Restructuring 52:1, 19-41.
[Crossref]
242. Yiyun Wu, Xiwei Zhu, Nicolaas Groenewold. 2019. The determinants and effectiveness of industrial
policy in china: A study based on Five-Year Plans. China Economic Review 53, 225-242. [Crossref]
243. Li Wang, Lukas Menkhoff, Michael Schröder, Xian Xu. 2019. Politicians’ promotion incentives and
bank risk exposure in China. Journal of Banking & Finance 99, 63-94. [Crossref]
244. Leng Ling, Danglun Luo, Guoman SHE. 2019. Judging a book by its Cover: The influence of physical
attractiveness on the promotion of regional leaders. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 158,
1-14. [Crossref]
245. Jiahua Che, Kim-Sau Chung, Xue Qiao. 2019. The king can do no wrong: On the criminal immunity
of leaders. Journal of Public Economics 170, 15-26. [Crossref]
246. Ting Chen, James Kai-sing Kung. 2019. Busting the “Princelings”: The Campaign Against
Corruption in China’s Primary Land Market*. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 134:1, 185-226.
[Crossref]
247. Ka Ho Mok, Jiwei Qian. 2019. A new welfare regime in the making? Paternalistic welfare pragmatism
in China. Journal of European Social Policy 29:1, 100-114. [Crossref]
248. Nan Jia, Kenneth G. Huang, Cyndi Man Zhang. 2019. Public Governance, Corporate Governance,
and Firm Innovation: An Examination of State-Owned Enterprises. Academy of Management Journal
62:1, 220-247. [Crossref]
249. . References 209-229. [Crossref]
250. Xiaobing Wang. 2019. Regulation and corruption in transitional China. Journal of Chinese Economic
and Business Studies 17:1, 47-64. [Crossref]
251. Shenghao Gao, Liming Wang, Ningyue Liu, Min Zhang. 2019. Fiscal decentralization and corporate
investment: empirical evidence from China. Journal of Economic Policy Reform 22:1, 51-68. [Crossref]
252. Xufeng Zhu, Youlang Zhang. 2019. Diffusion of Marketization Innovation with Administrative
Centralization in a Multilevel System: Evidence from China. Journal of Public Administration Research
and Theory 29:1, 133-150. [Crossref]
253. Hans H. Tung. Introduction 1-18. [Crossref]
254. Hans H. Tung. Authoritarian Institutions, China Style 59-80. [Crossref]
255. Eric Girardin, Zhenya Liu. The Political Economy of an Incomplete Market 93-119. [Crossref]
256. Hui Wang, Shenghua Lu. From Local Government-Led to Collaborative Governance: The Changing
Role of Local Governments in Urbanization 589-615. [Crossref]
257. Xufeng Zhu. Central-Local Relations in China 139-156. [Crossref]
258. Canfei He, Shengjun Zhu. Introduction 1-24. [Crossref]
259. Canfei He, Shengjun Zhu. How Does Geese Fly Domestically? Firm Demography and Spatial
Restructuring in China’s Apparel Industry 215-230. [Crossref]
260. Canfei He, Shengjun Zhu. What Drives the Evolution of Export Product Space in China? 281-302.
[Crossref]
261. Canfei He, Shengjun Zhu. How Does Regional Industrial Structure Evolve in China? 47-76.
[Crossref]
262. Canfei He, Shengjun Zhu. What Sustains Large Firms in China? 169-194. [Crossref]
263. Izaskun Zuazu. 2019. The growth effect of democracy and technology: An industry disaggregated
approach. European Journal of Political Economy 56, 115-131. [Crossref]
264. Yanfen Huang, Chao Zhang, Wei Liu. 2019. Who drives the formation and adoption of the "increasing
versus decreasing balance policy"?—Evidence from a policy process analysis. Land Use Policy 80,
175-184. [Crossref]
265. Huifen Cai, Agyenim Boateng, Yilmaz Guney. 2019. Host country institutions and firm-level R&D
influences: An analysis of European Union FDI in China. Research in International Business and
Finance 47, 311-326. [Crossref]
266. Jinhua Cheng. Decentralization for Economic Growth: A Critical Review 17-44. [Crossref]
267. Jinhua Cheng. Central-Local Relations and the Rise of the Corporate Economy in Contemporary
China 113-175. [Crossref]
268. Ming Lu, Lijun Xia, Jinchuan Xiao. 2019. Pro‐social leadership under authoritarianism. Economics of
Transition and Institutional Change 27:1, 5-30. [Crossref]
269. Huiping Li, Qingfang Wang, Zhongwei Deng, Wei Shi, Hongwei Wang. 2019. Local Public
Expenditure, Public Service Accessibility, and Housing Price in Shanghai, China. Urban Affairs Review
55:1, 148-184. [Crossref]
270. Gerard Roland. 2019. Coexisting with China in the 21 st century. Acta Oeconomica 69:s1, 49-70.
[Crossref]
271. Chunyang Wang, Qinghua Zhang. 2019. Land Cronyism and Corporate Political Cycles in China.
SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
272. Cha Li, Felipe A. Csaszar. 2019. Government As Landscape Designer: A Behavioral View of Industrial
Policy. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
273. Francesco D'Acunto, Michael Weber, Jin Xie. 2019. Punish One, Teach A Hundred: The Sobering
Effect of Punishment on the Unpunished. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
274. Yanfen Huang, Chao Zhang, Helen X. H. Bao, Huayi Yu. 2019. Public Services, Real Estate Taxes
&Amp; Fees, and Housing Prices in China: A Study Based on Chinese-Style Decentralization. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
275. Juncong Guo, Xi Qu. 2019. Fixed Effects Spatial Panel Data Model with Time-Varying Spatial
Dependence: An Application to Regional Expenditure Competition in China. SSRN Electronic Journal
. [Crossref]
276. Chang-Tai Hsieh, Chong-En Bai, Zheng (Michael) Song. 2019. Special Deals with Chinese
Characteristics. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
277. Meina Cai, Ilia Murtazashvili, Jennifer Murtazashvili. 2019. The Politics of Land Property Rights.
SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
278. Yubing Fan, Zeng Tang, Seong Park. 2019. Effects of Community Perceptions and Institutional
Capacity on Smallholder Farmers’ Responses to Water Scarcity: Evidence from Arid Northwestern
China. Sustainability 11:2, 483. [Crossref]
279. Canfei He, Shengjun Zhu. How Do Environmental Regulations Affect Industrial Dynamics in China?
231-249. [Crossref]
280. Canfei He, Shengjun Zhu. What Matters for Regional Industrial Dynamics in China? 77-95.
[Crossref]
281. John Joshua. Economic Policies, Paradigm Shifts and Their Implications 13-46. [Crossref]
282. William Weightman. 2019. Building an Innovative Economy: Institutionalizing Intellectual Property
Reform in China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
283. Jiaoliang Jiang, Xi Sun, Changyun Wang, Jianyu Zeng. 2019. Hold-up Problem with the Government:
Evidence from China (Presentation Slides). SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
284. Zhengyi Zhou. 2019. Public Sector Overmanning and Local Firm Value: Evidence from China. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
285. Xia Chen, Qiang Cheng, Ying Hao, Qiang Liu. 2019. GDP Growth Incentives and Earnings
Management: Evidence from China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
286. Xu Zhang, Kunlun Chen. 2018. Which scale matters? Rethinking cultural industry development
policies from a city network perspective. Journal of Urban Affairs 1-17. [Crossref]
287. Lihua Wang, Xiaoya Liang. 2018. The effect of historical government affiliations on resource
acquisition and organizing capability: evidence from Chinese private firms. Journal of Asia Business
Studies 12:4, 341-360. [Crossref]
288. Shengjun Zhu, Zhenfa Li, Canfei He. 2018. Who leads regional industrial dynamics? “New industry
creators” in Chinese regions. Growth and Change 83. . [Crossref]
289. Xiaoying Li, Yin-Fang Zhang, Laixiang Sun. 2018. Industry Agglomeration, Sub-National
Institutions and the Profitability of Foreign Subsidiaries. Management International Review 58:6,
969-993. [Crossref]
290. Mingxing Liu, Victor Shih, Dong Zhang. 2018. The Fall of the Old Guards: Explaining
Decentralization in China. Studies in Comparative International Development 53:4, 379-403. [Crossref]
291. Berthold M. Kuhn. 2018. China’s Commitment to the Sustainable Development Goals: An Analysis of
Push and Pull Factors and Implementation Challenges. Chinese Political Science Review 3:4, 359-388.
[Crossref]
292. Haiyan Jiang, Yuanyuan Hu, Honghui Zhang, Donghua Zhou. 2018. Benefits of Downward Earnings
Management and Political Connection: Evidence from Government Subsidy and Market Pricing. The
International Journal of Accounting 53:4, 255-273. [Crossref]
293. Weiqi Dai, Steven Si. 2018. Government policies and firms' entrepreneurial orientation: Strategic
choice and institutional perspectives. Journal of Business Research 93, 23-36. [Crossref]
294. Tianyang Xi, Yang Yao, Muyang Zhang. 2018. Capability and opportunism: Evidence from city
officials in China. Journal of Comparative Economics 46:4, 1046-1061. [Crossref]
295. Zhenhuan Lei, Jeffrey B. Nugent. 2018. Coordinating China's economic growth strategy via
its government-controlled association for private firms. Journal of Comparative Economics 46:4,
1273-1293. [Crossref]
296. Dong Phong Nguyen, Xuan Vinh Vo, Thi Tuan Anh Tran, Thi Kim Thoa Tu. 2018. Government
cost and firm value: Evidence from Vietnam. Research in International Business and Finance 46, 55-64.
[Crossref]
297. Nandiyang Zhang, David H. Rosenbloom. 2018. Multi-Level Policy Implementation: A Case
Study on China's Administrative Approval Intermediaries’ Reforms. Australian Journal of Public
Administration 77:4, 779-796. [Crossref]
298. Dan Li, Zhongliang Zhou, Yafei Si, Yongjian Xu, Chi Shen, Yiyang Wang, Xiao Wang. 2018.
Unequal distribution of health human resource in mainland China: what are the determinants from
a comprehensive perspective?. International Journal for Equity in Health 17:1. . [Crossref]
299. Haiwen Zhou. 2018. Will China Avoid the Middle-Income Trap?. The Chinese Economy 51:6,
483-502. [Crossref]
300. Chen Chen, Richard LeGates, Min Zhao, Chenhao Fang. 2018. The changing rural-urban divide in
China's megacities. Cities 81, 81-90. [Crossref]
301. Yaoqin Li, Xixiong Xu, Weiyu Gan. 2018. Political extraction and corporate cash holdings in China.
Asian-Pacific Economic Literature 32:2, 76-94. [Crossref]
302. Zheng (Michael) Song, Wei Xiong. 2018. Risks in China's Financial System. Annual Review of
Financial Economics 10:1, 261-286. [Crossref]
303. Christopher A. Hartwell. 2018. Bringing the benefits of David to Goliath: special economic zones and
institutional improvement. Regional Studies 52:10, 1309-1321. [Crossref]
304. GIAMPAOLO GARZARELLI, LYNDAL KEETON. 2018. Laboratory federalism and
intergovernmental grants. Journal of Institutional Economics 14:5, 949-974. [Crossref]
305. Gerald Yong Gao, Danny Tan Wang, Yi Che. 2018. Impact of historical conflict on FDI location and
performance: Japanese investment in China. Journal of International Business Studies 49:8, 1060-1080.
[Crossref]
306. Jie Gan, Yan Guo, Chenggang Xu. 2018. Decentralized Privatization and Change of Control Rights
in China. The Review of Financial Studies 31:10, 3854-3894. [Crossref]
307. Yijun Xing, Yipeng Liu, Sir Cary L. Cooper. 2018. Local Government as Institutional Entrepreneur:
Public-Private Collaborative Partnerships in Fostering Regional Entrepreneurship. British Journal of
Management 29:4, 670-690. [Crossref]
308. Junyan Jiang. 2018. Making Bureaucracy Work: Patronage Networks, Performance Incentives, and
Economic Development in China. American Journal of Political Science 62:4, 982-999. [Crossref]
309. Gerard Roland. 2018. The evolution of post-communist systems. Economics of Transition 26:4,
589-614. [Crossref]
310. Xufeng Zhu, Hui Zhao. 2018. Recognition of innovation and diffusion of welfare policy: Alleviating
urban poverty in Chinese cities during fiscal recentralization. Governance 31:4, 721-739. [Crossref]
311. Ricard Gil, Giorgio Zanarone. 2018. On the determinants and consequences of informal contracting.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy 27:4, 726-741. [Crossref]
312. Zhenghan Cao. 2018. Centralization and decentralization of power structure: A theory of ruling risks
and empirical evidence from Chinese history. Chinese Journal of Sociology 4:4, 506-564. [Crossref]
313. Christopher Marquis, Yanhua Bird. 2018. The Paradox of Responsive Authoritarianism: How Civic
Activism Spurs Environmental Penalties in China. Organization Science 29:5, 948-968. [Crossref]
314. Wilson Wong, Hanyu Xiao. 2018. Twenty years of Hong Kong and Macao under Chinese rule: being
absorbed under ‘one country, two systems’. Public Money & Management 38:6, 411-418. [Crossref]
315. Guang Zhang. 2018. The revolutions in China’s inter-governmental fiscal system. Public Money &
Management 38:6, 419-426. [Crossref]
316. Hongtao Yi, Frances Stokes Berry, Wenna Chen. 2018. Management Innovation and Policy Diffusion
through Leadership Transfer Networks: An Agent Network Diffusion Model. Journal of Public
Administration Research and Theory 28:4, 457-474. [Crossref]
317. Kyoung Shin. 2018. Environmental policy innovations in China: a critical analysis from a low-carbon
city. Environmental Politics 27:5, 830-851. [Crossref]
318. Sarah Eaton, Genia Kostka. 2018. What makes for good and bad neighbours? An emerging research
agenda in the study of Chinese environmental politics. Environmental Politics 27:5, 782-803. [Crossref]
319. Dawei Liu, Hang Xu. 2018. The politics of curtailment: multi-level governance and solar photovoltaic
power generation in China. Environmental Politics 27:5, 852-871. [Crossref]
320. Yang Yao. 2018. An Anatomy of the Chinese selectocracy. China Economic Journal 11:3, 228-242.
[Crossref]
321. Bei Qin, David Strömberg, Yanhui Wu. 2018. Media Bias in China. American Economic Review 108:9,
2442-2476. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
322. Gen-Fu Feng, Minyi Dong, Jun Wen, Chun-Ping Chang. 2018. The impacts of environmental
governance on political turnover of municipal party secretary in China. Environmental Science and
Pollution Research 25:25, 24668-24681. [Crossref]
323. Audrye Wong. 2018. More than Peripheral: How Provinces Influence China's Foreign Policy. The
China Quarterly 235, 735-757. [Crossref]
324. Zhonglu Li, Xiaogang Wu. 2018. Social Policy and Political Trust: Evidence from the New Rural
Pension Scheme in China. The China Quarterly 235, 644-668. [Crossref]
325. Hao Shi, Bing Ye. 2018. China's Abolition of the Agricultural Tax, Local Governments’ Responses
and Economic Growth. Fiscal Studies 39:3, 517-542. [Crossref]
326. Pi-han Tsai, Jianliang Ye. 2018. The Lame-Duck Effect and Fiscal Policy in China. The Developing
Economies 56:3, 197-220. [Crossref]
327. Yi Che, Lei Zhang. 2018. Human Capital, Technology Adoption and Firm Performance: Impacts of
China's Higher Education Expansion in the Late 1990s. The Economic Journal 128:614, 2282-2320.
[Crossref]
328. Canfei He, Shengjun Zhu. 2018. Evolution of Export Product Space in China: Technological
Relatedness, National/Local Governance and Regional Industrial Diversification. Tijdschrift voor
economische en sociale geografie 109:4, 575-593. [Crossref]
329. Xufeng Zhu. 2018. Executive Entrepreneurship, Career Mobility and the Transfer of Policy Paradigms.
Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis: Research and Practice 20:4, 354-369. [Crossref]
330. Zhonghua Huang, Xuejun Du. 2018. Holding the market under the stimulus plan: Local government
financing vehicles' land purchasing behavior in China. China Economic Review 50, 85-100. [Crossref]
331. Jiawei Mo. 2018. Land financing and economic growth: Evidence from Chinese counties. China
Economic Review 50, 218-239. [Crossref]
332. Dongmin Kong, Shasha Liu, Junyi Xiang. 2018. Political promotion and labor investment efficiency.
China Economic Review 50, 273-293. [Crossref]
333. Jichuan Sheng, Michael Webber. 2018. Using incentives to coordinate responses to a system of
payments for watershed services: The middle route of South–North Water Transfer Project, China.
Ecosystem Services 32, 1-8. [Crossref]
334. Jackie Zheng Yan, Sea‐Jin Chang. 2018. The contingent effects of political strategies on firm
performance: A political network perspective. Strategic Management Journal 39:8, 2152-2177.
[Crossref]
335. Jichuan Sheng, Michael Webber, Xiao Han. 2018. Governmentality within China's South-North
Water Transfer Project: tournaments, markets and water pollution. Journal of Environmental Policy
& Planning 20:4, 533-549. [Crossref]
336. Yaobo Shi, Chun-Ping Chang, Chyi-Lu Jang, Yu Hao. 2018. Does economic performance affect
officials’ turnover? Evidence from municipal government leaders in China. Quality & Quantity 52:4,
1873-1891. [Crossref]
337. Yuge Ma, Ke Rong, Diana Mangalagiu, Thomas F. Thornton, Dajian Zhu. 2018. Co-evolution
between urban sustainability and business ecosystem innovation: Evidence from the sharing mobility
sector in Shanghai. Journal of Cleaner Production 188, 942-953. [Crossref]
338. Yvonne Jie Chen, Pei Li, Yi Lu. 2018. Career concerns and multitasking local bureaucrats: Evidence
of a target-based performance evaluation system in China. Journal of Development Economics 133,
84-101. [Crossref]
339. Falin Zhang. 2018. The Chinese developmental state: standard accounts and new characteristics.
Journal of International Relations and Development 21:3, 739-768. [Crossref]
340. Baoqing Pang, Shu Keng, Lingna Zhong. 2018. Sprinting with Small Steps: China’s Cadre
Management and Authoritarian Resilience. The China Journal 80, 68-93. [Crossref]
341. Tao Qian, Qi Zhang. 2018. Intra-provincial Revenue Sharing and the Subnational Government's Fiscal
Capacity in China: The Case of Zhejiang Province. China & World Economy 26:4, 24-40. [Crossref]
342. Kaibin Zhong, Xiaoli Lu. 2018. Exploring the administrative mechanism of China's Paired Assistance
to Disaster Affected Areas programme. Disasters 42:3, 590-612. [Crossref]
343. Pierre F. Landry, Xiaobo Lü, Haiyan Duan. 2018. Does Performance Matter? Evaluating Political
Selection Along the Chinese Administrative Ladder. Comparative Political Studies 51:8, 1074-1105.
[Crossref]
344. Meir Alkon. 2018. Do special economic zones induce developmental spillovers? Evidence from India’s
states. World Development 107, 396-409. [Crossref]
345. Xuhong Su, Xing Ni. 2018. Citizens on Patrol: Understanding Public Whistleblowing against
Government Corruption. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 28:3, 406-422.
[Crossref]
346. Di Guo, Yan Guo, Kun Jiang. 2018. Governance and effects of public R&D subsidies: Evidence from
China. Technovation 74-75, 18-31. [Crossref]
347. Ying Hao, Jing Lu. 2018. The Impact of Government Intervention on Corporate Investment
Allocations and Efficiency: Evidence from China. Financial Management 47:2, 383-419. [Crossref]
348. Canfei He, Yan Yan, David Rigby. 2018. Regional industrial evolution in China. Papers in Regional
Science 97:2, 173-198. [Crossref]
349. Tengda Lu, Xieer Dai, Jun Chen, Ming Dai. 2018. Pricing Industrial Discharge Quota (IDQ): A
Model Reflecting Opportunity Cost of Performing Ecological Responsibility. Sustainability 10:6,
2032. [Crossref]
350. Kean Fan Lim. 2018. Researching state rescaling in China: methodological reflections. Area
Development and Policy 3:2, 170-184. [Crossref]
351. Shijun Jia, Yourong Wang, Gang-Zhi Fan. 2018. Home-Purchase Limits and Housing Prices:
Evidence from China. The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 56:3, 386-409. [Crossref]
352. Ben Ma, Xinye Zheng. 2018. Biased data revisions: Unintended consequences of China's energy-
saving mandates. China Economic Review 48, 102-113. [Crossref]
353. Changjie Zhan, Martin de Jong. 2018. Financing eco cities and low carbon cities: The case of Shenzhen
International Low Carbon City. Journal of Cleaner Production 180, 116-125. [Crossref]
354. Xufeng Zhu, Hui Zhao. 2018. Experimentalist Governance with Interactive Central-Local Relations:
Making New Pension Policies in China. Policy Studies Journal 23. . [Crossref]
355. Wen Fan, Fangsheng Zhu, Phyllis Moen. 2018. Micro-level experiences of macro-level change: A
cohort perspective on China’s shift away from state-sector employment. Advances in Life Course
Research 35, 77-86. [Crossref]
356. Xiangyu Shi, Tianyang Xi. 2018. Race to safety: Political competition, neighborhood effects, and coal
mine deaths in China. Journal of Development Economics 131, 79-95. [Crossref]
357. Wubiao Zhou. 2018. Property Rights, Deregulation, and Entrepreneurial Development in a Transition
Economy. Management and Organization Review 14:1, 73-103. [Crossref]
358. András Székely-Doby. 2018. Why Have Chinese Reforms Come to a Halt? The Political Economic
Logic of Unfinished Transformation. Europe-Asia Studies 70:2, 277-296. [Crossref]
359. Daniel Z. Li, Qi Zhang. 2018. Policy choice and economic growth under factional politics: Evidence
from a Chinese Province. China Economic Review 47, 12-26. [Crossref]
360. Yulia Muratova, Jakob Arnoldi, Xin Chen, Joachim Scholderer. 2018. Political rotations and cross-
province firm acquisitions in China. Asian Business & Management 17:1, 37-58. [Crossref]
361. Ning Liu, Shui-Yan Tang, Xueyong Zhan, Carlos Wing-Hung Lo. 2018. Political Commitment,
Policy Ambiguity, and Corporate Environmental Practices. Policy Studies Journal 46:1, 190-214.
[Crossref]
362. , , . 2018. Investment Promotion, Fiscal Competition and Economic Growth Sustainability.
Sustainability 10:2, 45. [Crossref]
363. Zhu Xufeng, Zhao Hui. 2018. Social Policy Diffusion from the Perspective of Intergovernmental
Relations: An Empirical Study of the Urban Subsistence Allowance System in China (1993-1999).
Social Sciences in China 39:1, 78-97. [Crossref]
364. Zhenghan Cao, Xiaoming Zhang. 2018. Structure hypothesis of authoritarian rule: evidence from the
lifespans of China’s dynasties. Journal of Chinese Governance 3:1, 1-24. [Crossref]
365. Katsuji Nakagane, Kohei Mitsunami. 2018. Nexus between privatization and marketization during
transition process: an experimental analysis based on China’s provincial panel data. Journal of
Contemporary East Asia Studies 7:1, 50-75. [Crossref]
366. Wei Li. Recent Developments in Public Sector Reforms, China and Hong Kong 5340-5347. [Crossref]
367. Dongliang Cai, Zhen Yang, Wu Jiang, Qiuhua Xu. The Empirical Evidence of the Effect on the
Enterprises R&D from Government Subsidies, Political Connections and Rent-Seeking 499-510.
[Crossref]
368. Xiaoke Zhang, Tianbiao Zhu. Understanding Business–Government Relations in China: Changes,
Causes and Consequences 3-45. [Crossref]
369. Haakon Vennemo, Kristin Aunan. Air Pollution and Greenhouse Gas Emissions in China: An
Unsustainable Situation in Search of a Solution 139-157. [Crossref]
370. Hüseyin Oğuz Genç, K. Ali Akkemik. Developmental State, Industrial Policy, and Green Growth in
China 285-310. [Crossref]
371. Albert G. Hu, Peng Zhang, Lijing Zhao. Patents and Innovation in China 161-180. [Crossref]
372. Yonghua Zou, Wanxia Zhao. 2018. Making a new area in Xiong’an: Incentives and challenges of
China’s “Millennium Plan”. Geoforum 88, 45-48. [Crossref]
373. Guiying Laura Wu. 2018. Capital misallocation in China: Financial frictions or policy distortions?.
Journal of Development Economics 130, 203-223. [Crossref]
374. Marshall W. Meyer. China: Strategy in a Growth-Driven Economy 234-240. [Crossref]
375. Jiaxing You, Bohui Zhang, Le Zhang. 2018. Who Captures the Power of the Pen?. The Review of
Financial Studies 31:1, 43-96. [Crossref]
376. James Kai-sing Kung, Chicheng Ma. 2018. Friends with Benefits: How Political Connections Help to
Sustain Private Enterprise Growth in China. Economica 85:337, 41-74. [Crossref]
377. Bin Ke, Zengquan Li, Qing Ye. 2018. Institutional Environment Quality and the Longevity of Large
Schumpeterian Entrepreneurs. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
378. Zhenhuan Lei, Jeffrey B. Nugent. 2018. Coordinating China's Economic Growth Strategy via Its
Government-Controlled Association for Private Firms. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
379. Meir Alkon. 2018. Do Special Economic Zones Induce Developmental Spillovers? Evidence from
India's States. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
380. Hao Ren, Shaojie Zhou, Angang Hu. 2018. After the President Left My Town: Chinese State Leaderss
Domestic Visits Impact on Local Government Performance. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
381. Federico Balbiano di Colcavagno. 2018. Tax Diversity and Economic Growth. SSRN Electronic Journal
. [Crossref]
382. Qing Hu, Wenjing Li, Chen Lin, Lai Wei. 2018. What Causes Privatization? Evidence from Import
Competition. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
383. Xiandeng Jiang, Dongmin Kong, Chengrui Xiao. 2018. Policy Certainty and Heterogeneous Firm
Innovation: Evidence from a Developing Country. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
384. Jinbo Luo, Xiaoran Ni. 2018. When Short Seller Meets Government Stakeholder: The Case of
Corporate Tax Avoidance. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
385. Xu Zhang, Yajuan Li. 2018. Concentration or deconcentration? Exploring the changing geographies
of film production and consumption in China. Geoforum 88, 118-128. [Crossref]
386. Yunsen Chen, Jianqiao Huang, Sheng Xiao, Ziye Zhao. 2018. Corporate Subsidiary Locations,
Politics, and Firm Value. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
387. Dongxing Ji, Xiaoran Ni. 2018. How Can Local Policy Uncertainty Encourage Firm Innovation: A
Competitive Advantage Channel. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
388. Brice Fabre. 2018. Les facteurs politiques des finances publiques locales : un état des lieux. Vie &
sciences de l'entreprise N°206:2, 20. [Crossref]
389. Chunfang Cao, C.S. Agnes Cheng, Changyuan Xia, Cheng Zeng. 2018. Corporate Tax Benefits from
Politicians’ Hometown. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
390. Hanming Fang, Zhe Li, Nianhang Xu, Hongjun Yan. 2018. In the Shadows of the Government:
Relationship Building during Political Turnovers. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
391. Kyoung Shin. 2017. Mission-Driven Agency and Local Policy Innovation: Empirical Analysis from
Baoding, China. Journal of Chinese Political Science 22:4, 549-580. [Crossref]
392. Junxue Jia, Guangrong Ma. 2017. Do R&D tax incentives work? Firm-level evidence from China.
China Economic Review 46, 50-66. [Crossref]
393. Liang Zheng, Zhong Zhao. 2017. What drives spatial clusters of entrepreneurship in China? Evidence
from economic census data. China Economic Review 46, 229-248. [Crossref]
394. Yinxi Xie, Yang Xie. 2017. Machiavellian experimentation. Journal of Comparative Economics 45:4,
685-711. [Crossref]
395. Fox Z.Y. Hu, Jiwei Qian. 2017. Land-based finance, fiscal autonomy and land supply for affordable
housing in urban China: A prefecture-level analysis. Land Use Policy 69, 454-460. [Crossref]
396. Le Zhang. 2017. CEOs' early-life experiences and corporate policy: Evidence from China's great
famine. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 46, 57-77. [Crossref]
397. Xianbi Huang. 2017. Market Penetration, Institutional Niches and Job Searches in Reforming China.
The China Quarterly 232, 1070-1093. [Crossref]
398. Puyuan Shi, Mengwei Ni. 2017. The allocation mechanism of authority and accountability in Chinese
government hierarchies: A case study of the “Earmarked Project System”. The Journal of Chinese
Sociology 4:1. . [Crossref]
399. Zhenghan Cao, Guoqiang Feng. 2017. The level of decentralization and property rights protection––
a sociological analysis of property rights. The Journal of Chinese Sociology 4:1. . [Crossref]
400. Yani Lai, Jiayuan Wang, Waiming Lok. 2017. Redefining property rights over collective land in the
urban redevelopment of Shenzhen, China. Land Use Policy 69, 485-493. [Crossref]
401. Xiao Li, Yuanbo Qiao, Junming Zhu, Lei Shi, Yutao Wang. 2017. The “APEC blue” endeavor:
Causal effects of air pollution regulation on air quality in China. Journal of Cleaner Production 168,
1381-1388. [Crossref]
402. Yang Po, Liu Yunbo. 2017. Balanced Development for Provincial-Level Coordination and Higher
Vocational Education. Chinese Education & Society 50:5-6, 469-498. [Crossref]
403. Wendy Y. Chen, Fox Zhi Yong Hu, Xun Li, Junyi Hua. 2017. Strategic interaction in municipal
governments' provision of public green spaces: A dynamic spatial panel data analysis in transitional
China. Cities 71, 1-10. [Crossref]
404. Changjie Zhan, Martin de Jong, Hans de Bruijn. 2017. Path Dependence in Financing Urban
Infrastructure Development in China: 1949–2016. Journal of Urban Technology 24:4, 73-93. [Crossref]
405. Stefan Brehm, Jesper Svensson. 2017. A fragmented environmental state? Analysing spatial compliance
patterns for the case of transparency legislation in China. Asia-Pacific Journal of Regional Science 1:2,
471-493. [Crossref]
406. Ping Lei, Xinyu Tian, Qi Huang, Dayi He. 2017. Firm size, government capacity, and regional
environmental regulation: Theoretical analysis and empirical evidence from China. Journal of Cleaner
Production 164, 524-533. [Crossref]
407. Fabrizio Zilibotti. 2017. Growing and Slowing Down Like China. Journal of the European Economic
Association 15:5, 943-988. [Crossref]
408. Xufeng Zhu. 2017. Inter-regional diffusion of policy innovation in China: A comparative case study.
Asian Journal of Political Science 25:3, 266-286. [Crossref]
409. Sheng Liu, Feng Tao, Huiqin Zhang. 2017. Term Limits of Public Officials, Environmental
Regulations, and Sustainable Development: An Analysis Based on Empirical Spatial Econometrics.
Emerging Markets Finance and Trade 53:9, 2141-2155. [Crossref]
410. Wan-wen Chu. 2017. Industry policy with Chinese characteristics:a multi-layered model. China
Economic Journal 10:3, 305-318. [Crossref]
411. Gani Aldashev, Giorgio Zanarone. 2017. Endogenous enforcement institutions. Journal of Development
Economics 128, 49-64. [Crossref]
412. Genia Kostka, Jonas Nahm. 2017. Central–Local Relations: Recentralization and Environmental
Governance in China. The China Quarterly 231, 567-582. [Crossref]
413. Di Guo, Kun Jiang, Chenggang Xu. 2017. Institutions and Managerial Task Allocation: Evidence
from Chinese Entrepreneurs. Journal of Human Capital 11:3, 397-422. [Crossref]
414. Peng Bin, Andrea Fracasso. 2017. Regional Consumption Inequality in China: An Oaxaca-Blinder
Decomposition at the Prefectural Level. Growth and Change 48:3, 459-486. [Crossref]
415. Na Ni, Xueyong Zhan. 2017. Embedded Government Control and Nonprofit Revenue Growth. Public
Administration Review 77:5, 730-742. [Crossref]
416. Taiyang Zhong, Bruce Mitchell, Steffanie Scott, Xianjin Huang, Yi Li, Xiao Lu. 2017. Growing
centralization in China’s farmland protection policy in response to policy failure and related upward-
extending unwillingness to protect farmland since 1978. Environment and Planning C: Politics and
Space 35:6, 1075-1097. [Crossref]
417. Douglas A. Schuler, Wei Shi, Robert E. Hoskisson, Tao Chen. 2017. Windfalls of emperors'
sojourns: Stock market reactions to Chinese firms hosting high-ranking government officials. Strategic
Management Journal 38:8, 1668-1687. [Crossref]
418. Yuhuilin Chen, Xiuping Hua, Agyenim Boateng. 2017. Effects of foreign acquisitions on financial
constraints, productivity and investment in R&D of target firms in China. International Business
Review 26:4, 640-651. [Crossref]
419. Bo Miao, Yu-wai Vic Li. 2017. Local Climate Governance under the Shadow of Hierarchy: Evidence
from China’s Yangtze River Delta. Urban Policy and Research 35:3, 298-311. [Crossref]
420. Kean Fan Lim, Niv Horesh. 2017. The Chongqing vs. Guangdong developmental ‘models’ in post-
Mao China: regional and historical perspectives on the dynamics of socioeconomic change. Journal
of the Asia Pacific Economy 22:3, 372-395. [Crossref]
421. Tao Li. 2017. Financial Decentralization and Geographical Stratification of Access to Higher
Education in China: The Case of Shanghai. Chinese Sociological Review 49:3, 212-238. [Crossref]
422. Yanghua Huang, Nimesh Salike, Feiteng Zhong. 2017. Policy effect on structural change: A case of
Chinese intermediate goods trade. China Economic Review 44, 30-47. [Crossref]
423. Anders C. Johansson, Danglun Luo, Johanna Rickne, Wei Zheng. 2017. Government intervention in
the capital allocation process: Excess employment as an IPO selection rule in China. China Economic
Review 44, 271-281. [Crossref]
424. Denise van der Kamp, Peter Lorentzen, Daniel Mattingly. 2017. Racing to the Bottom or to the
Top? Decentralization, Revenue Pressures, and Governance Reform in China. World Development 95,
164-176. [Crossref]
425. Guy Grossman, Jan H. Pierskalla, Emma Boswell Dean. 2017. Government Fragmentation and Public
Goods Provision. The Journal of Politics 79:3, 823-840. [Crossref]
426. Jiangnan Zhu, Dong Zhang. 2017. Does Corruption Hinder Private Businesses? Leadership Stability
and Predictable Corruption in China. Governance 30:3, 343-363. [Crossref]
427. Ying Zheng, Chuanming Chen, Hualiang Ren. 2017. Who will keep an eye on government policy?
Evidence from Chinese pharmaceutical firms. Chinese Management Studies 11:2, 346-364. [Crossref]
428. András Székely-Doby. 2017. A kínai fejlesztő állam kihívásai. Közgazdasági Szemle 64:6, 630-649.
[Crossref]
429. Wenming Xu, Jianwei Chen, Guangdong Xu. 2017. An Empirical Analysis of the Public Enforcement
of Securities Law in China: Finding the Missing Piece of the Puzzle. European Business Organization
Law Review 18:2, 367-389. [Crossref]
430. Jichuan Sheng, Michael Webber. 2017. Incentive-compatible payments for watershed services along
the Eastern Route of China’s South-North Water Transfer Project. Ecosystem Services 25, 213-226.
[Crossref]
431. Xiaohui Hu. 2017. From Coal Mining to Coal Chemicals? Unpacking New Path Creation in an Old
Industrial Region of Transitional China. Growth and Change 48:2, 233-245. [Crossref]
432. Bernard Chavance. 2017. Ownership Transformation and System Change in China. Revue de la
régulation :21. . [Crossref]
433. Longjin Chen, Jian Huang, Jianjun Li. 2017. Fiscal Decentralization, Satisfaction with Social Services,
and Inequality Under the Hukou System. Social Indicators Research 132:1, 377-394. [Crossref]
434. Junming Zhu, Marian R. Chertow. 2017. Business Strategy Under Institutional Constraints: Evidence
From China's Energy Efficiency Regulations. Ecological Economics 135, 10-21. [Crossref]
435. Fabrice Defever, Alejandro Riaño. 2017. Subsidies with export share requirements in China. Journal
of Development Economics 126, 33-51. [Crossref]
436. Peter S. Hofman, Jeremy Moon, Bin Wu. 2017. Corporate Social Responsibility Under Authoritarian
Capitalism: Dynamics and Prospects of State-Led and Society-Driven CSR. Business & Society 56:5,
651-671. [Crossref]
437. Zhonghua Huang, Xuejun Du. 2017. Strategic interaction in local governments’ industrial land supply:
Evidence from China. Urban Studies 54:6, 1328-1346. [Crossref]
438. Wen Wang. 2017. The Effects of Political and Fiscal Incentives on Local Government Behavior: An
Analysis of Fiscal Slack in China. International Public Management Journal 20:2, 294-315. [Crossref]
439. Lili Kang, Fei Peng. 2017. Wage flexibility in the Chinese labour market, 1989–2009. Regional Studies
51:4, 616-628. [Crossref]
440. Jing You, Huihua Nie. 2017. Who determines Chinese firms' engagement in corruption: Themselves
or neighbors?. China Economic Review 43, 29-46. [Crossref]
441. Yuan Wang, Eddie Chi-man Hui. 2017. Are local governments maximizing land revenue? Evidence
from China. China Economic Review 43, 196-215. [Crossref]
442. Di Guo, Yan Guo, Kun Jiang. 2017. FUNDING FORMS, MARKET CONDITIONS, AND
DYNAMIC EFFECTS OF GOVERNMENT R&D SUBSIDIES: EVIDENCE FROM CHINA.
Economic Inquiry 55:2, 825-842. [Crossref]
443. Bin Chen, Yuk-shing Cheng. 2017. The Impacts of Environmental Regulation on Industrial
Activities: Evidence from a Quasi-Natural Experiment in Chinese Prefectures. Sustainability 9:4, 571.
[Crossref]
444. Jinyu Yang, Bin Liu, Lihua Yuan. 2017. Land and resources acquisition, equity investment increase
and enterprise overinvestment. Nankai Business Review International 8:1, 57-79. [Crossref]
445. Chenggang Xu. 2017. Capitalism and Socialism: A Review of Kornai's Dynamism, Rivalry, and the
Surplus Economy. Journal of Economic Literature 55:1, 191-208. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF
with links]
446. Canfei He, Qi Guo, David Rigby. 2017. What sustains larger firms? Evidence from Chinese
manufacturing industries. The Annals of Regional Science 58:2, 275-300. [Crossref]
447. Daxuan Zhao, Tien Foo Sing. 2017. Air pollution, economic spillovers, and urban growth in China.
The Annals of Regional Science 58:2, 321-340. [Crossref]
448. Mingtian Yao, Sylvia Tramberend, Pavel Kabat, Ronald W.A. Hutjes, Saskia E. Werners. 2017.
Building Regional Water-Use Scenarios Consistent with Global Shared Socioeconomic Pathways.
Environmental Processes 4:1, 15-31. [Crossref]
449. Xiaoyi Han, Chih-Sheng Hsieh, Lung-fei Lee. 2017. Estimation and model selection of higher-order
spatial autoregressive model: An efficient Bayesian approach. Regional Science and Urban Economics
63, 97-120. [Crossref]
450. SCOTT Y. LIN. 2017. State Capitalism and Chinese Food Security Governance. Japanese Journal of
Political Science 18:1, 106-138. [Crossref]
451. Changdong Zhang. 2017. A Fiscal Sociological Theory of Authoritarian Resilience. Sociological Theory
35:1, 39-63. [Crossref]
452. Tanya Tang, Phyllis Lai Lan Mo, K. Hung Chan. 2017. Tax Collector or Tax Avoider? An
Investigation of Intergovernmental Agency Conflicts. The Accounting Review 92:2, 247-270. [Crossref]
453. Ehsan Rasoulinezhad. 2017. China’s foreign trade policy with OPEC member countries. Journal of
Chinese Economic and Foreign Trade Studies 10:1, 61-81. [Crossref]
454. Shang-Jin Wei, Zhuan Xie, Xiaobo Zhang. 2017. From “Made in China” to “Innovated in China”:
Necessity, Prospect, and Challenges. Journal of Economic Perspectives 31:1, 49-70. [Abstract] [View
PDF article] [PDF with links]
455. Jiwei Qian. 2017. Improving Policy Design and Building Capacity in Local Experiments: Equalization
of Public Service in China's Urban-rural Integration Pilot. Public Administration and Development
37:1, 51-64. [Crossref]
456. Nan Jia, Kyle J. Mayer. 2017. Political hazards and firms' geographic concentration. Strategic
Management Journal 38:2, 203-231. [Crossref]
457. Zhonghua Huang, Xuejun Du. 2017. Government intervention and land misallocation: Evidence from
China. Cities 60, 323-332. [Crossref]
458. Yi Zhou, Shengjun Zhu, Canfei He. 2017. How do environmental regulations affect industrial
dynamics? Evidence from China's pollution-intensive industries. Habitat International 60, 10-18.
[Crossref]
459. Mark Gradstein. 2017. Government decentralization as a commitment in non-democracies. Journal of
Comparative Economics 45:1, 110-118. [Crossref]
460. Robert Cull, Lixin Colin Xu, Xi Yang, Li-An Zhou, Tian Zhu. 2017. Market facilitation by local
government and firm efficiency: Evidence from China. Journal of Corporate Finance 42, 460-480.
[Crossref]
461. Xiaohui Hu, Robert Hassink. 2017. Place leadership with Chinese characteristics? A case study of the
Zaozhuang coal-mining region in transition. Regional Studies 51:2, 224-234. [Crossref]
462. Yasushi Suzuki, Mohammad Dulal Miah. 2017. China’s ”New Normal”: An Interpretation from
Institutional and Marxian Views. Journal of Comparative Asian Development 16:1, 21-46. [Crossref]
463. Kean Fan Lim. 2017. On the shifting spatial logics of socioeconomic regulation in post-1949 China.
Territory, Politics, Governance 5:1, 65-91. [Crossref]
464. Canfei He, Shengjun Zhu, Xin Yang. 2017. What matters for regional industrial dynamics in a
transitional economy?. Area Development and Policy 2:1, 71-90. [Crossref]
465. Liang-Chih Chen, Shiuh-Shen Chien. 2017. Industrial upgrading and interaction between the
advanced small south and China: the case of Taiwan’s machine tool industry. Area Development and
Policy 2:1, 91-107. [Crossref]
466. Wei Li. Recent Developments in Public Sector Reforms, China and Hong Kong 1-9. [Crossref]
467. Eric Rougier. Analysing the Capitalisms of Developing Countries: What’s the Point? 3-33. [Crossref]
468. François Combarnous, Eric Rougier. Systems, Institutional Complementarities and Politics: Various
Methodological Considerations 63-92. [Crossref]
469. Hüseyin Oğuz Genç, K. Ali Akkemik. Developmental State, Industrial Policy, and Green Growth in
China 1-26. [Crossref]
470. Yasushi Suzuki, Mohammad Dulal Miah. China’s ‘New Normal’: Explaining China’s Economic
Development from Institutional and Marxian Perspectives 21-41. [Crossref]
471. Xiao Li, Yuanbo Qiao, Lei Shi. 2017. The aggregate effect of air pollution regulation on CO 2
mitigation in China's manufacturing industry: an econometric analysis. Journal of Cleaner Production
142, 976-984. [Crossref]
472. Albert G.Z. Hu, Peng Zhang, Lijing Zhao. 2017. China as number one? Evidence from China's most
recent patenting surge. Journal of Development Economics 124, 107-119. [Crossref]
473. Jiahua Che, Kim-Sau Chung, Yang K. Lu. 2017. Decentralization and political career concerns. Journal
of Public Economics 145, 201-210. [Crossref]
474. Deepak Sardana, Ying Zhu. Background: Reforms in China and India 13-41. [Crossref]
475. Deepak Sardana, Ying Zhu. Conclusion: China and India at a Crossroad in Their Transformation
251-279. [Crossref]
476. Stefanie Weil. Policy-Making Compared: China, the EU, and the US 15-39. [Crossref]
477. Jipeng Zhang, Jianyong Fan, Jiawei Mo. 2017. GOVERNMENT INTERVENTION, LAND
MARKET, AND URBAN DEVELOPMENT: EVIDENCE FROM CHINESE CITIES. Economic
Inquiry 55:1, 115-136. [Crossref]
478. Noah Buckley, Ora John Reuter. 2017. Performance Incentives Under Autocracy: Evidence from
Russia's Regions. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
479. Wenming Xu. 2017. Understanding Public Enforcement of Securities Law in China: An Empirical
Analysis of the Enforcement Outcomes of CSRC's Regional Offices. SSRN Electronic Journal .
[Crossref]
480. Meng Miao. 2017. Insider Takes All! Value of Political Connections in a Property Rights Reform.
SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
481. Angela Huyue Zhang. 2017. The Anti-Competitive Effects of State Ownership. SSRN Electronic
Journal . [Crossref]
482. Xing Li, Chong Liu, Xi Weng, Li-An Zhou. 2017. Target Setting in Tournaments: Theory and
Evidence from China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
483. Qi Zhang. 2017. Distributive Politics under Institutionalized Authoritarianism: Evidence from China's
Subnational Land Finance. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
484. Shijun Jia, Yourong Wang, Gang-Zhi Fan. 2017. Home-Purchase Limits and Housing Prices:
Evidence from China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
485. Ronald W. Anderson. 2017. Chinese Debt Capital Markets: An Emerging Global Market...With
Chinese Characteristics. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
486. Ruixue Jia. 2017. Pollution for Promotion. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
487. Randall Morck, Bernard Yin Yeung. 2017. East Asian Financial and Economic Development. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
488. Chang Liu, Li-An Zhou. 2017. Estimating the Short- and Long-Term Effects of MAO Zedonggs
Economic Radicalism. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
489. Duoduo Xu, Xiaogang Wu. 2017. From Political Power to Personal Wealth: Privatization, Elite
Opportunity, and Social Stratification in Post-Reform China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
490. Jiang Zhu. 2017. Local Officials’ Change and Corporate Investment—Evidence from Listed
Companies in Strategic Emerging Industries. Open Journal of Business and Management 05:02,
290-297. [Crossref]
491. Yongtao Li, Jiguang Zheng. 2017. An Empirical Analysis of Fiscal Decentralization on Public Goods
Spending. Theoretical Economics Letters 07:03, 398-405. [Crossref]
492. Donghui Wu, Qing Ye. 2017. Publicity and Auditor Behavior: The Case of Hurun Rich List in China.
SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
493. Ole-Kristian Hope, Yi Li, Qiliang Liu, Han Wu. 2017. Protecting the Giant Pandas: China's
Censorship of Negative News. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
494. Meir Alkon. 2017. All Climate is Local: How Provincial Preferences Undermine China's Coal
Commitments. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
495. Nan Chen, Zemin (Zachary) Zhong. 2017. The Economic Impact of China's Anti-Corruption
Campaign. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
496. Keun Lee, Xudong Gao, Xibao Li. 2016. Industrial catch-up in China: a sectoral systems of innovation
perspective. Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society 1/2, rsw037. [Crossref]
497. John C. Moore, Ying Chen, Xuefeng Cui, Wenping Yuan, Wenjie Dong, Yun Gao, Peijun Shi. 2016.
Will China be the first to initiate climate engineering?. Earth's Future 4:12, 588-595. [Crossref]
498. Simon Alder, Lin Shao, Fabrizio Zilibotti. 2016. Economic reforms and industrial policy in a panel
of Chinese cities. Journal of Economic Growth 21:4, 305-349. [Crossref]
499. Xunan Feng, Kam C. Chan. 2016. Information advantage, short sales, and stock returns: Evidence
from short selling reform in China. Economic Modelling 59, 131-142. [Crossref]
500. Xun Cao, Andrew Kleit, Chuyu Liu. 2016. Why invest in wind energy? Career incentives and Chinese
renewable energy politics. Energy Policy 99, 120-131. [Crossref]
501. Yani Lai, Bosin Tang. 2016. Institutional barriers to redevelopment of urban villages in China: A
transaction cost perspective. Land Use Policy 58, 482-490. [Crossref]
502. Ling Chen, Barry Naughton. 2016. An institutionalized policy-making mechanism: China’s return
to techno-industrial policy. Research Policy 45:10, 2138-2152. [Crossref]
503. Ganghua Chen, Songshan (Sam) Huang, Jigang Bao. 2016. The multiple logics of tourism
development in China. Journal of Sustainable Tourism 24:12, 1655-1673. [Crossref]
504. Luigi Bonatti, Andrea Fracasso. 2016. MODELLING THE TRANSITION TOWARDS THE
RENMINBI'S FULL CONVERTIBILITY: IMPLICATIONS FOR CHINA'S GROWTH. Bulletin
of Economic Research 68:S1, 146-170. [Crossref]
505. Jie Mao, Chunhua Wang. 2016. Tax incentives and environmental protection: evidence from China’s
taxpayer-level data. China Finance and Economic Review 4:1. . [Crossref]
506. Hao Liang, Luc Renneboog, Sunny Li Sun. A State-Stewardship View on Executive Compensation
39-91. [Crossref]
507. Pei Li, Yi Lu, Jin Wang. 2016. Does flattening government improve economic performance? Evidence
from China. Journal of Development Economics 123, 18-37. [Crossref]
508. Ting Chen, J.K.-S. Kung. 2016. Do land revenue windfalls create a political resource curse? Evidence
from China. Journal of Development Economics 123, 86-106. [Crossref]
509. Philipp Boeing. 2016. The allocation and effectiveness of China’s R&D subsidies - Evidence from
listed firms. Research Policy 45:9, 1774-1789. [Crossref]
510. János Kornai. 2016. Még egyszer a „rendszerparadigmáról”. Tisztázás és kiegészítések a posztszocialista
régió tapasztalatainak fényében. Közgazdasági Szemle 63:10, 1074-1119. [Crossref]
511. Chang Liu, Guangrong Ma. 2016. Taxation without representation: local fiscal response to
intergovernmental transfers in China. International Tax and Public Finance 23:5, 854-874. [Crossref]
512. Chen Shaowei, Li Rui, Wang Youqiang. 2016. Role and significance of political incentives:
understanding institutional collective action in local inter-governmental arrangements in China. Asia
Pacific Journal of Public Administration 38:4, 211-222. [Crossref]
513. Yiping Fang, Anirban Pal. 2016. Drivers of urban sprawl in urbanizing China – a political ecology
analysis. Environment and Urbanization 28:2, 599-616. [Crossref]
514. Pranab Bardhan. 2016. State and Development: The Need for a Reappraisal of the Current Literature.
Journal of Economic Literature 54:3, 862-892. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
515. Octasiano M. Valerio Mendoza. 2016. Preferential policies and income inequality: Evidence from
Special Economic Zones and Open Cities in China. China Economic Review 40, 228-240. [Crossref]
516. Xing Liu, Shuiquan Jiang. 2016. Bank equity connections, intellectual property protection and
enterprise innovation – A bank ownership perspective. China Journal of Accounting Research 9:3,
207-233. [Crossref]
517. Clayton Munnings, Richard D. Morgenstern, Zhongmin Wang, Xu Liu. 2016. Assessing the design
of three carbon trading pilot programs in China. Energy Policy 96, 688-699. [Crossref]
518. Yongzheng Liu, James Alm. 2016. “Province-Managing-County” fiscal reform, land expansion, and
urban growth in China. Journal of Housing Economics 33, 82-100. [Crossref]
519. Xufei Ma, Zhujun Ding, Lin Yuan. 2016. Subnational institutions, political capital, and the
internationalization of entrepreneurial firms in emerging economies. Journal of World Business 51:5,
843-854. [Crossref]
520. Meina Cai. 2016. Land for welfare in China. Land Use Policy 55, 1-12. [Crossref]
521. Jin Shi, Canfei He, Qi Guo. 2016. How did geese fly domestically? Firm demography and spatial
restructuring in China's apparel industry. Area 48:3, 346-356. [Crossref]
522. Lijuan Miao, Feng Zhu, Zhanli Sun, John Moore, Xuefeng Cui. 2016. China’s Land-Use Changes
during the Past 300 Years: A Historical Perspective. International Journal of Environmental Research
and Public Health 13:9, 847. [Crossref]
523. Harry X. Wu. 2016. Sustainability of China's Growth Model: A Productivity Perspective. China &
World Economy 24:5, 42-70. [Crossref]
524. Zengji Song, Abraham Nahm, Jun Yang. 2016. Institutional environment, political connections of
partial state ownership, and performance. International Journal of Social Economics 43:8, 856-870.
[Crossref]
525. Jiwei Qian, Ka Ho Mok. 2016. Dual Decentralization and Fragmented Authoritarianism in
Governance: Crowding Out among Social Programmes in China. Public Administration and
Development 36:3, 185-197. [Crossref]
526. Xiude Chen, Quande Qin, Y.-M. Wei. 2016. Energy productivity and Chinese local officials’
promotions: Evidence from provincial governors. Energy Policy 95, 103-112. [Crossref]
527. Kean Fan Lim. 2016. ‘Emptying the cage, changing the birds’: state rescaling, path-dependency and
the politics of economic restructuring in post-crisis Guangdong. New Political Economy 21:4, 414-435.
[Crossref]
528. Shaun Goldfinch. 2016. The Advantages of Ambiguity? Development, Rule Formation and Property
Rights During Transition in China. Asian Studies Review 40:3, 394-412. [Crossref]
529. Di Guo, Yan Guo, Kun Jiang. 2016. Government-subsidized R&D and firm innovation: Evidence
from China. Research Policy 45:6, 1129-1144. [Crossref]
530. Xufeng Zhu, Youlang Zhang. 2016. Political Mobility and Dynamic Diffusion of Innovation: The
Spread of Municipal Pro-Business Administrative Reform in China. Journal of Public Administration
Research and Theory 26:3, 535-551. [Crossref]
531. Yu Qin. 2016. ‘No county left behind?’ The distributional impact of high-speed rail upgrades in
China. Journal of Economic Geography 126, lbw013. [Crossref]
532. Zhiqiang Dong, Yongjing Zhang. 2016. Accumulated social capital, institutional quality, and economic
performance: Evidence from China. Economic Systems 40:2, 206-219. [Crossref]
533. Torsten Heinrich, Shuanping Dai. 2016. Diversity of firm sizes, complexity, and industry structure
in the Chinese economy. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 37, 90-106. [Crossref]
534. Wen Wang, Fangzhi Ye. 2016. The Political Economy of Land Finance in China. Public Budgeting
& Finance 36:2, 91-110. [Crossref]
535. Károly Mike. 2016. Merre vezessen a magyar kapitalizmus útja? Látkép Ronald Coase
világítótornyából. Közgazdasági Szemle 63:6, 597-614. [Crossref]
536. John Knight. 2016. The Societal Cost of China's Rapid Economic Growth. Asian Economic Papers
15:2, 138-159. [Crossref]
537. Adam Przeworski. 2016. Democracy: A Never-Ending Quest. Annual Review of Political Science 19:1,
1-12. [Crossref]
538. Tain-Jy Chen. 2016. The development of China’s solar photovoltaic industry: why industrial policy
failed: Table 1. Cambridge Journal of Economics 40:3, 755-774. [Crossref]
539. . China's Innovation Challenge 8, . [Crossref]
540. Gordon Redding. Impact of China’s invisible societal forces on its intended evolution 56-86. [Crossref]
541. Michael A. Witt. The road ahead for China 87-107. [Crossref]
542. Douglas B. Fuller. China’s political economy 121-151. [Crossref]
543. Andrew Atherton, Alex Newman. 2016. The emergence of the private entrepreneur in reform era
China: re-birth of an earlier tradition, or a more recent product of development and change?. Business
History 58:3, 319-344. [Crossref]
544. Fulong Wu. 2016. Emerging Chinese Cities: Implications for Global Urban Studies. The Professional
Geographer 68:2, 338-348. [Crossref]
545. Xiaoming Zhang, Zhenghan Cao. 2016. From manipulation to integration: the strategic
transformation of grassroots control in China. Journal of Chinese Governance 1:2, 284-302. [Crossref]
546. Xufeng Zhu. 2016. Dynamics of central–local relations in China’s social welfare system. Journal of
Chinese Governance 1:2, 251-268. [Crossref]
547. Yan Wu, Nico Heerink. 2016. Foreign direct investment, fiscal decentralization and land conflicts in
China. China Economic Review 38, 92-107. [Crossref]
548. Jidong Chen, Jennifer Pan, Yiqing Xu. 2016. Sources of Authoritarian Responsiveness: A Field
Experiment in China. American Journal of Political Science 60:2, 383-400. [Crossref]
549. Lena Kuhn, Stephan Brosig, Linxiu Zhang. 2016. The Brink of Poverty: Implementation of a Social
Assistance Programme in Rural China. Journal of Current Chinese Affairs 45:1, 75-108. [Crossref]
550. Thomas F. Remington. 2016. Regional Variation in Business-Government Relations in Russia and
China. Problems of Post-Communism 63:2, 63-74. [Crossref]
551. Jihai Yu, Li-An Zhou, Guozhong Zhu. 2016. Strategic interaction in political competition: Evidence
from spatial effects across Chinese cities. Regional Science and Urban Economics 57, 23-37. [Crossref]
552. Yanhong Ma, Qiuhong Zhao, Menghao Xi. 2016. Decision-makings in safety investment: An
opportunity cost perspective. Safety Science 83, 31-39. [Crossref]
553. Ross Wilson. 2016. Does Governance Cause Growth? Evidence from China. World Development 79,
138-151. [Crossref]
554. Dimitar D. Gueorguiev, Paul J. Schuler. 2016. KEEPING YOUR HEAD DOWN: PUBLIC
PROFILES AND PROMOTION UNDER AUTOCRACY. Journal of East Asian Studies 16:1,
87-116. [Crossref]
555. Xiang Zhang, Lunyi Li, Ziheng Li. 2016. Political Background and Household Entrepreneurship in
China. China Accounting and Finance Review 18:1. . [Crossref]
556. Yin-Fang Zhang, Ping Gao. 2016. Integrating environmental considerations into economic regulation
of China's electricity sector. Utilities Policy 38, 62-71. [Crossref]
557. Philipp Boeing, Elisabeth Mueller, Philipp Sandner. 2016. China's R&D explosion—Analyzing
productivity effects across ownership types and over time. Research Policy 45:1, 159-176. [Crossref]
558. Jun Zhang, Jamie Peck. 2016. Variegated Capitalism, Chinese Style: Regional Models, Multi-scalar
Constructions. Regional Studies 50:1, 52-78. [Crossref]
559. Li Dang, Ruilong Yang. 2016. Anti-corruption, marketisation and firm behaviours: evidence from
firm innovation in China. Economic and Political Studies 4:1, 39-61. [Crossref]
560. Tobias J. Burgers. An Unmanned South China Sea? Understanding the Risks and Implications of the
Arrival of the Digital and Robotic Revolution in Military Affairs in the SCS 77-94. [Crossref]
561. Jun Du, Tomasz Mickiewicz. 2016. Subsidies, rent seeking and performance: Being young, small or
private in China. Journal of Business Venturing 31:1, 22-38. [Crossref]
562. Yelena Kalyuzhnova, Christian A. Nygaard, Yerengaip Omarov, Abdizhapar Saparbayev. Local
Content: Concepts, Perspectives and Economy 11-73. [Crossref]
563. Qiao Liu. The Improbable Surge of Corporate China 1-23. [Crossref]
564. Qiao Liu. The “Great” Hope Struggles 79-101. [Crossref]
565. Qiao Liu. Shake Up the Foundations 155-183. [Crossref]
566. Marshall W. Meyer. China: Strategy in a Growth-Driven Economy 1-7. [Crossref]
567. Li-An Zhou. 2016. The administrative subcontract: Significance, relevance and implications for
intergovernmental relations in China. Chinese Journal of Sociology 2:1, 34-74. [Crossref]
568. Yi Lu, Mona Luan, Tuan-Hwee Sng. 2016. The Effect of State Capacity Under Different Economic
Systems. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
569. Michael Rochlitz. 2016. Political Loyalty vs Economic Performance: Evidence from Machine Politics
in Russiaas Regions. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
570. Ora John Reuter, Quintin Beazer. 2016. Who's to Blame? Political Centralization and Electoral
Punishment Under Authoritarianism. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
571. Minmin Xi. 2016. The Effectiveness of Governmental Regulatory Control at Firms Level: A
Contingency Perspective of Performance Measurement System. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
572. Leng Ling, Guoman SHE. 2016. Judging a Book by Its Cover: Beauty Effects in the Promotion
Tournament of Regional Leaders. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
573. Xi Lu, Peter L. Lorentzen. 2016. Rescuing Autocracy from Itself: China's Anti-Corruption
Campaign. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
574. Zhi Wang, Qinghua Zhang, Li-An Zhou. 2016. To Build Outward or Upward? The Spatial Pattern
of Urban Land Development in China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
575. Yijun Dong. 2016. Officials’ Rotation, Economic Growth and Environmental Accidents: Do They
Affect the Political Promotion?. Modern Economy 07:10, 1120-1133. [Crossref]
576. Yang Yao, Muyang Zhang. 2015. Subnational leaders and economic growth: evidence from Chinese
cities. Journal of Economic Growth 20:4, 405-436. [Crossref]
577. Juan Feng, Erik Lichtenberg, Chengri Ding. 2015. Balancing act: Economic incentives, administrative
restrictions, and urban land expansion in China. China Economic Review 36, 184-197. [Crossref]
578. Hao Liang, Luc Renneboog, Sunny Li Sun. 2015. The political determinants of executive
compensation: Evidence from an emerging economy. Emerging Markets Review 25, 69-91. [Crossref]
579. Ning Hsieh. 2015. Economic Security, Social Cohesion, and Depression Disparities in Post-transition
Societies. Journal of Health and Social Behavior 56:4, 534-551. [Crossref]
580. Haitian Lu, Hongbo Pan, Chenying Zhang. 2015. Political Connectedness and Court Outcomes:
Evidence from Chinese Corporate Lawsuits. The Journal of Law and Economics 58:4, 829-861.
[Crossref]
581. Xinye Zheng, Feng Song, Yihua Yu, Shunfeng Song. 2015. In Search of Fiscal Interactions: A
Spatial Analysis of Chinese Provincial Infrastructure Spending. Review of Development Economics 19:4,
860-876. [Crossref]
582. Xibao Li. 2015. Specialization, institutions and innovation within China's regional innovation systems.
Technological Forecasting and Social Change 100, 130-139. [Crossref]
583. Guiying Laura Wu, Qu Feng, Pei Li. 2015. Does local governments’ budget deficit push up housing
prices in China?. China Economic Review 35, 183-196. [Crossref]
584. Li Han, James Kai-Sing Kung. 2015. Fiscal incentives and policy choices of local governments:
Evidence from China. Journal of Development Economics 116, 89-104. [Crossref]
585. Rong Tan, Tianxiao Zhou. 2015. Decentralization in a centralized system: Project-based governance
for land-related public goods provision in China. Land Use Policy 47, 262-272. [Crossref]
586. Yonghua Zou, Wanxia Zhao, Robert Mason, Meizhen Li. 2015. Comparing Sustainable Universities
between the United States and China: Cases of Indiana University and Tsinghua University.
Sustainability 7:9, 11799-11817. [Crossref]
587. Jun Du, Xiaoxuan Liu. 2015. Selection, Staging, and Sequencing in the Recent Chinese Privatization.
The Journal of Law and Economics 58:3, 657-682. [Crossref]
588. Ruixue Jia, Masayuki Kudamatsu, David Seim. 2015. POLITICAL SELECTION IN CHINA:
THE COMPLEMENTARY ROLES OF CONNECTIONS AND PERFORMANCE. Journal of the
European Economic Association 13:4, 631-668. [Crossref]
589. Qun Bao, Jiuli Huang, Yanling Wang. 2015. Productivity and Firms’ Sales Destination: Chinese
Characteristics. Review of International Economics 23:3, 620-637. [Crossref]
590. Michael Rochlitz, Vera Kulpina, Thomas Remington, Andrei Yakovlev. 2015. Performance incentives
and economic growth: regional officials in Russia and China. Eurasian Geography and Economics 56:4,
421-445. [Crossref]
591. Deming Luo, Yanjun Liu, Yiyun Wu, Xiwei Zhu, Xiangrong Jin. 2015. Does development zone have
spillover effect in China?. Journal of the Asia Pacific Economy 20:3, 489-516. [Crossref]
592. Xianxiang Xu, Yuanhua Gao. 2015. Growth target management and regional economic growth. Journal
of the Asia Pacific Economy 20:3, 517-534. [Crossref]
593. Cheng Yuan, Lei Zhang. 2015. Public education spending and private substitution in urban China.
Journal of Development Economics 115, 124-139. [Crossref]
594. Adam Szirmai. Socio-Economic Development 3, . [Crossref]
595. Xin Wan, Yuanyuan Ma, Kezhong Zhang. 2015. Political determinants of intergovernmental transfers
in a regionally decentralized authoritarian regime: evidence from China. Applied Economics 47:27,
2803-2820. [Crossref]
596. Barbara Krug, Alexander Libman. 2015. Commitment to local autonomy in non-democracies: Russia
and China compared. Constitutional Political Economy 26:2, 221-245. [Crossref]
597. Alexey Baranov, Egor Malkov, Leonid Polishchuk, Michael Rochlitz, Georgiy Syunyaev. 2015. How
(not) to measure Russian regional institutions. Russian Journal of Economics 1:2, 154-181. [Crossref]
598. Yin-Fang Zhang. 2015. The Regulatory Framework and Sustainable Development of China's
Electricity Sector. The China Quarterly 222, 475-498. [Crossref]
599. Gordon Redding, Michael A. Witt. 2015. Advancing Indigenous Management Theory: Executive
Rationale as an Institutional Logic. Management and Organization Review 11:2, 179-203. [Crossref]
600. B. Lu, J. Piggott. 2015. Meeting the Migrant Pension Challenge in China. CESifo Economic Studies
61:2, 438-464. [Crossref]
601. Paul Minard. 2015. Government discretion: how high a barrier to entry for Chinese private
enterprises?. Journal of Asian Public Policy 8:2, 134-148. [Crossref]
602. Johannes Binswanger, Manuel Oechslin. 2015. Disagreement and Learning about Reforms. The
Economic Journal 125:584, 853-886. [Crossref]
603. Jay Pan, Xuezheng Qin, Qian Li, Joseph P. Messina, Paul L. Delamater. 2015. Does hospital
competition improve health care delivery in China?. China Economic Review 33, 179-199. [Crossref]
604. Gregory Brock, Yinghua Jin, Tong Zeng. 2015. Fiscal decentralization and China's regional infant
mortality. Journal of Policy Modeling 37:2, 175-188. [Crossref]
605. Thomas F. Remington. 2015. Why is interregional inequality in Russia and China not falling?.
Communist and Post-Communist Studies 48:1, 1-13. [Crossref]
606. LOTTA MOBERG. 2015. The political economy of special economic zones. Journal of Institutional
Economics 11:1, 167-190. [Crossref]
607. Yong Wang. 2015. A model of sequential reforms and economic convergence: The case of China.
China Economic Review 32, 1-26. [Crossref]
608. Michael Rochlitz. 2015. At the Crossroads: Putin's Third Presidential Term and Russia's
InstitutionsJudahB. (2013) Fragile Empire: How Russia Fell in and out of Love with Vladimir
Putin. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.HillF. and GaddyC. G. (2013) Mr Putin: Operative
in the Kremlin. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.LedenevaA. (2013) Can Russia
Modernise? Sistema, Power Networks and Informal Governance. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.SixsmithM. (2011) Russia: A 1,000-Year Chronicle of the Wild East. London: BBC Books.
Political Studies Review 13:1, 59-68. [Crossref]
609. Jiwei Qian. 2015. Reallocating authority in the Chinese health system: an institutional perspective.
Journal of Asian Public Policy 8:1, 19-35. [Crossref]
610. Guangyong Lei, Wenzhong Wang, Mo Liu. 2015. Political uncertainty, dividend policy adjustments
and market effects. China Journal of Accounting Studies 3:1, 49-83. [Crossref]
611. Carsten Herrmann-Pillath. Chinas Transformationen im 20. Jahrhundert: Wirtschaftliche, politische
und kulturelle Interdependenzen 355-370. [Crossref]
612. Kazuyuki Motohashi. Comparison of Economic Institutions in China and India 57-76. [Crossref]
613. Canan Mutlu, Mike Peng, Marc van Essen. Privatization and Principal-Principal Conflicts in
Transition Economies 239-265. [Crossref]
614. Son Ngoc Chu, Ligang Song. 2015. Promoting Private Entrepreneurship for Deepening Market
Reform in China: A Resource Allocation Perspective. China & World Economy 23:1, 47-77. [Crossref]
615. Jiuli Huang, Yanling Wang, Qun Bao. 2015. FIRM PRODUCTIVITY AND SALES
DESTINATIONS: EVIDENCE FROM  WITHIN CHINA. Economic Inquiry 53:1, 205-219.
[Crossref]
616. Kenneth S. Chan, Xianxiang Xu, Yuanhua Gao. 2015. The China Growth Miracle: The Role of the
Formal and the Informal Institutions. The World Economy 38:1, 63-90. [Crossref]
617. Bingyong Zheng. 2015. Bureaucratic Corruption and Economic Development. SSRN Electronic
Journal . [Crossref]
618. Jidong Chen, Jennifer Pan, Yiqing Xu. 2015. Sources of Authoritarian Responsiveness: A Field
Experiment in China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
619. Ricard Gil, Giorgio Zanarone. 2015. On the Determinants and Consequences of Informal Contracting.
SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
620. Philipp Boeing, Elisabeth MMller, Philipp G. Sandner. 2015. China's R&D Explosion Analyzing
Productivity Effects Across Ownership Types and Over Time. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
621. Deming Luo, Yanjun Liu, Yiyun Wu, Xiwei Zhu, Xiangrong Jin. 2015. Does Development Zone
Have Spillover Effect in China?. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
622. Gregory Brock, Yinghua Jin, Tong Zeng. 2015. Fiscal Decentralization and China's Regional Infant
Mortality. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
623. Li Han, James Kai-Sing Kung. 2015. Fiscal Incentives and Policy Choices of Local Governments,
Evidence from China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
624. Wang Li, Lukas Menkhoff, Michael Schrrder, Xian Xu. 2015. Politicians' Promotion Incentives and
Bank Risk Exposure in China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
625. Bin Ke, Wei Yu, Ying Zheng. 2015. Do Government Controllers Use the Corporate Control Market to
Help Improve the Performance of Publicly Listed Chinese SOEs?. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
626. Pei Li, Yi Lu, Jin Wang. 2015. Does Flattening Government Improve Economic Performance?. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
627. Sen Ma. 2015. 'Curse' of Ability? Performance, Political Connection and Promotion of Chinese City
Leaders. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
628. Yvonne Jie Chen, Pei Li, Yi Lu. 2015. Accountability, Career Incentives, and Pollution: The Case Of
Two Control Zones in China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
629. Qiao Liu, Wei Luo, Pingui Rao. 2015. The Political Economy of Corporate Tax Avoidance. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
630. Zhaoyang Gu, Song Tang, Donghui Wu. 2015. The Political Economy of Labor Cost Behavior:
Evidence from China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
631. Ning Wang. 2015. The Chinese Economic System Under Mao. Man and the Economy 2:2. . [Crossref]
632. Kai Lyu. 2015. The Institutional Transformation of China’s Stock Exchanges: A Comparative
Perspective. Accounting, Economics and Law - A Convivium 5:1. . [Crossref]
633. Yuyu Chen, Mitsuru Igami, Mo Xiao. 2015. Privatization and Innovation: Productivity, New Products,
and Patents in China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
634. Jun Du, Xiaoxuan Liu, Ying Zhou. 2014. State advances and private retreats? — Evidence of aggregate
productivity decomposition in China. China Economic Review 31, 459-474. [Crossref]
635. Julan Du, Hongsheng Fang, Xiangrong Jin. 2014. The “growth-first strategy” and the imbalance
between consumption and investment in China. China Economic Review 31, 441-458. [Crossref]
636. Lei Tian, Zhongmin Wang, Alan Krupnick, Xiaoli Liu. 2014. Stimulating shale gas development in
China: A comparison with the US experience. Energy Policy 75, 109-116. [Crossref]
637. T.-J. Chen, Y.-H. Ku. 2014. Indigenous innovation vs. teng-long huan-niao: policy conflicts in
the development of China's flat panel industry. Industrial and Corporate Change 23:6, 1445-1467.
[Crossref]
638. János Kornai. 2014. The soft budget constraint. Acta Oeconomica 64:Supplement 1, 25-79. [Crossref]
639. Alex Bryson, John Forth, Minghai Zhou. How Much Influence does the Chinese State have Over
CEOs and their Compensation? 1-23. [Crossref]
640. Alex Bryson, John Forth, Minghai Zhou. CEO Incentive Contracts in China: Why does City Location
Matter? 25-49. [Crossref]
641. Fuming Jiang, Lixian Liu, Bruce W. Stening. 2014. Do Foreign Firms in China Incur a Liability of
Foreignness? The Local Chinese Firms’ Perspective. Thunderbird International Business Review 56:6,
501-518. [Crossref]
642. Natasha Agarwal, Chris Milner, Alejandro Riaño. 2014. Credit constraints and spillovers from foreign
firms in China. Journal of Banking & Finance 48, 261-275. [Crossref]
643. Lei Feng, Helen X.H. Bao, Yan Jiang. 2014. Land reallocation reform in rural China: A behavioral
economics perspective. Land Use Policy 41, 246-259. [Crossref]
644. Jinghai Zheng, Liming Wang. 2014. Institutions and Development: The Case of China in
Comparative Perspectives. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade 50:sup6, 4-20. [Crossref]
645. Ying Bai, James Kai-sing Kung. 2014. The shaping of an institutional choice: Weather shocks, the
Great Leap Famine, and agricultural decollectivization in China. Explorations in Economic History 54,
1-26. [Crossref]
646. Yunxiao Dang, Zhilin Liu, Wenzhong Zhang. 2014. Land-based interests and the spatial distribution
of affordable housing development: The case of Beijing, China. Habitat International 44, 137-145.
[Crossref]
647. James Kai-sing Kung. 2014. The Emperor Strikes Back: Political Status, Career Incentives and Grain
Procurement during China's Great Leap Famine. Political Science Research and Methods 2:2, 179-211.
[Crossref]
648. X. Zhan, C. W.-H. Lo, S.-Y. Tang. 2014. Contextual Changes and Environmental Policy
Implementation: A Longitudinal Study of Street-Level Bureaucrats in Guangzhou, China. Journal of
Public Administration Research and Theory 24:4, 1005-1035. [Crossref]
649. John B. Knight. 2014. China as a Developmental State. The World Economy 37:10, 1335-1347.
[Crossref]
650. Ciqi Mei, Zhilin Liu. 2014. Experiment-based policy making or conscious policy design? The case
of urban housing reform in China. Policy Sciences 47:3, 321-337. [Crossref]
651. Alex Bryson, John Forth, Minghai Zhou. 2014. Who posts performance bonds and why? Evidence
from China's CEOs. China Economic Review 30, 520-529. [Crossref]
652. Ben Ma, Guojun Song, Lei Zhang, David A. Sonnenfeld. 2014. Explaining sectoral discrepancies
between national and provincial statistics in China. China Economic Review 30, 353-369. [Crossref]
653. Yongzheng Liu, Jorge Martinez-Vazquez. 2014. INTERJURISDICTIONAL TAX
COMPETITION IN CHINA. Journal of Regional Science 54:4, 606-628. [Crossref]
654. Marius Korsnes. 2014. Fragmentation, Centralisation and Policy Learning: An Example from China's
Wind Industry. Journal of Current Chinese Affairs 43:3, 175-205. [Crossref]
655. XIAOBO LÜ, PIERRE F. LANDRY. 2014. Show Me the Money: Interjurisdiction Political
Competition and Fiscal Extraction in China. American Political Science Review 108:3, 706-722.
[Crossref]
656. Haitian Lu, Jiajia Fu. 2014. Structural Changes in the Chinese Stock Market: A Review of Empirical
Research. China Accounting and Finance Review 16:2. . [Crossref]
657. Edmund Malesky, Jonathan London. 2014. The Political Economy of Development in China and
Vietnam. Annual Review of Political Science 17:1, 395-419. [Crossref]
658. Di Guo, Kun Jiang, Byung-Yeon Kim, Chenggang Xu. 2014. Political economy of private firms in
China. Journal of Comparative Economics 42:2, 286-303. [Crossref]
659. Yi Che. 2014. Mismatch. China Agricultural Economic Review 6:2, 229-247. [Crossref]
660. Jorrit Gosens, Yonglong Lu. 2014. Prospects for global market expansion of China’s wind turbine
manufacturing industry. Energy Policy 67, 301-318. [Crossref]
661. Yingqi Wei, Nan Zheng, Xiaohui Liu, Jiangyong Lu. 2014. Expanding to outward foreign direct
investment or not? A multi-dimensional analysis of entry mode transformation of Chinese private
exporting firms. International Business Review 23:2, 356-370. [Crossref]
662. Ming Du. 2014. CHINA'S STATE CAPITALISM AND WORLD TRADE LAW. International
and Comparative Law Quarterly 63:2, 409-448. [Crossref]
663. Krzysztof Nawratek. 2014. AN URBAN PARTISAN: CARL SCHMITT’S AND JACOB TAUBES’
GUIDE FOR URBAN REVOLUTION. JOURNAL OF ARCHITECTURE AND URBANISM
38:1, 3-10. [Crossref]
664. Loren Brandt, Debin Ma, Thomas G. Rawski. 2014. From Divergence to Convergence: Reevaluating
the History Behind China's Economic Boom. Journal of Economic Literature 52:1, 45-123. [Abstract]
[View PDF article] [PDF with links]
665. Junxue Jia, Qingwang Guo, Jing Zhang. 2014. Fiscal decentralization and local expenditure policy in
China. China Economic Review 28, 107-122. [Crossref]
666. Suresh Radhakrishnan. 2014. The China puzzle: Opportunities for accounting research. China Journal
of Accounting Research 7:1, 1-8. [Crossref]
667. Danny T. Wang, Wendy Y. Chen. 2014. Foreign direct investment, institutional development, and
environmental externalities: Evidence from China. Journal of Environmental Management 135, 81-90.
[Crossref]
668. Alex Bryson, John Forth, Minghai Zhou. 2014. Same or Different? The CEO Labour Market in
China's Public Listed Companies. The Economic Journal 124:574, F90-F108. [Crossref]
669. Ralph W. Huenemann. 2014. The World Bank and China: Future Prospects. Asia & the Pacific Policy
Studies 1:1, 251-256. [Crossref]
670. Guanghua Yu. Contract Enforcement Revisited 45-70. [Crossref]
671. Nicholas Crafts, Kevin Hjortshøj O’Rourke. Twentieth Century Growth 263-346. [Crossref]
672. Yang Yao. The Chinese Growth Miracle 943-1031. [Crossref]
673. Yonghua Zou. 2014. Contradictions in China's affordable housing policy: Goals vs. structure. Habitat
International 41, 8-16. [Crossref]
674. Lotta Moberg, Vlad Tarko. 2014. Why No Chinese Miracle in Africa? Special Economic Zones and
Liberalization Avalanches. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
675. Lei Feng, Helen X. Bao, Yan Jiang. 2014. Land Reallocation Reform in Rural China: A Behavioral
Economics Perspectivee. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
676. Johannes Binswanger, Manuel Oechslin. 2014. Disagreement and Learning About Reforms. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
677. Li Shi-Qiang. 2014. Jurisdiction, Decision Rights Allocation and the Elitism of China's Governments.
SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
678. Ora John Reuter, Noah Buckley. 2014. Patrons, Clients, and Technocrats: A Study of the Effects of
Regime Type on Bureaucratic Appointment Strategies. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
679. Hong Lan, Craig Anthony Hart, Mei Yujia, Zlatko J Kovacic. 2014. Fiscal Decentralization,
Environmental Accountability and the Provision of Environmental Public Goods in China: Evidence
from 30 Provinces. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
680. Michael Rochlitz, Vera P. Kulpina, Thomas F. Remington, Andrei A. Yakovlev. 2014. Performance
Incentives and Economic Growth: Regional Officials in Russia and China. SSRN Electronic Journal
. [Crossref]
681. Mun S. Ho, Zhongmin Wang. 2014. Green Growth (for China): A Literature Review. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
682. Shiqiang Li. 2014. Jurisdiction, Decision Rights Allocation and the Elitism of China's Governments.
SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
683. André Lieber. 2013. The Chinese Ideology: Reconciling the Politics with the Economics of
Contemporary Reform. Journal of Chinese Political Science 18:4, 335-353. [Crossref]
684. Wendy Y. Chen, Danny T. Wang. 2013. Urban forest development in China: Natural endowment or
socioeconomic product?. Cities 35, 62-68. [Crossref]
685. Helmut Wagner. 2013. Challenges to China’s Policy: Structural Change. Comparative Economic
Studies 55:4, 721-736. [Crossref]
686. Jian Chu, Xiao-Ping Zheng. 2013. China's Fiscal Decentralization and Regional Economic Growth.
Japanese Economic Review 64:4, 537-549. [Crossref]
687. Yuk-Shing Cheng, Kim-Sau Chung. 2013. Too many mothers-in-law?. Journal of Development
Economics 105, 69-76. [Crossref]
688. Seong-Jin Choi, Nan Jia, Jiangyong Lu. 2013. The Structure of Political Institutions and Effectiveness
of Corporate Political Lobbying. Organization Science 141223041331004. [Crossref]
689. Kang Hua Cao, Javier A. Birchenall. 2013. Agricultural productivity, structural change, and economic
growth in post-reform China. Journal of Development Economics 104, 165-180. [Crossref]
690. Jianxing Yu, Xiang Gao 中中中中中中中. 2013. Redefining Decentralization: Devolution of Administrative
Authority to County Governments in Zhejiang Province (中中中中中中中中中中中中中中中中中中中中中中中). Australian
Journal of Public Administration 72:3, 239-250. [Crossref]
691. YI ZHANG, HEIN ROELFSEMA. 2013. DUAL AND COMMON AGENCY ISSUES IN
INTERNATIONAL JOINT VENTURES: EVIDENCE FROM CHINA. The Singapore Economic
Review 58:03, 1350020. [Crossref]
692. Keshab Bhattarai, Sushanta Mallick. 2013. Impact of China's currency valuation and labour cost on
the US in a trade and exchange rate model. The North American Journal of Economics and Finance
25, 40-59. [Crossref]
693. Bat Batjargal, Michael A. Hitt, Anne S. Tsui, Jean-Luc Arregle, Justin W. Webb, Toyah L. Miller.
2013. Institutional Polycentrism, Entrepreneurs' Social Networks, and New Venture Growth. Academy
of Management Journal 56:4, 1024-1049. [Crossref]
694. Yong Wang. 2013. Fiscal decentralization, endogenous policies, and foreign direct investment: Theory
and evidence from China and India. Journal of Development Economics 103, 107-123. [Crossref]
695. Pierre Salmon. 2013. Decentralization and growth: what if the cross-jurisdiction approach had met a
dead end?. Constitutional Political Economy 24:2, 87-107. [Crossref]
696. Haifeng Huang. 2013. Signal Left, Turn Right. Political Research Quarterly 66:2, 292-305. [Crossref]
697. Jamie Peck, Jun Zhang. 2013. A variety of capitalism … with Chinese characteristics?. Journal of
Economic Geography 13:3, 357-396. [Crossref]
698. Danny T. Wang, Flora F. Gu, David K. Tse, Chi Kin (Bennett) Yim. 2013. When does FDI matter?
The roles of local institutions and ethnic origins of FDI. International Business Review 22:2, 450-465.
[Crossref]
699. M. A. Witt, G. Redding. 2013. Asian business systems: institutional comparison, clusters and
implications for varieties of capitalism and business systems theory. Socio-Economic Review 11:2,
265-300. [Crossref]
700. Jin Wang. 2013. The economic impact of Special Economic Zones: Evidence from Chinese
municipalities. Journal of Development Economics 101, 133-147. [Crossref]
701. Lili Wang, Adam Szirmai. 2013. The Unexpected Convergence of Regional Productivity in Chinese
Industry, 1978–2005. Oxford Development Studies 41:1, 29-53. [Crossref]
702. Luigi Bonatti, Andrea Fracasso. 2013. Hoarding of international reserves in China: Mercantilism,
domestic consumption and US monetary policy. Journal of International Money and Finance 32,
1044-1078. [Crossref]
703. Guonan Ma, Robert McCauley, Lillie Lam. 2013. The Roles of Saving, Investment and the Renminbi
in Rebalancing the Chinese Economy. Review of International Economics 21:1, 72-84. [Crossref]
704. Linda Yueh. 2013. What Drives China's Growth?. National Institute Economic Review 223, R4-R15.
[Crossref]
705. Yipeng Liu, Xuanwei Cao, Yijun Xing. A Tale of Two Cities in Regional Entrepreneurial
Policymaking: A Comparative Study of Suzhou and Wuxi from a Path-Dependence Perspective 55-77.
[Crossref]
706. Célestin Monga. Theories of Agglomeration: Critical Analysis from a Policy Perspective 209-224.
[Crossref]
707. Xiaobo Zhang. Clusters as an Instrument for Industrial Policy: The Case of China 227-243. [Crossref]
708. RICHARD A. EASTERLIN. 2013. HAPPINESS, GROWTH, AND PUBLIC POLICY †.
Economic Inquiry 51:1, 1-15. [Crossref]
709. Neil McCulloch, Edmund Malesky, Nhat Nguyen Duc. 2013. Does Better Provincial Governance
Boost Private Investment in Vietnam?. IDS Working Papers 2013:414, 1-27. [Crossref]
710. James Kai-sing Kung, Ting Chen. 2013. Do Land Revenue Windfalls Reduce the Career Incentives
of County Leaders? Evidence from China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
711. Simon Alder, Lin Shao, Fabrizio Zilibotti. 2013. Economic Reforms and Industrial Policy in a Panel
of Chinese Cities. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
712. Bat Batjargal, Michael A. Hitt, Anne S. Tsui, Jean-Luc Arregle, Justin Webb, Toyah Miller.
2013. Institutional Polycentrism, Entrepreneurss Social Networks, and New Venture Growth. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
713. Ralph Huenemann. 2013. The World Bank and China: Future Prospects. SSRN Electronic Journal
. [Crossref]
714. Zhangkai Huang, Lixing Li, Guangrong Ma, Jun Qian. 2013. The Political Economy of Corporate
Finance: Evidence from Re-Nationalizationn in China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
715. Yongjing Zhang. 2012. A view from behavioral political economy on China's institutional change.
China Economic Review 23:4, 991-1002. [Crossref]
716. Xiaodong Zhu. 2012. Understanding China's Growth: Past, Present, and Future. Journal of Economic
Perspectives 26:4, 103-124. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
717. Wenying Fu, Javier Revilla Diez, Daniel Schiller. Regional Innovation Systems within a Transitional
Context: Evolutionary Comparison of the Electronics Industry in Shenzhen and Dongguan Since the
Opening of China 177-195. [Crossref]
718. Sumru Altug, Barış Tan, Gözde Gencer. 2012. Cyclical dynamics of industrial production and
employment: Markov chain-based estimates and tests. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control
36:10, 1534-1550. [Crossref]
719. Jun Zhang. 2012. From Hong Kong’s Capitalist Fundamentals to Singapore’s Authoritarian
Governance: The Policy Mobility of Neo-liberalising Shenzhen, China. Urban Studies 49:13,
2853-2871. [Crossref]
720. M. Ellman. 2012. What Did the Study of Transition EconomiesContribute to Mainstream
Economics?. Voprosy Ekonomiki :8, 98-121. [Crossref]
721. Zhiyong Liu, Yue Qiao. 2012. Abuse of Market Dominance Under China’s 2007 Anti-monopoly Law:
A Preliminary Assessment. Review of Industrial Organization 41:1-2, 77-107. [Crossref]
722. Wenying Fu, Javier Revilla Diez, Daniel Schiller. 2012. REGIONAL INNOVATION SYSTEMS
WITHIN A TRANSITIONAL CONTEXT: EVOLUTIONARY COMPARISON OF THE
ELECTRONICS INDUSTRY IN SHENZHEN AND DONGGUAN SINCE THE OPENING OF
CHINA. Journal of Economic Surveys 26:3, 534-550. [Crossref]
723. Jinping Song, Enru Wang. 2012. China’s Information and Communication Technology in Geographic
Perspective. Eurasian Geography and Economics 53:4, 502-526. [Crossref]
724. R. A. Easterlin, R. Morgan, M. Switek, F. Wang. 2012. China's life satisfaction, 1990-2010.
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 109:25, 9775-9780. [Crossref]
725. Yuanyuan Wang, Jing You. 2012. Corruption and firm growth: Evidence from China. China Economic
Review 23:2, 415-433. [Crossref]
726. Yipeng Liu, Michael Woywode, Yijun Xing. 2012. High technology start-up innovation and the role
of guanxi : an explorative study in China from an institutional perspective. Prometheus 30:2, 211-229.
[Crossref]
727. Carlo Milana, Harry X. Wu. 2012. Growth, institutions, and entrepreneurial finance in China: a
survey. Strategic Change 21:3-4, 83-106. [Crossref]
728. Karen Eggleston. 2012. Health Care for 1.3 Billion: An Overview of China’s Health System. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
729. Xi Li, Xuewen Liu, Yong Wang. 2012. A Model of China's State Capitalism. SSRN Electronic Journal
. [Crossref]
730. Mark Harrison. 2012. Communism and Economic Modernization. SSRN Electronic Journal .
[Crossref]
731. Michael A. Witt, Gordon Redding. 2012. Asian Business Systems: Institutional Comparison,
Clusters, and Implications for Varieties of Capitalism and Business Systems Theory. SSRN Electronic
Journal . [Crossref]
732. Michael A. Witt, Gordon Redding. 2012. China: Authoritarian Capitalism. SSRN Electronic Journal
. [Crossref]
733. Xiang Kong. 2011. Why are social network transactions important? Evidence based on the
concentration of key suppliers and customers in China. China Journal of Accounting Research 4:3,
121-133. [Crossref]
734. Yipeng Liu. 2011. Book review. Scandinavian Journal of Management 27:3, 344-346. [Crossref]
735. Haifeng Huang. 2011. Signal Left, Turn Right: Central Rhetoric and Local Reform in China. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
736. Kai Lu. 2011. The Institutional Transformation of China's Stock Exchanges. SSRN Electronic Journal
. [Crossref]
737. Yi Che. 2009. Mismatch: Land Reallocations, Recovery Land Rental and Land Rental Market
Development in Rural China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]

You might also like