The Broken Window Fallacy

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 9

Economic Modelling 39 (2014) 204–212

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Economic Modelling
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/ecmod

Analysis on the dynamics of a Cournot investment game with


bounded rationality
Zhanwen Ding ⁎, Qiao Wang, Shumin Jiang
Faculty of Science, Jiangsu University, Zhenjiang 212013, PR China

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: In this work, a dynamic system of investment game played by two firms with bounded rationality is proposed. It
Accepted 21 February 2014 is assumed that each firm in any period makes a strategy for investment and uses local knowledge to make in-
Available online 28 March 2014 vestment strategy according to the marginal profit observed in the previous period. Theoretic work is done on
the existence of equilibrium solutions, the instability of the boundary equilibriums and the stability conditions
Keywords:
of the interior equilibrium. Numerical simulations are used to provide experimented evidence for the complicat-
Cournot game
Bounded rationality
ed behaviors of the system evolution. It is observed that the equilibrium of the system can loose stability via flip
Investment bifurcation or Neimark–Sacher bifurcation and time-delayed feedback control can be used to stabilize the chaotic
Dynamic system behaviors of the system.
Chaos control © 2014 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction “where each firm increases its output if it perceives a positive marginal
profit and decreases its production if the perceived marginal profit is
Cournot (1838) introduced earliest the mathematical model which negative (Bischi & Naimzada, 1999)”. Much work has been done on
describes production competitions in an oligopolistic market. In a clas- the dynamical Cournot games performed by players with this kind of
sical Cournot model each participant uses a naïve expectation to guess marginal profit method. The models with homogeneous players (all
that opponents' output remains at the same level as in the previous pe- players are boundedly rational players and use the marginal profit
riod and adopts an output strategy which solves the corresponding method to adjust strategies) are considered in Agiza et al. (2001),
profit maximization problem. Since then, a great number of literatures Agiza et al. (2002), Ahmed et al. (2000), and Bischi and Naimzada
have been devoted to enrich and expand the Cournot oligopoly game (1999). Some other work has focused on modeling the system with het-
theory. Much work has paid attention to the stability and the complex erogeneous expectations. Agiza and Elsadany (2003) and Zhang et al.
phenomena in a dynamical Cournot game with this kind of naïve expec- (2007) studied the dynamics of a Cournot duopoly game with one
tation [e.g., (Teocharis, 1960; Puu, 1991; Puu, 1996; Puu, 1998; Agiza, bounded rationality player and one naïve player. Agiza and Elsadany
1998; Kopel, 1996; Ahmed & Agiza, 1998; Agliari et al., 2000; Rosser, (2004) and Dubiel-Teleszynski (2011) considered a duopoly model in
2002)]. As a more sophisticated kind of learning rule with respect to which one player has bounded rationality and the other has adaptive ex-
naïve expectations, adaptive expectations or adaptive adjustments pectation. In the model by Fan et al. (2012), there is one player using the
have been proposed in other dynamical models [e.g., (Okuguchi, 1970; marginal profit method and one player adjusting production in terms of
Bischi & Kopel, 2001; Agiza et al., 1999; Rassenti et al., 2000; the market price in the previous period. Ding et al. (2009) studied the dy-
Szidarovszky & Okuguchi, 1988)]. In recent years, many researchers namics of a two-team Cournot game with heterogeneous players.
have paid attention to a kind of bounded rationality, with which a player In these models for dynamical Cournot game, output is a key variable
(without complete information of the demand function) uses local and each player is able to take any needed output updating for the pur-
knowledge to update output by the marginal profit. Bischi and pose of local profit maximization; thus it is based on an implicit assump-
Naimzada (1999) gave a general formula of the dynamical Cournot tion that all players could provide sufficient quantity of products on the
model with this form of bounded rationality, assuming that producers market. However, this implicit assumption may be impractical in an
behave as local profit maximizers in a local adjustment process, economy market where investment plays the most important role. For
instance, in an emerging industry with immature development (e.g., a
⁎ Corresponding author. new energy market), it is unlikely for a firm to hold productivity large
E-mail address: dgzw@ujs.edu.cn (Z. Ding). enough due to its lack of investment accumulation. As a strategic

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2014.02.030
0264-9993/© 2014 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
Z. Ding et al. / Economic Modelling 39 (2014) 204–212 205

behavior in these economic activities, investment accumulation plays a Agiza et al., 2002; Agliari et al., 2000; Ahmed et al., 2000; Bischi &
significant role in achieving a good production level. Moreover, we Naimzada, 1999; Rassenti et al., 2000):
know that even in a mature industry, the production capacity of a firm
is greatly dependent on its large-scale investment stock. Only when C i ðqi ðt ÞÞ ¼ ci qi ðt Þ; i ¼ 1; 2; ð4Þ
the investment comes up to a certain level can a firm provide as much
goods as the market demands. Therefore, during the developing period
of an infant industry, the competition among producers lies mainly in where c1 and c2 are both positive.
their investment strategy. To obtain a competitive market share and With all the assumptions above, we get firm i's profit in period t as
get superiority over opponents, producers must consider their invest- follows:
ment strategies in successive periods.
The main purpose of our work is to formulate a novel model, which π i ðx1 ðt Þ; x2 ðt ÞÞ ¼ qi ðt Þpðt Þ−C i ðqi ðt ÞÞ−xi ðt Þ
2 2
puts investment decision as a substitute for output adjustment into the ¼ ðaBi −Bi ci ÞðθK i ðt−1Þ þ xi ð t ÞÞ−bBi ðθK i ðt−1Þþ xi ðt ÞÞ
dynamical Cournot game. In our model, all producers are also assumed −bBi B j ðθK i ðt−1Þ þ xi ðt ÞÞ θK j ðt−1Þ þ x j ðt Þ −xi ðt Þ
to have bounded rationality and make their investment decisions in line i≠j; i; j ¼ 1; 2:
with the marginal profit in the previous period. That is to say, each firm
ð5Þ
will increase its investment if it perceives a positive marginal profit and
decrease its investment if the perceived marginal profit is negative. It is
analyzed as to how this novel dynamical Cournot game, in a local ad- By differentiating πi(x1(t),x2(t)) (i = 1, 2), we obtain firm i's marginal
justment process, evolves to equilibrium or exhibits complicated dy- profit with respect to its investment in period t(i = 1, 2, respectively):
namic behaviors.
This article is organized as the following. In Section 2, we model the ∂π1 ðx1 ðt Þ; x2 ðt ÞÞ
dynamical investment game played by players with bounded rationali- ϕ1 ðt Þ ¼
∂x1 ðt Þ
ty. In Section 3, we discuss the existence and local stability of the equi- 2 ð6aÞ
¼ aB1 −1−B1 c1 −2bB1 ðθK 1 ðt−1Þ þ x1 ðt ÞÞ
librium points for the system. In Section 4, we show the dynamic −bB1 B2 ðθK 2 ðt−1Þ þ x2 ðt ÞÞ;
features of this system with numerical simulations, including bifurca-
tion diagram, phase portrait, stable region and sensitive dependence
on initial conditions. In Section 5, time-delayed feedback control is ∂π2 ðx1 ðt Þ; x2 ðt ÞÞ
ϕ2 ðt Þ ¼
used to stabilize the chaotic behaviors of the system. ∂x2 ðt Þ
ð6bÞ
¼ aB2 −1−B2 c2 −bB1 B2 ðθK 1 ðt−1Þ þ x1 ðt ÞÞ
2
2. The model −2bB2 ðθK 2 ðt−1Þ þ x2 ðt ÞÞ:

Our work focuses on firms' investment competition rather than their We suppose both players have bounded rationality and use the mar-
output competition. We pay attention to a duopoly investment game, ginal profit method to update their investment strategy in the next pe-
where producers' investment choices are substituted for their output riod, as supposed in the existing work on the classical Cournot games for
decisions discussed in classic Cournot games. output competition [e.g., (Agiza et al., 2001; Agiza et al., 2002; Agiza &
We consider a competition between two firms (players), labeled Elsadany, 2003; Agiza & Elsadany, 2004; Ahmed et al., 2000; Bischi &
by i = 1,2, producing homogeneous goods. The strategy of each Naimzada, 1999; Ding et al., 2009; Dubiel-Teleszynski, 2011; Fan et al.,
firm is to choose an investment in every period. Both players make 2012; Zhang et al., 2007)]. It means that each firm will increase its in-
their decisions in discrete periods t = 0,1,2 ⋯. We write Ki(t − 1) for vestment flow in period t + 1 if the marginal profit in the current period
firm i's capital stock in period t − 1, and xi(t) for its investment in t is positive; otherwise the firm will decrease its investment. Then the
period t. We pay our attention mainly to relatively long economic investment adjustment mechanism for player i can be modeled as:
periods and assume that the previous accumulated capital Ki(t − 1),
after depreciating in a period, keeps a residual value θKi(t − 1)
xi ðt þ 1Þ ¼ xi ðt Þ þ α i ðxi ðt ÞÞϕi ðt Þ; i ¼ 1; 2; ð7Þ
(0 b θ b 1, identical for both firms). Then the capital stock Ki(t) for
firm i is formulated as
where αi(xi(t)) is a positive function which gives the extent of firm i's in-
K i ðt Þ ¼ θK i ðt−1Þ þ xi ðt Þ; i ¼ 1; 2: ð1Þ vestment variation based on its marginal profit. For simplicity, we also
put the function αi(xi(t)) in a linear form (Agiza & Elsadany, 2003;
We suppose that for firm i, its totally accumulated capital Ki(t) Agiza & Elsadany, 2004; Agiza et al., 2001; Agiza et al., 2002; Bischi &
determines its potential production capacity in period t and it produces Naimzada, 1999; Ding et al., 2009; Dubiel-Teleszynski, 2011; Fan et al.,
at full capacity to make its output qi(t). Namely, qi(t) is assumed to be a 2012; Zhang et al., 2007): αi(xi(t)) = αixi(t), where αi is a positive con-
function of Ki(t). For simplicity, we consider a linear form of output func- stant representing the relative adjustment speed. Then the dynamics
tion: qi(t) = BiKi(t), where Bi is a positive constant. From Eq. (1) we have (7) takes its form as:

qi ðt Þ ¼ Bi ðθK i ðt−1Þ þ xi ðt ÞÞ; i ¼ 1; 2: ð2Þ xi ðt þ 1Þ ¼ xi ðt Þ þ α i xi ðt Þϕi ðt Þ; i ¼ 1; 2: ð8Þ

For the price in the market, we consider a linear inverse demand func-
From Eqs. (1), (6a)–(6b) and (8), we obtain a four-dimensional dis-
tion (Agiza & Elsadany, 2003; Agiza & Elsadany, 2004; Agiza et al., 2001;
crete dynamic system:
Bischi & Naimzada, 1999; Ding et al., 2009; Dubiel-Teleszynski, 2011;
Rassenti et al., 2000; Szidarovszky & Okuguchi, 1988; Zhang et al., 2007): 8
>
>
2
x1 ðt þ 1Þ ¼ x1 ðt Þ þ α 1 x1 ðt ÞðaB1 −1−B1 c1 −2bB1 ðθK 1 ðt−1Þ
>
>
pðt Þ ¼ a−bQ ðt Þ; ð3Þ >
> þ x1 ðt ÞÞ−bB1 B2 ðθK 2 ðt−1Þ þ x2 ðt ÞÞÞ;
>
<
x2 ðt þ 1Þ ¼ x2 ðt Þ þ α 2 x2 ðt ÞðaB2 −1−B2 c2 −bB1 B2 ðθK 1 ðt−1Þ
ð9Þ
where a N 0,b N 0, and Q(t) = q1(t) + q2(t) is the total supply by both >
>
2
þ x1 ðt ÞÞ−2bB2 ðθK 2 ðt−1Þ þ x2 ðt ÞÞÞ;
>
>
firms. We also suppose that the production cost function of each firm >
> K ðt Þ ¼ θK ðt−1 Þ þ x ðt Þ;
>
: 1 1 1
takes a linear form (Agiza & Elsadany, 2003; Agiza & Elsadany, 2004; K 2 ðt Þ ¼ θK 2 ðt−1Þ þ x2 ðt Þ:
206 Z. Ding et al. / Economic Modelling 39 (2014) 204–212

If we denote Ki(t − 1) by Ii(t) (and hence Ki(t) by Ii(t + 1)), i = 1,2, In the following, all the nonnegativity conditions (12a)–(12d) are
then we can rewrite system (9) as the following standard dynamics assumed.
8
>
>
2
x1 ðt þ 1Þ ¼ x1 ðt Þ þ α 1 x1 ðt ÞðaB1 −1−B1 c1 −2bB1 ðθI1 ðt Þ þ x1 ðt ÞÞ 3.1. Stability of the boundary equilibriums
>
>
>
> −bB1 B2 ðθI 2 ðt Þ þ x2 ðt ÞÞÞ;
>
< 2
x2 ðt þ 1Þ ¼ x2 ðt Þ þ α 2 x2 ðt ÞðaB2 −1−B2 c2 −2bB2 ðθI2 ðt Þ þ x2 ðt ÞÞ ð10Þ To investigate the local stability of an equilibrium (x1,x2,I1,I2) of sys-
>
> −bB1 B2 ðθI 1 ðt Þ þ x1 ðt ÞÞÞ; tem (10), we work out its Jacobian matrix J:
>
>
>
> I1 ðt þ 1Þ ¼ θI1 ðt Þ þ x1 ðt Þ;
>
:
I2 ðt þ 1Þ ¼ θI2 ðt Þ þ x2 ðt Þ: J ðx1 ;0
x2 ; I1 ; I 2 Þ 1
2
A1 −bB1 B2 α 1 x1 −2θbB1 α 1 x1 −θbB1 B2 α 1 x1
B C
System (10) describes a duopoly game played by two boundedly ra- B −bB1 B2 α 2 x2 A2 −θbB1 B2 α 2 x2 −2θbB2 α 2 x2 C
2
¼B C;
tional players making decision in a process of dynamical investment. In @ 1 0 θ 0 A
the following sections, we are to investigate the dynamical properties of 0 1 0 θ
this model. ð13Þ
where
3. Equilibrium points and stability
2
A1 ¼ 1 þ α 1 ðaB1 −1−B1 c1 Þ−2α 1 bB1 ðθI 1 þ 2x1 Þ−bα 1 B1 B2 ðθI2 þ x2 Þ;
Let xi(t + 1) = xi(t) and Ii(t + 1) = Ii(t) (i = 1,2) in system (10),
then we get 2
A2 ¼ 1 þ α 2 ðaB2 −1−B2 c2 Þ−2α 2 bB2 ðθI 2 þ 2x2 Þ−bα 2 B1 B2 ðθI1 þ x1 Þ:
8  
>
>
2
x1 ðt Þ aB1 −1−B1 c1 −2bB1 ðθI 1 ðt Þ þ x1 ðt ÞÞ−bB1 B2 ðθI2 ðt Þ þ x2 ðt ÞÞ ¼ 0;
>
>   An equilibrium (x1,x2,I1,I2) will be locally asymptotically stable if all
< 2
x2 ðt Þ aB2 −1−B2 c2 −2bB2 ðθI 2 ðt Þ þ x2 ðt ÞÞ−bB1 B2 ðθI1 ðt Þ þ x1 ðt ÞÞ ¼ 0; the eigenvalues (real or complex) of the Jacobian matrix J(x1,x2,I1,I2)
>
>
> ðθ−1ÞI 1 ðt Þ þ x1 ðt Þ ¼ 0;
> lie inside the unit disk, i.e. |λ| b 1 holds for any eigenvalue λ of J(x1,x2,
:
ðθ−1ÞI 2 ðt Þ þ x2 ðt Þ ¼ 0: I1,I2). An equilibrium (x1,x2,I1,I2) will be unstable if there is an eigenval-
ð11Þ ue λ of J(x1,x2,I1,I2) such that |λ| N 1.
Solving equations in Eq. (11), we obtain four equilibrium states of
dynamics (Eq. (10)), which are listed as follows: Proposition 1. The boundary equilibrium E0 is an unstable equilibrium.

E0 ¼ ð0; 0; 0; 0Þ;
! Proof. Taking the expression of the equilibrium E0 into Eq. (13), we get
ð1−θÞðaB2 −1−B2 c2 Þ aB2 −1−B2 c2 the Jacobian matrix at E0 as the following:
E1 ¼ 0; ; 0; ;
2bB22 2bB22 0 1
1 þ α 1 ðaB1 −1−B1 c1 Þ 0 0 0
B 0 1 þ α 2 ðaB2 −1−B2 c2 Þ 0 0C
! B
J ðE0 Þ ¼ @ C;
1 0 θ 0A
ð1−θÞðaB1 −1−B1 c1 Þ aB1 −1−B1 c1
E2 ¼ ; 0; ; 0 ; 0 1 0 θ
2bB21 2bB21
which has four eigenvalues:
     
E ¼ x1 ; x2 ; I 1 ; I 2 ; λ1 ¼ λ2 ¼ θ; λ3 ¼ 1 þ α 1 ðaB1 −1−B1 c1 Þ; λ4 ¼ 1 þ α 2 ðaB2 −1−B2 c2 Þ:
where
From the nonnegativity conditions (12a)–(12b) and the positivity of the
 ð1−θÞðB1 B2 ða þ c2 −2c1 Þ þ B1 −2B2 Þ parameter αi, it follows that |λ3,4| N 1. So the equilibrium E0 is unstable.
x1 ¼ ;
3bB21 B2
Proposition 2. The boundary equilibriums E1 and E2 are both unstable.

 ð1−θÞðB1 B2 ða þ c1 −2c2 Þ þ B2 −2B1 Þ Proof. At the boundary equilibrium point E1, the Jacobian matrix
x2 ¼ ; (Eq. (13)) is given by
3bB1 B22
0 1
U

I1
B B ða þ c2 −2c1 Þ þ B1 −2B2
¼ 1 2 ; B 1 þ 2B 0 0 0 C
B 2 C
3bB21 B2 B ðθ−1Þα 2 B1 V θðθ−1Þα 2 B1 V C
J ðE1 Þ ¼ B
B 1 þ ðθ−1Þα 2 V θðθ−1Þα 2 V C
C;
B 2B2 2B2 C
@ 1 0 θ 0 A
 B1 B2 ða þ c1 −2c2 Þ þ B2 −2B1
I2 ¼ : 0 1 0 θ
3bB1 B22
where U = α1(B1B2(a + c2 − 2c1) + B1 − 2B2),V = aB2 − 1 − B2c2. By
E0,E1 and E2 are all boundary equilibriums and E∗ is a unique interior simple calculation, we get four eigenvalues of the matrix J(E1):
equilibrium. In order to make these equilibrium points have economic
meaning, we only consider the nonnegative cases. Since b, B1, B2 and θ λ1 ¼ θ;
are positive parameters, E1,E2 and E∗ are all positive provided that α 1 ðB1 B2 ða þ c2 −2c1 Þ þ B1 −2B2 Þ
λ2 ¼ 1 þ ;
2B2
aB1 −1−B1 c1 N 0; ð12aÞ
1
λ3;4 ¼ ð1 þ θ þ α 2 ðθ−1ÞðaB2 −1−B2 c2 Þ
2 qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
aB2 −1−B2 c2 N 0; ð12bÞ 2
 −4θ þ ð1 þ θ þ α 2 ðθ−1ÞðaB2 −1−B2 c2 ÞÞ Þ:

B1 B2 ða þ c2 −2c1 Þ þ B1 −2B2 N 0; ð12cÞ


According to the inequality (Eq. (12c)) and the condition that B2 and
α1 are both positive, we see that λ2 N 1 and hence conclude that the equi-
B1 B2 ða þ c1 −2c2 Þ þ B2 −2B1 N0: ð12dÞ librium E1 is unstable. A similar approach shows that E2 is unstable too.
Z. Ding et al. / Economic Modelling 39 (2014) 204–212 207

1.3

1.1

0.9

0.7

0.5

0.3
0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 1.6 1.8 2
α1
1.9

1.7

1.5

1.3

1.1

0.9
0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 1.6 1.8 2
α1

1.15 0.65

0.95
0.55

0.75
0.45
0.55

0.35
0.35

0.15 0.25
1 1.05 1.1 1.15 1.2 1.25 1.3 1.35 1.4 8 8.2 8.4 8.6 8.8 9 9.2
α1 α1

1.95

1.75 1.6

1.55 1.55

1.35 1.5

1.15 1.45

0.95 1.4
1 1.05 1.1 1.15 1.2 1.25 1.3 1.35 1.4 8 8.2 8.4 8.6 8.8 9 9.2
α1 α1

Fig. 1. Bifurcation diagrams with respect to the adjustment rate α1.

3.2. Stability of the interior equilibrium where U is the same one denoted in J(E1) and W = α2(B1B2(a + c1 −
2c2) − 2B1 + B2). If P(λ) denotes the characteristic polynomial of the
Now we consider the asymptotical stability of the interior equilibri- Jacobian matrix J(E∗), then
um E∗. The Jacobian matrix J at E∗ = (x∗1,x∗2,I∗1,I∗2) takes its form as
4 3 2
0 1 P ðλÞ ¼ λ þ p1 λ þ p2 λ þ p3 λ þ p4 :
2ðθ−1ÞU ðθ−1ÞU 2θðθ−1ÞU θðθ−1ÞU
B 1 þ C
B 3B2 3B1 3B2 3B1 C
   B ðθ−1ÞW 2ðθ−1ÞW θðθ−1ÞW 2θðθ−1ÞW C By calculation, we get
J E ¼B B 1þ C;
3B2 3B1 3B2 3B1 C
B C 2 2 2
@ 1 0 θ 0 A p1 ¼ ½B α ð1−θÞX þ B2 α 2 ð1−θÞ
3B1 B2 1 1
0 1 0 θ þ B1 B2 ð−2α 1 ð1−θÞ þ α 2 ð1−θÞY−3ðθ þ 1ÞÞ;
208 Z. Ding et al. / Economic Modelling 39 (2014) 204–212

α1=0.2 α1=0.2 α1=1.75 α1=1.82 α1=1.98


1.45 1.7 1.8 1.8 1.8
A)
θ=0.35 1.6 1.6 1.6
1.5
1.4 1.4 1.4
1.445
1.2 1.2 1.2
1.3
1 1 1

1.44 1.1 0.8 0.8 0.8


1.5 1.55 1.6 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.7 1.3 1.5 1.7 1.9 1.3 1.5 1.7 1.9 1.3 1.5 1.7 1.9

α1=1.1 α1=1.3 α1=1.36 α1=1.38 α1=1.4269


B) 1.45 1.8 1.8 1.8 1.8
1.7 1.7 1.7
θ=0.5 1.6
1.5 1.5 1.5
1.4
1.445
1.3 1.3 1.3
1.2

1 1.1 1.1 1.1

1.44 0.8 0.9 0.9 0.9


1.5 1.6 1.5 1.7 1.9 1.5 1.7 1.9 1.5 1.7 1.9 1.5 1.7 1.9

α1=8.4 α1=9.1 α1=9.195 α1=9.23 α1=9.3079


1.45 1.48 1.49 1.5 1.5
C)
θ=0.69
1.46

1.445 1.45
1.45 1.45
1.44

1.44 1.42 1.42 1.4 1.41


1.5 1.55 1.6 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.7 1.5 1.6 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.7 1.4 1.5 1.6
X Axis−−I1, Y Axis−−I2

Fig. 2. Phase portraits for Fig. 1(A, B, C) with various values of θ and α1.

1 2 In our model, we have


p2 ¼ ½2B2 α 2 ðα 1 ðθ−1Þ−1−θÞð1−θÞ
3B1 B2
2 P ð1Þ ¼ 1 þ p1 þ p2 þ p3 þ p4
þ B1 α 1ð1−θÞX ðα 2 ð1−θÞY−2
 ðθ þ 1ÞÞ  2
α α ðθ−1Þ ðB1 B2 ða þ c1 −2c2 Þ−2B1 þ B2 ÞðB1 B2 ða þ c2 −2c1 Þ þ B1 −2B2 Þ
2 2 ¼ 1 2 :
þ B1 B2 2α 2 θ −1 Yþ3 1 þ 4θ þ θ 3B1 B2
þ α 1 ð1−θÞðα 2 ðθ−1ÞðaB2 þ 4B2 c1 −5B2 c2 −5Þ þ 4ð1 þ θÞÞÞ;
Then from the nonnegativity conditions (12c)–(12d), we know that
the first condition P(1) N 0 must hold. In addition, Det(M±1 ) = 1 ± p4 =
2θ 2 2
p3 ¼ ½B α ð1−θÞX þ B2 α 2 ð1−θÞ 1 ± θ2 N 0 also holds since 0 b θ b 1. Consequently, we conclude that the
3B1 B2 1 1
þ B1 B2 ð−2α 1 ð1−θÞ þ α 2 ð1−θÞY−3ð1 þ θÞÞ; interior equilibrium point E∗ of system (10) is asymptotically locally sta-
ble if it meets the following conditions

2
p4 ¼ θ ; P ð−1Þ ¼ 1−p1 þ p2 −p3 þ p4 N0; ð14aÞ

 
þ −
where X = aB2 + B2c2 − 2B2c1 + 1, Y = aB2 + B2c1 − 2B2c2 − 2. Det M 3 N0; Det ðM 3 ÞN0; ð14bÞ
For all the roots of the polynomial P(λ) (the eigenvalues of the
Jacobian matrix J(E∗)) to lie inside the unit disk, Schur–Cohn Criterion where Det(M) represents the determinant of the matrix M.
[e.g., (Elaydi, 2005)] gives the necessary and sufficient conditions as:
4. Numerical simulation
(i) P(1) N 0;
(ii) (−1)4P(−1) N 0; In this section, we show by numerical simulations how the system
(iii) The determinants of the 1 × 1 matrices M±
1 and the 3 × 3 matrices evolves under different levels of parameters, especially of the capital re-
M±3 are all positive, where sidual rate θ and the adjustment speed α. In all the numerical simula-
0 1 0 1 tions, the other parameters are fixed: a = 5, b = 1, c1 = 0.3, c2 = 0.5,
1 0 0 0 0 p4 B1 = 0.6 and B2 = 0.8.
 
M1 ¼ 1  p4 ; M3 ¼ @ p1 1 0A  @ 0 p4 p3 A: For three cases of the capital residual rate θ, Fig. 1 is about bifurcation
p2 p1 1 p4 p3 p2 diagrams of system (10) with respect to the adjustment rate α1 while
Z. Ding et al. / Economic Modelling 39 (2014) 204–212 209

A) θ=0.35 B) θ=0.5
6 6

4 4

α2 α2

2 2

0 0
0 2 4 6 8 10 0 2 4 6 8 10
α1 α1

C) θ=0.69
6

α2

0
0 2 4 6 8 10
α1

Fig. 3. Stability region in (α1, α2)-plane for different levels of θ.

the other one is fixed as α2 = 2.2. Fig. 1(A) shows the bifurcation dia- about at, respectively, α1 = 0.285, 1.18 and 8.42. It tells that if the residual
gram for θ = 0.35: period doubling bifurcation comes up at about rate θ is higher (i.e. the depreciation rate is lower), the equilibrium insta-
α1 = 0.285 and chaos occurs while α1 increases to about 1.85. bility will be delayed much more and the system will be led to chaos much
Fig. 1(B) is about the case θ = 0.5: period trebling bifurcation occurs later. That is, a larger residual rate (or a smaller depreciation rate) has
at about α1 = 1.18 and period doubling bifurcation follows when α1 in- a stronger stabilization effect on the system's dynamical evolution. This
creases, and chaos occurs in the end of the bifurcation process. In conclusion can be also drawn from another kind of simulation as shown
Fig. 1(C) for θ = 0.69, more complicated dynamical behaviors can be in Fig. 3. By computer work on the stability conditions (18a)–(18b) for
observed. The equilibrium is stable for α1 taking its value up to about three cases (θ = 0.35, 0.5, 0.69), stable regions in the (α1,α2)-plane are
8.42, then it becomes unstable and bifurcates into two stable fixed numerically obtained and are plotted in Fig. 3. Comparing Fig. 3(A), (B)
points; Neimark–Sacher bifurcation occurs at about α1 = 9.15, then a and (C), we see that an increasing θ expands the stability region rapidly.
period window follows after about α1 = 9.21; and such a complicated Fig. 4 shows the sensitivity of system (when loosing stability) to
process (period doubling bifurcation, Neimark–Sacher bifurcation, peri- initial conditions, with θ = 0.5, α1 = 1.426, α2 = 2.2, x2(1) = 0.72,
odic window, etc.) continues leading the system to chaos. I1(1) = 1.56 and I2(1) = 1.44. Fig. 4(A) plots the orbits of firms' invest-
The observations from Fig. 1(A) and (B) tell that the Nash equilibrium ment: the blue ones take an initial value x1(1) = 0.78 and the red ones
of the system can loose stability via flip bifurcations, and Fig. 1(C) shows take a slightly deviated value x11(1) = 0.78001. Fig. 4(B) is about the or-
that the stability loss may also be due to Neimark–Sacker bifurcations. bits of firms' capital stock under the same initial conditions as Fig. 4(A).
So the system can drive to chaos either in a flip bifurcation process or in Fig. 4(A) and (B) shows that the difference between the orbits with
a Neimark–Sacher bifurcation process. About the three cases in Fig. 1, slightly deviated initial values builds up rapidly after a number of itera-
two-dimension phase portraits for some values of α1 are shown in tions, although their initial states are indistinguishable.
Fig. 2, which gives a more detailed description of the orbits of the system. In Fig. 5(A) and (B), the bifurcation diagrams are plotted for the capital
The phase portraits in Fig. 2(A) (θ = 0.35) are obviously related to a peri- residual rate θ when α2 is fixed as 2.2. Fig. 5(A) is for α1 = 1.98 and
od doubling process leading to chaos. Fig. 2(B) (θ = 0.5) also shows a flip Fig. 5(B) is for α1 = 9.305. Fig. 5(A) shows a reverse period-doubling bifur-
bifurcation process, where chaos occurs in the end after periods 3,6,12,⋯. cation, while Fig. 5(B) combines reverse period-doubling bifurcation and
Fig. 2(C) (θ = 0.69) shows that there exits a Neimark–Sacker bifurcation reverse Neimark–Sacher bifurcation. The two figures show that the system
so that a couple of closed invariant curves is observed when the system trends towards stability with the residual rate increased, which also tells
loses stability, and it also shows that multi-period orbit follows after the that a high residual rate has a positive effect on the system stability.
Neimark–Sacker bifurcation and chaotic attractors occur in the end.
Besides different bifurcation processes leading to chaos, Fig. 1 also 5. Chaos control
shows that the point that the system begins to lose stability will be
much different when the residual rate θ changes. In Fig. 1(A), (B) and From the numerical simulations above, we see that the adjustment
(C) for θ = 0.35, θ = 0.5 and θ = 0.69, the equilibrium stability loss begins rate and the capital residual rate have great influence on the stability
210 Z. Ding et al. / Economic Modelling 39 (2014) 204–212

A)
x1(t)−Blue, x11(t)−Red
1.2
1
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
500 550 600 650 700 750 800 850 900 950 1000
t
x2(t)−Blue, x21(t)−Red

0.8
0.6

0.4
500 550 600 650 700 750 800 850 900 950 1000
t

B)
I1(t)−Blue, I11(t)−Red
2

1.5

1
500 550 600 650 700 750 800 850 900 950 1000
t
I2(t)−Blue, I21(t)−Red
0.8

0.6

0.4

0.2
500 550 600 650 700 750 800 850 900 950 1000
t

Fig. 4. Sensitivity of the system to initial conditions when losing stability.

of system (10). If the model parameters fail to locate into the stable It is easy to see that the new system (15) has the same equilibriums
region required, the behaviors of the dynamics will be much com- as system (10) and it takes the following equivalent form:
plicated. In a real economic system, chaos is not desirable and will 8
>
> 1 2
be not expected, and it is needed to be avoided or controlled so > x1 ðt þ 1Þ ¼ x1 ðt Þ þ
> α x ðt ÞðaB1 −1−B1 c1 −2bB1 ðθI1 ðt Þ þ x1 ðt ÞÞ
>
> 1þk 1 1
that the dynamic system would work better. In this section, we >
> −bB1 B2 ðθI2 ðt Þ þ x2 ðt ÞÞÞ;
<
use the time-delayed feedback control [e.g., (Elabbasy et al., 2
x2 ðt þ 1Þ ¼ x2 ðt Þ þ α 2 x2 ðt ÞðaB2 −1−B2 c2 −2bB2 ðθI2 ðt Þ þ x2 ðt ÞÞ
2009; Ding et al., 2011; Holyst & Urbanowicz, 2000)] to control >
>
>
> −bB1 B2 ðθI1 ðt Þ þ x1 ðt ÞÞÞ;
system chaos. We modify the first equation of system (10) by in- >
>
>
> I ðt þ 1Þ ¼ θI 1 ðt Þ þ x1 ðt Þ;
tercalating a controller k(x t − x t + 1 ) as a small perturbation, : 1
I 2 ðt þ 1Þ ¼ θI 2 ðt Þ þ x2 ðt Þ:
where k N 0 is a controlling coefficient. Then the controlled system ð16Þ
is given by
The Jacobian matrix of the controlled system (16) is given by

J ðx1 ; x2 ; I1 ; I 2 Þ
8 0 2 1
>
>
2
x1 ðt þ 1Þ ¼ x1 ðt Þ þ α 1 x1 ðt ÞðaB1 −1−B1 c1 −2bB1 ðθI1 ðt Þ þ x1 ðt ÞÞ α1 bB1 B2 α 1 x1 2θbB1 α 1 x1 θbB1 B2 α 1 x1
>
> B 1 þ 1 þ k A1 − − − C
>
> −bB1 B2 ðθI2 ðt Þ þ x2 ðt ÞÞÞ þ kðxðt Þ−xðt þ 1ÞÞ; B 1þk 1þk 1þk C
>
< 2
x2 ðt þ 1Þ ¼ x2 ðt Þ þ α 2 x2 ðt ÞðaB2 −1−B2 c2 −2bB2 ðθI2 ðt Þ þ x2 ðt ÞÞ ð15Þ ¼B B −bB1 B2 α 2 x2 1 þ α 2 A2 −θbB1 B2 α 2 x2 −2θbB2 α 2 x2 C
2
C;
> @ 1 0 θ 0 A
>
> −bB 1 B2 ðθI 1 ðt Þ þ x 1 ðt ÞÞÞ;
>
> 0 1 0 θ
>
> I ðt þ 1Þ ¼ θI1 ðt Þ þ x1 ðt Þ;
: 1
I2 ðt þ 1Þ ¼ θI2 ðt Þ þ x2 ðt Þ: ð17Þ
Z. Ding et al. / Economic Modelling 39 (2014) 204–212 211

A) α1 = 1.98 1.15

1.5 0.95
1.3
0.75
1.1
0.9 0.55

0.7 0.35
0.5
0.15
0.3 0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5
0.34 0.36 0.38 0.4 0.42 0.44 0.46 0.48 0.5
k
θ
1.9 1.95

1.7 1.75
1.5
1.55
1.3
1.35
1.1
1.15
0.9
0.34 0.36 0.38 0.4 0.42 0.44 0.46 0.48 0.5
0.95
θ 0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5
k
B) α1 = 9.305
0.65 Fig. 6. Bifurcation diagram with respect to the controlling factor k.

0.55

0.45 In Fig. 6, it is actually observed that with the control coefficient k in-
creasing, the system gradually gets out of chaos and periodic windows
0.35 and achieves to stability when k N 0.2005. For k = 0.25, Fig. 7 shows
the stable behaviors of the orbits of the controlled system beginning
0.25
0.687 0.692 0.697 0.702 0.707 0.712 0.717 0.722 0.727 from the initial state (x1(0),x2(0),I1(0),I2(0)) = (0.94,0.87,1.56.1.44).
θ
6. Conclusion
1.6

1.55 In this work we have taken into consideration firms' investment de-
cisions as substitute for the output choices considered by the existing
1.5
work on classic Cournot games. We have formulated a novel Cournot
1.45 form of investment game played by two players with bounded rational-
1.4 ity. The main idea in our model is that each firm's decision is to choose
0.687 0.692 0.697 0.702 0.707 0.712 0.717 0.722 0.727 its investment in each period according to the marginal profit observed
θ from the previous period. We have established a corresponding

Fig. 5. Bifurcation diagrams with respect to the residual rate θ.


1
0.9
where A1 = aB1 − 1 − B1c1 − 2bB21(θI1
+ 2x1) − bB1B2(θI2 + x2) and x
0.8 1
A2 = aB2 − 1 − B2c2 − 2bB22(θI2 + 2x2) − bB1B2(θI1 + x1).
As has been shown in Fig. 1(B), chaotic behavior of system (10) oc- 0.7 x
2
curs when all the model parameters take their values as 0.6
0.5
ða; b; B1 ; B2 ; c1 ; c2 ; α 1 ; α 2 ; θÞ ¼ ð5; 1; 0:6; 0:8; 0:3; 0:5; 1:426; 2:2; 0:5Þ: 0.4
0.3
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
Using this group of parameters values, we obtain the Jacobian matrix
t
(Eq. (17)) at the interior equilibrium as the following
1.8
1.7
J ðx1 ; x2 ; I1 ; I2 Þ
0 1 1.6 I
1:22408 0:643411 0:482558 0:321706 1
1− − − −
B 1 þ k 1þk 1þk 1þk C 1.5
B −1:22496 C
¼ B −0:91872 −2:02368 −0:45936 C: ð18Þ 1.4 I2
@ 1 0 0:5 0 A
1.3
0 1 0 0:5
1.2
1.1
From the stability conditions (14a)–(14b), we get that all the eigen- 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
values of the matrix (18) will lie inside the unit disk provided that t
k N 0.2005. That is, when k N 0.2005 the controlled system (16) will
be asymptotically locally stable. Fig. 7. Stability of equilibrium with k = 0.25.
212 Z. Ding et al. / Economic Modelling 39 (2014) 204–212

dynamics of players' investment adjustment and done a detailed dy- Ahmed, E., Agiza, H.N., 1998. Dynamics of a Cournot game with n-competitors. Chaos,
Solitons Fractals 9, 1513–1517.
namic analysis for it. There are three boundary equilibriums and a Ahmed, E., Agiza, H.N., Hassan, S.Z., 2000. On modifications of Puu's dynamical duopoly.
unique interior equilibrium in this system. We have shown the instabil- Chaos, Solitons Fractals 11, 1025–1028.
ity of the boundary equilibriums and found the conditions for local sta- Bischi, G.I., Kopel, M., 2001. Equilibrium selection in a nonlinear duopoly game with
adaptive expectations. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 46, 73–100.
bility of the interior equilibrium by Schur–Cohn Criterion. We have Bischi, G.I., Naimzada, A., 1999. Global analysis of a dynamic duopoly game with bounded
made similar numerical simulations for the system evolution as done rationality. In: Filar, J.A., Gaitsgory, V., Mizukami, K. (Eds.), Advanced in Dynamics
in other existing work on classic Cournot games for output competition, Games and Application. Birkhauser, pp. 361–386.
Cournot, A., 1838. Researches into the Mathematical Principles of the Theory of Wealth.
including bifurcation diagrams, phase portraits, stable regions and sen- Hachette, Paris.
sitivity to initial state. It is shown that a relatively high residual rate (or Ding, Z.W., Hang, Q.L., Tian, L.X., 2009. Analysis of the dynamics of Cournot team-game
low depreciation rate) can strengthen the system stability. It is observed with heterogeneous players. Appl. Math. Comput. 215, 1098–1105.
Ding, Z., Hang, Q., Yang, H., 2011. Analysis of the dynamics of multi-team Bertrand game
that the equilibrium of the system may loose stability via different bifur-
with heterogeneous players. Int. J. Syst. Sci. 42, 1047–1056.
cations, either flip bifurcation or Neimark–Sacker bifurcation. It is also Dubiel-Teleszynski, T., 2011. Nonlinear dynamics in a heterogeneous duopoly game with
shown that time-delayed feedback control can be used to stabilize the adjusting players and diseconomies of scale. Commun. Nonlinear Sci. Numer. Simul.
chaotic behaviors of the system. 16, 296–308.
Elabbasy, E.M., Agiza, H.N., Elsadany, A.A., 2009. Analysis of nonlinear triopoly game with
heterogeneous players. Comput. Math. Appl. 57, 488–499.
Acknowledgements Elaydi, S.N., 2005. An Introduction to Difference Equations. Springer, New York.
Fan, Y.Q., Xie, T., Du, J.G., 2012. Complex dynamics of duopoly game with heteroge-
neous players: a further analysis of the output model. Appl. Math. Comput.
We are very grateful to the anonymous referees for the valuable 218, 7829–7838.
comments and suggestions that greatly help us to improve the paper. Holyst, J.A., Urbanowicz, K., 2000. Chaos control in economical model by time-delayed
Financial support by the National Natural Science Foundation of feedback method. Physica A 287, 587–598.
Kopel, M., 1996. Simple and complex adjustment dynamics in Cournot duopoly models.
China (Nos. 71171098 and 51306072) and by the Jiangsu Provincial Chaos, Solitons Fractals 7, 2031–2048.
Fund of Philosophy and Social Sciences for Universities (No. 2010-2-8) Okuguchi, K., 1970. Adaptive expectations in an oligopoly model. Rev. Econ. Stud. 37,
is gratefully acknowledged. 233–237.
Puu, T., 1991. Chaos in duopoly pricing. Chaos, Solitons Fractals 1, 573–581.
Puu, T., 1996. Complex dynamics with three oligopolists. Chaos, Solitons Fractals 7,
References 2075–2081.
Puu, T., 1998. The chaotic duopolists revisited. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 33, 385–394.
Agiza, H.N., 1998. Explicit stability zones for Cournot game with 3 and 4 competitors. Rassenti, S., Reynolds, S.S., Smith, V.L., Szidarovszky, F., 2000. Adaptation and convergence
Chaos, Solitons Fractals 9, 1955–1966. of behavior in repeated experimental Cournot games. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 41,
Agiza, H.N., Elsadany, A.A., 2003. Nonlinear dynamics in the Cournot duopoly game with 117–146.
heterogeneous players. Physica A 320, 512–524. Rosser, J.B., 2002. The development of complex oligopoly dynamics theory. In: Puu,
Agiza, H.N., Elsadany, A.A., 2004. Chaotic dynamics in nonlinear duopoly game with T., Sushko, I. (Eds.), Oligopoly Dynamics: Models and Tools. Springer, Berlin,
heterogeneous players. Appl. Math. Comput. 149, 843–860. pp. 15–29.
Agiza, H.N., Bischi, G.I., Kopel, M., 1999. Multistability in a dynamic Cournot game with Szidarovszky, F., Okuguchi, K., 1988. A linear oligopoly model with adaptive expectations:
three oligopolists. Math. Comput. Simul. 51, 63–90. stability reconsidered. J. Econ. 48, 79–82.
Agiza, H.N., Hegazi, A.S., Elsadany, A.A., 2001. The dynamics of Bowley's model with Teocharis, R.D., 1960. On the stability of the Cournot solution of the oligopoly problem.
bounded rationality. Chaos, Solitons Fractals 12, 1705–1717. Rev. Econ. Stud. 27, 133–134.
Agiza, H.N., Hegazi, A.S., Elsadany, A.A., 2002. Complex dynamics and synchronization of a Zhang, J.X., Da, Q.L., Wang, Y.H., 2007. Analysis of nonlinear duopoly game with heteroge-
duopoly game with bounded rationality. Math. Comput. Simul. 58, 133–146. neous players. Econ. Model. 24, 138–148.
Agliari, A., Gardini, L., Puu, T., 2000. The dynamics of a triopoly Cournot game. Chaos,
Solitons Fractals 11, 2531–2560.

You might also like