Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 14

THEODORE N.

GREENSTEIN North Carolina State University

Economic Dependence, Gender, and the Division of


Labor in the Home: A Replication and Extension

The fundamental question in the study of the gen- the phenomenon is more likely one of deviance
dered division of household labor has come to be neutralization than of gender display.
why, in the face of dramatic changes in women’s
employment and earnings, housework remains
‘‘women’s work.’’ As a possible answer to this The past 15 years have seen a veritable explosion
question, Brines (1994) presented a provocative of research on the gendered division of household
conceptual model of the relationship between eco- labor. This time period has also seen dramatic in-
nomic dependence and the performance of house- creases in labor-force participation of married
work by wives and husbands. She concluded that women, with an increasing number of wives be-
the link between economic dependence and house- coming primary breadwinners in their households.
work follows rules of economic exchange for Despite these changes, however, married women
wives, but among husbands, a gender display still do the majority of housework. In the face of
model is operative. This paper replicates and ex- these shifts from traditional gender-based eco-
tends Brines’ model by (a) replicating her work nomic roles, the fundamental question in this area
using a different data set; (b) adding additional has come to be: Why does housework remain
women’s work?
controls to the model, including a measure of gen-
The consensus of the empirical literature is that
der ideology; and (c) modeling a distributional
the division of household labor tends to be rela-
(as opposed to absolute) measure of housework.
tively traditional. Wives perform a far greater pro-
For a measure of hours spent doing housework,
portion of household tasks than do their husbands
the results of my analyses are consistent with
in households where the wife earns more than her
Brines’ suggestion of separate gender-specific husband (Atkinson & Boles, 1984) and even in
processes linking economic dependence and households where the husband is not employed
amount of housework performed. For a distribu- (Brayfield, 1992). This combination of market and
tional measure of housework, on the other hand, nonmarket work is likely to force married women
my analyses contradict Brines’ findings and sug- into working what Hochschild called the ‘‘second-
gest that both husbands and wives are acting to shift’’ (Hochschild, 1989).
neutralize a nonnormative provider role when Not only do married women perform far more
they do housework. Further analyses suggest that household labor than their husbands; the kinds of
household tasks that wives and husbands perform
Department of Sociology & Anthropology, North Carolina differ. Many researchers (for example, Blair &
State University, Raleigh, NC 27695-8107 (tedpgreenstein@ Lichter, 1991; Brayfield, 1992; Lennon & Rosen-
ncsu.edu).
field, 1994; Mederer, 1993) have noted that house-
Key Words: division of household labor, economic depen- hold labor remains highly segregated by sex.
dence, housework. Women primarily do the tasks that traditionally

322 Journal of Marriage and the Family 62 (May 2000): 322–335


Economic Dependence, Gender, and the Division of Labor 323

have been thought of as ‘‘women’s work’’ (e.g., oneself with regard to marital and family roles
cooking, laundry, housecleaning), whereas men traditionally linked to gender. Gender ideology
primarily do ‘‘male’’ tasks (e.g., yard work, auto can be distinguished from gender identity, which
maintenance). Lennon and Rosenfield reported Goffman (1977, p. 315) suggested is ‘‘the deepest
that men do about 70% of the traditionally male sense of what one is,’’ in that gender identities are
tasks, whereas women perform about 75% of the self-definitions such as male or female, whereas
traditionally female tasks. ideologies are the elements that make up that def-
To explain these gender-based inequalities in inition. Two men who think of themselves as male
task allocation and in task type, social scientists (their gender identity) can have different ideas
have developed at least four major conceptual ap- about what being male implies (their gender ide-
proaches. Each of these perspectives (with the ex- ologies). One man may assert that being male
ception of the gender ideology perspective) im- means believing that domestic labor is women’s
plicitly or explicitly assumes that housework is work, whereas another man may feel that being
seen as an undesirable task and that husbands and male means doing an equal share of household
wives attempt to minimize the amount of house- work. Marriage and other intimate relationships
work they do. Each of the four approaches sug- provide arenas in which these ideologies are
gests processes or factors that affect this division played out. In addition to its manifest functions of
of household labor. providing emotional and economic support and
The relative resources (or resource bargaining) enhancing childbearing and childrearing, marriage
approach takes an exchange-based perspective. also serves the latent function of providing an op-
The division of household labor is seen to result portunity for husbands and wives to behave in
from implicit negotiation between spouses over ways that validate their identities as male and fe-
inputs (e.g., earnings) and outcomes (e.g., who male, that is, to display the visible aspects of their
does the housework) in the household. In general, gender ideologies.
the research literature supports this perspective Scholars employing this perspective have as-
(for example, see Blair & Lichter, 1991; Ferree, sumed that activities such as the routine perfor-
1991; Kamo, 1988). The relative resources ap- mance (or nonperformance) of household chores
proach might account for the observation that will reflect the gender ideologies of husbands and
housework remains women’s work by arguing that wives. Many researchers have hypothesized that
because wives tend to bring fewer resources into the division of household labor among couples
the negotiation process, they are less able to pro- who hold more traditional beliefs about gender
duce an outcome in which the housework is equal- and marital roles will be relatively traditional (that
ly divided between themselves and their husbands. is, the wife will do the bulk of the domestic labor),
The relative resources approach would seem to whereas couples holding less traditional (i.e.,
suggest that recent increases in the earnings levels more egalitarian) ideologies will have a more bal-
of wives should have produced proportional de- anced division of labor. The findings of studies
creases in the amount of housework wives do, but employing the gender ideology perspective gen-
longitudinal data do not seem to support this hy- erally have been consistent with this prediction
pothesis. (e.g., Blair & Lichter, 1991; Hiller & Philliber,
The time availability perspective draws on hu- 1986; Kamo, 1988; Presser, 1994; Sanchez, 1994);
man capital theory (for example, see Becker, husbands holding more egalitarian gender ideol-
1991) and focuses on how family members’ time ogies tend to perform more hours of housework
is allocated between market and domestic work. and a greater proportion of household labor,
This perspective implies that there should be a whereas traditionally oriented husbands tend to do
strong association between the number of hours a less. Some researchers, however, have either
wife works outside the home and the number of failed to find such an effect (e.g., Coverman,
hours she spends doing domestic work. Although 1985; Crouter, Perry-Jenkins, Huston, & McHale,
most studies find that employed wives spend a 1987; Geerken & Gove, 1983) or found an effect
decreased number of hours doing housework, only in particular situations (e.g., Blair & Johnson,
these differences tend to be small. The time avail- 1992; Coltrane & Ishii-Kunz, 1992). In general, it
ability approach, therefore, does little to explain appears that studies examining the absolute
why housework remains women’s work. amount of housework (e.g., those that have ex-
The third approach is that of gender ideology. amined the number of hours per week spent doing
Gender ideologies are how a person identifies housework) do not tend to find effects of gender
324 Journal of Marriage and the Family

ideology on husbands’ contributions to house- I find problematic Brines’ contention that men
work, whereas those that have studied relative and women use different processes to relate their
contributions to housework (e.g., husbands’ per- economic dependence to the amount of house-
centage of total hours spent on household tasks) work they perform. Her explanation of this dif-
typically do find effects of ideology. A gender- ference was a structural one, based on what she
ideology–based explanation of why housework re- saw as differences in how ‘‘manhood’’ and
mains women’s work might suggest that although ‘‘womanhood’’ are culturally defined. Brines con-
women’s ideologies have been changing, men’s tended that although manhood is an achieved sta-
have not. Supporting this explanation, research by tus (the boy ‘‘becomes’’ a man) womanhood is
Greenstein (1996a) indicated that the division of perceived as an ascribed status, because woman-
household labor approaches equality only in mar- hood is seen ‘‘as a natural condition, in part be-
riages where both the wife and the husband hold cause women’s bodies and reproductive capacities
nontraditional (egalitarian) gender ideologies. are seen as placing them closer to nature’’ (Brines,
The fourth approach to understanding the gen- 1994, p. 683). Thus, she argued, nonnormative
dered division of household labor, the economic economic roles pose a greater threat to the iden-
dependency model (for example, see Brines, tities of dependent husbands than to breadwinner
1994), suggests that housework is women’s work wives. The result is that husbands and wives tend
because wives are more likely to be economically to invoke two different gender-specific strategies
dependent on their husbands. Because of this de- to their behavior. The amount of housework wives
pendency, wives can be expected to allocate more do is predicted to be a positive monotonic func-
time to domestic work than can their husbands. tion of economic dependence; breadwinner wives
Brines’ (1994) findings provided support for this do not feel the need to overcompensate for their
model. She found a negative relationship between nonnormative economic role by doing more
the proportion of family income that wives earn housework than might be expected under a de-
and the amount of time they spend on housework. pendency model. However, dependent husbands
Brines suggested that two separate gender-spe- are theorized to react to their nonnormative role
cific processes link economic dependence and per- by doing less, not more, housework as their eco-
formance of housework. For wives, the relation- nomic dependence increases.
ship between economic dependence and The situation in households characterized by
housework follows basic exchange principles: As breadwinner wives and dependent husbands, then,
wives’ economic dependence decreases, the is one in which the amount of housework per-
amount of housework they do (measured in hours formed by both the wife and the husband decreas-
per week) also decreases. Brines called this the es as the wife’s share of household income in-
dependency perspective. In her analyses of data creases. There are a number of mechanisms
from the Panel Study of Income Dynamics through which this outcome might occur that do
(PSID), Brines found a negative linear relation- not implicate tenuous assumptions about the cul-
ship between the wives’ proportion of family tural framing of manhood and threats to claimed
earnings and the number of hours of housework identities. Specifically, it seems likely that in
they performed per week. households where the wife is the primary bread-
Brines argued that a different process is at winner, a greater share of market earnings is di-
work for husbands. Here, she found a curvilinear rected toward purchasing household goods and
relationship in which husbands at the extremes of services in the market, thus resulting in fewer total
the dependence continuum do the least house- hours of housework performed in households with
work, whereas husbands whose earnings are ap- breadwinner wives and dependent husbands. Al-
proximately equal to those of their wives do the though Brines did control for restaurant meal ex-
most. Her explanation of this result is based on penditures in her analyses, she assumed a non-
what she called the ‘‘gender display’’ perspective. additive effect, that is, that the consumption of
Under this reasoning, couples who violate the tra- market goods and services affects the division of
ditional structure of the breadwinner husband with household labor in the same manner for all types
a dependent wife might be expected to resort to of marriages.
more traditional divisions of housework to The purposes of this paper are fourfold. First,
achieve ‘‘gender accountability’’ in terms of how I attempted to replicate Brines’ findings, which
they are viewed by their partners, their friends, were based on the Panel Study of Income Dynam-
and themselves. ics (PSID), using the National Survey of Families
Economic Dependence, Gender, and the Division of Labor 325

and Households (NSFH; Sweet, Bumpass, & Call, that when the gender ideologies of the wives and
1988) data set. There are at least two advantages husbands are taken into account, the gender dis-
to using the NSFH data for this project. First, play effect will be minimized, or it may be that
whereas the PSID asks a global question concern- gender ideology functions as a moderating or con-
ing the amount of housework the respondent per- trol variable in the gender display process. Con-
forms (‘‘About how much time do you spend on sider the possibility that the operation of the gen-
housework in an average week [excluding child der display process is contingent on gender
care]—I mean time spent cooking, cleaning, and ideology. It may be that traditional husbands and
doing other work around the house?’’), the NSFH wives who occupy nontraditional provider roles
(as detailed below) asks a series of questions may feel compelled to resort to more traditional
about nine different household activities. Second, divisions of housework to achieve ‘‘gender ac-
the NSFH includes measures of gender ideology countability’’ but that nontraditional husbands and
that allow us to study these effects on the process wives do not.
of the division of housework. Third, I examined Brines’ models when the de-
On the other hand, there are limitations in the pendent variable of interest, housework, is mea-
NSFH data as well. Unlike the PSID, which gath- sured on a distributional or relative (as opposed
ered extensive information about work history, to absolute) basis. In Brines’ analyses, the depen-
there is no detailed information in the NSFH dent measure of housework is the self-reported
about unemployment spells. Thus, although number of hours of household tasks performed per
Brines was able to assess the effects of short- and week. From a sociological viewpoint, however,
long-term joblessness, I cannot. Second, the there are conceptual advantages to employing a
NSFH does not provide specific information con- distributional (that is, relative as opposed to ab-
cerning the reasons why a respondent might be solute) measure of housework. There are many
out of the labor force. Brines was able to limit her factors that might operate to affect the number of
analyses to marriages in which neither partner was hours of housework performed by wives and hus-
jobless because of retirement, physical disability, bands: preferences for cleanliness or elaborate
schooling, or confinement to an institution; I was meals; work schedules that dictate dining out; de-
able only to crudely approximate these conditions mand for domestic labor in terms of home size
by restricting my sample to married couples where and complexity; and relative preferences for non-
both spouses were under age 65 and neither market (domestic) goods and services as opposed
spouse’s ability to hold paid employment or per- to those purchased in the market.
form housework was affected by disability or en- On the other hand, analyses of a distributional
rollment in an educational institution. measure of housework—for example, the per-
Second, I have added additional conceptually centage of total housework hours performed by
relevant controls to the basic model. In an attempt wives and their husbands—are more likely to cap-
to see whether the findings in Brines’ analyses ture the distributive justice or equity aspects of the
were caused by variables not included in the mod- division of housework. Because an important
el, I estimated models that added controls for fac- thrust of the literature on household labor has
tors that are likely to be related to the division of been the interpretation of reactions to inequalities
housework. I included terms for region of resi- in the division of household labor in the context
dence and whether the couple resides in a met- of equity (for example, see Greenstein, 1996b;
ropolitan area because it seems likely that the di- Sanchez, 1994; Thompson, 1991), it may be
vision of housework may vary by region and worthwhile to conceptualize the relationship be-
whether the residence is urban. I added a dummy tween dependence and housework within this
variable indicating Hispanic background. I includ- framework. Regardless of how much total domes-
ed a second-order term for number of children in tic labor is performed, it seems reasonable that
the household because the literature (e.g., Kamo, any justice phenomena that might operate in terms
1991) suggests that the effect of the number of of the division of housework are likely to reflect
children on the amount of housework is nonlinear. the relative (as opposed to actual) amounts of
Most important, I added an indicator of gender housework performed.
ideology to the model. It seems reasonable to as- My fourth goal was to recast this problem in
sume that if the phenomenon Brines observed is, the more general context of deviance neutraliza-
in fact, a gender display, its operation is somehow tion (Goode, 1978; Sykes & Matza, 1957). My
related to gender ideology. It may be, for example, model of this problem suggests that when a rela-
326 Journal of Marriage and the Family

tive or distributive measure of housework is con- Dependent Variables


sidered, wives and husbands respond in the same
way when they find themselves in nonnormative Indicators of housework. Each spouse was asked
provider roles in the family. I predicted that both to indicate ‘‘the approximate number of hours per
husbands and wives would engage in deviance week that you, your spouse/partner, or others in
neutralization to reduce the costs of being per- the household normally spend’’ preparing meals,
ceived as deviant. This model argues that both washing dishes, cleaning house, doing outdoor
tasks, shopping, washing and ironing, paying bills,
breadwinner wives and dependent husbands will
doing auto maintenance, and driving other house-
react to their nonnormative role by exaggerating
hold members to work and school. I calculated
the stereotypical level of housework that they per-
total hours spent doing all tasks by wives, hus-
form. Breadwinner wives, according to this mod- bands, related children in the household, and oth-
el, would do more housework than expected from ers in the household. I also calculated relative or
a linear dependency model, whereas dependent distributional versions of these measures by com-
husbands would do less. puting the proportion of all hours spent on these
Atkinson and Boles (1984) introduced this idea tasks that the husband and wife performed.
to the literature in a study of marriages that were To minimize the number of cases lost because
organized around the wife’s career. They found of missing data on the household task items, miss-
that husbands and wives used the ‘‘concealing’’ ing responses to the task items were coded as hav-
and ‘‘covering’’ processes identified by Goffman ing spent 0 hours in that activity for respondents
(1963) to help reduce the stigma of their deviant who answered at least seven of the nine individual
roles. Husbands concealed by limiting their social tasks. Those who responded ‘‘some time spent
interaction and by remaining silent about their (amount of time unspecified)’’ were coded as hav-
wives’ careers, for example; they also covered by ing spent 1 hour in that activity. I also experi-
making humorous remarks about their wives’ ca- mented with alternative methods of dealing with
reers. Although Atkinson and Boles (1984, p. 865) the missing data, for example, coding all missing
noted that ‘‘wives appeared to emphasize some data as 0 hours and substituting the mean value
aspects of their traditional role as much as possi- for the ‘‘some amount spent (amount of time un-
ble to make up for their participation in a tradi- specified)’’ response. Consistent with the findings
tionally male role,’’ the design of their study pre- of South and Spitze (1994) from this same data
cluded a comparison of the relative amounts of set, I found that the treatment of the missing data
housework performed by breadwinner and depen- essentially did not affect my substantive conclu-
dent wives. The NSFH data allow such a com- sions.
parison. Inspection of the NSFH housework data indi-
cates numerous respondents who reported total
hours in domestic plus market labor of more than
DATA AND MEASUREMENT 168 hours per week. Such responses may reflect
invalidity in the self-reports of hours spent in
The data for these analyses came from the first housework or (more likely) the fact that respon-
wave of the National Survey of Families and dents performed many household tasks concur-
Households, a national probability sample of rently. To adjust for this problem, I coded any
13,017 adult respondents interviewed in 1987 or respondent who reported spending more than 100
1988. In married couple and cohabiting house- hours per week in any activity as having spent 100
holds, a questionnaire was also administered to hours in that activity. There are so few of these
the respondent’s spouse or partner. The analyses cases, however, that coding them to any plausible
here focus on the 2,912 married couples who pro- value has no effect on the substantive implications
vided codable responses to all of the measures in of the analyses.
the analyses. For each couple, both the husband
and wife were under age 65, and neither spouse
Independent Variables
was disabled or enrolled in an educational insti-
tution. All analyses used the NSFH couple Economic dependence. The measure of economic
weights to adjust for oversampling, differential dependence employed was the same used by
probabilities of selection, and differential response Brines (1994), originally suggested by Sørensen
rates. and McLanahan (1987), where economic depen-
Economic Dependence, Gender, and the Division of Labor 327

dency 5 (earningsself 2 earningspartner)/(earningsself (Kamo, 1991) suggests that the effects of the num-
1 earningspartner). The potential values of this mea- ber of children on the amount and division of
sure range from 21, which indicates that the re- housework may be nonlinear. Relative resources
spondent is completely dependent on his or her theory suggests that both the respondent’s educa-
spouse for economic support, to 11, meaning that tion in years and his or her hours employed per
the respondent provides complete earned-income week should affect the division of household la-
support to his or her spouse; a value of 0 means bor. The logged value of total family income was
that neither partner is economically dependent on included. Finally, because it is possible that the
the other, that is, that the partners have equal earn- division of housework varies across ethnic, re-
ings. Note that this measure is perfectly correlated gional, and urban-rural groups, I included mea-
with wife’s (or husband’s) proportion of family sures of respondent’s race, region of residence,
earnings (assuming no other earners in the fami- and whether the couple lived in an SMSA.
ly).
RESULTS
Traditionalism. NSFH respondents were asked a
series of questions that were used to construct a
Descriptive Statistics
summated scale of gender ideology. On a 1–7
scale where 1 5 strongly approve and 7 5 strong- Table 1 presents weighted means and standard de-
ly disapprove, respondents were asked how much viations for the entire sample of couples. Overall,
they approved of ‘‘mothers who work full-time the 2,912 marriages and the wives and husbands
when their youngest child is under age 5’’ and are fairly representative of the population of mar-
‘‘mothers who work part-time when their youn- riages that existed and the men and women who
gest child is under age 5.’’ On a 1–5 scale, where were married during the study period (1987–
1 5 strongly agree and 5 5 strongly disagree, 1988). The couples had been married an average
respondents were also asked how much they of 17 years. About 70% lived in metropolitan ar-
agreed with the following four items: ‘‘It is much eas. The couples averaged about 1.5 children.
better for everyone if the man earns the main liv- Mean total family income was about $38,000.
ing and the woman takes care of the home and Children in the households performed, on average,
family’’; ‘‘Preschool children are likely to suffer about 3 hours of housework per week, whereas
if their mother is employed’’; ‘‘Parents should en- others (over the age of 19 years) in the household
courage just as much independence from their contributed about 1 hour.
daughters as their sons’’; and ‘‘If a husband and The husbands’ average age was about 40 years;
wife both work full-time, they should share house- wives were about 2.5 years younger. About 8% of
work tasks equally.’’ Appropriate item scoring the wives and husbands were African American,
was reversed to produce a scale where higher and about 6% were Hispanic. The husbands and
scores indicate more traditional gender ideologies. their wives tended to have some postsecondary
Because the individual items had different ranges, education, with means of 13.3 and 13 years of
the items were first standardized and then formal education respectively. Wives average
summed, yielding a Cronbach’s a of .68 for the about 38 hours of housework (about 64% of the
wives and .66 for the husbands. The summated total) per week, whereas husbands average about
scores were standardized to a mean of 100 and a 17 hours. Wives average about 24 hours per week
standard deviation of 15. in market labor; husbands averaged about 40
hours.
The economic dependence scores indicate, as
Control Variables
expected, that wives tended to be economically
There are a number of background characteristics dependent on their husbands. The wives, on av-
of the wives, husbands, and their marriages that I erage, earned about 28% of total couple income.
included in the model as statistical controls. Num- The wife earned at least 40% of the couple’s in-
ber of related children in the household is includ- come in about 31% of the couples and had earn-
ed because the number of children in the house- ings at least twice that of her husband in about
hold undoubtedly affects the amount (and 6% of the couples.
probably the distribution) of housework. A One issue that should be considered with these
squared term for the number of children was in- data is the problem of possible sample selection
cluded in the models because the literature bias resulting, in part, from the structure of the
328 Journal of Marriage and the Family

TABLE 1. DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS

Variable Couple Characteristics

Duration of marriage (in years) 16.93 (11.02)


Region of residence
Northeast 19.0%
North Central 27.6%
South 33.3%
West 20.1%
Residing in metropolitan area 70.6%
Number of related children in household 1.29 (1.26)
Total family income $50,123 ($50,790)
Hours per week of housework by children 3.07 (8.04)
Hours per week of housework by others 1.59 (10.71)
Wives Husbands
Age (in years) 38.06 (10.50) 40.51 (10.93)
Race
African American 5.4% 5.8%
Hispanic 6.2% 6.2%
White, non-Hispanic and other 88.4% 88.0%
Education (in years) 13.01 (2.43) 13.35 (2.79)
Economic dependence 2.468 .468
Housework
Total hours of housework per week 37.31 (22.56) 16.67 (14.53)
Percentage of all hours spent on housework 63.5% 30.3%
Market labor hours per week 24.09 (19.24) 42.53 (16.15)
Traditionalism score 98.79 (14.97) 99.39 (15.26)
Note: Unweighted N 5 2,912 married couples for all analyses. Table entries are means (percentages for categorical
variables) and, in parentheses, standard deviations.

NSFH interviews. The married couples included two figures representing the relationship between
in these analyses were composed of a primary re- wives’ economic dependence and hours of house-
spondent (either the husband or wife) and a sec- work performed (in Figure 1) and between wives’
ondary respondent (in these analyses, the primary economic dependence and proportion of hours of
respondent’s spouse). Of the 6,785 married, housework performed (in Figure 2). Note that Fig-
spouse-present, primary respondents in NSFH ure 1 suggests a generally negative relationship
(Wave 1), 5,648 had spouses who completed at between wives’ economic dependence and the
least part of the secondary respondents’ interview. number of hours of housework performed per
Comparison of background characteristics of cou- week (wives who have no earnings perform, on
ples who provided codable responses to all vari- average, about 45 hours of housework per week,
ables in these analyses to those who did not shows whereas wives who are the sole earners perform
that although there are some statistically signifi-
about 30 hours) and a weak positive relationship
cant differences between the two groups, there are
for husbands (husbands who have no earnings
no substantial or systematic differences, especially
on those variables central to these analyses. The perform about 18 hours of housework per week,
wives in the analytic sample, for example, per- whereas those who are the sole earners perform
formed an average of 37.6 hours of household la- about 15 hours).
bor and 33.1 hours of market labor per week, The relationships between wives’ economic
compared with 37.8 and 31.9 hours for those dependence and proportion of total hours of
wives not in the analytic sample. Husbands in the housework performed presents a different picture.
analytic sample performed about 17.7 hours of Here, the relationship for wives is decidedly non-
housework and 44.4 hours of market labor, com- linear, as is the relationship for husbands. These
pared with 17.6 and 41.4 hours for those husbands figures represent bivarate relationships, however;
not in the analytic sample. the following analyses add a number of theoreti-
For comparison to Brines’ analyses, I present cally relevant predictors to the model.
Economic Dependence, Gender, and the Division of Labor 329

FIGURE 1. OBSERVED HOURS OF HOUSEWORK FIGURE 2. OBSERVED PROPORTION OF HOUSEWORK


PERFORMED PER WEEK BY HUSBANDS AND WIVES BY PERFORMED BY HUSBANDS AND WIVES BY LEVEL OF
LEVEL OF WIFE’S ECONOMIC DEPENDENCE WIFE’S ECONOMIC DEPENDENCE

Replication
tially similar to Brines’. In particular, I observed
The analyses presenting the replication appear as a linear negative relationship between wives’ eco-
Model I in Table 2 and Table 3 for wives and nomic dependence and amount of housework per-
husbands, respectively. All of these analyses use formed (as in Brines’ analyses, the second- and
the seemingly unrelated regressions (SUR) tech- third-order effects of economic dependence did
nique to estimate the effects of the independent not approach statistical significance and are not
and control variables on the dependent measures included in Model I); this relationship is depicted
of housework. The SUR technique is especially graphically in Figure 1. Thus, I draw the same
appropriate for situations where the error distur- conclusion from Model I that Brines does: The
bances across comparable equations are assumed linear dependency model provides the best fit to
to be correlated because of unmeasured charac- the wives’ data. Wives’ hours of housework de-
teristics common to each model. In these analyses, creases as their economic transfer to their hus-
I assume that there are unmeasured (and probably bands increases.
unmeasurable) characteristics of the marriages and My results for husbands (Model I in Table 3)
the households that are related to the division of are also similar to those obtained by Brines. As
housework. Thus, Model I in Table 2 (wives’ data) can be seen in Figure 1, there is a second-order
and Model I in Table 3 (husbands’ data) are com- curvilinear relationship between economic depen-
parable and are estimated jointly using SUR, as dence and husbands’ hours of housework in the
are the three other comparable models. The prin- same inverted U-shape she observed in the PSID
cipal advantage of the SUR technique in these data. As husbands’ economic dependence increas-
analyses is that it allows for more efficient esti- es, their housework contributions also increase,
mators of the parameters than does OLS regres- but only to a point; around the midrange of de-
sion. pendence, the husbands’ housework contributions
Model 1 in Table 2 presents a replication of begin to decline. Brines interpreted this result as
Brines’ analyses for wives. My results are essen- evidence of the gender display model.
330 Journal of Marriage and the Family

TABLE 2. SUR MODELS PREDICTING MEASURES OF HOUSEWORK FOR WIVES

Variable Model I Model II Model III Model IV Model V

Adjusted model R 2
.122* .138* .151* .163* .163*
Constant 46.33* 31.82* 59.18* 54.63* 53.22*
Economic dependence 23.36* 22.95* 23.88* 24.00* 24.01*
(Economic dependence)2 .49 .49 26.28* 6.08* 9.12*
Age .01 2.03 .00 2.01 2.01
African American 1.04 .82* 23.56* 23.89* 23.89*
Hispanic 25.89* .50 .50
Education 2.98* 2.86* 2.11 2.05 2.05
Number of children 2.73* 2.65* .63 .07 .07
(Number of children)2 .01 .16 .16
In (family income) .23 .39 .38 .53 .53
Housework by children .17* .15* 2.67* 2.69* 2.69*
Housework by others .07* .09* 2.27* 2.26* 2.26*
Hours employed per week 2.22* 2.20* 2.05* 2.05* 2.05*
Traditionalism .15* .03* .04*
In metropolitan area 23.14* 23.03* 23.03*
In Northeast 2.54 2.19 2.19
In South .84 4.07* 4.07*
In North Central .82 2.06 2.06
Interaction of traditionalism 2.03
and dependence2
Note: Sample size for all analyses 2,912. * 5 coefficient that is at least twice its standard error. Cell entries are metric
(unstandardized) regression coefficients. Model I 5 hours of housework per week; Model II 5 hours of housework per
week, expanded; Model III 5 % of total housework hours per week; Model IV 5 % of total housework hours per week,
expanded; Model V 5 % of total housework hours per week, expanded.

TABLE 3. SUR MODELS PREDICTING MEASURES OF HOUSEWORK FOR HUSBANDS

Variable Model I Model II Model III Model IV Model V

Adjusted model R2 .056* .061* .100* .115* .115*


Constant 24.91* 30.04* 38.08* 42.00* 44.10*
Economic dependence 21.77* 21.66* 24.22* 24.30* 24.29*
(Economic dependence)2 22.16* 21.74* 26.19* 25.83* 210.40*
Age 2.12* 2.09* 2.13* 2.13 2.13*
African American 3.66* 3.74* 2.41 2.73* 2.74*
Hispanic .34 .47 .48
Education .11 .04 .13 .12 .13
Number of children 2.13 1.17* 21.21* 21.69* 21.68*
(Number of children)2 2.34* .11 .11
Ln (family income) .01 2.08 .46 .38 .37
Housework by children .30* .31* 2.18* 2.18* 2.18*
Housework by others .04 .04 2.14* 2.15* 2.15*
Hours employed per week 2.10* 2.10* 2.04* 2.04* 2.04*
Traditionalism 2.05* 2.03* 2.05*
In metropolitan area .26 2.38* 2.38*
In Northeast 21.07 22.56* 22.59*
In South 21.47* 23.43* 23.46*
In North Central 2.40 21.79 21.81
Interaction of traditionalism .05
and dependence2
Note: Sample size for all analyses 2,912. * 5 coefficient that is at least twice its standard error. Cell entries are metric
(unstandardized) regression coefficients. Model I 5 hours of housework per week; Model II 5 hours of housework per
week, expanded; Model III 5 % of total housework hours per week; Model IV 5 % of total housework hours per week,
expanded; Model V 5 % of total housework hours per week, expanded.
Economic Dependence, Gender, and the Division of Labor 331

FIGURE 3. PREDICTED HOURS OF HOUSEWORK FIGURE 4. PREDICTED PROPORTION OF HOUSEWORK


PERFORMED PER WEEK BY HUSBANDS AND WIVES BY PERFORMED BY HUSBANDS AND WIVES BY LEVEL OF
LEVEL OF WIFE’S ECONOMIC DEPENDENCE WIFE’S ECONOMIC DEPENDENCE

separate gender-specific processes are supported.


Extension of the Model These relationships are depicted in Figure 3.

Models II in Tables 2 and 3 present the results of


Distributional Measures of Housework
an expanded model for wives and husbands, re-
spectively. Even with controls for region of resi- I present in Models III of Tables 2 and 3 analyses
dence, metropolitan residence, and gender ideol- analogous to those in Brines’ paper and in Models
ogy, the basic conclusions drawn from Models I I but employing a distributional measure of the
are maintained. We also see statistically significant division of housework: the percentage of all hours
effects of metropolitan residence (for wives), of housework that are performed by wives and
however, and, most important, effects of gender their husbands. Recall from Table 1 that wives, on
ideology. Consistent with conventional wisdom, average, contribute about 64% of all hours of
traditional wives perform more housework, housework, whereas husbands contribute about
whereas traditional husbands perform less. Both 30% (the remaining 6% is performed by children
Models II represent statistically significant in- and other household members).
creases in prediction power (R2) over the corre- Using this distributional measure of the divi-
sponding Models II. sion of housework, I obtained estimates for hus-
Model II demonstrates the same gender display bands similar to those in Model I. For husbands,
processes as noted in Model I. For wives, the lin- essentially the same conclusions drawn by Brines
ear effect of dependence on hours of housework and from my Models I can be drawn from the
suggests that an exchange process (rather than a Model II: a curvilinear (second-order) inverted U-
gender display process) is operating. For hus- shaped pattern suggesting a gender display pro-
bands, the squared term for economic dependence cess. This relationship is depicted in Figure 4.
is statistically significant, suggesting a gender dis- Starting from the right-hand side of the figure,
play process. Thus, even when additional controls husbands do progressively more housework until
are added to the model, Brines’ conclusions about just after the midway point of economic depen-
332 Journal of Marriage and the Family

dence, that is, the point at which husbands and wives, and a curvilinear (gender display) relation-
wives are earning approximately equal salaries. ship for husbands. Next, I extended the model by
After that point, even though husbands’ economic adding controls for region of residence, urbanness
dependence is increasing, they do progressively of residence, a second-degree term for number of
less housework. related children in the household (to test for non-
For wives, however, the results are not consis- linear effects), and gender ideology. Adding these
tent with Model I or Brines’ analyses. Contrary to controls did not change the finding that gender-
Brines’ findings, there is a statistically significant specific processes link economic dependence and
squared term for economic dependence. The sign number of hours of housework performed for
of the dependence terms suggests a U-shaped pat- married men and women.
tern (not inverted as in the case of the husbands). Nonetheless, when I extended the model to use
In other words, the effect of economic dependence a distributional (as opposed to absolute) measure
of wives on the distributional measure of house- of housework performed, I obtained results that
work also seems to be a gender display process. contradict Brines’ conclusion that ‘‘married men
Figure 2 suggest that as wives become less eco- and women appear to respond quite differently to
nomically dependent on their husbands, the pro- issues of dependency’’ (p. 682). When the depen-
portion of housework performed declines, reach- dent measure of housework is distributional (the
ing its minimum just past the midway point proportion of total hours spent on housework per-
(where wives and husbands are earning approxi- formed), I observed that breadwinner wives tend-
mately equal salaries). From that point, the pro- ed to do more housework than would be predicted
portion of housework performed by wives again under an economic dependency model, but that
turns upward. dependent husbands did less. In Brines’ terms,
In Models IV in Tables 2 and 3, I extend the both wives and their husbands are exhibiting a
model employing a distributional measure of gender display process when the outcome variable
housework by adding the same controls I em- is a proportion of total hours spent on housework.
ployed in Models II. Even with these additional That the same process seems to link economic
controls, the conclusions drawn from Models III dependence and proportion of housework per-
are upheld. Contrary to Brines’ findings using an formed by husbands and wives is a far more par-
absolute measure of housework, analyses employ- simonious finding than that of Brines. More im-
ing a distributional measure suggest both hus- portant than parsimony, however, is the question
bands and wives are exaggerating the stereotypi- of why this process is occurring. Is it gender dis-
cal level of housework performed. The play, or is it some other process? If it is a gender
breadwinner wives are doing more housework display process, we would expect that its opera-
than would be predicted under an economic de- tion is somehow related to gender ideology, but
pendency model, whereas the dependent husbands Model IV shows clearly that the relationship be-
do less. tween economic dependence and proportion of
housework performed is nonlinear even with a
measure of gender ideology in the model. Fur-
Interactive Effects of Gender Ideology
thermore, the lack of a statistically significant in-
In Models V, I add an interaction between the teraction term between gender ideology and the
squared term for dependence (for both wives and squared term for dependence in Model V suggests
husbands) and the gender ideology measure. This that the nonlinear effect is not conditional on ide-
effect is not statistically significant for either hus- ology. Nontraditional husbands are as likely to do
bands or wives. a smaller share (and nontraditional wives to do a
larger share) of household labor as traditional hus-
bands and wives.
DISCUSSION
The lack of effects of gender ideology on this
I began this paper by setting four objectives. First, ‘‘gender display’’ process leads me to interpret
I successfully replicated Brines’ analyses of the this finding in the more general context of devi-
PSID using data from the NSFH with hours of ance neutralization. As a result of their nonnor-
housework performed per week as the dependent mative economic roles, breadwinner wives and
variable. As in Brines’ paper, I observed a linear economically dependent husbands occupy deviant
(dependency) relationship between economic de- identities. Atkinson and Boles’ study showed just
pendence and hours of housework performed for how extreme reactions to these deviant identities
Economic Dependence, Gender, and the Division of Labor 333

can be. Speaking to a breadwinner wife, one even more common 20 years from now. There-
woman said ‘‘I’d rather die than end up like you’’ fore, it is reasonable to ask who, exactly, are these
(Atkinson & Boles, 1984, p. 864). In conversation couples characterized by wives who are primary
with a man whose wife was an office manager, breadwinners? Survey research in general, and
another man asked, ‘‘Does she manage you, too?’’ secondary analysis in particular, is ill-equipped to
(Atkinson & Boles, p. 864). answer this question, which is best answered by
One mechanism for neutralizing this deviant qualitative, in-depth studies, such as that con-
identity is to overcompensate for it by exagger- ducted by Atkinson and Boles.
ating behaviors or appearances that contradict the On the other hand, it is apparent that for the
deviant identity. Breadwinner wives might try to majority of married couples—those characterized
neutralize their deviant economic identity by do- by relatively traditional employment roles—the
ing far more housework than might be predicted relationship between economic dependence and
by the time availability or relative resources mod- performance of housework is essentially linear
els. Economically dependent husbands, on the and negative. For example, the predicted propor-
other hand, might attempt to neutralize their de- tion of housework performed by wives is highest
viant identity by doing far less housework than (about 68%) when wives are totally economically
these models would predict. These are precisely dependent upon their husbands; this figure falls in
the results observed in Models III and IV. The a generally linear fashion to about 59% toward
proportion of housework done by wives and their the midpoint of economic dependence (where
husbands is most equal at about the midpoint of wives and husbands have equal earnings). Simi-
the economic dependence continuum, that is, at larly, if we examine the predicted proportion of
the point where wives and husbands have approx- housework performed by husbands from the eco-
imately equal earnings. These inequalities in- nomic dependence midpoint (where husbands are
crease as we move away from the midpoint of predicted to perform about 35% of the house-
economic dependence in both directions, however. work) to the extreme right-hand side of Figure 4
Although dependent wives are predicted to do the (husbands who are completely economically de-
largest share of housework (about 68% of the to- pendent on their wives are predicted to perform
tal), the share of housework performed by wives about 26% of the housework), we also notice a
decreases as their economic dependence decreas- generally linear downward trend.
es. Then, at about the midpoint of economic de- One question that might be raised about these
pendence, their share of housework starts increas- findings has to do with the composite nature of
ing so that the model predicts that wives who are the housework variable. As noted above, summing
primary breadwinners will do more housework the number of hours involved in each of nine
than wives who earn about the same amount as common household tasks creates the housework
their husbands. This overperformance of house- variable. It is conceivable that combining routine
work corroborates the notion that a deviance neu- (or ‘‘feminine’’) tasks with nonroutine (‘‘mascu-
tralization process is taking place. line’’) tasks in the measure of housework might
A similar process, albeit in the opposite direc- obscure the processes involved. It might be argued
tion, seems to occur among the husbands. Starting that an economically dependent husband who
from the right-hand side of Figure 4 and moving won’t do the dishes might be engaging in a gender
toward the left, the model predicts that economi- display, but for such a husband to cut back on his
cally dependent husbands will do the least house- yard work suggests a different process at work.
work (about 25% of the total) whereas husbands Additional analyses (not reported here) show a
who are sole breadwinners are predicted to do statistically significant curvilinear relationship be-
more of the total housework (about 33%). tween economic dependence and (a) proportion of
Although wives earned more than their hus- ‘‘feminine’’ tasks performed (preparing meals,
bands in about 15% of these couples, only about washing dishes, cleaning house, and washing and
4% of the wives earned as much as two thirds of ironing) and (b) proportion of ‘‘masculine’’ tasks
household income. Couples who are on the far performed (auto maintenance, outdoor tasks). A
right-hand side of Figure 4 (i.e., couples charac- similar relationship was noted for ‘‘gender-neu-
terized by a breadwinner wife and an economi- tral’’ tasks (paying bills, driving other household
cally dependent husband) are relatively unusual in members to work and school, and grocery shop-
today’s society, but are more common than they ping), although these effects failed to meet con-
were 20 years ago and will almost certainly be ventional levels of statistical significance. Thus,
334 Journal of Marriage and the Family

these analyses support the argument that the op- 4 suggest an interesting implication for future
erative process is one of deviance neutralization trends in gender equity in marriage. The couples
rather than gender display. that most closely approach an equal distribution
Another perspective that might be invoked to of housework tend to be those couples in which
explain these findings is Hochschild’s principle of the breadwinner role is shared, that is, those cou-
‘‘balancing.’’ Hochschild noted that although ples in which each spouse brings home about half
there was no statistically significant relationship of the family earnings. As marriages in this coun-
between a husband’s relative earnings and how try continue the trend toward dual-earner couples
much housework he performed, among the hus- with increasingly equal incomes, it would appear
bands in her study who earned less than their that a likely outcome would be a continuing trend
wives, none shared housework with their wives. toward equality in the household division of labor.
She explained this outcome by suggesting that ‘‘if
men lose power over women in one way, they NOTE
make up for it in another way. . . . In this way,
The National Survey of Families and Households was
they can maintain dominance over women. How funded by a grant (HD21009) from the Center for Pop-
much responsibility these men assumed at home ulation Research of the National Institute of Child
was thus related to the deeper issue of male pow- Health and Human Development. The survey was de-
er’’ (Hochschild, 1989, p. 221). The precise mech- signed and carried out at the Center for Demography
and Ecology at the University of Wisconsin, Madison,
anism through which this balancing process is under the direction of Larry Bumpass and James Sweet.
supposed to operate, however, is unclear. The Institute for Survey Research at Temple University
What do the findings of this study tell us about did the fieldwork. This paper has benefited from dis-
the relationship of economic dependence to per- cussions with Maxine P. Atkinson, Melissa R. Biber,
formance of housework by wives and their hus- Katherine Hyde, and Barbara J. Risman. The analyses
and interpretations herein are those of the author.
bands? First, in terms of the amount (hours) of
housework performed, they suggest that different
processes are operating for wives and husbands. REFERENCES
For wives, there appears to be a monotonic neg- Atkinson, M. P., & Boles, J. (1984). WASP (wives as
ative relationship between economic dependence senior partners). Journal of Marriage and the Family,
and hours of housework performed, with econom- 46, 861–870.
Becker G. S. (1991). A treatise on the family (Enlarged
ically dependent wives doing the most housework. ed.). Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
For husbands, there appears to be a nonlinear re- Blair, S. L., & Johnson, M. P. (1992). Wives’ percep-
lationship in which husbands married to women tions of the fairness of the division of household la-
with approximately equal earnings do the most bor: The intersection of housework and ideology.
Journal of Marriage and the Family, 54, 570–581.
housework. Blair, S. L., & Lichter, D. T. (1991). Measuring the di-
Second, in terms of the proportion of house- vision of household labor: gender segregation of
work performed, the data suggest that both wives housework among American couples. Journal of
and husbands who occupy nonnormative earner Family Issues, 12, 91–113.
roles (that is, breadwinner wives and dependent Brayfield, A. A. (1992). Employment resources and
housework in Canada. Journal of Marriage and the
husbands) seem to exaggerate the amount of Family, 54, 19–30.
housework they do in the direction of appearing Brines, J. (1994). Economic dependency, gender, and
more consistent with the norm for their gender. the division of labor at home. American Journal of
Third, the data strongly suggest that the effects Sociology, 100, 652–688.
Coltrane, S., & Ishii-Kunz, M. (1992). Men’s house-
of economic dependence on proportion of house- work: A life course perspective. Journal of Marriage
work performed might best be conceptualized as and the Family, 54, 43–57.
the result of a more general deviance-neutraliza- Coverman, S. (1985). Explaining husbands’participation
tion process rather than one specifically of gender in domestic labor. Sociological Quarterly, 26, 81–97.
display. There are two key pieces of evidence that Crouter, A. C., Perry-Jenkins, M., Huston, T. L., &
McHale, S. M. (1987). Processes underlying father-
these effects may not be gender processes. First, involvement in dual-earner and single-earner fami-
the curvilinear effects of economic dependence lies. Child Development, 23, 431–440.
are still present even when gender ideology is in- Ferree, M. M. (1991). The gender division of labor in
cluded in the model; and second, there is no in- two-earner marriages: Dimensions of variability and
change. Journal of Family Issues, 12, 158–180.
teraction between gender ideology and the curvi- Geerken, M., & Grove, W. (1983). At home and at
linear aspect of the relationship. work: The family’s allocation of labor. Beverly Hills,
The findings presented in Table 3 and Figure CA: Sage.
Economic Dependence, Gender, and the Division of Labor 335

Goffman, E. (1963). Stigma. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Mederer, H. J. (1993). Division of labor in two-earner
Prentice Hall. homes: Task accomplishment versus household man-
Goffman, E. (1977). The arrangement between the sex- agement as critical variables in perceptions about
es. Theory and Society, 4, 301–331. family work. Journal of Marriage and the Family,
Goode, E. (1978). Deviant behavior: An interactionist 55, 133–145.
approach. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall. Presser, H. B. (1994). Employment schedules among
Greenstein, T. N. (1996a). Husbands’ participation in dual-earner spouses and the division of household la-
domestic work: Interactive effects of husbands’ and bor by gender. American Sociological Review, 59,
wives’ gender ideologies. Journal of Marriage and 348–364.
the Family, 58, 585–595. Sanchez, L. (1994). Gender, labor allocations, and the
Greenstein, T. N. (1996b). Gender ideology and percep- psychology of entitlement in the home. Social Forc-
tions of the fairness of the division of household la- es, 73, 533–553.
bor: Effects on marital quality. Social Forces, 74, Sørensen, A., & McLanahan, S. (1987). Married wom-
1029–1042. en’s economic dependency, 1940–1980. American
Hiller, D. V., & Philliber, W. W. (1986). The division of Journal of Sociology, 93, 659–687.
labor in contemporary marriage: Expectations, per- South, S. J., & Spitze, G. D. (1994). Housework in mar-
ceptions, and performance. Social Problems, 33, ital and nonmarital households. American Sociologi-
191–201.
cal Review, 59, 327–347.
Hochschild, A., & Machung, A. (1989). The second
shift. New York: Viking. Sweet, J., Bumpass, L., & Call, V. (1988). The design
Kamo, Y. (1988). Determinants of household division and content of the National Survey of Families and
of labor: Resources, power, and ideology. Journal of Households. Madison, WI: Center for Demography
Family Issues, 9, 177–200. and Ecology.
Kamo, Y. (1991). A nonlinear effect of the number of Sykes, G. M., & Matza, D. (1957). Techniques of neu-
children on the division of household labor. Socio- tralization: A theory of delinquency. American Socio-
logical Perspectives, 34, 205–218. logical Review, 22, 664–670.
Lennon, M. C., & Rosenfield, S. (1994). Relative fair- Thompson, L. (1991). Family work: Women’s sense of
ness and the division of housework: The importance fairness. Journal of Family Issues, 12, 181–196.
of options. American Journal of Sociology, 100, 506– West, C., & Zimmerman, D. H. (1987). Doing gender.
531. Gender and Society, 1, 125–151.

You might also like