Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 8

ISSUE 2006/05

OCTOBER 2006
bruegelpolicybrief

SINGLE MARKET
TRAILS HOME BIAS
by Juan Delgado SUMMARY It is now 20 years since the Single Market Programme was launched
Research Fellow at Bruegel with the goal of eliminating barriers to the movement of goods, services, capi-
juan.delgado@bruegel.org
tal and people. Over this period the EU has made substantial progress through
a truly impressive legislative effort. But in the process have Europeans really
become more “European”? While large industries have embraced the opportu-
nities of the Single Market to become more international in outlook, Europeans
basically continue to shop, invest and work at home. And though equity mar-
kets are still making progress, the integration of product markets appears to
have stalled, and labour remains largely fragmented.
Home Bias in Product and Equity POLICY CHALLENGE
Markets Despite the improvements in integration of
40 50 60 70 80 90 100
European markets, home bias remains high.
While there was a fall in home bias in equity
%
markets during 2001-2003 not much has
Product Markets changed in product markets. This adds weight
to the argument that traditional internal mar-
US
2001 EU15 ket policies may have had their day and it is
time for a rethink. Policies for the 21st century
2003 must adapt to an increasingly service-oriented
and innovation-driven economy. The focus
Equity Markets should be on favouring entry and competi-
tion, facilitating the diffusion of innovation,
US and creating conditions for a further inte-
2001 EU15 gration of the value chains across Europe.
Reforms should also aim to reduce the
2003 imbalances in integration across countries
and across markets. A single currency can-
not deliver without a Single Market.
Source: Bruegel estimates based on
OECD & IMF CPIS.
SINGLE MARKET TRAILS HOME BIAS

THE Single Market Programme integration policies aim at remo- 1. MEASURING HOME BIAS
02 (SMP) was launched in the mid-
80s with the aim of enhancing
ving those obstacles that prevent
mobility of products, capital and We define “home bias” as the
bruegelpolicybrief

growth and competitiveness in people across borders. One sign of excessive consumption or absorp-
Europe through the creation of an success would be more consump- tion of domestically produced pro-
area without internal frontiers allo- tion of foreign goods, a rise in ducts, or excessive investment in
wing the “free movement of goods, foreign assets in investment port- domestic equity compared with
persons, services and capital”. folios, and an increase in foreign two theoretical benchmarks.
workers in national labour markets.
The end result should have been a  In the first one (a “Frictionless
more integrated Europe in which But just what would a fully integra- Economy”2), the share of a country
“home countries” were less rele- ted economy look like? This policy in any consumption basket is
vant in consumers’, investors’ and brief assesses in a simple way the determined by the size of its eco-
workers’ decisions. extent to which economic deci- nomy. This definition assumes that
sions have become less domestic in the absence of home bias consu-
But 20 years later, national borders and more European by looking at mers have equal access to and no
still matter and there is widespread the evolution of “home bias” in preferences for goods or assets
disillusion about what further pro- consumption, investment and from any part of the world.
gress can be expected. Some labour decisions. The same metho- Therefore, the amount of products
observers dismiss integration dology is applied to product and and assets from each country is
efforts as pointless and claim that equity markets, which allows the determined by the share of that
nations are here to stay. Others comparison of results across coun- country in the world production
argue that the economic model tries and across markets. The ana- and market capitalisation respecti-
1
See the European underpinning the SMP is exhausted lysis complements the previous vely.
Commission public and that a new approach to market issue of this series (Véron, 2006)
consultation on the integration is needed.1 which examined the meaning of A limitation of the first benchmark
Future of the Internal
Market at
“home” for European businesses. is that it ignores the role of dis-
http://ec.europa.eu/inte In spite of international specialisa- tance. Hence, it assumes that only
rnal_market/strategy/in tion and outsourcing, countries’ Section 1 presents a number of Australia’s weight in OECD produc-
dex_en.htm. consumption baskets and invest- indicators for home bias and analy- tion should determine the share of
2
ment portfolios still contain a pre- ses how the EU15 compare to Australian-produced products in,
For example, as
Germany accounts for dominant share of domestically other countries according to these say Hungarian total consumption.
9% of OECD production, produced products and domestic indicators. Section 2 looks at some This is obviously extreme.
German products assets (not to mention the predo- explanations for home bias and
should weight 9% in minance of national-born workers examines its evolution and econo-  The second benchmark (an
each consumption bas-
ket in the absence of
in national labour markets). This is mic consequences. Finally, section “Integrated Economy”3) recognises
home bias. In reality, commonly known as the “home 3 provides some policy recommen- the role of distance. It is based on
German products bias puzzle” (see Box 1). Market dations. actual trade data (which implicitly
account for 85% of
German consumption.
The home bias there- BOX 1
fore amounts to 76 per- THE ‘HOME BIAS PUZZLE’
centage points (85% The inability of economic theory to explain the empirical observation that consumers over-purchase domestically
minus 9%). produced goods and services and investors over-invest in domestic equity is known as the “home bias puzzle”.
3
For example, using The attempts to quantify and explain the “home bias puzzle” are pervasive in recent economic literature.
data on bilateral trade McCallum (1995) first estimated that the trade between Canadian provinces is 20 times greater than the trade
with other countries it between border US states and Canadian provinces, even if there were no substantial barriers to trade. Nitsch
is estimated that (2000) estimates that on average EU countries trade internally 7 to 10 times more that with partner countries
Germany would import
12% of its total
(after adjustment for size, distance and other variables). Equally, for asset holdings, Portes and Rey (2005)
consumption from a quantify the size and determinants of financial home bias. However, the explanation and policy implications of
country equal in size the existence of home bias are not fully convincing in the literature. Recent literature has explored the links bet-
and distance. The cur- ween trade and financial markets (see e.g. Obstfeld and Rogoff, 2000) in order to explain home bias in financial
rent share of domestic markets. Frictions in product markets could be responsible not only for home bias in product markets but also for
products in consump-
tion in Germany is 85%. the excessive home bias in equity markets that otherwise would not be consistent with the current degree of glo-
The home bias using balisation of financial markets. Lane and Milesi-Ferretti (2004) offer empirical evidence of this link. Finally, most
this benchmark is the- recent literature finds that incomplete contracts between final goods producers and intermediate suppliers, and
refore 73% (i.e. 85% lack of a common institutional setting, could play an important role in explaining home bias (Antras, 2003).
minus 12%).
SINGLE MARKET TRAILS HOME BIAS

reflects existing obstacles to EUROPEANS SHOP LOCALLY Economy” (Chart 2 in Fig. 1). As
trade) and defines a country’s
home bias as the difference bet-
Europeans have a strong bias for
goods and services produced
the EU15 countries’ share of
domestic products is well above 03

bruegelpolicybrief
ween what it trades with itself and within the EU. Of all the OECD pro- their share in OECD production,
what it would trade with a country ducts consumed in the EU15, 96% they appear to be highly home bia-
of similar size and distance.4 come from the EU15. The weight of sed. By contrast, the US which
nationally-produced goods and accounts for close to 45% of OECD
The two benchmarks can be calcu- services in domestic demand is production appears to be much
lated in a similar way for equity similar in the US. less home biased. The same is
holdings. (See Box 2 for formulae.) actually true, though to a lesser
The key question, however, is how extent, for the EU as a whole,
Neither of the benchmarks is per- much EU15 countries trade among whose home bias is only 60%.
fect and they involve a number of themselves. The answer is: Not a
caveats.5 The first one is great deal. On Introducing geographic distance
more straightforward but average, an EU15 generally reduces the home bias of
lacks realism. The second ‘Of all the OECD country spends EU countries but does not remove
is closer to reality but 86% on national it (Chart 3 in Fig. 1). Trade within
depends on estimated products consumed products, 10% on the typical EU country remains
parameters. in the EU15, 96% products from much higher than one would
other EU15 coun- expect in an “Integrated Economy”
We use OECD countries as a come from the EU15.’ tries and 4% on and trade among them, or with the
reference for integration. products from rest of the world, much lower.
The aim of taking such a broader other OECD countries (Chart 1 in Distance also changes the picture
sample is to analyze whether there Fig. 1). for the US, however in the opposite
are differences in integration bet- way: it now appears to be more
ween EU members and other coun- The first benchmark ignores geo- home biased than the countries of
tries. Intra-OECD imports account graphic distance, as would be the EU.
for 70 % of total OECD imports.6 appropriate in a “Frictionless
Fig. 1
Home Bias in Product Markets (%) (2003)
Chart 1 Chart 2 Chart 3
Domestic products in domestic demand Frictionless Economy Benchmark Integrated Economy Benchmark
40 50 60 70 80 90 100 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
4
The distance of a coun-
BE US BE try to itself converges
NL BE NL to zero when its size
diminishes. It increases
AT OECD AT with the geographical
HU NL HU size of the country.
CZ AT DE
5
DK HU DK For example, both
assume that all pro-
SE DE EU15 Avg ducts in the economy
PT CZ UK are fully tradable. This
NO EU15 Avg CZ assumption, although
DK SE unrealistic, provides a
GR benchmark for the
DE JP PT limits of integration.
FI SE FR
6
EU15 Avg FR GR The share varies howe-
UK OECD ver from country to
ES country e.g. while the
FR PT FI share of imports from
UK ES ES OECD countries in total
IT NO IT imports is between 80
GR and 85 percent in most
OECD JP EU states, it is around
US IT NO 60 percent in the US
JP FI US and 40 percent in
Japan.
Source: Bruegel estimates based on OECDand CEPII. SE, ES and NL (2002 data). OECD excluding Australia, New
Zealand, Korea, Ireland, Iceland, Poland, Slovak Republic, Switzerland and Turkey. EU15 excluding Ireland.
SINGLE MARKET TRAILS HOME BIAS

On a country-by-country basis, wealth is invested within the EU15 total OECD market capitalisation.
04 home bias is generally lower in
core EU15 countries (Netherlands,
which is slightly lower than the
share Americans invest within the
Home bias of the EU as a whole is
around 58%.
bruegelpolicybrief

Belgium, Austria and Germany) US.


than in the periphery (Greece, Italy, Distance in the case of equity hol-
Spain, Nordic countries). The average EU15 country invests dings is a proxy for transaction and
around 65% of its equity wealth at especially information costs.
Amongst new member states, the home, 18% in other EU15 countries Introducing distance into the pic-
Czech Republic and and 17% in other OECD ture does not affect the home bias
Hungary have a lower countries. On average, of EU countries much(Chart 3 in
degree of home bias ‘Home bias in EU15 countries invest at Fig. 2). However, it does change
than the EU15 average, the EU is similar home less than OECD the picture for the US, which now
which reflects the countries, which invest appears to be much more home
increasing integration to other OECD domestically 80% of their biased than the average EU coun-
of these countries with countries when equity wealth (Chart 1 in try.
Western Europe. Fig. 2).
we account for Within the EU there are large asym-
In conclusion, home country size and In a “Frictionless metries in the degree of diversifica-
bias remains very large Economy” (Chart 2 in Fig. tion: holdings of domestic equity
in the EU and it is simi- distance.’ 2), once again since EU15 range from 41% in Austria to 93% in
lar to other OECD coun- countries’ market capitali- Greece. Austria, Belgium, Italy,
tries when we account for country sation is small, their home bias Sweden and Germany invest the
size and distance. appears high. The US, even though least in domestic equity7 while
it invests more than EU countries Greece and Spain invest heavily in
EUROPEANS INVEST AT HOME at home, appears less home biased domestic equity. New Member
Europeans also invest heavily in than the typical EU15 country States’ equity wealth is mainly
the EU15: 83% of their equity since it accounts for half of the domestic.

Fig. 2
Home Bias in Equity Markets (%) (2003)
Chart 1 Chart 2 Chart 3
Domestic Equity in Equity Holdings Frictionless Economy Benchmark Integrated Economy Benchmark

30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100

BE US BE
AT BE AT
NO AT NO
SE NO DE
DE OECD SE
IT DE IT
FI SE FI
DK IT DK
EU15 Avg FI EU15 Avg
CH UK FR
FR DK UK
UK EU15 Avg CH
OECD CH OECD
ES FR JP
US JP US
7 JP ES ES
Austria and Italy are
amongst the smallest CZ CZ CZ
financial markets in the GR GR GR
EU, what to some HU HU HU
extent might explain PL
their higher investment
PL PL
in foreign assets.
Source: Bruegel estimates based on IMF CPIS, Eurostat and CEPII. OECD excluding Korea, Turkey, New Zealand,
Ireland, Luxembourg, Iceland, Netherlands and Portugal. EU15 excluding Ireland, Luxembourg, Netherlands and
SINGLE MARKET TRAILS HOME BIAS

Home bias in holdings of domestic 2.WHAT IS WRONG WITH Home bias in product markets has
equity by EU countries is lower
than in trade but still large if one
HOME BIAS? not substantially changed over the
past few years (Fig. 3). 05

bruegelpolicybrief
takes into account that the costs of Summing up, Europeans work, Unfortunately, long enough series
investing abroad are much lower mostly shop, and even to a large including services are not availa-
than the costs of goods and servi- extent invest at home. Despite the ble. However, if we look only at
ces trade. process of European integration, goods (Fig. 4) we see that home
the degree of home bias in the bias in the EU decreased substan-
EUROPEANS DO NOT TRAVEL TO WORK three markets remains considera- tially between the mid-90s and
The same methodology can be ble. 2000 but the momentum decrea-
used for assessing home bias on sed afterwards. In fact, intra-EU
the labour market but the results But are things changing as a trade in goods grew faster than
are not very informative since the consequence of the Single Market GDP between the mid-90s and
geographical mobility of labour is Programme? Not much. 2000, but it stalled in early 2000.
very low in Europe. This applies not
only cross border but also within- While significant, the
countries, especially compared to Fig. 3 effect of the Single Market
the US. Home bias(%) in product markets in an on trade in goods – as well
Integrated Economy: US vs EU15 as those of overall liberali-
The share of Europeans working in 100 sation – has thus not been
an EU country different to their US sustained enough to com-
90
home country is less than two per EU 80 pensate the move to a
cent. Given the low mobility of wor- 70 more service-based eco-
kers, the ranking of countries 60 nomy. Therefore, home
according to any home bias indica- 50 bias in product markets
40
tor would be determined by the 2000 2001 2002 2003 has remained stable in the
size of the country. last few years.
Source: Bruegel estimates based
on OECD. EU15 Excluding Ireland. In equity markets, however, home
BOX 2
METHODOLOGY

This policy brief uses two indicators of home bias arrived at by comparing the share of consumption of domestic
products (investment in domestic equity) in total consumption (total investment) by nationals with two bench-
marks derived from two alternative definitions of (absence of) home bias.
Under the first definition, a “Frictionless Economy”, the benchmarks are constructed as follows:

Product Markets B1 = Domestic Production


Total OECD Production

Equity Holdings B1 = Market Capitalisation


Total OECD Market Cap.
Under the second definition, an “Integrated Economy”, using data on current trade (or investment) we estimate the
impact of distance and economic size on trade, On this basis we can calculate how much a country would import from (or
invest in) a partner of equal economic and geographic size. This amount is equivalent to the demand for domestic pro-
ducts in the absence of home bias. The second benchmark would therefore be:
Product Markets B2 = Estimated Demand Domestic Products (no Home Bias)
Total Domestic Demand

Equity Holdings B2 = Estimated Holdings of Domestic Equity (no Home Bias)


Total DomesticEquity Investment

See www.bruegel.org for data sources and detailed methodology.


SINGLE MARKET TRAILS HOME BIAS

is not as integrated as the US. After


06 Fig. 4
EU15: Home Bias in Goods in a
Frictionless Economy (%) 66
controlling for size and distance,
trade between US states is still two
bruegelpolicybrief

to three times higher than trade


64 between EU member states (Wolf,
62 2000).
60 Progress in communication and
58
information technologies allows for
an increase in the tradability of
56 goods and services and facilitates
the internationalisation of produc-
54 tion chains. Increasing trade of pro-
52 ducts that were previously not tra-
dable and higher intra-industry
50 trade should have boosted trade.
1988 1991 1994 1997 2000 2003 Home bias should therefore
decrease naturally as a conse-
Source: Bruegel estimates based on OECD.
quence of technological progress
bias has decreased substantially In the case of equity holdings, and the increased potential for
in the recent years (see Fig. 5). The information and the “familiarity” trade. However, this has not happe-
preference for home companies effect (i.e. the fact that investors ned within the EU.
stocks remains probably higher over-invest in companies which
than what can be explained by are best known to them) play an WHERE ARE THE MEMBER STATES?
information asymmetries, but important role. Furthermore, imper- The degree of home bias in product
change is without doubt under fect integration of product markets markets and equity holding varies
way.8 tends to weaken significantly from country
integration of to country. Table 1 shows
The evidence therefore is that (a) financial mar- ‘The EU is not as inte- home bias in product mar-
national borders still matter (b) kets. kets and equity holdings in
their importance varies considera- grated as the US. the EU using the integrated
bly from country to country and This is why Trade between US economy benchmark. The
(c) while there is momentum in there is evi- comparison only includes
financial markets, it has stalled in dence of home states is two to three those countries for which
product markets and has barely bias even within times higher than comparable data are availa-
started in labour markets. the United trade between EU ble. The EU15 average home
States. On ave- bias is set as a reference.
WHERE DOES HOME BIAS COME rage the internal member states.’
FROM? flow of trade According to this indicator,
It is difficult to disentangle the within US states Belgium and Austria are
extent to which home bias is due to is three times higher than the trade less home biased both in equity
non-policy reasons. Consumers between US states. US citizens also holdings and consumption than
might have different preferences disproportionately invest in stocks the EU15 average. On the other
and some products are not easily of companies headquartered in end, Greece and Spain are very
tradable at long distance. Some, their home region. However, the EU home-biased with reference to the
such as public services, are not tra- EU15 average in both mar-
Fig. 5
ded at all. Moreover, if firms decide kets.
Home bias(%) in Equity in an
to produce in the destination mar- Integrated Economy: US vs EU15
kets, foreign trade is replaced by The Nordic countries,
local production and, in this case, Germany and Italy have rela-
100
8
home bias in trade would produce a US 90 tively large home bias in
The latest indicators consumption and fairly diver-
produced by the ECB
misleading indicator of market EU 80
show increasing inte- integration. Also, the increasing 70 sified portfolio holdings. In
gration in the equity weight of services in the economy, 60 the case of Italy this could be
market both by using which in principle are less tradable 50 explained by the small size of
price- and quantity- 40
than goods, makes economies in its equity market in compari-
based indicators. 2001 2002 2003 2004 son to its economic size.
general less exposed to trade.
Source: Bruegel estimates based on IMF CPIS,
& Eurostat. EU15 excluding IE, LU, NL and PT.
SINGLE MARKET TRAILS HOME BIAS

Finally, the two new Member tating outsourcing and increasing REDUCE ASYMMETRIES
States in the sample, Hungary and
Czech Republic, have rapidly inte-
the tradability of goods and servi- Reducing market integration
ces. asymmetries both within and 07

bruegelpolicybrief
grated their product markets but across countries should also be a
their equity portfolios remain lar- The Single Market is not an idea of clear objective in order to enhance
gely local. the past. But the strategy needs the efficiency of macroeconomic
rethinking and a new impetus. The policies. Within the euro area,
programme launched in the 1980s exchange rates and interest rates
3. POLICY relied on the assumption that are no longer available to tackle the
RECOMMENDATIONS gains would come from economies consequences of asymmetric
of scale as fewer plants would pro- shocks. Therefore, in order to make
The SMP has removed many obsta- duce for a bigger market. It largely sure that monetary policy res-
cles on the way to European inte- downplayed market entry and the ponds effectively to the needs of
gration. However, while the integra- churning effect of competition. It the economy it is important that
tion of financial markets is still also overlooked the possibility of countries make progress in the
making good progress, the integra- outsourcing and offshoring, which process of integration. A single cur-
tion of product markets shows were uncommon at that time. It rency cannot deliver without a sin-
signs of exhaustion despite the focused on the ove- gle market.
fact that the home bias measures rall effect of market
presented in this policy brief show unification, disre- Insufficient integration
that it still has considerable poten- garding the poten- may also hinder further
tial. tially enabling effect market reforms. A country
of key sectors. ‘The Single Market introducing reforms in a
A NEW APPROACH TO SINGLE specific product market
MARKET POLICIES Internal market poli- strategy needs might achieve lower prices
In this context the review of the cies for the 21st rethinking and a but also higher real inte-
Single Market policies that the century should new impetus.’ rest rates, since monetary
European Commission has recently focus on favouring policy is not likely to res-
launched is a timely initiative. The entry and competi- pond to changes in one
traditional approach to achieving tion, facilitating the country. This would
integration through the removal of diffusion of innova- increase the cost of capi-
non-tariff barriers and sectoral har- tion, and creating tal and would therefore
monisation has manifestly lost conditions for a further integration mitigate the potential impact of
steam. Furthermore, the economic of the value chains across Europe. reforms. The fact that price levels in
context has substantially changed This is not only achieved through the euro area have not converged
in the last twenty years and policies horizontal policies but also through since the end of the nineties might
should adapt to a new environment. policies targeted at those sectors be a reflection of this phenomenon.
Services have increased their role in which help reduce trade costs and
the economy, innovation has increase tradability. Some key Asymmetries within countries can
become a major driver of economic examples in this respect are trans- also involve risks, especially when
development, and technology plays port, infrastructure, banking and product markets are more open
a much more important role in facili- retail trade. than financial markets. For exam-
ple, Hungary and the Czech
Republic are relatively open to
HOME BIAS IN EQUITY HOLDINGS trade, but hold most of their equity
wealth in domestic assets. This
Table 1 makes their economies especially
LOW MEDIUM HIGH vulnerable to shocks in their pro-
duct markets. A loss in competiti-
veness of their domestic industry
LOW AT, BE would be immediately translated
HOME into their financial markets, increa-
BIAS MEDIUM DE, SE UK, DK HU, CZ sing the effect of the shock in the
IN country’s wealth. Nowadays,
PRODUCT equity markets in new member
MARKETS HIGH IT FI, FR GR, ES
states, although rapidly growing,
Source: Bruegel estimates based on OECD, IMF CPIS, & Eurostat.
SINGLE MARKET TRAILS HOME BIAS

are underdeveloped and quoted quences for the reform of other gies between financial, product
08 equity is neither an important
source of funding for firms nor an
markets. and labour market reforms, such
reforms need to take into account
bruegelpolicybrief

important savings instrument. However, reforms in the product the links between the three mar-
Therefore, the impact of a shock on market might also be hindered in kets. They must also tackle simul-
wealth would be limited at present. anticipation of the potential taneously all affected markets,
However, the pattern of equity hol- effects in other markets: This was without expecting that reform in
ding needs to transform as finan- for example the case of the contro- one market will automatically leve-
cial wealth develops in the new rage reform in the others.
member states.
The current momentum of financial
FOSTERING REFORM ‘Financial integration integration and reform could cer-
Recent economic analysis emphasi- tainly help reform in other fields.
ses the complementarity between can not continue But financial integration can
reforms. It suggests that reforming advancing if there is no hardly continue advancing if there
product markets facilitates reforms in is no progress in product and
labour markets9 and reduces home progress on other labour markets. The current imba-
bias in equity holdings10. Liberalising fronts.’ lances in the progress of integra-
product markets reduces the rents tion make the whole process fra-
enjoyed by firms and therefore crea- gile and undermines the ability of
tes pressure for the introduction of the EU to make the most of one of
more flexibility in labour markets. its greatest achievements – the
Equally, more competition makes versial Services Directive where Single Market.
profits more volatile and increases the possible effects on labour mar-
the need for a more diversified portfo- kets played an important role on its The author wants to thank Narcissa
lio in order to hedge the higher risk. watering down. Balta for her excellent research assis-
Thus, the slow down of product tance and fruitful discussions in the
market reforms has direct conse- In order to fully exploit the syner- preparation of this policy brief.

REFERENCES

Pol Antras, “Firms, Contracts, and Trade Structure”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 118, No. 4, pp. 1375-1418,
Nov. 2003.
Olivier Blanchard and Francesco Giavazzi, “Macroeconomic effects of Regulation and Deregulation in Goods and
Labor Market”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, MIT Press, vol. 118(3), pages 879-907, 2003.
Philip R Lane and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti, “International Investment Patterns”, CEPR Discussion Papers 4499,
2004.
John McCallum, “National Borders Matter: Canada – U.S. Regional Trade Patterns”, The American Economic Review,
Vol. 85, No.3, pp.615-623, 1995.
Volker Nitsch, “National Borders and International Trade: Evidence from the European Union”, The Canadian Journal
of Economics, Vol.33, No.4, pp.1091-1105, 2000.
Maurice Obstfeld and Kenneth Rogoff, "The Six Major Puzzles in International Finance: Is There a Common Cause?",
NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 15, 2000.
Richard Portes and Helene Rey , “The Determinants of Cross-Border Equity Flows”, Journal of International
Economics Vol. 65, pp. 269-296, 2005.
Nicolas Véron, “Farewell National Champions”, Bruegel Policy Brief, Issue 2006/04, 2006.
H.C. Wolf, “Intranational Home Bias in Trade”, Review of Economics and Statistics, No. 82(4), pp.555-563, 2000.

Bruegel is a European think tank devoted to international economics, which started operations in Brussels in 2005.
It is supported by European governments and international corporations. Bruegel’s aim is to contribute to the quality
of economic policymaking in Europe through open, fact-based and policy-relevant research, analysis and discussion.

9
See Blanchard and The Bruegel Policy Brief series is published under the editorial responsibility of Jean Pisani-Ferry, Director.
Giavazzi, 2003. Opinions expressed in this publication are those of the author(s) alone.
10
See Obstfeld and Visit www.bruegel.org for information on Bruegel's activities and publications.
Rogoff, 2000 Bruegel - Rue de la Charité 33, B-1210 Brussels - phone (+32) 2 227 4210 info@bruegel.org

You might also like