Home-Biased Gravity The Role of Migrant Tastes in International Trade

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 18

World Development 129 (2020) 104863

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

World Development
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev

Home-biased gravity: The role of migrant tastes in international trade


Penglong Zhang
School of Public Policy and Management, Tsinghua University, Qinghua West Road, Beijing 100084, China

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: Immigrants tend to buy products from their home countries. As a result, the more immigrants of a given
Accepted 24 December 2019 ethnicity a country has, the more it will tend to import from those immigrants’ countries of origin. This
Available online 8 January 2020 effect of migrant heterogeneity is ignored by the standard gravity literature that assumes homogeneous
preferences among resident consumers. This paper embeds that observed regularity into a structural
JEL classification: gravity model. Gravity derived from the Almost Ideal Demand System generates bilateral trade shares
D10 with three distinct components: ethnic composition of the resident population, bilateral trade cost,
F11
and per capita income. Using international trade and transnational migration data among 40 countries,
F14
F22
this paper estimates the home bias of each ethnic group in tastes. The results show that consumers’ tastes
for products from their country of origin deviate from unbiased levels by 35 percent on average. Ethnic
Keywords: taste bias is found to explain half of the trade bias. Counterfactuals suggest that anti-immigration policy
Home bias significantly impedes trade with immigrants’ countries of origin.
Taste bias Ó 2019 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
Migration
World
China

1. Introduction that assumes homogeneous preferences among resident national


consumers.4 The home bias in taste (defined as taste bias hereafter)
The world is still far from flat today. Numerous studies have for home goods is believed to contribute to the trade bias, but is
found that international trade flows are too small relative to empirically indistinguishable from trade costs in the gravity model.
intra-national trade to be explained by observable trade costs— Ignoring the taste bias would lead us to overestimate the extent to
the ‘‘border puzzle” or the ‘‘home-bias-in-trade puzzle”.1 The home which trade liberalization can foster market integration. Failure to
expenditure shares are much larger than the levels under hypothet- account for preference heterogeneity causes problems in welfare
ical frictionless trades, which are equal to the countries’ production gains across consumers.5
shares.2 This implies a large home bias in trade (defined as trade bias This paper replaces the assumption of the representative con-
hereafter). sumer with heterogeneous ethnic consumers in terms of taste bias.
Consumers have home-biased preferences,3 and bring their Specifically, any given consumer has a taste biased toward the
idiosyncratic preferences with them when they migrate. Thus immi- goods produced by her country of origin, regardless of where she
grants tend to buy products from their home countries. This effect of currently resides. Thus consumers are heterogeneous in terms of
migrant heterogeneity is ignored by the standard trade literature the extent of their taste biases. I extend the structural gravity
model by building and estimating a structural component of
home-biased preferences. The gravity model generates bilateral
trade shares with three distinct components: ethnic composition
of the resident population, bilateral trade cost, and per capita
E-mail address: zhangpenglong@tsinghua.edu.cn.
1
The border puzzle is a widely discussed problem in macroeconomics and income. Using international trade and migration data, this paper
international finance, first documented by McCallum (1995). Anderson and van estimates the taste bias of each ethnic group. The results show that
Wincoop (2003) develop the structural gravity model to explain the puzzle with consumers’ tastes for products from their country of origin deviate
multilateral resistances. However, even after controlling for multilateral resistances, from unbiased levels significantly.
there is still a border barrier that is too high to be explicable by tariffs and freight
costs (see Anderson & van Wincoop, 2004).
2 4
In a standard benchmark, if foreign products were just as accessible and desirable Atkin (2013) and Bronnenberg, Dubé, and Gentzkow (2012) use domestic
as domestic ones, then under complete specialization each country would consume migration to explore the regional taste differences. Di Comite, Thisse, and
its expenditure share of every other country’s production. Vandenbussche (2014) propose a new model where consumer preferences are
3
Empirical work using micro-level data provides considerable evidence. See Morey heterogeneous across countries, but there are no migrations.
5
(2016) on rice. See Lewbel and Pendakur (2017).

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2019.104863
0305-750X/Ó 2019 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
2 P. Zhang / World Development 129 (2020) 104863

Similar to Atkin (2013), I define tastes for goods as pure budget goods produced by her home country (where she is originally from).
share shifters in expenditure-share equations, which measure how On the other hand, her taste is also biased toward the goods pro-
much a consumer likes particular goods when qualities and prices duced locally (where she is currently living). The gravity equation
are exactly the same. In the Armington setup,6 a consumer with with assimilation also captures the local effect, in addition to the
unbiased tastes (a hypothetical metropolitan consumer) spends taste effect, price effect, and income effect in the baseline model. It
her income equally on goods from different countries,7 while a con- measures the size of the relative trade ‘‘promoter” that stimulates
sumer with fully biased tastes (a hypothetical parochial consumer) internal (local) trade due to the local bias in taste. This implies that
spends all her income only on home good given all else equal. Any internal trade is larger than foreign trade by a local bias, all else
arbitrary consumer is then somewhere in between those two equal. The intuition is that the consumption pattern of the immi-
extremes. Next, I define the taste bias of a consumer as the relative grants converges to that of the native people.
distance between the unbiased and fully-biased tastes. The taste bias In the empirical part of the paper, I start by estimating the
is 0 for unbiased consumers and 1 for fully-biased consumers. In home-biased gravity model without assimilation. The taste shifters
order to distinguish taste differences from income differences acting are the ethnicity-specific coefficients of immigrant stock shares.12
through non–homotheticity, I adopt the Almost Ideal Demand Sys- Using international manufacturing trade and transnational migra-
tem (AIDS) constructed by Deaton and Muellbauer (1980).8 tion data among 40 countries, I find that the import share is signif-
The basic assumption in this paper is that a consumer’s tastes icantly increasing in immigrant share for most ethnic groups. On
only depend on her country of origin, and are unrelated to where average, the taste shifter is 0.35. I also estimate sectoral gravity in
she currently lives. Thus, consumers from the same ethnic group the agricultural and service sectors, and for final and intermediate
share the same tastes regardless of where they are located.9 One goods, as well as in multiple manufacturing industries. It is found
viable explanation of this is the habit formation in relation to tastes that consumers have larger taste biases in agricultural products,
proposed by Atkin (2013), who argues that adult taste favors the while they are almost unbiased on services. Import share is more
foods they consumed as a child and the preferences gained in child- sensitive to immigrant share for final goods than for intermediate
hood persist into adulthood.10 Thus, immigrant consumers are goods.
biased toward the goods from their country of origin, all else equal, Then I check the estimation results of the home-biased gravity
regardless of where they are located. For example, an Italian immi- with assimilation. In order to control for the assimilation effect, I
grant living in the U.K. is biased toward Italian clothing products, proxy the local bias with the share of the refugee population of
and a Japanese immigrant living in the U.S. prefers Japanese elec- the destination country. Voluntary migrants usually have tastes
tronic products, even though they left their home countries years similar to, or converge tastes to those in the destination, while
earlier. Note here the Japanese immigrants living in the U.S. refer forced migrants (e.g.. refugees) are usually less assimilated. The
to those born in Japan or Japanese citizens, and thus are different results show that immigrants at the countries with larger refugee
from the Japanese Americans who are already very assimilated. Sim- shares are less likely to exhibit local bias (assimilation) in their
ilar for the Italian immigrants living in the U.K. This assumption in tastes. Compared with the baseline results, the taste bias estimated
relation to preferences yields an aggregate demand system that is with assimilation is smaller on average. Although the taste bias is
feasible to estimate. overestimated without assimilation, the differences are moderate
With the taste structure and the ethnic-preference assumption, for most ethnic groups, implying that the baseline estimation
I derive a home-biased gravity equation by aggregating expenditure results are robust.
shares across ethnic groups within each country. In addition to I also address two potential econometric issues. First, the esti-
trade costs and income effects, the gravity equation also captures mated coefficient is subject to potential endogeneity issues. I use
the impact of the trade promoter that stimulates bilateral trade two instrument variables and conduct two sets of estimations
shares via immigration. The intuition is that the biased immigrants based on level and difference equations. The first instrument is
spend larger shares of their income on products from their home the lagged variable. I instrument the stock share of immigrants
country than the native residents, thereby increasing the import in 2010 by that in 2000. The second instrument is an exogenous
share from their home country to their host country. push factor. I instrument the immigrant share by the interaction
The assumption that tastes only depend on origin, not on cur- of the natural disasters of origin and the distance to destination.
rent country, is very strong. Migrants likely choose a certain coun- Natural disasters are measured as the average fraction of the pop-
try because their tastes are more aligned with the tastes in the ulation affected by natural disasters in each during decades. I start
destination, and thus their tastes are different from those of the with estimating the gravity equation in level by two-stage least
population staying in the home country. Also, immigrants assimi- square method, and the results show that the potential endogene-
late and change their tastes in order to adapt to the dominant soci- ity problem leads to an overestimation of the taste bias. However,
ety, the native people of the destination country.11 Thus I also the effect is negligible since the differences remain within one
extend the model by adding migrant assimilation. I redefine the taste standard deviation. Then I further estimate the gravity equation
structure. On the one hand, a consumer has a biased taste toward by taking first differences between the two cross-sections to elim-
inate any potential time-invariant omitted variables. Again I
6 instrument the change of immigrant share by the interaction of
Each country specializes in the production of a distinct variety.
7
I allow for asymmetric tastes for the hypothetical metropolitan consumer in both natural disasters of origin and the distance to destination. The
the model and the empirical analysis. The simplification used here is just for the result is smaller, but the difference remains moderate. Thus the
purposes of the intuition discussion. baseline results are robust.
8
Recent studies have generally interpreted high income-elastic goods in the model Second, the trade-creating effect of immigration could also
as high-quality goods and the low income-elastic goods as low-quality goods. Trade
papers by Hallak (2006), Fieler (2011), Caron, Fally, and Markusen (2014), Feenstra
work through the trade cost channel by which the migration net-
and Romalis (2014) and Fajgelbaum and Khandelwal (2016) find that richer countries work reduces information barriers. I add a variable measuring
export goods with higher income elasticities. the network effect into the regression. It is the probability that, if
9
I also allow for taste differences between ethnic consumers at home and abroad we select an individual at random from each country, they will
in the extension section.
10
Atkin (2013) provides ample evidence from the psychology and nutrition
literature. See Bronnenberg et al. (2012) for further discussion.
11 12
Some papers find immigrants change their values and norms. See Bucheli, See Lanati and Thiele (2018) and Berthélemy, Beuran, and Maurel (2009). for
Fontenla, and Waddell (2019). more details about the difference between migrant flows and migrant stocks.
P. Zhang / World Development 129 (2020) 104863 3

have a connection defined as a common national origin. This mea- variety. Let pni be the price in country n of the good imported from
sure extends the one used in Rauch and Trindade (2002) that only country i. The iceberg trade cost from i to n is t ni . No-arbitrage con-
captures the ethnic-Chinese network. The results show that the dition implies that pni ¼ pii t ni . There are N ethnic groups of con-
network effect channel does not have a significant effect on the sumers, indexed by h as the national origin. Each ethnic group is
aggregate manufacturing import share. globally distributed and thus each country is populated by N ethnic
Using the estimated parameters, I conduct two counterfactual groups. Note that n; i; h ¼ 1; 2; . . . ; N. Let snh be the immigrant pop-
experiments. First, I decompose the contribution of the taste effect, ulation share in country n from country h if h – n, and snn be the
trade cost effect, and income effect to the trade bias. About half of P
native population share in country n. Then Nh¼1 snh ¼ 1 holds for
the trade bias is explained by the trade cost, and the other half is all n.
explained by the taste bias, with very little explained by the Consumers are assumed to have the Almost Ideal Demand Sys-
income effect. Second, I check how migration policy affects trade tem (AIDS) preference introduced by Deaton and Muellbauer
bias. The results show that countries decrease import shares signif- (1980). Specifically, any consumer who is from country h and
icantly with a migration ban. resides at country n has expenditure functions given in logarithmic
This paper contributes to the gravity literature in international form as
trade in two aspects. First, it introduces consumer preference
heterogeneity into gravity models, which is additional to gravity Y
N

model with firm heterogeneity (Chaney, 2008; Helpman, Melitz, ln ehn ¼ ln Q hn þ uhn ðpni Þ/i ; ð1Þ
i¼1
& Rubinstein, 2008), and non-homothetic gravity model with con-
sumer income heterogeneity (Fajgelbaum & Khandelwal, 2016). where ehn is the minimum expenditure at which the consumer can
Second, it allows for taste biases when discussing trade with the obtain utility uhn given prices pni . The price index ln Q hn is given in
AIDS preference, which is supplementary to translog gravity model logarithmic form as
(Novy, 2013), trade that includes the entry of new goods (Feenstra,
2003), and price and income of international comparison (Neary, X
N
1X N X N

2004). ln Q hn ¼ ahi ln pni þ c ln pni ln pni0 : ð2Þ


i¼1
2 i¼1 i0¼1 ii0
My paper helps to explain the ‘‘border puzzle” using home-
biased preferences, which is supplementary to other explanations, Applying the Shephard’s lemma and differentiating the expenditure
e.g.. trade costs (Obstfeld & Rogoff, 2001), multilateral resistance function with respect to log price pni generates the expenditure
(Anderson & van Wincoop, 2003), non-homothetic preferences share in good i for consumer h at country n equal to
(Caron et al., 2014), multi-stage production (Yi, 2010), and scale !
effects (Ramondo, Rodríguez-Clare, & Saborío-Rodríguez, 2016). X
N
ehn
whni ¼a þ h
i cii0 ln pni0 þ /i ln ; ð3Þ
Chaney (2014) and Allen (2014) discuss resistance as a result of i0¼1 Q hn
information barriers. Head and Mayer (2013) summarize the
sources of resistance as imperfect information, localized tastes, for i ¼ 1; . . . ; N. We assume that all shares are non-negative.
and distribution networks. It is also related to the work on border These expenditure shares have some nice features. First, ahi is a
effect based on micro evidence (Cosßar, Grieco, Li, & Tintelnot, taste parameter of consumer h for the good i which shifts the
2018). expenditure share independently from the prices and income. Sec-
There is a large body of literature on the effect of international ond, cii0 is the cross-price elasticity for good i when i0 – i and the
migration on international trade. Some papers have explored the own-price elasticity for good i when i0 ¼ i. Third, /i is the income
effect of immigration on bilateral trade flows. In particular, immi- elasticity which captures the non-homothetic component of the
grants are found to reduce barriers to exports by facilitating com- preference. Positive /i implies luxury goods (with high quality)
munication between firms and reducing setup costs in the while negative /i implies necessary goods (with low quality).13 I
destination country, which is termed the ‘‘network effect” by refer to ehn =Q hn as adjusted ‘‘real” income (expenditure) by individual
Rauch and Trindade (2002). This trade cost channel of migration price index which varies by the individual consumption basket com-
on trade is also examined by Combes, Lafourcade, and Mayer positions. To satisfy homogeneity of degree one, the parameters are
(2005), Iranzo and Peri (2009) and Felbermayr, Grossmann, and P P
constrained by ahi 2 ½0; 1, Ni¼1 ahi ¼ 1 for all h, Ni¼1 cii0 ¼ 0 for all i0,
Kohler (2015). This paper is along this line by providing a different PN
perspective on the preference channel. and i¼1 /i ¼ 0. Symmetry is imposed to satisfy the Young’s Theo-
The rest of this paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, I pre- rem, cii0 ¼ ci0i . When /i ¼ 0 for all i, AIDS becomes the homothetic
sent the model and derive the home-biased gravity. In Section 3, I translog preference.
estimate the gravity to obtain the estimates of the taste biases and I specialize the general cii0 to
all the other theoretical parameters. Section 4 presents the coun- cii0 ¼ cbi ðdii0 þ bi0 Þ; ð4Þ
terfactual experiments. I conclude in Section 5.
where the Kronecker delta dii0 is 1 when i ¼ i0 and 0 otherwise,
P
bi 2 ½0; 1, and Ni¼1 bi ¼ 1. Specialization (4) satisfies all the general
2. Model
restrictions. bi ¼ 1=N is the special case proposed by Feenstra
(2003).14 The variation of parameters bi allows for asymmetric
I present how to incorporate home-biased preferences into the
demand responses to price changes.
trade framework in Section 2.1, and derive the home-biased grav-
ity equation in Section 2.2. Section 2.3 discusses the gravity’s In equation (3), ahi is a taste parameter for good i but heteroge-
implications for the home-biased trade. Section 2.4 extends the neous across consumers. It is unvarying to where consumers con-
model with more general assumptions. sume but varies to where they are originally from. The explanation
is the habit formation in tastes proposed by Atkin (2013), who

2.1. Preferences 13
Note that cii0 and /i are semi-elasticities since they relate shares to logs of prices
and income, but I refer to them as elasticities to save notation.
The world consists of N countries, indexed by i as exporter and n 14
This special case is followed by Novy (2013) and Fajgelbaum and Khandelwal
as importer. Each country specializes in the production of a distinct (2016).
4 P. Zhang / World Development 129 (2020) 104863

argues that adults favor foods consumed as a child, and the pref- Equivalently, equation (7) could be taken as the expenditure
erences developed in childhood persist into adulthood.15 There- shares of a ‘‘representative” consumer in market n who is a
fore, consumers from the same ethnic group share the same ‘‘mixed-blood” with all ethnic origins. Since ethnic compositions
tastes regardless of where they live.16 This leads to an important differ, the representative consumers in different markets have dif-
factor in consumer tastes, home bias. For any consumer, she has ferent demand.
a biased taste toward the goods produced by her home country Next, I let X ni be the value of imports of importer n from expor-
(where she is originally from) whatever her host country (where ter i, and let En be the total expenditure of the importer. Denote wni
she resides and consumes) is. For example, an Italian immigrant as the share of aggregate expenditures in country n devoted to
living in the U.S. (born in Italy, not an Italian American) has a goods from country i, i.e.. wni ¼ XEnin . Then equation (7) could be
biased taste toward Italian products even though he has resided rewritten as
in the U.S. for years.
    
First, I assume a hypothetical world unbiased consumer with X ni p   tni
P ¼ ai  cbi ln ii þ hi sni  ai hn  cbi ln þ /i
tastes for good 1; 2; . . . ; N as fa1 ; a2 ; . . . ; aN g, and Ni¼1 ai ¼ 1. Then En 
p Pn
I assume ethnic consumer h’s tastes as
 
en
 ln  ; ð9Þ
ahi ¼ ð1  hh Þai þ hh dhi ; ð5Þ Qn
PN PN
where the Kronecker delta dhi is 1 when i ¼ h meaning home ¼
where p i¼1 bi pii and ln Pn ¼
i¼1 bi ln t ni . Income of each expor-
goods, and 0 otherwise, and hh 2 ½0; 1 is the taste shifter which P
ter i equals the sum of sales to every country, Y i ¼ Nn¼1 X ni , where
measures how biased ethnic consumer h’s taste is toward her Y i measures exporter i’s total income. Denote Y as the total world
PN h  
home good h. This specialization satisfies conditions i¼1 ai ¼ 1 income and ln r n ¼ ln en =Q  n as the real expenditure. By canceling
for all h. For any consumer h, she raises her taste for home good h  i
term ai  cbi ln ppii , I term the resulting expression as the home-
h by a shifter hh , while reduces those for all the other goods by
1  hh (as well as the home good to make sure taste aggregates biased gravity
equal to 1). When hh ¼ 0, ethnic consumer h are unbiased, exactly   r
X ni Y i   t ni n
like the hypothetical world consumer. When hh ¼ 1, the con-  ¼ hi sni  hi Psi  ai Psn  cbi ln þ /i ln ; ð10Þ
sumers from ethnic group h have fully biased tastes, i.e. 1 for
En Y Pi P n r
home good while 0 for all the others. Thus the set of taste shifters
where
fhh gNh¼1 is the measurement of the taste biases across ethnicities,
and it is the key set of parameters in this paper. Now I rewrite XN   XN  
En tni
the expenditure equations (3) as ln Pi ¼ ln t ni ; ln P n ¼ bi ln ; ð11Þ
Y Pi
  ! n¼1 i¼1
pni ehn
whni ¼ ð1  hh Þai þ hh dhi  cbi ln þ /i ln ; ð6Þ and
n
p Q hn
P XN   X
n ¼ Ni¼1 bi ln pni . And cbi
where average price in market n is ln p En N
 
Psi ¼ sni ; Psn ¼ hi sni  Psi ; ð12Þ
are the semi price elasticities and /i are the semi income n¼1
Y i¼1
elasticities.
and
2.2. Home-biased gravity
XN  
En
ln r ¼ ln r n : ð13Þ
In this part, I first aggregate individual expenditure shares Y
n¼1
across all ethnic groups within each market (country), and then
X ni
derive the gravity equation for each country pair. On the left hand side, En
 YYi is the deviation of bilateral trade
I assume that ethnic groups within a country share the same per unit of n’s expenditure from its frictionless level YYi . There are
income, i.e. ehn ¼ en . 17 Aggregating individual expenditure shares three terms on the right hand side, which capture the taste effect,
across ethnic groups gives the market import share of country n from price effect, and income effect, respectively. The second term,
P 
country i by wni ¼ Nh¼1 snh whni , i.e.. cbi ln PtniPn , is the effect of relative bilateral trade resistance,
    i
  p en where ln Pi and ln P n are the outward and inward multilateral
wni ¼ 1  hn ai þ hi sni  cbi ln ni þ /i ln  ; ð7Þ
n
p Qn resistances in log, respectively. This term is the same to that in
 
n ¼ PN snh hh , and the
where the average taste bias in market n is h
Anderson and van Wincoop (2003). The last term, /i ln rrn , is the
h¼1
non-homothetic component of the gravity equation and captures
average price index in market n by aggregating individual price
the effect of relative income per capita of market n where ln r is
index ln Q hn , the average world income per capita in log. This term is the same
X
N to that in Fajgelbaum and Khandelwal (2016).
n ¼
ln Q snh ln Q hn : ð8Þ The first term, hi sni  hi Psi  ai Psn , is one of the most important
h¼1 novelties in this paper. It captures the effect of the relative trade
‘‘promoter” that stimulates bilateral trade via bilateral migration.
The intuition is that immigrants raise the average market taste
for their home country’s products. The magnitude of the promoter
15
He terms this process habit formation and provides ample evidence in the is increasing in how large the bilateral immigrant share, sni , is, as
psychology and nutrition literature.
16
well as how large their taste shifter, hi , is. I refer to Psi and Psn
Tastes are assumed to be exogenous. Lan and Li (2015) discuss how economic
openness affects nationalism.
respectively as the outward and inward ‘‘multilateral promoters”
17
On the absence of data, I skip within-country cross-ethnicity income difference, that summarize the average trade promoters between a country
but keep cross-country income difference. and its trading partners.
P. Zhang / World Development 129 (2020) 104863 5

2.2.1. Symmetric home-biased gravity 2.4. Extension: home bias with assimilation
The home-biased gravity expressed by equation (10) is flexible
because it allows asymmetries in ethnic groups. In order to com- Immigrants usually assimilate. In other words, migrant tastes
pare the home-biased gravity with the CES gravity in Anderson depend on origins as well as destinations. Some studies find that
and van Wincoop (2003), I impose symmetry conditions, i.e. consumers eventually converge to the consumption patterns of
hi ¼ h, ai ¼ 1=N, bi ¼ 1=N and /i ¼ 0 for all i, denote c0 ¼ c=N, then their new place of residence.19
we get the symmetric home-biased gravity In this section, I introduce ‘‘local bias” in addition to ‘‘home
  bias” into the model to allow immigrants to assimilate. I redefine
X ni Y i   tni
 ¼ h sni  Psi  Psn  c0 ln ; ð14Þ the taste parameter used in equation (3). On the one hand, a con-
En Y Pi Pn
sumer has a biased taste toward goods produced by her home
P   country (where she is originally from). On the other hand, her taste
where multilateral terms are ln Pi ¼ Nn¼1 EYn ln t ni ,
P  P   P   is also biased toward the locally-produced goods (where she is liv-
ln Pn ¼ N1 Ni¼1 ln Pt ni
, Psi ¼ Nn¼1 EYn sni , and Psn ¼ N1 Ni¼1 sni  Psi :
i ing). Specifically, I assume ethnic consumer (ethnic group) h’s
When h ¼ 0, the taste effect is shut down and the symmetric tastes at location (country) n to be
home-biased gravity is identical to the translog gravity in Novy
(2013). Recall the CES structural gravity in the log form as follows, ahni ¼ ð1  hh  Hn Þai þ hh dhi þ Hn dni ; ð17Þ
 
X ni Yi t ni where the Kronecker delta dni is 1 when i ¼ n, meaning local goods,
ln  ln ¼ Xni þ ð1  rÞ ln ; ð15Þ
En Y Pi P n and 0 otherwise, and Hn 2 ½0; 1 is the local shifter which measures
how the tastes of the consumers at location n is toward to local
 1r PN En tni 1r  1r PN Y n  tni 1r P
where Pi ¼ n¼1 Y P , and Pn ¼ i¼1 Y P : good n. This specialization still satisfies conditions Ni¼1 ahni ¼ 1 for
n i

Comparing equations (14) and (15) provides the difference in all h and all n. For any consumer h at location n, she raises her taste
the functional form on the left-hand side: a difference in shares for home good h by a shifter hh , for local good n by a shifter Hn ,
versus a difference in log shares. The own-price effect in the two while reduces those for all the other goods by 1  hh  Hn . Thus
gravity equations is essentially the same, while the cross-price the set of local shifters fHh gNh¼1 is the measurement of the local
effects are captured by price index terms that differ, but would biases across locations. Now I rewrite the expenditure
ordinarily be econometrically controlled for by origin and destina- equations (3) as
tion fixed effects. More importantly, the unobservable bilateral   !
taste effect Xni is offered a micro fundamental structure in this pni ehn
whni ¼ ð1  hh  Hn Þai þ hh dhi þ Hn dni  cbi ln þ /i ln :
paper, whereas it is taken as part of the error term in the tradi- n
p Q hn
tional gravity literature. Since the multilateral promoters are
ð18Þ
absorbed by origin and destination fixed effects, econometrically,
the difference boils down to an additional term, the immigrant Aggregating the individual expenditure shares across ethnic groups
share. The coefficient for immigrant share is exactly the taste gives the market import share of country n from country i by
shifter. P
wni ¼ Nh¼1 snh whni , i.e..
   
2.3. Home-biased trade   p en
wni ¼ 1  hn  Hn ai þ hi sni þ Hn dni  cbi ln ni þ /i ln  :
n
p Qn
Since we are interested in trade bias, I can write down the home ð19Þ
share deviation based on the home-biased gravity equation (10) as
Then the home-biased gravity with local bias becomes
X nn Y n  
HBn   r
En Y X ni Y i   t ni n
  r  ¼ hi sni  hi Psi  ai Psn  cbi ln þ /i ln
  t nn En Y Pi Pn r
¼ hn snn  hn Psn  an Psn  cbn ln þ /n ln
n
; ð16Þ  
Pn Pn r Ei
þ Hn dni  Hi ; ð20Þ
Y
where HBn is defined as country n’s home bias in trade, or trade bias,
that measures the deviation of home expenditure share from its where ln Pi , ln P n , and Psi are the same as the baseline model,
frictionless level.18 Equation (16) shows that trade bias can be while
explained by three separate effects: the taste effect, the price (trade
X X N   !
cost) effect, and the income effect. Regarding these three effects, the N
  En0
Psn ¼ hi sni  Pi þ Hn 
s
Hn0 : ð21Þ
following implications are obtained. Y
i¼1 n0¼1
Implication 1. Non-immigration countries have a larger trade bias
than immigration countries, ceteris paribus. Home countries of more On the left-hand side, X ni
 YYi is the deviation of the bilateral trade
En
biased consumers have a larger trade bias, ceteris paribus.
per unit of n’s expenditure from its frictionless level YYi . Again, the
Implication 1 holds because @HB nn
¼ hn > 0 and the intuition is
@snn first term, hi sni  hi Psi  ai P sn , captures the effect of the relative trade
that immigration countries (with smaller snn , like the U.S.) import ‘‘promoter” that stimulates bilateral trade via bilateral migration
more than non-immigration countries (with larger snn , like Japan)
from origin i to destination n. When everybody is unbiased, i.e.
since large amount of immigrants spend more on products pro-
hi ¼ 0 for all i, the trade promoters are shut down. This taste term
duced by their home countries, resulting in less domestic expendi-
is exactly the same as it is in the home-biased gravity without
ture share of the host country. The magnitude of this effect is
determined by the natives’ taste shifter for home good relative to 19
Bronnenberg et al. (2012) use micro-level data to infer that approximately 40% of
that for the global good, which are controlled by Psn and Psn . the geographic variation in market shares is attributable to persistent brand
preferences. They also show that their findings strongly reject the hypothesis that
18
In Anderson and Yotov (2010), they propose and estimate a similar index all that matters is where consumers lived in childhood: consumers who move after
^
 1r age 25 still eventually converge to the consumption patterns of their new place of
^tnn
constructed home bias (CHB) by CES structural gravity: CHBn ¼ XYnii =Y
=Y ¼
^ ^
n
. residence.
Pn Pn
6 P. Zhang / World Development 129 (2020) 104863

assimilation which is expressed by equation (10). So are the price sumer for product i, which is equal to her expenditure share on prod-
term and income term. ucts from country i in the global market. Thus we use the size of the
However, the home-biased gravity with assimilation has an product set produced by country i to measure the unbiased level of
 P
additional term, Hn dni  Hi EYi . It captures the local effect, in addi- taste for good i. 22 Specifically, I proxy ai ¼ EMi = i0 EM i0 where EM i is
the extensive margin in global trade estimated by Hummels
tional to the taste effect, price effect, and income effect in the base-
and Klenow (2005).23 Then the home-biased gravity equation
line model. It measures the size of relative trade ‘‘promoter” that
becomes
stimulates internal (local) trade due to the local bias in taste. Spe-
cially, when i ¼ n, then dni ¼ 1, equation (20) indicates the internal X ni
¼ hi sni  c0 ln tni þ w ln r ni þ kn ai þ f i þ g n þ ni ; ð22Þ
(domestic) trade for country n, in which the internal trade ‘‘pro- En
moter” is Hn . When i – n, then dni ¼ 0, it indicates the foreign
where ln r ni ¼ ln rn  ln ri , f i ¼ Y i =Y  hi Psi þ c0 ln Pi þ w ln ri  ln r,
trade, in which the ‘‘promoter” becomes zero. This implies that
and g n ¼ c0 ln P n þ w ln r n  ln r þ w ln r  ln r . Here ln r i comes from
internal trade is larger than foreign trade by a local bias, Hn , all else
the income elasticity which is the coefficient of ln rn . I proxy bilat-
equal. The intuition is that the consumption pattern of the immi-
eral trade costs with bilateral observables. Specifically,
grants converges to that of the native people. When consumers
everywhere have no local bias, i.e.. Hn ¼ 0 for all n, the internal ln t ni ¼ q ln dni þ qb borderni þ ql lang ni þ qt tariffni þ qi internalni þ eni ,
trade promoter is shut down, and this gravity equation corre- where dni is the bilateral distance between origin i and destination
sponds to that in the baseline model, i.e.. equation (10). n. Parameter q reflects the elasticity between distance and trade
costs, borderni and lang ni are common border and common lan-
guage, tariffni is tariff level, and eni is idiosyncratic errors for trade
3. Estimation
costs. Importantly, internalni is 0 for import and 1 for internal trade,
similar to Ramondo et al. (2016). Then the specification of the
In this section, I estimate the home-biased gravity derived in
home-biased gravity is
Section 2. Section 3.1 describes the data and the specification,
and Section 3.2 presents the main results by estimating the base- X ni b l t
¼ hi sni þ b ln dni þ b borderni þ b lang ni þ b tariffni
line model, i.e.. equation (10). The estimation results of the gravity En
with assimilation, equation (20), are discussed in Section 3.3. I also
þ b internalni þ w ln r ni þ kn EMi þ f i þ g n þ ni :
i
ð23Þ
discuss some other econometric issues in Section 3.4.
And f i ; g n could be controlled by fixed effects of origins and destina-
3.1. Data tions. There are 86 parameters to be estimated
n o
b l t i
b; b ; b ; b ; b ; w; fhi g40
i¼1 ; fki g40
i¼1 . Here fhi g40
i¼1 are the coefficients of
To estimate the home-biased gravity, I merged datasets on
bilateral migration, trade, and gravity. First, the migration data the interaction terms of sni and exporter dummies. And fki g40 i¼1 are

are from the United Nation International Migrant Stock Dataset, the coefficients of the interaction terms of EMi and importer dum-
which presents estimates of total immigrant stock at mid-year by mies. They are just used to control for the effects of multilateral pro-
origin and destination for the years 2000 for all countries and moters. Recall the real expenditure per capita is defined as
 
 n , where en , nominal expenditures per capita, are
ln r n ¼ ln en =Q
regions of the world. The estimates are based on official statistics
on the foreign-born or the foreign population.20 Second, trade flows observable too. Aggregate price index ln Q  n can be proxied by a
 
are from the World Input-Output Database (WIOD), which records 24
Stone index following literature, that is ln Q  n ¼ PN wni ln p dq ,
i¼1 ii ni
bilateral (and domestic) trade flows and production data for 40 where pii are the quality-adjusted prices estimated by Feenstra and
countries (27 European countries and 13 other large countries) Romalis (2014) and the value of q will be discussed later.
across 35 sectors that cover food, manufacturing, and services. Third, Because we do not directly observe trade costs, I cannot
I obtained bilateral distance, common language, border, and tariff separately identify q and cb. Following Fajgelbaum and
information from the CEPII’s Gravity database. Price levels, adjusted Khandelwal (2016) and Novy (2013), I set q ¼ 0:177. Then the
for cross-country quality variations, are obtained from Feenstra and
parameters of interest fhi gNi¼1 could be estimated directly and other
Romalis (2014). GDP, GDP per capita, and population are from the
theoretical parameters f/i gNi¼1 and c are identified by
Penn World Tables.  P
Recall the home-biased gravity equation (10), where there are a /i ¼ w ln r i  ð1=N Þ Ni0¼1 ln ri0 , and c ¼ Nb=q.
large number of parameters to estimate. Actually only the taste The estimates of taste differences might be biased due to the
shifters fhi gNi¼1 are the focus of this paper. Thus I can reduce the good composition. For example, the immigrants tend to be less
number of estimated parameters by imposing some restrictions. biased if their origin country is more specialized in goods that
First, let bi ¼ 1=N for all i, which leads constant own price elasticity are less tradable, or that serve as intermediate inputs and are not
following Feenstra (2003).21 Second, income elasticities and expor- directly sold to consumers. To fix this composition effect, I also
ter income are assumed to satisfy /i ¼ wc þ w ln r i for all i, similar to estimate sectoral (and industrial) gravity equations for 14 manu-
Feenstra and Romalis (2014) and Fajgelbaum and Khandelwal facturing industries, and the final and intermediate good sectors,
PN as well as food and service sectors using more disaggregated data.
(2016). The theoretical restriction i¼1 /i ¼ 0 implies
P Disaggregated estimation enables my results to be compared with
wc ¼ wð1=N Þ Ni¼1 ln r i , transforming this linear relationship to
P the micro-level studies on home preferences in the literature.
/i ¼ wðln r i  ln r Þ where ln r ¼ ð1=NÞ Ni0¼1 ln r i0 , and reducing the
Specifically, I estimate
number of income elasticity parameters to be estimated from N to
one. Recall ai is the taste of the hypothetical unbiased world con-

20 22
Research on immigration is often hampered by data limitations. Large-scale The Armington setup assumes one differentiated good per country. The size of the
individual-level surveys do not ask about immigrants’ legal status, and government product set of each country is equivalent to the attributes of its good.
23
records on legal permanent residents are presented as aggregate tabulations with no I replace the extensive margin with alternative measures in robustness check.
24
individual-level information. Caballero, Cadena, and Kovak (2018); Desmond and Deaton and Muellbauer (1980) first time use a Stone index to proxy the AIDS
Kubrin, 2009; Lyons, Vélez, and Santoro, 2013; Ravuri, 2014. price index. The trade literature, like Atkin (2013) and Fajgelbaum and Khandelwal
21
I allow asymmetric price elasticities in robustness check. (2016), follow this approximation.
P. Zhang / World Development 129 (2020) 104863 7

X kni k kb kl kt
Table 1
¼ hki sni þ b ln dni þ b borderni þ b lang ni þ b tariffni Home-biased Gravity Estimates: Baseline.
Ekn
Bilateral import share (X ni =En )
þ b internalni þ wk ln r kni þ kkn EMi þ f i þ g kn þ kni ;
ki k
ð24Þ
Distance 0.009*** (0.001)
Common border 0.023*** (0.002)
where all variables with a superscript k are defined in the same way Common language 0.014*** (0.002)
Tariff 0.008*** (0.001)
to those without any superscript but in good class k. I run the
Income 0.006*** (0.001)
regressions separately using corresponding data. Internal 0.141** (0.071)
JPN  Immigrant 0.670*** (0.075)
CHN  Immigrant 0.657*** (0.073)
3.2. Main results BRA  Immigrant 0.586*** (0.074)
USA  Immigrant 0.583*** (0.080)
IDN  Immigrant 0.576*** (0.074)
The baseline results are reported in column (1) in Table 1. The AUS  Immigrant 0.556*** (0.087)
estimates of the fixed effects are dropped since they are not the TUR  Immigrant 0.545*** (0.075)
parameters of interest. The estimate of distance elasticity is signif- IND  Immigrant 0.542*** (0.074)
icantly negative at 0.009, suggesting that distance reduces bilat- KOR  Immigrant 0.529*** (0.074)
ITA  Immigrant 0.517*** (0.076)
eral trade flows. Under the assumption that q ¼ 0:177, the
RUS  Immigrant 0.503*** (0.073)
estimate implies that c ¼ 2:03. The additional trade costs—com- ESP  Immigrant 0.495*** (0.078)
mon border, common language, tariff, internal trade—also have CAN  Immigrant 0.491*** (0.085)
the intuitive signs. The estimate of the income elasticity parameter, FIN  Immigrant 0.444*** (0.076)
IRL  Immigrant 0.437*** (0.082)
w, is significantly different from zero at 0.006. This means that peo-
FRA  Immigrant 0.425*** (0.077)
ple in richer countries are more likely to spend on products from ROM  Immigrant 0.417*** (0.074)
richer countries. GRC  Immigrant 0.393*** (0.075)
Table 1 also reports the estimates of the 40 hi parameters, one BGR  Immigrant 0.389*** (0.074)
corresponding to each ethnic group. The four ethnic groups with PRT  Immigrant 0.366*** (0.075)
SWE  Immigrant 0.341*** (0.079)
the highest h values are Japanese, Chinese, Brazilians, and Ameri-
POL  Immigrant 0.340*** (0.074)
cans. The four ethnic groups with the lowest h values are Luxem- MEX  Immigrant 0.334*** (0.074)
bourgers, Maltese, Belgians, and Dutchmen, with taste shifters TWN  Immigrant 0.333*** (0.075)
not different from 0. This indicates that the former ethnicities are LTU  Immigrant 0.327*** (0.076)
DEU  Immigrant 0.304*** (0.080)
highly home-biased consumers, whereas the latter are almost
CZE  Immigrant 0.259*** (0.075)
unbiased. On average, the taste bias measured by the ethnicity- GBR  Immigrant 0.254*** (0.078)
specific immigrant coefficients is 0.352. These results provide evi- AUT  Immigrant 0.252*** (0.081)
dence of the taste bias and estimate the magnitude of the bias for CYP  Immigrant 0.240*** (0.083)
every ethnic group. LVA  Immigrant 0.207** (0.082)
HUN  Immigrant 0.191** (0.076)
To further investigate the taste biases, I also estimate the sec-
SVK  Immigrant 0.181** (0.075)
toral gravity using equation (24) with more disaggregated data. SVN  Immigrant 0.159** (0.074)
First, I estimate the taste biases in the three sectors as shown in EST  Immigrant 0.127 (0.085)
Fig. 1 and the full results are presented in Table A.1 in the appen- DNK  Immigrant 0.116 (0.077)
NLD  Immigrant 0.107 (0.078)
dix. Compared with the manufacturing sector (the baseline esti-
BEL  Immigrant 0.049 (0.080)
mates), the agricultural sector tends to be more favored by home MLT  Immigrant 0.013 (0.079)
consumers, while the service sector is much less biased. In other LUX  Immigrant 0.156 (0.104)
words, consumers have larger taste biases (0.448 on average) in Observations 1600
relation to agricultural products, while almost unbiased (0.053 Adjusted R2 0.973
on average) on services. This makes sense based on the habit for- Mean 0.352
mation assumption that food tastes are even more persistent. Std 0.191
The taste bias is 0.257 on average when pooling all sectors. Note Notes. Table reports the estimates of the home-biased gravity equation using
that Indians are the most biased ethnic group in the agricultural bilateral manufacturing trade data. Exporter- and importer-specific fixed effects are
sector. This is consistent with what we usually observe, whereby both included. Robust standard errors in parentheses. Significance *.10, **.05, ***.01.
Indian immigrants prefer Indian food even though they are usually
highly educated and unbiased. Next, I estimate the results for three
types of goods as shown in Fig. 2 and the full results are presented
in Table A.2 in the Appendix. Import share is more sensitive to effect to some extent, but not all since disaggregation can never be
immigrant share for final goods than for intermediate goods on as fine as reality.
average.
Table 2 shows consumers’ average taste biases for various 3.3. Results with assimilation
industrial goods. They are calculated by the industry-by-industry
results (see Table A.3 and A.4 in the Appendix). Their tastes are To estimate the gravity equation (20), I follow the methodology
more biased for Textiles, Leather, transportation products, and in the baseline estimation. Note that Hi Ei =Y is captured by the
food, beverages, and tobacco, while they are less biased in non- exporter-specific fixed effects. dni is a dummy for internal trade.
metallic minerals, rubber and plastics, and electrical and optical In order to control for the assimilation effect, I proxy the local bias
equipment. The most biased ethnic groups in various industries parameters in a linear way Hn ¼ lT n for all n, where T n is a variable
are also reported. For example, Australians and Americans are that is correlated with the degree of assimilation. Three alterna-
the most biased when buying food, beverages, and tobacco, Japa- tives are provided to measure T n . The first one is a constant,
nese and Koreans are the most biased when buying transportation T n ¼ 1. This indicates that all migrants assimilate at the same
products, and Canadians are the most biased when buying wood degree across all destinations, with the coefficient l > 0. In this
products. More disaggregated estimation reduces the composition case, the assimilation effect is fully captured by the internal trade
8 P. Zhang / World Development 129 (2020) 104863

The second one is the native population share, T n ¼ snn , with


the coefficient l > 0. This is reasonable because immigrants are
more likely to assimilate in a country with a bigger native popu-
lation share in order to adapt to the dominant society. It is equal
to one minus the total immigrant population share for each
destination.
The third one is the share of the refugee population of the des-
tination country, T n ¼ Refugeen , with the coefficient l < 0. Volun-
tary migrants usually have tastes similar to, or converge tastes to
those in the destination, while forced migrants (e.g.. refugees)
are usually less assimilated. Thus the more refugees there are in
the destination country, the less assimilated the immigrants are.
The data is from UNHCR Population Statistics Database which
reports the UNHCR’s populations of concern from the year 1951
up to 2017 by location of residence, origin, and their status (refu-
gees, asylum seekers, etc.). I use the total refugee stock share in
each country until 2010.25 The three destinations with the largest
refugee population share are Malta, Sweden, and Germany, while
Fig. 1. Taste Shifters hi by Sector. Figure plots ethnicity i’s taste bias toward home
the three destinations with the smallest refugee population share
products in different sectors.
are Indonesia, Korea, and Mexico. Given the proxy of the assimilation
degree, the number of local bias parameters to be estimated is
reduced from forty to one. Thus the specification of the gravity equa-
tion (20) is

X ni b l t i
¼ hi sni þ b ln dni þ b borderni þ b lang ni þ b tariffni þ b T n
En
 internalni þ w ln r ni þ kn ai þ f i þ g n þ ni : ð25Þ

In contrast to equation (23), the dummy variable internal here inter-


acts with the proxy variable T n . The basic idea behind this interac-
tion is equivalent to capturing the variation of border barriers
across locations.
The results with the native share as a proxy are reported in col-
umn (2) in Table 3. The coefficient of the interaction term of the
internal trade and the native population share is significantly pos-
itive, which suggests that consumers located in countries with a
higher native share are more likely to exhibit local bias in their
tastes. Table 3 also reports the estimates of the 40 hi parameters,
Fig. 2. Taste Shifters hi by Good. Figure plots ethnicity i’s taste bias toward home
one for each ethnic group. After controlling for local bias in the
products for different types of goods. gravity equation, the home taste shifters estimated are mostly
smaller. On average, the taste bias measured by the ethnicity-
specific immigrant coefficients is 0.302, which is lower than the
Table 2 value of 0.352 in the baseline estimation.
Home-biased Gravity Estimates: by Industry. The results with the refugee population share as a proxy are
Industry Mean Standard Deviation reported in column (3) in Table 3. The coefficient of the interaction
term of the internal trade and the refugee share is significantly
Aggregate 0.352 0.189
Textiles 0.893 0.258 negative, which suggests that immigrants at the countries with lar-
Leather and footwear 0.783 0.349 ger refugee shares are less likely to exhibit local bias in their tastes.
Transport equipment 0.479 0.266 After controlling for local bias in the gravity equation, the home
Food, beverages, and tobacco 0.454 0.207 taste shifters estimated are mostly further smaller. On average,
Machinery 0.408 0.240
the taste bias measured by the ethnicity-specific immigrant coeffi-
Chemical products 0.375 0.276
Manufacturing, nec 0.349 0.230 cients is 0.282, which is lower than the value of 0.352 in the base-
Basic metals and fabricated metal 0.311 0.198 line estimation. Here, the three ethnic groups with the highest h
Wood products 0.222 0.191 values are Chinese, Japanese, and Americans. The three ethnic
Printing and publishing 0.196 0.180
groups with the lowest h values are Luxembourgers, Maltese, and
Electrical and optical equipment 0.192 0.214
Rubber and plastics 0.050 0.256
Belgians.
Other non-metallic minerals 0.001 0.145 Overall, compared with the baseline results, the taste bias esti-
mated with assimilation is smaller on average. Without assimila-
Notes: Table reports the estimates of home-biased gravity equation with industrial
trade flow data. Only the means and the standard deviations of the taste bias
tion, the taste bias is overestimated. But the differences are
estimates are reported. Robust standard errors in parentheses. Significance *.10, moderate for most ethnic groups, which implies that the baseline
**.05, ***.01. estimation results are robust.

dummy variable and, thus, the specification is the same as the


baseline estimation. In other words, the baseline estimates are 25
Since 2007, the refugee population also includes people in a refugee-like
equivalent to those with symmetric assimilation. situation.
P. Zhang / World Development 129 (2020) 104863 9

Table 3
Home-biased Gravity Estimates: Assimilation.

(1) (2) (3)


Import share Import share Import share
Distance 0.009*** (0.001) 0.009*** (0.001) 0.009*** (0.001)
Border 0.023*** (0.002) 0.023*** (0.002) 0.023*** (0.002)
Language 0.014*** (0.002) 0.014*** (0.002) 0.014*** (0.002)
Tariff 0.008*** (0.001) 0.008*** (0.001) 0.008*** (0.001)
Income 0.006*** (0.001) 0.006*** (0.001) 0.006*** (0.001)
Internal 0.141** (0.071)
Internal  Native share 0.308*** (0.102)
Internal  Refugee share 0.009*** (0.003)
JPN  Immigrant 0.670*** (0.075) 0.590*** (0.076) 0.576*** (0.079)
CHN  Immigrant 0.657*** (0.073) 0.568*** (0.079) 0.588*** (0.070)
BRA  Immigrant 0.586*** (0.074) 0.498*** (0.079) 0.495*** (0.078)
USA  Immigrant 0.583*** (0.080) 0.549*** (0.065) 0.521*** (0.072)
IDN  Immigrant 0.576*** (0.074) 0.488*** (0.078) 0.467*** (0.083)
AUS  Immigrant 0.556*** (0.087) 0.587*** (0.049) 0.490*** (0.078)
TUR  Immigrant 0.545*** (0.075) 0.467*** (0.075) 0.469*** (0.073)
IND  Immigrant 0.542*** (0.074) 0.453*** (0.080) 0.470*** (0.072)
KOR  Immigrant 0.529*** (0.074) 0.448*** (0.076) 0.426*** (0.082)
ITA  Immigrant 0.517*** (0.076) 0.450*** (0.073) 0.458*** (0.068)
RUS  Immigrant 0.503*** (0.073) 0.417*** (0.077) 0.417*** (0.075)
ESP  Immigrant 0.495*** (0.078) 0.446*** (0.068) 0.410*** (0.078)
CAN  Immigrant 0.491*** (0.085) 0.505*** (0.053) 0.444*** (0.071)
FIN  Immigrant 0.444*** (0.076) 0.376*** (0.073) 0.390*** (0.067)
IRL  Immigrant 0.437*** (0.082) 0.427*** (0.059) 0.381*** (0.072)
FRA  Immigrant 0.425*** (0.077) 0.365*** (0.071) 0.378*** (0.065)
ROM  Immigrant 0.417*** (0.074) 0.329*** (0.078) 0.332*** (0.075)
GRC  Immigrant 0.393*** (0.075) 0.314*** (0.076) 0.317*** (0.073)
BGR  Immigrant 0.389*** (0.074) 0.303*** (0.078) 0.330*** (0.067)
PRT  Immigrant 0.366*** (0.075) 0.300*** (0.072) 0.276*** (0.078)
SWE  Immigrant 0.341*** (0.079) 0.299*** (0.067) 0.303*** (0.064)
POL  Immigrant 0.340*** (0.074) 0.255*** (0.077) 0.275*** (0.069)
MEX  Immigrant 0.334*** (0.074) 0.248*** (0.077) 0.236*** (0.079)
TWN  Immigrant 0.333*** (0.075) 0.258*** (0.075) 0.221*** (0.085)
LTU  Immigrant 0.327*** (0.076) 0.263*** (0.072) 0.256*** (0.073)
DEU  Immigrant 0.304*** (0.080) 0.272*** (0.065) 0.264*** (0.065)
CZE  Immigrant 0.259*** (0.075) 0.180** (0.076) 0.188*** (0.071)
GBR  Immigrant 0.254*** (0.078) 0.206*** (0.068) 0.208*** (0.066)
AUT  Immigrant 0.252*** (0.081) 0.228*** (0.062) 0.208*** (0.067)
CYP  Immigrant 0.240*** (0.083) 0.236*** (0.058) 0.192*** (0.070)
LVA  Immigrant 0.207** (0.082) 0.195*** (0.059) 0.109 (0.085)
HUN  Immigrant 0.191** (0.076) 0.125* (0.073) 0.128* (0.070)
SVK  Immigrant 0.181** (0.075) 0.109 (0.074) 0.100 (0.075)
SVN  Immigrant 0.159** (0.074) 0.076 (0.077) 0.084 (0.072)
EST  Immigrant 0.127 (0.085) 0.138** (0.054) 0.024 (0.088)
DNK  Immigrant 0.116 (0.077) 0.057 (0.071) 0.069 (0.065)
NLD  Immigrant 0.107 (0.078) 0.057 (0.069) 0.063 (0.065)
BEL  Immigrant 0.049 (0.080) 0.017 (0.064) 0.007 (0.070)
MLT  Immigrant 0.013 (0.079) 0.062 (0.069) 0.046 (0.062)
LUX  Immigrant 0.156 (0.104) 0.025 (0.025) 0.211** (0.086)
Observations 1600 1600 1600
Adjusted R2 0.973 0.973 0.973
Mean 0.352 0.302 0.282
Std 0.191 0.174 0.185

Notes. Table reports the estimates of the home-biased gravity equation after controlling for local bias. Exporter- and importer-specific fixed effects are both included. Robust
standard errors in parentheses. Significance *.10, **.05, ***.01.

3.4. Other results The results are reported in Table 4. Column (1) shows the esti-
mates of the coefficients and the estimates of fixed effects are
3.4.1. Symmetric bias dropped since they are not the parameters of interest. The estimate
To compare the estimates with those found in the extant liter- of distance elasticity is significantly negative, suggesting that bilat-
ature, I also estimate the symmetric home-biased gravity. The eral distance reduces trade flow between countries. The coeffi-
econometric specification of equation (14) is cients of the other gravity variables are also significant. The
X ni coefficient of immigrant share is estimated to be 0.405, signifi-
¼ hsni þ b ln dni þ b borderni þ b lang ni þ f i þ g n þ v ni ;
b l
ð26Þ cantly different from zero, which confirms the existence of con-
En
sumer taste bias. This result is also close to the average taste
where f i ¼ YYi  hPs þ c0 ln Pi and g n ¼ c0 ln P n  hPsi . To make the
shifter estimate of 0.352 in the baseline regression.
estimates comparable with literature, I drop the sample of domestic
I also use equation (26) to obtain estimates for a different cross-
trade shares and keep foreign trade observations only. Thus, the tar-
section, the year of 2000. The reason for this is to check that the
iff term is captured by the importer’s fixed effect,26 and the internal
results are not the artifact of a particular time period. Column (2)
trade dummy is dropped.
reports the estimates. The taste bias estimate is 0.467, which is
similar to that in 2010, confirming the robustness of the results.
26
Our measure of a country’s tariff is the average rate across all its trade partners.
10 P. Zhang / World Development 129 (2020) 104863

Table 4
Symmetric Home-biased Gravity Estimates.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)


Share Share 2000 Share log Flow log Flow log Flow (PPML)
Immigrant share 0.405** 0.467**
(0.204) (0.205)
Distance 0.010*** 0.010*** 0.010*** 1.305*** 1.060*** 0.862***
(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.045) (0.050) (0.039)
Common border 0.024*** 0.023*** 0.026*** 0.304*** 0.161 0.293***
(0.004) (0.005) (0.005) (0.118) (0.104) (0.073)
Common language 0.012*** 0.013*** 0.014*** 0.379*** 0.299** 0.217**
(0.004) (0.005) (0.004) (0.140) (0.129) (0.089)
log Immigrant stock 0.173*** 0.088***
(0.019) (0.018)
Constant 0.106*** 0.108*** 0.110*** 19.393*** 17.865*** 15.013***
(0.013) (0.014) (0.013) (0.528) (0.553) (0.429)
Observations 1560 1560 1560 1560 1560 1560
Adjusted R2 0.598 0.538 0.590 0.915 0.925

Notes: Table reports the estimates of symmetric home-biased gravity equation with manufacturing trade flow data. Exporter- and importer-specific fixed effects are both
included. Robust standard errors in parentheses. Significance *.10, **.05, ***.01.

This is consistent with my basic assumption that consumer tastes immigrants from different source countries is a potential candidate
are persistent. Column (3) tests the gravity after shutting down the for an instrumental variable for migration.28 Previous immigrant
taste bias, i.e.. translog gravity, and the results are very similar to share is a relevant instrument, but the limitation is that the immi-
those in Novy (2013). Together with the results as shown in col- grant stock is usually quite persistent.
umn (1), they reveal that the coefficients of the traditional gravity The second instrument is the exogenous push factor. I instru-
variables change very little regardless of whether the additional ment the immigrant share by the interaction of natural disasters
migration variable is included. This implies that migration share of origin and the distance to the destination. Llull (2018) proposes
is not correlated with the traditional gravity variables, and explains a novel approach by using the exogenous variation obtained from
a part of the variance in trade shares that traditional gravity vari- the interaction of push factors, distance, and skill cells to study the
ables do not capture. effect of immigration on wages. Four push factors are considered in
For sake of completeness, I also check the specifications of the his paper: wars, political regime changes, natural disasters, and
CES structural gravity in the literature. Column (4) estimates the economic variables.29 I use natural disasters in my paper because
standard CES structural gravity. Since the dependent variable is the other three variables might either affect or be affected by trade.
in log form, the estimated elasticity differs from that as shown in The natural disaster of the migrant-sending country is origin-
the first three columns. Column (5) adds the immigrant stock in specific, and is thus captured by the origin fixed effect in the regres-
log as an additional dependent variable which measures the level sion. Thus I interact the natural disaster with distance. It is reason-
of migration. The trade flow increases by 0.173 percent when the able because the natural disaster pushes more migrants to
immigrant population increases by 1 percent. I also check the neighboring countries than to countries that are further away. Nat-
results by using the PPML method along the gold-standard of the ural disasters, calculated from EMDAT database, are measured as
gravity literature and report the estimation in column (6). Com- the average fraction of the population affected (needed immediate
pared with the OLS estimation in column (5), both the distance assistance, displaced, or evacuated) by natural disasters (droughts,
and immigrant elasticity are smaller in magnitude while the bor- earthquakes, floods, and storms) during 1950–2010. The two coun-
der coefficient becomes larger. Since the differences are not large, tries with the largest population share affected by natural disasters
the OLS results are robust overall. are China and India (31.8% and 31.4%, respectively). I use the multi-
plicative inverse of the log distance to make the instrument posi-
3.4.2. Endogeneity tively correlated with the immigrant share, in order to consistently
There are some concerns related to the estimation. The first is compare with the first instrument, previous immigrant share, which
that the immigrant share may be correlated with trade shocks. is also positively correlated with the endogenous variable.
When this is the case, the OLS estimation leads to inconsistent I start with estimating the level equation of the gravity model,
results. Such endogeneity bias can arise from two sources. The first equation (26) by two-stage least square method. The results are
is reverse causality. It is possible that a positive shock to the value reported in Table 5. Taking the previous immigrant share as the
of bilateral trade between the two countries leads to more migra- instrument, the coefficient of immigration is 0.321 (with standard
tion between them. For example, more people might migrate inter- deviation of 0.169), positively significant as shown in column (2). It
nationally to do business associated with more international trade. is only 0.084 less than the OLS estimate as shown in column (1).
The second is omitted variables. Migration may be correlated with And column (3) reports the results using natural disasters inter-
unobserved factors that also affect trade, such as the trading part- acted with distance to instrument the immigrant share. The coeffi-
ners’ cultural similarity or bilateral economic policies.27 cient is 0.289 (with standard deviation of 0.139), positively
To address the possible endogeneity problem, I use two instru- significant too. It is only 0.116 less than the OLS estimate as shown
mental variables and conduct two sets of estimations based on in column (1). The second-stage results show that the potential
level and difference equations. The first instrument is the lagged endogeneity problem leads to an overestimation of the taste bias.
variable. I instrument the share of immigrants in 2010 by that in However, the effect is negligible since the differences remain
2000. Altonji and Card (1991) used past settlements of immigrants within one standard deviation.
as instruments for current inflows. Card (2001) suggests that his-
torical settlement patterns and the total number of newly arriving 28
See Hanson (2010) and Llull (2018) for more discussion on valid instruments for
migration.
27 29
There is a large literature that discusses the factors that affect international Llull (2018) builds a structural model in which immigration and wage are both
migration. See more detailed discussion in De (2010). endogenously determined.
P. Zhang / World Development 129 (2020) 104863 11

Table 5 arrive from Asia, driven in large part by the arrival of Indian and Chi-
Symmetric Home-biased Gravity Estimates: Endogeneity. nese immigrants. Recall that the baseline model results (Section 3.2),
(1) (2) (3) in which taste bias is asymmetric across ethnic groups, Chinese and
Share Share Share Indians are two of the most biased consumers among the 40 groups.
Immigrant share 0.405** 0.321* 0.289** Since the coefficient of immigrant share estimated in the difference
(0.204) (0.169) (0.139) model measures the average taste bias across all new immigrants
Distance 0.010*** 0.010*** 0.010*** during 2000–2010, it turns out to be quite larger than that in the
(0.001) (0.001) (0.001)
Common border 0.024*** 0.024*** 0.023***
level model, mostly driven by Chinese and Indian immigrants, as
(0.004) (0.004) (0.004) well as those from other Asian countries.
Common language 0.012*** 0.013*** 0.014*** Although the difference model can partially solve the omitted
(0.004) (0.004) (0.004) variable problem, it cannot address the endogeneity coming from
Constant 0.106*** 0.107*** 0.104***
trade shocks that cause migration. Again I instrument the change
(0.013) (0.013) (0.012)
of immigrant share by the interaction of natural disasters and
First stage
the distance. The results are reported in column (3) in Table 6.
lagged Immigrant share (Instrument) 0.972***
(0.038) The coefficient is 0.237, positively significant. It is robust using
Natural disaster  Distance 0.128*** the gravity variables (distance, border, and language) as controls
(Instrument) as shown in column (4). The first-stage results are also reported.
(0.006) The coefficients of the instrumental variable are significantly pos-
F-stats 41.208 44.330 itive. The exclusion F-statistics are reported too. Thus both instru-
Observations 1560 1560 1560 ments are not weak. Compared with the OLS results of the
R2 0.619 0.618 0.605
difference model as shown in column (1) and (2), the coefficients
Notes: Table reports the estimates of symmetric home-biased gravity equation with of the change of the immigrant share are much smaller, implying
instrumental variables. Exporter- and importer-specific fixed effects are both the OLS estimates indeed suffer an endogeneity problem. For
included. Robust standard errors in parentheses. Significance *.10, **.05, ***.01. example, joining WTO in 2001 made both the trade share of Chi-
nese products and the population share of Chinese immigrants
I also check whether the two instruments are valid for the
grow faster. Thus the OLS method overestimates the coefficient
immigrant share in 2010. Table 5 also reports the first-stage results
due to the omitted time-varying variables. So the instrumental
corresponding to the two second-stage coefficients. They use the
variable is needed when estimating the difference model. Com-
same control-variable settings. The coefficients of both instrumen-
pared with the baseline result of 0.405 as shown in column (1) in
tal variables are significantly positive.30 The exclusion F-statistics
Table 5, the result combining both the difference model and the
are reported in Table 5. Thus both instruments are not weak.
instrumental variable is smaller, but the difference remains moder-
To further check if the baseline estimates are biased due to that
ate. Thus the baseline results are robust.
both migration and trade are influenced by time-invariant factors,
Overall, the results in this section suggest that the baseline esti-
like the mentioned cultural similarity, I also estimate the gravity
mation results are robust, although the endogeneity problem
equation by taking first differences between the two cross-
causes overestimation to some extent. The magnitude of the esti-
sections to eliminate any potential time-invariant omitted vari-
mation bias is small, and endogeneity issues are not significant
ables. More specifically, I estimate
concerns. One reason is that immigrant stock share is a state vari-
X ni able, which accumulates over a long period, while import share is a
¼ hDsni þ f i þ g 0n þ v 0ni ;
0
D ð27Þ flow variable, which is recorded annually in the dataset. Thus,
En
there is a very weak reverse causality. Moreover, different from
where D is the difference between the corresponding variable in the trade flow which is more likely to be correlated with the omit-
0
2010 and 2000, and f i (g 0n ) is the difference between origin (destina- ted variables that affect migration, trade share is much less since
tion) fixed effect in 2010 and 2000. The differences corresponding the endogenous variation in trade flow is partially offset by the
to the gravity variables (distance, border, and language) are can- total flow that is also correlated with omitted variables that affect
celed out since they are time-invariant and their coefficients remain migration. Another reason is that a large proportion of interna-
constant over time.31 tional migration is for non-economic reasons, e.g.. conflict, climate,
The results are reported in column (1) in Table 6. The migration education, religion, or economic factors but unrelated to trade, e.g..
coefficient is 0.782, which remains significantly different from job opportunities. This makes the migration more exogenous.
zero. It is robust using the gravity variables (distance, border,
and language) as controls as shown in column (2). The immigrant 3.4.3. Alternative channel
share coefficients estimated in the difference model, equation (27), The second related concern is that the coefficient of immigrant
is much larger than that in the level model, equation (26). The pos- shares may capture the effects of factors other than taste bias. The
sible reason is that the composition of the world immigrants has taste shifters may be overestimated because migration increases
changed after 2000. The population of Asian immigrants has grown trade not only through the preference channel but also through
faster than others. For example, the U.S. Asian population grew 72% the trade cost channel. As Rauch (2001) and Rauch and Trindade
between 2000 and 2015, the fastest growth rate of any major racial (2002) argue, migration builds up business, and social networks
or ethnic group.32 Although the majority of the U.S. foreign-born across national borders can help to alleviate problems related to
residents are Latin American, recent immigrants are most likely to contract enforcement and provide information about trading
opportunities. In order to check the network channel, I construct
30
Note the inverse of the distance is used, and thus the instrument is positively a new variable
correlated to the immigrant share.
31
I also keep the gravity variables in the regression for robustness checkS. See X
N

Table 6. Networkni ¼ snj sij : ð28Þ


32 j¼1
The data is from the U.S. Census Bureau. See the report of the Fact Tank news
https://www.pewresearch.org/fact-tank/2017/09/08/key-facts-about-asian-ameri-
cans/https://www.pewresearch.org/fact-tank/2017/09/08/key-facts-about-asian- This variable represents the probability that, if we select an individ-
americans/. ual at random from each country, they will have a connection
12 P. Zhang / World Development 129 (2020) 104863

Table 6
Symmetric Home-biased Gravity Estimates: Endogeneity (Difference Model).

(1) (2) (3) (4)


D Share D Share D Share D Share
D Immigrant share 0.782*** 0.839*** 0.237*** 0.215***
(0.214) (0.215) (0.078) (0.056)
Distance 0.000 0.002**
(0.000) (0.001)
Common border 0.002 0.007
(0.001) (0.007)
Common language 0.004*** 0.018**
(0.001) (0.007)
Constant 0.000* 0.002 0.004** 0.019**
(0.000) (0.002) (0.002) (0.008)
First stage
Natural disaster  Distance (Instrument) 0.005*** 0.006***
(0.001) (0.001)
F-stats 64.451 22.643
Observations 1560 1560 1560 1560

Notes: Table reports the estimates of symmetric home-biased gravity equation in difference with instrumental variables. Exporter- and importer-specific fixed effects are both
included. Robust standard errors in parentheses. Significance *.10, **.05, ***.01.

defined as common national origin. By construction, it is symmetric 4. Counterfactuals


for country pairs. When j ¼ CHN, it is an indirect link identical to
that in Rauch and Trindade (2002), and when j ¼ n; i, it is a summa- 4.1. Variation decomposition
tion of two direct links, similar to that in Combes et al. (2005). How-
ever, my measure extends these links to a summation of all indirect First, I examine the extent to which the trade bias can be
and both direct links, and thus captures the network effect as much explained by the taste effect, trade cost effect, and income effect,
as possible. Then, I re-specify the bilateral trade cost by adding a respectively. Recall the formula implied by home-biased gravity
new variable, Network, and rerun the regression using equation equation
(26) to control for the possible network channel.   r
The results presented in Table 7 show that the coefficients of   tnn n
HBn ¼ hn snn  hn Psn  an P sn cbn ln þ /n ln :
network is insignificant both with migration included as shown |fflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflffl{zfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflffl} P P
n n |fflfflfflfflfflffl
ffl r ffl}
{zfflfflfflfflfflffl
G s |fflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflffl
ffl {zfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflffl
ffl }
in column (2), and without migration as shown in (4). Column n
Gtn Gin
(3) and (5) show the results when emigration share is added, but
this coefficient is not significant either. This is straightforward, Specifically, I term the taste effect, trade cost effect, and income
because emigrants contribute to the bilateral network, but not to effect as Gsn , Gtn , and Gin respectively. Then I calculate the contribu-
the preference effect. Column (6) checks the network effect in tion of each effect to the trade bias of each country by
CES gravity. The coefficient of network is 13.504, which is signifi- l
Contributionn ¼ Gln =HBn where l ¼ s; t; i. Column (1) in Table 8 lists
cantly positive, consistent with the findings of Rauch and
the trade biases for 40 countries, which are the deviations of the
Trindade (2002), which implies that my measure of the network
home shares from their frictionless levels in the manufacturing sec-
effect is valid. All of this evidence indicates that the network chan-
tor. The average bias is 54%. Columns (2)-(4) report the percentage
nel has negligible effect on the import share of aggregate manufac-
contributions of the three effects on trade bias. On average, 43.2% of
turing products. Moreover, different to trade flow which is more
the market trade bias is explained by the trade cost, 56.3% by the
likely to be affected by network, trade share is much less since
home-biased taste, only 0.5% by the income effect. In other words,
the network effect in trade flow is partially offset by the total flows
the trade cost and the home-biased taste are the main causes of
that is also affected by network effect.
the trade bias, while the income effect is negligible. Head and

Table 7
Symmetric Home-biased Gravity Estimates: Network Effect.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)


Share Share Share Share Share log Flow
Immigrant share 0.405** 0.604** 0.398**
(0.204) (0.242) (0.202)
Distance 0.010*** 0.010*** 0.010*** 0.010*** 0.010*** 1.291***
(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.045)
Common border 0.024*** 0.025*** 0.025*** 0.025*** 0.027*** 0.147
(0.004) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.120)
Common language 0.012*** 0.013*** 0.013*** 0.013*** 0.014*** 0.296**
(0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.005) (0.134)
Network 0.212 0.097 13.504***
(0.136) (0.096) (2.761)
Emigrant share 0.192 0.207
(0.130) (0.134)
Constant 0.106*** 0.108*** 0.108*** 0.108*** 0.111*** 19.160***
(0.013) (0.013) (0.013) (0.013) (0.013) (0.529)
Observations 1560 1560 1560 1560 1560 1560
Adjusted R2 0.598 0.599 0.599 0.591 0.592 0.916

Notes: Table reports the estimates of symmetric home-biased gravity equation with the migration network effect controlled. Exporter- and importer-specific fixed effects are
both included. Robust standard errors in parentheses. Significance *.10, **.05, ***.01.
P. Zhang / World Development 129 (2020) 104863 13

Mayer (2013) show that between 50% and 85% of the distance effect to 1. How does the country’s trade bias respond to this shock?
on trade flows are the result of the indirect trade costs (that they Using the equation above, I calculate the percentage change in
term as ‘‘dark trade costs”). Cosßar et al. (2018) estimate the home trade bias DHBn =HBn for each country. The results are reported in
bias in the automobile market and conclude that about 2/3 of the column (2) in Table 9. The increase in trade bias is small, only
reduced form home bias is due to the taste effect. Compared with 3.7% on average. However, the increase is much greater for immi-
those findings, my results showing that the contribution of the taste grant countries, with Australia’s trade bias increasing by 12.8% and
effect is 56.3% is reasonable and consistent. that of Canada increasing by 10.5%. A ban on immigration in the U.
S. would increase the intra-national trade by 6.6%.
4.2. Policy implications Note that the net change of the home market share due to the
migration ban is not necessarily positive. For example, in Table 9,
In this subsection, I discuss how migration policy affects the the home share of China decreases by 26.6% if all foreign immigrants
trade bias using the parameter values estimated in the baseline leave and all Chinese emigrants return. The intuition is that the mul-
regression. If the bilateral immigrant share snn changes, it has a tilateral promoter (Psn ) increases much more than the bilateral pro-
direct effect on the corresponding trade bias HBn . However, the moter (snn , more precisely internal promoter since n ¼ i). China has
change in snn also has an indirect effect on trade bias through a a very small immigrant population, and, thus, the migration ban
change in multilateral promoters. Specifically, raises the native population share very little. But a large amount
of Chinese emigrants return and consume at home without paying
DHBn ¼ hn Dsnn hn DPsn  an DP sn ð29Þ
|fflfflffl{zfflfflffl} |fflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflffl{zfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflffl} trade costs for Chinese products any more. This increases the global
direct effect indirect effect demand for Chinese products, and then the price of Chinese prod-
The taste bias hn only captures the direct effect of a change in snn on ucts relative to that of the foreign product (partially captured by
HBn . The indirect effect is captured by the multilateral promoters Psn ) goes up. This term of trade effect makes Chinese consumers
hn DPsn and an DP sn . spend smaller expenditure shares on the home products. This also
Consider an extreme migration policy, such as a ban on migra- happens for some other countries sending a large amount of
tion, for country n, in an effort to raise the native population share migrants globally, e.g.. India and Japan as shown in Table 9.

Table 8 Table 9
Counterfactuals: Contribution Decomposition. Counterfactuals: Migration Policy Implications.

Share Contribution of (%) Shares % D shares with


Trade bias Trade cost Taste Income Country Trade Bias Zero migration Full migration
Brazil 86.3 34.5 65.2 0.3 Brazil 86.3 0.6 66.1
India 84.1 35.9 62.1 2.1 India 84.1 0.6 62.8
Indonesia 81.5 29.7 69.4 1.0 Indonesia 81.5 0.9 68.7
Japan 79.7 25.6 74.3 0.1 Japan 79.7 5.0 80.7
Korea 77.1 34.7 65.2 0.1 Korea 77.1 0.2 66.0
Turkey 75.5 30.2 69.8 0.1 Turkey 75.5 2.1 69.0
Russia 74.2 34.0 66.0 0.0 Russia 74.2 0.4 65.9
Australia 70.4 33.6 66.2 0.2 Australia 70.4 12.8 65.1
Italy 68.5 29.4 70.4 0.1 Italy 68.5 2.0 71.0
Spain 65.3 29.9 70.1 0.1 Spain 65.3 4.9 69.5
China 62.9 24.9 74.3 0.8 China 62.9 26.6 101.9
Finland 62.8 31.5 68.3 0.2 Finland 62.8 4.2 66.5
Canada 62.4 33.3 66.5 0.2 Canada 62.4 10.5 66.2
United States 61.3 26.8 72.9 0.4 United States 61.3 6.3 85.4
Romania 60.9 31.6 68.3 0.1 Romania 60.9 2.3 66.4
Ireland 59.1 33.5 66.1 0.4 Ireland 59.1 9.9 64.3
Greece 58.6 33.8 66.2 0.0 Greece 58.6 3.2 64.2
France 58.6 32.2 67.6 0.2 France 58.6 2.7 67.7
Bulgaria 58.5 33.4 66.5 0.1 Bulgaria 58.5 2.7 64.4
Taiwan 58.4 43.6 56.1 0.3 Taiwan 58.4 3.0 54.5
Mexico 58.2 42.9 56.8 0.3 Mexico 58.2 1.7 55.6
Portugal 56.1 36.7 63.3 0.0 Portugal 56.1 4.5 61.3
Poland 53.5 36.6 63.4 0.0 Poland 53.5 2.5 61.4
Sweden 51.8 37.9 61.8 0.3 Sweden 51.8 6.6 59.7
Lithuania 51.6 38.6 61.4 0.0 Lithuania 51.6 5.0 59.3
Germany 49.3 44.3 55.4 0.3 Germany 49.3 4.4 55.3
Czech 45.0 42.5 57.5 0.0 Czech 45.0 3.7 55.1
United Kingdom 43.8 44.4 55.3 0.2 United Kingdom 43.8 5.2 53.2
Cyprus 42.9 49.8 50.0 0.2 Cyprus 42.9 9.6 48.2
Austria 42.2 44.0 55.5 0.5 Austria 42.2 8.3 52.9
Latvia 39.6 52.2 47.7 0.0 Latvia 39.6 9.0 45.4
Hungary 38.5 50.3 49.7 0.0 Hungary 38.5 5.1 46.8
Slovakia 37.2 51.2 48.8 0.0 Slovakia 37.2 4.9 46.1
Slovenia 35.7 55.0 45.0 0.0 Slovenia 35.7 4.3 42.8
Estonia 32.1 64.8 35.2 0.0 Estonia 32.1 9.7 33.0
Denmark 31.9 62.7 36.7 0.6 Denmark 31.9 5.9 33.7
Netherlands 31.8 64.7 34.5 0.8 Netherlands 31.8 6.1 30.7
Belgium 25.4 77.7 21.5 0.7 Belgium 25.4 7.0 17.1
Malta 20.9 99.7 0.2 0.1 Malta 20.9 6.8 0.3
Luxembourg 10.3 89.6 0.9 9.5 Luxembourg 10.3 15.5 2.4
Mean 54.1 43.2 56.3 0.5 Mean 54.1 3.7 56.0
St.d. 18.0 16.9 17.6 1.5 St.d. 18.0 6.5 20.1

Notes: Table reports the contribution decomposition of the home bias in trade. Notes: Table reports the policy implications of the home-biased gravity.
14 P. Zhang / World Development 129 (2020) 104863

Conversely, if we removed all migration barriers for country n whether the taste biases differ within ethnic groups. Second, differ-
and allow consumers to freely migrate across its borders, country ent generations of migrants would enable us to check whether
n would eventually have exactly the same ethnic composition as taste bias decays over time. More challenging and perhaps beyond
the world population. The results are shown in column (3) in Table 9. the scope of the present model, is identifying the deep underlying
The trade bias decreases by 56% on average, which is much greater causes of taste bias formation. These are all promising directions
than the increase in the case of the migration ban. China’s trade for future research.
biases will decline the most because China has a very small immi-
grant population and Chinese consumers are highly biased in taste. Declaration of Competing Interest

The authors declare that they have no known competing finan-


5. Conclusion
cial interests or personal relationships that could have appeared
to influence the work reported in this paper.
Trade models usually assume identical preferences across con-
sumers. Differences in demand across countries, such as home-
biased tastes, are often included in unobservable ‘‘trade costs,” Acknowledgement
which are indistinguishable. Thus, it is important to quantitatively
assess the two because declines in trade costs and the homogeniza- I would also like to thank the editor, two anonymous referees,
tion of tastes have different implications for trade policies and wel- James Anderson, Pol Antrás, David Atkin, Susanto Basu, Pablo
fare changes. This paper provides a structural component of home- Fajgelbaum, Yushan Hu, Amit Khandelwal, Arthur Lewbel, Ben Li,
biased preferences that is feasible to estimate. Bilateral market James Rauch, Roberto Rigobon, Fabio Schiantarelli, Felix Tintelnot,
tastes are determined by combining bilateral migration and Zhijie Xiao, Juanjuan Zhang and the seminar participants at Boston
migrants’ taste bias. I estimate taste bias for each ethnic group and College, MIT Sloan School of Management, Tsinghua University, the
find that taste bias explains more of the trade bias than trade costs. meetings of the Midwest International Economics Group, as well as
The home-biased gravity model suggests several extensions. the European Trade Study Group. All errors are mine. This research
First, endogenous migration can be included in the model to derive did not receive any specific grant from funding agencies in the
more policy implications. Second, another potential extension is to public, commercial, or not-for-profit sectors.
allow for within-country income differences to further investigate
variations in taste biases. Empirically, there are some other possi- Appendix A. Appendix to tables
ble extensions. First, more information on immigrants, such as
their level of education, age, and religion could be included to test Tables A.1–A.4.

Table A.1
Home-biased Gravity Estimates: by Sector.

(1) (2) (3) (4)


Manufacturing (Baseline) Agricultural Service Total
Distance 0.009*** (0.001) 0.005*** (0.001) 0.001*** (0.000) 0.001*** (0.000)
Border 0.023*** (0.002) 0.022*** (0.003) 0.001 (0.001) 0.010*** (0.001)
Language 0.014*** (0.002) 0.010*** (0.003) 0.002** (0.001) 0.005*** (0.001)
Tariff 0.008*** (0.001) 0.000 (0.000) 0.006 (0.007) 0.000 (0.000)
Income 0.006*** (0.001) 0.001** (0.000) 0.002*** (0.000) 0.000*** (0.000)
Internal 0.141** (0.071) 0.253** (0.104) 0.807*** (0.080) 0.556*** (0.039)
JPN  Immigrant 0.670*** (0.075) 0.409*** (0.109) 0.094** (0.037) 0.382*** (0.041)
CHN  Immigrant 0.657*** (0.073) 0.637*** (0.108) 0.118*** (0.033) 0.368*** (0.040)
BRA  Immigrant 0.586*** (0.074) 0.665*** (0.108) 0.092*** (0.032) 0.378*** (0.040)
USA  Immigrant 0.583*** (0.080) 0.606*** (0.117) 0.149** (0.060) 0.392*** (0.044)
IDN  Immigrant 0.576*** (0.074) 0.678*** (0.108) 0.108*** (0.030) 0.356*** (0.041)
AUS  Immigrant 0.556*** (0.087) 0.776*** (0.127) 0.167** (0.074) 0.412*** (0.048)
TUR  Immigrant 0.545*** (0.075) 0.684*** (0.109) 0.018 (0.100) 0.332*** (0.041)
IND  Immigrant 0.542*** (0.074) 0.694*** (0.108) 0.071 (0.218) 0.372*** (0.040)
KOR  Immigrant 0.529*** (0.074) 0.266** (0.109) 0.059 (0.146) 0.289*** (0.041)
ITA  Immigrant 0.517*** (0.076) 0.353*** (0.111) 0.109*** (0.031) 0.328*** (0.042)
RUS  Immigrant 0.503*** (0.073) 0.626*** (0.106) 0.103*** (0.029) 0.334*** (0.040)
ESP  Immigrant 0.495*** (0.078) 0.466*** (0.114) 0.105*** (0.032) 0.329*** (0.043)
CAN  Immigrant 0.491*** (0.085) 0.586*** (0.124) 0.087*** (0.033) 0.322*** (0.047)
FIN  Immigrant 0.444*** (0.076) 0.352*** (0.111) 0.056* (0.031) 0.262*** (0.042)
IRL  Immigrant 0.437*** (0.082) 0.545*** (0.120) 0.216*** (0.034) 0.086* (0.045)
FRA  Immigrant 0.425*** (0.077) 0.532*** (0.112) 0.116*** (0.031) 0.319*** (0.042)
ROM  Immigrant 0.417*** (0.074) 0.617*** (0.108) 0.095*** (0.030) 0.261*** (0.041)
GRC  Immigrant 0.393*** (0.075) 0.510*** (0.109) 0.082*** (0.031) 0.279*** (0.041)
BGR  Immigrant 0.389*** (0.074) 0.393*** (0.108) 0.078*** (0.030) 0.224*** (0.041)
PRT  Immigrant 0.366*** (0.075) 0.486*** (0.110) 0.096*** (0.031) 0.275*** (0.041)
SWE  Immigrant 0.341*** (0.079) 0.406*** (0.115) 0.064** (0.032) 0.256*** (0.043)
POL  Immigrant 0.340*** (0.074) 0.514*** (0.108) 0.086*** (0.030) 0.243*** (0.041)
MEX  Immigrant 0.334*** (0.074) 0.639*** (0.108) 0.105*** (0.029) 0.274*** (0.041)
TWN  Immigrant 0.333*** (0.075) 0.253** (0.110) 0.061** (0.029) 0.215*** (0.041)
LTU  Immigrant 0.327*** (0.076) 0.126 (0.111) 0.054* (0.031) 0.181*** (0.042)
DEU  Immigrant 0.304*** (0.080) 0.291** (0.117) 0.102*** (0.033) 0.281*** (0.044)
CZE  Immigrant 0.259*** (0.075) 0.462*** (0.109) 0.070** (0.031) 0.176*** (0.041)
GBR  Immigrant 0.254*** (0.078) 0.487*** (0.114) 0.091*** (0.032) 0.310*** (0.043)
AUT  Immigrant 0.252*** (0.081) 0.390*** (0.118) 0.075** (0.033) 0.232*** (0.044)
P. Zhang / World Development 129 (2020) 104863 15

Table A.1 (continued)

(1) (2) (3) (4)


Manufacturing (Baseline) Agricultural Service Total
CYP  Immigrant 0.240*** (0.083) 0.331*** (0.121) 0.078** (0.034) 0.264*** (0.046)
LVA  Immigrant 0.207** (0.082) 0.489*** (0.120) 0.095*** (0.034) 0.273*** (0.045)
HUN  Immigrant 0.191** (0.076) 0.346*** (0.111) 0.022 (0.031) 0.108*** (0.042)
SVK  Immigrant 0.181** (0.075) 0.341*** (0.110) 0.070** (0.031) 0.180*** (0.042)
SVN  Immigrant 0.159** (0.074) 0.482*** (0.109) 0.093*** (0.031) 0.209*** (0.041)
EST  Immigrant 0.127 (0.085) 0.598*** (0.124) 0.084** (0.035) 0.236*** (0.046)
DNK  Immigrant 0.116 (0.077) 0.545*** (0.112) 0.032 (0.032) 0.223*** (0.042)
NLD  Immigrant 0.107 (0.078) 0.012 (0.114) 0.027 (0.032) 0.198*** (0.043)
BEL  Immigrant 0.049 (0.080) 0.161 (0.117) 0.027 (0.033) 0.149*** (0.044)
MLT  Immigrant 0.013 (0.079) 0.485*** (0.114) 0.013 (0.032) 0.109** (0.043)
LUX  Immigrant 0.156 (0.104) 0.018 (0.151) 0.450*** (0.043) 0.120** (0.057)
Observations 1600 1600 1600 1600
Adjusted R2 0.973 0.963 0.998 0.995
Mean 0.352 0.448 0.053 0.257
Std 0.189 0.200 0.103 0.100

Notes: Table reports the estimates of home-biased gravity equation with sectoral trade flow data. Exporter- and importer-specific fixed effects are both included. Robust
standard errors in parentheses. Significance *.10, **.05, ***.01.

Table A.2
Home-biased Gravity Estimates: by Good.

(1) (2) (3)

Aggregate (Baseline) Final Intermediate

Distance 0.009*** (0.001) 0.008*** (0.001) 0.009*** (0.001)


Border 0.023*** (0.002) 0.023*** (0.002) 0.023*** (0.002)
Language 0.014*** (0.002) 0.015*** (0.002) 0.013*** (0.002)
Tariff 0.008*** (0.001) 0.006*** (0.001) 0.008*** (0.001)
Income 0.006*** (0.001) 0.004*** (0.001) 0.002** (0.001)
Internal 0.141** (0.071) 0.012 (0.075) 0.263*** (0.072)
JPN  Immigrant 0.670*** (0.075) 0.770*** (0.079) 0.578*** (0.076)
CHN  Immigrant 0.657*** (0.073) 0.831*** (0.078) 0.553*** (0.075)
BRA  Immigrant 0.586*** (0.074) 0.828*** (0.078) 0.451*** (0.076)
USA  Immigrant 0.583*** (0.080) 0.748*** (0.084) 0.496*** (0.082)
IDN  Immigrant 0.576*** (0.074) 0.866*** (0.078) 0.411*** (0.075)
AUS  Immigrant 0.556*** (0.087) 0.733*** (0.092) 0.498*** (0.089)
TUR  Immigrant 0.545*** (0.075) 0.741*** (0.079) 0.436*** (0.076)
IND  Immigrant 0.542*** (0.074) 0.810*** (0.079) 0.411*** (0.076)
KOR  Immigrant 0.529*** (0.074) 0.695*** (0.079) 0.429*** (0.076)
ITA  Immigrant 0.517*** (0.076) 0.656*** (0.080) 0.422*** (0.078)
RUS  Immigrant 0.503*** (0.073) 0.535*** (0.077) 0.497*** (0.074)
ESP  Immigrant 0.495*** (0.078) 0.631*** (0.083) 0.419*** (0.080)
CAN  Immigrant 0.491*** (0.085) 0.703*** (0.090) 0.418*** (0.087)
FIN  Immigrant 0.444*** (0.076) 0.529*** (0.080) 0.375*** (0.078)
IRL  Immigrant 0.437*** (0.082) 0.525*** (0.087) 0.349*** (0.084)
FRA  Immigrant 0.425*** (0.077) 0.625*** (0.081) 0.322*** (0.078)
ROM  Immigrant 0.417*** (0.074) 0.689*** (0.078) 0.259*** (0.075)
GRC  Immigrant 0.393*** (0.075) 0.596*** (0.079) 0.287*** (0.076)
BGR  Immigrant 0.389*** (0.074) 0.547*** (0.078) 0.320*** (0.076)
PRT  Immigrant 0.366*** (0.075) 0.500*** (0.080) 0.316*** (0.077)
SWE  Immigrant 0.341*** (0.079) 0.476*** (0.083) 0.251*** (0.080)
POL  Immigrant 0.340*** (0.074) 0.573*** (0.078) 0.225*** (0.076)
MEX  Immigrant 0.334*** (0.074) 0.697*** (0.078) 0.094 (0.075)
TWN  Immigrant 0.333*** (0.075) 0.572*** (0.079) 0.242*** (0.077)
LTU  Immigrant 0.327*** (0.076) 0.554*** (0.081) 0.150* (0.078)
DEU  Immigrant 0.304*** (0.080) 0.530*** (0.084) 0.179** (0.082)
CZE  Immigrant 0.259*** (0.075) 0.473*** (0.079) 0.131* (0.076)
GBR  Immigrant 0.254*** (0.078) 0.375*** (0.082) 0.174** (0.080)
AUT  Immigrant 0.252*** (0.081) 0.372*** (0.085) 0.156* (0.082)
CYP  Immigrant 0.240*** (0.083) 0.347*** (0.088) 0.221*** (0.085)
LVA  Immigrant 0.207** (0.082) 0.378*** (0.087) 0.120 (0.084)
HUN  Immigrant 0.191** (0.076) 0.478*** (0.080) 0.040 (0.078)
SVK  Immigrant 0.181** (0.075) 0.384*** (0.080) 0.049 (0.077)
SVN  Immigrant 0.159** (0.074) 0.257*** (0.079) 0.089 (0.076)
EST  Immigrant 0.127 (0.085) 0.319*** (0.089) 0.003 (0.086)
DNK  Immigrant 0.116 (0.077) 0.179** (0.081) 0.068 (0.079)
NLD  Immigrant 0.107 (0.078) 0.205** (0.083) 0.018 (0.080)
BEL  Immigrant 0.049 (0.080) 0.191** (0.084) 0.055 (0.082)
MLT  Immigrant 0.013 (0.079) 0.172** (0.083) 0.174** (0.080)
LUX  Immigrant 0.156 (0.104) 0.011 (0.110) 0.281*** (0.107)
Observations 1600 1600 1600
Adjusted R2 0.973 0.972 0.974
Mean 0.352 0.528 0.248
Std 0.189 0.207 0.198

Notes: Table reports the estimates of home-biased gravity equation with intermediate and final trade flow data. Exporter- and importer-specific fixed effects are both
included. Robust standard errors in parentheses. Significance *.10, **.05, ***.01.
Table A.3

16
Home-biased Gravity Estimates: by Industry I.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)


Baseline Mining Textile Leather and Wood Printing and Coke, refined Chemicals
footwear products publishing petroleum
Distance 0.009*** (0.001) 0.007*** (0.001) 0.006*** (0.002) 0.008*** (0.003) 0.007*** (0.001) 0.004*** (0.001) 0.021*** (0.003) 0.012*** (0.001)
Border 0.023*** (0.002) 0.022*** (0.002) 0.022*** (0.004) 0.027*** (0.005) 0.021*** (0.002) 0.021*** (0.002) 0.042*** (0.006) 0.024*** (0.003)
Language 0.014*** (0.002) 0.013*** (0.002) 0.016*** (0.004) 0.013*** (0.005) 0.009*** (0.002) 0.012*** (0.002) 0.013** (0.006) 0.017*** (0.003)
Tariff 0.008*** (0.001) 0.004*** (0.001) 0.010*** (0.002) 0.005** (0.002) 0.002** (0.001) 0.007*** (0.001) 0.001 (0.002) 0.011*** (0.001)
Income 0.006*** (0.001) 0.004*** (0.001) 0.002 (0.002) 0.003** (0.001) 0.001* (0.001) 0.002*** (0.001) 0.002 (0.001) 0.005*** (0.001)
Internal 0.141** (0.071) 0.240*** (0.069) 0.541*** (0.125) 0.519*** (0.165) 0.496*** (0.067) 0.493*** (0.064) 0.567*** (0.182) 0.059 (0.091)
JPN  Immigrant 0.670*** (0.075) 0.637*** (0.073) 1.112*** (0.131) 0.868*** (0.173) 0.321*** (0.070) 0.415*** (0.067) 1.414*** (0.191) 0.844*** (0.095)
CHN  Immigrant 0.657*** (0.073) 0.684*** (0.072) 1.283*** (0.129) 1.271*** (0.171) 0.435*** (0.069) 0.398*** (0.066) 1.459*** (0.188) 0.841*** (0.094)
BRA  Immigrant 0.586*** (0.074) 0.636*** (0.072) 1.303*** (0.130) 1.367*** (0.172) 0.416*** (0.070) 0.335*** (0.067) 1.429*** (0.190) 0.674*** (0.095)
USA  Immigrant 0.583*** (0.080) 0.713*** (0.078) 1.006*** (0.141) 0.538*** (0.186) 0.322*** (0.076) 0.396*** (0.072) 1.505*** (0.205) 0.802*** (0.102)
IDN  Immigrant 0.576*** (0.074) 0.657*** (0.072) 1.178*** (0.130) 1.256*** (0.171) 0.433*** (0.070) 0.336*** (0.066) 1.220*** (0.189) 0.763*** (0.094)
AUS  Immigrant 0.556*** (0.087) 0.723*** (0.085) 1.015*** (0.153) 1.303*** (0.202) 0.431*** (0.082) 0.398*** (0.078) 1.515*** (0.223) 0.634*** (0.111)
TUR  Immigrant 0.545*** (0.075) 0.678*** (0.073) 1.196*** (0.131) 1.384*** (0.173) 0.326*** (0.071) 0.382*** (0.067) 1.360*** (0.192) 0.870*** (0.095)
IND  Immigrant 0.542*** (0.074) 0.603*** (0.073) 1.311*** (0.131) 1.374*** (0.173) 0.386*** (0.070) 0.278*** (0.067) 1.495*** (0.191) 0.666*** (0.095)
KOR  Immigrant 0.529*** (0.074) 0.563*** (0.073) 1.216*** (0.131) 1.050*** (0.173) 0.310*** (0.070) 0.289*** (0.067) 1.375*** (0.191) 0.638*** (0.095)
ITA  Immigrant 0.517*** (0.076) 0.557*** (0.075) 1.252*** (0.134) 1.143*** (0.177) 0.285*** (0.072) 0.319*** (0.068) 1.375*** (0.195) 0.523*** (0.097)

P. Zhang / World Development 129 (2020) 104863


RUS  Immigrant 0.503*** (0.073) 0.591*** (0.071) 0.544*** (0.128) 0.516*** (0.169) 0.341*** (0.069) 0.291*** (0.065) 1.491*** (0.186) 0.564*** (0.093)
ESP  Immigrant 0.495*** (0.078) 0.622*** (0.076) 0.804*** (0.138) 0.923*** (0.182) 0.335*** (0.074) 0.330*** (0.070) 1.249*** (0.200) 0.513*** (0.100)
CAN  Immigrant 0.491*** (0.085) 0.582*** (0.083) 1.038*** (0.149) 0.555*** (0.197) 0.449*** (0.080) 0.291*** (0.076) 1.471*** (0.217) 0.634*** (0.108)
FIN  Immigrant 0.444*** (0.076) 0.535*** (0.074) 0.704*** (0.134) 0.574*** (0.177) 0.340*** (0.072) 0.354*** (0.068) 1.151*** (0.195) 0.333*** (0.097)
IRL  Immigrant 0.437*** (0.082) 0.335*** (0.081) 0.693*** (0.145) 0.600*** (0.192) 0.245*** (0.078) 0.375*** (0.074) 0.881*** (0.212) 0.606*** (0.105)
FRA  Immigrant 0.425*** (0.077) 0.536*** (0.075) 0.837*** (0.135) 0.447** (0.178) 0.238*** (0.072) 0.268*** (0.069) 1.258*** (0.196) 0.390*** (0.098)
ROM  Immigrant 0.417*** (0.074) 0.592*** (0.072) 0.838*** (0.130) 0.448*** (0.171) 0.283*** (0.070) 0.233*** (0.066) 1.188*** (0.189) 0.307*** (0.094)
GRC  Immigrant 0.393*** (0.075) 0.520*** (0.073) 1.050*** (0.132) 1.107*** (0.174) 0.146** (0.071) 0.245*** (0.067) 1.302*** (0.192) 0.282*** (0.096)
BGR  Immigrant 0.389*** (0.074) 0.367*** (0.072) 1.335*** (0.130) 1.164*** (0.172) 0.240*** (0.070) 0.111* (0.067) 1.316*** (0.190) 0.273*** (0.095)
PRT  Immigrant 0.366*** (0.075) 0.420*** (0.074) 1.138*** (0.133) 1.044*** (0.175) 0.354*** (0.071) 0.153** (0.068) 1.250*** (0.193) 0.369*** (0.096)
SWE  Immigrant 0.341*** (0.079) 0.452*** (0.077) 0.550*** (0.139) 0.000 (.) 0.352*** (0.074) 0.316*** (0.071) 0.506** (0.202) 0.230** (0.101)
POL  Immigrant 0.340*** (0.074) 0.562*** (0.073) 0.671*** (0.130) 0.753*** (0.172) 0.322*** (0.070) 0.177*** (0.067) 1.304*** (0.190) 0.349*** (0.095)
MEX  Immigrant 0.334*** (0.074) 0.612*** (0.072) 1.063*** (0.130) 1.317*** (0.171) 0.257*** (0.070) 0.145** (0.066) 1.103*** (0.189) 0.501*** (0.094)
TWN  Immigrant 0.333*** (0.075) 0.528*** (0.074) 1.111*** (0.132) 0.404** (0.175) 0.095 (0.071) 0.106 (0.068) 1.311*** (0.193) 0.553*** (0.096)
LTU  Immigrant 0.327*** (0.076) 0.430*** (0.075) 0.952*** (0.135) 1.247*** (0.178) 0.175** (0.072) 0.096 (0.069) 0.993*** (0.196) 0.626*** (0.098)
DEU  Immigrant 0.304*** (0.080) 0.420*** (0.078) 0.483*** (0.141) 0.440** (0.186) 0.189** (0.076) 0.102 (0.072) 1.247*** (0.205) 0.095 (0.102)
CZE  Immigrant 0.259*** (0.075) 0.454*** (0.073) 0.756*** (0.132) 0.482*** (0.174) 0.308*** (0.071) 0.059 (0.067) 1.083*** (0.192) 0.153 (0.096)
GBR  Immigrant 0.254*** (0.078) 0.375*** (0.076) 0.701*** (0.137) 0.498*** (0.181) 0.195*** (0.074) 0.279*** (0.070) 0.924*** (0.200) 0.086 (0.100)
AUT  Immigrant 0.252*** (0.081) 0.427*** (0.079) 0.664*** (0.142) 0.529*** (0.188) 0.261*** (0.076) 0.136* (0.073) 0.793*** (0.207) 0.193* (0.103)
CYP  Immigrant 0.240*** (0.083) 0.398*** (0.082) 0.613*** (0.147) 0.664*** (0.194) 0.295*** (0.079) 0.196*** (0.075) 0.000 (.) 0.023 (0.107)
LVA  Immigrant 0.207** (0.082) 0.324*** (0.080) 0.861*** (0.145) 0.722*** (0.191) 0.393*** (0.078) 0.105 (0.074) 0.000 (.) 0.028 (0.105)
HUN  Immigrant 0.191** (0.076) 0.449*** (0.074) 0.773*** (0.134) 0.658*** (0.177) 0.084 (0.072) 0.123* (0.068) 1.180*** (0.195) 0.157 (0.097)
SVK  Immigrant 0.181** (0.075) 0.307*** (0.074) 0.564*** (0.133) 0.504*** (0.175) 0.263*** (0.071) 0.010 (0.068) 1.211*** (0.194) 0.124 (0.096)
SVN  Immigrant 0.159** (0.074) 0.318*** (0.073) 0.919*** (0.131) 0.799*** (0.173) 0.067 (0.070) 0.142** (0.067) 0.470** (0.191) 0.092 (0.095)
EST  Immigrant 0.127 (0.085) 0.330*** (0.083) 0.621*** (0.149) 0.566*** (0.197) 0.178** (0.080) 0.046 (0.076) 0.539** (0.217) 0.016 (0.108)
DNK  Immigrant 0.116 (0.077) 0.195*** (0.075) 0.513*** (0.136) 0.478*** (0.179) 0.063 (0.073) 0.156** (0.069) 0.722*** (0.198) 0.190* (0.098)
NLD  Immigrant 0.107 (0.078) 0.227*** (0.076) 0.551*** (0.138) 0.541*** (0.182) 0.107 (0.074) 0.115 (0.070) 0.725*** (0.200) 0.095 (0.100)
BEL  Immigrant 0.049 (0.080) 0.139* (0.078) 0.674*** (0.141) 0.596*** (0.186) 0.157** (0.076) 0.005 (0.072) 0.936*** (0.205) 0.041 (0.102)
MLT  Immigrant 0.013 (0.079) 0.058 (0.077) 0.742*** (0.139) 0.501*** (0.183) 0.241*** (0.074) 0.031 (0.071) 0.425** (0.202) 0.009 (0.101)
LUX  Immigrant 0.156 (0.104) 0.380*** (0.102) 1.095*** (0.184) 0.665*** (0.242) 0.290*** (0.099) 0.623*** (0.094) 0.588** (0.268) 0.032 (0.133)
Observations 1600 1600 1600 1560 1600 1600 1520 1600
Adjusted R2 0.973 0.984 0.899 0.842 0.986 0.986 0.882 0.944
Mean 0.352 0.454 0.893 0.783 0.222 0.196 1.069 0.375
Std 0.189 0.207 0.258 0.349 0.191 0.180 0.397 0.276

Notes: Table reports the estimates of home-biased gravity equation with industrial trade flow data. Exporter- and importer-specific fixed effects are both included. Robust standard errors in parentheses. Significance *.10, **.05,
***.01.
Table A.4
Home-biased Gravity Estimates: by Industry II.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)


Baseline Rubber Other nonme- Metals Machinery Electrical optical Transport Manufacturing
and tallic minerals equipment and equipment and recycling
plastics
Distance 0.009*** (0.001) 0.011*** (0.001) 0.008*** (0.001) 0.010*** (0.001) 0.008*** (0.002) 0.011*** (0.002) 0.004** (0.002) 0.010*** (0.002)
Border 0.023*** (0.002) 0.029*** (0.003) 0.017*** (0.002) 0.026*** (0.003) 0.024*** (0.003) 0.013*** (0.003) 0.022*** (0.004) 0.022*** (0.003)
Language 0.014*** (0.002) 0.014*** (0.003) 0.006*** (0.002) 0.012*** (0.003) 0.014*** (0.003) 0.012*** (0.003) 0.020*** (0.004) 0.020*** (0.003)
Tariff 0.008*** (0.001) 0.011*** (0.001) 0.002** (0.001) 0.008*** (0.001) 0.015*** (0.001) 0.010*** (0.001) 0.016*** (0.002) 0.004** (0.002)
Income 0.006*** (0.001) 0.002* (0.001) 0.001* (0.001) 0.000 (0.001) 0.001 (0.001) 0.001 (0.001) 0.003*** (0.001) 0.003** (0.002)
Internal 0.141** (0.071) 0.368*** (0.097) 0.728*** (0.058) 0.217** (0.085) 0.108 (0.106) 0.054 (0.109) 0.178 (0.123) 0.115 (0.114)
JPN  Immigrant 0.670*** (0.075) 0.437*** (0.102) 0.167*** (0.061) 0.619*** (0.089) 0.885*** (0.112) 0.604*** (0.115) 1.006*** (0.129) 0.587*** (0.120)
CHN  Immigrant 0.657*** (0.073) 0.445*** (0.100) 0.212*** (0.060) 0.634*** (0.088) 0.807*** (0.110) 0.508*** (0.113) 0.936*** (0.127) 0.560*** (0.119)
BRA  Immigrant 0.586*** (0.074) 0.325*** (0.101) 0.175*** (0.061) 0.514*** (0.088) 0.621*** (0.111) 0.431*** (0.114) 0.789*** (0.128) 0.716*** (0.119)
USA  Immigrant 0.583*** (0.080) 0.373*** (0.109) 0.075 (0.066) 0.556*** (0.095) 0.699*** (0.120) 0.344*** (0.123) 0.781*** (0.138) 0.365*** (0.129)
IDN  Immigrant 0.576*** (0.074) 0.278*** (0.101) 0.175*** (0.061) 0.117 (0.088) 0.176 (0.110) 0.530*** (0.113) 0.913*** (0.127) 0.415*** (0.119)
AUS  Immigrant 0.556*** (0.087) 0.189 (0.119) 0.182** (0.071) 0.621*** (0.104) 0.525*** (0.130) 0.072 (0.134) 0.752*** (0.150) 0.611*** (0.140)
TUR  Immigrant 0.545*** (0.075) 0.298*** (0.102) 0.011 (0.062) 0.360*** (0.089) 0.735*** (0.112) 0.478*** (0.115) 0.243* (0.129) 0.460*** (0.120)
IND  Immigrant 0.542*** (0.074) 0.317*** (0.102) 0.117* (0.061) 0.529*** (0.089) 0.634*** (0.111) 0.423*** (0.115) 0.777*** (0.129) 0.009 (0.120)
KOR  Immigrant 0.529*** (0.074) 0.309*** (0.102) 0.058 (0.061) 0.489*** (0.089) 0.598*** (0.112) 0.466*** (0.115) 0.845*** (0.129) 0.570*** (0.120)

P. Zhang / World Development 129 (2020) 104863


ITA  Immigrant 0.517*** (0.076) 0.286*** (0.104) 0.126** (0.063) 0.494*** (0.091) 0.730*** (0.114) 0.403*** (0.117) 0.562*** (0.132) 0.630*** (0.123)
RUS  Immigrant 0.503*** (0.073) 0.419*** (0.099) 0.172*** (0.060) 0.593*** (0.087) 0.527*** (0.109) 0.492*** (0.112) 0.533*** (0.125) 0.617*** (0.117)
ESP  Immigrant 0.495*** (0.078) 0.262** (0.107) 0.156** (0.064) 0.526*** (0.093) 0.604*** (0.117) 0.232* (0.120) 0.552*** (0.135) 0.605*** (0.126)
CAN  Immigrant 0.491*** (0.085) 0.253** (0.116) 0.013 (0.070) 0.472*** (0.101) 0.525*** (0.127) 0.069 (0.131) 0.814*** (0.147) 0.475*** (0.137)
FIN  Immigrant 0.444*** (0.076) 0.133 (0.104) 0.066 (0.063) 0.360*** (0.091) 0.732*** (0.114) 0.451*** (0.117) 0.279** (0.131) 0.428*** (0.123)
IRL  Immigrant 0.437*** (0.082) 0.096 (0.113) 0.020 (0.068) 0.218** (0.099) 0.153 (0.124) 0.650*** (0.127) 0.318** (0.143) 0.101 (0.133)
FRA  Immigrant 0.425*** (0.077) 0.209** (0.105) 0.032 (0.063) 0.474*** (0.092) 0.615*** (0.115) 0.218* (0.118) 0.653*** (0.132) 0.416*** (0.124)
ROM  Immigrant 0.417*** (0.074) 0.142 (0.101) 0.110* (0.061) 0.352*** (0.088) 0.329*** (0.111) 0.035 (0.114) 0.711*** (0.128) 0.496*** (0.119)
GRC  Immigrant 0.393*** (0.075) 0.142 (0.102) 0.065 (0.062) 0.455*** (0.089) 0.229** (0.112) 0.195* (0.115) 0.346*** (0.129) 0.437*** (0.121)
BGR  Immigrant 0.389*** (0.074) 0.022 (0.101) 0.026 (0.061) 0.472*** (0.088) 0.355*** (0.111) 0.116 (0.114) 0.173 (0.128) 0.464*** (0.119)
PRT  Immigrant 0.366*** (0.075) 0.079 (0.103) 0.079 (0.062) 0.319*** (0.090) 0.389*** (0.113) 0.310*** (0.116) 0.331** (0.130) 0.504*** (0.122)
SWE  Immigrant 0.341*** (0.079) 0.140 (0.108) 0.031 (0.065) 0.328*** (0.094) 0.525*** (0.118) 0.139 (0.121) 0.795*** (0.136) 0.191 (0.127)
POL  Immigrant 0.340*** (0.074) 0.107 (0.101) 0.060 (0.061) 0.256*** (0.088) 0.328*** (0.111) 0.086 (0.114) 0.352*** (0.128) 0.419*** (0.119)
MEX  Immigrant 0.334*** (0.074) 0.144 (0.101) 0.101* (0.061) 0.205** (0.088) 0.091 (0.111) 0.014 (0.114) 0.428*** (0.128) 0.655*** (0.119)
TWN  Immigrant 0.333*** (0.075) 0.013 (0.103) 0.025 (0.062) 0.369*** (0.090) 0.477*** (0.113) 0.038 (0.116) 0.638*** (0.130) 0.130 (0.121)
LTU  Immigrant 0.327*** (0.076) 0.102 (0.104) 0.168*** (0.063) 0.009 (0.091) 0.084 (0.114) 0.018 (0.118) 0.482*** (0.132) 0.550*** (0.123)
DEU  Immigrant 0.304*** (0.080) 0.011 (0.109) 0.047 (0.066) 0.325*** (0.095) 0.620*** (0.120) 0.139 (0.123) 0.588*** (0.138) 0.292** (0.129)
CZE  Immigrant 0.259*** (0.075) 0.109 (0.102) 0.033 (0.062) 0.229** (0.089) 0.414*** (0.112) 0.098 (0.115) 0.655*** (0.129) 0.316*** (0.121)
GBR  Immigrant 0.254*** (0.078) 0.188* (0.107) 0.012 (0.064) 0.294*** (0.093) 0.509*** (0.117) 0.007 (0.120) 0.414*** (0.135) 0.290** (0.126)
AUT  Immigrant 0.252*** (0.081) 0.180 (0.110) 0.017 (0.066) 0.316*** (0.096) 0.477*** (0.121) 0.119 (0.124) 0.171 (0.139) 0.391*** (0.130)
CYP  Immigrant 0.240*** (0.083) 0.049 (0.114) 0.109 (0.069) 0.253** (0.100) 0.159 (0.125) 0.081 (0.129) 0.154 (0.144) 0.355*** (0.135)
LVA  Immigrant 0.207** (0.082) 0.196* (0.112) 0.184*** (0.068) 0.067 (0.098) 0.061 (0.123) 0.034 (0.127) 0.125 (0.142) 0.273** (0.132)
HUN  Immigrant 0.191** (0.076) 0.093 (0.104) 0.156** (0.063) 0.068 (0.091) 0.564*** (0.114) 0.029 (0.117) 0.366*** (0.131) 0.272** (0.123)
SVK  Immigrant 0.181** (0.075) 0.024 (0.103) 0.015 (0.062) 0.208** (0.090) 0.171 (0.113) 0.097 (0.116) 0.450*** (0.130) 0.095 (0.122)
SVN  Immigrant 0.159** (0.074) 0.037 (0.102) 0.120* (0.061) 0.179** (0.089) 0.173 (0.112) 0.115 (0.115) 0.170 (0.129) 0.334*** (0.120)
EST  Immigrant 0.127 (0.085) 0.431*** (0.116) 0.292*** (0.070) 0.117 (0.101) 0.113 (0.127) 0.048 (0.130) 0.252* (0.146) 0.147 (0.136)
DNK  Immigrant 0.116 (0.077) 0.236** (0.105) 0.158** (0.063) 0.101 (0.092) 0.225* (0.115) 0.177 (0.119) 0.123 (0.133) 0.004 (0.124)
NLD  Immigrant 0.107 (0.078) 0.418*** (0.107) 0.178*** (0.064) 0.090 (0.093) 0.201* (0.117) 0.127 (0.120) 0.160 (0.135) 0.239* (0.126)
BEL  Immigrant 0.049 (0.080) 0.397*** (0.109) 0.176*** (0.066) 0.065 (0.095) 0.124 (0.120) 0.051 (0.123) 0.168 (0.138) 0.022 (0.129)
MLT  Immigrant 0.013 (0.079) 0.364*** (0.108) 0.262*** (0.065) 0.054 (0.094) 0.034 (0.118) 0.008 (0.121) 0.151 (0.136) 0.241* (0.127)
LUX  Immigrant 0.156 (0.104) 0.524*** (0.143) 0.426*** (0.086) 0.025 (0.125) 0.094 (0.156) 0.164 (0.161) 0.187 (0.180) 0.208 (0.168)
Observations 1600 1600 1600 1600 1600 1600 1600 1600
Adjusted R2 0.973 0.951 0.989 0.967 0.917 0.892 0.901 0.930
Mean 0.352 0.050 0.001 0.311 0.408 0.192 0.479 0.349
Std 0.189 0.256 0.145 0.198 0.240 0.214 0.266 0.230

Notes: Table reports the estimates of home-biased gravity equation with industrial trade flow data. Exporter- and importer-specific fixed effects are both included. Robust standard errors in parentheses. Significance *.10, **.05,
***.01.

17
18 P. Zhang / World Development 129 (2020) 104863

References Fieler, A. C. (2011). Nonhomotheticity and bilateral trade: Evidence and a


quantitative explanation. Econometrica, 79, 1069–1101.
Hallak, J. C. (2006). Product quality and the direction of trade. Journal of International
Allen, T. (2014). Information frictions in trade. Econometrica, 82(6), 2041–2083.
Economics, 68, 238–265.
Altonji, J. G., & Card, D. (1991). The effects of immigration on the labor market
Hanson, G. (2010). International migration and the developing world. Handbook of
outcomes of less-skilled natives. In Immigration, trade, and the labor market
Development Economics, 5, 4363–4414.
(pp. 201–234). University of Chicago Press.
Head, K., & Mayer, T. (2013). What separates us? Sources of resistance to
Anderson, J., & van Wincoop, E. (2003). Gravity with gravitas: A solution to the
globalization. Canadian Journal of Economics, 46, 1196–1231.
border puzzle. American Economic Review, 93, 170–192.
Helpman, E., Melitz, M., & Rubinstein, Y. (2008). Estimating trade flows: Trading
Anderson, J., & van Wincoop, E. (2004). Trade costs. Journal of Economic Literature.
partners and trading volumes. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123, 441–487.
XLII:691–751.
Hummels, D., & Klenow, P. (2005). The variety and quality of a nation’s exports.
Anderson, J., & Yotov, Y. (2010). The changing incidence of geography. American
American Economic Review, 95, 704–723.
Economic Review, 100(5), 2157–2186.
Iranzo, S., & Peri, G. (2009). Migration and trade: Theory with an application to the
Atkin, D. (2013). Trade, tastes and nutrition in india. American Economic Review, 103,
eastern–western european integration. Journal of International Economics, 79(1),
1629–1663.
1–19.
Berthélemy, J.-C., Beuran, M., & Maurel, M. (2009). Aid and migration: Substitutes or
Lan, X., & Li, B. G. (2015). The Economics of Nationalism. American Economic Journal:
complements?. World Development, 37(10), 1589–1599.
Economic Policy, 7(2), 294–325.
Bronnenberg, B., Dubé, J.-P., & Gentzkow, M. (2012). The evolution of brand
Lanati, M., & Thiele, R. (2018). The impact of foreign aid on migration revisited.
preferences: Evidence from consumer migration. American Economic Review,
World Development, 111, 59–74.
102(6), 2472–2508.
Lewbel, A., & Pendakur, K. (2017). Unobserved preference heterogeneity in demand
Bucheli, J. R., Fontenla, M., & Waddell, B. J. (2019). Return migration and violence.
using generalized random coefficients. Journal of Political Economy, 125,
World Development, 116, 113–124.
1100–1148.
Caballero, M. E., Cadena, B. C., & Kovak, B. K. (2018). Measuring geographic
Llull, J. (2018). The effect of immigration on wages: Exploiting exogenous variation
migration patterns using matrículas consulares. Demography, 55(3), 1119–1145.
at the national level. Journal of Human Resources, pp. 0315-7032R2.
Card, D. (2001). Immigrant inflows, native outflows, and the local labor market
Llull, J. (2018). Immigration, wages, and education: A labour market equilibrium
impacts of higher immigration. Journal of Labor Economics, 19(1), 22–64.
structural model. The Review of Economic Studies, 85(3), 1852–1896.
Caron, J., Fally, T., & Markusen, J. (2014). International trade puzzles: A solution
Lyons, C. J., Vélez, M. B., & Santoro, W. A. (2013). Neighborhood immigration,
linking production and preferences. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129,
violence, and city-level immigrant political opportunities. American Sociological
1501–1552.
Review, 78(4), 604–632.
Chaney, T. (2008). The intensive and extensive margins of international trade.
McCallum, J. (1995). National borders matter: Canada-u.s. regional trade patterns.
American Economic Review, 98, 1707–1721.
American Economic Review, 85, 615–623.
Chaney, T. (2014). The network structure of international trade. American Economic
Morey, M. (2016). Preferences and the home bias in trade. Journal of Development
Review, 104(11), 3600–3634.
Economics, 121, 24–37.
Combes, P.-P., Lafourcade, M., & Mayer, T. (2005). The trade-creating effects of
Neary, P. (2004). Rationalizing the Penn world table: True multilateral indices for
business and social networks: Evidence from France. Journal of International
international comparisons of real income. American Economic Review, 94,
Economics, 66, 1–29.
1411–1428.
Cosßar, A. K., Grieco, P. L., Li, S., & Tintelnot, F. (2018). What drives home market
Novy, D. (2013). International trade without CES: Estimating translog gravity.
advantage?. Journal of International Economics, 110, 135–150.
Journal of International Economics, 89, 271–282.
De, H. H. (2010). Migration and development: A theoretical perspective. The
Obstfeld, M., & Rogoff, K. (2001). The six major puzzles in international
International Migration Review, 44(1), 227–264.
macroeconomics: Is there a common cause?. NBER Macroeconomics Annual,
Deaton, A., & Muellbauer, J. (1980). An almost ideal demand system. American
15, 339–390.
Economic Review, 70, 312–326.
Ramondo, N., Rodríguez-Clare, A., & Saborío-Rodríguez, M. (2016). Trade, domestic
Desmond, S. A., & Kubrin, C. E. (2009). The power of place: Immigrant communities
frictions, and scale effects. The American Economic Review, 106(10), 3159–3184.
and adolescent violence. The Sociological Quarterly, 50(4), 581–607.
Rauch, J. (2001). Business and social networks in international trade. Journal of
Di Comite, F., Thisse, J.-F., & Vandenbussche, H. (2014). Verti-zontal differentiation
Economic Literature. XXXIX:1177-1203.
in export markets. Journal of International Economics, 93(1), 50–66.
Rauch, J., & Trindade, V. (2002). Ethnic chinese networks in international trade.
Fajgelbaum, P., & Khandelwal, A. (2016). Measuring the unequal gains from trade.
Review of Economics and Statistics, 84, 116–130.
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 131, 1113–1180.
Ravuri, E. D. (2014). Return migration predictors for undocumented mexican
Feenstra, R., & Romalis, J. (2014). International prices and endogenous quality.
immigrants living in dallas. The Social Science Journal, 51(1), 35–43.
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129, 477–527.
Yi, K.-M. (2010). Can multistage production explain the home bias in trade?.
Feenstra, R. C. (2003). A homothetic utility function for monopolistic competition
American Economic Review, 100, 364–393.
models. Economics Letters, 78, 79–86.
Felbermayr, G., Grossmann, V., & Kohler, W. (2015). Migration, international trade,
and capital formation: Cause or effect?. Handbook of the Economics of
International Migration, 1B, 913–1025.

You might also like