Micro I. Lesson 5: Consumer Equilibrium 5.1 Optimal Choice: MU P MU P

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 32

Microecono mics I. Antonio Zabalza.

University of Valencia 1

Micro I. Lesson 5 : Consumer Equilibrium

5.1 Optimal Choice

If preferences are well behaved (smooth, convex,


continuous and negatively sloped), then at the
optimal choice of the consumer,
Slope of i.c. = Slope of b.c.
MRS = Price ratio
MU x px
=
MU y p y

Optimal Choice

Why?
Consider a situation in which the above equality
does not hold. Also, remember that moving along
the bc is equivalent to using the market. Moving
along the ic shows the minimum amount of y I need
to compensate for loss of x. If the market gives me
an amount of y that is greater than the minimum I
require, I will follow the market.
Microecono mics I. Antonio Zabalza. University of Valencia 2

U(C)

U(B)
B

B’ U(A)
A x

B’’
Microecono mics I. Antonio Zabalza. University of Valencia 3

At A, for instance, if I give up 1 unit of x (distance


AB’’), the market gives me 1 unit of y (distance
B’’B). But I would be satisfied with less; say, 0.25
units of y (distance B’B’’). Then, it is optimal for me
to trade in the market, and go to point B where my
utility U(B) is higher than that at point a, U(A).

If I keep applying this reasoning I end up at point C.


(Check that you understand this). Point C represents
the best I can do, given my opportunities. Point C
therefore represents the optimal choice, the
equilibrium, of the consumer. Going beyond point
C, would lower again my utility.

Mathematics: Maximization of utility subject to a


given budget constraint. Method of Lagrange.

Max U = U (x , y )
x, y

s.t. px x + py y = m

L = U ( x , y ) + λ  m − px x − p y y 
Microecono mics I. Antonio Zabalza. University of Valencia 4

First order (necessary) conditions

δ L δU
= − λ px = 0 (1)
δx δx
δ L δU
= − λ py = 0 (2)
δy δy
δL
= m − px x − p y y = 0 (3)
δy

This is a system of 3 equations in 3 unknowns: x, y


and λ. From (1) and (2) we have that

δ U δ x MU x
λ= =
px px
δ U δ y MU y
λ= =
py py

MU x MU y MU x px
= ⇒ =
px py MU y px

Then, to solve for x and y we consider equation (3)


to get this more simplified form of the above system.

MU x px
= (4)
MU y px
m = px x + py y (5)
Microecono mics I. Antonio Zabalza. University of Valencia 5

This is a system of 2 equations with two unknowns


(x,y). (Notice that in general the marginal utilities
will depend on x and y). Equation (4) is the equality
of slopes of bc and ic discussed above. What the
result above says is that this condition is not enough;
we need also that the budget constraint is fulfilled
(equation 5).

Solving this system will, in general, give us the two


demand functions for x and y that we are after.

x = x ( px , p y , m)
y = y ( px , p y , m )

The purpose of this lesson is to find out how the


three variables ( px , p y , m) influence the demand for
x and y. Before, we give an example of this
derivation for a particular utility function: Cobb-
Douglas.
Microecono mics I. Antonio Zabalza. University of Valencia 6

Example:
Cobb-Douglas (CD) utility function:
U (x , y) = x a y b
Max U = x a y b
x, y

s.t. px x + py y = m

L = x a y b + λ  m − px x − p y y 

Necessary conditions:

δL
= ax a −1 y b − λ p x = 0 (1)
δx
δL
= bx a y b−1 − λ p y = 0 (2)
δy
δL
= m − px x − py y = 0 (3)
δy

Eliminate λ from (1) and (2), and together with (3)


you obtain

ax a −1 y b bx a y b −1
= (4)
px py
m = px x + py y (5)

System of two equations with two unknowns.


Microecono mics I. Antonio Zabalza. University of Valencia 7

Equation (4) can be expressed in the form


MU x px
= ,
MU y p y
which for this particular case is
ax a −1 y b px
a b −1
=
bx y py
or,
ay px
= .
bx p y

So the system, in this simplified form is


ay px
= (4)
bx p y
m = px x + py y (5)

Solving for x and for y, we find the two demand


equations:
a m
x=
a + b px
b m
y=
a + b py

With a CD utility function, the demand for each


good depends on income (positively) and its own
price (negatively). It does not depend on the price of
the other good.
Microecono mics I. Antonio Zabalza. University of Valencia 8

Another characteristic of this utility function is that


the parameters of the function give information
about the expenditure shares on each good.

px x a
Share of expenditure on x : =
m a+b
py y b
Share of expenditure on y : =
m a+b

Sufficient condition
Equations (1), (2) and (3) are the necessary
conditions. They are not sufficient. For instance,
consider the following situation:

Point of
tangency

Point of maximum
A utility

At A, the first order conditions are met and yet utility


is not maximized. You need also another set of
conditions which are sufficient. These conditions
boil down to the requirement that preferences have
to be convex. See that in the figure they are concave.
Microecono mics I. Antonio Zabalza. University of Valencia 9

Extreme examples

Corner solutions

Maximum utility, but at this point


Slope of ic > slope bc
MRS > price ratio

A particular example of a corner solution is when


the two goods are perfect substitutes: Suppose
U=x+y and px = 2; p y = 4; and m = 12 .

ic slope: 1

bc slope: 1/2

3
Maximum U

6
Microecono mics I. Antonio Zabalza. University of Valencia 10

Here
px MU x 1
< ; <1
py MU y 2
Maximum is obtained at point A, where only x is
consumed. So the demand function in this case is
m
x=
px
Kinky solutions

Suppose the two goods are perfect complements


with the following utility function:
U = min { x, y}
and px = 2; p y = 4; and m = 24 .
y

4
A

x
4 12

The optimal choice must lie on the diagonal and on


the budget constraint. Therefore, the optimal choice
is found by solving the system
Microecono mics I. Antonio Zabalza. University of Valencia 11

y=x
m = px x + py y
The solution is
m
x= y=
px + p y
For the particular example used here
24
x= y= =4
6

5.2 Changes in the equilibrium position

Now we want to investigate how the equilibrium just


studied is altered (displaced) by changes in the
exogenous variables of this problem. In particular,
we want to know how the equilibrium changes
when, m, px and py change. Or to put it in other
words. The result of the previous analysis was the
derivation of two demand curves
x = x ( px , p y , m)
y = y ( px , p y , m )
We want to sign the partial effects of the three
exogenous variables m, px and py on the demand of
x and y.

We will consider three types of changes:


a) Simultaneous change in prices and income by
the same proportion.
b) Change in income only.
Microecono mics I. Antonio Zabalza. University of Valencia 12

c) Change in one price only.

Equiproportional change in prices and income

If m, px and py all move by the same proportion, the


bc does not change and therefore the point of
equilibrium does not change either.

Suppose initial bc is
m0 = p0x x + p0y y
Multiply all prices and income by k (if, for instance,
k=1.1, then all variables increase by 10%). The new
bc is
km0 = kp0x x + kp 0y y
But k can be cancelled out by dividing both sides of
the equation by k. So, the original bc remains
unchanged.
m0 = p0x x + p0y y

Change in m only

We know that an increase in m moves the bc out.


The position of the final equilibrium depends on
whether the goods are normal or inferior. Suppose
first that both goods are normal. Then, if there is an
increase in income from m0 to m′ , more of both
goods will be bought. This is represented in the
following figure.
Microecono mics I. Antonio Zabalza. University of Valencia 13

B m0
∆y

A
m′

x
∆x

The demand curve that treats prices as given


parameters and income as a variable, is known as the
Engle curve. It takes the form: x = x ( m, p x , p y ) .

( px , p y )

B
m′
m0
A

x
x 0
x′
Microecono mics I. Antonio Zabalza. University of Valencia 14

We say that a good is inferior if when income is


raised, holding everything else constant, less of this
good is bought. Say x is inferior. Then,

m0
∆y

A
m′

x
∇x

Exercise: Derive the shape of the Engle curve


corresponding to good x, when x is an inferior good.

Property: The sum of the income elasticities of each


good, weighted by its corresponding expenditure
share, must be equal to one.

We start with the budget constraint:

m = px x + py y

Then, differentiating both sides of the equality by m,


we find:
Microecono mics I. Antonio Zabalza. University of Valencia 15

dm ∂x ∂y
= px + py
dm ∂m ∂m
∂x ∂y
1 = px + py
∂m ∂m
px x  ∂x m  p y y  ∂y m 
1=  +
m  ∂m x  m  ∂m y 
1 = s xε xm + s yε ym

As we were looking for, the weighted average of


income elasticities must add up to 1.

Implications of this result:


a) Not all goods can be inferior. Not all Engle
curves can have negative slope.
b) Goods that take a large share of expenditures
are unlikely to have either very large or very
low income elasticities, since the average must
equal one.

Problem for home: Say we divide goods in two


types: food and non-food. We know food takes 60%
of expenditures, and the income elasticity of non-
food is 2. What is the income elasticity of food?

Exercise: Find the slope and graphical shape of the


Engle curve for good x when the utility function is
Cobb – Douglas. What about when the goods are
perfect substitutes? And perfect complements? You
Microecono mics I. Antonio Zabalza. University of Valencia 16

will see in this exercise that all Engle curves for


these specific cases are straight lines. This is like
this because the points of equilibrium in the goods
space when income rises is also a straight line from
the origin. In these cases we say that preferences are
homothetic.

Change in one price (holding constant m and the


other price)

Suppose px decreases with p y and m constant.


y

B
p0x
px'
A

x
∆x

Normally if the price of one good goes down, the


quantity consumed of that good goes up.
∇px ⇒ ∆x
and viceversa.
Microecono mics I. Antonio Zabalza. University of Valencia 17

The demand curve


The following graph shows how the demand curve is
derived out of the consumer equilibrium. In fact,
each point in the demand curve is a point of
equilibrium for the consumer at different price
levels.
y

B
p0x
px'
A

x
∆x

px

A
p0x
B
p1x
Demand curve

x ( p x , p y , m)

x
∆x
Microecono mics I. Antonio Zabalza. University of Valencia 18

Exercise: Draw the demand curves (and identify the


slope of the curve) for CD preferences, for perfect
substitutes and for perfect complements.

The demand curve not always is downward sloping.


This is an anomaly, but in principle it can happen.

p0x
px'
A

x
∆x
Demand curve
px x ( p x , p y , m)

A
p0x
B
p1x

x
∇x
Microecono mics I. Antonio Zabalza. University of Valencia 19

Goods which display this anomalous behaviour are


called Giffen goods. [Illustration concerning
consumption of horse meat].

5.3 Income and substitution effects

Now we want to decompose the effect of the change


in one price in two effects:
a) a first effect which is equivalent to a change in
relative prices holding income constant. This is
called the substitution effect.
b) A second effect which is equivalent to a change
in income holding relative prices constant. This
is called the income effect.

Suppose initially we are at point A ( x 0 , y 0 ) , with


prices ( p0x , p 0y ) and income m0 . Therefore, the
budget constraint at this point is:
p0x x 0 + p 0y y 0 = m 0 (1)

Suppose now the price of x goes down to p1x , and we


ask what is the income the consumer would now
need to buy the old bundle of goods. This income,
m1, is
p1x x 0 + p 0y y 0 = m1 (2)

Clearly m1 < m0 . More precisely, the change in


income can be found substracting equation (1) from
equation (2).
Microecono mics I. Antonio Zabalza. University of Valencia 20

m1 − m 0 = p1x x 0 + py0 y 0 − ( px0 x 0 + p0y y 0 )


= x 0 ( p1x − px0 )
∆m = x 0 ∆p x
So, the change in income needed to buy the old
bundle is equal to the initial quantity of x times the
change in the price of x.

Suppose after the price change in x we take away


∆m from the consumer, so his new bc passes through
A but is flatter than his old bc. Will he remain at A?
Clearly not. He can do better than this by going to B
( x s , y s ) . As compared with point A, the consumer
has adjusted his consumption by buying more of the
good that has become relatively cheaper (x) and less
of the good that has become relatively more
expensive (y). The change from point A to point B is
the substitution effect.

We can represent it formally as a change in the


demand for x from the initial position
x0 = x ( p0x , p y0 ,m 0 ) at point A, to the position
x s = x ( p1x , p y0 , m 1 ) at point B. If we denote ( x s − x0 )
by ∆x s , then

∆x s = x ( p1x , p x0 , m1 ) − x ( p0x , p y0 , m 0 )

x s = x ( p1x , p y0 , m 1 ) is called the compensated demand


for x. “Compensated” because is the demand for x as
Microecono mics I. Antonio Zabalza. University of Valencia 21

a result of a fall in the price of x when the consumer


is compensated for the increase in income generated
by the fall in the price of x.

Income effect

The movement from A to B is a hypothetical


movement. At his final choice, the consumer is
spending all his income; so he will be at a point such
as C in the final budget line, where the demand for x
is x n = x( p1x , p 0y ,m 0 ) . Now, observe that the move
from B to C is like a pure income effect (income
increases from m1 to m0 , while prices remain
constant at p1x and p0y ). If we call x n − x s = ∆x n , we
have that the income effect is,

∆x n = x( p1x , p y0 ,m0 ) − x ( p1x , p 0y , m1 )

Total effect

The total effect is the move from A to C. That is


from x0 to x n . Or using the same terminology as
above,
∆x = x n − x 0
∆x = x( p1x , p y0 ,m 0 ) − x ( px0, p y0 , m0 )
Microecono mics I. Antonio Zabalza. University of Valencia 22

( p0x , p y0 , m 0 )

( p1x , p 0y , m1 )

yn C

y0 A

B
s
y ( p1x , p y0 , m 0 )

x
0 s n
x x x
Microecono mics I. Antonio Zabalza. University of Valencia 23

The Slutsky equation

Notice that the total effect can be written as the sum


of the substitution and income effects.

( x n − x 0 ) = ( xs − x 0 ) + ( x n − x s )
∆x = ∆x s + ∆x n
This expression is called the Slutsky equation.

Signing the substitution effect


If px goes down, as in the figure above, then the
change in demand for x that results from the
substitution effect must be non-negative.

If p1x < p0x ⇒ x( p1x , p 0y , m1 ) ≥ x ( px0 , p y0 ,m 0 )


Or,
If p1x < p0x ⇒ ∆x s ≥ 0
Why is this so? Because the indifference curves are
well behaved (continuous, smooth, negatively sloped
and convex). Convince yourself that with this type
of i.c. it cannot be otherwise. Points to the left of A
will lie on lower i.c. and therefore will not be
chosen. Conclusion: The substitution effect always
moves opposite to the price movement. We say the
substitution effect is negative: if the price goes
down, the demand for the good due to the
substitution effect increases, and vice versa.
Microecono mics I. Antonio Zabalza. University of Valencia 24

Signing the total effect

Contrary to what happens with the substitution


effect, the total effect can be signed most of the
times, but not always. It depends on whether the
good is normal or inferior. To see that, recall the
Slutsky equation.

∆x = ∆x s + ∆x n
Normal goods
∆x = ∆x s + ∆x n
(−) = (− ) + (− )
Both substitution and income effects work in the
same direction. Consequently, as price goes down,
quantity demanded goes up, and vice versa. The
total effect is negative.

Check you understand why income effect in this


case is negative. px ↓⇒ m ↑⇒ x ↑ . Price and good
demanded due to income effect move in opposite
directions.
Microecono mics I. Antonio Zabalza. University of Valencia 25

Inferior goods
∆x = ∆x s + ∆x n
(?) = (− ) + (+ )
Here the sign of the final effect depends on the
relative strength of substitution and income effects.
We have two possibilities:
a) Substitution effect dominates in absolute terms.
Then the total effect is negative. This is what
will usually happen.
b) Income effect dominates in absolute terms.
Then the total effect is positive: as price goes
down, quantity demanded goes up and vice
versa. This means that the demand curve is
upward sloping. We call this type of goods,
Giffen goods. They are very rare.

A conclusion regarding inferior and Giffen goods:


a Giffen good must be an inferior good, but no all
inferior goods are Giffen goods.
Microecono mics I. Antonio Zabalza. University of Valencia 26

Expressing the Slutsky equation in terms of


rates of change with respect the change in
price.

∆x = ∆x s + ∆x n
∆x ∆xs ∆xn
= + (1)
∆ p x ∆ p x ∆p x
Recall previous result,

∆ m = x∆ p x
If the price goes down, this expression gives us a
negative number (the amount of income that, as a
result of the price fall, has to be taken away from the
consumer so that he can just afford the old bundle
A). To identify the income effect from B to C we
want to work with the negative of this (negative)
amount: specifically, with the amount of money that
is given to the consumer so that he can go from the
budget AB to the final budget at C. For this purpose
we define a new change in income, (∆n) , which is
just the negative of the previously defined income
change, ( ∆m) ,
∆n = −∆m
∆n = − x∆p x
∆n
∆px = − (2)
x
Microecono mics I. Antonio Zabalza. University of Valencia 27

Substituting (2) into (1)

∆x ∆x s ∆x n
= −x
∆px ∆px ∆n

Which is the Slutsky equation expressed in terms of


rates of change. Notice that now the income effect is
expressed directly as a change in x due to a change
in income and, therefore, for a normal good, is
positive.

From this equation we state the Law of Demand: If


the demand for a good increases when income
increases (that is, if the good is normal), then the
demand for that good must decrease when its price
increases.

∆x ∆x s ∆x n
= −x
∆px ∆px ∆n
(−) = (− ) − (+ )(+ )

Naturally, this can be said because we know the


substitution effect is always negative.
Microecono mics I. Antonio Zabalza. University of Valencia 28

Another way of measuring the substitution effect:


the “Hicks” substitution effect.

The previous way of measuring the substitution


effect was proposed by an economist called Slutsky.
Another economist (John Hicks) proposed another
way of identifying the substitution effect. To
compare them we define both:

Slutsky substitution effect: Change in demand when


prices change but the consumer’s purchasing power
is held constant so that the original bundle remains
affordable.

Hicks substitution effect: Change in demand when


prices change but the consumer’s income is changed
so that he can reach his original utility level. That is,
change in demand when prices change but
consumer’s utility is held constant at its original
level.

For small (infinitesimal) changes in prices both


measures coincide.

For large (non infinitesimal) changes in prices they


differ. This can be seen graphically.
Microecono mics I. Antonio Zabalza. University of Valencia 29

( p0x , p y0 , m 0 )

( p1x , p 0y , m1 )

B’ ( p1x , p y0 , m 0 )

x
0 s n
x x x
px x sH

p0x A

C
p1x
B’ Demand curve (dc)

Compensated dc (Slutsky)
Compensated dc (Hicks)

x
Microecono mics I. Antonio Zabalza. University of Valencia 30

In the graph we identify three demand curves:

Usual demand curve (dc):

x = x ( p x , p y , m)

Compensated dc (Slutsky):

x = x( px , p y ,purchasing power)

Compensated dc (Hicks):

x = x ( px , p y , u )

Check you understand the ceteris paribus clause of


each of these three demand curves.

Exercise:
How would the graph below look like if good x
instead of being normal was inferior? (What will be
the relative configuration of the three demand
curves?)
Microecono mics I. Antonio Zabalza. University of Valencia 31

5.4 Implications of the MRS conditions

Observation of demand behaviour can give us


information about the underlying preferences of
consumers who display that behaviour.

In a competitive market, prices are the same for


everybody. Thus, if consumers are at equilibrium
positions,

px
MRS1 = MRS 2 = MRS 3 = ... = MRSn =
py
Everybody will adjust their consumption of goods
until their own “internal” marginal valuation (MRS)
equals the market’s external valuation ( px p y ) .
Marginal changes in consumption, therefore, will be
valued the same for everybody.

Example (Varian’s): Suppose that in a competitive


market one bottle of milk costs 1€ and one pack of
butter costs 2€. This means that,

MU b p
MRS = = b =2
MU m pm
Any project (policy) that gives people goods for
more than what they value them is profitable, and
vice versa.
Microecono mics I. Antonio Zabalza. University of Valencia 32

Project A: 1 pack of butter is produced with 3 bottles


of milk. This is not a good project. Using market
prices, it is equivalent to saying that 2€ are produced
with 3€. People value more the inputs than the
output of this project.

Project B: 3 bottles of milk are produced with 1 pack


of butter. This project is OK. Using market prices, it
is equivalent to produce 3€ with 2€. Here people
value inputs less than output.

Conclusion: Prices are not arbitrary things; rather,


they reflect how people value things at the margin.

You might also like