Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 16

Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa and the Middle East

Speculation Illicit and Complicit


Contract, Uncertainty, and Governmentality

Ritu Birla

T
he question of the regulation of futures markets, their contractual performatives and institutional
forms, has a long history going back to global financialization under colonialism at the turn of
the twentieth century. In 1911 the Indian Jute Mills Association, the premier organization of Brit-
ish interests in that industry, wrote to the government of Bengal to complain about vernacular Marwari
traders who, the IJMA claimed, had launched a fictitious system of what were called “pink and white con-
tracts” in speculative jute futures. The association asserted that these so-­called contracts mimicked the
formality of law, all the while manipulating the market and disrupting British managing agencies’ supply-­
and-­demand predictions. According to the IJMA’s counsel, “A section of the Marwari community . . .
[had] invented a means of satisfying their craving for the gains of chance in a system of contracts pur-
porting to evidence the purchase and sale of jute . . . but we believe in no single instance has jute ever
been delivered under them.”1
Exposing the contentious ground of speculation, such archival episodes call for studying market en-
gagements with uncertainty and their political-­economic institutionalization. Debates over the legitimacy
of speculative practices are central to the history of that modern abstraction called the economy. As the
failed vernacular deployment of written contracts betrays here, speculation can at once be condemned
as a dangerous addiction to chance, and so staged as the illicit outside of the market, even as law and its
administrative rituals legitimize speculation as market rationality, enabling some economic agents while
prohibiting others. The dense colonial discourse on vernacular capitalism’s customary speculative mar-
kets and criminal “gambling” inclinations in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries throws
the problem of speculation and uncertainty into relief as a question of governing, asking us especially to
consider the influence of financial imaginaries and derivative markets on ideas and practices of govern-
ment, law, and administration.2
India’s colonial market governance foregrounds the problem of the legal-­governmental legibility

This article is dedicated to the memory of Sri Radhakrishna Birla, who 2. Derivatives refer at their most basic to “a transmission of some value
asked “Satta: Jua Ya Vyapar?” (“Speculation: Gambling or Business?”) in from a source to something else” and so encompass all forms of wager-
his autobiography many years ago. Radhakrishna Birla, Bhuli Bathein Yad ing on the future (Martin, “After Economy?,” 85). Financial speculation
Karun (Amritsar, 1968). cultivates multiple possible futures in order to profit from and reproduce
the circulation of capital and so may be subject to reinterpretation as
1. IJMA to the Bengal Chamber of Commerce, October 25, 1911, in Bengal
“not so much an exchange of equivalents as the universal transmutabil-
Chamber of Commerce, Report, 2:168 – 70.
ity of fluctuation” (Cooper, “Turbulent Worlds,” 167).

3 92 Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa and the Middle East


Vol. 35, No. 3, 2015 • doi 10.1215/1089201x-3426253 • © 2015 by Duke University Press

Published by Duke University Press


Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa and the Middle East

Ritu Birla • Speculation Illicit and Complicit 393

of speculation in processes of economization — in tures markets in much the same ways as merchants
the subcontinent and also more broadly.3 Colonial around the world at the turn of the twentieth cen-
anxieties about vernacular capitalism’s differences tury, trading in key commodities such as jute, cot-
refracted and magnified anxieties present in areas ton, grain, and silver, as well as stocks. At its most
where, unlike in British India, common law and the basic, futures trading referred to forward trad-
generalized operation of written contract acknowl- ing, which allowed for payment of current market
edged the default existence of private mercantile prices (“spot prices”) for commodities for future
exchanges, as in the UK and the United States.4 delivery. The renegotiation of agreements with
The colonial arena calls for making visible tech- the ongoing deferral of delivery, and the settling
niques by which vernacular practices came to be of agreements without delivery across networks
recognized as economic, a project that illuminates of multiple buyers and sellers, fueled specula-
on-­t he- ­g round dynamics and extends the analy- tive activity that bet on the rise and fall in mar-
sis of governmentality and finance, enabling new ket prices.6 These practices reflected the growing
readings of institutions such as private exchanges global integration of markets through new space-­
in the metropole.5 Moreover, as a spectacular scene time proximities produced by the telegraphic quo-
of (mis)translation, colonialism draws attention to tation of spot prices and, more broadly, new legal
different framings of uncertainty itself. frameworks and institutions for the circulation
This essay delves into the Indian colonial of financial capital. In the colonial context, how-
context to detail a shift in the governing of vernac- ever, the worldwide anxiety produced by the nov-
ular speculation from policing to administrative elty and ubiquity of speculative market practices,
procedure in formal exchanges from about 1925 which sought to distinguish between gambling and
to 1947. This transformation, a governmentalization market rationality, was manifest in the mapping of
of speculation grounded in contract law, evinces distinct spatial and temporal stages: the anachro-
three interrelated processes to be highlighted nistic, customary, and informal kinship-­based op-
here. First, deeply localized, embedded practices erations of the bazaar, and the formal legalities of
fueled global financialization and were variously modern economy.
translated by both colonial authorities and ver- Colonial authorities confronted speculative
nacular actors. Second, the jurisprudential travels practices that profited from uncertainty and a mul-
of common law on wagering and its relationship tiplicity of future outcomes by aggressively distin-
to the futures contract reflected new attention to guishing between the spurious, informal nature of
uncertainty in governmental rationality, manifest vernacular conventions, which were governed as a
densely in the discourse on speculation in this pe- realm of native “culture,” and the formal, modern
riod of financialization and unstable imperial po- market inscribed by contract. As I have argued,
litical economy. Third, the ongoing production of from about 1880 to 1925, the bazaar was rendered
the distinction between formal and informal mar- highly suspect as an arena for immoral betting and
kets structures this speculative governance. gambling.7 But from about 1925 to 1947, this gov-
In India, vernacular merchants cultivated fu- ernmental framing of formal and informal worlds

3. Economization refers to processes by which political economy, from Adam Smith to Jeremy Keynes affirmed the risk-­minimizing thesis in
activities and arenas are understood and insti- Bentham especially; attending to the political his General Theory of Employment, Interest, and
tutionalized as economic. See Çalişkan and Cal- economy of finance elaborates Foucault’s in- Money in 1936, while the economist Holbrook
lon, “Economization Part 1.” sights on neoliberal political economy. Working in 1954 argued that all futures trades
anticipate profit and therefore should be un-
4. On similar anxieties in the United States and 6. Buyers could deploy such trades to offset
derstood as speculative ventures. For a sum-
the UK, see Preda, Framing Finance, and Levy, anticipated rises in market price, and sellers
mary of the debate, see Meyer, “Futures Mar-
Freaks of Fortune. On the common law recog- could offset anticipated price falls. Futures
kets as Hedging Markets.” The analysis here, in
nition of on-­the-­ground speculative practices came also to include other forms of “time-­
contrast, turns to Frank Knight to step outside
in private mercantile exchanges in the United bargains” such as options, in which traders
the debates around risk and into the question
States, despite antibucketshop legislation, fixed a price for sale against market fluctua-
of uncertainty.
see Stout, “Why the Law Hates Speculators,” tion. There has been long debate as to whether
721 – 22. futures trading enables hedging in service of 7. On colonial market governance and the pro-
minimizing risk or risk-­t aking speculation in duction of the bazaar as a site of gambling, see
5. Michel Foucault’s mapping of liberal govern-
service of maximizing profit. John Maynard Birla, Stages of Capital.
mentality comes from attention to classical

Published by Duke University Press


Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa and the Middle East

394 Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa and the Middle East • 35:3 • 2015

came to be deployed not toward a moral hygien- selective coding of speculation as legitimate risk-­
ist eradication of speculative activity in the bazaar taking and risk-­m inimizing — w ill then be illus-
but toward a selective integration of it into legality trated through an especially dense site in the legal
as risk management.8 Supplementing my earlier archive, a case in the Bombay High Court of 1928,
research, I detail these tactics here. Rather than Emperor v. Thavarmal Rupchand (1929), 31 BOMLR
reproduce the logic of colonial governmentality 158. This case is an exemplary condensation of legal
to fine-­t une a master distinction between gam- discourse, for it details shifts in the transition from
bling and proper market practices, this analysis colonial policing to formal association and admin-
addresses the folding of speculative engagements istration and reflects the political conditions — 
with uncertainty into formal domains of economy the consolidation of a capitalist class — t hat in-
and governance; it thus moves from a focus on the form them.10 It tells a rich ethnographic story of
illicit to an analysis of the complicit. the criminalizing of an association of bazaar mer-
To do so, I highlight tensions between the chants alongside the affirmation of a more influ-
legal concept of contract as a guarantee for the ential one. As such, it exposes techniques by which
future that requires and polices the delivery of customary speculative practices are both distin-
goods, and contract as a speculative medium, guished from and folded into formal market or-
which enables settlement on the price differences ganization, ultimately highlighting the mistransla-
of goods ordered, without delivery.9 After a brief tion of vernacular vocabularies of uncertainty and
discussion of the theoretical ground for an analysis contingency.
of the folding of speculation into logics of risk, I The story of speculation and governance in
turn to the legal discussions and transformations the Indian colonial context is presented here as a
in case law spawned by global speculative circuits. terrain on which questions in the social studies of
I draw attention to significant precedents in Brit- finance, most especially those attentive to the dis-
ish jurisprudence that focus on the distinction tinction between risk and uncertainty, may mingle
between the wager and the futures contract. This with historical studies of governmentality. Colonial
distinction was made first via an emphasis on the governmental rationality — or perhaps more ap-
intention (rather than the actual fact) of delivery, propriately governmental imagination11 — began
and second through a fine-­t uning of the roles of a robust play with uncertainty in the 1920s; it was
client and broker, or the contract’s principal and informed by the political economy of the inter-
agent. Elaborating on both, I map basic trajecto- war period. From the escalation of nationalist
ries of UK case law that validate brokers’ specula- demands to the expansion of the financial influ-
tive activities and the authority of exchanges. Next, ence of London (the City), to imperial currency
I chart major Indian jurisprudential trends that manipulations and the decreasing profitability of
deploy these precedents and that are representa- empire after World War I, the interwar context
tive of that legal system’s grappling with the prob- demands attention to speculative modalities of
lem of vernacular financial speculation from about governing and genealogies across imperial liberal-
1925 to 1947. The implications of these shifts — the ism and neoliberalism.12 Before turning to global

8. The attention to speculation here supple- that highlight the reproduction of informality 11. On the politics of uncertainty, imagination,
ments established literature on discourses of as precarity, see Roy, “Subjects of Risk” (on mi- and futurity, see Appadurai, Future as Cultural
risk and governmentality; see O’Malley, “Un- crocredit and “bottom billion capitalism”), and Fact.
certain Subjects” and “Governmentality and Chatterjee, Lineages (on corporate and noncor-
12. For a reading of contemporary speculative
Risk.” Under colonial economic liberalism, the porate capital).
governing, see Cooper, “Turbulent Worlds.”
production of informality is central to the map-
9. In the case of shares in company stock, “de- The classic history of London finance in high
ping of the formal market terrain; this is inten-
livery” refers to the completion of the sale and imperialism is Cain and Hopkins, “Gentlemanly
sified in the case of speculation. These colo-
taking of ownership. Capitalism II.” For an excellent analysis of the
nial processes resonate with discussions of
imperial political economy of the period, see
contemporary neoliberal globality. Hernando 10. I read this “condensation” in the spirit of
Balanchandran, “Reappraisal.”
de Soto’s influential work on harnessing the Gayatri Chakravorty Spivak’s approach to the
“dead capital” of the Latin American agrarian colonial archive, elaborated in the now-­classic
underclass celebrates informality and its role in “Rani of Sirmur.”
global markets. For contrasting critical stances

Published by Duke University Press


Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa and the Middle East

Ritu Birla • Speculation Illicit and Complicit 395

circuits and transformations in contract and case finance studies shows, for example, that specula-
law, I briefly elaborate on recent approaches to tion itself has become an elastic term with many
risk, uncertainty, and marketization that inform meanings that define it as exactly what it is not,
the analysis here. that is, as a practice motivated by a probabilistic,
risk-­measuring ethos, one that even calculates
Framing Speculation: Risk, Uncertainty, and Contract risks against risks. In this vein, the world of finance
Bringing Timothy Mitchell’s postcolonial analyt- speaks of “risk-­hedging,” or profiting from those
ics of economic “enframing,” which exposes the “who are willing to trade at unfavorable terms in
politics of infrastructure (legal, technological, order to offload risk.”16 As research in the anthro-
governmental), to Çalişkan and Callon’s attention pology and social studies of finance argues, terms
to marketization, we may think of colonial India like these seek to tame speculation’s play with un-
as a scene of market framing.13 Framing, the de- certainty and locate it within logics of economic
lineation of the market domain, always maps an rationality.17 Against this tendency, recent work
exterior to the frame. It also evinces “moments in these fields has deployed and clarified the dis-
of overflow” that “mark the emergence of [the] tinction between risk and uncertainty, especially
frame’s shortcomings.”14 Colonial governmentality via the early twentieth-­century economist Frank
maps the subcontinental bazaar as an anachronis- Knight, a founder of the Chicago school of eco-
tic outside to the market and its rationalities. Spec- nomics, whose Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit, pub-
ulation, the engagement with uncertainty, exists in lished in 1921, first laid out the distinction.18 For
the bazaar and inside the official market; it marks Knight, because there is “much question to how
an overflow. Contract, the tool for assigning own- far the world is intelligible at all,” uncertainty in-
ership in futures transactions and for enforcing forms all economic transactions (209). Placing un-
the delivery of commodities, operates at the bor- certainty at the heart of all human exchange, he
der between this inside and outside. Contract po- defines risk as “measurable uncertainty” (231 – 33).
lices the boundaries between the market and the Risk is known only by measuring ex ante probabil-
bazaar. But contract also opens this border, for it ity: practices of risk-­t aking or risk-­avoiding occur
translates play with uncertainty into discourses of when the probabilities of various future outcomes
risk.15 As I elaborate, the common law category of can be determined beforehand. On the other
the wagering contract especially enables such com- hand, uncertainty is “not susceptible to measure-
plicities, for it renders wagering and betting void, ment and hence to elimination,” so here “the
but not illegal. probabilities of future outcomes cannot be known
To pursue these different incarnations of beforehand” (232). Uncertainty channels luck and
contract and the governmental techniques that the aleatory, whereas risk management deploys
fold uncertainty into logics of risk-­t aking and risk-­ prediction — mathematical, statistical, and social
minimizing, it is important to take note of recent (as judgment and “estimation”) (236, 197 – 233).19
research attentive to this folding. Work in law and It is also important to emphasize that while

13. Mitchell, Rule of Experts, especially section markets, on the one hand, and legal and politi- 18. Knight, Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit, espe-
3; Çalişkan and Callon, “Economization Part 1”; cal institutions on the other” (Framing Finance, cially chaps. 7 – 8. Knight’s text was published
and Çalişkan and Callon, “Economization Part 19). This calls for attention to the governmen- the same year as Keynes’s Treatise on Probabil-
2,” 8. talization of speculation. ity, but Keynes later also elaborated the distinc-
tion between risk and uncertainty. See Keynes,
14. Çalişkan and Callon, “Economization Part 16. Similarly, the recent concept of informa-
“General Theory of Employment,” 161 – 63. See
2,” 8. tion arbitrage codes speculators as exactly not
also Dow and Dow, “Animal Spirits Revisited.”
gamblers but “savvy researchers who invest
15. Contract is a medium for what Alex Preda
in . . . costly information” to produce the best 19. Following Knight, speculation is thus not
calls “the enclosure of the stock exchange”
probability estimates (Stout, “Uncertainty,” some anachronistic leftover of a premodern
and similar institutions for speculation. It is a
1186 – 87). enchantment; it exists in the deep texture of
medium for the differentiation between the
modern capitalism. See Bear, “Antinomies of
market and its outside that “cannot be under- 17. See, for example, Appadurai, “Ghost in the
Audit.”
stood as just another modernization story,” for Financial Machine”; Mizayaki, “Between Arbi-
the “boundary work implied by such differen- trage and Speculation”; Riles, “Collateral Ex-
tiation is irreducible to distinctions between pertise”; and Zaloom, “Productive Life of Risk.”

Published by Duke University Press


Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa and the Middle East

396 Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa and the Middle East • 35:3 • 2015

speculation is not the primary object of Knight’s Speculation as a Global Phenomenon:


study, it does play a significant role in what he evoc- Crime, Common Law, and the Wagering Contract
atively calls the “methods for meeting” or “deal- At the turn of the twentieth century, vernacular
ing with” uncertainty (238 – 39). As the rhetoric practices in India were de facto at one with those
of dealing evokes, dealing with uncertainty is not of emergent futures exchanges globally: specula-
the same as seeking to measure or control the fu- tion (the broad Hindustani term for which was
ture. Knight proposes two fundamental methods satta) included forward trading in commodities for
to “meet” and “deal”: first, “consolidation,” that is, delivery at a given time (sowda, fatka), options or
reducing uncertainty by grouping, since “uncer- the settling on a price for a given time (badni), and
tainties are less in groups of cases than in single betting on price differences in commodities and
instances,” and second, “specialization,” or select- securities (teji- ­mundi).23 Multiple forward trades
ing certain groups to “bear uncertainty” (255).20 among groups of traders would be renegotiated,
For Knight, “the most important instrument in resulting in profit or loss as spot prices rose or fell,
modern economic society for the specialization of and often these trades would be resolved without
uncertainty, after the institution of free enterprise delivery of the actual commodity. This global burst
itself, is Speculation” (255). Significantly, the best of speculative practices required working out the
example of this, he argues, is the hedging contract, relationship between formal legal mechanisms
or futures contract, for through it, the industrial and customary mercantile arrangements. While
producer, facing unpredictable shifts in the value British case law had already begun grappling with
of materials in his operations between the time of the distinction between the wager and the futures
the acquisition of raw materials and the selling of contract by the 1880s, conflicting case law along-
finished goods, can “shift” this uncertainty onto side the global expansion of speculative finance
the specialized speculator: “Where a single flour capital fueled by imperial conquest saw British
miller or cotton spinner would be in the market Parliamentary Select Committees in 1895 and 1898
once, the speculator can enter it hundreds or thou- conduct inquiries about futures trading. Soliciting
sands of times, and his errors in judgment must assessments from British representatives in Berlin,
show a correspondingly stronger tendency to can- Vienna, Saint Petersburg, Washington, DC, Brus-
cel out and leave him a constant and predictable sels, Athens, Stockholm, Berne, Buenos Aires, and
return on his operations” (255 – 56).21 For Knight, Budapest on “time-­bargains,” they called for “leg-
then, the engagement with uncertainty that is islative measures respecting gambling in ‘option’
speculation fuels producers’ attention to risk in and ‘future’ contracts.”24 The inquiries elaborated
the management of enterprise. Knight promotes on the vast range of customary practices, matched
the intimacies of uncertainty and risk even as he by diverse governmental strategies, from calls to
distinguishes them. His analysis demands that we protect the autonomy of merchant exchanges in
resist taking governmental-­legal media such as Germany to plans for taxing speculative profits in
contract, the very guarantee for the future, and the United States.25 But perhaps most striking was
administrative proceduralism, which subjects the exactly the question of gambling in options and fu-
future to rationalization and prediction, on their tures contracts. This issue captured the fundamental
own terms, instead investigating them as specula- legal problem at play: Was the explosion of settling
tive media and technologies.22 in price differences without delivery of commodities

20. Consolidation for Knight is best illustrated 22. Colonial market governance offers a ripe 23. For a detailed discussion of these and other
by the actuarial sciences of insurance, since context for such analysis. Such postcolonial de- forms of vernacular speculative activity such
while a single individual’s relationship to death ployments of Knight may contribute to recent as barsat ka satta (speculating on rainfall), see
is utterly uncertain, insurance consolidates work on the neoliberal coding of swashbuck- Birla, Stages of Capital, chap. 4.
thousands of instances of death, rendering it ling risk as “the premier device for combining
24. House of Commons, Reports.
predictable. On consolidation and insurance, a supposed instrumentally rational approach
see Knight, Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit, 245 – 51. to action with a post-­hoc moralization of any 25. Ibid., 232 – 65.
market outcome whatsoever” (Mirowski, Never
21. For a rich discussion of Knight on specula-
Let a Serious Crisis Go to Waste, 120 – 21).
tion and consolidation in the US context, see
Kreitner, “Speculations.”

Published by Duke University Press


Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa and the Middle East

Ritu Birla • Speculation Illicit and Complicit 397

a problem of wagering and betting? Were option tale in which the authority of exchanges ultimately
and future contracts to be understood as “wager- trumped the classification of speculative activities
ing contracts,” understood for centuries as void by as betting and wagering. This UK story (with simi-
common law, and if so, should they be legislated lar trends in the United States) occurs in the long
against? period from 1870 to 1930 and informs Indian pol-
The legal dilemma posed by the worldwide icy at an accelerated pace between about 1925 and
burgeoning of speculative markets — t he question 1947. As such, it is worth briefly charting key turns
of whether to follow the customary lex mercatoria in UK case law that inform the Indian context.
or to regulate via direct legislation — had been a In Britain, jurisprudence on market specu-
question in Britain since the 1844 Select Commit- lation focused on established common law. The
tee on Gaming, and subsequent gaming and bet- courts and statutes thus dealt with speculative com-
ting legislation in the 1840s and 1850s.26 But these mercial transactions not by criminalizing them but
regulations had been specifically directed at rec- by deeming them invalid and not actionable. Sec-
reational games and lotteries conducted in what tion 18 of the Gaming Act of 1845 codified com-
were called “public gaming” houses; they reflected mon law, clearly articulating that no legal action
a mid-­nineteenth-­century moral paternalism to- could be taken to recover any money or thing lost
ward the working classes alongside the expansion or allegedly staked or won in a wager.28 Case law
of policing and concepts of public order. These after the 1880s transformed the terms of the dis-
gaming regulations were transported to India course on wagering by fixing on intentionality, the
in the 1860s, but here, unlike in the UK, “public fundamental criterion for adjudicating contracts.
gaming” was applied to speculative mercantile ex- Key precedents deployed intentionality in two op-
changes in the bazaar. Thus by the 1920s, two bills posing ways: first to distinguish futures contracts
were put forward by native members of the Bengal performed in exchanges from wagers, and sec-
assembly to establish what were called native baras, ond to call for evidence and read them as wagers.
or trading exchanges, to legitimize vernacular or- These dialectics then opened up a new interpreta-
ganizations of traders as economically beneficial tion of the relationship between the broker conduct-
and rational.27 Significantly, these proposals cited ing futures trades in an exchange and the client
the common law affirmation of private exchanges (or principal) for whom the broker is an agent.29 In
and customary mercantile practice in the UK, but 1878 Thacker v. Hardy, a case about a stockbroker
they failed. and his client, established that contracts for the
Because Indian policy subjected informal settlement of prices — t hose regularly conducted
exchanges and practices to criminal investigation in exchanges — were legitimate contracts, as long
from the 1880s to the 1920s, it differed substan- as there was an intention to deliver what was sold.30
tially from Britain (and the United States), where Intention to deliver here distinguished the futures
common law was crucial in managing new forms contract from the mere wager, and this decision
of speculative activity. In the UK, elastic jurispru- thus supported practices in exchanges, whose reg-
dence affirmed the crucial common law defini- ularized procedures and rules were understood to
tion of the wagering contract as void, but not ille- evince such intention.31 However, in 1886, Univer-
gal, while also affirming the authority of private sal Stock Exchange v. Strachan, another precedent-­
mercantile exchanges. Case law tells a fascinating setting case do with “stock-­jobbing,” or betting on

26. On gaming law, see Munting, Economic and 29. This case law is wrapped up in another, on through Justice Oliver Wendell Holmes, de-
Social History of Gambling. On the relationship agency. See Wright, Law of Principal and Agent. clared that the intent of brokers to close out
of gambling legislation to mercantile norms, their contracts by “setting-­off” — that is, to set-
30. For a summary, see Bennett, “High Court.”
see Cranston, “Law through Practice.” tle contracts via counter-­transactions without
See also Cranston, “Law through Practice,”
delivery — did not invalidate their transactions.
27. Birla, Stages of Capital, 193 – 98. 31 – 32.
See “Legislation Affecting Commodity and
28. For key cases in the 1820s that affirm com- 31. Many UK and US decisions evince this trend, Stock-­Exchanges,” Harvard Law Review 45, no.
mon law, see Cranston, “Law through Practice,” and it is perhaps most significantly manifest 5 (1932): 912 – 25, and Board of Trade of Chicago
30 – 31, and Dos Passos, Treatise on the Law, es- in 1905 in Board of Trade of Chicago v. Chris- v. Christie, 116 Fed. 944.
pecially chap. 7. tie, in which the US Supreme Court, speaking

Published by Duke University Press


Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa and the Middle East

398 Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa and the Middle East • 35:3 • 2015

the rise and fall of stock prices, deployed the crite- kets in the context not of gaming but of taxation.
rion of intention very differently. Here, the court In this circumstance, speculative dealings were ul-
argued that even if a futures transaction appeared timately validated as “real” commercial contracts
to be a legitimate contract, evidence for such in- to be taxed. At this time, cases concerning the Liv-
tention must be actively investigated. If such inves- erpool Cotton Exchange and the London Metal
tigation revealed that the intention of both parties Exchange confirmed that speculative transactions
was to profit on stock-­jobbing and simply settle dif- conducted by a broker were not wagers. By the
ferences without delivery, then the transaction was 1930s exchange-­t raded transactions were deemed
indeed a wager and void.32 This case thus fortified enforceable, as long as parties intended “to enter
the criterion of intentionality in order to expand into a legal contract, which gave legal rights and
the application of the common law on wagers to imposed legal obligations.”35 This was so even if
futures contracts.33 their intention was speculative, that is, for settle-
But equally as influential was the broader ment of prices without delivery. Case law elabo-
context and ramifications of the Thacker v. Hardy rated Thacker v. Hardy as a clear precedent that
case, in which a stockbroker had sued his client “contracts between brokers are valid.”36 By about
for commission and indemnity for carrying out 1930 brokers were not to be understood as gam-
speculative transactions in which the broker had blers but as commercial agents operating within a
become personally liable. The case thus directly system of rules laid out by commodities exchanges.
addressed the broker-­client relationship. To avoid Indeed, by this time the expansion of the Roman
payment, the defendant/client claimed that all law category of the “aleatory contract,” which cov-
the broker’s transactions were wagering and gam- ered contracts dependent on future contingency,
bling, and therefore void in law. But the court held also aligned contract doctrine with the customary
against the defendant, declaring that the broker authority of merchant exchanges and practices, or
was entitled to recover what was owed him, even the lex mercatoria.37 Definitive US federal regulation
though both broker and client had clearly articu- in this period settled the distinction between the
lated their intentions to transact settlements in wager and speculative market futures through the
price differences without any delivery. The broker’s concept of the “anticipatory breach” of contract.38
transactions for the client could not be understood
as wagers, for wagers required the commitment of Indian Case Law after 1925:
both parties to win or lose on a future uncertain Intentionality, Delivery, and Derivative Value
event. But a broker cannot win or lose, as he oper- The jurisprudential developments in Britain were
ates simply as the agent for the client.34 actively taken up in Indian courts beginning in the
Thacker v. Hardy informed pursuant inter- 1920s, when the focus on the intention of futures
pretations of transactions between brokers as legit- trades, rather than the criminalization of gam-
imate. In the 1920s the English Court of Appeal bling, informed juridical logic. In India the proac-
turned to the validity of dealings in futures mar- tive investigation and interpretation of intention

32. Cranston, “Law through Practice,” 32; Uni- 34. The reasoning of Justice L. J. Cotton in 37. The authority of private exchanges bur-
versal Stock Exchange Ltd. v. Strachan, AC 166 Thacker v. Hardy is summarized clearly in the geoning since the 1870s in the UK and the
(1896), summarized in Shewkissen Mohata and decision of Chimanlal Purshottamdas Shah v. United States had been growing slowly. In the
Ors. v. Mangalchand Maloo and Ors. Nyamatrai Madhavlal. Hereafter cited as Pur- United States, the state resisted directly reg-
shottamdas v. Madhavlal. ulating private exchanges of merchants, like
33. By 1892 one of the most cited cases in mod-
the Chicago Board of Trade. See Stout, “Uncer-
ern tort law clarified that the wager was not 35. On Cooper (Inspector of Taxes) v. Stubbs
tainty,” 1199 – 204.
part of a fixed game; rather, it was entered into (1925), 2 KB 783, and Barnett v. Sanker (1925), 41
by two persons, “touching the issue of a future TLR 660, see Cranston, “Law through Practice,” 38. Kreitner, “Speculations,” 1103 – 4 . In this im-
uncertain event.” UK case law thus began to 32 – 33. See also “Notes on Recent Cases: Barnett portant development, anticipation, rather than
distinguish wagering and gaming, which again v. Sanker.” inclination to security or guarantee of any spe-
pushed the courts to assess speculation not cific future, produced a wholly new category of
36. “Legislation Affecting Commodity Ex-
through the lens of legislation on gaming but contractual relations directed at multiple pos-
changes and Stock-­Exchanges,” 913.
through the common law on wagering (Carlill sible outcomes.
v. Carbolic Smoke Ball Co., cited in Pannalall Kis-
hanlal v. Lal Chand Sohanlal, AIR 1960 Cal 261).

Published by Duke University Press


Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa and the Middle East

Ritu Birla • Speculation Illicit and Complicit 399

that had been launched by Universal Stock Exchange this, this member’s “fatka business” was deemed
v. Strachan produced new challenges of translating wagering. However, and significantly, the bench
vernacular practices and forms of contract. While qualified that nothing in the decision “should be
British precedent informed foundational princi- regarded as a finding against the East India Jute
ples of adjudication, the “voluminous” case law on Association, Ltd., or [its] transactions. On the
speculation (to cite one Bombay High Court judge contrary, it appears . . . that its system is admirably
in Emperor v. Thavarmal) produced a dizzying adapted to various classes of business, substantial
array of stories, exactly because the hermeneutics trade, speculative trade, and wagering.”39
of “discovering” intention, alongside the very his- Representative bookends for the range of
tory of adjudicating customary practice in India, governmental responses to vernacular futures
emphasized attention to the specificity of context, trading, from criminalization for nondelivery to
moderating deployments of precedent from In- the affirmation of influential “native” exchanges
dian courts. Still, a basic outline of trends can be and their intentions to deliver, these two jute specu-
mapped with select cases that draw from the key lation cases alone highlight the novel and selective
UK precedents, as well as the active deployment validation of vernacular speculative practices, a
of Section 30 of the Indian Contract Act (1872), process that occurs through a detailed sifting of
which had codified the UK common law rule of bazaar practices and the meanings of their docu-
the wager as void, in cases that had been previously mentary media. A case that richly details the slip-
assessed under the gaming acts. periness of legal interpretation on vernacular
In markets where competition between documentation occurs in 1925 in the Madras High
Indian and British firms was strong, such as the Court, which delves into the workings of patta patti
jute trade in Calcutta, the long history of police futures delivery orders/contracts concerning two
raids on native godowns (warehouses), searches firms and their transactions in bales of “Japan
of account books, and accusations of gaming twist” yarn. Patta patti was a Gujarati term that had
continued as late as the 1930s. Thus a 1930 Calcutta been introduced by Gujarati traders into Madras
High Court case concerning futures trading in a Presidency, and it literally meant “adjustment or
vernacular exchange, the Bengal Jute Association, settlement.”40 Patta patti transactions, like many
rendered it a “common gaming house” through in futures exchanges, were often circular; sellers
an extensive investigation of delivery orders that would, after a round of speculative transactions
the chief magistrate had called “blind” for merely and countertransactions, buy back the goods that
intending to “conceal the fact that delivery was they had sold and settle without delivery. Indeed,
not intended at all” (Thakurdas Mundra and Ors. the lower court in this case had validated these
v. Emperor, 1930 AIR 1930 Cal 637). Still, shortly speculative circulations as market transactions,
thereafter, in 1933, amid global depression and decreeing that there was no proof that they were
the growing anxiety among British interests wagering. But the Madras High Court overturned
about the fatka bazaar in jute, a case concerning this decision, focusing on the fact that “patta pat-
one member of the politically inf luential East ties or delivery orders . . . passed through several
India Jute Association, also an association of hands and in the short space of seven days all the
Indian interests, delivered a different message. 100 bales which passed through various hands
Its judgment cited Thacker v. Hardy to determine came back to the plaintiff” without delivery. This
that in the futures contracts under investigation, accelerated circulation required investigation, as
this member was acting not as a broker but as a per Universal Stock Exchange v. Strachan, as to the
principal in the speculative contracts. Because of intention of delivery.41 Evoking contagion while

39. Justice Ameer Ali’s judgment on behalf of 40. (Diwan Bahadur) Govindoss v. Sukdevadoss 41. The case cites Universal Stock Exchange v.
the bench in Karunakumar Datta Gupta v. Lan- Ramprasad. Hereafter cited as Govindoss v. Strachan and another much-­cited precedent
karan Patwari, AIR 1933 Cal 759. Ramprasad. from the Queen’s Bench, In re Gieve (1899), 1
Q.B. 794, on the roles of principal and agent in
a contract.

Published by Duke University Press


Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa and the Middle East

400 Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa and the Middle East • 35:3 • 2015

speaking market rationality, the court mapped the delivery rituals and time frames, describing them
various travels of the patta patties, and the various in their Hindu year format.43 At the lower court
hands they passed through, without endorsement level, the client had alleged that “he had lost all his
and without being stamped as hundis (vernacular property and that the plaintiff [the broker], who
negotiable instruments). It stated that no evidence was the son of a friend of his, tempted him to spec-
could be found for even intention of delivery. In- ulate on the Stock Exchange, agreeing not to hold
deed, the decision emphasized that the patta pat- him responsible for giving or taking delivery . . .
ties, and other “havala chits,”42 were deployed to and promising that he would so manage the busi-
keep up appearances of proper trade, but were ness that no loss would fall on the defendant.” But
simply wagering contracts, and so void. Still, it is in the High Court, the bench demanded a reading
important to note that despite the evidence, the of the full context of the evidence, for “to ascertain
transactions were not criminalized and made sub- the real intention of the parties the Court must look
ject to gaming law; instead, they were now ren- at all the surrounding circumstances and can even go
dered void as wagers. behind a written contract” that appears to evince
This 1925 case had deployed British prec- intention of delivery. Thus deploying Universal
edent to “discover” lack of intention to deliver. It Stock Exchange v. Strachan, it then cited Thacker v.
can be contrasted with a later one in the Bombay Hardy to consider whether both parties to the con-
High Court from 1937, Chimanlal Purshottamdas tract sought to win or lose, as in a wager, and then
Shah v. Nyamatrai Madhavlal, which used Thacker v. elaborated on Bombay High Court precedents on
Hardy to overturn a lower court case and validate speculative transactions made by brokers. These
speculation in a bazaar exchange as legitimate supported the interpretation of speculative trans-
business. In this case, a broker, Mr. Shah, appealed actions conducted in exchanges as legitimate busi-
a lower court decision made in favor of his client, ness.44 Emphasizing the context of the Share Ba-
in which Shah had sued his client for remuneration zaar, the court asserted the role of broker as agent,
of his commission (Chimanlal Purshottamdas Shah v. with a fixed commission, whose transactions could
Nyamatrai Madhavlal (1937), 39 BOMLR 1083; also be subject neither to the definition of wagering
173 Ind Cas 205). The client, Madhavlal, had taken nor to Bombay gambling legislation (Bombay Act
out a mortgage bond for security on losses in the III of 1865 [Purshottomdas v. Madhavlal]).
Ahmedabad Share Bazaar (stock exchange) and so These juridical trends after about 1925 mark
had the resources to make the payment. The client a shift in the enforcement of contracts and the as-
had argued that the bazaar transactions were all sessment of intentionality: a shift from an empha-
wagers, therefore null and void, and so he owed sis on the material realization of the contract’s
nothing, and the lower court had agreed. At the promise (the policing of delivery) to procedural
High Court level, however, a detailed accounting rituals for formal association. Said differently, a
of the evidence that demonstrated the court’s fa- trader who settled without delivery came to be as-
miliarity with vernacular procedures resulted in a sessed based on his status as member in a formally rec-
reversal of the decision in favor of the broker. Sig- ognized association. As I mentioned, through to the
nificantly, the judgment took time to elaborate on 1930s, raids on godowns and businesses continued;

42. Havala or hawala is well known as a term 43. Justice Rangenekar, the author of the judg- 44. These cases included J. H. Tod v. Lakhmidas
for informal funds transfer in Islamic con- ment, thus states: “It appears from the evi- Purshotamdas (1892), ILR. 16 Bom. 441; Pero-
texts. In the subcontinent, it referred to a dence that in Samvat year 1989 the appellant sha Cursetji v. Manekji Dossabhoy (1898), ILR.
variety of informal transactions; here it re- was working as a sub-­broker of . . . a sharebro- 22 Bom. 899, on the dealings in government
ferred to slips/“chits” that were not officially ker and a member of the Stock Exchange of paper and shares of a mill; and Sassoon v. Tok-
stamped. As such, the court declared that “the Ahmedabad, and as such . . . he put through ersey (1904), ILR 28 Bom. 616, in which the deal-
havala chits which are supposed to represent various transactions . . . from Jeth delivery to ings were in American futures. The court also
the amount of the actual cash payable under Aso delivery 1985. . . . The dealings between the cited Forget v. Ostigny, a Privy Council judg-
these contracts are not even stamped as hun- parties continued until Maha delivery in Sam- ment of 1895 of the Queen’s Bench of Lower
dies when passed” (Govindoss v. Ramprasad). vat 1986” (Purshottamdas v. Madhavlal). Canada, which defined financial speculation as
“a legitimate commercial transaction” and an
“everyday occurrence” (Forget v. Ostigny, cited
in Preda, Framing Finance, 109).

Published by Duke University Press


Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa and the Middle East

Ritu Birla • Speculation Illicit and Complicit 401

for example, the Indian Chamber of Commerce, invested in the formal scripts of legitimate associa-
the foundation of the Federation of Indian Cham- tion. It also stands out especially as a tale of the
bers of Commerce and Industry (FICCI, founded criminalization of one vernacular merchant, Tha-
in 1926), petitioned the Bengal government in 1928 varmal, in the face of another more established
about numerous occasions of police harassment in and politically influential one, Sir Purshottamdas
the jute trade, complaining of police raids on what Thakurdas, the prominent Indian National Con-
they called “bona fide” speculative markets and the gress leader and lead author-­to-­b e of the famed
unjustified confiscation of account books (Indian 1944 Bombay Plan, the articulation of the new
Chamber of Commerce, Annual Report, 477). The capitalist elite’s claims to manage the economic
formalization of vernacular trade in organizations development of the emergent nation.45 Equally as
such as FICCI, which reflected the expansion of significant, it was the Bombay government that
municipal governance after the 1919 Government launched the case to support Thakurdas.
of India Act as much as India’s greater integration Thavarmal was a member of the Mahajan
into global markets in the interwar period, also Association, a cotton-­brokering business that had
evinced the consolidation of a capitalist class, one been formed in June 1925 and registered with the
that had benefited from speculation in and access Registrar of Companies at that time.46 According
to key commodities during wartime. This period to one justice’s summary, the “formation of this as-
thus also witnessed new gaps between vernacular sociation was viewed with disfavor by the East India
actors and their more established national repre- Cotton Association, which had been recognized by
sentatives. The translation of certain vernacular the Government as the official body controlling
practices into the market frame reflected a new the cotton trade.” Thakurdas, chairman of the
governmentalization of speculation. These processes East India Cotton Association, had informed the
emerged in the speculative political economy of government that the Mahajan Association “was
the 1920s and 1930s, amid currency manipulation, merely an association for gambling in cotton.” Its
wartime fiscal burdens, and depression. As the building, in a series of chawls (balconied tenement
Duke Memorandum, which established dyarchy in structures) in the heart of the bazaar in “New Satta
India, provocatively stated, the “business of Indian Gully, off of Satta Gully, in Sheikh Memon Street,”
budget-­making” was not “inaptly called ‘a gamble was raided by the police on January 21, 1926, under
on rain,’ ” a play with chance akin to the popular a special warrant, and 327 persons were arrested
and extensively reproached popular native prac- for gambling (Emperor v. Thavarmal, point 32).
tice of betting on the monsoon (25). After the arrests, the chief presidency magis-
trate of Bombay had actually acquitted Thavarmal
Governmentalization, Speculation, and Translation: and his associate Dady Mehta, an indication that
Emperor v. Thavarmal the legal registration of the Mahajan Association
Emperor v. Thavarmal Rupchand, a 1928 Bombay helped render it legitimate and that its speculative
High Court case with an exceptionally detailed practices in cotton futures were familiar territory
judgment, captures micro movements in this mo- to the courts. But the Bombay government, on be-
ment of transformation from policing gambling half of Thakurdas and the East India Cotton Asso-
to procedure for speculation, enabled by the dis- ciation, then appealed that decision, claiming that
tinction between informal and formal worlds Thavarmal’s business never even contemplated
produced about and by sectors of vernacular capi- the delivery of goods (Emperor vs. Thavarmal, point
talism. Dealing with key questions in case law at 35). The government deployed evidence from the
the time, it offers a thick description of the legal seized account books and then provided “expert”
transformations of the period that evinced anxiety testimony given by Mehta against his former as-
about the fluidity of vernacular conventions as they sociate Thavarmal on the Mahajan Association’s

45. Thakurdas et al., Brief Memorandum.

46. The term mahajan is a Hindi word for well-­


established merchant.

Published by Duke University Press


Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa and the Middle East

4 02 Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa and the Middle East • 35:3 • 2015

transactions in “American Futures” and in what The association’s documentary and admin-
was called kacchi khandi. istrative performance — of formal procedure and
Considering the statutory prohibition on associative legal scripts — evinced new strategies
gambling, the court initially addressed two related by bazaar merchants to fold their market practices
issues: the legitimacy of the search warrant and into law. But these modernization rituals did not
whether the account books found on the prem- moderate the court’s assessments of the associa-
ises could be understood to be “instruments of tion’s account books in what were called “kaccha
gaming.” This required assessment of the police American Futures” and “Kachi Khandi” trans­
evidence and whether the speculative activities actions. These were subject to surveillance and
happened in public, which would render them the distinction between pukka and kaccha business,
gambling, or within the confines of the associa- terms that emerged from the vernacular trading
tion. The court delved into an unusually micro- worlds, both elite and everyday.
scopic mapping of public space in the bazaar,
evincing established police surveillance tech- Pukka Intentions and Associations,
niques. Simultaneously, it also conveyed a growing Kaccha Transmutability
recognition of futures trading as a legitimate busi- As law and governance came to embrace financial
ness activity when conducted by proper organiza- speculation, and so validate play with uncertainty
tions. It focused on police accounts of speculative as risk management, legal experts were at pains
transactions in the street, under a tarpaulin, with to articulate differences between what were ubiq-
one justice asserting “not the slightest doubt that uitously called pukka (f. pukki, ripe, fully formed,
this open [public] space which is immediately in solid, permanent, and certain) and kaccha (f.
front of the premises . . . is used as a market where kacchi, raw, malleable, uncooked, without solid
cotton business is carried on” (Emperor vs. Tha- form) transactions.47 The colloquial meanings of
varmal, point 35). Speculation was not the prob- the words are extensive and subtle; in speculative
lem; its context was. transactions, the former referred broadly to writ-
The judgment’s second part reads like a deep ten documents from legal contracts to extensively
ethnographic description of the kinds of specula- negotiable vernacular hundis and chits, while the
tive financial transactions that were commonplace latter referred to transactions agreed on verbally,
at the time, offering insight into established tech- albeit most often informed by the weight of gen-
niques that distinguished gambling from specula- erations of symbolic capital. Pukka and kaccha were
tion, on the one hand, and a new governmental also vernacular descriptors for official procedure
interest in identifying legitimate associations for and informal convention, but these terms also ex-
futures and securities trading, on the other. Like tended beyond the flat formal/informal distinc-
other cases, the court sought to assess the inten- tion, for they posed commitment to certainty and
tion to deliver, and the evidence it solicited de- openness to uncertainty as related (as rawness and
tailed vernacular documentary practices, scouring ripeness are) rather than simply opposed a priori.
the content of the account books and highlighting Their generalization in the bazaar, and in govern-
the Mahajan Association’s administrative perfor- mental imaginaries, speaks to the ongoing force of
mativity in its memorandum of association, the customary mercantile practices. Colonial authori-
convening of a “Parakh,” or surveying committee, ties could not simply criminalize the range of kac-
and a defaulting committee, to regulate souda (for- cha practices in futures trading, which evoked en-
ward) or satta (speculative) transactions. All this trepreneurial engagements with uncertainty found
“would seem to indicate that the intention of the in globally relevant and recognized exchanges like
Mahajan Association was to do genuine business” the Chicago Board of Trade.
(Emperor v. Thavarmal, point 17). What were these kaccha khandi transactions?

47. The terms pukka and kaccha arhatia, or


commission agent, are still operative in the ag-
ricultural commodities sector.

Published by Duke University Press


Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa and the Middle East

Ritu Birla • Speculation Illicit and Complicit 403

The term khandi comes from the Sanskrit khand to be carried forward from week to week, with
(noun, m.) for a piece, quantity, a cut, section, or “fresh brokerage” for each new carry-­forward (Em-
division. It often refers to an installment.48 This peror v. Thavarmal, point 16).49 The pace produced
may have referred to the kinds of payments allowed by the smaller units of sale evinced the purpose
on the transactions, payments in installments, like of “pay[ing] differences only without contemplat-
a mortgage. It was also an appropriate name for ing delivery of cotton under any circumstances,”
the derivative market that it was — the khandi trans- for the lower transaction costs (five as opposed to
action being a share, piece, or cut of the trade in one hundred bales) “would appeal to a larger class
American cotton futures, generated by commis- of individuals, particularly the lower middle and
sions. Unwritten and easily open to renegotiation, poorer classes” (Emperor v. Thavarmal, point 18).
kaccha khandi reflected the accelerated pace of the Proper financial speculation demanded
burgeoning global futures markets of the day. But scale, social networks, and respectability, as mani-
the government of Bombay read kaccha transac- fest in formal association, which legitimized non-
tions as operating at such a frenzied pace that they delivery. Thus even when the East India Cotton
could evince only the intention of nondelivery, and Association’s transactions operated just like the
that tied them to an earlier history of gambling. kaccha transactions of its less-­established competi-
Law appropriated the vernacular distinction be- tor, even at times without written contracts, its
tween kaccha and pukka to distinguish legitimate speculative transactions were legitimized:
speculative contracts (pukka) from kaccha prac-
The analogy between the “Hedge” forward con-
tices, which were aligned with wagers. tract of the East India Cotton Association and the
To fortify the issue of nondelivery as a cri- Kacha Khandi [sic] transaction . . . [is] illusory.
terion against the Mahajan Association, the In a “Hedge” contract . . . sometimes there need
justices also drew key distinctions between the not be a written contract or Kabala; in the Kacha
government-­backed East India Cotton Association Khandi transactions, as they were being carried
and the Mahajan Association on the grounds of on, there never  was a written contract or Kabala. . . .
scale, arguing that the smaller units of sale offered Such a mode of transacting business might be per-
missible when the business is between a broker and a
by the latter were also evidence of an intention to
broker, or as in the case of the East India Cotton As-
wager without any commitment to delivery. The ac-
sociation’s “Hedge” contracts, . . . as a cover for already
cused had argued that their kachhi khandi transac-
pending business. . . . Under the East India Cotton
tions were analogous to the “legitimate business” Association Rules, . . . in “Hedge” contracts the
of the East India Cotton Association’s “forward liability to give or take delivery is not altogether
contracts commonly known as ‘Hedge’ contracts,” eliminated. (Emperor v. Thavarmal, point 18; em-
and the differences reflected only the size of units phasis mine)
sold and the “amount and manner of brokerage”
“Pending business” — t he always already condi-
(Emperor v. Thavarmal, point 16). But the court
tion of formal market association — alongside the
emphasized this difference in scale to illustrate
affirmation of the scale and standardized rules of
the dangerous speed of forward trading. The East
the exchange enabled the coding of play with un-
India Cotton Association’s minimum unit for busi-
certainty as attention to risk. Knight’s speculative
ness was one hundred bales, while the Mahajan’s
hedge contract here emerges as the medium for
was only five. This, alongside the former’s maxi-
bearing uncertainty, in the context of specializa-
mum brokerage rate of eight annas based on the
tion and consolidation by large-­scale grouping. In
total price of bales realized versus the latter’s maxi-
this vein, the judgment declared that even the East
mum brokerage of two annas per each bale no mat-
India Cotton Association’s teji- ­mandi contracts, or
ter what the value, allowed for the latter’s contracts
derivative bets on the market price of one’s estab-

48. I owe this insight to Sri B. L. Sarda, a retired 49. An anna was a unit of Indian currency
businessman in Jaipur, via a discussion ar- equivalent to one-­sixteenth of a rupee.
ranged by Dr. R. K. Birla (telephone interview
by the author, February 20, 2013).

Published by Duke University Press


Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa and the Middle East

404 Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa and the Middle East • 35:3 • 2015

lished forward contracts, “although . . . of a highly into a contract of sale or purchase of securities
speculative nature, may, under certain circum- that only difference in prices should be paid, the
stances, be regarded as a legitimate business and transaction, even though speculative, is valid and
not void, for “there is no law against speculation
may act as an insurance against the fluctuations
as there is against gambling.” But, if the parties
of a constantly changing market” (Emperor v. Tha-
do not intend that there should be any delivery of
varmal, point 23).
the shares but only the difference in prices should
Indeed, as the Calcutta High Court declared be accounted for, the contract, being a wager, is
in 1940, futures trading without delivery had be- void. (Madhubhai Amathalal Gandhi v. The Union of
come generally accepted, as cases emphasized es- India, 1961 AIR 21; also 1961 SCR (1) 191)
tablishing the intention of delivery, whether or not
Through the criterion of intention, practices
delivery occurred (Shewkissen Mohata and Ors. v.
of seeking profit from uncertainty were thus slowly
Mangalchand Maloo, AIR 1941 Cal 341). By the time
folded into law, which reproduced the distinction
of the developmentalist nation-­state’s Forward
between informal (or uncertainty-­engaging) and
Contracts and Securities Contracts Regulation
formal (or risk-­managing) practices and mapped
Acts in the 1950s, key statutes of postindependence
it onto the kaccha/pukka distinction. At the same
administrative law, the central government forti-
time, kaccha/pukka continued to overflow the infor-
fied the authority of associative organization as an
mal/formal framing, as vernacular enactments of
arm of governmental administration, closely map-
formal procedures evinced; these conveyed an un-
ping procedures and clearly defining terms such
derstanding of law’s doublespeak — its compulsive
as the “specific delivery contract,” directed at ac-
investment in performatives of certainty, even as
tual delivery as distinct from the more generic for-
it enabled almost obsessive play with uncertainty.
ward contract, “securities,” and provisions for the
Thus among bazaar merchants, pukka contracts
official registration and recognition of stock and
were often ornately performative, almost passive-­
futures exchanges (Forward Contracts Regulation
aggressively enacting contract’s anxieties about
Act [1952] and the Securities Contracts Regula-
contingency: a payment of one hundred rupees
tion Act [1956]). By the 1960s the content of cases
would detail that “one hundred” was “twice of
had shifted completely to the legitimacy of asso-
fifty,” and “one third of one hundred and fifty,”
ciations, grounded in a standard taxonomy of fu-
before being officially stamped.50 The colonial rule
tures trading, to ensure that speculation would not
of law translated and circumscribed pukka, a ver-
perish into gambling. In 1962 the Indian Supreme
nacular term for a certainty that shared in kaccha
Court thus affirmed the status and authority of the
transmutability, into the universal equivalence of
new Bombay Stock Exchange (the formalized in-
contract.
carnation of the Native Share and Stock Brokers
Association) by summarizing over a half-­century of
Uncertainty, Proceduralism,
case law on the wager:
and the Colonial-­Neoliberal Rule of Law
There are three modes of dealing in shares and The Indian story evinces a dynamic between ad-
stores, namely, (1) spot delivery contract . . . (2) ministrative proceduralism and the engagement
ready delivery contract, which means a contract
with uncertainty in market practice. As such, in
for the purchase or sale of securities . . . which is to
closing I would like to briefly link this historical
be performed immediately or within a reasonable
time; (3) forward contracts. . . . If the stock ex-
data to recent themes in the social study of finance
change is in the hands of unscrupulous members, as elaborated by Arjun Appadurai, as well as with
the second and third categories of contracts . . . questions in the genealogy of neoliberal govern-
may degenerate into highly speculative transac- ing.51 Appadurai reads Max Weber’s Protestant Ethic
tions or, what is worse, purely gambling ones. against the grain, linking it to the theories of one
Where the parties do not intend while entering of Weber’s most avid students, Frank Knight, to

50. Sarda interview.

51. Appadurai, “Ghost in the Financial Machine”


and “Spirit of Calculation.”

Published by Duke University Press


Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa and the Middle East

Ritu Birla • Speculation Illicit and Complicit 405

foreground uncertainty in discourses of global fi- thought as it emerged in the 1930s and 1940s,
nance. Weber’s engagement with the radical uncer- which specifically channels Weber’s attention to
tainty of Calvinism, the uncertainty of being cho- the “problem of irrational rationality in capitalist
sen for salvation, manifests as an argument for the society.”54
relationship between Protestant ascetic discipline/ As I have elaborated here, the regulation of
methodicality and capitalism’s calculative spirit. financial speculation and the bazaar in colonial
These are distinguished from the “irrational re- India presents an important early exercise of a con-
liance on any sort of technical procedure” that certed, coordinated juridico- ­economic framing of a
Weber calls magicality.52 Turning the distinction market. Foucault emphasizes in his analysis of early
between the spirit of calculation and magicality neoliberal thought that neoliberalism seeks exactly
on its head, Appadurai emphasizes that for Weber, this: a juridico-­economic order built on a tight
“magic is a kind of coercive proceduralism.” Link- bond between law and economy apparent even in
ing magicality and capitalist methodicality in the its utilitarian ancestry. Neoliberals, Foucault em-
concept of proceduralism, this reading makes it phasizes, transformed the concept of laissez-­faire
“possible to identify a series of . . . coercive and into a project of vigilance. This was tied to their
divinatory performative procedures . . . at the idea of competition as the very ground for social
heart of global capitalism and in particular, of the vitality and progress, but one that required pro-
financial sectors.”53 While I do not seek to unpack tection from monopoly (133 – 3 4). Counteracting
the magicality of speculative practices (as others monopoly and sustaining the terrain of competi-
in this section do), it is the link between procedur- tion required a framework for the ongoing play of
alism and uncertainty beyond probability-­calculation competition (163). Overarching vigilance was thus
that is useful here, for Appadurai’s analysis chal- not to be understood as heavy interventionist state
lenges us to consider how uncertainty may be re- control or the authoritarian exercise of direct sov-
produced in an obsessive-­compulsive addiction to ereignty that is police power (132 – 33, 167). Vigi-
procedure. As distinct from risk management and lance would be manifest through a new enfram-
the calculation of probability, the fetishization of ing of market society, the rule of law. As opposed to
procedure can mark engagement with, or perhaps panoptical surveillance, the rule of law established
more precisely rule by, uncertainty. As such, Ap- and enforced the rules of the game: “For both the
padurai unpacks Weber’s temporizing of modern state and for individuals, the economy must be a
bureaucratic rationalities and traditional, “magi- game: a set of regulated activities . . . in which the
cal” irrationality and poses the embeddedness of rules are not decisions which someone takes for
the latter in the former. others. It is a set of rules which determine the way
Understood thus, the colonial shift in the in which each must play a game whose outcome is not
regulation of speculative markets from the coer- known by anyone. The economy is a game and the legal
cive force of police to the administration of policy institution which frames the economy should be thought
and procedures indicates new governmental en- of as the rules of the game” (173; emphasis mine). Neo-
gagements with uncertainty even as they speak in liberal governmentality relies on the coding of the
languages of security. These developments evoke market as a game with an unpredictable outcome.
Foucault’s reading of neoliberal governmentality, The rule of law, distinguished from authoritarian
most especially its juridical framing of the market sovereignty — a s colonial liberalism sought to dis-
as a game with an uncertain outcome, one tied to tinguish itself — is a market framing that cultivates
fortified concepts of social competition and the uncertainty, while buttressing administrative pro-
rule of law. Here, Appadurai’s reading of Weber ceduralism, so that this game of chance is never-
resonates with Foucault’s analysis of neoliberal theless not simply an irrational gamble. Like the

52. Appadurai, “Ghost in the Financial Ma- 54. Foucault, Birth of Biopolitics, 105, and Lec- liberalism”; Dardot and Laval, “New Way of the
chine,” 527. tures 1 – 5 more generally. For important elab- World”; Gane, “Emergence of Neoliberalism”;
orations of Foucault on the relationship of and Mirowski and Plehwe, Road from Mont
53. Ibid., 527, 532.
liberalism and neoliberalism, see Brown, “Neo- Pèlerin.

Published by Duke University Press


Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa and the Middle East

406 Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa and the Middle East • 35:3 • 2015

futures contract, it channels the full range of spec- References


ulation’s meaning, from surveillance to venture.55 Appadurai, Arjun. The Future as Cultural Fact: Essays on the
Colonial market governance articulated a Global Condition. London: Verso, 2013.
liberal project of improvement for “moral and ma- ——— . “Ghost in the Financial Machine.” Public Culture
terial progress” and installed a regime for the free 23, no. 3 (2011): 517 – 39.
circulation of capital in the name of the rule of ——— . “The Spirit of Calculation.” Cambridge Anthropol-
law. The speculative modalities of colonial market ogy 30, no. 1 (2012): 3 – 20.
governance illuminate connections across the im- Balachandran, Gopalan. “Reappraisal: Finance and Poli-
perial institutionalization of a public of economic tics in Late Colonial India, 1917 – 1947.” South Asia 19,
actors and neoliberal governmental rationalities no. 1 (1996): 77 – 101.
promoting the entrepreneurial subject, venture, Bear, Laura. “The Antinomies of Audit: Opacity, Insta-
and competition. They also ask about how high bility, and Charisma in the Economic Governance
imperial financialization might inform the “spec- of a Hooghly Shipyard.” Economy and Society 42, no.
3 (2014): 375 – 97.
ulative methodologies” of contemporary global
governing in today’s “globally integrated financial Bengal Chamber of Commerce. Report of the Bengal Cham-
regime.”56 The regulation of vernacular futures ber of Commerce 1911. Vol. 2. Calcutta: Bengal Chamber
of Commerce, 1912.
markets in India and their coding in law and pol-
icy may inform a genealogy of contemporary neo- Bennett, Edmund. “High Court of Justice of England,
Queens Bench: Thacker v. Hardy.” American Law Reg-
liberal governance as speculative governance, moti-
ister 27, no. 4 (1879): 254 – 61.
vated by uncertainty as well as vigilance.
Colonialism, which mapped the globe via Birla, Ritu. Stages of Capital: Law, Culture, and Market Gover-
nance in Late Colonial India. Durham, NC: Duke Uni-
centers and peripheries, has taught us about the in-
versity Press, 2009.
timacies of formal and informal economic worlds,
Brown, Wendy. “Neoliberalism and the End of Liberal
and indeed of the very production of the distinc-
Democracy.” Theory and Event 7, no. 1 (2003): 1 – 25.
tion between the two through the installation of the
rule of law. This essay has thus been informed by Cain, P. J., and A. G. Hopkins. “Gentlemanly Capitalism
II: New Imperialism, 1850 – 1945.” Economic History Re-
an interest in the mutual history of the idea of in-
view 40, no. 1 (1987): 1 – 26.
formality, speculative practices, and languages of
Çalişkan, Koray, and Michael Callon. “Economization
global governing, a history that bears the imprint
Part 1: Shifting Attention from the Economy to Pro-
of imperialism and its market governance. Here I
cesses of Economization.” Economy and Society 38, no.
have addressed a key site for that history: specula- 3 (2009): 369 – 98.
tive market practices that play with the valuation of
——— . “Economization Part 2: A Research Program for
an uncertain future, amid imperial financialization
the Study of Markets.” Economy and Society 39, no. 1
and territorial conquest at the turn of the twenti- (2010): 1 – 32.
eth century. If this moment signaled an aggressive
Chatterjee, Partha. Lineages of Political Society. New York:
global expansion of finance capital, contemporary Columbia University Press, 2011.
neoliberal globality, which also operates on and
Cooper, Melinda. “Turbulent Worlds: Financial Markets
cultivates a distinction between the formal and the
and Environmental Crisis.” Theory, Culture, and Soci-
informal as the global and the local, extends and ety 27, nos. 2 – 3 (2010): 167 – 90.
unearths new territory for financialization and the
Cranston, Ross. “Law through Practice: London and
proliferation of market values through new govern- Liverpool Commodity Markets, c. 1820 – 1975.” LSE
mental (ir)rationalities. Law, Economy and Society Working Papers. London
School of Economics and Political Science, Law De-
partment, no. 14, 2007.

55. The etymology of speculation evokes vigi- 56. These speculative methodologies — environ- of value” (as derivative markets evince) (Coo-
lance and surveillance (see the opening state- mental, military, and financial — evince the ab- per, “Turbulent Worlds,” 172, 179).
ment for this special section). sence of any “final determination to the value

Published by Duke University Press


Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa and the Middle East

Ritu Birla • Speculation Illicit and Complicit 407

Dardot, Pierre, and Christian Laval. The New Way of the Mirowski, Philip, and Dieter Plehwe, eds. The Road from
World: On Neoliberal Society. New York: Verso, 2013. Mont Pèlerin: The Making of the Neoliberal Thought Col-
De Soto, Hernando. The Mystery of Capital: Why Capital- lective. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press,
ism Triumphs in the West and Fails Everywhere Else. New 2009.
York: Basic Books, 2000. Mitchell, Timothy. Rule of Experts: Egypt, Techno-­Politics, Mo-
Dos Passos, John Randolph. A Treatise on the Law of Stock dernity. Berkeley: University of California Press, 2002.
Brokers and Stock-­Exchanges. New York: Harper, 1882. Mizayaki, Hirokazu. “Between Arbitrage and Speculation:
Dow, Alexander, and Sheila H. Dow. “Animal Spirits Re- An Economy of Belief and Doubt.” Economy and Soci-
visited.” Capitalism and Society 6, no. 2 (2011): 1 – 23. ety 36, no. 3 (2007): 396 – 415.

“The Duke Memorandum.” In Papers Relating to the Ap- Munting, Roger. An Economic and Social History of Gambling
plication of the Principle of Dyarchy to the Government of in Britain and the USA. Manchester, UK: Manchester
India, 1 – 37. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1920. University Press, 1996.

Foucault, Michel. The Birth of Biopolitics: Lectures at the “Notes on Recent Cases: Barnett v. Sanker.” Cambridge Law
Collège de France, 1978 – 79. Translated by Graham Journal 2 (1924 – 26): 379 – 80.
Burchell. New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2004. O’Malley, Pat. “Governmentality and Risk.” Sydney Law
Gane, Nicholas. “The Emergence of Neoliberalism: School Research Paper No. 09/98 (September 2009).
Thinking through and beyond Michel Foucault’s Social Science Research Network. Posted Septem-
Lectures on Biopolitics.” Theory, Culture, and Society ber 25, 2009. papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm
31, no. 4 (2014): 3 – 27. ?abstract_id=1478289.

House of Commons. Reports from Select Committees and ——— . “Uncertain Subjects: Risks, Liberalism, and Con-
Other Papers on Gambling and Lotteries. Irish Univer- tract.” Economy and Society 29, no. 4 (2000): 460 – 84.
sity Press Series of British Parliamentary Papers: So- Preda, Alex. Framing Finance: The Boundaries of Markets
cial Problems, Gambling, vol. 2. Shannon: Irish Uni- and Modern Capitalism. Chicago: University of Chi-
versity Press, 1971. cago Press, 2009.
Indian Chamber of Commerce. Annual Report of the Com- Riles, Annelise. “Collateral Expertise: Legal Knowledge
mittee for the Year 1928. Calcutta: Indian Chamber of in the Global Financial Markets.” Current Anthropol-
Commerce, 1929. ogy 51, no. 6 (2010): 795 – 818.
Keynes, John Maynard. “The General Theory of Em- Roy, Ananya. “Subjects of Risk.” Public Culture 24, no. 1
ployment.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 51 (1937): (2012): 131 – 55.
209 – 23. Spivak, Gayatri Chakravorty. “The Rani of Sirmur: An
Knight, Frank H. Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit. New York: Essay on Reading the Archive.” History and Theory 24,
Kelly and Milman, 1957. no. 3 (1985): 247 – 72.
Kreitner, Roy. “Speculations of Contract, or How Contract Stout, Lynn A. “Uncertainty, Dangerous Optimism, and
Law Stopped Worrying and Learned to Love Risk.” Speculation: An Inquiry into the Limits of Demo-
Columbia Law Review 100 (2000): 1096 – 138. cratic Governance.” Cornell Law Review 37 (2011 – 12):
Kumar, Richa. “Mandi Traders and the Dabba: Online 1177 – 212.
Commodity Futures Markets in India.” Economic and ——— . “Why the Law Hates Speculators: Regulation and
Political Weekly 55, no. 31 (2010): 63 – 70. Private Ordering in the Market for OTC Derivatives.”
Levy, Jonathan. Freaks of Fortune: The Emerging World of Duke Law Journal 48 (1999): 701 – 86.
Capitalism and Risk in America. Cambridge, MA: Har- Thakurdas, Purshottamdas, G. D. Birla, Ardeshir Dalal,
vard University Press, 2012. Lalbhai Kasturbhai, John Mattai, Ardeshir Shroff,
Martin, Randy. “After Economy? Social Logics of the De- and J. R. D. Tata. A Brief Memorandum Outlining a
rivative.” Social Text 31, no. 114 (2013): 83 – 106. Plan for the Economic Development of India. New York:
International Secretariat, Institute of Pacific Rela-
Meyer, Thomas O. “Futures Markets as Hedging Markets tions, 1944.
and the Relative Effects of Speculation on Hedg-
ing Effectiveness.” Working Paper Series CDFM, no. Weber, Max. Economy and Society. Vols. 1 – 2. Berkeley: Uni-
210, September 1990. Columbia University Business versity of California Press, 1978.
School Center for the Study of Futures Markets. Wright, Eric Blackwood. The Law of Principal and Agent.
Mirowski, Philip. Never Let a Serious Crisis Go to Waste: How 2nd ed. London: Steven and Sons, 1901.
Neoliberalism Survived the Financial Meltdown. London: Zaloom, Caitlin. “The Productive Life of Risk.” Cultural
Verso, 2013. Anthropology 19, no. 3 (2004): 365 – 91.

Published by Duke University Press

You might also like