Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 22

Innovation Policies and Locational Competitiveness:

Lessons from Singapore


1st ASIALICS International Conference on “Innovation Systems and Clusters in Asia:
Challenges and Regional Integration”, 1-2 April 2004, Bangkok, Thailand

Alexander Ebner
Krupp-Chair of Public Finance
University of Erfurt
D-99105 Erfurt, Germany

alexander.ebner@uni-erfurt.de

Abstract

The Singaporean development experience illustrates the prospects as well as limits of innovation policies
in the context of globalisation, highlighting the attraction of foreign direct investment as a means of
technological upgrading. This points to her regional position as a manufacturing and service hub, for
Singapore is viewed as an infrastructural nodal point interconnected to global production networks, thus
adapting to the changing structural conditions of the world economy. Paralleling efforts in the domain of
technological innovation, the Singaporean policies for locational competitiveness aim at a pragmatic
harmonisation of the needs of international investors with local developmental objectives. Consequently,
the Singapore model of development represents a paradigmatic case regarding the challenges of
technological globalisation.
Alexander Ebner 2

1. Introduction

Building institutional networks for the assimilation of technological innovations has


emerged as an indispensable policy rationale in sustaining economic development. This
implies a strategic coupling of development strategies and innovation policies that
provides opportunities for catch-up growth in the context of the international division of
labour. Following the neo-Schumpeterian line of reasoning, the resulting development
trajectories may be assessed with respect to the evolution of the corresponding techno-
economic paradigm, perceived as an ideal type of productive organisation that has been
shaped most recently by the impact of information and communication technologies,
fuelling the process of globalisation. Reflecting the establishment of global production
and innovation networks, both foreign and local multinational enterprises have emerged
as strategic partners of governments. However, as globalisation implies both a
centralisation and decentralisation of economic activities, these developmental
tendencies imply institutional and spatial restructuring on various scales. In particular,
they highlight the developmental role of high-level agglomerations in an economic
context that is increasingly associated with regional integration and other institutional
constellations that complement the national terrain of interaction. Accounting for the
innovation-driven dynamism that is associated with these agglomerations, most
prominently denoted as ‘global cities’, then, the role of locational competitiveness in the
attraction of global knowledge and investment flows, as well as the corresponding
innovation policies, become of utmost importance for the assessment of innovation
systems.
Accounting for these aspects, the Singaporean development experience illustrates most
convincingly the prospects as well as limits of innovation policies in the context of
globalisation and its locational aspects. Indeed, current development efforts in the
Southeast Asian city-state economy of Singapore have been attributed primarily to the
implementation of specific policies which attract foreign direct investment as a means of
employment creation and technological upgrading. In order to sustain her competitive
position as a trade, service and communication hub, Singapore promotes the
developmental vision of an ‘intelligent island’ in a global knowledge-based economy.
The present paper assesses the Singaporean development trajectory in the context of
neo-Schumpeterian arguments, in particular exploring institutional and spatial aspects
that reflect the impact of globalisation. It proceeds in three sections. First, the
conceptual terrain is prepared by exploring the neo-Schumpeterian approach to
economic development. Technological globalisation is discussed with reference to the
restructuring of innovation systems on various scales, reflecting the rationale of
locational competitiveness. Second, the Singaporean development experience and
current attempts of sustaining its dynamism by implementing innovation-oriented
policies with a conceptual bias towards locational aspects are taken to the fore. Third,
the Singaporean system of innovation is explored; with the adaptive relationship
between local government and international capital as an essential characteristic that
shapes attempts of building a local science and technology infrastructure. The paper
concludes that coping with the dominant techno-economic paradigm offers persistent
challenges for the Singapore economy. An important problem is posed by the formation
of institutions in support of knowledge spill-over effects among multinational and local
enterprises, which should contribute to locally embedded capabilities.
Innovation Policies and Locational Competitiveness: Lessons from Singapore 3

2. Technological Globalisation and Locational Competitiveness

The Logic of Technological Globalisation

Proponents of post-national constellations in a ‘borderless world’ usually define


globalisation by components like the establishment of international capital markets, the
formation of global industrial structures in supply, production, and sales, the dynamism
of information and communication technologies, as well as the convergence of
consumption standards (Ohmae 1995: 3n). However, the actual pattern of globalisation
points to the complexity of distinct institutional, technological and spatial processes that
combine tendencies of decentralisation and centralisation. The fundamental role of
technological innovation as a driving force in these processes is well captured by the
aspect of technological globalisation, for an increasing proportion of technological
innovations is exploited in international markets, while global technological
collaboration expands. The global generation of technology, however, reflects only a
partial internationalisation of technological activities, as these remain biased towards
home country locations (Archibugi and Michie 1995: 125n). Globalisation then implies
that Northern America, Europe, and East Asia emerge as the decisive world regions in
terms of production, investment, and trade, with the United States as the dominant
economy in technological terms, as indicated by the lead position in gross expenditures
on R&D (Ebner 2002).
Multinational enterprises have emerged as the decisive organisational carriers in the
globalisation of innovation-related activities, as reflected by three aspects: First, the
international exchange of patents, licenses, personnel and the related segments of
knowledge. Second, the emergence of a global labour market for R&D personnel and
the internationalisation of personnel resources that are concerned with R&D. Third, the
extension of co-operative arrangements like joint ventures and consortia, as well as the
intensified participation in inter-firm research programmes (Paoli and Guercini 1997).
This refers to a combination of organisational decentralisation and spatial centralisation,
to be assessed in the context of the innovation networks of multinational enterprises,
which contain a range of functions from market oriented product development to basic
research units. The latter tap spatial agglomerations of knowledge-intensive units such
as excelling academic centres, perceived as ‘pockets of innovation’ (Granstrand et al.
1993: 414n). Accordingly, technological globalisation implies the integration of
geographically dispersed and locally specialised activities (Cantwell 1999: 238).
Organisational decentralisation generates benefits from an adaptive R&D strategy which
focuses on local markets and users, highlighting local knowledge. Yet centralisation,
mostly in the corporate home country, may be beneficial with regard to the
corresponding science-base and patterns of technological specialisation, accompanied
by advantages from local co-operation with headquarter units (Howells and Wood
1993).
Accordingly, technological globalisation implies spatial restructuring on various scales.
High-level agglomerations in ‘global cities’ express that process. They obtain
interrelated functions as coordination points of the world economy, key locations and
market places, and major sites of production and innovation (Sassen 1994: 4). The
related notion of ‘technopoles’ points to districts which are primarily located in
metropolitan areas, providing agglomeration dynamics in high-technology industries
through a specific ‘milieu of innovation’, while exhibiting control functions with a
Alexander Ebner 4

global reach (Castells 1996: 389n).1 Complementing these perspectives, the concept of
the ‘competence block’ points at agents and organisations, like universities, that are
involved in the local creation of increasing returns to innovative search (Eliasson 2000:
236n). Resembling the notion of a ‘triple helix’, the systemic communication between
universities, industries and government actually promotes the local production and
diffusion of knowledge (Leydesdorff and Etzkowitz 1997: 155n). Indeed, the
outstanding role of universities and research districts has been exemplified by the cases
of Silicon Valley, with nearby Stanford University, and the Route 128 district around
Boston, with Harvard and MIT as neighbouring academic centres of excellence
(Saxenian 1994). This is in accordance with the suggestion that technological
globalisation implies a persistent drive for territorial specialisation concerning
knowledge-intensive activities.
Locational competitiveness in terms of the territorial attraction of high-value added
economic activities then depends on competitive advantages like the institutional setting
of a specific territory that is crucial for embedding local innovation capabilities. Global
networks of production, distribution and finance contribute to the centralisation of high
value added economic activities within ‘neo-Marshallian network nodes’ (Amin and
Thrift 1992). This position confronts suggestions, which maintain that globalisation
reinforces regional communities in terms of a re-emergence of a type of regional
economies with a structural dominance of small and medium-sized enterprises, which
had been eliminated during the emergence of large-scale industrial production patterns
(Storper and Scott 1995: 511n). The related types of regional externalities would
involve the transfer of tacit knowledge, the existence of localised knowledge pools as
well as specific industrial cultures that drive technological specialisation and regional
policy capacities (Cooke and Morgan 1998: 6). Yet critics of the regionalisation thesis
argue that globalisation rather tends to weaken regional linkages, whereas the local
access to the global networks of multinational enterprises becomes crucial for sustaining
economic development (Amin 1994: 25). As a result, the particular logic of these global
networks constrains developmental policy initiatives, enforcing an adaptation to the
rationale of locational competitiveness.
The neo-Schumpeterian concept of techno-economic paradigms in economic
development provides further insights concerning these institutional, technological and
spatial dimensions of globalisation. A techno-economic paradigm denotes the ideal
typical productive organisation and the related form of productivity growth within and
across firms, industries and countries. Paradigm changes include the establishment of
new modes of regulation that contribute to the fine-tuning of technologies and
institutions during a trial and error process (Freeman and Perez 1988: 58n).
Accordingly, the international division of labour is characterised by the technological
leadership of those countries which are best equipped for meeting the paradigmatic
infrastructural and institutional requirements. The recent transition from a Fordist model
of energy-intensive mass-production to a knowledge-intensive paradigm, based on the
productive impact of information and communication technologies, characterises
opportunities for economic development and catch-up growth (Freeman 1996).
Therefore, the process of technological globalisation and the corresponding policy

1
Theories of economic development and industrial change in a Schumpeterian tradition have continuously
accounted for these aspects, as indicated by Perroux‘s approach to ‘growth poles’, following the thesis
that economic growth would proceed as a geographically concentrated process that is driven by innovative
industries. Locations of growth poles then define positions in the hierarchy of the international division of
labour (McKee 1991: 86n).
Innovation Policies and Locational Competitiveness: Lessons from Singapore 5

rationale of locational competitiveness may be assessed as reflections of a changing


techno-economic paradigm that affects also the structuration of national innovation
systems.

The International Restructuring of Innovation Systems

The neo-Schumpeterian system of innovation concept complements the notion of


techno-economic paradigms by examining the role of institutions for the generation and
diffusion of innovations within a territorial setting (Ebner 1999: 143n). In a broad sense,
a system of innovation is defined as ‘the network of institutions in the private and public
sector whose activities and interactions initiate, import, modify and diffuse new
technologies’ (Freeman 1987: 1). Based on the assumption that knowledge is the
fundamental resource in economic development, and learning the decisive economic
activity which is embedded in a specific institutional context, it is argued that systems of
innovation consist of actors and their interactive relationships in the evolution of
economically useful knowledge (Lundvall 1992a: 1n). However, the notion of systems
of innovation shall not suggest the image of a consciously designed and smoothly
working entity. It corresponds rather with a set of interacting agents engaged in trial-
and-error processes (Nelson and Rosenberg 1993: 4n). On the firm level, these
interactions denote primarily user-producer relationships, perceived as modes of
cooperation between producers and users of certain innovations, communicating user
needs and technological opportunities in terns of interactive learning (Lundvall 1992b:
47n). Industrial structures and the institutional set-up of an economy then determine the
shape and performance of an innovation system, with institutional components like
R&D facilities, education programmes and patent systems as decisive determinants of
competitiveness.
Systems of innovation represent those institutional and organisational means which are
essential for coping with paradigm changes in providing ‘windows of opportunity’ for
catch-up growth. Infrastructural investments and institutional changes supporting
continuous learning processes are decisive elements of that process (Dosi, Freeman and
Fabiani 1994: 11n).2 The provision of appropriate institutional conditions for technology
transfer then denotes a key problem of catch-up growth. Mechanisms of technology
transfer to developing economies comprise of foreign direct investment, joint ventures,
licensing agreements, and sub-contracting, including arrangements on original
equipment manufacture as well as own-design and manufacture. Additionally, foreign
and local customers, informal means and partnerships, as well as overseas acquisitions
and equity investments need to be taken into account (Hobday 1995: 35n).3 In assessing
these mechanisms, it needs to be reconsidered that firms in latecomer economies tend to
reverse the pattern of technological trajectories that is associated with developed
economies, ranging from basic production and incremental process change via design,
process and product innovations to competitive R&D (Kim 1999: 114n). Moreover,
technology transfer involves procedures and bodies of understanding which need to be

2
Ideally, however, continuous learning is accompanied by ‘unlearning’, including the restructuring of
institutional networks as a facet of comprehensive structural changes (Maskell and Malmberg 1995: 25).
3
However, modes of technology transfer are industry-specific. It has been argued that equipment purchase
and licensing are common procedures in supplier-dominated and scale-intensive industries, paralleled by a
focus on R&D and workforce hiring in science-intensive industries, while firms in specialised supplier-
industries primarily cope with users (Bell and Pavitt 1993: 264n).
Alexander Ebner 6

considered in terms of technological innovation, for the assimilation of technologies


already employed elsewhere also involves elements of novelty, risk-taking and learning
(Nelson and Pack 1999: 432). Yet adaptive technological learning may result in
stagnation when the technology frontier is approached with a lack of local capabilities
(Amsden and Hikino 1993: 159).4 Technological capabilities are accordingly embodied
in economic agents and the institutions that enable as well as constrain their activities,
involving private and public, as well as local and foreign agents (Dahlman and Nelson
1995: 89). They are an outcome of institutional factors such as incentives, regulations
and legal frameworks which accompany the material basis for innovation (Lall 2000:
14). The East Asian development experience illustrates the evolution of these
capabilities in constellations of paradigm change. Despite variations, the institutional
set-up of national innovation systems in the East Asian newly industrialising economies
have been marked by common properties: an expanding education system with an
emphasis on tertiary education and engineering, a rapid growth of business in-house
R&D, a share of industrial R&D above 50% of gross expenditures on R&D, a rapid
development of science and technology infrastructures, heavy investment in advanced
telecommunications (Freeman 1996: 178). Moreover, following the example of the
Japanese developmental state, government initiatives in innovation policies have played
a decisive role in catch-up growth (Chang 1994: 298n).
However, globalisation has fuelled both an internationalisation and regionalisation of
innovation systems. The decreasing policy competence of nation-states in governing
globalisation by means of a ‘techno-nationalism’ parallels the emergence of regional or
transnational ensembles as well as industry-specific patterns of interaction on a global
scale (Nelson and Rosenberg 1993: 17n). Yet this does not mean that national systems
of innovation are completely deconstructed. Due to the unparalleled institutional impact
of the nation state they may become subject to the strategic partnership of multinational
enterprises (Chesnais 1992: 265n). National systems of innovation thus may be styled as
segmented layers of institutions and production modes which integrate regional and
local ensembles, such as technopoles, with their particular technological and
institutional logic (Garrouste and Kirat 1995: 235n). This is in accordance with the
suggestion that economic and political modes of interaction on the national level remain
essential, accompanied by local, regional or supranational levels of interaction (Freeman
and Soete 1997: 315). Accordingly, globalisation has promoted the structural openness
of economies. Domestic growth becomes more dependent from external influences,
accompanying further external constraints on policy options that resemble the case of
small open economies as price-takers on international markets. This tendency puts into
effect an outward orientation that is transmitted as a competitive pressure for structural
adaptation (Soete 1988). Corresponding development strategies highlight the
international restructuring of innovation systems with a focus on attracting foreign direct
investment, supporting the international expansion of local enterprises and promoting
local technological specialisation (Niosi and Bellon 1996). This restructuring involves a
drive towards commercialisation on the grounds of transnational private-public
partnerships, as universities lean towards service oriented interactions with the business
sector on an international scale (Galli and Teubal 1997). These efforts underline
attempts of building alliances between local authorities and transnational capital,
4
This problem was most relevant for efforts in building indigenous science and technology bases in the
context of import substitution policies which were exceedingly popular in Latin America during the
1960s. Technology assimilation has belonged to the key factors in the failure of these policies (Pack 2000:
69n).
Innovation Policies and Locational Competitiveness: Lessons from Singapore 7

especially on the structural, meso-economic level of interaction (de la Mothe and Paquet
1996: 26n).5 Reflecting the paradigmatic role of information and communication
technologies, this implies that localities need to participate in global knowledge flows in
ways which allow for integrating them into the global networks of multinational
enterprises (Gibbs and Tanner 1997: 32).
These developmental aspects of innovation policies and locational competitiveness are
well represented by the case of Singapore, the Southeast Asian city-state which has
managed to proceed from the status of an underdeveloped economy towards a developed
economy status during a thirty years period since 1965. In recent debates on the East
Asian development experience, Singapore has been singled out as a successful example
of industrial policies promoting development efforts by strategic interventions (Soon
and Tang 1993: 18). Yet more specifically, Singapore’s economic development exhibits
both structural and spatial features that need to be taken into account. With regard to its
position as a manufacturing and service hub, Singapore is viewed as an infrastructural
nodal point that is interconnected to transnational business networks, promoting a
‘pragmatic adaptation’ to changing conditions of the world economy (Castells 1988:
10). Singaporean policies for promoting locational competitiveness have been
characterised as attempts to adjust and restructure the city-state in accordance with the
needs of international investors that should harmonise with local objectives (Ho 1993).
Moreover, allowing for the spatial components of technological globalisation, Singapore
has been characterised as a role model for the development of a combined global city-
technopole complex, that is, as a model of innovation-based development strategies in
globalisation (Castells 1996: 390). Therefore, despite Singapore’s status as a city-state
type of small open economy, it may be argued that her case provides general lessons for
promising modes of coping with an evolving techno-economic paradigm, highlighting
economic processes that become ever more relevant for all countries and regions world-
wide. Indeed, Singapore represents a paradigmatic case of economic development in the
context of globalisation.

3. Contours of the Singaporean Development Experience

Growth and Development of the Singapore Economy

The Southeast Asian city-state of Singapore, an island of about three million resident
inhabitants at the southern tip of the Malayan peninsula, represents the smallest of the
East Asian newly industrialising economies regarding territory and population, yet she
exhibits their highest GNP per capita while obtaining a most favourable position with
regard to other development indicators (World Bank 2000: 230n). Singapore’s
development from a staple port to a global business agglomeration highlights a
favourable location that made Singapore part of the major naval trade routes and
corresponding communication networks since the 19th century. Already the
establishment of Singapore as a trade post by the British had been pursued for logistical
motives (Huff 1994: 7n). The corresponding outward oriented growth mode of a re-

5
Locational competition on a national level then implies that firms and states meet on the grounds of a
“triangular diplomacy”, based upon comparative bargaining advantages in conflict, competition and co-
operation (Stopford and Strange 1991).
Alexander Ebner 8

export economy regained its importance after Singapore’s independence, which was
followed by the factual expulsion from the Malayan Federation in 1965. Yet it also
reflected a favourable international setting that benefited all the Asia-Pacific newly
industrialising economies (Islam and Chowdhury 1997: 10n). In this sense, Singapore’s
economic development owes its dynamism to the historical evolution of global
capitalism.
The growth of aggregate output from 1965 to 2001 was indeed impressive, as
Singapore’s GDP at 1990 market prices multiplied by almost 18 times, while per capita
GNP at current market prices multiplied by 23 times (Department of Statistics 1996a: 2;
1996b: 4n; 2000: 2; 2001: 2 ). Accordingly, from the 1960s to the 1990s, average annual
growth rates of GDP performed in a range from 8% to 10%, expressing a sustained
hyper growth of national income (Low et al 1993: 30n). Moreover, gross fixed capital
formation grew at an average annual rate of 11% from 1965 to 1995, paralleled by
exceptional savings rates which increased from a share of 11% GNP in 1965 to 50%
during the 1990s (Department of Statistics 1996b: 3n; 2001: 2). Recession phases in the
early 1970s, the growth slowdown of the mid-1980s, and the Asian financial crisis in
1997 could not revert this growth process, which has been highly dependent on foreign
markets, especially the United States and Japan (MTI 2001: 14). Supporting this role of
the external sector with a foreign trade volume that has currently exceeded GNP by
three times, macroeconomic stability has prevailed (Soon and Tan 1993: 34n).
Corresponding structural changes in the composition and contribution of sectors and
industries have resulted from the expansion of the manufacturing industries, with almost
half the manufacturing industries output and value added provided by electronic
products and components during the 1990s (Department of Statistics 2000: 88n). The
latter derived their growth dynamism principally from international demand for
semiconductors and computer peripherals, confirming Singapore’s role as a
manufacturing hub in the transnational business networks of the electronics industries.
However, reflecting the expansion of financial and business services, almost 70% of
Singapore’s GDP are made up of service activities in a broad sense (MTI 2001: 14n).
The service sector obtains an equally high employment share in total workforce
allocation, with a majority of the workforce absorbed by local small and medium
enterprises which tend to exhibit comparatively low productivity levels (MTI 2001: 21n,
61).
Accordingly, decisive impulses for Singapore’s growth and development have been
provided by the manufacturing and service activities of multinational enterprises,
replacing the historical pattern of a staple port economy (Huff 1994: 299n). Since the
1970s both the foreign and the local sector experienced an expansion of net investment
commitments in manufacturing industries, with the foreign sector accounting for a share
of almost 70%. The parallel increase of foreign equity investment in financial services
then underlines Singapore’s global city status (Department of Statistics 1996b: 14).
Whereas Japan has become a decisive country of origin for the latter, the United States
have remained the leading country of origin for foreign net investment commitments in
manufacturing, providing a share of almost 50% during the 1990s (Department of
Statistics 2000: 71, 95). Nonetheless, outward-oriented industrialisation has not yet
produced a coherent internal structure of economic activities, for a majority of local
small and medium enterprises, especially in the service sector, lacks from a productivity
performance that meets international standards, thus pointing to a persistent lack of local
technological capabilities (Yun 1998: 398n). In this context, an assessment of local
enterprises and their investment performance needs to account for government-related
Innovation Policies and Locational Competitiveness: Lessons from Singapore 9

local enterprises as a representation of the specific Singaporean blend of governmental


entrepreneurship that has tended to crowd out private initiative. In conclusion, then, it
has been suggested that those firms which interact directly with multinational
enterprises benefit most decisively from technology assimilation in terms of sustained
learning effects (Hobday 1995: 136n).

Development Strategies of a Globalising City-State

Following the factual expulsion form the Malayan Federation in 1965, involving a brief
phase of import substitution, Singapore attempted to combine the autonomy of a nation-
state with the locational advantages of a city-state, well endowed with relevant
infrastructures. Indeed, confronted with comparatively poor endowments in physical and
human capital, the Singaporean government attempted to capitalise on infrastructural
assets inherited from the British, primarily the port and its refinery equipment (Huff
1994: 273n). Hence, Singapore promoted a policy motive of locational competitiveness,
aiming at the attraction of foreign direct investment by providing an institutional and
infrastructural environment that should conform to the needs of international investors.6
Attracting labour-intensive foreign direct investment as a means of creating employment
dominated the policy rationale since the mid-1960s, moving gradually to a more capital-
intensive investment pattern in the mid-1970s, which implied a shift in the pattern of
incentives provided by the Singapore authorities (Rodan 1989). In the aftermath of the
recession in 1985, and also due to the emergence of locational competitors in the newly
industrialising economies of the ASEAN area and beyond, Singapore’s government
turned to a strategy of providing opportunities for high value-added business activities,
primarily knowledge-intensive segments that should preserve Singapore’s role as a
service and manufacturing hub (Islam and Chowdhury 1997: 206n). The complex array
of economic policies associated with that development strategy represents a flexible and
pragmatic approach towards maintaining competitiveness. The support of a continuous
upgrading of the value-added operations of the subsidiaries of multinational enterprises,
and local enterprises interacting with them, should involve spill-over effects as well as
self-directed benefits. Moreover, not only structural policies, but also monetary and
fiscal policies have been subordinated to the primacy of maintaining locational
competitiveness. Thus, the corporatist regulation of nominal wages and industrial
relations through Singapore’s National Wages Council has been perceived as a major
locational policy instrument (Chew 1996).
All of this has contributed to a pattern of government involvement in economic life that
even allows for speaking of a Singaporean blend of ‘supply side socialism’ (Peebles and
Wilson 2002: 11). However, while the immobile factor land and the comparatively
immobile factor labour have been subject to intense regulative interventions, the mobile
factor capital has been subject to measures of development planning with a rather
indicative character, involving a broad range of material incentives (Huff 1994: 339n).7
Moreover, Singapore’s government governs market processes through its influence on
the management of government-linked enterprises like Temasek Holdings. Indeed,

6
This approach that had become prominent with Taiwan’s export processing zones, although the
Taiwanese industrial policy approach put more emphasis on small enterprise networks (Haggard 1999:
353n).
7
A lack of rent-seeking behaviour in the determination of market interventions seems to have contributed
most successfully to that policy (Bercuson et al. 1995: 18n).
Alexander Ebner 10

despite recent efforts in privatisation and deregulation, government-linked former state


enterprises account for the bulk of high value-added economic activity of local firms.
This affects also the strategic promotion of foreign direct investment by Singaporean
enterprises (Yeung 1998: 405n).8
In this context, the Economic Development Board EDB may be perceived as the core
organisation in Singapore’s policy networks with a leading function in the hierarchy of
government boards. The EDB has been continuously guiding Singapore’s development
trajectory under the motive of ‘strategic pragmatism’, that is the practice of matching the
strategic interests of government with the corporate needs of international investors
(Schein 1996). The EDB was primarily concerned with the provision of industrial
estates in the 1960s, then evolving as a major organisation in Singapore’s development
planning in the 1970s and heralding restructuring efforts of the 1980s towards higher
value-added operations in targeted industries. This implied a broader approach to
service provision in cooperative interactions with multinational enterprises during the
1990s, coordinated by the EDB with other government boards and agencies (Low et al
1993: 63n). Eminent were also learning efforts regarding policy orientation and
implementation. The high-wage policy in the early 1980s, for instance, was originally
initiated in order to support the relocation of labour-intensive manufacturing, while
promoting a local expansion of high value-added production segments. However, this
policy was confronted with an actual shortage of skilled manpower, accompanied by an
unwillingness of foreign investors to comply with the wage constraints imposed by
government. All of this contributed to an economic downturn in 1985 (Yun 1998:
381n). The consequence was a policy reorientation towards technological upgrading by
means of distinct innovation policies that should reinforce the participation of foreign
investors in local policy networks, in order to maintain Singapore’s locational
competitiveness (MTI 1986).9
This post-recession orientation since the late 1980s was explicitly influenced by the
cluster approach of Michael Porter, which underlines the systemic nature of institutional
conditions and industrial linkages that constitute the clusters of competitive industries.
According to the underlying model of development stages, an economy usually passes,
first, a stage of factor driven growth with comparative advantages in factor endowments
and an extensive use of these factors. Investment driven growth, the second stage, with
investment and foreign technology fuelling the growth process, is followed by the third
stage of innovation-driven growth, whereas a final wealth-driven stage signals
stagnation (Porter 1990: 545n). With reference to that scheme, Porter then suggested
that Singapore would perform at the factor driven stage, lacking from ‘home base’
qualities for the development of competitive local industries (Porter 1990: 566). Lessons
for developing economies, also of relevance for Singapore, underlined the formation of
industrial clusters, advanced R&D capabilities, appropriate education systems, upgraded
infrastructures, the internationalisation of domestic structures and the nurturing of local
firms to become multinational enterprises (Porter 1990: 676n).
Accordingly, the government report on Singapore’s competitiveness that responded to
the mid-1980s recession dealt primarily with cost competitiveness, focusing on wage

8
This pattern is well grasped by the Schumpeterian approach with its distinction of the economic
functions of entrepreneurship, namely the carrying out of innovations, and its institutional carriers, which
may include government in certain historical situations (Ebner 2000b: 366n).
9
It has been argued that this responsiveness mirrors a continuous ‘reinvention’ of governance
mechanisms, assessed as a key indicator of Singaporean state capacity in governing the economy (Low
1998: 269n).
Innovation Policies and Locational Competitiveness: Lessons from Singapore 11

regulation, whereas long-term development was said to be based on Singapore’s role as


a business and service hub. In this framework, the expansion of R&D activities was
reconsidered with regard to tax incentives and funding schemes, accompanied by
manpower provision and a distinct R&D infrastructure (MTI 1986: 147n). Subsequent
government proposals like the ‘Strategic Economic Plan’, published in 1991, reiterated
these motives. This policy programme set the vision of attaining the status of a
developed economy by the year 2030, focussing on the realisation of an innovation-
driven development pattern in Porter’s sense. This should imply the expansion of
institutional networks for innovation, based on the infrastructures of a knowledge-
intensive techno-economic paradigm. Strategic thrusts included the enhancing of human
resources in terms of education and training, the corporatist involvement of key interest
groups, an intensified international orientation regarding knowledge infrastructures and
networks, as well as the promotion of an innovative milieu with skilled manpower and
R&D facilities (Economic Planning Committee and MTI 1991: 57n). Indeed, these
proposals heralded the emergence of a distinct innovation policy, leading to the
establishment of the National Science and Technology Board NSTB and the
corresponding formulation of the ‘National Technology Plan’ in 1991, which announced
the promotion of applied innovation activities. Related measures should include the
selective funding of R&D, as well as the provision of manpower and institutional
infrastructures (NSTB 1991).
These innovation policies were accompanied by specific industrial strategies regarding
manufacturing and service clusters and the redevelopment of local enterprises with the
aim of productivity enhancement. Distinct means addressed unit labour costs,
productivity and profitability, accompanied by efforts in structural diversification
regarding ‘home base’ qualities for multinational and local enterprises alike, with
multinational enterprises perceived as long-term partners in promoting economic
development (Economic Planning Committee and MIT 1991: 71n). Due to a perception
of localisation and regionalisation as facets of globalisation, multinational enterprises
were even assisted in their relocation efforts throughout Asia. Regionalisation, in
particular, was addressed as a policy focus by the ‘growth triangle’ strategy of
establishing special zones for labour-intensive manufacturing processes in Johor and
Riau, the border-regions of Singapore’s land and labour affluent neighbours Malaysia
and Indonesia. Furthermore, local enterprises have been encouraged to build up ventures
overseas, focusing on ASEAN, India and China and thus again supporting Singapore’s
role as a regional business hub (Low et al. 1993: 157n). In terms of policy
implementation and industrial specification, all of this was translated into assistance
schemes for cluster development, innovation support, business service incentives, and
schemes for the funding of overseas infrastructural projects, administered by the
Economic Development Board (EDB 1996). A related cluster development initiative
that was launched in 1999 as the ‘Industry 21’ plan highlighted information technology
and life sciences as excelling areas (EDB 2000: 10n). Furthermore, in agreement with
the notion of an emerging techno-economic paradigm based on information
technologies, Singapore is set to become an ‘intelligent island’ with a competitive
national information infrastructure (NCB 1992). Related policies have been marked by
an emphasis on deregulation and privatisation in the telecommunications sector,
paralleled by a refinement of infrastructural facilities and services, as illustrated by the
‘Singapore One’ initiative in establishing an economy-wide broadband network. This
coincides with operations in strategic domains like e-commerce and e-government (MTI
2001: 78n). All of these activities hint at a tendency of blending Singapore’s
Alexander Ebner 12

development strategies with distinct innovation policies as a manifestation of the


evolving Singaporean system of innovation and its infrastructural as well as institutional
underpinnings.

4. The Evolution of the Singaporean System of Innovation

The Innovation Performance of the Singapore Economy

The Singaporean system of innovation combines the policy capacity of a nation-state


with the socio-economic features of a global city. The Singaporean innovation system
leverages on foreign direct investment, for multinational enterprises dominate R&D
activities in the private sector, whereas local firms that are performing R&D activities
comprise of diverse types like small and medium-sized enterprises in the supporting
segment of multinationals, government-linked companies in technology-intensive
industries, and private sector start-up firms in promising technology sectors (Wong
1995: 15n). Accordingly, Singaporean policies for building an innovation system are
concerned with establishing bridging institutions that facilitate knowledge spill-over and
learning effects. They combine the rationale of locational competitiveness with a
cooperative approach to skills development and technological upgrading, thus
highlighting the key role of the education sector. Following the outward-oriented
character of the Singaporean innovation system, the two universities and four
polytechnics are engaged in major cooperative efforts with multinational enterprises,
accompanying training facilities that have been set up in cooperation with foreign
enterprises as well as foreign government agencies (Ebner 2004).
Singapore’s government implements its innovation policy measures primarily through
the Agency for Science, Technology and Research, ASTAR, since 2002 serving as
successor of the National Science and Technology Board, whereas the Economic
Development Board as a hegemonic institution in terms of strategic relationships with
foreign investors exercises a rather indirect influence through its development strategies.
Investment schemes administered by the EDB are also fit to promote innovation
activities. The corresponding rationale of the Singaporean innovation system is well
described by the notions of service provision and market orientation, quite in accordance
with the official goal of transforming Singapore into a technologically advanced service
hub, including the provision of R&D facilities. Indeed, in developmental terms, the
Singaporean innovation system is bound to complete a ‘total business centre’ strategy
(Economic Planning Committee and MIT 1991). Schemes for attracting high value-
added business headquarter functions have been paralleled by the implementation of
research grants and fiscal incentives for the support of innovation activities, benefiting
companies like Hewlett-Packard and Philips which have set up their regional R&D
centres in Singapore and drastically expanded their local production and service
capacities, yet also affecting local firms in their expanding innovation efforts. Grants
like the Research Incentive Scheme for Companies RISC and the Innovation
Development Scheme IDS accompany fiscal schemes for the tax deduction of R&D
expenditures. However, these programmes also hint at the matter of supplying education
and training for an increasingly knowledge-intensive type of production (Mani 2002:
128n).
Innovation Policies and Locational Competitiveness: Lessons from Singapore 13

With regard to innovation performance, output indicators like granted patents have been
approaching the Hong Kong level of activity recently, as far as patents granted in the
United States are concerned (Mani 2002: 124n). This reflects efforts in building a local
science base. Expenditure on R&D as well as R&D manpower may serve as innovation
input indicators. As Table 1 depicts, Singaporean efforts in expanding R&D operations
are evident. Gross expenditure on R&D (GERD) increased 30-fold between 1981 and
1999, increasing even in the midst of the Asian crisis and reaching $2,656 million in
1999. This corresponds with a growth of the GERD to GDP ratio from 0.26% in 1981 to
1.84% in 1999 (NSTB 2000: 3). Still, in comparison with the other East Asian newly
industrialised economies, the Singaporean system of innovation exhibits a persistent
‘GERD lag’ (Masuyama 1997: 3n). However, given Singapore’s character as a
metropolitan agglomeration, benchmarking efforts with reference to global cities and
metropolitan regions would provide more suitable material for a comparative
assessment. Firms of the private sector, mostly multinational enterprises, take the lead
position by accounting for two thirds of gross expenditures. Indeed, between 1990 and
1999, private sector R&D expenditures increased by 5 times from 309 million
Singapore Dollars to 1670 million Singapore Dollars (NSTB 2000: 9n). In 1999, private
sector R&D spending concentrated on the domain of engineering sciences, with a focus
on the electronics, electrical, and mechanical segments, accompanied by computer and
related sciences, as well as by chemical science. This reflects the impact of the lead
industries in the manufacturing sector, and thus the congruence of the dominant pattern
of R&D with industrial production. R&D expenditures in the public domain, including
government, higher education and public research facilities, also seem to follow this
pattern, as they are shaped by the industry-specific articulation of private sector
concerns for the commercial application of new knowledge. Accordingly, the bulk of
R&D expenditures is dealing with experimental development and applied research,
amounting to 86% of total expenditures, whereas pure and strategic types of basic
research amount to 14%, with a comparatively strong presence in public research
facilities, as well as in higher education (NSTB 2000: 10).

Table 1: Innovation Input Indicators in Singapore, 1981-1999

Gross Expenditure GERD/GDP Ratio Research Scientists and


on R&D Engineers per 10,000
Year $M % Labour Force
1981 81.0 0.26 10.6
1990 571.7 0.86 27.7
1991 756,7 1.02 33,6
1992 949.3 1.19 39,8
1993 998.2 1.07 40,5
1994 1,175.0 1.10 41.9
1995 1,366.6 1.16 47.7
1996 1,792.1 1.39 56.3
1997 2,104.6 1.50 60.2
1998 2,492.3 1.80 65.5
1999 2,656.3 1.84 69,9
Sources: MIT (1997), NSTB (2000: 3n).
Alexander Ebner 14

Table2: R&D Expenditures of Local and Foreign Companies by Industry, 1999

(1) Foreign (2) Local (3) Total (2)/(3)


Industry Group Companies Companies
$M $M $M %
Manufacturing 780.99 585.05 1366.05 42
Electronics 518.32 237.80 756.12 31
Chemicals 99.89 26.69 126.58 20
Engineering 102.41 237.73 340.14 69
Precision Engineering 84.13 191.93 276.05 69
Process Engineering 6.02 3.72 9.74 38
Transport Engineering 12.26 42.09 54.35 77
Life Sciences 58.55 31.13 89.68 34
Light Industries/ 1.82 51.71 53.52 96
Other Manufacturing
Services 151.84 152.98 304.82 50
IT/Communications 71.17 105.70 176.87 59
Finance and Business 18.98 12.25 31.23 38
Other Services 61.69 35.03 96.72 36
All Industry Groups 932.83 738.03 1670.86 44
Source: NSTB (2000: 34); calculations by author.
Definition of local: 30% or more locally owned; definition of foreign: less than 30% locally owned.

Table 2 depicts R&D expenditures by industry group, as contributed by local and


foreign companies in 1999.10 Evidently, multinational enterprises take the lead in
providing the Singaporean innovation system with R&D impulses. This is immensely
relevant in those industries which are associated with the technologically advanced
production segments, as the local content of R&D activities amounts only to 31% in
electronics and to 20% in chemicals, well below the average 42% level of the whole
manufacturing sector. Indeed, sustained international contributions to institution-
building in the domain of knowledge generation and dissemination constitute the
institutional core of the Singaporean innovation system.

Industry-University Relations and Singapore’s Science Base

Realising the developmental goal of turning the city-state into a knowledge-intensive


agglomeration, points to the role of academic centres of excellence with access to the
global innovation networks of multinational enterprises and their high-level knowledge
flows. As a means of complementing applied and production-related R&D operations,
the establishment of a local science base becomes crucial for sustaining Singapore’s
locational competitiveness under the conditions of technological globalisation. A lack of

10
These data need to be interpreted with the caveat that NSTB statistics define local ownership by a 30%
margin, which makes research consortia and joint ventures with a strong qualitative impact of
multinational enterprises more difficult to assess.
Innovation Policies and Locational Competitiveness: Lessons from Singapore 15

basic research and a shortage of skilled manpower in science and technology have been
already identified as critical features of the Singaporean innovation system, following
strategic decisions on innovation policies in the mid-1980s, which had avoided the
support of basic research explicitly due to financial uncertainty and a lack of adequate
manpower, mirroring the benchmarking models of the Japanese and Taiwanese
innovation systems (MIT 1986). From a developmental perspective, then, this
reorientation may be associated with the formulation of the ‘Strategic Economic Plan’ in
1991. Conceptually, it is quite in accordance with the argument that the East Asian
development trajectories are generally in need of further impulses regarding R&D and
product innovation, as they approach the technological frontier (Hobday 1995: 200n).
However, its general motive resembles the matter of locational competitiveness in
globalisation, accounting for the spatial and institutional dimensions of innovation in
economic development.
The evolving science base of Singapore’s innovation system is founded on interactions
among private and public as well as local and international agents, with an exposed role
for local institutions of tertiary education and their affiliated research institutes. Indeed,
Singapore’s innovation policies have recently promoted the establishment of R&D
facilities in the education sector, providing a knowledge infrastructure for collaborations
with multinational corporate partners, while supporting a local segment of
entrepreneurial spin-off ventures in knowledge-intensive industries. Beyond the
confines of innovation policy, these research institutes and centres represent an
institutional cornerstone in Singapore’s currently implemented development strategies
(NSTB 1999). The fundamental role of tertiary academic institutions in Singapore’s
development strategy may be exemplified with reference to the formation of a R&D
cluster in the ‘Technology Corridor’, set up in the Southwest of the island as a
connection of the Jurong industrial estates, which are prominent as a location for the
manufacturing operations of multinational enterprises, with the surrounding universities
and polytechnics, accompanied by neighbouring business, service and science parks.
The ‘Corridor’ is thus meant as an agglomeration of knowledge-based agents from them
private and public sectors, operationally biased towards R&D activities. The expansion
of the science park located next to the main campus of the National University was
announced as a first step in developing that ‘Corridor’, referring to the pioneering
establishment of science park facilities already in 1980 (EDB 1996). Moreover, a second
district that belongs to the science park project has been established in a nearby area
since the late 1990s, with further expansions under way.
In this context, the National University of Singapore, NUS, is not only the leading
academic organisation in higher education; it is also a decisive player in university-
industry collaboration on applied R&D. NUS provides a campus location for regionally
outstanding research institutes, such as the Institute for Systems Science, the Institute for
Molecular and Cell Biology and the Institute for Microelectronics, pointing to a research
focus on information and communication technology, microelectronics as well as life
sciences. Reflecting the strategic bias towards international private-public partnerships,
these institutes co-operate with multinational enterprises and international research
partners, covering a range from contract research to mutual agreements of understanding
(NUS 1996). The second major academic player is Nanyang Technological University,
NTU, with research institutes like the Advanced Materials Research Centre and the
Gintic Institute of Manufacturing Technology. Compared with NUS, the strategic
outlook of R&D activities at NTU exhibits an even more applied orientation, closer to
the innovation segment of product improvement (NTU 1996). This assessment holds
Alexander Ebner 16

also for Singapore’s four Polytechnics, which are engaged in the promotion of R&D
activities only on a comparatively minor scale: Ngee Ann, Singapore Polytechnic,
Nanyang, and Temasek.11
These efforts coincide with the assessment that Singapore’s emphasis on the
commercial segments of scientific and technological activities has neglected the need to
develop local capabilities in basic research as an indispensable component of a
sustainable innovation portfolio. This aspect is reflected by a low level of interaction
between public research facilities and private enterprises, accompanied by a lack of
networking interaction among local small and medium-sized enterprises (Wong 1995:
34n). Indeed, especially the integration of those small and medium-sized enterprises
which do not belong to the high-tech segment of the private sector represents a
persistent challenge (Wong 1999: 281n). However, even R&D collaborations between
public research facilities and high-tech firms seem to provide opportunities for further
improvement, not at last due to the specific R&D cultures that are associated with
business and academia respectively (Phillips and Yeung 2003). Yet in general, apart
from these institutional frictions within the high value-added domain of the Singaporean
innovation system, it seems that spill-over effects from the knowledge-intensive
industries all over the Singapore economy with its large segment of small enterprises in
the service sector need to be improved, at least with regard to the corresponding
productivity profiles. Still, the tendency of an economic dualism reflects the overall
structure of global cities and knowledge agglomerations, which contain a large
proportion of low-wage and low-skills segments in their service sectors, set apart from a
high-wage and high-skill segment (Sassen 1994). At this point, the logic of
technological globalisation, with its combination of local specialisation and global
flexibility may contradict integrative development strategies which seek a strengthening
of structural cohesion in the local economy.

5. Conclusion

The Singaporean development trajectory has been supported by policies for maintaining
locational competitiveness in terms of a continuous adaptation to the changing
conditions of the world economy. These responsive policies have accounted for
developmental opportunities which were offered by changes of the dominant techno-
economic paradigm, recently highlighting the emergence of a knowledge-based
economy. Accordingly, the general relevance of the Singaporean development
experience lies in the increasing importance of knowledge agglomerations in the process
of globalisation, as reflected by the notion of global cities and their milieus of
innovation, which promote high value-added activities. They receive their structural
impact from the role as strategic hubs in the production and innovation networks of
multinational enterprises. Accordingly, interactions between the state and multinational
enterprises, both local and foreign, which characterise the Singaporean innovation

11
However, the problem of comprehensive restructuring towards a knowledge-based economy involves
also the provision of adequate manpower (Wong and Ng 1997: 139). The most important skills
development programmes are implemented by the Singapore Standards, Productivity and Innovation
Board SPRING with a focus on the productivity and innovation performance of local small and medium-
sized enterprises (SPRING 2002). The Institute of Technical Education, established as an institution for
secondary education and training, provides training programmes that are co-organised by multinational
enterprises (ITE 2002).
Innovation Policies and Locational Competitiveness: Lessons from Singapore 17

system, exhibit a paradigmatic character. All of this points to the role of multinational
enterprises as strategic partners of governments. Multinational enterprises may introduce
novelty into a local economic system, thus promoting an innovation-driven development
process, while government coordinates economic change through the induction of spill-
over effects. However, a major problem is posed by institution-building in support of
local technological capabilities. In this context, the Singapore government needs to
harmonise its policies with the objectives of multinational enterprises; a situation which
may include conflicting interests in various situations. In particular, the requirement of
structural and institutional flexibility may conflict with an integrative development
approach that supports the cohesion of the local economy. As indicated by the socio-
economic dualism of global cities and related high level agglomerations, then, balancing
the integration in global innovation networks with the socio-economic coherence of the
local economy denotes a decisive challenge in promoting economic development by
means of the corresponding systems of innovation. Indeed, globalisation implies
fundamental changes in the structuration of innovation systems. National systems of
innovation were originally meant to represent a variant of national system of production,
exhibiting national linkages in a systemic setting of interactions, whereas the local
innovation systems of knowledge agglomerations are linked with diverse networks of
production and innovation within segmented layers of interaction that highlight the logic
of locational competitiveness. With the state as the decisive actor in charge of the
institutional means for the support of economic development, their coordination remains
of decisive importance for the design and implementation of innovation policies.
Alexander Ebner 18

Literature

Amin, A. (1994) Post-Fordism: Models, Fantasies and Phantoms of Transition, in A. Amin (ed.)
Post-Fordism: A Reader, Oxford: Blackwell, pp.1-39.
Amin, A. and Thrift, N. (1992) Neo-Marshallian Nodes in Global Networks, International
Journal of Urban and Regional Research, Vol.16, No.4, pp.571-587.
Amsden, A. and Hikino, T. (1993) Borrowing Technology or Innovating: An Exploration of the
Two Paths to Industrial Development, in. R. Thomson (ed.) Learning and Technological
Change, New York: St.Martin’s Press, pp.243-266.
Archibugi, D. and Michie, J. (1995) The Globalisation of Technology: A New Taxonomy,
Cambridge Journal of Economics, Vol.19, Nr.1, pp.121-140.
Bell, M. and Pavitt, K. (1993) Accumulating Technological Capability in Developing Countries,
in L.H. Summers and S. Shah (eds.) Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Conference on
Development Economics 1992, Supplement to the The World Bank Economic Review,
Washington: World Bank, pp.257-281.
Bercuson, K. et al. (1995) Singapore: A Case Study in Rapid Development, Washington: World
Bank.
Cantwell, J. (1999) Innovation as the Principal Source of Growth in the Global Economy’, in D.
Archibugi, J. Howells, and J. Michie (eds.) Innovation Policy in a Global Economy, Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, pp.225-241.
Castells, M. (1996) The Information Age: Economy, Society and Culture, Vol.1: The Rise of the
Network Society, Cambridge: Blackwell.
Chang, H.-J. (1994) State, Institutions and Structural Change, Structural Change and Economic
Dynamics, Vol.5, No.2, pp.293-313.
Chesnais, F. (1992) National Systems of Innovation, Foreign Direct Investment and the
Operations of Multinational Enterprises, in B.-Å. Lundvall (ed.) National Systems of
Innovation: Towards a Theory of Innovation and Interactive Learning, London: Pinter, pp.265-
295.
Chew, S.B. and Chew, R. (1996) Industrial Relations in Singapore: Past Developments and
Future Challenges, in B. Kapur et al. (eds.) Development, Trade and the Asia-Pacific,
Singapore: Prentice Hall, pp.122-140.
Cooke, P. and Morgan, K. (1998) The Associational Economy: Firms, Regions and Innovation,
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Dahlman, C.J. and Nelson, R. (1995) Social Absorption Capability, National Innovation
Systems and Economic Development, in B.H. Koo and D.H. Perkins (eds.) Social Capability
and Long-Term Economic Growth, London: Macmillan, pp. 82-122.
de la Mothe, J. and Paquet, G. (1996) Evolution and Inter-Creation: the Government-Business-
Society Nexus, in J. de la Mothe and G. Paquet (eds.) Evolutionary Economics and the New
International Political Economy, London: Pinter, pp.9-34.
de Mayer, A. (1997) Management of International R&D Operations, in H. Vernon-Wortzel and
L. Wortzel (eds.) Strategic Management in a Global Economy, Third Edition, New York et al.:
Wiley, pp.419-429.
Department of Statistics (1996a) Yearbook of Statistics 1995, Singapore: SNP.
Department of Statistics (1996b) Singapore Statistical Highlights 1965-1995, Singapore: SNP.
Department of Statistics (2000) Yearbook of Statistics 2000, Singapore: SNP.
Innovation Policies and Locational Competitiveness: Lessons from Singapore 19

Department of Statistics (2001) Yearbook of Statistics 2001, Singapore: SNP.


Dosi, G., Freeman, C. and Fabiani, S. (1994) The Process of Economic Development:
Introducing Some Stylized Facts and Theories on Technologies, Firms and Institutions,
Industrial and Corporate Change, Vol.3, No.1, pp.1-45.
Ebner, A. (1999) Understanding Varieties in the Structure and Performance of National
Innovation Systems: the Concept of Economic Style, in J. Groenewegen and J. Vromen (eds.)
Institutions and the Evolution of Capitalism: Implications of Evolutionary Economics,
Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp.141-169.
Ebner, A. (2000a) Systems of Innovation between Globalisation and Transformation: Policy
Implications for the Support of Schumpeterian Entrepreneurship, in A. Kukli ski and W.M.
Orłowski (eds.) The Knowledge-Based Economy – The Global Challenges of the 21st Century,
Warsaw: State Committee for Scientific Research of the Republic of Poland, pp.80-99.
Ebner, A. (2000b) Schumpeter and the ‚Schmollerprogramm‘: Integrating Theory and History
in the Analysis of Economic Development, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, Vol.10, No.3,
2000, pp.355-372.
Ebner, A. (2002) The Logic of Technological Globalisation: Recent Evidence on R&D in the
European Union, in C. Heinrich and H.J. Kujath (eds.) Externe Effekte, Kollektivgüter und
Strategien der Regionalisierung, Münster: Lit, pp.57-87.
Ebner, A. (2004) Development Strategies and Innovation Policies in Globalisation: The Case of
Singapore, in S. Mani and H. Romijn (eds.) Innovation, Learning and Technological Dynamism
of Developing Countries, Tokyo: United Nations University Press, pp. 48-76.
Economic Development Board (1996) Yearbook 1995-1996, Singapore: EDB.
Economic Development Board (2000) Yearbook 1999-2000, Singapore: EDB.
Economic Planning Committee and Ministry of Trade and Industry (1991) The Strategic
Economic Plan: Towards a Developed Nation, Singapore: SNP.
Eliasson, G. (2000) Industrial Policy, Competence Blocs and the Role of Science in Economic
Development, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, Vol.10, No.1-2, pp. 217-241.
Freeman, C. (1987) Technology and Economic Performance: Lessons from Japan, London:
Pinter.
Freeman, C. (1996) Catching-Up and Falling-Behind: The Case of Asia and Latin America, in J.
de la Mothe and G. Paquet (eds.) Evolutionary Economics and the New International Political
Economy, London: Pinter, pp.160-179.
Freeman, C. and Perez, C. (1988) Structural Crises of Adjustment, Business Cycles and
Investment Behaviour, in G. Dosi et al. (eds.) Technical Change and Economic Theory, London:
Pinter, pp.38-66.
Freeman, C. and Soete, L. (1997) The Economics of Industrial Innovation, Third Edition,
London: Pinter.
Galli, R. and Teubal, M. (1997) Paradigmatic Shifts in National Innovation Systems, in C.
Equist (ed.) Systems of Innovation: Technologies, Organizations and Institutions, London:
Pinter, pp.342-370.
Garrouste, P. and Kirat, T. (1995) Des Systémes Nationaux d’Innovation aux Formes
Institutionelles de la Politique Technologique, in M. Baslé et al. (eds.) Changement Institutionel
et Technologique: Èvaluation, Droits de Propriété Intellectuelle, Systéme National
d’Innovation, Paris: CNRS, pp.215-235.
Gibbs, D. and Tanner, K. (1997) Communications Technology, Local Economies and
Regulation Theory, Tijdschrift voor Economische en Sociale Geografie, Vol.88, No.1, pp.29-40.
Alexander Ebner 20

Granstrand, O. et al. (1993) Internationalization of R&D – A Survey of Some Recent Research,


Research Policy, Vol.22, No.5-6, November, pp.413-430.
Haggard, S. (1999) An External View of Singapore’s Developed Status, in L. Low (ed.)
Singapore: Towards A Developed Status, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp.345-375.
Ho, K.C. (1993) Industrial Restructuring and the Dynamics of City-State Adjustments,
Environment and Planning A, Vol.25, No.1, January, pp.47-62.
Hobday, M. (1995) Innovation in East Asia: The Challenge to Japan, Aldershot: Elgar.
Howells, J. and Wood, M. (1993) The Globalisation of Production and Technology, London:
Belhaven.
Huff, W.G. (1994) The Economic Growth of Singapore: Trade and Development in the
Twentieth Century, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Institute of Technical Education (2002) Breakthrough Changes: Annual Report 2001/02,
Singapore: ITE.
Islam, I. and Chowdhury, A. (1997) Asia-Pacific Economies: A Survey, London: Routledge.
Kim, L. (1999) Building Technological Capability for Industrialization: Analytical Frameworks
and Korea’s Experience, Industrial and Corporate Change, Vol.8, No.1, pp.111-136.
Lall, S. (2000) Technological Change and Industrialization in the Asian Newly Industrializing
Economies: Achievements and Challenges, in L. Kim and R. Nelson (eds.) Technology,
Learning, and Innovation: Experiences of Newly Industrializing Economies, Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, pp.13-68.
Leydesdorff, L. and Etzkowitz, H. (1997) A Triple Helix of University-Industry-Government
Relations, in H. Etzkowitz and L. Leydesdorff (eds.) Universities and the Global Knowledge
Economy: A Triple Helix of University-Industry-Government Relations, London: Pinter, pp.155-
162.
Low, L. (1998) The Political Economy of a City-State: Government-made Singapore,
Singapore: Oxford University Press.
Low, L. et al. (1993) Challenge and Response: Thirty Years of the Economic Development
Board, Singapore: Times.
Lundvall, B.-Å. (1992a) Introduction, in B.-Å. Lundvall (ed.) National Systems of Innovation:
Towards a Theory of Innovation and Interactive Learning, London: Pinter, pp.1-22.
Lundvall, B.-Å. (1992b) User-Producer Relationships, National Systems of Innovation and
Internationalisation, in B.-Å. Lundvall (ed.) National Systems of Innovation: Towards a Theory
of Innovation and Interactive Learning, London: Pinter, pp.45-67.
Mani, S. (2002) Government, Innovation and Technology Policy: An International Comparative
Analysis, Cheltenham: Elgar.
Maskell, P. and Malmberg, A. (1995) Localised Learning and Industrial Competitiveness, BRIE
Working Paper No.80, Berkeley Roundtable of International Economy, Berkeley University.
Masuyama, S. (1997) The Evolving Nature of Industrial Policy in East Asia, in S. Masuyama et
al. (eds.) Industrial Policies in East Asia, Singapore: ISEAS, pp.3-18.
McKee, D. (1991) Schumpeter and the Political Economy of Change, New York et al.: Praeger.
Ministry of Trade and Industry (1986) The Singapore Economy: New Directions, Singapore:
SNP.
Ministry of Trade and Industry (1991) Economic Survey of Singapore 1990, Singapore: SNP.
Ministry of Trade and Industry (1997) Economic Survey of Singapore 1996, Singapore: SNP.
Innovation Policies and Locational Competitiveness: Lessons from Singapore 21

Ministry of Trade and Industry (2001) Economic Survey of Singapore 2000, Singapore: SNP.
Nanyang Technological University (1996) Research in NTU, Singapore: NTU.
National Computer Board (1992) A Vision of an Intelligent Island: IT 2000 Report, Singapore:
SNP.
National Science and Technology Board (1991) National Technology Plan 1991: Window of
Opportunities, Singapore: SNP.
National Science and Technology Board (1999) Singapore Technology Infrastructure,
Singapore: NSTB.
National Science and Technology Board (2000) National Survey of R&D in Singapore 1999,
Singapore: NSTB.
National University of Singapore (1996) Technology and Expertise Directory, Singapore: NUS.
Nelson, R.R. and Pack, H. (1999) The Asian Miracle and Modern Growth Theory, Economic
Journal, Vol.109, July, pp.416-436.
Nelson, R.R. and Rosenberg, N. (1993) Technical Innovation and National Systems, in R.R.
Nelson (ed.) National Innovation Systems: A Comparative Analysis, Oxford: Oxford University
Press, pp.1-18.
Niosi, J. and Bellon, B. (1996) The Globalization of National Innovation Systems in J. de la
Mothe and G. Paquet (eds.) Evolutionary Economics and the New International Political
Economy, London: Pinter, pp. 138-159.
Ohmae, K. (1995) The End of the Nation State: The Rise of Regional Economies, London:
Harper Collins.
Pack, H. (2000) Research and Development in the Industrial Development Process, in L. Kim
and R. Nelson (eds.) Technology, Learning, and Innovation: Experiences of Newly
Industrializing Economies, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp.69-94.
Paoli, M. and Guercini, S. (1997) R&D Internationalisation in the Strategic Behaviour of the
Firm, STEEP Discussion Paper Nr.39, Science Policy Research Unit, University of Sussex.
Patel, P. and Pavitt, K. (1994) National Innovation Systems: Why They Are Important and How
They Might Be Compared, Economics of Innovation and New Technology, Vol.3, No.1, pp.77-
95.
Pavitt, K. and Patel, P. (1999) Global Corporations and National Systems of Innovation: Who
Dominates Whom?, in D. Archibugi, J. Howells, and J. Michie (eds.) Innovation Policy in a
Global Economy, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp.94-119.
Phillips, S-A. M. and Yeung, H. Wai-Chung (2003) A Place for R&D? The Singapore Science
Park, Urban Studies, Vol.40, No.4, 707-732.
Porter, M. (1990) The Competitive Advantage of Nations, New York: Free Press.
Rodan, G. (1989) The Political Economy of Singapore’s Industrialization: National State and
International Capital, London: Macmillan.
Sassen, S. (1994) Global Cities in a World Economy, London: Pine Forge.
Saxenian, A.L. (1994) Regional Advantage: Culture and Competition in Silicon Valley and
Route 128, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Schein, E.H. (1996) Strategic Pragmatism. The Culture of Singapore’s Economic Development
Board, Singapore: Toppan and MIT.
Singapore Standards, Productivity and Innovation Board (2002) Annual Report 2001/02,
Singapore: SPRING.
Alexander Ebner 22

Soete, L. (1988) Technical Change and International Implications for Small Countries, in C.
Freeman and B.-Å. Lundvall (eds.) Small Countries Facing the Technological Revolution,
London: Pinter, pp.85-97.
Soon, T.-W. and Tang, C.S. (1993) Singapore: Public Policy and Economic Development,
Washington: World Bank.
Stopford, J. and Strange, S. (1991) Rival States and Rival Firms: Competition for World Market
Shares, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Storper, M. and Scott, A.J. (1995) The Wealth of Regions: Market Forces and Policy
Imperatives in Local and Global Context, Futures, Vol.27, No.5, pp.505-526.
Wong, P.K. (1995) National Innovation System: The Case of Singapore, ASEAN-ROK
Cooperation Project Working Paper, Seoul: Science and Technology Policy Institute.
Wong, P.K. (1999) University-Industry Technological Collaboration in Singapore: Emerging
Patterns and Industry Concerns, International Journal of Technology Management, Vol.18,
Nos.3/4, pp.270-283.
Wong, P.K. and Ng, C.Y. (1997) Singapore’s Industrial Policy to the Year 2000, in S.
Masuyama et al. (ed.) Industrial Policies in East Asia, Singapore: ISEAS, pp.121-141.
World Bank (2000) World Development Report 1999/2000: Entering the 21st Century, Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
Yeung, H.Wai-Chung (1998) The Political Economy of Transnational Corporations: A Study of
the Regionalization of Singaporean Firms, Political Geography, Vol.17, No.4, pp.389-416.
Yun, H.A. (1998) Innovative Milieu and Cooperation Networks: State Initiatives and
Partnership for Restructuring in Singapore, in H.-J. Braczyk, P. Cooke and M. Heidenreich
(eds.) Regional Innovation Systems: The Role of Governance in a Globalized World, London:
UCL Press, pp. 379-412.

You might also like