Deadweight Loss - Wikipedia

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 5

5/28/22, 10:51 AM Deadweight loss - Wikipedia

Deadweight loss
Deadweight loss, also known as excess burden, is a
measure of lost economic efficiency when the socially optimal
quantity of a good or a service is not produced. Non-optimal
production can be caused by highly concentrated wealth and
income (economic inequality), monopoly pricing in the case of
artificial scarcity, a positive or negative externality, a tax or
subsidy, or a binding price ceiling or price floor such as a
minimum wage.

Contents
Examples
Monopoly Deadweight loss created by a binding
Subsidy price ceiling. The producer surplus
Tax always decreases, but the consumer
surplus may or may not increase;
Harberger's triangle
however, the decrease in producer
Hicks vs. Marshall surplus must be greater than the
increase, if any, in consumer surplus.
Deadweight loss of taxation
Determinants of deadweight loss
How deadweight loss changes as taxes vary
Deadweight loss of a monopoly
See also
References
Further reading
External links

Examples
Assume a market for nails where the cost of each nail is $0.10. Demand decreases linearly; there is a
high demand for free nails and zero demand for nails at a price per nail of $1.10 or higher. The price of
$0.10 per nail represents the point of economic equilibrium in a competitive market.

Monopoly

If market conditions are perfect competition, producers would charge a price of $0.10, and every
customer whose marginal benefit exceeds $0.10 would buy a nail. A monopoly producer of this product
would typically charge whatever price will yield the greatest profit for themselves, regardless of lost
efficiency for the economy as a whole. In this example, the monopoly producer charges $0.60 per nail,
thus excluding every customer from the market with a marginal benefit less than $0.60. The deadweight
loss due to monopoly pricing would then be the economic benefit foregone by customers with a
marginal benefit of between $0.10 and $0.60 per nail. The monopolist has "priced them out of the
market", even though their benefit exceeds the true cost per nail.

Subsidy
https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Deadweight_loss 1/5
5/28/22, 10:51 AM Deadweight loss - Wikipedia

Conversely, deadweight loss can also arise from consumers buying more of a product than they
otherwise would based on their marginal benefit and the cost of production. For example, if in the same
nail market the government provided a $0.03 subsidy for every nail produced, the subsidy would reduce
the market price of each nail to $0.07, even though production actually still costs $0.10 per nail.
Consumers with a marginal benefit of between $0.07 and $0.10 per nail would then buy nails, even
though their benefit is less than the real production cost of $0.10. The difference between the cost of
production and the purchase price then creates the "deadweight loss" to society.

Tax

A tax has the opposite effect of a subsidy. Whereas a subsidy entices consumers to buy a product that
would otherwise be too expensive for them in light of their marginal benefit (price is lowered to
artificially increase demand), a tax dissuades consumers from a purchase (price is increased to
artificially lower demand). This excess burden of taxation represents the lost utility for the consumer. A
common example of this is the so-called sin tax, a tax levied against goods deemed harmful to society
and individuals. For example, "sin taxes" levied against alcohol and tobacco are intended to artificially
lower demand for these goods; some would-be users are priced out of the market, i.e. total smoking and
drinking are reduced. Products such as alcohol and tobacco have historically been highly taxed and
incur excise duties which are one of the categories of indirect tax.
Indirect tax (VAT), weighs on the
consumer, is not a cause of loss of surplus for the producer, but affects consumer utility and leads to
deadweight loss for consumers. Indirect taxes are usually paid by large entities such as corporations or
manufacturers but are partially shifted towards the consumer. Furthermore, indirect taxes can be
charged based on the unit price of a said commodity or can be calculated based on a percentage of the
final retail price. Additionally, indirect taxes can either be collected at one stage of the production and
retail process or alternatively can be charged and collected at multiple stages of the overall production
process of a commodity.

Harberger's triangle
Harberger's triangle, generally attributed to Arnold Harberger,
shows the deadweight loss (as measured on a supply and
demand graph) associated with government intervention in a
perfect market. Mechanisms for this intervention include price
floors, caps, taxes, tariffs, or quotas. It also refers to the
deadweight loss created by a government's failure to intervene
in a market with externalities.[1]

In the case of a government tax, the amount of the tax drives a


wedge between what consumers pay and what producers
receive, and the area of this wedge shape is equivalent to the
deadweight loss caused by the tax.[2]

The area represented by the triangle results from the fact that The deadweight loss is the area of the
the intersection of the supply and the demand curves are cut triangle bounded by the right edge of the
short. The consumer surplus and the producer surplus are also grey tax income box, the original supply
cut short. The loss of such surplus is never recouped and curve, and the demand curve. It is called
represents the deadweight loss. Harberger's triangle.

Some economists like Martin Feldstein maintain that these


triangles can seriously affect long-term economic trends by pivoting the trend downwards and causing a
magnification of losses in the long run but others like James Tobin have argued that they do not have a
huge impact on the economy.

Hicks vs. Marshall

https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Deadweight_loss 2/5
5/28/22, 10:51 AM Deadweight loss - Wikipedia

It is important to make a distinction between the Hicksian (per John Hicks) and the Marshallian (per
Alfred Marshall) demand function as it relates to deadweight loss. After the consumer surplus is
considered, it can be shown that the Marshallian deadweight loss is zero if demand is perfectly elastic or
supply is perfectly inelastic. However, Hicks analyzed the situation through indifference curves and
noted that when the Marshallian demand curve is perfectly inelastic, the policy or economic situation
that caused a distortion in relative prices has a substitution effect, i.e. is a deadweight loss.

In modern economic literature, the most common measure of a taxpayer's loss from a distortionary tax,
such as a tax on bicycles, is the equivalent variation, the maximum amount that a taxpayer would be
willing to forgo in a lump sum to avoid the distortionary tax. The deadweight loss can then be
interpreted as the difference between the equivalent variation and the revenue raised by the tax. The
difference is attributable to the behavioral changes induced by a distortionary tax that are measured by
a substitution effect. However, that is not the only interpretation, and Lind and Granqvist (2010) point
out that Pigou did not use a lump sum tax as the point of reference to discuss deadweight loss (excess
burden).

Deadweight loss of taxation


When a tax is levied on buyers, the demand curve
shifts downward in accordance with the size of the
tax. Similarly, when tax is levied on sellers, the supply
curve shifts upward by the size of tax. When the tax is
imposed, the price paid by buyers increases, and the
price received by seller decreases. Therefore, buyers
and sellers share the burden of the tax, regardless of
how it is imposed. Since a tax places a "wedge"
between the price buyers pay and the price sellers get,
the quantity sold is reduced below the level that it
would be without tax. To put it another way, a tax on
good causes the size of market for that good to
decrease.
The Deadweight loss of taxation;the tax increases the
For example, suppose that Will is a cleaner who is price paid by buyers to Pc and decreases price
working in the cleaning service company and Amie received by sellers to Pp and the quantity sold
hired Will to clean her room every week for $100. The reduces from Qe to Qt.
opportunity cost of Will's time is $80, while the value
of a clean house to Amie is $120. Hence, each of them
get same amount of benefit from their deal. Amie and Will each receive a benefit of $20, making the
total surplus from trade $40.

However, if the government were to decide to impose a $50 tax upon the providers of cleaning services,
their trade would no longer benefit them. Amie would not be willing to pay any price above $120, and
Will would no longer receive a payment that exceeds his opportunity cost. As a result, not only do Amie
and Will both give up the deal, but Amie has to live in a dirtier house, and Will does not receive his
desired income. They have thus lost amount of the surplus that they would have received from their
deal, and at the same time, this made each of them worse off to the tune of $40 in value.

Government revenue is also affected by this tax: since Amie and Will have abandoned the deal, the
government also loses any tax revenue that would have resulted from wages. This $40 is referred to as
the deadweight loss. It causes losses for both buyers and sellers in a market, as well as decreasing
government revenues. Taxes cause deadweight losses because they prevent buyers and sellers from
realizing some of the gains from trade.[3]

In the graph, the deadweight loss can be seen as the shaded area between the supply and demand
curves. While the demand curve shows the value of goods to the consumers, the supply curve reflects the
cost for producers. As the example above explains, when the government imposes a tax upon taxpayers,
the tax increases the price paid by buyers to Pc and decreases price received by sellers to Pp. Buyers and
https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Deadweight_loss 3/5
5/28/22, 10:51 AM Deadweight loss - Wikipedia

sellers (Amie and Will) give up the deal between them and exit the market. Thus, the quantity sold
reduces from Qe to Qt. The deadweight loss occurs because the tax deters these kinds of beneficial
trades in the market.[3]

Determinants of deadweight loss

Price elasticities of supply and demand determine whether the deadweight loss from a tax is large or
small. This measures to what extent quantity supplied and quantity demanded respond to changes in
price. For instance, when the supply curve is relatively inelastic, quantity supplied responds only
minimally to changes in the price. However, when the supply curve is more elastic, quantity supplied
responds significantly to changes in price. In other words, when the supply curve is more elastic, the
area between the supply and demand curves is larger. Similarly, when the demand curve is relatively
inelastic, deadweight loss from the tax is smaller, comparing to more elastic demand curve.

A tax results in deadweight loss as it causes buyers and sellers to change their behaviour. Buyers tend to
consume less when the tax raises the price. When the tax lowers the price received by sellers, they in
turn produce less. As a result, the overall size of the market decreases below the optimum equilibrium.
The elasticities of supply and demand determine to what extent the tax distorts the market outcome. As
the elasticities of supply and demand increase, so does the deadweight loss resulting from a tax.[3]

How deadweight loss changes as taxes vary

Taxes may be changed by the government or policymakers at different levels. For instance, when a low
tax is levied, the deadweight loss is also small (compared to a medium or high tax). An important
consideration is that the deadweight loss resulting from a tax increases more quickly than the tax itself;
the area of the triangle representing the deadweight loss is calculated using the area (square) of its
dimension. Where a tax increases linearly, the deadweight loss increases as the square of the tax
increase. This means that when the size of a tax doubles, the base and height of the triangle double.
Thus, doubling the tax increases the deadweight loss by a factor of 4.

The varying deadweight loss from a tax also affects the government's total tax revenue. Tax revenue is
represented by the area of the rectangle between the supply and demand curves. When a low tax is
levied, tax revenue is relatively small. As the size of the tax increases, tax revenue expands. However,
when a much higher tax is levied, tax revenue eventually decreases. The higher tax reduces the total size
of the market; Although taxes are taking a larger slice of the "pie," the total size of the pie is reduced.
Just as in the nail example above, beyond a certain point, the market for a good will eventually decrease
to zero.[3]

Deadweight loss of a monopoly

A deadweight loss occurs with monopolies in the same way that a tax causes deadweight loss. When a
monopoly, as a "tax collector," charges a price in order to consolidate its power above marginal cost, it
drives a "wedge" between the costs born by the consumer and supplier. Imposing this effective tax
distorts the market outcome, and the wedge causes a decrease in the quantity sold, below the social
optimum. It is important to remember the difference between the two cases: whereas the government
receives the revenue from a genuine tax, monopoly profits are collected by a private firm.[3]

See also
Excess burden of taxation
Optimal tax
Pareto efficiency
Tax choice

https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Deadweight_loss 4/5
5/28/22, 10:51 AM Deadweight loss - Wikipedia

References
1. "Negative Externality" (http://economics.fundamentalfinance.com/negative-externality.php).
Retrieved February 11, 2012.
2. Gruber, Jonathan (2013). Public Finance and Public Policy. New York: Worth Publishers. ISBN 978-
1-4292-7845-4.
3. N. Mankiw-David Hakes (2012). Principles of microeconomics. South-Western Cengage Learning.

Further reading
Case, Karl E.; Fair, Ray C. (1999). Principles of Economics (5th ed.). Prentice-Hall. ISBN 978-0-13-
961905-2.
Hines, James R., Jr. (1999). "Three Sides of Harberger Triangles" (http://www.nber.org/papers/w685
2.pdf) (PDF). Journal of Economic Perspectives. 13 (2): 167–188. doi:10.1257/jep.13.2.167 (https://
doi.org/10.1257%2Fjep.13.2.167)..
Lind, H.; Granqvist, R. (2010). "A Note on the Concept of Excess Burden". Economic Analysis and
Policy. 40 (1): 63–73. doi:10.1016/S0313-5926(10)50004-3 (https://doi.org/10.1016%2FS0313-592
6%2810%2950004-3).

External links
Worthwhile Canadian Initiative "Too much stuff: the deadweight loss from overconsumption" (http://w
orthwhile.typepad.com/worthwhile_canadian_initi/2012/09/parsley-and-the-other-deadweight-loss.ht
ml)

Retrieved from "https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Deadweight_loss&oldid=1083930124"

This page was last edited on 21 April 2022, at 16:35 (UTC).

Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License 3.0;


additional terms may apply. By using this
site, you agree to the Terms of Use and Privacy Policy. Wikipedia® is a registered trademark of the Wikimedia Foundation,
Inc., a non-profit organization.

https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Deadweight_loss 5/5

You might also like