Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 14

Journal of Cleaner Production 295 (2021) 126505

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Journal of Cleaner Production


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jclepro

Political governance, corruption perceptions index, and national


dynamic energy efficiency
Wen-Min Lu a, Qian Long Kweh b, *, Mohammad Nourani c, Cheng-Yi Lin d
a
Department of International Business Administration, Chinese Culture University, No. 55, Hwa-Kang Road, Shilin District, Taipei, 11114, Taiwan
b
Faculty of Management, Canadian University Dubai, P.O. Box 117781, 1st Interchange, Sheikh Zayed Road, Dubai, United Arab Emirates
c
School of Management, Universiti Sains Malaysia, 11800, Penang, Malaysia
d
Department of Financial Management, National Defense University, No. 70, Sec. 2, Zhongyang North Rd., Beitou, Taipei, 112, Taiwan

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: This study estimates national dynamic energy efficiency of 49 countries for the period of 2007e2016 by
Received 10 October 2020 using a dynamic data envelopment analysis model and explores (i) the relationships between the CPI and
Received in revised form national dynamic energy efficiency, (ii) political governance and CPI, (iii) political governance and dy-
11 February 2021
namic energy efficiency, and (iv) the mediating role of the CPI on the association between political
Accepted 21 February 2021
Available online 25 February 2021
governance and national dynamic energy efficiency. Empirical results corroborate that European and
high-income countries perform better than their counterparts in national dynamic energy efficiency and
Handling editor. Mingzhou Jin the CPI, which has a positive effect on national dynamic energy efficiency. The proxies of political
governance, such as political stability, bureaucratic quality, personal safety and security of private
JEL classification: property, and legal and regulatory frameworks, also affect CPI and national dynamic energy efficiency,
D73 respectively. The CPI has a mediating effect on the relationship between political governance and na-
D24 tional dynamic energy efficiency. Overall, this study suggests that governments can promote probity
P16 policies to further improve national dynamic energy efficiency.
Keywords: © 2021 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
Corruption perceptions index
National dynamic energy efficiency
Data envelopment analysis
Political governance

1. Introduction economic growth (for example, Sharma and Mitra, 2019; Sinha
et al., 2019), and the role governance (for example, Aidt et al.,
According to the United States Environmental Protection 2008; Dzhumashev, 2014). However, their results have been
Agency,1 carbon dioxide emissions have significantly increased inconclusive.
since 1900 worldwide due to fossil fuel combustion for heat and Intuitively, corruption dampens the productivity of capital by
electricity generation, industrial processes for economic growth, different means, cripples the move of governments toward public
and deforestation for agriculture and other land-use changes. It is welfare, and encourages rent-seeking behaviors (Lambsdorff,
thus not surprising to see that researchers have explored energy 2002). For example, Mauro (1995) and Mo (2001) found that cor-
efficiency (for example, Hu and Wang, 2006; Stern, 2012; Zhang ruption dampens economic growth due to rent-seeking activities
et al., 2011). Examining factors of carbon dioxide emissions is (Aidt, 2016). However, given the existence of cumbersome eco-
another important task as the consequence of carbon dioxide nomic policies, economists support some degree of corruption as
emissions, viz. climate change, is threatening our ecosystems the catalyzer for economic development (Bardhan, 1997;
(Sharma, 2011; Zhang et al., 2017). Among all, studies have docu- Kalyuzhnova and Belitski, 2019; Swaleheen, 2006). That is, cor-
mented the effect of corruption on environmental quality and ruption may improve efficiency and ultimately economic growth.
To illustrate further, Chowdhury et al. (2015) found that corruption
plays a dual role as both sand and grease for international entre-
* Corresponding author. preneurship. Moreover, Kauper (2006) confirmed the existence of
E-mail addresses: wenmin.lu@gmail.com (W.-M. Lu), qlkweh@cud.ac.ae good or bad corruption (e.g., entrepreneurs may benefit from cor-
(Q.L. Kweh), mohammad@nourani.net (M. Nourani), lcy6988@gmail.com (C.-Y. Lin).
1 ruption when coordination failures exist in the system) and argued
https://www.epa.gov/ghgemissions/global-greenhouse-gas-emissions-data.

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2021.126505
0959-6526/© 2021 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
W.-M. Lu, Q.L. Kweh, M. Nourani et al. Journal of Cleaner Production 295 (2021) 126505

that economists ignore the possibility that inefficient institutions considering the time effect and the number of carry-overs, the
may lead to inefficient capital markets (Chowdhury et al., 2015). DSBM model measures the efficiency of all countries in examina-
Taken together, the literature on the association between cor- tion under the same frontier and conditions. Although the Malm-
ruption and economic growth has found mixed evidence (Bardhan, quist index also considers time effect, it does not consider the
1997). More importantly, Aidt et al. (2008) observe that the nega- impact of the number of carry-overs. Moreover, the Malmquist
tive effect of corruption on economic performance depends on index compares two years of data each time, suggesting different
governance regimes. Corruption is negatively related to economic frontiers and thus different comparison benchmarks. Therefore,
growth in a high-quality governance regime, but this scenario is considering the cross-country and multiperiod dataset used in this
rarely seen in a low-quality governance regime. Majority of the study, we apply the DSBM model to better gauge national dynamic
studies on corruption and energy efficiency taken a growth indi- energy efficiency.
cator, usually measured by GDP from energy consumption. How- Third, this study contributes to the literature by applying the
ever, if we hold the assumption that inefficiency is a major corruption perception index (CPI) developed by Transparency In-
phenomenon in an economy, then corruption can be linked to ternational (TI) to proxy for corruption.2 The CPI is a quantified
capital inefficiency in a situation where the link between corrup- perception of corruption in the public sector with ratings given by
tion and economic growth is not solid. This study assumes that country expert or businessperson, rendering it credible. Mean-
corruption is a primary source of capital inefficiency, thereby while, the proxies of political governance, including political sta-
deteriorating economic growth. bility, bureaucratic quality, and personal safety and security of
Therefore, different from prior studies (for example, Aidt et al., private property, are obtained from International Institute for
2008; Dzhumashev, 2014) that link governance and corruption to Management Development (IMD) (World Competitiveness Year-
economic growth, this study argues that incorporating corruption book) as they are inclusive of estimating political governance. In
as a mediating variable can better explain the inconclusive rela- summary, this study pioneers carrying out a mediating role of
tionship. That is, political governance may have an effect on eco- corruption perception index on dynamic national efficiency. The
nomic growth through the mediating effect of corruption. findings can serve as a reference for improving lives in general,
Specifically, using 49 countries worldwide as our sample, we including corruption decline and better dynamic energy efficiency
examine the relationships between the CPI and national dynamic as a general, related work such as Helbing et al. (2015) would
energy efficiency, political governance and CPI, political governance suggest.
and dynamic energy efficiency, and the mediating role of the CPI on The rest of this paper is organized as follows: Section 2 discusses
the association between political governance and national dynamic the background related to corruption, political governance, and
energy efficiency. economic performance; Section 3 describes the research frame-
This study differs from related studies in a number of ways. First, works, the model, and the sample data used in this study; Section 4
in contrast to prior studies (Kauper, 2006; Mohamadi et al., 2017; discusses the findings; and Section 5 concludes the paper.
Salinas-Jimenez and Salinas-Jime nez, 2007), this study extends the
debate on energy efficiency (Hu and Wang, 2006; Stern, 2012; 2. Literature review
Zhang et al., 2011) and applies the dynamic slack-based measure
(DSBM) model. This economy evaluation approach enables us to 2.1. Political governance and national dynamic energy efficiency
estimate the relative country-level efficiencies in transforming re-
sources such as capital, labor force, and energy consumption into The theory of production of Cobb and Douglas (1928) puts for-
outputs such as gross domestic product (GDP) and carbon dioxide ward that increasing the input factors, labor and capital, will ulti-
emissions. Moreover, we can separate the outputs into desirable mately raises the output quantities. The direct conclusion of the
portion, viz. GDP, and undesirable portion, viz. carbon dioxide theory is the improvement in economic efficiency deducts from the
emissions. The non-radial DSBM model proposed by Tone and increases in labor and capital. However, the level of economic ef-
Tsutsui (2010) also considers the inadequacy of not only input ficiency is affected by other factors (Mankiw et al., 1992) including
and output slacks, but also carry-over slacks, which address time institutional and governance factors. Political institutions are by far
accumulation effect in the analysis. That is, using the DSBM model, one of the main reasons for variations in economic performance
this study proposes a national dynamic energy efficiency after ac- (Shittu Waliu et al., 2020). Such statement is supported by the hi-
counting for the undesirable output of carbon dioxide emissions. erarchy of institutions hypothesis (Acemoglu et al., 2005) where it
Overall, this study makes a few theoretical and practical con- accentuates the dependency of economic institutions on political
tributions. First, contrary to most of the literature, we use dynamic institutions.
energy efficiency as a measure of a country’s economic perfor- In line with the importance of political governance in stimu-
mance. The DSBM model, which is one data envelopment analysis lating economic performance, current research highlights the
(DEA) method (Charnes et al., 1978) allows us to consider a few critical role of supportive government policies in energy efficiency
indicators simultaneously instead of relying on a single measure, by means of reducing CO2 emission and energy saving in general
such as GDP or GDP growth as economic performance (Dyson et al., (Visscher et al., 2016). Langlois-Bertrand et al. (2015) proposed
2001). It is important to note that DEA does not require the pre- classified the impediments of energy efficiency into three broad
determination of parameters; the weights are defined using a categories, political obstruction, lack of policy coordination, and
mathematical approach, which makes the analysis objective (Lu conflicting guidelines in the governance structure. Delina (2012)
et al., 2016). investigated the strategies in which coherent governance may
Second, through the application of the DSBM model, the multi- ensure maximum energy efficiency of institutions. Further,
period efficiency evaluation provides us with a more reliable cross- exploring the governance capacities in the EU-28 economies,
country comparison than do a window analysis (Klopp, 1985) and Pereira and Da Silva (2017) found that political support, including
the Malmquist index (Fa €re et al., 1994), which are used for esti- more robust governance monitoring and reporting system, is the
mating the efficiency changes over time (Tone and Tsutsui, 2010; main concern to deliver an improvement in energy efficiency for
Wanke et al., 2015). The DSBM model also measures long-term
dynamic energy efficiency more precisely by using carry-over
2
variables (Lu et al., 2014; Nourani et al., 2018). That is, by https://www.transparency.org/en/cpi/2020/index/nzl.

2
W.-M. Lu, Q.L. Kweh, M. Nourani et al. Journal of Cleaner Production 295 (2021) 126505

member states. Similarly, quality governance found to be influential performance.


on energy efficiency of the EU-28 economies during 1995e2014 The effects of corruption on economic performance have
(Apergis and Garcıa, 2019). Using a panel data of 23 OECD countries focused on any indicator leading to economic growth (Sharma and
over 1980 to 2013, Chang et al. (2015) found that government Mitra, 2019), which prioritized growth indicators per se, such as
ideology is an important factor of energy efficiency. GDP, investment, and public expenditure. Cieslik and Goczek (2018)
In a more recent global study, Yao et al. (2021) measure energy contended that corruption lowers investment and subsequently
efficiency using Super-SBM approach and found that political pulls down economic growth. In a cross-country study,
regime has a major influence on energy efficiency. The authors Duerrenberger and Warning (2018) documented that corruption
pointed that the political governance of a country, through tailoring caused the reduction of incentives in educational spending by
more favorable policies, is essential for improvement in energy governments. Mo (2001) claimed that higher corruption by one
efficiency. More precisely, politically conservative nations are less unit lessens the growth rate by 0.545 percentage points and that
in favor of investment in energy-efficient technologies, thus, less political instability is the key factor by which corruption distresses
energy efficiency can be attained (Gromet et al., 2013). In this vein, economic growth.
democratic countries are usually under pressure by their voters to More studies supported similar findings. Farooq et al. (2013)
take considerable actions for the improvements in energy effi- claimed that corruption impedes economic growth, and Kunieda
ciency (Yao et al., 2020). In summary, the extant literature on po- et al. (2014) and Saha and Ben Ali (2017) concluded that financial
litical governance and energy efficiency supports that political openness and economic and political freedoms decrease the
situation of a country has a significant role for the improvement negative effect of corruption on economic growth. Delgado et al.
energy efficiency. Therefore, we develop the following hypothesis: (2014) found that corruption dampens the usefulness of foreign
direct investment (FDI) to improve economic growth, and
Hypothesis 1. Political governance is related to national dynamic
Dzhumashev (2014) highlighted the influence of optimal govern-
energy efficiency.
ment size in the relationship between corruption and economic
performance. Similarly, d’Agostino et al. (2016) discussed that
2.2. Corruption and national dynamic energy efficiency corruption has several negative effects on economic growth in
countries with high military spending. Pless and Fell (2017) argued
According to TI (Transparency International, 2018), the fight that electricity reliability depends on the level of corruption, and
against corruption in the world made little or no progress in 2017. such dependence will subsequently influence economic growth
Among 180 countries ranked using a scale of 0 (highly corrupt) to and development.
100 (very clean), more than two-thirds score below 50 with an Studies focusing on productivity and efficiency as measures for
average score of 43, which is alarming in the current global civili- economic performance have also been conducted. Applying the
zation. TI defines corruption as “the abuse of entrusted power for Malmquist productivity indices, Salinas-Jime nez and Salinas-
private gain.” This definition points to agency problems as the Jimenez (2007) studied the relationship between CPI and produc-
origin of all forms of political and economic corruption (Rose- tivity and elucidated that less corrupt economies, on average,
Ackerman and Palifka, 2016). Helbing et al. (2015) accentuated experience fast growth rates. Wu et al. (2017) suggested that
that deterrence strategies are often not effective in impeding the increased corruption levels can directly reduce regional total factor
large-scale corruption, as a common crime activity, because the productivity, and Faruq et al. (2013) applied DEA as a measure of
actual system behavior is not captured in the conventional ap- performance, without mentioning the model used, and confirmed
proaches and a complexity science may help in saving human lives. that poor bureaucratic quality and corruption decrease firm effi-
Leff (1964) and Huntington (1968) argued that corruption can ciency. Halkos and Tzeremes (2010) found a U-shaped relationship
increase economic performance by eliminating bureaucratic delays between corruption perception levels and economic efficiency
or the bribery of hard-working employees. Their study opened when using DEA window analysis, a measure of performance to
debates about the corruption performance nexus, and many studies account for time-varying data. The traditional window analysis and
have investigated the relationship by using various approaches and Malmquist index neglect the linking of activities and focus on
proxies. Lui (1985) established the efficiency-enhancing role of optimizing periodical efficiency separately while considering time
corruption. By referring to the efficient grease hypothesis, changes (Nourani et al., 2018). These linking activities are also
Kaufmann and Wei (1999) examined the theory that bribery leads called carry-over activities, relating to the fact that some variables
to low effective red tape and corroborated that companies paying are carried from one period to another (Tone and Tsutsui, 2010).
bribes spend considerable time on managerial negotiation, leading Compared with window analysis (Klopp, 1985) and the Malmquist
to high capital costs. As opposed to Leff (1964) and Huntington index (Fa€re et al., 1994), a dynamic DEA (DDEA) model considers
(1968), the majority concluded that corruption by any means cau- that a decision made in one period of time influences the suc-
ses inefficiency through the misuse of economic resources. ceeding periods. The model allows for a long-term dynamic process
Wu et al. (2017) classified the corruption performance nexus by incorporating carry-over activities (Lu et al., 2014). In this study,
into three types. First, economists believe that corruption leads to we take the initiative to employ a non-radial DDEA model, namely,
political and economic rent-seeking and capital inefficiency (cor- the DSBM model introduced by Tone and Tsutsui (2010), which
ruption sand theory). Second, they believe that when a standard independently accounts for the inadequacy of inputs, outputs, and
system is lacking, such as in some developing or underdeveloped carry-over activities.
countries, corruption improves efficiency by greasing the govern- The benefits of controlling corruption can also mean less
ment bureaucratic necessities. Third, they believe that corruption greenhouse gas emissions (Vasylieva et al., 2019). This upholds that
plays the greasing and gridding effects. For instance, Aidt et al. the improvement of national energy efficiency as the economic
(2008) affirmed that the relationship between corruption and performance of a nation can be achieved by means of lesser cor-
growth relies on governance regimes; where high-quality political ruption (Fredriksson et al., 2004). The literature on corruption and
institutions are present, corruption traces negative effects on energy efficiency is rich, and a number of research has confirmed
growth but not when low-quality institutions are present. Through the impeding effect of corruption on energy efficiency improve-
a survey conducted on Indian manufacturing firms, Sharma and ment. However, majority of the studies on corruption and energy
Mitra (2015) supported theories on the effects of bribes on firm efficiency considered GDP from energy consumption. For instance,
3
W.-M. Lu, Q.L. Kweh, M. Nourani et al. Journal of Cleaner Production 295 (2021) 126505

Ozturk et al. (2019) showed that low corruption results in more rate, raw material export value, and FDI were set as control vari-
energy efficiency, estimated by a growth indicator, for all income ables to explore the correlation between CPI score and national
group economies. Sinha et al. (2019) found that public sector cor- dynamic energy efficiency (Fig. 1).
ruption has enhanced environmental degradation BRICS and Next Factors that affect dynamic energy efficiency vary because the
11 countries from 1990 to 2017. CPI is affected by many types of behaviors. In the second part, the
There are a few studies that explored corruption and energy effects were identified by decomposing the CPI into the relevant
efficiency nexus by measuring the latter using mathematical pro- variables of political governance. Proxy variables for political
graming approach. Using a panel data of 30 provinces in China from governance (i.e., political stability, bureaucratic quality, and per-
2005 to 2016, Hao et al. (2020) found that higher level of corruption sonal safety and security of private property) enabled further
enhanced hindering effect of local area labor mismatch on green exploration of their relationships with the CPI (Fig. 2).
total factor energy efficiency. In another study considering China as In the third part, associations between the governance variables
a setting, Wang et al. (2020) confirmed that government corruption (i.e., political stability, bureaucracy, and personal safety and private
directly reduced ecological efficiency and intensified resource property security) and national dynamic energy efficiency were
misallocation leading to further reduction of ecological efficiency. explored. Secondary school enrolment rate was chosen as a control
The authors used dynamic panel data for the regression estimation, variable to capture the proxy variables of the CPI and determine the
however, they did not consider dynamic efficiency technique for main factors affecting dynamic energy efficiency (Fig. 3).
ecological efficiency calculation.
Lambsdorff (2003) argued that channels of influence exist 3.2. Framework of dynamic energy efficiency assessment
through which corruption affects economic performance. He
decomposed corruption into governance-related components, The assessment of national dynamic energy efficiency was
including civil liberties, government stability, law and order, and divided into input and output. Capital, labor force, and energy
bureaucratic quality extracted from Gastil (1986) and the Interna- consumption were used as inputs, while GDP and carbon dioxide
tional Country Risk Guide. Governance-related components emissions were used as desirable and undesirable outputs,
received little attention from corruption-performance researchers respectively. Capital, which exhibits an annual carry-over charac-
(Randrianarisoa et al., 2015). Corruption may have been derived teristic, at the end of Period t was carried forward to Period t þ 1 to
from different types of behavior, and the decomposition will help measure the dynamic energy efficiency of Period t þ 1. Carry-over
find the sources of the greasing or gridding effects of corruption on was used to assess the annual operational performances of coun-
economic performance. This approach could answer why corrup- tries to obtain their long-term dynamic energy efficiency. The ef-
tion leads to good economic growth in some scenarios. The present ficiency values were calculated after considering energy
study attempts to fill this gap. consumption and environmental impact factors. Fig. 4 presents the
The literature has explored the influence of countries’ gover- assessment framework.
nance on corruption and the consensus confirmed the positive
association. For example, Lee et al. (2020) found that the gover-
3.2.1. Dynamic slack-based measure with undesirable outputs
nance plays a significant role in innovative activity for corrupt
Ignoring unintended by-products as a part of any economic
firms. Mohamadi et al. (2017) suggests that ideal governance must
activity in a production process is inevitable. The issue of undesir-
efficiently maintain corruption under control. While the direct re- €re et al.,
able outputs was discussed in the efficiency context (Fa
lationships between political governance and corruption as well as
1986, 1989). The proposition was to impose Shephard (1970)
corruption and energy efficiency have been explored and
concept of weak disposability on the production possibility set. In
confirmed using different approaches, it is still not known whether
the current study, the authors proposed replacing the assumption
corruption can play a mediating role between political governance
of strong disposability of undesirable outputs with being weakly
and energy efficiency. Hence, this study attempts to propose a
disposable while the desirable outputs remain strongly disposable.
comprehensive model considering political governance, corrup-
Among the models developed to deal with environmentally
tion, and energy efficiency by considering a dynamic approach.
undesirable outputs, non-radial directional distance function (DDF)
Taken together, we develop the following hypothesis:
(Chung et al., 1997; F€ are and Grosskopf, 2004) may provide a
Hypothesis 2. Corruption mediates the association between po- reasonable efficiency measure (Zhou et al., 2008) because it
litical governance and national dynamic energy efficiency.

3. Research design

3.1. Research framework

The regression analysis was divided into three parts. The first
part examined the effect of national CPI scores on their dynamic
energy efficiency, the second explored the association between
political governance variables and the CPI, and the third investi-
gated the effect of political governance variables on the dynamic
energy efficiency of countries. By identifying the associations
among the three components (i.e., CPI, political governance vari-
ables, and dynamic energy efficiency), political governance vari-
ables that can serve as alternative indicators to the CPI can be
identified alongside factors that affect dynamic energy efficiency to Fig. 1. CPI and national dynamic energy efficiency.
Note: This diagram depicts the association between CPI and national dynamic energy
improve government policies and promote overall national dy- efficiency. Secondary school enrollment rate, raw material export value, and foreign
namic energy efficiency. direct investment are included as control variables in performing this association
In the first part, variables such as secondary school enrolment analysis.

4
W.-M. Lu, Q.L. Kweh, M. Nourani et al. Journal of Cleaner Production 295 (2021) 126505

Fig. 3. Political governance and national dynamic energy efficiency.


Note: This diagram depicts the association between political governance and national
Fig. 2. Political governance and CPI. dynamic energy efficiency. While political stability, bureaucracy, and personal safety
Note: This diagram depicts the association between political governance and CPI. and security of private property are proxies of political governance, CPI and secondary
While political stability, bureaucracy, and personal safety and security of private school enrollment rate are treated as control variables.
property are proxies of political governance, secondary school enrollment rate is a
control variable.
respectively, as opposed to the radial efficiency models. Input and
output vectors can be altered simultaneously (Kao, 2018). The
concurrently conforms to the attributes of environmental reference model provides a reliable efficiency estimation for under-
technology and distinguishes desirable and undesirable outputs. performing DMUs.
€re and Grosskopf (2003, 2009) argued that weak disposability is
Fa This study employs the DDEA model with an undesirable output
consistent with the standard axioms of production theory. while considering carry-over activities as proposed by Tone and
Although substantial supports have emerged for the DDF model, it Tsutsui (2010). Fig. 4 shows that capital is the carry-over carried
is not flawless. Regarding the notion of weak disposability for un- from one term to another and assumes that n DMUs (j ¼ 1, …,n)
desirable outputs, researchers have disputed the validity of equality emerge over T periods (t ¼ 1, …,T). At each period, DMUs have m
constraints under weak disposability assumptions (Chen and desirable inputs (i ¼ 1, …,m), s desirable outputs (r ¼ 1, …,s), and q
Delmas, 2012; Førsund, 2009). Leleu (2013) discussed that an
undesirable outputs (p ¼ 1, …,q). In this study, xijt (yrjt ; ybpjt ) rep-
equality sign means that unconstrained shadow prices are associ-
ated with undesirable outputs. From an economic viewpoint, a resents the amounts of desirable inputs used respectively by
decrease in undesirable output involves economic loss, such as desirable and undesirable outputs produced by DMUj at period t.
pollutants. Hence, the cost associated with this loss must be non- The notion zhjt (h ¼ 1, …,nfree; j ¼ 1, …,n; t ¼ 1, …,T) is the amount
positive. When converted to a dual programming model, the DDF of carry-over (link) between t and tþ1 periods, and nfree is the
considers that an undesirable output loses its non-negative number of carry-over (link). The notions are all observed values up
constraint, theoretically implying the positive cost of this change. to period T, and N DMUo (o ¼ 1, …,n) is the observed one.
In another stream of non-radial models, Tone (2001) and Tone This study employs the cooperative idea of Kao (2018) by adding
and Tsutsui (2009, 2010, 2014) introduced the slack-based mea- relevant constraints to the efficiency evaluation model. The coop-
sure (SBM) model. The SBM does not lean on weak or strong erative idea is followed for two reasons (Kao, 2018). One, to meet
disposability assumptions and recognizes a non-dominated target the continuity condition, the carry-over item taken from the former
for benchmarking in a production possibility set. Predetermining a period (e.g., time t) must be equal to that taken from the latter
directional vector is unnecessary because a decision-making unit period (e.g., time tþ1). Two, when the two divisions are operating
(DMU) is free to select the improvement directions in accordance independently, responsible managers from the former period (e.g.,
with maximizing its efficiency score. time t) aim at maximizing the production, whereas those from the
The SBM model is a general form of distance function measure latter period (e.g., time tþ1) aim at minimizing the production to
wherein the inputs and outputs are free to have different distance achieve better efficiency.
parameters (Tone, 2001). To achieve full efficiency, the SBM allows Non-oriented efficiency was solved as follows:
input and output vectors to non-proportionally reduce or expand,

2 0 13
PT Pm s Pq sb Pnfree sfree
1 4 1 @ A5
t¼1 1  mþqþnfree þ þ
it pt ht
T i¼1 xiot p¼1 ybpot h¼1 zhot

TE0 ¼ min " !# (1)


1
PT 1
Ps sþ Pnfree sfreeþ
T t¼1 1þ sþnfree
rt
r¼1 yrot þ ht
h¼1 zhot

5
W.-M. Lu, Q.L. Kweh, M. Nourani et al. Journal of Cleaner Production 295 (2021) 126505

Fig. 4. The assessment framework of national dynamic energy efficiency.


Note: This diagram depicts the assessment framework of national dynamic energy efficiency. The observed periods are T and Tþ1, and countries from A to N. The inputs are labor
force and energy consumption, the inputted carry-over is capital, and the desirable (undesirable) outputs are GDP (carbon dioxide emissions.

respectively.
ltj represents the intensity of DMUj at time t. Equations (2)e(4)
S:T:
Xn delineate the constraints for the inputs and desirable and unde-
(2)
x l þ s
t
xiot ¼ j¼1 ijt j it ; ði ¼ 1; :::; m; t ¼ 1; :::; TÞ sirable outputs, and Equations (5)e(7) specify the carry-over items
as being freely determined while satisfying the continuity
Xn assumption between inputs and outputs. The values are allowed to
 sþ
t
yrot ¼ y l
j¼1 rjt j rt ; ðr ¼ 1; :::; s; t ¼ 1; :::; TÞ (3) reduce or expand from the observed one. Equation (8) defines the
VRS assumption. Accounting for Equations (2)e(8) in an optimum
Xn t
solution of Equation (1),
ybpot ¼ yb l
j¼1 pjt j
þ sb
pt ; ðp ¼ 1; :::; q; t ¼ 1; :::; TÞ (4)

Xn Xn n
* þ*
z l ¼
t
z l
tþ1
; ðch; t ¼ 1; :::; T  1Þ (5) lt*
j ; j ¼ 1; :::; n; sit ; i ¼ 1; :::; m; srt ; r ¼ 1; :::; s;
j¼1 hjt j j¼1 hjt j
o
freeþ free
sb
pt ; p ¼ 1; :::; q; sho ; sho ; h ¼ 1; :::; nfree :
Xn
zhot ¼ z lt
j¼1 hjt j
 sfreeþ
ht
; ðh ¼ 1; :::; nfree; t ¼ 1; :::; TÞ (6)
The result is a value ranging between 0 and 1 for each DMU
when all the excesses and shortfalls are 0. When TEo* ¼ 1 in Equa-
Xn tþ1 free
zhot ¼ z l
j¼1 hjt j
þ sht ; ðh ¼ 1; :::; nfree; t ¼ 1; :::; T  1Þ tion, (1), the target DMU is affirmed to be overall efficient:

(7)
2 0 1
Xn Pm s* Pq sb* Pnfree sfree*
lt ¼ 1; ðt ¼ 1; :::; TÞ 41  1 @ it
þ pt
þ ht A
mþqþnfree i¼1 xiot p¼1 ybpot h¼1 zhot
j¼1 j
(8) *
TEot ¼ " !# : (9)
ltj  0; s þ b freeþ
it  0; srt  0; spt  0; sht
free
 0; sht  0: Ps Pnfree sfreeþ*
1 sþ*
1þ sþnfree
rt
r¼1 yrot þ ht
h¼1 zhot
þ b freeþ
where s
it , srt , spt , sht , and sfree
ht
are the input excess, desirable
When TEot * ¼ 1 in Equation (9), the target DMU is confirmed to
output shortfall, undesirable output excess, carry-over output
shortfall at time t, and carry-over input excess at time tþ1, be efficient in period t with zero excesses and shortfalls.
6
W.-M. Lu, Q.L. Kweh, M. Nourani et al. Journal of Cleaner Production 295 (2021) 126505

3.3. Sample data source

Note: This table summarizes the referenced input and output variables in terms their respective unit of measurement and definitions. These variables are sourced from (1) The World Bank, (2) TI, (3) IMD (World Competitiveness
(Hu and Wang, 2006; Yang et al., 2015; Zhang et al.,

This study employed data from 2007 to 2016 to observe multi-


year changes in the dynamic energy efficiency of sampled coun-
tries under different technical standards. After the elimination of
countries with incomplete data and non-sovereign states, data
from 49 countries comprised the final sample. The main data
sources were the World Competitiveness Yearbook published by
IMD, the CPI published by TI, and the World Bank database.
2011; Zhou et al., 2006)

3.4. Definitions of variables

Three inputs (i.e., capital, labor force, and energy consumption)


Reference

and two outputs (i.e., GDP and carbon dioxide emissions) were
used to determine the national dynamic energy efficiency. In
generating higher demand in the economy, a country employs
Measurement of economic situations within a country, which includes the market price of all final goods and

labor force and uses renewable and non-renewable energy with


the help from fixed assets such as property, plant and equipment.
According to the accounting concept of carry-overs (Warren et al.,
People aged at least 15 years and in line with the International Labour Organization’s definition of an

2020), items that are accumulated and carried over from one
current accounting period to another are different from those
being expensed off in the current accounting period. As capital
meets this carry-over concept, this study classifies capital as an
inputted carry-over variable. While GDP is the desirable output
from the inputs, carbon dioxide emissions, being the undesirable
output, denotes where this study takes into account environ-
mental impact factors. Energy efficiency is positively related to
total factor productivity (Stern, 2012), while carbon dioxide
emissions are more prevalent in low-income countries (Haseeb
Added fixed asset expenditure plus net change value in reserves

and Azam, 2020). An almost-similar concept can be seen in Li


Tons of oil equivalent Greenhouse gases produced by the combustion of fossil fuels

et al. (2019) and Javeed et al. (2020) about environmental pol-


icies and performance at the firm level and in Sinha et al. (2019)
Yearbook), and (4) Directorate General of Budget, Accounting and Statistics, Executive Yuan, The Republic of China.
Total sum of renewable and non-renewable energy use

and Chen et al. (2018) about corruption and environmental


quality. Overall, the selections of inputs, carry-over, and outputs to
services produced during a year in the country

estimate national dynamic energy efficiency are in line with prior


studies (Hu and Wang, 2006; Yang et al., 2015; Zhang et al., 2011;
Zhou et al., 2006). Table 1 exhibits the relevant definitions.
Political governance was also decomposed to further explore
the relationship between CPI score and national dynamic energy
economically active population

efficiency. Table 2 shows the related definitions.

4. Empirical analysis

4.1. Dynamic energy efficiency of countries globally


Definition

A sustainability concept from the energy-efficiency perspec-


tive was integrated to measure the dynamic energy efficiency of
sample countries from 2007 to 2016. The higher the efficiency
value, the more favorable the performance measured. Efficiency
Tons of oil equivalent

reached the benchmark if the value was equal to 1. Conversely,


improvement was necessary if the value was 0. The countries
USD (millions)

USD (millions)
No. of people

were divided into three regions, namely, Asia, Europe, and the
(millions)

(millions)

(millions)

Americas, covering a total of 49 countries. These countries were


classified according to the World Bank’s classification of annual
Unit

income into high-income, upper-middle-income, and lower-


Definitions of inputs and outputs.

middle-income countries for comparative analysis.


Undesirable
carry-over

Desirable

Table 3 shows that the average efficiency value in Europe was


Inputted

output

output

0.762, which was 6.24% higher than the overall average of 0.6996,
Input

Input
Type

with the overall dynamic energy efficiency of the region having


risen slowly since the 2008 global financial crisis. By contrast, the
consumption

Carbon dioxide

average efficiency in Asia after 2008 fluctuated but exhibited a


emissions
Labor force

declining trend, with an average efficiency of 0.5765 being the


Variable

worst of the three regions. The KruskaleWallis test (Brockett and


Energy
Capital
Table 1

GDP

Golany, 1996) was employed to identify significant differences in


efficiency among the regions. At 5% significance level, the
7
W.-M. Lu, Q.L. Kweh, M. Nourani et al. Journal of Cleaner Production 295 (2021) 126505

Table 2
Definitions of regression variables.

Variable Function Unit Definition Source

CPI Main variable Score Scaled from 0 to 100, a high score indicates less corruption TI
Secondary school enrolment Control variable Percentage Net enrolment rate is the ratio of official school-age children enrolled in the The World Bank
rate official school-age population
Raw materials export value Control variable Percentage Ore and metal goods as constituted in Article 27 of the Standard The World Bank
International Trade Classification
FDI Control variable USD FDI refers to reported direct investment equity flows in the economy The World Bank
Political stability Political governance Score Score of 0e10; the higher the score, the more stable the politics IMD (World
variable Competitiveness Yearbook)
Bureaucracy Political governance Score Score of 0e10; the higher the score, the higher the quality of the IMD (World
variable bureaucracy Competitiveness Yearbook)
Personal safety security of Political governance Score Score of 0e10; the higher the score, the safer the society IMD (World
private property variable Competitiveness Yearbook)

Note: This table summarizes the regression variables in terms their respective unit of measurement and definitions. The respective sources of variables are also included.

Table 3
Summary of national dynamic energy efficiency values for each region.

Year Asia Europe Americas Overall

National dynamic energy efficiency 2007 0.5607 0.7096 0.5910 0.6531


2008 0.6087 0.7402 0.7474 0.7063
2009 0.5895 0.7638 0.6374 0.6995
2010 0.6058 0.7556 0.7117 0.7095
2011 0.5696 0.7588 0.6959 0.6996
2012 0.5731 0.7882 0.6498 0.7113
2013 0.5634 0.7905 0.6534 0.7107
2014 0.5587 0.7891 0.6272 0.7048
2015 0.5631 0.7671 0.6869 0.7016
2016 0.5723 0.7567 0.6993 0.6996
Kruskal-Wallis test (p-value) Average 0.5765 0.7620 0.6700 0.6996
<0.000

Note: This table reports the yearly national dynamic energy efficiency by three regions, namely Asia, Europe, and Americas. The second last row of numbers are the average
values of the national dynamic energy efficiency over the sample period. The Kruskal-Wallis test shows that national dynamic energy efficiency is significantly different among
countries by region.

Table 4
Summary of the national dynamic energy efficiency values by levels of income.

Year High-income Upper-middle-income Lower-middle-income Overall

National dynamic energy efficiency 2007 0.7492 0.4280 0.4563 0.6531


2008 0.7845 0.5475 0.4786 0.7063
2009 0.8021 0.4654 0.4712 0.6995
2010 0.8047 0.5335 0.3846 0.7095
2011 0.8035 0.5077 0.3444 0.6996
2012 0.8242 0.4982 0.3382 0.7113
2013 0.8198 0.5060 0.3465 0.7107
2014 0.8102 0.4894 0.4020 0.7048
2015 0.7995 0.5332 0.3320 0.7016
2016 0.8027 0.5183 0.3219 0.6996
Kruskal-Wallis test (p-value) Average 0.8000 0.5027 0.3876 0.6996
<0.000

Note: This table reports the yearly national dynamic energy efficiency by three levels of income, namely high-income, upper-middle-income, and lower-middle-income. The
second last row of numbers are the average values of the national dynamic energy efficiency over the sample period. The Kruskal-Wallis test shows that national dynamic
energy efficiency is significantly different among countries by different levels of income.

efficiency values were significantly different among the regions. yet to recover from the effects of the 2008 financial crisis. The
Table 4 reveals that high- and low-income countries exhibited KruskaleWallis test was employed to investigate significant dif-
similar trends in average efficiency values. The average efficiency of ferences among the different high-income and low-income coun-
high-income countries was the highest at 0.8, 10.04% higher than tries and understand their differences in dynamic energy efficiency
the overall average of 0.6996. The upper-middle-income countries each year. At 5% significance level, the differences had a significant
followed at 0.5027, 19.69% lower than the overall average. Lower- effect on dynamic energy efficiency.
middle-income countries had an average efficiency of 0.3876, Under the dynamic energy efficiency assessment framework,
31.2% lower than the overall average. The operational efficiency after energy consumption and carbon dioxide emissions were
value of high-income countries slowly increased after 2008. By considered, the national dynamic energy efficiency values (DEVs) of
contrast, the overall operational efficiency value of lower-middle- countries differed significantly according to regional characteristics
income countries significantly declined post-2009. As of 2016, the and income levels. High-income countries and technologically
dynamic energy efficiency of lower-middle-income countries had advanced regions possessed excellent competitiveness in

8
W.-M. Lu, Q.L. Kweh, M. Nourani et al. Journal of Cleaner Production 295 (2021) 126505

Table 5
Summary of CPI scores in the regions.

Time period Asia Europe Americas Overall

CPI 2007 55.3077 65.0345 52.2857 60.6327


2008 55.6154 64.1034 52.4286 60.1837
2009 55.6154 63.3793 52.1429 59.7143
2010 55.6154 62.7931 52.0000 59.3469
2011 56.0000 62.5862 51.7143 59.2857
2012 56.9231 63.4138 53.8571 60.3265
2013 56.7692 63.6552 53.0000 60.3061
2014 57.1538 64.4138 53.8571 60.9796
2015 56.9231 65.5172 53.0000 61.4490
2016 56.8462 64.9310 52.1429 60.9592
Kruskal-Wallis test (p-value) Average 56.2769 63.9828 52.6429 60.3184
<0.000

Note: This table reports the yearly CPI by three regions, namely Asia, Europe, and Americas. The second last row of numbers are the average values of the CPI over the sample
period. The Kruskal-Wallis test shows that CPI is significantly different among countries by region.

Table 6
Average CPI of countries by levels of income.

Year High-income Upper-middle-income Lower-middle-income Overall

CPI 2007 71.9118 37.8182 27.5000 60.6327


2008 71.0882 38.4545 27.2500 60.1837
2009 70.7647 37.4545 27.0000 59.7143
2010 70.4412 36.7273 27.2500 59.3469
2011 70.5588 36.0000 27.5000 59.2857
2012 69.8529 41.1818 32.0000 60.3265
2013 69.7941 41.1818 32.2500 60.3061
2014 70.5294 41.2727 34.0000 60.9796
2015 71.4118 40.6364 34.0000 61.4490
2016 70.5882 40.5455 35.2500 60.9592
KruskaleWallis test (p-value) Average 70.6941 39.1273 30.4000 60.3184
<0.000

Note: This table reports the yearly CPI by three levels of income, namely high-income, upper-middle-income, and lower-middle-income. The second last row of numbers are
the average values of the CPI over the sample period. The Kruskal-Wallis test shows that CPI is significantly different among countries by different levels of income.

Table 7 than the overall average score of 60.32. The upper-middle- and
Effect of CPI on national dynamic energy efficiency. lower-middle income countries had average scores of 39.13 and
Independent variables OLS Truncated regression 30.4, respectively. In sum, the higher the income level of a country,
Constant 0.0893 0.4410
the more favorable the CPI score, with high-income countries
CPI 0.0068*** 0.0060*** maintaining above-average scores throughout the study period. By
Secondary School Enrolment Rate 0.0024*** 0.0010 contrast, upper- and lower-middle-income countries obtained
Raw Material Export Values 0.0026*** 0.0020*** scores that were nearly half of the overall average, far behind the
Foreign Direct Investment 0.0000 0.0002**
CPI scores of the high-income countries. At 5% significance level,
Number of observations 490
significant differences were noted in the CPIs of countries from
R-squared 0.3957 different income levels.
Adjusted R-squared 0.3908 A panel data regression model was employed to further inves-
Note: This table reports the OLS and bootstrapping truncated regression results of tigate the relationship between CPI and dynamic energy efficiency.
the effect of CPI on national dynamic energy efficiency. ** denotes that p-value < Secondary school enrolment rate (also a substitute for human
0.05, while *** represents p-value < 0.01. capital), raw material export values, and FDI were set as control
variables. The regression results in Table 7 reveal that doubling the
human capital variable increased the efficiency value by 0.24%,
promoting sustainable development. indicating that higher-quality manpower increases overall effi-
ciency. The CPI also exhibited a significant and positive correlation
4.2. Effect of the CPI on dynamic energy efficiency values with dynamic energy efficiency (i.e., when the CPI doubled, the
efficiency value increased by 0.68%). Note that the CPI ranged from
Table 5 presents the performance of the CPI in different regions. 0 (most corrupt) to 100 (least corrupt). For every 1% increase, the
The average CPI for Europe was 63.98, 6.1% higher than the overall overall efficiency value increased by nearly 0.7%. Raw material
average value of 60.32, followed by Asia with 56.28 and, lastly, the export value was also significant but was negatively correlated with
Americas with an average of 52.64. This study tested whether the efficiency. The reason may be because the implementation of low
annual CPIs differed significantly among the regions; the results interest rate policy to boost the economy when the global economy
corroborated that under the 5% significance level, the annual CPIs is at the trough of the economic cycle can directly affect exchange
differed significantly among regions. rate policies due to currency devaluation (which may stimulate the
Table 6 displays a comparative analysis of the high-, upper- output value of exports at the cost of creating extra pressure on
medium-, and lower-medium-income countries. The trends for imported goods). Domestic purchasing power will decline, forming
average CPI and income level are positively correlated. The average a mutual offset phenomenon.
CPI score for the high-income countries was 70.69, 10 points higher
9
W.-M. Lu, Q.L. Kweh, M. Nourani et al. Journal of Cleaner Production 295 (2021) 126505

Table 8 Table 9
Relationship between political governance variables and the CPI. Relationship between political governance variables and national DEV.

Independent Variables 1. CPI 2. CPI Independent Variables OLS Truncated regression

Constant 3.8054*** 41.4262*** Constant 0.1424 0.496


Secondary School Enrolment Rate 0.5257*** CPI 0.0087*** 0.008***
Risk of Political Instability 2.4643*** 2.4731*** Secondary School Enrolment Rate 0.0011 0.002***
Bureaucracy 1.4901*** 2.4561*** Risk of Political Instability 0.0005 0.007*
Personal Security and Private Property 6.5555*** 4.8396*** Bureaucracy 0.0534*** 0.059***
Personal Security and Private Property 0.0163* 0.013*
Obs. 490 490
R-squared 0.7823 0.8288 Obs. 490
Adjusted R-squared 0.7810 0.8273 R-squared 0.4194
Adjusted R-squared 0.4134
Note: This table reports the OLS results of the effect of political governance on CPI.
*** represents p-value < 0.01. Note: This table reports the OLS and bootstrapping truncated regression results of
the effect of political governance on national dynamic energy efficiency. *, **, and
*** denote the significance levels at the 0.10, 0.05, and 0.01 levels, respectively.
For a robustness check, we applied the bootstrapping truncated
regression approach proposed by Simar and Wilson (2007). The
result for the main testing variable remained statistically the same, be bought, then a country’s citizens will no longer believe in justice.
meaning that when the countries become less corrupt, the effi- When power can be bought and is not subject to orderly transfer, a
ciency scores increase. In the bootstrapping approach, the effects of space for corrupt behaviors opens.
secondary school enrolment rate and FDI are insignificant and Collinearity diagnosis was conducted prior to the correlation
significant, respectively, as opposed to the OLS method. regression analysis to avoid collinearity among variables that could
cause invalid regression results. The result validated that bureau-
cratic quality was highly collinear with the legal and regulatory
4.3. Effect of political governance on the CPI
frameworks. When the legal and regulatory framework variable
was removed and the collinearity diagnosis was performed again,
Various dimensions of integrity are measured because many
no collinearity was found.
factors affect the CPI of a country, and efficiency values may be
The results in Table 8 corroborate that the CPI was greatly
influenced by many factors. Influences can be determined by clas-
affected by political governance variables. The regression results
sifying CPI into political governance variables, particularly gov-
confirmed that political stability, bureaucratic quality, and personal
ernment stability, bureaucratic quality, civil liberties, and public
safety and security of private property exhibited significant and
security (Lambsdorff, 2003). In this study, political stability,
positive effects on the CPI, findings that are in line with those of
bureaucratic quality, personal safety and security of private prop-
past studies (Haass and Ottmann, 2017; Mohamadi et al., 2017).
erty, and legal and regulatory framework were measured from
Regarding political stability and bureaucratic quality, doubling their
0 (worst) to 10 (optimum) based on the collected data, and the
scores led to the CPI increasing by 247% and 245%, respectively. The
relevant variables were defined as follows.
personal safety and security of private property exhibited the
Political stability: The ability of a government to plan and
greatest effect, where doubling its score increased the CPI by 483%.
govern the future direction of a country. These goals can be ach-
These results imply that when people’s liberty and property can be
ieved through a highly centralized government, strong legislative
protected under a stable political environment with a high-quality
authority, and support from the country’s citizens. A stable political
bureaucratic system, their sense of the country’s integrity and
system means high chances of good policies being enforced, which
desire to discipline themselves will be enhanced, forming a
indicates that the system is efficient. As politicians work within a
virtuous cycle of reinforcement.
stable framework, they become less likely to be corrupted, and the
chances of reaching societal consensus are elevated. Hence, high
overall integrity lowers the risk of political instability. 4.4. Effect of political governance on national dynamic energy
Bureaucratic quality: An administrative body must be inde- efficiency values
pendent of political pressure that uses existing recruitment and
training mechanisms. Government services are characterized as Table 9 presents the relationship between political governance
being strong and possessing professional knowledge. Without variables and national DEVs. A stepwise regression method was
these characteristics, civil servants may create bottlenecks and raise used to determine the relationship. From the equations, the polit-
their income through corruption. Once corruption becomes an ical governance variables that affected dynamic energy efficiency
ethos, the bureaucracy becomes less concerned with other matters, reached significance after secondary school enrolment rate was
including political pressure. Therefore, corruption can cause an added as an alternative control variable for human capital.
inefficient bureaucracy. Doubling political stability and the personal safety and security of
Personal safety and security of private property: This variable private property increased the DEVs by 2.2% and 5.8%, respectively.
includes freedom to live without fear of physical harm, freedom of Bureaucratic quality exhibited a negative change with the DEV,
speech and belief, personal autonomy, and human and economic regardless of whether the CPI or human capital was added (see
rights. A government that restricts fundamental rights to liberty regression equations [2], [4] and [5]). When bureaucratic quality
and property is often distorting market values, leading people to was doubled, the DEV was reduced by 3.2%e5.3%. This phenome-
look for illegal methods to circumvent regulations and create op- non is noteworthy because production inputs were previously
portunities for corruption. emphasized in the measurement of efficiency, such as conventional
Legal and regulatory frameworks: A favorable legal and regu- capital, labor, and output evaluation of GDP. If this intuitive
latory framework signifies a country with a robust and accepted framework was assumed, then positive benefits between the inputs
judicial system, a strong court system, and an orderly mechanism and outputs may be supported. However, the negative effects of
for the transfer of power. Legal and regulatory frameworks can be increased energy consumption and environmental pollution on
seriously violated by corruption. If judicial decisions and laws can efficiency mean that rigid and conservative bureaucracies may be
10
W.-M. Lu, Q.L. Kweh, M. Nourani et al. Journal of Cleaner Production 295 (2021) 126505

Table 11
Mediator test for bureaucratic quality, DEV, and the CPI.

Step 1 Step 2 Step 3

DEV CPI DEV

Constant 0.524 27.043 0.253


Bureaucratic Quality 0.055***
Bureaucratic Quality 10.385*** 0.050***
CPI 0.010***

Note: This table reports the multiple linear regression results of how CPI mediates
the effect of bureaucratic quality on national dynamic energy efficiency. *** denotes
the significance level at the 0.01 level.

Fig. 5. Political governance, CPI, and national dynamic energy efficiency. 4.5. Corruption perceptions index as the mediator
Note: This diagram depicts the mediation effect of CPI on the association between
political governance and national dynamic energy efficiency. Political stability, bu- The mediation effects were tested individually to understand
reaucracy, and personal safety and security of private property are proxies of political
how the CPI relates to the relationship between political gover-
governance.
nance and dynamic energy efficiency (Fig. 5).
To test our Hypothesis 2, we employ a multiple linear regression
unable to respond to the changing needs of a country. Kaufmann analysis to determine how dynamic energy efficiency is affected by
and Wei (1999) studied the relationship between wasted time political governance variables because more than one independent
and capital cost in bureaucracies as a result of bribery, and they variable existed (i.e., political stability, bureaucratic quality, and
obtained an opposite result to that dictated by the grease money, personal safety and security of private property). The variable se-
finding that countries that spent more on bribery caused unnec- lection mode was simultaneous regression. Subsequently, the
essary inefficiency. In short, political governance affects national mediation effect had to be verified (i.e., b31 and b32). However, the
dynamic energy efficiency, in line with Hypothesis 1. verification of b31 and b32 could only be performed if the results of
Bureaucratic quality had a negative effect on dynamic energy b1 and b2 were significant. Therefore, political stability, bureau-
efficiency. Political stability and personal safety and security of cratic quality, and personal safety and security of private property
private property had significant and positive effects on dynamic had to be significant in the results of b1 and b2 before mediation
energy efficiency. A stable political situation enables a government effects could be tested (Baron and Kenny, 1986).
to concentrate on planning the country’s future direction and As shown in Table 10, Step 1 examined the effect of political
executing these plans through a highly centralized government, stability on national DEVs using the CPI as the mediator. A simple
strong legislative authority, and support from the country’s citi- regression analysis was initially performed, and the result revealed
zens. A more stable political system leads to higher chances of good that political stability had a significant effect on dynamic energy
policies being enforced, resulting in a more efficient system. Poli- efficiency (b1 ¼ 0.050***). Step 2 examined the effect of political
ticians who work within stable systems are less likely to be cor- stability on the CPI, and the result revealed that political stability
rupted, and cohesion is likely to be enhanced by increasing societal exhibited a significant effect on the CPI (b2 ¼ 7.442***), which
consensus. In the robustness check, the directions of the results for meant that Steps 1 and 2 met the mediation effect verification. Step
political governance variables remained the same. The risk of po- 3 involved multiple regression analysis of political stability and the
litical instability became significant when a bootstrapping trun- CPI on national dynamic energy efficiency, which revealed that
cated approach was applied. political stability did not have a significant effect on dynamic en-
The higher the overall integrity, the lower the risk of political ergy efficiency (b31 ¼ 0.011) and that the b31 coefficient value
instability. When citizens’ liberty and property are protected under was close to 0. Nonetheless, the CPI had a significant effect on dy-
a stable political environment with a high-quality bureaucratic namic energy efficiency (b32 ¼ 0.008***). The CPI mediated the
system, their sense of the country’s integrity and their desire for relationship between political stability and national dynamic en-
self-discipline are enhanced, forming a virtuous cycle. If rigid and ergy efficiency. Political stability enhanced a country’s CPI. Honest
conservative bureaucracies can be improved by providing space for and efficient political governance must be implemented to effec-
flexibility and cooperation with dynamic business environments, tively improve the efficiency of a country.
then the efficiency of the country will be improved. In Table 11, the effect of bureaucratic quality on national dy-
namic energy efficiency was examined with the CPI used as the
mediator. Step 1 involved a simple regression analysis, which found
that bureaucratic quality had a significant effect on national dy-
namic energy efficiency (b1 ¼ 0.055***). Step 2 examined the effect
of bureaucratic quality on CPI, revealing a significant effect
Table 10 (b2 ¼ 10.385***), with both meeting the requirements of the
Mediator test for political stability, DEV, and the CPI. mediation effect test. Step 3 was a multiple regression analysis of
bureaucratic quality and the CPI on national dynamic energy effi-
Step 1 Step 2 Step 3
ciency, which found bureaucratic quality had a significant effect on
DEV CPI DEV dynamic energy efficiency (b31 ¼ 0.050***) as did CPI
Constant 0.380 12.809 0.275 (b32 ¼ 0.010***). The CPI mediated the effect of bureaucratic
Political Stability, b1 0.050*** quality on national dynamic energy efficiency. Bureaucratic quality
Political Stability 7.442*** 0.011
exhibited a negative effect on dynamic energy efficiency after the
CPI 0.008***
CPI variable was added. The implication is that after considering the
Note: This table reports the multiple linear regression results of how CPI mediates CPI, although bureaucracy can improve a country’s integrity,
the effect of political stability on national dynamic energy efficiency. *** denotes the
significance level at the 0.01 level.
reduction in dynamic energy efficiency may occur due to the

11
W.-M. Lu, Q.L. Kweh, M. Nourani et al. Journal of Cleaner Production 295 (2021) 126505

Table 12
Mediator test of personal safety and security of private property, DEV and the CPI.

Step 1 Step 2 Step 3

DEV CPI DEV

Constant 0.251 2.090 0.268


Personal Safety and Security of Private Property 0.067***
Personal Safety and Security of Private Property 9.380*** 0.006
CPI 0.008***

Note: This table reports the multiple linear regression results of how CPI mediates the effect of personal safety and security of private property on national dynamic
energy efficiency. *** denotes the significance level at the 0.01 level.

rigidness of the bureaucracy and the need to balance this rigidness consider their energy consumption and the negative externalities
with the effectiveness of the bureaucracy. of the pollution caused by the environment in the production
In Table 12, the effect of personal safety and security of private process, their overall national DEV is still based on the economic
property on national DEV was determined, with the CPI used as the growth and ecological environment balance, and the mature and
mediator. In Step 1, a simple regression analysis of personal safety advanced technology level European countries perform best. At the
and security of private property on dynamic energy efficiency was same time, high-income countries perform best in productivity.
performed, and the result revealed a significant effect When discussing whether differences exist in the CPI between
(b1 ¼ 9.380***). Step 2 examined the effect of personal safety and regions and countries with different income levels, I found that if
security of private property on the CPI, also revealing a significant we look at it from a regional perspective, the overall corruption
effect (b2 ¼ 9.380***). Both met the requirements of the mediation performance of European countries is still the best, followed by
effect test. Step 3 was a multiple regression analysis of CPI and Asian countries and American countries, which are high. The ob-
personal safety and security of private property on dynamic energy tained countries also have a higher degree of incorruptibility. This
efficiency, with the result revealing that the effect of personal safety study also used the KruskaleWallis Test in the statistical verifica-
and security of private property was not significant on dynamic tion method without parent numbers to test. At a significant level
energy efficiency (b31 ¼ 0.006), and the b31 coefficient value was of 5%, the incorruptibility impression index of different regions and
close to 0. CPI exhibited a significant effect on dynamic energy ef- income levels were found to have significant differences, indicating
ficiency (b32 ¼ 0.008***). certain differences in the corruption impression index whether it is
The CPI mediated the effect of personal safety and security of explored by region or income level.
private property on dynamic energy efficiency, meaning that a In sum, when governments want to improve their national dy-
country’s integrity can be enhanced with greater personal safety namic energy efficiency through better CPI, they must consider
and security of private property. When life quality improves, rent- various political governance mechanisms (e.g., governments
seeking is reduced, enhancing a country’s integrity. Honest and should pursue political stability, personal safety, and the
efficient policy must be effectively implemented to improve a improvement of private property). Monitoring the legal system and
country’s dynamic energy efficiency. In summary, CPI mediates the implementing effective management of public officials as well as
relationship between political governance and national dynamic other effective policies and planning are also important measures.
energy efficiency.
CRediT authorship contribution statement
5. Conclusion
Wen-Min Lu: Methodology, and Framework, Formal analysis,
This study aims to explore the relationship between the CPI and Data curation, Supervision, Project administration. Qian Long
the national dynamic energy efficiency of 49 countries for the Kweh: Conceptualization, Writing e original draft, Writing e re-
2007e2016 period. Different from previous studies, this study view & editing, Project administration. Mohammad Nourani:
considers both the dynamic factor of capital and energy efficiency. Writing e review & editing, Validation, Visualization. Cheng-Yi Lin:
Results corroborate that European and high-income countries Writing e original draft, Investigation, Resources.
perform significantly better than others in terms of national dy-
namic energy efficiency and CPI. The CPI has a significantly positive Declaration of competing interest
effect on national dynamic energy efficiency. The proxies of polit-
ical governance affect national dynamic energy efficiency, such as The authors declare that they have no known competing
political stability, bureaucratic quality, personal safety and security financial interests or personal relationships that could have
of private property, and legal and regulatory frameworks. The CPI appeared to influence the work reported in this paper.
has a mediating effect among variables, such as political stability,
personal security and private property, and national dynamic en- References
ergy efficiency.
The results of the study found that if the country’s dynamic Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., Robinson, J.A., 2005. Institutions as a fundamental cause
of long-run growth. Handb. Econ. Growth 1, 385e472.
energy efficiency performance alone is divided by region, Europe as Aidt, T.S., 2016. Rent seeking and the economics of corruption. Consititut. Polit.
a whole performs best, followed by the Americas, and Asia per- Econ. 27 (2), 142e157.
forms the worst. If the criterion used is the overall country’s DEV Aidt, T.S., Dutta, J., Sena, V., 2008. Governance regimes, corruption and growth:
theory and evidence. J. Comp. Econ. 36 (2), 195e220.
performance, then the advantages and disadvantages are arranged
Apergis, N., Garcıa, C., 2019. Environmentalism in the EU-28 context: the impact of
as follows: high-income countries, middle-high-income countries, governance quality on environmental energy efficiency. Environ. Sci. Pollut.
and middle-low-income countries. For most emerging economies Control Ser. 26 (36), 37012e37025.
that comprise the Asian region, if their efficiency is measured by Bardhan, P., 1997. Corruption and development: a review of issues. J. Econ. Lit. 35
(3), 1320e1346.
traditional gross domestic production alone, then they must have Baron, R.M., Kenny, D.A., 1986. The moderatoremediator variable distinction in
had significant growth in the past 10 years. However, if you social psychological research: conceptual, strategic, and statistical

12
W.-M. Lu, Q.L. Kweh, M. Nourani et al. Journal of Cleaner Production 295 (2021) 126505

considerations. J. Pers. Soc. Psychol. 51 (6), 1173. 254, 120197.


Brockett, P.L., Golany, B., 1996. Using rank statistics for determining programmatic Kalyuzhnova, Y., Belitski, M., 2019. The impact of corruption and local content policy
efficiency differences in data envelopment analysis. Manag. Sci. 42 (3), in on firm performance: evidence from Kazakhstan. Resour. Pol. 61, 67e76.
466e472. Kao, C., 2018. A classification of slacks-based efficiency measures in network data
Chang, C.-P., Lee, C.-C., Berdiev, A.N., 2015. The impact of government ideology on envelopment analysis with an analysis of the properties possessed. European J.
energy efficiency: evidence from panel data. Energy Efficiency 8 (6), 1181e1199. Operat. Res. 270 (3), 1109e1121.
Charnes, A., Cooper, W.W., Rhodes, E., 1978. Measuring the efficiency of decision Kaufmann, D., Wei, S.-J., 1999. Does ’grease money’ speed up the wheels of com-
making units. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2 (6), 429e444. merce? IMF Working Papers 1e21. Working Paper No. 00/64. https://www.imf.
Chen, C.-M., Delmas, M.A., 2012. Measuring eco-inefficiency: a new frontier org/en/Publications/WP/Issues/2016/12/30/Does-Grease-Money-Speed-Up-
approach. Oper. Res. 60 (5), 1064e1079. the-Wheels-of-Commerce-3524#:~:text=Using%20data%20from%20three%
Chen, H., Hao, Y., Li, J., Song, X., 2018. The impact of environmental regulation, 20worldwide,not%20lower%2C%20cost%20of%20capital.
shadow economy, and corruption on environmental quality: theory and Kauper, D.F., 2006. Corruption and Efficiency. University of California, Riverside.
empirical evidence from China. J. Clean. Prod. 195, 200e214. Klopp, G., 1985. The Analysis of the Efficiency of Productive Systems with Multiple
Chowdhury, F., Audretsch, D.B., Belitski, M., 2015. Does corruption matter for in- Inputs and Outputs. University of Illinois at Chicago, p. 148.
ternational entrepreneurship? Int. Enterpren. Manag. J. 11 (4), 959e980. Kunieda, T., Okada, K., Shibata, A., 2014. Corruption, capital account liberalization,
Chung, Y.H., F€ are, R., Grosskopf, S., 1997. Productivity and undesirable outputs: a and economic growth: theory and evidence. International Economics 139,
directional distance function approach. J. Environ. Manag. 51 (3), 229e240. 80e108.
Cieslik, A., Goczek, L., 2018. Control of corruption, international investment, and Lambsdorff, J.G., 2002. Corruption and rent-seeking. Publ. Choice 113 (1), 97e125.
economic growth e evidence from panel data. World Dev. 103, 323e335. Lambsdorff, J.G., 2003. How corruption affects productivity. Kyklos 56 (4), 457e474.
Cobb, C.W., Douglas, P.H., 1928. A theory of production. Am. Econ. Rev. 18 (1), Langlois-Bertrand, S., Benhaddadi, M., Jegen, M., Pineau, P.-O., 2015. Political-
139e165. institutional barriers to energy efficiency. Energy Strategy Reviews 8, 30e38.
d’Agostino, G., Dunne, J.P., Pieroni, L., 2016. Corruption and growth in Africa. Eur. J. Lee, C.-C., Wang, C.-W., Ho, S.-J., 2020. Country governance, corruption, and the
Polit. Econ. 43, 71e88. likelihood of firms’ innovation. Econ. Modell. 92, 326e338.
Delgado, M.S., McCloud, N., Kumbhakar, S.C., 2014. A generalized empirical model of Leff, N.H., 1964. Economic development through bureaucratic corruption. Am.
corruption, foreign direct investment, and growth. J. Macroecon. 42, 298e316. Behav. Sci. 8 (3), 8e14.
Delina, L.L., 2012. Coherence in energy efficiency governance. Energy for Sustain- Leleu, H., 2013. Shadow pricing of undesirable outputs in nonparametric analysis.
able Development 16 (4), 493e499. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 231 (2), 474e480.
Duerrenberger, N., Warning, S., 2018. Corruption and education in developing Li, Y., Zeng, B., Wu, T., Hao, H., 2019. Effects of urban environmental policies on
countries: the role of public vs. private funding of higher education. Int. J. Educ. improving firm efficiency: evidence from Chinese new energy vehicle firms.
Dev. 62, 217e225. J. Clean. Prod. 215, 600e610.
Dyson, R.G., Allen, R., Camanho, A.S., Podinovski, V.V., Sarrico, C.S., Shale, E.A., 2001. Lu, W.-M., Kweh, Q.L., Nourani, M., Huang, F.-W., 2016. Evaluating the efficiency of
Pitfalls and protocols in DEA. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 132 (2), 245e259. dual-use technology development programs from the R&D and socio-economic
Dzhumashev, R., 2014. Corruption and growth: the role of governance, public perspectives. Omega 62, 82e92.
spending, and economic development. Econ. Modell. 37, 202e215. Lu, W.-M., Wang, W.-K., Kweh, Q.L., 2014. Intellectual capital and performance in
€re, R., Grosskopf, S., 2003. Nonparametric productivity analysis with undesirable
Fa the Chinese life insurance industry. Omega 42 (1), 65e74.
outputs: comment. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 85 (4), 1070e1074. Lui, F.T., 1985. An equilibrium queuing model of bribery. J. Polit. Econ. 93 (4),
€re, R., Grosskopf, S., 2004. Modeling undesirable factors in efficiency evaluation:
Fa 760e781.
Comment. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 157 (1), 242e245. Mankiw, N.G., Romer, D., Weil, D.N., 1992. A contribution to the empirics of eco-
€re, R., Grosskopf, S., 2009. A comment on weak disposability in nonparametric
Fa nomic growth. Q. J. Econ. 107 (2), 407e437.
production analysis. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 91 (2), 535e538. Mauro, P., 1995. Corruption and growth. Q. J. Econ. 110 (3), 681e712.
€re, R., Grosskopf, S., Lovell, C.A.K., Pasurka, C., 1989. Multilateral productivity
Fa Mo, P.H., 2001. Corruption and economic growth. J. Comp. Econ. 29 (1), 66e79.
comparisons when some outputs are undesirable: a nonparametric approach. Mohamadi, A., Peltonen, J., Wincent, J., 2017. Government efficiency and corruption:
Rev. Econ. Stat. 71 (1), 90e98. a country-level study with implications for entrepreneurship. Journal of Busi-
€re, R., Grosskopf, S., Norris, M., Zhang, Z., 1994. Productivity growth, technical
Fa ness Venturing Insights 8, 50e55.
progress, and efficiency change in industrialized countries. Am. Econ. Rev. 84 Nourani, M., Ting, I.W.K., Lu, W.-M., Kweh, Q.L., 2018. Capital structure and dynamic
(1), 66e83. performance: evidence from ASEAN-5 banks. Singapore Econ. Rev. 1650034,
€re, R., Grosskopf, S., Pasurka, C., 1986. Effects on relative efficiency in electric
Fa 0(0).
power generation due to environmental controls. Resour. Energy 8 (2), Ozturk, I., Al-Mulali, U., Solarin, S.A., 2019. The control of corruption and energy
167e184. efficiency relationship: an empirical note. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Control Ser. 26
Farooq, A., Shahbaz, M., Arouri, M., Teulon, F., 2013. Does corruption impede eco- (17), 17277e17283.
nomic growth in Pakistan? Econ. Modell. 35, 622e633. Pereira, G.I., Da Silva, P.P., 2017. Energy efficiency governance in the EU-28: analysis
Faruq, H., Webb, M., Yi, D., 2013. Corruption, bureaucracy and firm productivity in of institutional, human, financial, and political dimensions. Energy Efficiency 10
africa. Rev. Dev. Econ. 17 (1), 117e129. (5), 1279e1297.
Førsund, F.R., 2009. Good modelling of bad outputs: pollution and multiple-output Pless, J., Fell, H., 2017. Bribes, bureaucracies, and blackouts: towards understanding
production. International Review of Environmental and Resource Economics 3 how corruption at the firm level impacts electricity reliability. Resour. Energy
(1), 1e38. Econ. 47, 36e55.
Fredriksson, P.G., Vollebergh, H.R.J., Dijkgraaf, E., 2004. Corruption and energy ef- Randrianarisoa, L.M., Bolduc, D., Choo, Y.Y., Oum, T.H., Yan, J., 2015. Effects of cor-
ficiency in OECD countries: theory and evidence. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 47 (2), ruption on efficiency of the European airports. Transport. Res. Pol. Pract. 79,
207e231. 65e83.
Gastil, R.D., 1986. Freedom in the World: Political Rights and Civil Liberties. 1985 - Rose-Ackerman, S., Palifka, B.J., 2016. Corruption and Government: Causes, Conse-
86. Greenwood Press, New York. quences, and Reform. Cambridge University Press.
Gromet, D.M., Kunreuther, H., Larrick, R.P., 2013. Political ideology affects energy- Saha, S., Ben Ali, M.S., 2017. Corruption and economic development: new evidence
efficiency attitudes and choices. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. Unit. States Am. 110 from the middle Eastern and North African countries. Econ. Anal. Pol. 54,
(23), 9314e9319. 83e95.
Haass, F., Ottmann, M., 2017. Profits from peace: the political economy of power- Salinas-Jime nez, M.d.M., Salinas-Jime nez, J., 2007. Corruption, efficiency and pro-
sharing and corruption. World Dev. 99, 60e74. ductivity in OECD countries. J. Pol. Model. 29 (6), 903e915.
Halkos, G.E., Tzeremes, N.G., 2010. Corruption and economic efficiency: panel data Sharma, C., Mitra, A., 2015. Corruption, governance and firm performance: evidence
evidence. Global Econ. Rev. 39 (4), 441e454. from Indian enterprises. J. Pol. Model. 37 (5), 835e851.
Hao, Y., Gai, Z., Wu, H., 2020. How do resource misallocation and government Sharma, C., Mitra, A., 2019. Corruption and economic growth: some new empirical
corruption affect green total factor energy efficiency? Evidence from China. evidence from a global sample. J. Int. Dev. 31 (8), 691e719.
Energy Pol. 143, 111562. Sharma, S.S., 2011. Determinants of carbon dioxide emissions: empirical evidence
Haseeb, M., Azam, M., 2020. Dynamic nexus among tourism, corruption, democracy from 69 countries. Appl. Energy 88 (1), 376e382.
and environmental degradation: a panel data investigation. Environ. Dev. Shephard, R.W., 1970. Theory of Cost and Production Functions. Princeton Univer-
Sustain. 1e19. sity Press, Princeton, New Jersey.
Helbing, D., Brockmann, D., Chadefaux, T., Donnay, K., Blanke, U., Woolley-Meza, O., Shittu Waliu, O., Yusuf Hammed, A., El Moctar El Houssein, A., Hassan, S., 2020. The
Moussaid, M., Johansson, A., Krause, J., Schutte, S., 2015. Saving human lives: impacts of foreign direct investment and globalisation on economic growth in
what complexity science and information systems can contribute. J. Stat. Phys. West Africa: examining the role of political governance. J. Econ. Stud. 47 (7),
158 (3), 735e781. 1733e1755.
Hu, J.-L., Wang, S.-C., 2006. Total-factor energy efficiency of regions in China. Energy Simar, L., Wilson, P.W., 2007. Estimation and inference in two-stage, semi-para-
Pol. 34 (17), 3206e3217. metric models of production processes. J. Econom. 136 (1), 31e64.
Huntington, S.P., 1968. Political Order in Changing Societies. Yale University Press, Sinha, A., Gupta, M., Shahbaz, M., Sengupta, T., 2019. Impact of corruption in public
New Haven. sector on environmental quality: implications for sustainability in BRICS and
Javeed, S.A., Latief, R., Lefen, L., 2020. An analysis of relationship between envi- next 11 countries. J. Clean. Prod. 232, 1379e1393.
ronmental regulations and firm performance with moderating effects of Stern, D.I., 2012. Modeling international trends in energy efficiency. Energy Econ. 34
product market competition: empirical evidence from Pakistan. J. Clean. Prod. (6), 2200e2208.

13
W.-M. Lu, Q.L. Kweh, M. Nourani et al. Journal of Cleaner Production 295 (2021) 126505

Swaleheen, M.U., 2006. Three Essays on Corruption, Department of Economics, Boston, US.
Finance and Legal Studies. The University of Alabama, ProQuest. Wu, S., Li, B., Nie, Q., Chen, C., 2017. Government expenditure, corruption and total
Tone, K., 2001. A slacks-based measure of efficiency in data envelopment analysis. factor productivity. J. Clean. Prod. 168, 279e289.
Eur. J. Oper. Res. 130 (3), 498e509. Yang, L., Ouyang, H., Fang, K., Ye, L., Zhang, J., 2015. Evaluation of regional envi-
Tone, K., Tsutsui, M., 2009. Network DEA: a slacks-based measure approach. Eur. J. ronmental efficiencies in China based on super-efficiency-DEA. Ecol. Indicat. 51,
Oper. Res. 197 (1), 243e252. 13e19.
Tone, K., Tsutsui, M., 2010. Dynamic DEA: a slacks-based measure approach. Omega Yao, X., Shah, W.U.H., Yasmeen, R., Zhang, Y., Kamal, M.A., Khan, A., 2021. The impact
38 (3), 145e156. of trade on energy efficiency in the global value chain: a simultaneous equation
Tone, K., Tsutsui, M., 2014. Dynamic DEA with network structure: a slacks-based approach. Sci. Total Environ. 765, 142759.
measure approach. Omega 42 (1), 124e131. Yao, X., Yasmeen, R., Padda, I.U.H., Shah, W.U.H., Kamal, M.A., 2020. Inequalities by
Transparency International, 2018. Corruption Perceptions Index 2017. energy sources: an assessment of environmental quality. PloS One 15 (3),
Vasylieva, T., Lyulyov, O., Bilan, Y., Streimikiene, D., 2019. Sustainable economic e0230503.
development and greenhouse gas emissions: the dynamic impact of renewable Zhang, N., Yu, K., Chen, Z., 2017. How does urbanization affect carbon dioxide
energy consumption, GDP, and corruption. Energies 12 (17), 1e12. emissions? A cross-country panel data analysis. Energy Pol. 107, 678e687.
Visscher, H., Meijer, F., Majcen, D., Itard, L., 2016. Improved governance for energy Zhang, X.-P., Cheng, X.-M., Yuan, J.-H., Gao, X.-J., 2011. Total-factor energy efficiency
efficiency in housing. Build. Res. Inf. 44 (5e6), 552e561. in developing countries. Energy Pol. 39 (2), 644e650.
Wang, S., Zhao, D., Chen, H., 2020. Government corruption, resource misallocation, Zhou, P., Ang, B.W., Poh, K.L., 2006. Slacks-based efficiency measures for modeling
and ecological efficiency. Energy Econ. 85, 104573. environmental performance. Ecol. Econ. 60 (1), 111e118.
Wanke, P., Barros, C.P., Faria, J.R., 2015. Financial distress drivers in Brazilian banks: a Zhou, P., Ang, B.W., Poh, K.L., 2008. A survey of data envelopment analysis in energy
dynamic slacks approach. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 240 (1), 258e268. and environmental studies. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 189 (1), 1e18.
Warren, C.S., Jonick, C., Schneider, J., 2020. Financial Accounting. Cengage Learning,

14

You might also like