Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 187

CAMBRIDGE CLASSICAL STUDIES

General editors THE ROMAN BAZAAR


R. L. HUNTER, R. G. OSBORNE, M. MILLETT,
A Comparative Study of Trade and Markets in a Tributary Empire
D. N. SEDLEY, G. C. HORROCKS, S. P. OAKLEY,
W. M. BEARD

PETER FIBIGER BANG

CAMBRIDGE
UNIVERSITY PRESS
CAMBRIDGE UNIVERSITY PRESS
Cambridge, NewYork, Melbourne, Madrid,CapeTown.Singapore, SaoPaulo, Delhi
Cambridge University Press CONIUG1 OPTIMAE AC FII. IIS CAR1SSIM1S
The Edinburgh Building, Cambridge di2 SRV. UK
PublishedintheUnited StatesofAmericabyCambridge University Press,NewYork
www.cainbriclge.org
Informationonthistitle:www.cambridge.org/978o52l855327
e Faculty ofClassics, University ofCambridge 2008 Some valuing those of their own side or mind,
Still make themselves the measure of mankind:
Thispublicationisincopyright.Subjecttostatutoryexception Fondly we think we honour merit then,
andto theprovisions ofrelevant collective licensing'agreements,
no reproduction of any part may take place without When we but praise ourselves in other men.
the written permission of Cambridge Universitv Press. Alexander Pope, An Essay on Criticism
First published 2008

Printed inthe United Kingdom attheUniversity Press,Cambridge


A cataloguerecordforthispublicationisavailablefromtheBritishLibrary
Library of Congress Cataloguing in Publication data
Bang, PeterF. (Peter Fibiger)
TheRomanbazaar/ PeterPibigerBang.
p. cm. - (Cambridge classical studies)
Includes bibliographical references.
ISBN 978-0-521-85532-7 (hardback)
I. Bazaars(Mmtets) - Italy- Rome-'History: 2.Rome(Italy) - Commerce - History.
3. Rome (Italy) - Economic conditions. I. Title. II. Series.
HI.-5474. I82R663 2008
381 . I -clc22 2008031924
ISBN978-0-521-85532-7hardback

EX L16RIS
UNIV6RSITAT18
WVIOMAQENSIS I

Cambridge University Presshasnoresponsibility forthepersistence 01-


accuracy of URL.s for external or third-party internet websites refeiTed to
in this publication anddoes not guarantee thatanycontent on such
websites is, or will remain, accurate orappropriate.
CONTENTS

List of figures and tables page viii


A note about abbreviations x

Preface Xl
Key dates and terms in Mughal history Xlll
Roman weights, measures and coins XV

Prolegomena

PART I THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND THE COMPARATIVE


STUDY OF PRE-INDUSTRIAL SOCIETY 15

i Beyond The Ancient Economy"! Trade in the Roman


Empire and the problem of comparative history 17
2 An agrarian empire between market and tribute:
situating interregional trade in the Roman world 61

PART II IMPERIAL BAZAAR 129

3 A rough trading world: opaque, volatile and


discontinuously connected markets 131
4 A thin line: portorium, protection and predation 202
5 Community: cult, courts, credit and collaboration in
the bazaar 239
Epilegomena: taking stock - the world of goods 290

Bibliography 307
Index 351

Vll
LIST OF FIGURES AND TABLES

S.I d, bottom, floor mosaic from the section of the


portico belonging to the navicul(arii)
FIGURES AND TABLES et negotiantes Karalitani (C1L XIV, 4549, 21 =
no. 21 on the plan)
5. 2 Palmyra and its trading world 255-257
5. 2a, Map of the central part ot'Palmyra's trading
network (from G. Young, Rome 's Eastern
Frontispiece ThebazaarintheoldtownofDamascus onedayin Trade. International Commerce and Imperial
the spring 2001. Policy, 31 BC-AD^o^, London, 2001, p. 140)
5. 2b, top, view of the central cella (to the right) and
Figures the courtyard of the enormous temple of Bel in
Palmyra
i. t Olusegun Obasanjo is sworn in as president of 5. 2C, bottom left, section of the Bel temple's portico
Nigeria (PolFot, Denmark) page 39 5. 2d, bottom right, close-up of one of the statue
2. 1 The Mughal Empire (J. F. Richards, The Mughal bases with bilingual inscription
Empire, The New Cambridge History of India I, 5,
Cambridge, 1993, p. iv) 81 Where no source is indicated, the graphics and photographs are
the author's own.
2. 2 Rough model ofagrarian economy 85
2. 3 Roman GDP, surplus and tributary empire 114
3. 1 Grain prices in Amsterdam and Danzig in the Tables
eighteenth century (J. de Vries andA. Woude,The
First Modern Economy. Success, Failure and 2. 1 Estimate of disposable surplus, state impact and
Perseverance ofthe Dutch Economy, 1500-1800, interregional trade in the second century AD 87
Cambridge, 1997, p. 418) 148 2. 2 Living standards for different groups of population
3. 2 Roman Egypt and the province ofArcadia 159 under different productivity regimes I 18
3. 3 Price ofwheatin fifth-century province ofArcadia 163 3. 1 Variation in price levels in Arcadia 161
3.4 Price ofbarley in fifth-century province ofArcadia 164 3. 2 Commodity prices, probably in Oxyrhynchus, during
3. 5 Price of wine in fifth-century province of Arcadia 167 fifteen months of the fourth century AD 168
5. 1 Piazzale delle Corporazioni (plan from CILXIV, 251-252
suppl. Ostiense, p. 662)
5. ia, top, view ofPiazzale delle Corporazioni from
the theatre in Ostia
5.i b, bottom, plan ofthe complex
5.ic, top, close-upof the small temple in the centre
of the complex

vni
IX
A NOTE ABOUT ABBREVIATIONS PREFACE

A few minor and unproblematic deviations apart, in referring to "Habent sua fata libelli" the Roman writer remarked in days of
ancientsourcesI usethestandardabbreviations oftheOxfordLatin old. This is just as true of scholarship as of literature. Over the
Dictionary, Liddell and Scott's Greek-English Lexicon, 9th edn. years I have beenmet with extensivegenerosity, support, patience
andJ.Gates etal., Checklist ofGreek, Latin, Demotic andCoptic and liberal-minded curiosity from many people and institutions.
Papyri, Ostraca andTablets.
I am delighted to offer my heartfelt thanks to all of these at the
completion of this study. It originated as a PhD submitted at the
Faculty of Classics in Cambridge in 2003. The Danish Research
Agency financed the three preceding years of work in Cambridge,
for which Corpus Christi College provided a wonderful setting,
both for me and my family. Fondation Idella, Knud H0jgaards
Fond, Corpus Christi College and the Faculty of Classics gener-
ously gave supplementary funding. In Denmark, Erik Christiansen
and Uffe 0stergard helped me lay the foundationsto the research
I conducted in Cambridge and have been unwavering in their sup-
port. In Leicester, David Mattingly tolerated a polemical visitor
and provoked me to conceive the first ideas for a comparative
study of the Roman Empire. Sarah Scott encouraged me to think
of Cambridge. In 2001, The Danish Institute in Damascus and its
then director, Peder Mortensen, made a research trip to Syria and
the ruins of Palmyra an unforgettable experience. I owe particular
thanks to Joyce Reynolds, who has been such a kind friend, as
well as Dorothy Thompson and Michael Sharp for discussing mat-
ters ofepigraphyandpapyrology with me. RichardDuncan-Jones
and Muzaffar Alam gave me kind advice on different occasions.
Michael Crawford kindly let me have a preview of the new edition
of the text for the Asian Customs Law, still in preparation.
Richard Saller generously invited me to Chicago, supervised
my research for a term, did much more than one could reasonably
expect and introduced me to Walter Scheidel, who has continued to
offer friendship and inspirational discussions over the years. Keith
Hopkins volunteered to supervise my second year and made it one
Xl
PREFACE

of intellectual play and expanding horizons. Chris Bayly took a


kind interest in the project from very early on, gave me invaluable
guidance on Indian history and has grown into a trusted colleague KEY DATES AND TERMS IN MUGHAL HISTORY
and collaborator. Vincent Gabrielsen and my other colleagues in
the Saxo Institute at the University of Copenhagen had faith in
me, took me on as lecturer before the completion ofmy research
and encouraged my work in every aspect. However, with that
also came new obligations and new projects. Kari Erik Frandsen. 1526: Battle of Panipat, foundation of Mughal
the former director of the Institute, gave me the period of peace rule in northern India.
and quiet which enabled me to return to Cambridge for a second 1526-30: Babur, first Mughal emperor.
round in the first halfof 2007 andto start turning the thesis into a 1530-56: Humayum, reign interrupted by exile
book ThistimeRobinOsbornekindlyextendedhospitality aswell from 1540 until victorious return shortly
as stimulating discussions at King's, while the Danish Research before his death.
Council gave financial support. Dick Whittaker and Greg Woolf 1556-1605: Akbar.
originally examined the thesis, offered penetrating observations
andmadethedefence anoccasion whichI remember withjoy. The Conquest and cooptation of the Rajputs, conquest of Gujarat and
Bengal.
comments oftwo anonymous readers, aswell asmy lecturership
committee, further helped me to improve the manuscript and the 157^-85: seat of government transferred from
argument. Agra to FatehpurSikri, a newly erected
Above all, however, my thanks go to Peter Gamsey who first capital and palace complex, which was
took me on at Cambridge. I can hardly believe almost ten years again abandonedafter only a few years
have passed. Enjoying the privilege ofhis inspirational guidance, of use.
firm support, loyal friendship, tolerant patience and incisive com- 1605-27: Jahangir.
ments has not only benefited my work immensely, it has also set 1627-57: Shah Jahan.
anexample to whichI canonly everaspireinmy ownteaching.
On the domestic front, I owe an enormous debt of gratitude Expansion into the Deccan.
to my parents, who taught me to go my own ways, and to my in- c. 1632-43 Taj Mahal: construction of the mausoleum to the
laws;theyhavesupportedmeineverywaypossibleovertheyears. favourite wife of Shah Jahan, Mumtaz
Ultimately, however, it was my family, Helena, Julian and Mette. Mahal.
whomadeit allpossiblebyagreeingtofollowmeouton"foreign 1639-48: construction of the Red Fort of Delhi
adventures", bytoleratingmywhimsandbygivinglovingsupport which was henceforth elevated to serve
in times ofagonising doubts. It is to them that I dedicate this work. as the imperial capital under the name:
I wish it were perfect, they would deserve nothing less, but this is Shajahanabad.
the best I could do.
1650-56: construction of the Jami' Masjid
mosque in Shajahanabad/Delhi.
Copenhagen,autumn 2007 1658-1707: Aurangzeb (Alamgir).
1685-87: Annexation of the tributary sultanates of
Bijapur and Golconda in the Deccan.
Xll
Xlll
KEY DATES AND TERMS IN MUGHAL HISTORY

Lastthirdofthecentury:insurgencyoftheHinduMarathasdrags
downthe Mughals in a fruitless warof attrition.
ROMAN WEIGHTS, MEASURES AND COINS
Gradual weakening anddisintegration of Mughal rule follows in
the decadesafterthe deathofAurangzeb.
1707-12: Bahadur Shah.
The principal grain measures
I7I2-I3: Jahandar Shah.
I7I3-I9-- Farrukhsiyar. I modius = c. 6. 55 kg or c. 8. 62 1
17^9-48: Muhammed Shah.
[ medimnos = c. 40 kg or 52. 53 1
1739: occupation of Shajahanabad (Delhi) by I artaba = c. 30. 2 kg or c. 391; in late antiquity 21. 5 kg or 29 1
the Persian ruler Nadir Shah. The
Mughal capital is plundered and the Liquid measures
famous Peacock Throne carried away to
Persia. End of effective Mughal power. i metrete 39. 39 1
1837-57: BahadurShah2 (deposedafterthe i kotyle c. 0. 25 1
Great Indian Mutiny). I monochoron c. 7 1
i sextarius = c. \ pint (16 sextarii to a modius)
Mansabdar is the Mughal term for the individual members of
the imperial aristocracy. The mansab refer to the ranks which the Square measures
nobles were awardedby the emperor.
Jagirdar is occasionally used instead oiMansabdar. However. I mgerum = c. 2, 500 m square
heretheemphasisisontherevenueSissigments, jagirs, whichthe i aroura = c. 2, 760 m square
nobles received inreturn forservingthe'emperor. Coins
Zamindaris usedto denote local landowningelites acrossthe
Mughal Empire andassuch covers a broad spectrum ofwealth, i denarius (silver) = 4 sesterces (HS, bronze) = 16 asses
statuses and influence.
i aureus (gold coin) = 25 denarii = 100 sesterces
myriad denarii: in late antiquity, the silver contents of the denarii
dwindled to almost nothing and its value correspondingly col-
lapsed. Hence we now find the notion of myriad denarii (10, 000
denarii)

solidus: in the same period a new gold coin, the solidus, from the
time of Constantine struck at 72 to the pound, became the new
backbone of the Roman imperial coinage.
i drachma = 6 obols (in Egypt 7 obols)
i mina = 100 drachmai
I talent == 60 minai = 6, 000 drachmai
XIV
XV
PROLEGOMENA
PROLEGOMENA

an Oriental "artefact", as the form of trade characteristic of the by archaeology cannot easily substitute for our missing trade
pre-modem high cultures of the agrarian world. The bazaaris not statistics.4
incompatible with a Roman setting, far from it; in Damascus it is The general inadequacies of the evidence accentuate the role of
still possibletoobservehowthetwoco-exist,theoneorganically conceptualisation in historical research. Too often historians for-
built into the other, in the narrow alleys leading from the old Via get that the sources are not identical with history; they are only
Recta to the Umayyad Mosque, the former temple of Jove (see the fragmentary remains, the traces of the past world which we
Frontispiece).
seek to re-create in our writings. Sources are, in other words, not
Evidently, part of the problem of ancient economic history self-explanatory. They must be interpreted in order to bring us to
is the poor and fragmented state of the evidence. Compared to the ancient reality. This has, in fact, always been acknowledged by
historians ofEuropean tradeandcapitalism from theMiddle Ages most practitioners ofthe historical profession. But it wouldbe fair
through to the industrial revolution, the situation ofthe ancient his- to say that, with some very honourable exceptions, the discipline
tonan is deplorable. Nothing like the copious merchant archives, has neglected the development of interpretative tools. The way
company records, toll registers and lists published by brokers of that history was institutionalised as a discipline across universi-
pricey current in the bourses - the bread and butter of European ties in Europe and America in the nineteenth and early twentieth
trade history - exists from Roman antiquity. The ancient histo- centuries focused on promoting the detailed examination and crit-
rian hasto make do with much less andmust bewilling andable ical scrutiny of sources. How to combine the observations into a
to combine the testimony of very different kinds of sources. He coherent whole was, on the other hand, seen as a function of the
or she cannot afford to ignore the evidence of any one group personal inclinations of the individual scholar. Romanticist histo-
of material. Papyri, ostraca, wax tablets, Roman law, the classi- rians claimed to be artists, working on the basis of their personal
cal literature, inscriptions and archaeological evidence must all intuition and "divine" inspiration.5 Scholars of a more positivist
beconsulted andmadetocontribute tothefinalimage. Nosingle bent agreed. They tended to regard the "art" of interpreting the
group ofsources cansettheanalysis ona firmfooting^ Inscriptions evidence as a subjective activity, not really part of the proper "sci-
mentioning merchants, for instance, provide very little detailed entific" pursuit of history, which should simply stick to the sources.
information andarein anycaserelatively fewinnumber, leaving The latter was no solution; ultimately it was simply a way of giving
large tracts of the Empire completely in the dark. Archaeology up on writing history.6
hasproduced abundantevidenceoftransport ofgoodsaroundthe The historian of Hellenism, Droysen, followed by Max Weber
Mediterranean, but mainly through finds ofpotsherds in field sur- in the next generation, offered an alternative to this submission
veys and excavations. This tells us of transport of oil and wine to subjectivism. Intuition might be of service to historians dealing
in clay containers and trade in pottery. Perishable containers and withproblems andoccurrencesofwhichthey hadimmediateexpe-
goods are, on the other hand, often invisible. Thehugenumber of rience. However, as soon as they had to deal with questions beyond
grain ships bringing supplies from Egypt andAfrica to Rome have their personal horizon, their experience stopped being of any use
lefthardlyanytraceinthearchaeological record,whereastheprob- to them. Indeed it might often lead them to make false judge-
ably smallernumberofshipssailingwithcargoesofoil ancTwine ments and introduce anachronistic features to their analysis - the
dominate thewreckevidence. 3 Cloth, animportant commodity in
pre-industrialtrade,isalsolargelyunaccountedforbyarchaeology. 4 Whittaker 1989. 5 Meyer 1910.
As the "founder"of the modem historical profession in Denmark, KristianErslev quite
Though clearly of great worth, the distribution patterns reveafed possibly did, cf. Tandrup 1979. A small booklet (Erslev 1911),makinga sharpdistinction
between the critical scrutiny of sources and the subjective art of interpretation, has
3 Cf. Parker 1992. continuedto provoke intensedebateamong Danishhistoriansright up to the present day.
See Finley 1985b, chapter 4 for a general treatment of the question.
2
PROLEGOMENA PROLEGOMENA

cardinal sin ofthe professional historian. Suchconcerns arepar- small and household-based. However, they were and are not pas-
ticularly pertinent with regard to phenomena either far removed sive victims of uncertainty. Instead they tend to pursue strategies
in time and place from the historian, or such as cannot readily be which do not aim to eradicate the general conditions of uncertainty,
seen from the observation of individual examples but only appear but rather reproduce them as part of the solution. One such strat-
from the statistical study of large masses of evidence. Both con- egy, as observed by Clifford Geertz, is clientelisation. Merchants
ditions apply in the study of ancient economies. The response of in the bazaar seek to cultivate personal and lasting relations of
Droysen and Weber was to pay close attention to the formation exchange with particular business partners. This serves to shelter
of concepts - our analytical tools - or theory. By broadening and them against the all-pervasive risks and uncertainties of the bazaar,
refining his conceptual and theoretical repertoire, the historian but on the basis of specially trusted and favoured relations. The
acquires a method for improving andmaking explicit the assump- marketasa generalisedsphereofexchangeis not available,or only
tions that he brings to bear on the source material. Theory and in a very limited way, to the bazaar merchant. His is not a level
conceptual analysis are a means by which the historian controls playing field. Better opportunies might, for instance, be available
and compensates for his "deficient" experience.7 in a different market. However, if the merchant lacks his network
One example must suffice for demonstration. In common par- of personal alliances, he may not be able to make use of those
lancemarket trade isalwaysthesame. Careful theoretical examina- opportunities and will therefore prefer to remain in the market
tion ofmarkets, however, reveals thatthey may operate in very dif- he knows. Fragmentation of the market is not simply an imper-
ferent ways according to circumstances. The bazaar, for instance, fection; quite the reverse, it is reproduced by the way the bazaar
possesses a number of characteristics, which produce a distinct functions.
pattern oftradevery different from thatofmodern, capitalist mar- Describedin this way,thebazaarasa model ofmarketsis bound
kets, as we shall see more fully explained in Chapter 3. For the to be of particular interest to the student of pre-industrial trade. It
moment, a basic definition in ideal-typical terms will do. As a provides an attractive formula by which to treat the many irregu-
form oftrade,thebazaarhastakenshapefromthemanyirregular- larities characteristic of a world based on slow-moving animal and
ities characteristic of pre-industrial peasant societies. Compared weather-boundsea transport. Yet, even here is it possible to make
to modem markets, the bazaar isdistinguished by high uncertainty distinctions.Inthisstudy,thebazaarisusedasa conceptto describe
ofinformation andrelative unpredictability ofsupply anddemand. markets in complex agrarian societies before the development of
This makes the prices ofcommodities in the bazaarfairly volatile. (early) modem capitalism with its links to mercantilist privileges
Asa consequence, theintegration ofmarkets isoftenlowandfrag- and later liberal programmes of laissez-faire economics. These
He; it is simply difficult for traders to obtain sufficiently reliable policies helped to strengthen the position of the middleman, often
and stable information on which effectively to respond to devel- a man of dubious reputation and status in aristocratically domi-
opments in other markets. Considerable fragmentation of markets natecl societies, and saw a development towards more stable and
prevails. From a modern perspective where trade has focused on integrated markets during the seventeenth to nineteenth centuries
overcoming these obstacles to commercial integration by creating within the European-led,for lack of a better word, worlcl-system.9
a more transparent and predictable environment, this condition Theoretical and conceptual reflection enables the historian to
has often been mistaken for a seeming chaos and lack of organ- cultivate his analytical imagination and increases his capacity
isation. Most merchants operating in a bazaar environment'are
8 Geertz 1979is thebesttheoreticaldescriptionofthe bazaar.
9 Cf. Wallerstein 197411. Steensgaard 19733 and Persson 1999 on the link between Euro-
Droysen1977,esp.217-219and285-393;Weber1922:146-290;Finleyiq8'ib.chapter pean commercial policies, institutional innovations and the gradual improvement in the
4; Veyne )976b.
integration of markets; Bang 2006, for further discussion.
PROLEGOMENA PROLEGOMENA

for perceiving historical differences. 10 Traditionally historians of pre-industrial society. In addition, economics as a discipline is
have described Greco-Roman antiquity with concepts taken from more orientated towards the future than the past. Its objectives are
the "Western" historical experience. For a long period clas- different from those of history.
sics was seen as the epitome of civilisation and constituted the Both anthropology and economics offer valuable insights to the
backbone of elite education in Europe and America. As this posi- ancient economic historian. This study draws on some of these.
tion was lost in the cluster of processes normally referred to as But neither of the two disciplines has focused its attention on the
modernisation, a gap began to open up in people's minds between problems most relevant to the student of the ancient world - a
the European present and the Greco-Roman past. Increasingly pre-industrialhigh culture. The ancienthistorian is thrust back on
Greco-Roman culture has come to be seen as a foreign place and himself or herself to develop an adequate theoretical framework
theexperienceofmodernity asa correspondingly inadequateguide more thoroughly grounded in a historical experience relevant to
to the ancient past. This has set classicists and ancient historians his/her own subject. This brings us back to Weber's project. His
freetoexplore thelessfamiliaraspectsoftheancientworld. They ambition was to ground the social sciences securely in historical
have in particular sought inspiration from anthropology. This dis- experience. Theories developed in relation to the modem world
cipline, having developed a rich theoretical tradition, has proven had to be complemented by concepts developed to deal with pre-
a virtual gold-mine for ancient historians in search of organis- industrial conditions - a historical sociology. Weber's tool was
ing concepts. Indeed, the anthropological work of Clifford Geertz comparativehistory. 13By studyingothersocietieswhichresemble
greatly informs the use in this study of the bazaar as an ideal- the Roman world more closely, ancient historians acquire a more
type. But the relevance of anthropological research for ancient secure basis for their own interpretations. Comparative history
history also has very real limits. Anthropologists have tradition- provides them with the historical experience they lack.
ally eitherfocused on so-called primitive societies or studied tradi- The number of relevant historical parallels to the Roman Empire
tional, most commonly peasant, communities in isolation from the is relatively limited. Pre-industrial history does not present us with
outside world. " This is a problem for the student of an urbanised many giant, multiethnic agrarian empires sufficiently well known
high culture, which depended on its ability to break the isolation of to warrantcloser comparison. The last point bears emphasis. Pre-
theindividualpeasantvillagesandclaima partofagricultural pro- Colombian empires in the Americas, such as the Inca and Aztec,
duction for theconsumption ofurban dwellers andspecialists. The though smaller, might for instance be considered potential can-
isolated units of anthropology are too simple for the ancient real- didates for comparison. But our knowledge of these polities is
ity. '2 Economics might offer another possible theoretical avenue considerably less than of Rome. The sources are fewer and schol-
to the student of Roman trade. In particular, development eco- arship much less copious. The same goes for a number of ancient
nomics, dealing with societies where agriculture still holds a very and medieval imperial formations. 14 Anyhow, this is not to say that
prominent position, has something to offer. But much has already these are not interesting cases. 15 But from a pragmatic perspec-
changed in the third world. It doesnotrepresent a pristine version tive, the best candidates for comparison would seem to be found
in the context of sixteenth- to eighteenth-century Asia. Ottoman,
10 Bloch 1967:44-8i;Veyne 1971;Finley 19855. Ming/Ch'ing and Mughal history all offer attractive comparisons.
" A local emphasis, failing to take proper account of intercity/long-distance trade, is a
particular weakness of Geertz' early work (1963) on the bazaar.'The 1979 treatment 13 Weber 1972. See Skocpol 1979; Skocpol and Sommers 1980 on the analytical qualities
is moreawareoflinksbetweenmarkets,buttheattentionis still pointed'towardslocal of comparative history.
links.
14 The volume edited by Alcock, D'Altroy, Morrison and Sinopoli (2001), while interest-
Finley 1975:Chapter6 HardenandPurcell 2000strugglewiththisproblem; theyhave ing, did reveal the huge discrepanciesin the densityof information betweenthe Roman
difficulties combining their micro-analytical approach with a clear understanding of Empire and many potential comparisons.
wider processes such as state formation; see Bang 2004. 15 See Scheidel 2008 for an interesting attempt to compare Rome and Han China.

7
PROLEGOMENA PROLEGOMENA

These empires have size, dense documentary record and extensive adjusted to serve the historical inquiry. From an economic point
historiography speaking in their favour. of view, imperial capitals like Rome and Agra - giant cities of
But the choice is not merely a matter of expediency. The early the pre-industrial world with population figures reaching into the
modern timeframe means that all three imperial societies were, hundreds of thousands and financed by an enormous expenditure
in turn, confronted withexpansive,Europeancapitalism.Thishas of imperial tribute - clearly have much more in common than
causedMughal, Ottoman andChinesehistoriansto debateto what each of them has with a contemporary smallish peasant village
extent trade and markets in these empires resembled or differed within their respective cultural orbits in, say, Anatolia or Bengal.
from European (see Chapter i). The challenge facing these histori- "L'unite de lieu n'est que desordre. Seule 1'unite de probleme
ographies has in many ways been the same as that confronting the fait centre", as Marc Bloch once remarked. '8 This approach does
Roman historian: to find a way to account for vibrant commercial not exclude recognising differences. The production of calicoes in
networks and considerable exchange without denying the exis- Bengal during the Mughal era represents one of the most extensive
tence of significant differences to the emerging forms of modern pre-industrial examples of cloth production. A significant, though
capitalism, in other words to avoid the Scylla of primitivism and far from the biggest, part ofproduction went to foreign exports. '9
the Charybdisofmodemism. 16The historianofRoman trade can Roman products such as wine and glass did find their way out of
surely leam from these efforts. This study draws on the experience the Empire, but the Roman economy was without a similarly large
from all three empires, but Mughal Indiahasbeen singled out for export trade. In thatrespect, India,in spite ofhavingoften enjoyed
more detailedcomparison. Thischoiceisnotwholly arbitrary. The a reputation for being the quintessential traditional society, would
character and shape of the historiography of the Mughal Empire seem to be not less commercialised than the Roman world, rather
is such as to be particularly helpful in suggesting solutions to'the the opposite. This makes Mughal India a useful upper benchmark
problems which have occupied historians of the Roman economy for discussions of Roman trade and markets. Categories, in effect,
and trade - as will appear from the following chapters. Suffice it must be handled pragmatically and tailored to fit our analytical
here to note the availability of an extensive literature on trade in needs.
the IndianOceanandtheprominent position claimed by a model, This takes us to the problem of trespassing. Only rarely can
positing a close link between state taxation and commercialisa- comparative historians aspire to be experts in more than one field.
tion inexplaining economic developments in theMughalEmpire, Therefore they must depend, to a large extent, on the work of
much asin Hopkins' influential interpretation ofRoman economic colleagues in other areas of research. Inevitably, they are bound
history. to make some mistakes, just as their understanding of parts of
A Roman-Mughal comparison may seem to militate against the "foreign" material undoubtedly will leave much to be desired.
the instincts of traditional historical research. It disregards' both None of this should be seen as vitiating the endeavour. It bears
the unity of time and of space. Trans-epochal as well as cross- emphasis that the aim is not to produce a comprehensive and
cultural comparisons are often viewed with suspicion. '7 This is in detailed account of Mughal India. Not every detail or nuance is
many cases unwarranted. Neither cultures nor epochs are "sacred" important to the comparative historian. Emphasis must be placed
boundary markers. They are analytical, not arbitrary, I hasten to on the aspects which can help to elucidate the problems in which
add constructs, useful generalisations designedto throw light on he/she is interested. The same goes for scholarly disagreements.
specific aspects of reality. Such categories must be designed and No historiography is ever fixed. New generations tend to produce
new, competing versions of the past. Any historical question of
Bangetal. 1999;SeeBangandBayly2003forsomepreliminarycomparisons.
17 Even Tilly 1984. Bloch 1967: 44-81 is more nuanced. 18 Bloch 1934: 81.McNeill 1986:35 and84;Aymard 1990. '9 Prakash 1998.
PROLEGOMENA PROLEGOMENA

morethanmoderateinterestis boundtobecontested.Inpracticeit state system maintained not by a clear hegemon, but by a balance
is not possible, nor is it desirable,to accountfor every conflicting of power. 23
view in the interpretation of the comparativeexample. In general, Another terminological "mannerism" employed here is the con-
I have chosen what seemed to be the better-argued case, even if cept "agrarianatesociety". The term was coinedby the innovative
controversial, and restricted myself to indicating only some of the comparative historian of Islam, Marshall Hodgson, who used it
major fault lines in scholarly debateson the Mughal Empire. The to emphasise that literary high culture and cities co-existed with
aim, it should be remembered, has beento use Mughal history to peasant agriculture in the pre-industrial world. It was not simply
develop concepts for Roman history. 20 an "agrarian" society. The next issue is chronology. The emphasis
Remainingtobeexplainedarea fewmattersofterminologyand in this study is on the Roman Principate. However, occasionally
chronology.Theterm "tributary"empiremayrequireclarification. discussion of examples and evidence from both the late Republic
TributumdesignatesinLatinthetaxesowedbytheprovincestothe and late antiquity has been included in order to throw light on the
Roman imperial state. Duringthe 1970$andearly 1980$the term problems under examination. Though clearly seeing changes, the
gainedcurrency amongMarxist scholars to describethe predom- broader timespan was also marked by one fundamental continuity:
inance of the political power to tax in mobilising the agricultural the presence of a vast tributary empire in the Mediterranean world.
surplus ofpeasant producers. This distinguishes a tributary empire Finally, a word about citation of Greek and Latin texts. These
fromthemodemcolonialempiresoftheeighteenthandnineteenth are normally reproduced in English translation as a help to the
centuries. The latter treated their dependencies much more with a reader. The argument, however, is based on the language of the
view to commercial exploitation. Provinces provided the Romans original. Sometimes, therefore, I have not indicated the source of
withtaxrevenue;coloniesservedmoreassuppliersofrawproducts the English text, so as to be free to make the changes, modifications
and consumers ofmetropolitan exports. 2' Chris Wickham gave the and adjustments I deemed necessary, whenever the translation did
concept a well-directed twist, when he suggested it be used to dis- not originate with the present author. In most such cases the text
tinguishcentralised, imperial surplus extraction from rent claimed has been taken from the standard translations of the Loeb series.
by local, decentralised and independent feudal lords. 22 It is in this The first part of this study seeks to identify and develop the
sense that the term has been adopted in the present study, though most suitable comparative framework for the analysis of trade in
in an undogmatic way and without subscribing to the broader the Roman Empire. Chapter I treats the debate on the Roman
Marxistframework. In general"tributary"seemspreferableto the economy as an expression of a set of problems common to pre-
empty and less precise phrase "traditional" empire. Occasionally industrial studies in general: to whatextent should the evolution of
'tributary"hasbeenusedinterchangeablywith"agrarian"or"uni- European capitalism be treated as a general template for analysing
versal" empire. The term "universal" may help to clarify further trade in other complex agrarian societies? The evolution of a sys-
the notion of empire used here. It is generally reserved for vast tem of emergent nation states in early modem Europe is now seen
extensive hegemonic polities that manage to dominate and absorb as instrumental in the development of modern capitalism. Fierce
most states within their orbits. This sets a tributary empire apart competition and rivalry forced governments to promote economic
from the early modem absolutist monarchies which developed on development and often trade in particular. The Roman imperial
the basis of European feudalism and formed part of a pluralistic government was under no similar constraint. The ancient process
of state formation had united the greater Mediterranean under the
20 Paludan 1995: 197-203 is the best available discussion of this problem. See further rule of the Romans. Interstate competition was a much weaker
Goldstone 1991: xxvii and 50-60.
21 SeeHobsbawm1987,chapter3 fora treatmentofcolonialempires.
Wickham 1985;Wolf 1982;Amin 1973. 23 Tilly 1992; Watson 1992.
10 II
PROLEGOMENA PROLEGOMENA

force. The Roman state was already the most powerful and had eft to the initiative of merchant communities and their capacity
much less need to privilege commercial groups; it could concen- :'or self-organisation. Chapter 3 analyses market integration and
trate on taxing its vast population, particularly the peasant masses. argues that Roman merchants would generally have been less able
In that respect, the Roman Empire resembles the early modem to integrate markets than their later early modern European col-
empires of Asia, the Ottomans, the Mughals and China of the leagues. Instead, it suggests the bazaars of the Mughal Empire as
Ming and Ch'ing dynasties. These empires were all tributary and a useful parallel, presenting an image of more fragmented inte-
the chapter concludes by suggesting them as constituting a more gration, many local monopolies and relatively greater uncertainty.
proper category within which to analyse the character of Roman Chapter 4 examines the question of uncertainty in greater detail
trade. by looking at protection and customs duties in the Roman and
Chapter 2 explores the character of economic integration in the Mu.ehal Empires. Though customs claimed by the state were pre-
Roman world. Through a comparison with surplus extraction in dominantly fiscally motivated andfrequently predatory, the ability
Mughal India, it is shown how the formation of a tributary empire of merchants to smuggle and to circumvent the harshestcollection
affects the main driving forces behind long-distance or intercity points checked abuse by officials and kept the burden of indirect
trade. The imposition of an imperial tax saw a concentration of taxes within bounds. In the absence of elaborate state guaran-
wealth in the hands of the imperial government and aristocratic tees, the merchants of the bazaar developed their own private,
elites. Political consumption of the agricultural surplus, however, social institutions to tackle the uncertainties of commercial life.
depended on the availability of markets and long-distance trade. Chapter5 examinesthese in terms of communal, religious organi-
Intensified surplus extraction therefore went hand in hand with sations and the role of the household in supplying trading capital.
increased commercialisation. Market formation was driven by The epilegomena conclude the study; they sum up the argument
politically determined consumption rather than economic com- and identify some themes and avenues for further research with
petition. This argument is supported by a hypothetical quantitative respect to the development of imperial styles of consumption.
model of the Roman economy.
The second part of the study, "Imperial Bazaar", moves on to
examinetheinstitutionalconditionsoftradeandtheshapeofmar-
kets produced by the tributary empire. Its basic aim has been to
redress the balance in our image of trade under Roman hege-
mony. While Roman historians have frequently been impressed
by the image of tranquil order projected by the Empire, Mughal
historians have, in comparison, paid much more attention to the
predatorydimensionsofimperialrule.Bothaspects,however,need
to be accommodated within our understanding. Increased surplus
extraction, the creation of imperial coinages and the imposition
of imperial law, all facilitated trade and markets. But there were
clear limits to this process. Many irregularities still continued to
characterise the world of trade under the imperial peace. State
personnel did not only offer protection, they were also a source
of predation and insecurity for merchants. The administrative and
judiciary machinery was of very limited extent. Much was still
12 13
PART I

THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND THE COMPARATIVE


STUDY OF PRE-INDUSTRIAL SOCIETY

Ideally we should create a third discipline, the comparative study of literate


post-primitive (if I may), pre-industrial societies.
M. I, Finley, Anthropology and the Classics

After all, something has changed in the course of human history. We need terms
which can size the differences.
E. Gellner, Plough, Sword and Book
BEYOND THE ANCIENT ECONOMY^
TRADE IN THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND THE
PROBLEM OF COMPARATIVE HISTORY

AberdieseAnalogienmitmittelalterlichenundmodernenErscheinungen,schein-
bar auf Schrift und Tritt vorhanden, sind zum nicht geringen Teile hochst
unverlasslich und oft direkt schadlich fur die unbefangene Erkenntnis. Denn
jeneAehnlichkeitenkonnenleichttrugerischeseinundsincles tatsachlichnicht
selten.
Max Weber, Agran'erhaltnisse im Altertum, p. 4
En Asie, on a toujours vu de grands empires; en Europe, ils n ont jamais pu
subsister.
Montesquieu, L'Espritdeslois, 3. 17.6

Rome - the battlefield of Orient and Occident

Some years ago the world of classical scholarship saw one of


those rare genuine sensations. A manuscript was found and pub-
lished containing a set of very full notes, taken by father and
son Hensel, of Mommsen's lectures on the history of the Roman
emperors. Here atlast wasthe almost mythical, long hopedfor and
neverpublishedfourthvolumeofMommsen'slegendaryRomische
Geschichte. After having dealt, in three volumes, with Rome from
the earliest times up to the battle of Thapsus in 46 BC, the history
hadbeenplannedto proceedwith a treatment of the political his-
tory of the Romanemperors. It never happened.The subjectheld
little appealfor Mommsen. In his viewthe systemofmonarchical
government had workedbest "whensecond-ratemen were at the
head". ' Instead, a gap was left in the series and Mommsen con-
tinued his history of Rome with volume 5, published in 1885,
which contained a ground-breaking survey of the conditions pre-
vailing in the provinces. Rather than the decadent and mediocre
emperors, long familiar from the narratives of Tacitus and

Mommsen 1992: 231 (my translation). Skydsgaard 1997.

17
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY BEYOND THE ANCIENT ECONOMY?

Suetonius, the matter of real importance and interest, as Momm- earliest remnants of Roman law. But Roman law had not remained
sen saw it, in the history of this period was the gradual spread ciuiulit in the fetters of status society. It had continued to progress
of Greco-Roman civilisation throughout the provinces of the iiii. l i I it achieved a fully developed system of rational law based on
Empire. 2 Among thechapters on the eastern provinces he included contractual obligations and rights. Thus Roman law represented a
a treatment of the border zone between Rome and its formidable brkl.^e, figuratively speaking,betweenthe old status-baseddevel-
neighbourand adversary,the ParthianEmpire. Whatclashedhere opmental stage and modern Western rational, commercial society.
were not just two ancient, competing empires but two funda- By studying the evolution of Roman law and its culmination in the
mentally opposed principles of society and culture - the city- classical Romanjurists, it was possible to follow the birth process
based, Western-style bourgeois, Greco-Roman civilisation versus of the founding principles of Western civilisation.4
the Eastern civilisation of the Parthians, almost without towns and So Greco-Roman civilisation, or rather its greatest achieve-
based on the despotic control of large masses of toiling peasants irsents, were in many waysperceived aspresenting a developmental
living in villages. The border thus took on an almost mythologi- history similar to that of Europe since the Middle Ages. This is,
cal dimension in Mommsen's analysis, constituting a demarcation of course, a way of thinking which ultimately traces its roots back
line between East and West, Orient and Occident. to Renaissance ideology, proclaiming the new times as a rebirth
A few years earlier that great English historian of compara- of Greco-Roman antiquity, and which later received a new boost
tive jurisprudence, Sir Henry Sumner Maine (1822-1888), had from the art historian and archaeologistJohannJoachimWinckel-
defined the difference between East and West as a question of mann (1717-1768), who inspired the neo-classicist adoration of
societies basedon status rather than on contract - hierarchy versus the Greeks and to a lesser extent the Romans. Even in such an inclu-
liberal egalitarianism. As the ancien regime gradually gave way sive, overtly anti-classicist, history of antiquity as that of Eduard
in Europe during the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries and the Meyer (1855-1930), whichalso insistedon the importanceof the
continent established world dominance, the civilisations of Asia various Oriental or Levantine cultures as background and prede-
came to be seen as specimens of an unchanging traditional and cessors of the Greek and Roman world, only this last civilisation
hierarchic social order, which history somehow had left behind. is depicted as progressing through all or most stages of historical
Hegel, and later Marx, placed the Orient outside the dialectical development. In contrast, Pharaonic Egypt is seen as history gone
progression of world history. China and India were seen as static wrongaftera promisingstart, a caseofOrientalstagnationcaused
social systems betraying no signs ofdevelopment, always remain- by religious superstition and an oppressive clergy. 5 Thus the eco-
ing the same. They were without history.3 Thus, to Maine as to nomic historian, Karl Biicher (1848-1930), could hardly avoid
many others, Indian society with its age-old Vedic cultural tradi- appearing strongly provocative when he dared in his Die Entste-
tion, composedin an Indo-Europeanlanguage,offeredthestudent hung der Volkswirtschaftof 1893 to view Greco-Roman antiquity
of history a glimpse into the long bygone past of Europe. What in its entirety under the same heading, that of household economy
he saw was a society consisting of quasi-autarkic villages made (Oikenwirtschqft), in order to distinguish it from the Middle Ages
up ofpatriarchal households with the division of labour organised characterised by a city economy (Stadtwirtschaft) and the mod-
along caste lines and only limited influence exerted by the market. ern period with its national economies (Volkswirtschaft). Meyer
He believed that it was possible to detect the same traits in the immediately felt the need to rebut what he saw as a dangerous,
simplistic unilinear view of history, and chose an official meeting
.

' Mommsen 1904, Introduction.


Hegel 1996: 122-123; Marx's views on Indiaarebestexpressed in hisdispatches to the
New York Daily Tribune, e. g. 10 June 1853 and 22 July 1853, easily downloaded from 4 Maine 1871, chapter i and 1861. Meyer1910:192-193, 247-252 and 1924:89.
the Web or available in e. g. Marx and Engels 1960. 6 Bucher1911:85-150.
l8 i9
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY BEYOND THE ANCIENT ECONOMY7

of German historians in 1895 to dismiss rudely Bucher's views Here it occurred to Weber that in certain respects the fundamen-
as those of an amateur, unfamiliar with the sources. Bucher's tal principles governing the economy of the Greco-Roman world
description might, albeit with difficulties, fit the earliest, most had more in common with the Levantine or Oriental societies of
primitive, periods of Greco-Roman culture; but for later times antiquity than with the kind of economic formation one found
with the progress of civilisation, the extent of trade had become in early modem Europe. Therefore he treated the various ancient
much too large. Here one hadto employ his later economic types of civilisations known to him within a broad, common analytical
Stadt- and Volkswirtschaft. This analysis Meyer concluded with framework, trying not to sacrifice historical development or par-
the now legendary dictum that the ancient economy "in every ticulars by developing a range of more specific models to describe
respect, cannot be considered modem enough. Only one should the characteristics peculiar to each society and period. 10
avoid drawing on the nineteenth century for comparison, but use Meyer, however, was blind to this historical aspect of Biicher's
rather the seventeenth and eighteenthcenturies."7 and Weber's economic types and the accompanying compara-
One of the classic debates of historiography had been born, the tive perspectives, even though he himself insisted that history
struggle between "primitivists" and "modernists", which still, a was a discipline of the singular and the particular. In his inter-
century later, continuesto hauntscholarlydiscussions,often under pretation, Greco-Roman civilisation remained a quintessentially
the revealing name of minimalists versus maximalists, signifying Western bulwark against the Orient. In fact, the decline of the
that the problem has often wrongly been reducedto one of quan- Roman Empire was portrayed as a reversal, beginning in the East,
titles, mainly of trade. Yet, Max Weber (1864-1920) in his 1909 to more Oriental forms of society dominated by religion and
articleAgrarverhaltnisseimAltertum,hadalreadyobjectedthatthe stiffening tradition. " This idea received its fullest exposition in
main point ofBucher's models wasnot to assign antiquity to a first, M. I. Rostovtzeff(1870-1952)andhismonumentalThe Socialand
primitive stage of economy or to deny it the existence of historical Economic History of the Roman Empire of 1926. Here he set out to
development. 8 On the contrary, Bucher's message was strongly supply the empirical underpinning of Meyer's basic interpretative
historicist and had developed from a critique of the English classi- framework for Roman economic history during the Empire, not
cal economists' attempt to explain all economic phenomena within least through an innovative attempt to bring the growing archae-
one comprehensive or universal theory. Hence he tried to identify ological record to bear on the historical problems. To all intents
the organising principles, the economic structure, particular to each and purposes the history of the Roman Empire came to an end
historical society and epoch, rather than subsuming them all under with the beginning of the fourth century, from Rostovtzeff's point
one unifying logic. The ideal-type of the oikos economy, in fact, of view. To him the rest was, indeed, silence, and the remaining
far from being a first primitive stage of economic development, centuries, today known as late antiquity, were cursorily dealt with
was rather an attempt to grasp what set antiquity apart as a his- and hurried to their tragic end under the heading "The Oriental
torical epoch among the group of advanced civilised societies.9 Despotism andthe DecayofAncient Civilization".Greco-Roman
civilisation in all its constituent forms had now ceased to exist. It
7 Meyer 1924: 141: "in jeder Hinsicht nicht modern genug gedacht werden kann. Nur
darf man nicht das neunzehnte Jahrhundert zum Vergleich heranziehen, sondem das had become a foreign world - an Oriental world.
siebzehnteund achtzehnte"(my Englishtranslation). Seefurtherpp. 81-82 and 88-89;
Schneider 1990. 10 Weber l924a, Einleitung. See Bruhns 1985; Capagrossi Colognesi 1990; Love 1991;
Weber 19240:7-13. Capagrossi Colognes; 1995; Bruhns and Nippel 2000; Nafissi 2005 on the Weberian
9 Bucher 1911. pp. 85-92 are instructive for his historicist critique of classical eco- approach to ancient economic and comparative history.
nomics. Meyer missed both this dimension of Biicher's thought and its separation of " Meyer1924:142-160. 1910: l23-l53and 192-193 makes the connection of the Orient,
oikos economies from the "primitive" economies of anthropology. In Biicher's scheme stagnation, tradition and religion clearer.
the latter preceded the former category (pp. 92-116). Finley 1977: 315-317 saw this 12 Rostovtzeff 1957, chapter 12. Most of his overall interpretative schema can be found in
clearly. Meyer 1924:142-160. This ought to temper the current ritual praise of Rostovtzeff's
20 21
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY BEYOND THE ANCIENT ECONOMY?
Today such an evaluation seems somewhat dated, given the core institutions of Roman civilisation, in the Empire's ability to
flourishing state of late antique studies. One might even think in respond to increased military pressure along the frontiers. This
termsofa paradigmshiftin classicsandhistoryhavingtakenplace is Finley, doing the sums: "The Ancient World was hastened to
in the last half century or so. A seminal work in this process of its end by its social and political structure, its deeply embedded
changewasA. H. M. Jones' study ofThe LaterRomanEmpire of and institutionalized value system, and, underpinning the whole,
1964, which demonstrated that late antiquity could be studied as the organizationand exploitation of its productive forces.'"5 The
an epoch in its own right and notjust as an era of decay and disinte- Empire of late antiquity had now been firmly located within the
gration or a prologue to the final liquidationofthe classical world. defining cultural characteristics of the classical world; during
Moreover,byreflectingupontherelativeweightofagricultureand the same exercise Finley had radically shifted the focus of our
trade in the economy of the Empire, Jones came to hold a notion of understanding of the Greeks and Romans, stressing the "otherness"
the ancient economy fundamentally different from that of Eduard oftheancientworldandrejectingtheallegedcloseaffinitybetween
Meyer or Rostovtzeff. He characterised the Roman world, in late the social and economic forms of antiquity and early modem
antiquity as in other periods, as overwhelmingly agrarian. Trade, Europe.
so much emphasisedby the modernists, he relegated to a minor Instead, Finley sought his inspiration from the, formerly unac-
position in the overall structure of the economy. Thus changes in ceptable, analysesof Bucher, Weberandtheirpupils, andin addi-
the patterns and volume of trade might not, after all, be indicators tion from the writings of various anthropologists. The economist
of fundamental economic change. '3 and anthropologist Karl Polanyi (1886-1964), whose seminar at
In many ways the taskof teasingout the implications ofJones' Columbia during the late 1940s and early 1950$ Finley attended,
decisive shift of emphasis for our understanding of the econ- wascited for the fundamental inapplicabilityof'market-centred,
omy of the Roman Empire remains at the very centre of schol- modern economic theory to the study of antiquity; further,
arly activity and controversy. One result has been that people are Polanyi's notion of economics as the study of "the satisfaction
now less inclined to take a view of late antiquity as fundamen- of material wants"echoesthrough Finley's discussionofthe issue
tally different from and completely alien to the preceding peri- of the presence or absence of an economic policy, modern style, in
ods, and tend instead to emphasise many continuities, without Greek and Roman states. 16 But there were limits to the usefulness
denying changes. '4 A good example, and one of the most per- ofPolanyi's conceptualisation for Finley's project. Reciprocal gift-
sistent attempts to come to terms with the agrarian "nature" of giving and authoritarian redistribution, the two modes ofeconomic
the Greco-Roman world is, of course, the ground-breaking The organisation seen as characteristic of pre-modern economies by
Ancient Economy of 1973, composed by Moses Finley, Jones' Polanyi, were inadequate to explain the ancient reality. Even if the
successor as professor in Cambridge. Here developments in late Greco-Roman world did not operate on capitalist lines, markets
antiquity, such as increasedstate control, contraction in the market still played too much of a role in the economy to describe it in
sector, tying of peasants to the land and a crisis in the economy terms ofPolanyi'salternatives. '7 Forthe concrete analyses,Finley
of the towns, are seen as the result of limitations, imposed by the
15 Finley i985a: 176. I6 Finley 19853: 26 and 160-161.
utilisation of the archaeological material as against Finley's alleged neglect (Harris 17 Cf. the important role ascribed to Athens' function asa commercial centre for the Aegean
1993: 14-15 and n. 26; Harden and Purcell 2000: 6l2). It is doubtful whether his basic
world in generating income to the city after the loss of the empire (Finley l9»5a: 131-
interpretation was in any determining way formed by archaeology. See Salmeri 1998 134)- It is commonly forgotten that Finley rejected Polanyi's concrete models for not
for a sobering reading of Rostovtzeff.
allowing enough influence to markets and trade (Finley 1970). It is, therefore, not a
3 SeeJones [964,chapter2[, andmorebroadly 1974;Christiansen 1995:51. little ironic when Nafissi 2005, chapter 10 describes The Ancient Economy as a decline
14 Pleket 1990: 29-30; De Ligt 1993: 4; Garnsey and Whittaker 1998; Gamsey and into Polanyian orthodoxy and at the same time takes it to task for excluding the ancient
Humfress 2001.
Middle East from the analysis. Yet, the latter was not included on the express grounds
22
23
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY .?
BEYOND THE ANCIENT ECONOMY'!

turnedto inspirationtakenfrommore complexpre-industrialsoci- i)!ilical usage. 20 Still, one should not lose sight of the liberating
eties. The growing body of peasant studies, with its emphasis on erspectives - for which the close relationship between history and
locating markets in "traditional" settings, was a key influence. 18 anthropology to this day can work as a suitable symbol - that have
In anotherplace, the workofthe anthropologistLouisDumonton allowed new questions to come to the fore and not least sought to
the Indiancaste system, Homo Hierarchicus,is utilised to embark v ide more historical and often also more theoretically refined
on a long discussion emphasising the role of hierarchy and social answers by exploring the limits of the experience and concepts of
status in Greco-Romansociety. 19Thus, newandexcitingcompar- the modern world. 2'
ative perspectives were opened up; and aspects or themes, often Hven if we stay within the field of Roman history, a long series
associated with the exotic societies of anthropological discourse of studies, influenced by anthropology and comparative history,
or pre-modern Asian civilisations, were now allowed to appear springs to mind. I shall restrict myself to mentioningjust a few.
and come to the forefront in the picture painted of the classical Paul Veyne asserted the primary importance of gift-giving, tradi-
world. tioiuilly the preserve of anthropologists, to the Greek and Roman
Of course, Finley was far from alone in this. It is easy to for- world in his Le Pain et Ie cirque of 1976. A few years previously,
get this today, but the i96os and 1970s were also the era of de- Ramsay McMullen in Roman Social Relations (1974) had called
colonisation andthetiersmondiste movement, firedbythewritings ulicntion to the high levels of extra-legal violence and the limited
of Jean-Paul Sartre and Franz Fanon. New prominence was given e\!ension of official authority. Before that, Peter Garnsey had doc-
to notions ofcultural relativism, andthe limitations andhistoricity iimcnted the profound importance of status, social and legal, in
of Western concepts were explored and highlighted by thinkers (lie heyday of classical Roman law, where Maine had interpreted
suchasFoucaultand,in thefieldofeconomics,by thesundrycrit- the elaboration ofthejuristic literature as a transition to a modem,
ics ofdevelopment theory. It would be difficult to maintain that all Ci.'alitarian contract-based form of society. Even more systematic
that was said and done during these years was for the good. After comparisons between the Roman and some of the more famous
all, this was also the period that produced the various kinds ofvery Askin pre-modern empires and civilisations have been attempted.
dogmatic Marxism and the horrifying crimes of a Pol Pot, trying to Keith Hopkins drew continuously in his work on comparisons with,
realise the thirdway in a version profoundly different from current especially, Chinese imperial history. 22 In his study of Patronage
iiiulcr the Early Empire (1982) Richard Saller included compar-
isonswiththe administrationofthe OttomanandChineseEmpires;
thatmarkets seemed to play lessofa role andthat it resembled more a Polanyian scenario
(28-29). This view of the ancientNearEast may be mistaken (cf. n. 19), but hardly and Dick Whittaker (1994) has recently attempted to understand
makes the picture rendered of Greco-Roman antiquity any more Polanyian. Above ail the Roman imperial frontier through a model developed by Owen
The Ancient Economy wasa Weberianstudy.
18 SeeFinley 19850,chapter4,n.2 (referringtoa nowclassiccollection ofpeasantstudies Lattimore to explain Chinese history. Inspired by these studies,
edited by T. Shanin), further nn. 29, 33, 34, 70. In his essay "Anthropology and the a number of collaborative efforts in the field of Roman imperial
Classics"(1975), Finleyinsistedon a comparativecategoryofcomplexpre-industrial comparisons have also seen the light of day during the last few
societiesas the most relevant for classical studies ratherthan the primitive tribes often
the object of anthropological research. years. 23
19 Finley l985a: 43-44, thoughthere are remnants ofthe old Orient-Occidentdivide on
pp. 27-29; but there the question is of delineating the boundaries of the subject, not of
seeking out comparanda. Manning andMorris 2005 convincingly argue that thevarious
NearEasternsocietiescouldusefullybeincludedinourconceptoftheancienteconomy; 20 Finkielkraut 1988. -" Contra Engels 1990:131-142.
they were not asdifferent as was previously thought. But for Pinley (198511: 30-3 l with 22 Hopkins l978a; 1980; 19833; and 1995-6.
n. 31), following Braudel, not ignoring him as Manning and Morris 2005: 15-17 claim, 23 Bang et al. 1999; Alcock, D'Altroy, Morrison and Sinopoli2001; BangandBayly 2003
the Greco-Roman world was a Mediterranean world, not a river valley world. and a project conducted by WalterScheidel(2008) comparing Rome and Han China.

24 25
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY BEYOND THE ANCIENT ECONOMY?

unexpected assistance from the present postmodernist dislike of


Returning to Rostovtzeff? generalised explanations. One view asserts "that whatever clas-
sificatory or analytical system we use has to accommodate, in a
All the same, these tendencies have hardly gone uncontested. For way that the rnonocolore and essentially synchronic constructs of
instance, in a recent collection of essays, Inventing Ancient Cul- Blicher and Finley cannot, a possible extreme diversity of types
ture, the editors set out to restore the prominenceofGreco-Roman of activity within the same society". 28 Another book, edited by
antiquity in our understanding ofthe birth ofmodernity, whichthey Helen Parkins, confidently declares that we are now Beyond the
findhascometobetoostronglyassociatedwiththeEnlightenment Consumer City - the model Finley used to describe the economic
era. 24 Certainly, in the field of social and economic history debate foundation of Greco-Roman urbanism- andemphasises the need
hasbeenheated,to saytheleast, from thevery beginning,andone for a diversity of approaches. 29 One can readily applaud Parkins'
cannot help but feel that it was somewhat premature when Keith desire to have ancient urbanism examined from a variety of view-
Hopkins,introducinga collection ofarticles presentedto Finleyin points. After all, no model can ever hope to be exhaustive; its
1983,termedFinley'sandA. H. M.Jones'jointly developedinter- application is of necessity restricted to a limited number of prob-
pretation "the new orthodoxy". After all, that very collection did lems. But it is less than clear why an openness towards a plurality
not display such a consensus. The impression was rather that of a of approaches would require the theory of the consumer city alone
multiplicity of viewpoints and strong disagreements. 25 Even if we to be banned or left behind. Certainly, Parkins presents no very
allow thatThe AncientEconomyhasoccupieda dominatingposi- convincing case to back up her claim. On the contrary, in her own
tion atthevery centre ofscholarlydebate,the directionofresearch contribution to the book she is hard pressed to find her way. "None
hasto a largeextent beendecidedby Martin Frederiksen'sdismis- of this contradicts Weber's consumer city model", she has to admit;
sivereviewin the JournalofRomanStudies.Colouredby a general indeed her analysis sets out from a perspective "that incidentally
distrust of the theoretical reflections in which Finley so excelled underlines the validity of Weber's model while adding some sig-
and by a strong positivist inclination, he set out to show that the nificant refinements". 30 One could reasonably have left it at that.
ancient evidence revealed a more complex and varied reality than Even so, Parkins still insists that the level of involvement in the
allowedfor by Finley's simplifyingmodels. 26 urban economy of the land-based elite was somehow too large to
That sort of objection, however, is banal. No treatment of a be accommodated by Finley and Weber's model. The logic is far
bygone world, however detailed, can ever claim to be more than from compelling.3
a simplification. The important question to ask is whether in the There is something a little doctrinaire about this kind of reac-
chosenperspective a specific analysis seems to be a fair approx- tion, yet the style of argumentation is widespread. In their book
imation of the ancient reality for which it seeks to account. Seen The Corrupting Sea,PeregrineHardenandNicholasPurcell man-
in this light much of the criticism has been less than success- age within the space of two pages on the one hand to concede
ful. 27 Nonetheless,Frederiksen'spositivistobjections havestruck that the understanding of the city as a centre for aristocratic con-
a strong chord in academe, and have, of late, received somewhat sumption of an agricultural surplus is whatbest sums up the phe-
nomenon of ancient urbanism and on the other to reject the model
24 Golden and Toohey 1997. Schiavone 2000 elegantly demonstrates the futility of such as "dated": for there was allegedly more growth in the economy
anenterprise. 25 Garnsey,HopkinsandWhittaker1983.
26 Frederiksen 1975. SeeDrexhage, Konen andRuffing 2002: ii and21 for some very than allowedfor by Finley.32 The issuesraisedby Parkins,Harden
recent echoes of Frederiksen's objections. Bang, Ikeguchi and Ziche 2006 for a collec-
tion of papers which, on the contrary, advocate the need for the conscious use oftheory 28 Davies 1998:241. .>9 Parkins 19975,preface. SeefurtherParkins 1998: II-I3.
in the study of the ancient economy. 30 Parkins l997a, citations from pp. 107 and 84. 31 Pace Mattingly 19973: 215.
27 Erdkamp 2001; see Saller 2002 for some cautionary observations. 32 Harden and Purcell 2000: 106-107.
26 27
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY BEYOND THE ANCIENT ECONOMY''

and Purcell are not unimportant. In the final analysis, however, the track as attempts are made to pinpoint its precise location on a lin-
model survives and this is, more or less, openly admitted. Thus ear spectrum between the two opposites of primitive and modem,
Harden and Purcell depend to a large extent on Morley's thought- as indeed recommended by Frederiksen in his review. 36 In that
provoking study of classical Rome - the quintessential consumer analytical game, less is never more. 37 A tendency has emerged
city - which argues that the immense buying power created by in current scholarship almost automatically to support taking a
the politically directed concentration of economic resources from more optimistic view of the ancient phenomena, be it rationality,
an extensive empire in the capital also acted as a stimulus on its growth, trade, market integration or the economy in general. 38 No
Italian hinterland, promoting more intensive forms of agricultural wonder then, that Rostovtzeff is again celebrated as the great-
production.33 In Parkins' case, an acceptance of even extensive est economic historian of Mediterranean antiquity and attempts
aristocratic investment in the urban economy does not alter the have been made at resurrecting his general interpretation of eco-
fact that the wealth of that class was grounded in agriculture or nomic development in the first centuries AD. Oncemore the story
that the cities depended for the satisfaction of their consumption has been told of how a flourishingempire-widemarket developed
needs on the surplus from its landed estates. A strong presence in under the favourable influence of the Fax Romana, in which the
theurbaneconomywouldratherserveto putevenfurtheremphasis provincescompetedformarketsharesandgraduallyoustedItalian
on aristocratic dominance in the city and thus underline the cities' products.39 More broadly,this return of"modernism"canbe seen
generaldependenceonthe largehouseholdsoftheelite. 34Farfrom in what one of the veterans of the struggle has called "a drift back to
having made the consumer-city model obsolete, the critics seem the bad old ways when huge trade, industry and capital formation
to be exploring aspects or areas of activity where the model can
accommodate several variations. Not polarised confrontation, but 16 Frederiksen 1975: l7l. Whittaker 1995; Bang l997a; and Drinkwater 2001 warn against
constructive engagement is what is neededhere. This would allow this tendency.
37 Attempts at quantification, for instance, often incline towards the highest possible
a more fruitful debate about the model to emerge where attention estimate, e. g. van Minnen 1986 (extrapolation from very thin and fragmentary material
could be clearly concentrated on charting variations, identifying to postulate a very large global estimate of the Oxyrhynchite cloth trade, though we
sub-types and adding new dimensions to our understanding of would expect seasonal fluctuation rather than permanent high activity); Wilson 2001
(twenty-two household establishments, with small fulling installations in Timgad dated
ancient urbanism, for instance by exploring the formation of urban broadly within a bandof three centuries, are taken as a sign of large-scale activity. Yet,
networks and hierarchies.35 the twenty-two individually small establishments are unlikely all to have existed at the
same time, much change happens over three centuries, and even if they did, at five
Further examples of misdirected critique at Finley and the members per household, the entire "industry" could be accounted for by some 100-
"primitivist" postion need not detain us here. Enough has already 120 persons); Adams 2007: 227-228 (focusing on a Ptolemaic village customs register
indicating brisk activity in one month. But, as he also notes, this may be due to a post-
been said to make it clear that the unconstructive, sometimes harvest peak in grain transports. The more numerous Roman customs registers indicate
almost extreine reaction against "the Cambridge orthodoxy" has less intense activity to be the norm, cf. Alston 1998 for a more cautious analysis).
3 Harris 1993; Greene 1994: 25-26; Harris 2000 and Temin 2001 for systematic surveys
been accompanied by a tendency to blur discussions and more of the economy and trade of the Roman Empire seeing more growth, trade, markets and
importantly to allow a much less precise use of analytical con- development than Finley allowed. Harden and Purcell 2000 simply define exchange
cepts to reassert itself. The unfortunate outcome has been that the (market, gift, redistribution) as the central characteristic of pre-moclern Mediterranean
civilisation.
debate on the ancient economy has become stuck on a well-wom yl Tchernia 2006 for a critique of this trend. A new example of the continuing cache of
Rostovtzeff's general interpretive framework is provided by Rizzo's discussion of the
changingpatterns of imports to Rome (2003: 230) as reflected in ceramic assemblages,
33 Morley 1996. seeing Italian production decline in the face of provincial competition. Carandini 1983^
34 Parkins 19970: 88-89 is not far from that conclusion. Wallace-Hadrill 1991 and 1988; 1989 are the most outspoken examples. But elements can also be found in e. g.
Whittaker 1993, chapter 12 and 19946 are very clear aboutthis. Pater.son 1998; von Freyberg 1989, chapters 2 and 3. 5 and in the very interesting and
35 Whittaker 1995 is an interesting exploration of the limits of the explanatorypower of balanced attempt by Lo Cascio 1991 to "unite" Rostovtzeff and Weber. For Rostovtzeff
the model. as the great historian, see note 12 above.

28 29
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY BEYOND THE ANCIENT ECONOMY?

were discovered in every petty street-corner workshop of Roman was not organised as "an enormous conglomeration of interde-
towns".40 pendent markets". Recently, however, the economist Peter Temin
Two examples will suffice. One deals with the production of argued that Finley was quite simply wrong, the economy of the
Italian terra sigillata, the mould-cast, red-slip ceramic tableware Roman Empire representedjust such a conglomeration.44 This is
found by archaeologists in widespread locations during the late an extraordinaryclaim. Onemight conceivablyimaginethat some
Republic and early Empire. The other is a broader discussion of markets had begun to be linked by middle- and long-distance
the market in the Roman world. Let us take terra sigillata first. Sur- trade. But to see the entire economy, spanning several continents,
veyingrecentarchaeologicaldevelopments in ourpictureofItalian as organised by a set of interlinked markets is quite another mat-
production centres, Philip Kenrick concluded: "The level oforga- ter. It is doubtful whether the mature eighteenth-century European
nization and the closeness of relationship which this implies seems economy, outside some restricted pockets, could be described in
to me to justify us in regarding this as an industry in an entirely such terms.45 Given our almost complete lack ofprice datawhich
modern sense. "41 Yet, one looks in vain for any attempt at a close could substantiate this conclusion, caution might be advisable. 46
definition of modem industry that would justify the label in this But to Temin the mere occurrence of markets is enough to justify
particular context, especially in view of a whole series of studies the claim. "If about seventy-five per cent of the population of the
that have emphasised the large differences to the modem world Roman Empire wasengaged in farming, then it is not unreasonable
in the production of ancient fine ware. 42 Apparently the mere to suppose that over half of production was carried on by house-
existence of branch workshops, maintaining connections with a holding rather than by market exchanges", he observes undeterred.
mother unit, is taken as sufficient "proof. But we find Assyrian For, according to Temin, the prevalence of households in organ-
merchants establishing branches in other cities in the early second ising economic activity does not mean that peasant production
millennium BC. In fact, the very same archaeological excavations was not determined by the market, only "that most of eachfarm s
have shown, and mapped with increasing detail, that production activities were devoted to maintaining its workforce".47 This will
remained decentralised and not just confined to a few centres or not do; it is an attempt to explain away the fact that for most
large workshops. Ironically, Rostovtzeff himself, the leading pro- peasants, the market will only have constituted a subsidiary outlet
ponent of the old-style modemism, saw precisely this as what anddidnotprovide themwiththeirprimary meansof subsistence.
marked the limits to the modern nature of the Roman economy.
The technological and economic advantages to be gained from a 44 Temin200[: 181.
concentration of capital and production in large units were insuf- 45 Cf. the cautious analyses ofPersson 1999 and Erdkamp 2005. See Osbome 1996 for
an interesting study of some link-up between market and production in the archaic age.
ficient to produce and sustain an industrial development, modem But that does not make the economy as a whole a conglomeration of interdependent
style. 43 markets, cf. Morley 2007: 96.
46 A later MIT working paper by Kessler andTemin (2005) reasserts this claim of such
Second, the nature of the market in the Roman world. Finley Empire-wide integration based on a good handful ofprice observations scattered across
tooktheseeminglyunproblematicalviewthattheancienteconomy several centuries. The scarcity ofobservations, however, only serves to reinforce the pat-
tem detected, the authors declare optimistically. That is methodologically unwarranted;
there is simply far too little data even to begin that form of analysis. An Empire-wide
40 Whittaker 1995:22. 4I Kenrick 1993:36. SeealsoWilson2001. study of market integration on the basis of price data is beyond our reach. At best,
42 Cf.Fulle 1997andPrachner1980ontheorganisationofltalicterrasigillataproduction, and even that is debatable, the price data recovered from Egypt may allow us a broad
stressing the limited scale of most potteries and the importance of travelling potters. impression of conditions in one province. See Chapter 3 of this book for what can
Furtheron the interpretationofGallicterrasigillataproduction, seethediscussionsby hesitantly be achievedand with the opposite conclusion.
Woolf 1998, chapter 7 and Whittaker2002. Seminal are Goudineau 1974 and Marsh 47 Temin 2001: 180. The observation that even in today's rich societies a large part of
1981. economic activity is still kept within the family misses one crucial distinction. Most
43 Rostovtzeff 1957: 172-179. See Larsen 1976 for the organisation of early Assyrian middle-classhouseholdsdependonwageincomefortheirsubsistence,whereaspeasants
merchants. have historically produced their own subsistenceoutside the market.

30 31
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY BEYOND THE ANCIENT ECONOMY'!

A peasant household, therefore, cannot easily be abstracted to the solution, Herder-style, was the most appealing. This meant under-
model of a profit-orientated firm, as Temin seems to be doing; lining the differences between "us" and "them" and subsequently
its primary objective was different, the reproduction of the family seeking to understand the logic governing "the other" rather than
unit. In other words, even on Temin's own premises more than half applying our own habitual notions of normalcy.
of the Roman economy was not organised as "a conglomeration To the critics, however, it is exactly that approach which is
of interdependent markets". The question of a market economy the central problem. Here are Peregrine Harden and Nicholas
in the Roman Empire is clearly less straightforward than Temin Purcell: "The consequence has inevitably been to devalue practices
allows. which cannot be usefully seen as embryonic modernity.. . For
On closer inspection the various modernising uses of concepts, the telescopic perspective encourages the itemizing of absences
which have been explored here, seem to a large extent to have been and shortfalls ... Ultimately, however, the project was sabotaged
guided less by analytical than by value judgements. A clear indi- by the use of the 'minimalizing' comparative technique. Its trust
cator is the recurrent use of terms such as "complex" and "sophis- remained essentially negative: a generation was taught... what
ticated", qualifying or supporting the descriptions. By themselves was not important in the pre-medieval Mediterranean. "50 The con-
these are almost empty words, meaning as little as "not primi- trasting comparisons between the ancient and the early modern
tive" or "something not inferior". Struggling to free themselves world, inherent in the Weberian approach, are (mis)perceived as a
from the confident shadow of nineteenth-century evolutionism, derogatory portfolio of defects and flaws - in the Italian archae-
twentieth-century social anthropologists have taught us that there ologist Carandini's words "an annihilation of the past" and "self-
is no such thing as a primitive culture, only imperceptive inves- deification of the modem world".5' But it is difficult to see how
tigators. Hence words such as complex and sophisticated often one could argue against a strongly modernist position, preferring
appear in texts mainly as apologetic or defensive value markers. A instead to emphasise the unique or historical characteristics of the
remark made in connection with a discussion of ancient accounting Greco-Roman world, without showing the contrasts and differ-
by historianWilliamHarris illustrates my point neatly. Againstthe ences. That does not imply an essentially negative argument. On
claim that the ancient agricultural writers did not show any signs the contrary, it is the central point in Weber's and Finley's analyses
of modern economic rationality and capitalist accounting prac- that we find a world governed by other principles: the dominance
tices, the objection is voiced: "But Columella has in turn been of agriculture, the dependence of urbanisation on aristocratic con-
defended."49ObservationsthattheGreeksandRomansstructured sumption, the importance of slavery and the all-pervasive influ-
their thinking about estate management on other principles than ence of an ideology of social status which privileged political over
those at the core of modem accounting and management theory, entrepreneurial activities.
are taken as making an implicit statement about their cultural short- In any case, the current dissatisfaction with comparisons focus-
comings and lack of rationality. But that is not the case; it only ing on the contrasts and differences between the Greco-Roman
means that they organised their thought in a fashion different from world and later European developments has brought about a very
some patterns which have been gaining ground since the birth of interesting change in the use of comparative history for the study of
modern capitalism.49 Essentially the problem is one of empathy. the ancient economy. Pioneered by works such as D'Arms' Com-
To Weber and Finley, as to most anthropologists, the culturalist merce and Social Standing, a number of scholars have taken up
the theoretical challenge of the "primitivist" position and begun in
4 Harris 1993: 25 (my emphasis). For a further example, see Rathbone 1991, a more systematic fashion to re-examine the relationship between
chapters 8-9.
49 Cf. Kehoe 1997; see Mickwitz 1937 for a classic analysis. See Tchernia 2005 for a
recent collection of papers dedicatedto this issue. Harden and Purcell 2000: 146. 5I Carandini l983a: 178-179.

32 33
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY BEYOND THE ANCIENT ECONOMY?

theeconomy oftheRomanEmpireandthatofmedievalandearly It is difficult to disagree strongly with Picket's position, stated


modem, capitalist Europe. Rather than differences and contrasts, it in such very general terms. It is certainly salutary to be reminded
is now similarities and analogies which are sought out and empha- in our comparisons that the scale anddimensionsof pre-industrial
sised.52 Observing that the Empire contained a number of very economies were of another, much smaller order than in the mod-
large cities, with the one million inhabitants of Rome at the apex, ern world, that they, so to speak, belong on the same baseline. 54
they justly note that only at a very late stage was the European However, this is not where the main argument is. Even Finley, for
economy able to equal that achievement. London, the largest city instance, emphasisedthat urbanisationin Greco-Roman antiquity
intheeighteenthcentury,didnotreacha millioninhabitantsbefore reached a historical high point, only equalled very late in history.
l8oo. Hence, for instance, they warn againstpostulating any sig- He also expressed strong doubts about relying too much on analo-
nificant difference in the size of the market. Instead, they take their gies furnished by anthropological studies of, say, gift-giving in
lead from the many developments in the study ofthe pre-industrial, much simpler societies. The market as a form of exchange was
still agrarian-based,Europeaneconomy,emphasisingtheslowness far too important in antiquity; and no one who has walked around
and limited extent of change. In the larger perspective, this was the Monte Testaccio - the man-made, almost eighth hill of Rome
a world, in the catchphrases coined by the French Annales histo- consisting (for the most part) of oil-bearing amphorae discarded
rians, of la longue duree or histoire immobile, where economic in the days of the Empire - can seriously doubt the existence of
change tended to be cyclical, caught as it was in the Malthusian quite large volumes of exchangewithin the RomanEmpire.55 But
trap where productivity gains in agriculture were underminedby Picket takes the analysis much further, constructing the Roman
growingpopulation.Thecrucialdevelopmentfirstcameaboutwith Empire closely on the model of early modern Europe. Thus a pic-
the Industrial Revolution around 1800. Until then the productive ture emerges where regions of relative low-level agriculture and
and technological base of society was organic and set clear limits only sparse urbanisation intermingle with dynamic, more modem
to growth. Faced with this more "primitive" or static version of centres dominated by highly specialised agriculture in the Dutch
early modern Europe, the Dutch historian and epigraphistHarry style, and towns relying more on trade and export manufacture for
Picketconcludesthatit isnowtime "finallyto call into questionthe their survival than on aristocratic consumption. Other contribu-
view of the primitivists that the world of the Roman Empire was tions to the debate point in the same direction when they suggest
so very different from later pre-industrial Europe as they claim. In thatthe Roman Empireshouldbeseenas a marketeconomy work-
this ... I would like to suggest that the economy of the Roman ing essentially at a level comparable to that of the Atlantic world
Empire was more closely related to the economy of pre-industrial in the eighteenth century. 56
Europeuntil the eighteenthcentury thanour owntime. "53 The problem with such analyses is that they depend on a very
loose use of the notion of functional equivalents. Being strongly
52 The approach was pioneered in studies of e. g. D'Arms 1981 and Schleich 1983. By disinclinedevento considerthepossibleimportanceofdifferences,
far the best and most important specimen is Picket 1990 which is a systematic attempt
to produce a synthesis of the Roman economy by analogy to early modern Europe
they tendto prefereitherto declarethemmarginalor automatically
(1400-1800).Otherexamples includeHarris 1993; van Nijf 1997;Laurence 1998 and
1999; Harris 2000; Harden and Purcell 2000; and Temin 2001.
53 "endlich die Auffassung der 'Primitivisten' in frage stellen, dass sich die Welt des
Romischen Reiches so wesentlich van der spateren vorindustriellen Europa under- 54 Nicolet 1988: 37-38 and e. g. Andreau i994b: 191 and 1995: 948 point in the same
scheidewiebehauptet.Indem. ..mochteichdieVermutungaussern,dassdieWirtschaft direction.
des RomischenReichesmit der Okonomie des vorindustriellen Europabis zum 18. Jh. 55 Finley 1970, 1975,chapter6 and1977,forinstance.OnMonteTestaccio,seeRodnguez-
vielleicht enger verbunden war als mit unserer Gegenwart" (my translation). Picket Almeida 1984; Blazquez Martmez and Remesal Rodriguez 1999-2001.
1990:28. 5 Temin 2001. Also Harris 1993:19.

34 35
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY BEYOND THE ANCIENT ECONOMY'7

assert that "the methods may have been different, but the economic
consequences are the same". 57 A discussion of the rank-size dis- From traditional Asia to early modern Eurasia
tribution of Roman towns is symptomatic. Referring to De Vries'
influential study ofurbanisation and urban networks in early mod- At first sight the persistent attraction of early modern Europe
ern Europe, Picket concludes that the rank-size distributions of as yardstick for the ancient world appears curious. The last half
Roman cities can be seen as roughly similar, even if admittedly century has seen a strong challenge building up to the notion of
there are some differences, especially among the very large cities European developments as the quintessential expression of history.
of the Roman and early modem world. In De Vries' study, how- Europe's paradigmatic status in world history has suffered consid-
ever, it is a central point that the shapeof urban systems is closely erable erosion and is no longer self-evident. Nonetheless, the
linked to the specificsocio-economicstructure ofanygivenpartic- current modernising trends in ancient history are not an isolated
ular society. Differencesat the top of urban hierarchies,therefore, phenomenon. Similar doubts about the legitimacy of analysing
oughtnotto be quickly brushedasideasofonly trivial importance; differences between "the West and the rest" have occurred in a
they may reflect significant differences in economic organisation whole range of disciplines. During the 1990S a rather curious
between the two societies. 5 Braudel, after all, argued that capital- debate took place between Marshall Sahlins and Gananath Obey-
ism was a higher-orderphenomenon,connectedprecisely with the sekere, both distinguished American anthropologists, about the
top of societal hierarchies in early modern Europe rather than the proper interpretation of Captain James Cook's death on Hawaii on
virtually immovable mass of peasant producers and small towns. 59 his second return, 14 Febmary 1779. To Sahlins the explanation
In Picket'sanalysis,however, this type of issueis simply bypassed has to be found in the particular cognitive and cultural universe
in favour of a broader, more inclusive understanding of "mod- of the Hawaiians. Unfortunately for Cook, his arrival was linked
ern" economic phenomena. But there is a price to be paid for to their calendar of religious ritual by the Hawaiians, who saw
such a manoeuvre: a potential loss of explanatory power. Ulti- him as their returning god Lono. Cook willingly played along, not
mately, the economies of early modern Europe and the Roman knowing that the festival part of the year would end in the king
Empire followed very different paths of development. The more re-establishing his primacy by appropriating the powers of Lono.
we downplay the differences, the less able are we to understand Even then nothing would have happened if Cook had not been
why.Thatis unsatisfactory.The aim shouldbeto findbetterhistor- forced by a broken mast to return after first having left the island.
ical models to help us elucidatetheparticular natureofthe Roman This action was perceived as a threat to the cosmic order where
economy.61 the king was now in command. That order had to be re-created
and Cook/Lono was killed so that his powers could properly be
passedto the king. To Obeysekeresucha culturalist interpretation
is the result of blatant racism, making a mockery of the cogni-
57 Picket 1990: 39: "die Methoden mogen verschieden sein, aber die Wirtschaftlichen tive abilities of the indigenous population and denying them their
Folgen sinddieselben"(my Englishtranslation). The method waspioneeredby D'Arms
1981:165-169.
rightful place within common humanity; of course, the Hawaiians
58 See Woolf 1997 for a discussion linking these differences to the presence of a single could tell the difference between a white explorer and their god.
unifying empire in the Romanworld. Instead he wants to render fuzzy the clear distinctions between the
59 Braudel 1982:455-457.
60 Picket 1990: 146. Similar in style is Harris 1993: 24, advising Love 1991 to adopt a visiting Westerner and the indigenous culture. One cannot avoid
more inclusive definitionof capitalism so as to make room for antiquity. De Vries 1990
explains his approachto urban networks.
' For a similar wish to transcend this problem cf. the introductions to Mattingly and 62 Hodgson in 1974 and 1993, presents one of the most thoughtful attempts to re-evaluate
Salmon 2001 and Manning and Morris 2005. the position of Europe in world history.

36 37
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY BEYOND THE ANCIENT ECONOMY?

West. Indeed, how could it possibly be in the present world? The came under the influence of Europe. Instead the main concern has
legacy of European imperialism is a heavy one and the romanticist been to establish a more global point of view and, in the words of
emphasis on the native cultural tradition has more often than not, Eric Wolf's influential book, include The People Without History.
quite understandably, been combined with a wish to gain access One of the most remarkable results of these endeavours is the
to the technological and economic resources of modernity. The American Islamist Marshall Hodgson's great work of comparative
scenes which one could see some years ago of Hindu nationalists history The Venture of Islam. Hodgson asked how world history
celebrating in the streets of Delhi because India had now joined the should be conceived before the establishment of European world
atomic powers are only an extreme illustration of a more general hegemony. His answer was to relegate Western feudalism to the
condition.66 In his essays on Istanbul, Orhan Pamuk, the great margins of the historical narrative. The dominant force in the world
novelist, has managed to capture well the tortured and complex from the seventh to the seventeenth century was, he observed, the
relationship between Westernising and "othering" in the cultural civilisation of Islam. Europe need not, in other words, be taken as
identity of third world countries: paradigmaticofhistory as such.68
The viciouscycle is fed by Westemisingintellectuals wholongto hearthepromi-
In the study of India and the Indian Ocean economy Hodgson's
nent writers and publishers of the West praise them for being like Westerners. analysis was foreshadowedby the Dutch historianJ. C. van Leur.
Writers like Pierre Loti, by contrast, make no secret of loving Istanbul and the In the 1930s he began to reject the notion of European superiority
Turkish people for the opposite reason: for the preservation of their Eastern par- right from the arrival of Vasco da Gama in the early sixteenth
ticularity and their resistance to things Western. In the days when Pierre Loti was century. European hegemony was a much later development, van
criticising Istanbullus for losing touch with their traditions, he had only a small
Leur maintained; during the first centuries of their presence the
following in Turkey, most of this ironically, among the Westemising minority.
But whenever the nation is embroiled in an international dispute, the Westemised influence and importance ofthe Europeans were only marginal and
literary elite makes an indignant peace with the "Turkophilism" of Pierre Loti's certainly amounted to far less than commercial, let alone political
highly sentimental andexoticwritings.67 control. This is how he drew the larger picture:
The position of being "other" both holds out a promise of autonomy Such an East, retiring into isolation, standing to one side along the path of the
and a danger of falling into the trap of the merely quaint and exotic, West, the path ofhurried activity, world trade, world economy, modem life, seems
an object of domination. to have been foreign to the eighteenth century. That century did not know any
superior Occident,nor any self-isolatingOrientno longerprogressingwith it. It
This problem of "empowerment" was accentuated by the pro-
knew a mighty East, a rich fabric of a strong, broad weave with a more fragile
cess of de-colonisation in the decades following the Second World Western warp thread inserted in it at broad intervals. 69
War. No longer was it possible for historians to regard the Western
world as the sole agent of social development, the faber histo- For a long period after the Portuguese first establishedtheir sea
riae, when it now became clear that history did not end with the empire in the Indian Ocean, Asia remained largely unaffected and
European colonial empires. Hence there has been a growing dissat- followed its own course of history. The application of European
isfaction with the traditional view of world history as the unfold- periodisations was therefore meaningless.
ing drama of Western development from the birth of civilisation in At a general level, van Leur's ideas have formed the basis of a
Mesopotamia through antiquity, the Middle Ages and Renaissance newparadigmwhichhasbeendeveloping sincethe SecondWorld
to modernity, leaving the rest of the world in the sidings until it War. One important implication of his view, which has emerged
withevergreaterclaritysincethe 1950s,istheexistenceofa strong,
EvenHuntington , chapters 4-5 sees how "indigenisation" and modernisation may
go together. Hodgson 1974.SeefurtherHodgson1993:44-71 and91-94.
Pamuk 2005: 213. 9 Van Leur 1955: 289.
40 41
BEYOND THE ANCIENT ECONOMY'?
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY
of northern India in the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries to a
independent. South and South-East Asian trading world and mer-
chant community before the beginning of European colonialism hierarchy of markets. 74
from themiddleoftheeighteenthcentury. 70The Asianmerchants Similar developments have taken place in other branches of
Asian or Oriental studies. In 1966 Maxime Rodinson coun-
proved to behighly competitive. Only in a certain restricted num-
ber of trades where the European chartered companies were able tered the widespread assumptions about the cultural blockage of
to impose their own terms ofcommerce didthey lose out. But for a Islam towards capitalism. In his analysis, he objected that even
long period they held their own in most other fields, restricting the Mohammed had been a trader and that the religion was, in many
influence of the Europeans to that of yet another participant in the ways, quite favourable towards mercantile activities; Islam and
already existing trading system. 71 In that respect, van Leur's ana- capitalism were not mutually incompatible. The following year,
lysis wasonly thebeginning. Stressing, like Finley,theclearlimits Goitein publishedthe first volume of his extraordinary account of
of commercial development in the pre-modern world, he empha- a community of Jewish traders centred in medieval Cairo, show-
sisedtheephemeral position oftradewithin"thehighlytraditional ing a strong andhighly developed commercial world. In Ottoman
agrarianworldstill basedcompletely onself-sufficiency, withlittle studies, the picture of a stagnant and inefficient empire in the
independent city life" and "closed village communities as social plunderinghandsofan Oriental despothasbeendiscarded.Before
and economic basis". 72 However, as the resilience of Indian and it became "the sick man of Europe" the Ottoman Empire had
other Asian merchants has been documented, the emphasis has been a strong and equal adversary with a flourishing economy,
changed markedly and is now placed rather on the large amounts a highly developed market sector and capital formation.75 Then
of trade and the vigorous commercial developments in that part there is China, where research seems to defy everything we take
of the world. As the controversial historian of early modern trade, for grantedaboutpre-industrialsocieties.JosephNeedhamandhis
team of assistants, for instance, have identified a strong scientific
Niels Steensgaard, hasremarked, it isasifthemyth ofthe immense
riches ofAsiahasbeen substitutedfor that ofthe static, traditional tradition under the various Chinese imperial dynasties, in many
Orient.73 Even so, the foundation of van Leur's judgement has ways the equal of Greek and, for a long time, European science.
suffered some erosion. The study of the allegedly autarkicIndian This is to say nothing of the spectacular rise in steel production
village communities, the archetype of traditional society, has all underthemedievalSongdynasty,not significantlysurpassedagain
but gone through a revolution. It is now clear that these villages before the Industrial Revolution, or the large internal rural com-
were not entirely closed economies but also entered into wider mercial developments under Ming and Ch'ing, all brought to our
marketing networks. For the Mughal Empire, its leading historian attention by scholars such as Elvin, Hartwell and Skinner.76
Irfan Habib has identified a long period of commercialisation of The result of all this has been a strong challenge to our very
the agricultural surplus provoked by the tax demands of the state. notion of modernity. As it has become increasingly clear that
Thishasbeenfollowedby seminalworksofscholarssuchasB.R. the concept of traditional society is difficult actually to locate
Grover, K. N. Chaudhuriand C. A. Bayly, linking the rural world empirically in the pre-industrial world, even in the archetypal case
of India, the very notion of differences between early modem
Europe and the other complex civilisations of Eurasia has come
7° Braudel 1984;Arasaratnam1990; Marshall 1993;Wills 1993;andDisney1995:484- 74 Habib (963; Graver 1966;Chaudhuri 1978;Bayly 1983.See Inden 1990:chapter4 on
535 areconvenientandshortoverviews.Formoredetailedtreatments, seeChaudhuri Indian village economies.
1985; 1990 and Das Gupta and Pearson 1987.
71 Steensgaard 19733: 405-41 (, though often misunderstood, is the best analysis of the 75 Inalcik 1969; Faroqhi 1991; Inalcik and Quataert 1994; Atfanir 1997. Bj0rkelo 1999 is
a convenient survey.
resilienceofAsianmerchants,togetherwithDasGupta 1979;Prakash1985;andBaner-
7 Some of their more optimistic conclusions may be in need of moderation. For some
jee 1990.
72 Van Leur 1955, quotations from 283 and 282. 73 Steensgaarcl 1987. cautionary critiques, see Finlay 2000 and Wagner2001.

42 43
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY BEYOND THE ANCIENT ECONOMY?

under strong attack. In the now classic, if controversial, Oriental- continent in modernising today. The many, presently, much more
ism (1978) and the sequel Culture andImperialism(1993) it was successful Asian economies can, on the other hand. be seen as
argued by Edward Said that the differences were but a romantic the result of a much greater infrastructural compatibility between
fiction of the Europeanmind, longing for the exotic. This was in EastandWestwhichultimately datesbackto common roots in the
the best case. In the worst, they were an imperialist construction Bronze Age and the rise of civilisation. This shared legacy consists
designed to dominate the colonised societies. Thus static tradi- in the development of similar socio-economic institutions which
tional society with all its connotations ofcommunal heart-warming Goody summarises as social stratification, literacy, specialisation,
Gemeinschaft and lack of commercial activity had not been there division of labour and a mercantile capitalism.80 The result was
before. Rather, it was imposed on the dynamicAsian societiesby a series of complex and broadly similar pre-industrial agrarian
the colonialist regimes - a case of the development of underde- economies shaped by Smithian market dynamics and Malthusian
velopment. 77 Understandably, we are now called upon to undo the constraints, to borrow a set of concepts developed within late
wrong and re-admit these societies into modernity. Here is Sanjay imperial Chinese history by R. Bin Wong and more extensively by
Subrahmanyam, a prominent historian of South Asian economies: Kenneth Pomeranz. 81
"Having taken away so much from the societies of South Asia, it
seems to be high time that social science at least gave them back From "primitive" capitalism to agrarian empire
what they had by the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries - their
admittedly very ambiguous 'early modernity'. "78 FIowever, it is difficult not to feel a little uneasy about this attempt
If the developments in the study of the economy of the Roman to inscribe capitalism into the DNA string of civilisation as such.
Empire are added, an image gradually emerges of a very old pre- There is a very real danger of doing away with most of human
industrial Eurasian world of comparable high cultures. Lately,
history, lumping it together under the same heading as a mir-
there have been a number of attempts to synthesise this condi-
ror image of early modern Europe: a kind of Eurocentrism by
tion. Most radically, some have posited the existence of an all- the backdoor. Of course, on a very broad, minimal, definition
embracing world system of long-distance trade across Eurasia such as the existence of market trade, generating Marx's famous
since the Bronze Age, determining the fate of its constituent soci-
sequence ofM(oney)-C(ommodity)-M(oney), capitalism probably
eties. However,thatisanextremeposition,consideringthelimited has to be seen as ubiquitous in civilised societies. However, market
amounts of trade passing across the Eurasian land mass. 79 Rather trade already provides conceptual coverage for that phenomenon.
more challenging are the recent attempts to reinvigorate a diffu- Capitalism, on the other hand, will always remain linked to the
sionist approach to the study of historical societies. So far, the developments culminating in the Industrial Revolution. True, the
CambridgeanthropologistJackGoodyhasprovidedthemost sys- link was a complex one rather than a linear progression, as E. A.
tematically worked-through version of this line of thought. To Wrigley insisted two decades ago. The Netherlands, which had
him the great divide does not run between Europe and Asia but spearheaded economic developments in the seventeenth century,
between Eurasia and black Africa. The latter never shared in the
fell behind during the eighteenth century and failed to make the
Bronze Age urban revolution and this explains the problems of the
transition to coal and steam till relatively late. The Dutch, though,
77 Wolf1982isthemostsystematicattempttodevelopthisidea.Morenuanceddiscussions
of Indiacanbe found in Bayly 1988:chapter5; Breckenridgeand van der Veer 1993;
and Bayly 1999. 80 Goody 1990; 1996; 1998: l-26. Perlin 1983; 1993.
78 Subrahmanyam1998: loo and l990b. Seealso Pomeranz2000. 81 Pomeranz 200odeveloping anideaofWong 1997:Part (. FurtherGoldstone 1998:2002.
79 Frank and Gills [993 and Frank 1998, inspired by Schneider 1977 and Abu-Lughod SeeParthasarathi2002 for a critique ofPomeranz,pointingout that he underestimates
1989.SeeSubrahmanyam 1996:xv-xvi for a Scepticalnote. the importanceofEuropeanmarketdevelopments andstatepolicies.

44 45
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY BEYOND THE ANCIENT ECONOMY?

had begun to use peat on an extensive scale for production pur- I donot advocateintroducinga banoncomparisonsbetweenthe
poses, but their industries lost out to protectionist competition Roman Empire and early modern Europe. Recently, for instance,
from French and British manufacturers.82 Capitalism was gradu- attention has been called to a possible similarity in the effects
ally coming together to drive economic development in a system that eighteenth-century London and early imperial Rome had on
which transcended individual countries and produced a dynamic their respective hinterlands. The two capital cities were of com-
succession of leading economies, as Braudel described it in the parable size and both represented an enormous concentration of
final volume ofhis great work on capitalism. Why these develop- spending power; the effects of Rome on her hinterland might have
ments took place in early modern Europe rather than somewhere been parallel to those of London on hers, where the rising demand
else is a question that cannot be avoided, indeed should not, con- of the city generated economic development in the countryside,
sidering their world-shattering effects. Of course, there is a risk marked by rising productivity and an increased commercialisation
of seeming Eurocentric in providing answers. But that should be of agriculture. 85 But we also need to explore the limits to this
treated as a challenge, not as an excuse to brush aside the issue. comparison. The enormous spendingpower of the Roman market
Thetaskconfronting us isto provide explanations ofearly modem was the result of the concentration in that city of a large part of the
European developments without denying the existence of histori- resources generated by a territorial empire spanning the Mediter-
caldynamicsinotherculturesandtimes. 83HereneitherGoodyand raneanworld with a population ofperhaps 60 million. In 1750, on
Pomeranz. nor Picket, with their strong determination to identify the other hand, when London's population reached 700,000, she
analogies and parallel patterns, have much to say. Yet, if the basic still had to rely mainly on the British Isles and a few commercial
tenor of their argument is correct, suggesting answers seems more colonies and outposts around the world, in all comprising a popu-
necessary than ever, unless we have given up trying to understand lation in the order of magnitude of say 10 million. In comparison
the different trajectories of world history. To cite a recent col- with the ancient imperial metropolis, London's resource base was
lection of papers, we need a kind of historiography "committed much smaller. The English capital had to compensate by making
neither to justifying European domination, nor to explaining it much larger earningsfrom foreign trade than did Rome to finance
away".84 its consumption.86
The relationship between empire, concentration of spending
82
Wrigley 1988. Jongman 2006 takes Wrigley to show deye lopments
that the economic
power and commercialisation-cum-growth was first brought to the
preceding industrialisation wereunimportant, andthatthereistherefore little todistin-
guishearlymoderncapitalism.WhileI agreewithJongmanthatweneednotshapeour forefront of the debate on the economy of the Roman Empire by
analyses of the ancient economy on the early modem model, his reading of Wrigley Keith Hopkins, three decades ago. 87Taking his point ofdeparture,
is an overinterpretation. Wrigleydescribestheperiodof vigorouspre-industrialeco- like Weber and Finley, from the politically defined consumption
nomicdevelopment as a necessaryprecondition,but not an automaticguaranteefor
an industrial breakthrough (l988:'ll-l2, 113-118). Even so, Wrigley's vision of the patterns of the agricultural surplus, he drew attention to the way
processremainsheavilyAnglocentricandpayslittleattentiontotheoveralldynamicof these were modified by the creation of large empires. 88 A part of
theemerging capitalist system. Thatwould havecome out moreclearly ifhehadalso
includedprocessesofstateformationandmilitarycompetition,cf.McNeill1982(mil- the resources which had formerly been available to the multitude
itarycompetition);Wong 1997:chapter6 (comparativedifferencesin stateformation of local cities around the Greco-Roman world was now confis-
betweenEuropeandChina);DeVriesandWoude1997(onthemodemcharacterofthe
Dutch economy). catedandredirectedto serve the purposes of the Roman imperial
83 OnthislatteraspectI agreewithMorley2007:6-9,butthatdoesnotrequirethestudent
ofancienttradetoplaydownthedifferencestoearlymoderncapitalism Landes1998: 85 Hopkins 1995-6:59;Morley 1996.
415-418 is a pointed, 'if perhaps too strong, critique ofthis basically Saidian tendency 86 PaceMorley 1996:29,whotendstounderestimatethesignificanceofthisdifference.
to ignoreortonedownthequestionofdifferences Pearson 1991:45;Wong 1997: 1-8, SeeWrigley [987: chapter6 andReed 1996for theeconomyofLondon.
andBayly2000insistonthecontinuedneedtodifferentiateourimageofpre-industrial 87 Hopkins l978a;1980;19830;l983b;and 1995-6.
Eurasia. SeenowalsoErdkamp2001onthesimilaritiesofthe"consumercity"andHopkins'
84 Manning and Morris 2005: 9. model.

46 47
BEYOND THE ANCIENT ECONOMY?
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY

authorities. Basically, that meant that they were channelled to I do not share the confidence of this conjecture in its reliance
Rome, the capital of the Empire, and the army, stationed along on functional equivalents. A basic, if rarely noted, premise of
the frontiers. Since many of these taxes were, presumably, paid in Hopkins' argument is that there is no such thing as the market,
coin or at some stage after delivery in kind, sold on the market and in the abstract general sense. It is not just out there, happening
on its own. Rather, it needs to be created and often even pressed
converted into money, most areas of the Empire where there was
or forced into existence under pre-industrial conditions. Hence it
no government spending would have hadto earn their tax money
becomes crucial to understand how the particular markets are artic-
backif they were goingto continue to beableto paytheirannual
taxes and not run out of coin. The result was a limited growth and ulated, howthey are moulded and shapedby the social andpolitical
commercialisation process where taxpayers around the Empire institutions of society and the context in which they appear. This,
entered the market to earn their tax money, and export flows of of course, was Polanyi's point and the one that has survived the
manufactured products arose between the areas in tax deficit and many empirical criticisms of his economic models. It has even
entered the mainstream of economics through the institutional
those in surplus.
Hopkins' model hasjustly attracted much attention. Not surpris- analysis of DouglassNorth.92 In this particular instance, the rela-
tive weaknessoftherising nation state andits consequentreliance
ingly, 'giventhecurrent climate ofdiscussion, many haveempha-
sised the elements dealing with growth and commercialisation, onprivateloanscannotjust bereducedto a matterofconsumption
whereas the limits to these processes and the close affinity of the in relation to the economy. A main result of that situation was
model with that of "the consumercity" tend to be ignoredor dis- the formation of an efficient international market in capital. The
missed. 89Hopkins hasevenbeencriticised forunderestimating the development began when the large medieval fairs of Europe were
amount oftrade and the penetration of market forces in the Roman turned into meeting places for the rich banking firms, connected
Mediterranean. 90 Here, Harry Picket's endorsement and the spe- with the European monarchs, where they could settle accounts and
cial twist he gives to the taxes-and-trade model are of particular deal in bills of exchange. Gradually, as the scale of transactions
interest. Rejecting itsWeberianfoundations, hesetsoutto compare increased, more permanent structures became necessary and in
thetax system oftheRomanEmpirewiththatoftheearlymodem the seventeenth century this function was taken over by the stock
European nation states. He stops atthe need ofthe latter to borrow exchanges of Amsterdam and London. During the same period
from private financiers and the gradual creation of a permanent, the government debts of the Netherlands and England were put
on a more stable basis in the form of negotiable, interest-bearing,
funded government debt. This institution is wholly lacking in the
bonds. Thus this line of investment was now effectively opened up
Roman Empire. In Picket's view, this is a reflection ofthe greater
strength ofthe imperial state; it did not need to resort to such to groups other than the closed cliques of leading financiers. The
measuresto finance'itsactivities. It could simply rely on taxingits result was an important extension of investment opportunities for
subjectsdirectly. Fromaneconomicperspective, however,thetwo commercial capital. 93 The point is that such an institutional devel-
fiscal regimes would have produced similar results. In both cases opment seems to be largely absent from the Roman Empire. We
the state absorbedthe wealth of its citizens and created a similar do find a hierarchy of periodic fairs and markets. However, they
amount or kind of economic activity through its consumption. 91 remained, to a very large extent, gathering places where the rural
population could sell its surplus production and have its limited
8t) SeeErdkamp2001 for a similarview of the"consumercity .
90 SeePaterson1998:153andPicket1990forcritiquealongtheselines.Greene1986isa 92 Steensgaard 1981; 1984 and Lane 1966: 383-428 are some of the most perceptive
typicalexampleemphasisingcommercialisationandgrowth.Themodelhasalsobeen analyses of the close bonds between markets and the socio-political formation. See
criticised from more "primitivist" perspectives, e. g. Jongman 1988; Whittaker 1989; further Polanyi, Arensberg and Pearson 1957; North 1990; and Morris 2002.
Duncan-Jones 1990; and Whittaker 1995.
93 De Vries 1976: chapter7 and Braudel 1982: 8i-l 14.
'" Picket 1990: 39 and 46-47.
49
48
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY BEYOND THE ANCIENT ECONOMY?

needs for market services supplied. The larger fairs also seem to be seen as the result of profits generated from the administration
have played a role in regional and interregional trade. A few even of Mediterranean trade. Rather, their success came about because
developed into important foci of long-distance trade, such as the they controlled an unusually large hinterland which provided them
one on Delos. But they do not appear to have fulfilled the role of with a vast agricultural surplus, especially in olive oil, that could
"international"credit markets. We should, perhaps,ratherturn our be exported.97 In other words, Picket tends to ignore the fact that
attention to the cities. Here we do, of course, find market build- differences in social organisation produce the articulation or dom-
ings and squares, but there is nothing to suggest that they would inance of very different economic interests. The Roman Empire
have operated on lines resembling those of the formalised stock may, on very rare occasions, have allowed considerations about
exchanges of seventeenth-century Amsterdam and London. What the safety of its traders against encroachments in foreign countries
is more, on Picket's interpretation of the taxes-and-trade model, to enter into decisions about war and peace. But that is a very
stressing the absence of government debt, we would not expect far cry from the active strategies of Dutch merchants in the seven-
this either.94 teenth century, successfully waging war around the globe to secure
Nor should we, asPicket concedes, expect any kind ofbourgeois and conquer markets. Here commerce was the dominant motive.
developmentgivingriseto a classoflargemerchantsandfinanciers Could we imagine the Roman Empire in a situation like that of the
able to challenge the economic preponderance of the political elite Spanish Habsburgs fighting on and off against the Dutch rebels for
based in landed wealth. However, that cannot just be written off as eighty years and in the end depending on the very same Dutchmen
a difference in social structure. It had economic consequences as to provide credit to finance their armies? It all came to an end in
well. It would, for instance, be difficult to imagine a situation like 1648 when the Dutch merchants finally decided that peace was
that described by Braudel for the West Indies, where the plantation more profitable than war, and shut their coffers. 98
ownersoften hadlargeproblems makingendsmeet whilethe mer- In a historical perspective this early modern European develop-
chants who bought their produce and sold it back in Europe made ment, often described in the convenient shorthand ofmercantilism,
huge profits. 95 Indeed, in the Roman Empire things took place in appears to be very much the exception, a unique occurrence."
the opposite fashion. Wealthy landowners remained firmly in the Adam Smith sensed this clearly when he chose in The Wealth of
driving seat. In parting with their produce, they seem generally Nations to portray the preceding centuries of European economic
to have been able to shift most of the risk onto the commercial history as a perversion of the natural hierarchy between agricul-
middlemen, to judge from the business procedures envisaged in ture, manufacture and commerce. The so-called mercantile sys-
legal regulations and prevailing forms of contract. 96 This impres- tem had allowed the merchants too much power and far too many
sion is confirmed by what we know about elite mobility in the privileges, and had made it possible for them to appropriate and
Empire. The crucial component seems to have been access to large control a disproportionately large part of the total wealth of soci-
agricultural resources; it was the cities with the largest and rich- ety to the detriment of the overall well-being of the economy. This
est countrysides available that proved most successful in getting should, according to Adam Smith, now be brought to an end; the
members of provincial elites promoted into the imperial aristoc- leading position of agricultural production should be recognised
racy. The spectacular rise of members of the elite of North African and mercantilist policies abandoned. The principle of laissez-faire
Lepcis Magna, culminating in the Severan emperors, should not
97 See Mattingly I988b on LepcisMagna's aristocracy; Syme 1977 and Corbier 1991:223
for the situation in general.
94 Finley 19853: 195-196,confirmedby deLigt 1993andFrayn 1993.OnDelos,seeRauh 98 Burke 1988: 229-230. On Dutch trade, see Israel 1989. See to Cascio 1991 and
1993- See Andreau 1999: chapter 11, pace Harris 2006, for the relative weakness of the Andreau l994a and 2003 for the relationship between market and government in the
financial "sector" in the Roman economy. Roman Empire. Harris 2003 effectively confirms their description.
95 Braudel 1982: 272-280. 96 Morley 1996: [59-166. 99 Gellner l988b; Pearson 1991.

50 51
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY BEYOND THE ANCIENT ECONOMY?

would then operate to restore the proper and economically most of East Africa. 103 The scale of operations was truly magnificent.
beneficial relationship between the different sectors of the econ- The first expedition is believed to have been made up of some
omy. '00 We are a far cry from the horizons of modern-day free 28,000 men and perhaps up to 255 ships of varying sizes, inclucl-
trade enthusiasts. Indeed, it is striking when one reads through the ing 62 enormous treasure ships. This was far beyond anything the
pages of The Wealth of Nations how Smith's vision of the Chinese small European states at that time could even dream of achieving.
Empire, resting on the backs of a multitude of hard-working peas- The handful of Portuguese ships that began to arrive in the Indian
ants and a large internal market, in some respects came quite close Ocean at the end of the fifteenth century would have been no match
to his ideal of the natural relationship between agriculture and for these gigantic fleets. This has led a number of scholars to ask
trade. 101 why it was not the Chinese who sailed around Africa and began to
China may even be much closer to the historical norm than the establish colonies in Europe.
liberal Smith, who also saw oppression and consequent distortion As it happened, the Chinese had already aborted their expe-
of the economy caused by the political elite, would have liked to ditions when the Portuguese arrived. A mounting Mongol threat
admit. In post-war scholarship the Chinese Empire has, in analyti- on the inner Asian frontier, a war in Vietnam and the building of
cal contrast to Europe, come to represent the more normal pattern Beijing as the new capital strained imperial finances. In 1421 the
of development, where a political elite, depending on agricultural undertakingof newexpeditionswascalled offtemporarily. A final
rent-taking, is able to dominate the commercial groups of society. voyage was completed between 1431 and 1433 before the project
The locus classicus ofthis literature is a counterfactual explanation was finally abandoned. In 1436 the building of new sea-going ves-
of why China, clearly the leading economic power in the world sels was prohibited, and the crews and resources were channelled
around 1400, eventually lost its lead to Europe. 102 In the thirteenth into traffic on theGrandCanal andpublic buildingactivities. After
century a brisk trade had developed in South East Asia, dominated a few years the know-how necessary to resume the expeditions
by Chinese merchants. But when the Ming dynasty took over from had been lost. The scene was set for the Portuguese and other
the Mongols in 1368 this foreign trade was prohibited. Instead Europeans to embark on the slow and very gradual road towards
the authorities tried to control contacts with the world outside and dominance. This is as far as the counterfactual will take us. Nor-
attempted to organise foreign exchange relations within a large mally, the ills of despotism or Confucian dislike of eunuchs and
imperial tribute system. As a consequence a number of very large trade are called upon to explainthis historical "mistake". A closer
naval expeditions, headed by the legendary eunuch admiral Zheng look, however, reveals that the very size of the Chinese expe-
He, were sent out from China between 1405 and 1433, navigating ditions marks a very significant difference from the much more
the South China Sea and the Indian Ocean, even reaching the coast commercially motivated European fleets. There was no way that
the stupendously costly activities of Zheng He could ever have
'"° Smith 1976: 276-85, 360-427 and Book 4. Smith's analysis lives on in the new eco- beenprofitablein a commercial sense.Theyhaveto beunderstood
nomic history which downplays the significance of foreign trade to eighteenth-century within the more "traditional" framework of the imperial tribute
Britain, e. g. Wrigley [987 and 1988. The argument ignores the contribution of a much
strengthened commercial infrastructure (institutions), that is simply taken for granted, system. The motives were never commercial and it would be a
cf. O'Brien 1998. mistake to see them as an abortive attempt to establish a com-
101 It isno coincidencethatElvin'sclassicanalysisoflate imperial China(1973),describing
thecountry ascaughtin a high-levelequilibriumtrap, is rightout ofthepagesofSmith mercial world-system, in what would become the European style.
(as is Pomeranz 2000). Smith expected something similar to happen for England, They were intended to announce the might of the Ming emperor
Wrigley 1988.
'"2 McNeill 1982: chapter 2. See further Wallerstein l974a; Jones 1981; 1988;and Landes
1998. '"3 See Dreyer 2007 for the history of the these fleets.

52 53
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY BEYOND THE ANCIENT ECONOMY'.'

andbring foreign princes to recognise his suzerainty by rendering had always failed in Europe whereas they seemed to prosper in
tribute. 104 Asia. The reasons for this "failure" are now sought in the feudal
Such an interpretation would also help to make sense of the society that arose in Europe after the disintegration of the west-
situation prevailing in the following centuries, where the ban on ern parts of the Roman Empire. 10 An important characteristicof
foreign trade was upheld for long periods. China is a large area to this social system was the fragile position of centralised forms of
control, and it turned out to be impossible to prevent even large power, which produced a very fragmented kind of social forma-
numbers of Chinese merchants setting out to sea. However, the tion split up into many small units. There were several attempts
ban meant that the merchants were, so to speak, outside the sphere to re-establish a strong imperial system in the European theatre.
recognisedby the state. Oneconsequencewas,thatthey oftenhad The dramatis personae include such prominent figures as Charle-
to depend on the protection of local Chinese gentry, who knew the magne, the Catholic Church and the Holy Roman Empire. Yet,
"value" of their service; another, that they were left in a vulnera- these ambitions always faltered, if sometimes only just, and suf-
ble position vis-a-vis the emerging aggressive European merchant fered their final defeat with the compromise in Augsburg in 1555.
empires. Thus we have examples of massacres in the Chinese This settlement left in tatters whatever was left of the dreams of
overseas trading communities carried out by various European the Habsburg emperor Charles V to unite most of Europe under his
nations without the Chinese imperial state paying much notice. It authority. Disillusioned, the emperor left it to his brother Ferdinand
did not recognise the existence of these traders. In other words, the to negotiate the peace and instead began to organise his abdica-
interests of the commercial groups in Chinese society were never tion in the following year. This saw the division of the Habsburg
articulated to the same extent as those behind European mercan- heritage into an Austrian and a Spanish branch.
tilist policies. 105 Therefore we do not find attempts by the state to Instead of an empire, a system of smaller competing states grad-
support the formation of commercial institutions as powerful as ually evolved out of the feudal world. Yet, central royal power
those developed in cooperation by Europeanmerchants and states remained relatively weak against the multitude of feudal baronies.
to strengthen and stabilise the market system - state bonds, joint For our purposes, the most important result of this state of affairs
stock companies and the like. It follows that we should imagine the was that the king often had to ally with mercantile groups to con-
ChineseEmpire as going along quite anotherhistorical trajectory. solidate his authority. This brought these groups into much closer
It was not a tailed or trapped move towards what we have come to proximity to state power than had been the case historically. To
understand as modernisation. 10 begin with, this gave rise to the numerous strong medieval cities
Montesquieu more than 250 years ago provided an important where the merchants were allowed freedom of rule to a very large
clueto the understandingof the reasonsofthis development, when degree. Sometimes they even became the government, such as in
he seizedon the difference in state formation processes. 107 Focus- the rich communes of northern Italy, with Venice, Florence, Pisa
ing his attention, as did many Enlightenment intellectuals, on the and Genoa leading the way, and in the northern parts of Europe with
large Asian empires facing Europe and its traders, such as the the Hanseatic league. Trade and the interests of commerce were
Ottoman Empire, SafavidPersia,Mughal IndiaandCh'ing China, fast becoming of great importance to the state. As arms technology
hewasstruck bythecontrasts andnotedthatlargeagrarianempires developed and became much more expensive, especially with the
104Pearson 1991: 104-105; Landes 1998:93-98. EIvin 1973: 220 describes the voyages
as "prestige ventures". In general, see the analysis ofDreyer 2007: chapters I and 3. Landes 1998: chapter 3, though too simplistic. For the general processes at work see
105 Elvin 1973: 215-225: Gungwu 1990. North and Thomas 1973; Anderson 1974; Wallerstein 1974: chapters 3-4; Braudel
" Wong 1997:chapters4-6 is a pertinentdemonstrationofthis. Pomeranz2000underes- 1981; Jones 1981; Braudel 1982: McNeill 1982; chapters 3-4; Braudel [984; Wickham
timates issues of state formation and institutions, cf. Bayly 2000 and Pamuk 2000. 1985; Mann 1986: chapters 12-15; Burke 1988; Jones 1988; Kennedy 1988: chapter2;
107 See Roberto 2003 for an interesting analysis ot'Montesquieu. Crone [989; Mauro 1990; Brady 1991; 0stergaard 1996; Bayly 2004.
54 55
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY BEYOND THE ANCIENT ECONOMY?

introduction of artillery andnew forms offortification designed to commercial rivalry. It was, quite simply, difficult to run a vast
withstand bombardment from cannons, royal power was strength- territorial empire along the same lines of policy.
ened in relation to the feudal barons, who could not afford the An early and almost too perfect illustration of the difference
new technology on their own. Centralisation followed and the between agrarian empires and the emerging new organisational
nation states ofEurope came into being. However, increased inter- forms in Europe is provided by the relationship between a num-
state competition and the enormous, continuously rising costs of ber of Italian merchant republics, with Venice in the forefront,
warfare caused by the ensuing arms race made it crucial for state and the surviving, Byzantine, part of the Roman Empire in the
powerto cooperate withallpropertied groupsofsociety inorderto first centuries of the second millennium. During a period ofpolit-
secure ever larger revenues. Thus the alliance with the commercial ical and military weakness the Byzantine emperor found himself
sections of society wascontinued; numerous measures, known in forced to concede various trading privileges to the Italian mer-
the convenient shorthand as mercantilism, were introduced, even chants in return for military support. In effect, a situation arose
aggressive warfare, in order to favour andpromote the interests of where the Empire's own merchants were put at a disadvantage in
the traders of each nation, with the motive of generating as much Constantinople in comparison to the Italian merchants - this was
income aspossible. Themilitary balanceofpowernow wenthand mercantilist protectionism stood on its head. The point about this
in hand with an unprecedented kind ofeconomic interstate rivalry. is not its "perversity" from a European point of view, as Donald
The result was a much strengthened and stabilised institutional Treadgold, the author of a recent synthetic history of the Byzan-
base for the mercantile sector of society. '09 tine Empire, would have us believe. It is rather that the economic
Characteristically, the states which formed the closest alliance weight of the commercial groups was normally simply not suffi-
with the commercial parts of society proved strongest during the ciently important in a large agrarian empire, which could draw on
seventeenth and eighteenth centuries. Hence the spectacular rise income from huge masses of peasants, ever to give rise by itself to
of the Dutch Netherlands and the repeated British victories over a similar strong position for the mercantile sections of society.
much larger France. On the face of it, one would have expected it This does not mean that merchants in such imperial formations
to be otherwise, given the fact of French absolutism and the need were entirely powerless. We can turn to the richest trading city of
for the weaker British state/king to come to terms with parliament. the Mughal Empire, Surat, in the eighteenth century for indica-
Voltairecapturedthe situationvividly whenhe noted that tions of the limits within which they could act. Rising up against
an unusually extortionate governor, the rich merchants of the city
WhathasmadeEnglandpowerfulis thefactthatfromthetimeofElizabeth,all actually managed to drive him out of the town. But that was the
parties have agreedon thenecessity offavoring commerce. The sameparliament
thathadthekingbeheadedwasbusywithoverseastradingpostsasthoughnothing end of it. There was no attempt at systemic change, and they had
washappening.ThebloodofCharlesI wasstill steamingwhenthisparliament, to settle for a new governor, belonging to the nobility. Thus the old
composed almost entirely offanatics, passedthe Navigation Act of 1650. "° order was restored. "3
All this makes early modern Europe a very bad guide indeed
Interestingly, amongthe statescontendingfor a dominantposi- for understanding the economies of the large agrarian empires of
tion in Europe, it was Habsburg Spain - the state formation most Eurasian history. Quite simply, they do not appear to provide any
resembling an old-style territorial empire - in spite of all her gold
and silver flowing in from the New World, that proved least able
to accommodate the demands of the new situation of intensified ''' Wallerstein >974a: chapter 4; De Vries 1976: 249-250; North 1990: 112-1 15.
''2 Treadgold 1997: chapters 18-21, especially pp. 699-706. On p. 704 the situation is
described as "the perverse policy of reverse protectionism". Pearson 1991 and Wong
iw) Hont 2005. De Vries 1976 is excellent on the resulting institutional arrangements. 1997: chapter 6 make the point in general for these empires.
"° Cited from Landes 1998: 234. See also Gellner l988b: 114-115. ' '3 Das Gupta 1979: Chapter 4.

56 57
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY BEYOND THE ANCIENT ECONOMY?

strong parallel to the pattern of institutional developments we find empires were, for all we know, not on the same path of historical
in the competitive state system of the early modern period. The, development. The strategy of reverting to explanations of the func-
at times, very large observable amounts (hence the modernising tional equivalent type is ultimately unsatisfying, as I tried to argue
critiques of "othering" analyses) of trade in these empires were from the example of Picket. Being mainly defensive in character,
located in a different structural and institutional setting. In some it only succeeds in taking a very narrow view of the phenomena
respects, the empires even seem incompatible with the expanding and ignoring their markedly different contexts. For the study of the
capitalism of the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries. There is a Roman imperial economy this carries, at least, two implications.
strong argument that they may have fallen victim to its develop- First, it is time, finally, to abandon the tyranny of Europe over
ment. A large and growing literature focuses on how the Ottoman Rome. The unusual pattern of European history cannot do service
Empire found it very difficult to keep up with European develop- as a yardstick to measure the very different imperial experience.
merits and was gradually undermined and incorporated into the Second, in terms of comparative history it seems reasonable to
European economic system. "4 The Mughal Empire had disin- suggest that analogous or parallel comparisons to help understand
tegrated before the beginning of the British conquest of India, the institutional and structural characteristicsof the Empire should
though there were perhaps signs that a reestablishment of imperial rather be sought among the Asian empires that so impressed the
authority wasimminent under the leadership of one or other ofthe Enlightenment intellectuals.
Mughal successor states. In the event, it all came to nothing with Certainly, in terms of sheer scale, the Asian empires constitute
the rise of British supremacy. More important from our point of a much more fitting parallel to the Roman world. From a histori-
view is thepossibility that theinitial weakening ofimperial author- cal perspective, all of them, like Rome, are characterised by quite
ity came about through the increased involvement of India in the substantial amounts of trade and urbanisation. They also seem to
growing European worid-system. The resulting large imports of show significant similarities in the structural location of commer-
bullion into the Indian economy as payment for spices and cot- cial groups and the market sector in society. In respect to state for-
ton calicoesmay havecontributedto underminingthe established mation, they represent an alternative path of development during
power structure. "5 The humiliating defeat of the Chinese Empire the early modern period to that experiencedby Europe. While the
in the Opium War (1839-42) spelled out to the authorities the need feudal fragmentation of Europe eventually crystallised into a sys-
for modernisation and industrialisation. But this proved a goal dif- tem characterisedby medium-sized states, these empires emerged
ficult to achieve within the already existing system. Eventually as hegemonic powers dominatingtheir regions. The establishment
"industrialization did take place in twentieth-century China, but of the Ming dynasty in 1368, later succeded by the Ch'ing in
this China was no longer an agrarian empire. ""6 1648, saw the restoration of a Chinese Empire dominating East
Thus it appears futile to insist on envisaging these empires in Asia. During the fifteenth and sixteenth centuries, the Ottoman
analogy to the competitive system of more or less mercantilist sultans conquered vast stretches of the Mediterranean and Mid-
nation states arising in early modem Europe. Such comparisons, die East. Finally, the Mughals rose to dominate India during the
whenscrutinisedclosely, seemdestinedtoendup in a catalogueof sixteenth and seventeenth centuries. None of these empires was
failures and near misses. The large traditional or classic agrarian initially locked into interstate competition to the same extent as the
emerging nation states of Europe. Therefore they were not under
'14 See Keyder 1997; Landes 1998; chapter 24; and Pamuk 2000 for brief surveys. Inalcik the same pressure to generate new revenues from their existing
and Quataert 1994: vol. 2, parts 3 and 4 for greater detail. Islamoglu-Inan 1987 and tax bases to survive, for instance by granting commercial privi-
Masters 1988 for world-system-inspired approaches.
115Steensgaard 199011.Wink 1989for re-establishmentofcentral control.
leges. Instead they enjoyed the benefits derived from expansion.
116Wong 1997: l5l. McNeill 1982: 257 aboutthe OpiumWar. Having conquered many of their neighbours, each of the empires
58 59
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY

controlled a much bigger agrarian economy than the European


monarchies. The imperial governments were able to field vast
armies by relying on collecting (land) taxes from their extensive
AN AGRARIAN EMPIRE BETWEEN MARKET
provincialterritories; they were, in that sense,"tributaryempires"
AND TRIBUTE: SITUATING INTERREGIONAL
rather than mercantilist states. 117 Enjoying the benefit of at least
TRADE IN THE ROMAN WORLD
another millennium of slowly accumulating social developments,
these empires hold the further attraction as comparandathat they
are unlikely to be more "archaic" than Rome in any meaningful [Tjhe decline of Rome was the natural and inevitable effect of immoderate
sense. Making a shift in our comparisons of the Roman world to greatness ... as soon as time or accident had removed the artificial supports, the
stupendous fabric yielded to the pressure of its own weight. The story of its
this group of Asian tributary states, therefore, would allow us to ruin is simple and obvious; and instead of inquiring why the Roman empire was
explore in greater detail the relationship between market system destroyed, we should rather be surprised that it had subsisted so long.
and agrarian empire, in other words to understand it as a particular Gibbon, The Decline and Fall of the Roman Empire, vol. IV, p. 119
type of political economy or system. The next chapterwill begin
to explore how this can be done.
Those are the immortal words of Gibbon, uttered with his charac-

117Woolf1990points in thesamedirection. Pleket 1990: 151remainsscepticalon thedis- teristic acrimony while contemplating the decline and fall of the
tinction between empire and mercantilist state system, but does not see the consequences Roman Empire. At first, they may come as a surprise. After all, this
of the very different articulations of commercial interests. was the very same man who proclaimed the age of the Antonine
emperors "the period in the history of the world during which the
condition of the human race was most happy and prosperous".1
But to Gibbon, the golden second century was an aberration. Only
a fortuitous succession of unusually capable, conscientious and
moderate emperors had made it possible. In the long mn, the cor-
rupting influence of absolute power was bound to prevail and turn
the enlightened monarchy into an oppressive tyranny. Ironically it
was left to Commodus, son of the philosopher king Marcus Aure-
lius, to bring out the true face of imperial rule. With his accession
to the throne the history of the Empire became one of despotism,
corruption, military anarchy, brutal oppression and the withering
away of its powers. And yet, in spite of its alleged pernicious influ-
ence on society, the Roman Empire lasted for centuries. Indeed,
it came as a shock to Gibbon in writing his history to realise the
almost, from this point of view, perverse ability of the imperial
system to renew itself andregain its strength;2 he needed six long
volumes finally to lay the leviathan to rest.

' Gibbon 1993, vol. i : 90 and further 90-99. Gamsey and Humfress 2001, chapter 10 on
Gibbon.
2 Robertson 1997.

6o 6i
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY AN AGRARIAN EMPIRE BETWEEN MARKET AND TRIBUTE

The relationship between the predatory and benign aspects of elements in their understanding of the great empires. Some, like
imperialrule remainsa key issuein ourunderstandingoftheeffect Voltaire, chose to ignore the "darker" side and instead eulogised
ofRome andotheragrarianempiresontheireconomies.Thischap- the imperial claims to absolute power. In his Essai sur les moeurs et
ter argues that these two aspects of the imperial experience cannot I 'esprit des nations he presented imperial China as the paragon of
be separated, but have to be seen as two sides of the same coin. rational order, an idealised counter-image to ancien regime France.
Economicdevelopment wasthe result ofpolitical exploitation, not This solution tailed to win the majority opinion. Most intellec-
its victim. This requires us to shift our attention from markets tuals were more impressed by the oppressive effects of imperial
as the organising force in the economy to the process of trib- rule. In L'Esprit des lois Montesquieu fiercely denounced the rosy
ute extraction and mobilisation of peasant surplus production. A image of China; tributary empires were based on the principle of
comparison of the interlinked processes of surplus extraction and fear. 4 Later, Adam Ferguson followed suit in his tract on civil soci-
elite building in the Mughal and Roman Empires demonstrates ety. The absence in the empires of a close alliance with commercial
the importance of imperial tribute in determining economic flows groups and the concomitant predominance of political consump-
in the empires. Markets, from that perspective, do not determine tion (cf. Chapter i), was fundamentally at odds with the world
the structure of the economy; instead they play a crucial role in view of the increasingly powerful and confident bourgeois soci-
mobilising the agricultural surplus and turning it into a disposable eties of Europe. Empires seemed the embodiment of everything
resource. The chapter concludes by discussing to what extent the adverse to the kind of social order they promoted, with clearly
processes of tribute extraction spawned economic growth in the defined civil liberties and parliaments to contain the ruling power.
Roman Empire. In the bourgeois view, the empires appeared to be antagonistically
opposed to their very economic and societal bases. Here is one of
Adam Ferguson's damning observations:
Agrarian empires between market and tribute
Were despotic empire... to continue for ever unmolested from abroad ... it
appearsto have in itselfno principle ofnew life, and presents no hope ofrestora-
Ultimately, the universal empire had presented itself as a paradox
tion to freedom and political vigour. That which the despotical master has sown,
to Gibbon, a perception he shared with many of his contempo- cannot quicken unless it die; it must languish and expire by the effect of its own
raries. In The Wealth of Nations, Adam Smith described China of abuse... National poverty, however, and the suppression of commerce, are the
the Ch'ing dynasty as one of the richest societies in the world with means by which despotism comes to accomplish its own destruction.5
a highly productive irrigation agriculture, substantive division of
labour and an extensive inland trade. But at the same time he saw
Stagnationand misery were all that agrarianempires had in store
for their poverty-stricken subjects. Commerce and the market were
the rule of the "Son of Heaven" as inimical to the economy; the
left very little room in the imperial order.
imperial tributary elite depressed the economic performance of
It took Max Weber to realise that the picture was much over-
the country through political privileges, taxation, arbitrary admin-
drawn and strongly stereotyped; empires would not have been able
istration andoutrightpredatory encroachmenton the wealthofthe
to exist under such purely traditional conditions. Here he made the
producing and mercantile layers of society. 3 Market and tribute fundamental observation that once a traditional, or in his termi-
existed in contradiction to each other; they seemed incompatible
nology, patrimonial state began to grow, the household of the ruler
and yet they were co-existing. The Enlightenment philosophers
would no longer be able to control the entire area of his realm.
never really managedto dissolvethis tension andincorporateboth
The ruler had to form alliances with local communities, mainly

3 Smith 1976: 11 i-l i2. Montesquieu 1955, part I: 3, 9-10; 7, 7 and 8, 21. 5 Ferguson 1995: 262-263.

62 63
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY AN AGRARIAN EMPIRE BETWEEN MARKET AND TRIBUTE

aristocracies, in order to establish longer-lasting control and have observations of Weber and instead accentuated and aggravated the
representatives carrying out his commands. The much dreaded internal contradictions in the concept of tributary empire. In The
despotism of the sociological tradition was not really possible. Political System of Empires (1963) Shmuel Eisenstadt attempted
The power of emperors and the imperial state was only appar- to develop Weber's basic analysis of complex agrarian societies.
ently absolute and arbitrary. In practice, the ruler over extensive Eisenstadt's analysis is not without merits. Its focus on the ability
areas had to negotiate and accept limitations on his exercise of of the empires to generate "free floating resources", that is their
power. Consequently the empires were characterised by a tension capacity for mobilising the agricultural surplus outside its imme-
or uneasy co-existence between the tax-extracting central power of diate context, has much in common with the view which will be
the emperor (tribute) and locally entrenched power wielders (feu- presented here. But the study has one crucial drawback. It treats
dal elites), living off agricultural rents. The resulting institutionali- the empires entirely within a framework of very abstract 1950$
sationofgovernmentinto relatively stablepatterns of activity was, modernisation theory. This prevents the empires from appearing
asWebersawit, thebeginningsofmore complextypes of society in their own right. Analysing Roman imperial administration in
with a more pronounced specialisation of functions. This led him terms of a modem-style bureaucracy is, for instance, not very
to include his treatment oftributary empires in a general discussion revealing when we remember that it had no institutions which
ofthedevelopment ofmodern forms ofstateandbureaucracy.6 served to guaranteethat promotion happenedon the basisofmerit
For our present purposes, however, this choice has had some or professionalqualificationratherthanthroughpersonal favour.8
unfortunate consequences. An opportunity was partly missed to Eisenstadt s approach tends, in other words, to miss some of the
break free from the contradictions in the Enlightenmenttradition. important organisational characteristics of the empires. They are
In Weber's analysis of the origins of modem states, the crucial perceived as incipient cases of modernisation still needing to shed
factor became the ability ofthe feudal level ofsociety to curb what much of the dead weight of traditional society before coming
seemedthearbitrary aspirations ofthetributary state. However, the to fruition. Essentially this confronts agrarian empires with two
more successfully this was done, the less chance the empire stood options: eitherthey transform successfully into mercantilist nation
of survival. Only where feudalism had been triumphant and the states and modernise or they remain traditional empires and even-
imperial superstructure had disintegrated, did society set off on a tually kill off whatevermodern elements they possess.9
developmental path eventually leading to modernisation. Inthe last John Kautsky has taken this further in The Politics of Aris-
analysis, the antithetical relationship between empire andits econ- tocratic Empires (1982) by sharpening the contrasts appearing
omy and civil society therefore remained central for Weber. The in Eisenstadt s image. Here the empires are simply defined as
tributary systems may have shown some signs of institutionalising essentially traditional. Trade and other such phenomena are, on
social and economic diversification. But ultimately the two phe- the other hand, seen as signs of modernisation per se and hence as
nomena were incompatible. Conceptually, this resulted in a hybrid fundamentally outside the aristocratic order. This is a very unfortu-
characterisationof these systems aspatrimonial-bureaucratic.7 nate solution. Most agrarianempires andcertainly the best known
That was problematic. It was the tensions in Weber's concep- had considerable amounts of trade taking place within them. But
tualisation which came to define the path ahead for later work Kautsky'ssystemcannotreally accountforthis. Commercialphe-
in historical sociology. Several influential studies in the Webe- nomenaare left in a kind of analytical no-man's land betweenthe
rian tradition have tended to disregard the cautiously balanced aristocratic and the present world until the agrarian or tributary
empires finally hadmodernisationforced uponthem from without
6 Weber 1972:580-652. See also Wickham 1985.
7 SeeWeber1972:619.Seepp.593,604and625-653forhiscontinuedadherenceto the
Enlightenment interpretation. Saller 1982: 111-116. 9 Eisenstadt 1963:351-360.

64 65
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY AN AGRARIAN EMPIRE BETWEEN MARKET AND TRIBUTE

by a conquering European modernity and in that process were only an enormous concentration of spending capacity, but also
transformed into a new type of society. 10 with populations reaching up towards the million mark (or above),
A conceptualisation oftrade andeconomic activity that situates a gigantic logistical accomplishment. 3 "Low enabling powers'
these phenomena firmly within the tributary empires constantly does not appearan adequateexpression with whichto capture such
eludes us. The relationship between traditional empire and trade phenomena. Thinkers less suspicious of state power have there-
seems todefy ouraccustomed categories. According toestablished fore been more inclined to note a paternalistic, beneficial side to
notions they ought to be like oil and water: mutually exclusive. imperial government. This point of view can be traced back to the
The essence of the orthodox view is neatly summarised in John Jesuit missionaries reporting about the enlightened, orderly rule
Hall's notion of capstone government. Apparently, an imperial of the Chinese emperor to the reading public of Europe in the sev-
centre could only maintain control by weakening its underlying enteenth and eighteenth centuries. 4 In more recent times, Weber
society and economy. For its own survival, it was forced to prey tentatively suggested that the imperial inclination to give priority
on any dynamic development and finally to block and destroy it. to consumer over producer interests was a first premonition of the
In that way, the empire prevented local groups from becoming welfare state. 5 More than anyone else, however, it is Karl Polanyi
wealthy and strong enough successfully to challenge its authority who has given expression to this view with his notions of redis-
and refuse to pay taxes. Thus imperial rule was secured by creating tribution and administered trade. Disgusted by capitalism he set
a power stand-off whichlowered the level of social activity and about exploring historical alternatives to a modem market econ-
put a lid on creative energies. Empires had"strong blocking but omy. One such alternative he found in a group of ancient Middle
weak enabling powers", as Hall has phrased it." Eastern empires. Apparently the economies were organised with-
out price-fixing markets. Instead resources were allocated within
a framework of state-controlled redistribution of production and
Redistributionor integratedmarket systems? legally fixed prices. To Polanyi's mind, this was a planned econ-
omy of a sort and he did not hesitate to draw parallels between
To be sure, it is not difficultto findexamples of imperial authori- his ancient redistributive empires and the economy of the Soviet
ties abusing their power to plunder and depress the subject popu- Union; essentially they wereof the samekind.
lations. A recent book on Roman Syria stresses how the imperial Polanyi's ideas have proved fertile in Roman soil. They have
army damaged the local economies to a large extent. The sol- stimulated a substantial number of studies which have been able
diers often proved a dangerous presence, being only too prone to to show the large influence that state-administered redistribu-
terrorise provincial inhabitants in order to extort money or other don exercised on the movement of material resources around
desirableresourcesfortheirownbenefit. '2 Yet,therearesomevery the Roman Empire. The archaeological record showing the
important aspects ofthe imperial experience for whichthewhole distribution of exported oil and wine amphorae has, for instance,
label of capstone government seems inappropriate. For instance,
the empires were able to create some of the largest urban concen- 3 See Braudel 1981: 489-491, 498-504 and 525-559 about pre-industrial metropoleis;
trations in the pre-industrial world. Metropoleis such as Mughal Blake [991 on Delhi; Morley 1996 on Rome.
14 See Bitterli 1991: 60-65 and 270-272 about the place of China in early modem Euro-
Delhi, Peking and Rome represent, by pre-modem standards, not pean discourse. The reports of the Jesuits had a strong influence on philosophers such as
LeibnizandVoltaire. Oneofthecentral works in thegenreis fatherDu Halde's Descrip-
tion geographique, historique, chronologique, politique et physique de la Chine et de
Kautsky 1982, chapters l, 2 and 15. la Tartarie, Paris 1735. Whereas Voltaire was delighted with it, Montesquieu, with his
Hall 1985: 35.Seefurtherchapter2 andpp.99-109.Mann 1986,chapter5 fora critique doctrine of the division of power, attacked it vehemently in L'Esprit de lois (1955, part
of this whole tradition. 1:8, 21).
; Pollard 2000, chapters 3 and 7. 15 Weber 1972:651-653. '<> Polanyi,ArensbergandPearson 1957,chapters 2 and 13.

66 67
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY AN AGRARIAN EMPIRE BETWEEN MARKET AND TRIBUTE

to some extent been persuasively linked to the so-called annona often several times over, that had so far been disregarded locally
system, or rather systems which the state used to organise food in spite ofdire threats ofheavy andfrighteningpunishments. Even
supplies for Rome and the armies. 17 Yet, in its pure form the officials in chargeofthe cultivation ofgovernment landcould not,
notion of redistribution cannot be elevated to the organising prin- as a rule, be expectedto obey orders promptly, if at all. 22
ciple of the imperial economy. It is in a way, modernising in spite Thus, on closer inspection the idea that the imperial economy
of itself. Polanyi's redistribution simply exaggerates the organi- was controlled by a large redistributive system that organised all
sational strength of imperial systems such as that of the Romans. or most of the transfer of resources in the Roman world has shown
From a modern perspective the striking thing is rather the very itselfto beinadequate andalso somewhat unrealistic. 23The Empire
limited capacity for bureaucraticcontrol of pre-modem states and simply lackedthebureaucraticcapacityfor sucha thing.Theredis-
often their outright impotence. tributive measures were very restricted in number and scope and
Some administrative documents from the Egyptian nome (dis- only comprised a small part of the economy. In the first two cen-
trict) Panopolis, dating to around AD 300, offer ample illustration turies AD they weremainly limitedto supplyingmuch, thoughnot
and deserve to be presented in some detail. Two papyrus scrolls all, of the grain needed to feed the population of the capital, and
contain copies of letters sent to and from the office of the strate- most, though even that is contested by some, of the requirements
gos, the local representative of the imperial authorities. 19 From this of the army. 24 There are indications in the sources that the system
correspondence we learn that the strategos was expected to sub- grew larger, mainly from the Severan dynasty onwards. But the
mit monthly accounts of the collection of taxes and the expenses extent is quite unclear and it has recently been concludedthat the
incurred in government service. However, the predecessor had evidencedoesnotlendsupportto anynotionofradicalchange.The
neglected his duties for some time and had now left the area without system remained limited in scope.25 Correspondingly, the pendu-
leaving a proper record behind. In practice, therefore, the accounts, lum is now swingingbacktowards (re-)assigningthe central state
which according to imperial command and expectation ought to apparatus a traditionally more marginal position in the economic
have been kept in scrupulous order, were in a mess and could not life of the Roman world.
easily be corrected. 20 Ofcourse, we know ofthis affairbecausean As was to be expected, while the dimensions of the state have
attempt was made to remedy past neglect, though precisely with beenshrinkingin the eyes ofmoderncommentators, so the impor-
what effect is uncertain. The letter scrolls do not uniformly docu- tance of private market trade has received new and increased
ment governmental failure; they also reveal an administration, at emphasis, as already noted in Chapter I. One theme which in
least periodically, attempting to tackle attempts at evasion. But, particular has been able to command scholarly attention in the
they do indicate that the gap between imperial prescription and last decade or more is the possible formation of large markets and
reality would often have been a wide one. The scrolls are also full their integration on an empire-wide scale.26 Much of this reads
of letters from higher-level officials giving and repeating orders, like a catalogueof "free trade" promotion. The role of the Roman
17 Peacock and Williams 1986, chapter 5. Some single studies emphasisingstate redistri- " For repetition followed by threats, see for instance P. Beatty Panop. I: lines I 10-119
bution: Midclleton 1983; Wickham 1988; Whittaker l994a; Foraboschi 1994; Remesal and [66-179 (lines 184-187 show one of the repeated orders having gone through).
Rodnguez 1997. For officials on state land ignoring orders P. Beatty Panop. 1, lines 205-212. Another
18 Saller 1982,chapters 3 and5; GamseyandSaller 1987,chapter2. example of "juicy" threats P. Panop. l, lines 100-108.
19 P. Beatty Panop. I and 2. 3 Harris 1993:14-18.
20 P. Beatty Panop. [, lines 64-71 and 90-107. The problem of disorderly or imperfectly 24 Garnsey and Saller 1987, chapter 5. Harris 1993: l-j is too sceptical about state control
submitted accounts occurs repeatedly in the correspondence, e. g., P. Beatty Panop. i, of military supplies.
lines 72-76; 2: lines 10-14 and 61-67. 5 Gamsey and Whittaker 1998.
21 Cf. P. Beatty Panop. 2, lines 68-71 and 128-152(seeking a pragmatic settlement rather 26 Fulforci 1987; Carandini 1988; von Freyberg 1989; Harris 1993;Parker 1996; Harris
than effectuating punishments for tax evasion). 2000.

68 69
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY AN AGRARIAN EMPIRE BETWEEN MARKET AND TRIBUTE

state is mainly perceived as indirect, assisting the trading world written into the DNA of Mediterranean civilisation. Here is one
more or less consciously by providing a better infrastructure. In of their observations: "We may even regard the state of affairs
this context many old ideas have been recycled and brought to today, in which the Mediterranean lands produce a fifth of the
new prominence. Here we find the notion that the Fax Romana, planet's vegetables and a third of its fruit but depend on imports
the imposition of a common currency, standardisedmeasures, the for two-thirds of their own grain, as a logical extension of the
highlydeveloped system ofRoman law andmore orderly adminis- intensification that we have been discussing."29 Of course, there
tration, all workedto improve economic efficiency, lowerthe costs is an element of rhetorical hyperbole here which perhaps ought
oftradingandpromote market integration. CharacteristicallyHop- not to be given too much weight. Yet, William Harris has made a
kins' model, linking imperial monetary taxationwithinterregional comment to much the sameeffect, namely that the economic inte-
trade flows, which was discussed in the previous chapter, has been gration of the Empire was probably equal to that of the European
adopted within this picture, not as providing the dominant mech- market system including the colonies around l750. 30
anism, but at most as just one factor within the whole range of These are extravagant claims, as can be briefly shown with the
economic catalysts. 27 aid of a few examples. Let us leave the position of the Mediter-
Somego even furtherandrelegate the state to a position ofpure ranean in the modem world economy aside andtake a closer look
exploitation on the fringes of the economy. In The Corrupting Sea at the formation of the early modern European colonial market
Peregrine Harden and Nicholas Purcell argue that the pre-modern system. During the Middle Ages the sugar consumed by Europe
states in the Mediterranean mainly worked to intensify exploita- was produced in the Mediterranean area. But that was almost
tion, sometimes with locally disruptive effects.2 The basic pat- brought to a complete end when sugar cultivation was moved, first
tern in the economy, however, was defined rather by the regional to the plantations of the Atlantic islands and then to Brazil and the
ecology. Accordingto their argument, extreme geographical frag- West Indies, whose production systems became completely organ-
mentation, splintering even micro-regions into many sub-types, isedaroundthis activity. Laterthe samethinghappenedto coffee,
combined with an unstable and erratic pattern of annual rainfall to which was moved from Yemen to Java and the plantations of the
make subsistence agriculture an impossibility; there was no such New World; meanwhile tea was brought from Chinato India and
thing as an average harvest which the peasants could depend upon, Ceylon. The drivingforcebehindtheserelocations oftheproduc-
only extreme variability. The much praisedandidolisedautarkyof tion of export crops was the search for greater profits; in the new
the peasants is a modem myth. In the Mediterraneanreality, aim- locations production was either cheaper, more easily controlled
ing for self-sufficiency was a suicidal strategy. To survive, peasants and organised or had greater room for expansion. 31 Sugar, coffee
had to rely on surplus production and exchange. "Every crop is a
cash-crop", the authors assert. The crucial role of exchange was t! HardenandPurcell 2000: 279 and 273 for the first quotation. Pp. 270-274 summarise
muchhelpedby the seawhichservedto bindthefragmentedlocal- theirviews. Chapters 5, 6 and9 develop theirview of Mediterraneaninterdependence,
ities together. It made the transfer and exchange of agricultural connectivity in their terminology. The Corrupting Sea is a bold work of synthesis and
should be admired for that. However, it is also a very difficult book and does not
products between individual localities a fundamental feature of always appearconsistent in its views. For instance, while elite exploitation is seen as
the Mediterranean world. Interdependence and economic integra- anextensionofthebasicproductivepattern, it is still mostly viewedasdisruptiveand a
threatto thewell-beingofthe"victim"population(278-287,incontrastwithp. 223),in
tion, thoughvarying with levels ofexploitation, were, so to speak, otherwords,asrepresentinga breakfromtheecologicalstandardpattern.Ifthatis so,it
becomescrucial to explorehowdifferentregimesofelite exploitationmouldeconomic
27 Lo Cascio zoooc is the best-argued example. Paterson 1998 is extreme, rejecting the activity. However,that is precisely whatthey rule out by blurring distinctions between
relevance ot'Hopkins' model. the BronzeAge,classicalantiquityandtheMiddleAges. Fora critique,seeBang2004.
28 HardenandPurcell 2000,chapter7. iu Harris 1993: 19;Temin 2ooi. 3I Steensgaard 19900and i99ob.

70 71
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY AN AGRARIAN EMPIRE BETWEEN MARKET AND TRIBUTE

andtea, however, are only examples of a general process in which


the economic geography of Europe and large tracts of the world Interregional trade and agricultural surplus areas
were gradually reorganised to fit the needs of a commercial system
basedon a steadilydeepeningregionalspecialisation.3 Theunder- Now, obviously all interregional trade which achieves a degree of
lying principle received its classic expression in David Ricardo, regularity implies some kind of interdependence; a great city like
the father of modern international trade theory, when he observed Rome would not have existed without grain imported from the
that foreign commerce and the resulting international division of provinces. But we are still far from the kind of economic integra-
labour ensured that: tion demandedbythemodernisingmodel. Taketwoofourarchae-
each country naturally devotes its capital and labour to such employments as are ologically best-recorded products: wine andoil. Thebeginning of
most beneficial to each . .. while by increasing the general mass of productions, wineimportstoRomeinthelateRepublic/eariyEmpirefromGaul
it diffuses general benefit, and binds together by one common tie of interest and and Spain, carried in the so-called Dressel 2-4 amphorae, did not
intercourse the universal society of nations throughout the civilized world. It is bringanendto thedelivery ofItalian supplies to thecapital. -34Sim-
this principle which determines that wine shall be made in France and Portugal, ilarly, the enormous growth in the early Empire in production and
that corn shall be grown in America and Poland, and that hardware and other
goods shall be manufactured in England.33
export of Spanish and, later, African olive oil did not extinguish
oleo-culture in other areas of the Roman world. 35 The extent of
Subscribingto a Ricardianvision oftheEmpire,in otherwords, regional specialisation, in other words, remained quite limited. A
involves positing a radical, artificial, commercial remoulding of recent archaeological survey of the city of Leptiminus in modern
productionpatterns in the Roman world. The result would haveto Tunisia offers a strong additional confirmation. 36 The town seems
bea systemwhereprovincial economiesweretransformedto serve to have had a very substantial export of olive oil and fish sauce
the needs of a steadily deepening interregional division of labour from the second to fourth centuries AD, to judge by the amounts
based on regional specialisation, economic competition and com- of waste from amphorae production found on the site. On the other
parative advantages in a conglomeration of interdependent mar- hand, the city had no local supplies of iron and had to cover its
kets. Spelledout in suchdetail, few,perhaps,wouldbepreparedto needs through imports. Yet, the archaeological survey documents
accept the implications of some of the optimistic assertions made the existence of a local iron "industry"; substantial amounts of
on behalf of the Roman and ancient Mediterranean economy. It debris from the smelting of iron ore was found on the site. The
is doubtful, for instance, whether this image is in fact what Hor- most likely explanation is that ore was brought in as ballast in the
den and Purcell intended to create in their analysis. After all, the ships carrying offthe oil. Significantly, it was apparently not more
ambition to integrate history and ecology can be read as an attempt expedient to import the metal after it had been processed into bars,
to create a completely new framework for our understanding of let alone manufactured into finished products. Undeniably, this is
exchange activities in the ancient world. Even the old Polanyian
notion of redistribution is developed and expanded, in The Cor- Tchernia 1986. Panella and Tchernia 1994. Whittaker 1985: 50-51 summarises the
amphorae material.
rupting Sea,to covera broaderrangeoftypesofexchange.Clearly,
35 Keay *984' Mattingly T988a;andRemesalRodriguez 1998are good treatments of
an alternative to the Ricardian notion of long-distance trade is AfricanandSpanisholive oil. In late antiquity but beginningat an earlierdate, olive
needed. oil, produced in the numerous villages dotting the limestone massifofnorthern Syria,
has also been interpreted as an instanceof regionalspecialisationin the pioneering
surveyworkofTchalenko. However,re-examinationofthismaterial in the lastdecades
hasunderminedhis interpretation. The agriculturein the areawas"amixedregime
dominated byarablecultivation" anddidnotdependontheexportofoilforitsexistence,
32 SeeWallerstein 1974andWolf1982for a world-systemdescriptionofthisdevelopment. soPollard2000:201-203and232-236,buildingonTate 1992.
33 Ricardo 1996: 93. 36 Mattingly et al. 2001.
72 73
AN AGRARIAN EMPIRE BETWEEN MARKET AND TRIBUTE
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY
production of the former imports of wine and pottery and even-
an example of regional interdependence, but also ofvery fragile tually even began to send substantial consignments of wine to
and limited specialisation. Rome. 40
Thisconclusion oughtnottobecontroversial. Ithasbeenrepeat-
Thus through the lenses ofmodem trade theory, the inclusion of
edly observed that Greek and Roman states failed to take com- Gaul intheEmpireparadoxicallyappearsto underminetheexisting
mercial advantage of their colonies in the way that early modem
regional specialisation; economic integration seems to suffer and
European states'attempted to in the organisation oUhe Atlantic the Empire enters upon a process of Entspezialisierung(declining
economy. Montesquieu must have been among the first to make specialisation), to quote the recent work of a German economist. 41
this observation, when he noted that ancient states did not treat
Rather than the expected increased regional division of labour
theircolonies asopportunities forincreasingeconomic specialisa-
tion and the division of labour. Incontrast to the mercantilist strate- where Gaul would have specialised in a different product (say,
ham or iron tools) it could use in exchangefor Italianwine,Roman
giespursuedbyhis contemporaries, the ancientsdidnot attemPt exports collapsed and the province became self-sufficient in goods
to secure the continued commercial dependence of the colonies
it had formerly imported.42 According to modern economic per-
on the metropolis through the granting of export and production
ceptions this apparent decreasingdivision of labour ought to be a
monopolies. 3'7Inspiteofcountless claims tothecontrary archae- sign of economic crisis and decline. And this, too, is what Ros-
ology'has, by and large, confirmed this picture. Interestingly, it tovtzeffandhis modern Italian followers have suggested. The fall
was"Rostovtzeff, the founder of the concorrenw paradigm, who
in Italian exports has been seen as an indicationof a growingeco-
firstsuppliedtheevidence.Withthecomingofthe"Romanpeace nomic crisis, as first Italy and then the Empire as a whole entered
hefoundit increasingly difficulttomakethepatternsproducedby
a downwardspiral ofdecliningdivisionof labouranddiminishing
thearchaeological datafitthe Ricardianmodel. Ratherthangoing
economic integration. 43 This is unconvincing for several reasons.
theirownway^specialisinginparticulargoods,theprovincesbegan
First, howeveroneestimatestheconditionofItalyfrom the second
to emulate the products ofItaly. 38
This is the problem known in the historiography as the (very century AD onwards, a hotly debated issue, the peninsula seems
to have been in good economic health at least throughout the first
questionable)'''crisisofItaly".39InthesecondcenturyBCconsid- century AD and probably for much longer. The changes that do
erablequantities ofItalianexports startto appearintheMediter- occur are better described as transformations than decline.44
ranean,especiallyintheAegeanandGaul.Tojudgefromarchae-^ Second, to describe the incorporation of Gaul in the Empire
oTogicalfinds,theseexports seemprimarily to haveconsistedof as a process of decreasing economic integration is to take too
wYn°e (carried in Dressel I and Lamboglia 2 amphorae) and fine
narrow a view of the relationship between province and imperial
pottery(theblack-glazedCampanian,followedbythered-glossed
Arretine terra sigillata) riding "piggy back" on the shipments of
wine. Inthefinafphase oftheRepublic withtheconquest ofGaul, -I" Panella 1981; 1993. Panella and Tchernia 1994 survey the evidence.
the consoUdation'of empire in the eastern Mediterranean andthe 41 Von Freyberg 1989: 151-152. Woolf 1992: 283-293 also sees integration culminating
in the first century BC.
coming ofAugustus, thelevel ofactivity dropped significantly. In 42 Gren ] 941 also noted how imports from Asia Minor to the Balkans were never balanced
the West, for instance, the wine exports from Italy to Gaul expe- by a counterflow of specialised goods produced in the Balkans.
43 For this school of thought Giardina and Schiavone 1981 and Carandini 1988.
rienced a steep fall and then petered off during the first century 44 Tchemia 1986 is a devastatingcritique. See furtherPatterson 1987; Whittaker 19946;
AD. In the same period, Gaul gradually established a domestic Vera 1994; andGiardina 1997, chapter5. The development ofItaly is better explained
in terms of developments in patterns of landholding and political office among the
political elites. See Patterson 2006 for an attempt to synthesise such a view of Italy.
Sallares2002raisesthequestionofepidemicdiseasesforourunderstandingofimperial
37 Montesquieu1955,part4,2i,21. 3s Rostovtzeft'1957,chapter^3-5.^ Italy.
39 Carandini 1988is themostoutspokenproponentot the decline01 iiaiy iiicuiy.
75
74
AN AGRARIAN EMPIRE BETWEEN MARKET AND TRIBUTE
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY
centre. It significantly overestimates the economic effects of the of the British Raj. 48 Chaudhuri summarises the basic conditions
Italianwine'exports. Theseexports werenot the result ofa deep of interregional trade in that part of the world: "But the compo-
economic interdependence between the two regions. Onthe con^ sition of trade.. . was not mainly determined by the nature of
that specialisation [i. e. interregional division of labour]. .. The
trary, they seem to have been the outcome of a very restricted
set'of circumstances, mostly depending on a very low degree of most important consideration was the ability of a local economy
to create a surplus over and above subsistence demand and to
integration between the two areas. During the age of expansion
the demand for "barbarian" slaves and metal increased in Italy. maintain this level. "49 The generation of an agricultural surplus
With contacts increasing between Roman and Celtic civilisations, was a key factor in enablingthe development ofother commercial
the Gaulic nobility acquired a taste for wine, a product of the and productive activities within a region. Most of what happens
Mediterranean. In'return for this exotic and luxurious product, in the Roman Mediterranean fits nicely into such a pattern. In the
Gaulic nobles seem to have provided Roman merchants with an westernpart the link betweencommercial prosperity andsustained
abundant supply ofmetals andslaves ofCeltic origin. After Gaul agricultural surplus production is pretty straightforward, with agri-
was made a province this traffic became unacceptable and came cultural products dominatingthe scene. It is the regions showing
to a swift end. With the loss of these very particular conditions, considerable agricultural expansion such as the Guadalquivir val-
the~wine trade was doomed. 45 At the same time, however, social ley in Spain or much of Roman North Africa which turn up in
and economic integration became more extensive and involved the evidence as commercially dominant. The study of the eastern
greaterresources. Gaulmayhavestopped sendingmany slavesto Mediterraneanis, at leastin terms ofarchaeology,less developed.
Rome. but it now had to pay a far more substantial imperial trib- Still, whatwe know seemsconsonantwith this model. Alexandria,
ute andsupply troops fortheRoman army. 46The imperial system for instance, praised by Dio Chrysostomus as the leading entrepot
made greater'demands onthe economic resources ofpost- rather intheEast,wasalsothe"capital"ofEgypt,themostfertileagricul-
than'pre-conquest Gaul. On top of this, the province entered a tural province in the Empire.50 Ephesos, another emporium often
phaseofpartialadoptionofRomaninstitutions material culture mentionedfor its prosperoustrade, wasone ofthemost important
andproductive strategies. Urbanisation increased andproduction cities in the agriculturally rich province of Asia.5'
For what it is worth, the close connection between the creation
bothgrewandbecamemorediversified. 47Itsimplydoesnotmake
mudTsense to describe this process of inclusion and intensified ofan agricultural surplus andcommercialprosperity also appears
contact spanning a much broader spectrum ofactivities asoneof as a dominating feature of a late antique work of commercial
decreasing economic integration andspecialisation. Social com- geography of the Roman world known as the Expositio Totius
Mundi. The authornotes, for example, that the cities ot'Phoenicia,
plexitydidnotdecline,itincreased Itis,inotherwords,difficultto famed for their trade, all had an abundant production of grain, oil
explaintheexperienceofRomanimperialismwithinaRicardian
framework. Economic integration developed according todifferent and wine.52 Inevitably, in the short-term, such a trading system
principles. 4S Habib 1999: 39-62 and Moo.svi 2000: 345-346 underline that a closely integrated
In fact, a better comparison than the strongly articulated com- market system did not develop in India before the construction of railways in the late
mercialspecialisation thatwefindintheEuropeancapitalistworld^ nineteenth century.
49 Chaudhuri 1985:l82.
system,isthesituationintheIndianOceanworldbeforethearrival 50 Strabo 798. 13 and Dio Chrysostomus XXXII, 35-36. Dio's description ofAlexandria's
grandeurcharacteristically startsby noting its basis in the rich Egyptianhinterland.
45 Tcherma1983;1986:74-ioo,14^146and158-172,and2006. ^ ^ ^^ ^^ 51 Strabo 641, 24. Pleket 1994 and Kobes 1999 emphasise the importance of trade to
46 TacitusHist.iv. 26and71 portraystributeandarmyleviesasimportantta< Ephesos,thoughthey underestimateagriculture, in my view.
5 Expositio Totius Mundi 23-33 (confirmed by MiIIar [993: 274-295). The close link
the Gallic rebellion in 69-70.
betweentrade andfertile cultivation is ubiquitousthroughoutthework.
47 Woolt'2001 and 1998.

76 77
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY AN AGRARIAN EMPIRE BETWEEN MARKET AND TRIBUTE

would be susceptible to fluctuations causedby harvest failures or extraction are thus likely to constitute a key factor in explaining
other shocks to the agricultural economy that eroded the surplus developments in economic circulation. Compared to the ecology,
andthus"driedupsuppliesofcommercialgoodsanddestroyedthe it represents a much more dynamic variable. So, the discussion
livelihoods of both artisans and farmers". To return to our Indian has come full circle. We are back with tribute extraction and the
comparison, during a disastrous famine in the province of Gujarat' Roman state.
in 1630 the substantial export production of cloth dwindled away
as scores of spinners, weavers and peasants alike either fled the
province in search of food or succumbed to hunger. 53 A similar The place oftribute extraction in the economy: Rome and
image of the vulnerability of the commercial sector in the face Mughal Indiacompared
of agricultural failure in surplus areas is painted by a late Roman
chronicle describing a famine in Edessa: "Everything that was Consonant with the prevailing "minimalist" view of the Empire,
not edible was cheap, such as clothes and householdutensils and it hasbecome customary to stress the markedly small share ofthe
furniture, for these things were sold for a half or a third of their total economy whichthe Roman state wasableto command. By
value, and did not suffice for the maintenance of their owners, themostprobableestimates, it wasintheregionof5-8%ofgross
because of the great dearth of bread."54 production. Someareinclinedto goevenlowerandoptfor3-5%
Catastrophicfamines,however, wererare. Normally the fluctu- orless.Butthisdoesnotseemrealistic; it hardlyallows anyroom
ations in output would be less severe, though far from insignifi- whatsoever for the state in the economy. s? Historians of Mughal
cant.55 In the longerterm, otherfactorstake on greaterprominence Indiastruggle withtheopposite problem: thestateseemstotakeup
in shapingthe sizeanddistributionofthe surplus. Chaudhurilists too much oftheeconomy. Forcenturies the Mughals have served as
conditions such as the general fertility of the area, population den- the quintessential example ofan oppressive despotism ruthlessly
sity and the level oftechnology. One factor, though, is conspicuous plundering its miserable subject population downto the very last
by its absence: surplus extraction. One of the great accomplish- penny. It might therefore be useful to confront the experience of
merits of the vast body of peasant studies has been to make clear the two empires in order to sharpen our idea of the impact of the
that peasanthouseholds are not normally orientated towards pro- Roman state on the Mediterranean economy.
ducing a large surplus for circulation outside the farm. They aim The Mughal Empire was a large and powerful state based on
rather to fulfil the basic needs of the household with as little effort the floodplains of northern India. -58 It was founded in the 1520$
as possible. Usually they have not been the main beneficiaries of byBabur, a central Asian aristocratic warrior adventurer, claiming
theproductionofsubstantialsurplusesabovetheirownsubsistence descent from the great conqueror Timur Lenk. Sometime ruler of
needs. The bulk of their surplus produce was normally claimed by Samarkand, andlaterKabul,hisluckchangeddramatically forthe
various political lords and would not have been produced with-
out pressure from above. 56 Changes in the patterns of surplus !t.o.'.'lS:..o.[SUPPIiesforbaclyears(Gamsey 1988:54).However, this"normal"surplusis
partofsubsistenceproductionandshouldnotbeconfusedwiththesurplusproducedfor
thepolitical elite^HordenandPurcell 2000,chapter7,inspiteofperceptire comments
on the effects of political pressure on surplus'production, fail to make tha't'cruciai
53 SeeChaudhuri 1985:32-33and 182-183abouttheeffectofshon-termshocksontrade. distinction Wolf1966 chapterI treatsthedifferent"surpluses"producedbypeasant^
Quotation from p. 182.
54 The Chronicle of Ps. -Joshuathe Stylite, chapter39, trans. W.Wright,cited in Gamsey
^kinsj995-6:,. 46-18for5-7%;Locascio2000C'foIlowmgGoldsm'thI987^^^^^
1988:4.
E'l>'.r.an.!st,imate,of3-5%'butsusPectinglhateventhismaybetoohigh.ThisTsunlikely.'
Duncan-Jones(1994:52^ estimatesthereveniieoftheRomansTateVnigypt"m"the
55 Garnsey 1988, chapters 2 and 3. secondcenturyat 20-25%oftheprovince'sGDP.Thisrevenuealonewouldsufficeto
56 Chayanov 1986 remains fundamental on the productive logic of the peasant household. !:'T8_!tatei"come,CI?setothethreshotdsuggestedbyLoCascio,withEgypt'producing
Peasants will normally aim to produce a little above their subsistence needs. This 58 iLdls,?fT'r?onateIy ,largesharec"f', theEmPire'sGDP(seeFurthernoteT76'bd'ow).~
strategy ensures protection in years of less than average harvest results and enables SeeRichards 19938fora survey ofMughiil history.
78 79
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY

better when, in a series of invasions, he succeeded in conquering Extent of Mughalempire. 1530


the remains of the Delhi Sultanate. During the next two centuries Extent of Mughal empire, 1605

the Empire continued to expandanddevelop. Akbarwhoruled Extent of Mughal empire. 1707


Babur's Afghankingdom showing
from 1556toi 605isgenerallyrecognisedastheconsolidatorofthe attempted Mughal expansion
~ ~" T"~ Suri empire
mature Mughalstate.Underhisgrandson,Shahjahan(r. 1628-57), Attempted Mughalexpansion
theEmpireseemstohavereachedits"Antonine"moment embod-
le d Tn Spectacular architectural feats such the Taj Mahal and as

the Red Fort of Delhi. Aurangzeb (r. 1658-1707), his successor,


seemingly continuedthetriumphal marchofMughalarms with
large conquests in the southern parts of India. At the end ofhis
reien. however, strains had built up in the system. It had proven
impossible to consolidate some of the new acquisitions.entered
In the
deca des after the death of Aurangzeb, the Mughal Empire
its "third-century crisis", from which it wasnever to recover. Fre-
quent challenges to the reigning monarch andregional fragmen';
t'ation graduaUy divested the Mughal emperor of his power and
territories many years before the British delivered the coup de Bihar
"^JHARKHANp
graceanddeposedthelastincumbent intheaftermath oftheGreat 'atamau "V

IndianMutinyofT857.
In terms of size and dimensions, the Mughal Empire may
arguably be seen as the most attractive of the potential eariy
modem comparisons sketched out in the previous chapter. The
Ottoman Empire admittedly sharedmuchof.itsterritory withthe
Romans, but thetotal extent, both in terms of geography andpop-
ulation, was significantly smaller. The reach ofMughal territories ARABIAN BA Y Of
wassmaller, too, though with anaction radiusof some 1,200Jan BENGAL
protrudingfromthecapitalDelhi,itwasdistinctlysizeable.-59The
population, however, wasbiggerthantheRoman butstill within a
comparable orderofmagnitude. Bytheturnofthesixteenthcen-^
tury,ltheMughal Empire'is generally estimated tohawcomprised
some loo-no million inhabitants. 60 By then, the Chinese pop-
ulation had already grown to an even bigger size. The Mughals,
therefore, provide'the closest biggerearly modernparallel to the
Romaneconomy (seeFig.2. 1 fora mapoftheMughalEmpire).
5t) Gommans2002: io8. ^ ..... "" ,.^ _"_.."
6° Mo'o's'vFl ^Tchapter estimates 100 million_in 1600. Habib
17 &Raychauclhy^^8^,
for all of India
c:h^pter6'est'i'matet 'l'lo million for the Mugha) Empire and 150 million
in 1600, growing moderately to 200 million in 1800. Fig. 2. 1 The Mughal Empire (Richards, New Cambridge History of India,
1993, p. iv)
8o
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY AN AGRARIAN EMPIRE BETWEEN MARKET AND TRIBUTE

Despite its reputation as an insatiable Leviathan, the Mughal to warrant closer comparison. Of course, there are also impor-
Empire also resembled the organisation of the Roman Empire m tant differences, the most obvious being that the Mughal Empire
several ways. To begin with, it was a conquest state A unitary was landlocked whereas the Roman surrounded the Mediterranean
system was therefore out of the question. In spite of the impe- Sea. From the present perspective, however, this rather works to our
nal facade of homogeneous administration, the system can best advantage. Traditionally the realm of the Mughals has been seen as
be described as a patchwork, accommodating a large variety of the quintessentially land-based, destructive, predatory empire that
localandregionalarrangementsofsubmission. 6'Next,bothpoli- kept the economy in a stranglehold. In recent years, this image has
ties belong to the category of patrimonial-bureaucratic empires' gradually begun to disintegrate and new interpretations, exploring
Thismeans thatthe statewasbasedon a large imperial household, a more positive connection between economy, trade and empire,
the army and an imperial aristocracy filling important positions have evolved. 5 At the heart of this historiographical tumabout
within the system. IntheMughal Empire thetitle usedto describe is a model which links the collection of imperial taxes with an
the imperial elite was mansabdar, which would be roughly the increasing monetisation of the economy, much as Keith Hopkins
equivalent of Roman senators and knights in the imperial ser- has suggestedfor Rome. This makes the MughalEmpire an attrac-
vice and officers in the army. Bureaucratic features, on the other tive comparative tool for identifying alternative approaches to the
hand, were not strongly developed. The mechanisms governing Roman trading system.
the administrative and military system, for example, depended A central concern for historians of the Mughal Empire has
more on patronage connections to the emperor than bureaucratic been what one might call "the taming of the revenue intake". Our
principles suchaspromotion onmerit, clearly definedlinesofcom- sources for Mughal taxation are dominated by official, adminis-
mandand spheres of authority. 63 Similarly, both empires divided trative records, often of an ideological nature such as the courtier
provincialruleintotwobranches.Thegovernorwouldbeinmili- Abu al-Fazl's survey of the Empire and its institutions, contained
tarycommandandresponsibleforkeepingtheprovince loyal and in the late sixteenth-century Ain-i Akbari. Working from these
peaceful. The collection of taxes, on the other hand took place it seems that the Empire aimed at taking half of the gross agri-
under the authority ofa separate official, answering directly to the cultural production in taxes. 66 This is incredibly high. It implies
imperial centre. 64 that the Empire came close to confiscating the total agricultural
An exhaustive listing of all similar features is unnecessary. surplus and sometimes even more. In practice, that must have
Clearly, thetwo tributary systems resemble eachother sufficiently been impossible. An anecdote about one of the nawabs of Awadh,
Burhan-ul-Mulk, is revealing about what must have happened.
6' On the Mu.ghal Empireandits heterogeneouscomposition, see Richards 1993.^ See When trying to increase tax collection, he was asked which set of
further Aia m"l986; Blake 1991; Hintze 1997; Alam and Subrahmanyaml998;^Habib
'l999^hapter 5. See Richard's 1975 t'or monograph studying the provincial^ settlement
a tax rolls he wanted employed, those of the coward or those of the
i'nGolc'onda.' For the Roman Empire Garnsey and Saller 1987; Jacques and Srt man. Only the coward's lists were normally in use and they oper-
1990;andLepelley 1998emphasiseorganisational heterogeneity andtheimportai
patrimonialism ratherthanbureaucracy ated at a more moderate level of extraction. 7 The Mughal Empire
62 Weber 1972:580-624developedby Blake 1979onthe Mughals. LoCascio2000b: also seems to have recognised the precarious connection between
8'dismisses the notion of a patrimonial-bureaucratic empire. But his own analysis,
pp^.13-79, 97-149and163-176,ofthecomplexitiesoftheRomanimperialpa(rimonit<m official claims and actual revenue. Discounting systems were
does not convincinglybring it beyondthe model.
63 Blake 1979,AIamandSubrahmanyam2000: 112-130.SeeSaller 1982,chapter3 on
Roman imperial administration. .....,, "__:. 65 Habib 1999(1963)is a firststep.Laterresearchhastaken thisfurtherandpartedwith
^ The third'book of the Ain-i Akbari, a grand description of the JVfughaj the notion of destructive despotisms: Bayly 1983, Alam 1986, Richards l993a, Hintze
c. 1600,explainstheprinciplesofimperialprovincialadministratio"-seef"rtherBl'&e, 1997 and Alam and Subrahmanyam 1998.
Habib 1999:230-236.
7979:8'6--90;Richards1986,introductionand1993:5»-59.SeeEck2000onRoman 7 Alam 1986:2I2-2I3;n.28 relates theanecdoteaboutthe tax lists.
provincial administration.
82 83
THE .ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY AN AGRARIAN EMPIRE BETWEEN MARKET AND TRIBUTE

introduced that allowed the imperial administration to allocate


ES Disposable
parts of the revenue, not at the exaggerated (imaginary) official surplus
level but at something which at least for a while resembled the E3 Agricultural
actual figure more closely. 68Inthe Ain-iAkbari onealsoreadsthe subsistence
advice that the level of taxation should be adjusted so as to take
account of the strongly varying agricultural potential and hence Fig. 2. 2 Roughmodel of agrarianeconomy
tax-carrying capacity ofdifferent areas. 69A recentestimate, there-
fore. more moderate, but still high, sets imperial tax as one-third other than the immediate reproduction of the agricultural sector.
ofstaples such asrice, millet and wheat. More valuable crops were This was the negotiable part of the economy. The rest was spoken
probably taxedcloser to one-fifth. 70 for in advance to cover the subsistence requirements of the food
Several aspects of this can be brought to bear on the Roman producers themselves. 73
case. The following sections will deal with the imperial state and The implications of this can be brought out with greater clarity
the economic surplus and with the process of taxation and elite by attempting a simple quantitative model of the Roman economy.
formation. Stateandsurplus, first. OurMughalcomparison teaches The very attempt at quantification may seem of dubious worth,
us, that 5-7% of gross production is a misleadingly low measure given the many uncertainties in our knowledge ofmacro-economic
of the Roman state's impact on society. To be sure, in modem parameters in the Empire. The results, however, must not be mis-
terms the figure clearly is absolutely low; a welfare state such as taken for exact figures. Quantitative speculation cannot generate
Denmark claims approximately one halfof GDP in tax and still the statistics which we do not possess. Nonetheless, as a heuristic
leaves people more forprivate consumption than everbefore Yet device it can provide us with a rough idea of orders of magni-
the Mughal case reminds us that the limits set on the scale of tude. Even imprecise figures can be an advantage here. Economies
activities in a pre-industrial economy dominated by agriculture are finite, quantifiable entities. By giving the Roman economy a
are much narrower than we are accustomed to thinking of today. hypothetical, quantitative expression we can control our qualita-
If the dimensions of the Roman state were small, so was the size tive analyses with much greater precision than would otherwise be
of the economy. 71 Agriculture may in general have been a little possible. Quantification, however imperfect, helps us to choose
more productive on the floodplains of northern India than in the between competing hypotheses by making their implications
Mediterranean. Still, pre-colonial Indian conditions provide us clearer.74 It is also important to recognise that the construction of
witha roughideaofthespaceweareoperating within.Notmuch this sort of model is not completely arbitrary, in spite of the uncer-
more thanhalfoftotal production, andoften less,wouldhavebeen tainties. We do have bits and pieces of the information we need
available for extraction in the first place (see Fig. 2. 2). 72 Therefore from the Roman world. This can be combined with what we know
a more realistic appreciation ofthe scale of state expenditure can of agricultural economies from other periods and regions to pro-
only be gained from seeing it in relation to the total disposable vide us with a reasonably realistic impression of the Roman situ-
surplus; It is the size of the disposable surplus which effectively ation. Only industrialisation has created enormous differences in
defines the amount of resources that can be diverted for purposes the productive capacities of complex societies. Agrarianate soci-
68 Alam 1986:24-25. Habib 1999,chapter7 treatsthediscountingmethodsin greater eties do show local and regional variations in wealth, but these
detail.
<"' Ain-i Akbari, book 3, chapter 7. 70 Richards 1993: 85. 73 Haswell 1967: 88; Kula 1976: 62-75; and Garnsey 19985: 22-28 about the centrality
of the surplus.
7) Braudel 1981 is fundamental.
72 Moosvi 2000: 33"posits a fifty-fifty scenario forthe Indianagricultural economy arour 74 Hopkins 1995-6: 41-46 is a strong defence of the approach. Bang 2002b attempts to
develop the distinction between heuristic device and statistical model.
1600.

84 85
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY AN AGRARIAN EMPIRE BETWEEN MARKET AND TRIBUTE

fall within a relatively narrow range. And what is more important, Table 2. 1 Estimate of disposable surplus, state impact and
the differences tend to be ironed out when very large areas such interregional trade in the second century AD
as the Mediterranean, India or China are compared. 75 It follows
thatestimates on a global scale, suchasarerelevant to theRoman i. The population of the Empire in the mid secondcentury AD is set
at 60 million.
Empire, operate within a fairly manageable margin ofuncertainty, 2. Minimum subsistence is set at 250 kg wheat equivalent per person
say 30 or 40%. per year.
'ItakemyleadfromHopkins' recentattempttoquantifythesize 3. Agriculture was relatively low-yielding. A reasonableestimate puts
of the Roman economy. 76 The calculation has been summarised average yield at 4 x seed. This means that 25% of total minimum
in Table 2. 1. The all important component in an estimate of the produce would have to be put aside for next year's crop.
4. Minimum GDP will then be:
Roman, as of any agrarian, economy is the size of the population.
Duetotherelatively modest differences inproductivity thenumber 60 million x (250 kg subsistence + 83. 33 kg seed)
== 20 million tonnes wheatequivalent
ofproducers is goingto bethe singlemost important determinant 5. A large part of the population will have had to live close to this
of the size of the economy. The population of the Mediterranean
level. But cities were normally privileged, some people were also
world around 1600 was set by Braudel at 60-70 million. 77 The very rich and not all peasants were equally poor. Production of
number in Roman times is unlikely to have gone far beyond that; manufactured goods and services by the 10-20% not employed in
neither Gaul nor northern Italy were as densely populated as later. primary agricultural production also needs to be added. It seems
Moreover, historical demographers operate with a slowly rising reasonable with Hopkins to increase total production by half in
secular trendbeneath thecyclical pattern ofpre-industrial popula- order to get to actual GDP: 20 million tonnes x 1. 5 = 30 million
tonnes wheat equivalent.
tion growth and decline. 78 Taking that into account, Frier's recent 6. The average price of wheat is set at HS 3 per modius (6. 55 kg). To
more detailed estimate of the Empire, province by province, can- judge from prices in Egypt this may be a bit on the high side. But
not be wide off the mark. Allowing for a slow rise during the first since this operates against the point I am trying to make it only
two centuries AD, he sees the population as reaching a peak of serves to strengthen the model.
approximately 60 million in the middle of the second century just 7. This makes GDP: 30 million tonnes x HS 3/modius == HS 13, 700
million
before the arrival of the Antonine plague. 79
8. From comparative evidence of other pre-industrial societies we can
From there it is possible to derive an estimate of the mini- operate with a proportion of 10-20% living in cities and 80%
mum agricultural production neededtokeepthispopulation alive. working the land to feed the remaining 20%. The total disposable
Modem studies, based on observation in developing countries surplus can then be defined as GDP minus minimum subsistence
and colonies, provide a fairly good ideaof the minimal material for 80% and seed required to produce subsistence for 60 million.
requirements of populations living in agricultural societies. On That is unrealistically generous, but by increasingthe surplus which
actually entered circulation outside the peasanthousehold and its
average a person needs to consume 250 kg wheat equivalents per village network, I work againstthe point I am attempting to make.
year to subsist at an absolute bare minimum level. Within this 9. In numbers this makes our estimate of the total disposable surplus:
[ 3, 700 - (48 million x 250 kg + 60 million x 83. 33 kg) x HS
75 Bairoch 1993: loi-l 10andPomeranz2000,chapters I and3. 3/modius = HS 6, 000 million (in round figures) or 40-45 % of
76 Hopkins 1995-6: 44-48. 77 Braudel 1972: 394-398. ^ _ ^., """.. ":. GDP.
7s Scheicfel2000:63-76 suggeststhepossibilityofa maximumpopulation or so miiiiuiL io. Following Duncan-Jones,set state expenditure in the middle of the
Bu't"tha~t'does~nonake account ofa rising secular trend through Eumsian pre-industrial second century AD at approximately HS 900 million. Direct state
populationhistory.OnthisseeBraudel1981:31-34and88-92andLivi-Bacchi1992: expenditure then constitutes 15 % of the disposablesurplus.
79 Fner^oooa:812,buildingonBeloch 1886,nowfollowedbyScheidel2007a.Seealso (cont.)
Frier 20()0b.

87
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY AN AGRARIAN EMPIRE BETWEEN MARKET AND TRIBUTE

Table 2.1 (cont.) In the absence of that, wheat equivalents are a useful fallback.
Before industrialisation food grains play a dominant role in the
ii. To this should be addedthe imperial elite: 600 senators with an economy of the vast majority. As a consequence, the value of the
annual income (not to be mistaken for the census requirement) of
around HS i million each, and a similar number of knights, whose rest of production tends to stand in a rough relationship to the
income is estimated at half that of senators. The income of the price of grain. In times of famine, for instance, the value of non-
imperial elite then can reasonably be assumed to be in the same essentials drops sharply because people need to draw heavily on
range as that of the state: HS 900 million. In other words, the central their resources to procure highly priced cereals or their substitutes.
aristocracy can account for another 15% of the disposable surplus. Therefore it makes good sense initially to express an agrarian
12. io% of GDP, entering interregional (intertown) trade, works out at economy in terms of wheat equivalents. 81
23% of disposable surplus.
20% of GDP, entering interregional (intertown) trade, works out at Thus, by combining population size with subsistence require-
46% of disposable surplus (add another 10% and we would reach ments minimum production in the Empire can be set to
69% of surplus which wouldbe totally unrealistic). 60 million x 250 kg = 15 million tonnes wheat equivalent. The
13. Increasing GDP by one-third would accommodate, in the model, imperialeconomy,however,couldnothavefunctionedatthislevel.
either raising the price of grain from HS 3 to 4/modius, or setting Twomore factors shouldbe addedto the calculation. First, it takes
population at 80 rather than 60 million, or seeing actual production
seed to grow grain. Now the seed : yield ratio is far from an uncom-
taking place at 2 times rather than i . 5 times subsistence. That
would bring GDPup to approx. HS 18,000 million, and reduce the plicated expression of productivity. High yields may for instance
combined weight of imperial state and aristocracy to 17-23% of be obtained by a low sowing rate, making the return per hectare
the surplus. Follow any two of these three options and the more modest. For our present purposes we need not go into the
corresponding figures would be 13-17% of the surplus. That would finer details of these problems. What we need is a rough measure
still denote a significantinfluence on the economy, but with GDP at and 4 times seed has been adopted, acknowledging that behind
some HS 24,000 million, the costs of the central government
institutions (HS 900 million) would now only take up a miseriy this figure there were enormous local differences. We do not pos-
3-4% of the total economy. sessmuch goodinformationonyields in theGreco-Romanworld,
To conclude, any understanding of economic integration in the Empire but the scraps we do find in the various agricultural treatises do
must needs take the imperial tribute extraction as its point of departure. not strongly contradict this choice. Moreover, scientific analysis
It is able to accountfor a very substantial part of all interregional flows of ancient grains found by archaeologists confirms that they will
of resources, be they in the form of trade or of redistribution. have been fairly low-yielding. 82 Finally, on comparative grounds,
wecanalsoarguethatyieldmusthavebeenhigherthanthree-fold
figure food accounts for around four-fifths, the rest is provision because otherwise the peasants would have found it difficult to
for a little clothing, firewood, housing etc. It should, perhaps, be support the elaborate urban-centred social system. On the other
stressed,thatthesearereal minimums, presupposinga low level of hand, they would probably also have been below five-fold or we
activity, rather thanthe somewhatgenerous prescriptive standards would have to accept a much higherlevel ofurbanisation than most
of calorific intake recommended by United Nations agencies. 80 arewillingto concede.83So4 times seedcanbeusedwithreason-
The notion of wheat equivalents may require a little further able confidence as a broad measure. This adds an extra 5 million
explanation. Ideally, of course, we would like to have statistics for " Gamsey 1988:3-7 citing thechronicle ofJoshuatheStylite on a famine in lateRoman
all the different products that people consumed apart from wheat, Edessa.Forcomparativeconfirmationoftheroughrelationshipbetweenpricesinfood
andnon-e.ssentials,seeChatterjee 1996:54.
in order to determine their relative significance in the economy.
In addition to Hopkins, seeGamsey 2000: 706-709 ongrainproductivity.
De Vries 1984: 242-243 works with a standard peasant household of 5 members and
80 dark andHaswell 1970,chapter I andpp. 57-62. 8 hectaresofland.Withyieldsof3 : i thehouseholdwouldproducelessthanits own
89
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY AN AGRARIAN EMPIRE BETWEEN MARKET AND TRIBUTE

tonnes wheatequivalent, andsubsistenceproduction in the Empire second century. Similar prices are attested for Pisidian Antioch
comes out at 20 million tonnes wheat equivalent (Table 2. 1, steps (HS 2. 25), a small town inAsiaMinor, andRomanAfrica. Onthe
3-4). otherhandprices in Rome were probably more like HS 8-10per
While many peasants,village artisans andpoor townsfolkprob- modius. 87 Hopkins haschosen HS 3 ashis average. If anything,
ably existed at or close to subsistence level, considerablenumbers that is probably on the high side, since most .grainwasconsumed
had a standard of living above this. 84 Cities, for instance, were outside thelarge urban concentrations wherefoodwasmore expen-
privileged places where large resources were concentrated. It is sive. Using a price of HS 3 per modius brings our estimate of GDP
not uncommon to hypothesise city populations as consuming agri- in the Roman Empire in the mid second century roughly to HS
cultural products at twice the minimum level. 5 Some of this will 13, 700 million (Table 2. 1, steps 5-7).
have been used as raw materials by urban manufacturers. This Admittedly therearegreatuncertaintiesinvolvedinthecalcula-
reminds us that we also need to include the production of higher- tion. But as a rough measure I think it will do. Stated in per capita
value goods and services performed by the 10-20% of population income it works out at HS 229. 88 Some years ago, an economist
living in the cities as well as manufacturing in the countryside. All estimated per capita income in the Empire in the first century AD
in all, our minimum estimate of the economy probably needs to be as HS 38o. 89That is problematic. This figure wasreached without
increased by half in order to arrive at the real GDP. This brings using any significant analytical checks to assure that the estimate
our estimate of the Roman GDPto 30 million tonnes wheat equiv- wouldberealistic.As anaverageHS380,infact, seemsunrealisti-
alent. Finally, this number must be converted into monetary terms cally high when we compare it to what we know ofRoman wages.
to enable comparison with state expenditure. Our information on Adjusting for differences in wage levels between city and coun-
wheat prices in the Empire is fragmented, but suffices to give a tryside and between men and women, it implies that the average
broad impression. 86 In most parts of Egypt the price of wheat male working income was higher than the pay of a legionary in
seems to have been around HS 2 per modius, at least until the late the first century andonly a little less in the secondcentury. Thisis
subsistence. At 4 : I the household would be able to support 1. 4 persons employed
implausible. Thelegionarieswerea powerful andprivilegedgroup
outside agriculture. With yields rising to 5 : I the number of persons would go up to 34 in Roman society. We would expect them to do considerably bet-
or about 40% outside agriculture. Erdkamp 2005: 34-54 argues, perhaps a little one- ter than the average adult male labourer. Consequently, per capita
sidedly, for the possibility of higher yields in the Mediterranean, especially Italy, with income should be comfortably below HS 380. Indeed, if the infor-
a potentially even higher surplus to sustain aon-agricultural activities. But, as he also
emphasises, his model farm is a Utopia, designedto draw attention to the significanceof mation preserved about the wages of Roman labourers is used as
peasant agriculture for creating a low-yield regime. The model "high-yield" farm would
only be possible on the best of lands, and could not reproduce its own labour force. In
an alternative basis from which to calculate a possible GDP, we
other words, it depended on the availability of a peasant population in the surrounding arrive at a per capita income a little below our estimate. 90 It looks
countryside. Average productivity would thus be much lower than the hypothetical as if the dimensions of the model are roughly correct.
maximum.
84 See Gamsey 1998, chapter 4 on the near subsistence existence of many groups in the 87 DuncaiWones 1982: 144-147 andRickman i98oa,chapter6 collect much oftheevi-
Greco-Roman world. dence. The normal price range was HS 2-4. Egyptian'wheat prices are collected in
85 Habib 1999:84-85. See further De Vries 1984: 242-243, whoobserves that it is rela- Dunt-a"-Jones1990:151;Drexhage1991;andRathbone1997.
tively more demanding on resources to maintain people in cities than in the countryside. I." whlatecluivalentsthefigureis500kgperpersonornet'productionofseed417kg.
ForHellenisticBabylonanimpressivecontinuousseriesofpriceshavebeenpreservedin In 1960,India,still heavilydominatedbya very basicagriculturalregime,hadana
the astronomical records. Aperghis 2001 makes use of this material to model the macro pej;caPltaagrlculturalproductionof382kgwheatequivalent(darkandHaswelI1970:
conditions of the Seleucid economy in Mesopotamia. Unfortunately, he has forgotten 78). This lends credence to our estimate.
to include production above subsistence, which weakens his results considerably. For 89 Goldsmith 1987:35.
example, the state is seen as confiscating60% ot'GDP,even though that means that the I, lmmII,chob^ged to Richard saller t'or presenting this argument to me in correspon-
peasants are left with less than their subsistence requirements. He also opts for a level d.en';e'. t,'?i"g Dunc:an-Jones '982: 54SaIIersetsurbanmale labourat HS3 aday'and
of urbanisation at 50% of population. That seems extremely optimistic. See Aperghis !lur. .at. HS .I;;'', He sets population 60 million with half actually working (250 days
at

2004 for a broad study of the Seleucid economy. peryear),20%livingincitiesandfemaleincomeathalftherateofmale,a practicethat


90 91
AN AGRARIAN EMPIRE BETWEEN MARKET AND TRIBUTE
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY

We can now use our GDP as the basis for an attempt to quantify and circuses", and the army) probably took up at least 15% of
the disposable surplus, the really crucial element in the Roman the disposable suq^lus, as opposed to only 6% of gross produc-
economy. In this exercise, it is important to reach a generous tion. This is quite substantial, especially when we remember, as
estimate, more likely to be an overestimate than the opposite, since pointed out by Hopkins, that the state often spent its tax income
this will work against the point I am trying to make. Therefore I at some remove from where it had been collected (Table 2. 1, step
havetriedto includesomeanalytical"buffers"whichwillbeableto lo). 94 If, for example, we hypothesise that interregional transfer of
absorb most of the effects on our conclusion of an increase in GDP resources amounted to something like 10% ofGDP, c. 65% could
of, say, 10or20%. Again, taking thebetter-known situation around arguablybe accountedfor by the flows ofmoney, goodsandredis-
1600 as our starting point, urbanisation seems to have reached a tribution in kind caused by net tribute extraction. If the figure for
new high of 16-17% of the Mediterranean population. 91 Figures intermediate and long-distance exchange of resources is increased
for the Roman Empire are unlikely to have been significantly to 20% ofGDP, the proportion comes down to 33%. But at 20% of
higher, but we allow a generous 20%. This leaves 80% of the GDP intercity transfers will amount to more than two-fifths of the
populationtoproducetheagricultural surplus.Todothat,itneeded disposable surplus (Table 2. 1, step 12). Since a large part of the
its minimum subsistence requirements and seed for producing the surplus was undoubtedlyconsumedin its region of origin, interre-
minimum GDP. All production in Roman society above those gionalexchangecannoteasilyhavebeenmuchhigher.I will return
two elements, I take as the disposable surplus. This is, in fact, with some more detailed reflections to support this view later in
very generous. Peasants also had to feed their draught animals the chapter. For now it will suffice to observe that even in what
and would probably in many areas have been able to reserve a seems a "worst case scenario", net government expenditure is still
little more than the bare minimum for the consumption of the far from a marginal economic force. Thus as a preliminary conclu-
household.92 Leavingthis aside,the disposablesurpluscomesout sion it seems clear that the imposition of imperial tribute cannot
atroughly HS 6,000million. Basically this meansthat only about easily be bypassed in our understanding of the development in the
40-45% of the Roman economy would have been available for intermediate and long-distance transfer of resources. At the very
taxation, market circulation and so on (Table 2. 1, steps 8-9). least, it must have significantly modified the pre-existing pattern in
Roman government expenditure in the second century AD can the Mediterranean world. The Roman state may after all not have
be estimated at approximately HS 900 million. 93 Combining this been quite so marginal an economic presence as our GDP figure
estimate with our GDP enables us to see that the net expenditure initially indicated. In that way it is moving closer to our Mughal
of the imperial system (mainly the emperor's household, "bread example.

is attestedfromantiquity.Finallyheassumesthatthesexdistributionofthepopulation Tribute extraction, elite building and


was fifty-fifty. This works out at HS 10,000 million. To this he adds20%for elite
incomeand7-8%forstateincome.ThefinalresultisapproximatelyHS 13,000million economic integration
orHS217percapita.IfweinsertGoldsmith'sestimateofHS380intotheequationwe
see, since only half of the population worked, that average working income would be
twice thebasefigure, thatis760. Ifmale income isdouble thatoffemale, averagemale Our comparison with the Mughal Empire, though, still confronts
working incomewould thenbeHS i ,013.Forcomparison theannualpayofa legionary us with a glaring discrepancy between the size of the two states:
was HS 900 in the first century andHS 1,200 in the secondcentury (Duncan-Jones the Roman state probably took up less than 10% of GDP whereas
1982: lo). Temin 2006 goes even lower in his estimate, alsobasedonprices, but with
less analytical sophistication. the Mughal state controlled perhaps up to one-third. That is curi-
1)1 DeVries 1984:69-77. ous and should make us wonder. In terms of organisation, we
92 dark and Haswell 1970, chapter 4 argues that of production up to 350 kg wheat
equivalent perperson, most will usually remain within thepeasanthousehold. 94 Hopkins 19786; 1980; and 1995-1996.
93 Duncan-Jones 1994: 45; Hopkins I995-6; Walters 1999: 202-234.

92 93
AN AGRARIAN EMPIRE BETWEEN MARKET AND TRIBUTE
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY

remember, the Empires looked much alike. Could they really have admonitionto the appointeenot to makeanychargesunsanctioned
experiencedsuchdifferingsuccessrates?Ifwecomparetheimpe- by local custom.98 Clearly, even officially,to saynothingof actual
rial armies, by far the largest items of state expenditure in both practice, the state had to recognise considerable room for "cre-
realms, we would not expect such a stark contrast. The army of ative" interpretation by its various representatives. The price the
the Great Mughal seems to have comprised around 200, 000 cav- local elite groups had to pay for their increased powers was greater
airyand40,000infantry,whereastheRoman,consistingmainlyof dependency on the state for their position. Though still in a posi-
infantry, counted approximately 400, 000soldiers attheendofthe tion of substantial autonomy in the day-to-day running of things,
second century AD. 95 Even allowing for the greater expenses con- openly disloyal, rebellious or overly recalcitrant wmindars risked
nected with the equipment of armed horsemen, the Mughal army facing the Mughal army and replacement by a more manageable
substitute, for instance a local rival."
is still surprisingly small, especially when we addthat the sizeof
theMughal population wasarounddoublethatofthe Roman. 96 The increased flow of surplus production out of the Indian coun-
Apparently, thegreatershareofthesurplus ina muchlargerecon- tryside, brought about by this alliance of local and state power,
omy didnot easily translate into military striking power ofvastly went into financing the central imperial institutions: the large
different dimensions. Something is missing from the equation. We household of the great Mughal himself and the imperial, military
forget that we are comparing netexpenditure ofthe Romans with nobility, the so-called mansabdars, who controlled and recruited
gross income ofthe Mughals. Taxes never come in cheaply. Being the largest part of the cavalry army. Of those two the lion's share
without a large, disciplined, but costly modern-style bureaucracy was taken by the mansabdars. It has been estimated that they were
to effectuate their commands, the Mughals instead had to create allocated about 80% of the enormous revenues of the Empire,
loyal andpowerful aristocratic groups atvarious levels ofimperial whose collection they had to organise through their agents and in
society to perform the functions of government. In return, these collaboration with the local elite groups. Most of this, probably
groups weresupported bytheassignment ofvery substantial shares around 60% or so, was intended as salary for the soldiers they
of the tax revenue. were obliged to maintain. The rest mainly consisted of a personal
Thus the Empire came to reshape the structure of north Indian payment for their services rendered towards the great Mughal and
elite society. At the baseofthe imperial formation alliances were was intended to finance their aristocratic and luxurious lifestyle.
formed with village headmen and local bigwigs, the so-called Thus the Mughal Empire can be likened to a giant revenue pump
zamindars. ^ Their position in the countryside was strengthened at the end of which was created an incredibly rich imperial elite
astheywereleftinchargeofcollection andpayment oftheimperial with large tbllowings organised around their grand households
taxes. This enhanced their control and authority over the peasantry dominatingthe main cities of the Empire.
and enabled them to increase their incomes, often substantially,
from their share in the imperial revenues and from tax rebates
or exemptions of substantial areas of land under their direct con- 9 Richards 1986:41. Impositionoftaxesis neverneutralin relationto theexistingsocial
structure. They are bound to invest their administrators with increased powers which
trol. not to mention from the increased opportunities to impose will be used to their private benefit. Hinton 1966, chapters 2-4, an anthropological
illicit or unofficial extra "taxes"; a Mughal letter formula for the micro-study of the Chinese village of Fanshen, provides one of the most revealing
descriptions of the repertoire of coercive tools available to a gentry in control of state
appointment ofthe headman for a district of villages includes an taxation for bringing the peasantry into economic dependence and for the eventual
confiscation of its lands.

95 Hassall 2000: 320-321 and Duncan-Jones 1994: 34- 99 AIam 1986, chapter 3, especially 92-93; Richards l993a: 86-91; Ali 1997: 84-87;
Habib 1999, chapter 5, especially 208-222.
96 Moosvi1987,chapter17;HabibandRaychaudhuri1982,chapter6. '"" Richards l993a, chapter3, especially75-78.SeefurtherQaisar 1967andMoosvi 1987.
97 Bayly 1983;'Alam1986,chapter3;Richardsl993a:86-91;All 1997:84-87;Hintze See Blake 1991 for grand households.
1997,chapter6; andHabib 1999,chapters4-5.

94
95
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY AN AGRARIAN EMPIRE BETWEEN MARKET AND TRIBUTE

As sketched here, much in this process of intertwined state and control claimed by the Mughal emperor over the landholdings of
elite formation seems rather familiar from what we know about the imperial elite was a tool which enabled him to punish and
the development of the Roman Empire. Perhaps, it is time for a reward individual members of the imperial aristocracy. It could
more inclusive understanding oftheRoman imperial state orrather not, however, be used to reserve all revenue for the emperor him-
a less unitary one? One peculiarity of the Mughal arrangement, self; he had to allow the aristocracy effective control of much of
though, would normally be taken to contradict this. The majority the imperial revenue. The regime of the great Mughal depended
of themansabdarswere not allowedto form more enduringlinks on his ability to attract the service of great and powerful men.
with the countryside which could be transformed into permanent Such men expected to be granted areas from which to collect rev-
landholdings. Every so often their revenue assignments would be enue in return for their loyalty. The Mughal emperor had to assign
reshuffled and they were allocated new areas from which to col- to his aristocracy most of his notional rights to agricultural rev-
lect their taxes. 10' This contrasts with the Roman world, where enue in a form of prebends called jagirs, a term which is perhaps
the resources of the imperial elite, consisting of senators and best described as denoting a kind of fief with the restriction that
knights, were invested in enormous conglomerations of private the monarch retains a greater degree of ultimate control than was
landholdings. Ever since the famous French traveller and dealer in normally the case in feudal Europe. A failure by the monarch to
diamonds, Jean-Baptiste Tavernier (1605-89), reported back to a secure access for his aristocracy to collect the wealth of extensive
horrified European public on how the so-called despotic practices agricultural areas would plunge Mughal rule into crisis. '05
oftheMughalsdeniedthenobility therighttoprivateproperty, this The contrast between the two systems, one based on private, the
has been taken as the defining difference between the powerful, other on prebendal, aristocratic land tenure, can, in other words,
independent more feudal forms of aristocracy found in the West easily be made too stark and risks concealing a more fundamen-
and the weaker, state-dependent Oriental nobilities. '02 Therefore tal similarity. In many ways, observing the Mughal system, where
the tribute extractionof theRomanstate is generally describedas tribute dominated rent-taking, provides a tmer picture of the work-
being structurally opposed to the independent rent-seeking activi- ings of the Roman system. 106 Certainly, the accumulation of vast
ties of the landed elites. They are perceived astwo separate forms property portfolios in the hands of the Roman imperial elite was
ofpowercompeting forthelimited surplus production ofthepeas- intimately connected with its access to the resources generated by
antry. 103 the acquisition of empire in the Mediterranean. It is in no way clear
There is no denying that the Empire knew a structural conflict that the Roman imperial elite was more independent and powerful
between, for example, senators and emperor, about the distribution than its Mughal equivalent. The mansabdars may not generally
of the surplus, but so did Mughal India. An important concern of have been allowed the luxury of vast private landholdings, but
the imperial establishment was to prevent the mansabdars from then they constituted the army and administered most of the impe-
maintaining fewersoldiers thanthey wererequired to whilepock- rial revenues. Had they in that position been conceded even more,
eting the saved expenses for their own benefit. 104 The ultimate one may seriously doubt that there would have been an empire
rather than a string of petty principalities. On the other hand, the
101 Richards 1993: 66-68. Seefurther Alam 1986, chapter I; Ali 1997, chapter 3; Hintze Roman senate, in spite of its landed wealth, usually found itself
1997,chapters4 and8; andHabib 1999,chapter7.
.
°2 Tavemier 1889: 260 (book II, chapter l).
.
°3 Thus Hopkins2000: 254-257 and Rathbone2000. 105 Richards 1975; Pearson 1976; All 1997 (1966): 92-94.
104 Ali 1997: 53-59 and Habib 1999 discuss this question but tend to underestimate Cf. Haldon 1993: 63-87 who argues against Wickham 1985 that aristocratic rents
theextentot thephenomenon;evenif themansabclarmaintainedthefull numberof should not be seen as structurally distinct from tribute extraction. Wickham 2005: 57-
soldiers he might still pocket a profit if he could hire the soldiers for less than the 60 now accepts this, but with an important modification: only as long as a centralised
awardedamount,e.g. Richards 1993:64-65. state maintains an ability to tax the peasantry.

96 97
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY AN AGRARIAN EMPIRE BETWEEN MARKET AND TRIBUTE

the weaker party when it confronted the emperor and/or the army. senators received nothing. '" It is the same pattern of thought we
It was that experience which gave the historical work of Tacitus find behind Pliny's description of Trajan, donating and selling
both its impassioned verve and disillusioned detachment. In times off parts of the imperial estates to members of the Roman elite;
of dynastic turmoil, it was not in the senate that the new emperor the princeps is complimented for allowing his friends (amid) to
was made; strong support in the army was overwhelmingly the benefit, instead of treating the Empire as identical with his own
decisive factor. When the courtier and senator Nerva was put on household. "2
the throne in Rome after the murder of Domitian in AD 96, his Ofcourse, that was precisely whattended to happen. Being so
feeble hold on power was only secured through the adoption of closely woven into the fabric of the imperial system, the fortunes of
one of the foremost generals of the Empire, Trajan, as heir to the the elite were highly vulnerable or permeable. The great narrative
throne. 10? histories of the early empire of Tacitus and Dio Cassius provide
Nothing illustrates better the relative weakness of the senatorial ample illustration of greedy emperors killing senators and other
order as opposed to the imperial system than its manifest failure aristocrats in order to confiscate their property. Yet, it would be a
effectively to make membership of the senate hereditary. As shown mistake to see this only as a question of periods of terror under
by Hopkins and Burton, even in the case of the more successful a few mad and cruel rulers. The phenomenon had much deeper
senators, who rose to the highest offices and obtained the consul- roots thanthis, andfoundits truest expressionin a setofpractices
ship, only a third managed to have male descendants within the next common to "good" and "bad" emperors alike. During the early
three generations reaching a similar standing. Some families would Empire the custom developed among members of the elite and
have died out in the male line. But a significant number would just various sections of the imperial apparatus to include the princeps
have withdrawn from politics in the capital altogether. '08 Partici- as co-heir in their wills. Furthermore, the emperor appropriated
pating in politics at the imperial court was a high-risk activity. The the right to properties left without an heir, without a valid will, and
expenditure alone required to maintain a senatorial household and those belongingto people condemnedon serious chargessuch as
lifestyle could be crippling to any fortune, however big. '09 Most murder or offences againstthe state. "3 Here is how Pliny, in his
senators would have found it necessary to add to their income the Panegyric to Trajan, elegantly labours to turn black into white,
substantial profits that could be made from holding high offices pressure into heartfelt gratitude:
in the imperial administration, such as army commands or gover-
norships of provinces. 110 Indeed, senators expected to be allowed You are not named as heir because someone else has given offence, but on your
own merits, set down by your personal friends and passed over by strangers. The
a substantial share of the resources generated by the imperial sys- onlydifferenceinfactbetweenyourformerprivatelifeandyourpresentsupreme
tem. The senatorial historian Dio Cassius, for instance, makes position lies in the greater number of those who love you, as your own affections
Maecenas advise Augustus to take the leading magnates across aremorewidelyspread.Onlycontinueonthiscourse,Caesar,andexperiencewill
the Roman world as "partners in empire". There is a distinct busi- show whether the reputation and purse alike of a prince are not better enriched
when his subjects make him their heir at their death from choice rather than from
nesslike flavour to the choice of vocabulary. Later in the Roman
compulsion. "4
History, Dio criticises his own emperor, Caracalla, for giving his
freedmen too great a share of the imperial proceeds while the Dio Cassius 52, 19, i-3 uses the expression "xoivcovoi CTOI Tf)s apxr)s". The term is
also used about proper business partnerships, e.g. Liddell and Scott, Greek-English
107 Syme 1958, chapters I and 2 for NervaandTrajan. SeeRoda 1998: 213-221 in general Lexicon s. v. I, 2. For Caracalla, Dio Cassius 78, l8, 4. See further Cassius Dio 52, 5,
about the impotence of the senate. Cf. Tac. Hist. I, 4. 1-2;52, I2;52,28 abouttheexpectationsofsenatorsofsharingin theproceedsofthe
108 Hopkins 1983(1: 134-146. I09 Hopkins 1983(1: 149-175. empire. Millar 1964: ro2-i 18 and chapter5 is still valuable.
''" Suet. Vesp. 4. 3 is quite telling about this. Here it is a cause for comment that Vespasian 112 Plin. Pan. 50. "3 Millar 1977: 153-174.
refrainedfrom enrichinghimselfduringhis governorshipof Africa, so endangeringhis 114 Plin. Pan. 43, citation from paragraphs 1-4, with Millar 1977: 156-157and Saller
credit. Most aristocrats knew better, cf. Brunt 1990, chapter 4. 1982:7I-73.

99
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY AN AGRARIAN EMPIRE BETWEEN MARKET AND TRIBUTE

Onegets a very clear sense oftheharsher reality behind this glossy process went in two directions, from the centre to the provinces
rhetorical image when Pliny goes on to describe it as a favour if andfrom the provincesto thecentre. Alreadyestablishedmembers
theemperoracceptsbeingpassedoverina willbysomeonewhom of the imperial elite would to a larger extent than hitherto acquire
he hadbenefited in some material way or other. estates scattered around the provinces. As provincial administra-
Anyabsolute distinction betweentheprivate fortunes oftheelite tors, they profitedfrom the dispensingofjustice andthe collection
andtheimperialstatethereforeseemsmistaken.Theestatesotsen- of taxes by various more or less sinister methods such as accep-
ators and knights equally belonged to the world of high politics. tance of gifts, "bribery", pocketing of parts of the imperial rev-
The connection comes out in full clarity during times of dynastic enues and collection of extra dues. 'I9 Some of this would have been

collapse. Theensuing struggles forthethrone andchanges inpower transformedinto provincial real estate. Throughprosopographical
relationships werenormally accompanied bya redistribution ofthe studies it is possible to follow howsome senatorialfamilies, based
wealth of the elite on a considerable scale. Aristocrats linked with in Italy, gradually built up large estates in parts of the provinces
the losing factions risked facing destruction, confiscation oftheir where they had governed. 120 An important aspect of this process
property andits subsequent redistribution among themembers of was the lending of money at high rates of interest by wealthy
the victorious coalition, many of whom would have been stimu- Roman aristocrats to provincial communities, lacking money to
latedbythedesireforspoilsorbytheunsettledstateoftheirprivate pay their taxes. '21 Seneca is said to have lent something like HS
affairs"."5 It istellingthattherateofhereditarysuccessionamong 40 million, at a very high rate of interest, to needy communities
the highest-standing and hence best-established consulars seems in the newly conquered province of Britain, only to have the debt
to have fallen from around 50% to only 30% in times of political called in shortly after. The harshness with which he proceeded to
instability. [ I6Basicallythen,theenormousfortunesoftheimperial collect the debts was supposed to have been an important con-
elite depended upon having access to the power resources gener- triburing factor to Queen Boudica's rebellion. 122 Undoubtedly, an
atedby the empire andultimately controlled by the emperor. "7 exacerbating factor was that many had seen their lands confiscated
This reflected the fact that they were also very much the creation in the process of settling the debt. In the late fourth century the
ofthe empire. The period ofrepublican expansion hadwitnessed Syrian orator Libanius complained that aristocrats in state offices
thebuild-upofproperty andwealthinthehandsoftheRomanelite exploited their positions to lend money to town councillors and
ona steadilyincreasingscale financedbyprofitsdrawnfromth^ then took over their estates whenpayment failed. 123
exploitation andconquest oftheconstantly expandingEmpire." A central element in all of this was the easier access enjoyed by
The growth of aristocratic property portfolios continued under people of high standing to the coercive machinery of the Empire.
the Principate. It wasfuelled by a stronger integration ofprovm-
ciallandholdingsintothetributary systemoftheRomanstate.The Plutarch's description (Moralia 8l4D) of the leading imperial offices in the provinces
as "TToAuTaAavTous"(generatingmuchmoney) is revealing. Onprovincial administra-
lion: Saller 1982, chapter 5; Woolf [998, chapter 2; Eck 2000: 281-288. Specifically
"5 Tac. Hist. [I, 7. Thecloselink betweenviolentdynasticstrugglesandredistribution on taxation: Neesen 1980; Garnsey 1988, chapter 15; Merola 2001.
ot aristocraticwealthisa mainthemeot'Tacitus' Histories,e.g.1, 2;I, 20, I, 88;md Roda 1998: 214-215 with bibliography.
II, 84.Of'course oneshouldbecautious oftakingTacitus' laments too seriously. The Howgego 1994. Dig. 18. 5. 9 discusses the selling-up of land burdened with tax arrears.
122
sug~gestion,however,thataristocratswithfinancialproblemshadeverythm8tojam 123
Dio Cassius 62, 2, I.
Lib. 48, 3 and 14. Though late, Libanius is no less relevant for the earlier period. The
from'the turmoil surely isquiterevealing, notbecausewe should acceptTacitus' sneer
thatallthe"troublemakers"werebankrupts,butbecauseoftheunderlyingexpectation practice was ingrained in Roman provincial administration. Apart from Seneca, it is
thatsuchpeople wouldbeabletoprofitsubstantially fromjoining a rebellion. vividly attested in the correspondence of Cicero. The letters, Alt. 5. 21; 6. 1; 6. 2 and
6. 3 (with Rauh 1986), discuss Brutus' usurious loans to provincial communities. See
"6 Hopkins i983a: 138-139, including table 3. 6.
"7 Sal'ler 1982,chapter2 andMillar 1977:275-355showtheintegrationot theelitein a further Plutarch's essay, "That we Ought Not to Borrow", in the Moralia, paragraphs
828E-829E on the general importance of money lending for the redistribution of land
network of imperial patronage.
in provincial communities.
'I8 Hopkins 19780: 39-56. Seefurther Shatzman 1975: i i-[76.
101
100
T
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY AN AGRARIAN EMPIRE BETWEEN MARKET AND TRIBUTE

Senators, knights and other persons of substance would often, for played a crucial role in enabling it to acquire and maintain estates
instance, have been able to use their connections within the impe- in different regions of the Empire. '3"
rial system to secure the support of government troops to settle Another way forward was to team up with a local aristocrat
conflicts to their own advantage, not least in connectionwith the and town councillor who enjoyed sufficient influence locally to
collection ofdebts. 124The importanceofthis shouldnotbeunder- promote and guard the economic interests of rich outsiders. Liba-
estimated. Roman society wasnot strongly regulated andpeaceful. nius, for example, complains about how the leading members of
Violencewasendemic.Peoplewho suddenlyfoundthemselves in the town councils as middlemen for people in government posi-
weaker positions, such as orphans and widows, frequently expe- tionshandledruinous loansthatdeprivedtheirless prosperouscol-
rienced difficulties in holding on to their material possessions. 125 leagues oftheir landholdings. '3' Undoubtedlythese local bigwigs
Claims needed to be defended and asserted in order to count. 126 profited substantially from their involvement in those transactions
This was also true of the legal system. Hearing a case, as Aulus with people in higher positions. As such, this only represents a par-
Gelliusinformsus,wasnotjust a matterofweighingtheevidence. ticular instance of a more general phenomenon. Plutarch urged the
The general standing and social clout of the litigants were equally leading town councillors to cultivate the patronage of members
important matters to take into consideration. 127 A trial was to a of the imperial provincial administration because "the Romans
very large extent a question of measuring out the relative power themselves are most eager to promote the political interests of
and influence of the contestants. '28 Hence the established prac- their friends" and would serve them "as a firm bulwark". 132 The
tice ofusing one's powerful connections to influence the outcome. reason for this was, of course, that the Empire depended on the
Again it does not require much imagination to see how a Roman payment of taxes. But being without a large bureaucratic corps, it
senator or knight with a stake in the financial exploitation of the needed to create a group of local allies who were strong enough
provinces would benefit from this. To judge from the collections to control the area, ensure its continuous peaceful subjugation and
of letters preserved from antiquity, it was an aspect of the mutual handle the actual collection of the imperial tribute. In his auto-
exchange of favours inside the personal networks of the imperial biography Josephus, a local Jewish grandee, provides us with
elite to write to provincial governors with whom one had links, a close-up of how this was done in practice. When the Jewish
asking them to look kindly on the cases of one's friends, proteges rebellion had been almost quelled, Titus, the Roman commander,
and connections. Ofcourse, it is difficult to know how much influ- offered to spare Josephus' friends and relations from punishment
ence such recommendations exercised on the governor/judge, and andcaptivity, thuspreservinghisnetworkofsocialcontacts. After-
it will in any case have varied from case to case, according to the wards Josephus was presented with lands in Judaea, first by Titus
circumstances. But the very fact that these letters were written, and then later by his father, the ruling emperor, Vespasian. Later
shows that people expected them to have an effect. 129 Thus, it still, the emperor Domitian added to the gift by granting tax immu-
seems reasonable to suggest that the various kinds of support that nity to his properties in Judaea. Throughout this period of imperial
the imperial elite could mobilise from the state system must have favouritism Josephus also enjoyed the support and protection of
the emperors against political rivals who tried to bring him down
124 Brutusattemptedtoobtainmilitarysupportforthecollectionofprovincialdebtsfrom by accusinghim of treason againstthe Roman cause. 33
CiceroasgovernorofCilicia,Cic. Att. 6. 1.5-6. Seefurthertheanecdotalevidencein
Apuleius' Metamorphoses (VII, 6-7) and MacMullen 1990: 191-193. ]3° Saller 1982, chapter 4 for the importance of access to the resources generated by the
[25 Krause 1994, chapter 10 and pp. 232-235 and Krause 1995, chapter 13, especially Empire to the imperial elite.
pp. 195-200. 131 Libanius 48, 37-41. I32 Plutarch Moralia 8140.
126 Millar 1981: 66-71 and MacMullen 1990, chapter 18. 133 Josephus Vit. 422-430. The autobiography is itself a defence written to counter the
.
27 Gellius 14.2 withGamsey 1970:210-211. I28 Saller1982:56-60. accusations of a rival, Ju.stus of Tiberias (Vit. 336-367, 410). Brunt 1990, chapter 13
129 Saller 1982: 152-154. on Josephus and Empire.

102 103
AN AGRARIAN EMPIRE BETWEEN MARKET AND TRIBUTE
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY
to the prosperous insiders themselves. Plutarch admonished the
Josephus, however, was also exceptional. The vast majority of
local aristocrats would never have experienced anything resemb- leading citizens not to (ab)use the support of the Roman author-
ities to satisfy their own greed and drive away the less power-
lingtheclosedirectpatronageoftherulingdynastythatheenjoyed.
Yet on a scale less grand, the privileged cocktail of protection, ful. 13 Libanius adds greater detail to the picture. Much to his
land and tax benefits was offered to those in powerful positions, dismay, the local landed magnates did not just act as middlemen
who where willing to co-operate, around the provinces of the for people in higher positions. They also took advantage of their
power actively to increase their own wealth by imposing too heavy
Empire. 134 In organisational terms, the Empire was only lc)osely
burdens on their lesser colleagues in the city councils and after-
integrated. As has been said so many times before, the world of
the Romans was, rather, a patchwork of conquered city states. wards forcing expensive loans upon them that made them lose their
lands. '39
Thesewereretainedat the time ofconquestasthebasicandinter-
True, both Plutarch and Libanius criticise the system. In that
nally largely self-governing administrative units. In areas where
respect, they are also witnesses to ideological attempts to limit the
city state organisation had been lacking, the Roman conquerors
introducedit in orderto satisfythe needsofthe imperial adminis- most brutal effects of its workings. The Roman jurists, too, gave
rulings that prohibited the uneven distribution of tax burdens and
tration. Among the functions of city government was the respon-
government requisitions. 140 Such ideological misgivings and legal
sibility for the payment of the imperial taxes. Each city tem-
admonitions, however, should not be interpreted as fundamental
tory was assessed at a set amount of tribute, and the leading and
richest citizens were effectively left in charge of distributing the attempts to combat and change the basic principles of the exploita-
burden internally within the landowning segment of the citizen tive machinery. Plutarch, after all, recommended municipal rule
by the leading and richest members of each community, supported
body. 135Obviously, this gavethem considerable power androom
for manoeuvre. To begin with, they were normally able to ensure by Roman government representatives. Rather, these phenomena
should be seen as (feeble) mechanisms to contain those activities
that their own property would be underestimated, one way or
another. 136 Moreover, this did not just enable them to avoid pay- within bounds in order to ensure the longevity of the system. The
sheep had to be sheared, perhaps even fleeced, but not gutted. Too
ing their full share of the taxes. Usually, it also meant increasing
the burden on those less well off and hence less able to shoulder harsh a regime might undermine the tax-paying capacity of the
it. 137 Thus an avenue of access was opened up for the extension cities by causing social unrest, banditry or just impoverishment
of rural credit. We have already seen how this was used as an and abandonment of cultivated land. It was a question of main-
investment opportunity by rich outsiders, but it was also open taining a balance. But that balance remained heavily tilted towards
the members of the most prominent families around the cities of
the Empire because they were the most important guarantors of
'34 Some general references must suffice: Jones 1940; Gamsey 1988,chapter 15; Brunt social stability. 4
1990,chapter 12; JacquesandScheid 1990,chapters5-7.
'35 /GV(l), 1432-1433 (with Hopkins 1995-6: 68, n. 28) showhow thecity of Messene n!i Plut. Mora;;a8l5a.
allocated its'tax of"100,000 denariiamong its citizens. See further Bay 1972: 32-47;
!39 Libanius 48, 37-41. The practice of overburdening weaker members of the councils
Jones 1974, chapter 8; Neesen 1980; Brunt 1990, chapter 15. is confirmed by rulings in the Digesta, e. g. Dig. L.4. 3. I5 (Plutarch Moralia 827-832
I3f> P. Beatty Panop.2, lines68-71 and 145-152is a goodexample.Theleadingmag- warns more generally against the corrosive effect of credit on the economic fortunes
natesm'Panopolis hadcolluded with a village official to leave some cultivated land of councillors). Control of taxation and loan-giving was a powerful tool of wealth-
undeclared, thereby effectively carving outtax-free landsfortheirownbenefit. acquisition in the hands of pre-industrial elites. Hinton 1966: 50 is illuminating.
'37 dc. U Verr.2, n8 isclearaboutthismechanism.SeeVeyne1990:200(andnote292) 140 D(g. L.4. 3. l5(Ulpian).
whoalso addsthe testimony of CodexJustinianus,Xl, 58 (57), I: a law of AD 313
whichobservesthat"thetabulariiofthecities,incollusionwiththepowerful,shiftthe 4 Cic. Q. fr. I, 1, 25 is clear about the need to avoid internal stmggles in the cities,
banditry etc. to maintain the tax capacity of the province.
burden of taxes onto the lesser people".

i05
104
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY AN AGRARIAN EMPIRE BETWEEN MARKET AND TRIBUTE

One gets a very clear idea of this from the institution of courts a certain Opramoas of Rhodiapolis.145 Normally attention has
to hear complaints of provincials about the activities of Roman focused on the enormous gifts that he bestowed on the Lycian
governors. In Cicero's speeches against the most notorious culprit communities during a period of a quarter century (AD 125-52).
in provincial maladministration, Gaius Verres, a recurrent strategy They seem to add up to something like 1,000,000 denariior about
of discrediting the accused is to emphasise how he alienated and four times the minimum legal requirement of a senatorial for-
encroached on the wealth of the leading members of the Sicilian tune. 146 This is munificence on a truly staggering scale. In Paul
provincial communities. Verres' crime as governor was not just Veyne s interpretation, Opramoas is the ideal embodiment of the
his deeds of self-enrichment, but more the damage done to those spirit ofeuergetism, a virtuoso taking to an extreme the habit of the
upon whom Roman rule was based. In seeking to profit from his aristocracy of making public benefactions by performing financial
office Verres had not respected the established social hierarchy. suicide in a kind of ancientpotlatch. '47
Therefore, according to Cicero, he could only muster the support I remain sceptical about that interpretation. Opramoas was not
ofsmall fry andpersonsofdubiousreputationandpowerwhohad alone in the province and neighbouring regions in demonstrating
gained from his attacks on the homines nobilissimi primique^ such spending capacity. '48 Ultimately, of course, in the absence
Whether a governor would be prosecuted and punished for his of his private accounts we will never know whether he did indeed
(mal)administration seems, in other words, to have been decided ruin his patrimony. But what we do know is that gift-giving on this
less by what he did than whom he did it to. It was essential that level, sustained for many years, requires a substantial build-up of
he secured support from a section of the provincial upper classes wealth and the generation of very large incomes. Altruism is not
with sufficient strength to be able to block attempts to have him nearly enough to maintain such activity. Here we find Opramoas
indicted after his time of office had expired. 143 and his family, exactly as we might expect, playing a central role
As in the Mughal Empire then, the imposition of Roman hege- in the political life of the province and cultivating the patronage of
many considerably modified the pre-existing pattern of power Roman magistrates andemperors. According to the inscriptions the
around the numerous cities of the empire. The administration of family had a prominent record of office holding within the Lycian
imperial tribute extraction enhanced the strength of the leading koinon, or league, perhaps stretching back before Roman rule. 149
local landowners. As a result, these elite groups were able grad- But the first member for whom we have more detailed informa-
ually to accumulate wealth and property on a larger scale than tion is Opramoas' father Apollonios. He played a dominant role
before. 144 A clear sign of this is that "big men" with very large in his hometown Rhodiapolis, holding all its major offices, and
financial capacities indeed begin to surface in our sources. The attained a position of some prominence in the provincial coun-
province of Lycia, on the south coast of Asia Minor has revealed cil, though he does not seem to have reached the highest office
some of the best evidence for this process through its very strongly of lykiarch. 150 However, he had certainly managed to concentrate
developed epigraphic habit. A whole dossier of inscriptions, recov- enough wealth and influence during his career to see two sons,
ered from a funerary monument, describe the brilliant career of including Opramoas, off to even greater glory and influence. We
meet Opramoas first in AD 125, when his father performed the
142 dc. II Verr. 2, ll. Further II, 2, 14, 22, 35-49 dismissing provincial supporters of office of archiphylax both in his own name and in the name of
Verres as small fry anddesperate people hopingto benefitby turning the social order
upside down. 145 TAM 905. Kokkinia 2000 presents a new improved edition of the text, with detailed
143 CIL XIII. -(162, with Saller 1982:132. "real kommentar". Heberdey 1897 reconstructed the chronology of the information
144 See Brunt 1990, chapter 12 and Garnsey 1988: 246-251 for this development. For contained in the inscriptions.
studies of individual provinces, seee. g. Garnsey 1978 (Africa), Millet 1990(Britain), 14(' SeeCoulton 1987: [72 fora recentdiscussion. 147 Veyne 1990: 149-150.
Jones1940;Quass1993;Merola2001;Dmitriev2005(GreekEast),Woolf1998(Gaul) 148 Coulton 1987. I49 TAM 905, [VC, lines 13-14.
and 0rsted 1986 (Noricum and Illyricum). 150 TAM 905, I1B, IIIE-Fand VIIIC.

io6 Toy
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY AN AGRARIAN EMPIRE BETWEEN MARKET AND TRIBUTE

his two sons. This was an office which required great financial base by excessive expenditures. Instead, the inscriptions convey
resources. In the honorary decreesOpramoasis describedas hav- the impression of a family steadily increasing its resources and
ing paid "the taxes owed to the imperial coffers by the province sphere of influence. A further indication of this is that as his career
with his own money and only afterwards began the collection with progressed he seems to have acquired considerable interests in
greatphilanthropy". '51 Onewouldliketoknowtheeconomic real- the province outside his hometown Rhodiapolis. Some of the later
ity behind this phrase. But in the light of the foregoing discussion inscriptions show him as having acquired citizenship in several
it seems farfrom unlikely that Opramoas or, to bemore precise, his other Lycian communities. He is also described as pursuing poli-
father, would have been able to profit from handling theprovincial ties actively in all the cities of Lycia- a fact which is documented
taxes. If nothing else, we find the family securing the patronage of by the very wide distribution of his benefactions across a broad
the governor lulius Frugi, who praised them in official letters. 152 selection of the cities in the province. 155 They could, of course,
At any rate, the patrimony of the family was certainly not be interpreted as an instance of pure generosity, but it seems more
ruined orendangered bythis. Onthecontrary, during thefollowing reasonable to take them as a sign of Opramoas' need to cultivate
twenty-five years Opramoas (and his brother) expanded the power his interests on a province-wide scale. He had now grown beyond
his hometown.
of the family and rose to the highest positions in the province,
including secretary and lykiarch, the leader ofthe provincial coun- In this connection, it is certainly not without interest that the
cil and high priest ofthe imperial cult. All of this brought him into family continuedits expansivemove in the next generation. One of
close contact with successive Roman governors. Their many letters the last inscriptions proudly records that a nieceof Opramoashad
of praise addressed to the provincial council allow us a glimpse enteredthe imperial elite by marryingthe senator, ClaudiusAgrip-
of how Opramoas continued the work ofhis father and expanded pinus. '5 The couple is also known from a fascinating inscription
his network of imperial supporters. 153 Several of the governors found in the Lyciancity Oenoanda,listing a genealogy of another
even assisted in bringing Opramoas to the attention oftheemperor leading Lycian family. '57 From that we can see that Agrippinus
AntoninusPius,whohonouredhim in letters on morethan a dozen eventually reached the office of consul. In the generations follow-
occasions.154This does not look like a man eroding his economic ing this union we find senators, consuls and even a governor for
the province ofLyciaandPamphyliafrom this family. Agrippinus
151 TAM 905, IIE, lines 10-14. From the proceeding information andtext 14 and XIIIC, himself was from an old family of lykiarchs. One of his forefa-
line 4, it is clear that his first positions were held through his father. thers was lykiarch as early as around the middle of the first century.
'52 7-AM905.IF.ContraQuass 1993: 177-178.whoonlyseestheeuergetisticsideofthe
handling of taxes. Two generations later we find Agrippinus' grandmother marrying
'53 Opramoasenjoyed the patronageof effectively every governor in Lyei a duringthe a Roman aristocrat, who held the governorship of Spain and also
period.Weknowthe nameofthegovernorin twenty-twoyearsofthe twenty-eight
years covered by the inscriptions, and all of those more than ten governors found it commanded a legion. The daughter of this marriage married a
worth their while to support Opramoas - one or two of them, though, only after some lykiarch and in the next generation we then find the son, Claudius,
initialresistance.Oncompletion ofthe lykiarchyOpramoaswasvoted extraordinary
honours.Askedtosupport'this,thegovernorcrypticallyrepliesthatthekoinonoughtto and the daughter, Claudia Helena, re-entering the imperial
follow established practice. This isprobably notsupport, asKokkiniatakesit tobe, but aristocracy.
ratheranattempttocurbtheambitionsofOpramoas.Thefollowinggovernorcontinues
theresistanceto theseextraordinaryhonoursbut is outmanoeuvredby Opramoaswho As a group the inscriptions show in detail how the interac-
securesthebackingoftheemperor(TAMgos,VIIA-VIIIA,Kokkinia2000:225-228). tion of local elites with the tributary empire gradually led to the
Rather than a "potlatch" aristocrat, Opramoas better fits Tacitus' category (Ann. xv,
xx) of leading provincial magnates whose great wealth allowed them to dominate the
province and were of crucial importance to the governor. 155 TAM905, VIIIB-Ementionssixcitieswithoutbeingexhaustive.Texts53 and59show
154 TAM 905, texts 37-51 areletters from the emperor honouring Opramoas. Several had the wide dispersal of Opramoas' benefactions.
beensupportedbythepatronageofgovernors.Heberdey1897:70-71hasa convenient 156 TAMgos-XVIIID,lines 12-13.
list. 57 IGRIII,500. SeeHeberdeyandKalinka 1896for a graphicrepresentation.

io8 log
AN AGRARIAN EMPIRE BETWEEN MARKET AND TRIBUTE
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY
formation of stronger and richer elite groups. At the pinnacle of customary emphasis on a conflict of interest between tributary
this elite, are to be found some families which had risen to a level empire and various rent-taking aristocratic strata is only one part
of wealth that made them big even in a provincial context and of the imperial experience. The empire is not just engaging in a
whose interests would often have exceeded the bounds of their socially destructive war against its aristocracy where it will either,
local community. This made them attractive partners for already as a capstone in John Hall's phrase, curtail and break the landed
elites or disintegrate into numerous small cells. Rather, the central
established members ofthe imperial elite, both interms ofmarriage
and as resourceful allies who could be promoted into the highest power depended for its existence on partly dissolving the oppo-
orders of imperial society as they invariably needed replenish- sition and successfully integrating the more local forms of power
ment. '58 Detailed and painstaking prosopographical research into into the imperial fabric. Some years ago the late Burton Stein, a
historian of pre-colonial India, put forward the concept of seg-
the composition of the Roman senate has revealed how during
the first two centuries AD under the auspices of the emperors, it mentary state to denote this kind of political system. By this he
changed from a body of Italian aristocrats to a gathering of the meant that the imperial state could not be reduced to the cen-
"best"men" from across the Empire. '59 This is, of course, a sign tral institutions of the emperor's household and the army, it also
of the relative weakness of the senatorial aristocracy. But it also encompassed "a large sub-stratum of local lordships, magnates
reveals the strength ofthe imperial system. It managed, asit were, or... honoratiores". '6' The great advantage ofStein's formulation
to (re)fashion and (re)produce its own elite. 160What is more, this is that it recognises that state (tribute) and local forms of power
was done on a steadily increasing scale as larger and larger accu- (feudal rent) are not absolutely separate. As aristocracies come to
mulations of provincial land were merged into the existing stock participate in the functions of the state system, through office hold-
of wealth in the hands of the imperial elite. Thus, to talk about ing and the collection of taxes, the two forms of authority begin
the weakness of the imperial aristocracy is paradoxical, for it grew to blend. Invariably they become intertwined and, depending on
richer and came to command larger social resources through its the success and durability of the imperial formation, mutually
supportive.
dependence ontheimperial system. LiketheMughal Empire, the Tribute extraction, in other words, was never just a question
Roman Empire appears to have worked like a powerful revenue
of depleting the resources of local communities. In return for
pump.
handling taxation, aristocrats were, as we have seen, allowed to
profit substantially at various strategic points in the process. This
Tributary integration: themarket assurplus transformer needs to be added to the bill if we are to reach a proper assess-
ment of the economic impact of the Roman state. At least for
Thus the comparison with Mughal India adds a new perspective the central aristocratic groups, senate and knights in the impe-
to our understanding of patrimonial bureaucratic empires. The rial administration, it is possible to get an idea of how this works
out in our quantitative model of the imperial economy (Table 2. 1,
's8 Saller1982,chapter5 onthepatternsoftheprovincialpatronageoftheunperialelite.
'w The exoression is commonplace in the contemporary literature: Aristeides Or.^ step 11). Based on Pliny's letters, Duncan-Jones has estimated the
2^4^'7'l"and'DioCassiusr52, 15 with Oliver 1953; Millar 1964: . 02-118^md annual income (not to be mistaken for the census requirement)
Aapte'r 5"ChastagnoFl992 a"dKoda 1998: 172-213, chapter n survey±%reseal;ch of a middling senator at approximately HS i million in the early
on the changing composition of the senate. Stein 1927, chapters 3-4 and ?>rlerw1"^
White l973a, e.g. 402-417 are still valuable Hammond 1957 is tu"clame"taL,
furtherAli-5ldyi977;Hiilfmann1979;Epigrafiae ordinesenatono
and
1982. Particularly
on knights, see Pflaum 1950; Demougin 1988; Demougin Deyi jver 1999. ^
.
60 A'c'l'eaTexpressionofthiswasthecreationofa secondlegoftheimPerial^elite^as Stein 1985(1, especially 387-388 and 410-411, citation from 411. See further Stein
knightswe'readmittedtopowerfulpositionsintheEmpirenexttothesenate;seeSal 1998: 18-30, stressing the duality of conflict and dependence.
1982,especiallychapter3;Hopkins l983a:[76-184.
Ill
110
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY AN AGRARIAN EMPIRE BETWEEN MARKET AND TRIBUTE

second century AD. 162 Some senatorial households would have have been within a range of 10-20% of GDP in both cases. This
experienced inuch greater incomes. On the other hand, some also does not look impressive. But when we realise that this would
had problems even in meeting the economic requirements of a have constituted close to one-third of the disposable surplus in
political career. 163 Hence it seems reasonable to adopt the figure the Roman case (and it cannot have been wildly different in the
based on Pliny's experience as an average annual income for the Mughal case) it is clear that it could not easily have been much
6oo or so senators, even though we might actually be underestimat- larger (Fig. 2. 3 is a graphicrepresentationof the model). '67
ingthewealthofthesenatethen. '64Thecontoursoftheequestrian As already mentioned, the revenues of the imperial system
tranche of the central imperial elite are more hazy. But to judge (emperor, armyandcentralaristocracy)werespentunevenlyacross
from the growing number ofequestrian procuratorships (127 are the empires and often at a considerable distance from their collec-
attested in the reign of Marcus Aurelius) it would have required a tion point. IntheRomancaseit wasto a very largeextentconsumed
group more or less equal in size to the senate to fill the spaces. 5 by emperor andelite in the capital and in the borderregions where
The wealthiest and most powerful knights clearly were richer than the army was stationed. 168 This means that much of the revenue
many members of the senate. But this would not generally have intakehadto enterregionalandinterregionalcirculationin orderto
been the rule, rather the opposite would have been the case if the reach its point ofexpenditure. In Table 2. 1, step 12, 1 have tried to
lower property qualification of this group is anything to go by. A indicate the consequences of different proportions of GDP going
fair guestimate would put the income of the equestrian members outside its nearest marketing network, that is, entering intercity
of the central imperial aristocracy at half that of the senate. In resource flows. At 10% ofGDP, about 20-25% of the disposable
numbers this gives 600 x HS I million + 50% = HS 900 million surplus would be spoken for in this way. At 20% of GDPit would
or an extra 15% of the disposable surplus to be addedto the 15% be 45-50%. Clearly this must be pushing against the maximum
which was estimated above for central government expenditure limit of whatcould have happened. Even though the consumer-city
(Table 2. 1, step 11). model has been hotly debated, few people would doubt that a very
This makes the Roman Empire look a lot more like the Mughal large section of the surplus was spent locally by the municipal
Empire, especially if we take into consideration that the Mughals' aristocracies around the numerous ordinary cities of the empire.
notionalintakeofone-thirdofproductioninreality wouldprobably Data from both eighteenth- and nineteenth-century India and late
have been closer to one-fourth or one-fifth. Then when we imperial China, too, suggests that we should envisage a level of
subtract the substantialpart that went into the pockets of the local intercity exchange of between 10 and 20% of GDP in the Roman
aristocracies, the wmindars, the two empires come to look very Empire. 9
much alike. The revenue of the central imperial system seems to

Duncan-Jones 1982, chapter I. See also Hopkins 2000, n. 5 for some comments on the 167 Huang 1974: 159-i61 on MingChinashowsthenarrowlimits forimperialtaxation.
material informing us of the scale of aristocratic wealth. 168 Whittaker 1993, chapter 12: 61-62 for a balanced account of imperial aristocratic
163 Millar 1977: 297-300. 4 Chastagnol 1992,chapter [0. consumption.
15 Whittaker 1993,chapter)2: 61-62 adoptsa similarfigurefor thesizeoftheequestrian lb9 Yang 1998: 223-224 lists a number of estimates from eighteenth- and nineteenth-
section of the imperial elite. Pflaum 1950 and 1960-1 are the classic studies of the century India. They indicate a rise in the marketable surplus from 20 to 30% of
equestrian imperial procurators. production. Ofthis a significantportion is bound to have been sold withinthe region
166 The Mughal revenue intake is a thorny issue. But independently of how we assess this ofproduction.Oneestimatesawabout 10%ofagriculturalproductionenterwidernet-
problem two things operate in favour of lowering towards one-fourth or one-flfth of worksofcirculation. Expressedasa proportion ofGDP,whenmanufacturedproducts
GDP. The figure of one-third is of agricultural production. To be strictly comparable and other luxuries are added into the calculation, this suggests a level of interregional
to our Roman figure, it should be adjusted to take account of urban production and trade of about 10-20% of'GDP. Perkins 1969: 115-120 estimates total value of inter-
services which only contributed modestly to Mughal taxes. On top of this, many cash regional trade in late imperial Chinaat 15-20%of gross farm output. Expressedas a
crops were only taxed at a rate of one-fifth. Taken together these two factors go a long proportion of GDP (farm output plus production and services in the cities) the figure
way to bring the Mughal tax figure within "our" range. will be a little lower, perhaps 10-15%.

112 ii3
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY AN AGRARIAN EMPIRE BETWEEN MARKET AND TRIBUTE

53 State net specialising in single products and exchanging them with one
expenditure
another. '72

0 Imperial This may be stated with confidence. Even if we should have


elite underestimated the value of the economic surplus and interre-
E3 Remaining gional trade in our model by, say, a third, the conclusion is not
surplus much affected; imperial expenditurewould still be able to account
E3 Agricultural for up to 50% of our maximum level of intercity transfers. This
subsistence would, for instance, be the case if the average price ofgrain rather
than the HS 3 adopted in our calculations was closer to HS 4 per
Fig. 2. 3 Roman GDP, surplus and tributary empire
modius. But that would haveto beconsidered a highprice in many
regions of the empire, acceptable perhaps in times of threatening
For our understanding of the economy of the Empire this sce-
famine, but not characteristic of the prevailing conditions. 173 A
nario has important implications. To begin with, it is difficult to
similareffectwouldbe producedby increasingtheestimateofthe
identity market exchange as the dominant organising force ofeco-
Roman population from 60 to 80 million. However, that popula-
nomic integration in the empire. At our imagined maximum level
tion figure represents the plausible maximum. It is as high as the
of interregional resource transfers, expenditure related to the cen-
more optimistic of modern considered estimates go. Ofcourse, the
tral imperial system would be able to account for up to two-thirds.
compounded effect of adopting both modifications to the model
In practice, some of this would have gone into property trans-
would be more serious, though far from damaging. Such a pro-
fers from tribute payers to the tribute-receiving groups in society.
cedure would reduce the combined weight of imperial state and
This is the implication of the processes of increased concentra-
aristocracy in the surplus to approximately 15%. That would still
tion of agricultural land in aristocratic hands described above.
be a very noticeable, but admittedly weaker, force in the imperial
But even in that case, a large part of the politically extracted sur-
economy (see Table 2. 1, step 13 for a summary).
plus would still have had to be exchanged between the different
But why would we choose to compound our most optimistic
regions of the empire. '7" No wonder that archaeologists again and
estimates? It is certainly not necessary in order to accommodate
again emphasise the different scale of activity between Greek and .

a more optimistic" view of exchange in the empire. A model of


Roman history. 171 Imperial tribute extraction must have dramat- an agrarian economy which provides for some 10-20% of GDP
ically changed and expanded or at least considerably modified
to be transferred between localities does not present a "minimal-
the pre-existing pattern of economic circulation in the Mediter-
ist" scenario of Roman exchange activities, quite the reverse. It
ranean world. If we want to speak of economic unity in the Roman
bears emphasis that the different parameters adopted in the model
Empire we would do well to start by looking for tribute extraction
cannot simply beincreased atwill. One ofthe advantages ofquan-
and the shared processes of elite formation and concentration of
titative speculation is that it enables us to observe how the different
landed property rather than a conglomeration of interconnected
parameters are interrelated. Increasingthe value of GDP, without
capitalist markets. Consumption related to the profits of empire
changing our estimate of state expenditure, has the questionable
comes out as such a powerful stimulus that there cannot be much
room for a development in interregional trade driven by regions Cf.Perkins1969:I2&-I23onthepatternofinterregionaltradeintheChineseEmpire;
the politically determinedconsumption ofemperorandhiselite dominatedoverinter-
regional specialisation.
170 See Jongman 2006: 248-50 for an attempt to model the scale of property transfers Cf. the edictof the governorAntistius Rusticusproclaiming i denariuspermoclius
spawned by the imposition of an imperial tribute. ot grain (twice the normal level) as the maximum permitted price during a famine in
171 Mattingly and Salmon 2001: 3-14. PisidianAntioch(AE 1925, 126= Sherk 1988, no. 107).
ii4 TI5
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY AN AGRARIAN EMPIRE BETWEEN MARKET AND TRIBUTE

implication of reducing the weight of government institutions to In other words, though we do not and never will know the exact
almost nothing in the economy. In the present case of a compound sizeofthe Romaneconomy,our speculativemodellinghasto oper-
increase in grain price and population size, the costs of impe- ate within certain constraints. Increasingone parameter may well
rial court and army are reduced to 3-4% of GDP. That would be require us to reduce another in order to keep the dimensions real-
difficult to justify. '74 The model already operates with a "small- istic. Perhapsthe most problematic parameterin the quantification
scale" Roman state. There is little reason to make it even smaller. of the Roman economy is the choice of multiplier from minimum
Only a generation ago, leadinghistorians suchasJonesand Brunt subsistence to GDP, set by Hopkins to 1. 5. One cannot claim that it
thought of Roman taxation as oppressive. '75 The Roman emperor could not possibly be any bigger. But it could not be much bigger.
was the single biggest landowner in the empire; and the fiscus The limits canbeexploredby setting up a simpleequationdescrib-
drew substantial rents from these extensive properties. A recent ing the living standards which are possible for different population
estimate of taxation in the province of Egypt sees the Roman segments underdifferent productivity/incomeregimes (how many
authorities claiming perhaps some 20% of provincial economic times subsistence). Table 2. 2 explains the mathematics and sum-
output. Taken together, these two observations alone would suf- marises the results of using different values for the agricultural
fice to bring Roman government income within the range of 3- population, for economies in the range of 2-3 times minimum
4% of GDP, thus precluding the need for any further taxation subsistence. Let us examinethe implications of the most prosper-
around the rest of the empire. To this list must also be added ous scenario sketched in the table, 3 times minimum subsistence.
income from precious metal mines and stone quarries. It is diffi- If 80% of the population was engaged in agriculture then it would
cult to fit the Roman state within the narrow limits of 3-4% of be able to have a living standard at 2. 5 times minimum subsis-
GDP. '76 tence while the 20% non-agricultural/urban could live at 5 times
subsistence. Make the agricultural population 60% and the corre-
spending figures would fall to 2 and 4 times subsistence. With the
174 For some general reflections, Hopkins 1995-6 (more accessible in Scheidel and von
Reden 2002: 201-203). agricultural population constituting only 40%, it could still live at
175 Brunt 1990,chapter 15;Jones 1974,chapter8. 1. 88 times minimum subsistence and the non-agricultural popula-
176 Exact figures cannot be hoped for, of course. But 'crown' lands, as in most other
pre-industrial monarchies, are unlikely not to have constituted several per cent of tion at 3. 76 times. This does not seem a realistic possibility for the
agriculturalproperty.Egypt,however,allowsatleastsomehypotheticalreflection;it is Empiretakenasa whole,whichmixedrichandpoorregions.Three
the province whichprovides us with the most abundant evidence of levels of taxation times subsistence would imply that the entire Roman world was
and"production. Working from this Duncan-Jones (1994: 52-55) has estimated the
revenue claim of the Roman state in Egypt in the second century to be in the area of approaching the level of productivity which was achieved (excep-
HS 250million. Veryroughly thiscanbeestimated as20-25% oftheprovince's GDP. tionally) in England by the middle of the eighteenth century, one
Egyptwasanextremely productiveprovincewithgrainyieldsbeyondcomparisonin
the' Roman world. It also had a rich luxury trade passing through it. If we estimate of the most prosperous pre-industrialeconomies on record, where
Egypt'sGDPasatleast10%oftheimperialtotalwecannotpossiblybegoingtoohigh only four out of ten had to be employed in agriculture. Stateddif-
rathertheopposite. This meansthatthe taxclaim on Egyptalone will haveequalled
at least 2% of imperial GDP (one-fifth of 10% of imperial GDP). As already noted, ferently, it wouldrequiretheRomaneconomyasa wholeto sustain
Duncan-Jones (1994: 45-46) estimates government expenditure in the second century a level of production whichwas probably not even achieved in its
to be around HS 900 million. This is about 3. 6 times the value of the Egyptian tax
figure which equalled a minimum of 2% of GDP. HS 900 million, and hence state agriculturally most prosperous region, the fertile, Nile-inundated
expenditure, will then have beenaround 7% of GDP.This is, at least suggestive. The province of Egypt. '77 Both conditions are implausible.
figuresareveryuncertainandthemethodofcalculationistoosimplistic.ThusHopkins
1995-6:44 findsDuncan-Jones' estimate ofEgyptian revenue implausibly high partly
because Hopkins overestimates the proportion of this revenue in the state budget 177 ThestudybyD.ThompsonofthePtolemaicvillageKerkeosirisrevealedanagricultural
partlybecauseheforgetsthata substantialpartoftherevenuewaslikelyto"disappear' regime with 7 aroura available per family. With yields at TO times seed, and I artaba of
betweencollection point and state consumption. However, there is no doubtthatthe wheat sown per aroura, then if all land for convenience's sake is imagined to have been
Egyptian revenues were of extreme importance for the Roman state. planted with wheat, total net production would be 63 artabai. A family of five would

116 ll7
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY
T
AN AGRARIAN EMPIRE BETWEEN MARKET AND TRIBUTE

Table 2. 2 Living standardsfor different groups ofpopulation would suggest that the plausible range for the Roman economy
under different productivity regimes would have to be placed somewhere between i and 2 times mini-
mum subsistence. [7SThis locates the hypothetical maximum at the
Let a be the proportion of the population engaged in agriculture, then lowratherthanthehighendofourtableofalternative,moreoptim-
the non-agriculturally employed population is (i-a); and let x represent istic scenarios for Roman living standards. Pressin. g the Roman
the basic standard of living for the agricultural population and allow the
economy to a maximum of 2 times subsistence would as much
non-agricultural population to live at twice this level. S equals
subsistence and y is the number of times subsistence at which per as double my estimated surplus (though in practice probably less
capita production takes place. since it was calculated generously). The imperial state and aris-
2x(i-a)+xa=y * S tocracy wouldthen accountfor a minimum of 15%ofthe surplus.
x (2-a) = y * S As already stated, that would be far from a negligible influence
x = y/(2-a) * S on economic circulation; it would still represent a very significant
change from conditions before the impositionofEmpire. But this
Livingstandards(x) expressedastimes subsistencefor the agricultural/ low result would haveto be consideredan absolute minimum and,
(urban) population at different production levels
as explained, an unlikely estimate of the share of the imperial
(y) Production at: system in the overall economy. Within the plausible limits for the
(a) Population 3 times 2. 5 times 2 times Roman economy, therefore, it would be difficult not to ascribe to
in Agriculture subsistence subsistence subsistence imperial surplus extraction, the role of a key stimulus of interre-
gional economic flows.
8o% 2. 5" (5) 2. 08 (4. i 6) 1. 67(3. 34)
6o% 2. 14(4. 28) 1. 79(3. 58) 1.43(2. 86) This stimulus, however,didnotplay itselfoutonly or primarily
40% 1. 88(3. 76) 1. 56(3. 12) 1. 25(2. 5) withina state-redistributivesystemofgoodsinkind,suchasmight
be envisaged along the line of thought of Polanyi. The imperial
At 3 times subsistence a scenario of only 40% of the population state, for one thing, as already argued, did not havethe organisa-
employed in agriculture begins to look plausible. Standards of living for tional capacity. Markets were a necessary intermediary. Taking a
the agricultural population can be maintained at a reasonably generous last glance at ourMughalcomparison, wecan saythatin the kind
level while the non-agricultural population does very well. Both groups oftributary system describedhere,the role ofmarketexchangeand
would in fact be marginally better off than a population with 80% in
agriculture with per capita income at 2 times minimum subsistence. interregional trade is not first and foremost that of co-ordinating
The latter scenario, however, would still be a reflection of fairly wealthy and organising the economy in an interregional division of labour.
conditions far away from an agricultural minimum state, and most Ratherits task is the subordinateone of actingas transformerand
likely represents a hypothetical maximum for the Roman economy.
11S Macltiison 2001, 46 (figures for the "developed"world). In general chapter I and
appendix B. I suspect that Maddison underestimates production both in the ancient
When we look at the Roman Empire in its entirety, comparisons world and in early modern China. The European figures, however, are more reliable.
of averages are more appropriate on a continental scale, rather Herehe presentsa developmentrisingfrom a real minimum percapitaof$400around
AD 1000 to approximately twice that level in [700. In general, as North 2005: 91
than with smaller, particularly prosperous regions. Estimates of observes from these data, the difference between rich and poor countries fluctuates
average per capita incomes for pre-industrial Europe as a whole between I and 2 times. Jongman 2006: 241 is right in guessing 2-3 times subsistence
asthe upper limit forproductivity. Butthe largerthe geographicalareaunderconside-
ration, the closer the maximum average will approach 2 times. The richest agricul-
require some 32 artabai for a very minimal own consumption, a family of four some tural regions weregenerally fairly circumscribedandappearagainsta more extensive
24 artabai. Total production would therefore be between 2 and 2.5 times minimum background of considerably less productive regions. Saller 2002: 259-261 places the
subsistence. The Roman world could not possibly have exceededthat. Romaneconomy in a bandbetween 1.2 and 1.5 timessubsistence.
ii8 ii9
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY AN AGRARIAN EMPIRE BETWEEN MARKET AND TRIBUTE

conveyer of the extracted surplus. 179 The majority of tax payers Merchants and traders, to borrow an expression commonly used
were grain-producingpeasants, but the requirements of the impe- by Mughal historians, served to oil the wheels of the agricultural
rial state were much more diverse. Neither the Roman nor the economy and the process of tribute extraction. Sometimes, this
Mughal government anddifferent layers of imperial elites, would sawthecreation oflinks betweencommercial investment, money-
have been able to put to good use all the food grains which they lending and collection of taxes. In Roman history, such activities
potentially commanded. "The good husbandman", as even that have traditionally been connected with the great companies of
arch-proponent of traditional agricultural virtues, Cato, admon- publicani, the tax-farmers who played a prominent role in mid-
ished, "should be a seller, not a buyer". Therefore government and die and late republican history. But the phenomenon should by
aristocratic elites required the services of markets and traders to no means be seen as confined to that period or as restricted to
mobilise parts of the suq?lus by converting agricultural produce that scale of activity only.183 In early imperial Pompeii we find
into money which could be stored and used later in other contexts the more humble auctioneer Jucundus also engaging in farming
to buy different products. In the Mughal Empire, a significant part urban revenues. '^ Documents from second-century Egypt add
of the taxes came to be remitted in coin rather than kind. Something a few more tesserae to our fragmentary mosaic. One contract
similar was suggested by Hopkins for the Roman Empire. But in reveals a member of the local political elite, who was active in
bothEmpires,this processofcommercialisingthe agricultural sur- the collection oftaxes, financing the trading trip of a group ofmer-
plus is likely to havebeen uneven. Some, even many, taxes would chants. Another, recent, andbynowfamous, papyms, the so-called
still have been paid in kind; not all peasants would have been heav- Muziris Papyrus, provides evidence of a loan to finance a cargo
ily involved in market transactions. Often, the peasant would have of Oriental luxury goods, presumably intended for the market in
handed over part of his production to bigger landowners or tax Rome, to the value ofalmost HS 7 million. As Rathbone, among
collectors, who would then have undertaken to cart the produce to others,hassuggested,it is difficultnotto seetheinvolvementofthe
market, near or distant according to circumstances. Alternatively, imperial aristocracyhere. Investingin a cargoworthseveraltimes
the landownermight pass on the produce to merchants at the farm the minimum fortune of a Roman senator was an efficient way of
gate or even unharvestecl on the field. 18' The imperial government transferring wealth from the provinces to the imperial capital. 185
would also frequently have availed itself of markets to convert In that perspective, the dichotomy between market and state redis-
excessproduce into monetary wealth. Instalments of the Egyptian tribution, which has attracted so much attention over the years,
grain tax found their way onto the private market in Puteoli, the reveals itselfto bea modernist construct. In theEmpire both activ-
harbour where the imperial grain fleet arrived from Alexandria ities, often in direct collaboration, aimed at turning the extracted
before the construction of better port facilities at the mouth of the tribute into flexible resources which could be disposed of in other
Tiber. Even surplus medicinalherbsfrom the Cretanestates ofthe contexts. 186
emperors were sold on the market through commercial agents. '82
, "?"? 2007: 3I-54 fora general discussion, butwith a focus on late antique material.
179 Bayly 1983: 63-68. This is the frequently overlooked implication ofHopkins' taxes- 1!<4Cf. the tablets from hisarchive containing receipts confirming payment byJucundus
and-trade model.
to the city of what is due on these account: CILIV, suppl. [, pp. 382-404 (tablets nos.
Is° Hopkins 1995-6(cited in Scheidelandvon Reden2002: 216-17). 138-151) with Andreau 1974: 53-71.
'8' Cato Agr. ,quotation from 11.7 ("patrem familias vendacem, nonemacem esseoportet"); 1 Rathbo"e 2003: 215-225. Foranalysis ofthedocuments, seeCasson 1986;1990;and
advance sales: CXLVI-I1:sale of wine injars: CXLVIII. Rathbone 2001.
182 Galen XIV, 9 (on the medicinal herbs), TPSulp. 45, 46, 51, 52, 79 (on Alexandrian De Salvo 1992: 69-78 is a good example of how meaningless the distinction between
wheat used for commercial speculation in Puteoli). Lo Cascio 2006 for the imperial freetradeandstateredistribution canbe.Theboatscarrying thegrainarriving inRome
state as a large seller in the market. mayhavebeenfreebuttheircargoesweredominatedbystateshipments.

120 121
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY AN AGRARIAN EMPIRE BETWEEN MARKET AND TRIBUTE

in biggerolive presses and the like. '92 There may also havebeen
Growth and/or tributary concentration some pockets of rising agricultural prosperity where producers
were able to take advantage ofexpanding markets to increase spe-
Sucha system of markets developing aroundpolitical exploitation cialisation and improve productivity. Such processes have been
is what Weber referred to as political capitalism or even "Raub suggested for Rome's Italian hinterland (Etruria-Campania)dur-
Kapitalismus" (robber capitalism). 187 According to the standard ing the late Republic and early Empire. '93 Yet it is difficult to reach
view, this is an arbitrary and disruptive sort of economic activity. an assessmentof the impact ofthose and similardevelopments in
But there is an "error" in perspective here. Clearly the type of terms of increasing overall productivity in the Roman economy at
economic exploitation which I have described in such detail above large.Mostsuchdevelopments,I suspect,will haveimprovedeco-
does not fit the doctrines of liberal, legally ordered economics nomic performance only marginally. 194 Elsewhere I have argued
well. 188 However, while it did not offer the stability and security that the greater efficiency of African as compared to Spanish oil
of economic assets which we have come to expect today, the close amphorae would have lowered the sales price of oil by less than
alliance between empire and aristocratic groups did nonetheless 5%. 195
constitute a solid and enduring kind of order. In a closely argued Ultimately, in the absence of statistics, the measurement of per
critique of the sociological tradition on tributary empires, Michael capi ta growth will remain beyond our grasp. This should be no

Mann has suggested that the alliance between state and aristocracy cause for sleepless nights. Per capita growth is in any case a very
was socially productive; their mutual collaboration produced a problematical concept to apply to an economy which was heav-
synergistic effect which increased extraction and the agricultural ily dominated by pre-modern agricultural production. The classic
surplus and therefore allowed greater scope for the development illustration of this is economic developments in Europe following
of manufacture and trade. '89 the Black Death. In the aftermath of the pandemic, aggregate pro-
This brings us to the question of growth. But first some clarifi- duction plummeted while the decimated population experienced
cation of the meaning of the term is called for. Growth is far from a strong growth in per capita income as more and better land
being an unambiguous concept. Clearly, from a modern perspec- became available to the individual peasant. '96 In traditional agri-
tive the most interesting question to pursue is whether the economy culture, increased production is often only achieved at the price of
of the Roman Empire experienced significant growth in per capita falling marginal returns. Essentially the peasant is faced with the
incomes. 190 Some have argued along these lines, albeit with con- choiceofworkingexistinglandharderorexpandingthecultivated
siderable differences in degree. 191 Central to this argument has area by bringing more marginal lands under the plough. Either
been the identification of some gradual developments in technol- way the increase in production tends to require a proportionately
ogy, suchasgrowthin thetonnageofships,reductionofthe weight bigger increase in the amount of labour. Production expands, but
of amphorae in relation to the volume of their contents, investment
192 Hopkins 19836;PeacockandWilliams 1986:51-53;Greene2000;Wilson2002.
193 On this, see Scheidel 20073 (building on Morley 1996) and 2007b.
'87 Lo Cascio 1991; Whittaker 1994; Schiavone 2000, chapter 3 have a clear understanding 94 Saller 2002 for some cautionary observations; moderate growth can easily explain
of the submission of the market to tributary forces. Love 1991: 223-245 on Weber's developments.
political capitalism. ly5 Bang 2002a,n. 69. Cf. Lelener 2006.
188 Jones 1988: 135 notes that it is difficultfrom a modem perspective to understandhow 19f> Livi-Bacci [992: 47-54; more generally Braudet 1981: 32-34, pace Persson 1988 (in
markets could work under those circumstances.
the long ran no pre-industrial agrarian economy can really escape this constraint, cf.
189 Mann 1986: 167-174 and chapter 9. Wrigley 1988.Stagnationshouldnot primsirilybeput downto a result of exogenous
190 Millett 2001 discusses modern notions of growth and the ancienteconomy. shocks, as Persson 1988: 131-135 also has to concede). See Scheidel 2002 for an
19' Compare the cautious account ot'Hopkins 1995-6 with Mattingly 1996 and Hitchner attempt to understand theeconomic effects ofthe Antonine Plague affecting the Roman
2005. world in the l6os AD in terms parallel to the Black Death.
122
123
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY AN AGRARIAN EMPIRE BETWEEN MARKET AND TRIBUTE

productivity declines. The income of the peasant grows but it is would have had to be shared by more producers and the area of cul-
by no means clear that his living conditions improve correspond- tivation to be extended into new zones, bringing less fertile, more
ingly. 197 Obviously this puts very severe limits on how much the marginal lands under cultivation. 201 This would have pulled in the
production of the individual peasant households can be increased. opposite direction, producing a tendency towards falling per capita
That being so, the total command over or availability of human production, as individualpeasantfamilies wouldhavehadto work
labourisprobably a muchbetterkeytounlocking thesecretsofthe harder simply to achieve the same outcome. Even so, in aggregate
economic performance oftheEmpire thanthe notion ofsubstantial terms the economy would still have continued to expand as long
and sustainedincreasesin productivity in the economy at large. as the new producers were able to grow a surplus. 202 Obviously, it
Tobeginwith,theincreasedpowerofthetribute-cum-rentnexus will never be possible to work out the combined economic effect
may have succeeded in forcing peasants to work harder. This can of these two countervailing forces of agricultural intensification
be seen as a process in which the tributary system mobilised the in exact terms. But we may gain a clearer understanding of the
resources ofmral underemployment. The scope for such intensifi- problem through a hypothetical experiment. If we assume that the
cation varied considerably according to local conditions. It was politically induced increase in household production would have
greatest and most visible in the western provinces where sur- been nullified by a fall in productivity caused by the need to culti-
plus extraction was brought closer to the greater level of inten- vate more marginal lands, thus preserving per capita production at
sityrequiredto sustainMediterranean civilisation. '98Butboththe an unchanged level, we are still looking at an aggregate expansion
growth of slavery in the wake of the Roman conquests and the of the economic surplus by around one-third between the time of
development which can be followed in the legal sources, where Augustus and the early years of Marcus Aurelius. In other words,
a distinction between honestiores and humiliores from the early actual per capita growth is not necessary to explain much, if not
second century AD gradually overtakes the distinction between most, of the increased level of activity that archaeologists have
Roman citizens and aliens, may indicate a general intensification documented for the early Empire. 203
in the exploitation of ilpopulo minuto. 199 This points to by far the most important aspect of the devel-
It is questionable, however, whether this trend towards inten- opments presented by the Roman economy: sheer mass. The for-
sified cultivation ever materialised as a sustained increase m per mation of a Mediterranean empire need not necessarily have led
capita production. There were countervailing forces. Completely to a substantial growth in per capita production, at most only a
stationary populations are rare. It now seems generally agreed that moderate increase. 4 But the Empire brought together the pro-
therewasa modestriseinthepopulationfigureduringthefirsttwo ductive capacity of many more people under the same tributary
centuriesAD. Themost plausiblerecentestimateseesthepopula-
tion growing from around 45 million in the ageofAugustus tojust 101 Developments in Africa are a good example, Barker and Mattingly 1996, Dietz,
over 60 million in the middle of the second century AD before the Sebai and Ben Hassen 1995, 0rsted et at. 2000. So is the Syrian limestone mas-
onsetoftheAntonineplague.200As a consequence,existingfields sif, Pollard 2000: 201-236. Both expanded the agricultural frontier into marginal
zones.
Pace Hitchner 2005: 222, n. 30 who holds that the Roman Empire stayed clear of the
197 Boserup 1965;Sahlins 1972:Chayanov 1986,chapter2. constraint of falling marginal returns. But he has misunderstood the concept. It does
lt)8 Woolf 2001. See Hopkins 2000: 257-259 for some model calculations showing how not imply thatproductionfalls off, as hethinks, only that increasedproductionhappens
rents and taxes increase the area of cultivable land neededby the peasant household at lower productivity.
to sustain itself. Insteadof more land, peasantsmay haveto work existingfieldsmore 3 Mattingly and Salmon 2001: 3-14 in general emphasise the difference in scale of
intensively. individual economic phenomena as a central distinction between Greek and Roman
199 N0rlund 1920;Garnsey 1970;Finley 1980,chapter4 on this. GarnseyandHumfress economic history. Greene 1986; 2000, Wilson 2002 assembles much of the archaeo-
2001, chapter5 for a nuanced discussion. logical evidence for the increased scale of Roman economic activity.
200 Frier200oa: 8 [2-8 it. 204 SeeSaller2002 for a moderategrowthscenario.

124 125
THE ROMAN EMPIRE AND COMPARATIVE STUDY AN AGRARIAN EMPIRE BETWEEN MARKET AND TRIBUTE

umbrella.205 That was the decisive feature of the imperial econ- If the Mughal comparison is anything to go by, the stronger
omy. It enabled it to mobilise, amass and concentrate resources concentration of surplus consumption would have increased the
from a much wider area than its predecessors. As a result, the scale of individual resource flows, creating some large "centralised
dimensions of the political economy changed dramatically onto a trades" and "arterial routes". 2°9 Such a scenario seems equally rel-
vastly different scale of activity. 20 The clearest illustration of this evant for the Roman Empire. The supplies reachingRome are an
is the formation of very large, individual market concentrations. obviouscaseinpoint. Butthepattern isalsofoundintheprovinces.
The imperial capital Rome is, of course, the leading example. With Gaul, for instance, presents an image of strongly concentrated
a population generally believed to have reached the million mark, trades closely linked with the imperial system. Here the Rhone-
it constituted a concentration of demand not to be equalled in Sa6ne-Rhine axis stands out as the dominant artery, serving as the
Europe again until the Industrial Revolution. However impressive, supply route for the imperial legions stationed on the Gennanic
Rome should not monopolise our attention. Compared with the border. This gaverise to a system wheretheneedfor servicing the
urban network of early modern Europe, the system of cities which state transports favoured the development of a private commer-
made up the Empire stands out by the more dominant position cial infrastructure andtrade. But outside this interregional arterial
occupied by large urban concentrations (over 100, 000). Alexan- channel, the exchange economy seems to have been operating in
dria, Antioch and Carthage taken together are generally believed rather more local or regional cells. 210
to havecomprisedperhaps anothermillion inhabitants.207 In addi-
tion, there are almost a dozen other putative candidates for the over in Syria was given a very large hinterland to dominate and administer. Alexandria.
100, 000 category. As late as 1700 Europe still did not decisively too, benefitedenormously from its dominantpolitical position in Egypt. The same
goesforCarthage,whichreceivedanextensivechora(territory) to drawits resources
exceed that number, even though it had a larger population base. from.Again,theeffectsofempireweremanifest,notonlyindirectexpenditureofthe
Instead it had many more medium-sized cities (over 10,000). In imperial patrimonium, butalso in thefashioning andmaintenance ofprovincial elites.
2"t) Bayly 1983: 65 and 159 and chapter 3.
l8oo, between 300 and 400 had reached that level. The numerous, 210 Middleton 1983;Whittakerl994a;Jacobsen1995.
but quite modest, cities in the Roman world notwithstanding, a
similarly dense layer of medium-sized cities is hard to identify. In
other words, the tributary system maintained a much steeper urban
hierarchy, concentrating resources from a very broad base into a
relatively restricted numberof very largecities.208

205 Livi-Bacci 1992: 109 following Boserup 1981 sees the aggregateeffect of large popu-
lations as more important for the formation of large urban concentrations than marginal
variations in per capita income under pre-industrial conditions.
20 Cf.Wickham2005arguingthatthekeydifferencebetweentheeconomiesoftheRoman
and post-Roman West is the gradual collapse of taxation; this significantly reduced the
scale of economic activity.
207 Hurst 1993 reminds us not to inflate ancient urban populations. Carthage, though still
large, may have been smaller than is often thought.
208 Woolf 1997points inthesamedirection butwarnsagainstseeingtheempire asprimarily
responsible for the strongly pronounced hierarchy in the East. The urban system had
alreadyexistedbeforeimperial rule. Thereforehe points to tradeandcultural exchanges
asequally importantin shapingthe system. But, ashealso recognises(p. 12),thegrowth
of large cities in the eastern Mediterranean was closely linked with the formation of
larger states. Moreover, Roman rule maintained this hierarchy by underwriting the
strength of the aristocracies residing in the most prominent urban centres. Antioch

126
127
PART II

IMPERIAL BAZAAR

The bazaar is more than a place set aside where people are permitted to come
each day to deceive one another, and more, too. than one more demonstration of
the truth that, under whatever skies, men prefer to buy cheap and sell dear... It
is a distinctive system of social relationships centering around the production
and consumption of goods and services (i.e. a particularkind ofeconomy), and it
deservesanalysisassuch. .. Bazaar,thatPersianwordofuncertainoriginswhich
hascome to stand in Englishfor the oriental market, thus becomes, like the word
market itself, as much an analytic idea as the name of an institution.
Clifford Geertz, Meaning and Order in Moroccan Society

That that trade was not of a "bourgeois commercial" sort has already been
indicated... The financiers of trade were often princes, religious dignitaries,
and nobles. The merchant gentlemen, as popolo grosso, led a seigneurial way
of life when compared to the popolo minuto, the masses of craftsmen and
"actual traders". Furthermore, the princes and lords were themselves often mer-
chants ... Their trade could be occasional or regular. The former could result in
sudden obstruction of markets, forced purchases, temporary monopolisation.
J. C. van Leur. Indonesian Trade and Societv
3

A ROUGH TRADING WORLD: OPAQUE,


VOLATILE AND DISCONTINUOUSLY
CONNECTED MARKETS

Weknowhowvariedthepricesofthingsarebetweenindividualcitiesandregions.
Gaius, Digesta 13.4.3

In short, whatever is obstructing the development of a modern economy out of


the general backgroundof the bazaareconomy, it is not lack of a "business-like
orientation on the part of the pasaar traders .. . What the bazaareconomy lacks
is not elbow room but organisation, not freedom but form.
Geertz, Peddlers and Princes, p. 47

Some thirty years ago a sanctuary for a hitherto almost unknown


ancient goddess, Nehalenia,was found on the Dutch coast, in the
former Roman province of Germania Inferior. The most remark-
able part of the find was the discovery of a fairly large body of
votive inscriptions put up mainly, it seems, by sailors and mer-
chants thanking Nehalenia for their safe return: "To the goddess
Nehalenia for the good preservation of his merchandise Marcus
SecundiniusSilvanus, trader in pottery to the province of Britain,
kept his promise freely anddutifully. '" Even in theirconcise,mat-
ter of fact appearance the inscriptions provide us with a chilling
glimpse into the world ofmerchants andothertravellers in ancient
times. At best, travel was a slow and arduous trial; complaints over
long delays, bumpy roads and never-endingnauseaare legion. At
worst it was a dangerous undertaking for which you might have
to pay with your life; wreckage, illness or assault by pirates and
highwaymenwere always lurkingjust aroundthe corner. In such
' AE, 1973, 370: "Deae N[e]haleniae | ob merces recte conservatas M(arcus)
Secund(inius?) Silvanus | negotiator cretariu[s] | Britannicianu[s] | v(otum) s(olvit)
l(ibens) m(erito). " The inscriptions can be found in AE 1973, 362-380 and 1975, 641-
656 with furtherexamplesin 1980and 1983.Seealso StuartandBogaers 1971 and200l,
two catalogues from exhibitionspresenting the find.
2 Successfullycompletedtravels wereaccomplishmentstotakenoticeof. Hencethefuneral
inscription (5/G3 1229), mentioning the seventy-two safejourneys madeby a traderfrom

i3i
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A ROUGH TRADING WORLD

circumstances one could never be too sure. The protection of the


gods was enlisted as a matter of routine. Indeed, the superstitions of Transport
mariners have at all times been legendary and have provided a rich
material for novelists across the centuries. Think, for instance, of By modem standards, the means of transport were both slow and
Melville's immortal description of an American whalingcommu- very much at the mercy of the elements. 4 The latter was more
nity in Moby Dick, not to mention the more comical chord struck true of travel by water than by land. However, even on land the
by Petronius exploiting the prohibition against cutting one's hair weathercouldaffecttravelling conditions significantly. Duringthe
at sea to put his hard-tested (anti)heroes in yet another ridiculous rainy seasons, rivers and lakes might rise above their usual bound-
pickle.3 aries and cause roads to flood, flush away bridges and seriously
This secondpart ofthe bookwill explore the conditionsoftrade impede crossing. Roads, either not built to the best of Roman
in the RomanEmpire. The first part identifiedthe broadcharacter- standards or not properly maintained, might turn into bottomless
istics of the political economy and the main driving forces behind mud holes. In the colder regions of the empire winter could see
interregional trade. The inquiry now proceedsto examinehowthe roads transformed into slippery ice patches whereas burning sun
formation of a tributary empire affected the institutional set-up in some of the hotter areas would often have forced travellers to
for trade. Further comparisons drawn from Mughal India will be go by the cool but also more frightening night rather than during
employed to suggest new ways of thinking about Roman traders. daytime. Employed as pack animals or used as traction power for
A central concern will be to integrate the risks and uncertainties carts, donkeys, mules, oxen and camels (horses only to a lesser
of ancient commerce into our general understanding of market extent) constituted the basis of Roman land transport. That made
institutions. This third chapter will deal with the basic character of it, on average,considerablyslowerthan waterbornetransport, but
markets and conditions of trade in the Roman Empire. Emphasis above all a lot more expensive, both relatively and absolutely. The
will be placed on the limits to market integration and the volatil- animals needed considerable amounts of fodder to keep going.s
ity of commercial links. A middle section attempts to deepen the Working from Diocletian's price edict, A. H. M. Jones suggested
image of market fragmentation through a very tentative analy- that, roughly speaking, transport on land by wagon increased the
sis of the few and scattered price records surviving from Roman price ofwheat by 50% for every 100miles whereas thecorrespond-
Egypt. The chapter then moves on to consider evidence of enduring ing figure for seatransport was only i . 3%. One should not pay too
cultural and institutional fragmentation within the Roman trading much attention to the exact figures. The relative proportions ofthe
world, in spite ofthegreaterlegal andmonetary coherencebrought price of land and watertransport would have varied considerably
about by the imperial government. At the end, the bazaar, with its according to local circumstances. As a rule of thumb, however,
many irregularities and uncertainties, is suggested as a model for the relationship, which seems to receive comparative confirma-
the functioning of Roman markets. tion, between the price of sea, riverine and land transport can be
estimated as I : 5 : 5o.6

Hierapolis, Flavius Zeuxis, around Cape Malea to Italy. Andre and Baslez 1993: 437- Braydel 1972: 246-311 remains one of the best descriptions ofpre-modem transport
447 ancl483-526 is a convenient selection of the material pertaining to the insecurite in the Mediterranean. What follows draws heavily on his analysts. For ancient travel.
chronique of travel in the Greco-Roman world. See also Millar 1981 using Apuleius' collect much
Metamorphoses to give a vivid impression of the hassles and uncertainties of ancient
travel. working from
3 Petr. Sat. 104-105. thepriceetlict ofDiocletian.withtheadjustmentsofDuncan-Jones 1982:366-369.
Seefurther Hopkins2000:263, n. 18and 19835, i02-[05. dark andHaswell'1970,
chapter 12 lists some comparative figures of transport costs.
132 133
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A ROUGH TRADING WORLD

As Braudel was one of the first to observe, and as many ancient something like three to one in the Mediterranean. We cannot know
historians now agree, that did not reduce land transport to total whetherit would havebeen exactly the same in Roman times. But
insignificance. 7 The high price on land transport was more of an it does provide us with a useful pointer.
impediment to low-value bulky goods, such as grain, than low- So it is almost true of the pre-industrial world that land divides
bulk, highly priced luxuries where transport costs constituted a whereas water unites - but only almost. Sea transport was far less
much smaller percentage of the total price. In special circum- expensive and often a necessary requirement for large bulk trans-
stances land transport might even compete successfully with water. fers. However, it was also much more sensitive towardschanging
During the first century AD the caravan route bringing frankin- weatherconditions. On the micro level, we see it when a ship en
cense, of the best and purest crop, from southern Arabia to Gaza route had to go into the nearest harbour and wait, in unfavourable
on the Mediterranean seaboard, continued in spite of increasing seasons perhaps even for weeks, until the storm blew itself out
navigation in the region. The caravanscould leave in the beginning andthe seacalmeddownagain.If the ship foundno ready shelter
of the autumn while ships had to await the arrival of the north-east and still survived the adverse conditions it might find itself blown
monsoon. This gave the caravans a time advantage. They could off course, occasionally to such an extent that the only practical
normally expect to arrive in Gaza as the ships left South Arabia. response was to change its destination. On the other hand, some-
The caravan merchants were thus able to bring their goods first to times there would be too little wind and the ship would just have
the market. This would quite possibly have been sufficient com- been drifting with the currents until the wind rose again, orthe crew
pensationfortheirhighertransportcosts. Evenmorebulkygoods would have had to row. " On the macro level, we encounter the
such as pottery can at times be found to have travelled consider- greatdependencyon the weatheras an organisationof navigation
able distances overland in large quantities. The famed production around the rhythm of the changing seasons. During wintertime
of red-glossed fine ware in La Graufesenque (floruit first century the risk of sailing increased substantially in the Mediterranean
AD) in southern France had no nearby waterway. Pots, cups and and navigation came almost to a standstill or at least the inten-
bowls would have travelled in the thousands on the roads leading sity of shipping was much reduced. The Romans talked of a mare
away from the production centre each year. 9 Even so, in general clausum at least between November and March/April, with most
there is no way of escaping the fact of the primacy of water for navigation probably taking place safely within the margins of the
transport over longer distances. The economic logic dictated this summer period. 12
and this logic was not lost on the ancients either. It is noticeable All this workedto make travel times on the seavery uncertain
how the elder Pliny in his geographical description of the Empire, andhighly fluctuating. In his NaturalHistory, Pliny informs us of
when assessing the potential resources of an area, repeatedly takes some record crossings, such as from Puteoli to Alexandriain nine
time to observe whether a river is navigable or not; that would
determine how easily the surplus produce could be mobilised.
In terms of the value of transported goods, Braudel estimated that Heliodorus Aethiopica V offers many illustrations of the changing fortunes of life at
in the sixteenth century the relation of water to land transport was sea, especially in the more unfavourableseasons(chapter23 for roving). See Synesius
Litt. 129 for an example of a ship being blown so much off course that it changes its
destination to Alexandria.
7 See Braudel [972: 284-295. See Laurence 1998 and Harden and Purcell 2000, 12 SeeRouge 1966:32-33 formareclausum. Itisclear,however, thatsomesailingdidtake
chapter 9 for two recent discussions stressing the vitality of land transport. placeduringthewinterseason.IntheeasternMediterranean,forinstance,sailingduring
Young200i: l04-Io6. thewinterbetweenRhodesandEgypt is attested for anearlierperiod,cf. Demosthenes
9 See Whittaker 2002; see Goody and Whittaker 2001; for proto-industry in southern Against Dionysoclorus 30. Heliodorus Aethiopica V, chapter 18 points in the same
France. See further, Vernhet 1991. direction. But here it is also observed that it took special skills and, in the end, even
10 E.g. Plin. Nat. Ill, [2: "Singilis fluvius... ab ea navigabilis" and 21: "Hiberus amnis navigatorspossessingthosemightchooseto winterin a harbour,at leastforpart ofthe
navigabili commercio dives". bad season.

134 i35
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A ROUGH TRADING WORLD

days. 13 But that was unusual. If we are to judge from the speed But the optimism of Harden andPurcell, reflected in the deceptive
of imperialcommunicationsomethinglike threeorfourtimesthat catchphraseconnectivity, is misplaced. The proper point to make
numberofdayswouldhavebeenmorecommon,butwithconsider- is rather the opposite: transport remained a serious challenge or
able individual variations andwith some trips taking substantially even obstacle to economic integration for most of pre-industrial
longer. 14 The general situation does not seem to have been very history. 16Individual markets were not easily tied together so asto
different from the Mediterranean in the sixteenth century. For that behavein unison.Withslow,irregularandperiodicallydiscontinu-
period, Fernand Braudel estimated the length ofa seavoyage from ous transport and communication it was simply very difficult, on a
east to west to have been in the order of two to three months regional basis, on the continental scale ofthe Roman Empire quite
and often even more, with substantial additions to be made for impossible, to match demand and supply across individual market-
penetration beyond the coastal regions. There had of course been places in an even, steady and predictable way. 17 Rather, resources
some technological modifications since antiquity, but they were would normally have come in uneven, not easily predictable,
marginal improvements. The pattern of relatively slow, irregular clusters. The problem is conveniently illustrated from Apuleius'
and for periods even discontinuous transport and communication GoldenAss by the story told by oneofits characters,a small trader.
lines, had still to be broken. The same goes for tonnage. Most Havinghadnews of the availability of some goocl-quality cheese
shipsin bothperiods wouldhavebeenrelatively small, below TOO at a very attractive price in a neighbouring area, he rushed to the
tonnes and more often than not closer to 50 tonnes. Bigger ships place only to find that everything had already been sold. His efforts
were certainly built and used, especially on routes between the had been in vain; the market had already been cleared. 18
largest cities, but they were far from the norm. 15 Acting on wrong or out-of-date information, which did not cor-
respond to the actual situation in the marketplace on the time of
arrival, was an ever-looming risk for the pre-industrial merchant.
Volatile and opaque markets
It was not just that the goods might have cleared by the time of
his arrival. Too many competitors might havepickedup the same
Mysteriously this basic continuity over many centuries has been news, flocked to the market and causedthe low price to increase
taken by some classicists asconfirmation that communication and violently so as to endanger the profitability of making the trip in
transport did not impose strong limits on the economic perfor- the first place. On the other hand, high prices might attract too
mance and workings of markets in (Roman) antiquity. To be sure,
a lot of movement of commodities on sea and on land did occur.
many sellers trying to out-compete each other; or, alternatively,
buyers might fail to show, causing a shortage in demand and the
market to plummet well below normal levels. '9 The latter seems
13 Plin. Nat. XIX, 3. '4 Duncan-Jones 1990, chapter 1. to describe the situation in the example above from the point of
15 Ingeneral Braudel 1972: 295-311 and354-375 remains fundamental on theseproblems
and la longue duree in Mediterranean transport, in spite of the ambitions of Harden view of the cheeseseller. He had to part with his goods at a very
and Purcell 2000 to overtake him. Parker 1992: 26, based on a catalogue of some low price to a single well-positioned merchant whojust happened
1, 200 ancient shipwrecks, concludes that most ships were a good bit below 100 tonnes
capacity. P. Bingen 77, treated by the editor Heilporn and by Rathbone 2003: 226,
contains information about some eleven ships arriving in an Egyptian port, probably 'b Braudel1972:375-379 conveys a goodsenseoftheproblems andfrequent breakdowns
AlexandriaduringthesecondhalfofthesecondcenturyAD.Twoofthese,onea Roman in economicintegration. SeealsoShaw2001:423-425 for a relatedcritique.
grain freighter, the other used to carry pine trunks, were well above 100 tonnes. The 17 See Erdkamp 2005, chapter4 forananalysis of the Roman grain market stressing low
majority, however, hada tonnage between 30and75 tonnes. Rouge 1966:47-80 argued, [8
carry-overofstocks in theoperationofmarkets through time andacrossdistances.
before the rise of underwater archaeology, for the comparable dimensions of shipping Apul. Met. I, 5.
in the Roman Empire and the early modem Mediterranean. His general conclusion is 19 SeeforexampleP. OsloII,63(thirdcentury).Thisisanestateletterinwhichanagent
convincing, but he tends to overestimate the size ofthe ships. He would have done well reports that he cannot sell his goods at the price at which he has been instructed to sell
to consulthisgreatcompatriot, Braudel,whohadalreadywrittenon this. them. The market is much lower.

136 137
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A ROUGH TRADING WORLD

to be in the area. Another illustration can be found in one of the how the hidden hand could ensure that such fluctuations would
letters ot'Cassiodorus. The state needed to make some requisitions find a strong and ready response in other markets that would be
from an area with plentiful stocks. But it was out of season and able to iron out the differences and create a more stable situation -
there were few merchants in the area. Therefore demand was low except in a very imperfect, almosthaphazard,way.
andpeople were forcedto accepta very unattractivepricefortheir Ceteris paribus, the volume of transactions alone was not
goods. 20 enough to establish stable markets with closely correlated move-
Closely connected to the information problems were logistical ments of prices. In the short run there would normally be only a
difficulties. A merchant might act on correct information and still very weak link between price developments in particular demand
seehisplansfall through.Hisshipmentofgoodsmightbeseriously markets on the one hand and the quantities of a given commod-
delayedenroute. Or,alternatively, hemighthaveto leavea market ity sent from the various individual supply markets on the other
before the goods he wanted to buy hadarrived, either dueto delayed hand. 23 The result was a trading world characterised by chronic
cargoes or becausefair weathermade it expedientor the close of bottlenecks, imbalances and asymmetries in the supply of avail-
the trading season made it imperative for him to set sail. 21 It would able information and goods. A humorous letter of Pliny sums up
also, occasionally, be difficult to find a ship which could bring thesituationofdearthinoneregionandglutwithcollapsingprices
orders to an agent in another harbour at the required time. Equally not too far away:
it could be a problem to find cargo space for hire when needed.
Surplus of shipping in an area with nothing to export and shortage My Tuscan fields, I hear, have been wiped out by hail, and in the Transpadane
there's a bumper crop but prices havecollapsed in consequence. Only my Lau-
in a neighbouring region with stocks ready for export were not rentineyieldsmea return.OfcourseI havenothingtherebeyondhouse,garden
unheard of.22 In other words, the pre-modern merchant had to act andsandybeachhardby; still for me it is the sole sourceofprofit. For'that's
in a highly uncertain market situation, governed by the rhythm where I do most of my writing. I don't cultivate the land- for I havenone- but
of the seasons, where it was difficult to predict or estimate the myself in my studies. 24

amounts of goods brought to the individual marketplace and the


In recent years economists have become increasingly interested
number and buying capacity of his competitors. Such markets
in the consequences of such market imperfections and asymme-
would normally be quite prone to violent fluctuations in the short tries. So far their efforts have been rewarded with several Nobel
term. Price changes of say 10, 20 or 30% within a few months, prizes sincethe 1990s.25 Therecipients arguethattraditionaleco-
weeks or sometimes even between days were the order of the day, nomics have overestimated the tendency of markets to become
making it a very risky business environment. Under the ruling integrated and move in unison. A classic illustration of this is
regime of communication and transport it is difficult to imagine the huge gap between the comparatively moderate interest rates
20 Cassioclorus Variae XII, 22. 2. Rouge 1966 diligently gathered much late material show- in Indian cities and the usurious rates that Indian peasants have
ing the irregularities of Roman trading, especially pp. 416-417 for more examples. often had to pay to the village money lender. For he, unlike the
2' Seasonalityoftrading:PhiloLeg. Gai. 15;Sirk.s 2002(on Dig.45. 1. 1 22. 1).TPSiilp.46,
53 and79 (asexplainedby theeditorCamodeca)showa loanbeingadvancedin March
to a Puteolan grain trader on the security of a consignment of grain. Had the loan not 23 Steensgaard 19733:58;ingeneralpp.22-59foraninci.siveanalysisofmarketscharac-
been repaid by the Icfes of May, the lender was entitled to auction off the grain just in terisecl by weak integration and short-term fluctuations.
time to beat the arrival of the Alexandrian grain fleet whose fresh supplies would cause Plin. £p. iy, 6, [-2:"Tusci^randineexcussi,inregioneTranspadanasummaabundantia,
prices to fall in the market. See also Cic. Fain. XIV, 4, 5 (ship departing Brundisium seeIpar vilitas nuntiatur. Solum mihi Laurentinum meum in reditu. Nihil quidem ibl
before arrival of letters in order not to lose fair weather). possideo praetor tectum et hortum statimque harenas, solum tamen mihi'in'reditlL
22 Cassiodorus Variae XII, 24. The letters of Synesius offer some striking illustrations. Ibi plurimum scribo, nec agrum quem non habeo sed ipsum me studiis excolo. " The
No. 129 mentions letters which have gone astray and have been delayed many months. passageisanalysedbyTchemia 1986: 178.Erdkamp2005: 167-169isspeculativeand
Nos. 134 and 148 describe problems about finding cargo space and ships heading to the overcomplicates the issue.
required destination. 25 ForexampleDouglassNorth,GeorgeAkerlof, MichaelSpenceandJosephStiglitz.
138 i39
A ROUGH TRADING WORLD
IMPERIAL BAZAAR

banks, knows the individual borrowers. He can therefore better their own products and receive supplies by sea; for us inland our
assesstherisk involvedin advancinga loanto a particularpeasant, surpluses are unprofitable and our scarcities irremediable, as we
have no means of disposing of what we have or of importing what
the argument goes. Should a middleman attempt to bring thecity
andvillage creditmarkets together, herisksattracting all thebad we lack. "29 But even inland areas were not completely isolated.
Grain, for instance, was certainly transported out of the innerparts
payers, due to his lack oflocal knowledge and soon goes out of ot'Anatolia to be sold in Mediterranean markets. 30 Nonetheless, it
business. Consequently the village money lender rests secure in
his local monopoly and the markets remain separate. The lesson was a costly and burdensome undertaking from which cities some-
canbeputinmore general terms: market environments withhuge times sought to relieve themselves at a price. As Cicero explains,
irregularities, low transparency, great uncertainties and slow and inland cities might accept to pay, in lieu of their grain taxes, a lump
at times erratic transport, make it expensive and difficult for eco- monetary sum calculated on the basis of the higher prices prevail-
nomic agents to transact andmove goodsfrom market to market ing in more busy coastal markets, rather than having to deliver
When transaction costs are high, it cannot be taken for granted their taxes in kind on the coast. 31 With cities enjoying close access
that markets will tend towards the same equilibrium. 26 Such con- to waterways, however, the concrete market-type begins to require
siderations areofobvious interest to students ofpre-modem trade. considerable modification. Perhaps the situation can be more use-
One crucial implication for our understanding of the Roman (as fully described in terms of concrete connections. It is the density
ofmost ofthepre-industrial) trading world, is that any notion of and stability of those that we need to look at.
the empire as constituting one generalised market, where prices Most cities in the Mediterranean world were small (less than
converge around a common equilibrium price across the many 10, 000 inhabitants). Markets, therefore, were generally small too
individual markets, cannot easily be maintained. 27 and could not easily sustain close permanent connections, espe-
In contrastto marketin the abstract,generalised,modem sense, cially because the needs of many cities will have fluctuated from
it iscustomary to speakofconcrete, individualmarketplaces exist- year to year. This is most marked in agricultural products where the
ing in isolation. But here it is important to keep in mind that we strong interannual fluctuations in harvests would have made cities
are dealing with two ideal-types at each end of a broad spectrum constantly change between the roles of exporter and importer of
of varying"degrees of integration. 28 The purely concrete market- small amounts of grain etc., as illustrated by the above quotation
type mightreasonably catchthesituation in someRoman inland from Gregory. Those markets were normally served by a system
towns far from waterways or the most frequented roads. Gre- often referred to as cabotage: small merchant ships would more
gory of Nazianzus, explains the plight of food shortage in the or less casually tramp along the coast from harbour to harbour in
mland city of Caesarea in Cappadocia: "Coastal cities support search of a good bargain. 32 This, combined with the constant shifts
such shortages without much difficulty, as they can dispose of in the needs of markets, did not work in favour of bringing areas
closely together. On the contrary, the loosely linked small cabotage
26 Forsomepioneringstudiesofthenewperspective,seethenowclassicpaperbyAkerlof markets, characterised by impermanent connections, accentuated
(1970),alsoRotschild 1973andNorth 1990,especiallypages60-80. the uncertainties and risks of pre-modern trade. The arrival or
^ Temin 2001: 179isanexampleofthetendency oftraditional economics to playdown non-amval of as little as one or two extra ships during the sailing
the'effe'cts'ofmarketimperfections:theymightin theshortruncreatennbalanresbut
theycould not prevent an equilibrium from materialising across the Roman Empire 9 Gregory ot'Nazianzus In Laudem Basilii 34-35 (Migne, Pair. Gr. 36, 541-544, quoted
iri'the middle- or long-term perspective. It is precisely this expectation that the new from Jones 1964: 844). See further the discussion of Gamsey 1988: 22-24 for a per-
institutional economics has undermined. _
ceptive analysis, pointing out that Gregory probably overstates his case.
28 Marshall 1890: 323-330, the founder of neo-classical economics, already made. this 3 Mitchell 1993, vol. i (last chapter, analysing the economy).
obse'rvation/But~neo-c~iassical economics has never been very interested in exploring
31 Cic. II Verr. 3, 191 with Erdkamp 2005: 197-198.
thespaceinbetweenthetwoextremes.Hencethesuccessofinstitutional andtransaction 3 Harden and Purcell 2000, chapters 4 and 5 make a great deal out of this.
cost economics today.

140
i4i
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A ROUGH TRADING WORLD

season might have had a decisive influence on the price in the more steady and predictable demand than other markets. In that
market. Consequently prices would often be highly volatile and respect, the large consumptive nodal points reduced commercial
the markets would be dominated by interlocal asymmetries and risks. But they were far from unproblematic markets to negotiate.
imbalances.33 Coming to a large city, without a prior established social network,
The situation begins to change somewhat when attention is carried risks of its own. That theme, however, will be developed
turned tothe small groupofvery largecities/markets intheEmpire: more fully in Chapter 5. For the moment, I am interested in a dif-
Rome, Alexandria, Antioch, Carthage, Ephesos and a few others. ferent aspect; the giant markets were logistical feats that strained
In somecommodities,suchasthemosthighlypricedluxuries,mar- capacities to the full, and supplies were in constant danger of
kets will still have been very narrow. This is what Cicero alleged breakdown or temporary interruption. 37 In that way they remained
had been the experience of the Roman knight Rabirius Postumus, nervous and volatile. In a tense situation, even the arrival of as few
whohad imported a valuable Egyptian cargo of"paper, linen and as five ships with grain might suffice to ease for the moment the
glass" to the imperial capital. But the promise of a rich profit had worries of a riotous urban mob, as one of the letters written by
turnedout to be "treacherousanddeceptive",becausemany other Sidonius during his tenure of the urban prefecture in fifth-century
ships had arrived in Rome carrying the same goods and caused Rome demonstrates. 38
prices to fall. 34 But such luxury markets were nonetheless very Finley's classic illustration of the vulnerable and unstable char-
much larger and represented a far more stable concentration of acter of the larger urban markets was the food crisis in fourth-
demand than could be mustered in the smaller towns. This is even century Antioch during the stay of the emperorJulian. Only with
moretrue inthecaseofstaplefoods.Therequirementsofthelarge Julian s intervention was the emerging crisis averted, but not even
citieswereofa sizethatcouldnotbesuppliedinthesmallscale,ad then without problems, through the importation of grain from
hocmannerofcabotage.Totakethemostextremeexample,Rome nearby imperial estates and later from Egypt as well. Market net-
would probably have required something like 1,500 shipments of works had been unable to solve the problem by responding to the
loo tonnes to supply its needs for grain.35 Clearly, more perma- growing demand and bringing in supplies from surplus areas. 39
nent connections and larger concentrations of merchants, transport The various accounts of the crisis add an extra dimension to our
facilities, infrastructure and routes to maintainthese hadto come understandingof the problem. It was not only a question of high
into existence in order to serve the needs of such giant markets. transportation costs. Local power wielders exploited their control
The big cities thus represent several steps up the ladder of inte- of the agricultural surplus in the region to take advantage of the
gration. 36From the merchants' perspective, they offered a higher, shortage and increasethe local market asymmetries by very con-
siderable hoarding in order to drive up prices further and make
33 Pace Harden and Purcell 2000, chapters 5 and9. Gibson and Smout 1995: 270 provide
a clearexposition ofthelowdegreeofeconomic integration createdbyphenomena such market. The interpretation ottered above clashes directly with Harden and Purcell 2000,
ascabotage,characterisedbyimpermanentconnections,andofthestructuraldifference e.g. p. i2l, who reduce the larger markets to an outgrowth of cahotageand therefore
from laraermarkets. SeealsoTchernia 1986, 172-193.Goitein 1967,chapters 3 and 4 tone down their importance. These markets, in fact, represent a qualitative change.
provides'a very useful description oftheuncertainties ofa worldofsmall Mediterranean They could not possibly be sustained by the casual small-scale movements of coastal
markets in the early Middle Ages. The general conditions would not have been very tramping. Theyneededa farmorepermanentinfrastructure. It is in thisperspectivethat
different in antiquity. the major shipping (and land) routes take ona very important role asthemain conveyers
34 Cic. Pro Rabirio40 ("fallacesquidemet fucosae")withErdkamp2005:177. It does of economic integration.
little that the passage has been emended, best by Mommsen; the general meaning is 37 The phenomenon shouldnot be seen as restricted to grain supplies. Thus Suetonius'
quite unequivocal. biography ofAugustus (42. 1) and Ammianus Marcellinus book 14, chapter 6, I, report
35 Gamsey 1983^ 118estimatesRomangrainimports atbetween 150,000and200,000 of wine shortages in the Roman market.
tonnes wheat. 3 SidoniusEpistulae[, 10withGarnseyandHumfress2001, 114.
36 SeeTchernia 1986, 189-193 for a related point. Morley 1996 explores the cre;ition of TO Finley >985a: 127. See further Gamsey and Humfress 2001: I20-I2I and Hopkins
.

more stable connectionsofeconomic integrationcreatedby the demandoftheRoman l978a:46-47 for discussionofthe emperorJulian'sreliefofthe food crisis in 362-3.

142 143
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A ROUGH TRADING WORLD

a killing. The intervention of the emperor provoked resistance in significant individual characteristics shaped by the institutional
thesegroups. They continued tokeeptheirgrainfrom themarket in fabric which supports them. 43 This is what historians should be
the city andeven hadthe "audacity" to buy up some ofthe imperial studying.
"relief supplies brought to Antioch. One can easily understand In dealing with markets in Bengal the EastIndia Company drew
why more modest merchants hesitated to step in and alleviate this on a set of trading strategies which in the two preceding centuries
particular crisis. It wouldhaveamounted to commercial suicidefor had transformed and gradually created a number of more coher-
such people, outsiders at that, to challenge the deeply entrenched ent and integrated markets in Europe.44 The various chartered
localmonopolypositionenjoyedbya verypowerfulgroupoflocal joint stock companies were themselves a prime expression of this
landowners. 40 The example carries a significant lesson which is development. The cmcial characteristic was the ability to create
rarely drawn: in the pre-industrial world closer integration of eco- greater and more long-lived concentrations of trading capital than
nomic resources and tighter coordination of markets, in particular, hitherto. This enabled the merchants to adopt a longer-term per-
depended ona handanything buthidden. It wasimpossible without spective of the market and create buffers which could absorb some
the intervention of very tangible and overt forms of organisational of the endemic irregularities of pre-industrial trade. The larger
power, to tie supply anddemand across locations into a more stable capital base enabled them to extend control over trading in many
relationship wheremarkets would be more closely integratedand individual markets. Control is here to be taken literally. It was
behave more uniformly.4 far from uncommon that military force was employed to achieve
A further clear demonstration of this is providedby Indiain the the objective.45 A report submitted to the Dutch East IndiaCom-
aftermathofMughalrule andtheearlybeginningsofBritishhege- pany (VOC) in the late i620s by Francisco Pelsaert, the Dutch
mony. After a disastrous famine in Bengal in the 17708 the British factor in the Mughal capital, Agra, conveys a very clear idea of
EastIndiaCompanyattemptedto organisea more stableandinte- this process. 46 VOC's commercial presence in the Agra area was
gratedcompany/state-controlledgrainmarketin theprovince. The primarily motivated by the local production of incligo, a highly
scheme was a fiasco and quickly abandoned; the Company had desired dye. It bought considerable quantities, to a large extent
failed to gain control over the numerous rural supply networks. financed by selling its primary commodity, spices imported from
Short of that, it was unable to establish a more stable and trans- various South-East Asian islands. These spices, however, were
parent situation in the grainmarkets in Bengal.The internal grain alsomarketed in largequantities by the company on the Coroman-
market in Bengal, however, was only a secondary concern of the del Coast (the south-east Indian litoral). In too large quantities,
Company. In areas ofcrucial importance for its operations, such as as a matter of fact, according to Pelsaert. The problem was that
opium production andtrade, it didnot tolerate defeat. Here control
waspursuedruthlessly,withwhatevermeansnecessary,untilit was 43 North 1990. North, in a way, has brought the challenge of'Polanyi into the mainstream
achieved and the market situation stabilised.42 The Indian exam- of economic theory.
44 Braudel and Spooner 1967 offer a useful overview of the gradual creation of more
pie is particularly instructive because it so clearly shows the clash stable, lessfluctuatingandmore uniformpricemovements in Europeanmarketsduring
of two different market regimes. There is a growing awareness theseventeenthandeighteenthcenturies.SeeGrangerandElliott 1967andGibsonand
Smout 1995 for two case studies of this process. For the extremely close correlation of
amongeconomiststhatmarkets arenever"just"markets;theyhave the price of grain in Amsterdam and in Danzig, see De Vries and Woude 1997: 414-419.
45 See Steensgaard 19730,chapter3 andChaudhuri 1985, chapter4 for analysesof the
40 Julian Misopogon 3680-3705 confirmed by Libanius Oratio [8, 195. chartered companies. Glamann 1958 demonstrated how the Dutch East IndiaCompany
41 Contra Harris 1999, who supposes that the mere existence of a substantial trade in did not possess a simple monopoly, but together with the other chartered companies
slaves would have worked to create uniform movements of prices across a large group created and developed a competitive European market in spices. Cf. Pearson 1993, who
of individual, separate markets. providesanotherexampleofthe importanceofthedevelopmentoforganisationsforthe
42 Chatterjee 1996, chapter 5 offers a very clear analysis of the British East India Com- integration of markets.
pany's first decades in Bengal. 46 Pelsaert 1925,chapter5.

144 M5
A ROUGH TRADING WORLD
IMPERIAL BAZAAR

to lower the price of pepper in Europe throughout the seventeenth


manyIndianmerchants, willingtoaccepta lowerprofit, imported century. 47
the Dutch spices from theCoromandel Coast to the Agra areaand
destabilised the market with falling prices as the result. This did Perhaps some will argue that the joint stock companies were
considerable damage to the Dutch capacity to procure indigo in exceptions, not even representative of European trade in the
the area. Lower prices on spices meant less money to buy indigo. period. On formalistic grounds that is correct. But in real terms it
would be more precise to say that they were the most articulated
Ontop ofthat, it becamemore difficult to reachanadvantageous examples of a general trend in institutional developments. When
pricewiththeindigosellers. Seeingthatthefactorwasfinancially Dutch supremacy in European trade during the seventeenth century
vulnerable they could press him harder and claim a higher price.
Therefore Pelsaert suggested thatthecompany shouldmakebetter receives explanation, it is the same general features that are evoked.
use of its control over the spice trade to cut the supplies from the Exemplifiedby suchinstitutions asthe Beurs, Korenbeiirs,Wissel-
Coromandel Coast ofhis Indiancompetitors in Agra. This would, bank, enormous warehouses and publication of printed biweekly
of course, mean smaller profits in the trade on the Coromandel price notations, it is the unprecedented strength and capacity of
Dutch commerce to control, organise and integrate markets which
Coast. But they would be more than compensated by the greater
income generated by the operations in Agra. What is remarkable repeatedly receive emphasis. 48 Perhaps its biggest achievement
here is the conscious formulation of a strategy to coordinate and was the level of integration it achieved in the Baltic grain trade.
It is truly astonishing to observe how closely the price in Danzig
integrate operations in widely separated markets into a coherent followed developments in Amsterdam in the eighteenth century
system.
Other aspects of this process included the financial ability to (Fig. 3.i).49
fund the build-up of extensive stocks, sometimes equal to the Strong political support, greater and more permanent concen-
turnover of several years, in order to make trading less dependent (rations of capital and much improved information, the achieve-
on the erratic fluctuations in supplies. In addition, attempts were ments of Dutch international capitalism were an expression of a
madebymerchantstopushbeyondwholesalemarketsandextend general process in parts of Europe which saw the position of the
middleman strengthened considerably. The wave of mercantilist
control right to the door of the producer through the advancement
oflargecreditsor,ifmoreforcefulmethodswererequired,through privileges, employed particularly by the rivals of the Dutch, were
aimed precisely at this goal. Later the process was given a fresh
military action.Thusthegreaterorganisational powerofmerchants
enabled them to get a much firmer grip on the erratically working impetus by absolutist governments seeking to push through a pro-
gramme of free trade, in emulation of eighteenth-century Britain.
supply networks andre-shape thebasicconditions oftrade. The This strategy was pursued by governments to open up their terri-
result'was thegradual growth ofmore stable andintegrated markets
tories for trade and loosen the control of local societies over their
where it made good sense to coordinate activities in individual
own markets. For, as Adam Smith remarked about the grain trade,
locations closely in order to achieve long-term goals rather thanto
obtain short-term profits. For instance, in spite of achieving a very
high degree of control with European pepper imports, the East 47 Steensgaarcl l973a: 146 and 152-153. In general Chaudhuri 1985, chapter4.
Indiacompanies didnot take advantage ofthe situation to drive up 4 Apart from Steensgaard 19730 and Chaudhuri 1985, see Klein 1965; Barbour 1966;
Wallerstein 19740; Israel 1989; De Vries and Woude 1997; Lesger 2006 for expo-
pricesexcessively andmakea quickmonopolistic profit. Instead, sitions of the principles and institutional strength of Dutch trade. See also Braudel
they preferred to keep the price at a level where the temptation to 1982 for numerous perceptive comments about the growth of the modern world
economy.
challenge theirdominance wouldneverbetoo great. Infact they 49 See de Vries and Woude 1997: 414-419 for the integration of the grain markets in
were able to operate a gradually narrowing profit margin. While Amsterdam and Danzig. Christensen 1941 is the classic analysis of the Dutch Baltic
grain trade and its institutional strengths.
pricesroseintheproduction areasinIndonesiatheystill managed
147
146
r
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A ROUGH TRADING WORLD

"literally with recourse to the forces of order" in the face of local


(a)
opposition.5'
The question at hand now is whether we should expect
the tributary-fuelled process of market formation, described in
chapter 2, to have causeda similar set of closely integrated mar-
kets to emerge in the Roman Empire. Finley was adamant in his
denial. 52 Not suiprisingly, his critics have seized the opportunity
to argue the opposite. 53 If we turn once more to our Mughal par-
allel, it does not warrantsucha reaction. As the experienceof the
chartered companies shows, markets did not easily adapt to the
more stable forms gradually developing in Europe. Rather they
seem in generalto haveremainedless strongly integrated.Volatile
prices, erratic fluctuations and significant local differences and
asymmetries continued to dominate the bazaars of north India. 54
It wouldbewrong,though,to mistakethisfora signofa primitive
trading world; in certain limited ways the Indian bazaar had at
its disposal tools for transacting business which were, in evolu-
tionary terms, more advanced than those at the command of the
Roman merchant. Most important among those was the hundi, an
Indian form of the bill of exchange. 55 It is now clear to Roman
historians that merchants may to a limited extent have been able
to organise cashless transfers of money, for instance with bankers
^."..v-v-v"r acting as intermediaries. But it is equally clear that a fully fledged
1738/42 1758/62 1778/82 and solidly institutionalised system of bills of exchange did not
Period
materialisein the Romanworld. Otherwise,wewouldexpectit to
Fig. 3. 1 Grain prices in Amsterdam and Danzig in the eighteenth century have left far stronger traces in the historical record than is in fact
(De Vries and Woude 1997: 418) the case (see Chapter5). The performance of the Mughal trading

"no trade deserves more the full protection of the law, and no
51 Persson1999: 146,ingeneralchapters4 and6. SeefurtherBraudelandSpooner1967.
trade requires it so much; because no trade is so exposed to pop- On local opposition to the process, see Thompson 1993, chapters 4 and 5. The lack
ularodium".50 Imperfectionsandfragmentationdidnot disappear of interestof largeempires in pursuingsuchpoliciesoffavouritism, wouldthuscarry
significantconsequencesfor thedevelopmentoftrade, paceMorley 2007:58.
from European trade. Nevertheless, the result was a gradual sta- -"" Finley 19850, "FurtherThoughts", first section.
bilisation and tighter integration of markets, both nationally and 53 Harris 1993. 1999 and 2000 (the latest piece was written before the two first mentioned
andis more cautiousasbefitsa chapterin The Cambridge Ancient History), Rathbone
internationally, created across large stretches of Europe and the 1997 (o" Egypt), and Temin 2001.
Atlantic world from the seventeenth till the nineteenth centuries 54 Blake 1987:451-455; Prakash 1991:64-65; Habib [999: 39-62, 68-82and90-102;
and Moosvi 2000 on the "imperfections" of markets in the Mughal Empire. Marshall
1976and Chatterjee 1996complement with material from the late Mughal andpost-
Mughal period.
50 Smith 1976, vol. 1:527. 55 Habib 1972 foranexposition ofthehundisystem in the Mughal Empire.
148 149
I
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A ROUGH TRADING WORLD

world can therefore be seen to offer an upper benchmark for the The experience of Banarasidas caneasily be matched by mate-
Roman experience. rial from the Roman Empire. In times ofmilitary upheaval we hear
At the same time, it provides us with a useful guide for our of trading wealth being a convenient target for cash-hungry gener-
understanding of Roman trade. In spite of the few limited techno- alsandsoldiers.InAppian'shistoryofthecivil wars,themerchants
logical advantages that it held over Rome, it was unable to trans- ofPalmyra barely avoid the onslaught ofAntonius by escaping to
form the basic irregularities and volatile conditions of pre-modem the other side of the Euphrates. 60 During the so-called year of
trade. Even after the introduction of the railway and the telegraph the four emperors, Tacitus tells of a town in northern Italy which,
under British colonial rule at the turn of the nineteenth century - swelled by merchants coming to a large fair, became a tempting
two features which significantly reduced many of the obstacles. target for the approaching armies.6' Even more revealing about
to economic integration - the Indian "bazaar" remained a very the general conditions is the comic anecdote in Apuleius' Golden
risky and fragile business environment. Many European compa- Ass about the zealous market official whom the hero encounters
nies, therefore, preferred to do business in Indiaoutsidethe sphere during a visit to the marketplace. 62 Whenthe agoranomos (market
ofthe indigenousmarket; theyneededfargreaterstability andpre- overseer) discovers that the hero has been overchargedfor a fish,
dictability to satisfy their profit requirements. 5 This goes to show he rushes down to the poor market seller to set him right. Now, the
that the chronic economic imbalances of the bazaar world can-
comic point hinges on the fact that the unfortunate agoranomos
not be reduced to a simple question of technological deficiencies. makesa fool ofhimselfbyfailingtogivethepetty hucksterhisjust
Social institutions played a crucial role. 57 The tributary process deserts and put him in hisproper place, while destroying the fish.
of commercialisation rested on a very different social balance of Our hero is left with neither fish nor revenge. Leaving the world
power. It did not invest the merchants of the Mughal "bazaar" with of literary fantasy behind, we have a letter among the Vindolanda
the kind of strong organisational powers and corporate influence tablets that conveys a similar impression.63 There we encounter
that were necessary to control and conquer the endemic irregu- an overseas trader, a homo transmarinus, filing a complaint about
larities of pre-industrial trade and production. A telling index of a beating he has received from a centurion. Likewise, aristocrats
this is that Indian traders were not normally in a powerful position could occasionally be found to intervene in the operation of mar-
vis-a-visthe aristocratic andpolitical elite.58 A small poetic auto- kets andexploittheirgreatermusclepowerto cornera line oftrade
biography written in the seventeenth century by a Jain merchant, in order to make a quick profit, as Vespasian reputedly did. 64 In
Banarasidas, provides interesting evidence of this condition from general, the position of the commercial middleman remained vul-
a merchant's horizon. Aristocrats and imperial authorities in his nerable. Roman authorities often looked with suspicion upon his
story often prey on the readily consumable riches of merchants. activities. Inscribed on a stele in the Piraeus, a set of regulations of
Time and time again traders are taken hostage in order to fill the Hadrianattempted to securea plentiful andcheapsupply offishfor
empty or just insatiable coffers ofMughal nobles. 59 Eleusis, presumably during the Mysteries, by, among other things,
seeking to limit the role of middlemen in the trade; their activities
5f) Ray 1988. Steensgaard 1973;) made the same point for an earlier period. were denounced as harmful speculation which only served to drive
57 Marshall 1976 offers a pertinent argument in support of this. up prices. 5
58 Marshall 1976; Pearson 1976; Das Gupta 1979; HabibandRaychaudhuri 1982: 183-
202 and 339-41; Das Gupta and Pearson 1987, chapters 4 and 6; Chatterjee 1996;
Subrahmaniam 1999. Pace Subrahmanyam 1995, who remains unconvincing. The few
examples he can point to are marginal and tend rather to reinforce the validity of the poetically evocative intheearly 198os. SeeSnell 2005fora studyofthe literary aspects
established historiography. of this text.
59 Banarasiclas' poem, the Ardha-Kathdnak, written in a dialect of Hindi, has received " AP.P-Bc5'9- (" Tac-Hist-m'30-34. 62 Apul.Met.I,24-25.
two recent translations: a drier, but literally more direct by Sharma 1970 and a more
.

yi Tab. lWo/. 344. 64 Suet.Vesp. 16. 1. 65 OHver [989, nol77^


i5o l5l
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A ROUGH TRADING WORLD

It would be wrong to mistake this greater social vulnerability procedures werejust the opposite ofthepolicies that were gradu-
of merchants in tributary empires with an absolute powerlessness ally introduced during the early modern period in Europe. 72 What
or complete lack of political influence. Merchants were far from mattered to theGreco-Roman elites, however, wastheavailability
always passive victims, asthe letter from Vindolanda also informs of well-supplied markets in the many cities which made up the
us. They, too, could stand up for themselves or seek the patronage political framework of the Empire and of which they continued
of powerful people. 66 However, compared to the world of their to be the local leaders. Placed under the supervision of the local
early modem European counterparts theirs was a rougher place, aedile or agoranomos, whose task it was to regulate business and
a less secure business environment. 67 But it was not an impos- ensure thattraders actedfairly without, asthey sawit, undue spec-
sible one. We even find some examples of officially empowered ulation, the markets of the Roman world remained subject to the
merchant organisations in the Roman Empire. One example is the "moral economy" of the polis/civitas. 73
small association of salt traders in Tebtunis in Egypt, known from
a papyms dated AD47. 68It showsthat themerchants possessed a
Sojourn on the Nile: the Egyptian price series
monopoly in salt in the area and regulated their mutual relation-
ships. This has been taken as evidence of something approach-
ing strong medieval guilds. 69 That would be wrong, though. The So far the discussion has been conducted mainly on impression-
Egyptian salt merchants had not really acquired a similarly strong, istic evidence. Historians and economists examining market inte-
independent corporate power.Themonopoly existsentirely within gration, however, are normally used to basing their analysis on
a context of state regulation and, most importantly, state taxation.
long, continuous series of recorded prices in different locations.
It is clearfrom thepapyrus thatthatthemonopoly rights arewholly But such statistical analysis is beyondthe means of the historian
dependent onthe merchants administering andpaying the salt tax for vast swathesofpre-industrialhistory. Recordswere eithernot
due to the state. It was, in other words, totally subordinate to the collected or have not survived. Only in exceptional cases is it
fiscal requirements of the tributary system. 70
Political leaders, thus, might both recognise and make use of basicallyintheeyesofthearistocrata sordidactivity,particularlyaspractisedbythose
that buy up goods only to sell them on. Yet if conducted in a'grandmanner,'which
the services of traders. But this generally happened in a context broughtgoodsnototherwiseavailableto market, thenit mightbedeemedworthyof
whichvalued urban consumers over the interests of exporters and respect. SeeGiardina 1986for thecomplex ideological websurrounding merchants in
the middleman. Illustration is provided by Hadrian's restrictions antiquity, thoughhe makestoo muchof a contrastbetweenthedespisedsmall trader
andthehonourablebigmerchant.Thewholesalerwasalsosubjecttosocialprejudice
on the export of olive oil from Athenian territory. Measures were and suspectedof immoderate greed, speculation andlying, as'is clearfrom'Cicero's
taken to ensure that local needs were met before export could own discussion of the secretive merchant in Off. 3. 50 and"the contempt administered
byPetroniustohisliterarycharacterTrimalchio,thestereotypicalfreedman,vulgarand
take place. 71 In many respects, as Adam Smith pointed out, such greedybeyondmeasure(cf. Sat. 75, 8-76, 9).
72 The theme of the third book oftheWealthof Nations, e.g. Smith 1976, vol. 3: 380,
66 E.g.theletterfromCicero(Fam. 13.75)askingfortheprolongationofsomeprivileges 422. See Bang 2006 for an attempt to relate the problem of Roman'markets" to"the
the grain merchant C. Avianius Flaccus had enjoyed regarding his deHveries of grain questions raisedby Smith's understanding of history. The formation of empire should
to Rome. For the Mughal Empire, the studies by Das Gupta 1979; Chatterjee 1996; not automatically be assumedto havecreated a similar strengtheningof commercial
chapters3 and4; andHasan2004offertelling illustrationsof themore fragilepower networks;paceErdkamp2005: 196,it gaveriseto a very differentprocessofmarket
and influence enjoyed by Indian merchants. formation.
67 Bayly 2000 is, to date, one of the best attempts to balance the greater institutional 73 SeeAlston 2002: 274-277 and337-339; Garnsey 1988: 257-268; Jones 1940: 215-
security of the rising European capitalism with a recognition of the non-passivity of 219. See Jakab 1997, chapters 2 and 3 for a legal analysis of the functions of the
merchants in the agrarian, aristocratic world. aedileandagoranomos Thompson 1993,chapter4 contrastedthemoraleconomyof
68 P. Mich. V, 245. 69 VanNijf 1997: 13-14suggestssuchan interpretation. local communities privilegingthe interestsofconsumers, withthe neweconomyin
70 See Weber 1972: 592, 644-645 and 652 for this distinction. eighteenth-century England, which strove to break down barriers between markets and
7' SEGXV, 108.SeeingeneralFinley 19853:160-164.ThefamouspassagefromCicero ensure greater economic integration by siding with the middleman. See Erdkamp 2002
Off. 1. 150-151, in fact, illustrates the ideological ambivalence in relation to trade: foranattempttoemploy thisconceptinananalysisoffoodriotsintheRomanEmpire.
152 153
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A ROUGH TRADING WORLD

possible to break through the mist ofpre-statisticaltime. The for- Coincidence, regulation or some other extra-economic cause may
tuitous preservation on clay tablets of astronomical records from be equally responsible. A useful additional test of market inte-
Hellenistic Babylon, for instance, does make it possible to catch a gration is whether developments in individual markets follow the
glimpseofthevicissitudesofcommoditypricesandpre-industrial same course. If prices develop in parallel fashion there is a good
trade forlong stretches oftime. 74TheRoman historian canexplore chance that it is the outcome of commercial integration. Providing
theextentto whichmarketswereintegratedwithreferencetoprice information on prices in different markets, the Egyptian evidence
material from Egypt, owing its survival to the protection offered makes it possible to explore tentatively all three dimensions of
to papyri by the dry conditions of the desert. commercial integration.
No papyri records, however, can match the continuity of the. The material mainly originates from urban and rural, half-
Babylonian material. In that respect, the Roman is more fragmen- commercialised, contexts in Middle Egypt. 76 No major market is
tary and episodic. But what it lacks in continuity, the Romano- represented. This is both a strength and a weakness. It is a strength
Egyptian evidence does to some extent make up for in geo- because the testimony offered by this material can be taken as
graphical variation. The Hellenistic clay tablets, it seems rather broadly representative of conditions in the vast majority of mar-
ungracious to observe, are restricted to one city. A significant kets aroundthe Empire, whichwouldhavebeenno more, in factin
feature of pre-industrial trade was the relative unpredictability of most cases even less, centrally placed in Roman commercial life.
prices. Yet, prices fluctuate in all markets, sometimes violently, It is a weakness because it tells little about the situation in leading
even in quite well-integrated systems. Price instability may be a markets that might be expected to have pioneered a movement
symptom oflimited market integration, butisnoabsolute test.Two towards greaterintegration, had such a process occurred. Yet, we
other,complementary, criteriaarenormally employedtodetermine are in no positionto choose.The inhabitedpart of the region con-
the degree ofcommercial integration: unity ofprices andparallel sisted only of a narrow strip of land following the course of the
developments. Generally, integration ofindividual markets works Nile andthe BahrYusufcanalrunning parallel to it, andwidening
as a stabilising influence on prices. The effect of small changes fora distanceto includetheFayumwithLakeMoeris.Thiswas,in
in local supply anddemand is evened out through exchangewith fact, a physical environment whichoughttohavefavoured integra-
other locafities. This, in turn, will cause prices in individual loca- tion. With easy accessto water and only short distances to cover
tions to converge towards the same equilibrium. Near unity of by land, transport would have been far less of a problem than in
prices in differentmarkets is a useful indicatorofmarket mtegra- most otherplaces. The relevant evidence spans a period from the
tion. But there are always costs involved in moving goods from early first to the early fifth century AD. Unfortunately, most prices
one location to another. Even in well-integrated markets, prices in thefirst-to third-centurypapyriareonlymentionedinisolation.
are never completely identical; they may vary between two loca- This makes the density of information which can be gained from
tions within a span defined by the costs of bringing the two mar- these, a few exceptions apart, insufficient to study short-term mar-
kets together. If this span is wide, the single markets will remain ket developments in any detail. The early prices mostly only allow
largely'autonomous ofeachother. 7-5Ontheotherhand pricesimi- us to form an impression of the level of prices in the region. 77
larity need not necessarily be the result ofcommercial integration.
76 Rathbone 1991 clearly shows how market trade co-existed withforms ofnatural econ-
74 SeeAperghis2004:78-86for an analysis,noting the volatility of the Babylonian omy on the Appianusestate in this area. Farm labourers werenotjust employed on
market. a free contractual basis. Various ways to tie at least some of them to the estate were
75 Thisisanimportantmodification whichErdkamp2005: 199-200failstoaccommodate pursued. Wageswould, for instance,oftenhavebeenpaidin kind.
fullyinhisexpositionofthetheoreticalissuesinvolvedinmeasuring marketintegraho^ Rathbone1997offersaninterestinganalysisofthismaterial,butoverestimatesitspoten-
GibJson'and'S'mout-l995; Stiegler and Sherwin 1985 set out the different criteria for tial for studying market integration. The evidence only allows a very broad impression
examiningmarket integration. ofsome long-term trends, cf. Erdkamp2005:204.

154 i55
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A ROUGH TRADING WORLD

In late antiquity, however, the Roman state began gathering prices and then presented the authorities with an average or the
information on prices. Relevant urban professional associations, predominant price. We must also allow for significantdifferences
the collegia, were asked or required to submit monthly reports to in standards here. Not all collegia are likely to have been equally
the authorities about the prices, especially of raw materials, cur- rigorous, nor will information about all products havebeen equally
rent inthemarketplace. A considerable number ofthese individual important. By far the most elaborate of the preserved surveys, for
declarations survive. 78 These were then compiled and drawn up instance, documents developments in grain and wine prices quite
in surveys at various levels in the administrative hierarchy, list- closely, whereasthepricesfor less importantproductssuchasmeat
ing recorded prices over a time period for the different names or radish oil are consistently registered as unchanged throughout
(districts). Two such price series have been published among the the year. 8' The quality of single records is bound to have var-
Oxyrhynchus Papyri, one from the second quarter of the fourth ied, though it is impossible in individual cases to ascertain with
century and one from the early fifth. 79 Official registration of certainty whether a record is false or not. Even so, none of this
commodity prices was intimately linked with the changes intro- is likely to distort the information so as to render the overall
duced to late antique taxation. The government needed informa- impression of the market situation unreliable. Generally the image
tiononwhichto calculatethevalueoftaxclaimsandconsumption emergingfrom the dossiers seems to fit quite well with our knowl-
demands. Forced purchases ofgoods were a regular feature ofthis edge of markets in Roman Egypt. Thus the documents do not
system andwere supposed to beremunerated at therates current fail to register the existence of the government monopoly in the
inthelocalmarket.Similarly,duesinkindwereoften^converted salt trade familiar from the Pnncipate; they also, as will appear
intoa lumpcashpaymentaccordingtothegoingmarketprice80 below, reveal that of the agricultural products wine probably had
While the broad picture is reasonably clear, some uncertainty the most "developed" market in the province. This is just what
still remains as to the details. It is not known how the collegia we would expect of the primary cash crop of the estates of the
arrived at the prices they submitted to the administration We can landowning elite. 82Taken as a whole then andbearing in mind the
see that most prices did vary over time andaccording to location, poor state of the evidence for prices in most pre-industrial soci-
which is an indication that they do bear some relationship to the eties, the Romano-Egyptiangovernmentprice seriesdoprovide an
situation in the marketplace. But records were "only" submitted extremely detailed image of the situation in the markets of Middle
on a monthly basis. Ifprices changed it isunlikely that they did so Egypt at two cross-sections in time. Some distortion in the details
only once a month. Presumably the collegia registered the daily is probable, but not enough to invalidate a tentative analysis.
The fifth-century series consists of a centrally drawn-up set of
lists of the price of gold, silver and eight commodities in each of
78 E.g. P. Oxy.3624-3626.Forbasicdiscussionoftheseandtheotherlateantiqueprice
rerords."see'the-editor's introductions to P. Oxy. 3628-3636, 3773 and_3624-3626. See the nine nomes of the province of Arcadia in Middle Egypt. The
further Lo Cascio 1998andBagnall 2000: 89-9[ decisively contraFikhman 1991-2 records span one year and the prices are given in four-monthly
(thepricesaremarketprices,notadministrativelyfixedprices).
TO 'P~dxy~. ~T, -l~l3 (dating to 340) and P. Oxv. 3628-3636 (dating probably tothe; early
c.

fifthcentu'ry)arebyfarthe bestspecimens. Thefirstofthesewasprobably producedby


th'elocaTauthorities in Oxyrhynchus, theothercompiled in a provincial officebasedon Thisismostconvenientlyseenfromthetableonpp. 73-74oftheeditor'sintroduction
material submitted by "thetabularii ofeachcity", asstated in P. Oxy. 3628, lines^1-3. to P. Oxy. 3628-3636, summarising the information of the reports. The permanence of
80 E.g, Justinian,AppendixConstitutionum Dispersarumvii, § 26(inXI
Corpus luris CiviUs prices of some goods such as meat could very well be a reflection of the existence of
Lo Cascio only a very limited market in those goods rather than failure to report developments.
mB Novellae, 'ed. Schoell and Kroll), C Theod. VII 4, 10 and 46; 15. 2.

1998removes anyremainingdoubtsastothecharacterofthesedocuments, mey^must On top of this is the question of tax-inspireci monopolies in Egypt. The salt trade was
be'understood in the context of late antique taxation practices. Cerati 1975 remains a monopoly contracted to private individuals (P. Mich. V, 245), which explains the
fundamental on^the importance ofso-called coemptio andadaeratio in thefourth and uniform rate of salt in the survey.
fifth centuries. Bang 2007: 31-39 attempts to place the phenomenon in its economic 82 SeeRathbone 1991, chapter 6 on the agricultural production oflargeEgyptian estates;
context.
see further Sarris 2006 on the great Egyptianestates.

i56 157
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A ROUGH TRADING WORLD

intervals. 83Thismakesthedatainadequateforinvestigatingshort-
term fluctuations, other than in a very broad way. Limiting the
number of recorded prices to three each year for a particular com-
modity inevitably serves to underplay change. This is particularly
so since the prices recorded are likely to represent four-monthly
averages. The calculation of averages automatically irons out dif-
ferences betweenmonths and thus artificially minimises the level Arcadia
of fluctuation occurring in the market. From our present perspec-
tive. however, the set of lists is of particular interest because,
uniquely, they allow us to test for the two other criteria for mea-
suring the degree of market integration: variation in price levels
betweenmarkets andthe degreeof uniformity in developments in
commodity prices across locations. In theory, it should havebeen
possible to achieve a cross-section of prices at three points in time
for all nine names making up the province. But the document, as AphroditODolis
we have it, was never finished. Gaps for three nomes have been
left by the scribe to be filled in later. Wear and tear of the papyrus
has further reduced the available information. The names of two
of the names are lost, as is a considerable number of prices. Of
the eighteen originally recorded wheat prices, only eleven are still Theodosjopolis * .. --/*
Heracleopolis
legible, of wine only twelve. Yet, enough survives to enable a
tentative analysis.
First, let us deal with the variation inprice levels. Comparing the East Mediterranean:
quotations of commodity prices reveals the existence of remark-
ably large differences between the prices current in the individual ^i£ &V-
cities, even within the relatively small area covered by Arcadia,
not more than 100miles in length (see Fig. 3. 2). For instance, the Oxvrhvnchus
difference between the lowest and highest prices simultaneously
listed for meat is 25%, for radish oil, 31%, and 32% for lentils.
Even the value of the gold coin, the solidus, expressed in myr-
iads of denarii, shows some rather surprising differences. Thus
in the period from September to December there was a 5% gap Fig. 3. 2 Roman Egypt and the province of Arcadia
between the price in Cynopolis and neighbouring Oxyrhynchus,
83 P. Oxy. 3628-3633. In working on the papyri I have checked the Berichtigungsliste
and used the images made available in electronic form by the homepage of the Centre
for the Study of"Ancient Documents, University of Oxford (www. csaclox. ac. uk) to
confirmsomeuncertainreadingsofprices in thematerial.In thatconnection,I should
liketoexpress mywarmgratitude to DorothyThompson forspending a most enjoyable
Thursdaymorningwithme,tryingtodecipherthescriptusedbythescribe.
i58 159
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A ROUGH TRADING WORLD

less than 20 miles apart. This is the sort of behaviourwe would Table 3. i Variation in price levels in Arcadia
expect from a system of imperfectly integrated markets.
This impression is confirmed if we model the market condi- i: Variation span of prices, the difference between highest and lowest
price
tions in greater detail for some of the most important products,
Sept. -Dec. Jan.-Apr. May-Aug.
wheat, barley andwine.They all reveal the existenceof consider- Wheat 88% 67% io8%
able price spans between individual markets (see Table 3. 1). For Barley 30% 78% 33%
wheat, the difference between highest and lowest simultaneously Wine 7% (43%) 15% 27%
recorded price is betweentwo-thirds and, if we can trust the very
low Arsinoite values, a little more than 100% in the year under 2: Commodity prices, real figures (indexed numbers) in the nomes of
Arcadia
examination, though the figure is of course less for some cities.
For instance, the level in the Aphroditopolite name, less than TOO Wheat(den. myr./art.-index) Sept. -Dec. Jan.-Apr. May-Aug.
miles downstream, is 46% higher than the corresponding price Cynopolite 307. 7(ioo) 300(97) 325(106)
Oxyrhynchite 316.7 (i03) -
recorded for the Cynopolite nome in the September-December Uncertain 450(146) 500(162) 500 (162)
interval. In order better to assess this difference we must adjust for Uncertain 450(146)
transport costs. To take advantage ofhigherprices the grain would Arsinoite* 240 (78) 240 (78)
have needed to be taken down the Nile by boat from Cynopolis Aphroditopolite 450 (146) 450(146) -
to reach the Aphroditopolite market. Information pertaining to the Barley (den. myr. /art. -index ) Sept. -Dec. Jan.-Apr. May-Aug.
cost of transport is scanty. But the papyrus evidence we do have Cynopolite 285.7(100) 278.6(98) 300(105)
shows with consistency that the rent of a boat, including some Oxyrhynchite 292. 3 (102) -
Uncertain 270(94) 400(140) 270(94)
basic handlingcharges, is unlikely to havebeen very substantial.
Uncertain
Most graintransport ontheNile seems to havecost less than 3% of Arsinoite 225 (79) 225 (79) 225 (79)
the value of wheat. Cynopolite wheatcould easily have absorbed Aphroditopolite 225 (79)
this extracost. 4
Wine (den. myr. /sex. -index) Sept. -Dec. Jan. -Apr. May-Aug.
Part of the explanation for the very high discrepancy may lie Cynopolite 20. 6 (l00) 20. 6(100) 22.5(109)
in that pronounced enemy of market integration, the levying of Oxyrhynchite 22.5 (109)
local customs (see further Chapter 4). We know, though the evi- Uncertain 21. 4(104) 23. 6(ii5) 28. 6(139)
dence is heavily weighted towards the high empire, that it was Uncertain
Arsinoite 20 (97) 23. 8 (ii6) 27. 5(133)
normal for customs dues to be paid on exports from and imports
Aphroditopolite ? 28.6 ? 28.6(139)
to each nome. Whether this also included paying for goods in
transit on the Nile each time a boat crossed a name boundary is
* The grain prices in the Arsinoite nome may be suspiciously low since
they also fail to register any developments during the year. But this is
84 See Adams 2007 for a recent analysis of Egyptian transport. The price evidence is a matter for speculation. Therefore these data have not been excluded
collected by Johnston 1936 andDrexhage 1991. P. Oxy. 522 (second century AD) gives from the calculations. Exclusionwould, in any case, not alter the basic
a pure freight rate of 21 drachmae (dr. ) per 100artabai for Oxyrhynchus to Alexandria. picture.Thevariationspaningrainpriceswouldbelessened,especially
Setting wheat at a reasonable 8 dr. per artaba this comes out at 2. 5%. The boat, dealt for wheat,but it wouldstill behigh.
with in the papyrus, carried 3,400 artabaimaking the freight rate 712 dr. To this were
addedvarious handling and loading charges,bringingthe total bill to 762 dr. 3 obols
(ob. ) or 2. 8%forwheatat 8 dr./artaba.Otherpapyri statefreightrates inkind,e. g. BGU
Ill, 802,col. 22 givingpricesfor boattransportfrom theArsinoitenometo Alexandria
ofthree differentagriculturalproducts. All come out at lessthan I % ofthecargo.
i6o i6i
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A ROUGH TRADING WORLD

unclear. The craftiness of custom officials is legendary and, to


Priceof wheatin fifth-century provinceof Arcadia
judge from comparative examples, it would not be at all surprising
if transit boats were charged too, possibly at a lower rate. The In myriads of denarii per artaba In indexed numbers
Cynopolite name is separated from the Aphroditopolite by the nome
Sept.-Dec. Jan.-Apr. May-Aug. Interval 1 2 3
Hermopolite. Customs would then at a minimum be exacted on Cynopolite 308 300 325 Cynopolite 100 97 106
Uncertain 450 500 500
departure and on entering Aphroditopolis. The going rate seems Uncertain 146 162 162
Arsinoite 240 240 Arsinoite
to have been around 3% each time. 85 To the approximately 3% Aphroditopolite 450 450
78 78
Aphroditopolite 146 146
needed for transport, this might have added an artificial barrier of
at least 6%, or more if dues also had to be defrayed for transit
Histogram of indexed wheat prices
through the Hermopolite nome. Neither cost would in this case
have been prohibitive. But the need, willy-nilly, to pay perhaps
up to 10% of the value of the grain in the process of bringing it
to market may have discouraged the establishment of a routine
iiCynopolite
commercial infrastructure, able to take advantageeven of smaller
H Uncertain
price differentials. DArsinoite
The impression of relatively low andfragile integration between . Aphroditopolite
the individual markets in the province of Arcadia receives further
confirmation when we proceed to compare the development in
grain prices over the recorded year. Unfortunately, the damage to
thepapyrimeansthatnotall priceinformationhasbeenpreserved.
Wecanonly follow theprice during all three four-monthly intervals
for Cynopolis and a city whose name does not survive (Fig. 3. 3).
This and the fact that there are only three prices recorded during Development of wheat prices
the year, mean that the result must remain very tentative. From 200
the graph it appears that price developments do not conform to the
same pattern. While prices stay essentially the same in Cynopolis 150 4
in the second interval, the price increases 11% (index price from
I
100 -I
.

Cynopolite
146to 162) in the unidentifiedcity. In the third interval, the pattern Uncertain
is turned around. NowCynopolis experiencesan increaseof some
8%, whereas the price remains unchanged at its high level in the
I 504

anonymous city. The situation for barley puts this pattern into
0
sharper relief (Fig. 3. 4). The uncertain city experiences a sharp 1

rise from the first to the second interval and Cynopolis remains .

Cynopolite 100 97 106


stable. By the third interval Cynopolis shows a slight increase in - Uncertain 146 162 162
4-monthly intervals
85 See Sijpesteijn 1987: 19-25 and de Laet 1949, 324-329 for customs rates in Egypt.
Sijpesteijn 1987: 6-7 is not justified in taking the virtual disappearance of evidence
pertaining to customs from the third century onwards as a sign that the exaction of tolls
Fig. 3. 3 Price of wheat in fifth-century province ofArcadia
had been discontinued.

162
i63
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A ROUGH TRADING WORLD

Price of barley in fifth-century province of Arcadia the price ofbarley, whereas thecity ofuncertain identity now has a
In myriads of denarii per artaba In indexed numbers steep fall inthepriceofbarley. Thepricesareveryfarfrommoving
in unison and market developments appear to vary considerably
3
between the cities.
name Sept. -Dec. Jan. -Apr. May-Aug. Interval 1 2
Cynopolite 286 279 300 Cynopolite 100 98 105 Perhaps, a little surprisingly the harvest cycle fails to manifest
Uncertain 270 400 270 Uncertain 94 140 94
Arsinoite 225 225 225 Arsinoite 79 79 79 itselfclearly. Themain grainharvest in Egypt seems normally to
have taken place in May. Prices could therefore be expected to
rise in the second interval of the year as stocks began to wear
Histogram of indexed barley prices
thinner, and drop again in the third interval after the new crop.
Only the unidentified city conforms more or less to this pattern.
But its wheatprice remains high for the May-August interval. A
possible explanation would be that the harvest came late in this
1 Cynopolite
M Uncertain
particular year. The delayed rise in the Cynopolite grain prices
could then be a reflection of this and perhaps also indication of
DArsinoite
a bad or disappointing crop. 86 Another likely explanation might
be distortion caused by the method of registration. However, ' if
market integration was fragile, we should expect local deviations
from the "standard" pattern. If it had been possible to test for a
muchgreaternumberofcitiesandperhapsovera longertimeframe,
and the average pattern still failed to conform to the rhythm ofthe
Development of barley prices agricultural year, it would be a greater cause for concern. In this
case, however, the number of examples is so small that individual
150 -T
irregularities are only to be expected and may, in fact, be a result
of market imbalances.
I ioo 4 -^-Cynopolite
3 -*--Uncertain
Finally, let us consider wine. In contrast to the grain prices, a
-A-Arsinoite
very clear harvest cycle pattern comes through in the evidence;
I 50 -)-
prices are low in the post-harvest interval (September-December)
0
and rise steadily towards harvest time in August, reaching cul-
1 mmation in the the third interval. This requires introducing extra
-»-Cynopolite 100 98 105 subtlety into the analysis. Shared patterns of price develo'pment
-a-Uncertain 94 140 94 cannot, in and of themselves, be taken automatically as evidence
-ik-Arsinoite 79 79 79 of close integration. They may not be due to a close coordination
4-monthly intervals of supply and demand across marketplaces. Equally important
may be exogenous influences common to all the markets, such
Fig. 3.4 Price of barley in fifth-century province ofArcaclia as the arrival of a plague, political collapse or shared weather

Rathbone199^1:228-231documentstheprevalenceofa harvestpatternlaterthanthe
norm for the Fayum.

164 i65
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A ROUGH TRADING WORLD

conditions. This last factor, by producing similar harvest results Price of wine in fifth-century province of Arcadia
across the region, is undoubtedly part of the explanation for the In myriads of denarii per sextarius In indexed numbers
shared pattern in the wine markets. However, wine was the pri-
mary cash crop of Egyptian agriculture, and we should probably nome Sept.-Dec. Jan.-Apr. May-Aug. Interval 1 2 3
bepreparedto accept some integrationof markets. Cynopolite 20. 6 20. 6 22. 5 Cynopolite 100 100 109
Uncertain 21. 4 23. 6 28. 6 Uncertain 104 115 139
Thus, even though their courses are not absolutely identical, Arsinoite 20 23. 8 27. 5 Arsinoite 97 116 133
with the price leader changing twice during the year, the curves
for the unidentified city and Arsinoe do appear to show some Histogram of indexed wine prices
resemblance.87 On the other hand, the fragile and limited nature
of the integration in the wine trade is clearly brought out by the
overall development in the market. At the beginning of our period
the prices of the unidentified city, Arsinoe and Cynopolis are very
close together within a range of 7% from bottom to top, while at
the end of the year that gap has increased to 28%, and Cynopolis . Uncertain
has seen a significantly different development than the other two HArsinoite
markets (Fig. 3. 5). Incidentally it is worth observing that local
customs duties might have been an important barrier to integration
in the wine markets. All in all, this leaves an image of a set
of markets where integration was limited, links were fragile and
vulnerable, and coordination between the individual markets fairly
weak. As a result conditions varied considerably from city to city,
even within this very limited territory. Development of wine prices
Moving on, a fourth-century papyrus lists information on the 160
monthly, presumably average, prices for gold, silver, wheat,
140
barley, lentils, vegetable seed and wine over a fifteen-month
120
period (see Table 3. 2). 88 As was to be expected we find a pattern 5
for the agricultural goods heavily influenced by the seasons with a 100
E .

Cynopolite
3
pronounced tendency for prices to peakjust before harvest and to 80 Uncertain
slump with a little delay after. But the agricultural seasonal cycle I 60 -*-Arsinoite
cannot account for all developments. Again some irregularities, 40
now less suqwising to us, emerge. Other factors clearly also had 20
a strong influencein the shortterm asthe monthly averagesshow. 0
87 One reason for their close resemblance could be that the unidentified city was located 1

close to Arsinoe, e. g. if it was identical with Herakleopolis at 26 km's distance, which Cynopolite 100 100 109
might well be the case.
Uncertain 104 115 139
88 P. Oxy. 3773. The editor assumes that the prices are real market prices. However,
if government officials could calculate four-monthly averages, I have no doubt that Arsinoite 97 116 133
collegia would be able to produce average monthly prices too. In view of the violent
fluctuations of some of the prices, it would be highly unlikely that prices within each
month were absolutely fixed. Fig. 3.5 Priceofwinein fifth-century province ofArcadia
166 l67
A ROUGH TRADING WORLD

Q Thepriceofbarleyisrevealing. Itsetsoffwiththeexpectedrise
^f:
£:'
IS asstocks wearthinner during winter. Then inMecheir it suddenly
drops by 20%, only to rise to its former level in the followins
^ s .- §'
month. The harvest sees a slump but only for two months, foL-
Ill loweda little surprisingly by a steepincreaseof33%. Thescript
Ni for wheat is slightly different. It shows an 11%'increase from
^ ^Sl Phaopi until Pachon, then drops in Pauni to the previous autumn
u t-~ S
-t M
^ &
level as the crop is harvested. But then in That a fall of another
^ ^I i ll% follows rather unexpectedly. For lentils, a similar pattern of
&<
^ Is some erratically fluctuating prices appears. Here, as for barley,
0
s
il
Q ~a
there is a surprising drop in Mecheir (12%) and the fall in prices
^ ^ c^ t~-
afterharvestisveryquickly offsetbya largeincreaseinPauni.Did
i the crop fail? Or was there some other shock, unknown to us? Be
i
-S; that as it may, the situation seems to have been unstable - as the
.

^ further 17% increase in Thoth and its immediate nullification in


Phaophi indicate Something similar couldbesaidaboutvegetable
3 I ^ seed, where weobserve anincrease ofsome 60% during the time
0
§i wecan follow the price. From these observations it should beclear
e r<~) .-0
that seasonal and other changes combined to make the markets
t c". '2
quite volatile during the year. Further, developments in individ-
i IS
i £ .c
ualgoods showfairly divergent patterns, anothersignof weakly
integrated markets. That becomes even clearer when we include
^ &1 5
~Q gold and silver in our observations. The document stems from
I^
in in >n 0
ttieperiodofconsiderable inflationaffectingtheimperial coinage.
The timeframe is not long enough for this to have a visible effect
.1 on the prices registered for the agricultural goods. But with gold
^
and silver it is another matter. Both seem to rise in Athyr. Then
a,
^
r^ m 1st
§5-5
silver sees an additional increase in Mecheir. In Pachon both silver
~§ s^ .
: II andgoldrise thoughnotbythesamepercentage. Verybelatedly
'£. & f-
QS| goldseemstofollow suit(fourmonths later, infact), whereassilver
climbs to itshighestlevelhitherto inThoth. Insum,thefourth- and
a ^ .s S
fifth-century government pricelistsconveyanimpressionofvery
M

m
-D' . 5 JS <?
opaque, weaklyintegrated markets withrelatively frail stabilising
u
'» 3 S S Ill mechanisms.
I i a a. s-^s-s Consisting ofmonthly andevenfour-monthly priceaverages, the
a
a !a a fourth- and early fifth-century lists must invariably have masked
f
"3
w -2 ^
u JU
some short-term fluctuations. Some ofthis wecanmake upforby
complementing ourimageofmarketsinMiddleEgyptbydrawing
169
A ROUGH TRADING WORLD
IMPERIAL BAZAAR

procurement of small quantities of wheat and wine. Taking wheat


in some of the earlier, but more disparate information on prices first, on 7 September in AD 45 the price is listed at 4.4 drachmae
w'e'D'os'sess from'the area. 89 Effectively we have only a handful (dr. ) per artaba. A fortnight later it has risen by 30% to 5. 7 dr.
Jdocuments offering sufficiently detailedevidence onwhichto Three days later it is 8 dr. or an extra 40% higher. 93 Two days
create short-term price series. Several oftheserelate to^thepnce later it drops to 7. 3 dr., that is by 9%. In October it goes up in
o^win^This'cames problems ofits own. Often it is^not possible two instalments to 8 dr. again. It is clear that even in the very
to ascertain whether a variation in price reflects different quali- short term, prices fluctuated quite violently at times. This conclu-
ties of wine or changing prices. 90 A couple of other series come
do sion is further supported by the data on wine from the grapheion.
from'internafe state accounts. While there is no doubt that they
In the same months, the prices for wine fluctuate within a band
reflect market prices, asarguedbyRathbone, overthelonger term, of 2. 50 dr. and 4. 58 dr. per keramion or by up to 80% in round
itis'farfrom dearthat they were adjusted according to short-term figures.94 This image of fragile market integration would appear
developments in themarket. Thus one showsaseasonal
surPnsm^stat)u- to clash with Rathbone's analysis, partly based on the same data.
"that 'does not even register the expectable changes. By a comprehensive statistical analysis of the fairly few attested
There^'for instance, nodrop inthemonths aftertheharvest. To prices for wheat, wine and donkeys from Middle Egypt in the first
eefrom thefigures, the level ofthe accounting price seems to three centuries AD he concluded that markets seemed to be well
JhavfeeYeenadjustedannuallyinJuneandmoreorlessmaintained integrated in the region. His conclusion was based on the identifi-
for the nexttwelve months.9' cation of a common long-term pattern with two periods of relative
This leaves us with the information that canbe s<
price stability within relatively broadprice bands from c. AD 40
theTebtums^p/^on, orrecordoffice,forSeptember andOcto- to 170 and again from 190 to 270. 95
ber AD> 45.92 Here we find a number of transactions for the First, the price bands are very broad. That for wheat in the first
period lies in an interval between 5 or 6 and 12 dr. per artaba.
M H.-J.Drexhage 1988and 1991 andRathbone ,997havegatheredAematerial This leaves plenty of room for local intra-annual variations. If we
: Sl;SSEji^iijis= look at the very small amount of data that constitutes this band

S;i^Siii^|^?S£S
^e^^^hb^T997:^:Thisproblem, ^c, d^^^J>^^
we find that it is essentially basedon ten prices from the Arsinoite
93 One possible explanation for this extraordinarily high leap could be a very poor Nile
^e^^^''hcP^^^tte^inedataProiectafairlycohercntJ'TClge'Th£tp^ inundation. Prices will therefore have soared in response to the expectation of a bad
^S^^s^'^uffi^n^sigm^amtorequireexptanauonj. ^refl^ harvest in the coming year, Rathbone 1997: 193. However, that remains only one
^S^^^^h?:^'Sm 'ES^ possible hypothesis. If we are to judge from slightly later material, the start-out price of
S^iZ^'and ^^lik£>ytavt, ten, b;^n^^'^^: The 4. 4 dr. per artaba was very low. We could therefore also just be seeing a return to more
d^'thereforewere theresultofa muchmorehomogeneous co".ectio"Pro(^dure_ normal prices.
9. ^^^^d^Rad^ne 1997:229-230).TheH^ation^mN^n^ 94 Pace Ralhbone 1997: 196-197, who concludes that changes over the very short term
91^S^^^'^^n^od^Th^^o^^^a^ were minimal. To support this conclusion he calculates the variation from the median
K^'^^no'infom^ion forJunebutinAugustittasns to^d^tA; (the middle point between the two extreme points in the price range). Over the short
^^:^^nc<. ta^ln0ctob^^^^Tghtl^b^^^^ term that is going to produce a false sense of continuity. For instance, a price rise of
H^Si^ijij^^cSS 100% is only goingto appearasa variationof33% aroundthemedian(example: price
goes from 5 to 10. Variation around the median will be only 2. 5 around 7. 5 or 33%)

sSijii'i'iHiiS^ss and a rise of 50% will come out as a fluctuation of 20%. The merchant, however, is
not going to pay the median price. His profit is going to depend on the variation in
^=^iiiss=s;s:
the'thirTcentury,wouldoftenhavebeenadministrativel^fixe^ _^_^^^
real prices. Cf. Steensgaard >973a: 42-59 for a similar approach to the calculation of
short-term fluctuations in pre-modern markets. Working on early modern trade he even
considers as violent much smaller variations than our evidence shows.
^ Sl ^iT^"^ gramp;i(:ei^M"/LI^2£^^^ 95 See Rathbone 1997: 210-216fora summary ofhisresults. H. -J.Drexhage 1988 is much
^^r^e^emo^^^emenriy'listedin^uncan-Jone^ 1990^becauseheliststhe closer to the present author's analysis.
gra"mprrices"according todate.SeealsoRathbone 1997:217and224.
l7l
170
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A ROUGH TRADING WORLD

nome andsevenfrom the Hermopolite. Takenseparately, thedata increase uncertainty in the short run, as the many surviving com-
produce an average of 7. 36 dr. for the Arsinoite and 9. 55 dr. or plaints clearly testify; often people wouldhavesuffered losses and
been forced to sell below the current market rate. Individual com-
30% higherfor the Hermopolite. Thisdifference may becoinci-
dental. Ten and seven figures respectively from a period of over munities did not exist in perfect economic isolation either. Trade
clearly didtakeplace. Inthe long run this must haveworkedto cre-
loo years canhardly beconsidered adequate evidence to allow
conclusions regarding differences in the price levels between the ate some broadly coherent features. Even if prices in one Egyptian
two names. But they'do remind us that we cannot exclude local city would normally have differed from those of its neighbours,
differences within thevery broadtrends located by Rathbone. In we would expect the variations to remain within limits. If they
tact.forourfifth-century dossierbasically all thewheatpricesfall had consistently been of an entirely different order, landowners
within a similarly wide span, and yet considerable fragmentation in the surrounding area would surely have moved in to benefit
characterised the market; The broad comparability of early and and thus gradually re-established a connection, however broad,
lateprices, incidentally, corresponds quite well withrecenttrendsth between individual prices in the region.98 The identification of
inlate antique scholarship stressing the continued
economic
heal some common long-term price trends, therefore, does not militate
andvitality ofmarkettradeinthefourthandfifthcenturies. 90The against the case for a relatively low level of market integration.
evidence of short-term fluctuation and the late antique records, They are only to be expected. " Rathbone, for instance, convin-
therefore, both suggest that the parameters, never made explicit, cingly suggests that the caesura between the two identifiable price
of Rathbone's analysis are faulty. The Egyptian prices from the bands was caused by the dismption that followed the arrival of
Principatearefullycompatiblewitha scenariowheremarketinte- the Antonine Plague in Egypt. '00 A similar leap in prices can be
gration remained fragile. observed across large sections ofEurope after the shock caused by
Second, it is important to recognise that this is not a question the Black Death. That was long before the arrival of more closely
of either total disintegration with completely isolated communi- integratedmarkets. Ratherthantheresult of a closeintegrationof
ties or fully correlated markets moving in absolute unison; we are supply and demand, the jump in prices after the Antonine Plague
trying to look atdifferences between a group ofhighly complex wascausedby anexogenousshocksharedby the wholeprovince.
pre-industrial societies with forces working on several levelsto
tie localities intowidernetworks. Theactivities ofthestatewould The limited institutional coherence of the tributary empire
have been one significant factor in creating some broad overarch-
ingpatterns, aswasarguedinthelastchapter.Ona micro^level So, the question is whetherthe Roman world ever made the move
state-defined rates for compulsory purchase or the conversion of beyond weakly integrated, volatile markets with some degree of
graintaxes into cashpayments may havehelped stabiliseprices long-term coherence to more closely correlated and stable mar-
inthelongterm withinthebroadbandsidentified byRathbone. 97 kets. The Egyptian evidence surveyed, so far, suggests a negative
Compulsory purchases, of course, would often have served to answer. But this answer could admittedly be better supported.
The evidence is disparate and spans approximately 400 years.
96 Bagnall 1993,Banaji2001,Sams2006andZiche2006.ITheyall'"sistand
onAein
continued
3v'o7e7 cJon"om^liteYn ate
much of the Empire during antiquity, particular 98 Steensgaardi973a:58 arguesthatshort-temiweakintegrationofmarketsdoesnot
Egypt'The7efore"it'is"not unreasonable to usethismaterial, atleastasanindicator . exclude the creation of broader conjunctures over the long-term.
conditions in the preceding centuries.
97 SeeRathbone~i997: I96-W t'orthissuggestion. Statepurchases andc°"v^onrate^ 99 Grover 1966 provides an analysis of that sort of low-level integration in the Mughal
Empire.
^n onTv'hav'e be7en' very'broiid 'stabilising'factors. According to Rathbone's P"ceband^,
rtie'spanofvariationsbecomesnarrowerinthethirdcenturywhenevidenceofconversion '°° seeScheidel2002forananalysisoftheeffectsoftheAntoninePlagueinEgyptseen
in the light of the Black Death.
stops for a period.

172 173
T
IMPERIAL BAZAAR
A ROUGH TRADING WORLD
Significantchanges took place within that period. On top of this,
the information does not originate from some of the more impor-
wouldbearistocratic households. Theyoftencontrolled enormous
tant markets in cross-regional trade, where the pulse beat quicker
amounts ofagricultural produce forsale,atleastsufficient tomake
and closer integration was more likely to make its first appear-
themimportant players ona localorregional scale7However"l
ance. However, we do have a few scraps of information issuing
did"<,)tdTend
rested their
°"theirabilitytotiemclrketstogetherThei!:'powe'I-
on position in the political hierarchy and in the con trol
from people in touch with more central markets. One of those is
provided by a letter sent from Coptos in the early second century.
oftheagricultural surplus. Indeed, often they seemrather to have
The city held a central position in the long-distancetrade between
exploited thisposition tobenefitfromenhancingtheendemic mar^
Egypt and India, and developed into an important interregional
imperfections; I have already mentioned the resentment ofthe
market in the province. 101 The sender had been commissioned by
wealthyd.assesinAntiochtothevariousimperialattemptUo'all'^
a certain Apollonius to procure a number of goods there to the
viatea particular foodcrisis.Libaniusgavewordstothe'sentiment
underlying theresistance. In a letter toa high-ranking offic'iai"t'het
substantial value of a little less than t , 000 dr. The letter, there-
fore, offers an interesting glimpse of conditions in a fairly impor-
count of the Orient, Rufinus, he only grudgingly admitted'that
tant commercial town and may help us to fill in the blanks. The
^interference in a food crisis hadbeen necessary'and that Ae
writer tells of his careful efforts, mostly crowned with success,
interference with the "autonomy of the marketplace7'"hacTbee'n
to secure a good bargain for his correspondent. At the end of the
tlwlesserevil. '^often landowners wereunwiTlingto matee;en
business report, he declares his willingness to undertake further
thatconcessiorLSomegroupstooktheirresistanceotointe7vention
commissions on behalfof Apollonius andthen addsa bit ofexpert
^thewayto theemperor's court: a ruling ofMarcusA'urelius'
information: "the price of bullion is now 326 dr., for as you know,
andVerusfelt obliged toemphasise that"decurions'shouldnotbe
the prices at Coptos change from day to day". " Again, it is the
'. to.provide. graintotheirdtizensatlesstha"theprevailing
impression of endemic and erratic local price fluctuations that
market. price"-, '05Ingeneraltheelitedldnotlookfavourably (
seems to receive confirmation. This image also conforms to the
attempt to reduce its capacity to exploit its economic resources'.
^aramg andspeculative manipulation ofthemarket bythenower-
general expectations of the Roman elite. According to the second-
century jurist Gaius, prices of many important commodities such
fill, notleast in thenecessities oflife duringtimes of"cr-^nd
in the ancient
as wine, oil, grain andeven credit, were likely to showstrong local r,Tl n!lu.l!commonplace sources.
'06
It speaks vol-
ume^thatamongthe/elativelyfewdirectionsabout'ev'e'rydaylife
,

or regional variations. 3 ,

We can go further by contemplating whether it is possible to


in the Lex Irnitana (a Spanish municipal law dating to'th"e late
pinpoint any institutions with the capacity and sufficient power
to be able to establish the long-term control of markets necessary l^aniusEp.1379,2 ("TTIVayopavauTovo. ov")withGarnseyandWhittaker1998:
to make them more closely interdependent. An obvious candidate "s ^t, 30^(Marcianus)LFOr thlsanda fewsimilarPassages, seemostrecently Lo
=S^?SSIi^i=S
"" Plin. Nat. V, 60 on Coptos. For a recent collection of papers, see Autour de Coptos.
102 Translation, Johnston 277 of P. Giss. 47 (= W. Chr. 326). The text, however, must
be read with the corrections to line 29 published in the first Berichtigungsliste by
S^i=sii^iiSS
Preisigke from 1922.
"'3 Dig. 13.4. 3. Similar is Pliny Nat. XXXIII, 57. One might also adduce more literary
forms of evidence. To satirists. novelists and philosophers alike trade remained an ^i^m hisforty-sixthspeechharpingonabou^seif^on^t^ Sn^ ^)^
uncertain activity, a game of chance first and foremost. See Erdkamp 2005, chapter 4
for a broadly similar assessment of integration and fragmentation in the Roman grain E'g', phil os, tratus v't:. APOtA:I5 (tre;lted by Gamsey '988: 76). The Elder Cato i
trade. 3^ ^ I^^, ^e^riS[S;
ablel t^^SS
sufficient storage capacity be
tohoa^^u^al^^^<hS
174
175
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A ROUGH TRADING WORLD

first century), we find a sombre prohibition against any kind of Empire, such as Alexandria and Syrian Antioch. 113 From taxation
hoarding. 107Thepoliticalelitenormally possessedsufficientsocial the imperial state controlled enormous amounts of grain, sufficient
power to be ableto benefit from the volatile market environment to make it by far the biggest player in the field. This allowed it to
and the endemic, sometimes wilfully created, imbalances in sup- organisethe grain supply of the imperial metropolis into a much
plies. It had no incentive to try to change things by investing more settled and stable pattern than was achieved in republican
in greatermarketpredictability instead. 108At times, exploitative, times. "4 This did undoubtedlycreatea more predictableenviron-
short-term speculation is even presented asa convenient solution ment for the Roman consumer and secondary private suppliers.
for aristocrats in need of more cash.I09 This was an attitude the But the result wasto a largeextentbroughtaboutby crowdingout
Roman elite shared with its later Mughal counterparts. 110 the market. A very large part of the grain was simply handedout
Moving a step further up the ladder we find another possi- free to the citizen population as a privilege and what was left in
ble candidate to-exercise a stabilising and integrating influence the imperial granaries would have been sold, probably at a fairly
on markets, the different segments of the imperial state. Faced low market rate. "5
with the danger of social upheaval, cities, provincial governors
andtheemperor occasionally all hada strong interest in checking "3 Sharp 1998: 127-140 for some observations on a scheme meant to benefit the food
the worst abuses. '" But such intervention, as pointed out above, supply of Alexandria.
114 The grain supply of Rome has received extensive treatment. See Pavis d'Escurac
happened with a view to local conditions, not market integration. 1976;Rickman i98oa; Garnsey 1988; Herz 1988;Sirk.s 1991; Hobenreich 1997; and
At anyrate, most initiatives werediscontinuous, implemented on Ercfkamp 2005, chapter 5.
an ad hoc basis and only during times of severe crisis to ensure ' '5 The Roman state seems to have handed out grain free ofcharge to 150, 000 to 200, 000
people at anannual rateof60 moclii per person. At a generous annual consumption rate
social peace. "2 The bigexception, ofcourse, wasthefood supply of 175 kg wheatperpersonthiswouldhavesufficedto feedwithgraina populationof
of the imperial capital Rome, perhaps followed by some precau- 350, ooo to 450,000 in very round numbers. In other words, via the grain dole alone
the Roman state probably satisfied the grain needs of not less than one-third of the
tionary measures of more limited help in other large cities of the populationofthecapitalandprobablycloserto one-half.Ontopofthismustbeadded
state saleson the"free"marketin thecapital.Regrettablyweareleft very muchin the
dark by our sources. We should not imagine a static picture. The proportion of state
sales in the market is likely to have increased asthe state apparatus in the capital grew
. °7 LexIrnitana,section75. (ThoughnotthemostrecentLatinversion,Gonzales1986 during the Principate. I suspect that during the Principate, the state would relatively
offers aneasily accessible edition andwith a parallel Englishtranslation.) quickly have become a very important supplier of the "free" market as well. From
.
°8 Erdkamp"2005:155-74makestheimportant'pointthatRomanlandownersoperated taxes, the state commanded far more grain than it needed for both the army and the
witha'tewca'rry-over of grain stocks'from year to year. Whenprices were volatile free handouts. Rome would have been a convenient place to sell some of this. It is not
it madebettereconomicsenseto profit on highpre-harvestpricesthanon long-term necessary to imagine the creation of a strong centralised commercial administration
storage. Biglandownersthereforewerepartofa regimewhichreproducedmarket in Rome. Documents in the banker's archive found outside Pompeii, the so-called
imperfectionsandfragmentation,paceHobenreich1997:268-282 Murecine tablets, show us that consignments of Alexandrian wheat were released on
109 Suet.Vesp. 16 i. Whittaker 1985suggeststhatthereisa stronglinkbetweenmember- themarketvia small, individualprivatemiddlemen(TPSulp.45-46and51-52,dating
ship'oHheimperialeliteandimportstoRome.Presumablysenatorsexploitedtheir to the reign of Caligula, mention the giving of 13, 000 modii of Alexanclrian wheat,
powerto gainadvantagesintheRomanmarket. stored in a Puteolean granary, as security. Dig. 39. 4. [0. 8 confirms that it was normal
''" A'li"1997"chapter6.forexamples.Inthatchapterhealsotreatsanimperialfannan procedure for the state to avail itselfofprivate merchantsto sell the produce which it
(edict/clenouncing the manipulation ofthemarket by Mughal nobles. controlled). A letter of the emperor Haclrian (Oliver 1989, no. 187) refer to the state
.
" Apart'from theLe^/mttem(/(GonzaIes 1986)(themunicipallevel) onecouldp^ shipments of Alexandriangrain as intended for the market ("Trpos TT|V ayopav") of
evidencefrompapyriandinscriptionsshowingRomangovernorsorderingthat^tocks the capital. This may suggest that state sales were routine, which is why Nero hoped
be'made available for sale in the market, not exceeding a specified price^e. g. Lucius to gainon highgrainprices in Rome (Suet. Nero45. 1). Finally, reports ofan episode
AntistiusRusticus'measuresfora grainshonagein PisidianAntioch(AE 1925, [2&, of speculative hoarding of state grain during Commodus' reign seem to imply that
trans. Sherk 1988, no. 107). ^ _^ , ^ ^ _, ^ state grain played or had come to play an important role in the market (Herodian I,
"2 TheDhenomenonhasreceivedfull treatment in Gamsey 1988.withslightlydifferei i2, 4 and Dio Cassius 73, [3, l). Rickman l98oa seriously underestimated the role of
"lasis in Erdkamp 2005. chapter 6. Seefurther Grenier 1997 tbr some perceptive the state in the grain supply because he assumed unrealistically high per capita grain
commentsonhowadhocattemptsto curbthemarketwouldhaveworkedto increase consumption. See Gamsey 1988, 231-239 for a general, albeit on balance probably
commercial unpredictability ratherthan improve thefunctioning ofmarkets. still too conservative, discussionof the role of the state in the Roman grain market;

176 177
T

A ROUGH TRADING WORLD


IMPERIAL BAZAAR

The emperor did not run a commercial establishment Moye- would not have been the least important elements in this selection
ment of grain to the capital happened independently of market process. Josephus relates how Herod the Great, during a famine
considerations. It wasa question ofstate. Theemperor couldnot, whichaffected large parts of the Levant, was able to secure a con-
if he valued his own security, let increased demand in other areas signment of Egyptian wheat by exploiting his connections with
oftheempire havea decisive effect onthesupplies broughtto^the the prefect of Egypt, C. Petronius. For he, "thoughmany persons
had come to him becauseof the same needs, was a friend of Herod
Roman market. As Hadrian wrote ina letter tothecouncil ofEph-
and wished to rescue his subjects, and so he gave them priority
esos,~onTywhentheneedsoftheimperialcapitalhad[beeniserved in the export of grain". "8 Access to the market in surplus grain
wouldothercommunities beallowedtobuystategrain. "6 A bad
harvest ina grainsurplus-producing province suchasEgypt, caus- was, in other words, far from open or equal. It is not impossible
to imagine that preferential treatment will often have increased
ingpricesto risein Alexandria, wouldnotbeallowedto have^a market imbalances in the region, ensuring supplies where they
strong effectonthemarket inthecapital. Iftheemperor hadgrain
were not urgently needed. Therefore it seems implausible to look
to spare,hemightopenthestategranaries[nMey:mdnamevm to the Roman state, though it might quite possibly have created
shipbackstocks from Rome andsell it atreducedrates. Butthis more stable conditions in some markets, for the creation of a set of
would only be doneto avert disasterandthedecisionwastaken
withoutregardtocommercial considerations. "7Thusitisunlikely tightly integrated markets between the core regions of the Mediter-
that'there ever arose a very close link between the situation in the ranean through the disposal ofits suiplus grain. It simply lacked the
Alexandrianand Roman grain markets. organisational apparatus necessary to make it respond quickly and
"In years of abundance, on the other hand, the imperial state effectively to market developments acrossthe empire. It is telling
could dispose of far more Egyptian grain than it needed for the that in the case of the food crisis in Syrian Antioch, treated above,
cap'itafand the army. Some"of this would have been exported there was no "marketing" agency which ensured that grain held
from Alexandria to locations in the eastern Mediterranean expe- on neighbouring imperial estates and in Alexandriawas shipped
riencing a temporary or permanent graindeficit.This would, to to the city in need. That only happenedat the emperor's personal
intervention. "9
some extent, have exercised a stabilising influence on the Levan-^
tin'egrain "market". However, asthe above-mentioned letter of Indirectly, of course, the state did promote some stabilisation
HadrTan to Ephesos goes on to show, being admitted to the mar- of market conditions across the Empire. The development of a
ket in Alexandria was a matter of acquiring a political privilege
118 Josephus, Ant. Jud. 15. 307. Gamsey 1988, 255-257 emphasises how commercial
from the emperor or more often the prefects of either Egypt or considerations would generally have been overruled by various political motives.
o'fthe grain supply. Much else other than commercial considers Market response in the Alexandrian export market would therefore habitually have
tions was bound to enter into the decision whether access should been heavily distorted.
' '9 SeeGrenier 1997for a relatedpoint. However,hegoesfurtherandseesstate involve-
begrantedornot. Patronageconnections andpolitical influence ment in the grain supply ofRome as increasing uncertainty by making the market sector
muchsmallerandhencemoresusceptibleto shocks.Apartfrom suddeninterventions,
e.g. fixing a price level far below the market rate, I think this is going too far. The
Erdkamp 2005, chapter 5 f°r a more generous estimate. As the^bi^ ^ww[ presenceofenormous statesupplies will simply havereducedthestrategicbargaining
power ot private grain. Therefore it must have exercised a stabilising influence on
m'Ave"e'mpu:e,"the"imperial statewasby implication a majorsellerinthemarket, as the situation. However, this is not to deny that there were still occasional attempts to
recently argued by Lo Cascio 2006. destabilise the market; sometimes they surface in the sources. But the contrast with
116 Oliver 1989, no. 187. ^ _ .. ^ . ^ _ ^_:.
. -7 SeeP\m. 7an. 30-32onthere-shipment ofgraintoAlexandriatoaverta famme_ the republican period is marked. Not least the risk involved in speculation must have
fact'that'thi's'occurrencereceived'extensivetreatmentin a panegyricto th^empj-ror increased in the imperial period. The executive powers of the emperor were much
E^es"to"stow"howunusuaritmust have been. The same impression i^convey^edl to largerand aboveall faster-workingthan thoseofthe republican state. He wouldhave
^it u7ind^n'ant repo'rt'ofGermanicus' opening of the granaries in Alexandria been able (and expected) to intervene more quickly if the situationthreatened to get
out of hand.
alleviatehighprices, Ann. II, 59-
179
178
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A ROUGH TRADING WORLD

tributary empire extending over a number ofdiverse areasrequired immediate institutional homogeneity. 123 Pragmatism was crucial
some kind of administrative framework. Both the Mughal and to the operationofempire.
Roman Empires gradually created increased monetary and legal Thetendency towardshomogenisation wasgreatestinthesphere
cohesion between different regions. They also spread the use of of coinage. With the consolidation of Mughal rule under the
coins and written forms of contract, in the Roman Empire, par- emperor Akbar (r. 1556-1605), an imperial currency was intro-
ticularly in the west, which in many regions had only used such ducedwithgold, silver andcoppercoins. '24Localcoinages were
instrumentsrudimentarilybeforetheconquest. 120Thoughnottobe discontinued; no new issues were struck. In some regFons, for
belittled, I doubt that greater unity of law and coinage would have instance the commercially important province of Gujarat, the old
beenanythingmore thanfacilitativein allowingmoreexchangeto currencyremainedincirculationfora considerabletimenexttothe
take place between localities. By themselves these were passive Mughal issues Butbyandlarge, theimperial currency managed to
media. Roman commercial law, for instance, was mostly reactive. establish aneffective monopoly inside therealm within a surpris-
It did not so much drive institutional developments as develop ingly short span of time. The price the Great Mughal had to*pay
in response to the practices emerging among traders. Law and for this success waseffectively to relinquish the ability to manip-
coinage were part of the infrastructure. As such their creation did ulate the coinage or pursue an active monetary policy. Instead the
provide important support for and expand the sphere of commer- Mughal state made the coins attractive by striking them at almost
cial activities; butthey didnotconstitute organisations whichcould 100% purity and by keeping the monetary system open; anyone
actively coordinate andremould links between individual market- with gold or silver could have it stmck for a fee at"the Mughal
places. 121 Moreover, these institutions were not primarily meant mint. The value ofcoins, therefore, was effectively identical with
to create unity between markets. They were designed to serve the their precious metal contents.
needs of the imperial state: to ease the collection of taxes, allow The Roman state wasunwilling or unable to goquite sofar. The
it to make payments and regulate relations among its most impor- greatconsolidator ofRoman rule, Augustus, alsoreformed thecur-
tant subjects. On special occasions that might be taken to imply a rency after the tumultuous civil wars of the late Republic. '^ He
complete imposition of the institutions of the conquerors. "None created a three-tiered system basedon gold, silver and lower value
of the cities should be allowed to have its own separate comage brass/bronze coins and fixed the exchange rate between the differ-
or system of weights and measures; they should all be required to entdenominations bydecree.InthewesternpartoftheEmpire,the
use ours", as the senator and historian Dio Cassius makes Mae- Roman experience resembles the Mughal achievement. The virtual
cenas proclaim in an advisory speech addressed to Augustus. '22 purity of the golden aureus and the silver denarius secured their
That was a statement of ideology. In both the Mughal and Roman acceptance and dominance from the beginning. By the reign of
Empires, though with variations in actual outcome and degree, the Claudius,thecitiesofthewesternprovincesevenstoppedstriking
needs of the state fell far short of the creation of absolute and their own base denominations. In the eastern part of the Empire,
the situation was very different for silver and bronze. Here the
'2" SeeLoCascio20000,chapter i foraninterestingif perhapstoooptimistictreatmentot
this. Thesameholds for Meyer2004,chapter7, treatingtheuseofRomantabletsas a ^ Lo Cascio20000: i8, "L'evoluzioneamministrativaaccompagnae talorafavorisce
form ofdocumentationin theprovinces. Thevery fewfindsoftabletsin theprovinces questoprocesso diintegrazione, chee ancheunprocessodiprogressiva uniformiwone
do not warranther wide-rangingconclusions. See Aubert 2004on the use of writing e omogeneizwwne"(my emphasis). This is to go too far.
among merchants. H.a^lLI 9"',i32,T435 for thT asic facts- For fl111 treatment of the Mughal monetary
a

121 Morley 2007, chapter 4 is right to place the emphasis in his interpretation of Roman 12, '^s.tem'. seeHaide'', I9j?7a"dthevariouscontributions in Richards 1987.
law and coinage on their providing some basic state services (see p. 66 for the mostly "' My..treatment. oftheRomanimperialcoinagesystemis basedonCrawford F986b;
reactive nature of Roman commercial law).
Howgego 1992, 1^94 and 1995, chapter 3-(wi'th interesting comparisons"to other
122 Dio Cassius 52, 30, 9. ancient empires); Harl 1996, chapters 4 and5; andWalters 1999,chapter 6.
i8o i8l
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A ROUGH TRADING WORLD

conquering power hadencountered the well-established monetary regional silver currencies for most of our period does say some-
practices of the Hellenistic states. To a large extent, the Roman thing about the limits of institutional integration in the empire. 128
administration was satisfied with continuing this system, partly Proceeding to the legal sphere, we find that ambiguous unity
leaving it to provincial communities, in groups or individually to gives way to considerable institutional fragmentation. Again, the
strike theircoinage. Thus locally minted copper coinageofsmaller Mughal comparison offers a useful yardstick. The Mughals were
denominations continued and proliferated throughout the eastern Muslims conquering territories with a population predominantly
part of the Empire, reaching an unprecedented peak in the num- subscribing to the variegated cults and practices we call Hinduism.
ber ofissuing communities during thereign of Septimius Severus As Muslim rulers the Timurids saw themselves as the upholders
(AD 193-211). A number ofregional silver coinages, though now of Islamic law, the shar'iya. This was the law of the mperial
mostly issued by the imperial authorities, were maintained for a administration andcourts, supplemented withedictsissuedbythe
longtime,inAsiaintothesecondcentury, inCappadociaandSyria emperor to tackle specific problems. Occasionally this gave rise to
into the third and Egypt only saw the abolition of her own closed- conflicts when imperial wishes clashed with established Islamic
currency system under Diocletian (AD 284-305). 126 All this is doctrine. However, the main institutional gap was in relation to the
not to deny that even considerable monetary transfers happened largenon-Muslimpopulation.Theadministrationhad.forobvious
between the provinces. As is well known from later historical reasons, to respect the locally varying customs of Hindu law. and
epochs, such transfers are possible without homogeneity and if largely allowed the Hindu population to conduct its own aclmin-
the model presented in Chapter 2 is basically correct, those must istration of justice. Thus within the Mughal realm several legal
have taken place. The aureus would probably have been the main systems co-existed, and occasionally blended or clashed. I29
medium for this; credit may also have played a role. '27 But the TheRomanemperorsdidnothaveto accommodatea canonical
idea of the imperial monetary system as removing all obstacles imperial law, at least not until well into late antiquity. They could
to an unmediated transfer of economic resources between differ- therefore very gradually gofurther in legal integration. But essen-
ent areas needs serious qualification. Unity of currency only came tially they were faced with the same problem asthe Timurid rulers
about through a slow and gradual process. The fact that some of of north India. Roman law was primarily the law of Roman citi-
the most important and prosperous provinces retained valuable zens.Originally thisgroupdenotedtheconquerors. Butgradually
126 See Christiansen 1988 and 2004 for discussion of the Roman administration of the
Egyptianclosed-currencysystem. Nero seemsto haveexploitedthis to debasethe The services of money changersandassayerswere, in otherwords, not madecom-
Egyptiancurrency substantially, usingtheprofitstofillhisemptycoffersinRomeand pletely redundant by Roman hegemony. This is, in any case, a problematic notion in
incidentallyto createa fiduciaryEgyptiancoinage.On a smallerscale,the Roman a currencysystembasedonthevalueofpreciousmetals,asthe'Mughalcasereminds
state s. eemstohavebeenablealsotostriketheothereasternsilvercoinswitha slightly us.Evenwithouttheneedforexchangingcurrencies,themoneychangerstillhadan
lowerfinenessthanthemainstreamimperialdenarius(Harl 1996:98-106).Tolerance importantrole in assayingthegenuineness,qualityandweightofcoins,for instance
in the east may, therefore, not just have been a sign of weakness. Compared to the makinga discountfor older, worncoins. Apuleius Met. X,~9 showsus the needfor
Mughal state, the Roman administration wasableto pursue a farmore active monetary a money changer in a transaction involving gold coins and Suet. Nero 44. 2 distin-
policy. guishesbetweenfreshandoldcoins. Ingeneral seeHarl 1996, 113-122, 259-260 and
127 Hopk'ins 1995-6fortheimportanceoftheaureusin interregionaltransfers.Duncan- Andreau1999,36-37forthecontinuedneedformoneychangersandassayersunder
Jones l994:"l67-170 and 2003 suggests, on the basis of hypothetical extrapolation the Empire.
however,that the value of gold coins constituted a very significantpan of the total 129Mughalhistoriographyhasnotbeenheavilypreoccupiedwiththelegalsystem(s)of
imperialcoinage.SeefurtherHopkins1980contraDuncan-Jones1990,chapter2 for a fhe.H"Trf' t>.ut. seeHintze 'j?97' I75-l78 andHasan2004, chapter6, documenting
debateabout whether circulation ofimperial silver coinagehappened across theEmpire in detail the interaction in Gujarat of the imperial court with local legal customs
orin regionalcells. Howgego1994offersaninterestingqualificationofthisdebate. and adjudicatory bodies. Not surprisingly in the light of the separation of India and
The two phenomenawere not mutually exclusive. Significantmonetary exchanges Pakistanafter independencefrom British rule, historianshave beenmore interested
couldtakeplacebetweenprovinceswithouterasingall regionalpeculiaritiesin the in the religious dimension ofthe meeting of Islam and Hinduism and the degree to
compositionof the coinpopulation.SeeHarris2006andRathbone2003forcredit whichindividualMughalrulersattemptedtoaccommodateHinduelementswithinthe
transfers; De Ligt 2002for theprevalence of cashoverpapertransactions. imperial umbrella, e.g. Hodgson 1974,59-99.
l82 i83
1
A ROUGH TRADING WORLD
IMPERIAL BAZAAR

In fact, the situation was even more complicated than this. Even
underthe emperors the right ofRoman citizenship wasextended before the constitutio antoniniana the divisions between the sphere
toparticularly privilegedcommunities groupsandindividualsin of local and imperial law were never firmly settled. The bound-
therprovinces. In that"waytheright ofcitizenship spread,bul. it aries were permeable. Provincial populations could and did some-
happened patchily and in an uneven Pattern-7he, develoPmCTt times avail themselves of Roman legal forms and brought their
was also far more a phenomenon of the west than the east in the
quarrels before the imperial provincial authorities. '35 A group of
empire l3°ThusRomancitizensremaineda minority untilC&ra- wooden tablets from the mid second century testifies to the spread
calTa(AD211-17)issuedtheconstitutio antoninianaandextended of Roman forms of contract in Dacia. 13 These documents contain
this'righttomostofthepopulation. '3' Evenafterthatdate,how^ examples of provincial subjects availing themselves of legal forms
ever,thelegalsituation wasfarfromhomogeneous. Atthetimeof which in strict law were only available to Roman citizens. Yet,
conquest'foreigners, peregnni, had to a large extent been allowed as recently remarked by Eva Jakab, the legal niceties were not
to'maintain their old laws, just as they were left in charge_of the
crucial to the contracting parties. They treated the Roman formula
local administration ofjustice. Sobeneaththeumbrella ofRoman
pragmatically; it provided documentation of their transactions. 137
imperiallawa patchworkoflocalandregionalpracticesandcus-^ A fairly recent find in a cave of some thirty-five documents dating
toms'had" continued to exist. '-32 As Mitteis long ago was thejirst
from AD 93-132 in the newly established province of Roman Ara-
to'observe, thatcouldnothavechangedfundamentally afterCara-
cafla's'edict. Itisa simple matter oflogistics: thenumber ofpeople bia reveal the same kind of pragmatic adaptation. 138 The dossier
of papers concern the (family and property) affairs of a Jewish
thoroughly steepedinthecomplexrulesofimperiallawwerefar woman, Babatha, belonging to the village gentry in the province.
too few. '33 Neither was there any drastic attempt to discard sud^
We find her, among other things, engaging in a number of fairly
denlyprovinciallawenbloc.Itwasexpectedtoliveon,recogmsed prolonged conflicts over property which seem to have reached
as custom in a Roman law context. Thus we find Greek orators
stalemate. In that situation, the parties try to involve the Roman
appealing totheparticular customs ofcommunities longafterthe authoritiesto tip thebalancein theirfavour. 139Firsttheopponentis
dramaticextension of the citizenship, and occasionally it is possi^
ble to observe how local legal practices begingradually to blend presented with a lawsuit at the governor's court. This was presum-
into andtransform Roman law in the provinces. 134 ably intended as a threat because shortly afterwards the opponent
is made a not very favourable offer to settle the dispute out of
court. 140 What has especially caught the attention of scholars is
the close adherence, in some of the documents, to the formulas
. 3» SeeSherwin-White 19732t'orthe spreadofRoman citizenship. ^ ^ ^ __. :".. :.
.
3- Thoughsignificant'pocketsofnon-citizenscontinuedtoexistthroughoutlate^^ and procedures of Roman law and litigation. All this has caused
^ss"^1 ^s^^7rnuana~^esl9s6^how^^part of ^ empi surprise since Jewswere in general thought to have settled affairs
munTttes'wKh Latin rights, aphenomenon
restricted the to western
re
mhAt'also'have'adopted Roman law. But this will have varied from community to in their own courts. In consequence, there has been a tendency to
community, see Galsterer 1997. . .. " . _, c. "l. ":,
G'ais'terer"''!'986 "is" a'clear'exposition of this. See Jacques and Scheid
. 3^ IJW
about 135 Augustus' Fourth Edict for Cyrene (in de Visscher 1940) rules that if the parties
A"aplte^6. 'See" also Lin'ton 1993, though he appears slightly too optimistic
agreed to it they could have an all-Roman court. However, the Verrine orations of
:radualuniformity of imperial law. _ _ ^ ..,. ___,., ":" Cicero should teach us not to put too much emphasis on the aspect of consent to the
.
33 Mitteis 1891,chapter6. Modrzejewski1970providesMUluminatmga^lys^ use of Roman courts. In practice, the Roman governor must have had broad scope to
re'la'nonshTpbet'we'enRomanlawand Egyptiancustomsbothbeforeanda^rCara^a. exercise discretionary powers.
^lft, ^Garnsey'2004:'notmg thatAeGreek orator Menanderrf ^^a^(t^ 136 CILIII, 2, pp. 921-960. I37 Jakab 1997:166-170.Cf. Meyer2004:182-183.
R'uss'e"lTa'ndWilson', Oxford; [98"!)eulogisedthecontinuedexistenceoflocalcustoms 13 Lewis 1989(P. Yadin)haspublishedandeditedthetwenty-sixdocuments written in
evenaftertheextensionofRomanlawtothemajorityofcities. Greek.
-34Th^mix^ofRomanlawwithlocalcustomscanforinstancebegaugedfromfce 139 Cotton 1993: 102-ioy for instance.
fifth-'century Romano-Syrian lawbook. Mitteis 1891 remams theclassictreatment. 140 The pattern can be seen in P. Yadin 14 and 15 and in P. Yadin 23 and 24.
See'alsoTaubenschlagl'955andModrzejewski1970and 1990.
185
184
T
IMPERIAL BAZAAR
A ROUGH TRADING WORLD
make somewhat more optimistic assertions as to the unity of the
legal "independence", asit were. '45Egypt, wherewritten records
legal system in the Empire. 141
and notaries were widespread before the annexation, sawthe con-
The evidence, however, does not so much support unity as
patchy integration, fluidity and regional variation. Jews in Galilee
tinuation ofmuch ofherHellenistic legalpractices withrelatively
little Roman influence, particularly in the field of commercial
are certainly known to have used both rabbinic and village/city
courts controlled by the Jewish gentry in addition to Roman courts.
lawI4t) Newly enfranchised Romans in the provinces normalTy
In Egypt they, too, availed themselves both of Jewish and Hellenic
alsoseemtohaveretainedtherighttousetheforeignlawsoftheir
courts. I42 If the Babatha texts demonstrate a use of Roman law to a
hom^community. '47 This wasnot anempty gesture; a papyrus
from Egypt showstwo Roman citizens entering a contractuafrela-
surprising extent, they also contain testimony of major deviations,
pointing to a continuation of local practice, such as polygamy and
tionshipwitheachotherusinga Greekformula.[48EveninItaly
payment of taxes in pre-Roman coinage. '43 In one complaint to
wecanfindRoman citizens contracting withperegrini usingele-
ments of non-Roman legal forms. Among the wax tablets found
the governor over her son's guardians Babatha suggests she will
outside Pompeii in the archive of the Sulpicii bank is a document
be able to invest her son's trust fund at a rate of 1. 5% per month.
This probably implied lending the money out on interest. Thus
pertaining to a contract for freight between the shipper Menelaos
from Ceramos in CariaandtheRoman merchant P.Attius Severus.
there is a good possibility that Babatha in her complaint to the
In thedocument Menelaos, writing in Greek, declares thathehas
governor effectively suggested violating the normal Roman legal
annual maximum limit on interest of 12%. 44 Roman law was
receiveda sumofmoney(thesumrepresentingthecargo)fromthe
appropriated by provincial subjects and adjusted to fit their own
slaveofP.Attius Severustobereturnedaccordingtothecontract
purposes and cultural contexts.
forfreight. Onthenextpagefollows a surety declaration"by an
To estimate the level of penetration of Roman legal procedures it
M BarbatusCeler,nowwrittenbya scribeinLatin.Formally,the
document complies with the standards of Roman law. BuUtafso
is alsonecessaryto takethe general conditionsoftheprovince con-
reveals interesting deviations from the pattern otherwise attested
cemed into account. Both Dacia and Arabia lacked polls institu-
tions prior to the Roman conquest. This would make a more direct
in the Sulpicii archive. Both declarations conspicuously omit to
transfer of Roman institutions more likely. But other provinces
presenttheobligation asarisingoutofa mutually expressedagree-
complained against the use of Roman courts and defended their
ment aboutthecontracting matter. Instead, theyfollow the Greek

141 See Johnston 1999: 9-1 I for a cautious, balanced attempt to formulate that position. 145T7hlcyrene Edirts, ofAugustus provideevicienceofthis(especially no.s.i and4,inde
Other examples are Norr 1998 and Serrao 2000. Based especially on the Lex Jrnitana WO).Theyarea responsetocomplaintsfromGreekprovincials'tlTa't'
to Roman Judges- Tlxrefore'the
(Gonzales 1986), Hackl 1997 argues this specifically for court procedures, with Egypt are^°"s.i" o^, thin 8SLbemg sul'mltted emperor
'>ullt hat. ^omplaiTinvolvi",g from dlfferent cTfes mCy'renethey^ha'IL'a's
Greeks
alone as an exception. I find his conclusion unwarranted. It simply disregards the
contrary evidence and fails to take account of differences in status between provinces. ^e;nhav. e, lrcek ^Idges;'lnd_SI!OUId neverbe Judged-
ag""-'"^r wiil"by a'P'urel'y
142 See Goodman 1983, chapter 10 for the co-existenceofrabbinic,Jewish-Hellenicand Roma'!.JUrypaneLFortheconti"ueduseofGreek'lawtoreg"ulate'relaU'ons'evet'n"at^
Roman law courts in Galilee. p^^aneve}among thed[ffeKMcit'eslseeMarsha"'98o:Anotherexampl^rfth^
143 P. Yadin 16 is a census declaration to the Roman authorities testifying continuity in continuinguseoflocallawisAthens,cf. Lintott 1993: 158.
money, measures and taxes. P. Yadin 26 documents potygamy. Wolff 1980:797-804
'4b Modrzejewski1970;Taubenschlag1955.
147

rightly distinguishesbetweenadherenceto Romanprocedureandcontinuationoflocal ThLCIasslc.example is the Tabula ~Ba^ana. Here tribal chieftain is made Roman
a a

custom in substance. c^n/ahL'ure^e"lis. (cf' sherwm-white i973b). Interestmg"matenaTfo, :'c^r


144 P. Yaclin 15. In his commentary Lewis suggests that Babatha must have been thinking as,prctsT of.;hi,s. problem is, Prov'decl .^ A"gustus'"Third Cyrene°Edict'(de vS.s^cher
of lending the money out at interest. But he makes no connection to the maximum to9^ IIruledthatenfra"chiseciProvi"cialswouldnotescape'the'dutie'soTt'heir'hon'ie
of 12%. P. Yadin I I documents a loan advanced by a Roman centurion charging the
legally prescribed maximum of I % per month, so it was used by Romans in the area. HRAm: V,9,\therontract wasfwPi8nusandtheformwastheun-RomansynchorSsis.
But we should not be surprised if the suggestion made here is true. Mitteis 1891: se^LFi^. "!LI2° wuh thejid'tor's comme"t:-"mufaum'inter'^verR ^^^
156-158provides several similar examples. adihirogra^hIfoT amredJictam"-CAtr^r^A"m. too'>'warnot'Tstandard7o^''^
contractin Romanlaw,cf. GaiusInst.3. 133-134.
l86
l87
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A ROUGH TRADING WORLD

practice where contractual obligations are incurred by unilateral or other, we should expect considerable variations in interpreta-
declaration: unprodotto ellenistico-romano. 149 Roman law did not tion from region to region. It was standard legal advice to Roman
create a homogeneousregime, it provideda flexibleframework. 150 administrators to allow local conditions to influence the outcome
This impression of mixture and fluidity is parallelled in courts of trials. '-54 That made sense. Instruments of legal enforcement
presided over by Roman magistrates in the provinces. These will were not developed aselaborately asthe imperial law. Essentially
not always only have followed the prescriptions of Roman law. Roman law left it to private initiative to execute the rulings of
From Spainthere is a very early illustration of this. The governor the court in civil law cases. '-5-5In that situation, as was alscHater
conducts the proceedings in a dispute over boundaries between realised by Mughal judges, it would often be crucial to accom-
two Spanish towns. He also defines the issue to the native jury modate provincial sentiments andsecure the backingofthe local
according to Roman notions. But the jury is asked to reach a community. 's6 Such considerations are even more pertinent in
decision based on Spanish laws or customs!^' Several centuries evaluating cases where locals, such as the magistrates andjurors
later and from the opposite end of the empire a summary of some in the small Spanish town with Latin rights, Imi, most of whom
Egyptiancourt proceedings gives the same impression. A conflict would have had only a rudimentary knowledge of Roman law.
has arisen between a certain Dionysiaand her father. They take it begantoconducttheirlegalbusinessaccordingtoitscomplicated
to the Roman court. During the trial, the father suddenly attempts rules; it goes without saying that results must~at times have been
to close the question once and for all by claiming that according to idiosyncratic, atleastfora fairly longperiod.'57Thusthesituation
Egyptianlawthefatherwasentitled, atanytimehesawfit, to break was above all characterised by some institutional fluidity caused
up the marriage of his daughters and take them back into custody. bytheco-existence ofimperiallawwithmanylocally orregionally
The interesting thing here is the appeal to non-Roman laws in a varying practices. '58
Roman court. In this particular case, the magistrate decided not to An illustration of how the co-existence and clash of different
condone the father's wish, probably on the basis of the precedent legal practices might attimes have caused uncertainty andconfu-
of a denial by another magistrate in a similar case. But we have sion inthetrading world is provided by a letter written in early
several other instances where decisions are made expressly with medieval Cairo wherea Jewishmerchant community hadto han-
reference to Egyptian custom. '52 die both Jewishand Muslim law: "So-and-so confided to me one
To sum up: there is no doubt that Roman law created a very grad- anda thirdqintars ofindigo...This wasdonewithoutanyspec-
ual, piecemeal and patchy increase in legal unity across the empire ification. I did not know whetherthe merchandise was given to
during the Principate. But it never broke the pattern of strong me as a commenda or a shipment, and if it was a commenda.
local variations in customs and practices. 153 Indeed, implement-
ing Roman law in the provinces required both pragmatism and 54 severalinstancescanbefoundintheDigest,e.g.25.4. 1. 15.
flexibility. Even when Roman law was employed in some form 55 Nippel1995:iod-112.
156 SeeHasan^2004, chapters 5 and6 forsome casestudies ofMughal Gujarat showin(
holthe.a.dminis,tratio.", of. the shar"m Iaw ofthe emp"'ewas'°often~adjusted"or'
149 TPSulp. 78 with the commentary by Camodeca. 15° Jakab 2006.
local predilections andpower relationships.
151 This is the so-calledTabulaContrebiensis. Cf. Galsterer 1986:22.
'" LexmhaMtantsofthIS
Irniuma,chapter93(Gonzales 1986)dictates"fcuseofRomancivil lawamons
5 P. Oxy. 237: For an interesting discussion see Katzoff 1972. The interesting thing
the. sma11 Latin municiPiu>"- All the confidencem
strong""R^man6
about the precedents cited (P. Oxy. 2, 237, col. vii, 19-43) is that the decisionis left to
;sat!on'Lth.is. newly fbund law has inspired needs to be tempered by recogmsmg'that
aalinstructionisnotthesameaspractice.JacquesandScheid1990:232notenst
the wife. So in a way Roman law does not really enter the picture. P. Oxy. 2, 237, col at even the prescription to use Roman law still seems to expect~the~inhabUa'nt's"to
viii 21-43 cites precedents in other matters where the Roman authorities decided to complement it with local practices.
uphold the local law traditions. For the co-existence of many layers of legal tradition SeeJakab 1997, 165-220forexamples oftheintermingling oflocal and Roman law
in Egypt in general, see Modrzejewski 1970.
153 Galsterer 1986 and Gamsey 2004.
regardingthesaleofslaves.ThespreadofRomanlaw~wasaccompanied'byflexible
adaptation and adjustment.
i88
189
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A ROUGH TRADING WORLD

whether it wasaccording to Muslim or to Jewishlaw. "159Intimes had only a rudimentary pre-conquest experience of those instru-
of disagreement such questions could be crucial. A ruling in a ments. But it would be far too modernising to depict them as
casebytheemperorsSeverusandAntoninus(Caracalla)fromAD providing a unifiedinstitutional foundationfor trade in the Roman
204 reveals a clash of Roman and Jewish commercial customs. world. The Empire did not create a homogeneous and solidly gen-
Roman law espoused theprinciple that a stolen piece ofproperty eralised market sphere; institutionally, considerable heterogene-
could alwaysbe reclaimed from thecurrent possessor by the on- ity remained. Some enduring residual fragmentation of law and
ginalowner.Thisheldirrespectively ofhowmanytimestheobject coinage in the empire, however, is only one aspect of the question
had been sold or resold or of whether it had been bought in good of the continuous vitality of local and regional trading practices.
faith. Among legal scholars, incidentally, this state of affairs has But it doesprovide a good starting point, even ifwearenever likely
generallybeenconsideredanimpedimenttotrade.Itwasdifficult to see more than the tip of the iceberg. Gaius, in his treatment of
for buyers to be surethatthere wasnotheft in thepasthistory of contracts in the Institutes (a manual of Roman law) includes some
observations on the differences between Roman and Greek forms
goodsandhenceto beassuredofownership Not all aspectsof
Roman law worked automatically to the benefit oftrade, it is well of contract. 161 This can probably be taken as a sign that the cul-
to remember. But this is not what interests us here. Jewish law tural divide between east and west in the empire also found an
took a more even-handed view ofthe legal problem. It recognised expressionintheorganisationoftrade.InthepapyrifoundatDura
the right of the original possessor to vindicate his property, but Europos contracts composed accordingtoGreeklawcontinue tobe
was also concerned to protect the innocent buyer. The good was predominant for a considerablenumberof years afterthe Roman
only to bereturned against payment ofthe sum for which it had conquest. The same goes for Egypt, where Roman influence in
beenbought.Inthecaseathand,a groupofJewishmerchantshad commercial law was very modest - in fact considerably less so
attempted toassertthisprinciple whensomeoftheirmerchandise than in family law- and a local variety ofGreek forms ofcontract
hadbeenrecognised bytheoriginal owner asstolen. Theemperors, prevailed. 162 Talmudic literature combined with various Roman
however, wereunyielding in imposing theRomanlaw view. "See rulings (one of them is cited above) indicate the existence of par-
to it. therefore, henceforth to be more careful in your dealings, lest ticular Jewish-Semitic forms of commercial practice. F63 Various
you may incur not only losses ofthisnature butalsothe suspicion scattered comments in the ancient sources also give an impression
ofcriminal activity", themerchants werereprimanded.' of the existence of different customs for conduct at sea and the
ownership of wrecked goods washed up on the coasts. We have,
The world ofbazaarsin the tributary empire for instance, references by name to both Rhodian and Pontic sea
laws.I64
Imperial coinage andlawdid undoubtedly facilitate market trans- But tradingpractices includemore thanformal laws. Ina ruling
actions, especially bybringingcoinageandwrittenlawtoareasthat of the emperors Antoninus and Verus on buying and selling, the
. 59 QuotedfromGoitein 1967,183.Inhisanalysisoflegalconditionsm theMoroccanSuq,
Chfford'Geertz 1979, 192-197, too, offers a comparative example oftheco-existence " Gaius Inst. 3. 93-141 (especially 133-134). OnGreekcommercial lawseegenerally
Pringsheim 1950.
andmixture oflocal, Muslim andFrenchcoloniallaw. _ . .. ..
.
60 C^VI, 2, 2:"Impp. SeverusetAntoninusAA. negotiatoribus Incivilemremdesiaerans, 162 SeeTaubenschlag 1955:50onthestrengthoflocalcommercial lawinEgypt;Wolff
ut'agnftas'res"furtivasnon prius reddatis, quam pretium fuerit
solutuma
doming et at. 1978for a detaileddiscussionofthevariousformsofcontractin HeUenisticand
Cui:ate"i~gitur'cautius negoti'ari,
ne non tantum in damna
huiys modi, s^d^^lam^n Roman Egypt; BradfordWelles, FinkandGilliam 1959:20-22 onthepapyri contracts
of DuraEuropos.
crimmis'suspicionemincidatis." Thecasewasingeniously analysedbyDaube^o^ 163 Yaron 1964.
7','whoTe'translation-has been used above. See further Yaron 1964 for ex amples 164 Rouge1966,part3,chaptersI and5 offersa goodsurveyoftheevidence, evenifI do
rfdiffenng'commercialprinciplesinRomanandJewishlaw.Ingeneral,seeGoodman not share his conclusions in all details.
1983, chapter 10.

190 i9i
A ROUGH TRADING WORLD
IMPERIAL BAZAAR

We must imagine the world of the Roman trader as steeped


judge is advisedto take into accountwhetherprice andmeasure in local and regional traditions. It would have been a regionally
havebeenestablished in accordance withthe local custom. 105The
fragmentedworld not quickly penetrated by the outsider. This was
type of measure shows strong variations between regions. The
picture canbefilled out in greatestdetailfortheeasternpartof partly a reflection of the great difficulties that stood in the way of
the empire. The provinces of AsiaMinor, SyriaandEgypt each creating standardisation. Even when weightsclearly approach the
hadtheir own predominant standards, none ofthem identical with same standard, it is often possible to observe considerable devia-
the main Roman measures. '66 Locally a regional standard might tions; a cargo of lead ingots from the first century AD reveals fluc-
tuations in the Roman pound between 319 and 330 g.I7°Tampering
varyquiteconsiderably.Inthepreservedpapyri,theEgyptiangrain
measure, theartaba,appearsinthreewidelyusedforms withminor with weights seems to have been an endemic problem. Contracts
variations and a substantial number of additional local forms.' therefore often specify in detail the specific set of weights to be
A curious work by a fourth-century Cypriote bishop, Epiphanius, used and where the weighingwas to take place, in order to ensure
addsto this imageby depicting a worldwitha bewildering variety some sort of control over the process. 17' The precise time for the
of measures and their variations. On Cyprus, for instance, two weighing or filling would often be of crucial importance. Most
kinds of medimnoi were in use. In the coastal area around Gaza products originated in agricultural processes requiring little or no
and Ashkalon a local wine measure, the sapation, could contain processing by modem standards. 172 Organic products are highly
from 14to 22 xestai.The xestes wasagaina very common measure susceptibleto change.Levelsofmoisture in a product,forinstance,
but known in many varieties. Epiphanius lists Italic, Alexandrian, fluctuate with the season and distance from harvest. Such changes
castrensis, Pontic'and Nicomedian types. '68 The picture can be greatly affectthe actual volume of a given product receivedby the
merchant. Products also show considerable geographical and inter-
complicated further. Weighing andfilling is not anunambiguous,
annual variations, due to differences in growing conditions. Grain
objective and purely formal process. It involves many socially
negotiable choices.Therefore knowledge ofthe"formal" standard is a good example. As Pliny informs us in his Natural History, a
was insufficient. The trader had to be familiar with the prevailing measure of grain differed widely according to its region of origin
measuring habits in a particular region. According to Epiphanius^ in terms of weight and baking capacity. Balearic wheat would,
a metretes of wine on Cyprus contained 100 xestai, but would for example, produce 35 pounds of bread to the modius as com-
normally be filled with 104 xestai from the press, the 4 being pared with the Egyptian producing 20 pounds or less. 73 Qualities
discounted asdregs. Another example was whether a measure was
filled to the brim or with a heap on top. A gratuitous discount 2125 specifies that the grain has been measured with a total discount of 1. 5 artabai.
mightalsooftenapplyasa matterofcourse,eitherinfavourofthe Duncan-Jones 1979 is excellent on all this. De Romanis 1998 is a recent, interesting
attempt, inspired by Kula 1986, to go beyond traditional metrology and combine the
buyer or seller according to theprevailing custom andbalance of analysis of variations in measure with social processes, even if too rationalising in
power. 169 its attempt to fit the disparate information into an elaborate theory of changes in
bargaining power in the levy of customs on the Egyptian trade on the Indian Ocean.
170 Based on the table on p. 16 in Domergue and Liou 1997. Such small deviations add
up. In the Cabrera 6 wreck, a lead ingot of 32-33 kg might be up to almost i kg under
weight as a result of the minor deviations (no. 14 in the table). Duncan-Jones 1982,
.
66 Hari'1996':315-318offersa convenientoverview.Hultsch 1882,especiallypart5, appendix, conducts similar tests on weights found in Italy.
/idesa detailedsurvey ofdifferentstandards.
171 Falsificationof weights, e.g. Dig. 19. 1.32. Control of weighingprocess and specifica-
.
67 Duncan-Jones1979andRathbone19838providethebesttreatmentsofvariations m tion of measures, P. Yadin 21-22; P. Mich. 245.
-68 EDiohanTusDememurisetponderibus(ed.J.E.Dean1935),chapters590, 39, 41. See 172 Hopkins 19786: 50-52 is a rare attempt to take this aspect into consideration.
173 Plin. Nat. XVIII, 67. See also Plin. Nat. VIII, 189-197 for geographical variations
K'ruit'andWorp1999forthebewilderingvarietyofEgyptianliquidmeasures. in wool and 19, 9-15 for flax. Wine of course is the classic example of a regionally
.
(") EpiphamusDremensurisetponderibus, "chapters28and72b Seealsc'chapter2t^ varying commodity.
adi^tmctKmbetweenfillingthemeasureeitherbypressingdownorshaking.P. Oxy.
193
192
T
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A ROUGH TRADING WORLD

were difficult to control and prone to variations. It was not with- kg clay). This suggests that we should model the trading world,
out reason that Roman lawyers discussed how wine that had gone not as a generalised market sphere, but as weak and patchily inte-
sour should be treated in sales law. 174 As a consequence of this grated system consistingof a numberof segmentedandcompart-
general condition, adulteration ofgoods wasendemic. Wheat, for mentalised circuits, some of only regional extent, others crossing
instance might be mixed with small quantities of barley and earth, a number of regions. 178
sometimes even with grain which had gone rotten in the store- The world of the Roman trader was an uneven, rough and het-
houses. Expensive spices or frankincense could be blended with erogeneous place. Imbalances, asymmetries and bottlenecks in
lookalike substitutes etc. Pliny again offers a sobering catalogue transport, goods, informationandsocial institutionalisation, were a
of methods. 75 chronicfeature.Thismadeforrelativelylowtransparencyandhigh
The merchant had to keep his eyes open and be familiar with unpreclictability. It was a high-risk, high transaction-cost environ-
every trick of the trade. In this respect close knowledge of local ment. I79 Correspondingly, it wascharacterised by large numbers of
conditions was crucial. For most areas of the empire we cannot relatively small traders andconsignmentsofgoods. Betternot put
reconstruct regional practices in any detail or assess the degree all your eggs in one basket; a typical, medium-sizedship's cargo
of fragmentation. But the distribution and production patterns of say 50-75 tonnes contained a considerable mixture of prod-
revealed by some of the major amphorae types may serve as a ucts in relatively small quantities. There would also normally be
pointer. Truly global productions arenotfound; amphorae typolo- morethanonemerchantbehindsucha shipment.Frominscriptions
giesdiffer distinctly betweeneastandwest. Bothproduction and found on the remains of cargoes in ancient shipwrecks, it is occa-
distribution seem to a large extent dominated by regional and sionally possible to gauge some minimum numbers. The Pecio
in a few cases superregional patterns. '76 Dressel 6, for instance, Gondolfo wreck, for instance, contained small consignments of
was firmly based in the Adriatic with exports finding an outlet in fish sauce belonging to at least four different merchants. Another
Rome. and to a smaller extent in the nearby Aegean.Dressel 2-4 exampleistheSud-Lavezzi2. HerewefindthenametagofAppius
was linked with the coastal regions of the north-westem Mediter- lunius Zethus on both a group of lead ingots and the ship's anchor.
ranean (Tyrrhenian Italy, Provence andeastern Spain). Thesecon- Shipownerand merchant are here one andthe same. But inscrip-
tainers, to a larger orsmaller extent, all entered long- ormore often tions on some 235 copper bars found in the wreck reveal that the
mid-rangenetworksofexchange.Buttheyneverlosttheirregional ship catered for other merchants as well, not unlike the Phoenician
character. 177 It is telling that the Baetican oil amphora, Dressel 20, merchant captain described in Heliodorus' Ethiopian Tales; the
wasneverassimilatedto thedistincttypesofAfricaProconsularis, captain owned the main part of the cargo in his charge. But the
eventhoughthelatterhada muchhighercarrying capacity (oil per ship catered for a number of other merchants as well. The captain,
so to speak, brought his own competitors along to market. '80
'74 Dig. 18.9. 2.
'75 SeeP\m. Nat. book XII. On adulteration of wheat, see e. g. P. Oxy. 708 and 2125. 178 SeeDuncan-Jones 1990,chapter3,usingthedistribution patterns ofstampedterracotta
eventheemperorrefrainedfrom iiuchpractices. CodexTheodosianus XI, 14, I orders lamps for a similar argument.
freshwheattobemixedwithstalegrainfromthestategranariesbeforedistribution. 179 On the scale set out in North 1990the Roman Empire would have hadthe institutional
.
76 ThecatalogueoftypesinPeacockandWilliams1986clearlyrevealsa wryregional weaknessesofmarkets in the leastsuccessfuldevelopingcountriesandmostcomplex
productionpatternforamphorae.Formoredetail,seeEmpereurandGarlan1986, historicalsocietiesbeforethedevelopmentofcapitalismin theearlymodernEuropean
Amphores romaines 1989-,'Whitbread 1995, Eiring and Lund2004. Kruit andWorp world-system.
1999convincingly confirmtheregionalcharacteroftransportcontainersfromanalysis '80 HeliodorusAethiopicaV, l3-l5and 19.ForPecioGondolfo,seeLiouandRodriguez
of papyn. Almeida 2000. For Sud-Lavezzi 2, see Domergue 1998. On the basis of some 1, 200
177 Thisis"nottodenytheexistenceofcross-regionalfertilisationandborrowings & ancient wrecks, Parker 1992 concludes that most had more than one kind of article
Rhodianamphorae,influencingproductionstylesinItalyortheproductionofDressel on board; and this is based only on the visible remains. Most organic material has
2-4 in Egypt. On the latter, see Empereur 1999. long since perished and must be included in our analysis to produce a fuller image.

194 195
T
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A ROUGH TRADING WORLD

Students of traditional trade in the early modem Levant and and occurrences beyond their influence. The observation of Clif-
Indian Ocean have referred to this sort of sociological profile ofthe ford Geertz placed at the beginning of this chapter epitomises the
marketplace asthe pedlar-market. 18' That hasbeen strongly chal- dilemma. Even if the merchants lacked the social power to begin
lenged, with some justification. '82 Even among relatively small radically to transform the prevailing irregularities, they cannot be
merchants it is possible to detect significant differences. There is, described as passive victims. The enterprising spirit and shrewd-
after all. a considerable contrast between the small trader riding nessofthe traditional trader is proverbial. A central point in thenew
with his donkey bringing a few goods from village to village and a institutional economics is that high transaction costs do not only
merchant taking several tonnes of grain, wine or fish sauce to the create market imperfections, they also foster different approaches
market of a major city. Some large merchants surface in the main to the market. They generate distinct patterns of behaviour and
markets of that world, too. In the Mughal Empire, Surat, a nodal give rise to commercial strategiesdesignedto cope with the many
point in the Indian Ocean trade, boasted a small group of great uncertainties. This is why attention to social differences between
merchant princes. The Roman Empire canparallel the experience, the merchants is important. They show the existence of a hierarchy
for example with inscriptional evidence from the city of Palmyra, andthus of a particular social system replete with institutionalised
which played a central role in the long-distance trade in Oriental forms of behaviour and specialisation of functions. The markets
luxuries: "This statue of Marcus Ulpius Yarhai, son of Hairan son of traditional trade should not be seen in terms only of one of its
of Abgaros, was erected in his honour by the caravan led by his players, the pedlar, they constituted an entire social universe - the
son Abgaros from Spasinou Charax because he helped it in every bazaar.
possible way. " 3 I use the concept ofthe "bazaar"advisedly. As a type, the bazaar
Pointing out the existence of these differences within the uni- describes the form oftrade characteristic ofcomplex agrarian soci-
verse of the pedlars may appear a trifling matter, easily brushed eties; it isnotidenticalwiththeclusterofpetty retailersandface-to-
aside. 184It is tempting only to focus onthe many market imperfec- face bargaining experienced by tourists travelling the Middle East
tions of this world and reduce the merchants to powerless atoms today. These are only the sad, if sometimes still exotic and colour-
in a seeming chaos being thrown from sideto sideby the elements ful, remains of a formerly vibrant trading world - a backwater now
bypassed by the main currents of trade which have all been sub-
sumed underthe institutions ofmodem capitalism. Inpre-capitalist
Thesmall scaleofmanyconsigmentsofgoodscharacteristicofpre-industrialtradeis
alsodocumentedbycustomreceiptsandaccountsfoundin RomanEgypt.Sijpesteijn societies,thebazaarrepresentsthemaincommercial system, in the
1987,appendix i and0. Kerenike.publishedby Bagnall,HelmsandVerhoogt2000 colonies of European empires, the indigenous sector. Historically,
nos. 1-117, show goods respectively leaving and arriving in peasant villages and long-distance and wholesale trade, brokers and auctions have all
passing the customs station in the coastal city of Berenike as part of long-distance
trade. In both cases, however, goods are shipped in small quantities which could be formed part of commercial life in the bazaar. '85 Understood as a
carried by a few donkeys or camels. system and a hierarchy, the bazaarhas involved much more than
.
81 Most brilliantly, but also most controversially, Steensgaard 19730, building on van
Leur 1955 andLane 1966,followedby DasGupta 1979. a mere cluster of shops in an urban centre. It also reached out to
182 Chaudhuri 1979 and Bayly 1983, chapter 11 are the best-developed critiques. But the periodic fairs and markets ofpeasant society, whose schedules,
neithervanLeur,norSteensgaardclaimedthattherewerenobigtradersinAsiaorthat
therewerenoattempts atlocalmonopolies. Theyalsonoted themanyimperfections of as both the ancienthistorianandanthropologist can confirm, were
earlymodernEuropeantrade.Steensgaard'spoint,however,wasthatthemonopolies
enjoyed bythecharteredcompanies paradoxically didnotdistort, butbegantostabilise ls5 Failureto includesuchphenomenaintheanalysisisanimportantweaknessofGeertz
and integrate markets. 1963, largely remedied in 1979. For these activities in India, see Chaudhuri 1978 and
'^ InventairedesinscriptionsdePalmyreX, 107.SeeDasGupta1979forSurat;Tchemia Bayty 1983, chapters 10 and 11. For Rome, see Talamanca 1955; Andreau 1974 and
2000;andCurtis 1991: 152-158for stratificationamongRomantradersin wineand 1987; Rauh 1989; and Ankum 1972, who on p. 377 made the important observation
fish sauce, garum. thatauctionsalesacquiredtheirimportancein Romansocietypreciselybecauseofthe
184 AsFinley i985a:33 and 136andWhittaker1993,chapter 15:5 tendto. absence of many modern market institutions.

196 197
7
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A ROUGH TRADING WORLD

frequently coordinated with market days in nearby cities. Stretch- standards of goods and commercial customs. Taken together these
ins back to its rural hinterland, the bazaar also projected outwards features put a high premium on the phenomenon which Geertz in
to enter widerurbannetworks of exchange.186But in comparison another context has deemed "local knowledge", close and detailed
with the capitalist institutions gradually evolving in seventeenth- understandingofconditionsin a specificlocale. As a consequence,
and eighteenth-century Europe, the bazaar represented a distinct Geertz explains, success in commerce was less a question of gen-
form oftrade. Institutionally it hadnot somuch begunto transform erally assessing the situation across a wide number of markets
the basic uncertainties of pre-industrial trade, as it had learned to and then weighing your options than it was about getting it right
live with its asymmetries and irregularities. As a trading envi- in your own particular market. "Sampling", of course, did take
ronment, the bazaar is distinguished by low transparency. The place; but the coordination of activities in separate markets was
combinationof solidroots in peasanteconomies, sometrade over less important than in a more closely integrated system: What does
longer distances and a considerable degree of uncertainty, makes it help you that you can get a cheaper consignment of cloth in a
the bazaar an attractive model for the functioning of markets in the distant competing market, if you cannot be sure of its quality?
Roman Empire. The widespreadhigglingandhaggling,whichmore than anything
Clifford Geertz has developed the bazaar as an ideal-type and else has come to symbolise the bazaar in common perceptions,
givenittheoreticalcoherence. ' 87Heidentifiesa numberofdefining is a reflection of this problem. A prolonged period of intensive
characteristics. Key among these arepoor information, fragmented negotiation enables the parties to examine and reach agreement
organisation and low standardisation: the features described above on all the intricate details and conditions relating to the particular
as central for our understanding of Roman trade. In comparison set of goods on offer. It is mastery of the specifics whichensures
to modern markets, bazaars had few institutions collecting and success. 9
disseminatinggeneralisedinformation,suchas,for instance,price This has significant implications for the conduct of trade. The
statistics. TheRomanandMughaltradingworlddidnot knowthe bazaar should not be understood as a failed attempt to transform
development, following inthe wake ofthe introduction oftheprint- the many uncertainties of its environment. Instead the pervasive
ingpress, ofwidely published price information innewspapers and risks andimbalanceshadbeendomesticated,asit were. They were
other media. '88 Instead merchants had to rely to a greater extent on to some extent reproduced and perpetuated by the institutions of
personal connections andcorrespondents. The bazaarwasa place the bazaar. Rather than removing the endemic irregularities, the
rife withrumours. In terms ofcommercial organisation,the bazaar merchants of the bazaarhaddeveloped commercial strategies that
allowed them to co-exist with the risks and often to turn them to
represents a fragmented environment. Prices differed, as wehave
seen, considerably, both inside and between markets and, as shall their advantage. 190A good illustrative example can be found in the
be examined more fully in Chapter 5, business was situated within report, mentioned above, made by Francisco Pelsaert, the Dutch
a household context. Finally, there was significant variation in the factor stationed in Mughal Agra. Pelsaert recommended spread-
ing and coordinating activities between different markets in order
to be less dependent on the varying individual local situations
186 Geertz 1979: 188-189(for localaswellashigher-levelconnections);deLigt 1993is andcreategreatercontinuity. In contrast, the strategypursuedby a
nowfundamentalonfairsandruralmarketsin theRomanEmpire;Shaw 1984remains
valuable; further discussion ofthe Roman andCampanian evidence is provided by the
contributions of Andreau, Marino and Ziccardi in Lo Cascio 2000a.
187 The following ideal-type summarises the analysis anddescription of'Geertz 1979, two 189 See Geertz 1979: 221-229 for the logic of intensive bargaining as distinct from exten-
sive sampling.
key sections are pp. 124-125 and 197-217.
.
88 The practice of including among other omens the prices of central commodities in 190 VanLeur1955;Goitein 1967;Stoianovich 1974;Bayly 1983,chapters 10-11;Chaud-
astrologicalrecordsassignsofdivinefavourordisaffectioncouldhardlyhavefilled a huri 1985; Ray 1988; Yang 1998; and Datta 2000 provide a good impression of the
similar role and there is no evidence to suggest that, pace Andreau 1997. functioning of these kinds of market.

198 199
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A ROUGH TRADING WORLD

small group ofPelsaert's Indian competitors sought to profit rather mercantilist-style privileges, they still hadto obtain a level ofpro-
from the irregularities ofthe indigotrade. Insteadofaimingat per- tection from political authorities. Customs dues can, in fact, be
manent control of the market situation, a number of Muslim and understood as a kind of protection money, with all the ambiguities
Hindumerchants, residentin theproductionarea,boughta portion this implies. Chapter 4 will explore how the price of protection
of the indigo harvest from the peasants some months in advance, was negotiated between merchants and the "protection selling"
sufficient to put them in a favourable position in years with a bad authorities. How this relationship was worked out, provided one
harvest. As a result, they controlled the local market in years of ofthe underpinningsofcommerciallife. A thirdmechanismwhich
low yield and were able to pocket a temporary monopoly profit is of great importance to the bazaar merchant is the formation of
in selling to the Dutch. In good years, however, the Dutch were personal relations of trust and communal ties. These will be the
able to do without them. 19' Indian history is full of such, often object of Chapter 5. If uncertainty is high, then one way to tackle
locally entrenched, groups of traders aiming to take advantage this is to forge specific alliances. You do not as a rule do business
of and increase the market imbalances in order to secure tempo- with all merchants, you preferto trade withyour personal connec-
rary, short-lived local monopolies. 192 They are not foreign to the tions or members from yourowngroup, people whocanbetrusted
Roman world either. One thinks of the food crisis in Syrian Anti- to a greaterdegreeandwhomay be willing to bailyou out in times
och. treated above; or that stock character of classical moralising, of trouble. Clientelisation and formation of group solidarities, as
the grain-speculating merchant. Often mistakenly portrayed asthe Geertz explains, serve to cushion the insider againstuncertainty.
quintessential capitalist relying on superior organisation to tie mar- But this is achieved by making the market situation less trans-
kets together, he represents the epitome ofbazaartrade, always on parent and more impenetrable for the outsider. To the individual
the lookout to make a profit from irregular and excessively high agent, the market never presented itself as a generalised sphere
prices in some locality. '93 Instead of integrating markets closely, of commercial activity, a level playing field, it was only acessible
the approach of the bazaar would often have been more oppor- through a "limited set" of concrete relations. 194 Combined then,
tunistic or speculative, with the merchant constantly seeking to the next two chapters will explore some of the distinct strategies
bring himself in a situation where he could benefit from a market andmechanismswhichenabledRomanmerchantsto copewiththe
imbalance. ubiquitous uncertaintiesandmarket asymmetries ofa bazaarenvi-
Such commercial opportunism was one of the strategies widely ronment. If I am alloweda metaphorfrom epidemiology,they will
employed by merchants to navigate therough waters ofthebazaar. try to show how uncertainty went from being virulent to endemic.
A second, no less important, aspect was the organisation of pro-
tection. If bazaartraders were not generally the beneficiaries of 194 Geertz 1979:2l7-22o(clientelisationandmarketfragmentation); 188-189(themarket
as a specific set of concrete limited relations); 154-172 (communal organisations);
137-138 (the relationship between protection and passage toll as underpinning trade).
"" Pelsaert 1925: I5-l6.
192 Datta 2000, especially 208-220, provides abundant evidence of speculative, destabil-
ising local monopoly strategies pursued by merchants in late Mughal/early colonial
Bengal. Datta, p. 325, correctly insists that these practices were crucial for the com-
mercialisation process in the first place.
"» Philostratus Vita Apollonii, 4, 32 offers an example of the grain speculator. SB 7242
(= Johnston 240), is a business letter seeking to use "insider-knowledge to create
a temporary local monopoly in peaches. Rouge 1966, part 3, chapter 6 mistakes
such activities for the capitalist speculator. See Kudlien 1994 for several valuable
observations on the particular mixture of freedom and monopolies which made up
ancient trade; Giarclina 1986 for an interesting analysis of the secretive mentality of
the ancient merchant.

200 201
A THIN LINE: PORTORIUM, PROTECTION AND PREDATION

far greater than or at least similar to the costs of transport. 3 In the


last chapter, for instance, we saw how exciseduties quite possibly
burdened even the low-value, high-bulk grain trade in the province
A THIN LINE: PORTORIUM, PROTECTION ot'Arcadiain late RomanEgypt as much as or more than transport
AND PREDATION costs.
Attention is too easily focused on the high-profile phenomena of
pirates and bandits when assessing the problems of ancient mer-
chants. In everyday experience, the merchant would on average
Shouldyouwishto abusea taxfarmer, youmighttry saying: oppressor, burcten, have had to deal with customs officials much more frequently.
garrotter,raidingplunderer,shark,fiercerthanthesea,wilderthana winter^storm. That could be bad enough. The Empire was not a Rechtsstaat. A
op pressor "of'thFdown-trodden, inhuman, insatiable^immodera^'
burdensome,

Je^ymoneygrubbingsod,violator,strangler,crusher burglar, st-ip-Jack-Mked, in


routine encounter with a customs official could be a harrowing
snatche^thietD -overcharger, reckless, shameless, unblushing, painanimal,tten^c^. and all
experience. At times there would not have been much to set him
^ageTwilcUnhospitable, brute, reef, sharp rock, wreckage, pure
apart from the common bandit. As the rich vocabulary of Pollux,
theoAerviletermsyoucanfindtoapplytosomeone'scharacten the second-centuryauthorofa Greekthesaurus, showsthe distinc-
Pollux, Oiwmasticon, 1A, 30-3'
tion was in popular perception commonly seen as a question of
He[thetaxofficial]mustassessaccuratelythevalueofthegoodstha"heme^
will reveal any
semantic power rather than of real facts.4 "There is no one who
chantro f"'those'mahals bring in so that no future investigation
does not know how great is the audacity and recklessness of the
dis"crepancy.-Therebytheofficersofthatplaceaccordingtothejaluatiol\m^ bands of publicans", the king of Roman jurisprudence, Ulpian,
c'ollectt"th'eproperrevenuesfromthat(merchandise)fortheexaltedstate.Apart
fromVhees^biished rate, hemust not take anything from themerchants. ^ ^ added.5 Imperial governments might on occasion, as illustrated by
"Richards. Ooc-umcnf Formsfor the Official Orders ofAppointment inthe the Mughal set of norms for good conduct issued to its customs
MitRhal Empire,
collectors, attempt to curb the worst excesses. But in practice it
was only a thin line separating protection and predation in the
trading world of the Roman and Mughal Empires. This chapter
In his description of the route taken by the caravans^importing will attempt to examine the process of customs collection as a
frankincense'from southern Arabia to Gaza on the Mediterranean balance of power between state fiscalism, local elites and com-
littoral, Pliny observes how the costs of various local levies^ mercial agents. That balancewas never primarily struck in favour
toUs accumulated to a grand total of 688 denariiper camel load
evenbeforecustoms wereexactedbyRomanpublicans.'
speaking, this amount wasequal to the annual salaryot^three 3 This point has been made most strongly by F. C. Lane 1966, passim, and later developed
RomanTegionariesortheaveragepercapitaincomeofsometwelve by Steensgaard 19733, 60-68 and 1981. Rouge 1966, 450-451 followed by De Salvo
[992, 3I7-32I recognisethe importantpart playedby customsbutnevertheless speculate
personsintheEmpire. 2 Thisisa powerful,ifadmittedlye^n^ that the technical costs of transport and handling would have been much higher. That
reminder that one of the most important expenses in pre-modern view is notjustified, as a general rule. A papyms may provide further illustration (BGU
tradewasthepayment ofcustoms duties. Oftenitwouldhavebeen Ill, 697). A camel driver hastransported alumfor merchants in the village of'Soknopaiou
Nesos. The distance covered is relatively short, yet he had to pass one customs station.
That already brought the payment of customs to halfthe transport costs.
4 It is interesting to note that accortfing to Ulpian it was generally agreed among Roman
lawyers that a wronged party could sue the customs collector both under the special title
' PlinyNat.XII,32.OntheArabiantrade,seeYoung200J,chapter3.Thetranslationof regulating collection of tolls and under the title for simple theft and robbery, cf. Dig.
PoTluxisheavilymodifiedfromMeijerandNijf1992:82.^ ^ ^^^ ^ ^ ^ (Ulpian) 39. 4. 14.
^ ^leuoArd^aTy'^nua'rp ay"ofa"legionary around the time ofPlmy ^econd half^n;'^ 5 Dig. 394. i2. pr. : "Quantae audaciae, quantae temeritatis sint publicanorum factiones,
SuOTydI^DTwTU2a2'5pdaeynaomaTch^Zn^^^^ nemo est qui nesciat."
a percapitaincomeofapproximately 57. 5 denarii(HS230).
203
202
A THIN LINE: PORTORIUM, PROTECTION AND PREDATION
IMPERIAL BAZAAR

ofthemerchant. The imperial peace, it will appear, may well have pay. Thus in the system of customs collection there was a built-in
benefited trade; but traders were also made to pay. propensity towards squeezing the merchants as much as possible.
Abuse was never just a question of the occasional corrupt official
falling prey to the temptations offered by a position of power; it
Predation was structural. 9 Even in cities where commercial interests could
be expected to enjoy better representation than on average, con-
Abuseofpower,confiscations,racketeeringandoverchargingwere frontation between the collectors of customs and the traders was
frequently complained ofinconnection withtheexaction oftolls inevitable. The surviving customs law ofPalmyra, the Roman cara-
Aninstructiveexampleisprovidedbyanedictissuedbytheprefect van city in the Syrian desert, was precisely the product of such a
ofEgypt in the micfsecond century AD: "I [the prefect ofEgypt] conflict. 10 Not that the relationship was always a matter of brute
aminformedthatthecustoms collectors haveemployed fraudulent force, confiscation or overt overcharging. The squeezing mecha-
andclever tricks againstthose who are passing through the coun- nism could take many forms. The customs officials had several
try andthatthey are,in addition, demanding whatisnotowingto more subtle tools at their disposal.
themandaredetainingthosewhoareinurgenthaste,inorderthat Often customs duties were levied at a percentage rate charged
some may pay for a speedier release. "6This is not a phenomenon on the value of the goods carried by the traders. This required
which was'unique to'the Roman world. It seems to havebeen a the customs collector to make a (subjective) judgement on their
general problem in pre-modern societies. Fromthemanytrading value. That left plenty of discretionary scope to the publican for
records, descriptions andgovernmental orders surviving from the increasing his intake by going for an estimate in the higher ranges
MughalEmpirea similarpictureemerges. 7 Ina segmentary impe- of the normal price band. Customary practices also played a con-
rial"formation, as discussed in Chapter 2, offices invested their siderable role in collecting the duties. By appealing to tradition
holders with a personal share, as it were, in state power. Offi- publicans were often able stealthily to introduce a host of extra
cials could and did normally expect to profit from their entrusted administrative charges on the traffic passing through their sta-
positions. Hence the widespread practice of state auctioning of tion. " Egyptian papyri show how, in addition to the actual tax, a
offices, rights andperquisites. Theprofit nexus wasneverclearer sometimes very significant number of surcharges applied as well.
than in the field of tax-farming where the state delegated part of
interpretation. There is no evidence of a general shift to direct state collection. In any
its sovereignty, the right to collect taxes, to private contractors case, if such a transition did occur, it never comprised the entire empire and it would have
in return for a fixed sum of money or a proportion of the tax been short-lived. From the beginningof the fourth century the evidence unequivocally
proceeds. Most customs andexciseduties in theRoman Empire shows the predominance of tax-t'arming. A more likely interpretation would link the
changes observable in the late second-century epigraphic record to a gradual transition
were collected by tax-farmers or, to use another term, publicans in some provinces from the use of large tax-t'anner companies to a decentralised system
(publicani)s Naturally they would try to make their investment of more localised contractors. While response to Brunt has varied in the detail, his
broader picture seems very widely accepted, cf. Cottier 2003; France 2003; and Lo
Cascio 200311.
9 Pace the apologetic and unanalytical comment by Sijpestein 1987: 90-91: "That they
6 P. Princ. 11, 20, col. l with Reinmuth 1936.
[the customs officials] mi.sbehaved on occasion is only human. " This simply fails to
7 Hasan"2004,~34^40(revenuefarming)andchapter7 (customscollection)^ CteGupta
the Mughal . far take account of the social context of the phenomenon. The widespread use of auctions
3', 'e. K"'Tl'6'4T and 206-207. For examples from sources,
see
man^ to delegate the right of collection heavily favoured the interests of state and publicans
^iym^nare dicTs)"pres:erved'in e. g: chapters 105 and 117 of &eM^'at-[Ahmad^ over those of the tax payer, as argued by Malmendier 2002 in her study of the auctions
th'e'descriptionby Tavernier 1889, vol. i, chapter 2 of the payment of customs in for the Roman companies of publicani during the Republic.
1(1 Matthews 1984.
8 DeLaet1949,followedby Vittinghof . 953:3»4-394andthelately inpartly France^OOK '' Overestimationof goods: (Ps)-Quint. Declam. 340 with Vittinghof1953:395-397;For
43'3T3 8^^g"ed thaUarge parts"of the Empire during reigns o^Marc^sAyreJms the role of custom, e. g. Dig. (Paul) 39.4.4. 2: "In omnibus vectigalibus fere consuetudo
md Septimius Severus sawa transition to direct statecollection ofcustoms. Brunt 1990, spectari solet" and Codex Justinianus IV. 62. 4. Gradual introduction of extra charges,
^ap"tert'l7"convincingly"demonstrated thattheepigraphic evidencefarfromsupports this
205
204
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A THIN LINE: PORTORIUM, PROTECTION AND PREDATION

Here is an account dating from around the turn of the first century paraphraseFarhatHasan'srecentanalysisoftheMughalsystem. '6
AD for the payment ofthe Memphis harbour toll:'2 The British and Dutch chartered companies trading in seventeenth-
century Mughal India had by imperial order been exempted from
550artabaeofwheat,customs,44dr. ; wharfage(?), 6 dr. ; tax 4 dr. ; examination all levies inland and would only have to pay the imperial duty
dues. 4 dr.; to the banker, I dr. ; administration, 5 dr.; exchange, I d''-; to an on exports and imports exacted at entry or exit to the Empire in
interpreter, ! dr. ; rudder (possibly a pilot's fee), 14 dr. 4 ob. ; a guard and boat,
4 ob. ; for the clerks. 4 dr. ; to Artemis, I dr. ; affidavit, I dr. ; receipt, 4 ob. ; on the coastal regions of Bengal and Gujarat. That was imperial law.
accountof libationfee to examiner,2 dr. ; total, 91 dr. Reality proved quite different. The companies had repeatedly to
defend their exemption. Occasionally the Great Mughal would
It isnoteworthy howanextra47 dr. is addedto theproperduty of issue a. farmcm (edict) enjoining customs officials to refrain from
44 dr., to cover various administrative charges, thus doubling the exacting the illegal duties from the British and Dutch. That might
amount to be paid. The surcharges would not always have been at help, briefly. After a short while the old ways returned and the
quite this level. Other accounts show them comprising a smaller, companies again found themselves pressed to pay inland duties,
though still significant, proportion. A shipment of some 400 wine irrespective of the ruling of the Mughal court. I7
jarshad118dr.addedtotheexcisedutyproperof300dr includ- The story does not read very differently as told by Tacitus com-
ing 30 dr. in additional charges ("TTpoo-5iaypa(p6|j£va"). 13 In a menting on Nero's attempt to curb the most excessive abuses of
list covering a month's collection of duty andexamination fees at Roman publicans. At the end of a list of Nero's countermeasures
a small customs stationin a village oftheFayumthefinal account Tacitus makes the following sobering remark: "and there were
is drawn up by adding to the accumulated sum of 959 dr. 3. 5 ob. other very fair rulings which were observed for a time and then
a further 8. 5% for administration ("xsipi cmKov") and exchange
allowed to lapse. The abolition, though, of the 'fortieth', 'fiftieth'
("aAAay-n")/4 Takentogether thepapyri provide telling evidence and the other illicit (sur)charges the publicans had invented, is
of the considerable ability ofpublicans and administrative person- still in force. '"8 Considering the evidence we have just seen for
neltomanipulate orinfluence theeffectiveratefortheexactionof the collection of excise duties in Egypt, some of which was con-
customs. '5 temporary with Tacitus, it is clear that the modest success of the
The imperial states did try to constrain the activities of the Neronian reform did not consist in the eradication of the demand
customs collectors within certain bounds. Mughal and Roman for surcharges across the Roman Empire. If Tacitus is right, as he
emperors alike occasionally reprimanded customs officials and may well be, the lasting influence of the reform would have to be
admonished them not to charge more than their due. But one seen as limited to specific sets of customs, such as for instance
maylegitimately question howefficient theseinitiatives were. One the Asian portorium. More probably, Tacitus' observation meant
cannot quite escape the impression that most were rather irregu- no more than that the emperors periodically simply repeated the
lar. remote, ineffective and recommendatory in character - to ban in judging legal disputes only to see it lapse again during the
everyday practice of regular commercial life.
Tac. Ann. XIII, 51. The Palmyrene tax law (C/S II, 3. 3913; translation in Matthews
1984),sectioni a (preamble)indicateshowtheflexibleframeworkofcustomgavense Cf. Hasan 2004: I 19: "Direct imperial intervention in the management of the fiscal
to conflicts betweenmerchants and publicans. system did take place, but it was irregular, remote, recommendatory and usually inef-
.
2 P. 'Oxy. 1650, 001. i. Seeespeciall/deLaet1949:317-321forananalysisofthis a fective."

related documents. ,....,." 17 See Hasan 2004: ll6-l [8 and 124-125 for a translation of afarman by the emperor
13 P. Oxy. 1651. The editors wrongly published the papyrus as "account ot rreigm. Aurangzebdating to 1667 regarding the trade of the companies from Surat in Gujarat.
14 SB7365, dating to AD 104. A translation is provided byJohnston 1936,no 347. Seealsothefannanfrom 1665containedin chapter 106ofthe Mir'at-iAhmadi(p. 235).
'5 See'also'thee'xpressexemption,recordedbyBean 1954: 102,ofthemerchantsfrom See Prakash 1972 on the precarious hold of the European companies on the privileges
havingtopayasurtax"inthenameofAphroditeorasanykindof'declarationfee' they enjoyed in the trade from Bengal.
18 Tac. Ann. XL[I, 5l.
during a festival suspension ofthe regular customs duesin Caunos.
206 207
A THIN LINE: PORTORIUM, PROTECTION AND PREDATION
IMPERIAL BAZAAR

maintained that this still applied even after a Roman magis-


The impression of relatively feeble state constraints on cus- trate had granted a trial against the culprit. 23 This, of course,
toms collectors receives confirmation from the legal prescriptions
would have opened an avenue for a last-minute "amicable" set-
and rulings preserved mainly in the Digest. ^ The Roman jurists tlement where the obviously wronged merchant could have his
introduced a special title/action to regulate the activities of pub-
licans. 20 The basic principle seems to have been that they were goods returned without having to go through with the trial. But
liable for double the sum they hadunlawfully taken. As observed this has to be set against the much greater leeway such a mea-
sure granted the publicans in their negotiations with dissatisfied
by thejurists, the paradoxical result was that the tax collectors merchants. The possibility of returning with impunity enabled
were generally in a better position than normal persons illegally them to hold on to goods for longer, draw things out and test
appropriating'the property of others; they faced a penalty of the the stamina, determination and social clout of the opposing mer-
quadruple amount Therefore thejurists do not seem entirely to chants. Given the seasonal nature of much trading, and the time
have excluded the possibility that a wronged party could choose
and effort required to seek out a court, sometimes far away, this
to sue for simple theft instead. 21 But that does seem more of a concession must have worked to the distinct advantage of the
theoretical option than a reflection of the day-to-day running of
publicans. 4
things.Whyelseshouldthejurists everhavebotheredaboutdevel- The relative leniency shown in the legal rules against the col-
oping andcommenting upon thespecial title? A ruling, attributed lectors of customs duties is in stark contrast to the uncharitable
to the Severan jurist, "Paulus, tried to lessen the gap slightly by attitude towards the possessors of imperfectly declared or unde-
beefingupthepenalty, ifviolencehadbeeninvolved, totriplethe dared goods.25 The responsibility for declaring the goods rested
exacted amount with the added possibility of extraordinary pun-
ishments - the latter measure for the sake of"public discipline". 22 solely with the merchant. The publican hadno duty to be of assis-
tance with instructions or advice. Only, one readschillingly, "care
However, generally the current seems to have run in the opposite
direction. There was a broad consensus among the jurists that an
accused publican could free himself of all further liabilities^sim- 23 Dig. (UIpian) 39. 4. 1.4 : "et restituendi f'acultas publicano vi abreptum datur, quad
ply by returning the wrongfully exacted objects or money. Some si t'ecerit, omni onere exuitur et poenali actione ex hac parte edicti liberatur. Dig.
39. 4-5-P''-. a preserved comment of Gaius, starts off by denying the right of restitution
approach towards after trial has been granted. Inthe next sentence, henevertheless ends up concluding the
'9 In the late Empire, from the time of Constantine,
the state abusive opposite. This indicates that the text might have been interpolated. But when and how,
'lTcans"doesl "formaUyseem to have become significantly inUnewith^
tougher,
it"is difficult to say. It might just be an abbreviation of a longer argument eventually
raTtendencyin penalties.Failureto recogniseimmunitiesor overcharging^were leading to a less rigorous interpretation of the edict of the urban praetor. Tojudge from
^o'wsometimesorderedtobepunishedbydeathorexile(C.Th.IV, 13, i and3;CJIV^ Ulpian's very general statement, there is no compelling reason to take the opinion as a
6l'^(^4). Theoldmorelenientprocedures,howeverwerestillincludedinthelegal post-classical invention.
axlifications(a,dex~JustinianusIV,62,3;Dig.39.4?^"").Thusit isquestionable 24 On a similar note, the expectation of Cottier 2003: 226 that a decisionfrom AD 5 to
whether the harsher imperial punishments ever translated into a coherent new regime remove casesconcerningtheAsianportoriumfrom thegovernor'scourt to thepraetor
(d'e'Laet"1949,475-482alsoemphasisestheco-existenceofnewandoldmeasures^ peregrinus in Rome would have enabled a more equitable administration of justice,
Mor7'unpo'nanriy;'ifanythingtheneedtoresorttoextremeactions^uch_as/he^e,at
the limited cannot be taken for granted. The Roman publicani would have been well connected in
v"i7Drobablv rather an "indication than
of weakness strength -

jibllity the imperial capital. So that would not have prevented the working of influence. What
^"the'TO'v^rnment'to'regulate. daily practice. Capital punishment is not a very flexible is certain, however, is that the threshold for seeking redress via the courts would have
t'ooT.'Onbalance;it wouldprobablyhavebecomemoredifficultforpeopleofmoderate been raised substantially. The merchant would now have to go all the way to Rome, a
sta'tus'to"obtaina judgementagainstquasi state officials suchas publicansbecause much more time-consuming and costly enterprise. Taking on the publicans had become
ther>enaltv-was so"drastic and potentially much more disruptive to socialpeace. more difficult, cf. Engelmann and Knibbe 1989: 120.
persrons"ofinfluenceitwasa differentmatter. Publicanswouldnowhavefounditeven 25 Seede Laet 1949: 437-444 for a basic treatment. It is symptomatic ofthe asymmetrical
more difficult to challenge such people. legal position of publicansand merchantsthat de Laetcould makedo with less than
20 DeLaet 1949:444-445 for a basic, though notvery analytical, treatment. two pages for actions against publicans, whereas he spends seven pages paraphrasing
21 Dig. (Ulpian) 39. 4. 1 . 2-4. _ .. . ., . , __. _. collection
""". ".:, of the titles in the Digest against smugglers. See Klingenberg 1977 for a more thorough,
22 ('exce rpted from
D?g. 39'^9. '5 the a^late
SententiaePa^ third-century
butjuriciically over-systematic analysis.
rulings'ascribedto Paulus,butcertainlynotall ofwhichweregenuine).
209
208
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A THIN LINE: PORTORIUM, PROTECTION AND PREDATION

should be taken that he does not mislead those who are willing to few andyielded only cautiously. 29 Favour remained firmly on the
declare".26Falselydeclaredorundeclaredgoodswere,asa general side of the customs collector. In a case concerning false declara-
rule, simply confiscated. 27 If an error in declaration had resulted tion of some slaves, the emperors Marcus and Verus "gracefully"
in the tax collector getting more than his due, it was apparently conceded that the poor wretch could get away with paying double
even necessary for the emperors Severus and Antoninus (Cara- customs, it the failure to declare was unintentional, by mistake
calla) to specify that the merchant should have the excess amount rather than fraud. 30 Though certainly far preferable to outright
returned. 28 There were other modest concessions granted in the confiscation, this was still a harsh penalty. Double duty was the
name of equity. Had bad weather forced a merchant to unload sanctionimposedonpeoplewhofailedto defraythecustoms after
his goods from a ship withoutdeclaringthem at customs first, he declaration had been made. 31 But in this case, it was to be paid
was not to sufferconfiscation. Equally, a fragment of an Egyptian on some slaves who would have been exempt had the "error" not
customs law states, if the tax collector had ordered a cargo to be occurred. As far as one can tell from the context, the slaves were
unloadedwithout finding any goods not declared, he should carry for personal use and could thus normally have been passed free
the costs of unloading himself. But such mitigating measures were ofcharge.32 Confiscatedgoodswere, as a rule, auctionedoffwith
the profits accruing to the tax collectors and the authorities. The
previous owner might even be offered the opportunity to buy back
26 Dig. (Marcian) 39. 4. 16. 5-6. According to Tacitus (Ann. XIII.5I), Nero declared that his lost property. It does not require much imagination to see how
all customs laws should be made public so people could at least read them. To what
extent this happened it is difficult to say, but the very need to promulgate such a theright ofconfiscation andthepractice ofselling backthegoods
reform speaks volumes. The inscription with the Asian Customs Law, dating from to the original owners might sometimes have been turned into a
AD 62 and found in Ephesos, shows that some inscriptions certainly were set up fol-
lowing the Neroniandecision. But, considering the great scarcity of finds of customs profitable system of abusewherepeople wereforced to "ransom"
laws from all over the Empire, it is doubtful whether the reform was generally imple- their own property. 33
merited. The Asian Customs Law was published by Engelmann and Knibbe 1989. A
revised version is available in Merola 2001, appendices 1-4. A new edition is now in The wronged party could of course always attempt to get his
preparation. case heard in the court of the often distant Roman provincial
27 Asian Customs Law (MonEph. ), lines 45-56 with Dreher 1997: 89-91. See also (Ps)-
Quint. Declam. 359: "Quadprofessusnon fuerit, perdat"and P. Oxy. 36. Klingenberg's
authorities. This did undoubtedly happen, as the legal responsa
attempt (1977: 62-65) to introduce a distinction between non-declaration and false preserved inthe Digesttestify. Butlitigationwasandstill is a slow
declaration where only the former would lead to confiscation can now safely be rejected and burdensome way of resolving conflicts. In addition it could
on the basis of the Asian Customs Law, pace Dreher 1997: 89, n.45 who attempts to
rescue the interpretation by seeing it as a later legal development. There is no good
reason to take such a view. Klingenberg's interpretation was based on a priori reasoning 29 Dig.(Marcian) 39. 4. 16. 8;P. Oxy.36.Klingenberg 1977:70-82makesthemostofthese
with no basis in the legal evidence. In fact, his own discussionforced him to recognise few concessions.
that a falsely declared quantity fell under the right ofconfiscation. That left only the false 30 Dig.(Marcian)39.4. 16. 10.DeLaet1949:443,followedtosomeextentbyVittinghof
declaration of quality. In that case, Klingenberg maintained, declaration had actually 1953:395-397,isnotjustifiedinmakingthisa generalprinciple.Bothscholarsignore
been made and the goods would therefore not have been subject to confiscation. I thecharacterofthejudicialpronouncementsin theDigest.Thepronouncements"often
doubt Romancustoms officials wouldhavebeenmuch impressedby such an argument. representjudgements inconcrete casesandfarfrom alwaysadduptoa coherent system
A merchant attempting to pass off some bales of precious silk as a few bundles of without internal contradictions.
coarse, inexpensivecloth would surely, on detection, have seenhis goods confiscated 31 Asian Customs Law(MonEph.), § 38.
for smuggling. The Asian Customs Law confirms this. The act of making a declaration -12 Dig. (Marcian)39.4 16. 10follows in closeconnectionwith39.4. 16.9 concerningan
(professio/apographe) is treated as requiring a statement of kind, value, weight and error made by a minor in declaring the slaves for his personal use. The slaves to
number (Asian Customs Law (MonEph. ), § 18, and line 50 in particular). The problem be returned againstdoubleduty are thus best seento belongto the samecategory.
raised by Klingenberg, however, is a real one: when could the obligation to declare be Cf.CodexJustinianusIV.6I.3 exemptingsoldiersfromsufferingconfiscationofduty-
held to havebeenmet? Some legitimate disagreementamongthe parties over estimates exempt goods. In general, however, goods exempt from duty stifl risked confiscation'if
of value, for instance, must have been allowed for. It is symptomatic of the favourable wrongly declared, see Kiingenberg 1977: 70.
position accorded by the law to the publicans that the legal material practically left open 33 Dig. (Paulus) 39.4. 11.4, cf. 394. l6. pr. Klingenberg 1977: 115-116treats this as an
the question of when the duty to declare had been fulfilled. issueof whetherthe dominushada rightto buybackhisproperty. This is besidethe
28 Dig. (Marcian) 39.4. 16. 14. point.

210 211
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A THIN LINE: PORTORIUM, PROTECTION AND PREDATION

be fairly risky to complain about an abusivetax collector. First of


all, it was far from unlikely that the provincial authorities were in Parasitical fiscalism
collusion with the publicans. 34 Second, many customs officials
would have had a relatively sizeable staff of slaves and other ser- If legal regulations were heavily tilted in favour of the customs
vants at their disposal. These came in handy during situations officials,it wasbecausetheinterestsoftheimperialstatehadmore
of conflict. T\\efamilia publicanorum constituted a ready instru- in common with those of the tax collectors than of the merchants.
mentofpowerwhichmightexpedientlyconvincedissatisfied"cus- Customs duties were not, as they later became in mercantilist
tomers" to hold their tongue, pay up and move on. One guard, for strategies, an important tool whichthe government usedto shape
instance,reportingaboutfraudulentcustomscollectioninanEgyp- and promote economic activity in the empire. The main interest
tian village, wasdelivereda severebeatingby the local publicans of the state in the exaction of customs was fiscal. 37 Trade was
in return for his efforts. A central concern in the section of the to a large extent viewed as a flow of resources which could be
Digest dealing with publicans is how to treat abusive conduct of tapped into for the sake of revenue. Hence, in order to maximise
their slaves and other dependants. 35 Not all publicans, of course, their proceeds, neither the Romans nor the Mughals did much
need to be seen as equally powerful. There is a greatdistance sep- which would lessen the appeal of handling the levy of duties.
aratingthe big and notorious Roman companiesfarming some of This has made the two tributary empires look very strange indeed
the imperial customs across large districts and the small contrac- to modern commentators. Customs were not something mainly
tors collecting dues at the gates of Egyptian villages. But whether charged on exports, and especially imports, in order to work as
big or small, thepublicanshadto besufficientlywealthyto pledge an economic barrier between a state and the outside world. The
property to the state in guaranteeofthecontract. They wouldhave imperial systems taxedtheinternal movement ofgoodsas well as
had to be men of at least some substance in their communities, ofthosecrossing theirexternal boundaries almost indiscriminately.
though far from always members of the political elite. 36 Thus, The empires did not totally abstain from graduatingthe customs
whether a specific incident was ever reported to the courts might and excise rates. But it happened for very different reasons and
come downto a questionofthepowerandinfluencepossessedby along quite different lines. In general terms, provisioning policies
thepersonsinvolved anda considerationofthecostandtrouble of and consumer interests were more prominent in shaping policies.
judicial proceedings set againstthe sum required to strike a deal Tributary elites put greater store on well-suppliedmarkets, to the
withthepublican.Thebalancemustoftenhavecomeoutin favour equaladvantageofurbanconsumptionandtaxationpotential,than
of bending and putting up with the publicans. on guardingthe interests of any specificgroup ofmerchants.
The sharpest illustration of this is the concessions granted by
the Great Mughals to some of the European chartered compa-
34 Cicero's Verrine orations are essentially a catalogue of the various ways this could
happen. The phenomenon has been dealt with in Chapter 2 above. nies trading on India in the seventeenth century. These enabled
35 P. Amp. 77 = Wilcken, Chr. 277 = Johnston 1936, no. 348 for the attack on the European traders to participate more or less on equal terms with
guard reporting irregularities. Dig. 39.4. 1.5-39.4. 3 and 39.4. 12 deal with thefamilia the native population in commercial pursuits. Indeed, from a
publicanorum.
36 LexIrnitana(Gonzales 1986),chapters63-64forbidsmembersofthelocal council (as mercantilist point of view, the privileges had the absurd result
well as their close kin and dependants) to contract for local vectigalia. This practice, that in some periods the European merchants even seem to have
however, was not observed empire-wide. See Andreau [974 for a study of a man of
middling wealth contracting for some vectigalia in Pompeii. On the other hand, rich enjoyed some advantages incomparison to theirIndiancolleagues,
councillors might on occasion bid for the collection of vectigalia outside their home
town. A member of Antioch's council is known to have contracted for the collection of 37 Originally propounded by Cagnat 1882, the view has largely been confirmed by later
theimperial customson EasternluxuriespassingthroughPalmyra, Inv. Palm. X, 29(R. research such asdeLaet 1949 (with some exeptions); Vittinghof 1953; and France 1994
Drexhage 1988, no. 29). and 2001.

212 213
IMPERIAL BAZAAR
A THIN LINE: PORTORIUM, PROTECTION AND PREDAT10N

particularly with respect to road tolls and sales taxes. 3 The lack full the revenue-generating potential of this particular branch of
of external customs barriers is a slightly more contentious issue in trade.42
the Roman case. Though convincingly criticised when it was first In the absence ofa strong, systematic mercantilist impulse in the
aired, Sigfried de Laet's hypothesis of the creation of an external tributary empires, the fiscally dominated approach to the exaction
customs barrier, especially on the eastern frontier of the Empire, of customs did nonetheless on occasion give way to other objec-
has refused to die out and is occasionally cited with some approval tives. 43 In both empires we find examples of the state extending
in scholarly discussions. 39 The basis of this theory is the imperial customs privileges to some groups or activities. 44 But concessions
levy of 25% ad valorem charged on the import of Eastern luxuries wererarely, ifever,grantedwitha strongwishtoremouldtheeco-
in the provinces of Egypt, Syria and Arabia. There is, however, nomic system. The motives were different, mainly political or ide-
not one scrapofevidencein support ofthe view thatthis very high ological innature. IntheMughal Empirethisisbroughtoutclearly
duty was imposed to impede commercial exchanges with the East. by the attempt ofthe last great Mughal emperor, Aurangzeb ( 1658-
Some three decades ago Paul Veyne demonstrated the absence of 1707) to favour Muslims over Hindus withregard to the payment
a mercantilistideology in the Empire.40Thereis, too, the unequiv- of imperial excise duty, the wkat. In afarman of 1665 he set the
ocal testimony of Strabo, the geographer. In his portrait of Egypt rate for Hindus at 2/40 and for Muslims at 1/40. Two years later
the high duty on Eastern luxuries is treated as part of a discus- he went even further and abandoned the duty for Muslims alto-
sion of the large proceeds generated by the Roman administration gether. Thishappenedaspartofa policy to boostMuslim imperial
in the province. The rich trade with the East is singled out by primacy. The policy, however, had unexpected consequences. In
Strabo for its revenue-generating qualities: "as far as India and the eyes of the emperor Muslim merchants abused their newly
the extremities of Aethiopia, from which the most valuable car- acquired privilege. They beganto handle the goods of their Hindu
goes are broughtto Egypt, andthence sent forth againto the other colleagues on payment of a commission fee. That way the Hindus
regions; so that double duties are collected, on both imports and avoided the imperial excise duties and the Muslims made an extra
exports; and on goods that cost heavily the duty is also heavy. "41 profit. The loser was the Mughal treasury, whichsaw the income
If customs were exacted at an onerous rate on Eastern luxuries,
from customs dwindle. This was not what the government had in
it was because the trade could support them. The imperial state,
mind. The exemption was intended as a political and ideological
motivated by fiscal concerns, took advantage of this condition symbol of the religious supremacy of Islam - "that the Muslims
and squeezed the merchants all the more tightly to exploit to the may be distinguished with obligation and kindness from vicious
unbelievers", as an imperial order stated. The privilege had not
been granted with a view to creating a Muslim commercial dom-
38 Prakash 1998: 119-134 and Hasan 2004: ll3-l(9and [24-125 for the different sales
tax, road toll and customs rates in seventeenth-century Mughal India. More generally,
inance in the Empire. Hence in 1681, after a little more than a
Pearson 1991: 96-98 and I 10-113 and Richards l993a: 203.
39 Especially France 1994: 142. See Dreher 1997: 85 for a more reserved endorsement.
For the original critique of de Laet, see Etienne [952 and Vittinghof 1953: 378- 42 For an analysis, looking at archaeological traces of customs exactionon the eastern
384.
40 Veyne 1979. trontjer, also emphasising the predominance offiscal motives, see Young 2001: 66-74
andthegeneraldiscussionin chapters5 and6.
41 Strabo XVII,line 13 (my emphasis). There are other examples of increasedcustoms to
take advantage of an unusually rich trade. One such is the attempt to tap into the wine
43 0rsted 1985:288-289triestodetecta protectionist dimension inthefiscallymotivated
trade with Gaul in the last century of the Republic, reported by Cicero in Pro Flacco
exaction of customs. This is unconvincing and is based purely on speculation. All
9, 19-20 ("pecuniam permagnam ratione ista cogi potuisse confiteor", my emphasis).
exactionof customstendsto makethemovementofgoodsmoreexpensive.Thisis an
The highest rate was charged on wine leaving the Empire as a luxury intended for
inevitableeffectoftolls andcannotbeseenin itselfastheresultofprotectionism.
barbaricum. Yet another instance is the taxing of purple shells at twice the normal rate
44 France 1994:143-144isrighttoinsistthatRomancustomscannotbeentirelyreducedto
in the Asian Customs Law (MonEph., line 20).
a fiscalquestion. Butadmitting thisdoesnotcommit onetogosearchingformercantilist
measures. Political and ideological objectives should not too readily be brushed aside.
214
215
IMPERIAL BAZAAR
A THIN LINE: PORTORIUM, PROTECTION AND PREDATION
decade,the exemption wascancelledandimperial exciseduty was military personnel and veterans. 48 Such exemptions were used, no
reintroduced for Muslims.45
doubt to some extent successfully, as we would expect from our
The same concern with limiting the fiscal effects of politically Mughal parallel, to gain commercial advantages. 49 Private con-
motivated concessions occurs frequently in Roman policies. The tractors transporting state goods, for instance, attempted to mix
Asian Customs Law recently found on an inscription in Ephesos their own goods with the official cargoes to avoid paying customs.
contains several examples. Among the privileges granted to the Soldiers would engage in trade andexploit the exemption to gain
colony of Augusta Troas, (re)founded by Augustus, was the grant the edge in the competition with private merchants. These were
ofthe rightto the imperial customs on goodsimported or exported inevitable consequence of political privilege. In the view of the
from its territory. However, goods which were passing through in imperial state, they were also unfortunate, causing an unintended
transit, still fell underthe rights of the publicans appointed by the lossofrevenue.Repeatedlythestatetriedtocontainthesepractices
Roman state.46 The aim, in other words, wasto grant an economic anddiminish its economic loss. 50The emperor Hadrian instructed
privilegeto a politically favouredcommunity, notto makeAugusta provincial governors, legionary commanders andtheirprocurators
Troas a dominant emporium. The same goes for the exemption when they dispatched people to buy things for their personal use
from customs for thirty days granted on imports, but not exports, to write a memorandum for the customs collectors indicating the
to the territory of most probably Pergamon and its harbour city exact amount ordered "so that anything brought in excess can be
Elaea, in order to facilitate supplies for the politically important subject to duty" 5' in the Asian Customs Law we read generally
festival of the Romaia Sebasta.47 If we change our perspective that the exemption for state transports also included the people
from individual grants of privileges to general imperial policies, who operated them. But only on items for their own use. This was
the impression is confirmed. similar to the arrangement for soldiers. Their freedom from excise
The Roman state did exempt some groups and activities from was limited to items for personal use. If the goods were intended
duty across the Empire. This comprised, among other things, for trading, customs were due according to normal rules. 52 When
all transports of state-owned "goods", and goods belonging to thetributary stategrantedcustoms privileges it wasnot inpursuit
of a general economic policy. The goal was more limited. ' Privi-
45 Mir'at-i Ahmadicontains the Mughal farmans dealing with the gradation in the rate
lege wasawarded ina more narrow trade-off thatjealously sought
of duties. See chapter 121 and the following for the cancellation of Muslim customs
48
exemption (citation in chapter 121); chapters 104, [o8 and more broadly 97 and 120
for the introduction of Muslim privilege, cf. Hasan 2004: I 17. For a broader treatment
?^. altl^ 427-^3'and 432-435 for a broad survey of the material.
Normally the
instruments oftravel wereexemptfor all persons.
of Muslim religious privilege, see chapters 97 and 120 of Mir'at-i Ahmadi; Richards 49 As pointed outby Whittaker 19940, chapter4.
[993a: 171-177;andfor some modem treatments, see Hodgson 1974, vol. 3:92-98. 50

4 Asian Customs Law (MonEph. ), lines 103-105 with Engelmann and Knibbe 1989:
Inaddition
^to the fo llowing examples; Dig. 39.4.9. 8, excerpted from the spurious
114-115.
entiw Pauli,^ deserves mentioning. It states that while the imperial fiscus'is free
from all duties, the merchants who market imperial goods cannotclaim any general
47 AsianCustoms Law(MonEph. ), lines 128-133withanalysisin EngelmannandKnibbe exemption from customs.
1989:125-129. Seede Ligt 1993:42-48 andparticularly 222-234for the dominanceof 51 Dig. (Gaius) 39.4.5.i.
symbolical and consumerist motives involved in the granting of festive ateleia combined
with a strong continued imperial fiscal interest. This. of course, does not rule out that
2 AsmncustomsLawWonEph. ),lines58-66.Tac.Ann.XIII,51.Theprivilegeofsoldiers
such privileges may also occasionally have turned out to be of benefit to transit trade
illater.me"tione(l'"codexJustinia'wsIv 61,7 (discussinga lateimperial~'sales"tax)
as well. But it was not normally the main purpose. The elevation of Delos, by the
andagaintheyarenotexemptinmattersofbuyingandselling.Constantine'intr'oduced
immunity for all navicularii. the transporters serving the state, even for goods
Roman authorities in the second century BC, to the status of a free harbour to harm
the central position of Rhodes in the eastern Mediterranean trade may be thought to
;"te"dedto sel1(c n-XI11- 5'5 with de Laet I949-:480 andDe Salvo ^2:259).
constitute evidence to the contrary. But not even here was trade the motivating force.
Butthetitle ofnavicularius wasconnected withobligations andit issymptomaticthat
The action was taken as punishment for wavering Rhodian support during the Third
theRoman state,just as the Mughal, did not look favourably uponthe'habitof some
Macedonian War and included stripping the island state of her Anatolian dependencies
naviculariitocarrythegoodsofothers.HenceC.Th.XIII,5,'24'specifies:"naviculam
as well, Scullard 1980: 287.
areexempt whenit isproved thatthey dobusiness fortheirownaccount (cum sibi rem
gerere probabuntur)".
2l6
217
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A THIN LINE: PORTOR/I./M, PROTECTION AND PREDATION

to safeguard the state fiscal interests while giving recognition to and exit through a customs district or station. 56 Consignments of
groups and individuals that for onereason or another were deemed goods travelling beyond the confines of their nearest region would
importanttothepoliticalorder,beit, forexample,assoldiers,gov- also normally have had to pay several tolls, sometimes at a consid-
emmental transporters or as those involved in significant religious erable number of stations. Customs multiplied with the distance
activities. travelled. -57The tendency for excise duties to accumulate is aptly
The imperial state did not havemuch incentive for changing the illustrated by some tax receipts found among the Egyptian papyri.
predominantly fiscal approach to the commercial sector. Neither
in the Romannor in the MughalEmpirehadexpansioneverbeen
closely tied to collaboration with commercial groups. Therefore 56 DeLaet 1949andVittinghof 1953:375-378, andnowconfirmed bytbeAsian Customs
thetributary statehadnocompelling reasonstoforgorevenue inthe Law, which applied to both imports andexports, cf. Dreher 1997. However, the notion is
difficult to reconcile with modem sentiments and doubts continue to be voiced without
short-term by favouring specific groups of traders. As the empires any good reasons, e. g. France 1994: 138-139. A letter from Cicero (Alt. II, 16, 4)
grew and the amount of trade inside the boundaries expanded to reveals thattheAsianpublicanieventriedtomakemerchants paytheAsianimport duty
againwhenthey moved from one city to anotherinsidethe province. It may also be
ever greater dimensions, compared to exchange with the world notedthatthe AsianCustoms Law(MonEph., lines [6-20) exempts people from paying
on the outside, this became even more the case. From the per- imports or exports twice on the same goods, in the same year, at the same customs
station. Thus, if a merchant had taken his goods to a city in the province of Asia and
spective of the treasury there was not much to be gained, except paid the import duty, if he then left againwith some of his goodsandreturned later in
loss of revenue, from helping one group of merchants to capture the yearhe would not have to pay customs on the same items again.Thepublishers
(Engelmann and Knibbe) typically prefer to take this to mean that the merchant was
a greater share of a largely internal commerce at the expense of exempted from paying re-export duty on goods already paid for at entry. This is not
other traders in the empire. 53 Instead, the exaction of customs was supported by the inscription which clearly deals with exports and imports separately.
directed to take profit on existingtrade flows irrespective of their On Egypt, see also Sijpesteijn 1987, chapter 5, who accepts the principle but believes
some goodsto be exempt, especiallywine, whichhetakesto betaxedonly on entry.
direction. Hence excise and other trade-related dues were regu- But a look at Sijpesteijn's data makes it clear that his conclusion is more likely to be
larly levied in nodal points or on traffic arteries where many goods a reflection of the prevailing flow of goods in the villages whose records have been
preservedthanevidenceof avoidanceofdoublepayment.Thuswinewasimportedin
more or less had to pass, such as at city gates, harbours, high- small quantities, whereasoil was sentout. Hence wine is documentedin relation with
ways,river crossings,bridgesandin thebazaars.54Customs were imports andoil withexportsfrom the villages.
57 Rouge 1966: 450, emphasising the accumutative burden of excise dues. See further
in the Roman world to a very large extent passagetolls. 55 It was 0rsted 1985: 285-289, followed by De Salvo 1992: 317-321 and France 1994: 140.
not uncommon to levy the tax on the same goods both on entry Drexhage 1994 and Drexhage, Konen and Ruffing 2002: 145-147 underestimate the
number of customs exacted. They strangely ignore the evidence from Egypt, where
customs receipts reveal the district duty of the Memphis harbour tax being added on
53 The first European mercantilist "economists" saw the global economy as a zero sum topot city customs(cf. n 59). Purcell2005insists,tomy mindrightly, ontheubiquity
game too (Anderson 1974). However, as the states were much smaller the advantage of local customs, yet maintains they did not accumulate (pp. 220-222). That seems
to be gained from capturing a greater share of the international economy at the loss of counter-mtuitive not to say a contradiction in terms. The customs inscription from
foreign competitors was all the more apparent. Only later, particularly in the eighteenth Caunos (SEG XIV: 639), cited as evidence, does not prove that customs were never
century, did the notion of real growth develop on the basis of these ideas Though paid on goods in transit. Quite the reverse, the inscription (very fragmentary) describes
it would be wrong to claim any automatic link between full-blown mercantilism and a regime of exemptions paid for by a local benefactor, propably as a suspensionto
small states in a partly internationalisedeconomy, it still seemsclearthat commercial encourage imports in connection with a periodically recurring religious festival (cf.
interests could bebetter heard in such systems. Thus without developing real mercantilist Schwarz200ib: 288-289). Othercustoms laws, such astheregulations concerning the
policies,theMughalsuccessorstatesineighteenth-centuryIndiadidgivemoreattention portorium collected in Asia, do not as a rule mention a specific exemption of transit
to commercialgroupsthantheir imperial predecessor(Bayly 1988: 1-78). goods. Indeed both the customs regulations preserved from the Lycian koinon and
54 P. Oxy. 1439-1440;ILS375 (collection at city gates); AsianCustoms Law(MonEph.) the province ofAsiaenvisage taxing transit goods. Augusta Troas andMyra eachhad
chapter 21 (customs office close to the landing of ships); P. Oxy, 1650 (Memphis the right to collect these respective customs on goods sold within their own districts.
harbour tax, excise at administrative district border); OGIS 674 (road tax); AE 1975:
Thosejustpassingthrough, however, hadtodefraydutytothecollectors oftheprovince
413(riverbank); Dig. 19.2.60.8 (bridgecrossing);P. Land.Inv. 1562versa(markettax). andthekoinon(MonEph.,lines 103-105;Schwartz200ia). Equally, Purcell refersto
55 Now again confirmed by France 2001, summarised in the conclusion. However, France the transit dues collected by Massilia at the mouth of the Rhone (Strabo 4. 1. 8). But
seems to me to underestimate the possibility of double customs payment, cf. note 57 merchantsalsohadtopaytheimperialcustomsonenteringtheGallicprovinces.Dues
below. would have been accumulating with distance.
2l8 219
T

IMPERIAL BAZAAR A THIN LINE: PORTORIUM, PROTECTION AND PREDATION

By chance, several receipts have survived documenting the pay- things on the ground. Alternatively the state might grant the aristo-
ment of different customs on the same consignments of goods. crats compensatory incomes. As a general solution, however, this
Thus we find small amounts of wheat, travelling a fairly short was equally problematic in the eyes of the imperial government;
distancenorthwardsfrom the village ofPhiladelphia,payingthree it was expensive and diverted scarce resources from other activ-
separateduties: onefor leaving the nome, onefor usingthedesert ities. So either way, the government tended to back away from
road and one for the so-called Memphis harbour tax. 58 the abolition of local dues and allow their continued collection
It is noteworthy,too, howthe different Egyptiantolls tendto be or silently tolerate their reintroduction after a short term of sup-
connected with different levels in the state system. The Memphis pression. The revenue pressure exerted by the different segments
harbour tax was charged on goods crossing between the larger of the Mughal polity consolidated the existence of a customs and
administrative districts, the so-called epistrategia, while there was excise regime with frequent collection points and the co-existence
also a more local tax for leaving the primary administrative unit, of many separate dues. 59
the name. This is a typical feature of segmentary state systems. This mechanism can be seen at play in the Roman Empire, too.
They consisted of many parts which both tried and had to be During the high Empire most regions of the realm were divided
allowed to tap into the economy and get their share of the tribute. into a number of large, separate customs districts where toll was
An analysis of the structure of Mughal customs collection in the collectedinthenameoftheRomanstateonentryorexit.Theexact
province of Gujarat makes the principle clearer. The central state nature of these districts is not entirely clear, but they bore some
exacted a customs-cum-sales tax on all movement of goods in the relation to provincial divisions, without necessarily being strictly
province. In addition to this there were numerous local tolls of identical. The Asian portorlum, for instance, was clearly arranged
various kinds. These were controlled by the various aristocratic aroundthe core of the old Attalid kingdomthat madeup the bulk
groups thattogether madeup the state on the ground. The central of the province of Asia Minor. But to this were added, among
Mughalstatedidformallyclaimtoexerciseauthorityoverthelocal other things, the customs collected in the strait of the Bosporus,
levies. Some of them were even gradually being drawn into the even though this area was outside the provincial boundaries of
orbit of the imperial system, as they became part of the revenue Asia. 60 Beneath the umbrella of imperial excise duties the exis-
assignments of Mughal nobles, the so-called jagirdars. But that tenceofa systemoflocallybasedtolls andlevies is attestedby our
was as far as it got. When the state attempted to exercise closer
control, for instance by outlawing local dues or reducing their
number, it encountered stiff opposition. The Mir'at-i Ahmadi - 59 Mir'at-i A. hmadi, chapter 117. See Hasan 2004, chapter 7, for the customs system in
Gujarat. Pp. 114-12i areparticularly relevant forthe analysis presented here. In general
a history of Gujarat - reports how on one occasion aristocrats about the many tolls in the Mughal Empire, see Habib andRaychauduri 1982: 186-189.
demanded economic compensation if they were to accept such TheEastIndiaCompanyaftertheconquestofBengalattemptedthecancellationofsuch
an abolition. In that situation there were essentially two options tolls but ultimately foundtheresistancefromlocal elitegroupstoo strong (Chatterjee
1996, chapter 5).
open to the state to defend its policy, neither of which was very 60 AsianCustoms Law(MonEph. ), lines 22-28 defines the Asiancustoms district; seelines
attractive. It might try to hold its own and compel the noblemen to 8-ll and 13-15for exactionofcustoms in thestraitoftheBosporus, cf. Nicolet 1993:
945-951- Some customs districts seem to have comprised several provinces, though
agree to respect the ban. In the long-term this was bound to be without losing all relation to the administrative framework, as in the cases of Gaul and
ineffectual. Aristocrats were not generally inclined to accepthav- lllyricum, cf. de Laet 1949 for these larger circumscriptions. France 2001 treats the
Gallicportoriumanew.He rejects the notionofcircumscriptionandconcludesthat the
ing their incomes reduced, especially not when they were running qiiadmgesima Galliarum was a passage toll separating Italy from the north-western
provinces. I am not entirely convinced. He seems to be misled by the chance preser-
vation ofevidencein the Alpine regions. See0rsted 1985:251-347 for an interesting,
58 P. Customs, list l, nos. 139-141,seealsonos. 184-186, 355-356, 362-363and4l9-42l but speculative and over-complex analysis of the material pertaining to the Illyrian
with Sijpesteijn 1987: 19. portonum.

220 221
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A THIN LINE: PORTORIUM, PROTECTION AND PREDAT10N

sources. To someextentthishasmilitatedagainstthepreconcep- the ancient reality. The challenge is to interpret the nature of the
tions of modern researchers expecting to find a rigorously defined lacunae in the material. Ifpositive evidence is scarce in the western
legal, coherent administrative system in the Empire. They have Empire, there are nevertheless indications that local excise duties
therefore suggested various ways around this so-called problem. were asmuch a part oflife there asthey were in the Greek-speaking
For instance, it has been claimed that these tolls were primar- east. Cities across the Empire were expected to possess their own
ily collected by communities that in legal terms were outside the vectigalia - taxes accruing, for example, from the leasing ofcom-
imperial system, the so-called civitates liberae ac foederatae. munal lands, pasturageand,not least, variousdueson commercial
There is no strong evidence in support of that proposition. One of traffic. It seems improbable that cities in the western provinces
the best-preserved inscriptions with an example of a local customs should, en bloc as it were, have abstainedfrom levies of different
law was found in Palmyra. The inscription was erected in the reign kinds on the movement of goods.66
of Hadrian. At that time the city had formally been part of the Imperial conquest, in other words, did not eradicate the exis-
province of Syriafor more thana century.63 tence of locally administered dues on trade. The conquerors toler-
Another way out of the "predicament" has been to claim that ated their continuance. As inthe Mughal Empire, local government
local tolls were a feature of the Greek east, whereas the Latin west needed financing and the provincial aristocracies did not bear the
waslargely withoutthis phenomenon.64Thatis unconvincing.An entire burden themselves. Formally, the Roman state did claim
octroi wascollected at the very gates of Rome, the capital. 5 It is some sort of sovereignty over these tolls. At the time of inclu-
undeniable that in terms of sheer wealth of epigraphic testimony sion in the imperial fabric, the local community would normally
local dues are far better attested in the eastern provinces than else- havereceivedtherightto continueorbeginthecollection of some
where, but this is more likely to be a function of the epigraphic such taxes. In the eyes of the Roman state the post-conquest set-
record than anything else. It is worth reminding ourselves that the tlement could not be changed without its express permission. The
sources are fragmentary traces rather than a direct reflection of introduction of new duesrequired imperial sanctionbasedon the
recommendation of the provincial governor, as Vespasian made
France 1999 admirably updates the material first gatheredby de Laet 1949: 351-361.
See Schwarz 200 ib, III, 4 for an excellent treatment of local customs exaction in
clear in reply to a request from the Baetican community Sab-
Anatolia. Outside the province of Egypt, the large rabbinic literature connected with ora. 67 Gradually the "hunger" for tribute led the Roman state to
Judaea has yielded some of the best evidence for the density of customs collection, cf.
Goldschmid 1897: 199-202.
confiscate and absorb more and more ofthese tolls into the impe-
62 France 1999: 99-100 (and more broadly France 2001) surprisingly reverts, it seems, to rial revenues. This happened slowly and piecemeal, apart from
the notion of Rostovtzeff 1902: 390 (and, it would seem Frank 1933-40, vol. [: 255) in Egypt where the state had already successfully come to con-
that the right to collect local portorialvectigalia was restricted to civitates liberae ac
foederalae. This view had already been exploded by de Laet 1949: 90 and 351 (and trol local dues before the Roman annexation. 68 In the rest of the
now confirmed by Schwarz 200 ib: 338-406), who observed that formal legal status was Empire, the development culminated in the fourth century when
not decisive. Quite the reverse, we even find attempts to levy the imperialportorium in
"free" communities, e. g. Byzantium. different emperors made several attempts to clear the table and
3 Young 2001: 137 summarises the evidence on the status of'Palmyra: "the city should includeall localvectigaliain the imperialtaxes.69
accordingly be understood as a tributary city of the province of Syria". Within modern
Palmyrene studies, the notion has gainedcurrency that the city became a civitas libera
following a visit ofHadrian, during which the city changed its name to Hadriana Tadmor. 66 ?orvecti8alia: .seeLexIrnitana(Gonzales 1986),chapter76;Sabora(CILII, 1423).
This doesnot affectour argument sincethe tax law, as is clear from the inscription, also SeeRouge 1966:449for a similarpointofview.
existed during the first century of Roman rule. However, as observed by Fergus Millar ^IIlI.4_2^', co"fiTled, by Dis' (Hermogenian) 394. pr
lo.

(l993: 325)> this modem assenion is completely baseless and may safely be discarded. Cf.someofthescatteredcommentsindifferenthistoriansabouttheusurpationoflocal
Under Septimius Severus, the city was made a Roman colonia. vectigalia by emperors. Forexample, Suet. Tib. 49. 2; Vesp. 16.
4 DeLaet 1949: 353 andFrance 2001: 278-283, whoessentially restricts thephenomenon 69 Jones 1964:732-733,whodatesthe generalconfiscationoflocalvectigaliato the
for all Gaul to Massilia.
reignsofConstantineandConstantiusII.Afteritsinitiation,thefortunesofthispolicy
65 CILVI, ioi6a = ILS375 with de Laet 1949: 347-349. fluctuated considerably. Julian abandoned it. Then it was reinstated. Then the cities
222
223
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A THIN LINE; PORTORIUM, PROTECTION AND PREDATION

That was far too ambitious. Even when the imperial fiscus had controlled the exaction of tolls; it had to recognise or silently tol-
achievedsome sort of control, it was still forced to recognise local erate a probably very significant number of additional local titles
claimsonthesetaxes,bothin EgyptandtherestoftheEmpire.This to tax existing trade flows. If tributary empires did not generally
normally happened in the form of allocations to local institutions erect tail customs barriers betweentheir subjects, they did not do
ofa proportion oftheproceedsfrom a giventax.70Julian,in a tem- much to promote long-distance trade by abolishing internal tolls
porary setback for the expansive policy, went further and simply either. Instead,the fiscal interests of the different segments of the
restored the old vectigalia to the communities. 7' His successors imperial system were allowed to dominate and the movement of
reversedthis decision.But it is doubtful if they everachievedmore goods was slowed by the need to defray the costs of a potentially
than partial success. Some local dues continued to evade imperial considerable number of duties.
authority as they had in the preceding centuries. From the first
through to the fourth century AD the emperor and his administra-
tion repeatedlyfoundit necessaryto enjoin local councilsthatthey Merchantresponseand bargainingpower
were not allowed to institute new customs and excise dues of their
own accord without imperial sanction.72 For the most part, impe- Yet, commercedidnotgrindto a halt. Thepublicanhadto balance
rial control, when it worked at all, is likely to have been relatively his short-term interest in squeezing the merchant against future
lax and discontinuous. The customs law found in Palmyra offers loss of revenue if the continuation of commerce wasjeopardised.
a fascinating glimpse into this. The surviving version, inscribed This gave the merchants a far from insignificant bargaining power
on stone in AD 137, set out to revise the regulations for the local vis-a-vis thecustoms collector. The imperial statedidnot only find
it hard to exert a tight control over customs exactions; in addition
collection of tolls. However, it also preserved the older version
and a few rulings by Roman officials in former disputes. What its representatives experienced similar difficulties in monitoring
is particularly interesting to note is that a Roman governor had and regulating trading activities. Merchants were not always easy
apparently been present when the old version was agreed upon. prey. Both they and their goods were mobile. This made them
difficult to tax.
The new law, on the other hand, appears to be entirely the work
of the local council acting independently of the Roman provincial Shouldthe imperialauthoritieshappento forget, thelessonwas
authorities. 73 In the light of this, it is difficult to speak of a unified regularlyrepeated.InthelateseventeenthcenturytheMughalstate
customs policy in the Empire. Roman hegemony did not lead to the attempted to change the procedure for the collection of a sales tax,
creation ofa single customs regime. The central state only partially zakat.Whereasmerchantshadformerly paidthetax at thetime of
purchase, they were now ordered to pay at the time of sale. The
were granted a proportion of the customs proceeds. Then these were again confiscated
chroniclerof the Mir'at-iAhmadiexplains:
and later granted yet again. I doubt if we should take this narrative as a reflection of
how things worked out on the ground. Rather the line of events suggests only partial the collection of tax at places of sale was decided upon because the price of an
or limited implementation of the imperial enactments. For similar scepticism about the article is higher at that place than at that of purchase. It thus means an increase in
success of these measures, see de Laet 1949:462. revenue.Butasthemerchantssoldmanycommoditiesatplaceswherecollection
70 For grants of part of the customs to the city councils, see C. Th. IV, 13, 5 and 7 and of taxes was not regular, the government suffered losses. An order was, therefore,
Codex Justinianus IV, 61, 13. The market tax of the Serapeum in Oxyrhynchus (P.
Land. Inv. 1562 verso) wasquite possibly allocated to the temple (Rea 1982). issued a second time for its collection at places of purchase. 74
71 Amm. Marc. XXV,4, 15. A very important element in Julian'smeasurewasthe resti-
tution of temple property. The problems encountered by the Mughal authorities in rais-
72 CIL II, 1423; Dig. 394. lo. pr; and Codex Justinianus IV, 62, 1-4. ing the sales tax mirror the experience of the Roman state in the
73 Compare the decree of the council of Palmyra, which introduces the tax law, with the
headingof the old law given later in the text. In Matthews 1984 this would be section
la with 2a. See further Rouge 1966: 448 in a similar direction. 74 Mir'at-iAhmadi,chapter126(p. 284inthetranslationofLokhandwala).
224 225
IMPERIAL BAZAAR
A THIN LINE: PORTORIUM, PROTECTION AND PREDATION

collection of the so-called collatio lustralis or chrysargyron, a tax They were intended to tap into trade flows, not force them under-
instituted by Constantine to be collected every five years from ground or out of business. It was not only a question of smuggling.
merchants and other businessmen. The emperors, Theodosius and The merchant could often choose between different itineraries to
Valentinianus prescribed "that no more should furtive commerce bringhisgoodsto market.Themostrecklesspublicansorthemost
render the merchant rare in the glorious cities and the throng of heavily and frequently taxed routes might find that they were being
traders hide in obscure and secluded places to the loss of public passed by to the advantage of revenue takers on alternative, but
revenue".75 The reach of public power, always a precarious thing less expensive routes. 79
in the agrarianate world, was particularly weak outside cities and The relationship between merchant andcustoms official should
the main traffic routes. The world of Mughal and Roman mer- not be seen as one-sided.Ratherit wasbasedon a tenuousbalance
chants alike was not only one of traditional abuse, it was also one ofpower.A gameofcatandmousewasplayedoutwheretherules
of equally traditional freedom, to paraphrase the late Ashin Das were subject to constant renegotiation according to concrete cir-
Gupta.7 Merchants, therefore, were often tempted simply to cir- cumstances. The result was the establishment of a fragile modus
cumvent taxation by conducting business in some remote village vivendi. 80 Some trades and merchants possessed more leverage
or bay far away from the toll station and hungry glances of cus- thanothers. According to the situation, particularly attractive "cus-
toms officials. Quantification is out of the question, but smuggling tomers", as it were, sometimes managed to wring smallish or
is bound to have been rife and to have gone largely undetected. 77 moderateprivileges andconcessionsfrom the customs authorities.
Relocating business to more remote areas did, of course, have Among such"fiscal"rebateswe findthepractice, in whichfamil-
some drawbacks. The traders would lose the central-place services iar merchants passing a customs station on a regular basis were in
offered by cities, such as a greater concentration of buyers and somecasesallowedtopostponethepaymentoftoll till theirreturn
sellers. They would also be outside the protection of the law whenthey could settle the bill out ofthe profits derivedfrom sell-
and hence more vulnerable to predation by bandits and power- ing their wares. 81 The large and valuable export of slaves from
ful landowners. Smuggling carried risks, but it offered enough of Anatolia was taxed at a slightly lower rate than slave imports. 82
an alternative to be a serviceable defence against new taxes or
unusually abusive or frequent customs exactions. In practice, the
'I3-ll. 7''andRit:hards[993a: 175and203.Thesimilarityofrangeissurelymorethan
flexibility of the merchant did impose some restrictions on the coincidental.

conduct of customs officials. It did not prevent arbitrary preda- 79 Theextremeexampleofthisphenomenonisofcoursewhenbanditsruthlesslydescend


on traders. In his Roman history (XIV, 2, 2-4) Ammianus Marcellinus describes how
tion but in the aggregate it would have exercised a moderating Isaurianbrigands,after havingplundereda numberof merchantcraft, found that their
influence, both on the conduct of officials and on the total tax bur- source of "revenue" dried up as ships simply avoided the coastal stretch under their
control. Mughal sources allow us to follow this in greater detail than Roman. From
den; hencethe generally relatively low officialcustoms rates, most Surat a letter survives from a governor trying to persuade traders, especially the Euro-
lying between 2% and 5% in the Roman and Mughal Empires.7 peancompanies, to return to Suratby promisingto stop overtaxing andprovide better
protection for caravans, cf. Hasan 2004: 35 and 50-51.
80 Sijpestein 1987:44, forinstance,documents howEgyptianpeasants/traders, knownto
the villagecustomscollector, wereableto pay theirtaxes in'advance.
75 C. Th., N. Val. 24: "ne ulterius furtiva negotiatio et clans urbibus rarum facial mer-
catorem et obscuris ac reconditis locis in damnum publicae functionis lateat turba
Dig. (Marcian) 39. 4. 16 I 2 providesevidence ofthepractice ofpostponing payment. On
mercantum".
a similar arrangement for the English East India Company inSurat, see Hasan 2004:
116.
76 Das Gupta 1987: 136; Hasan 2004: 117-118 treats the episode in the Mir'at-i Ahmadi.
77 See also Faroqhi 1984: 54-55 for an instructive description ofthe difficulties in detecting
?'isc:ustomarytointerpretthehigherimportrate(AsianCustomsLaw(MonEph. ), § 41,
1. 98) as an attempt through customs to discourage imports of slaves to Asia (Drexhage
smuggling in Ottoman Anatolia, complemented by pp. 66-69 on the ready distribution
1994: 6; Dreher 1997: 85). However, the difference only amounts to a few sesterces
of stolen goods.
78 SeedeLaet 1949 on Roman customs rates. OnMughal customs rates, seee. g. Tavemier per slave. Withslavesoftenpricedat severalhundredHS, theextraduty cannothave
1889, vol. I: 7; Mir'at-i Ahmadi, chapter 104 (between 1/40 and 2/40); Hasan 2004:
beenevenmoderately prohibitive. Therefore, I seethesmaller export duty asa courtesy
discountgrantedto a particularlyvaluableexport.
226
227
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A THIN LINE: PORTORIUM, PROTECTION AND PREDATION

In Palmyra a camel-load of unguents imported in alabaster ves- personal corruption".86 Generally, however, fiscal rebates were
sels was taxed at 25 denarii. But when the merchant left the town relatively fragile. Based on the concrete balance of power they
again he was only charged 13 denarii. This was probably a kind of were permanently under pressure, subject to renegotiation and, if
rebate intended to encourage traders to bring the merchandise to the Mughal evidence is anything to go by, constantly subject to
the city in the first place; unsold goods would be charged less than erosion. 87

the normal fare on departure.83 Luxury goods from India pass-


ing through Egypt were perhaps weighed with favourable scales The toll of the Fax Romana- drawingup a balancesheet
whenpaying someminor, local duesontheir wayto Alexandria. 84
In the same context, some merchants might secure the patronage
So far my discussion has focused on the parasitic dimension of
of persons of power inside the tributary system. This could pro- customs exaction. But the tributary system can, to some extent, be
vide such merchants with preferential treatment and perhaps even seen as offering the merchants something in return for the payment
sometimes, tax concessions. 85 That would be a plausible explana-
of dues: a modicum of social order, protection from brigandage
tion of the discount on exported slaves in the Asiancustoms law. and piracy. The Roman emperor claimed to have brought Fax to
Merchants supplying the Roman elite with much wanted slaves the subject populations of the Empire; in the process roads and
presumably usedtheirconnectionsto havethe concessionwritten seas had allegedly been cleared of pirates and bandits and made
into the law. However, patronage rarely comes gratis. Bribes or safe for merchants and travellers. The imperial propaganda of the
other reciprocating services would often have had to be paid as Fax Romana has been accepted by most generations of classical
a kind of compensatory tribute. The profits from such discounts scholarship. The notion of an imperial peace has also occasionally
would thus have re-entered the tributary system to a considerable
found its way into Indian history. The Pax Mogulica has been used
extent. This is presumably what was taking place when a group to describe a "golden" age before the fall of the great Empire and
of ferrymen put up, probably in consecutive years, inscriptions political chaos of the eighteenth century, by Indian historians to
and statues honouring the customs collectors of Chios "for their
boost national confidence and by British colonialist historians to
virtuous conduct towards them". The "honorific monuments", as
justify the Raj as a benevolent attempt to re-establishorder among
suggested by Onno van Nijf, "may have been the public face of the Orientals.
Broadly speaking, however, Mughal historiography has paid
83 PalmvreneTaxLaw,CISII, 3, 3913, panel 3a, lines 19-31. AgainI amcertainthatthis more attention to the brittle foundations and fragile nature of the
should not be seen as a customs barrier to imports. The practice of occasionally granting
a discountto goodsbeingre-exportedin orderto attractthemto themarketin thefirst so-called peace established by tributary empires. Not only large-
place is alsoknown from the inscription recording a local toll in Caunos in Lycia(SEG
XIV, 639 with the comments of Bean 1954). There a benefactor set up a foundation to
pay for a number of exemptions from the regular customs regime. See now Schwarz Seevan Nijf 1997: 92-93 on IK I, 74. Robert 1969: 545-548 published this and a more
20()lb: 385-394. Purpura 1985 unconvincingly argues that the Caunos prescriptions fragmentary but similar inscription which suggests that the practice was repeated over
were regular rather than exemptions from the generally established practice. several years.
84 P. Vindob. G 40822 (second column). For analysis of the discount in the weighing 87 The European chartered companies "just as some prominent indigenous merchants"
process seeCasson 1990.DeRomanis 1998isaninteresting ifultimately toospeculative managed to secure discounts through patronage. Such privilege came at a high price
attempt to make something out of these discounts. Rathbone 2001 now challenges and doubts were often voiced as to whether they might not have donejust as well by
this interpretation and substitutes a scenario with surcharges accruing to the customs simplypayingtheunmodifieclrate.ThediaryoftheSurmanembassyto theMughalcourt
officials. in 1714-1716, The Oriental and India Office Records (London), Home Miscellaneous
85 In the law codes it is often observed that merchants connected with great households Series, vol. 69, provides very instructive evidence on the high costs and the numerous
managedto escapetaxation (C. Th. XIII.1.5; 15 and 25). However,the phenomenon complications and intrigues arising out of attempts to obtain fiscal exemptions. The
should not be seen as restricted to late antiquity. Cicero (Fam. 13. 75) shows aristocratic fiscal privileges were also often ignored on the ground. Entangled in the shifting ties
patronage securing privileges in dealing with the authorities for a grain transporter/ of patronage networks, they were frequently being undermined and needed permanent
trader. defence. See in general Hasan 2004, chapter 7 and Prakash 1985: 41-45.

228 229
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A THIN LINE: PORTORIUM, PROTECTION AND PREDAT10N

but also small-scale local rebellions and other forms of low-level imperial state claimed the 25% customs duty on this traffic. Still,
violence hold a more prominent position in the history of the theRoman army doesnotappeartohavebeenconspicuously active
north Indian Empire than they do in most periods of Roman his- in ensuringthe safety of the caravans.Thatwasa task mainly left
tory. It wouldbefoolhardyto claimcategoricallythattherewere to semi-pnvate initiative and the city council ofPalmyra. The rich
no differences between the two empires in the respective levels inscriptionalevidencefrom the Syrianoasiscity informs us about
of violence. So many factors of culture, social organisation and the need for local grandees, commanding influence among the
geography affect the scope for successful banditry that one could deserttribes, to stepin andensurethesafepassageofthecaravans.
never expect exact similarity. Even so the difference can to a large In additionto this, the city seemsto havemaintaineda local militia
extent be explained with reference to separate historiographical which patrolled and stationed the desert routes, and fought offthe
traditions rather than genuine contrasts between past worlds. In occasionalbedouinattackon city territory. 92
the last couple of decades Roman historians have become increas- Much has been made of the proximity ofParthia and the politi-
ingly aware of the ideological nature of the claim of the Roman calinabilityoftheRomanarmyto actin the frontierzonewithout
emperors and the indications of persistent violent disorder in the increasing the risk ofprovoking war, to explain the role ofPalmyra
empire. Though successful for centuries, small-scale rebellions, in patrolling the desert. There may be a grain of truth in this, espe-
occasionally growing to significant proportions, violent disputes daily when the laxity on the Syro-Parthian route is contrasted
or even minor wars between local communities and raids by moun- with the heavier state control exercised in the Egyptian desert on
tain people, nomads and "barbarians" were part of the empire in the roads carrying Eastern luxuries. But the importance of such
the bestoftimes. The Roman world wasonly relatively pacified. 9 considerations can easily be exaggerated. Even in the Egyptian
Banditry and piracy continued to constitute a real menace for desert, the state presence seems to have been as much a question
merchants and other travellers, even in Italy.90 This was a fact of of keeping an eye on the valuable goods to reduce smuggling as
life acknowledged by all, including the imperial state. Roman law providing protection. The merchants were still expected to hire
prohibited the build-up of stores of arms intended for rebellion their own guards and pay a road tax on them as well. 93 If any-
or social disturbance, but its subjects were still allowed to retain thing, it is rather the relatively heavy presence on the Egyptian
weapons for their own defence. Merchants and travellers were to desert roads that constitutes the exception. The Roman army nor-
a large extent expected to be able to take care of themselves and mally left it to local initiative to maintain law and order around
defendtheirpossessionsfrom violent attackers.9 The relationship the empire. 94 In that respect there is nothing surprising about
between the level of taxation and the quality of protection was Palmyra's semi-autonomous policing of the desert. An inscrip-
not necessarily very close. An extreme illustration of this is the tion from the early third century shows the Rhodians organising a
caravan trade bringing luxuries from India through the Syrian
desert to Palmyra and from there further on into the Empire. The
92 Somrner2005:202-213(on the complexinterrelationshipbetweenPalmyraandthe
nomadic tribes of its hinterland, based on cooperation, intermittently disrupted by
armedconfrontation). SeefurtherTeixidor 1984; R. Drexhage 1988;Will 1992; and
88 The fragile foundationof the Mughal peacewas alreadya main theme in Habib 1963. Young 2001, chapter4.
See Hintze 1997 for some historiographical overviews. 93 OG/S674,line12(thoughemended)fordutypayableonaccompanyingguards.P.Vin-
89 Woolf 1993 and Brunt 1990, chapter 11. dob. G 40822, recto column 2 fortheuseofprivate guards incommercial transports in
90 Cf. Pliny Ep. 6. 25 reporting the disappearanceof a Roman knight duringtravel in Italy. Egypt.Young2001:69-74analysesthedesertroads.Faroqhi1984:52-55offerscom-
See Shaw 1984; Hopwood 1989; Griinewald 1999; andWolff2003 (though empiricist, parative confirmation from Ottoman Anatolia that imperial surveillance might happen
rather than analytical) for the continuation of'banditry. For piracy, Braund 1993 and De as much to avoid smuggling as to provide protection.
Souza1999, chapter6. De SouzaandWolffthough, seemtoo impressedwith the claims 94 Liebenam 1900: 357-359 long ago noted the sparing involvement of the imperial
of the imperial ideology of Fax. government in the policing of its territory. See Wolff 2003, chapter 8 for a recent
91 Dig. 48. 6. 1 with Brunt 1990:257-259. discussion.

230 231
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A THIN LINE: PORTORJUM, PROTECTION AND PREDATION
quasi-military expedition to teach bandits and pirates a lesson. 95 The stronger the position of the customs exactor, the greater the
The emperor Commodus praised the city of Bubon as a model proportion of tribute. In other words, fewerprotection-producing
worthy ofemulation by othercommunities because"you hastened rivals would lessen the opportunities open to merchants for taking
with suchgreatenthusiasmto the arrestofthe bandits,overcoming their goods by a different route. The result would be to weaken
them, killing some, and capturing others". 96 Much of this locally their negotiatingpowervis-a-visthe tribute takers andthe cost of
organisedprotection will have been rather amateurish, sometimes protection, taxation that is, would increase."
ad hoc in character and often of doubtful value. This, for instance, The large tributary empires had been created by conquering
was the experience of a pair of pig merchants returning from tributary rivals and absorbing them into the same system. As we
the village of Philadelphia to Arsinoe in second-century Egypt. have seen repeatedly above, it would be wrong to describe these
Though the locally employed guard came to their rescue, this did empiresasunitaryentitiesexercisinga strong,centralisedmonop-
not deter the bandits from attacking. On the contrary, the guard olistic powerin society. The emperors' reachfell far short ofthat.
simply receivedthe sametreatment asthe unfortunatetraders,who But the alliance between the different segments of the imperial
were tied, given a good beating andhad a pig stolen.97 state did in some ways reduce, not, I emphasise, eradicate, com-
Protection offered by the different segments of the imperial sys- petition and strengthen the position of tribute takers in the body
tem often left much to be desired. A relatively high degree of politic. The result, asargued in Chapter 2, wasan intensification of
low-level violence was tolerated. Not infrequently one gets the surplus extraction or, to use the language of Lane, rising monop-
impression that gangs of bandits were harboured by members of olistic profits in the sale of protection. Essentially these could be
the local elite, thevery group supposed to underwrite local order. 98 realised in two ways, raising the price and cutting costs. It is pos-
The exaction of customs cannot, in other words, simply be seen sible to argue that both methods occurred in the Roman Empire,
as paymentfor protection. Anyhow, this is not somethingwhichis not least in the sphere of customs collection.
peculiarto tributary empires. A pacifiedcivil society is only a rel- The need to accommodate the revenue demands both of the
atively recent phenomenon. The important but elusive question is central imperial state and of local aristocratically ruled commu-
how the Roman imperial system compares to other pre-industrial nities would probably have worked towards increasing the total
societies. In the sharpest attempt so far to conceptualise the process burden ofcustoms andother dues on trade. 100This didnot happen
of customs exaction in agrarianate societies, the American histo- overnight The process would have been slow, piecemeal andvery
rian F. C. Lane suggested that customs dues be seen as comprising gradual. Nonetheless, over time from the consolidation of impe-
two elements: the costs ofproducingprotection, anda furthertrib- rialrule underAugustus until thefourth century, sucha trend does
ute, a monopoly profit exacted by threat of using military force. seem to make itself discernible. The central imperial government
graduallyattemptedto confiscatemore andmore local tolls, aswe
95 S£ 1946-1947: 337-338, no. i5&-ni with De Souza [999:218-219.
9<' A£ 1979 no. 624 (translation quoted from Lendon 1997:137) with Wolff 2003: Il8-l2l, have already seen. It also occasionally introduced new dues, for
196-197. instance onparticular roadsand,in the fourth century, the so-called
97 P. Fay. 108. Alston 1995: 86-96 observes that the Roman state was involved in these
local arrangements. We possess papyri showingdistrict centurions ordering local com- chrysargyron tax to bepaid by trades people, among others. 101 The
munities to man watchtowers with guards. But the same papyri attest the crucial role local aristocratic segments ofthe imperial state would have sought
left to the initiative of local communities in executing imperial orders and the huge
scope for local "negligence". None of this is to deny the occasional imperial assistance w Lane 1966:383-428;Steensgaard1981.
to local policing units, but Alston 1995: 81-86 is too optimistic in his assessment of Incidentally Purcell 2005: 222 is open to the possibility of rising customs under the
the scope of this, as is Wolff 2003, chapter 9. The available manpower resources were Romans.
simply inadequate, as is clear from the convenient and still valuable surveys of Sherk 101 We know^ for instance, that Tiberius confiscated many local vectigalia (Suet. Tib.
1955 and 1957.
98 Shaw 1984;Hopwood 1989.
49.2). Galbaremittedsome.ThiswasannulledbyVespasianwhoneededmoney.He
evenaddednewandheavierones(Suet. Vesp. 16. 1). SeefurtherHerodianII.'iv, 7,
232 233
A THIN LINE: PORTORIUM, PROTECTION AND PREDATION
IMPERIAL BAZAAR

compensation for some of the lost vectigalia by introducing new level, that is to prevent it from erupting into full-scale war or open
excise duties. Such tolls remained important for financing local rebellion where tribute extraction would become endangered. As a
result, Roman conquestprobably effected a reduction in the over-
government. 102Taken together, the combined pressure for revenue
exerted by the (competing) demands of central government and all military burden in the Mediterranean region. Long ago Gibbon
local elite groups, one may hypothesise, would have created a remarked upon the relatively modest size of the imperial army.
trend towards slowly increasing the tax burden on trade. 103There Thus the Roman state was able to cash in a peace dividend from
were countercurrents too. Occasionally the emperor remitted or loweredcosts ofproducingprotection in the Mediterraneanworld.
cancelled vectigalia. He also tried to impose some kind of con- This lasted roughly for the period normally associated with the
trol on the number of locally exacted dues. However, as already heyday of the Pax Romana. By the reign of Marcus Aurelius the
argued above, these actions were of relatively limited extent and barbarians at the frontiers were beginning to catch up with Roman
usually only marginally successful; the emperor could always do military superiority. 105 This made the defence of the Empire more
with more money andhealsohadto placate local allies. The spo- difficult and military expenditure was again under pressure to rise.
radic attempts to reduce the burden can therefore best be seen as Gradually the peace dividend was eaten up in the coming centuries
by growing costs of the military.
precautionary and limited measures intended to counter the risk This scenario for the Pax Romana collides head on with tradi-
ofover-burdening and thus ofkilling offthe trade flows. They did
notreverse the general trend, andwere not even intended to; rather tional interpretations which have normally focused entirely on the
it was a question of safeguarding the fiscal interest. 104 many benefits of peace accruing to the free movement of goods
At the same time, the imperial system probably benefited from around the Empire. But the aim is not to deny that trade would
reduced military costs, though only for a period. Conquering and have benefited from a reduction in the incidence of disruptive wars
in the Mediterranean. The merit of the model, however, is to draw
incorporating many of its neighbours reduced the incidence of
full-scale war drastically in core areas ofthe Empire, such as Italy, our attention to the process of how the benefits of empire were
southern France, Asia province, and the Mediterranean Sea. This distributed and thus question the automatic, economic textbook
meant thatthe effort ofthe army could beconcentrated in thefron- assumption of a straightforward link between peace and grow-
tier regions, whereas internal policing, aswehave seen, wasleft ing interregional trade. Against the benefits of imperial law and
very much to the cheaper, irregular "troops" usedby local commu- coinage,must also be set the disruptive influences ofthe activities
nities. They were normally sufficient tokeep violence ata tolerable of the Roman state and its personnel. As one business representa-
tive observed in a letter to "Athenocloros, the merchant", he could
not send the requested grain unless a new boat was sent down
who mentions new tolls as one way forward for a princeps in need of extra money.
One senses a pattern of ever-wideningimperial customs exaction This culminated to him because his boats had been requisitioned by the army and
with Constantine, who laid claim to most local tolls. At around the same time, the werenot availablefor commercialtransport at thatmoment/06
clm'sargynm or collatio lustralis was introduced too, cf. Jones 1964: 431-432 and The significant point to appear from the model outlined above
871-872. ^ . ..
102 SeeSchwarz200[b: 338-406for a cleardemonstrationof the continuedimportance is that merchants were far from the first in line to benefit from the
of customs in city finances. imperial order. Here the imperial states really seem to partcompany
.
°3 Liebenam 1900: 359-360 points inthisdirection, too. Buthehadtoomuchconfidence
intheabilityofthecentralgovernmenttoregulatemunicipaltaxation. with early modern capitalism. Competition for "shares of trade"
I04 As de Laet'1949:463-467"remarkedwe know much less about the formal customs between the emerging nation states of Europe forced them into a
rates in late antiquitythanduringthe Principate.A mysterious octavahovers n the different process (see Chapter l). They had to continue to invest
background,though"itwasprobablya salestaxratherthana customsduty.Bethatas
it may.ingeneralthelateRomanstateseemstohaveincreasedtaxation.Thereislittle
reasonto thinkthatthis didnot also affecttrade.The introductionofthe chrysargyron
105 Whittaker i994a. '06 BGU XVI, 2644 (26 June, AD 4).
confirms this expectation.
235
234
IMPERIAL BAZAAR A THIN LINE: PORTORIUM, PROTECTION AND PREDATION

more of their income in steadily improving the basic conditions of in the Hellenistic period is easily exaggerated. Contemporary dis-
tradersbyofferingthembetterprotection,firstthroughmercantilist cussions of war and large-scale piracy were embroiled in a heavily
privileges, later through firm support for the "free" movement of ideologised discourse about the true representatives and defend-
goods in the face of local resistance, and finally by effecting a ers of civilisation. Military enemies were habitually branded as
gradual pacification of their civil societies from the seventeenth pirates and destroyers of civilised order. The Roman conquerors
until the nineteenth centuries. 107 The gains from the Fax Romana, adopted this symbolic language to set themselves apart from the
by contrast, were not invested in steadily improving the conditions alleged unruly chaos of the preceding period of the Hellenistic
of trade still further after its initial establishment. On the contrary, monarchies. One should therefore be wary of making the con-
the tributary state was content to accept the continued existence trasttoostark.ThecenturiesprecedingAugustussawconsiderable
of considerable low-level violence. 108 Indeed, its personnel often commercial developments. Activity in the western Mediterranean
contributed to everyday brutality and abuse, as we have seen in this expanded significantly, if we can trust the statistical increase in
chapter.Instead,thecentralgovernmentandlandedelitespocketed the number of shipwrecks which have been discovered, dating to
theprofitsfromthereducedcostsoforganisingprotectionandwere this period. "0 In the eastern Mediterranean Alexandria, Rhodes,
probablyeven ableslowly to increasethe price the merchantshad Delos and the opening up of trade with Indiaall suggest the vital-
to pay for this service. In spite of appearances, the conditions of ity of commercial activity. Takentogetherthis calls for caution in
tradeduringthehighEmpirewerenotnearlyasfavourableasthey estimating the initial improvement in the conditions of trade cre-
are often imaginedto have been. In the crucial areaof protection, ated by the Fax Romana. A revolution in transaction costs would
transaction costs, if anything, probably experienced a slow rise clearly be much too strong a description of what happened. At
from the consolidation of the Empire under Augustus until the most one can hypothesise moderate improvements which would
fourth century AD. '09 then have been subject to gradual erosion by rising tax payments
The question still remains, however, whether this slow rise in over the following centuries. In general, the tributary empire only
protectioncostseveroutweighedthebenefitsderivingfromtheini- broughtabout a moderate reduction in protection costs. It did not
tial reduction in large-scale violence in the Mediterraneanbrought fundamentally alter the basic conditions of the bazaar.
about by the consolidation of Roman rule. There is no simple If the Roman "peace" nevertheless did lead to an expansion
answer to that; we cannot make useful quantitative estimates of in the intercity movement of goods, the explanation, as argued
the different forces and balance them off against each other. Only in Chapter 2, can be found in the area of tribute extraction. The
broad impressions are possible. The key issue is just how much reduction intheincidenceoflarge-scale violence insidetheempire
of a burden on regular trade were war and the concomitant plun- meant that the process of tribute extraction became less subject to
dering, often referred to as piracy by the ancient authors, before disruptions. At least for a period, tribute extraction experienced
the coming of the so-called Roman peace. The size of this burden greater stability and, asa consequence, achieved greater intensity.
The result was an increased demand for the services of the Roman
107 In general Lane 1966, chapters 22-25; Hont 2005 for European state-building and
bazaar. The Empire gave it a greater and, for a long period, more
commercialcompetition;Persson 1999links thecreationofnationalmarketsunderthe
banner of laissez-faire with absolutist governments.
108 Strabo's stray remark (i i . 2. 12) about the negligence ofRoman governors in comparison Parker 1992.The wreckevidencedoesunmistakablyshowa rise in activity during
to local chieftains in combating brigandage in the more remote corners of the Black the last two centuries BC. The changes in the following centuries, however, need not
Sea seems no less relevant for conditions in general under Rome than the ideological necessarilybetakenasevidenceof stagnationor decline. Both EgyptianandAfrican
celebration of the fruits of peace. shipssailingtheMediterraneanareunderrepresentedin thematerial,thoughtradeand
109 Bang 2007 attempts to develop this argument to model the macro conditions of the transportfrom theseregionspickeduppreciselywhenthematerialbeginsto indicate
Roman political economy from the Republic until late antiquity. contraction, cf. Whittaker 1989.

236 237
IMPERIAL BAZAAR

stable flow of resources to handle. '" Such an interpretation finds


support in developments in north India during the dissolution of
the Mughal Empire in the eighteenth century. In areas where the
surplus extracting apparatus remained intact, or even intensified, COMMUNITY: CULT, COURTS, CREDIT AND
trade continued in spite of the increased level of violence. On COLLABORATIONIN THE BAZAAR
the other hand, in regions where the aristocratic, fiscal system
disintegrated, demand collapsed and trade dwindled away. "2
This chapterhasexamined oneaspectofuncertainty intheworld Poormen ofhumble birth sailtheseasandcome toplaces whichtheyhavenever
ofthebazaar:protectioncosts. Theproblem ofsecurity waslarger seenbeforeandwheretheyarestrangerstothepeopletheymeetandwherethey
than that ensuing from the high-profile phenomenaof piracy and donot alwayshavepeople to vouchforthem. Yettheycountonbeingsafeonly
banditry; it embraced also the no less important element offiscally by putting trust in theirRomancitizenship.
motivated customs exactions. However, the merchants and traders Cicero, SecondSpeechAgainstGainsVerres,V, [67
of the bazaar were not as defenceless in the face of corrupt and BanarasidasandhisfriendNarrotamdas wenttoBanarasforbusiness. Firstthey
abusive customs offrcials as they are often portrayed. Rather, a bal- offered prayers to Parsvanathand took a vow to observe the usual religious
practices.Theykeptall thefasts,gaveupgreenvegetables,andthecompanyof
ance of power existed between merchant and customs collector; prostitutes. InthebrighthalfofBaisakh(April), Samvat1671 (AD 1614),they
traders were able to establish a modus vivendi, however fragile, completed the vow andofferedworship.
with the authorities. Their ability to circumvent the toughest col- Banarasidas,Ardha-Kathanak(Sharma1970),p. 107
lection points limited theroom for manoeuvre left to theindividual
customs official. Too much brutality would underminehis income
in the long term. "3 Mechanisms were in place then that enabled The first of the epigraphs above is normally cited as proof of the
trade to take place in what to modern sentiments was a"rough' low social standing of Roman merchants. I am interested in a
environment. The next chapter will explore the character of such slightly different aspect ofCicero's rhetorical figure: the question
mechanisms further. of security and uncertainty in the world of the trader, habitually
travelling between different communities. In the preceding chap-
'" Cf. Wickham2005. "2 Bayly 1983, chapters 1-4. ter the customs collector was used as the ideal-typical example
113 Cf. Dirlmeier 1987on thefrequentcollection points oftransitduesalongthe Rhinein ofhowthe tributary state didnot manage unambiguously to make
medieval times. If themanycustomscollecteddidnot kill offtrade,it wasbecausethe
collectors were interested in its continuance. But this does not mean, pace the optimistic, conditions of trade secure. A dirigiste state might be expected to
but unfounded assertion of Purcell 2005, that customs did not burden or limit trade. have exercised strong controls on the movement ofgoods through
They did add significantly to the costs and hence limited potential consumption. all branches ofeconomic life. But that wasnot primarily the cause
of commercial uncertainty in the agrarian empires. Firm com-
mand of the market sector or the bazaarin its entirety was com-
pletely beyond the means of the imperial state. In fact, it was
unable even to curb its own officials. ' The inability of the state
to control commercial life, therefore, is not to be mistaken for
the existence of a de facto regime of laissez-faire. The tributary
Thepriceedictot'Diocletianisa tellingifunintentionaldemonstrationofhowunrealistic
suchcontrol wasunderRomanconditions;its grandiloquenttoneandsheerabundance
ofdetail are signsofweakness,not strength.
238 239
IMPERIAL BAZAAR
COMMUNITY

state simply was not strong enough to provide the level of guar-
anteed security and predictable administration implied by Adam engaging^withpersonsofsuperiorstatusorofficialrankposedall
Smith whenhecoinedhisinfluential adviceforoptimum economic
sorts ofphysical as well as financial risks. Merchants and traders.
performance. however, should not be seen as helpless in the face of these chal-
Telling confirmation of this can be found in Pliny's Bithynian
lenges. In the last chapter, their ability to vote with their feet. so to
correspondencewithTrajan.Thecity ofJuliopolisin theprovince speak,waj.seentohaveworkedasa counterbalance against'over~-
suffered from difficulties with looting and assault on civilians by
taxation. But merchant response was not restricted to individual
passingarmy contingents. Hence the city had applied to the gov-
acts of smuggling andavoidance. Instead the people of the trad-
ernor to have military personnel stationed to protect it from the i-ng^vorld.setaboutcreatinstheirownsocialinstitutions,back-up
abuses of troops on the march. Apparently Pliny was inclined to mechanisms asitwere,tocompensate fortherelatively weakgua7-
grant the city this favour which was already enjoyed by Byzan- antees provided by the state system. If at all possible most traders
tium. But Trajan said no on the grounds that it would set a danger- preferred to have "people to vouch for them". 4 Certainly, those
who could do so would not as a general rule have been content to
ous example to the rest of the cities in the province. The guards
in Byzantium were to remain the absolute exception, a carefully venture forth into thegreatunknown only trusting in theprotec-
tive powers oftheir Roman citizenship, as Cicero boasted. Instead.
guarded privilege, not a right. If another city was to receive impe-
rial guards, others would soon follow with the same demands. merchantsallovertheRomanworld.justasinotherpre-industrial
The result would be an intolerable increase in the administrative societies, attempted to forge personal links and construct social
burden of the province. Instead, Trajan preferred to direct his gov-
networks of various kinds which, to some extent, would cush-
ernor to do his best to see to it that breaches of military discipline ion them against the vicissitudes ofcommercial life, theprocess
were punished. This was effectively a decision to leave things Geertz referred to as clientelisation. Two key components of the
be. Pliny must already have been aware that he could not contain social fabric of the bazaar were communal associations and the
the military abuses with the normal means available to him. In household. This chapter examines the role of the former in creat-
practice, benign foresight and care, those much praised qualities
ing ties ofcommunity andtrust among traders andofthe latter in
in the emperor, turned out to make little difference to the sub-
providing basic capital and credit to finance commerce.
jects on the ground. Even Trajan, generally celebrated as optimus
princeps by an admiring posterity, had to allow a certain level of Communalassociation- thepowerofreligiousconviviality
abuse to continue unchecked.2 Roman peace did not come with
the night watchman demanded by classical economics. The trib- ThecopiousepigraphicrecordsurvivingfromtheEmpirecontains
utary empire lacked both the will and the capacity to fulfil the numerous inscriptions revealing the existence of a rich texture of
role.
communal merchantorganisations andotherprofessional bodiesin
The mainproblem ofthebazaartrader wasnottoomuch govern- many,cities"5 These/ecorcls' incised inmarble andputondisplay,
mental control, but too little. 3 Mixing in a foreign community or mainly inform us about the public life of the professional asso
ciations, or guilds. They bear witness to the religious and social
2 Plin. Ep. X, 77-78. Pace Wolff 2003: 203-204 who cites these letters as reflecting a
processofimproving imperial security arrangementsfor thepopulation. But that means
ignoring the negative answer to Pliny's request. In this case, that is ill advised. The letters
werepublishedandcirculatedas representinga standardworthy ofemulation. 4 Cic. II Verr. V, 167.
3 See Jones 1988, chapter 8 for the relatively low degree of social organisationof the Waltzing 1895-1900 remains unsurpassed and collects most of the evidence for nrn-
market sectorcreatedby the empires. SeefurtherGeertz 1963,chapter3, modifiedby Ss!onalassodatonsin!heRomanEmpirelnVOIS-3-4,including'thoseofmerchmt^
Geertz 1979. othercentra:IWOIte arcMickwiu'936; DeRobertis i-97"i':Aus nel"i'982:"De"sZ^
1992;vanNijf 1997.Mommsen 1843-isa seminalcontnbution."""""" "'"" "" "'"
240
241
COMMUNITY
IMPERIAL BAZAAR

rituals performed by thetraderconfraternities, collegia in Latin.6 an iron grip. Paradoxically, to the extent that the very hardened,
Students familiar with medieval guilds have been struck by the static and stylised version of the caste system has ever had any
general absence in their Greco-Roman predecessors of formally social reality, this seems to have been the result of the changes
recognised powers to regulate and define the rules of the trade, Indian society went through after the fall of the Mughal Empire
suchasnumberofpractitioners,pricesetc. Comparedto medieval and in particular during British colonial rule. During this period,
guilds, the professional associations of the ancient world appear organisation along caste lines was intensified. Caste was increas-
nottohavebeengreatlyconcernedwitheconomicobjectives.Their ingly employed by different groups as a means to defend, carve
focuswasoncommunitymatters, suchasensuringa properburial out and assert their position in a struggle over accessto resources
of deceased "brethren" or providing a setting for convivial gath- and privilege in a rapidly changing social order. As a result divi-
erings or cultic activities. The distinction between socio-religious sions between different segments of society became more clearly
clubs and economic guilds, however, can easily be overdrawn. defined and caste boundaries hardened. Before this period, during
Absence of a securely established monopoly on economic regu- Mughal rule, caste seems to have been much less dominant, far
lation, and predominance of "cultural" functions, should not, as more flexible and not nearly as highly articulated as was later to
be the case.
is the case for instance in Finley's work, be equated with eco-
nomic impotence per se, let alone lack of an economic function The family history of the seventeenth-century Baniatrader and
for these merchant societies in general.7 Once more, comparison Jain guru, Banarasidas, provides illustration. Originating from a
with Mughal Indiamay prove illuminating. clan of so-called Hindu Rajputs, probably peasants, the family
In many respects, discussions of the role of religious caste in converted to Jainism (a sect bordering on Hinduism) and joined
Indiaresemble thearguments ofclassicists overtheexactnature of the caste or sub-caste Srimal. But throughout the history, we find
professional associations in the ancient economy. Caste has been Banarasidas and members of his family still embracing more
portrayed as a religiously ordered division of labour in society. traditional Hindu beliefs and engaging in business partnerships
with members of other creeds and sub-castes. Banarasidas' father
The clearest expression of this view was offered by the French
ethnographer Louis Dumont in his Homo Hierarchicus (1966). Karagsen, though himself a Jain, collaborated in the jewel trade
In his version caste is seen as a rigid, unchanging system which, with a Siva worshipper and member of the Oswal sub-caste. Unit-
since time immemorial, has organised Indian society into a large ing these different socio-religiousgroups was a "vague"notion of
number of hereditary, functionally specialised groups, so-called the Baniacommunity. The Banias were a very broad and loosely
castes. Each caste would ideally comprise the members of a spe- defined group of Jain and Hindu commercial people (traders,
cific occupation; the salt-merchants' caste, the barbers' caste etc. bankers etc. ). 9 Add to this the co-existence of other similarly
But caste has in fact never been able to hold Indian society in such broad commercial groupings, such as Parsis, the Khattris, par-
ticularly in the central part of the Empire, and powerful Mus-
6 Patterson 1994 and van Nijf 1997 treat the public, ritual life of Greco-Roman civic
lim groups of merchants, for instance at the hub of the commer-
associations. cial network radiating from Surat using Banias as assistants, and
7 Seevan Nijf 1997,chapter i fora tentative critique ofFinley's analysis. Rauh 1993 shows the image of a clearly defined caste system begins to fall apart.
the economic function ofthe religious aspects oftrading guilds at Delos. Finley s analysis
(19853: 81 and 137-138) of the non-econoinic character of Greco-Roman collegia was The social reality appears much more fluid and far less tidy than
basedonWaltzing 1895-1900 via Mickwitz 1936. Waltzing, however, wasmore nuanced the traditional view allows. In economic terms this means it would
than Finley. He also argued that collegia, though different from medieval guilds, did
fulfil important economic functions: "L'influence et 1'utilite des colleges aupoint devue
economique furent-elles done nulles? Certes non... les negociants et les ouvners...
s'associaient afin de mieux defendre leur interets communs" (1895-1900, vol. I: i88- Bayly 1999 is fundamental.
189).
y Banarasidas, Ardha-Kathanak, in Sharma 1970: 52 and 56 and Habib 1990:382-383.

242 243
IMPERIAL BAZAAR COMMUNITY

be wrong to seethe differentmerchantcastesas identicalin func- and time again the sources allow us a glimpse of their potential
tion with medieval guilds. They were more social andreligious in for social mobilisation. In his speech against the governor Flac-
nature. They did not as a general rule constitute clearly formalised cus, the Jewish-Alexandrine intellectual Philo describes how the
bodies regulating their trades. Only in cases where a particular notorious Isidorus roused the membership of several Alexandrine
caste came to monopolise a trade locally did it establish control of confratemities against Flaccus. 12 The potential power of private
commercial practices in ways more closely resembling medieval associations centred on religious ritual and conviviality should not
guilds. More often castes formed rather loose conglomerates of be underestimated.
numerous locally co-existing sub-castes, usually of an ad hoc This lesson was not lost on the imperial authorities. Their atti-
nature, which could also combine to form cross-caste councils of tude towards private associations always remained ambiguous.
merchants. Though far from identical in their policies, both Mughal and
None of this deprived castes of economic significance. Though Romanemperors looked with suspicionon the capacityof various
not strongly corporate in character, local caste bodies did usually religiously organised, autonomous groups to turn rebellious, riot
still influence conditions in the bazaar in many ways and provided anddisrupttheestablishedsocialorder. 13OneoftheGreatMughal
some of the underpinnings and social architecture of commercial Aurangzeb's imperial farmans (edicts), for instance, declares that
life.Thecommonreligiousidentityproducedbylocalcastegather- "men and women visit shrines of saints on their anniversary days,
ingscouldoftenbemobilisedbymerchants whenneededtodefend Friday nights and nights of the last days of the months. This fact is a
their interests. In 1669 the qazi (local law-and-orderofficer) ini- cause of disturbance. It should be arranged that none should crowd
tiatedthe destruction of Hindu temples in Surat, the greattrading at the tombs. '"4 A few lines above in the samefarman the emperor
port, following an order from the Mughal emperor Aurangzeb. makes a similar-sounding complaint about a Hindu festival. In
The Baniacommunity answeredby closing their shops and leav- the Roman law codes under a title concerning private associa-
ing the city en masse. The consequence, asreported by the English tions we findthejurist Marcianusopiningthatreligiousgatherings
factor, was that "the people of Surat suffered great want ... there shouldbe tolerated as long as they do notevolve into illegal activi-
was not any provisions to be got, the tanksall and customs house ties. 15 This concern is mirrored in Tertullian's late second-century
shut; no money to be procured; soe much as for home expenses; defence of Christianity directed to the Roman authorities. It is
much less for trade, which was wholy at a stand. "" Only when telling that he chose to argue that the Church should be considered
the qau agreed to disregard the imperial order and abandon the legitimate by the Empire because it did not present a threat to the
policy of religious persecution did the Banias return and city life political and social order, in contrast to many other associations.
was restored to its former level of activity. Religious power was no Furthermore, in strict law professional organisations may quite
trifling matter in the tributary empires. It was a powerful rallying
point. The shared experience of cultic rituals, meals and festivals 12 Philo In Flac. 136-138 and Seland 1996.
created a sense ofcommunity among theparticipants, whichcould 13 See Veyne 1979 for the "disciplinary"attitude of the Roman authorities designed to
uphold the moral and social order of society.
be mobilised in social conflicts. 14 Mir'at-i Ahmadi, 233.
Greco-Roman collegia were not hereditary castes of course. 5 Dig.47. 22. 1. 1 .Thesuspicionthatreligiouslyorganisedbodiesmightturnrebelliousand
go againstthe state is a constant of Greco-Romanhistory, from the Bacchanalianaffair
But they did seek to create a communal identity around common in early second-century BC Roman Italy right down to the imperialjuristic writings of
participation in regular religious and convivial activities. Time the Antonine and Severanperiod. Goodexamplesof the suspiciousattitude are Philo In
Flaccum4 and Trajan's comment to Pliny (Ep. X, 34): "whatevername we give them
10 Ashin Das Gupta 1979: 14-15 and 74-88. and for whateverreason, if people assemble for a common purpose they soon turn into
'' The EnglishFactories,vol. 13: 190-192,citedin Singh 1972:224. SeefurtherHasail brotherhoods". See Cotter 1996.
2004: 4"-43 and 60-65. '6 Tertullian Apol. 38. 1-3.

244 245
IMPERIAL BAZAAR
COMMUNITY

possibly have been required to obtain an imperial authorisation. '7 and the concomitant deepening of its reach. Until quite recently,
But that was imperial hyperbole. In practice, many associations of there was a tendency to exaggerate the general extent of the pro-
merchants andothercommercial peoplecontinuedto existwithout cess, with historians trusting imperial claims ofomnipotence more
imperial blueprint and without interference from the authorities as than they do at present. But the most pronounced crystallisation
long as they did not actually disturb the social order. The govern- of corporate features happened primarily in connection with col-
ment had to tolerate their existence, outside the law as it were,
leges involved with imperial supply systems, such as the annonae
since it had neither the intention nor the ability to take on the of Rome, and the armies in the provinces. None of these associa-
functions performed by these bodies. tions were ever allowed to take on a strong independent identity.
In fact, the imperial state andlocal authoritieson occasionactu- Their functions were too important to the state. It kept them sub-
ally needed the cooperation of some of the many associations. dued as its servants and transformed them in the process. The
These were of course granted the right to meet. But more than shippers, corpora naviculariorum, serving the annona of Rome
that, through involvement with state institutions some of these and Constantinople were, for instance, changed into an associa-
professional bodies did develop a more consolidated corporate tion oflandowners, possessing specifically designated lands which
character of sorts with a formally recognised position in society. carried the obligation to supply ships for the annona. Hence the
In early imperial Egypt, local groups of merchants bought the famous hesitations of St Augustine as to whether to accept the
right to administerthe state-imposedmonopoly in the salt trade in inheritanceof one of those properties on behalfof the Church.22
their areas. 19 The municipal fire brigades formed on the basis of Thus, even if the tributary empire was never favourable, and
builders' associations in Italy and some cities in other parts of the often even inimical, to the formation of strong corporations, it
Empire are a prominent example.2" A further instance is the pay- both hadto accept the existence ofnumerous communal groupings
ment of sales taxes and fulfilment of other officially imposed obli- within the bazaar and at times actually promoted some corporate
gationsvia the agencyof some of the professionalassociations.21 features in order to serve its own ends. In the commercial centre of
However, the development of more consolidatedcoqrorate bodies late Mughal Surat, the need of the state for the active cooperation
was, as far as the sources allow us to judge, slow, uneven andpre- of merchants in the administration of local society does seem to
dominantly, thoughnot exclusively, a feature ofthe late Empire. It have invested some merchant bodies with more corporate charac-
was the product of the expansion of the administrative apparatus teristics. 3 Roman professional associations, therefore, were not
necessarily without a measure of bargaining power. Occasionally
17 Dig. 47. 22. 3. 1 supported by Dig. 47. 22. 1. pr. This explains the habit ofsome professional
collegia of announcing in inscriptions that they had permission to meet, e. g. CIL VI, the sources allow us a glimpse of commercial groups applying
4416. Waltzing 1895-1900,vol. I: 114-132 is still the best treatment. theircollectivemuscleto someperceivedwrong,muchin thestyle
18 A clear indication of this is the admission by Marcianus (Dig. 47. 22. l. pr. ) that people
of small means should be allowed to form burial societies without formal authorisation of castegroups andmerchantcouncils in the MughalEmpire. An
as long as they do not meet more than once a month. In practice, however, many inscription records the decision by a high-ranking official, proba-
more colleges were tolerated. Waltzing 1895-1900, vol. l: 132-140 clearly brings out bly the praefectus annonae, seeking to accommodate the com-
the discrepancy between formal law and administrative implementation. De Robertis
l97l, vol. i: 323-395 and de Ligt 2000, argue against Waltzing, but unconvincingly. plaint of the five corporations of shippers from Arles serving the
They suggest that the right of association granted to the tenuiores should be seen as a
general permission to form collegia for any puqwse they wished, including professional.
lt Augustine Serm. 355, 5 with Jones 1964: 827-828; De Salvo 1992 treats the corpora
Waltzing 1896, vol. 1: 142-153 correctly rejected this theory.
navicutariorum. Collegia reporting commodity prices, as we encountered in chapter 3,
19 P. Midi. V, 245 with van Nijf 1997: 13-14 and Alston 1998: 175.
would also have sharpened corporate profiles. In general, see Mickwitz 1936,
20 In Sentinum they were referred to as the tria collegia principalia, CIL XI, 5749. Cf.
chapter 5. See further Waltzing 1895-1900, vol. 2; De Robertis 1971, vol. 2, parts
Royden 1988 and Patterson 1994. 4-5, and Ruggini 1973.
21 P. Land. Inv. 1562 versa (second century) reveals some groups, e. g. the vegetable 3 Hasan2004: 43-49 (should bebalancedby the accountof trouble anddivision in Das
sellers, being taxed with a lump sum payable by the "guild" (line 13). Gupta 1979).
246 247
IMPERIAL BAZAAR COMMUNITY

annona, over some unspecifiedabuse. A local imperial procurator bespeak the existence of collective organisational power and the
is ordered to address and correct the injury in order to ensure the use of communal association by professional groups to defend
continued operation of state transports. 4 One should not, how- their economic interests. This might sometimes even have taken
ever, see this exclusively as a phenomenon restricted to corpora the form of tacit collective agreements on prices.28 The ambi-
involved in state service. To be sure, it is the area best attested in tion to defend and promote their collective interests, however, is
the sources. But that seems largely due to the character of what also reflected in the widespread habit of such societies to elect
has survived from antiquity. The "private" sector has not left us patrons from among their most prominent members and not least
many detailedrecords ofcollective commercial life. Most inscrip- from variousstrataofthepoliticalelite (local andimperial accord-
tions, our main source, are very short, concise and predominantly ing to circumstances). 29 The relationship of patronage cannot be
informative about"public ritual". On the otherhand, the activities reducedto a questionmerely offindingrichcontributorsto cult and
of the semi-official corpora are primarily known from various law convivial activities. Patrons could be asked to intervene in corn-
texts, imperial rulings and administrative decisions. It is only to mercial disputes, offerprotection in social conflicts andsoften the
be expectedthat suchtexts would tend to reflect the main areas of attitudeoftheauthorities.30Likewisecollegesmight,forexample,
direct state involvement in economic life. be employed in various ways to support their patrons in political
Even so, a few examples do survive in the records of collec- contests and conflicts.3'
tive action taken by professional groups not strongly integrated
intotheadministrativeapparatus.A damagedinscription,probably
A web of ties - buildingcommunity
late secondcentury, found nearMagnesiabut most probably from
Ephesos, informs us about a conflict with the bakers in the city. It is possible, however, to focus too much on the exterior role
Apparently a deadlockhadbeenreached:"Thepeople areplunged of collective organisations in the bazaar. Their function was not
into disorder and tumults. " As a last resort, a high-ranking impe-
simply that of defending the members against the outside world.
rial official was made to intervene by the city council and bring
Theirnature wasdual. They were at least as important in serving
"the seditious groups of bakers in the market" to order. 5 A set of
ascentres ofcommunity, assistingtheformationandreproduction
council minutes from Egypt treats of merchants complaining of
of social ties. The shared identity constructed around common
and in effect negotiating about the price they are offered for spin-
participationinculticcommensalitycreateda senseofcommunity
ning yarn to be used for a consignment of cloth requisitioned by
among the membership. It provided a social environment where
the imperial government. 2 Otherexamples include linenworkers
in Tarsus, weavers in Oxyrhynchus and builders in late antique
Sardis.27 Though not amounting to the solid privileges enjoyed 28 Thusa small setofimperialrulings,collectedin theCodexJustinianusundernumber
4.59, forbid the collusion ofcommercial bodieson matters ofprice. I seelittle reason
generally by many guilds in medieval Europe, these examples do to restrict thepossibilityofsuchinformal agreementsamonggroups ofmerchants and
other professionals to late antiquity.
29 CILXIII, 1688 (an equestrian patron for a guild of shippers); 1900, 1911 and 1916
24 !LS 6987 (second or early third century) with Hobenreich 1997:97-1l5. (municipal councillors as patrons ofcollegia); 1954 (a wine merchant, sevir andpatron
25 CIG 2374, translation cited from Broughton in Frank 1933-40, vol. 4: 847. Finley oftheequitesRomaniaswell ashiscollegium); ILS7490(anequestrianoil traderfrom
(l985a: 226 n. 57) wasunduly clismissiveofthe text. But he wasclearly right in arguing Baetica and wine merchant from Lugdunum and patron of the latter coqioration). In
against the vision ot'Rostovtzeff(l957: 178-179) of a capitalist system with an urban general, see Clemente 1972 and De Salvo 1992: 265-287.
labour class on strike against its capitalistexploiters. 30 Van Nijf 1997: 82-iir. The material from Ostia, treated best by Meiggs 1973,
2 P. Oxy. 1414 (late third or early fourth century). chapter 14, is particularly good. C1LXIV, 4144 (second century); CIL VI, 1759 (AD
27 Dio Chrysostomus Or. 34. 21-23 (weavers of Tarsus); van Minnen 1986 (Egyptian 389) and 1872 (AD 206) all show patrons actively defending the interests of their
weavers); Gamsey l998b, chapter 5 (builders of Sarclis). In general van Nijf 1997: collegia.
82-107. 31 Asin Pompeii,Mouritsen 1988:65-68and 175;Jongman1988,chapter7.
248 249
IMPERIAL BAZAAR COMMUNITY

business could take place. Here traders would forge contacts and
find "people to vouch for them". Nothing illustrates this better
than the habit of merchants, trading in foreign cities, of forming
and using communal associations, frequently structured around
their native identities, in their host societies. These not only pro-
vided shelter in a foreign environment, but also furnished traders
with socialconnections.32 Banarasidas,the MughalJainmerchant
mentioned above, settled in several different cities to do business
during his career. But it is characteristic that most of the time . -v'.--.. ';'. -'.-
he was moving within a network of relatively closely connected
sub-castes of the wider Bania community. It was, for instance, in I i .
'.,
this social setting that he found his frequently changingbusiness ' '. ''-.
associates.33
The networks of traders between as well as within cities cannot '. '-. ^'

be mapped with nearly the same precision in the Roman as in


the Mughal Empire. The epigraphic record, our main source, is
simply too fragmented and contains too many gaps. Alexandrian (a)
merchants might certainly be expected to figure prominently in the
corpus ofextant inscriptions. Several literary sources confirm their
commercial significance. Yet they hardly appear at all. 34 Nonethe-
less, there is sufficient material to allow us occasionally to follow
the community-building strategies pursued by Roman merchants
in some detail. Rome and its harbour city Ostia, the greatest mar- LU 0

ket in the Empire, has produced some illuminating evidence, most 0N


<

importantly in the famous Piazzaledelle Corporazioniin Ostiaof LU a:


^ 0
< Q-
the early to high Empire. There, a number of different "ethnic" N a:

groups of merchants and shippers each possessed a small section Is


a.
of a large portico surrounding a temple. The surviving pavement
mosaics give the names of some of these associations: The Ship- SS5!8StS8te8??':

persandMerchantsofKarales;StationoftheSabratensians"andso
on. Thus we see merchants from distantplaces "building"a social (b)
Fig. 5. 1 Piazzale delle Corporazioni
32 Per. Mar. Eryth. 16, first century AD, provides a clear demonstration of the principle. (a), top, view of Piazzaledelle Corporazioni from the theatre in Ostia
Merchants from Muza in Arabia maintained trade links with East Africa by employing
other Arab captainswho hadacquireda base in the foreigncommunity. (b), bottom, plan of the complex (from CIL XIV, suppl. Ostiense: 662)
33 See Habib 1990: 382-383 on Banarasidas. Markovits 2000 studies one such caste
network from the eighteenthto the twentiethcenturies.
34 It is tempting to see many of them lurking among the worshippers of the Egyptian
cults (e. g. Isis) which spread across the Empire. See Noy 2000: 245-251, though too
cautious, for a discussionregardingthe city of Rome.

250 251
IMPERIAL BAZAAR

towards the Persian Gulf and India. In addition, Palmyrene com-


munities did at some point exist in, amongotherplaces, Seleucia,
Babylon and Dura Europos, Coptos and Denderah in Egypt aswell
as in Rome (Fig. 5. 2). 41 The vitality of this network was supported
by a rich communal life centred on the religious and civic insti-
tutions of the "mother" city. Temples of their native gods were
established by the Palmyrenes when temporarily or permanently
resident away from home in the foreign cities. 42 Even as far away ^
as Coptos an inscriptionrecords the existence of what appears to 8
be a religious community building belonging to the Palmyrene M

merchants plying the waters of the Red Sea.43 The impressive


catchofinscriptionsrecoveredatPalmyraoffersilluminatingevi- I
dence of the workings of a moral economy inside this widespread u

merchant network. Several inscriptions found in the desert city's 2I


&.§
grandiose temple of Bel honour euergetists for their benefactions
towards or on behalf of Palmyrenes living in the diaspora. One g)'I
Aqqia was commemorated for erecting a temple in Vologesias. s§
m an
Anotherinscription showsthePalmyreneandGreekmerchantsin q

Seleucia setting up a statue to their leader, who had made bene- 11


d Vs
factions to the temple of Bel. Civic and religious ritual, securely
anchored in the institutions of the "home" city, was used as a tls
&
mediumformaintainingandexpressingsocialrelationshipsinside M£
the merchantcommunity even acrossdifferentlocalities.44 Ut '0
w tj

The practices of Indian merchants of the seventeenth and eigh- fc g,


teenth centuries may help further to elucidate the significance I
of such activities. Cultic and social ritual did not just offer a Q

focal point for establishing contacts and bringing people together.


0
&
41 Young 2001: 140 andR. Drexhage 1988,chapter4. SeeNoy 2000: 234-245 for the
Palmyrene presence in Rome.
42 Dirven 1999 has studied this phenomenon for Dura. 43 Young 2001: 8o-8l.
44 Inv. Palm. IX, 6a (Palmyrene and Greek merchants in Seleucia); CIS 11, 3, 3917 (the
tribe of Gadiboli honour Aqqia for a temple erected in Vologesias). See also CISII,
3, 39'6 and Inv. Palm. IX, ll. The practice should not be dismissed as a Palmyrene
exception.Anotherexampleofsuchcommunalties insidediasporasisprovidedbyan
inscriptionfrom Puteoli (OG/S595, AD 174). It records the attempt by the Tyrians
in Puteoli to exploit their connections with Tyre on the Phoeniciancoast to receive
financial support from its city council. Normally the Puteolan station ofthe Tyrians had
been subsidised by the branch of the diaspora residing in Rome. But this had come
to an end. The Tyrian city council, however, refused the request and decided that an
appealshouldbedirectedtotheRomancommunitytoresumesupportoftheirPuteolan
brothers.

254
IMPERIAL BAZAAR COMMUNITY

!i

ilife
^i^---.. - ; -':. ^'.. "-^.A^®
^^&--L
.

J'^, :< .. :< ?^ '. >. <


v!ff^ .

(d)
Figure 5. 2 (cont.)
'^..: (d), close-up of one of the statue bases with bilingual inscription

-,---, Its effect was much more profound and penetrating. It allowed
the commercial household a means of asserting or improving its
position within the business community. For the ambitious mer-
chant this "meant", to cite C. A. Bayly, "above all, playing an
active and steady part in the temple as well as the bazaar. "45 Life
I '.'. around "the temple" provided a context for merchants to express,

,
al (re)shape and cement social hierarchies within the world of the
bazaar. It was important in stabilising relations and adding sym-
bolic form to an otherwise fluent and opportunistic trading environ-
ment. The universe of the temple offered a vision ofhierarchy in the
world of the bazaar. It was, so to speak, a re-enactment and state-
ment in socio-religious terms of the shape of life in the business
community.
Fig. 5. 2 (cont.)
Such a model seems to capture well the epigraphic habit of
(b), top, view ofthecentral cella (to the right) andthecourtyardofthe
enormous temple of Bel in Palmyra the Palmyrene traders. In the inscriptions of the Bel-temple, the
(c), bottom, section of the Bel temple's portico colonnaded streets and the agora, a very clear sense of hierarchy

45 Bayly 1983: 373.


256 257
IMPERIAL BAZAAR COMMUNITY

among the traders emerges. 46 At the bottom, groups ofmerchants, havealreadyseenhowtheypaidfor temples orfor theperformance
most commonly the members of the caravans, pose as grateful of sacrifices.4
honorants, thanking benefactors for services rendered. Towards No other, or perhapsalmostno other, groupofmerchantswithin
theotherendofthe spectruma selectgroupofcommercialleaders the orbit of Greco-Roman civilisation ever managed to achieve
stand out as patrons of the smaller merchants. They receive pub- such a prominent position, including complete integration in city
lie honour for assisting the caravans "in every way possible". 47 government. That was a function of the uniquely important role of
Thereby their commercial primacy received a symbolic recogni- the rich Oriental luxury trade in Palmyra's economy. However, on a
tion, onoccasion even supported by declarations ofthe local senate. more modestscalesimilarclaimsto socialleadershipinthetrading
They werenotmerely wealthymen in themarket. They werecast world were made by the wealthier merchants across the Empire.
in the mould of community leaders, pillars of merchant society. The inscriptionspresent them actingas benefactorsandpatrons of
This is a role they seem readily to have accepted and reinforced. professionalassociations,andin particularas seviriAugustales,of
The grandees of Palmyra's long-distance trade even undertook to thepolis at large.Weseetheminvestingin munificence,payingfor
organise military expeditions to combat intrusive bedouins, who temples, festivals and dinners to the greater good of the bazaar.49
harassed the caravans. Thus they conformed to patterns commonly In thatway,ashasrecently beenremarked,commercial groups and
linked with Greco-Roman euergetism. Office holding in the city, especially their leaders were able to claim a publicly recognised
for instance, does not seem to have been beyond the reach of the role within the social hierarchy of Roman cities. 50 This motive
top-ranking merchants. Not only did they command local militias, was even more prominent in the status-seeking strategies of Indian
they also held other civic magistracies in the city. In additionwe merchants in the Mughal and especially early colonial era. But the
comparison also invites us to look for the economic significance
of such behaviour. In the world of Indian merchants the financial
46 How to interpret the hierarchy in the inscriptional record has been a concern of several credit and the social prestige enjoyed by a commercial household
scholars during the last century. Rostovtzeff 19326 saw it as evidence of a group of were not easily separable. Failure in "the temple" could easily lead
"merchant princes" in Palmyra. For Will 1957 the merchant princes were not really
merchants. They were more like desert sheikhs using their finances and their control of to serious damage in the bazaar. 51
vast pastures to supply the merchants travelling in caravans with funding and transport Such an experience would probably not have been foreign to
animals. Though free from the modernising connotations of Rostovtzeff's analysis, the merchants in the Roman world. The Latin word for credit was
distinction seems very artificial. The merchant princes of the Italian Renaissance, it
shouldbe remembered, alsocombinedcapitalistactivitieswith aspectsoftheworldof fides. Fides, however, was also a function of the trust and authority
the knights, as the viewer of Donatello's famous, first statue of St George in Florence one was able to command in the sphere of personal relations. The
will know. Young 2001: 149-157is a ratherconfusingandat times muddledcritique.
But he rightly insists that the material does not warrant a clear separation of traders word was one of the key concepts used to describe the relationship
and patron sheikhs. His own interpretation, however, almost eliminating the group between patron and client. 52 It was a social, as well as economic,
of "patrons" and making the caravan leader the most central commercial figure, is
unconvincing. It is also improbable on comparative grounds. It was normal in "rich'
tradesthattheleading,financingmerchantswouldbesedentarywhiletheirapprentices, 4 A prominent example is the commercial and civic leader Soadu; R. Drexhage 1988,
smaller merchants andpeople on the rise wouldbe travelling (van Leur 1955: 62-71; nos. 15 and 16 with pp. 101-102. Seealso CISII, 3, 3942.
Goitein 1967: 156-160; and Das Gupta 1991: 355-356). This is the arrangement we 49 Seviri Augustales: CILXIII, 1960, 1966, 1972; C/LXIV, 3l8 and 397; patrons, benefac-
encounter in Palmyra. Inv. Palm. X, 107 shows Akgar, son of the prominent merchant tions and handouts: C1LXIII, 1954; CILXIV, 4142, 4620-4622; payment for temples
MarcusUlpiusYarhai,conductinga caravanwhilehisfatherprovidesassistancefromhis and other public structures CIL VI, 814, 1035 (with Andreau 1987:122-123)and XIV,
base in Palmyra. The role ofcaravanleaderseemsa sort ofjunior leadershipposition: 2793; Rauh 1993: 289-338.
the culmination of a career for some; for others a stepping stone on the way to the 50 Van Nijf 1997, chapters 4-6. 5I Bayly 1983: chapter 10.
very top. Themerchantprinces,asre-emphasisedby Yon2002,mustbeplacedinthe 52 Skydsgaard 1976 on fides in relation to the conduct of business and credit. A crisis of
context ofa complex interrelationship between steppe andcity - they had a foot in each fides might therefore be a "financial"crisis, the collapse or narrowing of credit, Caes.
camp. BC 3. 1. 2; Cic. De Imp. Cn. Pomp. 19. See further Bang I997b and Verboven 2002:
47 Inv. Palm. X, 44, 107, III. 170-182, 287-330and 349-35I.
258 259
IMPERIAL BAZAAR COMMUNITY

measure of the pulling power and attractiveness of the household partner by performing sacrifices and beginning to observe his reli-
in interpersonal engagementsof all sorts. In their epitaphsRoman gious duties more strictly. Conduct of business and ritual acts are
merchantscanthereforebe founddescribingthemselves asfidelis- overlapping. Thus, he succeeds in depicting himself and his part-
simi. Some emphasise how they had always been open to help ner as sound, responsible people who could be trusted not to waste
friends in need and generous in extending hospitality. Complaints others' money on enjoyments (prostitutes and the like) instead of
about the failure of friends to honour their moral obligations are making profitable investments.
also voiced. It is in the same context that one should understand The world of Roman traders also knew such edifying tales. The
claims that merchants had led blameless, spotless (sine maculd), cult of Hercules was popular among traders. A short story about the
frugal (frugi) or "pure" (castus) lives or that they hadlived together Roman merchant Marcus Octavius Herrenus and his relationship
with their wives sine ulla animi laesione, "without damage to the to the cult of Hercules has been preserved for us in late antique
soul". This was a way of indicating that the household had been commentaries. Macrobius relates how Herrenus, after having had
a healthy and well-administered "enterprise"; its members would success in trade, failed to deliver on his promise of paying a tithe
make for reliable business associates. 53 Honour was integral to the of his profits to the temple of Hercules. During a voyage Herrenus
conduct of trade. 54 encounters a violent storm but escapes miraculously. Afterwards
Investment in social standingcannot, therefore, be dismissedas Hercules reveals to him in a dream that it is he who saved Herrenus
wasteful conspicuous consumption. It was sound business. Main- and conquered the storm. Hence Herrenus dedicates a temple in
taining a prominent position in the ritual and social life of the Rome to Hercules with the epithet "victorious".57 Long-term suc-
business community served to safeguardor improve thefides, the cess in business required proper conduct in the world of religious
credit and honour, of the merchant household. From this perspec- and civic ritual. The popularity ofthe cult ofthe goddess Fides (Pis-
tive, as remarked by C. A. Bayly, "the distinction between bad tis among Greeks) within Greco-Roman bazaars is another very
moral and bad economic conduct disappears".55 The communal visible demonstration ofthis.58 The collective life oftraders in the
activities of the merchants take on importance as a means of pro- empire performedanimportant functionin serving as a vehiclefor
viding the bazaarwith all the trappings of a social system proper. the dissemination of norms and the reproduction of social order
It was not merely a market. It became a social universe foster- anddiscipline among the participants. This can also be seen from
ing a sense of hierarchy and promoting norms of proper conduct the fact that professional associations were normally organisedas
between individual traders.56 The principle can be seen at work miniature replicas of a city state with popular assembly and magis-
very clearly in the autobiography, referred to earlier, ofthe Mughal trates. It was common that members of such societies would refer
JaintraderBanarasidas.In thequotationat the start ofthis chapter, to each other as "friends" or occasionally even as "brothers".59
he tells how he initiated a new business venture together with a

53 See ILS 7480, 7518, 7519, 7530, 7531, 7542 for a selection of expressions used by 57 Macrob. Sat. 3. 6. 11. Fordiscussions, see Rauh 1993: II6-I20and Coarelli 1988: 185-
merchants to describe the moral worth of their households. The link between moral 204. The catch of inscriptions and altars found at Colijnsplaat at the mouth of the
worth, social status and sound management of the household is a central theme in Rhine in the modern-day Netherlands is a good illustration of such activities. These
Greco-Roman moralising, Cicero Off. 2, 52-64 and 86-87; Plutarch Comparison of were dedications by Roman merchants and sailors to the goddess Nehalenia in the
Ansteides and Cato, Horace Senn. I, 2; 2, 3, l66-l8l and Ep. I, 6, 15-42. second/third century AD thanking her for safe passage and return; see Stuart and
54 Plant. Mere. 418-424 and Tab. Vindol. II, 343 connect failure to honour an agreement Bogaers 2001 for a catalogue.
with loss of fides and shame. In the Vindolandaletter the gloss erubescam(I will blush) 58 Rauh 1993: I [ [-112.
is used. 51j Waltzing 1895-1900, vol. 1: 322-333. Kloppenborg and Wilson 1996 passim. The
55 Bayly 1983: 385. organisation of professional associations along city state lines should therefore not
56 See P. Midi. 243. As emphasised by Hasan 2004: 62, collective organisations combined be seen entirely in terms of adherence to the city state, as van Nijf 1997: 68-69 and
economic and social roles. chapters 4-6 does. It was also a matter of creating a parallel society.

260 26l
T

COMMUNITY
IMPERIAL BAZAAR

Members who failed to live up to the societal ideals of the clubs be made to settle commercial disagreements through mediation
risked being fined or in the worst case faced expulsion. by neighbours or arbiters before approaching the official courts,
remained relevant for all of antiquity (and beyond). 4
As socialhierarchiesgrewsteeperandinternal coherencewithin
Courts, arbitration and witnesses the numerous poleis weakened during Roman rule, one may
legitimately surmise that the need for private legal arbitration
The ancientprofessional associations, in otherwords, constituted increased. 5 But very little is known of these practices. Our evi-
small parallel societies. In that respect they shared many of the dence tends to overemphasise the role of the state because its
functions of Indian castes. Both helped to give shape to commer- activitiesproduceda significantbodyoflegalwritingsandjuridical
cial society and create social institutions. One important task was documents.ThebishopsofearlyChristianity,it is clear, attempted,
theadministrationofjustice.Castesservedasjudicialbodiesofthe as part of the care of their congregations, to play the role of medi-
first instance. They would normally seek to regulate legal disputes ator and arbiter among quarrelling members of their flock. The
internally.Onlywhencastegroupsfailedtore-establishsocialcon- very few ordinances of professional associations surviving from
sensus and mediate between litigants was the local Mughal court Roman antiquity, however, leave us very much in the dark about
approached.61 Any judiciary role of Greco-Roman collegia was their part in conflict resolution, and any judgement must remain
never formally recognised to quite the same extent. The corporate conjectural. 7 But there are some strong indications that profes-
character ofthe city state wasfarmore clearly articulated in Greco- sionalassociationsplayeda farmoreactiverole in theprivateadju-
RomansocietythaninIndia.Everypolishaditsownlocalcourtand dication of conflicts than is usually thought. If "guild"ordinances
guarded its political rights within the imperial framework. Only were not normally very detailed, it is still clear that the general
rarely, such as in the case of Jewish diaspora communities, were assembly did, at least occasionally,hearanddecideon complaints
resident subgroups officially granted the privilege of using their raisedby the membership. Oneordinance,for instance,prescribed
own internal courts, though only grudgingly. 62 Even so, the city that members must not raise grievances about one another dur-
state and the imperial government left much room for semi-private ing communal dinners. Festive occasions were to be kept free of
administration and implementation of justice, indeed, depended internal skirmishes. Those should be reserved for treatment by
upon it. Both state institutions had fairly weak instruments of the monthly assemblies. 68 The regulations of an unknown asso-
enforcement available for the resolution of private disputes. In ciation from the village of Tebtunis in Roman Egypt, dating to
most cases it was left to the winning side of an argument to bring the reign of Tiberius, add more flesh to the bones. There a fine
a favourable verdict into effect. Self-help was always a crucial is imposed on one who takes legal action against any co-member
element in ancient justice. This made involvement of the "closest'
communityinmostlegaldisputesinevitable.Itssupportwasallbut 1968; Gamsey 1970; Gagos and van Minnen 1994; and Nippel 1995. See Galanter
indispensableto the litigants anda key factorin making solutions 1981 for an analysis pointing out the critical importance of arbitration, even for the
last.63TheexpectationofPlatoinThe Lawsthatanattempt would functioning of modem judiciary systems. With fewer tools of state enforcement, the
relevance can only have been greater in antiquity.
64 Plato Leg. 92oc-d.
65 Cf. Ziegler 1971: 161-163;Garnsey 1970is fundamental.
60 P. Mich. 243 and Waltzing 1895-1900,vol. I: 378. See Alston 2002: 207-212 for an f>6 See Harries 1999, chapter 10 for how this role continued to shape the character of
excellent analysisofthe intertwined social, cultural, religiousandeconomic functions episcopal justice even after it had been granted some official recognition during the
performed by urban "guilds" in the cities of Roman Egypt.
fourth century.
61 Hasan 2004: chapter 6; Bayly 1983, chapter 10.
67 SeeWaltzing 1895-1900,vol. i: 368-378for a basicdiscussionofthe general assem-
62 JosephusAnt. Jud.XIV, 185-267andXVI, 160-178withCotter 1996:86. blies of these associations where members would consider "toutes les affaires".
63 Finley 1983: 1-49 and 118-121. Gelzer 1912 is still unsurpassed on this, and is no less 68 fLS 7212: "si quis quid queri aut referre volet, in conventu referat".
relevant for the Empire than the Republic (Wallace-Hadrill 1989). Seefurther Lintott
262
263
IMPERIAL BAZAAR COMMUNITY

of the confraternity.69 The collegiumtried to ensure that conflicts that they have found the thieves and put the three outsiders in a
would be settled internally within the collective rather than in a rather awkward position. 71
court setting outside its immediate control. Lifting a conflict out of the immediate community and bringing
The aim of such measures was to contain conflicts and prevent it to a magisterial court carried risks of its own, not necessarily to
them from escalating to a level where they threatened the social be taken lightly. However unfair and hierarchically skewed medi-
order among the membership; the prohibition of prosecuting co- ation within the bazaar might occasionally become, it was still
members is mentioned together with a ban on defaming, intriguing often preferable to the courts. Mediation allowed greater scope for
against or corrupting the households of other members. To judge negotiation and the adoption of flexible solutions to conflicts. By
from Indian examples, such internally organised maintenance of comparison a formal trial was a blunter instrument. With few tools
the social consensus normally reinforced the established order of of enforcement available, an official judge might well handle the
things. Lower-rankingmembers and people on the fringes of the conflict roughly.
community found it difficult to stand up against more prominent
Why do you not judge for yourselves what is right? Thus, when you go with your
merchants.70 The episode set in the marketplace, whichPetronius
accuser before a magistrate, on the way make an effort to settle the case, or you
included in his novel, the Satyricon, suggests that this experience may be draggedbefore thejudge, and thejudge hand you over to the officer, and
was not foreign to the ancient world. The three travelling fictional the officer throw you in prison. I tell you, you will never get out until you have
heroes get embroiled in a commercial dispute with a peasant and paid the very last penny.
his wife involving a fine gown and an old rag. As things get heated
So the faithful are admonished in the Gospel of Luke.7 Pri-
thewiderbazaarcommunity interferes in theconflict. A prominent
vate settlement, as it aimed to restore social consensus, though far
member takes command of the situation. He takes custody of the
from "fair", normally offered a more lenient solution; the prospect
disputed objects until a judge can rule in the case, knowing well
of reaching a successful conclusion improved significantly if an
that the three foreigners, lacking support in local society, would
agreement, at least in some sense, acceptable to all parties could
probably not risk showing up at the trial. In that way, he hopes to be found. Court trials, on the contrary, were the result of failure or
keep the objects for himself. This is slapstick comedy of course.
breakdown in the conflict-solving mechanisms of the social net-
Butthecomedydoesnot ariseoutofa deliberatemisrepresentation
works in which the combatants were enmeshed. They represented
of the social mechanisms involved. Indeed, Petronius depends on
an escalation of strife. Harsher means were required to restore
exploiting these to produce the constant and incredible reversals of
peace in the community. 73
fortune which underpin the burlesque humour of the scene. Just as
The stakes and the risks were higher in a court trial. But on
the main characters of the novel believe that the old tunic, hiding a
average the chances of successfully challenging the reigning dis-
valuabletreasureonly they knowabout,is againwithintheirgrasp,
tribution of power in a community probably did not increase cor-
chaos erupts. The unsuspecting peasant couple suddenly realise
respondingly. Local courts, staffed by judges and juries drawn
that the gown put on sale by the three (anti)heroes hasbeen stolen
from the wife in the first place. Immediately they start shouting 71 Petr. Sat. 12-15, 7. See also P. Oxy. 3814 on the importance of local power to assert
one's rights within the community.
7 Luke 12:57-59 cited from Gagos and van Minnen 1994: 44; further pp. 30-48. Their
analysis, though about late antiquity, is equally valid for the Principate.
73 As rulings usually still required the active collaboration of the community to remain in
(") P. Mich. 243, lines 7-8 with the editor's commentary. P. Mich. 245, the ordinances of force, thejudge would often tend to reinforcethe alreadydominant party but now more
a guild of salt merchants, also indicates internal regulation of disputes. harshly in order to ensure his continued predominance. See Hinton 1966, chapters 3-4
70 Pearson 1976: 147-149 and Hasan 2004:95-99. for a comparative demonstration of this principle.

264 265
COMMUNITY
IMPERIAL BAZAAR

from the ruling groups of a city, could more often than not be not merely be seen as an alternative to private adjuclication. Fre-
supposed to reflect prevailing patterns of influence. The courts of quently, they seem to have been used to reinforce it. Indeed, the
governors and other imperial administrators were less entangled filing of lawsuits often served to scare an opponent into accepting
in local intrigue, but also more distant and with an interest, gen- private arbitration. 78 Among the Murecine wax tablets are some
erally, in maintaining amiable relations with local ruling groups documents pertaining to a business dispute between the banker
since imperial administration depended on the active collabora- Caius Sulpicius Cinnamus and his sometime companion Caius
tion of these. Add to this that the ancient notion ofjustice required Julius Prudens. The case was brought in front of a judge in Febru-
courts in reaching their decisions to take into account the general ary AD 55. A document shows the parties agreeing to transfer
status, standingandcharacterof litigants andthe witnessesappear- the case to private arbitration. Next in the dossier comes a num-
ing for or against them. Lawyers were even expected to play on ber of pronouncements of their chosen arbiter Marcus Barbatius
matters of hierarchy and influence in presenting a case. 74 From an Epaphroditus, setting time, date and location for hearing the case.
individualist perspective, this may seem harsh and unjust, but in Arbitration could be a rather prolonged affair. The dispute had not
a society where the enforcement of rulings usually required the yet been finally settled by March 56. But communications clearly
active collaboration of communities, finding in favour of estab- had not broken down completely. The process of mediation prob-
lished relations of power nevertheless represents a form ofjustice: ably enabled slow negotiations to go on in order to explore the
societal justice. 75 ground for reaching a compromise. 79
These documents remind us that when we think of mediation
The last point deserves emphasis. Even if courts generally
tended to favour and reinforce existing relations of power, they administered by the merchants themselves we need not necessarily
still did so within the context of a discussion of right and wrong. and certainly not primarily focus on the more formal aspects of life
There was thus a chance that occasionally a David might defeat a inside the business community such as the assemblies of collegia.
Goliath. Greco-Roman justice wasnot simply a "donedeal". 76Not The writings of the Roman jurists discuss the arbiter in relation
all contestants, moreover, would have been unevenly matched. So to the concept of a vir bonus, a "good man". It was standard to
courts were used, and sometimes to a surprising extent.77 Private agree on a person of some standing and moral authority within
administration ofjustice with its inclination towards the status quo the community to act as mediator.80Tojudge from the onomastic
was vulnerable to silent obstruction and the forces of inertia. In features of Barbatius' cognomen, he belonged to the same liber-
such cases, an indication of the willingness of one of the parties tine business circles in which the bank of the Sulpicii operated.
to up the stakes and take the conflict to another level might be The formal structure of the social and religious associations of the
just the thingrequiredto break a deadlock. Courts, therefore, need bazaar would most probably not have played any direct role in the
actual proceedings. Collegia and other communal bodies should
rather be seen as providing an environment that enabled "good
74 See Saller 1982, chapters 2 and 5 for patronage; Crook 1995 for the importance of
rhetoric in the practice of Greco-Roman law; Jongman 1988, chapter 6 for an attempt,
perhaps overly schematic, to argue that witnesses to documents were normally listed
according to rank and status. 7 Hasan 2004: 106 shows this for Mughal Surat. Harries 1999, chapter 9 makes this point
75 Geertz 2000, 175-195 for an example anddiscussionof similar phenomena. forcefully for the late Roman world. But her argument applies equally well to the
Principate.
7 Harries 1999: 181-184 makes this point even for the more hierarchical late antique
world. 79 TPSulp. 25, 34-39 and 48 with Camodeca's (1999) editorial comments. Another illus-
77 Some papyri indicatea remarkablenumberof grievancesbeingpresented to governors. (ration ofthis strategycanbefound in the dossierofdocumentscompiled over a number
Often, however, decisions of higher courts consisted in little more than returning the of years by the Jewish woman Babatha in the conflict regarding her son's inheritance.
case to a local forum. This kind of litigiousness, as Harries 1999: 184 observes, needs Petitions for a court hearing are drafted to cajole the unwilling guardians to enter into
negotiations, cf. P. Yacliii 13-15 with Cotton 1993.
to be understood in the context of the complex strategies pursued by local networks of
Dig. 17. 2.6 and 17. 2. 76.
power in a system ofcommunally administered justice.

266 267
IMPERIAL BAZAAR COMMUNITY

men" to stand out and be identifiable. The same considerations of India. 84 But their capital was normally of modest proportions,
are equally applicableto witnesses.Witnesseswhoenjoyed a high confined as they were to household organisation,just as with the
reputation in the bazaar would have been an important asset in merchants. Deposit banking was far from unknown. The small
judicial disputes. Their word carried greater weight andpeople of scale of the overall enterprise, however, imposed strict limits on
low standing in the community would have found it more diffi- the capacity of the banks to turn such deposits into working capi-
cult to get such persons to support their case. Symbolic capital tal. They were always vulnerable to insolvency. Most loans from
which arose out of life in the communal associations of the bazaar banks, though far from unimportant, were therefore short-term.
played an important part in the organisation and maintenance of They can perhaps better be described as financial services together
the commercial order and hierarchy. with money assaying and changing, giro transfers and bills of
exchange, which constituted the core operations of Indian banks
and money lenders in relation to the trading world. Such services
The structure of credit in the community
were not at all peripheral. They eased the workings of commer-
cial life considerably, for instance by facilitating money transfers
In their provision of contacts, symbolic capital, trust and credit,
between localities. But they did not constitute the foundation of
social hierarchy, rules of behaviour, arbitration and witnesses, the
trading capital. That came from the more or less extended house-
communal associations of the bazaar made a significant contribu- hold. 8-5
tion towards the production of "services" necessary to the activities
One common procedure, also practisedby Banarasidasand his
of merchants. These would also have included prospective part-
father, was to devolve a portion of the household fortune onto
ners in business and a network for the provision of extra capital.
a young member of the family or poorer business relation in a
Communal organisation enabled the merchant to access a larger
sort of partnership. With few means of his own, the contribution
pool of resources, social as well as economic, than was under his
of the junior partner consisted of his work. He was expected to
immediate command. But ties of community were far from alone
increase the capital outlay by conducting business, frequently on
in creating the social foundations of business; they overlapped and
long trading voyages. The profits were then to be shared in some
intersected with other forms of institutions. The most important of
way specifiedby custom andpersonal agreement. Suchasymmet-
these was the family and (extended) household.The oikos wasthe rical business partnerships were well suited to the uncertainties
basis of merchant operations.
and irregularities of the bazaar world. By parcelling out the cap-
While social and religious clubs provided an outer shell, so to
ital, the household spread its risks. It also acquired a convenient
speak, for business activities, family and household constituted
and above all fairly reliable means of setting up branches of the
the core. Banarasidas, our Mughal ideal-typical merchant, turned
family business in different cities. By employing persons who
repeatedly to family and relatives to raise his trading capital. 3
would regularly be dependent on the family, and furthermore, by
Banks and money lenders were certainly present in the bazaars
giving them a stake in the financial outcome, the household tried
to ensure that its representative would remain loyal to its interests.
See Bayly 1983: 375 on how merchants with a low standing found it difficult to get This avenue also opened an outlet for surplus capital otherwise
access to arbitration; Hasan 2004, chapter 6 in general for the social bias of courts of
the Mughal qwi. Gamsey 1970 has treated this for the Roman Empire.
Suchactivitiesare,forinstance,envisagedbytheprovisionsoftheSCdeBcicchanalihus 4 Indian banking is the most complex example of a pre-modern bankingsystem. It is
(S. Riccobono et at. (eds. ) 1941, Fontes luris Romani Antejustiniani, vol. I, Florence, therefore a useful benchmark for Roman banking. SeeJain l929;Habib 1972; Goldsmith
pp. 240-241), cf. the perceptive analysis of lines 10-14by Rauh 1993:254. Seefurther 1987; Goody 1996: 72-74 and 94; and Haider 1997, chapter 4.
his chapter 6 and Gabrielsen 2001. 85 Goitein 1967: 161-185 and229-266, though dealing with themedieval Jewishtrading
83 Banarasidas,Ardha-Kathanak,in Sharma 1970:67-68 and72-73. community in Cairo, provides a useful description ofthe structure ofcredit in the bazaar.
268 269
IMPERIAL BAZAAR
COMMUNITY

stored in the bountiful coffers of the Mughal elite. Members of The pattern of credit outlined above is sometimes loosely
the imperial aristocracy sometimes invested or speculated in trade referred to, with a phrase borrowed from the Italian Middle Ages,
through merchants connected with their great households. But as a "commenda"-system.s9 Commendawasthe term usedto des-
it is important not to exaggerate the significance of this. Aris- ignatea particularform ofpartnershipwhereone entrantprovided
tocratic involvement never amounted to commercial dominance.
the capital and the other the work while profits were shared on
One can probably better describe it as a process whereby tenta- a three-quarter to one-quarter basis. In a common variation of
cles spreading outwards from the larger households occasionally the arrangement, funds were contributed two-thirds to one-third,
penetrated the world of the bazaar without ever taking it over. 6 with the junior partner providing the work and receiving half the
Instead a picture emerges of a market sphere with many small profits. 90 Ever since Weber devoted a now classic study to this
individual units, comprising poorer and junior members - often phenomenon, commendahas been closely linked to an evolution-
travelling - of the merchant community. A considerable portion ary story about the rise of capitalism in northern Italy. In Weber's
of these would have been connectedwith larger, more established analysis commendawas treated as a first step towards achieving a
households consisting of senior merchants, richer financiers and separationofhouseholdfundsandbusinesscapital. The legal form
the odd aristocrat. 7
given to commenda contributed to a development which eventually
A different but equally asymmetrical form of credit extended enabled jurists to conceptualise the trading capital of merchants
by the financing segment of the trading world was the bottomry as a fund distinct from and independentof the household, in other
loan, used to finance trading voyages. In return the borrower had words as a firm in the modem understanding of the word. 91
to put up the cargo or sometimes the ship as security. If the ship One needs to make a distinction here. Weber was interested
was lost at sea the money was lost too. Thus the main risk was in how the various specific legal formulas, which developed in
borneby the lender whoreceived very high interestpayments on a the Italian city states, were gradually manipulated and shaped by
successfully completed journey. Rates of 15, 20 or 30% cover the jurists to formthe modemconceptofthetradingfirm. In that sense
normal range. Often such loans would be accompanied by quite commendamay havebecomepart ofa process thateventually saw
detailed instructions for the trip regarding destination, route and the first institutional shoots of capitalism appear in Italy. But in
duration.It wasalsocommonforthelenderto senda representative itself there was nothing intrinsically modern or "developed" about
to accompany the borrower and keep an eye on the investment. the commercial practice of commenda, as Weber was the first to
In effect the bottomry loan was another way of expanding the admit. 92 The researches of Udovitch and Goitein in the 1960$
business of the household without actually having to increase the identified varieties of commenda in Jewish, Byzantine and espe-
size of the firm. Instead, the financierrelied on semi-independent cially Islamic law that pre-dated the Italian practices.93 Used as
agent households. Merchants of more equal means also regularly, a convenient shorthand for the flexible, and frequently asymmet-
when need arose, pooled their resources in partnerships where rical forms of finance described above for India, commenda-style
risk and profit were shared more equally. Though sometimes of financing seems to be a common and very old expression of the
long duration, most of these were only short-term and frequently household-based economy of the bazaar. Our steadily expanding
changingengagements. They never really effected a separation of database on ancient Mesopotamian trade leaves little doubt that
the trading capital and the individual households. 88
89 VanLeur 1955: 62-73. See further Goitein 1967: 170-183.
86 Blake 1991: 109-110 and 117-118, modified by Chatterjee 1996: 66. c)" Lopez and Raymond 1955: 174-184 for a convenient list of illustrative examples of
87 DasGupta 1991 and Raychaudhuri [99[. medieval Italian cornmenda contracts in translation.
88 Banarasidas, Ardha-Kathanak, in Sharma 1970: 71, 107-110, illustrates the transient 91 Weber 19240. 92 Weber 19240:335-339.
nature of partnerships. 93 Udovitch 1962 andfurtherUdovitch [970 andGoitein 1967.
270
271
I
IMPERIAL BAZAAR COMMUNITY

the familiar medieval repertoire of partnerships, bottomry loans the need for a flexible and opportunistic approach to business
and commenda had strong roots in remote Middle Eastern history. and the concern to reduce the risks so characteristic of bazaar
These forms of finance were not in themselves the first step in a households.
development away from the oikos, but rather reflected its needs Another common feature is the high number of actors and the
for spreading risks and flexible adaptation to a shitting environ- relatively circumscribed nature of individual commercial capitals.
ment. 94 The Roman world seems to offer confirmation of this; and A good illustration is provided by a second-century letter sent
the story ot'Greco-Roman commercial credit needs to be fitted into from the Alexandrian banker Marcus Claudius Sabinus to two
this broader picture. The structure of Roman commercial capital merchants from Askalon. 98 The document records the payment of
provides a fairly accurate reproduction of the main features of the a loan of 7 talents 5, 160 dr. on behalf of two Roman citizens to
pattern outlined above based on the bazaarsof Mughal India.95 the two merchants together with their two further companions and
Commercial loans were generally short-term, rarely extended joint shipowners. The sum total is far from negligible, about half
for more than the duration of a single operation. The archive theminimumcensusfor a city councillorin a wealthycommunity
belonging to a group of Sulpicii freedmen bankers resident in and enough to procure some 150 tonnes of wheat - an above-
Puteoli, serving as a harbour for Rome under the Julio-Claudians, average grain cargo, but somewhat less than the capacity of the
offers a glimpse of the situation in what must have been one of the large Alexandrian grain freighters plying the route to Rome. The
busiest markets in the Empire. 96 Two grain traders, Caius Novius merchantspresumablyhadmorevaluablegoodsinmindsincetheir
Eunus and Lucius Marius lucundus, are attested raising money ship was a relatively small merchantman. Whatever the precise
on the security of a couple of medium-sized shipments of mainly natureofthetradingventure, it is highlyrevealingthatthefunding
Alexandrianwheat. Eunus secureda loan of some 13,000 sesterces of such a mid-range operation still saw two lenders sharing the risk
to be repaid immediately on the request of the lender, but only by and required four merchants to combine their resources to carry
handing over control of goods at least 3-4 times the value. lucun- the burden.
dus obtained 20, 000 sesterces for a two-month period by giving Family and extended household partake as important elements
a consignment of goods probably worth twice or three times as in all ofthe above examples from Roman business life. The Sulpicii
much into the custody of the lender. 97 Short timespan and high bank of Puteoli was based on a succession of freedmen relation-
securities are two of the features which are already familiar from ships. Caius Novius Eunus, the freedman trader, maintained rela-
the foregoing discussion of the character of credit in early modem tions to his old master, Caius Novius Cypaerus, who ran a ware-
India. They are a reflection of the close interrelationship between house where his former slave stored his goods." Ofthe four mer-
chants from Askalon, two were brothers. The painted inscriptions
94 Van Leur 1955: 73; Trolle Larsen 1967 and 1976; Goody 1996: 64-69 (in spite of the
on Spanishoil amphoraerecoveredfrom MonteTestaccioin Rome
modernist emphasis); Renger 2003. offer some of the best evidence on the household dynamics ofmer-
95 Cf. the reflections offered by Andreau [ 999: 151. Whatfollows runs counter to Temin
and Kessler 2007, but they mistake the societates publicanorum, the companies of
chantenterprises in the Roman Mediterranean. 100Frequently one
tax-farmers, for merchant companies and ignore the fact that these societates were
exceptional and to a large extent phased out with the advent of monarchy; they cannot
do service as a Roman version of the charteredjoint stock companies of early modem 98 SeeCasson 1986foranedition, translation, commentary andanalysis. Seefurther the
capitalism. discussion by Rathbone 2003: 217-2[9.
9 See Camodeca 1999 and 2003 for an edition and analysis of the archive. Though l» TPSulp.45.
descriptive and mainly derivative of Camodeca's work, Jones 2006 provides a useful '°° It matters little whether thestate wasultimately behindthese imports. Private personnel
introduction and survey of the evidence. conducted the actual transports of oil, at least until the third century. The material is
97 TPSulp. 45 and 5 1-52 (Eunus), 46; 53 + 79 (lucunclus). published in CIL XV and updated in Rodriguez-Almeida 1984: 222-233. De Salvo

272 273
IMPERIAL BAZAAR COMMUNITY

encounters partnerships based on a shared connection to the same Another inscription sports a business partnership of "DD. Caecil-
household, such as "Corneliorum" or "Fadiorum". '01 iorum et Aelii Optati". '04
Occasionallyit is possibleto follow the operationof such"busi- The provisionsofRomanlawaddconfirmationofthevalidity of
nessfamilies"in greaterdetail. Take for examplethe "DD.Caecil- the impressiongainedfrom the Spanishoil amphorae.They recog-
iorum". '02 In AD 149 potsherds document D. Caecilius Matemus nise several varieties of the asymmetrical and parcellised form of
operating on his own. D. Caecilius Hospitalis is also on record capital provision characteristic of commenda and related commer-
trading individually. But in AD 154 the two appear in partner- cial instruments. °5 First, there is the businesspartnership proper,
ship. At this point it is necessary to introduce a feature particularly the societas. This was conceived as a very flexible instrument by
prominent in Roman society - slavery. One might speculate that the Roman jurists. '06 The partnership might be comprehensive or
both or perhaps one of the two were former slaves. In that case, merely cover a single business venture. It was not generally treated
we seem to be faced with a situation where the one or both as as giving rise to an independent economic entity, except in excep-
slaves were provided with capital to set up individual branches of tional circumstances, but was seen mainly as regulating relations
the household. As they proved their worth, they were eventually betweenpartners ratherthan with the "outside"world. Therefore it
set free. But it is clear that they still kept close contacts with the was consensual. If consent was withdrawn, the partnership ceased
mother household, as evidencedby theirbusinesscollaboration. to exist. By the same token, the death of a partner saw the disso-
However, both the cognomina, Maternus andHospitalis, were only lution of the partnership. From a modem perspective, this kind of
rarely used of slaves. Maternus in particular seems to have been partnership looks like a fleeting and transient entity. But from a
common in the Spanish provinces, while the chance of Hospitalis bazaar perspective, what meets the eye is the adaptability of the
being used to designate a slave is marginally bigger. 103 Another instrument which allowed economic actors to adjust quickly to the
possibility, therefore, is that we are looking at the collaboration hazardsandopportunities offeredby a shiftingmarket. Oneyearit
of two freebom male members of the same family, or a mixture might prove expedient to be on your own, while in the next, greater
of statuses. At any rate, freeborn or libertine, the combination of advantages were to be had from pooling resources with one of your
members working individually with occasional collaboration in business connections, as we saw the Caecilii do above. This kind
partnerships between branches of the extended household is char- of partnership also facilitated diversification of risks. One might
acteristic of the flexible patterns produced by a commenda-type. explore opportunities in one line of trade or market together with
system. The presence of slavery modifies, but does not fundamen- one partner, while perhaps employing another part of the house-
tally alter the basicprinciple. Sometimes, ofcourse, suchcollabo- hold capital in a completely different range of products with other
ration also included business contacts from outside the household. partners or on your own.

1992: 183-225 and 255-256 shows the fluidity of partnerships in the Monte Testaccio 4 CIL XV, 3795; further 3951-3952 and 3973. Another example of business household
material. See further Liou and Tchernia 1994. and branches is given by Curtin 1991: 90-96 and 167-169 in his discussion of the
.
0' C/L XV, 3844, 3874. Pompeian producer and merchant of fish sauce, Umbricius Scaurus.
102 CILXV, 3764-3795 for the DD. Caeciliorum. Hospitalis in 3764, Matemus in 3765- 105 Verboven 2002, part 3 is an excellent attempt to understand the institutions of Roman
3766 andjointly in 3768-3781. "business law" as reflecting the honour and trust-based personal relationships of the
103 De Salvo 1992: 219-222 and 251 thinks of traders like Hospitalis and Matemus as household, rather than the needs of proto-modem commercial firms. Crook 1967,
belonging to the Spanish municipal aristocracy. Liou and Tchemia 1994 puncture chapters 6-7, is still useful on commercial life and the institutions of law.
much of the prosopographicalguessworkwhichhas attempted to identify the traders 106 Gaius Inst. 3. 148-154andDig. 17.2. ForsomemoderndiscussionsofRomansocietas
appearing on Dressel 20 amphorae with members of the landed elite in Baetica. The see Johnston 1999: 106-107; Zimmerman 1990, chapter 15. Arangio-Ruiz 1950 is a
names Matemus and Hospitalis are discussedby Kajanto 1965: 79-80. classic.

274 275
IMPERIAL BAZAAR COMMUNITY

The Roman societas, in other words, corresponds quite well arrangement. In Plautus' comedy The Merchant, the father invests
with the flexible patterns we have come to expect from our com- his son with a peculium for a trading voyage. On his return the
parisons and shares many of the formal properties characteristic son is to render accounts, pay back the principal and a share of
of partnership in other commenda-type systems. It also spans a the profits. The remainderis for him to keep. 110Many ofthe basic
wide spectrum of social relations ranging from complete equality characteristics of commenda are clearly present here.
to stark hierarchy. Among the many possible varieties, it should Nevertheless, the peculium is more frequently discussed as a
by now be unsurprising that the jurists recognised something akin way of achieving the limited liability of modem companies and
to a clear example of commenda. It is stated that a partnership can separating the business from the household. By making his depen-
exist between people where one brings the capital and the other dants do business on the basis of a peculium the master would not
the work. Additionally, profits may be sharedby agreement while be responsible for more than the size of this fund, it is claimed/"
loss is wholly borne by the capital investor. '07 In other words, the That is not quite what was envisaged by the Roman jurists. They
arrangement described by thejurists is a commenda in all but name. distinguished clearly between cases where the pater familias had
The only thing missing is that the contract has not been severed either ordered his dependants to conduct a particular business
from the general law of partnership and treated under a separate transaction or put them in charge as managers of a shop or busi-
heading. But that is a matter of legal formalism, not commercial ness enterprise, and cases where their dependants acted on their
practice. 108 own. Only in these latter cases would the liability of the household
Roman law elaborated in greater detail a number of other legal be restricted to the size of the peculium, otherwise liability was for
instruments which, like the unequal partnership, enabled the mas- the full amount, in solidum. As Gaius explained in his introduc-
ter to diversify his interests and devolve part of his capital onto tion to Roman law, if a person had entered into a transaction with
junior members or associates of the household. Most important a dependent person authorised by his master, he could certainly
of these were the regulations concerning agency or business man- always sue him on thepeculium. "But no one would be that stupid",
agersandthe so-calledpeculium}09Thepeculiumdenoteda share he went on, because the master was liable for the full amount irre-
ofthe householdresources given over as a personal fund to people spective of the current holdings of the peculium. "2 A ruling by
in the power of the head of the household, for instance sons and the emperor Alexander Severus upheld this view. Even if a person
daughters or slaves. This could be used much like a commenda was liable up to the amount of a peculium, the emperor observed,
he would still be liable for any enrichment he had drawn from the
107 Dig. 17. 2. 29. pr. -l; 17. 2. 5. 1; 17. 2. 30 and Gaius 3. 149. Santucci 1997 has recently transaction or for the full amount if he had put his dependant in
emphasised the importance of this institution. Reinhardt 1968: 24-68 presents a dis-
cussion of how Roman law came to recognise unequal partnerships. He portrays it in charge of the business. 113
gradual evolutionary terms from Republic to high Empire. This seems to me mistaken.
The principle is clearly attested already from the late Republic. If jurists continue Plaut. Mere. 80-97. At least this interpretation seems the most economical. Plautus
to discuss it, this is due precisely to the unequal social relationship underlying the describes the arrangement in terms of the father equipping the expedition and counting
practice. The more powerful partner would inevitably be tempted in some cases to out money to the son and giving him instructions about the minimum sale price. The
challenge the equality of his junior partner. Similar conflicts appear in discussions excess profit is described as a gain to the son's peculium. But the original capital
of commenda by Muslim jurists, cf. Udovitch 1962: 205 and more extensively 1970, should undoubtedly be seen as having entered his peculium as a debt to the father. It
chapters 3-6. wasthroughthepeculium that a son in potestate wasenabledto participatein business,
Ios Cf. Andreau 1999: 151. cf. Johnston 1999: 99-101.
109 Gaius Inst. 4. 69-74 remains an exemplary introduction to these instruments. The '" E.g. Johnston 1999: 101-105;Zwalve 2002.
relevant text in the Digest are: Book 14 for agency and business managers. Dig. 14.1 "2 Gaius Inst. 4.74, cf. Dig. (Gaius) 14. 5. 1.
(actio exercitoria); 14. 3 (actio institoria); 14. 5; Book 15 deals with the regulations "3 Codex Justinianus IV, 25. 2. Cf. Dig. (Ulpian) 14. 1. 1. 22. A slave forming part of the
concerning thepeculium. Some modem surveys and discussions: Kirschenbaum 1987; peculium of a son in power, still renders the pater-familias liable in full if the latter had
Aubert 1994, chapter 2; Wacke 1994; Johnston 1999: 99-108. The relevant chapters authorisedthebusinessmanagementofthe slave. Businesspursuedwith apeculium, in
of Buckland 1908 are still useful. other words, did not per se limit the liability of the master to the extent of its contents.

276 277
IMPERIAL BAZAAR COMMUNITY

The logic of the relationship between the head of the household Pauline case. But when the slave was acting on his own initiative,
and his agents appears with particular clarity from a case discussed it was important to protect the master from people trying to exploit
by the jurist Paul. A slave had been put in charge of lending out the situation andthereby inflicting a loss onhim. 116That ishowthe
money against security by his master. On his own volition the same limited liability of the peculium fits into economic practice, not as
slave had also begun to offer his services to grain merchants. He a generalised means of investment with limited liability. This is not
would take over their payment obligations towards their suppli- to say, of course, that during conflicts masters would not sometimes
ers. Only now, the slave had run away and one of the suppliers manipulate the rules to their advantage and try to claim limited
demanded payment from his master as liable for the conduct of liability. Inevitably they would, as is clear from the claims which
his business manager. The master denied responsibility since he sparked the two imperial rulings just treated. But such claims had
had not authorised the line of business giving rise to the dispute. no secure backing in law, nor in business practice, it would seem.
During the trial, however, it emerged that the master had under- That is the very clear impression conveyed by the documents in
written the activities of his slave in a range of other areas. The the archive belonging to the Sulpicii bankers. They provide some
prefect of the Roman grain supply, therefore, decided in favour of of our richest information on the employment of slave agents
the claimant. On the appeal, however, the legal councillors were and managers in business. A recurrent feature is the specification
inclined to find in favour of the defendant pater familias since he that a particular activity takes place at the master's command or
had not given a mandate for this particular line of business. But in authorisation. "7 The rules governing the use of business agents
the end, the emperor decided to uphold the sentence because the and the peculium reflected the need of households for a flexible
master had seemed "in everything to have regarded the slave as set of instruments through which to delegate the management of
acting in his name". "4 There is no question here of regarding the
conduct of business through slave agents in general as based on a ' Dig. (Gaius) 50. 17. 133 states the general principle that masters should benefit from
legally sanctioned form of limited liability. 115 their slaves, not receive harm. The jurists had little sympathy for those who inflicted
loss on other people by exploiting, colluding with or taking advantage of their slaves.
The limited liability ofthepeculium must be placed in a different Instead they emphasise the duty to act responsibly and with circumspection in dealing
context. It was an attempt to protect the master from receiving harm with other people's slaves active in business, cf. Dig. 14. 1. 1. pr; 14. 1. 7; 14. 1. 9. Slaves
from his slaves. One of the advantages ofcommencla proper is that acting on a peculiuin, therefore, could not give give away presents or stand surety
unless it was clearly in the interests of their master, cf. Dig. (Ulpian) 15. 1. 3. 5-9. For
it gives the agent a stake in a positive outcome of the business. an analysis, see Kirschenbaum 1987: 27-28 and Buckland 1908: 213-216.
As shown by the Plautine example a similar result could also be E.g. TPSulp. 45, 46, 48, 51. ?8. Cf. the discussion in Jones 2006: 138-142; the
evidence for authorisation is much clearer and more copious than the vague tit-bits
achieved directly through the primary activities connected with he can assemble for independent action with liability limited to the peculium. The
the peculium. A complementary method was to allow the slave, last practice can only be hypothesisecl (not more than that) in a few instances, often
of doubtful interpretation. Thus TPSulp. 25 contains the record of a hearing in front
next to his main operation, to do a little business on the side that of a Puteolan judge between the Sulpicii and one of their business associates Gaius
would enable him to earn money with which eventually to obtain Julius Prudens concerning an unpaid debt. In the record Sulpicius asks Prudens to
confirm that he is the owner of two named slaves. Some years before, Prudens had
his freedom. This seems to be the phenomenon underlying the mandated the Sulpicii to transact with these slaves in his own name (TPSulp. 48). Now
from his reply has been stricken the addition that the said slaves were in his power
"suaque im [sic] potestate". This was to avoid a "noxal action", that is a criminal trial,
"4 Dig. (Paul) 14. 5. 8. Jones explains, with the commentary provided by the editor of the tablets, Camodeca,
"5 The inadequacy of the focus on limited liability also emerges from Andreau's work. and ensure that the case was treated as a civil suit, e.g. an ordinary action on the
On several occasions he has discussed the cause celebre involving the future pope peculium. The actio de peculio, however, is not the sole alternative, some of the other
Calistus. According to Hippolytus (Ref. Omn. Haes. 9. 12.l-l 2) the imperial freedman middleman institutions could equally well be implied. But here Jones strangely ignores
Carpophorus had set up his slave Calistus in banking. When Calistus defaulted and Camodeca's commentary: "Sempre nello stesso ordine di idee di progressi rapporti
fled, his creditors came to the master Carpophorus. In 1999: 67-68 Andreau took this commerciali fra Ie parti si e pero preferito piuttosto pensare all' actio qiiod iussu o
as a case of the limited liability of the peculium. But now (2006: 205-208) he has all' actio institoria" (1999: 86). Avoiding the noxal action might equally well lead to
changed his mind and takes it as a case of full liability for the business manager. Pmdens being sued for the full amount, in solidum.
278 279
IMPERIAL BAZAAR COMMUNITY

its different economic activities/branches to junior members and to monitor the movements of the borrowers. Credit on an entirely
dependants (children, slaves and freedmen). In that respect, they different scale is attested by a papyrus detailing the specific con-
served some of the same functions as a commenda arrangement ditions of another bottomry loan; it was extended to a merchant,
proper. 118 probably in Alexandria, for a round-trip to Muziris in India to
Finally, the bottomry loan was a well-established practice in procure highly prized Oriental luxuries. The value of the cargo
Roman commerce, too; andthe form it took fits well the argument which served as security for the loan amounted to some 7 million
advancedhere abouta generalisedasymmetrical, commenda-sty\e sesterces, 6-7 times the minimum census requirement of a Roman
pattern of finance for the bazaar. "9 It was common practice for senator. To safeguard the investment, the lender had agents sta-
the lender to have a representative accompany the borrower on tioned at several nodal points along the route in Egypt. The terms
the trading voyage, thus reducing the latter almost to the level of specify that the borrower place the goods under the seal of either
a junior partner. One case discussed in the Digest by Scaevola, the lenderor his agentsat the warehousein Coptos while awaiting
an advisorto Marcus Aurelius, saw a slave representative situated shipment down the Nile and again on arrival in Alexandria. In the
in Berytus advancing a maritime loan to a merchant for a trip to preceding damagedsection of the papyrus, there may be mention
Brundisium andbackagain.A slave, Eros, was sentto accompany of further representatives located in the Red Sea harbour where
and supervise the borrower on the journey to make sure he abided the cargo would arrive from India and of a camel driver to take the
by the terms of the agreement. If for some reason, the merchant was goods through the desert. With that sort of economic and organ-
unable to start his return trip before the end of the sailing season, isational muscle, it should have been possible for the lender to
the loan was to be repaid immediately. Eros, the accompanying conduct the trade on his own account. However, by financingthe
slave, would then bring the money to Rome where, presumably, venture of another, he gained one important advantage: he ensured
themasterofthetwo slaves wasliving. Behindthisoperationstood that the man actually travelling to a foreign and far distant location
a financier sufficiently rich to maintain a branch of his household had a significant interest in a successful outcome. The travelling
in a foreign harbour. 120 merchant,on theotherhand,gainedthe advantageofhavingsome-
It is worthwhile emphasising the flexibility and adaptability of one with stronger shoulders carry the ruinous and very real risks
these instruments. Bottomry loans wereemployedto financecom- of losing the capital outlay on the way, to pirates, bad weather or
mercial ventures of very varying scale. The 47, 160 dr. advanced some other accident. 12'
to the four merchants from Askalon wasgiven as a bottomry loan. Thus, allowing for small culture-specific variations, the stmc-
In that case, the lenders do not seem to have had representatives ture of Roman commercial capital can be seen as an example of a
general bazaarpattern which the path-breaking historian of trade
118 The suggestion by Johnston [999: l02-lo8 that masters essentially left the initiative in the Indian Ocean, J. C. van Leur, described for the Indian Ocean
to their slaves as to how to invest the household resources, in order to enjoy limited in the sixteenthandseventeenthcenturies andsaw stretchingback
liability from a position of passivity, is implausible. Roman morality prescribed that
the paterfamilias did not neglect his household and kept a firm hold on the activities
of his subordinates (e. g. Cato Agr. II and IV). A master unable to control his slaves
and freeclmen was an object of condemnation and of ridicule (e. g. Sen. Apocolocyn-
tosis); he was one of the stock characters of Roman comedy. Roman jurispmdents 121 Some basic analyses (with varying emphasis) and text: Casson 1990 and Rathbone
expected masters to take care when setting up slaves in business. Thus UIpian (Dig. 2001. Further Rathbone 2003: 220-221; Young 2001: 54-58 and De Romanis 1996,
I4.3-1 [-4) insistedthat responsibilityremainedwith the master if an institor/agenthad chapter 4. The suggestion by Rathbone that the papyrus describing the terms of the
intentionally damaged the owner in conducting business with an unsuspecting third loan is a general master contract, a generic document which would then serve as basis
party. for drawing up loan agreements for specific trading voyages, is no more than a possible
9 Plutarch Cato Maior 21, 6 and the so-called Muziris Papyrus (Casson 1990; Rathbone hypothesis. The fact that an account of the specific cargo was written up on the versa
2001). after the completion of the journey, seems to me to speak against the inteqiretation of
120 Dig. 45. 1. 122. 1. Two recent discussions, Sirks 2002; Rathbone 2003: 2(6. the recto as a "generic"rather thana specificdocument.

280 28l
IMPERIAL BAZAAR
COMMUNITY

atleastto Hellenistic times. I22It wasa pattern characterised bythe wealth in the composition of elite incomes. In fact, the dominant
predominance of household organisation, fragmentation of capi- trend within Indian studies has been going in the exact opposite
tal in various commenda-like arrangements and transient partner- direction. Here most scholars have been keen to downplay the
ships,butalsobythepresenceofsomeverysubstantial andwealthy extent of involvement by the vast householdsofthe political elite
financiers. I23This,ofcourse,alsoopenedanavenueforoccasional
in commercial activities. They prefer to portray it as a marginal
aristocratic involvement at the financing level, as in India. There
phenomenon precisely in order to assert the vitality, strength and
hasbeenmuch debateabouttheprecise extent ofsuchactivities. '24
potential modernity of the traders of pre-colonial India. '26 That
Many contributions havebeenill guided. Considerable aristocratic
is a curious contrast in the strategies of argumentation. The same
involvement incommerce hasbeenclaimedbythecritics ofFinley phenomenon is ascribed the opposite meaning within each field
as a sign of the economic modernity of the Roman world. 125 But of scholarship in order to make similar claims about the relative
no plausible level of aristocratic interests in trade could possibly modernity of commercial life. The contrast cannot be explained
call into question hismainpoint, thepredominance ofagricultural merely as a reflection of a real difference between the worlds of
the Roman and Mughal lords. In neither empire does the evidence
Rathbone2003: 214-215 and 225-227, on the contrary, postulates a decisivebreak permit a sufficiently solid and detailed reconstruction of the phe-
withHellenisticpractices,inspiteoftheinstitutionalcontinuities,andpreferstoplace nomenon to enable such precise comparison. The contrast, in short,
the Roman phenomena in a context comparable to thejoint stock companies of the
seventeenth andeighteenth centuries. Thatseems excessive andbasedonanargument is a product of different historiographicaltraditions.
from exceptions. The anecdote told by Plutarch of Cato the Elder(Cato Maim 21 .6) This is an indication that the terms of the discussion are
whois allegedto havegroupedfifty merchantborrowerstogetherin a partnership wrong. Occasional aristocratic commercial investments. the extent
before lendingthem money, shouldnot be seenas the norm. Quite thereverse. The
number fifty is a round number, chosen foreffect rather thanverisimilitude, andisused of which must in any case be supposed to have varied signif-
byPlutarch toillustrate Cato'sexcessive andextraordinary zealinmoneymaking. The
otherpieceofkeyevidenceadduced,a rulingpreservedintheDigestona bottomryloan icantly with the opportunities offered by widely different local
(22.2.6),ismisunderstoodbyRathbone.Theattemptbythelenderto claimsecurity circumstances, do not represent a departure from the general
in goods financed by other lenders on other ships does not reflect the existence of a
partnership(andnopartnersarementioned).Thepointisthattheborrowingmerchant shape of the bazaar. '27 Indeed, the great concentration of eco-
had spread his risks by sending his goods on different ships financed by different nomic resources in the hands of the aristocracies in each empire
lenders. Now, thepresent lender hadclaimed whatremained afterrepayment ofthese makes some level of involvement almost inevitable. Wealth on a
otherloansasanadditionalsecurity. Whenthecargoofferedasprimarysecurityto
him waslost, he tried to reclaimhismoney by arguingthat the loss of the cargo, scale implied by the cargo from Muziris could be mustered by
in effect, only amounted to a diminutionof its value andthat the borrowertherefore only few men within the Roman Empire; and of those, the over-
had to make up the shortfall from the other pledged securities. This, however, was
rejected by thejurisprudents since the cargohadbeenlost underthe terms ofthe sea whelming majority will have belonged to the political elite. In
loanandtheriskaccordinglyrestedwhollywiththelender.Neitherofthebottomry the archive of the Sulpicii freedmen bankers, one can actually
loansattestedinthepapyri,incidentally,supportRathbone'sview.Thatinvolvingthe
partnership offourmerchants only represented a very modestconcentration ofcapital, observe a trickle-down of wealth from the imperial household into
whilethe enormous, andexceptional, wealthimpliedby the documentconcerning the business community of the harbour city of Puteoli. '28 On the
the commercial trip to Indiaonly involved one lender and one borrower. It is not an
important distinctionthatsomeRomanfinanciersofbottomry loanshadrepresentatives otherhand,the Indiancomparisonmay serve asa warningagainst
travelling with the lenders; that practice remained common also in the Middle Ages exaggerating the level of aristocratic dominance within the com-
andintheIndianOceantradebeforethejointstockcompanies. mercial life of the Empire. The Muziris cargo, after all, cannot
' The lastpoint merits emphasis since it is often wrongly claimed thatvanLeurdenied
thestructuralimportanceofbigfinanciermerchants(cf.hisanalysis1955:191-227).
SeeColin 2000for a discussionofsedentaryandtravellingmerchantsin theRoman
world. I2(' Chatterjee 1996,chapter3 contraBlake 1991: 117-118.
SeeGamsey 1976;seeWallace-Hadrill1991 for someofthebestcontributions. See 27 SeeBayly 1983:391-393fortheabilityofthebazaarto absorbtheinvolvementofthe
political elite.
furtherD'Arms 1981;Picket1983and 1984;andSchleich1983and
D'Arms 1981. 128 E.g.TPSulp.49,6^,69;Camodeca2003.SeeRathbone2003:219-223forthealmost
certain elite context of the Muziris cargo.
282
283
IMPERIAL BAZAAR COMMUNITY

easily be taken as representative of trade in general. The sheer the great political and financial power of the noble household to
concentration of monetary value represented by this transaction achieve their end. 133
necessarily implies that there would have been very few of these Thus far the basic structure oftrading capital in the Roman world
in any given year. Even so, some very wealthy merchants, rather appears to correspond with our image of the househo\d-commenda
than landed aristocrats, are likely to have existed in the centres pattern of the bazaar with many individual actors, fragmentation
for the richest and busiest trades. One thinks of the small group of capital and a restricted layer of richer financiers. In terms of
of merchant princes known from Palmyra. Below these heights financial services, however, the Roman system does not appear to
there would have been many more operating at a relative distance have developed quite the same array of instruments as existed in
from the households of the political elite.I29 The same banker's the bazaars of Mughal India. The availability of forms of insur-
archive which shows money finding its way into business from the ance was greater in India. But in particular the Indian merchant
emperor's patrimony, also indicates the existence of a commercial had access as a matter of routine to an institutionalised system
community by no meansgenerally dominatedby aristocraticmas- of bills of exchange and cheques known as hundis. These were
ters. 130The most likely scenario, therefore, would see aristocratic negotiable, in principle. In practice many obstacles reduced the
investments going into commercial activities next to those con- extent to which this was the case. The most important function
dueled by various more independent groups consisting of richer of the hundi was to enable cash-free paper transfers of money
merchants andfinanciers- the majority ofwhom wouldhavebeen betweenlocalities. 134Alongthemostfrequentedtradingroutes the
of middling wealth. '3' Suchinvolvement, in fact, blends in rather hundi-system operated quite well. Roman bankers and money
well with the commercial patterns of uncertainty and opportunistic lenders never established so routinely institutionalised a system
distortions by local monopoly groups established in Chapter 3. 132 as this. I35
Merchants and commercial ventures of the great Roman house- Nonetheless, the contrast can be exaggerated. Our sources for
holds would have been able to exploit the political muscle of the Roman banking operations leave many gaps. Much is simply
supporting aristocrat to gain special advantages. They might, for unknown about the detailed activities of Roman bankers. But
instance, have been more difficult to tax than their competitors from more recent research it is becoming increasingly clear that
who lacked the support of a grandee; or they might have found it bankers may have been of greater service to traders than is often
easiermomentarily to cornera specificline oftradeby mobilising thought. 13 For instance, payment not infrequently happened via
a bank account. Thus traders were able, though absent, to receive
and effect payment through their bank representative. Giro trans-
129 Some inscriptional examples of very rich and merely wealthy merchants: CIL VI,
29722; X, 1872; XIII, 1942, 1954, '96o, 2448; XIV, 4142, 4620-4622 (possibly); fers are also a possibility one should not dismiss out of hand.
A£ 1973, 646. D'Arms 1981, 140-148 recognised that for a large number among Many banks seem to have been local, but some bankers had cor-
the wealthiestfreedmen, the so-called seviriAugustales, it was not possibleto claim
aristocraticbacking,Abramenko 1993takesthistoo far; it is inconceivablethathardly
respondents or branches outside their home base which enabled
any freedmen Augustales would have owed theirprivileged position to their connec- them to conduct credit and money transactions across geographical
tion with an aristocratic household. These households were the major slave owners, locations without necessarily having physically to move coin. 137
thereforealsothemainmanumitters in Romansocietyandpotentially providedslaves
with better opportunities for enrichment.
130 E. g. TPSulp. 13-14, 53, 78, 8o. See the balanced treatment of Camodeca 2003 (the .
33 C. 77i. XIII. I, 5, 7, 15, 2i. Whittaker 1993. chapter 12.
Sulpicii,for instance,mayhavehadsomedistantconnectionstooneofthegreataristo- 134 Haider 1997: 185-189; Habib 1972.
cratic families, but as we meet them, they seem to have been operating independently). 35 De Ligt 2002, though he much exaggerates the capacity of the Mughal system, cf.
131 See also Andreau 1999, chapter6 for a discussion of such intermeciiary groups of Richards 1981.
independententrepreneurs and financiers. 13 Contra Biirge 1987andFinley 198511: 141. Andreau 1987is fundamental.
132 See Prakash 1985: 29-34 and 232-234 and Ali 1997, chapter 6 for Mughal nobles 137 The insistence by Rathbone 2003 and Harris 2006 on the importance of various kinds
using their political muscle to .gain from trade. of non-cash transfers in the Roman economy is surely correct. But their observations
284 285
T
IMPERIAL BAZAAR COMMUNITY

Finally the evidence from Roman Egypt, recently treated by Hider- and Pathermuthis your brother and Pallas. Salutations to the father from myself
and the aforesaid. We pray for the health of yourself and all your household all
ato, deserves mentioning. A fair number of papyri document the
your life long. '40
use of a sort of non-negotiable bill of exchange or cheque, a so-
called epitheke, to create short-term credit and effect paper trans-
A dyer, Ammon, contacts his business partner living in a differ-
fers of money between different locations in the province. 138 It
ent location about possibly travelling to the latter's place to buy
would be rash to elevate this into a widely used system of bills wool. However, to do so, he needs to know whether he would
of exchange. However, it does remind us that we risk underesti-
be able to obtain an epitheke, the Egyptian letter of credit, with
mating the intercity transfer of money by credit instruments in the
which to make payment. Furthermore, Ammon requires his partner
Roman world. Though clearly unable to match the Indian hundi,
Dionysius to handle his dealings with other dyers coming to the
the Roman financial instruments do not belong on an entirely dif-
market and inform him to whom he needs to transfer money. Thus
ferent planet. Perhaps they are better viewed as an earlier example
we see Ammon mobilising his personal connections to forward
of a system which gradually reached maturity and became more
his business venture in another place. Without such connections,
institutionalised during the Middle Ages andearly modem period
he would not be able to conduct business there, or only at much
across Eurasia. '39
greaterrisk. Note, therefore, howthe relations withthe partnerare
invested with greater and more enduring meaning by the use of
Compartmentalised networks of trade affectionatemetaphorsto createa senseoffamily, even thoughthe
two were not "brothers", strictly speaking.
This chapter has focused on the social relationships of Roman Personal contacts, or clientelisation as Geertz called it, were
traders, in particular those shaped by the household and commu- all-important in the world of the bazaar. They helped to shelter the
nal associations. The aim has been to demonstrate how the com- merchant in an uncertain and risky market environment. But such
mercial order depended on the ability of its members to form ties contacts worked through exclusion as well as inclusion. Traders
of community. These, both inside or outside the household, were outside the social network of personal contacts were at a disad-
of crucial importance to the success of the individual merchant. vantageor even excluded.In economic terms, the variouspersonal
Whereverhe went, the merchantwould try to use hispersonal net- and communal networks served to lower the transaction costs of
work in order to safeguard and promote his interests. A business insiders while creating higher barriers to entry in the market by
letter, dating to second- or third-century Roman Egypt, illustrates outsiders. Thus communal ties and clientelisation operated to turn
the point: the uncertainties and risks of the bazaar to the advantage of the
traders by reinforcing the fragmentation of business. The result
Ammon to Dionysius his brother, greetings... Provided you know that we could
find a letter of credit at your place in order to pay the money there, I am willing was a tendency towards the compartmentalisation of commerce.
to come to you to pay the wool. I think the other dyers, too, will go there for Trade would often have been conducted within relatively closed
this purpose. When they come, please deal with them on my behalf and write circles and goods would regularly move in separate or parallel
(and tell me) which one you want me to remit the money to. Many salutations channels. 14
from your mother Plousias and your sister Hermione and Amoitas your father

need to be balanced by the evidence which suggests a more limited role, cf. de Ligt
2002. For some cautious observations, see Andreau 1987, chapter 18; Andreau 1999:
42-44; Bogaert 2000; Camodeca 2003. 140 P. Oxy. Hels. 48 (trans. the editors). Hiderato 1999-2000: 94-95 treats the letter in
138 Hiderato 1999-2000 developing Preisigke 1910. relation to epitheke.
139 VanLeur 1955:71-73; Abu-Lughod1989;andGoody 1996,chapters2 and3. 141 Greif 1993. Cf. Geertz 1979.

286 287
T
IMPERIAL BAZAAR COMMUNITY

This is a phenomenon which can sometimes be documented to presumablyviadifferentchannels,to a largenumberofprovincial


a surprising extent from the archaeological record. *42 Italianterra locations. '46
sigillata, that is mould-made and stamped red-slip pottery from In the case of the Pisan productions, the legions stationed on
the late Republic and early Empire, may serve as illustration. Sur- the northern frontier will have been an important market. Simi-
viving in substantial quantities, enjoying a wide distribution and larly closed and separate circuits of supply havebeen suggested in
with finds having recently been collected in a database of more relation to deliveries made of Spanish olive oil to the Rhine army
than 35, 000entries, the distribution patterns ofthis type ofpottery and as a model more generally for how military units procured
can be examined in unusual detail and enable us to go beyond the their supplies. 147 In the analysis presented here, such activities
merely impressionistic. 143 The evidence points to the importance need not necessarily be taken as anomalous, state-induced devia-
ofdifferentnetworks for the distributionofthe products ofdiffer- tions from proper markets. As strategies they were not exclusive
entpotters andproductioncentres. A goodexampleisprovidedby to the state. '48 Rather, they blend well into the broad weave of
two of the larger manufacturers of Italian terra sigillata, P. Cor- personalised ties and social networks which have been described
nelius andL. Gellius. Bothenjoyeda roughlyequaldistributionin as crucial for the functioning of trade in general. In a bazaar envi-
Italy. Theproducts of Cornelius, however,wereexportedin much ronment, lacking the institutional supports developed by capital-
greater quantities to Spain and Morocco, whereas Gellius figures ism, the use of such strategies was an expression of how markets
far more prominently in north Italy and along the Danube. I44 Like- worked.
wise, the products bearing the stamp of MURRIUS, a potter ten-
tatively located in Pisa, are found particularly in NarboneseGaiil, 146 Thedifference,therefore,cannotsimplybeexplainedintermsofgeographyandthe
easier transport afforded by the location of Pi.sa much closer to the sea. Arretine
Hispania Tarraconensis and Africa Proconsularis. By contrast, the
products also travelled widely. Geography and social networks interacted to pro-
contemporary Pisan products ofCn. Ateius Euhodus also find their duce specific patterns. That phenomenon has also been documented for the distri-
way in substantial numbers to the provinces of GermaniaInferior button of the various provincial productions of sigillata in the Gauls and Germa-
nies of the second and third centuries AD, see Rapsaet 1987 and Rapsaet-CharIier
and Superior. 14-5 Euhodus was one of a number of Ateii potters, 1988.
most of them Pisa-based. Together they make up one of the most 147 Remesal-Rodn'guez 1997 (though the evidential base is weak; the numbers are too
small to make the statistical analysiscertain) andWhittakerl994a: 104-113.
prolific groups of producers. Yet their products are not particu- 148 Cf. Lo Cascio 2006 insisting that the state was not simply standing outside "the
larly prominent on Italian sites whereas they seem to have been market . As the biggest landowner, it would have engaged in markets as one, albeit
very powerful, seller ofagriculturalproduceamongothers.
exported in large quantities, not least to the Gennanic provinces.
This points to a more general difference between productions in
Pisa and Arezzo further inland. The former seem to have been
part of a commercial network focused on the north-west Meditcr-
ranean littoral, the Gauls and the Gennanies. Arretine products, on
theotherhand,dominatedtheItalianscene,butwerealsoexported,

142 SeeReynolds 1995: 139andLund 1999for some examplesofthecellularmovemeiit


of goods. Bounegru 2006: 86-88 indicates different domains for different Roman
commercial groups in the Danubian and Pontic area.
143 Kenrick 2000. 144 Kenrick 2000:46-49.
145 See Kenrick 2000 for statistics for potter 292 (Ateius Euhodus) and 1202 (Murriii.s).
However, even with [43 and 122 attested finds respectively, the level of statistical
uncertainty in the analysis of individualpotters is still quite high. A single big finil
couldinfluencethe overall shapeofdistributionpatternssignificantly.
288
289
EPILEGOMENA: TAKING STOCK - THE WORLD OF GOODS

Aristeidean paradigm, so to speak, reached its fullest fruition in


the work of Rostovtzeff, for whom it was the story of the creation
EPILEGOMENA of a liberal, enlightened monarchy that unified the Mediterranean
TAKING STOCK - THE WORLD OF GOODS into one vast economic space - a world market and cosmopoli-
tan bourgeois, capitalist society. Rostovtzeff's construction was
a fragile one. Even in his own analysis the bourgeois order was
constantly threatened by collapse into oppressive and destructive
A French missionary who had viewed these palaces found "it incredible how despotism. Our notion of empire has been caught up in this duality.
rich this sovereign [i. e. the Chinese emperor] is in curiosities and magnificent
objects of all kinds from the Occident". Yet the foreign treasures were only part
A 'primitivist' conception focuses on the exploitative and preda-
of an assemblage that aimed to make the imperial retreats complete with every tory character of empire. 4 'Modernists', on the other hand, have
imaginable creation of nature as well as humanity. As Granet says, even things conjured up a sort of ideal Smithian market economy.5
that no collector could find nevertheless figured there, sculpted or drawn: it was Both dimensions in our image of empire are, in fact, present in
a universal collection of "evocative singularities". Such diversity was directly Aristeides' speech. If the Roman Empire appears as an agent of
linked to the ruler's power.
economic integration, it is not exactly in the liberal, laissez-faire
Marshall Sahlins, Cosmologies of Capitalism, p. 432
sense, which Rostovtzeff envisaged. It is rather as the omnipotent
Here is brought from every land and sea all the crops of the seasons and the commander of the world's resources. The city of Rome is pre-
produce of each land, river, lake, as well as of the arts of the Hellenes and
sented as an irresistible magnet gathering all the globe's variety in
barbarians, so that if someone should wish to view all these things, he must either
see them by travelling over the whole world or be in this city [Rome]. It cannot the imperial centre. If it is not to be found there, it does not exist,
be otherwise than that there always be here an abundance of all that grows and is as Aristeides hyperbolically claims. This is Rome as ruler of the
manufacturedamongeachpeople. .. Whateverone does not see here neitherdid oecumene, a universal empire commanding, collecting and con-
nor does exist.
suming the world's diversity. Such is the Empire's resourcefulness
Aelius Aristeides, To Rome, Or. XXVI, 11-13' and strength that whole regions are laid bare by its demands. In
one ot'Aristeides' oratorical flourishes, the Arabs are depicted as
The blatant flattery and undisguised hyperbole of the second- having to travel to Rome and beg for incense should they wish to
century Greek orator, Aelius Aristeides' eulogy to Rome and enjoya shareofthatluxuriousproductoftheirowncountry. 6 Inthe
her Empire jar with modem sentiments. Students of the Roman universe of the Greek orator market trade becomes an expression
world are now increasingly convinced that Aristeides could not of imperial submissionandtributary obligations. The characterof
in earnest have subscribed to his rosy image of empire. They Roman trade is Janus-faced. Both aspects of the imperial experi-
have started searching for chinks in the rhetorical armour of the ence, greater flow of resources and exploitative command, must
Greek master: anything to suggest the resistance of a cultured be accommodated within the same framework in order to achieve
Hellene to his Roman oppressors. 2 Nonetheless, to generations of a satisfactory understandingof markets, trade andthe economy of
Roman historians the image conveyed by Aristeides' speech has the Roman Empire.
come to embody their view of the second-century Empire. 3 The
4 See Finley 198511: 182-183 for instance emphasising pure exploitation in response to
Keith Hopkins' taxes-and-trade model.
Translationadoptedfrom CharlesBehr (Aristeides,The CompleteWorks, vol. II, 1981) 5 See Persson 1988, chapter 5 for an interesting example of an economist suggesting
andJ. H. Oliver (1953).
parallels between Rome and the later integration of the European economy.
2 See Swain 1996: chapter 8 for a balanced discussion of Aristeides.
6 A different variation ofthis ideological theme isdeveloped in Pliny's Panegyric to Trajan
3 Schiavone 2000, chapters I and 2 draws attention to the central place of Aristeides' 29-32. There it appears in the claim that even Egypt has come to depend on Rome for
speech in Roman historiography.
its grain. The flow of economic resources is perceived within a context of tribute.
290
291
T

EPILEGOMENA: TAKING STOCK - THE WORLD OF GOODS EPILEGOMENA: TAKING STOCK - THE WORLD OF GOODS

It has been the aim of this study to construct such a framework - the Roman Empire. Rather than observing Rome in the traditional
not, however, in the form of a simple middling compromise. A perspective of later European developments, I have been looking
portrait of the Roman world as either a "tailed" version of moder- at the Empire through a Mughal-Indianlens. Perhaps in the pro-
nity or an agrarian economy approaching modernisation would cess Rome has come to look more like seventeenth-century India
be entirely unsatisfactory. Either of these unconvincing alterna- and seventeenth-century India more like Rome than was actually
tives would leave us with an unattractive conglomerate, neither the case. This may well provoke some classicists and historians
this nor that, and would fail to bring us past the current dead- of Indiaalike. It is a widespreadmisperception that the individual
lock in the debate about the Roman economy in general and trade characteristics of a particular culture are always to be considered
in particular. We need to rid our discussions of the implicit and paramount. But cross-cultural similarities should not a priori be
sometimes explicit modernisation narrative undergirdingmuch of seen as any less real than differences. Differences and similarities
the current disagreement. To escape our conceptual impasse we must be handled pragmatically. Whetherto emphasise one or the
need to turn to comparative history, and what is more, a kind of other depends on our questions and the problems we examine.
comparative history which has never before been attempted. We The first chapter argued that, in spite of the obvious cultural con-
need to identify different analytical contexts which resemble the trasts, thepolitical economyoftheRomanandMughalas well as a
Roman situation more closely than the early modem European number of other tributary empires differed in the same fundamen-
world that is normally used as point of reference (cf. Chapter i). tal way from the developing world/state system of early modern
Mughal India is one such possibility. Other pre-industrial empires Europe.
would lend themselves to the same exercise. But the historiog- This shared difference in the political economy of the two
raphy of the Indo-Muslim empire is particularly well suited to empires has been made the basis of the analysis. Comparisons
our purposes. The image of the Great Mughals presiding over a with Mughal India have enabled the identification of a number of
vast and expanding empire based on the floodplains of India has key processes, developments and characteristics which similarly
many features in common with the way Roman hegemony has shaped the economy of the Roman Empire in important ways. This
been understood. However, whereas the liberal, benevolent con- is not to deny that there were important differences between the
ception of Rome hasbeen slow to die, Mughal studieshavehadto Indo-Muslim and Greco-Roman worlds. There obviously were.
struggle with an equally persistent hardcore vision of an exploita- But it suggests that in relation to the fundamental economic pro-
tive, Oriental despotism. The notion of a possible modernity has cesses examined here, such differences are better treated as fac-
only rarely possessed the same plausibility to Mughal historians tors creating variations in the common pattern rather than as the
as it has enjoyed with students of Rome. Their task has there- foundations of entirely different social systems. Greco-Roman as
fore been slightly different. It has been a question of finding an well as Indo-Muslim civilisation have, in other words, not been
appropriate characterisation for a society in which a considerable individually reified as absolute, all defining entities, but rather
transfer of economic resources between regions takes place within treated as similar kinds of imperial high culture which developed
an assuredly, or at least more assuredly, non-modem context. This in response to a shared condition - a social technology designed
has produced an understanding of trade andmarkets that is of use or employed to handlerelated problems arising out of the need to
to us. mobilise the surplus of the peasant masses.7
In Chapters 2 to 5 I have attempted to use examples from In Chapter 2, the Mughal parallel suggested that the economic
the Mughal Empire, occasionally with the inclusion of additional impact of the Roman Empire should be seen both in terms of elite
material from otherplaces,to suggestideal-typesor models forthe
shape and character of markets and particularly intercity trade in 7 See Gellner l988b for such an approach, using the term agro-literate society.
292 293
EPILEGOMENA: TAKING STOCK - THE WORLD OF GOODS EPILEGOMENA: TAKING STOCK - THE WORLD OF GOODS

building and taxation. When that is done, it becomes clear that was achieved by the tributary empires on that account. Though a
the economic integration created by the formation of empire in homogenising influence, the trading world of the Roman Empire
the Mediterranean happened as a consequence of tribute extrac- remained steeped in local and regional practices.
tion. It was not a market-driven process, Ricardo-style, basedon a The many local variations and irregularities, however, must not
steadily deepening interregional division of labour. A hypothetical be mistaken for complete chaos and fragmentation. Instead Mughal
quantitative model helped to demonstrate that there could hardly Indiasuggests that the merchants developed a market form with a
have been room for such a development. The existence of a world particular shapeof its own. It is normally referredto as the bazaar.
empire, to borrow Wallerstein's term, did not so much prevent But it is not the "castrated" phenomenon, sidelined by modem
economic integration per se as create a different interregional flow developments, of petty retailers we meet as tourists in poor Mid-
of the limited agricultural surplus. The function of the market die Eastern countries today. These are only the sad remains of a
was here rather that of serving as a transformer of the politically formerly vibrant commercial universe. The larger bazaars of the
extracted agricultural surplus. In that role market trade greatly agrarianate world included long-distance trade, wholesalers, bro-
facilitated the capacity of the political elite to consume the surplus kers, auctions andspecialisedmoney lenders. However, if modem
outside its production area. capitalist markets have been characterised by a drive to integrate
The second part ofthe study, "Imperial Bazaar",examinedhow separate markets, stabilise and homogenise trading conditions,
this different function ofMughal and Roman traders alike affected increase security and reduce irregularities of trade, the bazaar oper-
the shape of the market world in institutional terms. A key con- ated at a more modest level of ambition. Its ability to transform the
cept was the organisational capacity of merchants. Neither Mughal commercial environment and provide more generally stable condi-
nor Roman traders acquired as solid and influential a position in tions was much less. But, as argued by Clifford Geertz, the bazaar
the political order of their respective societies as early modem merchant was not reduced thereby to the level of a powerless vic-
European traders did. The consequences of this were brought out tim of irregularity. Instead he developed strategies to manage or
in Chapter 3 by an analysis of the clash of European and Indian possibly even take advantage of the situation. The bazaar was a
trading institutions that occurred within the Mughal Empire. The world of many impenetrable, tightly knit groups seeking to profit
more limited social power of Indian merchants made for a lesser from local, most often short-term, monopolies. The much dis-
ability, on average, to integrate markets. Individualmarkets in the cussed famine in Antioch during the visit of the emperor Julian
Mughal Empire were therefore more prone to violent short-term presents us with precisely this form of commercial speculation.
fluctuations and were characterised by considerable fragmenta- The chapter therefore concluded by suggesting the bazaar as a
tion. It was a less predictable trading environment than gradually general model for the workings of Roman commercial life.
began to emerge in the Dutch and later British-led European world- The mechanisms and strategies developed by the bazaar mer-
system. This model wastested, to the extent that waspossible, with chants in the face of irregularity were explored further in the two
positive results on Romanmaterial, includingprice series from the following chapters. Chapter 4 examined the relationship between
province of Egypt. From here the parallel with Mughal Indiawas bazaar and state through the process of customs collection. On
expanded to include consideration of the ability of the imperial the basis of the Mughal comparison it was portrayed as a balance
apparatus to homogenise coinage, laws and measures. Often the of power. In spite of the customs collector's proverbial abusive-
Roman Empire has been seen as creating an institutionally uni- ness, the ability of merchants to go elsewhere did impose some
fiecl economic space in the lands surrounding the Mediterranean. limits on his exactions. Though far from satisfying modem notions
The Mughal comparison helped bring out the clear limits to what of security this balance of power did provide a fragile order that

294 295
EPILEGOMENA: TAKING STOCK - THE WORLD OF GOODS EPILEGOMENA: TAKING STOCK - THE WORLD OF GOODS

enabledtradeto take place. Ifthe imperial state didnot providethe the concept ofthe bazaaris farfrom exhaustedby that approach. It
level ofguaranteesofferedby thebourgeoisstate, the merchantsof canbedevelopedin otherdirections, too. Inthepopularperception
the bazaarcompensated by developing private forms of order and the bazaar is primarily a world of a bewildering variety of exotic
organisation. This was treated in Chapter 5, whichexplored com- rarities and enticing luxuries, a universe speakingto and stimulat-
munity building and social networks among the merchants in the ing the senses through fine, expensive cloths, delicate handcraft
bazaar. The focus was on communal structures and the household. and aromatic, colourful spices. That reputation is well earned and
By comparing Indian caste with Roman collegia it was suggested is closely connected with sumptuous forms of imperial expendi-
that a significant economic role underlay the often-noticed pre- ture. The dominance in societies such as the Roman and Mughal
dominantly socio-religious character of Roman professional asso- of consumption by the patrimonial households of the landed elite
ciations.Thoseassociationswereimportant in creatingor support- andthe emperorhadmore than institutional effects on the imperial
ing structures of community among the merchants; social norms bazaar. It also shapedthe world of goods in fundamental ways.
were disseminated, privatejudicial arbitration and credit possibly It is often stated that only with the advent of capitalism did
made available. The household, too, was an important source of trade across longer distances in ordinary commodities, staple
socialsupport. It providedthebasisofcommercialcapitalandfitted goods that is, become important;8 in the preceding aristocratic
into a hierarchicalpattern of commenda-stylefinancing.However, world, trade was only a question of luxuries. Outside the Euro-
by fostering clientelisation, to use Geertz' expression, both sets of pean Middle Ages, though even here there are grounds for hes-
institutions reinforced the fragmented shape of the bazaar. They itation, this view is in need of substantial revision. Both the
benefited insiders while making it very difficult for outsiders to Roman Empire and Mughal India knew large flows of staple
penetrate markets. This would have created a tendency for goods goods - not, however, of the generalised production and market-
to be channelled into compartmentalised and separate circuits of ing of goods aimed at the expanding mass-market of the middle
distribution.
classes that came to fruition during the seventeenth and particu-
This studyhasaimedtoprovidea differentcontextforourunder- lariy eighteenth centuries in, for example, Holland and England.9
standing of market trade in the Roman Empire. The prolonged But the consumption of elite income and imperial tribute did
battle of the modernists and primitivists has tended to descend intensify patterns of urbanisation and increase demand for sta-
into a quarrel over quantities: much or little, important or unim- pie goods. The Mughal and Roman emperor or grandee were in
portant? This is beside the point. Clearly large quantities of goods public view, their power constantly displayed in lavish expendi-
did move about in the Roman Mediterranean and markets served
ture on pageantry, public buildings(temples, markets etc. ), private
an important function in the empire. But the aristocratic and trib- "palaces" and large numbers of servants and retainers to provide
utary order hadvery differentneeds from capitalism. Thoseneeds
fashioned the shape of the world of market trade in a particular Israel 1989attemptstocountertheexclusivefocusonstaplegoodsinmanydescriptions
way and promoted distinct commercial patterns which differed of Dutch capitalism.
from the evolving capitalism of early modem Europe in signifi- 9 Describedby McKendrick,BrewerandPlumb 1982. See KIoft 1996and Morley 2007:
39-4&for a discussion of ancient forms of consumption. Yet, while it is important not to
cant ways. Roman tradewasnot bourgeoisor capitalist. It tookthe write ancient luxury consumption off as a trivial economic phenomenon, we still need
form of market exchange characteristic of the civilised societies concepts to distinguish different cultures of consumption, instead of simply elevating
modernmiddle-classconsumptionto the universal model. Pomeranz2000, chapter3, for
of the agrarian world: the bazaar. instance, finds greater similarity between early modern Chinese and European patterns of
The bazaar, however, does not only represent a particular way of consumption, with Indiahaving a much steeper hierarchy of consumers. However, with
the consolidation of the Ch'in dynasty, the Chinese pattern becomes more "imperial",
organising trade. Institutions have been the focus of this study. But less egalitarian and "bourgeois".

296
297
EPILEGOMENA: TAKING STOCK - THE WORLD OF GOODS EPILEGOMENA: TAKING STOCK - THE WORLD OF GOODS

a suitable backdropfor the grand spectacle of aristocratic life. 10If animals and spices frequently imported from afar and even beyond
thevisionofempireclaimedcommandoftheworld'sdiversitythat, the confines of the empires. '2 Palmyrene grave goods provide
too, included the availability of men and women in abundance - ample documentation for the import of Chinese silks into the
as servants, craftsmen, entertainers, producers or just audience. Roman Empire via India. Spices and incense were other products
All this increasedthe sizeofurbanpopulations. The top end ofthe which the Romans imported from the East. 13
urban hierarchy, in particular, saw the creation of some very big The notion of the marvellous and the singular was central to this
conurbations swelledby the enormous expenditureofthe emperor kind of consumption. Monarchs and aristocrats delighted in the
andleadingaristocrats.The luxury ofimperial culturenecessitated presentation of wonderful and sensational specimens of animals
the mobilisation of large urban populations to serve its needs and and objects. Scattered across the memoirs of the Mughal emperor
hencecreated a demandfor substantialstaple imports to the impe- Jahangir are many expressions of satisfaction prompted by the
rial capitalsandsomeothercitiesthathadoutgrowntheproduction reception of such objects:
capacity of their hinterlands. ' '
ThisdayDilawarKhan'ssoncamefrom Patan. . .andpaidhomage,presenting a
The idealofuniversalempirewasactedout in thelifestyle ofthe Kachhi horse. It was extremely well formed and easy to ride. No horse this good
emperor, closely emulated by the different strata of the landed elites had been presented since I came to Gujarat... On this day my son Shahjahan
to thebestoftheirvaryingfinancialcapacities.Aroundtheimperial showed me a pomegranate and a quince he had been brought from Farahabad.
court andthe great households of the leadingnobles an extremely Until now nothing this big had ever been seen. '4
elaborate culture of luxurious consumption evolved. It was based
on abundance and artistic refinement in art, handicrafts and haute
Ostentatiousexpenditureby thearistocratwasmeantto impress
andto dazzlenotonly thecommonfolk butalso, andmore impor-
cuisine,notto mentionlove-makinganderoticismaswell asphilo-
tantly, his peers. Roman and Mughal nobles joined in competi-
sophical reasoning. Of course there were differences in emphasis
tion over who could stage the most impressive, surprising and
between the two courtly cultures. Not every register was played to
extraordinarydisplays. The fashions of luxury were driven by the
the same extent or in the same way. The art of calligraphy, as any
agonistic impulse of the political elite. Occasionally one would
visitor to the Taj Mahal will testify, was far more important to the
see attempts to curb this competitive urge to consume. Sumptu-
Muslim Mughals than to Roman emperors who on the other hand
ary laws and moralising discourse, harping on the corruption of
promoted human sculpture to a much larger extent, to the benefit
manners or the frenzy of fashion and teaching personal restraint,
oflaterEuropeanmuseums. Butbothcultures setgreatstore by the
served intermittently to reinforce cohesion among the aristocra-
availability of the most valuable, prized and exotic luxuries such
cies and to protect their members from committing financial sui-
as precious stones and metals, expensive colours, rare materials,
cide in a kind of gigantic imperial potlatch. True nobility, that
was the message, depended on more than the mere ability to
See Blake 1991 on Mughal courtly consumption. Friedlander 1921-3 passim pio- spend. '5
neered the study of Roman styles of consumption, e. g. vol. I: 33-35; vol. 2, chap. xi,
and attempted to sever it from the realm of moralistic condemnation and fantasy. An
important point of his was that modern capitalist consumption had exceeded Roman.
Veyne l976b istheclassictreatment ofpublic munificencein the Hellenistic andRoman Dalby 2000: I aptly notes that "a geography of luxury runs though the literature of
worlds. For modem analyses, see Gamsey 1994, chapters 8-9 (food); Toner 1995 imperial Rome". Unfortunately his book is mainly descriptive rather than analytical, a
(leisure); Edwards and Woolf 2003 (the various aspects of imperial Rome). Weeber catalogue of ancient literary references.
13 Schmidt-Colinet, Stauffer and AI-As'ad 2000.
2003; 2006 is a useful, but mainly descriptive, survey of Roman luxury consumption.
'' SeeHabib& Raychaudhuri[982: 170-171and Richards 19930:28onthemainMughal 14 The Jahangirnama, trans. Wheeler M. Thackston, Oxford, 1999, p. 251. Phlegon's
cities and strongholds. On Mughal urban hierarchies and revenue flows: Moosvi 1987, Bookof Man'els (conveniently translated by William Hansen, Exeter, 1996)is a good
chapters 12-13; Blake [987; Richards 1987 (contributions of Blake and Richards); on example of Greco-Roman fascination with the strange and extraordinary.
Roman: Woolf 1997. 15 On these aspects of elite consumption, see Edwards 1993, in particular chapter 5.
298 299
EPILEGOMENA: TAKING STOCK - THE WORLD OF GOODS EPILEGOMENA: TAKING STOCK - THE WORLD OF GOODS

Since Sombart wrote his now classic work on Luxury and Cap- aristocratic entitlement to prestige goods, though they did that too.
italism, it has become customary to see modem middle-class con- Their aristocraciesmobilisedmarkets successfully to obtain access
sumption as emerging out of the tension between the democratic to a widened range of luxuries to adorn their dwellings and grace
force of fashion and the rearguard actions of aristocratic groups their ambience. The elaboration of the culture of consumption did
trying to limit competition by making key status markers their not, in their cases, lead to any notable middle-class challenges
legal preserve. As the Middle Ages gave way to the early modem to their hegemony. It is true that Roman satirists never seem to
era in Europe, old styles of aristocratic living became obsolete. tire of lampooning the unworthy upstart. Pride of place is taken
Wherefeudalnobleshadgloriedin the sizeoftheirretinues,early by Petronius' famous literary portrait of the stupendously wealthy
modem elites placed a growing emphasis on refinement in hous- freedman Trimalchio who, in spite of his riches, fails miserably
ing, dining and courtship. At the end of this process, aristocratic to win respect in the eyes of the aristocratic readership; his social
privilege gave way to bourgeois spending. Consumption became pretensions are held up to ridicule and terminate in farce. But, as
increasingly shaped by the middle classes and access to the mar- Paul Veyne argued long ago, the fleeting class of freedmen could
ket. 16In theoretical terms, this represented a shift in the culture of hardly represent a serious social challenge to the Roman elite. 9 It
consumptionfrom a coupon-to a fashion-regulatedsystem. Access did,however,providea convenienttargetof scornagainstwhichto
to prestige goods was not reserved to groups with particular privi- reaffirm elite identity. There is nothing intrinsically "democratic"
leges and entitlements (coupons). Instead the ability to follow the about fashion-driven consumerism. The Roman and Mughal ver-
changing dictates of fashion came to define high status. 17 sion served, rather, to consolidate the position of the imperial aris-
However, there is a danger of imposing too teleological a view tocracies and increasethehierarchicalgradientin society. Adam
on these developments. While the rule of fashion may in some Ferguson, one of the Scottish Enlightenment philosophers, under-
contexts serve to break down established hierarchies and widen stoodclearly thatthe emergingcommercial societyofhis ownday
participation to include broadergroups, there is nothinginevitable was something different from the Roman past. "The manners of
or automatic aboutthis outcome, not even in theEuropeancontext. the imperial court, and the conduct of succeeding Emperors will
The possession of vast retinues remained central to the Roman and scarcely gaincreditwiththose whoestimateprobabilitiesfrom the
Mughal nobles as they diversifiedtheir habits of consumption. standard of modem times", he commented of Rome.
The dichotomy of stable coupon and dynamic fashion systems Here again the bazaar, with its emphasis on the irregular, seems
seems too crude to do justice to the Roman and Mughal experi- a useful prism through which to observe the imperial styles of
ence. Both imperial societies were far too complex and dynamic consumption rather than treating them in an analytical framework
to rely primarily on law and established convention to regulate derived from the emerging middle-class consumer revolution of
the seventeenth, eighteenth and nineteenth centuries. One aspect
This view of the history of European consumption was anticipated by Ferguson in his ofthe repertoire ofgoods in the bazaaris the relatively low degree
Essay on the History of Civil Society of 1767, part sixth, section III (1995: 238-241).
17 Cf. Appadurai 1986: 32. But as his own discussion, pp. 23-41, indicates, the operation of standardisation. But merchants could also turn this characteris-
offashiondoesnot necessarilyunderminearistocraticdominance.Thepolardistinction tie into a virtue by stressing the unique properties and particular
betweencouponandfashionmay usefully capturethedifferencebetweenmany simple
societies known from anthropology and modem consumption; it is less well suited to quality of their products. That enabled them to respond to and
understand differences between complex agrarian, or as I prefer to call them, agrarianate,
societies. 19 Veyne 1961. Cf. Nicolet 1980 on the lack of a middle-class "challenge"to the Roman
18 Horace, Serm. 1, 100-130, by literary conceit, considered himself fortunate that he was aristocracy.
sufficiently unimportant to be able to travel without a huge retinue. Yet, Horace, the 20 See Qaisar 1967 for the steep economic hierarchy of the Mughal Empire. Gamsey
'simple-Iiving' poet of high equestrian substance, still took his modest meal served 1970remains fundamental on the intensification of social hierarchiesunder the Roman
by three(!) slaves. See Blake 1991, chapters 2-4 on the importance of the great noble imperial monarchy.
households in the Mughal Empire. 21 Ferguson 1799, vol. 5: 404 (with Pocock 2003: 410-411).
300 301
EPILEGOMENA: TAKING STOCK - THE WORLD OF GOODS EPILEGOMENA: TAKING STOCK - THE WORLD OF GOODS

cultivate the demand of the imperial courts and aristocracies. The - facilitated the creation of public authority and the cultivation
ideological principle underlying this form ofconsumption is neatly of elevated character, they also served as a test of nobility. These
captured by C. A. Bayly: rare, often foreign and always ruinously expensive products were
Whereas modern complexity demands the uniformity of Levis and trainers, the surrounded by a dangerous aura; they were difficult to manage and
archaic simplicity of everyday life demanded that great men prized difference control. Only the truly noble character knew how to master them,
in goods .. . and sought to capture their qualities. Modem "positional"goods are that was the claim. This belief was preached among the elites to
selt-referential to themselves and to the markets that create demand for them; the bolster their confidence and preserve their sense of exclusivity.
charismatic goods of archaic globalization were embedded in ideologies which
transcended them. In one sense archaic lords and rural leaders were collectors
Therefore the use of prestige goods was enveloped in complex
rather than consumers. What they did, however, was more than merely to collect
rituals and civilisational codes. Intricate and many of them tacit,
becausepeople,objects, foods,garmentsandstyles ofdeportmentthusassembled the rules of decorum were all important: "Let no one rashly claim
changed the substance of the collector... [the archaic lord aimed] strategically as his the art of dining. "26 These words Horace, the protege of
to consume diversity. 22 the arbiter of taste at the Augustan court, Maecenas, with double-
edged irony put into the mouth of one of his satirical characters
The collection and consumption of exotic rarities and novel
products was, like Pliny's Historia Naturalis, a cultural manifes- who is exposed as having failed himselfto grasp the true content
tation of the wide reach of imperial might. 23 As such this activity of what he was admonishing. Money was only a prerequisite to
formed an important part of the self-fashioning of Roman and participation in polite society. Exterior possession ofknowledge of
Mughal nobles as gentlemen and as men of power who were the proper manners and rituals of consumption was a "give-away"
and socially inhibiting in higher circles. Horatian satire merci-
free of ordinary constraints and could realise the full potential
of human life in all its aspects. 24 "Clothes maketh the man", as lessly exhibits the failings of the trite big spender who, for all his
display of luxuries, falls far short of the civilisational idiom and
the expression goes. Luxury goods were thus imbued with cer-
tain charismatic, mystical or even magical properties; they were therefore comes across as vulgar and embarrassing. A host who
culturally invested with transformative capacity. Expensive spices bores his guests with long lectures on the splendours ofthe dinner
he is serving them, instead of trusting their refinement and abil-
andotherrare natural substanceswere regularly used in medicine,
muchofit basedonhumoraltheoriesofbalancingbodilyelements. ity to appreciate the delicacies on their own, is trying too hard to
Equally, precious goods were used extensively in religious ritual. impress.27 The secret to social success wasthe effortless mastery
of the art of consumption which came from an internalisation of
The burning of incense, and other fragrant substances, was a staple
of solemn ceremony. 25 the proper manners, acquired through long exposure. The great
man was no mere commoner who had become rich. He was a con-
While such esoteric goods - "evocative singularities" as
Marshall Sahlinscalledthem in the epigraphto theseepilegomena noisseursurroundinghimselfwithall thetrappings ofhighculture
andknowinghowto put themto theirproper andbalanceduse, the
true embodiment of their spirit. 28
22 Bayly 2002:52-53.
23 SeeBeardandHenderson2001:96-105andchapter4 for someobservationson power
and the art of collecting in ancient Rome.
24 See Finley 1985(1, chapter 2 for the relevance of the gentlemanly ideal for ancient HOT. Serm II, 4, 35: "nec sibi cenarum quivis temere arroget artem" (trans. Frances
economic history; Blake 1991,chapter5 and Richards 1984on gentlemanly aristocratic Muecke, Warminster, 1993). Decorum is a key concept in Cicero's De Officiis, a manual
culture in the Mughal Empire. on the proper gentlemanly conduct. An example of a Mughal gentleman's manual is
25 As Miller 1969, chapters 1-2, made clear, much of our evidencefor the ancient spice provided by Husain 1913 (with the analysis of Blake 1991: 130-132).
trade is derived from medical treatises, e. g. Galen's De Antidosis. Forthe central position 27 Hor. Serm. II, 8.
of humoral theories of the body to the consumption of food, drink and medication, see 28 AsVeblenremarkedinhisTheoryoftheLeisureClass(1899:47):"thegentlemanmust
further Galen, On the Properties of Foodstuff's and On the Natural Faculties II, 8. consume freely", "of the right kind" and"in a seemly manner".
302
303
EPILEGOMENA: TAKING STOCK - THE WORLD OF GOODS EPILEGOMENA: TAKING STOCK - THE WORLD OF GOODS

The patterns of consumption developed by the aristocratic lead- and the considerably fewer merchants traversing the Middle East
ers were emulated by local elites across the empires and in some and Indian Ocean to bring back each year a fairly limited num-
areas trickled even further down the social hierarchy. Trade in fine ber of more valuable cargoes. 34 In the latter case, the increased
food grains and fruits, Kashmir! shawls, Bengali muslins, silks demand created by the development of imperial styles ofconsump-
from Gujarat and other prestige goods catered to the demand of tion marks a conjuncture in the history of old-world long-distance
the households of Mughal noblemen, wmindars, rural leaders and trade. It is in the Roman period that the pattern familiarfrom later
service gentry of the small towns.29 In the Roman Empire, the ages of precious metals flowing eastwards in return for Oriental
ruins of Pompeii document how the "high" styles of decoration spices, incense and cloth really takes shape and matures. From
were emulated by middling urban households, though of course in India as well as other foreign locations, these goods and many
a modifiedversion. 3 In the Gaulic provinces Roman-style goods, more arrived in the Roman world, particularly through Egypt and
in a limited range, also made their way to the more prominent Syria, with Alexandria and the caravan city of Palmyra as impor-
peasants such as village leaders.3' The dissemination, portrayed tant commercial hubs. 35
by Paul Zanker, of imagery andstyles related to the imperial court This basic system was to endure for centuries, though the for-
across Roman provincial societies was perhaps, rather than the tunes of individual centres fluctuated. By the sixteenth century,
result of propaganda, an expression of the wish by local grandees Palmyra had long since slipped back into obscurity and stopped
to participate in this culture of consumption, acquire the substance playing any role in long-distance trade. That function was now
of universal hegemony. 32 As courts and aristocracies set new stan- served by Aleppo while Cairo had eclipsed Alexandria as the
dards for prestige objects, the range and diversity of material cul- main market in Egypt. Since Roman times, this trade had gone
ture expanded, as archaeologists will testify, in both empires. through several ups and downs. But underneath the movement of
Thus, the imperial bazaar does not only offer a different insti- ebb and flow, the system had continued to develop and expand,
tutional context for our understanding of markets, it also opens a not least under the aegis of the creation of a vast Muslim ecumene
window to a different world of goods, a distinct culture of con- stretching from North Africa into Central Asia andIndia.3 With
sumption. Under the Romans, this is what unites the marketing the consolidation of the strong imperial monarchies of the Ming
of large quantities of the mould-made terracotta tableware known dynasty in China, the Ottomans in the Mediterranean, the Safavids
as terra sigillata, one of the most common artefacts of Roman in Persia and the Mughals in India, the pace and size of old-world
archaeology, and the imports of spices, cloths and ivory from the long-distance trade received new stimulus from increased demand
greater region of the Indian Ocean described in the Periplus Maris during the fifteenth and sixteenth centuries. It was to tap into the
Erythraei.33 As a concept, the bazaaris broad enough to accom- wealth of this trade in general and to cut into the profits earned
modate both the peddling of small batches of ornamented, red-slip by the Venetians in their capacity as the leading middlemen in
tablewares by traders travelling with a few pack animals between the Levantine trade in particular that Europeans, spearheaded by
the rural fairs and numerous villages of the Roman countryside,
34 The enormous values concentrated in relatively small quantities of Eastern prestige
29 Bayly 1983, introduction and chapter l; l986b: 297-302. goods are best documented by the so-called Muziris Papyrus which records a single
30 Wallace-Hadrill 1994, chapter 7. 3I See Woolf 2001 for this suggestion. cargoworthalmostHS7 million (7 times theminimumfortunerequirementfor a Roman
3 See Zanker 1988 on dissemination of styles; Morley 2007: 46-49 on the importance of senator). For edition and translation see Casson 1990 and Rathbone 2001.
imitation. 35 Raschke 1978 surveys much of the evidence and provides a sceptical antidote to the
33 As a concept the bazaar allows us to steer clear of some of the modernising connotations most optimistic speculations and wildest guesses hazarded about this emerging trade.
implied by using the modern notion of globalisation - as does Hingley 2005 - to See Tchemia 1992 and 1995; De Romanis 1996; Yong 2001 for a selection of more
understand the Roman Empire. There were some significant differences between the recent work on Rome's Oriental trade.
two processes. See Casson 1989 for the modem standardedition of the Periplus. 3 Chaudhuri 1985and 1990;Abu-Lughod1989;Curtin 1984.
304 305
EPILEGOMENA: TAKING STOCK - THE WORLD OF GOODS

the Portuguese, circumnavigated Africa and stumbled on America.


Neither of these events, as used to be thought, brought down the
old system which, after some initial disruption, continued to func- BIBLIOGRAPHY
tion. 37 But the establishment of commercial empires in the Indian
Ocean, notably by the Portuguese, the Dutch and the English,
combined with the arrival of American silver, did begin to modify
the contours of the pre-existing pattern. From the late seventeenth
century, this process intensified and European traders began to Abramenko, A. 1993, Die Municipale Mittelschicht in kaiserz. eitlichen Italien,
subject and transform the old system more deeply. 38 That spelled Frankfurt.

the end of the "imperial bazaar". The Mughal Empire thus stands Abu-Lughod, J. 1989, Before European Hegemony. The World System A. D.
1250-1350, Oxford.
at the end of a historical conjuncture which, irrespective of some
Adams, C. E. P. 1995, "Supplying the Roman Army: 0. Petrie 245", Zeitschrift
earlier preliminaries, came into its own for the first time under the
fiir Papyrologieund Epigraphik 109, pp. 119-124.
Romans. This adds historical depth to our comparison. For these 2007, Land Transport in Roman Egypt. A Study of Economics and Adminis-
were two tributary empires whose trade and markets followed tration in a Roman Province. Oxford.
similar patterns; they shared the world of the imperial bazaar. Adams, J. 1994, "Trading States, Trading Places: The Role of Patrimonialism
in Early Modem Dutch Development", Comparative Studies in Society and
//toorv36, pp. 3i9-355.
37 Das Gupta and Pearson 1987; Prakash 1997, introduction. See Periin 1993 for some
further, if perhaps occasionally too grand, observations on this world. Adanir, F. 1997, "Der Zerfall des Osmanischen Reiches", in A. Demandt (cd. ),
3 Bayly 2004, chapters 1-2 are now fundamental. Steensgaard l973a remains the best Das Ende der Weltreiche. Von den Persern bis zur Sowjetunion, Munich,
structural analysis, and further 1987. This also expandedthe quantities involved enor- pp. 108-129.
mously. In Zosimus' account of Alaric's first siege of Rome (V, 41, 4), a ransom was
Ain-i Akhari, by Abu'1-Fazl Allami, translated into English by H. Blochmann,
agreed involving the payment of 3,000 pounds of pepper. By implication this was sup-
posed to represent a very substantial consignment of the spice in late antiquity. By the ed. D. C. Phillott, 3 vols., 2nd edn, Calcutta, 1939.
end of the seventeenth century, the combined annual imports to Europe of the Dutch Akerlof, G. 1970, "The Market for 'Lemons'", Quarterly Journalof Economics
andEnglishEastIndiaCompaniesamountedto some7 million pounds, seeSteensgaard 84, pp. 488-500.
l99oa: 120. Obviously, these figures are not directly comparable. But there is no way Alam, M. 1986,The Crisis of Empire in MughalNorth India, NewDelhi.
to estimate total annual Roman pepper imports, so we are left with impressions. They
Alam, M. and Subrahmanyam, S. (eds. ) 1998, The Mughal State 1526-1750,
suggest a change in the orders of magnitude; the Roman ransom would not have made
a huge impression in the eighteenth century. As Gibbon concluded (1993, vol. 3: 277
Delhi.
and chapter 31): "the improvement of trade and navigation has multiplied the quantity 2000, "Witnessing Transition: Views on the End of the Akbari Dispensation",
andreduced the price [of pepper]". in Panikkar,Byres andPatnaik, pp. 104-140.
Alcock, S. 1993, GraeciaCapta. The LandscapesofRomanGreece,Cambridge.
i997a> "Greece: A Landscapeof Resistance?", in Mattingly i997a, pp. 103-
"5.
(ed.) l99?b. The Early Roman Empire in the East, Oxford.
Alcock, S., D'Altroy, T., Morrison, K. D. and Sinopoli, C. M. (eds.) 2001,
Empires. Perspectivesfrom Archaeology and History, Cambridge.
Alfoldy, G. 1977, Konsulat und Senatorenstand unter den Antoninen. Proso-
pographische Untersuchungenzur SenatorischenFiihrungsschicht,Bonn.
Ali, M. A. 1975, "The Passing of Empire: The Mughal Case", Modern Asian
Studies 9, pp. 385-396.
1985, The Apparatus of Empire. Awards of Ranks, Offices, and Titles to the
Mughal Nobility, 1574-1658, Delhi.

306 307
BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY

1986-7 "Recent Theories of Eighteenth Century India", Indian Historical Andreau, J., France. J. and Pittia, S. (eds. ) 2004, Mentalites et choix economiques
Review 12, 1-2, pp. 102-1 10. des Romains, Bordeaux.
l997> The Mughal Nobility under Aurangzeb, Delhi (1st edn, 1966). Anctreau, J. and Hartog, F. (eds. ) 1991, La cittu antica? La Cite antique. Opus
Alston, R. 1995, Soldier andSociety in Roman Egypt, London. 6-8, 1987-9.
1998, "Trade and the City in Roman Egypt", in Parkins and Smith, pp. 168- Ankum, H. 1972, "Quelques problemes concemant les ventes aux encheres en
202. droit Remain classique", Studi in Onore de Gaetano Scherillo l, Milan,
2002, The City in Roman and Byzantine Egypt, London and New York. PP. 377-394.
Amin, S. 1973, Le Developpement inegal, Paris. Aperghis, M. 2001, "Population- Production- Taxation- Coinage. A Model of
Amouretti, M. C. and Brun, J. P. (eds. ) 1993, La Production du vin etde I'huile en the Seleukid Economy", in Archibald et at., pp. 69-102.
Mediterranee [Oil and Wine Production in the Mediterranean Area}, Actes 2004, The Seleukid Royal Economy. The Finances and Financial Administra-
du Symposium International organise par Ie Centre Camille Julian et Ie t'wn of the Seleukid Empire, Cambridge.
Centre Archeologique du Var, Aix-en-Provence et Toulon, 20-22 novembre Appadurai, A. (ed. ) 1986, The Social Life of Things. Commodities in Cultural
1991, Athens and Paris. Perspective, Cambridge.
Amphores romaines et histoire economique. Dix ans de recerche. Collection de Arangio-Ruiz, V. 1950, La societa in diritto romano, Naples.
1'Ecole Fran§aise de Rome 114, Rome 1989. Arasaratnam,S. 1986,Merchants, CompaniesandCommerceonthe Coromandel
Anderson, A. C. and Anderson, A. S. (eds. ) 1981, Roman Pottery Research Coast 1650-1740, Delhi.
in Britain and North-West Europe. Papers Presented to Graham Webster, 1990. "Recent Trends in the Historiography of the Indian Ocean", Journal of
Vols. 1-2, BAR International Series 123, Oxford. World History 2, pp. 225-248.
Anderson, P. 1974, Lineages of the Ahsolutist State, London. Archibald, Z. H. et at. (eds. ) 2001, Hellenistic Economies, London.
Andre, J. -M. and Baslez, M. F. 1993, Voyager dans I'antiquite, Paris. Atsma, H. and Burguiere, A. (eds. ) 1990, Marc Block aujourd'hui: Histoire
Andreau, J. 1974, Les Affaires de Monsieur Jucundus, Rome. comparee et sciences societies, Paris.
1980, "Reponse a Yvon Thebert", Annales ESC, pp. 912-919. Aubert, J. -J. 1994, Business Managers in Ancient Rome. A Social and Economic
1987, La Vie financiere dans Ie monde romain. Les metiers de manieurs Study, Leiden.
d'argent (IVe siecle av. J. -C. -IlIe siecle ap. J. -C. ), Rome. (ed. ) 2003, Taches publiques et entreprise privee dans Ie monde romain,
1994a, "La cite romaine dans ses rapports a 1'echange et au monde de Geneva.
1'echange", in Andreau, Briant, Descat et al., pp. 83-98. 2004, "De 1'usage de 1'ecriture dans la gestion d'entreprise a 1'epoque
l994b, "L'ltalie imperiale et les provinces; desequilibre des echanges et romaine", in Andreau, France and Pittia, pp. [27-148.
flux monetaires", in L'halie d'Auguste a Diocletien. Collection de 1'Ecole Aubert, J. -J. and Sirks, B. (eds. ) 2002, Speculum luris. Roman Law as a Reflection
Frangaisede Rome 198, Rome, pp. 175-203. of Social and Economic Life in Antiquity, Ann Arbor, MI.
I995. "Vingt ans apres L'Economie Antique de Moses I. Finley", Annales. Ausbiittel, F.M. 1982,Untersuchungenw denVereinenimWestendesrmnischen
Histoire, Sciences Sociales 50, pp. 947-960. Reiches. Kallmiinz.
;997> "Deux etudes sur les prix a Rome: les "mercuriales" et Ie taux d'interet", Autour de Coptos. Actes du colloque organise au Musee des Beaux-Arts de
in Andreau, Briant, Descat, et al., pp. 105-120. Lyon (17-18 mars 2000). Topoi. Orient-Occident 3, Supplement, Lyon,
1999- Banking and Business in the RomanWorld, Cambridge. 2002.
2003, "Lescommer^ants, 1'eliteet la politiqueromainea la fin delarepublique Aymard, M. (ed. ) 1982, Dutch Capitalism and World Capitalism, Cambridge.
(IIIe-Ier siecles av. J. C. )", in Zaccagnini, pp. 217-243. 1990, "Histoire et comparaison", in Atsma and Burguiere, pp. 271-
20o6, "Roman Law in relation to Banking and Business: A Few Cases", in 278.
Bang, Ikeguchi andZiche, pp. 201-214. Baechler, J., Hall, J. and Mann, M. (eds. ) 1988, Europe andthe Rise of Capitalism,
Andreau, J., Briant, P., Descat, R. et at. (eds. ) 1994, Economie antique. Cambridge.
Les echanges dans I'Antiquite: Ie role de I'Etat, Saint-Bertrand-de- Bagnall, R. S. 1993, Egypt in Late Antiquity, Princeton, NJ.
Comminges. 2000, "Governmental Roles in the Economy of Late Antiquity", in Lo Cascio
Andreau, J., Briant, P., Descat, R. et al. (eds. ) 1997, Economie Antique. Prix and Rathbone, pp. 86-91.
et formation des prix dans les economies antiques, Saint-Bertrand-de- Bagnall, R. S. and Frier, B. W. 1994, The Demography of Roman Egypt, Cam-
Comminges. bridge.

308 309
BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY

Bagnall, R. S., Helms, C. and Verhoogt,A. 2000, Documentsfrom Berenike,vol. 19860, "The Middle East and Asia during the Age of Revolutions, 1760-1830",
I: Greek Ostrakafrom the 1996-1998 Seasons, Papyrologica Bruxellensia Itinerario 10, 2, pp. 69-84.
31, Brussels. i986b. "The Origins of Swadeshi (Home Industry): Cloth and Indian Society,
Bairoch, Paul 1993, Economics andWorld History: Myths and Paradoxes,New 1700-1930", in Appadurai, pp. 285-321.
York. 1988, Indian Society and the Making of the British Empire, The New Cam-
Bajekal, M. 1990,"TheStateandtheRural GrainMarket in EighteenthCentury bridge History of India 2, I, Cambridge.
Eastern Rajasthan", in Subrahmanyam 19903, pp. 90-120. 1989, Imperial Meridian, Harlow.
Balasz E., 1964, Chinese Civilization and Bureaucracy. Variations on a Theme, 2000, "South Asia and the 'Great Divergence'", Itinerario 24, pp. 83-103.
New Haven, CT. 2002. "'Archaic' and 'Modem' Globalization in the Eurasian and African
Banaji, J. 2001, Agrarian Change in Late Antiquity, Oxford. Arena, c. 1750-1850", in A. G. Hopkins (ed. ), Globaliwtion in World
Banerjee, K. K. 1990, "GrainTraders and the East IndiaCompany: Patnaand its History, London, pp. 47-73.
Hinterland in the Late 18th and Early 19th Centuries", in Subrahmanyam 2004, The Birth of the Modem World 1780-1914. Global Connections and
i99oa, pp. 163-189. Comparisons, Maiden, MA and Oxford.
Bang, P. F. 19970, Antiquity between "Primitivism" and "Modemism", Ar- Bayly, C. A. and Bayly, S. 1988, "Eighteenth-Century State Forms and the
bejdspapirerCenterforKulturforskning,AarhusUniversitet, no. 57,Aarhus, Economy", in Dewey, pp. 66-90.
www. hum. au. dk/ckulturf/pages/publications/pfb/antiquity. htm. Bayly, C. A. andSubrahmanyam,S. 1990, "PortfolioCapitalists andthePolitical
[99?b, "Aristokrati og handel i status-modellen - et clientela-perspektiv", Economy of Early Modern India", in Subrahmanyam i990a, pp. 242-265.
Historisk Tidssknft 97, i, pp. 1-28. Bayly, S. 1999, Caste, Societyand Politics in Indiafrom the EighteenthCentury
2002a,"RomansandMughals- EconomicIntegrationin a Tributary Empire", to the Modern Age, The New Cambridge History of India 4, 3, Cambridge.
in De Blois and Rich, pp. 1-25. Bean, G. E. 1954, "Notes and Inscriptions from Caunus", Journal of Hellenic
2002b, "Trade and Industry", Classical Review, n. s., 52, I, pp. 97-100. Studies 74, pp. 85-110.
2004, "The Mediterranean: A Corrupting Sea? A Review-essay on Ecology Beard. M. and Henderson, J. 2001, Classical Art. From Greece to Rome, Oxford.
and History, Anthropology and Synthesis", Ancient West and East 3, 2, pp. Bekker-Nielsen, T. 2004, The Roads of Ancient Cyprus, Copenhagen.
385-399. Beloch, K. -J. 1886, Die Bevolkerung der griechisch-romischen Welt, Leipzig.
2006, "Imperial Bazaar: Towards a Comparative Understanding of Markets in Berktay, H. 1991, "Three Empires and the Societies They Governed: Iran, India
the Roman Empire", in Bang, Ikeguchi and Ziche, pp. 51-88. and the Ottoman Empire", Journal of Peasant Studies 18, 3/4, pp. 242-263.
2007, Trade and Empire - In Search of OrganisingConcepts for the Roman Bharadwaj, K. 1985, "A View on Commercialisation in Indian Agriculture and
Economy", Past and Present 195, pp. 3-54. the Deve\opmentofC&p\talism", Journal of Peasant Studies 12, 1, pp. 7-25.
Bang, P. P. and Bayly, C. A. (eds. ) 2003, "Tributary Empires in History: Compar- Bitterli, U. 1991, Die "Wilden" unddie "Zivilisierten", Munich.
ative Perspectives from Antiquity to the Late Medieval", Medieval History Bj0rkelo, A. 1999, "Noen karakteristiske trekk ved 0konomisk virksomhet i Det
Journal 6, 2, special issue. osmanske riket", in Bang et at., pp. 121-143.
Bang, P. P., Ikeguchi, M. and Ziche, H. G. (eds. ) 2006, Ancient Economies, Blake, S. P. 1979, "The Patrimonial Bureaucratic Empire of the Mughals", Jour-
Modern Methodologies. Archaeology. Comparative History, Models and nal of Asian Studies 39, pp. 77-94.
Institutions, Bari. 1987, "The Urban Economy in Pre-Modern Muslim India: Shahjahanabad,
Bang, P. F. et al. (eds. ) 1999, Agrarimperier mellem Marked og Tribut. Den Jyske 1639-1739"; Modern Asian Studies 21, 3, pp. 447-471.
Historiker 86/87, Aarhus. 1991; Shajahanabad. The Sovereign City in Mughal India, Cambridge.
Barbour, V. 1966, Capitalism in Amsterdam in the ijth Century, Ann Arbor, MI. BlazquezMartfnez, J. M. and Remesal Rodnguez,J. (eds. ) 1999-2001,Estudios
Barker, G. and Mattingly, D. (eds. ) 1996, Farming the Desert: The sobre el Monte Testaccio (Roma), vols. 1-2, Barcelona.
UNESCO Libyan Valleys Archaeological Survey, vols. 1-2, Tripoli and Bloch, M. 1934, "Une etude regionale: geographie ou histoire?", Annales
London. d'Histoire Economiqueet Sociale6, pp. 81-85.
Bay, A. 1972, Den Romerske Finansadministrationfra Augustus til Hadrian, 1967, Land and Work in Medieval Europe. Selected Papers by Marc Block,
vols. 1-2, Horsens. trans. J. E. Anderson, Berkeley and Los Angeles.
Bayly, C. A. 1983, Rulers, Townsmen and Bazaars. North Indian Society in the Blois, L. de and Rich, J. (eds. ) 2002. The Transformation of Economic Life
Age of British Expansion7770-7870, Cambridge. under the Roman Empire. Proceedings of the Second Workshop of the

3io 3"
BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY

International Network Impact of Empire (Roman Empire, c. 200 B. C. -A. D. Buckland, W. W. 1908, The Roman Law of Slavery. The Condition of the Slave
476), Amsterdam. in Private L(IWfrom Augustus to Justinian,Cambridge.
Bogaert, R. 2000, "Les operations des banques de I'Egypte romaine", Ancient Barge, A. 1987, "Fiktion und Wirklichkeit: Soziale und rechtliche Strukturen
Society 30, pp. 135-269. des romischen Bankwesens", Zeitschrift der Savigny-Stiftung fur Rechts-
Boserup, E. 1965, The Conditions of Agricultural Growth. The Economics of geschichte. Romanistische Ahteilung 104, pp. 465-558.
Agrarian Change under Population Pressure, London. Burke, P. 1988, "Republicsof Merchants in Early Modem Europe", in Baechler,
1981, Population and Technology, London. Hall and Mann, pp. 220-233.
Bounegru, 0. 2006, Trafiquants et navigateurs sur Ie Bas Danube etdans Ie Font Burton, G. P. 1975, "Proconsuls, Assizes and the Administration of Justice under
Gauche a I'epoque romaine, Wiesbaden. the Empire", Journal of Roman Studies 65, pp. 92-106.
Bradford Welles, C., Fink, R. 0. and Gilliam, J. F. (eds. ) 1959, The Excavations Butcher, K. 1988, Roman Provincial Coins. An Introduction to the "Greek Impe-
at Dura-Europos final report, 5, pt. I: The Parchments and Papyri, New ricils". London.
Haven, CT. Byres, T. J. 2000, "Pre-Capitalist Economic Formations and Differential Agricul-
Brady, T. A., Jr. 1991, "The Rise of Merchant Empires, 1400-1700: A European tural Productivity: A Tentative Hypothesis", in Panikkar, Byres andPatnaik,
Counterpoint", in Tracy, pp. I 17-160. pp. 239-275.
Braudel, F. 1972, The Mediterranean and the Mediterranean World in the Age Byres, T. J. and Mukhia, H. (eds. ) 1985, Feudalism and Non-Eiiropean Societies,
of Philip II, vol. I, London. London.

1981, The Structures of Everyday Life. Civilization and Capitalism, vol. I, Cagnat, R. 1882, Elude historique sur les impots indirects chez les Romains
trans. S. Reynolds, London. jusqu'aux invasions des barbares d'apres les documents litteraires et
1982, The Wheels of Commerce, Civilization and Capitalism, vol. 2, trans. S. epigraphiques, Paris.
Reynolds, London. Calder. W. M. and Demandt, A. (eds. ) 1990, Eduard Meyer. Leben und Leistung
1984, The Perspective of the World, Civilization and Capitalism, vol. 3, trans. eines universal Historiker, Mnemosyne \ 12, Supplementum, Amsterdam.
S. Reynolds, London. Camodeca, G. 1999, Tabulae Pompeianae Sulpiciorum (TPSulp. ); Ediz. ione crit-
Braudel, F. and Spooner, F. 1967, "Prices in Europefrom 1450to 1750", in E. E. ica dell'archivio puteolano del Sulpicii, 2 vols., Rome.
Rich and C. H. Wilson (eds. ), The Cambridge Economic History of Europe, 2003, "II credito negli archivi campani: il caso di Puteoli e di Herculaneum ,
vol. 4, chapter 7, pp. 374-486. in Lo Cascio, pp. 69-98.
Braund, D. 1993, "Piracy under the Principate and the Ideology of Imperial CapogrossiColognesi,L. 1990, Economicantichee capitalismomoderno, Bari.
Eradication", in Rich and Shipley, pp. 195-212. 1995. "The Limits of the Ancient City and the Evolution of the Medieval
Breckenridge, C. A. and Veer, P. van der (eds. ) 1993, Orientalism and City in the Thought of Max Weber", in Cornell and Lomas, pp. 27-
the Postcolonial Predicament. Perspectives on South Asia, Philadelphia, 37.
PA. Carandini,A. 1981, "Sviluppo e crisi delle manifatturerurali e urbane", in Giar-
Bresson. A. 2000. La Cite marchande, Bordeaux. dina and Schiavone, vol. 2, pp. 249-260.
2003, "Merchants and Politics in Ancient Greece: Social and Economic i983a, "Columella's Vineyard and the Rationality of the Roman Economy",
Aspects", in Zaccagnini, pp. 139-164. Opus 2, pp. 177-204.
Brimnes, N. 1997, "Traditionaliseringen af Indien", Den Jyske Historiker 77/78, i983b, "Pottery and the African Economy", in Garnsey, Hopkins and
pp. 13-29. Whittaker, pp. 145-162.
Bruhns, H. 1985, "De WemerSombart a Max Weber et Moses Finley: LaTypolo- 1988, Schiavi in Italia. Gli strumenti pensanti del Romanifra tarda repubblica
gie de la ville de consommation", in Leveau, pp. 255-274. e media impero, Rome.
Bmhns, H. and Nippel, W. (eds. ) 2000, Max Weber und die Stadt im Kulturver- 1989, "Italian Wine and African Oil: Commerce in a World Empire", in Klaus
gleich, Gottingen. Randsborg (ed. ), The Birth of Europe, Analecta Romana Institiiti Daniel,
Brunt, P. A. 1990, Roman Imperial Themes, Oxford. Supplementum 16, Rome.
Biicher, K. 1911, Die Entstehung der Volkswirtschaft, 8th edn, Tiibingen (first Cartledge,P.,Cohen,E.E.andFoxhall,L. (eds. ) 2002,Money, LabourandLand.
published 1893). Approaches to the Economies ofAncient Greece, London.
1922, "Zur griechischen Wirtschaftsgeschichte", in K. Biicher, Beitrage 7,ur Casson,L. 1968, Review of Rouge 1966, American JournalofPhilology 89, pp.
Wirtschaftsgeschichte, Tubingen, pp. 1-97. 359-364.

312 313
BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY

1974' Travel in the Ancient World, London. Clemente, G. 1972,"IIpatronatonei collegiadell'imperoromano", StiidiClassici
1984, Ancient Trade and Society, Detroit, MI. e Orientali 21, pp. 142-229.
1986, "New Light on Maritime Loans: P. Vinclob G. 19792 (=SB VI 9571)", Coarelli, F. 1988, // Foro Boario, Rome.
in R. S. Bagnall and W. V. Harris (eds. ), Studies in Roman Law in Memory Colin, X. 2000, "Commer^ants itinerants et marchands sedentaires dans
of A. Arthur Schiller, Leiden, pp. 11-17. 1'Occident romain", in Lo Cascio 2000a, pp. 149-161.
1989,The PeriplusMansErythraeie, ed., trans. andcommentaTybyL. Casson, Corbier, M. 1991, "City, Territory and Taxation", in Rich and Wallace-Hadrill,
Princeton, NJ. pp. 2i1-239.
1990 "New Light on Maritime Loans: P. Vindob. G 40822", Zeitschnft fiir Cornell, T. and Lomas, K. (eds. ) 1995, Urban Society in Roman Italy, London.
Papyrologie und Epigraphik, 84, pp. 195-206. Cotter, W. 1996, "The Collegia andRomanLaw: StateRestrictions on Voluntary
Cerati,A. 1975,Caractereannonaireetassiette deI'impotfonderaubas-empire, Associations, 64 BCE-200CE", in Kloppenborg andWilson, pp. 74-89.
Paris. Cottier, M. 2003, "Le ferme des douanes en Orient et la lex portorii Asiae", in
Chastagnol, A. 1992, Le Senat romain a I'epoque imperiale. Recherches sur la Aubert, pp. 215-228.
composition de I'assemblee et Ie statut de ses memhres, Paris. Cotton, H. 1993, "The Guardianshipof JesusSon ofBabatha:Roman and Local
Chatterjee, K. 1996, Merchants, Politics and Society in Early Modern India, Law in the Province of Arabia", Journalof Roman Studies 83, pp. 94-108.
Leiden. Coulton, J. J. 1987, "Opramoas and the Anonymous Benefactor", Journal of
Chaudhuri, K. N. 1978, "Some Reflections on Town and Country in Mughal Hellenic Studies 107, pp. 171-178.
India , ModernAsian Studies 12, pp. 77-96. Crawford, D. J. 1971, Kerkeosiris. An EgyptianVillage in the Ptolemaic Period,
l979> "Markets and Traders in India during the Seventeenth and Eighteenth Cambridge.
Centuries", in K. N. ChaudhuriandC. Dewey(eds. ), Economy andSociety, Crawford, M. (ed. ) 19860, L'impero romano e Ie strutture economiche e sociali
New Delhi, pp. 143-162. delle province, Como.
1981, "The World System East of Longitude 20: The European Role in Asia i986b, "The Monetary System of the Roman Empire", in Crawford 19860,
1500-1750", Review 5. 2, pp. 219-246. pp. 61-70.
1985,Trade andCivilizationin the IndianOcean. An Economic History from Crone, P. 1989, Pre-industrial Societies, Oxford.
the Rise of Islam to 1750, Cambridge. Crook, J. A. 1967, Law andLife of Rome, 90 B. C. -A. D. 212, Ithaca,NY.
1990, Asia Before Europe. Economy and Civilisation of the Indian Ocean 1995; LegalAdvocacy in the RomanWorld, Ithaca,NY.
from the Rise of Islamto 1750, Cambridge. Crow, B. 1999,"ResearchingtheMarketSystemin Bangladesh",in Harris-White
Chaudhuri, S. 1983, "The Surat Crisis of 1669: A Case Study of Mercan- l999at PP-1>5-I5°-
tile Protest in Medieval India!", Calcutta Historical Journal 5, pp. 129- Curtin, P. D. 1984, Cross-CulturalTrade in WorldHistory, Cambridge.
146. Curtis, R. I. 1991,GarumandSalsamenta. ProductionandCommerce in Materia
Chayanov, A. V. 1986, On the Theory of Peasant Economy, with a foreword by Medic a, Leiden.
Teodor Shanin, Madison, WI. Dalby, A. 2000, Empire of Pleasures, London.
Chevalier, R. 1988,Voyages et deplacements dansI'empire romain, Paris. D'Arms, J. H. 1977, "M. I. Rostovtzeffand M. I. Finley: The Status of Traders
Christensen, A. E. 1941, Dutch Trade to the Baltic about 1600. Studies in the in the Roman World", in D'Arms and Eadie (eds. ), Ancient and Modern.
SoundToll Register and Dutch Shipping Records, Copenhagen. Essays in Honor of G. E. Else, Ann Arbor, MI, pp. 159-179.
Christiansen, E. 1982, "Marx, Slaver og Antikken", Historisk Tidsskrift 82, I, 1981, Commerce and Social Standing in Ancient Rome, Cambridge, MA.
pp. 63-94. D'Arms, J. H. and Kopff, E. C. (eds. ) 1980,The Seaborne Commerce of Ancient
1988, The Roman Coins of Alexandria, Aarhus. Rome. Studies in Archaeology and History, Memoirs of the American
1995' A History of Rome, Aarhus. Academy in Rome 36, Rome.
2004, Coinage in Roman Egypt. The Hoard Evidence, Aarhus. Das Gupta, A. 1979, Indian Merchants and the Decline ofSurat, c. 1700-1750,
Cipolla, C. M. (ed. ) 1970, The Economic Decline of Empires, London. Wiesbaden.

(^izak^a, M. 1985, "Incorporation of the Middle East into the European World- 1987, "India and the Indian Ocean in the Eighteenth Century", in Das Gupta
Economy", Review 8, pp. 353-377. and Pearson, pp. 131-161.
dark, C. and Haswell, M. 1970, The Economics of Subsistence Agriculture, 4th 1991, "Changing Faces of the Maritime Merchant", in Ptak and Rothennund,
edn. London. pp. 352-362.

314 315
BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY

1998, "Trade and Politics in EighteenthCentury India", in Alam and Subrah- Domergue, C. and Liou, B. 1997. "L'apparition de nonnes dans Ie commerce
manyam, pp. 361-397. maritime romain", Pallas 46, pp. 11-30.
Das Gupta, A. and Pearson, M. N. (eds. ) 1987, India and the Indian Ocean, Dreher, M. 1997, "Das Monumentiim Ephesenumund das romische Zollwesen ,
/500-/Soo, Calcutta. Milnstersche Beitrdge wr antiken Handelsgeschichte 16, 2, pp. 79-96.
Datta, R. 2000, Society, Economy and the Market. Commercialisation in Rural Drexhage, H. J. 1988, "... Scimus quam varia sint pretia rerum per singulas
Bengal, [760-1800, New Delhi. civitates regionesque... Zu den Preisvariationen im romischen Agypten ,
Daube, D. 1980, "Jewish Law in the Hellenistic World", in B. S. Jackson (ed. ), Miinstersche Beitrdge zurAntiken Handelsgeschichte7, 2, pp. l-lI.
JewishLaw in LegalHistory andthe ModernWorld, Leiden, pp. 45-60. 1991. Preise, Mieten/Pachten, Kosten und Ldhne irn rdmischen Agypten, St
Davies, J. K. 1998, "Ancient Economies: Models and Muddles", in Parkins and Katharinen.
Smith, pp. 225-256. i994> "Einfliisse des Zollwesens auf den Warenverkehr im romischen Reich
De Robertis, F. M. 1971, Storia delle corporazioni e del regime associativo nel - handelshemmend oder handelstordernd?", Miinstersche Beitrdge wr
mondo romano. vols. 1-2. Bari. antiken Handelsgeschichte 13, 2, pp. 1-15.
De Romanis, F. 1996, Cassia, cinnamono, ossidiana. Uomini e merci tra Oceano Drexhage,H.-J.,Konen,H. andRuffing,K. 2002, DieWirtschaftdes RSmischen
indiano e Mediterrcmeo. Rome. Reiches (i. -3. Jahrhundert), Berlin.
l998>"Commercio, Metrologia,Fiscalita",Melangesde I'Ecole Franfaisede Drexhage, R. 1988, Untersuchungen wm rdmischen Osthandel, Bonn.
Rome. Antiquite 110, pp. 11-60. Dreyer, E. L. 2007, Zheng He. China and the Oceans in the Early Ming Dynasty,
De Salvo, L. 1992, Economia privata e puhblici serviz. i nell'impero romano. I 1405-1433, New York.
corpora naviculariorum, Messina. Drinkwater, J. F. 2001, "The Gallo-Roman Woollen Industry and the
De Souza, P. 1999, Piracy in the Graeco-Roman World, Cambridge. Great Debate: The Igel Column Revisited", in Mattingly and Salmon,
Demougin, S. 1988, L'ordre equestre sous les Julio-Claudiens, Rome. pp. 297-308.
Demougin, S. and Devijver, H. (eds. ) 1999, L'ordre equestre. Histoire d'une Droysen, J. G. 1977, Historik, ed. Peter Leyh, vol. I, Stuttgart-Bad Cannstatt.
arisfocratie (lie siecle av. J. C -IIIe siecle ap. J. C. ), Collection de I'Ecole Dumont, L. 1980, Homo Hierarchicus. The Caste System and Its Implications,
Fran^aise de Rome 257, Rome. rev. English, edn, Chicago.
Dewey, C. 1988, Arrested Development. The Historical Dimension, Riverdale, Duncan-Jones,R. 1976, "The Price of Wheat in Roman Egypt underthe Princi-
MD. pate", Chiron6, pp. 241-262.
Dietz,S.,LadjimiSebai,L. andBen Hassen,H. (eds. ) 1995,AfricaProconsularis. l979> "Variationin EgyptianGrain Mesure", Chiron 9, pp. 347-375-
Regional Studies in the Segermes Valley of Northern Tunisia, vols. 1-2, 1982,The Economy of the RomanEmpire. Quantitative Studies, Cambridge.
Aarhus.
1990, Structure and Scale in the Roman Economy, Cambridge.
Dirlmeier, U. 1987, "Mittelalterliche Zoll- und Stapelrechte als Handelshemm- l994< Money andGovernment in the Roman Empire, Cambridge.
nisse , in H. Pohl. (ed. ), Die Auswirkungen von Zollen und anderen Haii- 2003, "Roman Coin circulation and the Cities of Vesuvius", in Lo Cascio
delshemmnissen auf Wirtschaft und Gesellschqft vom Mittelalter bis zur 2003b, pp. 161-180.
Gegenwart. Vierteljahrschrift fiir Sozial- und Wirtschaftsgeschichte, suppl. Duthoy, R. 1976, "Recherches sur la repartition geographique et chronologique
8o, pp. 19-39. des termes sevir augustalis, augustalis et sevir dans 1'empire romain",
Dirven, L. 1999, The Palmyrenes of Dura-Europos. A Study of Religious Inter- Epigraphische Studien n, pp. 143-214.
action in Roman Syria, Leiden. Eck, W. (ed. ) 1999, Lokale Autonomie und romische Ordnungsmacht in den
Disney, A. (ed. ) 1995, Historiography of Europeans in Africa and Asia 1450- kaiserzeitlichen Provinzen vom l. bis 3. Jahrhundert, Munich.
i8oo. An Expanding World, vol. 4, Aldershot. 2000, "The Growth of Administrative Posts", in The Cambridge Ancient His-
Dmitriev, S. 2005, City Government in Hellenistic and Roman Asia Minor, tory, vol. XI, 2nd edn, Cambridge, pp. 238-265.
Oxford. Edhem, E., Goffman, D. and Masters, B. 1999, The Ottoman City between East
Domergue, C. 1994, "L'etat romain et Ie commerce des metaux a la fin de la andWest. Aleppo, Ismir andIstanbul, New York.
Republique et sous Ie Haut-Empire", in Andreau, Briant and Descat et a!., Edwards, C. 1993, The Politics of Immorality in Ancient Rome, Cambridge.
pp. 99-113. Edwards, C. and Woolf, G. (eds. ) 2003, Rome the Cosmopolis, Cambridge.
1998, "A View ofBaetica's External Commerce in the 1st c. A. D. based on its Hiring, J. and Lund, J. (eds. ) 2004, Transport Amphorae andTrade in the Eastern
Trade in Metals", in Keay, pp. 201-215. Mediterranean. Acts ofthe InternationalColloquiumat the DanishInstitute

3l6 317
BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY

at Athens, September 26-29, 2002. Monographs of the Danish Institute at Finlay, R. 2000, "China, the West and World History in Joseph Needham's
Athens 5, Athens. Science and Civilisation in China", Journal of World History 11, 2,
Eisenstadt, S. 1963, The Political Systems of Empires, London. pp. 265-303.
Eisenstadt, S. and Schluchter, W. (eds. ) 1998, Early Modernities, Daedalus 127, Fintey, M. I. 1954, The World of Odysseus, New York.
3, special issue, Cambridge, MA. 1965, "Technical Innovation and Economic Progress in the Ancient World",
Elvin, M. 1973, The Pattern of the Chinese Past, Stanford, CA. Economic Histoiy Review, 2nd ser., l8, pp. 29-45.
Empereur, J. -Y. (ed. ) 1999, Commerce et arfisanat dans I'Alexandrie 1970. "Aristotle and Economic Analysis", Past and Present 47, pp. 3-25.
hellenistique et romaine. Actes du colloque d'Athenes, organise par Ie 1975 > The Use and Abuse of History, London.
CNRS, Ie laboratoire de Ceramologie de Lyon et I'Ecole Franfaise (ed. ) 1976, Studies in Roman Property, Cambridge.
d'Athenes, 11-12 decembre 1988, Athens. 1977. "The Ancient City: From Fustel de Coulanges to Max Weber and
Empereur, J. -Y. and Garlan, Y. (eds. ) 1986, Recherches sur les amphores grec- Beyond", Comparative Studies in Society and History 19, pp. 305-327.
ques, Paris. 1980, Ancient Slaveiy and Modern Ideology, London.
Engelmann, H. and Knibbe, D. 1989, "Das Zollgesetz der Provinz Asia. Eine 1983, Politics in the Ancient World, Cambridge.
neue Inschrift aus Ephesos", Epigraphica Anatolica 14, pp. 1-206. l9§5a. The Ancient Economy, 2nd edn, London.
Engels, D. 1990, Roman Corinth, Chicago. i985b, Ancient History. Evidence and Models, London.
Epigrafia deltaproduzwne e delta distribuwme. Collection de 1'Ecole Fran^aise Fischer, W., Mclnnis, R. M. and Schneider, J. (eds. ) 1986, The Emergence of a
de Rome 193, Rome, 1994. World Economy 1500-1914, Papers of the IXth International Congress of
Epigrafia e online senatorw=Atti del Colloquio Internaz. ionale AIEGL su Epi- Economic History, 2 vols., Wiesbaden.
grafiae Ordine Senatorio(1981: Roma), Tituli 4-5, Rome 1982. Foraboschi,D. 1994,"Economieplurali e interdipendenze",in L'ltalie d'Auguste
Erdkamp, P. 2001, "Beyond the Limits of the 'Consumer City'. A Model d Diocletien, Collection de 1'Ecole Fran^aise de Rome, Rome, pp. 215-218.
of the Urban and Rural Economy in the Roman World", Historia 50, 2000, "The Hellenistic Economy: Indirect Intervention by the State", in Lo
pp. 332-356. Cascio and Rathbone, pp. 37-43.
2002, "A Starving Mob has No Respect: Urban Markets andFood Riots in the France, J. 1994, "De Burmann a Finley: les douanes dans 1'histoire economique
Roman World, 100 B. C.-A. D. 400", in de Blois and Rich, pp. 93-115. de 1'empire romain", in Andreau, Briant and Descatet al., pp. 127-153.
2005,The Roman Grain Market, Cambridge. 1999; "Les revenues douanieres des communautes municipales dans Ie monde
Erslev, K. 1911, Historieskrivning. Grundlinier til nogle kapitler af historiens romain", in // capitolo delle entrate nelle finame municipali in Occidente
Theori, Copenhagen. ed in Oriente, Collection de 1'Ecole Fran^aise de Rome, 256, pp. 95-
Etienne,R. 1952,"Romeeut-elle unepolitiquedouaniere?",Annales ESC7, pp. 113.
371-377. 2001, Quadragesima Galliarum. L'organisation douaniere des provinces
Etienne, R. and Mayet, F. 1998, "Les 'mercatores' de saumure hispanique", Alpestres, Gauloises et Germaniques de I'empire Romain, Collection de
MelangesdeI'EcoleFrangaisede Rome. Antiquite 110,pp. 147-165. 1'Ecole Fran^aise de Rome 278, Rome.
Faroqhi, S. igS^, Towns and Townsmen of Ottoman Aizatolia. Trade, Crafts and 2003, "La Ferme des douanes dans les provinces occidentales et 1'empire
Food Production in an Urban Setting, 1520-1650, Cambridge. romain", in Aubert, pp. 193-214.
i99i> "In Search of Ottoman History", Journal of Peasant Studies 18, 3/4, Frank, A. G. 1998, ReOrient. Global Economy in the Asian Age, Berkeley and
pp. 211-241. Los Angeles.
Pawaz, L. and Bayly, C. A. (eds. ) 2002, Modernity and Culture. From the Frank, A. G. and Gills, B. K. (eds. ) 1993, The World System. Five Hundred Years
Mediterranean to the Indian Ocean. New York. or Five Thousand? London and New York.
Ferguson,A. 1995,AnEssayontheHistory ofCivilSociety,ed.F.Oz-Salzberger, Frank, T. (ed. ) 1933-40, An Economic Survey of Ancient Rome, vols. 1-6,
Cambridge (first published 1767). Baltimore, MD.
l799> The History of the Progress andTermination of the Roman Republic, a Frayn, J. M. 1993, Markets and Fairs in Roman Italy, Oxford.
new edn, revised and corrected, 5 vols., Edinburgh. Frederiksen, M. 1975, "Theory, Evidence and the Ancient Economy", Journal of
Fikhman, I. F. 1991-2, "State and Prices in Byzantine Egypt", Scripta Classica Roman Studies 65, pp. 164-171.
Israelica 11, pp. 139-148. Freyberg,H.-U. von 1989, KapitalverkehrundHandelim romischenKaiserreich
Finkielkraut, A. 1988,The Undoing ofThought, London. ('27 v. Chr. -2j5 n. Chr. ), Freiburg.

3i8 319
BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY

Frezouls, E. 1985, "Les ressources de I'euergetisme: Ie cas d'Opramoas de 2000, "The Land", in The Cambridge Ancient History, vol. XI, 2nd edn,
Rhodiopolis", in Leveau, pp. 249-254. Cambridge, pp. 679-709.
Friedlander, L. j 92 [-3, Darstellungen aus der Sittengeschichte Roms in der Zeit 2004, "Roman Citizenship and Roman Law in the Late Empire", in S. Swain
van Augustus his 7.um Ausgang der Antonine, vol. 10, ed. Georg Wissowa, and M. Edwards (eds. ). Approaching Late Antiquity. The Transformation
4 vols.. Leipzig. from Early to Late Empire, Oxford, pp. 133-155.
Frier, Bruce W. 2000a, "Demography", in The Cambridge Ancient History, Garnsey, P., Hopkins, K. and Whittaker, C. R. (eds. ) 1983, Trade in the Ancient
vol. XI, 2nd edn, pp. 787-816. Economy. London.
200ob, "More is Worse: Some Observations on the Population of the Roman Gamsey, P. and Humfress, C. 2001, The Evolution of the Late Antique World,
Empire", in Scheidel, pp. 139-159. Cambridge.
Fulford, M. 1987, "Economic Interdependence among Urban Communities of Garnsey, P. and Saller, R. 1987, The Roman Empire. Economy, Society and
the Roman Mediterranean", World Archaeology 19, I, pp. 58-75. Culture. London.
Fiille, G. 1997, "The Internal Organizationof the Arretine Terra SigillataIndus- Garnsey, P. and Whittaker, C. R. 1978 (eds. ). Imperialism in the Ancient World,
try", Journal of Roman Studies 87, pp. 111-155. Cambridge.
Gabba, E. 1988, Del buon uso delta ricchezw. Saggi di storia economica e sociale 1983 (eds. ), Trade and Faminein Classical Antiquity, Cambridge.
del mondo antico. Milan. 1998, "Trade, Industry and the Urban Economy", in The Cambridge Ancient
Gabrielsen, V. 1997, The Naval Aristocracy of Rhodes, Aarhus. History, vol. XIII, 2nd edn, Cambridge.
2001, "The Rhodian Associations and Economic Activity", in Archibald etal., Geertz, Clifford 1963, Peddlers and Princes. Social Development and Economic
pp. 215-244. Change in Two IndonesianTowns, Chicago.
Gagos, T. and van Minnen, P. 1994, Settling a Dispute. Towarda LegalAnthro- i979> "Suq: The Bazaar Economy in Sefrou", in C. Geertz, H. Geertz and L.
pology of Late Antique Egypt, Ann Arbor, MI. Roan, Meaning and Order in Moroccan Society, Cambridge, pp. 123-313.
Galanter,M. 1981,"JusticeinManyRooms:Courts,PrivateOrdering,andIndige- 2000, Local Knowledge. Further Essays in Interpretive Anthropology, New
nous Law", Journal of Legal Pluralism 19, pp. 1-47. York.
Galsterer, H. 1986, "Roman Law in the Provinces - Some Problems ofTrans- Gellner, E. i988a, "Introduction", in Baechler, Hall and Mann, pp. 1-5.
mission", in Crawford 19860, pp. 13-27. i988b. Plough, Sword and Book, Chicago.
1996, "The Administration of Justice", in The Cambridge Ancient History, Gelzer, M. 1912, Die Nobilitdt der Romischen Republik, Berlin.
vol. X, 2nd edn, pp. 397-413. Giardina, A. 1986, "Le merci, il tempo, il silenzio: Ricerche su miti e valori
i997> "Neues zu den romischen Stadtgesetzen", Zeitschrift der Savigny- sociali nel mondo Greco e Romano", Studi Storici, 27, 2, pp. 277-302.
Stiftung. Romanistische Abteilung, pp. 392-401. (ed. ) 1989, L'uomo romano, Rome and Bari.
Gamsey,P. 1970,SocialStatusandLegalPrivilege inthe RomanEmpire,Oxford. l997i L'ltalia Romana. Studi di stone di un'identita incompiuta, Rome.
l976> "Urban Property Investment", in Finley, pp. 123-136. Giardina, A. and Schiavone, A. (eds. ) 1981, Societa romana e produz. ione schi-
1978, "Rome's African Empire under the Principate" in Gamsey and Whit- avistica, vols. l-t, Bari and Rome.
taker, pp. 223-254. Gibbon, E. 1993, The Decline and Fall of the Roman Empire, introduction by
i983a, "Faminein Rome", in Gamsey and Whittaker, pp. 56-65. Hugh Trevor-Roper, vols. 1-6, London.
i983b, "Grain for Rome", in Garnsey, Hopkins and Whittaker,pp. 118-130. Gibson, A. J. S. andSmout, T. C. 1995,"RegionalPricesandMarketRegions:The
1988, Famine andFood Supply in the Graeco-RomanWorld, Cambridge. Evolution of the Early Modern Scottish Grain Market", Economic History
1991, "The Generosity of Veyne", Journal of Roman Studies 81, pp. 164- Review 48, 2, pp. 258-282.
i68. Glamann, K. 1958, Dutch-Asiatic Trade, 1620-1740, Copenhagen.
i994> Foodand Society in Classical Antiquity, Cambridge. i977> "The Changing Patterns of Trade", in The Cambridge Economic History
1996, "Prolegomenonto the Studyofthe Landin theLaterRomanEmpire", in of Europe, vol. V, Cambridge, chapter4.
J. H. M. Strubbe, R. A. Tybout and H. S. Versnel (eds. ), Energeia: Studies Goethe, J. W. van 1907, Maximen und Reflexionen, ecl. Max Hecker, Weimar.
on Ancient History and Epigraphy Presented to H. W. Picket, Amsterdam, Goitein, S. D. 1967, A Mediterranean Society. The Jewish Communities of the
pp. 135-153. Arab World as Portrayed in the Documents of the Cairo Geniza, vol. I,
i998a. Cities, Peasants and Foodin Classical Antiquity, Cambridge. Berkeley and Los Angeles.
l998b, Food and Society in Antiquity, Cambridge. Gokhale, B. G. 1979, Surat in the I'jth Century, London.

320 321
BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY

Golden, M. and Toohey, P. (eds. ) 1997, Inventing Ancient Culture, London. Grenier. J. -Y. 1997, "Economie du surplus, economie du circuit", in Andreau,
Goldschmid, L. 1897, "Les impots et droits de douane en Judee sous les Briant and Descat et at., pp. 385-404.
Remains", Revue des Eludes Juives 34, pp. 192-217. Grover. B. R. 1966, "An Integrated Pattern of Commercial Life in the Rural
Goldsmith, R. W. 1987, Pre-Modern FinancialSystems. A Historical Compara- Society of North India during the 17th and 18th Centuries", Proceedings
five Study, Cambridge. of the 3-/th Session of the Indian Historical Records Commision 38, New
Goldstone, J. 1991, Revolution and Rebellion in the Early Modem World, Berke- Delhi.
ley, CA. Grlinewald, T. 1999, Rduher, Rebellen, Rivalen, Rdcher. Studien zu Latrones im
1998, "The Problem of the 'Early Modern' World", Journal of the Economic romischen Reich, Stuttgart.
and Social History of the Oriental, pp. 249-284. Guarino, A. 1972, "Societas consensu contracta". Atti delta Accademia di Scienz.e
2002, "Efflorescences and Economic Growth in World History: Rethinking the Morali e Politiche delta Societa Nationale di Sciem. e. Lettere ed Arti di
'Rise of the West' and the Industrial Revolution", Journal of World History Napoli. 83. 261-359.
13, pp. 323-389. Gungwu, W. 1990 "Merchants Without Empire: The Hokkien Sojourning Com-
Gommans, J. 2002, Miighal Warfare. Indian Frontiers and High Roads to Empire, munities", in Tracy, pp. 400-421.
/500-/700, London and New York. Habib, I. 1963, The Agrarian System of'Mughal India, Bombay.
Gonzales, J. 1986, "The Lex Irnitana: A New Copy of the Flavian Municipal 1969, "Potentialities of Capitalistic Development in the Economy of Mughal
Law", Journal of Roman Studies 76, pp. 147-243. India , Journalof Economic History 29, pp. 32-78.
Goodman, M. 1983, State and Society in Roman Galilee, AD. 132-212, Totowa, 1972, "The System of Bills of Exchange (Hundis) in the Mughal Empire",
NJ. Proceedings of the Indian History Congress, (3j rd session, Muwffarpur),
Goody, J. 1990, The Oriental, the Ancient andthe Primitive, Cambridge. pp. 290-303.
1996, The East in the West, Cambridge. 1985, "Classifying Pre-Colonial India", in Byres and Mukhia, pp. 44-53.
1998, Food and Love. A Cultural History of East andWest, London. 1990. "Merchant Communities in Precolonial India",in Tracy, pp. 371-399.
Goody, J. and Whittaker, D. 2001, "Rural Manufacturing in the Rouergue from 1999, The Agrarian System ofMughal India, 2nd rev. edn, Oxford and Delhi.
Antiquity to the Present: The Examples of Pottery and Cheese", Compara- Habib, I. and Raychaudhuri, T. (eds. ) 1982, The Cambridge Economic History
tive Studies in Society and History 43, 2, pp. 225-245. of India, vol. I: c. 1200-c. 1750, Cambridge.
Gordon, S. 1990, "Burhanpur: Entrepot and Hinterland, , 650-7750", in Hackens, R and Miro, M. 1990 (eds. ), Le commerce maritime romain en
Subrahmanyam 19900, pp. 48-65. Mediterranee occidentale, PACT 27, Strasbourg.
Goudineau, C. 1974, "La ceramique dans I'economic romaine", Dossiers Hack), K. 1997, "Der Zivilprozess des friihen Prinzipats in den Provinzen",
d'Archeologie 6, pp. 103-109. Zeitschriftder Savigny-Stiftung, RomanistischeAhteilung 114. pp. 141-159.
Granger, C. W. J. and Elliott, C. M. 1967 "A Fresh Look at Wheat Prices and Haider, S. N. 1997, The Monetary System of the Mughal Empire, D. Phil. thesis,
Markets in the EighteenthCentury", EconomicHistory Review 20, pp. 257- University of Oxford.
265. Haldon, J. 1993, The State and the Tributary Mode of Production, London.
Greene, K. 1986, The Archaeology of the Roman Economy, London. Halfmann, H. 1979, Die Senatoren aus dem ostlichen Teil des Imperium
i994> "Technology and Innovation in Context: The Roman Background to Romaniimhis zum Ende des 2. Jahrhundertsn. Chr., Gottingen.
Medieval and Later Developments", Journal of Roman Archaeology 7, Hall, J. 1985, Powers and Liberties, Oxford.
PP. 22-33. Hammond, M. 1957, "Composition of the Roman Senate AD 68-235", Journal
2000, "Technological Innovation and Economic Progress in the Ancient World: of Roman Studies 47, pp. 74-81.
M. I. Finley Re-considered", Social and Economic History Review 53, I, Harl, K. W. 1996, Coinage in the Roman Economy, 300 B. C. -A. D. 700, London.
pp. 29-59. Harries, Jill 1999, Lawand Empire in Late Antiquity, Cambridge.
Greif, A. 1993, "Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Harris, B. 1987, "Merchants and Markets of Grain in South Asia", in Shanin, pp.
Trade: The Mahgribi Traders' Coalition", American Economic Review 83, 205-220.
pp. 525-548. Harris, W. 1980, "Roman Terracotta Lamps: The Organisationof an Industry",
Gren, E. 1941, Kleinasien und der Ostbalkan in der Wirtschaftlichen Entwick- Journal of Roman Studies 70, pp. 125-145.
lung der romischen Kaiserzeit, Uppsala Universitets Arsskrift 194 r: 9, 1993. "Between Archaic and Modem: Problems in Roman Economic His-
Uppsala. tory", in (ed. ) The Inscribed Economy: Production and Distribution in the

322 323
BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY

Roman Empire in the Light of Instnimentum Domesticum, Journal of Roman Hitchner, R. B. and Mattingly, D. 1995, "Roman Africa: An Archaeological
Archaeology Supplementary Series 6, Ann Arbor, MI, pp. I [-29. Review", Journal of Roman Studies 85. pp. 165-213.
i999i"Demography, Geography and the Sources of Roman Slaves", Joiirnal Hobenreich, E. 1997, Annona. Juristische Aspekte der Stadtmmischen Lehens-
of Roman Studies 89, pp. 62-75. mittelversorgung in Prinzipat, Graz.
2000. "Trade and Transport", in The Cambridge Ancient History, vol. XI, 2nd Hobsbawm, E. 1987, The Age of Empire, 1875-1914, London.
edn, Cambridge, pp. 710-740. Hodgson, M. 1974, The 'Venture of Islam. Conscience and Histon' in a World
2003, "Roman Governments and Commerce, 300 B. C. -A. D. 300", in Civilization, vols. 1-3, Chicago.
Zaccagnini, pp. 275-306. i993i Rethinking World History, ed. Edmund Burke III, Cambridge.
20o6, "A Revisionist View of Roman Money", Journal of Roman Studies 96, Hont, I. 2005, Jealousy of Trade. International Competition and the Nation-state
pp. 1-24. in Historical Perspective, Cambridge, MA.
Harris-White, B. (ed. ) 19993, Agricultural Markets From Theory to Practice. Hopkins, K. 19780, Conquerors and Slaves, Cambridge.
Field Experience in Developing Countries, London. i978b, "Economic Growth and Towns in Classical Antiquity", in P. Abrams
i999b, "Powerin PeasantMarkets", in Harris-White l999a, pp. 261-286. and E. A. Wrigley (eds. ), Towns in Societies. Essays in Economic History
Hartwell, R. 1962, "A Revolution in the ChineseIron and Coal IndustriesDuring and Historical Sociology, Cambridge, pp. 35-77.
the Northern Sung, 960-1126 A. D", Journal of Asian Studies 21, pp. 153- 1980, "Taxes and Trade in the Roman Empire 200 B. C. -A. D. 400", Journal
162. of Roman Studies 70, pp. 101-125.
1966, "Markets, Technology and the Structure of Enterprise in the Develop- i983a. Deathand Renewal, Cambridge.
ment of the Eleventh-century ChineseIron and Steel Industries",Journalof i983b, "Models, Ships and Staples", in Garnsey and Whittaker, pp. 84-109.
Economic History 26, pp. 29-58. 19830, "Introduction", in Garnsey, Hopkins and Whittaker, pp. ix-xxv.
Hasan, F. 2004, State and Locality in Mughal India. Power Relations in Western 1995-6. "Rome, Taxes, Rents and Trade", Kodai. Journal of Ancient Histoi-y
India, c. 1572-1730, Cambridge. 6/7, pp. 41-75.
Hassall, M. 2000, "The Army", in The Cambridge Ancient History, vol. XI, 2nd 2000, "Rents, Taxes, Trade and the City of Rome", in Lo Cascio 20ooa,
edn, pp. 320-343. pp. 253-268.
Haswell, M. 1967, Economics of Development in Village India, London. Hopwood, K. 1989, "Bandits, Elites and Rural Order", in Wallace-Hadrill,
Hatzfeld, J. 1919, Les trafiquants italiens dans {'Orient hellenique, Paris. pp. 171-189.
Heberdey, R. 1897, Opramoas. Inschriften vom Heroon w Rhodiopolis, Harden, P. and Purcell, N. 2000, The Corrupting Sea. A Study of Mediterranean
Vienna. History, Oxford.
Heberdey, R. and Kalinka. E. 1896, Bericht iiber wei Reisen im sudwestlichen Howgego, C. 1992, "The Supply and Use of Money in the Roman World", Journal
Kleinasien. Vienna. of Roman Studies 82, pp. 1-31.
Hegel, G. W. 1996, Vorlesungen iiber die Philosophie der Welt^eschichte, ed. l994> "Coin Circulation and the Integration of the Roman Economy", Journal
K. H. llting, K. Brehmer and H. N. Seelmann, Hamburg. of Roman Archaeology 7, pp. 5-21.
Herz, P. 1988, Stiidienwr romischen Wirtschaftsgesetzgebung. Die Lebensmit- i995> Ancient History from Coins, London.
telversorgung. Historic! Einzelschriften 55, Stuttgart. Huang, R. 1974, Taxation and Governmental Finance in Sixteenth-Century Ming
Hiderato, I. 1999-2000, "The Transfer of Money in Roman Egypt", Kodai 10, China, Cambridge.
pp. 83-104. Hultsch, F. 1882, Griechische und romische Metrologie, 2nd rev. edn, Berlin.
Hingley, R. 2005, Globalizing Roman Culture. Unity, Diversity and Empire, Huntington, S. P. 1996, The Clash of Civilizations and the Remaking of World
London and New York. Order. New York.
Hinton, W. 1966, Fanshen. A Documentary of Revolution in a Chinese Village, Hurst, H. 1993, "Cartagine, la nuova Alessandria", in A. Schiavone (ed. ), Storia
New York and London. cli Roma, vol. 3, 2, Turin, pp. 327-337.
Hintze, A. 1997, The Mughal Empire and its Decline. An Interpretation of the Husain, M. M. H. (ed. ) 1913, "The Mirza-Namah (The Book of the Perfect
Sources of Social Power, Aldershot. Gentleman) of Mirza Kamran with an English Translation", Journal of the
Hitchen, R. B. 2005, '"The Advantages of Wealth and Luxury': The Case Asiatic Society of Bengal 9, pp. 1-13.
for Economic Growth in the Roman Empire", in Manning and Morris, Inalcik, H. 1969, "Capital Formation in the Ottoman Empire", Journal of Eco-
pp. 207-222. nomic History 29, pp. 97-140.

324 325
BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY

Inalcik, H. and Quataert, D. (eds. ) 1994, An Economic and Social Histor/ of the Katzoff, R. 1972, "Precedents in the Courts of Roman Egypt", Zeitschnft der
Ottoman Empire, vol. 2: i6oo-i()i4. Cambridge. Savigny-Stiftung, Romanistische Abteilung 89, pp. 256-292.
Inden, R. 1990, Imagining India, Oxford. Kautsky, J. H. 1982, The Politics of Aristocratic Empires, Chapel Hill, NC.
Irvine, W. 1962, The Army of the Indian Moghuls. Its Organization and Admin- Keay, S. J. 1984, Late Roman Amphorae in the Western Mediterranean. A Typol-
istrat'wn. New Delhi. iigy and Economic Study: The Catalan Evidence, BAR International Series
Islamoglu-tnan, H. (ed. ) 1987, The Ottoman Empire and the 'World-economy, n6, Oxford.
Cambridge. (ec). ) 1998, The Archaeology of Early Roman Baetica, Journal of Roman
Israel, J. I. 1989, Dutch Primacy in World Trade 1585-1740, Oxford. Archaeology, Supplementary Series 29, Ann Arbor, MI.
Jacobsen, G. 1995, Primitiver Austausch oder Freier Markt? Untersuchun- Kehoe, D. 1993, "Economic Rationalism in Roman Agriculture", Journal, of
gen wm Handel in den gallisch-germanischen Provim. en wdhrend der Roman Archaeology 6. pp. 476-484.
romischen Kaiserzeit. St Katharinen. J997' Investment, Profit and Tenancy. The Jurists and the Roman Economy,
Jacques, F. and Scheid, J. 1990, Rome et I 'integration de I 'empire (44 av. J. . -260 Ann Arbor. Ml.
ap. J. C. ). Paris. Kennedy, P. 1988,The RiseandFall ofthe Great Powers. Economic Changeand
Jain, L. C. 1929, Indigenous Banking In India. London. Military Conflict from ,500 to 2000. London.
Jakab.E. 1997, PraedicereundCavere heim Marktkauf. Sachmangelim griech- Kenrick, Philip 1993. "ItalianTerra Sigillata: A SophisticatedRoman Industry",
ischen und romischen Recht. Munich. OxfordJournalof Archaeology 12, 2, pp. 35-42.
2003, "Pixierte Preise fur die Vermarktung des Weins im Heroninos-Archiv?", 2000, Corpus Vasorum Arretinorum, 2nd edn., Bonn.
Miinstersche Beitrdge wr Antiken Handelsgeschichte22, l, pp. 1-26. Kessler, D. andTemin, P. 2005, "Money andPricesin the Early Roman Empire",
2006, "Vertragsformulare im Imperium Romanum", Zeitschrift der Savigny- MIT Department of Economics Working Paper No. 05-11, Cambridge,
Stiftungfiir Rechtsgeschichte, Romanistische Abteilung 123, pp. 71-101. MA.
Jeannin,J. P. 1982, "Les interdependanceseconomiques dans Ie champ d'action Keyder, C. 1997, "TheOttoman Empire", in K. BarkeyandM. von Hagen(eds. ),
europeen des Hollandais (XVIe-XVIIesiecle), in Aymard, pp. 147-170. After Empire, Boulder, CO.
Johnston, A. C. 1936. Roman Egypt to the Reign of Diocletian. Baltimore, MD. Kirschenbaum, A. \c)%l, Sons, Slaves and Freedmen in Roman Commerce, Wash-
Johnston, D. 1999, Roman Law in Context, Cambridge. ineton. DC.
Jones, A. H. M. 1940. The Greek City from Alexander to Justinian, Oxford. Klein, P. W. 1965, De Trippen in de /ye eeuw. En studie over het ondernemers-
1964, The Later Roman Empire 284-602. A Social, Economic and Adminis- gedrag op de Hollandse stapelmarkt, Assen.
trative Survey, vols. 1-2. Norman. OK. Klingenberg, G. 1977, Commissum. Der Vervall nichtdeklarierter Sachen im
1974; The Roman Economy, ed. P. A. Brunt, Oxford. rdmischen Zollrecht, Graz.
Jones, D. 2006, The Bankers of Puteoli. Finance, Trade and Industry in the Kloft, H. 1996, "Uberlegungen zum Luxus in der frtihen romischen Kaiserzeit",
Roman World. Stroud. in J. H. M. Strubbe,R. A. Tybout andH. S. Versnel (eds. ), Energeia: Studies
Jones, E. L. 1981,The European Miracle, Cambridge. on Ancient History and Epigraphy Presented to H. W. Picket, Amsterdam,
1988, Growth Recurring. Economic Change in World History, Oxford. pp. 113-134.
Jongman, W. 1988, The Economy and Society of Pompeii, Amsterdam. Kloppenborg, J. S. and Wilson, S. G. (eds. ) 1996, Voluntary Associations in the
2000a, "Hunger and Power: Theories, Models and Methods in Roman Eco- Graeco-Roman World, London and NewYork.
nomic History", in H. Bongenaar(ed. ), Interdependency of Institutions and Kneissl, P. 1998, "Die Berufsvereine im romischen Gallien", in P. Kneissl and V.
Private Entrepreneurs, MOS Studies 2, Leiden,pp. 259-284. Losemann(eds. ), Im.periumRomanum. FestschriftfiirKarlChrist, Stuttgart,
2000b,"WoolandtheTextileIndustryofRomanItaly:A WorkingHypothesis", pp. 431-449.
in Lo Cascio 20ooa, pp. 187-198. Kobes, J. 1999, "Fremdes Getreide: Beobachtungenzum Problem der Getreide-
2006, "The Rise and Fall of the Roman Economy: Population, Rents and versorgung in der kaiserzeitlichen ProvinzAsia", Laverna 10, pp. 81-98.
Entitlement", in Bang, Ikeguchiand Ziche, pp. 237-254. Kokkinia, C. 2000, Die Opramoas-Inschrift von Rhodiapolis, Bonn.
Kajanto, L. 1965,The LatinCognomina,SocietasScientiarumFennica,Helsing- Krause, J. -U. 1994, Witwen und Waisen im rdmischen Reich, II: Wirtschaftliche
fors. und gesellschaftliche Stellung van Witwen, Stuttgart.
Kaser, M. 1996, Das romische Zivilprozessrecht, 2nd edn, rev. by K. Hackl, l995> Wihven und Waisen im rdmischen Reich, III: Rechtliche und soT. iale
Munich. Stellung van Waisen, Stuttgart.

326 327
BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY

Kruit, N. 1992, "Local Customs in the Formulas of Sales of Wine for Future Lintott, A. 1968, Violence in Republican Rome, Oxford.
Delivery", Zeitschrift fur Papyrologie und Epigraphik 94, pp. 167-184. I993> Imperium Romanum. Politics and Administration, London.
Kruit, N. and Worp, A. 1999, "Metrological Notes on Measures and Containers Liou, B. and Rodnguez-Almeida, E. 2000, "Les Inscriptions des amphores du
of Liquids in Graeco-Roman and Byzantine Egypt", Archiv fur Papyrus- Pecio Gondolfo", Melanges de I'Ecole Francaise de Rome. Antiquite 112,
forschung 45, pp. 96-127. I, pp. 7-25.
Kudlien, F. 1994, "Die Rolle der Konkurrenz im antiken Gesellschaftsleben", Liou, B. and Tchemia. A. 1994, "L'interpretation des inscriptions sur les
Miinstersche Beitrdge ziir Antiken Handelsgeschichte 13, I, pp. 1-39. amphores Dressel 20", in Epigrafia della produzione e delta distribuwme,
1997, "Der antike Makler - ein verleugneter Beruf, Miinstersche Beitrcige zur pp. 133-156.
Antiken Handelsgeschichte 16, I, pp. 67-84. Littleton, C. S. 1985, "Introduction", in Levy-Bruhl, pp. iii-lviii.
Kula, W. 1976, An Economic Theory of the Feudal System, London. Livi-Bacci, M. 1992,A Concise History of World Population, trans. Carl Ipsen,
Laet, S. de 1949, Portorium. Etude sur I'organisation douaniere chez les 2nd edn. Oxford.
Romains, Bruges. Lo Cascio, E. 1991, "Forme dell'economia imperiale", in A. Schiavone (ed. ),
Landes, D. 1998, The Wealth and Poverty of Nations. Why Some Are So Rich Storia di Roma, vol. 2, 2, pp. 313-365.
and Some So Poor. New York. 1998. "Considerazioni su circolazione monetaria, prezzi e fiscalita nel IV
Lane, F. C. 1966, Venice and History. The Collected Papers of Frederic C. Lane, secolo", in G. Crifo and S. Giglio (eds. ), Atti dell'Accademia Romanistica
Baltimore, MD. Costantiniana. XII Convegno Internazionale, Naples, pp. 121-136.
Larsen M. T. 1967, Old Assyrian Caravan Procedures, Istanbul. (ed. ) 2000a, Mercati Pennanentie Mercati PeriodicinelMondo Romano. Atti
1976, The Old Assyrian City-State and its Colonies, Mesopotamia 4, Copen- degli Incontri capresi di storia dell'economia antica, Bari.
hagen. 2000b, // Princeps e il suo impero. Studi di storia amministrativa efinan7. ia. na
Laurence, R. 1998, "Land Transport in Roman Italy: Costs, Practice and the romana, Bari.
Economy", in Parkins and Smith, pp. 129-148. 2000C, "The Roman Principate: The Impact of the Organization of the Empire
i999i The Roads of Roman Italy, London. on Production", in Lo Cascio and Rathbone, pp. 77-85.
Lendon, J. E. 1997, Empire of Honour, Oxford. 2003a, "Appaltatori delle imposte e amministrazione finanziaria imperiale",
Lepelley, C. (ed. ) 1998, Rome et I'integrationde I'empire (44 av. J. C. - 260 ap. in Aubert pp. 249-268.
J. C), tome 2: Approches regionales du Haut-Empire romain, Paris. (ed. ) 2003b, Credito e moneta nel mondo romano, Bari.
Lesger, Cle 2006, The Rise of the Amsterdam Market and Information Exchange: 2003C, "Mercato libero e 'commercio amministrato' in eta tardoantica", in
Merchants, Commercial Expansion and Change in the Spatial Economy of Zaccagnini, pp. 307-325.
the Low Countries, c. ,550-7630, Ashgate. 2006, "The Role ofthe State in the Roman Economy: MakingUse ofthe New
Leur, J. C. van 1955, Indonesian Trade and Society. Essays in Asian Social and Institutional Economics", in Bang, Ikeguchi and Ziche, pp. 215-234.
Economic History, The Hague. Lo Cascio, E. and Rathbone, D. (eds. ) 2000, Production and Public Powers in
Leveau, P. (ed. ) 1985, L'Origine des richesses depensees dans la ville antique, Classical Antiquity, The Cambridge Philological Society Supplement 26,
Aix-en-Provence. Cambridge.
Levi-Strauss, C. 1962, La Pensee sauvage, Paris. Lopez, R. S. and Raymond, I. W. 1955, Medieval Trade in the Mediterranean
Levy-Bruhl, L. 1910, Les Fonctions mentale dans les societes inferieures, Paris. World. Illustrative Documents Translated with Introductions and Notes,
1985, How Natives Think, with an introduction by C. Scott Littleton, London London.
(first published 1926). Love, J. R. 1991, Antiquity and Capitalism. Max Weber and the Sociological
Lewis, N. (ed. ) 1989, The Documents from the Bar Kokhba Period in the Cave Foundations of Roman Civiliwtion, London.
of Letters. Greek Papyri, Judean Desert Studies, Jerusalem. Lund, J. 1999, "Trade Patterns in the Levant from c. 100 BC to AD 200
Liebenam,W. 1900, Stddtevenvaltung im rdmischen Kaiserreiche,Leipzig. as Reflected by the Distribution of Ceramic Fine Wares in Cyprus",
Ligt, L. de 1993, Fairs and Markets in the Roman Empire. Economic and Social Munstersche Beitrdge zur Antiken Handelsgeschichte 18, I, pp. 1-22.
Aspects of Periodic Trade in a Pre-Industrial Society, Amsterdam. MacMullen, R. 1974, Roman Social Relations. 50 B. C. -A. D. 284, New Haven,
2000, "Governmental Attitudes towards Markets and Collegia", in Lo Cascio CT.
20ooa, pp. 237-252. I99°> Changes in the Roman Empire. Essays in the Ordinary, New Haven, CT.
2002, "Tax Transfers in the Roman Empire", in de Blois and Rich, pp. 84-102. Maddison, A. 2001, The World Economy. A Millennial Perspective, Paris.

328 329
^rr

BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY

Maine. H. S. i86i. Ancf'en/ Law. Gloucester. i997c- "Africa, a Landscape of Opportunity", in Mattingly l99?b, pp. 117-
1871, Village Communities in the East and West, London. 139.
Malinowski, B. 1924, Argonauts of the Western Pacific. London. Mattingly, D. J. and Salmon, J. (eds. ) 2001, Economies Beyond Agriculture in
1948, Magic, Science and Religion and Other Essays, New York. the Classical World, London.
Malmendier, U. 2002, Societas Puhlicanorum, Cologne. Mattingly, D. J.. Stone, D., Stirling, L. and Ben Lazreg, N. 2001, "Leptiminus
Manacorda,D. 1989,"Leanforedell'Italiarepubblicana",in Amplwres romaines (Tunisia): a 'Producer' City", in Mattingly and Salmon, pp. 66-98.
el histoire economique. Dix ans de recherche. Collection de 1 Ecole Mauro, F. 1990, "Merchant Communities, 1350-1750", in Tracy, pp. 255-286.
Fran^aisede Rome [ 14, Rome pp. 443-467. McKenclrick,N., Brewer,J. andPlumb,J.H. (eds. ) 1982,The Birthofa Consumer
Mann, M. 1986, The Sources of Social Power. A History of Power from the Society.The CommercializationofEighteenth-CentiiryEngland,Blooming-
Beginning to A. D. 1760, Cambridge. ton, IN.
Manning, J. G. and Morris, I. (eds. ) 2005, The Ancient Economy. Evidence and McNeill, W. H. 1982, The Pursuit of Power, Chicago.
Models, Stanford, CA. 1986, Mythistory and Other Essays, Chicago.
Markovits, C. 2000, The Global World of Indian Merchants, , 750-79^7. Traders McPherson, K. 1993, The Indian Ocean. A History of People and the Sea, Delhi.
of'Sindfrom Bukhara to Panama, Cambridge. Meiggs, R. 1973, Roman Ostia, 2nd edn., Oxford.
Marsh, G. 1981, "London's Samian Supply and its Relationship to the Devel- Meijer, F. and van Nijf, 0. 1992, Trade. Transport, and Society in the Ancient
opment of the Gallic Samian Industry", in Anderson and Anderson, pp. World. A Sourcebook. London.
173-238. Meilink-Roelofsz, M. A. P. 1962, Asian Trade and European Influence in the
Marshall, A. 1890, Principles of Economics, London. Indonesian Archipelago between ,500 and about 1630, The Hague.
Marshall,A. J. 1980,"TheSurvivalandDevelopmentofInternationalJurisdiction 1980, "The Structure of Trade in Asia in the Sixteenth and Seventeenth Cen-
in the Greek World", Aufstieg imd Niedergang der Rdmischen Well 2, 13, turies", in Mare Luso-Indiciim, IV, Paris, pp. 1-43.
pp. 626-661. Merola, G. D. 2001, Autoiwmia locale governo imperiale, Bari.
Marshall, P. J. 1976, "British Merchants in Eighteenth-Century Bengal", Bengal Meyer, Ecluard 1910, Einleitung. Elemente der Anthropologie. Geschichte des
Past and Present 86, pp. 151-163. Altertums. vol. i. I. Berlin.

1993, "Retrospect on J. C. Van Leur's Essay on the Eighteenth Century as a 1924, "Die Wirtschaftliche Entwicklung des Altertums", in E. Meyer, Kleine
Category in Asian History", Itinerario 17, I, pp. 45-58. Schriften, vol. I, 2nd edn, Halle, pp. 79-168.
Marx, K. and Engels, F. 1960, The First Indian. War of Independence, London. Meyer Elizabeth, A. 2004, Legitimacy and Law in the Roman World, Tabulae in
Masschale, J. 1993, "Transport Costs in Medieval England", Economic History Roman Belief and Practice, Cambridge.
Review46, pp. 266-279. Mickwitz, G. 1936, Die Kartellfunktionen der Zimfte und ihre Bedeutung bei der
Masters, B. 1988, The Origins of Western Economic Dominance in the Middle Entstehung des Zunftwesens, Helsinki.
East. Mercantilism and the Islamic Economy. 1600-1750, New York. 1937) "Economic Rationalism in Greco-Roman Agriculture", English Histor-
Matthews, J. P. 1984, "The Tax Law of Palmyra: Evidence for Economic History ical Review 52, pp. 577-589.
in a City of the Roman East", Journal of Roman Studies 74, pp. 157-180. Middleton, P. 1983, "The Roman Army and Long Distance Trade", in Garnsey
Mattingly, D. J. i988a,"0il for Export? A Comparison ofLibyan, Spanish and and Whittaker, pp. 75-83.
Tunisian Olive Oil Production in the Roman Empire", Journal of Roman Millar, F. 1964, A Study ofCassius Dio, Oxford.
Archaeology I, pp. 33-56. 1977; The Emperor in the Roman World, London.
i988b, "The Olive Boom: Oil Surpluses, Wealth and Power in Roman Tripoli- 1981, "The World of the Golden Ass", Journal of Roman Studies 71,
tania", Libyan Studies 19, pp. 21-41. pp. 63-75.
1996,"FirstFruit?TheOlivein theRomanWorld",in G. ShipleyandJ.Salmon 1993' The Roman Near East, j/ BC-AD 337, Cambridge, MA.
(eds. ), Human Landscapes in the Ancient World. Environment and Culture, 1998, "Caravan Cities: The Roman Near East and Long-Distance Trade by
London, pp. 213-253. Land, " in M. Austin, J. Harries and C. Smith (eds. ), Modus Operandi.
i997a; "Beyond Belief? Drawing a Line Beneath the Consumer City", in Essays in Honour of Geoffrey Rickman. Bulletin of the Institute of Classical
Parkins i997b, pp. 210-218. Studies 71, Supplement, London, pp. 119-137.
(ed. ) i997b. Dialogues in Roman Imperialism,JournalofRomanArchaeology i999> "The Greek East and Roman Law: The Dossier of M. Cn. Licinius
Supplementary Series 26, Ann Arbor, MI. Rufinus", Journal of Roman Studies, 89, pp. 90-108.

330 331
BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY

Miller, J. I. 1969, The Spice Trade of the Roman Empire, Oxford. Nafissi, M. 2005, Ancient Athens and Modern Ideology. Value, Theory and Evi-
Millett, M. 1990, The Romaniwtion of Britain. An Essay in Archaeological dence in Historical Sciences. Max Weher, Karl Polanyi and Moses Finley,
Interpretation, Cambridge. London.
Millett, P. 2001, "Productive to Some Purpose? The Problem of Ancient Eco- Needham,Joseph 1954, Science and Civilization in China,vol. I, Cambridge.
nomic Growth", in Mattingly and Salmon, pp. 17-48. Neesen, L. 1980, Untersuchungen w den direkten Staatsabgahen der romischen
Minnen, P. van 1986, "The Volume of the Oxyrhynchite Textile Trade , Kaiserzeit (27 v. Chr-284 n. Chr. ), Bonn.
Miinstersche Beitrdgewr Antiken Handelsgeschichte 5. 2, pp. 88-95. Neeve, P. W. de 1985, "The Price of Agricultural Land in Roman Italy and the
1987, "UrbanCraftsmen in Roman Egypt", Miinstersche Beitrdge ziirAntiken Problem of Economic Rationalism", Opus 4, pp. 77-109.
Handelsgeschichte 6, I, pp. 31-88. Nicolet, C. 1980, "Economie, societe et institutions au lie siecle av. J.-C. : De
Mirat-i-Ahmadi. A Persian History ofGujarat, by Ali Muhammad Khan, trans. la lex Claudia a 1'ager exceptus", Annales, Histoire, Sciences Sociales, pp.
M. F. Lokhandwala, Baroda 1965. 871-894.
Mitchell, S. 1993, Anatolia: Lcind, Men and Gods in Asia Minor, vols. 1-2, 1988, Rendre a Cesar. Economic et societe dans la Rome antique, Paris.
Oxford. 1991 a. Geography, Space and Politics in the Early Roman Empire, Ann Arbor,
Mitteis, L. 1891, Reichsret und Volksrecht in den ostlichen Provinzen des Ml.
rmnischen Kaiserreichs. Mit Beitrdgen wr Kenntnis des griechischen i99lb, "Le 'Monumentum Ephesenum' et les dimes d'Asie", Bulletin de Cor-
Rechts und der spatrdmischen Rechtsentwicklung, Leipzig. respondance Hellenique 115, pp. 465-480.
Mitteis, L. and Wilcken, U. 1912, Grunwge und Chrestomathie der i993i "Le 'Monumentum Ephesenum' et la delimitation duportorium d'Asie ,
Papyruskunde, vols. I-II, Leipzigand Berlin. Melanges de I'Ecole Fran^aise de Rome. Antiquite 105, pp. 929-959.
Modrzejewski, J. 1970, "La regle de droit dans 1'Egypte romaine", Proceedings 1996, Financial Documents and Geographical Knowledge in the Roman
of the XIIthInternational Congress ofPapyrology, Toronto, pp. 317-377- World. The Sixteenth J. L. Mvres Memorial Lecture. Oxford.
1990. Droit imperial et traditions locales dans I'Egypte romaine, Aldershot. Nijf, 0. M. van 1997,The CivicWorldofProfessionalAssociationsin the Roman
Mommsen, T. 1843, De collegiis et sodaliciis Romanorum, Kiel. East. Amsterdam.
[904, Romische Geschichte, vol. V, Berlin. Nippel, W. 1990, Griechen, Barbaren und "Wilde". Alte Geschichte und
1992, Romische Kaisergeschichte nach den Vorlesungen - Mitschriften van Sozialanthropologie, Frankfurt.
Sebastianund Paul Hensel 1882-86, ed. Barbara and Alexander Demandt, 1995, Public Order in Ancient Rome, Cambridge.
Munich. Nolle, J. 1999, "Marktrechte ausserhalbder Stadt: Lokale Autonomie zwischen
Montesquieu, C. 1955, De I'esprit des lois. Texte etahli et presente par Jean Statthalter und Zentralort", in Eck, pp. 93-114.
Brethe de la Gressaye. Paris. Non-, D. 1998,"RomischesZivilprozessrechtnachMax Kaser: Prozessrechtund
Moosvi, S. 1986-7,"TheGrossNationalProductoftheMughalEmpire,c. 1600", Prozesspraxis in der Provins Arabia", Zeitschrift der Savigny-Stiftung fur
Indian Historical Review 13, 1-2, pp. 75-87. Rechtsgeschichte. Romanistische Abteilung 115, pp. 80-98.
1987, The Economy of the Mughal Empire, c. 1595, Delhi. North, D. C. 1977, "Markets and Other Allocation Systems in History: The
2000, "The IndianEconomicExperience",in Panikkar,Byres and Patnaik,pp. Challenge of Karl Polanyi", Journal of European Economic History 6, 3,
328-358. pp. 703-716.
Morel, Jean Paul 1985, "La Manufacture. Moyen d'enrichissement dans 1'Italie 1990, Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance, Cam-
romaine", in Leveau, pp. 87-112. bridge.
Morley, Neville 1996, Metropolis and Hinterland. The City of Rome and the 2005, Understanding the Process of Economic Change, Princeton, NJ and
Italian Economy 200 B. C. -A. D. 200, Cambridge. Oxford.
2000, "Markets, Marketing and the Roman Elite", in Lo Cascio 2000a, pp. North, D. C. and Thomas, R. P. 1973, The Rise of the Western World. A New
21 I-223. Economic History, Cambridge.
2007,TradeinClassicalAntiquity. KeyThemesinAncientHistory,Cambridge. Noy, D. 2000, Foreigners at Rome. Citizens and Strangers, Swansea.
Morris, I. 2002, "Hard Surfaces", in Cartledge, Cohen and Foxhall, pp. 8-43. N0rlund, P. 1920, Det romerske slavesamfund under afvikling, Copenhagen.
Mouritsen, H. 1988, Elections, Magistrates and Municipal Elite. Studies in Pom- O'Brien, P. K. 1998, "Inseparable Connections: Trade, Economy, Fiscal State,
peian Epigraphy, Analecta Romana Instituti Daniel, Suppl. 15, Rome. and the Expansion of Empire, 1688-1815", in P. J. Marschall (ed. ), Oxford

332 333
BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY

History of the British Empire, vol. 2: The EighteenthCentury, Oxford, pp. Patterson. J. R. 1987, "Crisis: What Crisis? Rural Change and Urban Development
53-77. in Imperial Apennine Italy", Papers of the British School at Rome 55, pp.
Obeysekere, G. 1992, The Apotheosis of Captain Cook. European Mythmaking 115-146.
in the Pacific, Princeton, NJ. [ 99[- "Settlement, City and Elite in SamniumanclLycia",in RichandWallace-
Oliver, J. H. 1953, "The Ruling Power: A Study of the Roman Empire in the Hadrill. pp. 147-168.
Second Century After Christ Through the Roman Oration of Aelius Aris- 1994. "The Collegia and the Transformation of the Towns of Italy in the
teides". Transactions of the American Philosophical Society n. s. 43, 4, Second Century AD", in L'ltalie d'Augitste a Diocletien. Collection de
pp. 871-1003. I'Ecole Frangaise de Rome 198, Rome, pp. 227-238.
1989, Greek Constitutions of Early Roman Emperors from Inscriptions and 2006, Landscapes and Cities. Rural Settlement and Civic Transformation in
Papyri, Philadelphia,PA. Early Imperial Italy, Oxford.
Osborne, R. 1991, "Pride and Prejudice, Sense and Subsistence: Exchange and Pavis d'Escurac, H. 1976, La Prefectiire de I'annone, service administratif
Society in the Greek City". in Rich and Wallace-Hadrill, pp. 119-145. imperial d'Augiiste a Constantin, Rome.
[996> "Pots, Trade and the Archaic Greek Economy", Antiquity 70, pp. 31- 1977. "Anstocratie senatoriale et profits commerciaux", Kteina 2, pp. 339-
44. 355.
Paludan, H. 1995, Familia og Familie. To europceiske kulturelementers mipde i Peacock, D. P. S. and Williams. D. F. 1986, Amphorae and the Roman Economy,
hftjmiddelalderens Danmark, Aarhus. London.
1996, "Pots, Trade and the Archaic Greek Economy", Antiquity 70, pp. 31-44. Pearson, M. N. [976, Merchants and Rulers in Gujarat. The Response to the
Pamuk, 0. 2005, Istanbul. Memories ofthe City, trans. MaureenFreely, London. Portuguese in the Sixteenth Century, Berkeley, CA.
Pamuk, S. 2000, "The Ottoman Empire in the Eighteenth Century", Itinerario 1985, "Land, Noble, and Ruler in Mughal India", in E. Leach, S. N. Mukherjee
24, pp. 104-116. and J. 0. Ward (eds. ), Feiidalism. Comparative Studies, Sydney, pp. 175-
Panella, C. 1981, "La clistribuzione e i mercati", in Giardina and Schiavone, pp. 196.
55-8o. i988a. Before Colonialism. Theories of Asian-European Relations, New
1993; "Merci e scambi nel Mediterraneo tardoantico", in A. Schiavone (ed. ), Delhi.
Storia di Roma, vol. 3, 2, Turin, pp. 613-697. tQSSb,"Brokers in WesternIndianPort Cities:TheirRolein ServicingForeign
Panella, C. and Tchernia, A. 1994, "Produits agricoles transportes en amphores: Merchants", Modern Asian Studies 22, 3, pp. 445-472.
L'huile et surtout Ie vin" in L'ltalie d'Au^uste a Diocletien, Collection de 1991- "Merchants and States", in Tracy 1991, pp. 41-1i6.
I'Ecole Fran^aise de Rome 198, Rome, pp. 145-165. 1998, Port Cities and Intruders. The Swahili Coast, India, and Portugal in the
Panikkar, K. N., Byres, T. J. and Patnaik, U. (eds. ) 2000, The Making of History. Earlv Modern Era. Baltimore. MD and London.
Essays Presented to Irfan Hahib, New Delhi. Pearson, R. 1993, "Taking Risks and Containing Competition: Diversification
Parker, A. J. 1992, Ancient Shipwrecks of the Mediterranean and the Roman and Oligopoly in the Fire Insurance Markets in the North of England During
Provinces, BAR International Series 580, Oxford. the Early Nineteenth Century", Economic History' Review 46, I, pp. 39-
1996, "Sea Transport and Trade in the Ancient Mediterranean", in E, E. Rice 64.
(eds. ). The Sea and History, Gloucester, pp. 97-109. Pelsaert, F. 1925, Jahungir's India. The Remonstrantie of Francisco Pelsaert,
Parkins, H. i997a, "The 'Consumer-city' Domesticated? The Roman City in translated from the Dutch by W. H. Moreland and P. Geyl, Cambridge.
Elite Economic Strategies", in Parkins i997b, pp. 83-111. Perkins, D. 1969, Agricultural Development in China, 1368-1968, Chicago.
(ed. ) i997b, Roman Vrbanism Beyondthe Comsumer City, London. Perlin, F. 1978, "Of White Whale and Country-men in the Eighteenth-century
1998, "Time for Change? Shaping the Future of the Ancient Economy", in Maratha Deccan", Journalof Peasant Studies 5, 2, pp. 172-243.
Parkins and Smith, pp. 1-15. 1981, "The Pre-Colonial Indian State in History and Epistemology", in
Parkins, H. and Smith, C. 1998 (eds. ). Trade, Traders and the Ancient City, H. Claessen and P. Skalnik (eds. ). The Study of the State, The Hague,
London. pp. 275-302.
Parthasarathi, P. 2002, "Review Article: The Great Divergence", Past and Present 1983, "Proto-Industrializationand Pre-Colonial South Asia", Past andPresent
176, pp. 275-293. 98, pp. 30-95.
Paterson, J. 1998, "Trade and Traders in the Roman World: Scale, Structure, and [993> The Invisible City. Monetary, Administrative and Popular Infrastruc-
Organization", in Parkins and Smith, pp. 149-167. tures in Asia and Europe, lyM -igoo, Aldershot.

334 335
BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY

1994. "Changes in Production and Circulation of Money in Seventeenth and Prakash, 0. 1972, "The Dutch East India Company in Bengal: Trade Privileges
Eighteenth Century India: An Essay ofMonetization Before Colonial Occu- and Problems, 1633-1712", Indian Economic and Social History Review 9,
pation", in Subrahmanyam,pp. 276-306. pp. 258-287.
Persson, K. G. 1988, Pre-Industrial Economic Growth. Social Organization and 1985,The DutchEast IndiaCompany andthe Economy of Bengal, 1630-1720,
Technological Progress in Europe, Oxford. Princeton, NJ.
i999> Grain Markets in Europe , 500-7900. Integration and Deregulation, 1991. "Precious Metal Flows, Coinage and Prices in India in the i7th and
Cambridge. the Early 18th Century", in E. van Cauwenberghe (ed. ), Money, Coins and
Pflaum, H. G. 1950, Les Procurateurs equestres sous Ie Haut-Empire romain, Commerce. Essays in the Monetary History of Asia and Europe, Louvain,
Paris. PP. 55-73.
1960, Les Carrieres procuratoriennes equestres sous Ie Haut-Empire romain, (ed. ) 1997,EuropeanCommercialExpansionin Early ModemAsia. AnExpan-
vols. 1-3, Paris. ding World, vol. 10, Aldershot.
Picket, H. 1983, "Urban Elites and Business in the Greek Part of the Roman 1998, European Commercial Enterprise in Pre-Colonial India, The New Cam-
Empire", in Garnsey, Hopkins and Whittaker, pp. 131-144. bridge History of India 2, 5, Cambridge.
1984, "Urban Elites and the Economy in the Greek Cities of the Preisigke, F. 1910, Der Girowesen im griechischen Agypten, Strasbourg.
Roman Empire", Miinstersche Beitrcige zur Antiken Handelsgeschichte I, Pringsheim, F. 1950, The Greek Law of Sale, Weimar.
pp. 3-36. Ptak, R. and Rothermund, D. (eds. ) 1991, Emporia, Commodities and Entre-
[990, "Wirtschaft", in F. Vittinghoff (ed. ), Europdische Wirtschqfts- und preneurs in Asian Maritime Trade, c. 1400-1750, Stuttgart.
Sozialgeschichte in der romischen Kaiserzeit, Stuttgart, pp. 25-160. Purcell, N. 2005, "The Ancient Mediterranean: The View from the Customs
J 994, "The Roman State and the Economy: The Case ofEphesus", in Andreau, House", in W. V. Harris (ed. ), Rethinking the Mediterranean, Oxford, pp.
Briant and Descat et al., pp. i15-126. 200-232.
Pocock, J. G. A. 2003, Barbarism and Religion, vol. 3: The First Decline and Puqiura, G. 1985, "II regolamento doganale di Cauno e la lex Rhodia in D.
Fall, Cambridge. I4. 2. 9", Annali Seminario Giuridico della Universita di Palenno 38, pp.
Polanyi, K. 1957, "The Economy as Instituted Process", in Polanyi, Arensberg 273-331.
and Pearson, pp. 243-270. Qaisar, A. J. 1967, "Distribution of the Revenue Resources of the Mughal Empire
1963, "Ports of Trade in Early Societies", Journal of Economic History 23, I, among the Nobility", in Proceedings of the Twenty-Seventh Session of the
pp. 30-45. Indian History Congress, Aligarh, pp. 237-243.
I977> The Livelihood of Man, London. Quass,F. 1993, Die Honoratiorenschichtin denStddtendesgriechischenOstens.
Polanyi, K., Arensberg, C. and Pearson, H. (eds. ) 1957, Trade and Market in the Untersuchungen 7.ur politischen undso7. ialen Entwicklung in hellenistischer
Early Empires, New York. und romischer Zeit, Bonn.
Pollard, N. 2000, Soldiers, Cities, and Civilians in Roman Syria, Ann Arbor, Quereschi, J. H. 1966, The Administration of the Mughal Empire, Karachi.
MI. Rapsaet, G. 1987, "Aspects de 1'organisation du commerce de la ceramique
Pollock, S. 1998, "India in the Vernacular Millennium: Literary Culture and sigillee dans Ie Nord de la Gaule au lie siecle de notre ere, I: Les donnees
Polity", Daedalus 127, 3, pp. 41-75. materielles", Miinstersche Beitrdge wr antiken Handelsgeschichte 6, 2,
Pomeranz, K. 2000, The Great Divergence. China, Europe and the Making of pp. 1-29.
the Modern World Economy. Princeton. NJ. Rapsaet-Charlier,M.-T. andG. 1988,"Aspectsde 1'organisationdu commerce de
Pomey, P. and Tchernia, A. 1977, "Le tonnage maximum des navires de com- la ceramique sigillee dans Ie Nord de la Gaule au lie siecle de notre ere I: Les
merce romains", Archaeonautica 2, pp. 233-251. donnees materielles", Munstersche Beitrdge zur antiken Handelsgeschichte
Ponsich, M. 1998, "The Rural Economy of Western Baetica", in Keay, pp. 171- 7, 2, pp. 45-69.
l82. Raschke, M. G. 1978, "New Studies in Roman Commerce with the East",
Postan, M. M. 1972, The Medieval Economy and Society. An Economic History Aufstieg und Niedergang der romischen Welt 2, 9. 2, pp. 604-1378.
of Britain in the Middle-Ages, Birkenhead. Rathbone, D. 19830, "The Weight and Meassurement of Egyptian Grains",
Posthumus, N. W. 1946, Inquiry into the History of Prices in Holland, Leiden. Zeitschrift fiir Papyrologie und Epigraphik 53, pp. 265-275.
Prachner, G. 1980, Die Sklaven und Freigelassenen im Arretinischen Sigil- l983b, "Italian Wines in Roman Egypt", Opus 1, pp. 81-98.
latengewerbe, Wiesbaden.

336 337
BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY

1991, Economic Rationalism and Rural Society in Third-Centw-y A. D. Egypt, 2001, "Politik und Landwirtschaft im [mperium Romanum am Beispiel der
Cambridee. Baetica", in Peter Herz and Gerhard Waldherr (eds. ), Landwirtschaft im
1997' "Prices and Price Formation in Roman Egypt", in Andreau, Briant and Imperium Romanum, St Katharinen.
Descat et at.. pp. 183-244. Ren.eer, J. 2003, "Trade and Market in the Ancient Near East: Theoretical and
2000, "Ptoleinaic to Roman Egypt: The Death of the Dirigiste State?", in Lo Factual Implications", in Zaccagnini, pp. 15-39.
Cascio and Rathbone, pp. 44-55. Reynolds, P. 1995, Trade in the Western Mediterranean. AD: 400-700. The
2001, "The 'Muziris' Papyrus (SB XVI11 13167): Financing Roman Ceramic Evidence, BAR International Series 600, Oxford.
Trade with India", in Alexandrian Studies II in Honour of Mostafa el Ricarclo, D. 1996, Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, Great Minds
Abbadi, Bulletin de la Societe Archeologique d'Alexandrie 46, Alexandria, Series. Amherst. NY.
pp. 39-50. Rich, J. and Shipley, G. (eds. ) 1993, War and Society in the Roman World,
2003, "The Financing of Maritime Commerce in the Roman Empire, I-II AD", London and New York.
in Lo Cascio 2003b, pp. 197-230. Rich, J. and Wallace-Hadrill, A. (eds. ) 1991, City and Country in the Ancient
Rauh, N. 1986, "Cicero's Business Friendships, Economics and Politics in the World. London and New York.
Late Roman Republic", Aevum 60, pp. 3-30. Richards, J. F. 1975, MughalAdministration in Golconda, Oxford.
1989, "Auctioneers and the Roman Economy", Historia 38. pp. 451-471. 1981, "Mughal State Finance and the Premodern World Economy", Compar-
1993. The Sacred Bonds of Commerce. Religion, Economy, and Trade Society ative Studies in Society andHistory 23, pp. 285-308.
at Hellenistic Roman Delos, 166-87 B. C., Amsterdam. 1984, "Norms of Comportment among Imperial Mughal Officers", in B. D.
Ray, R. K. 1988, "The Bazaar: Changing Structural Characteristics of the Tndige- Metcalf (ed. ). Moral Conduct and Authority. The Place of Adab in South
nousSectionoftheIndianEconomy BeforeandAftertheGreatDepression", Asian Islam, Berkeley, CA, pp. 255-289.
Indian Economic and Social History Review 25, pp. 263-318. 1986, Document Forms for Official Orders of Appointment in the Mughal
Raychaudhuri, T. 1991, "The Commercial Entrepreneur in Pre-Cotonial India: Empire, Cambridge.
Aspirations and Expectations: A Note", in Ptak and Rothermund, pp. 339- (ed. ) 1987,The Imperial Monetary Systemof Mughal India, Delhi.
351. 1990> "The Seventeenth Century Crisis in South Asia", Modern Asian Studies
Rea, J. 1982, "P. Lond. Inv. [562 Versa: Market Taxes in Oxyrhynchus", 24, 4, PP. 625-638.
Zeitschrift fur Papyrologieund Epigraphik46, pp. 191-209. i993a. The Mughal Empire, The New Cambridge History of India I, 5,
Reed. M. 1996, "London and its Hinterland 1600-1800", in P. dark and B. Cambridge.
Lepetit (eds. ), Capital Cities and their Hinterlands in Early Modern Europe, i993b' Power, Administration, and Financein Mughal India, Aldershot.
Aldershot, pp. 51-83. Rickman, G. i98oa, The Corn Supply of Ancient Rome, Oxford.
Reger, G. 1994, Regionalism and Change in the Economy of Independent Delos, i98ob, "The Grain Trade under the Roman Empire", in D'Arms and Kopff,
Berkeley, CA. pp. 261-275.
2003, "Aspects of the Role of Merchants in the Political Life of the Hellenistic Rizzo, G. 2003, Instrwnenta Urhis I. Ceramiche fini da mensa, lucerne ed anfore
World", in Zaccagnini, pp. 165-198. a Roma nei primi due secoli dell'impero. Collection de 1'Ecole Fran^aise
Reinhardt, F. 1968, Kapitalaufwendungen der Gesellschqfter und Gesellscha- de Rome 307, Rome.
ftvermogen in der klassischen romischen Societas, Heidelberg. Robert, L. 1969, OperaMinora Selecta, vol. I, Amsterdam.
Reinmuth, 0. W. 1936, "Two Prefecturial Edicts Concerning The Publican", Roberto, U. 2003, '"Del commercio dei Romani': Politica e storia antica nelle
Classical Philology 31, pp. 146-162. riflessioni del Settecento", in Zaccagnini,pp. 327-361.
Remesal Rodrfguez, J. 1983, "Olproduktion und Olhandel in der Baetica", Robertson, J. 1997, "Gibbon's Roman Empire as a Universal Monarchy: The
Miinstersche Beitrdge wr Antiken Handelsgeschichte 2, 2, pp. 91-112. Decline and Fall and the Imperial Idea in Early Modern Europe", in R.
1986, La annona militaris y la exportation de aceite betico a Germania, McKitterick and R. Quinauldt (eds. ), Gibbon and Empire, Cambridge,
Madrid. pp. 247-270.
i997> Heeresversorgiing und die Wirtschaftlichen Beziehungen wischen der Roda, S. 1998, "II Senato nell'alto impero Romano", in // Senate nella storia.
Baetica und Germanien, Stuttgart. fnstituto Poligrafico e Zecca Dello Stato, Rome, pp. 129-221.
1998, "Baetican Olive Oil and the Roman Economy", in Keay, pp. 183- Rodger, A. 1996, "Postponed Business at Imi", Journal of Roman Studies 86,
199. pp. 61-73.

338 339
BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY

1997. "Vadimonium to Rome (and Elsewhere)", Zeitschrift der Savigny- Saller. R. 1982, Personal Patronage under the Early Empire, Cambridge.
Stiftung. Romanistische Abfeilung 114, pp. 160-196. i994t Patriarchy, Property and the Roman Family, Cambridge.
Rodinson, M. 1966, Islamet capitalisme, Paris. 2000, "Statusand Patronage",in The CambridgeAncient History, vol. XI, 2nd
Rodnguez-Almeida, E. 1984, // Monte Testaccio. Ambiente, storia, materiali, edn, Cambridge, pp. 817-854.
Rome. 2002, "Framing the Debate over Growth in the Ancient Economy , in Scheidel
Rostovtzeff, M. I. 1902, Geschichte der Staatspacht in der Romischen Kaiseneit and von Reden. pp. 25 1-269. (Also published in Morris and Manning 2005,
bis Diocletian, Philologiis, Suppl. 9, pp. 329-512. pp. 223-238.)
19323, Caravan Cities, trans. D. and T. Talbot-Rice, Oxford. Santucci, G. 1997, // socio d'opera in diritto romano. Conferimenti e respons-
l932b,"LesinscriptionscaravanieresdePalmyre",in MelangesGustaveGlotz, abilita. Padua.
vol. II, Paris, pp. 792-811. Salmeri, G. 1998, "Per una lettura dei capitoli V-VII Della Storia economica e
i957>The SocialandEconomic History ofthe RomanEmpire,2ndedn, revised sociale dell'Impero Romano di M. Rostovtzeff, Athenaeum 86, pp. 57-84.
by P. M. Fraser, Oxford. Sarris, P. 2006, Economy and Society in the Age ofJustinian,Cambridge.
Rothermunci, D. 1991, "Asian Emporia and European Bridge-Heads", in Ptak Sartre, J. -P. 1961, "Preface", in Franz Fanon, Les Damnes de la terre, Paris.
and Rothermund, pp. 3-8. Sartre, M. 1991, L 'Orient romain. Provinces et societes provinciales en
Rotschild, M. 1973, "Models ofMarket Organization with Imperfect Information: Mediterranee orientale d'Auguste aux Severes (31. avant J.C. -2J5 apres
A Survey", Journalof Political Economy 81. pp. 1283-1308. J. C. ), Paris.
Rouge, J. 1966, Recherches sur I'organisation du commerce maritime en Scheidel, W. 2000, Debciting Roman Demography, Leiden.
Mediterranee soils I'empire remain, Paris. 2002, "A Model of Demographic and Economic Change in Roman Egypt after
1980, "Pret et societe maritime dans Ie monde romain", in D'Arms and Kopff, the Antonine Plague", Journalof Roman Archaeology 15, pp. 97-114-
pp. 291-303. 2007a, "Demography", in I. Morris, R. Saller and W. Scheidel (eds. ). The
1981, Ships and Fleets of the Ancient Mediterranean, trans. Susan Frazer, Cambridge Economic History of the Greco-Roman World, Cambridge,
Middleton, CT. pp. 38-86.
1985, Droit romain et sources de richesses non foncieres", in Leveau 1985, 2007b, "A Model of Real Income Growth in Roman Italy", Historia 56, pp.
pp. 161-176. 332-346.
Royden, H. L. 1988, The Magistrates of the Roman Professional Collegia in (ed. ) 2008, Rome and China: Comparative Perspectives on Ancient World
Italy. From the First to the Third Century A. D., Pisa. Empires, New York.
Ruggini, L. C. 1973, "Stato e associazioni professionali nell'eta imperiale Scheidel. W. and von Reden, S. 2002, The Ancient Economy, Edinburgh.
romana in Akten des VI. Internationalen Kongresses fur Griechische imd Schiavone, Aldo 2000, The Endof the Past, Cambridge, MA.
Lateinische Epigraphik, Munich, pp. 271-311. Schleich, T. 1983, "Uberlegungen zum Problem senatorischer Handelsak-
Ruprechtsberger, E. M. (ed. ) 1987, Palmyra. Geschichte, Kunst und Kultur der tivitaten. Teil I. Senatorische Wirtschaftsmentalitat in modemer und antiker
Syrischen Oasenstadt, Linz. Deutung", Miinstersche Beitrdge wr antiken Handelsgeschichte i, 2,
Sabloff, J. A. and Lamberg-Karlowsky, C. C. (eds. ) 1975, Ancient Civiliwtion pp. 65-90.
and Trade, Albuquerque, NM. [984, "Oberlegungen zum Problem senatorischer Handelsaktivitaten. Teil
Sahlins, M. 1972, Stone Age Economics, Chicago. 2. Zwischen 'otium' und 'negotium': Gelegenheitsunternehmungen und
I995> ^iow "Natives" Think About Captain Cook For example, Chicago and domestizierte Wirtschaft", Miinstersche Beitrdge wr antiken Handels-
London. geschichte 3, [, pp. 37-76.
2000, "Cosmologies of Capitalism: The Trans-Pacific Sector of 'The World Schmidt-Colinet, A., Stauffer, A. and Al-A.s'ad, Khaled 2000, Die Textilien aus
System'", in M. Sahlins, Culture in Practice. Selected Essays, New York, Palmyra, Mainz.
pp. 415-469. Schneider, H. 1990, "Die Biicher-Meyer Kontroverse", in Calder and Demandt,
Said, E. 1978, Orientalism. Western Conceptions of the Orient, New York and pp. 417-445.
London. Schneider, Jane. 1977, "Was there a Pre-capitalist World System?", Peasant
1993, Culture and Imperialism, London. Studies 6, I, pp. 30-39.
Sallares, R. 2002, Malaria and Rome. A History of Malaria in Ancient Italy, Schneider, Jiirgen 1986, "The Significance of Large Fairs, Money Markets and
Oxford. Precious Metals in the Evolution of a World Market from the Middle Ages to

340 341
BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY

the First HalfoftheNineteenthCentury", in Fischer,MclnnisandSchneider, Skinner, G. W. 1964, "Marketing and Social Structure in Rural China", Journal
pp. 15-36. of Asian Studies 24, I, pp. 3-43; 24, 2, pp. 195-228; and 24, 3. pp. 363-
Schwarz, H. 2001a, "Anmerkungen zu der Zollinschrift aus Myra", Epigraphica 399.
Anatolica 33, pp. 15-37. Skocpol, T. 1979, States and Social Revolutions. A Comparative Analysis of
2001 b, Die Finanwirtschaft kleinasiatischer Stdclte in der romischen France, Russia and China, Cambridge.
Kaiserwt, Bonn. Skocpol, T. and Sommers, M. 1980, "The Uses of Comparative Historical
Schwarz,L. D. 1992, Londonin the Age oflndustricilization,Cambridge. Inquiry", Comparative Studies in Society and History 22, pp. 174-194.
Scullard, H. H. 1980, A History of the Roman World 753 to 146, 4th edn, London. Skydsgaard,J. E. 1976, "The Disintegrationof the Roman LabourMarket and
Selancl,T. 1996."PhiloandtheClubs andAssociationsofAlexandria",in Klop- the Clientela Theory", in K. Ascani et al., Studia Romana in Honorem Petri
penborg and Wilson, pp. I [0-127. Krarup Septuagenarii,Odense, pp. 44-48.
Serrao, F. 2000, "Impresa, mercato, diritto: riflessioni minime", in Lo Cascio i997> "Theodor Mommsens romerske kejserhistorie", Historisk Tidsskrift 97,
2000C, pp. 31-68. 2, pp. 305-3I 2.
Shanin,T. (ed. ) 1987, Peasantsand Peasant Societies, 2nd edn, Oxford. Smith, Adam 1976, An Inquiry' into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of
Sharma, R. S. 1970, "The Ardha-Kathanak: A Neglected Source of Mughal Nations. Oxford.
History", Indica7, pp. 49-73 and 106-120. Smith, Anthony, D. 1986, The Ethnic Origin of Nations, London.
Sharp, M. 1998, The Food Supply in Roman Egypt, D. Phil. thesis. University of Snell, R. 2005, "Confessions of a 17th-century Jain Merchant: The Ar-
Oxford. dhakathanak of Banarasfdas", South Asia Research 25, pp. 79-104.
Shatzman, I. 1975, Senatorial Wealth and Roman Politics, Brussels. Sombart, W. 1913, Luxusund Kapitcilismus. Leipzig.
Shaw,B. D. 1981,"RuralMarketsin North AfricaandthePoliticalEconomyof Sommer, M. 2005, Roms orientalische Steppengreiw. Palmyra-Edessa-Dura-
the Roman Empire", Antiquitates Africanae 17, pp. 37-83. Eiiropos-Hatra. Eine Kiilturgeschichte van Pompeius bis Diocletian, Wies-
1984, "Bandits in the Roman Empire", Past and Present 105, pp. 3-52. baden.
2001, "Challenging Braudel: A New Vision of the Mediterranean", Journal of S0rensen, G. 1994, "Hvad er udvikling?", Den Jyske Historiker 66, pp. 19-32.
Roman Archaeology 14, pp. 1-25. Steensgaard, N. 19730, Carracks, Caravans and Companies. The Structural
Sherk, R. K. 1955, "The Inermes Provinciae of Asia Minor", American Journal Crisis in the European Asian Trade in the Early i-jth Century, Odense.
ofPhilology 76, pp. 400-413. l973b, "Universal History for Our Times", Journal of Modem Histoi-y 45,
1957, "Roman Imperial Troops in Macedonia and Achaea", American Journal pp. 72-82.
ofPhilology 78, pp. 52-62. 1980, "Asian Trade i5th-i8th Centuries: Continuity and Discontinuities",
(ed. and trans. ) 1988, The Roman Empire. Augustus to Hadrian, Cambridge. XVe Congres International des Sciences Historu/ues Rapports II, Bucharest,
Sherwin-White,A. N. 19730,The Roman Citizenship, 2nd edn, Oxford. pp. 488-500.
I973b, The Tabula of Banasa and the Constitutio Antoniniana", Journal of 1981, "Violence and the Rice of Capitalism: Frederic C. Lane's Theory of
Roman Studies 63, pp. 86-98. Protection and Tribute", Review 5, 2, pp. 247-273.
Sijpestein, P. J. 1987, Customs Duties in Graeco-Roman Egypt. Studia Amster- 1984, "Set t'ra 1984. En model for nyere tids verdenshistorie", in Tradition
damensia ad Epigraphicam, lus Antiquum et Papyrologicam Pertinentia 17, 0,1; Kritik. Festskrift til Svencl Elleh0j den 8. September 1984, Copenhagen,
Zutphen. pp. 413-435.
Singh, C. 1988, "Centre and Periphery in the Mughal State: The Case of 1987, "The Indian Ocean Network and the Emerging World-Economy
Seventeenth-century Panjab", Modern Asian Studies 22, pp. 299-318. (c. 1550-1750)", in S. Chandra (ed. ). The Indian Ocean. Explorations in
Singh, M. P. 1972, "Merchants and the Local Administration and Civic Life in Hlston, Commerce, and Politics, New Delhi, pp. 125-150.
Gujarat During the [ 7th Century", in Medieval India. A Miscellany, vol. 2, i990a, "The Growth and Composition of the Long-distance Trade of England
pp. 221-226, n. p. and the Dutch Republic before 1750", in Tracy, pp. 102-152.
1985, Town, Market, Mint and Port in the Mughal Empire, 1556-1707, New l99°b, "Opdagelsemes plads i verdenshistorien. Varer, ^delmetal og Tjene-
Delhi. steydelser i International Handel f0r 1750", Historisk Tidsskrift 90,
Sirks, B. 1991, Food for Rome, Amsterdam. pp. 221-246.
2002, "Sailing in the Off-Season with Reduced Financial Risk", in Aubert and I990C, "The Seventeenth-Century Crisis and the Unity ot'Eurasian History ,
Sirks, pp. 134-150. Modern Asian Studies 24, 4, pp. 683-697.

342 343
BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY

1991. "Emporia: Some Reflections", in Ptak and Rothermund, pp. 9-12. Tandrup, L. 1979, Ravn, vols. 1-2, Viborg.
Stein, A. 1927, Der romische Ritterstand. Ein Beitrag wr social- und personen- Tate, G. 1992, Les Campagnes de la Syrie du nord du lie au Vile siecle. Un
ffeschichte des romischens Reiches, Munich. exemple d expansiondemographu/ue et economique a la fin de I'antiquite,
Stein, B. 19853, "State Formation and the Economy Reconsidered. Part I", Paris.
Modern Asian Studies 19, 3, pp. 387-413. Taubenschlag,R. 1955,The Lawof'Greco-RomanEgyptinthe Lightofthe Papyri
i985b, "Politics, Peasants and the Deconstruction of Feudalism in Medieval (332 B. C. -A. D. 640), 2nd edn, Warsaw.
India", in Byres and Mukhia, pp. 54-86. Tavernier, J. B. 1889, Tavernier's Travels in India, vols. 1-2, ed. and trans.
1998. A History of India, Oxford. V. Ball, London (original French edn 1676).
Stigler, G. J. and Sherwin, R. A. 1985, "The Extent of the Market", Journal of Tchemia, A. 1983,"ItalianWinein Gaul at the Endofthe Republic", in Gamsey,
Law and Economics 28, pp. 554-577. Hopkins and Whittaker, pp. 87-102.
Stocking G. W., Jr 1995, After Tylor. British Social Anthropology TSSS-rgyr, 1986, Le Vin de I'ltalie romaine, Paris.
London. 1989, "Encore sur les modeles economiques et les amphores", in Amphores
Stoianovich, T. 1974, "Pour un modele du commerce du Levant: economie con- romaines et histoire economique. Dix ans de recherche. Collection de
currentielle et economie de Bazar 1500-1800", Bulletin. Association Inter- i'Ecole Fran^aisede Rome I 14, Rome, pp. 529-536.
nationale d'Eludes du Sud-Est Europeen 12, 2, pp. 6[-120. 1992, "Le dromadaire des Peticii et Ie commerce Oriental", Melanges de
1994, "Cities, Capital Accumulation, and the Ottoman Balkan Command I'Ecole Frangaisede Rome. Antiqiiite 104, pp. 293-301.
Economy, 1500-1800", in Tilly and Blochmans, pp. 60-99. 1995, "Moussons et monnaies: les voies du commerce entre Ie monde Greco-
Stuart, P. and Bogaers, J. E. (eds. ) 1971, Deae Nehalenniae. Gids Bij De Ten- Romain et 1'Inde", Annales. Histoire, Sciences Sociales 50, pp. 991-1009.
toonstelling Mehalennia de Zeeuwse Godin, Leiden. 2000, "Lavente du vin", in Lo Cascio 20000, pp. 199-211.
2001, Nehalennia. Romische Steindenkmdler aus der Oosterschelde hei Co- (ed. ) 2005, Autour de la rationalite antique, in Topoi. Orient-Occident 12-13,
lijnsplaat, Leiden. pp. 259-314.
Subrahmaniam, L. 1999, "India's International Economy, 1500-1800", Indian 2006, "Lacrise de L'ltalie imperialeet la concurrencedesprovinces", Cahiers
Historical Review 25, 2, pp. 38-57. du Centre de Recherches Historiques 37, pp. 137-156.
Subrahmanyam,S. 1989,"StateFormationandTransformationin Early Modem Teixiclor,J. 1984, Un Port romaindu desert. Palmyre et soncommerce d'Auguste
India and Southeast Asia", in P. J. Marshall etal. (eds. ) India and Indonesia a Caracalla, Semitica 34, Paris.
during the Ancien Regime, Leiden, pp. 91-109. Temin, P. 2001, "A Market Economy in the Early Roman Empire", Journal of
(ed. ) 19900, Merchants, Markets and the State in Early Modem India. Delhi. Roman Studies 91, pp. 169-181.
i99ob.The Political Economyof Commerce, Cambridge. 2006, "Estimating GDP in the Early Roman Empire", in E. Lo Cascio (ed. ),
(ed. ) 1994, Money and the Market in India i loo-f/oo, Delhi. Innovawme tecnica e progresso economico nel mondo romano. Ban,
1995."OflmaratandTijarat: AsianMerchantsandStatePowerin theWestern PP. 31-54.
Indian Ocean, 1400 to 1750", Comparative Studies in Society and History Temin, P. andKessler, D. 2007 "The Organizationofthe GrainTrade in the Early
37, PP. 750-780. Roman Empire", Economic History Review 60, 2, pp. 313-332.
(ed.) 1996, Merchant Networks in the Early Modern World, An Expanding Thebert, Y. 1980, "Economie, societe et politique aux deux demieres siecles de
World 8, Aldershot. la republique romaine", Annales. Histoire, Sciences Sociales,pp. 875-911.
I998' "Hearing Voices: Vignettes of Early Modernity in South Asia, 1400- Thompson, E. P. 1993, Customs in Common. Studies in Traditional Popular
l750"> Daedalus 127, 3, pp. 75-104. Culture, New York.
Swain, S. 1996, Hellenism and Empire. Language, Classicism, and Power in the Thrupp, S. L. 1958, "Editorial", Comparative Studies in Society and History I,
GreekWorld, AD50-250, Oxford. PP. 1-4.
Syme, R. 1958, Tacitus, vols. 1-2, Oxford. Tilly, C. 1984, Big Structures, Large Processes, Huge Comparisons, New York.
1977. La richesse des aristocraties Betique et de Narbonnaise", Ktema 2, I992' Coercion, Capital and European States, A. D. 990-7992, Oxford.
pp. 373-380. Tilly, C. and Blockmans, W. (eds. ) 1994, Cities and the Rise of States in Europe,
Talamanca, M. 1955, "Contributi allo studio delle vendite all'asta nel mondo A. D. 1000-1800, Boulder, CO.
classico", Atti della Accademia Nawmale dei Lincei 6, pp. 35-251. Tomber,R. 1993,"QuantitativeApproachesto theInvestigationofLong-Distance
Talbert, R. J. A. 1984, The Senate in Imperial Rome, Princeton, NJ. Exchange",Journal of Roman Archaeology 6, pp. 142-166.

344 345
BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY

Toner, J. P. 1995, Leisure and Ancient Rome. Cambridge. Reich", Zeitschrift der Savigny-Stiftung fur Rechtsgeschichte. Romanistis-
Torri, M. 1998,"MughalNobles, IndianMerchants, and the Beginningof British che Abteilung 110, pp. 14-59.
Conquest in Western India: The Case of Surat 1756-59", Modern Asian 1994. "Die adjektivischen Klagen im Uberblick, I: Von der Reeder- und der
Studies 32. 2. pp. 257-315. Betriebsleiterklage zur direkten Stellvertretung", Zeitschrift der Savigny-
Tracy, J. D. (ed. ) 1990, The Rise of Merchant Empires. Long-DistanceTrade in Snftungfur Rechtsgeschichte. Romanistische Ahteilung I[I, pp. 280-362.
the Earlv Modern World. Cambridse. Wagner, D. 2001, "The Administration of the Iron Industry in Eleventh Century
(ed. ) [991, The Political Economy of Merchant Empires, Cambridge. China", Journal of the Social and Economic History of the Orient 44, 2,
Treadgold, W. 1997, A History ofthe Byzantine State and Society, Stanford, CA. pp. 175-197.
Tylor, E. B. 1871, Primitive Culture, London. Wallace-Hadrill, A. (ed. ) 1989, Patronage in Ancient Society, London and New
Udovitch, A. L. 1962, "At the Origins of the Western Comm. enda: Islam, Israel, York.
Byzantium", Speculum 37, pp. 198-207. 1991. "Elites and Trade in the Roman Town", in Rich and Wallace-Hadrill
1970. Partnership and Profit in Medieval Islam, Princeton, NJ. 1991. PP. 241-272.
Veblen, T. 1899, The Theory of the Leisure Class, New York. 1994, Houses and Society in Pompeii and Herculaneum, Princeton, NJ.
Velissaropoulos, J. 1980, Les Naucleres grecs, Paris. Wallerstein, I. 1974;!, The Modern World-System, vol. I, San Diego, CA.
Vera, D. 1994, "L'ltalia agraria nell'eta imperiale: Fra crisi e transformazione", l974b, "TheRiseandFutureDemiseofthe WorldCapitalistSystem: Concepts
in L'ftalie d'Aujfuste a Diocletien, Collection de 1'Ecole Fran^aise de Rome for Comparative Analysis", Comparative Studies in Society andHistory 16,
198, Rome, pp. 239-248. pp. 387-415.
Verboren, K. 2002, The Eccmomy of Friends. Economic Aspects of "Amicitia" 1979. "The Ottoman Empire and the Capitalist World-Economy: Some Ques-
and Patronage in the Late Republic. Collection Latomus 269, Brussels. tions for Research", Review 2, 3, pp. 389-398.
Vemhet, A. 1991, La Graufesenque ceramiques gallo-romaines, Millau. Waltzing,J. P. 1895-1900,Etude historique sur les corporationsprofessionelles
Veyne, P. 1961, "Vie de Trimalchion", Annales ESC 16, pp. 213-247. chez. les Roinains, vols. 1-4, Louvain.
1971, Comment on ecrit I'histoire. Essai d'epistemologie, Paris. Watson, A. 1992.The Evolutionof InternationalSociety. A Comparative Histor-
i97^a L'lnventaire des differences, Paris. ical Analvsis. London.
i976b, Le Pain et Ie cirque, Paris. (Published in English, 1990.) Weber, M. 19200, "Die protestantische Ethik und der Geist des Kapitalismus",
1979. "Rome devant la pretendue t'uite de I'or: mercantilisme ou politique Gesammelte Aufsatze zur Religionssoziologie,vol. I, Ttibingen.
disciplinaire?", Annales ESC, pp. 21 1-241. i920b, 'Vorwort' in M. Weber, Gesammelte Aufsdtz. e zur Religionssoziologie
i990> Bread and Circuses, trans. B. Pearce, London. vol. I, Tiibingen.
Virlouvet, C. (ed. ) 1997, La Rome imperiale. Demographie etlogistique, Rome. 1922, Gesammelte Aufsiitz.e zur Wissenschaftslehre,Tiibingen.
Visscher, F. de 1940, Les edits d'Auguste decouverts a Cyrene, Louvain. l924a: "Agrarverhaltnisse im Altertum", Gesammelte Aufsdtz. e wrSozial- und
Vittinghof,F. ic)^, "PoTtoTmm", Paulys RealencyclopddiederclassischenAlter- Wirtschaftsgeschichte, pp. 1-288, Tubingen.
tumswissenschaft, 22, i, cols. 346-399. i924b: "Die sozialen Grunde des Untergangs der antiken Kultur", Gesammelte
Voltaire, P. M. A. de 1963, Essai sur les moeurs et I'esprit de nations et sur les Aufsdtzezur Sozial-undWirtschaftsgeschichte,pp. 289-311,Tubingen.
principaux fails de I 'histoire depuis Charlemagne jusqii 'a Louis XIII, 2 vols., 19240: "Zur Geschichte der Handelsgesellschaften im Mittelalter", Gesam-
Paris. melte Aufsdtze wr Social- und Wirtschaftsgeschichte, Tiibingen, pp. 312-
Vries,J.de 1976, EconomyofEurope inan AgeofCrisis , 600-7750,Cambridge. 443.
1984, European Urbanization, 1500-1800, London. 1972, Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft, Tubingen.
1990; "Problems in the Measurement, Description, and Analysis of Historical Wee, C. J. 1997, "Framingthe New East Asia", in R. Salim (ed. ), "The Clashof
Urbanization", in A. Woude, A. Hayomi and J. de Vries (eds. ), Urbcin- Civilizations?" Asian Responses, Karachi, Oxford and New York, chapter
ization in History. A Process of Dynamic Interactions, Oxford, pp. 43- 5.
6o. Weeber, K. -W. 2003, Luxus im alten Rom. Die Schwelgerei, das siisse Gift,
Vries, J. de and Woude, A. 1997, The First Modern Economy. Success, Failure Darmstadt.
and Perseverance of the Dutch Economy, 1500-1800, Cambridge. 2006, Liixus im alien Rom. Die dffentliche Pracht, Darmstadt.
Wacke, A. 1993, "Gallisch, Punisch, Syrisch oder Griechisch statt latein? Zur Whitbread, I. K. 1995, Greek Transport Amphorae. A Petrological andArchae-
Schrittweisen Gleichberechtigung der Geschaftssprachen im romischen ological Study, Athens.

346 347
BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY

Whittaker, C. R. 1985, "Tradeand the Aristocracy in the Roman Empire", Opus, Wolff, H. J. etal. 1978, Handhuch der Altertumswissenschaft, 10. 5. 2: Das Recht
International Journal for Social and Economic History of Antiquity 4, pp. dergriechischenPapyriAgyptens in cierZeitderPtolemaeerund des Prinzi-
49-75. pats, Munich.
1989, "Amphorae and Trade", in Amphores romaines et histoire economiqiie. 1980, "Romisches Provinzialrecht in der Provinz Arabia", Aufstieg imdNieder-
Dixans de recherche. Collection de 1'Ecole Fran^aisede Rome 114, Rome, gang der RomischenWelt 2, 13, pp. 763-806.
PP. 537-539. Walters, R. 1999, Nummi Signati. Untersiichungen zur rdmischen Mimzpragung
i993> Land, City andTrade in the Roman Empire, Aldershot. und Geldwirtschaft, Munich.
i994a> Frontiers of the Roman Empire. A Social, and Economic Study, Balti- Wong, R. B. 1997, ChinaTransformed, Ithaca, NY.
more. MD. Woolf, G. 1990, "World-systems Analysis and the Roman Empire", Journal of
i994b, "The Politics of Power: The Cities of Italy", in L'ltalie d'Auguste a Roman Archaeology 6, pp. 44-58.
Diocletien, Collection de 1'Ecole Fran^aise de Rome 198, Rome, pp. 127- 1992, "Imperialism, Empire and the Integration of the Roman Economy",
i43. World Archaeology 23, 3, pp. 282-293.
l995> "Do Theories of the Ancient City Matter?", in Cornell and Lomas, 1993. "RomanPeace", in Rich and Shipley, pp. 171-194.
pp. 9-26. 1997. "The Roman Urbanization of the East", in Alcock 19970, pp. 1-14.
2002, "Proto-industrialization in Roman Gaul", in Karen Ascani et al. (eds. ), 1998, Becoming Roman. The Origins of Provincial Civilimtion in Gaiil, Cam-
Ancient History Matters. Studies Presentedto Jens Erik Skydsgaardon His bridge.
SeventiethBirthday, Analecta RomanaInstitutiDanielSuppl. 30, pp. l 1-22. 2001,"RegionalProductionsin Early RomanGaul", in Mattingly and Salmon,
Wickham, C. 1984, "The Other Transition: From the Ancient World to Feudal- pp. 49-65.
ism". Past mul Present 103, pp. 3-36. Wrigley, E. A. 1987, Peoples, Cities and Wealth. The Transformation ofTradi-
1985, "The Uniqueness of the East", Journal of Peasant Studies 12, pp. 167- tional Society. Oxford.
196. 1988, Continuity, Chance and Change. The Character of the Industrial Revo-
1988, "Marx, Sherlock Hoknes and Late Roman Commerce", Journal of lution in England, Cambridge.
Roman Studies 78, pp. 183-193. Yang, A. A. 1998, Bazaar India. Markets, Society, and the Colonial State in
2005, Framing the Early Middle Ages, Oxford. Gangetic Bihar, Berkeley, Los Angeles and London.
Wierschowski, L. 1995, Die Regionale Mobilitat in Gallien nach dem Inschriften Yaron, R. [964 "Reichsrecht, Volksrecht and Talmud", Revue Internationale des
des f. -3. Jahrhunderts n. Chr., Historia Einzelschriften 91, Stuttgart. Droits de I'Antiquite, yd ser. 2, pp. 281-298.
Will, E. 1957, "Marchandset chefs de caravannesa Palmyre", Syria34, pp. 262- Yon. J.-B. 2002. Les Notables de Palrnvre. Beirut.
277. Young, G. 2001, Rome's Eastern Trade. International Commerce and Imperial
1992, Les Palmyreniens. LaVenise des sables (ler siecle avant- IIIemesiecle Policy, 31 BC-AD 305, London.
apres J. C. ), Paris. Zaccagnini,C. (ed. ) 2003, Mercanti e politica net mondo antico, Rome.
Wills, J. E., Jr. 1993, "Maritime Asia, 1500-1800: The Interactive Emergence of Zanker, P. 1987, Augustus und die Macht der Bilder, Munich (English
European Domination", American Historical Review 98, pp. 83-105. translation by A. Shapiro, Ann Arbor, MI, 1988.)
Wilson, A. 2001, "Timgad and Textile Production", in Mattingly and Salmon, Zelener, Yan 2006, "Between Technology and Productivity", in E. Lo Cascio
pp. 271-296. (ed. ), Innowione tecnica e progresso economico net mondo romano. Ban,
2002,"Machines,PowerandtheAncientEconomy",JournalofRomanStudies pp. 303-18.
92, pp. 1-32. Zevi, F. 1989. "Introduzione", in Amplwres romaines et histoire economique.
Wink, A. 1989, " 'Al-Hind' India and Indonesiain the Islamic World-Economy, Dix ans de. recherche. Collection de I'Ecole Fran^aise de Rome 114, Rome,
ca. 700-18oo",in P.J.Marshalletal., IndiaandIndonesiaduringthe Ancien pp. 3-19.
Regime, Leiden, pp. 33-72. Ziche, H. 2006, "Integrating Late Roman Cities, Countryside and Trade", in
Wittfogel,K. A. 1957,OrientalDespotism: A ComparativeStudy ofTotalPower, Bang, Ikeguchi and Ziche, pp. 255-276.
New Haven, CT. Ziegler, K. -H. 1971, Das private Schiedsgericht im antiken romischen Recht,
Wolf, E. 1966, Peasants, Englewood Cliffs, NJ. Munich.
1982, Europe and the People Without History, Berkeley and Los Angeles. Zimmermann, R. 1990, The Law of Obligations. Roman Foundations of the
Wolff, C. 2003, Les Brigands en orient sous Ie haut-empire romain, Rome. Civilian Tradition, Cape Town.

348 349
BIBLIOGRAPHY

0rsted, P. 1985, Roman Imperial Economy and Romanization, Copenhagen.


2000, "Roman State Intervention? The Case of Mining in the Roman Empire",
in Lo Cascio and Rathbone. pp. 70-76.
INDEX
0rsted, P., Carlsen, J., Ladjimi Sebai, L. and Ben Hassen, H. (eds. ) 2000, Africa
Proconsularis. RegionalStudiesinthe SegennesValley ofNorthernTunisia,
vol. 3: Historical Conclusions, Aarhus.
0stergard, U. 1973, "Den Antikke Procluktionsmade. Oversigt over histo-
rieskrivningen om forholdet mellem 0konomi og samfund i Antikken", Den
Jyske Historiker 5-6, pp. 4-42. AbuaI-Fazl 83 archaeology 2-3, 35, 288, 304
1976. "Studiet af ferkapitalistiske samfundsforhold - Mulighed og relevans. adulteration of goods 194 and economic integration 74, 287-9
Teoretiske og metodiske problemer". Den Jyske Historiker 6. pp. 52- Africa 2, 73, 77 difference in scale between Greek and

135. agency see business managers Roman economy 114


1996, "The Meaning of Europe - Empire, Nation-states, Civilization", Agra 9. 145. >99 Arezzo 288

Arhejdspapirer fra Center for Kulturforskning, Aarhiis Vniversitet 29, agrarianate society 11, 43-5, 85 see also terra sif;illata
Aarhus. status and contract 18-19 Aristeides, Publius Aelius 290-1
agricultural economy, limits of i 16-19 aristocratic investment in trade 270,
1997' "Hvad nu hvis. . . Kontrafaktiske hypoteser og "abne" situationer i his-
agricultural surplus, disposable 282-4
tone og historiefbrskning", Arbejdspapirerfra Centerfor Kulturforskning, commercialisation of [ 19-2 l Arles 247
Aarhus Universitet 46, Aarhus. quantification ot 91-3 army, Roman and Mughal 94
and the state 84-5 tasks of the Roman 233-4, 240
see also agriculture and trade Asian Customs Law 204-38 passim
agriculture 6 A.skalon 273
and trade 22-4. 50-2, 77-9 Assyrian merchants 30
Akbar 80 see also Mesopotamia, ancient
Akerlof, G. 139-40 Attalid kingdom 221
Aleppo 305 Augsburg 55
Alexander Severus 277 Aueusta Troas 216
Alexandria 77, 126, 142, 177-9, 228-9, Augustine 247
238, 245, 273. 281-305 Augustus 216
amphorae 35, 73. 74, 194-5, 273 Aurangzeb 80, 215, 244, 245
Amsterdam 147 Aztec Empire 7
Anatolia 227
Annales historians 34 Babatha archive 185-6
annona 247 Babur 79
see also redistribution Babylon 154, 254
anthropology 6, 24-5, 35> 37 Baltic grain trade 147
see also bazaar: Geertz; Malinowski; Banarasidas 150-1, 239, 243, 250, 260-1,
"otherness"; Polanyi; Sahlins 269
Antioch 126, 142, 177, 179 bandits 226
famine of 143-4 Bayly, C. A. 257, 302
Antonine emperors 61 bazaar 1-2, 6, 12, 129, 131, 294-6
Antonine Plague 86, 123-5, asymmetries and imbalances of 149-50
173 commercial strategies of 199-289
Antoninus Pius 108 passim
Apuleius 137, l5l community 240-68, 296-8
Arabia 202 definition of 4, 197-201
Arcadia (late Roman province in imperial styles of
Egypt) 157-66 consumption 294-301, 306

350 351
INDEX INDEX

bazaar (conf.) concessions obtained from Mughal Corrupting Sea, The 27, fd-l, 136-7 market integration in 153-73
local monopolies of 139-40, 143-6, emperor by 213-14 see also connectivity; ecology; Pharaonic 19
200 coordination of markets 145-6 primitivism-modernism Eisenstadt, S. N. 65
as a social system 197-8, 241 organisation of 145-9 credit and banks Elaea 216
Beijing 26-8, 66 Chayanov, A. V. 78 bottomry loans 270, 28o-l Eleusis 151
Bengal 9 Chinese Empire 51-4, 62 Indian 268-9 elite, Roman imperial 96-1 lo
Bervtus 280 chtysargyrcm 226, 233 short-term 269, 272-3 incomes of 111-13
bishops 263 Cicero, Marcus Tullius 106, 239, 241 "crisis of Italy" 74 empire
Black Death 123, 173 city states 104 customs dues [60-2, 202-"i8, colonial 10, 40, 243
see also Antonine Plague Italian 271 295-8 early modern Asian 7-10, 12, 25. 43,
Bloch, Marc 9 classics 6 concessions 227-9 54-60, 8o, 305
Bosporus, Strait of the 221-2 clientelisation 5. 201, 287-9 declaration of goods 236 failure of in Europe 55
Bouclica 101 see also credit; fides local and state 220-5 patrimonial-bureaucratic 64, 82 see
Braudel, Fernand 46, 50, 86, J 34 collegia 156-7, 242, 262, 267-8 multiple payment of 218-20 also empire, tributary; Weber
Bronze Age civilisation 44 ordinances of 263-4 political favour and preference 215-16 pre-Columbian 7
see also agrarianate society potential for social mobilization 244-5 and surcharges 205-6 tributary 10-11, 59-6o, 62, 122, 132,
Brundisium 280 patrons ol 249 see also protection 149
Bubon 232 see also communal association Cyprus 192 as agrarian empire io
Biicher, Karl 19-21, 23, 38 Columella 32 as concentrated mass 125
bureaucracy 65 commenda 270-2, 282 Da Gama, Vasco 41 and economic integration 110-21
business managers 276-80 see also business managers,peculium Damascus 2 and European state-system 54-60
see also commenda, pecuiiiim commercial customs and practices, Danzig 147 and institutional integration r 79
Byzantium 240 regional variation of 190-5, de-colonisation 24, 40 and modernisation 65-6
295-9 see also Orient/Orientalism; and parasitical fiscalism 21 3
cahotage 141-2 commercial imperialism, Portuguese 306 "otherness' as revenue pump 95, 109
Caesarea(in Cappaclocia) [40 Commodus 6l, 2-i2 Delhi 66, 80 as universal empire lo
Cairo 43, 189, 3"5 communal associations 241-68 Red Fort of 80 see also Aztec Empire; Chinese Empire;
capital and cargoes, parcelling of [95, and medieval guilds 241-2, 248 Delos so IncaEmpire; Mughal Empire;
269-70, 273, 275 collective action 248-9 Denderah 254 Parthian Empire
capitalism 2, 4-5> 8, 32, 45-6. 271, 291 corporate bodies 246-8 desert, Egyptian 23 [ Ephesos 77, 142, 178, 2l6
and the bazaar 150, 198, 295-8 government suspicions against 245-6 despotism 53, 61, 63, 96, 292-3 bakers in 248
and tributary empire 11, 235 see also collegia differences,cultural 9 Epiphanius 192
see also Europe, early modem compared comparative history 7-10, 24-5, 292 Dio Chrysostomus 77 eurocentnsm
to Rome; mercantilism and the notion of functional Dionysia, trial of 188 and global history 38-45
capstone government 66, [ l I equivalent 35-6, 49 Domitian 98, 103 Europe, early modern compared to
Caracalla 98, 184 conceptualisation 3-6, 26-8, 115 Droysen, Johann Gustav 3-4 Rome 33-6, 47, 71, 292
caravans 134, 231, 258 connectivity 71, 137 Dumont, Louis 35, 242 see also capitalism, mercantilism
Carthage 126, 142 Constantinople 57, 247 Dura Europos 19 [, 254 evidence 2-3, 222-3, 248, 250, 263
Cassiodorus 138 Constitutio Antoniniana 184 astronomical tablets of Hellenistic
Cassius Dio 98 consumer city/interests 9, 27-8, 47-8, 67, East IndiaCompany (English) Babylon 154
caste 242-4, 262 152-3, 213, 295-8 and markets in Bengal I 44 the Egyptianprice records 153-7, 294,
and medieval guilds 244 consumption, imperial styles of 297-301, ecology and economic integration 70-2 301, 306
Cato 120 304 economics, discipline of 6-7 exchange, levels of interregional I 13
charismatic goods 302-3 conspicuous 295-9 economy, moral 152-3, 254
see also consumption regulated by fashion 299 see also consumer city/interests fairs, periodic 49-50, 197-8
Charlemagne 55 Cook, James, death on Hawaii 37-8 economy, quantifying size of 86 falling marginal returns 123-4
Charles V (Holy Roman Emperor) 55 Coptos 174, 254, 281 Edessa 78 familia publicanorum 212
chartered joint stock companies, Coromandel Coast 145 Egypt 4, 191, 223, 232, 286 famines and trade 77-8
European 42, 149, 207 corpora naviculariorum 247-8 corporate commercial groups in 246 Fanon, Franz 24

352 353
INDEX INDEX

Fayum. the 155 Hopkins, Keith 25, -jo. 120 justice, administration of 188-90. 262 imbalances and imperfections 139-40,
Fei'Euson, Adam 6-t. 301 and Finley 26. 47 interaction of courts and private 142
fides (as symbolic capital) 259-62 and quantification 86 mediation 266-7 modem 4
see also credit on the Roman senate 98 mediation 263-5 the Roman state as actor in 176-9
Finley. M. I. 26, 28, 33, 42, 47, 282 see also taxes and trade rough 203, 240, 264-6, 268 as transfbrmers of agricultural
and anthropology 22-4 Horace 303 self-help 262 surplus 119-21, 294
on food crisis in Antioch 143 households in the economy 5, 19, 31-2, volatility of prices 4, 136, [42, 166-71
on merchant associations 242 78. 241, 268 Kautsky. J. 65 Marx, Karl 35, 45
and the politics of otherness 32 himdi, the 149 Kipling. Rudyard i measures, variation in standards of 191-2
.
/i'.S-CK.f 223 and cashless transfers of money in Melanesia -i8
Foucault. Michel 24 Roman society 285-6 La Graut'esenque 134 Melville, Herman 132
fragmentation, economic 5, 201, 287 laissez-faire 5, 51-4, 140, 239, 291 mercantilism/mercantilist privileges 5,
frankincense 134, 202 imperial government, weakness of 68-9, see also market integration; Smith; 51-2. 56, 65, 74, 147, 213
Frederiksen, Martin 26-7. 29 239-40, 262 Ricardo merchant princes 196, 258, 283-4
imperialism, European 40 Lane, F. C. 2^2-1 merchants
Gaius (the Romanjurist) 131, 174, 277 Inca Empire 7 see also protection acting as patrons 259
Garnsey. Peter 25 incense 291, 302 Lattimore, Owen 25 bargaining power of 151. 225-9, 248
Gaul 72-3, 127 Indian Mutiny see Great Indian Mutiny Lepcis Magna 50 fiscal monopoly of 152
Gaza 192 Indian Ocean 8, 41-2, 52, 53, 76-7, [96, Leptiminus 73 patronage of 228-9
Geertz, Clifforcf 5, 6, 129, 131. 197, 198 3"4 Levy-Bruhl, Lucien 38 religious association 254-7
see also bazaar trade and the agricultural surplus 76-7 Lex Irnitana 175 smuggling of 225-7
Gellius. Aulus 102 industrialisation 85 Libaniu.s 101, 103, 105 superstitions of 132
Gibbon. Edward 61 institutions 12-13 on the autonomy of the market 175 see also bazaar; markets;
gift-giving 25, [07 see also Akerlof: bazaar: markets; local knowledge 194, 199 middleman, the
Goethe, J. W. von l North: transaction costs see also Geertz Mesopotamia, ancient 271
Goitein, S. D. 43 integration, economic 12, 29, ll4-l5> see London 34, 47 Meyer, Eduard 19-21
Goody, Jack 44 also empire: tributary, and Lugdunum 253 middleman, the 5, 50-7, 147-8
Great Indian Mutiny 80 economic integration: market Luke (the evangelist) 265 Mitteis, Ludwig 184
Gregory of Nazianus 140 integration Lyeia 106-9 Moby Dick 132
growth, economic 48, 62, 122-7 integration, legal [80, 183-90 modernisation 6
aggregate or per capita 122-3, 125 clash of legal practices 189-90 Maecenas 303 Mommsen, Theodor 17-18
Guadalquivir Valley 77 co-existence of Maine, Henry Sumner 18, 25 monopoly, fiscal 246
Gujarat 78, 220 Egyptian custom 188 Malinowski, Bronislaw 38 Monte Testaccio 35, 273
Muslim and Hindu [aw I 83 Malthusian trap 34 Montesquieu 17, 54-60, 63, 74
Hadrian 151, 152, 178, 222 Roman and local law I 83 Mann, Michael 122 Mughal Empire 8-10, 79-84
Hall, John 66 Roman and Jewish law I 85-6, mansabdars 95-6 comparison with Roman Empire 13,
Hegel, G. W. F. 35 190 Marcus Aurelius 61. 280 57, 292-3
Heliodorus 195 pragmatic application of imperial mare clausum 135 comparison summarised 293-6
Hercules, cult of 261 law 185, 188-9 market integration 4, 13, 30-2, 68-9, 79, customs regimes 213-25
Hercler, J. G. t1 see also justice, administration of 110-15, 140 elite building 93-110
Herod the Great 179 integration, monetary 180-3 criteria of 154-5, 171-3 imperial styles of
hierarchies, urban 35-6, 126-7 Istanbul 40 limits to in the bazaar 131-201 consumption 296-304
high culture, urbanised 6-7 pasSim limits to local
see also agrarianate society Jewish diaspora 262 and regional variation 157-66 control/penetration 183-90,
historical sociology 7 Jones, A. H. M. 22, 26, 133 markets 4, 49, 140 206-7, 225-7, 268
hoarding 175-6 Josephus 103-4, 179 and big cities 142-3 market functioning as tribute
Hodgson, Marshall 11, 41 Jucundus 121 conditions of trade 111-2 transtormer 119-21
see also agrarianate society Julian (emperor) 143, 224 equilibrium 140 Mughal bazaars as bench-mark for
honestiores and humiliores 124 Juliopolis 240 and harvest cycle 165-6 Roman markets 149-53

354 355
1N D E X INDEX

Mughal Empire (cant.) Paul (the Roman jurist) 278 provisioning policies see consumer Smith, Adam 51, 62, 147, l52, 240
and old world Eurasian trade 304-6 Fax Romana 29, 70 city/interests Smithian dynamics 45, 48, 291
promoting corporate peace dividend 235 publicans <j)iihlicani) 121, 204 see also agrarianate society: economic
associations 246-8 quality of protection offered by 228-9, weak state constraints on 206-12 integration; markets
as tributary systems 110-2 l 238 Puteoli 253, 272. 283-4 societas 275-6
Murecine wax tablets see Sulpicii peculium 276 Tyrians in 254 and commenda 276
archive/bankers and limited liability 277-80 see also partnership
Muziris 281, 281-4 see also commenda: credit Rabirius Postumus, Caius 142 Sombart, Werner 299
pedlar-market 196-7 Red Sea 254, 281 Song dynasty 43
Navigation Act 56 see also bazaar redistribution 67-9, 72-3, 119-21, sources see evidence
Needham, Joseph 43 Peking see Beijing 125-7 Spain 73
Nehalenia 1^1. 261 Pelsaert, Francisco 145, 199 revenues, prebendal 96-7, 125 Spasinou Charax 253
Nero (attempt to curb abusive conduct of see also chartered joint stock Rhodes 231 spices 302
publicans) 207 companies Rhodian Sea Law 191 state

Nerva 98 pepper 146 Rhone-Saone-Rhinearterial route 71, segmentary 111


networks of trade, Pergamon 216 [27 size of Mughal 83-4, 93-4
compartmentalised 287-9 Petronius 132, 264-5, 301 Ricardo, David 72 size of Roman 69-70, 92-3, 115-16
Nile, River 155, 281 Philo 245 see also economic integration state-system, European 55-6
North, Douglass 49, 140 Piraeus 151 risk and uncertainty 4, 13 Stein, Burton 111
see also Akerlof: transaction costs pirates 131, 203, 230-2, 237 in trade 132 stock exchanges 50
Pisa 288 and the bazaar 199, 240-1, 269, Sulpicii archive/bankers 187-8, 267-8,
Obasanjo, Olusegun 38 see also terra sigillata 287 272, 279, 283-4
Obeysekere, Gananath 37 Plato 262 risk, diversification of 195-20 l, 275 Surat 57, 196, 243, 244, 247
Oenoanda 109-10 Plautus 277 Rodinson, Maxime 43 surplus extraction 78-9
olive oil 73-6, 289 Pliny (the Elder) 134, 135, 202, 302 Romaia Sebasta. festival of 216 see also taxes and trade
see also Monte Testaccio Pliny (the Younger) 99, 139, 240 Rome (the imperial capital) 2, 9, 142, Syria 66
Opium Wars 58 Plutarch 103, 105 222, 247, 254, 280
Opramoas of Rhodiapolis 106-9 Pol Pot 24 compared to London 47 Tacitus 98, 99, 207
Orient/Orientalism 1-2, 44 Polanyi, Karl 23, 49, 67, 119 concentration of consumption in 47, TajMahal 80, 296-8
and classics 17 see also anthropology; Finley; Geertz; 66, 127 Tarsus 248
Oriental luxury goods 121, 258, 281, Malinowski; primitivism- the grain supply of i 76-8, 273 Tavemier, J.-B. 96
305-6 modemism; redistribution; Rostovtzeff, M. I. 21, 29-55, 74, 75, 258, tax-t'armers
and customs dues 214-15, 228 Sahlins 291 see publicans
Ostia Pollux 202-3 taxation

Piazzaledelle Corporazioni 250-3 Pompeii 121 Sabora 223 and price records 155-6
"othemess", the politics of 6, 23, 32-3, population size 86, 124 Sahlins, Marshall 37, 290, 302 Roman and Mughal 79
37-40, 43-4, 46 predation 12, 13, 62, 66, 83, 122, 150-1, see also anthropology; "otherness", the see also custom dues; tribute
Oxyrhynchus 166, 248 204-12, 226, 235, 239 politics of taxes and trade 8, 12, 47-50, 62, 83,
primitivism-modemism I, [2, 19-36, Said, Edward 44 113-21, 291, 293-4
Palmyra 151, 196, 221-2, 228, 230-1, 291-2 Sardis 248 Tebtunis 170
283-4, 305 parallel debates 8, 37-45 Sartre, Jean-Paul 24 temple of Bel 254, 257
customs law of 224 private (aristocratic) property 97-110 Scaevola 280 terra sigillata 30, 74, 288-9, 304
merchant community of 253-4, production, decentralised 30, 74-6 Seleucia 254 Tertullian 245
257 productivity gains 122-3, 125 Seneca 101 theory
Pamuk, Orhan 40 protection 13, 200-1 seviri Auguxtales 259 see conceptualisation
Panopolis 68-9, 79 costs of 233-4 Shahjahan 80 third world, the 6
partnership 270, 273-6 locally organised 230-2, 234 Sidonius 143 Timur Lenk 79
see also commenda and predation 203-4 silver, American 306 Titus 103
Parthian Empire 18 see also Fax Romana slavery 274, 276-80 tonnage, ships 136

356 357
INDEX
II trade van Leur, J. C. 41-2, [29, 28l
European see capitalism Venice 57, 305
irregularities of 5, 12-13, 131-201; see Verres. Gaius 106
also risk and uncertainties Vespasian 103, 223
seasonality of 138 Veyne, Paul i, 25, 107, 214, 301
see also bazaar, markets Vindolanda 151, 152
Trajan 98, 99, 240 violence, endemic 102, 229-30
transaction costs 140, 197, 202-7, Vologesias 253, 254
219-20, 226, 229-38, 286-7, 289 Voltaire 56, 63
see also Akerlof; North
transport 133-6 Weber, Max 3-4, 7, 17, 23, 32'47.
tribute 52, 53, 62 67
and curtailment of fiscal on the ancient economy 20-1
rebates 216-18 on commenda 271
and rent 10. ill on political capitalism 122
and Roman and Mughal elite on the politics of othemess 33
building 93 and tributary empire 63-5
see also empire: tributary, and economic weighingand filling, as negotiable
integration process 192-3
Winckelmann. Johann Joachim 19
Ulpian 203 wine 73-6, 166-71
Ulpius Yarhai, Marcus 196, 258 Wolf, Eric 41
underemployment, rural 124 world-system 5, 76
urbanisation. ancient and early
modern 34-6 Zamindars 94
see also consumer city/interests Zheng He 52-3

358

You might also like