Acquisition Strategy: January 2016

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 7

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/311907849

Acquisition Strategy

Chapter · January 2016


DOI: 10.1057/978-1-349-94848-2_383-1

CITATIONS READS

3 9,650

2 authors, including:

Yeolan Lee
University of Alabama in Huntsville
14 PUBLICATIONS   84 CITATIONS   

SEE PROFILE

All content following this page was uploaded by Yeolan Lee on 10 September 2019.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


A

Acquisition Strategy when a target firm disagrees with an acquisition


deal, but a bidder firm acquires the target firm
Jaideep Anand1 and Yeolan Lee2 through tender offers. In contrast, a merger occurs
1
Fisher College of Business, Columbus, OH, when two similar-sized firms combine their
USA assets.
2
Ohio State University, Columbus, OH, USA
Firms have been widely increasing the use of
mergers and acquisitions (M&A) for various rea-
Abstract sons. For instance, some firms try to consolidate
Acquisitions are an integral part of corporate existing market share through M&A (e.g., steel
strategy. Acquisitions can potentially create and other resource commodity manufacturers),
value through several mechanisms; for exam- whereas other firms use M&A to extend their
ple, increasing market power, economies of knowledge bases (e.g., pharmaceutical and bio-
scale and scope, increasing the knowledge tech companies). In general, firms use M&A strat-
base, and complementary asset accessibility. egies to build market power, achieve economies
However, empirical studies often report the of scale and scope, reduce market hazards and
loss of value in acquisitions, especially for uncertainties, strengthen learning capabilities,
acquirers. Value loss in acquisitions can be acquire complementary assets and leverage inter-
related to several reasons; specifically, agency nal financial capital (Singh and Montgomery
problems, hubris target selection and/or 1987; Bradley et al. 1988; Anand and Singh
overpayment in bidding competitions. In this 1997; Capron et al. 1998; Anand 2005).
article, value-creation and value-loss mecha- However, achieving value creation through
nisms in acquisitions are discussed based on M&A is not always feasible. Indeed, a consider-
five theoretical perspectives. able number of M&A result in financial losses,
and academic research has identified several rea-
Definition An acquisition occurs when a bidder sons regarding loss of value in M&A: for exam-
firm purchases a target firm. If a target firm agrees ple, poor decision-making (Jemison and Sitkin
to an acquisition transaction, a friendly acquisi- 1986), overhead costs required for post-M&A
tion occurs. An unfriendly acquisition occurs integration (Agarwal et al. 2012), agency prob-
lems (Amihud and Lev 1981; Anand 2004) and
hubris target selection (Haleblian and Finkelstein
This entry was originally published on Palgrave Connect
under ISBN 978-1-137-49190-9. The content has not been 1999).
changed.

# The Author(s) 2016


M. Augier, D.J. Teece (eds.), The Palgrave Encyclopedia of Strategic Management,
DOI 10.1057/978-1-349-94848-2_383-1
2 Acquisition Strategy

Given the risk of possible value loss in M&A, Resource-Based View (RBV)
firms need to carefully formulate their M&A strat-
egies. Based on five theoretical perspectives, we RBV researchers focus on the factors that create
derive value-creation mechanisms in M&A. The value in M&A. According to the RBV, a firm’s
five theoretical perspectives include ▶ industrial heterogeneous and idiosyncratic resources are the
organization, ▶ resource-▶ based view, ▶ evolu- basis of generating competitive advantages
tionary theory, ▶ transaction cost economics and (Penrose 1959; Wernerfelt 1984; Barney 1991;
▶ agency theory. Conner 1991). The two characteristics of value-
creating resources are ‘stickiness’ (Dierickx and
Cool 1989) and ‘embeddedness’ (Granovetter
1985). These characteristics make it difficult for
Industrial Organization
other firms to imitate a focal firm’s resources and
at the same time make it difficult for the focal firm
The industrial organization economics
to sell the resources on the market (Teece 1982;
(IO) perspective shows how market structures
Seth 1990; Capron et al. 1998). Given the absence
are related to value creation in M&A. Scholars
of transaction methods to sell such resources (e.g.,
in IO argue that firms create value if they can build
licensing), M&A can be used to trade the idiosyn-
market power through M&A. For example, hori-
cratic resources. RBV emphasizes the ‘related-
zontal M&A can reduce the intensity of rivalry in
ness’ between buyer’s and target’s resources for
an industry, enhancing the overall profitability of
value creation (Singh and Montgomery 1987;
the acquirers (Porter 1980). In addition, firms can
Anand and Singh 1997). Resource similarity indi-
increase production scales by acquiring their com-
cates a degree of overlap existing between target
petitors. This horizontal M&A enables firms to
firms’ and acquiring firms’ resources. A high
lower production costs and achieve economies
degree of resource similarity enables acquiring
of scale (Moatti et al. 2011). Horizontal M&A
firms to consolidate the target firms’ businesses
can be also used to lessen multi-market competi-
easily (Henderson and Cockburn 1994), deepen
tions with rivals. In essence, firms tend to compete
product lines (Karim and Mitchell 2000; Anand
less vigorously in one market due to a possible
and Delios 2002) and strengthen general market-
risk of retaliation in other markets (Karnani and
ing skills (Capron and Hulland 1999). However,
Wernerfelt 1985; Gimeno 1999; Anand
some scholars find that excessive overlap between
et al. 2009).
target firms’ and acquiring firms’ resources can
Firms can also create value through vertical
also cause redundancy and thus lower M&A per-
M&A. If firms acquire distribution channels or
formance (Anand and Kim 2010). Other studies
service centres in the industry value chain, they
show an inverted U-shape relationship between
can gain greater access to, and thus more infor-
relatedness and M&A performance (Ahuja and
mation from, the end user. This forward vertical
Katila 2001; Cloodt et al. 2006).
M&A enables firms to better serve customers’
In addition, complementarity between target
needs and preferences. If firms acquire their sup-
firms’ and acquiring firms’ resources can play a
pliers in the value chain through backward M&A,
significant role in the value creation of M&A. If
they can gain strong control of raw materials and
firms can acquire complementary resources
production machines. As such, vertical M&A
through M&A, they can create synergistic gains
helps firms strengthen their control over value
as well as reduce overlapping resources (Harrison
chain activities and create economic value.
et al. 2001; Anand 2004; Kim and Finkelstein
When firms face an intense rivalry in their mar-
2009; Anand et al. 2010; Makri et al. 2010). For
kets, resource extension-oriented M&A can allow
example, firms with superior marketing skills can
them to create value and avoid further competition
acquire content producers to leverage their down-
(Mitchell 1989; Capron and Chatain 2008).
stream resources. By doing so, the firms can
increase synergistic gains through M&A.
Acquisition Strategy 3

Evolutionary Theory about minimizing external market uncertainties


and appropriability hazards (Williamson 1979).
The evolutionary theory suggests that M&A may When appropriability regimes are weak, firms
enable firms to overcome existing constraints in face high information asymmetry regarding
their organizations (Cyert and March 1963; Nel- opportunistic partners (Teece 1986). In such
son and Winter 1982). Organizational inertia pre- cases, M&A can become a reliable option to elim-
vents firms from rapidly responding to exogenous inate market failures, and thus stabilize business
environmental changes (Hannan and Freeman through internalization. Internal capital market
1977) and reduces their survival rates (Anand efficiency models also explain why conglomerate
and Singh 1997). Therefore, if M&A allows M&A can create value. Efficient internal markets
firms to alleviate organizational inertia and update for financial, human, technological and intangible
their existing resources, M&A can create value resources can allow firms to maximize efficiency
(Capron et al. 1998; Anand 2004). even if they acquire unrelated businesses (Myers
According to the evolution theory, the under- and Majluf 1984; Chang and Hong 2002).
standing of a target firm’s organizational culture
and system is an integral component of value
creation in M&A. In other words, acquirers must Agency and Hubris Perspectives
have pre-requisite knowledge on target firms’ rou-
tines and organizational cultures to create value Agency theory focuses on the difference between
from M&A. If acquirers do not possess absorptive the interests of shareholders and managers (Jensen
capacities to codify target firms’ embedded and Meckling 1976). In the absence of significant
knowledge (Cohen and Levinthal 1990; Anand direct financial stake in the firm, managers may
and Singh 1997), they may not fully utilize oppor- act in a risk-averse manner that favours conglom-
tunities afforded by M&A. In addition, post- erate M&A (Amihud and Lev 1981; Jensen 1986)
integration and coordination problems also and emphasizes growth and survival of the firm
increase the cost of M&A. The necessity to inte- over financial value (Anand 2004). This perspec-
grate considerably different organizational cul- tive, similar to the hubris perspective (Roll 1986),
tures and routines between target and acquiring offers a reason why managers extensively use
firms often results in financial burden for acquirers M&A despite the fact that M&A might result in
(Haspeslagh and Jemison 1991; Agarwal economic losses. If M&A is primarily driven by
et al. 2012). High post-integration costs can also the agency motives, therefore, possible economic
destroy target firms’ innovation skills (Ranft and losses are expected.
Lord 2002; Puranam et al. 2006). In sum, the Agency issues may not be independent of
evolutionary theory not only shows possible resource-based factors – for example, firms with
mechanisms of value creation, but also shows greater agency problems are likely to overextend
potential negative aspects of M&A. their resources into new markets, businesses,
applications (Anand 2004).

Transaction Cost Economics (TCE)


Conclusion
The sources of value creation in M&A based on
TCE are similar to those of RBV, but the two The aforementioned theoretical perspectives pro-
theories’ assumptions are significantly different. vide motives for M&A and mechanisms for value
While the RBV assumes the firm-level isolating creation and competitive advantages. These
mechanism creates value in M&A (Lippman and mechanisms are summarized in Table 1. Although
Rumelt 1982), TCE emphasizes that M&A is a large number of studies have identified value-
justified given market hazards and opportunistic creating or value-destroying factors in M&A,
behaviour of buyers. Therefore, TCE is concerned there are still some interesting unanswered
4 Acquisition Strategy

Acquisition Strategy, Table 1 Five theoretical motives for M&A and their corresponding strategies
M&A motives Value-creating M&A strategies
Industrial Market power, economies of scale and scope, tacit Consolidation strategy
organization collusion, mutual forbearance Elimination of overcapacity
Resource-based Redeployment of existing resources into new Redeployment strategy of existing
view opportunities resources
Acquisition of knowledge base, R&D skills and Target selection strategy based on the
complementary assets relatedness between target and bidding
firm
Transaction Overcoming market failures Value-appropriation strategy
cost economies Cost-saving by pooling financial and human resources Internal financial and human resource
under transaction hazard environments management strategy
Evolutionary Resolution of core rigidities through acquisitions of new Path-breaking routines and product
theory capabilities and routines extension strategy
Acquisition of embedded learning capabilities
Agency theory Misalignments with shareholders’ interests Monitoring strategy of the unrelated
M&A
Disciplinary takeovers

questions. For example, from an IO perspective See Also


more systematic research would answer some
interesting questions regarding how M&A in dif- ▶ Agency Theory
ferent markets can create conditions for tacit col- ▶ Evolutionary Theory
lusion. It may be interesting to study how rivalry ▶ Industrial Organization
in a focal market can affect a firm’s M&A decision ▶ Resource-Based View
and its subsequent performance in other unrelated ▶ Transaction Cost Economics
markets. In the RBV perspective, value-creating
M&A strategies have been mainly concerned with
relatedness or similarities between target’s and
References
acquirer’s resources, but it would also be appro-
priate to study the conditions under which Agarwal, R., J. Anand, J. Bercovitz, and R. Croson. 2012.
resource redundancy can destroy value. In the Spillovers across organizational architectures: The role
RBV, the lack of information on the value of target of prior resource allocation and communication in post-
firms is driven by the isolating mechanism, acquisition coordination outcomes. Strategic Manage-
ment Journal 33: 710–732.
preventing rivals’ imitative attempts. However, Ahuja, G., and R. Katila. 2001. Technological acquisitions
the insufficiency of information on targets can and the innovation performance of acquiring firms:
also create ‘lemon’ problems (Akerlof 1970) and A longitudinal study. Strategic Management Journal
market failures (Teece 1980). A better understand- 22: 197–220.
Akerlof, G.A. 1970. The market for ‘lemons’: Quality
ing of issues related to observability and opacity uncertainty and the market mechanism. Quarterly
of target resources would help develop a better Journal of Economics 84: 488–500.
framework for RBV applications. In sum, the five Amihud, Y., and B. Lev. 1981. Risk reduction as a mana-
perspectives have provided useful theoretical gerial motive for conglomerate mergers. Bell Journal of
Economics 12: 605–617.
grounds of value creations in M&A. With the Anand, J. 2004. Redeployment of corporate resources:
understanding of these mechanisms, we can A study of acquisition strategies in the US defense
expect more future studies to find sturdy evidence industries, 1978–96. Managerial and Decision Eco-
about value-creating M&A mechanisms. nomics 25: 383–400.
Anand, J. 2005. M&A strategies in mature and declining
industries: Theoretical perspectives and implications.
Acquisition Strategy 5

In Advances in mergers and acquisitions, ed. C. Cooper Granovetter, M. 1985. Economic action and social struc-
and S. Finkelstein. Oxford: Elsevier JAI. ture: The problem of embeddedness. American Journal
Anand, J., and A. Delios. 2002. Absolute and relative of Sociology 91: 481–510.
resources as determinants of international acquisitions. Haleblian, J., and S. Finkelstein. 1999. The influence of
Strategic Management Journal 23: 119–134. organizational acquisition experience on acquisition
Anand, J. and S. Kim. 2010. Sub-additivity in resource performance: A behavioral learning perspective.
combinations: Implications for M&A. Working paper, Administrative Science Quarterly 44: 29–56.
Fisher College of Business, Ohio State University. Hannan, M.T., and J. Freeman. 1977. The population ecol-
Anand, J., and H. Singh. 1997. Asset redeployment, acqui- ogy of organizations. American Journal of Sociology
sitions and corporate strategy in declining industries. 82: 929–964.
Strategic Management Journal 18: 99–118. Harrison, J.S., M.A. Hitt, R.E. Hoskisson, and
Anand, J., L.F. Mesquita, and R.S. Vassolo. 2009. The R.D. Ireland. 2001. Resource complementarity in busi-
dynamics of multimarket competition in exploration ness combinations: Extending the logic to organiza-
and exploitation activities. Academy of Management tional alliances. Journal of Management 27: 679–690.
Journal 52: 802–821. Haspeslagh, P.C., and D.B. Jemison. 1991. Managing
Anand, J., R. Oriani, and R. Vassolo. 2010. Alliance activ- acquisitions: Creating value through corporate
ity as a dynamic capability in the face of a discontinu- renewal. New York: Free Press.
ous technological change. Organization Science 21: Henderson, R., and I. Cockburn. 1994. Measuring compe-
1213–1232. tence? Exploring firm effects in pharmaceutical
Barney, J. 1991. Firm resources and sustained competitive research. Strategic Management Journal 15: 63–84.
advantage. Journal of Management 17: 99–120. Jemison, D.B., and S.B. Sitkin. 1986. Corporate acquisi-
Bradley, M., A. Desai, and E.H. Kim. 1988. Synergistic tions: A process perspective. Academy of Management
gains from corporate acquisitions and their division Review 11: 145–163.
between the stockholders of target and acquiring Jensen, M.C. 1986. Agency costs of free cash flow, corpo-
firms. Journal of Financial Economics 21: 3–40. rate finance, and takeovers. American Economic
Capron, L., and O. Chatain. 2008. Competitors’ resource- Review 76: 323–329.
oriented strategies: Acting on competitors’ resources Jensen, M.C., and W.H. Meckling. 1976. Theory of the
through interventions in factor markets and political firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership
markets. Academy of Management Review 33: 97–121. structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3: 305–360.
Capron, L., and J. Hulland. 1999. Redeployment of brands, Karim, S., and W. Mitchell. 2000. Path dependent and path
sales forces, and general marketing management exper- breaking change: Reconfiguring business resources fol-
tise following horizontal acquisitions: A resource- lowing acquisitions in the U.S. medical sector,
based view. Journal of Marketing 63: 41–54. 1978–1995. Strategic Management Journal 21:
Capron, L., P. Dussauge, and W. Mitchell. 1998. Resource 1061–1081.
redeployment following horizontal acquisitions in Karnani, A., and B. Wernerfelt. 1985. Multiple point com-
Europe and North America, 1988–1992. Strategic petition. Strategic Management Journal 6: 87–96.
Management Journal 19: 631–661. Kim, J., and S. Finkelstein. 2009. The effects of strategic
Chang, S., and J. Hong. 2002. Research notes and com- and market complementarity on acquisition perfor-
mentaries. How much does the business group matter in mance: Evidence from the US commercial banking
Korea? Strategic Management Journal 23: 265–274. industry, 1989–2001. Strategic Management Journal
Cloodt, M., J. Hagedoorn, and H. Van Kranenburg. 2006. 30: 617–646.
Mergers and acquisitions: Their effect on the innova- Lippman, S.A., and R.P. Rumelt. 1982. Uncertain
tive performance of companies in high-tech industries. imitability: An analysis of interfirm differences in effi-
Research Policy 35: 642–654. ciency under competition. Bell Journal of Economics
Cohen, W.M., and D.A. Levinthal. 1990. Absorptive 13: 418–438.
capacity: A new perspective on learning and innova- Makri, M., M.A. Hitt, and P.J. Lane. 2010. Complementary
tion. Administrative Science Quarterly 35: 128–152. technologies, knowledge relatedness, and invention
Conner, K.R. 1991. A historical comparison of resource- outcomes in high technology mergers and acquisitions.
based theory and five schools of thought within indus- Strategic Management Journal 31: 602–628.
trial organization economics: Do we have a new theory Mitchell, W. 1989. Whether and when? Probability and
of the firm? Journal of Management 17: 121–154. timing of incumbents’ entry into emerging industrial
Cyert, R.M., and J.G. March. 1963. A behavioral theory of subfields. Administrative Science Quarterly 34:
the firm. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice Hall. 208–230.
Dierickx, I., and K. Cool. 1989. Asset stock accumulation Moatti, V., P. Dussauge, and J. Anand. 2011. Horizontal
and sustainability of competitive advantage. Manage- M&A performance re-visited: Disentangling efficiency
ment Science 35: 1504–1511. from bargaining power. Working paper, Fisher College
Gimeno, J. 1999. Reciprocal threats in multimarket rivalry: of Business, Ohio State University.
Staking out ‘spheres of influence’ in the US airline Myers, S.C., and N.S. Majluf. 1984. Corporate financing
industry. Strategic Management Journal 20: 101–128. and investment decisions when firms have information
6 Acquisition Strategy

that investors do not have. Journal of Financial Eco- Singh, H., and C.A. Montgomery. 1987. Corporate acqui-
nomics 13: 187–221. sition strategies and economic performance. Strategic
Nelson, R.R., and S.G. Winter. 1982. An evolutionary Management Journal 8: 377–386.
theory of economics. Boston: Belknap. Teece, D.J. 1980. Economies of scope and the scope of the
Penrose, E. 1959. The theory of the growth of the firm. New enterprise. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organi-
York: Wiley. zation 1: 223–247.
Porter, M.E. 1980. Competitive strategy. New York: Free Teece, D.J. 1982. Towards an economic theory of the
Press. multiproduct firm. Journal of Economic Behavior &
Puranam, P., H. Singh, and M. Zollo. 2006. Organizing for Organization 3: 39–63.
innovation: Managing the coordination–autonomy Teece, D.J. 1986. Profiting from technological innovation:
dilemma in technology acquisitions. Academy of Man- Implications for integration, collaboration, licensing
agement Journal 49: 263–280. and public policy. Research Policy 15: 285–305.
Ranft, A.L., and M.D. Lord. 2002. Acquiring new technol- Wernerfelt, B. 1984. A resource-based view of the firm.
ogies and capabilities: A grounded model of acquisition Strategic Management Journal 5: 171–180.
implementation. Organization Science 13: 420–441. Williamson, O.E. 1979. Transaction-cost economics: The
Roll, R. 1986. The hubris hypothesis of corporate take- governance of contractual relations. Journal of Law
overs. Journal of Business 59: 197–216. and Economics 22: 233–261.
Seth, A. 1990. Sources of value creation in acquisitions:
An empirical investigation. Strategic Management
Journal 11: 431–446.

View publication stats

You might also like