Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 23

American Economic Association

Entry, Exit, Growth, and Innovation over the Product Life Cycle
Author(s): Steven Klepper
Reviewed work(s):
Source: The American Economic Review, Vol. 86, No. 3 (Jun., 1996), pp. 562-583
Published by: American Economic Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2118212 .
Accessed: 08/09/2012 15:18

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The
American Economic Review.

http://www.jstor.org
Entry,Exit,Growth,and Innovationover the Product LifeCycle

By STEVEN KLEPPER*

Regularities concerning how entry, exit, market structure, and innovation vary
from the birth of technologically progressive industries through maturity are
summarized.A model emphasizing differences infirm innovative capabilities and
the importance of firm size in appropriating the returnsfrom innovation is de-
veloped to explain the regularities. The model also explains regularities regard-
ing the relationship within industries betweenfirm size andfirm innovative effort,
innovative productivity, cost, and profitability. It predicts that over time firms
devote more effort to process innovation but the number of firms and the rate
and diversity of product innovation eventually wither. (JEL L10)

A similarview has emergedfroma number quarters,thisevolutionarypatternhascome to


of disciplinaryperspectivesabouthow tech- be knownas the productlife cycle (PLC).
nologicallyprogressiveindustriesevolve from Whilenumerousauthorshavecontributed to
birththroughmaturity.'When industriesare this description,perhapsthe most influential
new, thereis a lot of entry,firns offer many havebeenWilliamJ. AbernathyandJamesM.
differentversions of the industry'sproduct, Utterback.2 Buildingon the workof DennisC.
therateof productinnovationis high,andmar- MuellerandJohnE. Tilton(1969) andusing
ket shareschangerapidly.Despite continued the automobileindustryas a leading case,
marketgrowth,subsequentlyentryslows, exit they depictthe PLCas drivenby the way new
overtakesentryand thereis a shakeoutin the technologiesevolve. They stressthatwhen a
numberof producers,the rate of productin- productis introduced,thereis considerableun-
novationand the diversityof competingver- certaintyaboutuserpreferences(even among
sions of the productdecline,increasingeffort the users themselves) and the technological
is devotedto improvingthe productionpro- means of satisfyingthem. As a result,many
cess, and market shares stabilize. In some firmsproducingdifferentvariantsof the prod-
uct enterthe marketand competitionfocuses
on productinnovation.As users experiment
withthealternativeversionsof theproductand
* Department of Social and Decision Sciences, Car- producerslearn about how to improve the
negie Mellon University, Pittsburgh, PA 15213. I thank
product,opportunitiesto improvethe product
Wesley Cohen, Mark Kamlet, Jon Leland, John Miller, are depletedand a defacto productstandard,
RichardNelson, Ken Simons, Peter Swann, Bill Williams, dubbeda dominantdesign, emerges.Produc-'
and participants at the 1992 Conference of the Interna- ers who are unableto produceefficientlythe
tional Joseph A. SchumpeterSociety, the 1992 Conference dominantdesignexit, contributingto a shake-
on MarketProcesses and the Dynamics of CorporateNet-
works, Wissenschaftszentrum Berlin, and the Industrial out in the numberof producers.The depletion
Organization Seminars at the University of Maryland, of opportunitiesto improvethe productcou-
Berkeley, Penn State, and the London School of Econom- pled with locked-inof the dominantdesign
ics for helpful comments. The paper was greatly improved leadsto a decreasein productinnovation.This
by the unstinting suggestions of two anonymous referees
and the co-editor, Preston McAfee.
in turn reducesproducers'fears that invest-
'See, for example, Oliver E. Williamson's (1975) ac- ments in the productionprocesswill be ren-
count of how economists depict the evolution of new in- deredobsoleteby technologicalchangein the
dustries, Kim B. Clark's (1985) description of how
technology and internal firm organizationchange over the
course of industry evolution, and how a business consult-
ant, Philip G. Drew (1987), describes the way business 2 See in particularJames M. Utterback and William J.
schools depict the evolution of industries. Abernathy (1975) and Abernathy and Utterback (1978).
562
VOL. 86 NO. 3 KLEPPER: INNOVATIONOVER THE PRODUCT LIFE CYCLE 563

product.Consequently,they increasetheirat- ties and size in conditioning firm R&D


tentionto the productionprocess and invest spending, innovation,and market structure.
morein capital-intensivemethodsof produc- Followingvarioustheoreticalmodelsof asym-
tion,whichreinforcesthe shakeoutof produc- metric industry structure(Flaherty; Avner
ers by increasingthe minimumefficient size Shakedand John Sutton, 1987), it incorpo-
firm. rates the notion that the value of a unit cost
Whilethisview hashelpedto popularizethe reductionachievedthroughinnovationis pro-
PLC,it restscriticallyon the notionof a dom- portionalto the level of outputproducedby
inantdesign, an impreciseconceptthat does the firm. Coupled with convex adjustment
not appearto apply to all new products,es- costs, this impartsan advantageto the earliest
pecially ones for which buyer tastes are di- entrantswhich eventuallycauses a cessation
verse(MichaelE. Porter,1983). Furthermore, in entryand a shakeoutin the numberof pro-
it incorporatessomequestionableassumptions ducers.It also providesfirms with a greater
about technologicalchange. It assumes that incentiveto engage in process innovationas
productand processinnovationare inextrica- they grow, which leads to an increaseover
bly linkedandthatfirmswill not attendto the time in theireffortsto improvethe production
productionprocess until productinnovation process.Firnsarealsoassumedto havedifferent
has slowed sufficiently.Yet the historyof the capabilitiesthat lead them to pursuedifferent
automobileindustryand others,such as tires typesof productinnovations, a themepromoted
and antibiotics,indicatesthat greatimprove- by Nelson (1981) and used by Wesley M.
ments were made in the productionprocess Cohenand Klepper(1992) to explaindiffer-
well beforetheemergenceof anykindof dom- enceswithinindustriesin firmR&Dintensities.
inant design (S. Klepper and Kenneth L. Thisprovidesthebasisforexplainingthedecline
Simons, 1993). Indeed, many of these im- in productinnovation thatoccursovertime,link-
provementswere basedon humanand physi- ingit to thedeclinein thenumberof competitors
cal investments that were not rendered broughtaboutby the shakeoutof producers.It
obsolete by subsequentmajorproductinno- is shownthatthemodelcanalsoexplainvarious
vations.The dominant-design view also min- cross-sectionalregularitiesthat have accumu-
imizes the influenceof industrydemandon latedconcerningthe relationship withinindus-
incentivesto innovate,attributingthe slow- tries betweenfirm size and firm R&D effort,
downin productinnovationandrisein process R&Dproductivity, cost, andprofitability.
Thus,
innovationentirelyto the depletionof oppor- the modelprovidesa unifiedexplanationfor a
tunitiesfor productinnovationand the emer- widerangeof temporalandcross-sectional reg-
genceof a dominantdesign.Whilethe relative ularitiesconcerningindustryevolutionandfinn
importanceof demandandsupplyfactorshas behavior.
been hotly debated(David C. Mowery and The paperis organizedas follows. In Sec-
NathanRosenberg,1982), it has never been tion I, the prominentfeaturesof the PLC are
questionedthat demandfactorsplay an im- summarized.In SectionII, the modelis spec-
portantrole in shapingthe rate and direction ified. In Section III, preliminaryimplications
of technologicalchange. of the modelaredeveloped.In SectionIV, the
This paperproposesa new explanationfor model is shown to explain all the prominent
the PLC.Empiricalregularitiescharacterizing featuresof the PLC. In SectionV, the model
the PLCarefirstidentified.A formalmodelis is used to explainvariouscross-sectionalreg-
then constructedto explain the regularities. ularitiesbetween firm size, R&D, and firm
The modelbuildson recenttheoriesof indus- performance.In Section VI, the implications
try evolution(RichardR. Nelson and Sidney of the model are discussedand extensionsof
G. Winter,1982;BoyanJovanovic,1982) and the modelareconsidered.
effortsto modelthelinkbetweenmarketstruc-
ture and R&D (Nelson and Winter, 1978; I. The Natureof the ProductLife Cycle
ParthaDasguptaand Joseph Stiglitz, 1980;
ThereseM. Flaherty,1980). The model fo- The depiction of industryevolution con-
cuses on the role of firminnovativecapabili- veyed in the PLC is based upon case studies
564 THE AMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 1996

and quantitativeanalysesof the evolutionof EntrantsAccountfor


Disproportionate
Amount
MarketSharesof LargestFitmsStabilize--_

new industries.In this section,six regularities of ProductInnovation ProductR&D overtime

concerninghow entry,exit, marketstructure, ProcessR&D overtimc

andtechnological changevaryfromthebirthof
technologicallyprogressiveindustriesthrough
maturityaresummarized. Whileeveryitidustry E = >
Rut pathI\
has its idiosyncrasies,
theseregularities
provide
a compositepictureof the evolutionof techno- Entrypath2 Numberof producers

logicallyprogressiveindustries.
Thefirsttwo regularitiespertainto entryand 0 Time

exit. Michael Gort and Klepper(1982) and FIGURE 1. TEMPORAL PATTERNS OF ENTRY, NUMBER OF
Klepperand ElizabethGraddy(1990) exam- PRODUCERS, MARKET SHARES, AND INNOVATION
ine the annualtimepathin the numberof pro-
ducersfor 46 majornew productsbeginning
with their commercialinception. Utterback
andFernandoF. Suarez(1993) also consider These patternsare illustratedin Figure 1.
the time path in the numberof producersas Two alternativepathsfor entry are depicted.
well as the pathsin the numberof entrantsand In bothcases, entryeventuallybecomessmall
exits for 8 productssubjectto considerable andthe numberof firmsrisesinitiallyandthen
technologicalchange. Klepper and Simons declinesover time. Relatedto these two pat-
(1993) review the entryand exit pathsfor 2 terns are regularitiesin the way firm market
of the products studied by Utterback and shares change over time. Althoughmarket-
Suarezand2 otherproductssubjectto consid- sharedataoveranextendedtimeperiodarenot
erable technological change. Two patterns availablefor manyproducts,EdwinMansfield
emergefromthese studiesconcerningthe na- (1962) and Burton H. Klein (1977 pp. 89-
ture of industryevolution in technologically 128) have examined how the marketshares of
progressiveindustries: the leading producersof automobiles,tires,
aircraft,petroleum,and steel changed over
At the beginningof the industry,the number time.Theirfindings,whichaccordwitha num-
of entrantsmay rise over time or it may at- ber of case studies,suggesta thirdregularity
tain a peak at the startof the industryand whichis notedin Figure1:
then decline over time, but in both cases
the numberof entrantseventuallybecomes Eventuallythe rate of change of the market
small. sharesof the largestfirmsdeclinesand the
The numberof producersgrows initiallyand leadershipof the industrystabilizes.
thenreachesa peak,afterwhichit declines
steadilydespitecontinuedgrowthin indus- The otherthreeregularitiesaboutthe PLC
try output.3 pertainto technologicalchange.Becausetech-
nologicalchangeis moredifficultto quantify,
the regularitiesarebasedon a numberof case
studies4andtwo samplesof innovationsfor a
'These are general tendencies, and exceptions can al-
ways be found. Of greater significance is the possibility
that these patternsreflect a bias in the way new products
are typically defined. If these patterns tend to be inter- 'These include Abernathy (1978) and Abernathyet al.
rupted by major innovations but the innovations are de- (1983) for automobiles, Klein (1977) for automobiles and
fined as creatingnew productssubject to their own product aircraft,Tilton (1971) and Jerome Kraus (1973) for tran-
life cycles, the patterns could be artifactual.The bulk of sistors, Kenneth Flamm (1988) and Philip Anderson and
the new productsthat have been studied, however, did not Michael J. Tushman (1990) for computers, Arthur A.
experience such major innovations until many years after Bright (1949) and James R. Bright (1958) for light
they were introduced, and their evolution was generally bulbs, Thomas J. Prusa and James A. Schmitz (1991) for
characterized by long initial periods during which the PC software, and Abernathy and Utterback (1978) and
characteristic patterns in entry and the number of firms Utterback and Suarez (1993) for collections of products.
were observed. For furtherdetail, see Klepper (1992).
VOL. 86 NO. 3 KLEPPER: INNOVATIONOVER THE PRODUCT LIFE CYCLE 565

limited number of industries in the United portunitiesfor productand process innovation.


States (Utterback and Abernathy, 1975) and Two aspects of innovation are featured. First,
the United Kingdom (C. De Bresson and J. following Jacob Schmookler (1966) and a
Townsend, 1981). These studies suggest that number of theoretical models (for example,
for industries with rich opportunities for both Dasguptaand Stiglitz, 1980; Shakedand Sutton,
product and process R&D, three patterns in 1987), the demand for a firm's product is as-
product and process innovation can be identi- sumed to condition its incentive to innovate.
fied:5 This is assumed to be manifested differently
for process and product innovation. Process
The diversity of competing versions of the innovation is principally designed to lower a
product and the number of major product firm's average cost of production. Since the
innovations tend to reach a peak during the value of a reduction in average cost is propor-
growth in the numberof producersand then tional to the total output of the firm, it is as-
fall over time. sumed that the incentive for process innovation
Over time, producers devote increasing effort is conditioned by the total quantity demanded
to process relative to product innovation. of the firm's product. Product innovations, in
During the period of growth in the number of contrast, are often designed to attractnew buy-
producers, the most recent entrants account ers for a product. Accordingly, it is assumed
for a disproportionate share of product that the incentive for product innovation is
innovations. conditioned by the demand of new buyers.
Second, firms are assumed to be randomly en-
These three regularities are also noted in dowed with distinctive capabilities which in-
Figure 1. Together, the six regularitieslaid out fluence the kinds of innovations they develop.
above and summarizedin Figure 1 provide the The idea of distinctive firm competencies lies
focus for the theoretical analysis of the paper. at the heatt of the business-strategy literature
(Porter, 1980) and its relevance for innovation
II. The Model appears prominently in many industry case
studies.6It is assumed that these differences in
The model depicts the evolution from birth capabilities manifest themselves principally in
through maturity of an industry with rich op- product innovations, where firms often spe-
cialize in innovations that service distinctive
types of users (Eric von Hippel, 1988). In
contrast, process innovations tend to be incre-
' The three patternsare ascribed only to products with mental and based on information that firms
rich opportunitiesfor both productand process innovation commonly generate throughproduction (com-
because the bulk of the products for which patterns in pare Bright, 1958; Samuel Hollander, 1965).
innovation have been studied are, not surprisingly, ones
with such characteristics.Indeed, Abernathy(1978 p. 84), The model is stylized to highlight the two
K. Pavitt and R. Rothwell (1976), and Porter (1983 pp. featured aspects of innovation. It has the fol-
23-24), among others, contend that products without rich lowing structure. Time is discrete. In each
opportunitiesfor both product and process innovation do period, incumbent firms decide whether to
not follow the prototypical PLC. Examples cited as ex-
ceptions to the PLC include synthetic fibers and plastics,
which are claimed to be relatively homogeneous and pri-
marily subject to process but not product innovation, and
heavy electrical equipment, which is produced in small 6 For example, a numberof studies emphasize how sig-
batches and is claimed to be subject primarily to product nificant innovations can be traced back to expertise ac-
and not process innovation. While no evidence is pre- quired fortuitously. This is featuredin Hugh G. J. Aitken's
sented to buttress these claims and not all observers sub- (1985) analysis of early radio innovations, Flamm's
scribe to them (for example, see David A. Hounshell (1988) discussion of the influence of government spon-
[1988] regarding synthetic fibers), it is importantto rec- sored cryptography efforts during World War II on sub-
ognize that the evidence regarding innovation during the sequent innovation by computer firms, and Klein's (1977
PLC is primarilybased on productswith rich opportunities pp. 89-109) discussion of the skills brought into the
for both product and process innovation. This is reflected automobile industry at the 'turnof the century by entre-
in the model, which presupposes that the joint nature of preneurs with experience in mass production and inter-
product and process innovation drives the PLC. changeable parts manufacture.
566 THE AMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 1996

remain in the industry and a limited numberof cumulative distributionof innovative expertise
potential entrantsdecide whether to enter. All is the same for the potential entrants in each
firms produce a standardproduct. They decide period. This distribution is denoted as H(s),
how much process R&D to perform,which de- where H(s) is assumed to be continuous for
termines the average cost of the standardprod- all s < smaxand H(Smax)= 1 by definition.
uct. They also decide how much productR&D The firm's innovative expertise influences
to perform. Firms randomly differ in their its success at productR&D. The probabilityof
productinnovation expertise, which influences firm i developing a product innovation in pe-
their success at product R&D. In each period, riod t is si + g (rdi,), where rdi,is its spending
successful product innovators develop a dis- on product R&D and the function g(rdi,) re-
tinctive product innovation which they com- flects the opportunitiesfor productinnovation.
bine with the standard product to market a Each successful innovator adds its innovation
unique, distinctive product. Distinctive prod- to the standardproduct and markets a distinc-
ucts appeal to all buyers, but only new buyers tive variant of the industry's product, which it
pay the premiums for them, with each distinc- sells at a price exceeding the price of the stan-
tive product sold to a different class of new dard product, reflecting the value of its inno-
buyers. All firms monitor the product inno- vation. Distinctive variants are assumed to
vations of their rivals. This enables them to appeal to all buyers but only new buyers have
imitate all productinnovations one period after a positive demand for them at the prices
they are introduced and incorporatethem into charged, with each distinctive variant pur-
the standardproduct at no additional produc- chased by a different class of new buyers. Af-
tion cost. When the last period's product in- ter one period, all product innovations are
novations are incorporated into the standard copied and incorporated into the standard
product, buyers of the distinctive products be- product, so successful innovators have a one-
come buyers of the standardproduct and the period monopoly over theirdistinctive variants.
demand for the standardproduct by all other Let G denote the one-period gross monopoly
buyers increases, causing the demand curve profit (before subtractingthe amount spent on
for the standardproduct to shift to the right. product R&D) earned by each seller of a dis-
Producers share in the expansion in demand tinctive variant.It is assumed that g' (rdi) > 0
for the standardproduct in proportionto their and g"(rdit) < 0 for all rdit 2 0, reflecting
prior output and decide how much further to diminishing returns, and that g'(0)G > 1,
expand their output subject to a cost of ad- which ensures rdit> 0 for all i, t. In order to
justment. All decisions are made to maximize be able to imitate costlessly the innovations of
current profits, firms are price takers, and in its rivals, which is required to market a dis-
each period the price of the standardproduct tinctive product variant and also the standard
clears the market. product, firms monitor the innovations of their
The model is formally specified as follows. rivals at a cost of F per period. Thus, if a firm
In each period t, there are K, potential entrants. engaged in only product innovation and did
As firms enter and others randomly develop not produce the standardproduct, its expected
the innovative capabilities requiredto enter, K, profits in period t would be [si + g(rdit)] G -
changes. A priori no restrictions are placed on rdit- F. To simplify the model, it is assumed
whether K, rises or falls over time; this may that F > [si + g(rdit)] G - rditfor all rdit.This
differ across industries and also within indus- ensures that in order to have nonnegative ex-
tries over time. Each potential entrant is ran- pected profits, all firms must produce the stan-
domly endowed with innovative expertise dard product.
which it cannot modify over time. Let si de- Let Qt = f(pt) denote the total market de-
note the innovation expertise of firm i, which mand for the standard product in period t,
it knows prior to entry, and smax the maximum where Qt is the quantity demanded, Pt is the
possible innovation expertise. To simplify the price of the standardproduct, andft(pt) is the
dynamics of the model, it is assumed that in market demand schedule for the standard
each period there are one or more potential product in period t. Over time, f (pt) shifts to
entrantswith innovative expertise Smax and the the right at every price as last period's product
VOL 86 NO. 3 KLEPPER: INNOVATIONOVER THE PRODUCT LIFE CYCLE 567

innovations are incorporatedinto the standard l'(rcit) > 0 and l"(rcit) < 0 for all rcit 2 0,
product. It is assumed thatfi(p,) is continuous reflecting diminishing returns.Further,it is as-
and downward sloping for all t. Let Qit denote sumed that 1'(0)QQm1,i > 1, where Qmnin is the
the output of the standardproduct by firm i in smallest level of output ever produced by any
period t. It is determinedas follows. Assuming firm. This ensures rcit > 0 for all i, t.
that Pt falls over time (this will be shown in Given the assumptions, the expected profit
the next section), the total quantitydemanded, of firm i in period t, E(IIit), can be expressed
Qt, expands over time. All firms sell the same as
standardproduct at the same price. New buy-
ers are assumed to choose a seller based on a (1) E(Hit) = [si + g(rdit)]G - rdit
stochastic learning process in which the prob-
ability of a firm attractinga new buyer is pro- + [Qit_I(Qt/ Qt- l) + Aqit]
portional to its sales of the standardproduct in
the priorperiod,Qit - I. It is assumedthatit is X [Pt - c + I(rcit)]
optimal for a buyer to continue purchasing
from the same firm as long as the firm remains - rcit - m(Aqit) - F,
in the market. Accordingly, it is assumed that
incumbents in period t experience a rise in where [si + g(rdit)]G - rdit is the firm's
their sales of the standardproduct from Qit- I expected net profit from product R&D after
in period t - Ito Qit- I (Qt/Qt- I ) in period t, subtracting the cost of its product R&D,
where Qt/Qt - l denotes the growth in the total I[Qit-l(QtlQt_l + Aqit [pt - c + l(rcit)I -
quantity demanded of the standard product rcit- m(Aqit)is its net profitfromproducing
from period t - 1 to t. If desired, the firm can the standardproductaftersubtractingbothits
expand its output further, resulting in an in- spendingon processR&Dandthe costs of ad-
crease in its marketshare of the standardprod- justing its output,and F is the cost of moni-
uct relative to period t - 1. To do so, it must toringthe innovationsof its rivals.Expression
incur an adjustment cost of m(Aqit), where (1) appliesto entrantsin periodt as well as
Aqit is the expansion in its output in period t incumbents,with Qit- = 0 for entrants.All
above Qit- I(Qt/Qt- ). The function m(Lqit) firms are assumedto be atomisticand price
is such that m'(0) = 0, m'(Aqit) > 0 for all takers.In each period t they can projectthe
zqit > 0, and m"(Aqit) > 0 for all Aqit ' 0, market-clearing priceforthe standardproduct,
with m' (Aqit) growing without bound as Aqit Pt, butareuncertain aboutfuturepricesandthus
increases, reflecting increasing marginal ad- theirprospectsfor survival.Accordingly,it is
justment costs.7 assumedthey decide whetherto be in the in-
The average cost of production of the stan- dustryandif so, rdit,rcit,andAqit,to maximize
dard product for firm i is assumed to be inde- currentexpected profits, E(nit). Let rdi,t,
pendent of Qit and equal to c - l(rcit), where rc *, and Aq* denote the profit-maximizing
rcit is the amount spent on process R&D by choices of rdit, rci,, and \qit and E(HI*t) the
firm i in period t and the function l(rcit) re- expectedprofitsof the firmat these choices.
flects the opportunitiesfor process innovation. Potential entrantsenter if E(n*) > 0, are in-
Following Flaherty (1980), cost in period t is differentaboutenteringif E(HI*t) = 0, anddo
a function only of process R&D in period t. It not enter if E(HI*) < 0, where Aqit defines
is assumed that as rcitincreases, l(rcit) asymp- theirinitial outputof the standardproductif
totically approaches an upper bound and they enter.Similarly,incumbentsstay in the
industryif E(Hll*)> 0, are indifferentabout
staying in if E(HI) =0, and exit if E(HI*) <
0. Once incumbentsexit, their outputof the
7 If a firm wants to expand its marketshare, it will nor- standardproductis lost.
mally have to incur marketing costs to attract customers The industryis assumedto startin period1
from its rivals. The assumption that m"(Aqi,)> 0 reflects
the idea that the more the finn wants to increase its market
when demandandtechnologyfor the product
share in any given period, the greater the marketingcosts are such that there exists a price pi for
requiredfor expansion at the margin. which the quantitysupplied by firms with
568 THE AMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 1996

nonnegative expected profits equals the quan- Themodelis stylizedto keepit tractableand
tity demanded, Ql, where Q, > 0. Similarly, to highlightthe two key featuresof innovation
in every subsequent period p, is assumed to that underlieit. Productinnovationsare as-
clear the market. This requires that the quan- sumed to be introducedinto distinctivever-
tity demanded in period t, Q, = f,(p,), equals sionsof theproductandthenincorporated into
the quantity supplied by producers in period t the productsof all firms,which conformsto
taking p, as given: the way many productsevolve over time.'0
This preservesthe notion of an industryin
(2) Q, = , {Qit-I(Qt/Qt-1) + /qit}, which all firms produce the same product
i,t while allowing for (limited) productdiffer-
entiation.Eachproductinnovationis assumed
where the index i, t of the summation denotes to be sold to a differentclass of new buyersto
that the summationis over firms i in the market reflectthe idea thatfirmshave differentkinds
in period t. In terms of the actual mechanism of innovativeexpertisethatlead them to ser-
governing the change in price from period t - vice differentgroupsof buyers.Coupledwith
I to t, the dynamics of the model are simplified theassumptionthatproductinnovationsdo not
by assuming that for all incumbent firms in affect the demandfor the standardproduct,
period t, dE(H1*)/dp, > 0 for all prices pt this ensuresthat the incentive to engage in
within a broad neighborhood of pt 8 with productinnovationis determinedsolely by the
the equilibrium price constrained to lie in this demandof new buyers."Differencesin firm
broad neighborhood. The existence of such a innovativeabilitiesare structuredso thatthey
price in each period satisfying equation (2) is do not affectthe firm'soutputof the standard
demonstrated in the next section. As will be productnor the amountspent on productor
shown, market clearing is achieved through processR&D.Consequently, the firm'soutput
the effects of pt on Qt, Aqit, and on entry and of the standardproductis relatedto the firm's
exit in period t.9 R&D spendingonly throughits effects on the
returnsfrom processR&D, which highlights
the influenceof the demandfor the standard
producton processR&D.Opportunities forin-
8 Thisconditionrequiresthatin eachperiodt, thelower novation,as reflectedin the functionsg(rdi,)
p, thenthe lowerthe maximumpossibleexpectedprofits and l(rci,), are assumedconstantto abstract
of each firm,assumingthe firmcan sell as muchof the
standard productas it wantsatp,. Thepriceof thestandard fromthe effectsof changingtechnologicalop-
productaffectsE(r,*) in two ways:throughits effect on portunitieson the firm's R&D spending.All
theprofitperunitof the standard product,p, - c + l(rci,), decisionsarebasedon currentexpectedprofits
andthroughits effecton eachfirm'soutputof thestandard andprocessinnovationsarenot cumulativeto
productvia the total quantitydemandedof the standard simplify the dynamicsof the model and to
product,Qt. These two effects work in oppositedirec-
tions-the lowerpt then the lower the firm'sprofitper reflectthe limitedhorizonsof firmsin new in-
unit on the standardproduct,ceteris paribus,but the dustries.Many of these assumptionsare re-
greaterthefirm'stotaloutputof the standard product,cet- considered in the conclusion, where it is
eris paribus.Given thatl(rcj,)is bounded,at sufficiently arguedthat the spirit and principalimplica-
low prices E(rlH*) must be less than zero for all firms,
henceat sufficientlylow pricesthe firsteffect mustdom- tions of the model would not change if the
inatethe secondanddE(rI,*)dpt> 0. If dft(pt)ldpt = 0 at assumptionswere relaxed.
the relevantprices(thatis, the priceelasticityof demand
equaledzero),thenpt wouldhaveno effect on the firm's
outputof the standard p,roductandit is easy to see from
equation(1) thatdE(Hlit)ldpt > 0 forall prices.Moregen-
erally,if suitableconstraintsare placedon the function '?Forexample,in automobilesinnovationssuchas the
dft(pt)ldpt at the relevantpricesthendE(rH*)/dpt > 0 for electricstarterandthe inexpensiveclosed body werein-
all priceswithina broadneighborhood of pt troducedinto distinctivemodelsandthen copiedwidely
9 Note thatif exit occursin periodt then1j, Qit-I < by all manufacturers.
li, t- I Qit-I = Q,_ ,, where the index i, t - 1 denotes " This abstractsfrom strategicincentivesto innovate
summationover firmsin the marketin periodt - 1. As associatedwith the preemptionof rivals (RichardJ.
developedin the next section,exit will be necessaryfor GilbertandDavidM. G. Newbery,1982)andcannibalism
themarketto clearin eachperiod. of priorinnovations(JenniferReinganum,1983, 1985).
VOL 86 NO. 3 KLEPPER: INNOVATIONOVER THE PRODUCT LIFE CYCLE 569

III. Preliminary Results PROOF:


The profit-maximizing value of rdi, is de-
In order to facilitate the proof of later re- fined by equation (3), which is the same for
sults, a series of intermediate implications of all firms and does not change over time. Con-
the model are developed as lemmas. In deriv- sequently, all firms spend the same amount
ing these lemmas, it is assumed that there ex- rd * on product R&D, where rd * satisfies
ists a price p, in each period that clears the (3).
marketgiven the choices firms make about en-
try, exit, rdi,, rci,, and Aqi, taking p, as given. Analogous to E(fl *), letVi=V - (Q
The existence of such a path for price is estab- Qt-1) + Aq*][p, - c + l(rc*)] Qit - rci*
lished at the end of this section. m( Aq*) denote the firm's (incremental)
The first results pertain to firms in the mar- profitfrom the standardproduct.Lemma 1 im-
ket in period t, including firms that entered the plies that the firm's incremental profit earned
market during period t as well as earlier en- from product R&D in each period, [si +
trants. Differentiating (1) with respect to rdi,, g (rdi,)] G - rdi,, remains constant over time.
rci,, and Aqi, establishes the following first- Consequently, changes in the firm's expected
order conditions for an interior maximum for profits over time arise only from changes in
each firm i in the market in period t: V i*. Accordingly, most of the analysis of the
model focuses on the standardproduct.
(3) g'(rd1)G = 1 The second result indicates that in each pe-
riod t, firms in each entry cohort make the
(4) [Qit- (Qt/Qt-i) + Aq*]l'(rc*) = 1 same choices for rci, and Aqi, and have the
same output and incremental profits from the
(5) m'(Aq*) = - c + l(rc *), standardproduct. Letting the values of these
pt variables for entry cohort k in period t be de-
where optimal values are denoted by an aster- notedas rc', Aqk, Q,k,and V k, the following
isk. Furthermore,for a firm to be in the market result is established.
in period t, its expected profits in period t must
be nonnegative. Given the assumption of F > LEMMA 2: For allfirms i that entered in pe-
[si + g(rdi,)]G - rdi, for all rdi,, a necessary riod k and are still in the market in period t >
condition for E(nit) 2 0 is that for each firm k, rci, = rck, Aqit* = AqkI Qi = Qk, and
i in the market in period t: V = V t t

(6) ~Pt - c + l(rcit)> PROOF:


Since Qi - I = 0 for entrants in period t,
Assuming Aq*] + equations (4) and (5) imply rc * and Aq ,
X m(Aq*) -1"(rc*)[Qit-1(Qt/Qt-1)
> lP(rc*)2 to ensure that the joint hence Qit and V i*, must be the same for all
solutionof (4) and (5) for rc1,and Aqi,is a max- entrantsin t. It then follows from (4) and (5)
imum, the solutions to equations (3)- (6) will that rc *, Aq * , Qit, and V * must be the same
satisfy the second-order conditions. Conse- for these firms in every period they are in the
quently, for each firm i and period t, rd * > 0, market.
rc * > 0, and Aq * > 0, with these choices
satisfying equations (3) - (6). Thus, all firms Lemmas 1 and 2 imply that in each period
in the market in period t perform product and t the expected profits of firms that entered in
process R&D and increase their market share the same period differ only according to their
of the standardproductrelative to period t - 1. product-iniovation expertise si. Consequently,
Conditions (3) -(6) imply two results in each period the distributionof E(fli,) across
which reflect the simplified nature of the firms in the same entry cohort will be the same
model. as the distributionof si for these firms.
The firm's output in the prior period, Qit- I,
LEMMA 1: For all i and t, rdi, = rd *, where will determine its choice of rci, and Aqi, and
rd * satisfies g'(rd *)G = 1. hence Vit.This is reflected in Lemma 3.
570 THE AMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 1996

LEMMA 3: For each firm i in the market in PROOF:


period t, the larger Qi -, then the larger rci,, Since Aqi, > 0 for all i, t, it follows that
Aqi,, and Vi. Qit> Qit- I for all i, t. Rewriting equation (4)
as Qi,l' (rc * ) = 1, it follows from Qit > Qit-
PROOF: and l"(rci,) < 0 for all rci, that rci, > rci,t- .
Differentiating (3) -(5) with respect to
Qit- 1 and rearrangingyields The time paths for Aqi, and Vitfor incum-
bents cannot be so easily characterized.Equa-
tion (5) indicates that for each incumbent Aqi,
drc * / dQi,_ = g"(rd *)I will change over time according to the time
*) Gm"(A\q P(rc*)
- path of p, - c + I(rci,), the firm's profit per
x (Qt/ Qt_) / D unit of the standardproduct. The change in Vit
over time will also depend on the time path in
Pt - c + I(rci,). Lemma 4 implies that l(rci,)
dzAq*ldQi,_ = g"(rd )Gl'(rci*)2 rises over time, but Lemma 5 below indicates
I
p, falls over time. Consequently, without fur-
X (Qt/ Qt- ) / D ther assumptions it cannot be determined
whether Aqi, and Vitgenerally rise or fall over
d V i*/dQit- I = a3Vi*/ a3Qit-I time for incumbents.
That pt must fall over time can be easily
= [p, - c + l(rci*t) ] (Qt / Qt- 1), established.

LEMMA 5: For each period t, pt < p.- I


where D is the determinant of the matrix of
secondpartialsof E(ni,) with respectto rdi,, PROOF:
rci,, and Aqi, evaluated at rd *, rc *, and Recall that it was assumed that for each in-
Aq *. Since D < 0 based on the second-order cumbent firm i in period t, dE(n*)Idp, > O
conditions and p, - c + I(rc*) > 0 based on for all prices p, within a broad neighborhood
(6), each of these derivatives is positive. of pt - I, with the equilibrium price in period t
Therefore, the larger Qit- I then the greaterrci,, lying in this neighborhood. Lemma 5 is estab-
Aqi,, and Vit. lished by showing that for all prices p, 2 pt -I
in this neighborhood, the market cannot clear
Since Aq * is determined by Qit- I and in period t. Suppose p, = pt - I. Then, Qitmust
Aq* > 0 for all i, t, Lemmas 2 and 3 imply exceed Qi - I for all producersin period t - 1.
that in each period t the age of the firm fully This implies E(n*) > E(n1*) 20 for all
determines rci,, Aqi,, Vi,, and Qit, with each producers in period t - 1 and hence that no
greater the older the firm. Coupled with incumbent would exit in period t. The same
Lemma 1, this implies that in each period t condition must be true for all prices pt > p.- I
differencesacrossfirmsin E(ni,) arefully de- within a broadneighborhoodof pt - I given that
termined by two factors: the age of the firm dE(n* )Idp, > 0 for all such prices. But every
and its product innovation expertise si. firm that remains in the industry will expand
Lemma 1 establishes the time path of rdi,for its marketshare,hence the marketcannot clear
each firm while Lemmas 2 and 3 establish how if all firms remain in the industry. Therefore,
rci,, Aqi,, Qit, and Vitvary across firms in each pt must be less thanpt - .
period. It is also possible to investigate how
rci,, Aqi,, Qit,and Vitchange over time for each In order for every firm that remains in the
firm. For incumbents, Qitand rci, change over market to expand its market share, some firms
time as follows. must exit in every period. This will occur only
if price falls over time. It must fall sufficiently
LEMMA 4: For each firm i in the market in in each period t that E(n*) falls below zero
periods t - 1 and t, Qit > Qit- and rci, > for some firms in the market in period t - 1,
rci, -l. causing these firms to exit.
VOL. 86 NO. 3 KLEPPER: INNOVATIONOVER THE PRODUCT LIFE CYCLE 571

Using p, < p, - , it is possible to character- cohort had innovative expertise Smax. If St'
ize how the size of entrants, Aq,, the process Smax for all t then in every period E(fl*) 2 0
R&D of entrants, rc t, and the profits of en- for potential entrantswith innovation expertise
trants from the standardproduct, V t, change Smax,hence E(II*) > 0 for all prior entrants
over time. Let s' denote the minimum product with innovative expertise Smax.Consequently,
innovation expertise in period t among firms no incumbent with innovative expertise Smax
that entered in period k ? t. It is also possible would ever exit the industry. Since Aqi, > 0
to characterize how st, the minimum product for all firms that remain in the industry, firms
innovation expertise among entrants, changes with innovative expertise Smax will expand their
over time. Over time, rc,, Aqt, V,, and s, market share in every period. This cannot,
change as follows. however, occur indefinitely, as eventually
these firms would capture the entire market
LEMMA 6: For all periods I > k, rc' < and would not be able to expand furtherwith-
rck, AqI < Aqk, VI < Vk , and sl > Sk. out some of them exiting. This requires p,
eventually to fall to a level such that E(fI*) <
PROOF: 0 for some incumbents with innovative exper-
The choices of rci, and Aqi, for entrants in tise smax.At this point E(H*) < 0 for all po-
period t must satisfy equations (3) - (6) with tential entrants with si = Smax. Since pt falls
Qit--= 0. These equations differ across pe- over time, after this point E(II*) will con-
riods only because pt falls over time. To see tinue to be negative for potential entrantswith
how changes in pt affect rct, Aq ,, and also Si = Smax, hence s will exceed Smaxand no fur-
V,, set Qi1 = 0 in (3 )-(5 ) and differentiate ther entry will occur.
with respect to pt. This yields
One final result that will be useful concerns
drci*/ dp, = g"(rd * )Gl'(rc)/ D >0 how s' differs across entry cohorts in each pe-
riod. This is summarized as follows.
dAq /dp,
LEMMA 8: In each period t, s' > s' for
I > k.
g"(rd*)Gl"(rc*)Aq* /D > 0
-

dV /dp, = aV a/p, = Aq* > 0. PROOF:


In each period, E(J7i,) 2 0 for producers.
Given that pt < Pt- 1, it follows that rct, Given that V * is lower the younger the firm
Aq,, and V must fall over time. Furthermore, based on Lemma 3, it follows that the mini-
if V falls over time, the marginalentrantmust mum si required for survival must be greater
earn greater incremental profits from product for younger firms. Coupled with the fact that
innovation over time, which implies st must entrants start with higher minimum product
rise over time. innovation expertise than all prior entry co-
horts based on Lemma 6, it follows that the
Lemma 6 indicates that the minimum in- younger the cohort of firms then the greater
novative expertise required for entry rises the minimum product innovation expertise of
over time. Lemma 7 indicates that it eventu- the cohort.
ally rises to the point where no further entry
occurs. The various lemmas indicate how: (1) the
price of the standard product changes over
LEMMA 7: After some period, st > and time; (2) the initial values of rdi,, rcit, Aqi,,
no firms enter the industry. sna, and Vitchange over time for entrants;and (3)
the values of rdi,,rci,, and Qitchange over time
PROOF: for incumbents. Summarizing results, over
Recall that it was assumed that the distri- time pt declines, rdi,remains the same for en-
bution of innovative expertise H(s) was such trants and incumbents, rci,, Aqi,, and Vitde-
that at least one potential entrantin every entry cline over time for entrants,st rises over time
572 THE AMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 1996

for entrants, and rci, and Qt rise over time for p,_ 1,f(p,) {1 -Yi,t Qit- /Q,- | }-2i,tAqit <
incumbents after entry. The other time paths, 0. Given thatf,(pt) and Aqi, arecontinuousfunc-
which involve how Aqi,, V1t, and E(Ji,) tions of p, and all firms are assumed to be
change over time for incumbents after entry, atomistic and indifferentabout being in the in-
cannot be characterized generally. The only dustry when E(ll* ) = 0, it then follows that
pattern that must hold is that in each period, there must be a pricept which satisfiesequation
Vi,andE(Fi,) mustfall for some firms. (7) and thus clears the marketin period t.'2
It was assumed that a price p, existed in each Note that the existence of such a path for
period such that the market cleared given the price does not depend on positive entry in each
choices of firms taking p, as given. This will period, nor does it depend on the time paths in
now be establishedvia induction.It was as- the number of entrants, number of exits, and
sumedthatsuch a priceexistedin period1- number of firms. These time paths are ad-
this was how period 1 was defined. Suppose dressed in the next section.
such a price exists in period t - 1. It will be
shown that a market-clearing price pt then IV. The Regularitiesof the PLC
must exist in period t given the choices of
firmstakingthis pricept as given. Given that Six propositions are developed in this sec-
the market cleared in period t - 1, Qt- = tion corresponding to each of the empirical
-i,-I Qit- , where the summation is over regularities summarized in Section 2.
firmsin the marketin periodt - 1. In period Considerthe first regularityabout entry over
t, pt must satisfy equation(2), which can be time. Let Et denote the number of entrantsin
expressedas period t. The possible time paths in Et implied
by the model are characterizedin Proposition1.
(7) f,(p,){ 1 - Y;Qit-I/ Qt- I PROPOSITION 1: Initially the number of
i7t
entrants may rise or decline, but eventually it
will decline to zero.
- X Aqit = 0,
i,t
PROOF:
where the summation is over firms in the mar- The entry process is such that Et = Kt( 1 -
ket in periodt. In theproofof Lemma5 it was H(st)). Lemma 6 indicates st rises over time.
established that pt must be less than pt - and Hence Et will fall over time unless Kt rises over
mustinducesome firmsto exit; otherwise1 - time at a sufficient rate, which cannot be ruled
Yi,tQit- 1/Qt - I = 0 since the marketcleared in out a priori. Therefore, initially E, may rise or
periodt - 1 and equation(7) would be violated
giventhatAqi,> 0 for eachfirmin themarket.
Giventheassumption of dE(nHt*)Idpt > 0, the
lower pt then the more firms for which 2 The assumption that all firms are atomistic ensures

E(l*) < 0 andthusthe greaterthenumberof the continuity of f(p,){ 1 - .1j, Qit- ,IQt,- I-i, Aqi, as
finns exitingin periodt. The morefirmsthat a function of p, and hence the existence of a price pt sat-
isfying equation (7). A similar assumption is invoked in
exit thenthe greater{I - Yi,tQi- 1/Qt-1} and Jovanovic and Glenn H. MacDonald (1994) and Hugo A.
the smallerXi,tAqi, in equation(7). Further- Hopenhayn (1993) in their models of industry shakeouts
more,the smallerpt thenthe greaterf (pt) and (these are discussed furtherbelow). Alternatively, if firms
the smaller Aqt, for each firm, which reinforces were nonatomisticthen the quantitysupplied,Y, . Qi.- I(Q,I
the effect of exit on the market-clearingcondi- Q,- ) + Yi,t Aqi,, could exceed the quantity demanded,
tion. Thus, as pt decreases relative to pt -I, f(p1), at all prices Pt insufficient to induce the marginal
firm to exit but could fall short of the quantity demanded
f (pt){I- Yi,t Q1t-I/QIQt}rises and Ei,t Aqit at all prices sufficient to induce the marginal firm to exit.
falls in equation (7). Given that l(rc,t) is Then, there would be no price that would clear the market
bounded,at a low enough price E(nl* ) < 0 for in period t. Although beyond the scope of the paper, non-
atomistic firms might be accommodatedby allowing firms
each firm and all firms would exit the industry. to maintain backlogs of unfilled orders so that unsatisfied
Thus,at a low enoughpricef (p,) I 1 - Yjit Q,t-I demand at the equilibrium price in period t was satisfied
Q }-I I - Yi,t Aqit > 0, whereas for prices pt 2 through firm expansion in subsequent periods.
VOL 86 NO. 3 KLEPPER: INNOVATIONOVER THE PRODUCT LIFE CYCLE 573

fall over time. Lemma 7 indicates that in either in the industry in period 2 expand their market
case, E, will eventually decline to 0. share. Therefore, in order for the market to
clear in period 2, the total output of entrants
Proposition 1 can account for the two entry in period 2, K2( 1 - H(s2))\Aq2, must be less
patterns reflected in Figure 1. Intuitively, in than the output exiters in period 2 would have
every period, incumbentshave a lower average produced if they had remained in the industry
cost than entrantsbecause they spend more on and maintainedtheirmarketshare,K1(H(s ) -
process R&D due to the greater output over 1 (Q2/Q1)Aq 1. Since Aq 2< Aq 1based
H(s )l)
which they can apply the benefits of theirR&D. on Lemma 6, this condition can be satisfied
Entrantscan nonetheless gain a foothold in the even if K2(1 - H(s2)) > K1(H(s ) -
industryif they can earn sufficient profits from H(sl)). Thus, initially the number of firms
developing a distinctive productvariant,which may rise. Note that the number of firms could
requiressufficientproduct-innovationexpertise rise from period 1 to 2 even if K2 < K1, which
si. Over time, though, price is driven down would ensure that the number of entrants in
and the advantage of incumbents over entrants period 2, K2(1 - H(s2)), was less than the
grows, increasing the product-innovation ex- number of entrants in period 1, K1( 1 -
pertise requiredfor entry to be profitable.This H(s I)). Thus, the number of firms could rise
reduces the percentage of potential entrants initially even if the number of entrantsfell.
that enter over time, although the number of
entrantscan rise at any time if the number of Intuitively, over time price falls, the more
potential entrants K, rises sufficiently. Even- innovative incumbents expand, and the less in-
tually, price is driven to a level such that re- novative incumbents exit and are replaced by
gardless of their product-innovationexpertise, more innovative, smaller entrants.This can re-
the expected profits of all potential entrantsare sult in a rise in the numberof producers.How-
less than or equal to 0 and entry ceases. ever, as incumbentscontinue to grow their ad-
The second regularityindicates that initially vantages eventually become insurmountable
the total number of firms rises but eventually and entry ceases. Exit continues, though, as the
peaks and then declines steadily, as reflected largest firms with the greatest innovative ex-
in Figure 1. Proposition 2 indicates how this pertise expand their marketshare and push the
can be explained by the model. less fit firms out of the market. Consequently,
eventually the number of firms declines over
PROPOSITION 2: Initially the number of time.
finns may rise over time, but eventually it will Consider next the third regularityregarding
decline steadily. how the market shares of the leaders change
over time. Proposition 3 indicates that the rate
PROOF: of change of the market shares of all incum-
It was shown that p, must fall over time in bents must eventually slow.
Lemma 5, and by a sufficient amount to cause
some firms to exit in every period. Coupled PROPOSITION 3: As eachfirm grows large,
with Lemma 7, which indicates entry must eventually the change in its market share,
eventually stop, this implies that after some Aqi,/Q,, will decline over time.
period the number of firms steadily declines.
To see how the numberof firms could rise over PROOF:
time at some point prior to this, consider with- Given that Q, is nondecreasing over time,
out loss of generality the change in the number Aqi,/Q, will decline over time if Aqi, declines
of firms between periods 1 and 2. This change over time. Equation (5) indicates that Aqi, is
equalsthe numberof entrantsin period2, K2(1 - based on the firm's profit margin on the stan-
H(s2)), minus the number of exits in period dard product,p, - c + I(rci,). For incumbents
2, K1(H(s )-H(s )). The only constraint that remain in the industry, rci, will grow over
on the number of entrants and exits comes time, causing l(rci,) to grow. Eventually,
from the requirement that the market must though, I(rci,) will asymptotically approachits
clear in period 2. All incumbents that remain upper bound, and the rise in l(rci,) will
574 THE AMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 1996

approachzero. In contrast, Lemma 5 indicates quently, once entry ceases, li,t(si + g(rdi,))
thatp, will fall in every period to accommodate declines over time as the number of firms
the desires of incumbents to expand. There- falls.
fore, for incumbents that remain in the indus-
try, p, - c + l(rci,) will eventually decline, Proposition 4 explains the eventual decline
causing the increase in their market share, in the rate of product innovation in new in-
Aqi,/Q,, to decline. dustries reflected in the fourth regularity.
Since each firm performs a constant amount
Intuitively, in every period incumbents ex- of product innovation over time, once entry
pand. The rate at which they expand depends ceases and the number of firms declines then
on their profit margin on the standardproduct. the expected number of product innovations
With the marginal product of process R&D must decline. Corresponding to this is a de-
eventually approaching zero, all firms even- cline in the number of distinctive variants of
tually experience a decline in their profit mar- the product for sale. This explains the other
gin. This will induce them to decrease the rate part of the fourth regularity concerning the
at which they expand their marketshare. Since decline in the number of competing versions
the largest firms perform the most process of the product that eventually occurs in new
R&D, they will be the first to decrease the rate industries. Note that prior to the shakeout in
at which they expand their market share. Sub- the number of producers, the number of firms
sequently, smaller firms will follow.' increases over time as more innovative en-
The other three regularitiespertainto the na- trants displace larger, less innovative incum-
ture of innovation over the PLC. Regarding bents. This causes the number of competing
first the trend over time in the rate of product versions of the product to rise over time.
innovation, it is straightforwardto establish Thus, initially the market induces a rise in the
the following. diversity of competing product versions,
which eventually gives way to a steady de-
PROPOSITION 4: After entry ceases, the ex- cline in this diversity. In this sense, the emer-
pected number of product innovations of all gence of a "dominant design" for a product
finns, 1j, (si + g(rdi,)), declines over time. can be interpretedas the result ratherthan the
cause of the shakeout in the number of pro-
PROOF: ducers. In effect, the private benefits of large
Since rdi, = rd* for all firms according to size eventually compromise the diversity of
Lemma 1, si + g(rdi,) remains the same for competing product versions in the market.
any firm i that remains in the market. Conse- Since all product innovations are introduced
in competing versions of the product and sub-
sequently incorporated into the standard
product, over time the rate of product inno-
1' Note, though, that there is nothing in the model to vation in the standard product will also de-
ensure that the largest firms remain in the marketin every cline as the number of firms falls.
period. Exit will occur in every period, and there is nothing Consider next the trend over time in the ef-
in the model to rule out exit from the first cohort, which
contains the largest finns. Nonetheless, it is possible to fort devoted to process and product R&D. It
establish that the largest cohorts will be subject to the low- is easy to establish the following.
est rate of exit in the following sense. In each cohort that
experiences exit, the firms with the least innovative ex- PROPOSITION 5: For each firm i that re-
pertise will exit. Eventually, whole entry cohorts become
extinct. This will occur for entry cohort k when sk, the mains in the market in period t, rci,/rdi, >
minimum innovation expertise required for survival, ex- rci, - 1/rdi, - 1i
ceeds Smax. Based on Lemma 8, sk will exceed Smaxfirst for
the youngest cohorts, which always have the greatest min- PROOF:
imum product-innovation expertise. Thus, once entry
ceases the youngest cohorts, which are also the smallest,
For each firm, Lemma 1 indicates rdi,is con-
will experience the greatest rates of exit. This accords with stant over time and Lemma 4 indicates that rci,
the findings of numerous studies (for example, David S. rises over time. Hence rci,/rdi,must rise over
Evans, 1987; Timothy Dunne et al., 1989). time.
VOL 86 NO. 3 KLEPPER: INNOVATIONOVER THE PRODUCT LIFE CYCLE 575

Proposition 5 establishes that over time innovations per firm in period t of firms that
every firm that remains in the market in- entered in period k, where N' is the number
creases its effort on process relativeto prod- of firms in period t that entered in period k
uct R&D, which explainsthe fifthregularity. and the summation is over these firms. Prop-
Intuitively,since the returnsto productR&D osition 6 indicates that ik must be greater the
areindependentof firmsize while the returns younger the cohort.
to process R&D are a directfunctionof firm
size, as firmsgrow they increasetheireffort PROPOSITION 6: For all periods t, ik < ia
on process relative to productR&D. This is fork < 1.
just an extremecase of the generalidea that
the returnsto productR&D are less depen- PROOF:
dent on the outputof the firm (prior to the Since all firms spend the same amount on
R&D) than the returnsto process R&D. In product R&D, the expected number of inno-
this sense process and productR&D, which vations per firm, si + g(rdi,), is determined
are often collapsed into one based on an ap- exclusively by si. This implies that on average
peal to a Lancasterianattributesframework, the expected number of innovations per firm
are different. in each entry cohort will be determinedby the
Proposition5 applies to individualfirms. average innovative expertise of firms in the co-
Eventuallythe trendsat the firm level must hort. For each period t, Lemma 8 indicates that
also be mirroredat the marketlevel. Onceen- the minimum innovative expertise of cohort k,
try ceases, the smallest firms are dispropor- Sk, is greater the younger the cohort (that is,
tionatelydrivenfrom the marketgiven their the larger k). Therefore, the average value of
cost disadvantage.These firmshave the high- si will be greaterthe younger the cohort, hence
est ratioof productto processR&D because ak< il for k < 1.
they conduct the least amount of process
R&D. Thus, as they disproportionately exit Proposition 6 implies that entrants will be
andincumbentsincreasetheirlevel of process more innovative on average than incum-
relativeto productR&D,the ratioof totalpro- bents, which explains the last regularity. In-
cess to totalproductR&Dfor all firmsrises.'4 tuitively, the most recent entrants are smaller
Note, though,thatonce entryceases the total than all other firms and thus earn the least
processR&D of all firmsmightdecline over profits from the standard product. The only
time,just at a slowerratethanthe decline in way they survive given this disadvantage is
totalproductR&D.'" if they are more innovative on average than
The last regularityconcerninginnovation incumbents. Thus, it is not necessary to ap-
is that entrantstend to accountfor a dispro- peal to some kind of disadvantage of size in
portionateshare of productinnovationsrel- innovation, or to entrants having a greater
ative to incumbents. Let ik = (i,t(si + incentive than incumbents to innovate be-
g(rdit))/N' denote the expected numberof cause they have less to protect (compare
Reinganum, 1983, 1985), to explain the
greater innovativeness of entrants. Rather,
4 Prior to entry ceasing, there is a counteracting force
at the level of the market to the trend in the ratio of firm the greater innovativeness of entrants may
process to product R&D: smaller, more innovative en- be attributable to the selection process gov-
trantsdisplace larger,less innovative incumbents.Because erning the evolution of the market coupled
the entrantsare smaller, they have a higher ratio of product with an advantage of large firm size in ap-
to process R&D than the incumbents, which contributes
toward a higher ratio of product to process R&D at the
propriating the returns from R&D. Indeed, if
market level. Thus, it is possible that prior to entry ceas- incumbents either had strategic disincentives
ing, the ratio of process to product R&D at the market to innovate or were less efficient at innova-
level might fall over time. Once entry ceases, however, tion because of their larger size, then oppor-
the ratio must rise. tunities for profitable entry would persist
I Whetherthe total amountof process R&D of all firms
declines over time depends on the rate at which incumbent over time, which is not consistent with the
firms expand their process R&D relative to the rate of firm first regularity concerning entry eventually
exit, which is not determined within the model. becoming small.
576 THE AMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 1996

V. Cross-Sectional Implications of the Model Proposition 7 at the level of the industry as


well as for their more detailed predictions.
In this section it is shown that the model can The intuition behind Proposition 7 is simple:
explain various cross-sectional regularities re- the larger the firm then the greater the returns
garding how within industries R&D effort, from process R&D, hence the greaterthe effort
R&D productivity, cost, and profitability dif- devoted to R&D in general and process in par-
fer across firms according to their size. Since ticular. Alternatively stated, the larger the firm
the model was not set up to explain these reg- then the greater the output over which it can
ularities, its ability to explain them can be average the fixed costs of (process) R&D,
viewed as support for its account of the PLC. hence the greater its R&D effort. This implies
A simple cross-sectional implication of the that the close relationship between R&D and
model is that larger firms should performmore firm size is indicative of an advantage of size.
total R&D and also devote a greater fraction In contrast, most studies have interpretedthe
of their R&D to process innovation. close relationship to indicate no advantage of
size. They note that R&D does not tend to rise
PROPOSITION 7: For each period t, the more than proportionallywith firm size, which
larger the output of the firm at the start of the implies that increasing the average firm size
period, Qit- 1, then the greater its total spend- would not increase total industry R&D spend-
ing on R&D, rdi, + rci,, and the greater the ing. This has been widely interpretedto imply
fraction of its total R&D devoted to process there are no advantages of large firm size in
innovation, rci,/(rdi, + rci,). R&D (William L. Baldwin and John T. Scott,
1987 p. 111). But as Cohen and Klepper
PROOF: (1996b) emphasize, without such an advan-
This follows directly from Lemmas 1 and 3. tage it is difficult to explain why there is a
close relationship between R&D and firm
There have been numerous studies of the size.16
relationship between total R&D spending and In addition to predictions about R&D effort
contemporaneous firm size. It has been re- and firm size, the model has distinctive impli-
peatedly found that R&D and contemporane- cations about how firm size and R&D produc-
ous firm size are closely related, with firm size tivity are related.
explaining over 50 percent of the variation in
firm R&D in more R&D-intensive industries PROPOSITION 8: For each period t, the av-
(see Cohen and Klepper [1996b] for a review erage product of process R&D, l(rci,)/rci,,
of these studies). In terms of the composition and the average product of product R&D,
of firm R&D, F. M. Scherer (1991) analyzes (si + g(rdj,))/rdj,, vary inversely with the size
the patents issued to firms in the Federal Trade of thefirm, Qj.
Commission Line of Business Program in the
10-month period from June 1976 to March
1977. Assigning these patents to business units
and classifying them according to whether
they are process or product patents, Scherer 6 Note that in the model there is no innate advantage
finds that among business units with patents, of firm size in R&D, as Cohen and Klepper (1996b) point
the fraction of patents that are process in- out in a related setting. The advantage of large firm size
creases with the sales of the business unit. stems from the inability of firms to sell their innovations
Based on the assumption that the returns to in disembodied form and the costliness of rapid growth.
In the absence of these restrictions, successful innovations
process R&D are more closely tied to the size could be embodied in the entire industry output through
of the firm than the returns to product R&D, the sale of the innovations and/or the expansion of suc-
Cohen and Klepper (1996a) develop addi- cessful innovators, and the contemporaneous size of the
tional predictions at the level of the industry firm would have no bearing on the firm's incentives to
conduct R&D. While many other models assume, either
about the relationship between the fraction of implicitly or explicitly, that innovations cannot be sold
patents that are process and business unit sales. and thus link the returns to innovation to the size of the
Using Scherer's data, they find support for innovator, few assume any restrictions on firm growth.
VOL. 86 NO. 3 KLEPPER: INNOVATIONOVER THE PRODUCT LIFE CYCLE 577

PROOF: spend disproportionately more on R&D than


Given that l"(rci,) < 0 for all rci,, the larger smaller firms, but they appear to get less out
rci, then the lower will be l(rcj,)/rcj,. In each of their R&D spending than smaller firms, sug-
period t, the larger the firm then the greaterits gesting they are actually less efficient at R&D
spending on process R&D. Therefore, l(rci,)/ than their smaller counterparts.This interpre-
rci, will vary inversely with Qt. Regarding tation, though, raises more questions than it
product R&D, Proposition 6 indicates that the answers. If larger firms are less efficient at
expected number of innovations per firm is R&D, why do they conduct more R&D than
greaterfor smaller firms. Since all firms spend smaller firms? Even more fundamentally,how
the same amount on productR&D, this implies are large firms able to survive and prosper in
that (si + g(rdj,))/rdj, must be inversely re- R&D intensive industries if they are less effi-
lated to the size of the firm, Qit. cient at R&D than smaller firms?
These questions are readily answered by the
Proposition 8 is consistent with the findings model. All firms have the same R&D produc-
of studies that examine the relationship be- tivity in the model in the sense that the func-
tween total R&D effort and the numberof pat- tions g(rdi,) and l(rci,), which calibrate the
ents and/or innovations per unit of R&D. John productivity of product and process R&D re-
Bound et al. (1984) find that for publicly spectively, are the same for all firms. The
traded firms, the number of patents per dollar lower average productivity of both product
of R&D is considerably greater for firms with and process R&D in larger firms is a reflection
smaller R&D budgets. Examining this rela- of the competitive advantages conferred by
tionship within industries using data from a firm size. By applying their (process) R&D to
comprehensive census of innovations in 1982 a larger level of output, larger firms are able
conducted for the Small Business Administra- to appropriatea greater fraction of the value
tion, Zoltan J. Acs and David B. Audretsch of their (process) R&D than smaller firms.
(1991) generally find an inverse relationship This induces them to undertakemore process
across firms between the number of innova- R&D than smaller firms. Given the diminish-
tions per dollar of R&D and total R&D spend- ing returnsto R&D, by undertakingmore pro-
ing. If in addition total R&D spending does cess R&D larger firms march furtherdown the
not rise more than proportionally with firm marginal-product schedule of process R&D,
size within industries, as has generally been causing the average product of their process
found, then Proposition 8 further implies that R&D to be lower than in smaller firms. At the
the total product of R&D will not rise in pro- same time, by undertakingmore process R&D
portion to firm size. Equivalently stated, and getting a larger return from their process
within industries larger firms will account for R&D than smaller firms,they earngreaterprof-
a disproportionatelysmall share of process and its from process R&D than smaller firms. This
product innovations relative to their size. This is why they prosper despite the lower average
is consistent with Acs and Audretsch's find- productivity of their R&D than smaller firms.
ings (1988, 1991) based on the Small Busi- The greater profits they earn from process
ness Administration data, especially for more R&D also enables them to survive with less
R&D intensive industries, with Scherer's average product-innovation expertise than
(1965) findings concerning the rate of patent- smaller firms, which explains why they gen-
ing among large firms, and with the observa- erate fewer product innovations per dollar of
tions of Alice Patricia White (1983) for the product R&D than smaller firms.'7
select group of dominant firms she analyzes.
This interpretationruns counter to the con-
ventional interpretationof the inverse relation-
ship between R&D productivity and firm size. '7 Richard J. Rosen (1991) recently proposed an alter-

This finding has been widely interpretedas a native explanation for why large firms account for a dis-
furthersign of the lack of an advantageof firm proportionatelysmall share of innovations relative to their
sales which also relies on large size conferring an advan-
size in R&D (see, for example, Acs and tage in appropriatingthe returns from R&D. His expla-
Audretsch, 1991). Not only do large firms not nation, however, also relies on a stylized depiction of the
578 THE AMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 1996

The modelhas furtherimplicationsregard- PROPOSITION 10: The largest and most


ing how the advantagesconferredby size in profitablefirms will come from thefirst cohort
R&D will be reflectedin firmcost andprofit- of entrants. These firms will increase their
ability.It predictsthat largerfirmswill have market shares over time and consistently earn
lower averagecost. supernormalprofits.

PROPOSITION 9: For each period t, firm PROOF:


average cost c - l(rcj,) varies inversely with Firmsthatenteredin period 1 with innova-
Qit. tive expertiseSmaxwill always be largerthan
all subsequententrantsand will earn greater
PROOF: profitsthanall otherfirms.Consequently,they
Sincerci,variesdirectdy withQitandP'(rci,)> will consistentlyearnsupernormal profitsand
0 for all rci,,it follows directlythatc - l(rci,) will neverexit. Since Aqi, > 0 for all incum-
variesinverselywith Qit. bents,over time these firmswill also increase
theirmarketshares.
This predictionis consistentwith the find-
ings of RichardE. CavesandDavidR. Barton Proposition 10 implies that the market
(1990), who use plantdatafrom the Census sharesof the largestandmostprofitablefirms
of Manufacturers to estimateproductionfunc- in the industrywill not declineovertime.Fur-
tionsfor 4-digitSICmanufacturing industries. thermore,althoughthe profitsof these firms
Allowingproductivityto differ acrossplants, may declineover time as pricefalls, they will
they find that for the averageindustrylarger consistentlyearn supernormalprofits.These
plantsaremoreproductivethansmallerplants. predictions are consistent with Mueller's
In light of the high correlationbetweenplant (1986) findingsconcerningthe persistenceof
andbusinesssize, this findingis supportiveof marketshareandprofitabilityamongthe larg-
Proposition9. Consistentwiththeroleof R&D est manufacturing firmsovertheperiod1950-
in themodelin impartinga lowercost to larger 1972. Muellerfinds that a numberof these
firms,Caves andBarton(p. 126) findthe re- firmsmaintainedtheirmarketsharesover this
lationshipbetweenproductivityandplantsize 22-yearperiod.Whilethe averageprofitability
to be strongerin moreR&D intensiveindus- of these firmsdeclinedover time, they were
tries. Proposition9 is also consistentwith E. still eaming supernormalreturnson invest-
RalphBiggadike's(1979 pp. 65-66) findings mentin 1972. Consistentwith the role played
about entrants.Using detailed data on new by R&Din the modelin conferringan advan-
businessunitsof a subsetof firmsin the PIMS tageto largerfirms,Muellerfindsthatthe per-
dataset, Biggadikefindsthatentrantstend to sistenceof marketshareandprofitabilitywas
startwith a pronouncedproduction-costdis- strongerfor firmsin moreR&D-intensivein-
advantagethat declines over time as the en- dustries.Proposition10 also predictsthatthe
trantscapturea largershareof the market. most successfulandlong-livedfirmswill dis-
The modelhas furtherimplicationsregard- proportionately come from the earliestentry
ing how the advantagesconferredby firmsize cohorts.This is consistentwiththe findingsof
in R&D will be reflected in firm cost and Klepperand Simons (1993) concerningfour
profitability. productsthatexperiencedsharpshakeouts:au-
tos, tires,televisions,andpenicillin.They find
thatthe chancesof survivingat least 10 years
returns to risky R&D projects which suggests, counter to
were significantlygreaterfor the earliesten-
the evidence assembled in Mansfield (1981), that large trants,particularlyin autosandtires, andthat
firms will account for a disproportionatelysmall share of on averagethe largestfirmsenteredearlier.
riskier R&D. As the model indicates, as long as R&D is In summary,the cross-sectionalregularities
subject to diminishing returnsand large firm size provides indicatethatthelargerthefirmthenthegreater
an advantage in appropriatingthe returns to R&D, there
is little need to resort to other stylizations to account for
its spendingon R&D, the greaterthe fraction
the disproportionately small number of innovations ac- of its R&Ddevotedto processinnovation,the
counted for by larger firms. smallerthe numberof patentsandinnovations
VOL. 86 NO. 3 KLEPPER: INNOVATIONOVER THE PRODUCT LIFE CYCLE 579

it generates per dollar of R&D, and the lower might be expected to generate at least as many,
its average costs. Furthermore,earlier entrants if not more, innovations per dollar of R&D
tend to grow larger and survive longer. Since than the smaller finns. Yet the cross-sectional
all of these patterns are predicted by the regularities indicate that the number of patents
model, they provide support for it. The extent and innovations per dollar of R&D declines
of the support, though, depends on the degree with firm size. In terms of the significance of
to which these same patternscan be explained early entry, none of the theories emphasizes
by other theories, particularly theories that the importance of entry timing in conditioning
can account for various features of the PLC. the length of survival of firms that entered
The most relevant alternativetheories are the prior to the shakeout.'9Yet the cross-sectional
dominantdesign view reviewed in the introduc- regularities indicate that among products ex-
tion (compare Utterback and Suairez, 1993), periencing sharp shakeouts, the date of entry
which explains many features of the PLC, and was an importantdeterminantof the length of
theories recently advanced in Jovanovic and survival for the preshakeout entrants.20
MacDonald (1994) and Hopenhayn (1993) to Thus, the alternativetheories cannot readily
explain shakeouts. explain all the regularities.This does not imply
Each of these theories posits technology- that the forces they feature are not operative.
based mechanisms which increase exit and/or Indeed, these forces are largely complemen-
make entry harder,contributingto a shakeout. tary to the ones featured in the model. Judging
In Utterback and Suairez (1993) the mecha- from the cross-sectional regularities,however,
nism is a dominant design, which leads to exit the model appears to capture importantforces
of firms less able to manage the production that are not present in the other theories.
process for the dominant design. In Jovanovic
and MacDonald (1994) it is a major (exoge- VI. Implicationsand Extensions
nous) technological change which leads to exit
of firms that are unable to innovate in the new The notion that entry, exit, marketstructure,
regime. In Hopenhayn (1993) it is a slowdown and innovation follow a common pattern for
in product innovation that favors firms that in- new products has become part of the folklore
vest in process innovation, in the manner of of a number of disciplines, including econom-
the dominant design theory.'8 ics. Although the features of this pattern are
While the theories do not directly address based on a limited number of products and
the cross-sectional regularities, they can none- much of the evidence is impressionistic, they
theless be used to speak to them. In each the- appear to resonate with our experience. De-
ory, the firms that prosper and remain in the spite its popularity, though, there are many
industry during the shakeout are the better in- skeptics about the PLC, both in terms of its
novators.1t might be expected these firms logic and its universality. The principal pur-
would spend more on R&D, particularlypro- pose of this paper was to shore up its logical
cess R&D in the Utterbackand Suairez(1993)
and Hopenhayn (1993) models, have lower
costs, and grow to be larger. This could ex-
'9In each theorythe shakeoutis triggeredby events
plain the cross-sectional regularities involving which changethe basis for competitionamong incum-
firm size and total R&D, the fraction of R&D bents,whichif anythingmightbe expectedto undermine
devoted to process innovation, and average the valueof priorexperience.
cost. The other two regularities, however, are 20Moreover, it doesnotappearto be theshakeoutitself
more difficult for the alternativetheories to ex- whichaccountsfor this effect. Klepper(1996) findsthat
differencesin survivalratesfor the preshakeout entrants
plain. If larger firms are better innovators, they weremostpronounced whentheywereolderandhadsur-
vived a numberof yearsof the shakeout.In the model,
this can be explainedby the selectionprocess(compare
Klepper,1996).On average,laterentrantsare betterin-
18 Hopenhayn (1993) also posits other, nontechnology- novators.At youngages, this can offset the disadvantage
based mechanisms that could triggera shakeout.These are of late entryfor firmsurvival,but as firmsage and the
not considered because they cannot address the cross- selectionprocesscontinuesto operate,eventuallylateren-
sectional regularities involving R&D. trantsmustexperiencehigherhazardrates.
580 THE AMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 1996

foundations by showing how a simple model lative effect on cost of all past process inno-
could explain all the central features of the vations by all firms. This change would not
PLC. fundamentally affect the model.2' Even if cost
The proposed model grounds the PLC with differences across firms were allowed to cu-
two simple forces. One is that the ability to mulate, it would only reinforce the advantages
appropriate the returns to process R&D de- of the largest firms. If firms were allowed to
pends centrally on the size of the firm. The be forward looking, all firms would accelerate
other is that firms possess different types of the growth in their output to take account of
expertise which lead them to pursue different the advantages of size in R&D and accord-
types of product innovations. The advantage ingly undertakegreater process R&D in each
of size in process R&D causes firm process period (Klepper, 1992). But given the costs of
R&D to rise over time and eventually puts en- expanding output, firms would still grow by
trants at such a cost disadvantage that entry is finite rates in each period and it would still be
foreclosed. After entry ceases, firms compete advantageousto enter earlier.Indeed, the firms
on the basis of their size and also their inno- that would accelerate the growth in their out-
vative prowess. As firms exit and the number put the most would be those that expected to
of firms falls, the diversity of product R&D is survive longest, which would be the firms that
compromised, causing the number of product entered earliest with the greatest innovative
innovations and the diversity of competing expertise. Thus, allowing firms to be forward
product variants to decline. The same two looking would not alter the advantagesof early
forces also explain the relationship within in- entry and greaterinnovation expertise and thus
dustries between firm size and total R&D would not fundamentally alter the model. Fi-
spending, relative spending on product and nally, suppose some product innovations were
process R&D, the productivity of R&D, av- not embodied in the standard product but
erage cost, and profitability.The ability of the formed the basis for separate product niches.
model to explain these cross-sectional regu- If all permanent product variants could be
larities in addition to the temporalpatternsthat costlessly imitated one period after they were
define the PLC provides support for its expla- developed and process innovation lowered the
nation of the PLC. It also lends credence to the average cost of all product variants, then the
PLC as a leading case that captures the salient implications of the model would not change.
features of the evolution of technologically All firms would produce all product variants
progressive industries. and the incentives for process R&D would de-
A number of stylizations were invoked to pend on the total output of all variants.22
highlight the two key forces featured in the The depiction in the model of how market
model. Perhaps the most noteworthy were the structure and performance evolve over time
assumptions that average cost was a function for new products is different from the conven-
of only contemporaneous process R&D, de- tional industrial organization paradigm on
cisions were made solely on the basis of short- structureand performance.Historically, indus-
termprofits,and all innovationswere ultimately try characteristicswere seen as shaping the na-
embodied in the industry's standard product. ture of firm cost functions and barriers to
Although relaxing these assumptions would entry, which in turn determined structureand
complicate the model, it need not fundamen- performance. With few exceptions, firm dif-
tally alter the ability of the model to explain ferences within industries were thought to be
the PLC. Regarding process innovation, sup-
pose process improvements were allowed to
cumulate. If all process improvements were 2' The only implication of the model that would change
assumed to be costlessly imitated one period is Proposition 3, which would require further structuring
after they were introduced, firm differences in of the model to establish.
22 The only way the model would be fundamentallyal-
average cost would still be a function of only
teredis if each productniche requiredits own process R&D.
differences in contemporaneousfirm spending In this case, each product niche would be analogous to a
on process R&D. Firm average costs would separate industry, and the model would no longer be a
equal c, - I (rci,), where c, reflects the cumu- model of industryevolution but of industryfragmentation.
VOL 86 NO. 3 KLEPPER: INNOVATIONOVER THE PRODUCT LIFE CYCLE 581

irrelevant(Mueller,1986pp. 223-24). In re- generalizationswould no doubt enrich the


cent years, however, it has been recognized modelandallowit to accommodatedepartures
that firmdifferencesmay be at the root of a fromthe PLCthathavebeenobservedin some
numberof importantphenomena,such as the technologicallyprogressiveindustries(com-
positivecorrelationacrossindustriesbetween pareKlepper,1992), even in its starkformthe
industryconcentrationratios and mean firm model is able to addressa wide rangeof reg-
profitability(Harold Demsetz, 1973). The ularities.It demonstrates
thatmanyaspectsof
model takes this approacha step furtherby industryevolution and heterogeneitywithin
embeddingdifferencesin firmcapabilitiesin industriesin firmR&Deffortandprofitability
an evolutionarysettingin whichexpansionin can be explainedby couplingrandomdiffer-
outputat any given momentis subjectto in- ences in firmcapabilitieswith advantagesof
creasingmarginalcosts and firmsize imparts firmsize conferredby R&D.
an advantagein certaintypes of R&D. The
resultis a world in which initial firm differ- REFERENCES
ences get magnifiedas size begetssize, which
impartsan advantageto earlyentryand leads Abernathy, William J. The productivity di-
to an eventualdeclinein the numberof firms lemma. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Uni-
andthe rateof productinnovation.23 versity Press, 1978.
The starknessof the model precludesany Abernathy,WilliamJ.; Clark,KimB. andKantrow,
departures fromthisevolutionarypattern.This Alan M. Industrialrenaissance: Producing a
can be remedied by allowing for random competitivefiture for America. New York:
eventsthataltertherelativestandingof incum- Basic Books, 1983.
bents and potentialentrants.For example,if Abernathy,WilliamJ. and Utterback,James M.
cohortsdiffer in termsof the distributionof "Patterns of Industrial Innovation." Tech-
theirinnovativeexpertiseor if the innovative nology Review, June/July 1978, 80, pp. 41-
expertiseof incumbentsis undermined by cer- 47.
taintypes of technologicalchanges,thenlater Acs, Zoltan J. and Audretsch,David B. "Inno-
entrantsmayleapfrogovertheindustryleaders vation in Large and Small Firms." Ameri-
andthe firmsthateventuallydominatethe in- can Economic Review, September 1988,
dustrymay not come fromthe earliestcohort 78(4), pp. 678-90.
of entrants.24 Some productsare describedas . "R&D, Finn Size, and Innovative
eventuallybecomingcommodities, whichcould Activity," in Zoltan J. Acs and David B.
be accountedforin themodelby allowingtech- Audretsch, eds., Innovation and technolog-
nologicalopportunities
forinnovation eventually ical change: An international comparison.
to dryup. Incumbentfirmproductandprocess New York: Harvester Wheatseaf, 1991, pp.
R&Dwouldtheneventuallydeclineto zeroand 39-59.
the advantagesof earlyentrywouldeventually Aitken,HughG. J. The continuous wave: Tech-
be eliminated,allowingthe numberof firmsto nology and American radio, 1900-1932.
stabilizebeforethe shakeoutof producershad Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press,
runits fullcourse.Themodelcouldalsobe gen- 1985.
eralizedto includeotheractivities,suchas mar- Anderson, Philip and Tushman, Michael L.
ketingandadvertising, thatcouldsubstitutefor "Technological Discontinuities and Domi-
process R&D in impartingan advantageto nant Designs: A Cyclical Model of Tech-
larger firms (Sutton, 1991).25 While these nological Change." AdministrativeScience
Quarterly, December 1990, 35(4), 604-
33.
23The welfare implications of these and other predic-
tions of the model are developed in Klepper (1992). a more importantrole in conditioning the returmsto pro-
2 These and other generalizations of the model are an- cess than product R&D. This issue, and others, such as
alyzed in Klepper (1992). why firms are limited in their ability to control their in-
25Indeed, for some industrieseven productR&D could novation expertise, involve key aspects of the model that
play this role, although it would seem as if firm size plays merit furtherstudy.
582 THE AMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 1996

Baldwin, William L. and Scott, John T. Market Dunne,Timothy;Roberts,MarkJ. and Samuelson,


structure and technological change. Chur, Larry. "The Growth and Failure of U.S.
Switzerland: Harwood Academic Publish- Manufacturing Plants." Quarterly Journal
ers, 1987. of Economics, November 1989,104(4), pp.
Biggadike,E. Ralph. Corporate diversification: 671-98.
Entrystrategy and performance.Cambridge, Evans,DavidS. "Tests of Alternative Theories
MA: HarvardUniversity Press, 1979. of Firm Growth." Journal of Political
Bound, John; Cummins, Clint; Griliches, Zvi; Economy, August 1987, 95(4), pp. 657-
Hall, Bronwyn H. and Jaffe, Adam. "Who 74.
Does R&D and Who Patents?" in Zvi Flaherty,M. Therese. "Industry Structure and
Griliches, ed., R&D, patents, and produc- Cost-Reducing Investment." Economet-
tivity. Chicago: University of Chicago Press rica, July 1980, 48(5), pp. 1187-209.
for the National Bureau of Economic Re- Flamm, Kenneth. Creating the computer.
search, 1984, pp. 21-54. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institu-
Bright, Arthur A. The electric lamp industry. tion, 1988.
New York: Macmillan, 1949. Gilbert, RichardJ. and Newbery,David M. G.
Bright,JamesR. Automationand management. "Preemptive Patenting and the Persistence
Boston: Graduate School of Business Ad- of Monopoly." American Economic Re-
ministration,HarvardUniversity, 1958. view, June 1982, 72(3), pp. 514-26.
Caves, Richard E. and Barton, David R. Effi- Gort,Michaeland Klepper,Steven."Time Paths
ciency in U.S. manufacturing industries. in the Diffusion of Product Innovations."
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1990. Economic Journal, September 1982,
Clark,Kim B. "The Interaction of Design Hi- 92(367), pp. 630-53.
erarchies and Market Concepts in Techno- Hollander,Samuel.The sources of increased ef-
logical Evolution." Research Policy, ficiency: A study of Du Pont rayon plants.
October 1985, 14(5), pp. 235-51. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1965.
Cohen, Wesley M. and Klepper, Steven. "The Hopenhayn,Hugo A. "The Shakeout." Work-
Anatomy of IndustryR&D Intensity Distri- ing Paper No. 33, Universitat Pompeu Fa-
butions." American Economic Review, Sep- bra, 1993.
tember 1992, 82(4), pp. 773-99. Hounshell,David A. "The Making of the Syn-
. "Firm Size and the Nature of Inno- thetic Fiber Industry in the United States."
vation within Industries: The Case of Pro- Mimeo, HarvardBusiness School, 1988.
cess and Product R&D." Review of Jovanovic,Boyan."Selection and the Evolution
Economics and Statistics, 1996a. of Industry." Econometrica, May 1982,
. "A Reprise of Size and R&D." Eco- 50(3), pp. 649-70.
nomic Journal, forthcoming 1996b. Jovanovic, Boyan and MacDonald, Glenn H.
Dasgupta, Partha and Stiglitz, Joseph. "Indus- "The Life Cycle of a Competitive Indus-
trial Structureand the Nature of Innovative try." Journal of Political Economy, April
Activity." Economic Journal, June 1980, 1994, 102(2), pp. 322-47.
90(358), pp. 266-93. Klein, Burton H. Dynamic economics. Cam-
De Bresson, C. and Townsend, J. "Multivariate bridge, MA: Harvard University Press,
Models for Innovation: Looking at the 1977.
Abernathy-Utterback Model with Other Klepper,Steven. "Entry, Exit, and Innovation
Data." Omega, 1981, 9(4), pp. 429-36. over the ProductLife Cycle: The Dynamics
Demsetz,Harold. "Industry Structure, Market of First Mover Advantages, Declining Prod-
Rivalry, and Public Policy." Journal of uct Innovation, and Market Failure."
Law and Economics, April 1973,16(1), pp. Mimeo, Carnegie Mellon University, 1992.
1-9. . "Evolution, Market Concentration,
Drew, Philip G. "Despite Shakeout, Imaging and Firm Survival." Mimeo, Carnegie Mel-
IndustryNot Doomed to Being Greek Trag- lon University, 1996.
edy." Diagnostic Imaging, November Klepper, Steven and Graddy, Elizabeth. "The
1987, 9, pp. 95-99. Evolution of New Industries and the Deter-
VOL. 86 NO. 3 KLEPPER: INNOVATIONOVER THE PRODUCT LIFE CYCLE 583

minants of Market Structure." Rand Jour- Prusa, ThomasJ. and Schmitz,James A. "Are
nal of Economics, Spring 1990, 21 (1), pp. New Firms an Important Source of Inno-
27-44. vation?" Economics Letters, March 1991,
Klepper,Stevenand Simons,KennethL. "Tech- 35(3), pp. 339-42.
nological Change and IndustryShakeouts." Reinganum, Jennifer. "Uncertain Innovation
Mimeo, Carnegie Mellon University, 1993. and the Persistence of Monopoly." Ameri-
Kraus, Jerome. "An Economic Study of the can Economic Review, September 1983,
U.S. Semiconductor Industry." Ph.D. Dis- 73(4), pp. 741-48.
sertation, New School for Social Research, . "Innovation and Industry Evolu-
1973. tion." Quarterly Journal of Economics,
Mansfield,Edwin. "Entry, Gibrat's Law, In- February 1985, 100(1), pp. 81-99.
novation and the Growth of Firms." Amer- Rosen,RichardJ. "Research and Development
ican Economic Review, December 1962, with Asymmetric Firm Sizes." Rand Jour-
52(5), pp. 1031-51. nal of Economics, Autumn 1991,22(3), pp.
. "Composition of R and D Expendi- 411-29.
tures:Relationship to Size of Firm, Concen- Scherer,F. M. "Firm Size, Market Structure,
tration, and Innovative Output." Review of Opportunity,and the Outputof Patented In-
Economics and Statistics, November 1981, ventions." American Economic Review,
63(4), pp. 610-15. December 1965, 55(5), pp. 1097-125.
Mowery,DavidC. andRosenberg,Nathan.Inside . "Changing Perspectives on the Firm
the black box: Technology and economics. Size Problem," in Zoltan J. Acs and David
New York: Cambridge University Press, B. Audretsch, eds., Innovation and techno-
1982. logical change: An international compari-
Mueller,DennisC. Profits in the long run. Cam- son. New York: HarvesterWheatseaf, 1991,
bridge: Cambridge University Press, 1986. pp. 24-38.
Mueller,DennisC. and Tilton,John. "Research Schmookler,Jacob. Invention and economic
and Development Costs as a Barrier to En- growth. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Univer-
try." Canadian Journal of Economics, No- sity Press, 1966.
vember 1969, 2(4), pp. 570-79. Shaked, Avner and Sutton, John. "Product Dif-
Nelson, RichardR. "Assessing Private Enter- ferentiationand IndustrialStructure." Jour-
prise: An Exegesis of Tangled Doctrine." nal of Industrial Economics, December
Bell Journal of Economics, Spring 1981, 1987, 36(2), pp. 131-46.
12(1), pp. 93-111. Sutton,John. Sunk costs and market structure.
Nelson, Richard R. and Winter, Sidney G. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1991.
"Forces Generating and Limiting Concen- Tilton,JohnE. International diffusion of tech-
trationunder SchumpeterianCompetition." nology: The case of semiconductors. Wash-
Bell Journal of Economics, Autumn 1978, ington, DC: The Brookings Institution,
9(2), pp. 524-48. 1971.
. An evolutionary theory of economic Utterback, James M. and Abernathy, William J.
change. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Univer- "A Dynamic Model of Process and Product
sity Press, 1982. Innovation."Omega, 1975,3(6), pp. 639-56.
Pavitt,K. and Rothwell,R. "A Comment on 'A Utterback, James M. and Suairez, Fernando F.
Dynamic Model of Process and Product In- "Innovation, Competition, and Industry
novation.' " Omega, 1976, 4(4), pp. 375- Structure."Research Policy, February1993,
77. 22(1), pp. 1-21.
Porter, MichaelE. Competitive strategy. New von Hippel, Eric. The sources of innovation.
York: The Free Press, 1980. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1988.
. "The Technological Dimension of White, Alice Patricia.The dominant firm. Ann
Competitive Strategy," in Richard S. Arbor, MI: UMI Research Press, 1983.
Rosenbloom, ed., Research on technologi- Williamson,OliverE. Markets and hierarchies:
cal innovation, management and policy. Analysis and antitrust implications. New
Greenwich, CT: JAI Press, 1983. York: The Free Press, 1975.

You might also like