Jurnal MK 2

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 16

Received: 25 November 2019 Revised: 27 June 2020 Accepted: 28 June 2020

DOI: 10.1002/ijfe.2136

RESEARCH ARTICLE

Liquidity, time-varying betas and anomalies: Is the high


trading activity enhancing the validity of the CAPM in the
UK equity market?

Javier Rojo-Suárez | Ana Belén Alonso-Conde | Ricardo Ferrero-Pozo

Department of Business Administration,


Rey Juan Carlos University, Madrid, Spain
Abstract
In the last decades, a large number of multifactor assetpricing models have
Correspondence emerged with the aim of correcting the estimated equity risk premiums for
Javier Rojo-Suárez, Rey Juan Carlos
University, Department of Business some well-documented market anomalies. In any case, recent research on
Administration Paseo de los Artilleros s/n, asset pricing shows how the higher liquidity resulting from the globalization of
28032 Madrid, Spain.
financial markets has significantly reduced returns tied to many strategies
Email: javier.rojo@urjc.es
based on market anomalies. In this framework, questions arise about the possi-
Funding information ble renovated validity of classic assetpricing models. On this basis, in this
Comunidad de Madrid, Consejería de
Educación e Investigación PEJ16/SOC/AI-
paper we study to what extent the capital assetpricing model (CAPM) has
1627 PEJD-2018-PRE/SOC-8898 recovered its past explanatory power. Specifically, we propose a time-varying
beta CAPM in order to control for the variable nature of beta risk to changes
in the market liquidity, using the variation of the Amihud illiquidity measure
to account for the degree of trading activity. We test both the time-varying and
constant beta models on different sets of anomaly portfolios for the UK equity
market, and we compare their performance to that of the Fama–French three-
and five-factor models. Additionally, we test the constant beta model on a set
of actively managed portfolios, formed according to the variation in market
illiquidity in the previous year. Our results show that the pricing errors of the
CAPM have significantly decreased with respect to those of previous literature.
Furthermore, the time-varying beta model performs similarly to the Fama–
French models in most cases. These results are consistent with increased trad-
ing activity that reduces arbitrage opportunities and, therefore, enhances mar-
ket efficiency.

KEYWORDS
Amihud illiquidity measure, CAPM, Fama–French model, market anomalies, market efficiency,
time-varying beta

1 | INTRODUCTION of financial tasks, their empirical success has been tradi-


tionally small. Together with the difficulty of measuring
Although the classic assetpricing models, with the such a volatile variable as the market return (Black,
capital asset pricing model (CAPM) (Sharpe, 1964; Jensen, & Scholes, 1972; Fama & MacBeth, 1973; Miller &
Lintner, 1965) as its main exponent, enjoy high recogni- Scholes, 1972), findings on a variety of well-documented
tion and are extensively used in practice for a wide range market anomalies reveal severe weaknesses in the

Int J Fin Econ. 2020;1–16. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/ijfe © 2020 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 1
2 ROJO-SUÁREZ ET AL.

CAPM. These anomalies not only lead to an increase in For the specific case of the United Kingdom equity mar-
the gap between betas and expected returns, but in many ket, interestingly, Cuthbertson, Hayes, and Nit-
cases they also result in inverse patterns between both zsche (1997) clearly reject efficiency for the period from
variables. Remarkably, Cochrane (2011) shows that the 1918 to 1993. However, the authors show that the CAPM
CAPM works correctly prior 1963, properly capturing the provides results that are close to efficiency, despite the
value effect (see Figure A1 of his paper), that is, produc- fact that tests for short-termism provide evidence to the
ing higher betas for value portfolios and lower betas for contrary. Additionally, recent research expands the scope
growth portfolios. Conversely, for the period 1963–2009, of analysis, covering topics such as the relation between
the author shows that exactly the opposite is true. Since market anomalies and the real economy, while increas-
the pattern of expected returns persists (i.e., value stocks ing the focus on the persistence of alphas rather than
still provide the highest expected returns, and vice versa), their magnitude (Van Binsbergen & Opp, 2019).
this completely ruins the performance of the CAPM. Despite the above, research on stock return predict-
In any case, recent research on asset pricing shows ability has contributed to largely explain the failure of
how the high liquidity resulting from the globalization of classic assetpricing models. According to Roll's theorem
financial markets has significantly reduced returns tied (Roll, 1977), any portfolio on the mean–variance frontier
to many strategies based on market anomalies. Conse- contains exactly the same information about asset prices
quently, questions arise about a hypothetical renovated as the wealth portfolio –commonly proxied by a broad-
validity of classic assetpricing models, and more specifi- based portfolio such as the value-weighted London Stock
cally the CAPM. Accordingly, in this paper we study to Exchange portfolio. Therefore, the whole issue consists in
what extent the CAPM has recovered its past explanatory finding an efficient portfolio, which, together with the
power in one of the largest equity markets in the world risk-free rate, allows investors to price every asset. If mar-
according to the World Federation of Exchanges, the ket returns are independent and identically distributed
London Stock Exchange. Besides the classic constant beta (i.i.d.), this will be achieved simply by compiling enough
model (hereafter referred to as classic CAPM), we pro- historical data to ensure that estimates are statistically
pose a time-varying beta CAPM (hereafter referred to as significant. However, since return predictability and
scaled CAPM) that allows us to control for the variable time-varying expected returns are interchangeable terms,
nature of beta risk to changes in market illiquidity. We the forecastable nature of stock returns completely ruins
use the Amihud illiquidity measure to account for the the CAPM results out-of-sample, even when the model
degree of trading activity (Amihud, 2002). However, perfectly fits in-sample. Given the large number of vari-
unlike the majority of the literature, in order to avoid ables useful for forecasting stock returns,1 the poor
problems arising from the non-stationarity of this indica- results of the CAPM arise mainly from the variable
tor in sample, we use variations instead of levels. As nature of the expected returns, rather than arising from
shown below, our results reveal that, using market data other problems such as the difficulties in correctly deter-
for the period from January 1989 to December 2018, the mining the wealth portfolio. Table 1 summarizes the
pricing errors of the classic CAPM have significantly results achieved by some recent tests on the CAPM,
decreased with respect to those of previous literature. which typically introduce some variation to the classic
Moreover, the scaled CAPM performs similarly to the model, or conceive the proof as a way to highlight the
Fama–French models in most cases. strengths of some alternative assetpricing model.
While the first studies on market anomalies focus on The majority of the literature deals with this problem
several relations not captured by the CAPM, such as by using multifactor assetpricing models, which can be
those of expected returns with the size of the firm viewed as closed-form solutions for more general models
(Banz, 1981), the book-to-market equity (Basu, 1983), the such as the intertemporal CAPM (ICAPM) or the arbi-
price-to-earnings ratio (Rosenberg, Reid, & trage pricing theory (hereafter, APT). The ICAPM
Lanstein, 1985), the past short-term returns (Jegadeesh & (Merton, 1973) assumes that investors face shifts in the
Titman, 1993) or the past sales growth (Lakonishok, investment opportunity set which can be captured by dif-
Shleifer, & Vishny, 1994), currently many other variables ferent state variables. This approach automatically gives
constitute anomalies in the framework of classic rise to a multifactor assetpricing model, with the state
assetpricing models. Such is the case of accruals variables as right-hand side variables. Since shifts in the
(Sloan, 1996), idiosyncratic volatility (Ang, Hodrick, environment determine changes in the conditional distri-
Xing, & Zhang, 2006), asset growth (Cooper, Gulen, & bution of asset returns over time, the state variables must
Schill, 2008), net stock issuance (Fama & French, 2008), have some predictive power (Cochrane, 2005, p. 172). On
return-on-book equity (Chen, Novy-Marx, & the other hand, the APT (Ross, 1976) adopts a different
Zhang, 2011) or gross profitability (Novy-Marx, 2013). perspective, assuming that stocks share strong common
ROJO-SUÁREZ ET AL. 3

TABLE 1 Recent evidence on the CAPM performance

Passes model
Reference Country Test assets Sample Model R 2 statistic evaluation test
Campbell, Giglio, Polk, US 25 portfolios BE/ME, 6 risk- 1931–1963 Classic CAPM 74% No (J-test)
and Turley (2018) sorted portfolios, 18 1963–2011 Classic CAPM −20% No (J-test)
characteristic- and risk-
sorted portfolios and
managed versions of these
portfolios
Hyde and Sherif (2010) UK 9 industry portfolios and 6 1975–2005 Conditional Multiple No (J-test)
size-BE/ME portfolios CAPM values, poor
results
Jagannathan and US 100 size-beta portfolios 1963–1990 Classic CAPM 1.35% No (HJ-distance)
Wang (1996) Conditional 29.32% No (HJ-distance)
CAPM
Conditional 55.21% Yes (HJ-distance)
CAPM with
human capital
Jagannathan and US 25 size-BE/ME portfolios 1954–2003 Classic CAPM 0% No (HJ-distance)
Wang (2007)
Lettau and US 25 size-BE/ME portfolios 1963–1998 Classic CAPM 1% No (χ 2 test)
Ludvigson (2001) Conditional 31% Yes (χ 2 test)
CAPM
Conditional 77% Yes (χ 2 test)
CAPM with
human capital
Lustig and Van US 25 size-BE/ME portfolios and 1926–2002 Classic CAPM 28.3% Not reported
Nieuwerburgh (2005) the value-weighted market Collateral- 87.8% Not reported
return CAPM
Maio and Santa- US 25 size-BE/ME portfolios 1963–2008 Classic CAPM −0.42% Not reported
Clara (2012) 25 size-momentum portfolios 1963–2008 Classic CAPM −0.09% Not reported
Yogo (2006) US 25 size-BE/ME portfolios 1951–2001 Classic CAPM −62% No (J-test)

Note: Conditional versions of the model use different variables as instruments. Hyde and Sherif (2010) use the lagged excess market return,
the yield on a console bond less the return on a 30-day bill, the term premium calculated as the return for holding a 90-day bill for 1 month
in excess of the return on a 30-day bill, and the dividend yield spread. Jagannathan and Wang (1996) use the yield spread between BAA- and
AAA-rated bonds. Lettau and Ludvigson (2001) use the consumption-wealth ratio (cay). Lustig and Van Nieuwerburgh (2005) use the ratio
of housing wealth to human wealth (my). R2 statistics are not adjusted for degrees of freedom.

components –factors– and idiosyncratic movements do in the form of bounds on the Sharpe ratios of factor port-
not carry information about prices. Specifically, the APT folios and asset payoffs.
assumes that the errors provided by the regression of Although in practice it is often difficult to sort multi-
asset payoffs (i.e., returns, excess returns, etc.) on factors factor models into one of these two categories, some of
are uncorrelated across assets. Therefore, the APT consti- the most prominent assetpricing models are good exam-
tutes essentially a statistical characterization of asset pay- ples of both ICAPM and APT approaches. This is the case
offs, which does not require the strict economic of the Fama–French three-factor model (Fama &
assumptions tied to the ICAPM. However, in reality asset French, 1993), which adds two extra factors to the classic
payoffs do not follow a perfect factor structure, so the law CAPM –the small minus big market value factor (SMB)
of one price, by itself, can provide arbitrarily wrong and the high minus low book-to-market ratio factor
results (Cochrane, 2005, p. 177). In general, this forces (HML)– and still remains one of the most successful
the model to embed some economic restrictions, typically assetpricing models in the literature. Carhart (1997)
4 ROJO-SUÁREZ ET AL.

studies the persistence of returns in the U.S. mutual fund 62 industry portfolios, and the total sample of 107 portfo-
market, developing a performance attribution model that lios that results from aggregating the previous samples.
adds a momentum factor to the Fama–French three- Parallel to this, we test the performance of the classic
factor model. He achieves results consistent with market CAPM on a set of actively managed portfolios, formed on
efficiency on the basis of his four-factor model. On the the basis of the portfolios defined above and the Amihud
other hand, Fama and French (2015) improve their illiquidity measure of the market as a whole, for the pre-
three-factor model by adding two extra factors, namely, vious year. This allows us to check how the CAPM per-
RMW (the excess return of the most profitable stocks forms in pricing different trading strategies mechanically
minus the least profitable) and CMA (the excess return of driven by the variation in market illiquidity.
firms that invest conservatively minus aggressively). Hereafter, the paper proceeds as follows: Section 2
Notwithstanding the above, recent research shows how defines the model under analysis, Section 3 discusses the
the high global trading activity and the increase in the liquid- results, and Section 4 concludes the paper.
ity are reducing the spreads tied to many strategies based on
market anomalies. While some authors study the effects of the
increased trading activity on specific market anomalies 2 | THE M ODEL
(Green, Hand, & Soliman, 2011; Mashruwala, Rajgopal, &
Shevlin, 2006) and concrete variables, such as the trading costs Given a market that satisfies the law of one price, there is
of institutional investors (Chakravarty, Panchapagesan, & one single stochastic discount factor (SDF) in the payoff
Wood, 2005; French, 2008), others focus on the effects on the space which exactly prices all payoffs (Harrison &
liquidity (Hendershott, Jones, & Menkveld, 2011). Notewor- Kreps, 1979; Ross, 1978; Rubinstein, 2010). Consequently:
thy, Chordia, Roll, and Subrahmanyam (2011) conclude that,
in recent years, stock market intra-day volatility and cross- pt = Et ðmt + 1 xt + 1 Þ, ð1Þ
sectional predictability of returns has decreased, while
information-based trading activity has intensified, resulting in where pt is a N-dimensional vector of prices, mt+1 is the
a higher market efficiency. Consistently, Chordia, Sub- SDF, xt+1 is the N-dimensional vector of future payoffs,
rahmanyam, and Tong (2014) show how the greater trading and Et() is the expectation conditional on information at
activity has significantly downsized the majority of the market time t. Since asset returns are payoffs with price one, we
anomalies. Specifically, their results reveal that average can rewrite expression (1) as follows:
returns provided by strategies based on market anomalies
have approximately halved in recent years due to increases in 1 = Et ðmt + 1 Rt + 1 Þ, ð2Þ
hedge funds activity, short interest and aggregate share turn-
over. Accordingly, McLean and Pontiff (2016) show that port- where Rt+1 is a N-dimensional vector of returns at time t
folio returns tied to 97 variables useful for forecasting cross- + 1. Given that the difference between two returns is an
sectional stock returns are 58% lower post-publication. The excess return, that is, a payoff with price zero, then:
authors emphasize that post-publication declines are stronger
 
for variables with higher in-sample returns. On the other 0 = Et mt + 1 Ret+ 1 , ð3Þ
hand, returns are higher for portfolios with high idiosyncratic
risk and low liquidity. Bornholt (2013) states that, if the mar-
ket anomalies are not permanent, then the CAPM may be where Ret+ 1 is a N-dimensional vector of excess returns.
revived again. He explains how the beta anomaly –the fact Rearranging expression (3) to express expected excess
that the CAPM tends to underestimate the returns of the port- returns as a function of the SDF:
folios formed by stocks with low betas, and vice versa– has
 
weakened and it is reasonable to believe that it will disappear   cov t mt + 1 , Ret+ 1
Et Ret+ 1 =− , ð4Þ
over time. E t ð mt + 1 Þ
In this paper, we use both the Fama–French three-
and five-factor models (hereafter referred to as FF3 and
FF5 models, respectively) to check the performance of Expression (4) can be easily written in terms of a beta
the scaled CAPM and the robustness of its results, consis- model, simply by multiplying and dividing by vart(mt+1):
tently with common practice in the assetpricing litera-
  
ture. We test all models on four different sets of   cov t mt + 1 , Ret+ 1 vart ðmt + 1 Þ
Et Ret+ 1 = −
portfolios, namely, 25 portfolios sorted by size and book- vart ðmt + 1 Þ E t ð mt + 1 Þ ð5Þ
to-market equity (BE/ME), 20 portfolios sorted by the  
= βt mt + 1 ,Rt + 1 λt ðmt + 1 Þ,
e
growth of total assets in the previous fiscal year,
ROJO-SUÁREZ ET AL. 5

Assuming a SDF linear in a K-dimensional vector of log utility, the consumption is proportional to wealth, so
factors, mt + 1 = at + b0t f t + 1 , expression (5) gives rise to a f t + 1 = RW 4
t + 1 and expression (6) becomes the CAPM :
factor assetpricing model:
     W 
    Et Ret+ 1 = βt RW
t + 1 ,R t + 1 λt Rt + 1 ,
e
ð10Þ
Et Ret+ 1 = βt f t + 1 , Ret+ 1 λt ðf t + 1 Þ, ð6Þ

In any case, it should be noted that all expressions


where ft+1 is the vector
 of factors, at and bt are parame- above involve time-varying parameters. While classic
ters, βt f t + 1 ,Ret+ 1 is the matrix of order N × K of betas empirical testing of assetpricing models typically assumes
of excess returns on factors, and λt(ft+1) is the K- parameters that are constant over time, shifts in market
dimensional vector of prices of the factors. Logically, the structure and the forecastable nature of returns call into
equivalence of expressions (5) and (6) is guaranteed pro- question this approach. Consequently, as previously
vided that the parameters of the model are determined noted, in this paper we propose a model that controls for
consistently. Specifically, if we demean the factors of the the variable nature of the parameters of expression (10),
model for reasons of clarity, then at = Et(mt+1) and the in the presence of changes in the trading activity of the
parameters bt and λt(ft+1) must satisfy (Lettau & market. Specifically, we assume a linear SDF with time-
Ludvigson, 2001): varying parameters that depend on shifts in the illiquidity
level in the previous period. Using an approach equiva-
 −1
bt = −at cov t f t + 1 , f 0t + 1 λt ðf t + 1 Þ, ð7Þ lent to that of Lettau and Ludvigson (2001), we define the
SDF of our model as follows:

t + 1 = θ0 + θ1 ΔILt + ðψ 0 + ψ 1 ΔILt ÞRt + 1 ,


mt + 1 = at + bt RW
According to the law of one price, expressions above W

hold regardless of the economic content of the model and, ð11Þ


particularly, expression (6) holds regardless of the
approach used to explain the price formation process,
either the ICAPM or the APT. However, if we additionally where θ0, θ1, ψ 0 and ψ 1 are parameters, and ΔILt is the
assume that the pricing function leaves no arbitrage variation in the market illiquidity from the period ending
opportunities, then at least one positive SDF is in t − 1 to the period ending in t. The use of an illiquidity
guaranteed2 (Ross, 1978). Since marginal utility is assumed instrument allows us to drop the t subscripts in at and bt,
to be positive, this allows for a purely macroeconomic under the assumption that their variability over time
explanation of the price formation process. In this frame- arises from changes in the market illiquidity. This allows
work, the first-order condition for an optimal consumption us to write expression (3) as follows:
and portfolio choice allows us to express the SDF as a
 
function of the investor's marginal utility, as follows: 0 = E ½θ0 + θ1 ΔILt + ðψ 0 + ψ 1 ΔILt ÞRW e
t + 1 Rt + 1 , ð12Þ

u0 ðct + 1 Þ
mt + 1 = β , ð8Þ
u 0 ðc t Þ Rearranging terms, we get the following
scaled CAPM:
where β is the subjective discount factor,3 u0 (ct) is the
       
marginal utility, and ct is the consumption at time t in E Rte+ 1 = β RtW+ 1 , Rte+ 1 λ RtW+ 1 + β ΔILt ,Rte+ 1 λðΔILt Þ
real units. If the investor's utility function is separable, + β RtW+ 1 ΔILt , Rte+ 1 λ RtW+ 1 ΔILt ,
then u(ct, xt) = υ(ct) + ω(xt), and consumption is the only ð13Þ
relevant variable for asset pricing. In that case, without
assuming any specific property for asset returns, the
ICAPM arises naturally. Specifically, if optimal consump- It is worth noting that the last term on the right-hand
tion is a function of a vector of state variables zt, ct = g side of expression (13) helps us to capture the time-
(zt), then expression (6) holds automatically, with: varying pattern of the parameters in expression (10),
which allows us to express the unconditional mean
 0
f t + 1 = RW
t + 1 , zt + 1 , ð9Þ returns in terms of an unconditional multifactor model.
As mentioned above, we use the Amihud illiquid-
ity measure to estimate the illiquidity level of the
where RW t + 1 is the rate of return on a claim to total market, according to the following expression
wealth, or wealth portfolio. It is worth to note that, with (Amihud, 2002):
6 ROJO-SUÁREZ ET AL.

jRi,d j Reit −β0i f t = αi + εit , ð19Þ


ILi,d = , ð14Þ
VOLi,d

where jRi,dj is the absolute return of asset i on day d and and, consequently, lower intercepts, thereby improving
VOLi,d is the volume traded for asset i on day d in cur- the performance of the assetpricing model.
rency units. Although Amihud (2002) remarks that there Finally, following an approach similar to that of
are several aspects that determine the liquidity of Campbell et al. (2018), we also consider managed portfo-
stocks—market value, turnover, or the bid-ask spread, lios that change equity exposure according to the value of
among many others—and it is doubtful that there is a some variable, in this case ΔILt. At this point, it is worth
single measure that captures them all, the Amihud illi- to note that instrumental variables, such as the market
quidity measure is widely used by the literature to proxy illiquidity, may affect indistinctly on both sides of the
the market illiquidity. pricing function. Specifically, given an instrument zt—or
In order to aggregate ILi,d over time, we operate sepa- a vector of instruments—observable at time t, which is
rately in the numerator and denominator of expression informative about the state of the economy or predicts
(14), as follows: returns, then, following the methodology developed by
Hansen and Singleton (1982), we can write the pricing
Q
t function as follows:
jRi,d j
ILi,t = Pdt = 1 , ð15Þ  
d = 1 VOLi,d
0 = Et mt + 1 Ret+ 1 zt , ð20Þ

Additionally, to estimate the illiquidity of the market which automatically provides the following model of
as a whole, we calculate the weighted average of ILi,t covariances:
across assets, as:
 
  cov t mt + 1 zt , Ret+ 1
X Et Ret+ 1 =− , ð21Þ
N
ILi,t MEi,t E t ð mt + 1 z t Þ
ILt = , ð16Þ
i=1
ME t

However, expression (20) can also be written as


where MEi,t is the market equity of asset i at time t, and follows:
MEt is the total market equity at time t. Finally, regard-
 
less of the long-run behaviour of ILt, in order to avoid   cov t mt + 1 , Ret+ 1 zt
Et Ret+ 1 zt =− ð22Þ
problems arising from its non-stationarity in sample, we E t ðm t + 1 Þ
use the variation of ILt in our model.
All beta models described above set a restriction on the
intercepts of the time-series regressions that allow calculating Therefore, expressions (21) and (22) constitute two
beta estimates. Given the following time-series regression: different ways of testing the economic content of the
model. However, since pricing errors that arise from
Reit = αi + β0i f t + εit , ð17Þ these expressions are sensitive to model misspecification,
both approaches complement each other. For this reason,
in the following Section we test the assetpricing model in
where Reit is the excess return for the asset i at time t, αi is both ways.
the intercept, and εit is the error term, then the intercepts
must satisfy (Cochrane, 2005, p. 244):
3 | RESULTS A ND DISCUSSION
αi = β0i ½λ− Eðf t Þ, ð18Þ
We test the model defined in the previous Section on dif-
If the assetpricing model prices assets perfectly and ferent sets of portfolios, which comprise all stocks listed
the factors are excess returns, then λ = E(ft) and the in the London Stock Exchange for the period from
intercepts are zero. As previously noted, the fact that the January 1989 to December 2018. We compile all stock
returns provided by many anomaly-based strategies have data from Thomson Reuters Datastream database. Partic-
declined significantly in recent years, should imply lower ularly, we collect data for the following series, on a
returns for the following arbitrage portfolios: monthly basis: (a) total return index (RI series), which
ROJO-SUÁREZ ET AL. 7

allows us to determine asset returns, (b) market value Given the strong seasonal behaviour of the liquidity
(MV series), (c) market-to-book equity (PTBV series), premium (Batrinca, Hesse, & Treleaven, 2018;
(d) total assets (WC02999 series), (e) return on equity Eleswarapu & Reinganum, 1993), we adapt the approach
(WC08301 series), (f) tax rate (WC08346 series), followed by Jagannathan and Wang (2007) and switch
(g) primary SIC codes, (h) turnover by volume our final series to an annual basis.
(VO series), and (i) the market price (P series). Addition- Table 2 shows the main summary statistics for portfo-
ally, we compile RI, VOL and P series on a daily basis in lios and factors, while Table 3 shows the correlations
order to determine the Amihud illiquidity measure. Fol- between our test assets and the explanatory variables of
lowing Griffin, Kelly, and Nardari (2010), we use the the scaled CAPM, that is, RMRF and ΔIL. As shown,
generic rules provided by the authors for excluding non- both asset growth portfolios and industry portfolios pro-
common equity securities from Datastream data. Specifi- vide moderate mean returns and standard deviations in
cally, we remove from our sample all stocks issued by most cases. However, size portfolios exhibit mean returns
real estate investment trusts, venture capital trusts, cur- and volatilities abnormally high for the first and second
rency funds and exchange traded funds. Table B.1 in Grif- quintiles, mainly due to several specific firms that experi-
fin et al. (2010) lists the Datastream industry codes that enced important price increases in concrete periods. In
correspond to these securities. any case, the size and value effects work as expected, so
We use the three-month interest rate of the Treasury that, in general, the smaller the size and the higher the
Bill for the United Kingdom, as provided by the OECD BE/ME ratio, the higher the mean return, and vice versa.
database, as a proxy for the risk-free rate. With regard to factors, it is worth noting that the mean
We use this data to create four sets of portfolios, which return of RMRF amounts to 12.46%, which is a relatively
constitute our test assets.5 First, we create 25 size-BE/ME high value compared to other stock markets. In fact, the
portfolios, according to the Fama and French (1993) meth- Sharpe ratio of RMRF amounts to 0.7, outperforming
odology. Specifically, at the end of June of each year we other markets with Sharpe ratios of approximately
allocate all stocks to quintiles based on their market equity 0.4–0.5. Remarkably, the standard deviation of ΔIL
and, analogously, we allocate stocks in an independent (45.31%) more than doubles that of RMRF (17.71%),
sort to five BE/ME groups. Size-BE/ME portfolios are which contributes to significantly increase the volatility
determined as the intersection of the size and BE/ME of the SDF, as defined in expression (11).
groups. We determine value-weighted returns on the port- Regarding correlations, Table 3 shows that RMRF is
folios accordingly. Second, we form 20 anomaly portfolios strongly correlated with most portfolios under consider-
using the same approach, this time with total asset growth ation, with coefficients that exceed the 70% in the major-
as sorting variable. Third, we form all possible industry ity of cases. With respect to illiquidity, it should be noted
portfolios according to data available, using two-digit SIC that expression (13) considers ΔIL as measured at time t,
codes. As a result, the total number of industry portfolios while asset returns are measured at time t + 1. In order
amounts to 62. Finally, the fourth dataset comprises all to determine the optimal number of lags for ΔIL, we use
portfolios of the previous samples. It is worth to mention the Akaike information criteria, which provide an opti-
that, although value portfolios have traditionally been a mal lag number equal to 1 year. Accordingly, Table 3
challenging hurdle for the CAPM, Lewellen, Nagel, and shows the correlations between lagged ΔIL and portfolio
Shanken (2010) explain that the strong factor structure of returns. Although the results show that ΔIL is far less
these portfolios can easily lead to overstating the explana- correlated with asset returns than RMRF, many correla-
tory power of assetpricing models. To avoid this, the tions range from 20% to 30%, which reveals a positive
authors suggest using additional portfolios, for example relationship between the variation in market illiquidity
industry portfolios. Additionally, they suggest testing and stock returns.
models in samples that simultaneously combine portfolios In order to test the explanatory power of the model,
formed under different sorting variables. We have followed Table 4 and Figures 1 and 2 show the results provided by
these recommendations to configure our datasets. the scaled CAPM, according to expression (13), as well as
We use FF3 and FF5 models to compare their results those provided by the classic CAPM and the Fama–
with those provided by the scaled CAPM. Consequently, French models. We use GMM to estimate together time-
we use our data series to determine the required factors, series and cross-section parameters, correcting standard
following the Fama and French (1993) and Fama and errors for cross-sectional correlation and for the fact that
French (2015) methodology. As usual in the assetpricing betas are generated regressors. Following Lewellen
literature, we use the value-weighted market portfolio et al. (2010), Table 4 shows both the adjusted OLS and
minus the risk-free rate (hereafter, RMRF) as a proxy for GLS R2 statistics for all models. As the authors explain,
the wealth portfolio RW t + 1. the GLS R2 statistic constitutes a challenging check for
8 ROJO-SUÁREZ ET AL.

TABLE 2 Summary statistics

Panel A: 25 portfolios size-BE/ME

Book-to-market equity (BE/ME) quintiles

Means SD

Size Low 2 3 4 High Low 2 3 4 High


Small 101.43 88.20 91.39 93.03 87.17 173.99 135.94 158.39 121.54 91.39
2 42.32 81.06 51.24 53.60 54.60 67.68 208.33 85.55 65.24 74.09
3 25.20 30.96 29.78 31.62 51.14 42.46 44.98 38.98 48.11 88.49
4 23.98 22.84 21.43 25.79 34.48 42.69 32.66 30.23 27.11 41.20
Big 10.24 10.69 10.71 12.61 13.44 17.03 17.38 17.78 22.43 27.03
Panel B: 20 asset growth portfolios

Means SD
1–5 22.58 14.08 14.95 11.90 10.85 47.03 27.81 36.99 26.12 22.76
6–10 11.67 10.45 14.25 13.79 9.82 26.35 23.71 26.79 17.49 16.99
11–15 9.98 7.67 14.98 11.12 17.19 13.92 14.72 27.95 23.48 22.74
16–20 16.55 15.60 18.93 24.96 32.55 23.82 25.82 33.84 39.15 56.69

Panel C: 62 industry portfolios deciles

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Means 9.42 10.65 11.67 12.22 14.45 16.22 17.29 19.14 24.57 40.87
SD 21.75 23.02 27.41 29.42 31.77 35.47 37.71 45.93 56.83 130.06

Panel D: Factors

FF5 factors FF3 factors Illiquidity

RMRF SMB HML RMW CMA RMRF SMB HML ΔIL


Means 12.46 41.46 6.96 12.12 −11.54 12.46 41.42 6.96 11.61
SD 17.71 63.22 25.63 36.03 27.32 17.71 66.83 25.63 45.31

Note: We compile monthly series from Thomson Reuters Datastream database, for all stocks listed in the London Stock Exchange in the
period from January 1989 to December 2018. Using this data, we form the following portfolios: (a) 25 portfolios size-BE/ME, (b) 20 asset
growth portfolios, and (c) 62 industry portfolios. In order to determine excess returns, when appropriate we use the three-month interest rate
of the Treasury Bill for the United Kingdom. All results are annual percentages.

assetpricing models, since it is high only if the model can of 83.4% and 87.6%, respectively. The best performing
explain the maximum Sharpe ratio available on the test model is the FF5 model, with an OLS R2 statistic of
assets. Conversely, the OLS R2 statistic is weakly related 95.6%. Although these results worsen for asset growth
to the factors' location in the mean–variance space. portfolios (Panel B), both the scaled CAPM and the
Regardless of the specific sample, all results shown in Fama–French models provide roughly the same OLS R2
Table 4 allow us to conclude that the four models under statistics, with values around 75%. Remarkably, the GLS
study perform quite similarly, displaying a good explana- R2 statistic falls strongly for all models, except the FF3
tory power in the majority of cases. In any case, the model, which means that RMRF is far from being mean–
Fama–French models (FF3 and FF5) provide the best variance efficient.
results, closely followed by the scaled CAPM. Although Table 4, Panel C, shows that all models perform
the classic CAPM is the worst performing model, its worse for industry portfolios, but still within acceptable
results are significantly better than those of previous liter- limits. The results are very similar for the four models
ature, performing satisfactorily for all samples. Specifi- under consideration, with OLS R2 statistics of approxi-
cally, for size-BE/ME portfolios (Table 4, Panel A), the mately 65% and the scaled CAPM providing the highest
classic CAPM provides an OLS R2 statistic of 69.1%, while GLS R2 statistic (62.3%). It is worth to note that the J-test
the scaled CAPM and the FF3 model provide R2 statistics for overidentifying restrictions rejects all models in the
ROJO-SUÁREZ ET AL. 9

TABLE 3 Correlations
Panel A: 25 portfolios size-BE/ME

Book-to-market equity (BE/ME) quintiles

Size Low 2 3 4 High Low 2 3 4 High


RMRF ΔIL
Small 0.63 0.70 0.44 0.39 0.53 0.38 0.36 −0.10 −0.06 −0.01
2 0.67 0.60 0.59 0.67 0.66 0.29 0.30 −0.01 0.19 0.07
3 0.82 0.74 0.80 0.73 0.43 0.13 0.05 0.05 0.00 −0.16
4 0.80 0.82 0.83 0.84 0.71 0.19 0.13 0.16 0.22 0.05
Big 0.84 0.93 0.96 0.89 0.76 −0.01 0.20 0.20 0.20 0.09

Panel B: 20 asset growth portfolios

RMRF ΔIL
1–5 0.73 0.69 0.42 0.68 0.81 0.09 −0.17 −0.06 −0.07 0.13
6–10 0.89 0.80 0.87 0.71 0.89 0.23 0.16 0.24 0.23 0.17
11–15 0.85 0.79 0.89 0.82 0.73 0.12 0.21 0.22 −0.02 0.08
16–20 0.86 0.86 0.75 0.79 0.51 0.33 0.12 0.23 0.07 −0.29

Panel C: 62 industry portfolios deciles

RMRF ΔIL
1–5 0.41 0.47 0.55 0.57 0.64 −0.10 −0.02 0.01 0.04 0.07
6–10 0.69 0.72 0.75 0.80 0.93 0.11 0.15 0.22 0.28 0.48

Note: We compile monthly series from Thomson Reuters Datastream database, for all stocks
listed in the London Stock Exchange in the period from January 1989 to December 2018. Using
this data, we form the following portfolios: (a) 25 portfolios size-BE/ME, (b) 20 asset growth
portfolios, and (c) 62 industry portfolios. In order to determine excess returns, when appropriate
we use the three-month interest rate of the Treasury Bill for the United Kingdom. We use
annual series to estimate all correlations.

previous samples, while exactly the opposite is true for to be mean–variance efficient. Noteworthy, the J-test for
industry portfolios. In any case, these results must be overidentifying restrictions does not reject any model, as
interpreted with caution, since the J-test can easily reject was the case with industry portfolios.
models with low pricing errors if variances and Figures 1 and 2 show that fitted values satisfactorily
covariances in the spectral density matrix are low track the expected returns for the majority of the assets
enough. Conversely, models with high pricing errors may under consideration. Table 4 shows that in most cases
lead to false positives if they are correlated or highly the Fama–French models provide slightly lower mean
dispersed. absolute errors (MAEs) than the other models, although
The fourth sample (Table 4, Panel D), which com- the differences are more significant for size-BE/ME port-
prises all the previous data sets, provides satisfactory folios. Particularly, in this case the MAE for the scaled
results for all models, with OLS R2 statistics of 81.4% and CAPM amounts to 8.28%, while it falls to 4.21% in the
72% for the scaled CAPM and the classic CAPM, respec- FF5 model. As shown in Figure 1, the abnormal returns
tively. Once again, the FF5 model outperforms all the of size portfolios in the first quintile largely explain these
other models, with an OLS R2 statistic of 88.5%. As in the results.
previous samples, the GLS R2 statistics are significantly It should be noted that, in general, estimates for
lower, especially for the CAPM. In fact, GLS R2 statistics λ(RMRF) in both the scaled CAPM and the classic CAPM
are almost halved with respect to their OLS counterparts are statistically significant, while in Fama–French
for the scaled CAPM and the classic CAPM. On the other models, only λ(SMB) is statistically significant in the
hand, the GLS R2 statistics of the FF3 and FF5 models majority of the samples. On the other hand, Panel D in
decrease minimally, which seems to indicate that the fac- Table 4 shows that all risk prices are very close to the
tor-mimicking portfolio implicit in these models is close means of the factors (see Table 2) for models FF3 and
10

TABLE 4 Regression results for different sorts of portfolios

Row Model Intercept λ(RMRF) λ(SMB) λ(HML) λ(RMW) λ(CMA) λ(ΔIL) λ(RMRFΔIL MAE (%) R2 J-test
Panel A: 25 portfolios size-BE/ME
1 Scaled CAPM −.081 .226 −.126 −.018 8.28 .834 .542 120.782
(.118) (.104) (.269) (.047) (.000)
2 CAPM .063 .154 11.16 .691 .461 216.462
(.087) (.072) (.000)
3 FF3 −.090 .208 .430 .136 7.29 .876 .840 124.783
(.166) (.158) (.139) (.076) (.000)
4 FF5 −.070 .178 .398 .094 .092 −.086 4.21 .956 .775 125.077
(.169) (.168) (.126) (.063) (.134) (.099) (.000)
Panel B: 20 asset growth portfolios
5 Scaled CAPM .014 .112 −.122 −.013 2.45 .733 −.125 112.993
(.051) (.059) (.141) (.037) (.000)
6 CAPM .004 .128 2.87 .582 .082 130.313
(.050) (.060) (.000)
7 FF3 .067 .056 .342 −.003 1.91 .788 .718 148.218
(.047) (.059) (.155) (.070) (.000)
8 FF5 .058 .064 .311 −.001 .119 −.078 1.89 .778 .400 138.151
(.057) (.067) (.158) (.066) (.099) (.075) (.000)
Panel C: 62 industry portfolios
9 Scaled CAPM .045 .087 .044 .027 3.34 .625 .503 30.261
(.034) (.046) (.124) (.031) (.999)
10 CAPM .048 .083 3.34 .636 .623 37.616
(.044) (.055) (.990)
11 FF3 .041 .081 .217 .017 3.24 .667 .526 35.621
(.042) (.055) (.140) (.086) (.991)
12 FF5 .048 .076 .206 .014 .119 −.031 3.23 .666 .512 35.615
(.036) (.044) (.129) (.086) (.094) (.075) (.985)
Panel D: All portfolios
13 Scaled CAPM 5.85 .814 .411
ROJO-SUÁREZ ET AL.
ROJO-SUÁREZ ET AL. 11

GMM to estimate all models, assuming a spectral density matrix with zero leads and lags. We use the same spectral density matrix to run the J-test. The table displays two rows for each model,
portfolios and 62 industry portfolios. In order to determine excess returns, where appropriate we use the three-month interest rate of the Treasury Bill for the United Kingdom. Depending on
the model, we use either the market portfolio or the Fama–French factors as explanatory variables. In models 1, 5, 9 and 13, we scale the market portfolio using ΔIL as an instrument. We use
Note: We use all stocks listed in the London Stock Exchange, for the period from January 1989 to December 2018, to estimate the annual returns of 25 portfolios size-BE/ME, 20 asset growth
FF5. Although the disparities between these estimates

(1.000)

(1.000)

(1.000)
35.129

29.307

27.338
J-test are higher in the case of the scaled CAPM, in this
model, λ(RMRF) and E(RMRF) are not directly compa-
rable given the extra terms considered in expression
(13) to capture the time-varying nature of the expected
.720 .443

.846 .787

.885 .779
return of the wealth portfolio.
All the previous results test the validity of the model
R2

where the first row shows the estimates for the parameters and the second row shows the standard errors. Additionally, adjusted OLS and GLS R2 statistics are provided.
according to expression (13) or, equivalently, expression
(21). However, the economic content of the model can
MAE (%)

also be evaluated by studying the pricing errors that


6.36

5.32

4.88

arise when a set of actively managed portfolios, formed


according to the variation in market illiquidity in the
previous year, are priced using the CAPM, consistently
λ(RMRFΔIL

with expression (22). Consequently, Table 5 and


Figure 3 show the results provided by the CAPM on
−.004
(.034)

four different samples of managed portfolios, each


being determined as the product of the portfolios
included in the four original samples and ΔIL in the
λ(ΔIL)

previous year.
−.132
(.162)

As shown, OLS R2 statistics are close to 90% in all


samples, except for the 20 portfolios resulting from con-
trolling original asset growth portfolios for market illi-
λ(CMA)

quidity (sample 2 in Table 5). In this case, the OLS R2


−.162
(.068)

statistic amounts to 51.4%, a result very similar to that


provided by the CAPM in Table 4 for asset growth port-
folios. Figure 3 reveals that the highest pricing errors
λ(RMW)

correspond to portfolios number 19 and 20, that is,


(.082)
.148

those comprising firms with the highest asset growth.


As in previous samples, the GLS R2 statistics decrease
in all cases with respect to their OLS counterparts, and
λ(HML)

most notably for industry portfolios. In any case, it is


(.065)

(.065)
.102

.055

remarkable that, although the J-test for overidentifying


restrictions rejects the model in all cases, MAEs are sig-
nificantly lower than those shown in Table 4.
λ(SMB)

(.133)

(.126)

In short, all the results shown above are indicative


.423

.388

of a strong increase in the explanatory power of the


CAPM for the United Kingdom. Using a large sample
λ(RMRF)

of 107 portfolios, which combines different sorting


criteria, the classic constant beta model provides signifi-
(.083)

(.065)

(.075)

(.071)
.199

.156

.126

.117

cantly better results than those obtained by the previ-


ous literature, with OLS R2 statistics ranging from 72%
to 86.2%, depending on whether the test assets are
Intercept

scaled by market illiquidity or not. In this last case, the


−.074

−.018

−.023

−.014
(.079)

(.061)

(.063)

(.062)

CAPM provides an OLS R2 statistic of 81.4% when we


control betas for the variation in market illiquidity, and
(Continued)

the J-test for overidentifying restrictions does not reject


the model.
Model

CAPM

FF3

FF5

4 | C ON C L US I ON
TABLE 4

Row

Recent literature shows that increased trading activity


14

15

16

and liquidity levels in stock markets have significantly


12 ROJO-SUÁREZ ET AL.

F I G U R E 1 Realized excess returns versus fitted values for different sorts of portfolios. We use all stocks listed in the London Stock
Exchange, for the period from January 1989 to December 2018, to estimate the annual returns of 25 portfolios size-BE/ME, 20 asset growth
portfolios and 62 industry portfolios. In order to determine excess returns, where appropriate we use the three-month interest rate of the
Treasury Bill for the United Kingdom. Depending on the model, we use either the market portfolio or the Fama–French factors as
explanatory variables. Scaled CAPM scales the market portfolio using ΔIL as an instrument. We depict each of the 25 portfolios size-BE/ME
according to a code with two numbers, the first number being the size code (with 1 being the smallest and 5 the largest) and the second
number being the BE/ME ratio code (with 1 representing a low ratio and 5 a high ratio). Asset growth portfolios are represented by a
number that ranges from 1 to 20, where 1 corresponds to a portfolio comprising firms with the lowest asset growth, and 20 is a portfolio
comprising firms with the highest asset growth. We depict industry portfolios according to the letter “I” followed by the first two digits of the
SIC code

downsized the spreads provided by a large number of particularly the CAPM, will provide better results than
anomaly-based trading strategies and, consequently, have those achieved in previous research. Using data for the
enhanced market efficiency. In this framework, one London Stock Exchange, ranging from January 1989 to
would expect that classic assetpricing models, and more December 2018, our results show that the classic CAPM
ROJO-SUÁREZ ET AL. 13

F I G U R E 2 Realized excess returns versus fitted values for all portfolios under consideration. We use all stocks listed in the London
Stock Exchange, for the period from January 1989 to December 2018, to estimate the annual returns of 25 portfolios size-BE/ME, 20 asset
growth portfolios and 62 industry portfolios. In order to determine excess returns, where appropriate we use the three-month interest rate of
the Treasury Bill for the United Kingdom. Depending on the model, we use either the market portfolio or the Fama–French factors as
explanatory variables. Scaled CAPM scales the market portfolio using ΔIL as an instrument. We depict each of the 25 portfolios size-BE/ME
according to a code with two numbers, the first number being the size code (with 1 being the smallest and 5 the largest) and the second
number being the BE/ME ratio code (with 1 representing a low ratio and 5 a high ratio). Asset growth portfolios are represented by a
number that ranges from 1 to 20, where 1 corresponds to a portfolio comprising firms with the lowest asset growth, and 20 is a portfolio
comprising firms with the highest asset growth. We depict industry portfolios according to the letter “I” followed by the first two digits of the
SIC code

TABLE 5 Regression results for different sorts of managed portfolios

Row Test assets Intercept λ(RMRF) MAE (%) R2 J-test


1 25 portfolios size-BE/ME −.036 .074 2.30 .885 .608 169.907
(.033) (.090) (.000)
2 20 asset growth portfolios −.018 .078 1.12 .514 .426 48.361
(.018) (.072) (.000)
3 61 industry portfolios −.014 .067 1.08 .893 .267 351.821
(.016) (.082) (.000)
4 All portfolios −.018 .069 1.45 .862 .603 274.425
(.017) (.087) (.000)

Note: We use all stocks listed in the London Stock Exchange, for the period from January 1989 to December 2018, to estimate the annual
returns of 25 portfolios size-BE/ME, 20 asset growth portfolios and 62 industry portfolios. In order to determine excess returns, where appro-
priate we use the three-month interest rate of the Treasury Bill for the United Kingdom. Subsequently, we create three samples of managed
portfolios, each being determined as the product of the portfolios included in the original samples and ΔIL in the previous year. We use the
market portfolio as explanatory variable. We use GMM to estimate all models, assuming a spectral density matrix with zero leads and lags.
We use the same spectral density matrix to run the J-test. The table displays two rows for each sample, where the first row shows the esti-
mates for the parameters and the second row shows the standard errors. Additionally, adjusted OLS and GLS R2 statistics are provided.

performs satisfactorily for portfolios sorted according to a prevalence of these results for other markets and
variety of market anomalies. Furthermore, when we con- assets. Given the implications of the higher trading
trol the time-varying nature of parameters for shifts in activity underlined by recent literature on the topic,
the market illiquidity, as measured by the Amihud illi- one may expect that the higher the liquidity of the mar-
quidity measure, the CAPM provides results close to ket, the better the results provided by the CAPM. How-
those of the Fama–French models. ever, this point must be empirically evaluated, since
These results raise several questions about the the results provided by the model are highly influenced
apparent validity of the scaled CAPM. First, further by the characteristics of the market under analysis
research should be addressed in order to determine the (Mohanty, 2019).
14 ROJO-SUÁREZ ET AL.

F I G U R E 3 Realized excess returns versus fitted values for different sorts of managed portfolios. We use all stocks listed in the London
Stock Exchange, for the period from January 1989 to December 2018, to estimate the annual returns of 25 portfolios size-BE/ME, 20 asset
growth portfolios and 62 industry portfolios. In order to determine excess returns, where appropriate we use the three-month interest rate of
the Treasury Bill for the United Kingdom. Subsequently, we create three samples of managed portfolios, each being determined as the
product of the portfolios included in the original samples and ΔIL in the previous year. We use the market portfolio as explanatory variable.
We depict each of the 25 managed portfolios size-BE/ME according to a code with two numbers, the first number being the size code (with
1 being the smallest and 5 the largest) and the second number being the BE/ME ratio code (with 1 representing a low ratio and 5 a high
ratio). Asset growth managed portfolios are represented by a number that ranges from 1 to 20, where 1 corresponds to a portfolio comprising
firms with the lowest asset growth, and 20 is a portfolio comprising firms with the highest asset growth. We depict managed industry
portfolios according to the letter “I” followed by the first two digits of the SIC code

Second, efforts should be made to reconcile the eventual empirical success of the CAPM for the prefer-
mechanics of the CAPM with the preferences of inves- ences described by non-separable utility functions is
tors, as defined by modern utility functions. Although the imperative.
CAPM constitutes a particular case of consumption-based Third, recent research emphasizes the importance of
assetpricing models, the assumptions that allow us to market frictions, such as those tied to labour markets
connect them are, in general, unrealistic. Preferences (Kuehn, Simutin, & Wang, 2017). Other highlights the
such as those described by quadratic utility of log utility relevance of specific market variables, such as the volatil-
do not seem to correctly capture the rationality of inves- ity risk (Campbell et al., 2018). In this framework, future
tors. Therefore, research on the implications of the research should deepen the understanding of the
ROJO-SUÁREZ ET AL. 15

relationship between these variables and the wealth port- Basu, S. (1983). The relationship between earnings' yield, market
folio, in order to determine the degree to which the value and return for NYSE common stocks: Further evidence.
wealth portfolio has subsumed these variables or these Journal of Financial Economics, 12, 129–156.
Batrinca, B., Hesse, C. W., & Treleaven, P. C. (2018). Examining
effects have diminished.
drivers of trading volume in European markets. International
Finally, further research on the factors that drive the Journal of Finance & Economics, 23, 134–154.
relationship between high trading activity and the CAPM Black, F. S., Jensen, M. C., & Scholes, M. S. (1972). The capital asset
is mandatory. For this purpose, models linking asset pricing model: Some empirical findings. In M. C. Jensen (Ed.),
prices with low trading costs and market microstructure Studies in the theory of capital markets (pp. 79–124). New York,
(Acharya & Pedersen, 2003; Amihud, Mendelson, & NY: Praeger.
Pedersen, 2006) can contribute significantly to a better Bornholt, G. (2013). The failure of the capital asset pricing model
(CAPM): An update and discussion. Abacus, 49, 36–43.
understanding of that relationship. In parallel with this,
Brunnermeier, M., & Pedersen, L. (2007). Market liquidity and
research on the interplay between funding liquidity and
funding liquidity. Review of Financial Studies, 22, 2201–2238.
trading cost (Brunnermeier & Pedersen, 2007; Gârleanu & Campbell, J. Y., Giglio, S., Polk, C., & Turley, R. (2018). An inter-
Pedersen, 2011) can greatly enrich this analysis. temporal CAPM with stochastic volatility. Journal of Financial
Economics, 128, 207–233.
DATA AVAILABILITY STATEMENT Campbell, J. Y., & Shiller, R. J. (1988). The dividend-price ratio and
The data that support the findings of this study are expectations of future dividends and discount factors. Review of
openly available in Mendeley Data at http://dx.doi.org/ Financial Studies, 1, 195–228.
10.17632/56n2yxgpcf.2 Carhart, M. (1997). On persistence in mutual fund performance.
Journal of Finance, 52, 57–82.
ORCID Chakravarty, S., Panchapagesan, V., & Wood, R. A. (2005). Did dec-
imalization hurt institutional investors? Journal of Financial
Javier Rojo-Suárez https://orcid.org/0000-0002-7371-
Markets, 8, 400–420.
3154 Chen, L., Novy-Marx, R., & Zhang, L. (2011). An alternative three-
Ana Belén Alonso-Conde https://orcid.org/0000-0001- factor model. Working paper, available at SSRN: https://doi.
8333-2788 org/10.2139/ssrn.1418117
Ricardo Ferrero-Pozo https://orcid.org/0000-0003-0587- Chordia, T., Roll, R., & Subrahmanyam, A. (2011). Recent trends in
691X trading activity and market quality. Journal of Financial Eco-
nomics, 101, 243–263.
E N D N O T ES Chordia, T., Subrahmanyam, A., & Tong, Q. (2014). Have capital mar-
1 ket anomalies attenuated in the recent era of high liquidity and
This literature is too large to summarize here. Seminal contribu-
trading activity? Journal of Accounting and Economics, 58, 41–58.
tions are Shiller (1981), Campbell and Shiller (1988) and Fama
Cochrane, J. (2011). Presidential address: Discount rates. Journal of
and French (1988).
Finance, 66, 1047–1108.
2
Not necessarily in the payoff space. Cochrane, J. H. (2005). Asset pricing (revised ed.). Princeton, NJ:
3 Princeton University Press.
When the payoff space only includes excess returns, the subjective
discount factor is irrelevant. Cooper, M. J., Gulen, H., & Schill, M. J. (2008). Asset growth and
4
In addition to log utility, there are many other alternative the cross-section of stock returns. Journal of Finance, 63,
assumptions that lead to the CAPM. Chapter 9 in Cochrane (2005) 1609–1651.
provides a complete review on the topic. Cuthbertson, K., Hayes, S., & Nitzsche, D. (1997). The behaviour of
5
UKstock prices and returns: Is the market efficient? Economic
All data is publicly available at Rojo-Suárez, Alonso-Conde, and
Journal, 107, 986–1008.
Ferrero-Pozo (2020).
Eleswarapu, V., & Reinganum, M. R. (1993). The seasonal behavior
of the liquidity premium in asset pricing. Journal of Financial
R EF E RE N C E S Economics, 34, 373–386.
Fama, E., & MacBeth, J. D. (1973). Risk, return, and equilibrium:
Acharya, V., & Pedersen, L. (2003). Asset pricing with liquidity risk.
Empirical tests. Journal of Political Economy, 81, 607–636.
Journal of Financial Economics, 77, 375–410.
Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (1988). Dividend yields and expected
Amihud, Y. (2002). Illiquidity and stock returns: Cross-section and
stock returns. Journal of Financial Economics, 22, 3–25.
time-series effects. Journal of Financial Markets, 5, 31–56.
Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (1993). Common risk factors in the
Amihud, Y., Mendelson, H., & Pedersen, L. (2006). Liquidity and
returns on stocks and bonds. Journal of Financial Economics,
asset prices. Foundations and Trends in Finance, 1, 269–364.
33, 3–56.
Ang, A., Hodrick, R., Xing, Y., & Zhang, X. (2006). The cross-
section of volatility and expected returns. Journal of Finance, Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (2008). Dissecting anomalies. Journal
61, 259–299. of Finance, 63, 1653–1678.
Banz, R. W. (1981). The relationship between return and market value Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (2015). A five-factor asset pricing
of common stocks. Journal of Financial Economics, 9, 3–18. model. Journal of Financial Economics, 116, 1–22.
16 ROJO-SUÁREZ ET AL.

French, K. (2008). Presidential address: The cost of active investing. McLean, R. D., & Pontiff, J. (2016). Does academic research destroy
Journal of Finance, 63, 1537–1573. stock return predictability? Journal of Finance, 71, 5–32.
Gârleanu, N., & Pedersen, L. (2011). Margin-based asset pricing and Merton, R. (1973). An intertemporal capital asset pricing model.
deviations from the law of one price. Review of Financial Stud- Econometrica, 41, 867–887.
ies, 24, 1980–2022. Miller, M. H., & Scholes, M. S. (1972). Rate of return in relation to
Green, J., Hand, J. R. M., & Soliman, M. T. (2011). Going, going, risk: A reexamination of some recent findings. In M. C. Jensen
gone? The apparent demise of the accruals anomaly. Manage- (Ed.), Studies in the theory of capital markets (pp. 47–78).
ment Science, 57, 797–816. New York, NY: Praeger.
Griffin, J. M., Kelly, P., & Nardari, F. (2010). Do market efficiency Mohanty, S. S. (2019). Does one model fit all in global equity mar-
measures yield correct inferences? A comparison of developed kets? Some insight into market factor based strategies in
and emerging markets. Review of Financial Studies, 23, enhancing alpha. International Journal of Finance & Econom-
3225–3277. ics, 24, 1170–1192.
Hansen, L., & Singleton, K. (1982). Generalized instrumental vari- Novy-Marx, R. (2013). The other side of value: The gross profitabil-
ables estimation of nonlinear rational expectations models. Eco- ity premium. Journal of Financial Economics, 108, 1–28.
nometrica, 50, 1269–1286. Rojo-Suárez, J., Alonso-Conde, A. B., & Ferrero-Pozo, R. (2020).
Harrison, J. M., & Kreps, D. M. (1979). Martingales and arbitrage in Data for: Liquidity, time-varying betas and anomalies. Is the high
multiperiod securities markets. Journal of Economic Theory, 20, trading activity enhancing the validity of the CAPM in the UK
381–408. equity market? Mendeley Data, v1. Retrieved from https://doi.
Hendershott, T., Jones, C. M., & Menkveld, A. (2011). Does algo- org/10.17632/56n2yxgpcf.2
rithmic trading improve liquidity? Journal of Finance, 66, 1–33. Roll, R. (1977). A critique of the asset pricing theory's tests part I:
Hyde, S., & Sherif, M. (2010). Tests of the conditional asset pricing On past and potential testability of the theory. Journal of Finan-
model: Further evidence from the cross-section of stock cial Economics, 4, 129–176.
returns. International Journal of Finance & Economics, 15, Rosenberg, B., Reid, K., & Lanstein, R. (1985). Persuasive evidence of
198–211. market inefficiency. The Journal of Portfolio Management, 11, 9–16.
Jagannathan, R., & Wang, Y. (2007). Lazy investors, discretionary Ross, S. (1976). The arbitrage theory of capital asset pricing. Journal
consumption, and the cross- section of stock returns. Journal of of Economic Theory, 13, 341–360.
Finance, 62, 1623–1661. Ross, S. A. (1978). A simple approach to the valuation of risky
Jagannathan, R., & Wang, Z. (1996). The conditional capm and the streams. Journal of Business, 51, 453–475.
cross-section of expected returns. Journal of Finance, 51, 3–53. Rubinstein, M. (2010). The valuation of uncertain income streams and
Jegadeesh, N., & Titman, S. (1993). Returns to buying winners and the pricing of options. In Handbook of quantitative finance and risk
selling losers: Implications for stock market efficiency. Journal management (pp. 605–616). New York, NY: Springer.
of Finance, 48, 65–91. Sharpe, W. F. (1964). Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilib-
Kuehn, L. A., Simutin, M., & Wang, J. (2017). A labor capital asset rium under conditions of risk. Journal of Finance, 19, 425–442.
pricing model. Journal of Finance, 72, 2131–2178. Shiller, R. J. (1981). Do stock prices move too much to be justified
Lakonishok, J., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1994). Contrarian invest- by subsequent changes in dividends? American Economic
ment, extrapolation, and risk. Journal of Finance, 49, Review, 71, 421–436.
1541–1578. Sloan, R. G. (1996). Do stock prices fully reflect information in
Lettau, M., & Ludvigson, S. (2001). Resurrecting the (C)CAPM: A accruals and cash flows about future earnings? The Accounting
cross-sectional test when risk premia are time-varying. Journal Review, 71, 289–315.
of Political Economy, 109, 1238–1287. Van Binsbergen, J., & Opp, C. C. (2019). Real anomalies. Journal of
Lewellen, J., Nagel, S., & Shanken, J. (2010). A skeptical appraisal Finance, 74, 1659–1706.
of asset pricing tests. Journal of Financial Economics, 96, Yogo, M. (2006). A consumption-based explanation of expected
175–194. stock returns. Journal of Finance, 61, 539–580.
Lintner, J. (1965). Security prices, risk, and maximal gains from
diversification. Journal of Finance, 20, 587–615.
Lustig, H., & Van Nieuwerburgh, S. (2005). Housing collateral, con-
sumption insurance, and risk premia: An empirical perspective. How to cite this article: Rojo-Suárez J, Alonso-
Journal of Finance, 60, 1167–1219. Conde AB, Ferrero-Pozo R. Liquidity, time-varying
Maio, P., & Santa-Clara, P. (2012). Multifactor models and their betas and anomalies: Is the high trading activity
consistency with the ICAPM. Journal of Financial Economics,
enhancing the validity of the CAPM in the UK
106, 586–613.
equity market? Int J Fin Econ. 2020;1–16. https://
Mashruwala, C., Rajgopal, S., & Shevlin, T. (2006). Why is the accrual
anomaly not arbitraged away? The role of idiosyncratic risk and doi.org/10.1002/ijfe.2136
transaction costs. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 42, 3–33.

You might also like