Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 23

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/24077015

Anti-Poverty Programs in Indonesia

Article  in  Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies · February 2002


DOI: 10.1080/00074910215535 · Source: RePEc

CITATIONS READS

45 1,064

2 authors, including:

Daly Anne
University of Canberra
96 PUBLICATIONS   1,323 CITATIONS   

SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

Graduate outcomes - case studies to assess graduate skills View project

competition in banking industry View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Daly Anne on 25 August 2017.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, Vol. 38, No. 3, 2002: 309–29

ANTI-POVERTY PROGRAMS IN INDONESIA


Anne Daly
University of Canberra

George Fane*
Australian National University

Between 1994/95 and 1997/98, Indonesia’s spending on anti-poverty programs grew


from 0.1% to 0.3% of GDP. The introduction of the ‘social safety net’ raised anti-
poverty spending to 1.4% of GDP in 1998/99 and changed its main focus from job
creation schemes, financed mainly by loans and grants to small firms and commu-
nity groups, to in-kind subsidies for rice, public health care, scholarships for chil-
dren in poor families and grants to schools in poor areas. The most accurately targeted
program was health care, which covered twice as many people in the two poorest
deciles as in the remaining eight. For most other programs, this targeting ratio was
only about 1.5. We argue that the education and health care programs were the most
successful, and doubt that the rice subsidy, job creation and loans schemes were
worthwhile.

INTRODUCTION
This paper has three objectives: to de- (1) cash transfer schemes in which
scribe Indonesia’s main anti-poverty the net receipts are phased out as in-
programs and summarise government come rises;
spending on them, to survey research on (2) benefits in kind of rationed and
the extent to which they have reached subsidised amounts of ‘essential’
their target groups and to draw policy goods to people below some specified
conclusions. The third objective is much poverty line (‘essential’ goods are
the most difficult, and the policy con- those that make up a relatively large
clusions we draw in the final section are proportion of the total consumption
correspondingly tentative. of the poor, such as kerosene, rice,
We define ‘anti-poverty programs’ to health care and primary education);
be those whose benefits are specifically (3) job creation schemes for un-
targeted at the poor. We draw the line skilled workers;
between ‘targeted at the poor’ and ‘not (4) universally available price sub-
targeted at the poor’ in such a way that sidies, with no rationing, for essential
Indonesia’s anti-poverty programs are goods.
those that were part of the ‘social safety In industrial countries, cash transfers
net’ (SSN) introduced in 1998, the simi- (type 1) are often used to implement the
lar programs that preceded the SSN on most important social welfare pro-
a much smaller scale, and those that re- grams—such as unemployment and
placed it in 2001. sickness benefits, age and disability pen-
Programs that benefit the poor can sions and child support. However, cash
take any of the following forms: transfers are usually of little or no im-

ISSN 0007-4918 print/ISSN 1472-7234 online/02/030309-21 © 2002 Indonesia Project ANU


310 Anne Daly and George Fane

portance in most developing countries, ing. The individual schemes are identi-
which lack both the bureaucratic appa- fied in the body of table 1 and in the
ratus to administer such blanket cover- notes to it. The most important indi-
age schemes and the revenues to pay for vidual schemes are briefly described in
them. Instead, developing countries of- the next section. The section that follows
ten use government agencies, state- it summarises the development of anti-
owned firms, or government controlled poverty programs and Indonesia’s suc-
clinics and schools to provide essential cesses and failures in reducing poverty.
goods. If benefits in kind are restricted We then summarise research on the tar-
to the poor (type 2), then the programs geting of the main schemes and finally
come within our definition of anti- draw policy conclusions.
poverty programs; however, if the quan-
tities that each household is allowed to INDONESIA’S MAIN
buy are not phased out as income rises ANTI-POVERTY SCHEMES
(type 4), the schemes are outside our Cash Transfers
definition of anti-poverty programs. The only time Indonesia has used cash
Examples of this latter type include the transfers was in October–December 2000
Indonesian government’s fuel price sub- when, in partial fulfilment of conditions
sidies and its provision of universal free, stipulated in its January 2000 letter of
or highly subsidised, health care and intent to the IMF, the government re-
basic education. duced domestic fuel price subsidies and
Job creation schemes (type 3) differ partially compensated the poor by allo-
from pure price subsidies (type 4) by cating Rp 800 billion from the resulting
raising the price of something that the budgetary savings to finance three anti-
poor typically sell (unskilled labour), poverty programs, one of which aimed
rather than reducing the price of things to provide the poorest 6.7 million fami-
that they typically buy. Besides raising lies with Rp 30,000 per month (SMERU
the incomes of the poor, these schemes 2001). Data previously gathered by the
usually improve public infrastructure in National Fam ily Planning Agency
poor areas. One can debate whether job (BKKBN) were used to try to define and
creation schemes are targeted to the identify eligible households, but the pro-
poor, or are universally available to all gram proved very difficult to adminis-
sellers of unskilled labour, many of ter and was discontinued after three
whom are members of families above months.
the poverty line. We classify Indonesia’s
job creation schemes as anti-poverty Rationed and Targeted
programs because attempts were made Benefits in Kind
to locate them in poor areas and to em- Rice. In terms of expenditure, the most
ploy mainly poor people. Job creation important of Indonesia’s targeted
schemes and rationed and targeted ben- schemes providing rationed benefits in
efits in kind therefore provide the main kind is the subsidised rice program
examples of anti-poverty programs in OPK (Operasi Pasar Khusus, Special
Indonesia. Market Operations), which was intro-
Table 1 gives a summary of govern- duced partly in response to the eco-
ment spending by type of anti-poverty nomic crisis and partly in response to
program, as defined above, and table 2 the drought that affected many parts of
shows the size of the programs relative eastern Indonesia in 1997–98. It was
to total government anti-poverty spend- therefore targeted at poor villages and
Anti-poverty Programs in Indonesia 311

TABLE 1 Expenditure on Anti-poverty Programs as a Percentage of Total Central Government


Expenditure, 1994/95–2000 a

94/95 95/96 96/97 97/98 98/99 99/00 2000b

Cash transfers 0.11


Benefits in kind 0.49 0.69 5.73 5.14 2.96
Subsidised rice (OPK) 3.70 3.14 1.22
Health care & nutrition 0.16 0.34 0.97 1.16 0.99
Education 0.33 0.36 1.06 0.84 0.75
Job creation (including
infrastructure & loans) 0.61 1.37 1.21 1.27 3.94 1.87 2.58
IDT 0.59 0.61 0.53 0.13
KDP 0.22 0.33 0.29
UPP 0.04 0.28
PDM–DKE 1.16 0.40 0.24
Village & urban infrastructure 0.33 0.26 0.61 0.61 0.51 0.43
Labour intensive (PK) 1.01 0.22
Loan schemes 0.02 0.43 0.43 0.53 0.46 0.48 0.92
Other 0.49 0.12 0.20
Total 0.61 1.37 1.70 1.96 9.67 7.01 5.65
Memo items
Total anti-poverty
programs (Rp trillion) 0.43 1.07 1.54 1.98 14.24 13.95 10.35
Total anti-poverty
programs (% of GDP) 0.11 0.23 0.28 0.29 1.39 1.23 1.05

a
A brief indication of the programs included under each heading is given below. Full details
(including explanations of the acronyms used) can be obtained from a spreadsheet available
at: http://economics.anu.edu.au/staff/fane/fane.html (go to: ‘poverty’, and double click
on: ‘Daly & Fane, tables 1 and 2’).
• Cash transfers are those under the fuel subsidy replacement program.
• IDT, KDP and UPP: defined in text.
• PDM–DKE: Regional Empowerment Program to Alleviate the Crisis (a village credit
scheme).
• Village and urban infrastructure: P3DT; P2MPD; and the village infrastructure program
under the fuel subsidy replacement program.
• Labour intensive: three PK (padat karya) programs; two programs to allevia te
unemployment; and the program to alleviate the drought and manpower situation.
• Loan schemes: four programs financed through Bank Rakyat Indonesia; two financed by
Bank Indonesia; one financed by BKSN; the TPSP–KUD program financed by the Ministry
of Cooperatives; and the micro-finance facility under the fuel subsidy replacement program.
• Other: PEMD; and three programs to improve food production under the SSN.
b
Up to and including 1999/2000, Indonesia’s fiscal year ran from 1 April to 31 March. The
fiscal year 2000 was a transitional one that ran from 1 April to 31 December. As of 2001, the
Indonesian fiscal year coincides with the calendar year.
Sources: National budget data: see table 4; other data: Bappenas (National Planning Agency).
312 Anne Daly and George Fane

to those in drought affected areas. The three grades of primary school, for 17%
rice was acquired centrally by the na- of those in lower secondary school and
tional logistics agency (Bulog) and trans- for 10% of those in upper secondary
ported to distribution points throughout school. The actual coverage achieved in
the country. The government originally 1998/99 was much lower than these tar-
intended that each of the 8 million gets.2 The monthly value of the schol-
households in the poorest group, as in- arships was Rp 10,000 for primary
dicated by BKKBN data, should receive students, Rp 20,000 for lower second-
10 kilograms of medium quality rice per ary students and Rp 25,000 for upper
month at Rp 1,000/kg, when the mar- secondary students.
ket price was Rp 2,500–3,000/kg (Su- Data on poverty from the Central Sta-
marto, Suryahadi and Widyanti 2001). tistics Agency (BPS, Badan Pusat Statis-
The benefit per household was therefore tik) were used to identify relatively poor
about Rp 15,000–20,000 per month. This districts and municipalities. The central
is about 5% of the total expenditure of a government decided how many schol-
household of four people at the official arships and school grants each district
poverty line.1 The target allocation per and municipality would receive, and the
household was later doubled to 20 kg allocation of scholarships to particular
per month and the entitlement was ex- children was made at the level of indi-
tended to include the 9.4 million house- vidual schools, by committees that con-
holds in the second poorest group, as sisted of the school principal and
indicated by the BKKBN data. In April representatives of the local community,
2000 the allocation was changed again, parents and students. The actual alloca-
to between 10 and 20 kg per household tion of money was done from the cen-
per month. In practice, as described tral government to the student’s family
later, coverage and allocation per house- through the post office network.
hold were well below these targets. Block grants that could be spent on
Scholarships and School Grants. The books, materials, minor renovations, as-
recession of the late 1980s had been as- sisting poor children or waiving formal
sociated with a decline in school enrol- and informal school fees were allocated
ments and there was official concern in to schools in poor areas. Subdistrict gov-
1998 that this should not be repeated. ernments selected the primary schools
Therefore, before the beginning of the and district governments selected the
school year in late August 1998, the lower and upper secondary schools. The
government, the World Bank and the aim of the program was to provide
ADB (Asian Development Bank), as- grants to 60% of schools at each level.
sisted by other external donors includ- At the primary school level the annual
ing AusAID (the Australian Agency for block grants per school were Rp 2 mil-
International Development), hastily as- lion; for lower and upper secondary
sembled the Scholarships and Grants schools they were Rp 4 million and
Program (SGP), which was designed to Rp 10 million, respectively.
prevent a fall in school enrolments. The Health Care. Like the education pro-
external donors made their contribu- gram, the health care program that was
tions conditional on the government introduced as part of the social safety
not reducing its own real spending on net in 1998 included a mix of direct fund-
education. ing to individual households and block
The program aimed to provide schol- grants to service providers, such as hos-
arships for 6% of pupils in the senior pitals, clinics and family planning ser-
Anti-poverty Programs in Indonesia 313

vices (World Bank 2000). Health care Alatas argues that the guidelines on
cards that entitled holders to free health the use of funds were so vague that the
care from designated providers were program amounted to a mixture of cash
allocated to districts on the basis of the grants and loans for any income gener-
BKKBN estimates of the number of very ating purpose—and the loans were effec-
poor or poor households in the district. tively grants in the many cases in which
Local officials made the final allocations the funds were not repaid. The IDT pro-
to households. A separate nutrition pro- gram is classified here as a job creation
gram, which operated from 1998 until scheme, since it was supposed to help
2000, provided supplementary food and poor people ‘by creating and expanding
vitamins for infants and pregnant productive job opportunities through
women. promotion of various development ac-
tivities’ (Presidential Instruction No. 5/
Schemes to Create Jobs for 1993, cited and translated in Alatas 2000).
Unskilled Workers By comparing villages that received
Indonesia’s first anti-poverty program IDT funds with similar ones that did
was the IDT program (Inpres Desa not, Alatas concluded that the main
Tertinggal, Presidential Instruction for effects of the scheme were to raise
Underdeveloped Villages), which com- household expenditure, raise the em-
menced in the financial year 1994/95 ployment of women in rural areas, raise
and ended at the close of 1997/98. It the employment of children (aged 10 to
provided selected poor villages with 18 years) and raise the proportion of
Rp 20 million (then about $9,000) each spouses of household heads who were
per year. The selected villages were re- self-employed.
sponsible for distributing this amount A scheme with some similarities to
among groups of poor people, who the IDT scheme, in that it also supports
were invited to submit proposals for development spending at the village
using the funds. The allocations to vil- level, is the Kecamatan Development
lages were grants that did not have to Program (KDP), introduced in 1998/99
be repaid, but the allocations from vil- and financed by a World Bank loan. It
lages to groups whose proposals were has two components: the first provides
successful were supposed to be revolv- grants for the development of infrastruc-
ing loans. However, according to BPS ture; the second provides loans for busi-
data cited by Alatas (2000), only 60% ness activities. Each village can submit
of the recipients repaid any part of the up to two proposals, and the choice of
funds received. successful proposals is made at the sub-
About one-third of all villages were district level. Where a village puts up
selected according to criteria that in- two proposals, one must be from the
cluded the quality of village infrastruc- village women. Each subdistrict com-
ture, housing and the environment, mittee can choose its preferred mix of
average ownership of livestock and con- infrastructure and business activities.
sumer durables, the availability of elec- Village implementation of the infra-
tricity, school enrolment rates and structure projects is supported by tech-
indicators of health and infant mortality. nical assistance from the subdistrict
Alatas (2000) found that the selection of level, and there is an explicit require-
villages accorded almost perfectly with ment for the continued maintenance of
the criteria specified in the design of the the investment. The loans for business
program.3 activities are made to groups at market
314 Anne Daly and George Fane

rates and are supposed to be repaid creation schemes to the districts, which
within 18 months (National Manage- distributed them to the subdistricts. Par-
ment Consultants 2000). The KDP has ticular projects were then selected from
an urban equivalent, the urban poverty proposals made at the village level. The
program (UPP), which provides credit criteria that individuals had to satisfy to
for small and medium enterprises and qualify for inclusion in these programs
funds for community-based infrastruc- were less precise than those for the other
ture development in poor urban areas. crisis programs. Individuals wishing to
Additional job creation and infra- work on a job creation scheme were ex-
structure development schemes were pected to have some independent evi-
developed in response to the crisis. In dence that they were poor, unemployed
some cases, known as padat karya and in need of assistance under the pro-
(labour-intensive) programs, low- gram—for example, a letter from their
skilled workers were employed to build village head.
or repair public infrastructure. Of the
employees of these programs, 81% POVERTY REDUCTION
were male, and 64% of them were em- AND THE DEVELOPMENT
ployed to repair roads (Sumarto, Surya- OF ANTI-POVERTY PROGRAMS
hadi and Widyanti 2001: notes 24 and Three Phases of
25). In other cases, the government pro- Program Development
vided grants to local communities to fi- There have been three phases in the de-
nance loans to community groups, or velopment of Indonesia’s anti-poverty
to small and medium enterprises, to programs: the pre-crisis period, the cri-
fund labour-intensive projects. We re- sis, and the subsequent period of slow
fer to all these schemes, and not just the recovery. In the pre-crisis period, Indo-
padat karya programs, as ‘job creation nesia spent very little on anti-poverty
schemes’. programs, although their importance
In 1998/99 there was a rapid prolif- gradually increased between their intro-
eration of job creation schemes, as duction in 1994/95 and 1997/98, when
government ministries seized the oppor- total spending on them still accounted
tunity to tap the budget to finance for only 0.3% of GDP. The importance
schemes that they could control. Sepa- of these programs increased abruptly in
rate schemes were created to provide 1998, when the SSN was introduced in
employment in villages, in forestry, for response to fears that the economic cri-
women, for urban services, for roads sis might cause poverty to climb back to
and for irrigation. This chaotic situation the levels of the 1980s, or even the 1970s.4
was tidied up in 1999/2000, when the These fears turned out to have been ex-
number of separate schemes was re- aggerated, and total spending on anti-
duced to two—the Public Works Sector poverty programs has been reduced
Padat Karya Program and the Special subsequently, although it still far ex-
Initiative for Unemployed Women (Su- ceeds the pre-crisis level.
marto, Suryahadi and Widyanti 2001: Table 2 shows that the relative im-
note 14). portance of the different types of anti-
Using information on local condi- poverty programs varied in the three
tions—for example, the existence of a phases. Job creation schemes accounted
drought—and aggregate data on poverty for more than three-quarters of all
rates and infrastructure needs, the cen- spending on anti-poverty programs in
tral government allocated funds for job the period before the crisis. In response
Anti-poverty Programs in Indonesia 315

TABLE 2 Shares of Individual Programs in Total Anti-poverty Spending a


(%)

1994/95 1998/99 2000 b 1994/95


–1997/98 –1999/2000 –2000

Cash transfers 0.0 0.0 1.9 0.5


Benefits in kind 22.8 66.2 52.4 57.9
Subsidised rice (OPK) 0.0 41.5 21.6 32.0
Health care & nutrition 9.7 13.3 17.6 13.9
Education 13.2 11.4 13.2 12.1
Job creation (including
infrastructure & loans) 77.2 33.8 45.6 41.6
IDT 29.9 0.0 0.0 3.4
KDP 0.0 3.4 5.1 3.4
UPP 0.0 0.3 4.9 1.4
PDM–DKE 0.0 8.8 4.2 6.7
Village & urban infrastructure 22.0 6.7 7.7 8.7
Labour intensive (PK) 0.0 5.3 4.0 4.4
Loan schemes 25.3 5.8 16.3 10.5
Other 0.0 3.4 3.5 3.0
Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0

a
See table 1, note a.
b
See table 1, note b.

Source: Bappenas.

to the crisis, each broad type of anti- spending on anti-poverty programs is


poverty program received an increased still much lower than before the crisis.
share of total budget allocations, but the Cash transfers have always been of neg-
importance of the jobs, infrastructure ligible importance and were abolished
and loans schemes declined relative to entirely in 2001.
that of benefits in kind and, in particu- The SSN involved targeted, rationed
lar, relative to the newly introduced provision of subsidised amounts of
scheme to sell rice at subsidised prices food, health care and education, and job
to poor families. This scheme became creation schemes. It was designed and
the largest single program, accounting financed by the government in conjunc-
on its own for over 40% of total spend- tion with the main external donors—
ing on anti-poverty programs in 1997/ namely, the aid agencies of foreign
98 and 1998/99. In the post-crisis recov- governments, such as USAID (United
ery period, the subsidised rice scheme States Agency for International Devel-
has declined in importance relative to opment) and AusAID, and the multi-
the health care, education and infra- lateral lending agencies, such as the
structure schemes, and the relative im- World Bank and the ADB.
portance of job creation schemes has The SSN programs have a number of
recovered, though their share in total common elements that reflect the speed
316 Anne Daly and George Fane

with which they had to be developed World Bank jargon for involving local
and the objectives of the external donors. community organisations in imple-
The lack of alternative comprehensive in- menting programs, rather than relying
formation—household expenditure data entirely on local government bureau-
are available only for sample surveys of cracies. The SSN Adjustment Loan ne-
the population—forced the administra- gotiated between the government of
tors of the SSN programs to use BKKBN Indonesia and the World Bank illus-
criteria and data to decide which house- trates the design features demanded by
holds were poor. According to these cri- the donors.5 A condition of the loan was
teria, a household was in the poorest that each of the programs supported by
group (keluarga pra-sejahtera, sometimes it should have
translated as ‘pre-prosperous family’) if (i) internal monitoring and operational
it failed to meet all five of the following controls including monthly reports to
conditions: (1) all household members the oversight group and control team;
are able to practise their religious prin- (ii) independent verification of pro-
ciples; (2) all household members are gram performance and monitoring re-
ports; (iii) campaigns to reach the grass
able to eat at least twice a day; (3) all
roots level with information about the
household members have different sets program design, budget and channel
of clothing for home and work or school; for complaints; (iv) a complaint reso-
(4) the largest floor area of the house is lution mechanism that would be super-
not earth; and (5) the household has ac- vised by the control team; and (v) civil
cess to modern medical assistance for society involvement at every level of
sick children and to family planning ser- monitoring (Filmer et al. 1999: 2).
vices (Sumarto, Suryahadi and Widyanti To evaluate the SSN, the external do-
2001). These criteria were subsequently nors set up two monitoring units, the
expanded so that the poorest group also Central Independent Monitoring Unit
included families that consumed protein (CIMU) and the Social Monitoring and
only once a week, families with children Early Response Unit (SMERU). We
who dropped out of school for economic summarise the main findings of these
reasons, and families headed by unem- units in the next section.
ployed adults. Community groups and The SSN was wound up at the end
village leaders were allowed some scope of 2000, partly because Indonesia had
in adjusting coverage, particularly in begun to recover from the worst effects
situations where the BKKBN data were of the crisis, and partly because the gov-
thought to be deficient. For example, ernment and the main external donors
the BKKBN database covered only were dissatisfied with the design of
households with married couples and some of the programs. Although the
excluded households with a single or share of total government spending al-
widowed head (Kusumastuti et al. located to all anti-poverty programs
1998). Coverage was also considered in- certainly fell between 1998/ 99 and
adequate in many urban areas because 2000, the magnitude of the fall is prob-
of high levels of migration during this ably exaggerated by table 1. Part of the
period and the incomplete registration reduction recorded in table 1 was the
of households in locations to which result of Indonesia’s new decentralisa -
they had just moved. tion policies: with the passage of Laws
In designing the SSN, the donors 22 and 25 of 1999, many of the expendi-
tried to promote ‘good governance’ and tures that were formerly administered
‘empowerment’. The latter term is by the central government, including
Anti-poverty Programs in Indonesia 317

most of the SSN programs, became the and Damayanti 2000). Life expectancy
responsibility of district and municipal at birth rose from 55 years in 1980 to 65
governments. 6 There seems to be no years in 1997, and the estimated propor-
way of knowing how much is now be- tion of children dying before reaching
ing spent on anti-poverty programs at their fifth birthday fell from 125 per
the local government level, because 1,000 for those born in 1980 to 52 per
even the central government ministries 1,000 for those born in 1998 (World Bank
do not have comprehensive data on 2001: 276).
this. This is an important area for fu- The surveys conducted since the cri-
ture research. sis all confirm that poverty rose sharply.
The special mini survey of household ex-
Indonesia’s Performance penditure carried out by BPS in Decem-
in Reducing Poverty ber 1998 suggested that the headcount
Studies of poverty trends in Indonesia poverty rate was then 24%. However,
are unanimous in finding large falls in much of the apparent rise was due to an
poverty incidence during the New Or- increase in the poverty line. Relative to
der period, but disagree about their ex- the former poverty line, the headcount
tent and the rate at which poverty rate rose from 11% in 1996 to 17% in
incidence fell. Booth (1993: 59) reports 1998. Relative to the new poverty line,
that, according to a poverty line devised the rate rose from 18% in 1996 to 24% in
by Professor Hendra Esmara, the na- 1998 and then fell slightly to 23% in 1999.
tional headcount poverty rate (that is, Measured poverty after the onset of the
the proportion of people living in house- crisis may have slightly overstated real
holds whose average per capita income poverty because the anti-poverty pro-
is below the poverty line) fell from 47.4% grams that provided benefits in kind—
in 1970 to 45.2% in 1976, and then to subsidised rice, school grants and
34.4% in 1987. BPS has produced esti- subsidised health care and nutrition—
mates of national poverty incidence would not have affected the expendi-
from 1976 onwards. Relative to the BPS ture-based measures of poverty, even
poverty line, the headcount poverty rate though they reduced real poverty, be-
was lower than that found by Esmara cause their benefits were not included
and fell much more dramatically be- in measured expenditure. 7
tween 1976, when it was 40.1% relative
to the BPS line, and 1987, when it was EVALUATION OF THE
only 17.4% according to BPS (Booth SSN PROGRAMS
1999: table 6). Poverty continued to fall Comprehensive studies of the coverage
in the early and mid 1990s, and by Feb- and targeting performance of the SSN
ruary 1996 was estimated to be only 11% programs have been undertaken by re-
relative to the BPS poverty line (Booth searchers at SMERU. Table 3 summarises
1999: table 6). some of their principal findings. Two
There were corresponding improve- measures of ‘targeting’ are presented: the
ments in other social indicators in the ratio of a program’s coverage of the poor-
first three decades of the New Order est 20% of the population—as measured
regime. Almost universal entry into pri- by household expenditure surveys—to
mary education was achieved in the its coverage of the remaining 80% of the
early 1980s, and the net enrolment rate population, and the ratio of its coverage
has been maintained at about 95% at the of the poorest 20% of the population to
primary level since then (Jones, Hagul its coverage of the richest 20%.8 Since the
318 Anne Daly and George Fane

BKKBN poverty criteria are only fairly come within villages are small, or
weakly correlated with low expendi- where the official criteria are poor mea-
ture, it is not surprising that the pro- sures of poverty, this is an appropriate
grams turned out not to have been strategy. Another reason for not selling
targeted very accurately to those in the all the rice just to the households that
bottom 20% of the distribution of ex- met the official criteria is that it was
penditure.9 And since random errors in often difficult for poor households to
the survey data on expenditure would accumulate the Rp 20,000 needed to
make even a perfectly targeted scheme purchase their monthly allocation. In
appear to contain a random element, such cases, some rice remained unsold,
the estimated targeting performance of and some was sold to those who could
the schemes probably understates their afford it but were outside the original
true performance. target group (Kusumastuti et al. 1998).

Subsidised Rice Education


As described above, the objective of this In the first year, problems in the admin-
program in 1999/2000 was to provide istration of the SGP were encountered
20 kg of subsidised rice per month to the in remote areas, where the cost of col-
17.4 million households in the two poor- lecting the scholarship was high, and
est BKKBN groups. In the event, about occasionally exceeded its total value. In
10 million households in total actually addition, local post offices complained
received subsidised rice in 1999/2000 of congestion. However, Hardjono
(National Coordinating Team for Social (1999: 30–1) concluded that in the small
Safety Net Programs 2001), and not all region of West Java covered by her sur-
of them were in the two poorest groups. vey, the administration of the SGP was
The SMERU estimates summarised in relatively effective. A survey of 355 pri-
table 3 indicate that only 53% of those mary and lower secondary schools in 22
in the bottom 20% of the expenditure provinces conducted by CIMU found
distribution received subsidised OPK that 41% of the first tranche and 70% of
rice, and those in this poorest 20% were the third tranche for the 1998/99 school
only 40% more likely to benefit from the year were collected from the post offices
scheme than the rest of the population. by the schools rather than by the stu-
Nevertheless, the last column in table 3 dents themselves (CIMU 2000a). In sub-
shows that the scheme was relatively ac- sequent years, this initially informal
curately targeted away from households practice was officially sanctioned.
in the richest 20% of the population. In some cases, local committees de-
Among the problems encountered in cided to share the scholarships among
the distribution process were those re- students rather than give them to se-
lated to delays in distribution to remote lected poor students for the duration of
areas. Another reason why the target their schooling at a particular institution.
households typically received less than In other cases, some or all of the money
their full monthly allocations of subsi- was retained by the school to pay off
dised rice was that many village com- debts, replace fees or cover ongoing
munities insisted on allocating some costs. In these cases, the scholarships
rice to every household, rather than therefore acted like a block grant. Nev-
providing all the benefits to those that ertheless, the CIMU survey found that
met the official criteria (Kusumastuti et the majority of primary and lower sec-
al. 1998). Where the differences in in- ondary students directly received over
Anti-poverty Programs in Indonesia 319

TABLE 3 Coverage and Targeting of Anti-poverty Programs, August 1998 to February 1999 a

Program Coverage of Group by Program (%) Targeting Ratios


Poorest Poorest Whole of Coverage Coverage
20% of 40% of Potential of Poorest of Poorest
Potential Potential Group 20%/ 20%/
Group Group Coverage Coverage
of Remain- of Richest
ing 80% 20%
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

Subsidised rice 52.6 49.4 40.1 1.4 2.2


Primary scholarships 5.8 5.3 4.0 1.6 2.8
Lower secondary scholarships 12.2 11.2 8.5 1.6 2.5
Upper secondary scholarships 5.4 5.2 3.8 1.6 2.8
Health care 10.6 8.9 6.4 2.0 3.4
Nutrition 16.5 16.6 15.9 1.0 1.2
Job creation 8.3 7.6 5.6 1.7 3.3

Column (4) = [4 x column (1)]/[5 x column (3) – column (1)].


a

Coverage of the richest 20% = column (1)/column (5).


Coverage = number covered/size of potentially eligible group. The definitions of the number
covered and the size of the potentially eligible group vary from scheme to scheme and are
given below for the national coverage estimates in column (3). The definitions for the other
expenditure quintiles are exactly analogous.
Size of ‘potentially eligible’ group:
• Subsidised rice and job creation programmes: all 50.4 million Indonesian households.
• Scholarships: the number of children in the relevant type of school—29.7 million children
enrolled in primary school; 10.4 million in lower secondary school; and 6.4 million in upper
secondary school.
• Health care: the 27.6 million individuals estimated to have visited a health care provider
in the three months prior to the survey.
• Nutrition: the 20.0 million individuals in the group ‘pregnant women and children under
three years old’.
Number covered:
• Subsidised rice and job creation schemes: the number of households in which any member
had received any benefits under the relevant scheme in the six months prior to the survey.
• Scholarships: the number of children that had received a scholarship in the 1998/99
academic year.
• Health care: the number of individuals seeking treatment in the three months prior to the
survey who had used a health card to obtain free treatment.
• Nutrition: the number of individuals who had obtained benefits under the program in the
six months prior to the survey.
Source: Sumarto, Suryahadi and Widyanti (2001: appendix table 2). Their estimates are
derived from the special module on the SSN that was included in the National Socio-
Economic Survey (Susenas) conducted in February 1999 and that covered the preceding
six months.
320 Anne Daly and George Fane

two-thirds of their annual scholarship time of the crisis, the SGP helped allevi-
entitlement. There was, however, con- ate the effects of the crisis on poverty,
siderable regional variation in these out- but that the subsidies it provided to
comes. lower and upper secondary education
Since school fees had contributed to had smaller effects on poverty.
the high dropout rates of children from Concern has been expressed because
poor families in the late 1980s, govern- the scholarship program did not reach
ment schools were directed not to charge the very poor children who were not
fees for the 1998/99 academic year. Al- enrolled in any school, or those who
though the government did not directly attended low quality private schools
provide funds to replace the fees that that were excluded from the program
were supposed to be waived (CIMU (Jones, Hagul and Damayanti 2000).
2000b: 5), the SGP block grants helped There is also survey evidence that the
to compensate for fees in those schools aggregate picture may disguise differ-
that received these grants. ent results for particular groups. For
The SGP has been cited by both example, there is some evidence that
SMERU and the World Bank as one of dropout rates rose among poor urban
the most successful of the SSN pro- teenagers following the crisis (Filmer
grams, and total school enrolments did et al. 1999; Jones, Hagul and Damayanti
not fall. The age-specific school enrol- 2000).
ment ratio for 7–12 year olds remained The targeting scores reported in
constant at just over 95% between 1997 table 3 suggest that the SGP was better
and 1999, while the corresponding ra- targeted than the subsidised rice and nu-
tios for 13–15 year olds and 16–18 year trition programs, but not as well tar-
olds rose slightly over the same period, geted as the health care or job creation
from 77% and 49% to 79% and 51%, re- programs. Cameron (2000) reports simi-
spectively (BPS 1999: 53).10 However, lar overall targeting results using the 100
these increases are modest relative to the Villages Survey. However, her measure
13.5% increase in total government of targeting relates to households con-
spending on education (at constant taining students who received a schol-
1996/97 prices) between 1997/98 and arship, not to the scholarship status of
1999/2000 shown in table 4. an individual student. Her measure for
Lanjouw et al. (2001) use data from targeting will therefore overestimate the
the Susenas (National Socio-Economic number of individuals receiving schol-
Surveys) for 1995–98 to estimate the arships. Her estimates imply that the
marginal impact on households in each targeting improved with level of edu-
expenditure quintile of public spending cation, whereas table 3 implies that at
at the primary, lower secondary and each level of education the poorest 20%
upper secondary levels. They find that of students (measured according to av-
additional expenditure on primary edu- erage expenditure per household mem-
cation is particularly beneficial for ber) were 60% more likely to receive
households in the poorest quintile. scholarships than the richest 80%. 11
However, additional government ex- There is an important sense in which
penditure on lower and upper second- both the table 3 targeting estimates and
ary education provides relatively larger those of Cameron exaggerate the target-
benefits to richer households. These re- ing performance of scholarships at the
sults suggest that by preventing a cut in secondary school level, and particularly
expenditure on primary education at the at the upper secondary level: both sets
Anti-poverty Programs in Indonesia 321

TABLE 4 Total Budgetary Spending on Education, and Spending on Education under Anti-
poverty Programs, 1995/96 to 1999/2000

95/96 a 96/97 97/98 98/99 1999/ Growth


2000 96/97–
99/00
(% p.a.)

Expenditures (Rp trillion) b


Anti-poverty program
spending on education n.a. 0.30 0.36 1.56 1.67 77.2
Total anti-poverty programs 1.07 1.54 1.98 14.24 13.95 108.3
Education, routine budget 3.64 4.22 5.18 5.67 7.49 21.1
Education, development budget 1.81 2.14 2.09 1.98 7.21 50.0
Education, total budget 5.44 6.35 7.27 7.65 14.70 32.3
Education, total budget, 1996/97
prices 5.79 6.35 6.50 4.15 7.38 5.1
Shares (%)
Education anti-poverty
as % education budget n.a. 4.72 4.95 20.33 11.35
Education budget
as % of total budget 6.97 7.01 7.19 5.20 7.39
Education budget
as % of GDP 1.16 1.14 1.05 0.75 1.30

a
n.a. = not available.
b
Anti-poverty program spending on education is defined as in table 1 and derived from the
sources given there. CPI data are from the CEIC Ltd (Hong Kong) Asia Database. Budgetary
spending on education excludes spending on religious schools by the Ministry of Religion
and Home Affairs.

Sources: Budgetary data on education were taken from National Ministry of Education (2000:
157, table 81).

of estimates refer to coverage of children of school between August and Decem-


in school, not to coverage of all children ber 1998 as a function of scholarship
in the relevant age group. Since children availability and a set of control vari-
from poor families are much less likely ables that included the ages and gen-
than those from richer families to be der of the child and the socio-economic
enrolled in secondary school, it may well characteristics of its household. For
be that, relative to all children in the rel- each of the three levels of schooling
evant age group, the scholarships at (primary, lower secondary and upper
upper secondary level were targeted secondary), she estimated one regres-
towards rich families and away from sion that included a village-specific ef-
poor ones. fect and another that did not include
Cameron also estimated regressions such an effect. In five of the six result-
using the 100 Villages Survey to explain ing regressions, the estimated effect of
the probability of a child dropping out the scholarship program on the prob-
322 Anne Daly and George Fane

ability of dropouts was not statistically Bank 2000) reported difficulties in al-
significant, and in the sixth case—the locating funds, inadequate publicity for
regression with village-specific effects the program among beneficiaries and
for lower secondary school students— health care providers, and unnecessar-
the estimated coefficient implied that ily complex administrative procedures.
being in a household in which some Against these negative assessments,
child received a scholarship reduced there is evidence from some surveys
the probability (evaluated at the sample and field visits that the program helped
mean) of dropping out at the lower sec- to improve ante-natal and post-natal
ondary level by 3.5 percentage points. care and raised the availability of re-
In the 100 Villages Survey, 13.6% of sources in a health care system that was
lower secondary students were in facing extreme difficulties as a result of
households that received scholarships, the economic crisis.
but according to the Susenas data in Available evidence suggests that the
table 3 the coverage at this level was free health care service scheme achieved
only 8.5%. However, Cameron’s seem- a higher coverage rate among the poor
ingly low estimates of the effects of the and was more closely targeted to poor
SGP on retention rates relate only to households than the nutrition program.
dropouts in the course of a school year. SMERU’s analysis of the 100 Village
Using her data set it is impossible to es- Survey and the Susenas data shows that
timate the presumably much larger ef- the poorest 20% of households were
fect of the offer of a scholarship on the twice as likely to receive free health care
probability of re-enrolment at the start treatment as the non-poor. Lanjouw et
of a school year. al. (2001) estimate that households in the
Retention rates are not the only rel- poorest quintile of the expenditure dis-
evant criteria for assessing the SGP. tribution receive a share of the benefits
Jones, Hagul and Damayanti (2000) from public expenditure on primary
emphasise the positive implications of health care that is equal to their share in
the program for quality of education. total household expenditure, but that the
Increased funds for schools allowed poorest households share less than pro-
them to maintain facilities and to reduce portionately in public expenditure on
the fees for children who were not of- hospitals.
fered scholarships. There is also evi- The rate of participation in the nutri-
dence that this injection of funds enabled tion program, however, was almost
schools to be more generous with stu- equal for poor and non-poor households
dents who were unable to pay their (16.5% of poor households compared
school fees than had been the case in the with 15.9% of all households, according
late 1980s, when some schools excluded to the Susenas data).
students who were unable to pay (Jones,
Hagul and Damayanti 2000). Job Creation and
Infrastructure Development
Health Care The job creation schemes were intended
The subsidised health care program for to induce self-selection of poor unskilled
poor households that was introduced workers by paying no more than mini-
in 1998 was not subject to the same ex- mum wages. Sumarto and Suryahadi
tensive and systematic reviews as the (2001: 13) estimate that the average wage
education program. The World Bank of workers in these schemes was 54%
report on health care programs (World below the average daily wage in the con-
Anti-poverty Programs in Indonesia 323

struction sector and 4% below that in the ation schemes go to the poor. Even if
foodcrop sector. Hardjono’s sample was highly atypi-
However, estimates of the targeting cal—which we doubt—and even if most
performance of the job creation of the employees were unskilled work-
schemes are mixed. According to table ers in households below the poverty
3, the coverage of the poorest 20% (by line, the benefits to unskilled workers
expenditure) exceeded that of all other would still only be a small fraction of
households by 70%, and exceeded that the budgetary outlays by the govern-
of the richest 20% of households by a ment, given plausible estimates of the
factor of 3.3. Similar results were found elasticities of supply and demand for
from the 100 Village Survey. Hardjono unskilled labour. Suppose, for illustra-
(1999: 23) gives a different and much tive purposes, that the elasticities of sup-
less favourable picture of padat karya ply and demand for unskilled labour are
programs, on the basis of a small but three and minus one, respectively. Un-
very detailed survey in April and May der these assumptions, the direct ben-
1999 of a single area of 22 hamlets on efit of job creation schemes to unskilled
the northern coastal plain of West Java. workers would be only a quarter of the
In this sample, only 5% of participants total budgetary cost of the schemes.13 If
in padat karya schemes belonged to the elasticities are larger than those as-
households in the poorest quintile, sumed above for illustrative purposes,
whereas 34% belonged to households the benefits to unskilled workers would
in the middle quintile and 16% to be an even smaller fraction of the bud-
households in the richest quintile. getary cost of the programs. It is widely
Hardjono reports that villagers were argued that the supply of unskilled
cynical about these schemes on the labour is indeed very elastic in devel-
ground that employees were allegedly oping countries; and the demand is
selected on the basis of their connec- probably also very elastic, since the glo-
tions with village authorities or con- bal markets for manufactured goods
tractors. She also reports that: ‘It so produced by internationally mobile
happened that in one hamlet padat karya capital and unskilled labour have be-
work was in progress on the day when come increasingly competitive and in-
the survey was conducted. The small tegrated. Of course, there are additional
road that was being “improved” led to benefits to the poor from the infrastruc-
the lurah’s (village headman[’s]) house’ ture built or repaired by the job creation
(Hardjono 1999: 23). 12 schemes. However, if the purpose is to
Even the table 3 estimates of the tar- provide infrastructure, tendering among
geting of the job creation schemes are specialist firms that compete on the basis
much less impressive than the targeting of price, quality and efficiency is more
achieved by Argentina’s Trabajar Pro- efficient than ad hoc programs with mul-
gram, in which 80% of the employees tiple goals. Finally, to be efficient, the
were drawn from the poorest 20% of provision of infrastructure must be
households (Jalan and Ravallion 1999). planned well in advance, and projects
Nevertheless, they are still better than carefully selected using cost–benefit cri-
the estimates of targeting achieved by teria. In contrast, job creation schemes
any SSN scheme other than the health are often expanded, or contracted, ac-
care program. However, we believe that cording to short-term expediency—as
the table 3 estimates exaggerate the ex- happened in Indonesia in the wake of
tent to which the benefits of the job cre- the crisis.
324 Anne Daly and George Fane

The above analysis does assume that pared with macroeconomic perfor-
in the absence of the job creation mance. Despite spending very little on
schemes, unskilled wages would adjust poverty programs in the three decades
so that the people employed on them preceding the recent economic crisis,
would instead be employed in other Indonesia managed to reduce poverty
unskilled jobs. We think that this as- considerably, and despite greatly in-
sumption is much more realistic than creased spending on poverty programs
the alternative view that they would in 1998, poverty rose very sharply. Of
otherwise be unemployed. Strong evi- course, it does not follow from the rela-
dence for the flexibility of wages in In- tive unimportance of the schemes that
donesia is provided by the fact that the they have been wasteful.
huge fall in the demand for labour be- Economists have traditionally argued
tween August 1997 and August 1998 that benefits should be in cash, rather
was associated with a fall in real wages than in kind, on the ground that, for a
of about 34%; unemployment increased given amount of tax levied on the rich
over this period only from 4.7% to 5.5%, to finance a program, the poor benefit
and total employment actually rose by more if they are free to decide how to
3% (SMERU 1999: 1). spend the amount transferred to them
than if the government decides for them.
OVERVIEW This argument is correct as far as it goes,
To make a definitive appraisal of social but it ignores the fact that provision of
welfare programs it is necessary at least benefits in kind rather than in cash al-
to know the marginal cost to the rest of lows them to be targeted towards the
the society of raising the real incomes of needy at lower cost and with less harm-
the poor by some given amount by ex- ful effects on incentives. The reason is
panding each individual program. that subsidising products that are only
Given a value judgement about the rela- desired by those in need allows the ben-
tive social values of a unit of income to efits to be allocated by self-selection,
the poor and the rich, one could then rather than by administrative decision.
decide which programs should be ex- Health care subsidies provide the
panded and which contracted or abol- clearest illustration of this point: if large
ished. Even this information would be cash grants were made available to all
much too crude, both because there are those certified by doctors as needing
degrees of poverty and of affluence, and heart surgery, some healthy people
because different categories of poor would undoubtedly manage to acquire
people—for example, those who are ill, the cash benefits fraudulently to spend
and those who have low money in- on general consumption. In contrast,
comes—are benefited by very different fraudulent claims would not occur if the
amounts by different programs. Since no cash could be spent only on heart sur-
study has yet produced this information gery. The huge bulk of the Indonesian
for any of the Indonesian social welfare anti-poverty programs provided ben-
programs, any attempt to appraise them efits in kind, and we think that this
must be very tentative. choice was probably correct.
At least at the low levels of expendi- Table 3 shows that if the poor are de-
ture on anti-poverty programs that In- fined to be those in the lowest quintile
donesia has been able to afford, these of the distribution of households by ex-
programs have clearly been of minor penditure, then the SSN programs were
importance in alleviating poverty com- not particularly well targeted towards
Anti-poverty Programs in Indonesia 325

them, and quite substantial amounts of the assessments of which we are aware
the benefits went to all quintiles, includ- has attempted to estimate the extent of
ing the richest. This is consistent with wasteful competition. The second part
the evidence from field-based research of the condition probably holds for gov-
that many of the local committees in ernment subsidies to health care, nu-
charge of distributing benefits chose to trition and basic education (that is,
ignore program guidelines and to divide elementary and lower secondary edu-
the benefits of the programs equally cation). The evidence of Lanjouw et al.
among all villagers. Table 3 suggests (2001) suggests that public spending on
that the health care program was more primary education is a particularly ef-
effectively targeted towards the poor (as fective way of helping families in the
measured by low expenditure) than any poorest quintile of the expenditure dis-
other part of the SSN. In addition, since tribution. A strong case can therefore
self-selection ensures that health care be made for these subsidies as ways of
subsidies are targeted towards the sick, combating poverty in the medium to
it follows that table 3 understates the ef- long run.
fectiveness of this program in helping The danger in using education as a
the needy, who obviously include the way of alleviating poverty is that at any
sick as well as those with low monetary level of education beyond primary, the
expenditure. proportion of children from rich fami-
Poor targeting is not a decisive objec- lies who are enrolled is higher than the
tion to a program designed to reduce proportion from poor families. The net
poverty if the program satisfies two con- benefits of subsidies to education paid
ditions: it is paid for by the rich and it out of general tax revenue may end up
does not generate large inefficiencies. going to the rich, not the poor. This dan-
Part of Indonesia’s anti-poverty pro- ger was probably overcome in the SGP
grams have been directly financed by at the primary and lower secondary
central government revenue, and part levels by the deliberate attempt to tar-
by foreign loans—usually at concession- get the scholarships to poor families,
ary rates—that must eventually be re- and to target the grants to schools in
paid using government revenue. Since poor areas. In the case of subsidies at
non-tax revenues (for example, oil rev- the upper secondary level, the evidence
enue) cannot be increased to meet addi- is inconclusive.
tional spending, the marginal cost of While we think that scholarships and
anti-poverty programs falls on tax pay- grants for basic education that are tar-
ers. It seems reasonable to assume that geted at the poor are probably an effec-
the share of the poor in program ben- tive way of reducing poverty, we doubt
efits at least exceeds their share in tax that it makes sense to have two chan-
payments. We therefore assume that the nels for funding education, namely the
first condition is satisfied. special SGP arrangements and the regu-
The second condition is likely to be lar budgetary funding of government
satisfied if the program does not result and religious schools that is channelled
in a large amount of wasteful competi- through the Departments of Education
tion for benefits, and if the subsidised and of Home and Religious Affairs. The
product is such a basic item that it is reason for setting up the SGP as a sepa-
one of the things on which the poor rate funding channel appears to have
would freely choose to spend much of been that the external donors believed
any addition to their incomes. None of that funds channelled through the De-
326 Anne Daly and George Fane

partment of Education would be less Although table 3 shows that employ-


likely to reach schools and pupils than ment in job creation schemes was rela-
funds channelled through a special pro- tively accurately targeted towards the
gram over which they would have some poor, the net gains to unskilled workers are
control. To the extent that this argument likely to be only a small fraction of the
is valid, it suggests that increased au- budgetary cost of the schemes, given
diting and monitoring of the Ministry plausible estimates of the elasticities of
of Education might be an even better supply and demand for unskilled labour
way of helping schools and pupils than (see note 13).
setting up a separate channel for fund- Total spending on all social welfare
ing education. programs, as defined here, increased
We doubt that the subsidised rice pro- from around 2% of total government
gram and the various job creation pro- spending before the crisis to 10.7% in
grams were cost effe ctive ways of 1998/99. This share had already been
alleviating poverty. Table 3 implies that reduced to 5.7% in fiscal year 2000 and it
the targeting of the subsidised rice pro- is scheduled to fall still further. This level
gram was worse than that of any other of spending is probably too small to dis-
program except nutrition. In addition, tort incentives significantly, and we are
table 3 may overstate the extent to which not in favour of changing it.14 Rather, we
the rice program was targeted towards think that spending on these programs
the poor, because coverage is defined in should be concentrated on basic health
terms of the number of households that care, and on scholarships and grants for
benefited from the program, and does not basic education targeted to poor students
take account of the amount of subsidised and to schools in poor areas.
rice bought by each household. In some Cross-country comparisons, and
cases, according to SMERU’s studies, the Indonesia’s own history since the 1960s,
rice was made equally available to all suggest that, while they are outside the
households in particular villages, but the present definition of anti-poverty pro-
poor did not have enough funds to buy grams, the liberalisation of trade and
their full entitlements; in other villages, foreign investment are also very impor-
the rice was simply put on sale at a tant ways of reducing poverty.15 Simi-
subsidised price. In both these situations, larly, although improving the quality of
rich households are likely to have bought universal primary education and pub-
more rice than poor ones. It might have lic health are also outside the present
been possible to improve the targeting of definition of anti-poverty programs,
the rice program by distributing low, they are probably also effective ways of
rather than average, quality rice. reducing poverty.

NOTES
* We are grateful for help from many gov- 1 Separate official poverty lines are used
ernment officials, staff members at the for urban and rural areas in each prov-
SMERU (Social Monitoring and Early ince. In 2000, the average for urban areas
Response Unit) Research Institute, Vivi was Rp 92,000 per person per month. In
Alatas, Lisa Cameron and three anony- rural areas, the average was Rp 74,000
mous referees. None of these people is per person per month. The average size
responsible for opinions expressed, or of all Indonesian households in 2000 was
mistakes that remain. 4.0 people.
Anti-poverty Programs in Indonesia 327

2 According to the estimates in column (3) group that are enrolled in any level of
of table 3, the coverage was 4.0% at the school.
primary level, 8.5% at the lower second- 11 Cameron’s data (in her table 2) imply that
ary level and 3.8% at the upper second- the poorest 20% of households, by expen-
ary level. diture, were 10% more likely to receive
3 In 1993, of a total of 66,000 villages in her scholarships at the primary level than the
sample, only 75 were wrongly classified richest 80%. The corresponding excesses
as IDT and only one was wrongly classi- at the lower and upper secondary levels
fied as non-IDT. were 77% and 137%, respectively.
4 Evans (1998: 8) reports predictions that 12 Hardjono also found evidence of inverse
half the population would be in poverty targeting by one of the most important
by the end of 1998. revolving credit schemes (the village
5 The SSN Adjustment Loan was initially credit scheme known as PDM-DKE): only
intended to provide $600 million to fi- 5% of participants came from households
nance SSN programs, and a first tranche in the poorest quintile, whereas 38% be-
of $300 million was disbursed in 1998; longed to households in the richest
however, the World Bank decided in quintile (Hardjono 1999: 24). She at-
January 2001 that the conditions attached tributes this to the fact that loans were
to the loan were not being addressed sat- only given to households that were
isfactorily. It therefore cancelled the sec- judged to be creditworthy.
ond tranche of $300 million. 13 If, for example, job creation schemes em-
6 The decentralisation arrangements are ploy 4% of unskilled workers, their cost
summarised in McLeod (2000: 30–8). would be 4% of the unskilled wage bill,
7 We are grateful to the editor for this and they would raise unskilled wages by
point. 1%. This would be enough, given the il-
8 In table 3, ‘coverage’ of each program is lustrative elasticities assumed above, to
defined so as to exclude from the relevant raise the supply of unskilled labour by
population those that could not conceiv- 3% and to reduce private demand by 1%,
ably be covered by such a program. For thus making room for the 4% of unskilled
example, the population used for mea- labour demanded by the schemes. Since
suring the coverage of the scholarship unskilled workers have to give up lei-
programs is the population of children sure, the benefit of the schemes to them
enrolled at the relevant schooling level. is only the 1% rise in their wage rates, or
Details are given in the notes to the table. one-quarter of the cost of the schemes.
9 The December 1998 100 Village Survey 14 Administrativ e costs aside, efficiency
indicates that there is only a fairly weak losses are proportional to the square of
correlation between the expenditure - the rate of a tax or subsidy, whereas
based measure of poverty and the crite- transfers are proportional to the rate of a
ria used by the BKKBN to define ‘poor’ tax or subsidy. Therefore, at very low
households. Suryahadi, Suharso and Su- rates of taxes and subsidies, both trans-
marto (1999) estimate that only 25% of fers and efficiency losses are small, and
the households that are poor according efficiency losses are themselves small
to the BKKBN criteria were in the poor- compared to transfers.
est 20% of households according to the 15 For evidence that reducing barriers to
expenditure criterion, and that 38% of trade promotes growth, see Dollar (1992);
households in the poorest 20% accord- Edwards (1992; 1993; 1998); Harrison
ing to the expenditure criterion were not (1996); Sachs and Warner (1995); and
classified as ‘poor’ according to the World Bank (1993). For evidence that, on
BKKBN criteria. average, the poor share equally (in pro-
10 The age-specific enrolment ratio is the portionate terms) in growth with the non-
proportion of all children in the age poor, see Dollar and Kraay (2000).
328 Anne Daly and George Fane

REFERENCES
Alatas, Vivi (2000), Evaluating the Left Be- Filmer, Deon, Haneen Sayed, Boediono,
hind Villages Program in Indonesia: Ex- Jiyono, Nanik Suwaryani and Bambang
ploiting Progr am Rules to Iden tify Indriyanto (1999), ‘Impact of Economic Cri-
Effects on Employment and Expendi- sis on Basic Education in Indonesia’, Watch-
tures’, Princeton University, Princeton ing Brief, East Asia and the Pacific Region,
NJ (mimeo). World Bank, Washington DC. Online at
Booth, Anne (1993), ‘Counting the Poor in www.worldbank.org/eapsocial/library/
Indonesia’, Bulletin of Indonesian Economic wbrief2.pdf.
Studies 29 (1): 53–83. Hardjono , Joan (1999), ‘The Micro Data
Booth, Anne (1999), ‘Survey of Recent De- Picture: Results of a SMERU Social
velopments’, Bulletin of Indonesian Eco- Impac t Survey in the Purwaka rta–
nomic Studies 35 (3): 3–38. Cirebon Corridor’, SMERU Research
BPS (Badan Pusat Statistik) (1999), Welfare Institute Working Paper, Jakarta. Online
Indicators, Jakarta. at www.smeru.or.id.
Cameron, Lisa (2000), ‘An Analysis of the Role Harrison, Ann (1996), ‘Openness and Growth:
of Social Safety Net Scholarships in Reduc- A Time-Series, Cross-Section Analysis for
ing School Drop-out during the Indonesian Developing Countries’, Journal of Develop-
Economic Crisis’, UNICEF Innocenti ment Economics 48 (2): 419–47.
Working Paper No. 82, Florence. Online Jalan, Jyotsna, and Martin Ravallion (1999),
at www.economics.unimelb.edu.au/ ‘Income Gains to the Poor from Workfare:
lcameron/lisaspage.html. Estimates for Argentina’s Trabajar Pro-
CIMU (Central Independent Monitoring gram’, Policy Research Working Paper
Unit) (2000a), Warta [News], January, No. 2149, World Bank, Washington DC.
Jakarta. Online at: econ.worldbank.org.
CIMU (Central Independent Monitoring Jones, G., P. Hagul and Damayanti (2000), A
Unit) (2000b), Warta [News], September, Study of the Impact of the Scholarships
Jakarta. and Grants Program, World Bank, Jakarta
Dollar, David (1992), ‘Outward-Oriented (mimeo).
Developing Economies Really Do Grow Kusumastuti, Sri R., H. Akhmadi, P. Wi-
More Rapidly: Evidence from 95 LDCs, bowo, S. Budiati, M. Nabiu, S. Usman, L.
1976–1985’ , Economic Development and Bailey and J. Maxwell (1998), ‘Implemen-
Cultural Change 40 (3): 523–44. tation of Special Market Operation (OPK)
Dollar, David, and Aart Kraay (2000) , Program: Results of a SMERU Rapid Field
Growth Is Good for the Poor, World Bank Appraisal Mission in Five Provinces’,
Washing ton DC (mimeo ). Online at SMERU Research Institute Special Report,
www.worldbank.org/research/growth. Jakarta.
Edwards, Sebastian (1992), ‘Trade Orienta- Lanjouw, Peter, Menno Pradhan, Fadia
tion, Distortions and Growth in Develop- Saadah, Haneen Sayed and Robert Spar-
ing Countries’, Journal of Development row (2001), ‘Poverty, Education and
Economics 39 (1): 31–57. Health in Indonesia: Who Benefits from
Edwards, Sebastian (1993), ‘Openness, Trade Public Spending?’, World Bank Health
Liberalization, and Growth in Develop- and Population Working Paper No. 2739,
ing Countries’, Journal of Economic Litera- World Bank, Washington DC. Online at:
ture 31 (3): 1,358–93. econ.worldbank.org.
Edwards, Sebastian (1998), ‘Openness, Pro- McLeod, Ross H. (2000), ‘Survey of Recent
ductivity and Growth: What Do We Re- Developments’, Bulletin of Indonesian Eco-
ally Know?’ Economic Journal 108 (March): nomic Studies 36 (2): 5–40.
383–98. National Coordinating Team for Social
Evans, Kevin (1998), ‘Survey of Recent De- Safety Net Programs (2001), Indonesia’s
velopments’, Bulletin of Indonesian Eco- Social Safety Net Programs and Its Safe-
nomic Studies 34 (3): 5–36. guarding: An Expression of People’s
Anti-poverty Programs in Indonesia 329

Right to Development, Paper presented JPS Module in the 1999 Susenas’, SMERU
at a seminar on The Financial Crisis and Resea rc h Ins titute Working Paper,
the Right to Development, Jakarta, 27 Feb- Jakarta. Online at www.smeru.or.id.
ruary. Sumarto, Sudarno, and Asep Suryahadi
National Management Consultants (2000), (2001), ‘Principles and Approaches to Tar-
Kecamatan Development Program, Second geting: With Reference to the Indonesian
Annual Report, 1999/2000 , Jakarta. Social Safety Net Programs’, SMERU Re-
National Ministry of Education (2000), Indo- search Institute Working Paper, Jakarta.
nesia: Educational Statistics in Brief, 1999/ Online at www.smeru.or.id.
2000, Jakarta. Suryahadi, Asep, Yusuf Suharso and Sudarno
Sachs, J.D., and A. Warner (1995), ‘Economic Sumarto (1999), ‘Coverage and Targeting
Reform and the Process of Global Integra- in the Indonesian Social Safety Net Pro-
tion’, in W.C. Brainard and G.L. Perry grams: Evidence from 100 Village Survey’,
(eds), Brookings Papers on Economic Activ- SMERU Research Institute Working Paper,
ity, Brookings Institution, Washington DC. Jakarta. Online at www.smeru.or.id.
SMERU (Social Monitoring and Early Re- World Bank (1993), The East Asian Miracle:
sponse Unit) Research Institute (1999), Economic Growth and Public Policy, Oxford
‘Labor Market Adjustments as a Response University Press, New York.
to the Crisis’, And the Data Say, August, World Bank (2000), ‘Health Strategy in a Post-
Jakarta. Online at: www.smeru.or.id. Crisis, Decentralizing Indonesia’, Report
SMERU (Social Monitoring and Early Re- No. 21318–IND, Human DevelopmentSec-
sponse Unit) Research Institute (2001), tor Unit, East Asia and Pacific Region,
Bulletin, March/April, Jakarta. Online at World Bank, Washington DC. Online at
www.smeru.or.id. www-wds.worldbank.org.
Sumarto, Sudarno, Asep Suryahadi and World Bank (2001) World Development Re-
Winefrida Widyanti (2001), ‘Designs and port 2000/2001 , Oxford University Press,
Implementation of the Indonesian Social Oxford.
Safety Net Programs: Evidence from the
View publication stats

You might also like