Development Unchained - Trade and Industrialization in The Era of International Production

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 12

Global Policy Volume 10 . Issue 1 .

February 2019
29

Development Unchained: Trade and


Industrialization in the Era of International
Production

Research Article
Richard Kozul-Wright and Piergiuseppe Fortunato
UNCTAD

Abstract
Following a period of strong growth across all developing regions during the first decade of the millennium and a rapid
rebound from the 2008 financial crisis, a combination of falling commodity prices, increasing financial market volatility and
weak global demand has negatively affected growth performance in recent years. This growth slowdown has exposed the
absence of structural transformation in many developing countries even under robust growth conditions. As a result, increasing
attention has turned to the trade and industrialization opportunities offered by participation in global value chains (GVCs). How-
ever, while the evidence suggests a positive association between participation in GVCs and increased exports and inward FDI
flows, evidence on their supporting structural transformation is weak. This paper discusses strategic approaches to participation
in GVCs as part of a broader development agenda. In particular, it focuses on the opportunities offered by regional value chains
(RVCs) and South-South cooperation and examines the role of industrial policy, with reference to the case of Southern Africa.

Policy Implications
• Targeting the growth of export-oriented manufactures or increasing participation in GVCs offers neither automatic nor
straightforward pathways to industrialization. It is the type of participation in GVCs, the tasks that can be acquired and
the linkages across these tasks, that matter.
• Developing economies need to find the right mixture of (i) effective public agencies able to bargain with footloose firms
and (ii) support measures to build the clusters and linkages leading to industrial diversification.
• Industrial policy is critical to ensuring that mixture but its effectiveness depends on complementary macroeconomic, trade
and technology policies.
• It is of critical importance to leverage strategic links between production for GVCs or RVCs and domestic demand; for
example, adopting industrial policies towards priority export sectors that strategically link policy incentives that push for
exporting along with measures to expand the domestic market.

For a brief period from the start of the new millennium, the The weak recovery in the advanced economies has since
combined influence of a ‘great moderation’ in the macroe- given way to worries about secular stagnation, marked by
conomic environment (Bernanke, 2004) and a strong growth low investment rates, a productivity slowdown and height-
recovery from the dot.com crash, reinforced support for the ened policy uncertainty. In its wake, growth in many devel-
promise, long held by supporters of hyperglobalization, of a oping economies has suffered knock-on effects with some
new international economic order. Developing countries countries entering recession in 2016. Moreover, the slow-
appeared to be the big winners in this new environment down has raised fears that debts accumulated over the pre-
leading to much talk of a ‘great convergence’ (Wolf, 2011). vious decade are becoming unsustainable along with a
Thanks to a combination of rising commodity prices, growing realization that, despite their strong growth perfor-
increased capital flows and strong export demand, growth mance, many developing economies had failed to undergo
across all the developing regions picked up sharply, in some the kind of structural transformation that could underpin
cases reaching historic highs (Table 1). These economies sustained growth in to the future. Against this more chal-
also showed considerable resilience in the face of financial lenging background, hopes have been placed in the trade
shocks that followed the sub-prime meltdown and subse- and industrialization opportunities offered by global value
quent economic turmoil of 2008–09. As advanced countries chains (GVCs) coordinated by multinational enterprises
struggled to find economic traction, the idea that emerging (MNEs) through networks of affiliates, contractual partners
economies had ‘decoupled’ from the travails of the or arms’ length suppliers (Dollar et al., 2017).
advanced economies gained an attentive audience. This has GVCs have been around for centuries (Gereffi et al., 2001),
proved short-lived. but began to play a more visible role in the late

Global Policy (2019) 10:1 doi: 10.1111/1758-5899.12601 © 2018 University of Durham and John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
Richard Kozul-Wright and Piergiuseppe Fortunato
30

Table 1. Average annual per capita growth rate by region, 1971–2016 (%)
Developed Developing Transition Northern Sub-Saharan
World countries countries countries BRICS LDCs LAC Africa Africa Asia

1970s 2.1 2.9 3.5 4.0 3.7 0.7 3.6 4.2 0.6 3.1
1980s 1.2 2.3 1.2 3.0 3.1 0.4 0.1 0.1 0.7 2.5
1990s 1.2 1.8 2.9 4.7 5.6 0.1 1.1 1.0 0.6 2.1
2000s 1.3 1.0 4.1 5.8 6.3 4.0 1.6 3.0 2.6 3.0
2010–16 1.5 1.3 3.6 1.5 5.1 2.3 1.1 0.3 1.2 3.6

Source: UNCTAD Stat.

industrialization experience of the first-tier East Asian econo- only increase productivity but also upgrade production into
mies in sectors such as electronic goods and components, higher-value segments of their respective industries’. The task
clothing and leather products (Helleiner, 1973) and rising to for policy makers in developing countries is to ensure that all
prominence with a new generation of manufacturing expor- firms and households are ready and incentivized to make use
ters in South East Asia and Central America following the of these opportunities so as to leave no one behind.
debt crisis of the early 1980s. As a result, not only did global At the same time, the external context for industrialization
trade accelerate much faster than global output (Figure 1) in developing countries has changed significantly for rea-
but the nature of trade was transformed as products made sons other than the rise of GVCs. Today’s global economy is
in one country and shipped to another for sale were a much more open and contested space than when the East
replaced by a multistage iterative process, traversing several Asian late industrializers began their successful ‘catch-up’ in
geographic and organizational borders, each stage adding the 1960s, not only because of their success but also
value to a semi-finished product before reaching their final because of the subsequent liberalization drive across the
market. world and the entry of former centrally planned economies
These chains now span all sectors of the economy and into the global trading system with a concomitant rise in
according to the World Bank (2017) the result is a win-win the global supply of low-skilled labour. At another level, a
world for international firms and the countries where they combination of new information and communication tech-
locate their activities, ‘firms that have internationalized have nologies (ICTs), stronger intellectual property rights and
increased their productivity and efficiency by mixing and weakened labour laws have shifted the balance of power
matching comparative advantages from different locations. towards larger firms with dominant market positions and an
In developing countries, GVCs have allowed suppliers to not attendant ability to generate super profits (UNCTAD, 2017).

Figure 1. Ratio of world merchandise trade volume growth to world real GDP growth, 1981–2016.

Source: WTO Secretariat.

© 2018 University of Durham and John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Global Policy (2019) 10:1
Trade and Industrialization
31

This partly explains the fall in labour shares for low and exaggerated counting in official trade statistics, as intermedi-
medium-skilled workers that took place since the early ates cross borders many times in the process of production
1990s (Timmer et al., 2013). In the face of fewer restrictions in value chains. The recently developed OECD-WTO Trade in
on how these firms can move capital across borders, not Value Added database (TiVA) can help avoid some of these
only has it become easier and cheaper to organise far-flung pitfalls and represents an important starting point to better
production networks but to govern those networks in ways understand the impact of GVCs. TiVA identifies GVCs by the
that further skew the benefits in favour of lead firms. country-industry where the last stage of production takes
In this paper, we examine the main challenges and place before the product is sold (the so-called country-
opportunities faced by developing economies trying to industry-of-completion). It is therefore able to provide data
industrialize under the current global economic scenario. We on foreign value added (FVA), defined as the value added
discuss the downsides of GVCs in a developmental perspec- generated outside the country-of-completion.
tive and consider why regional value chains (RVCs) and Based on TiVA, Figure 2 depicts changes of FVA between
South-South cooperation might be more conducive to inclu- 1995 and 2011. It shows that the foreign content of exports
sive growth and development. We then looked carefully into has increased significantly in many, particularly Asian,
one specific region which presents interesting, and unex- economies but also in Europe and North America over the
ploited, potential to strengthen trade and productive inte- last two decades. Foreign content shares for example dou-
gration: Southern Africa. We use trade data to assess the bled over the period in India, Poland and Turkey, Korea, and
prospects of this region vis-a-vis the rest of the continent Vietnam and trebled in Cambodia, with significant increases
and present a simple simulation exercise based on the pro- also observed in OECD economies, such as Germany, whose
duct space methodology to assess the benefits of further foreign content share increased by 10 percentage points, up
integration. We also discuss in detail the role that modern to 25 per cent in 2011. It is worth noting that, on this mea-
industrial policy can play to turn integration and upgrading sure, the variation in both levels of participation and the
in RVCs into a driver of economic development. changes over time are considerable.
GVCs are often taken to be an inevitable outcome of
technological changes and a natural evolution of the global
GVCs, productive capacities and development
trading system; as such they are presented as a promising
From their modest start mostly in the clothing and con- basis for further trade and investment liberalization (OECD,
sumer electronics industries in the late 1960s, exchanges 2013; WTO et al., 2013). From a development perspective,
within international production networks have now spread GVCs are often seen to present an attainable first step on
to many other industries, albeit with a noticeable concentra- the industrialization ladder and to offer a more productive
tion in capital and technology-intensive industries such as integration into the global trading system (Baldwin, 2016);
automobiles, ICT and machinery. While there is little doubt rather than having to develop an entire product or break
that the rise of GVCs, measuring their economic significance into an extremely competitive market on their own, coun-
with precision is not an easy task. On one level, the growing tries can specialize in specific tasks or components of a mul-
importance of GVCs can be gauged by the large volume of titude of value chains, starting at the relatively accessible
trade in intermediate goods, which amounted to 46 per bottom, leveraging the advantage of cheap labour and stea-
cent of total merchandise trade in 2014. However, this dily building up capacity in more skill intensive and higher
increased volume of traded intermediaries can result in value added activities.

Figure 2. Foreign value-added as % gross export, 1995-2011.

Source: OECD-WTO TiVA Database.

Global Policy (2019) 10:1 © 2018 University of Durham and John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
Richard Kozul-Wright and Piergiuseppe Fortunato
32

However, the association between participation in GVCs Figure 4. FVA in manufacturing exports and manufacturing value
and development is not a straightforward one. As summa- added; other developing economies.
rized by Hanson (2005), beyond the immediate firm-level
transactions, whether FDI can help generate wider spillovers
to the local economy is still a controversial issue from an
empirical point of view. UNCTAD (2016), for example, shows
that when increases in the foreign value added of exports
occur in a larger context of greater production and exports
of manufactures (as in much of the Asian region, for
instance), GVCs participation can complement industrializa-
tion and structural change. However, when increasing partic-
ipation in GVCs reflects a reduction of domestic sourcing in
a context of weak export performance of manufactures,
GVCs participation may even delay structural transformation,
as in the case of many developing economies in Africa and
Latin America.
This is illustrated in Figures 3 and 4 below which plot the
association between changes in manufacturing value added
as a share of GDP and changes in the import content of
export-oriented manufactures (i.e. foreign value addition
(FVA)) between 1995 and 2011, for Asian economies and for
the remaining developing countries and economies in tran-
sition for which data are available. Much of the Asian region Source: UNCTAD TDR 2016.
shows a clear and strong positive association between GVC
participation and industrialization, while developing coun-
tries in other regions show the opposite relationship. the particularities of GVC structures and the consequent dis-
Claims for how GVCs can strengthen productivity (and tribution of power along the value chain require a more
contribute to economic growth) are largely based on con- nuanced analysis of corporate structure and behaviour. This
ventional trade models (see, for instance, OECD, 2013); was already apparent to developmental economists, such as
besides adopting an exclusively supply-side focus on the Paul Streeten, in the 1970s, when the emergence of such
productivity challenge these models tend simply to assume chains first became apparent (Streeten, 1973).
that the package of assets and skills associated with FDI In the context of the contemporary value chain landscape
automatically spillover in to the local economy. Empirical that implies examining the changing corporate strategy of
evidence to support this view is limited (see, for example, lead firms. The underlying corporate rationale for GVCs, par-
Winkler and Farole, 2015). From a development perspective, ticularly in more capital and technology intensive industries,
is that while most industries contain low-skill tasks that are
sensitive to wage costs, they also include intangible tasks
Figure 3. FVA in manufacturing exports and manufacturing value (R&D, design, marketing and branding) based on unique
added; Asia. resources and capabilities that other firms find difficult to
acquire; these are the basis of superior returns (Kaplinsky,
2005) which often take the form of rents1 (UNCTAD, 2017).
On the financial side, a combination of outsourcing and
rent-seeking creates super profits, and because there is less
need for reinvestment in production capacity, those profits
are increasingly devoted to returning shareholder value. This
dynamic is becoming more and more prevalent in the cur-
rent era, which is characterized by growing market concen-
tration and high profitability but little investment and an
emphasis by financialization on turning profits into cash
returns (Milberg and Winkler, 2013).
As mentioned above, GVCs lower barriers to entry at the
bottom of the value chain, making it easier for developing
countries to break into global exports of manufactures than
in the past. However, the conditions that ease access can
also act as barriers to upgrading since more accessible parts
of the value chain are associated with few forward and
backward linkages, limited institutional development, and lit-
Source: UNCTAD TDR 2016. tle possibility for knowledge externalities in the wider

© 2018 University of Durham and John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Global Policy (2019) 10:1
Trade and Industrialization
33

economy. Indeed, technological upgrading can be more dif- capital and high-skilled labour raised from 60.6 to 65.5 per
ficult for economies that are used by TNCs primarily as cent (Table 2).
bases for exports to third markets than for economies where Turning more towards regional markets in the South may
FDI is of the market-seeking, tariff-jumping kind. Since the offer an alternative setting to build more inclusive and sus-
latter form of FDI is more dependent on the domestic econ- tainable industrial activity. East Asian countries, particularly
omy, it gives the host country government greater bargain- South Korea, Taiwan, Singapore but also China – despite its
ing power for using FDI selectively to ensure that it will global reach in terms of exports and imports – have long
create spillovers and linkages with domestic industry in the recognized the importance of the East Asian regional pro-
context of a broader industrialization strategy. Most exam- duction network. Furthermore, in response to the collapse in
ples of successful use of FDI in industrialization and techno- trade after the financial crisis of 2007–08, also several suppli-
logical progress are from countries that have exploited this ers in other developing regions shifted their end markets
advantage effectively.2 from the North to the South in an effort to regionalize their
Developing economies with limited productive capacities supply chains. For instance, South African clothing manufac-
can therefore remain trapped in, and competing for, the turers moved into other countries in sub-Saharan Africa such
lowest value-adding activities at the bottom of value chains, as Lesotho and Swaziland, leading to an expansion of the
which can ultimately result in ‘thin industrialization’ and regional value chain led by South African retailers (Gereffi,
slow economic growth (Gereffi, 2014; UNCTAD 2014). These 2014).
activities are also detrimental from a dynamic perspective Regional value chains (RVCs) can be instrumental in
since they do not generate those local productive capacities, increasing value added in the developing regions. Given the
which are essential to meaningful development. size and productive capacities of many developing coun-
Participation in GVCs also carries the additional risk of tries, a local industrial strategy might quickly reach its limits.
specialization in only a very narrow range of production This can be overcome through a regional perspective as dif-
activities with a concomitantly narrow technological base ferent complementary advantages in the region could be
and overdependence on MNEs for GVCs access (OECD, leveraged and economies of scale, vertical integration and
2013). Such shallow integration also manifests itself in asym- horizontal specialization could be promoted. This is particu-
metric power relations between lead firms and suppliers larly important for smaller countries, which see regional con-
and in weak bargaining positions for developing countries. nections as crucial to complementing their own capacities
For example, the experiences of Mexico and Central Ameri- considering supply-side constraints.
can countries as assembly manufacturers have been likened RVCs are characterized by the end-product being
to the creation of an enclave economy, with few domestic exported by a country within the region, more often to a
linkages. The same can be said about the electronics and regional partner, and with many high value-adding activities
automotive industries in Eastern and Central Europe. In also undertaken within the region. They can therefore signif-
these cases, there has been significant ‘internal upgrading’ icantly contribute to the creation of value at the local level
within MNE affiliates, but this has involved very few spil- and offer more opportunities to participate, gain experience
lovers to the local economies in the form of productivity and build those local capacities needed to compete globally,
improvements and imitation by domestic firms, partly due thus serving as a stepping stone into GVCs (UNCTAD, 2015).
to limited linkages of MNEs with local firms and labour mar- Regional markets might also exhibit better upgrading
kets.3 Moving up the chain into more capital-intensive or
higher value-added production is particularly challenging in
such an environment, because it necessitates relationships Table 2. Factor shares in global value chains of manufactures,
with lead firms at the top that are ultimately focused on by region
maintaining their profitability and flexibility. Indeed, these Value added in value 2008 minus
firms sometimes intentionally use GVCs to induce and inten- chains of manufactures 1995 2008 1995
sify competition among suppliers and countries for their
In high-income countries $4,863 $4,864 $1
own benefit (Phillips and Henderson, 2009).
(billion US$)
Changing corporate behaviour has emerged as a major By:
source of the rising trend in inequality (Stiglitz, 2015)4 and it capital (%) 35.9 38.7 +2.9
seems likely that GVCs have been a (related) contributing high-skilled labour (%) 16.8 21.8 +5
factor to this worrisome trend, both in the advanced and medium-skilled labour (%) 33.3 30.3 3.0
developing countries (UNCTAD, 2016). As shown by Timmer low-skilled labour (%) 14 9.1 4.9
et al. (2013), in fact, we are witnessing a bifurcation in the In other countries (billion US$) $1,723 $3,820 $2,097
By:
factor content of GVCs with increasing capital and high-
capital (%) 55.2 58.4 +3.2
skilled labour income shares matched by declining shares high-skilled labour (%) 5.4 7,1 +1.7
for medium and particularly for low-skilled labour. According medium-skilled labour (%) 15.6 17 +1.4
to their estimates in high-income countries together capital low-skilled labour (%) 23.8 17,5 6.3
and high-skilled labour captured 52.7 per cent of manufac- Worldwide (billion US$) $6,586 $8,684 $2,098
tures value in 1995, increasing to 60.5 per cent in 2008; in
Source: Timmer et al. (2013).
low and middle-income economies, the share accruing to

Global Policy (2019) 10:1 © 2018 University of Durham and John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
Richard Kozul-Wright and Piergiuseppe Fortunato
34

potentials particularly in terms of functional upgrading, structural transformation in the region. Unlike extra-regional
including design, marketing, branding and distribution. trade, intra-regional trade in Africa, although limited in size,
Recent evidence, however, suggests that despite their gravitates around exports of manufactured and more
advantages RVCs are by far less developed than GVCs (Los sophisticated goods such as construction materials and food
et al., 2015).5 As a matter of fact, in the last couple of dec- processing (Fortunato and Valensisi, 2011). Indeed, in 2013,
ades the gap between the two has been widening rather about two-thirds of intra-African trade was in manufactured
than shrinking and, excluding Europe, in all of the world goods (UNECA, 2015). However, intra-African trade has
regions covered by the TiVA dataset the extra regional com- grown only modestly over the past decade and remains sig-
ponent of foreign value addition is significantly higher than nificantly below the share of exports directed towards more
the intra-regional one (Figure 5). Understanding the new developed regions, such as developing Asia and Europe,
markets and the investment and sourcing policies of lead and even Latin America.
firms and buyers selling in these markets will be a key in Raising internal demand, if sustained with adequate policy
the future to foster the expansion RVCs. measures, can in principle support an expansion of intra-
regional trade and production networks. Africa’s rapid
urbanization and its higher (albeit erratic) economic growth
Regional value chains in Southern Africa
since the start of the millennium have underpinned the ris-
Over the past two decades, the shares of Africa’s exports to ing demand for goods and services in the region, particu-
its traditional trading partners – the EU and the United larly from an expanding middle class. This is evident in
States – declined. The EU was the destination for 50 per Southern Africa, where a seven-fold increase in consumption
cent of Africa’s exports in 1995 but only 36 per cent in of high-value processed foods is forecast by 2040 (Tschirley
2013. For the United States, this percentage dropped from et al., 2013). High demand growth in the Southern cone has
15 per cent to 9 per cent over the same period. In the also underpinned the development of RVCs driven by South
meantime, China has emerged as Africa’s largest single trad- Africa’s apparel retail chains, supermarkets and agro-proces-
ing partner, absorbing 16 per cent of Africa’s exports in sing corporations.
2013 and developing countries as a whole now account for This represents a welcome novelty in the regional landscape
46 per cent of Africa’s merchandise exports and 53 per cent since domestic markets are too small to support significant
of its imports, up from 27 per cent and 34 per cent respec- industrial upgrading and scale economies in most Southern
tively, only 15 years earlier (UNECA, 2015). Geographic diver- African countries. As a matter of fact, industrial growth in
sification of Africa’s trade partners has not however been Southern Africa has been lower than in the other parts of the
accompanied by diversification of its exported products: pri- continent since the early 2000s, averaging 4 per cent annual
mary commodities still accounted for 77 per cent of the rate in the period 2000–12. The manufacturing sector, in par-
continent’s merchandise exports over the period 2000–13. ticular, has underperformed, recording an average rate of
Partly as a result of the commodity price boom in the early around 1 per cent. Services are absorbing most of the jobs
2000s, manufacturing sector continued its decline started in moving out of agriculture leaving employment in industry
the 1990s; its share of Africa’s exports decreased from 26 per stagnant at around only 8.4 per cent of the total labour force.
cent in 1995 to 21 per cent in 2004 and to 18 per cent in This hampers development prospects as most services jobs
2014 (Pesce et al., 2015). are informal and display low productivity and wages.
Against this background, intra-African trade and regional Nevertheless, Southern African economies seem well
production networks can be instrumental in increasing the placed for developing value chains at the regional level. As
industrial content of Africa’s exports and ultimately foster shown by UNECA (2015), together with Eastern Africa, the
Southern part of the continent stands out both in terms of
integration and trade complementarity and, indeed, the
Figure 5. Extra- and Intra-regional foreign value-added as % gross
export, 1995-2011.
share of intra-regional trade is higher in SADC than in any
other African Regional Economic Communities (Figure 6).
The potential for the development of value chains in the
region emerges clearly when comparing the pattern of
industrial trade within the SADC area with the industrial
exports directed to outside commercial partners. As docu-
mented in Figure 7, the latter have been steadily decreasing
along the last twenty years and, more importantly, they are
dominated by mining exports which explains almost half of
total industrial exports towards non-SADC economies in
2016. Conversely, agro-industry and labour-intensive manu-
factures (light industry) have been on a decreasing trend
and became marginal during the last decade.
When we look at trade flows within SADC the picture is
undoubtedly rosier; mining industry here plays only a sec-
Source: OECD-WTO TiVA Database. ondary role while agro-industry, light-industry and even

© 2018 University of Durham and John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Global Policy (2019) 10:1
Trade and Industrialization
35

Figure 6. Share of intra- regional exports in African economic communities, 2014.

Source: UNECA (2015).

Figure 7. SADC industrial exports to non-SADC economies.

Source: COMTRADE (2018).

more capital-intensive exports like the one taking place in of all goods exported in the world, where the distance
the machinery and equipment sector have been more between two goods is defined as the probability of export-
prominent over the entire period under scrutiny and ing one of the goods if an economy already exports the
together accounted for almost the 80 per cent of total other. In this framework, structural transformation entails
industrial exports in 2016 (Figure 8). moving from goods that countries already export to others
The ‘special’ condition of the southern cone of the conti- that are close enough, where ‘close enough’ is defined
nent, and the opportunities offered by further integration, based on the knowledge and capabilities needed to pro-
emerge clearly also when we look to the data from the per- duce a certain set of products. This ultimately configures a
spective of the product space literature (Hausmann and Kli- network of products, a sort of map in which economies
ger, 2007 and Hausmann et al., 2007). This literature sees move from one point to another, leading to diversification
production possibilities as a space in which economies and production of increasingly sophisticated goods. There-
move. More specifically, the product space is an illustration fore, mapping a country’s exports in the product space

Global Policy (2019) 10:1 © 2018 University of Durham and John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
Richard Kozul-Wright and Piergiuseppe Fortunato
36

Figure 8. SADC industrial exports to other SADC economies.

Source: COMTRADE (2018).

allows us to study how difficult it can be for that country to countries. The hypothetical country obtained merging the
diversify and succeed in exploiting new production and five different export baskets would export 674 products with
exporting opportunities. RCA below 1 and would not export 18 products. Moreover,
Figure 9 displays all non-exported products and products and more importantly, it would be much better positioned
exported with a revealed comparative advantage (RCA) to exploit existing opportunities for export diversification.
below 16 for five Southern African economies (South Africa, The large increase in the density of products outside the
Tanzania, Mozambique, Mauritius and Zambia) and for a export basket, evident from the figure, suggests the exis-
hypothetical country, resulting from the combination of the tence of complementarities between the productive struc-
five economies. This combination is obtained considering a tures of the five economies. Such complementarities would
‘best case scenario’ in which the RCA for each commodity is create a larger and more diverse pool of resources and
set at the maximum level observed among the five capabilities. This, in turn, would make products relatively clo-
ser, thus facilitating export diversification.7
Recognizing the peculiarities of the region and the impor-
Figure 9. An experiment of regional integration: export opportuni-
ties for a combined group of countries. tance of regional productive integration as a means to revi-
talize the industrial sector and foster economic growth, the
Southern Africa Development Community (SADC) has
recently launched a common industrial strategy with the
goal to promote development of an integrated industrial
base within SADC through the exploitation of regional syn-
ergies in value-added production and enhancement of
export competitiveness, including via collaboration in the
development of regional value chains with targeted inter-
ventions (SADC Industrial Development Policy Framework,
2013–2018).
Whether this initiative will finally succeed or not crucially
relies on the stance of the dominant economy of the region.
South Africa’s history of industrialization, labour policy and
infrastructure development has profoundly influenced the
economic and political relations in neighbouring countries,
and the country continues to dominate in the current con-
Source: UNCTAD (2018). text (Zalk, 2012). Indeed, the significant asymmetries

© 2018 University of Durham and John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Global Policy (2019) 10:1
Trade and Industrialization
37

between South Africa and the remaining economies of the under its presidency, South Africa is now taking the lead in
region might partly explain why the potential trade comple- this process. In fact, the South African Department of Trade
mentarities discussed above have not been exploited fully and Industry, which has a long tradition in using and com-
and failed to become an engine for industrialization. bining different policy tools to strengthen its manufacturing
A prominent example of such a dominance comes from sector and enhance employment, has fully embraced the
the agro-processing sector, where South Africa represents regional perspective and is pushing to put industrial policy
by far the leading exporter and the largest market for pro- at the core of the regional integration agenda.
cessed food. During the last decade, South Africa’s exports Southern Africa’s industrialization will ultimately depend
of processed food recorded a remarkable 18.4 per cent also on the progresses made on the integration agenda
annual growth rate rising from US$273 million to US$1.25 with other African economies. An ambitious agenda which
billion. A great contribution to this large increase in exports has been progressing fast along the last decade, but much
was made by the expansion of South African-owned super- work remains to be done. The COMESA-EAC-SADC Tripartite
markets across the region. Promoting partnerships between Free Trade Area (TFTA), for example, which brings together
supermarkets chains and domestic new processors would 26 African countries, and 58 per cent of the continent’s
favour a more equilibrated distribution of benefits in the GDP, was signed in 2015 and ratified already by 22 coun-
region, but unfortunately attempts in this direction are only tries. Bringing together countries which already belong to
at an embryonal stage. different trade regimes is not an easy task however; for
Oilseeds, animal feed and poultry, is undoubtedly one of many tariff lines negotiations are still undergoing and liber-
the chains with the highest potential in the sector (Pare- alization is expected to take place only over the next 5 to
moer, 2018). Indeed, many South African poultry producers 8 years (UNECA, 2015).
have already established operations in other SADC member The TFTA negotiations have taken place alongside negoti-
states and significantly increased investment into down- ations for the Continental Free Trade Area (CFTA) which
stream activities. Upstream integration, on the contrary, is were finally launched in March 2018. Before the agreement
absent and South Africa is still importing the soya oilcake can become operational, however, member states need to
needed for poultry feed from Argentina despite the capaci- submit their schedules of commitments for goods and ser-
ties existing in other SADC economies. High intra-regional vices and to work on the harmonization of rules of origin
transport costs are certainly responsible for this paradoxical across the various regional economic communities. This pro-
situation, but problems are exacerbated by the pervasive cess is proceeding slowly since member countries prioritize
informational asymmetries and lack of transparency different sectors and negotiations are therefore proceeding
which increase the search cost faced by small suppliers and in parallel on multiple fronts. The leadership of the largest
transporters. economies of the region, such as South Africa, Nigeria and
Another significant barrier in regional food markets is rep- Kenya, will be on crucial importance to untangle this knot.
resented by health standards and product specifications
which limit the ease with which products can be traded
Industrial policy to turn GVCs into drivers of
across borders as they undergo multiple testing procedures
development
in different countries. The East African Community is
addressing this constraint through a coordinated Standards Today’s policy makers can no longer expect export-led pro-
Harmonization and Conformity Testing Programme. After its duction and trade of manufactures that fuelled industrializa-
first 2 years, the programme reported a 59 per cent reduc- tion in the East Asian tigers to produce similar outcomes.
tion in testing costs and a 74 per cent reduction in average Indeed, as noted earlier, targeting the growth of export-
testing time in the region. An independent analysis on the oriented manufactures or increasing participation in GVCs
benefits of a similar programme within the SADC region linked to manufacturing offers neither automatic nor
should be undertaken, particularly with reference to highly straightforward pathways to industrialization and develop-
traded products (like edible oils, sugar and processed food). ment. This does not imply that countries should no longer
South Africa is also leading in the mining equipment sec- seek export markets. Rather, a more strategic approach is
tor, particularly in mineral processing and deep mining. As a needed in which countries are more selective in their
matter of fact, the great majority of the original equipment choices of processes, products and markets since both the
manufacturers (OEMs) operating in the region are based in composition of export-oriented manufactures – the more
South Africa to supply the regional market and include both technologically intensive and sophisticated the better – and
South African OEMs and global OEMs. Unless a regional the share of domestic value added determines whether
approach to the regulation and oversight of RVCs is and to what extent exporting will induce structural change
adopted, there is an ongoing concern that these firms will and productivity growth (Fortunato and Razo, 2014).
capture most of the value created in the emerging chains The type of participation in GVCs is crucial in this respect.
with only limited trickle-down effects on the other econo- Countries able to develop productive capacities in sync with
mies of the region. those needed by international production networks, and
A promising indication for the future is that, while the ini- position themselves at a relatively high level in the world
tiative on the regional industrial strategy was taken by Zim- distribution of tasks, should be well placed to sustain a
babwe that successfully put industry on the SADC agenda more inclusive growth process. However, from an industrial

Global Policy (2019) 10:1 © 2018 University of Durham and John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
Richard Kozul-Wright and Piergiuseppe Fortunato
38

policy perspective, simply complying with the demands of bolster regional trade and productive integration in support
lead firms in these chains is unlikely to facilitate the emer- of structural transformation. The East Asian experience has
gence of the kind of industrial base necessary for sustained been a notable example of successful regional integration,
growth and inclusive development. There is a little evidence and the economies of the region are now negotiating an
of technological and other spillovers from MNEs in the ambitious mega-regional trade agreement (Bown,
absence of effective government bargaining and policy 2017).Other developing regions have established a large
measures, even when greenfield investments have involved number of sub-regional trade agreements, but progress on
a fuller range of industrial activities, and evidence of the ground in the form of substantially larger intra-region
upgrading within value chains is equally elusive. A ‘develop- trade flows and productive integration has been limited.
mental state’ has therefore still a critical role to play espe- As discussed in this paper, a promising strategy to exploit
cially in favouring the emergence of a vibrant industrial the benefits of regional integration and support an ambi-
base, robust local markets and a dynamic enterprise sector tious development agenda focusing on productive capacity
(Kozul-Wright and Fortunato, 2015; UNCTAD, 2016). building and structural transformation centres on the devel-
The selection of the relevant sectors and industries for opment of RVCs. The success of such a strategy, however,
industrial policy support varies from country to country relies on the capacity of developing countries to provide an
according to their pre-existing areas of strengths and poten- environment conducive to RVCs participation and that
tial for upgrading, dynamic comparative advantage and, in would make domestic firms competitive along these chains;
the larger economies, creation of national champions that it also relies on ensuring that the benefits of RVCs translate
can become major players in the international markets. In into a domestic development by activating linkages across
South America, Brazil, a country with an already large indus- different productive sectors and trickling down to most of
trial base, prioritizes sectors such as capital goods, electron- the population. This in turn requires the adoption of a vast
ics and pharmaceuticals, while Uruguay, a small country in set of strategic policy measures both at the domestic and at
the same region, is promoting biotechnology, ICTs and cul- the regional level.
tural industries, but also the automotive industry within a Active cooperation among governments to identify and
broader framework of regional productive integration, in prioritize entry points into value chains and exploit regional
recognition of the limitations imposed by its small domestic complementarities is of crucial importance. This often
market. requires coordinating policy measures in different domains
New industrial policies are evolving over time, embodying to avoid mutual damages; in Southern Africa, for example,
some but not all characteristics of successful development the use of protective measures in Tanzania (on sunflower
strategies of the past, showing the ability to adapt both to oil) and in Zambia (on soya oil) is weakening the potential
technological changes and to local conditions and circum- for cooperation in agro-processing. Facilitating connections
stances (Andreoni and Chang, 2016). Trade and investment between firms operating in different countries at different
agreements at the bilateral, regional and multilateral levels parts of the chain is equally important; this obviously
have restricted policy space in some key areas (Wade, 2003; implies infrastructural investments to curb physical transport
UNCTAD, 2014) while the slowdown in developed countries, costs but also easing border restrictions, harmonizing test-
and the possibility that they have entered a period of secu- ing and certification systems and developing regional trad-
lar stagnation, is constraining export possibilities to these ing platforms for different commodities to facilitate price
economies. Accordingly, developing countries must design discovery.
their industrial policies in this more constrained environ- In order to maximize the developmental impact of RVCs
ment and respond to it through the adoption of innovative participation, however, standard trade facilitation policies
policies – or policy tools less subject to restrictions by inter- are not enough. Depending on the specificities of the coun-
national agreements–and by exploring new pathways for try (and the chain) under exam, a vast array of policies can
industrial development. be devised to facilitate the diffusion and the trickling down
The experience of Vietnam after its accession to WTO, fol- of the benefits associated with participation to production
lowed by a reduction in the simple average tariff rate from networks. Setting-up rapid development zones or free indus-
18.5 per cent in 2007 to 10.4 per cent in 2013, may serve to trial areas in those regions where natural resources are con-
illustrate this point. Vietnam has indeed made an effective centrated, for example, would favour private investment,
use of some of the flexibilities still allowed under WTO rules facilitate resource exploitation and upstream participation to
and commitments. The difference between bound and value chains, and potentially benefits also firms not operat-
applied tariff rates, for example, allowed the modulation of ing directly in resource extraction.
applied tariffs with a view to controlling energy prices and Finally, on the consumer’s side, it is particularly important
protecting certain industries from import competition. In to mitigate the potential negative impact of price changes
addition, the country managed to provide sectoral support on low-income households. In the SADC area, for example,
in several forms and to sustain R&D and infrastructure devel- the idea to promote small-scale, renewable energy-based
opment in disadvantaged areas of the country through sub- systems that can contribute to electricity security by turning
sidized loans and investment guarantees. consumers into self-producers is currently under examina-
Given the new constraints in the external environment, tion. But ensuring a fair distribution of benefits will ulti-
South–South cooperation is opening new opportunities to mately depend on the degree of inclusiveness of the

© 2018 University of Durham and John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Global Policy (2019) 10:1
Trade and Industrialization
39

governance structures and on the inclusion of local commu- References


nities and stakeholders (like labour unions and civil society
organizations) in the decision-making process. This is of Andreoni, A. and Chang, H.-J. (2016) ‘Industrial Policy and the Future of
Manufacturing’, Journal of Industrial and Business Economics, 43 (4),
course very challenging from a political point of view since pp. 491–502.
it would require an internal consensus in the host country Balassa, B. (1977) ‘Revealed Comparative Advantage Revisited: An
about the devolution of bargaining power to local commu- Analysis of Relative Export Shares of the Industrial Countries, 1953–
-vis central authorities) along with the embracing
nities (vis-a 1971’, The Manchester School of Economic and Social Studies, 45 (4),
of a shared decision-making process by part of the involved pp. 327–344.
MNEs. Barldwin, R. (2016) The Great Convergence: Information Technology and
the New Globalization. Harvard: University Press.
Bernanke, B. S. (2004) ‘The Great Moderation’. Paper presented at the
Notes meetings of the Eastern Economic Association, Washington, DC.
Available from: https://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/
1. Rents may be broadly defined as income derived solely from the
2004/20040220/ [Accessed 12 March 2018].
ownership and control of assets or from a dominant market position,
Bown, C. P. (2017) ‘Mega-regional Trade Agreements and the Future of
rather than from innovative entrepreneurial activity or the productive
the WTO’, Global Policy, 8 (1), pp. 107–112.
deployment of a scarce resource.
Dollar, D., Inomata, S., Degain, C., Meng, B., Wang, Z., Ahmad, N. et al.
2. One interesting counter example is the case of Singapore. The
(2017) Global Value Chains Development Report 2017: Measuring and
country has very proactively built its economy as an export plat-
Analyzing the Impact of GVCs on Economic Development. Washington,
form for manufacturing production since the 1970s, still it suc-
DC: Brookings Institution.
ceeded in building globally competitive local enterprises and in
Enos, J. and Park, W.-H. (1988) The Adoption and Diffusion of Imported
creating linkages between transnational corporations and local
Technology. London: Croom.
enterprises.
Fortunato, P. and Razo, C. (2014) ‘Export Sophistication, Growth and the
3. Industrial policy is crucial to activate spillovers. Enos and Park (1988)
Middle-Income Trap’, in I. N€ ubler, J.M. Salazar-Xirinachs and R. Kozul-
present an interesting case study. In the 1970s the governments of
Wright (eds.), Transforming Economies: Making Industrial Policy Work
South Korea, Hong Kong and Chile ordered the same kind of ethy-
for Growth, Jobs and Development. Geneva: International Labour
lene plant from Dow Chemicals. However, South Korea pressed Dow
Office and UNCTAD, pp. 267–287.
much harder to employ Koreans across the several stages of the pro-
Fortunato, P. and Valensisi, G. (2011) ‘Regional Trade Integration and
ject and the ratio of nationals to international Dow employees
Development Opportunities: Some Evidence from Africa’, Trade
increased in the subsequent plants Korea ordered from Dow.
Negotiations Insights, 6 (10), pp. 8–9.
4. As documented also in UNCTAD (2017), increasing market concentra-
Gereffi, G. (2014) ‘Global Value Chains in a Post-Washington Consensus
tion and rents, augmented through specific policy measures, have
World’, Review of International Political Economy, 21 (1), pp. 9–37.
helped to boost profits at the expense of wages and exacerbated
Gereffi, G., Humphrey, J., Kaplinsky, R. and Sturgeon, T. (2001)
inequality.
‘Globalisation, Value Chains and Development’, IDS Bulletin, 32 (3),
5. Technically, GVCs are identified by the country where the last
pp. 1–8.
stage of production takes place before the product is sold. In this
Hanson, G. H. (2005) ‘Comment’, in Moran, T. H., Graham, E. M. and
context, FVA is defined as the value added generated outside the
Blomstrom, M. (eds.), Does Foreign Direct Investment Promote
country-of-completion. To distinguish between RVCs and GVCs one
Development?. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.
can split the FVA into a regional (RFVA) and a global component
Hausmann, R., Hwang, J. and Rodrik, D. (2007) ‘What You Export
(GFVA). Where RFVA comprises all foreign value added generated
Matters’, Journal of Economic Growth, 12 (1), pp. 1–25.
in the region to which the country-of-completion belongs, while
Hausmann, R. and Kliger, B. (2007) ‘The Structure of the Product Space and
GFVA includes all value added contributed by all countries outside
the Evolution of Comparative Advantage’, CID Working Paper, No. 146.
the region.
Center for International Development, Harvard University.
6. We use the notion of RCA introduced by Balassa (1977), according to
Helleiner, G. K. (1973) ‘Manufactured Exports from Less-developed
which a country j has a comparative advantage in product k if the
Countries and Multinational Firms’, Economic Journal, 83 (329), pp.
share of this product within the country’s export basket is larger than
21–47.
the share of this product in the global market (RCA > 1),
Kaplinsky, R. (2005) Globalization, Poverty and Inequality: Between a Rock
P and a Hard Place. Cambridge, MA: Polity Press.
XjK = jk Xjk
RCAjk ¼ P PP Kozul-Wright, R. and Fortunato, P. (2015) ‘Sustaining Industrial
jk XjK = j k Xjk Development in the South’, Development, 58 (4), pp. 463–472.
Los, B., Timmer, M. P. and de Vries, G. (2015) ‘How Global Are Global
where Xjk is the value of exports by country j of good k. This defini-
Value Chains? A New Approach to Measure International
tion of RCA allows us to set a threshold for a country’s exports. When
Fragmentation’, Journal of Regional Science, 55 (1), pp. 66–92.
RCAjk is greater or equal to 1, we say that country j is an effective
Milberg, W. and Winkler, D. (2013) Outsourcing Economics: Global Value
exporter of product k, and when RCAjk<1 we say that country j is not
Chains in Capitalist Development. New York: Cambridge University Press.
an effective exporter of that product. We consider only those prod-
Myrdal, G. (1957) Economic Theory and Under-developed Regions.
ucts with RCA below 1 since we are interested in exploring the new
London: G. Duckworth.
export possibilities for the 5 economies under exam.
OECD (2013) Interconnected Economies: Benefiting from Global Value
7. How these benefits would be distributed among the five econo-
Chains – Synthesis Report. Paris: OECD.
mies, i.e. whether the initial asymmetries would generate concen-
Paremoer, T. (2018) Regional Value Chains: Exploring Linkages and
tration of production in one or two leading countries, and
Opportunities in the Agro-Processing Sector across five SADC
whether such an increase in exports would generate capital and
countries’, UNCTAD (forthcoming).
labour flows into the region to the detriment of the neighbouring
Pesce, O., Karingi, S. and Gebretensaye, I. (2015) ‘Global Growth Trade
countries, along the lines of a Myrdal backwash effect (Myrdal,
Prospects: An African Perspective’, in B., Hoekman (ed.), A Global
1957), are important questions that would deserve further research
Trade Slowdown: A New Normal. London: CEPR Press, pp. 279–302.
in the future.

Global Policy (2019) 10:1 © 2018 University of Durham and John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
Richard Kozul-Wright and Piergiuseppe Fortunato
40

Phillips, R. and Henderson, J. (2009) ‘Global Production Networks and Winkler, D. and Farole, T. (2015) Global Value Chain Integration and
Industrial Upgrading: Negative Lessons from Malaysian Electronics’, Productivity: Evidence from Enterprise Surveys in Namibia, South Africa,
Austrian Journal of Development Studies, 25 (2), pp. 38–61. and Swaziland. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Stiglitz, J. (2015) Rewriting the Rules of the American Economy: An Wolf, M. (2011) ‘In the Grip of a Great Convergence’, Financial Times.
Agenda for Growth and Shared Prosperity. New York: W. W. Norton World Bank (2017) Sustainable Value Chains and Inclusive Growth, in The
and Company. Inclusive Growth and Development Report 2017. Geneva: World
Streeten, P. (1973) Trade Strategies for Development. London: Macmillan. Economic Forum.
Timmer, M. P., Los, B., Rand, S. and de Vries, G. (2013) ‘Fragmentation, WTO, Fung Global Institute and Nanyang Technological University
Incomes and Jobs. An Analysis of European Competitiveness’, (2013) Global Value Chains in a Changing World. Geneva: World
Economic Policy, 28 (76), pp. 613–661. Trade Organization.
Tschirley, D., Haggblade, S. and Reardon, T. (2013) ‘Africa’s Emerging Zalk, N. (2012) ‘South African Post-Apartheid Policies Towards
Food Transformation’ White Paper Global Center for Food Systems Industrialisation: Tentative Implications for Other African Countries’,
Innovation, Michigan State University and USAID. in A. Noman, K. Bothchwey, H. Stein and J. E. Stiglitz (eds.), Good
UNCTAD (2014) Trade and Development Report 2014: Global Governance Growth and Governance in Africa: Rethinking Development Strategies,
and Policy Space for Development. New York: United Nations. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 345–371.
UNCTAD (2015) Global Value Chains and South-South Trade. New York:
United Nations.
UNCTAD (2016) Trade and Development Report, 2016: Structural Author Information
Transformation for Inclusive and Sustained Growth. New York: United
Richard Kozul-Wright is Director of the Division of Globalisation and
Nations.
Development Strategies of the United Nations Conference on Trade and
UNCTAD (2017) Trade and Development Report, 2017: Beyond austerity:
Development (UNCTAD) and former leading author of the World Eco-
Towards a Global new Deal. New York: United Nations.
nomic and Social Survey at UNDESA. He has published extensively on a
UNCTAD (2018) Structural Transformation and Export Diversification in
wide range of development policy issues.
Southern Africa. New York: United Nations.
UNECA (2015) Economic Report on Africa 2015: Industrializing through Piergiuseppe Fortunato is an economist at UNCTAD where he is
Trade. New York: United Nations. responsible for projects on structural transformation, industrial policy
Wade, R. (2003) ‘What Strategies are Viable for Developing Countries and Global Value Chains. He also worked at UNDESA and was an Assis-
Today? The WTO and the Shrinking of Development Space’, Review tant Professor at the University of Bologna. He has published exten-
of International Political Economy, 10 (4), pp. 621–644. sively on economic development and political economics.

© 2018 University of Durham and John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Global Policy (2019) 10:1

You might also like