Download as docx, pdf, or txt
Download as docx, pdf, or txt
You are on page 1of 21

The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical

Investigation
By DARON ACEMOGLU, SIMON JOHNSON, AND JAMES A. ROBINSON*

We exploit differences in European mortality rates to estimate the effect of institutions on economic
performance. Europeans adopted very different colonization policies in different colonies, with different
associated institutions. In places where Europeans faced high mortality rates, they could not settle and were
more likely to set up extractive institutions. These institutions persisted to the present. Exploiting differences
in European mortality rates as an instrument for current institutions, we estimate large effects of institutions
on income per capita. Once the effect of institutions is controlled for, countries in Africa or those closer to the
equator do not have lower incomes. (JEL 011, P16, P51)

What are the fundamental causes of the large At some level it is obvious that institutions matter.
differences in income per capita across countries? Witness, for example, the divergent paths of North
Although there is still little consensus on the and South Korea, or East and West Germany,
answer to this question, differences in institutions where one part of the country stagnated under
and property rights have received considerable central planning and collective ownership, while
attention in recent years. Countries with better the other prospered with private property and a
"institutions," more secure property rights, and less market economy. Nevertheless, we lack reliable
distortionary policies will invest more in physical estimates of the effect of institutions on economic
and human capital, and will use these factors more performance. It is quite likely that rich economies
efficiently to achieve a greater level of income (e.g., choose or can afford better institutions. Per-haps
Douglass C. North and Robert P. Thomas, 1973; Eric more important, economies that are different for a
L. Jones, 1981; North, 1981). This view receives variety of reasons will differ both in their
some support from cross-country correlations institutions and in their income per capita.
between measures of property rights and
economic development (e.g., Stephen Knack and
Philip Keefer, 1995; Paulo Mauro, 1995; Robert E.
Hall and Charles I. Jones, 1999; Dani Rodrik, 1999),
and from a few micro studies that investigate the
relationship between property rights and
investment or output (e.g., Timothy Besley, 1995;
Christopher Mazingo, 1999; Johnson et al., 1999).

* Acemoglu: Department of Economics, E52-380b, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Cambridge, MA 02319, and Canadian
Institute for Advanced Research (e-mail: daron@mit.edu); Johnson: Sloan School of Man-agement, Massachusetts Institute of
Technology, Cam-bridge, MA 02319 (e-mail: sjohnson@mit.edu); Robinson: Department of Political Science and Department of Eco-
nomics, 210 Barrows Hall, University of California, Berke-ley, CA 94720 (e-mail: jamesar@socrates.berkeley.edu). We thank Joshua
Angrist, Abhijit Banerjee, Esther Duflo, Stan Engerman, John Gallup, Claudia Goldin, Robert Hall, Chad Jones, Larry Katz, Richard Locke,
Andrei Shleifer, Ken Sokoloff, Judith Tendler, three anonymous referees, and seminar participants at the University of California-
Berkeley, Brown University, Canadian Insti-tute for Advanced Research, Columbia University, Har-vard University, Massachusetts
Institute of Technology, National Bureau of Economic Research, Northwestern University, New York University, Princeton University,
University of Rochester, Stanford University, Toulouse University, University of California-Los Angeles, and the World Bank for useful
comments. We also thank Robert McCaa for guiding us to the data on bishops' mortality
To estimate the impact of institutions on (potential) settler mortality -> settlements 
economic performance, we need a source of early institutions -> current institutions ->
exogenous variation in institutions. In this current performance
paper, we propose a theory of institutional
We use data on the mortality rates of soldiers,
differences among countries colonized by
bishops, and sailors stationed in the colonies
Europeans,' and exploit this theory to derive a
be-tween the seventeenth and nineteenth
possible source of exogenous variation. Our
centuries, largely based on the work of the
theory rests on three premises:
historian Philip D. Curtin. These give a good
1. There were different types of colonization indication of the mortality rates faced by
policies which created different sets of settlers. Europeans were well informed about
institutions. At one extreme, European these mortality rates at the time, even though
powers set up "extractive states," exemplified they did not know how to control the diseases
by the Belgian colonization of the Congo. that caused these high mortality rates. Figure
These institutions did not introduce much 1 plots the logarithm of GDP per capita today
protection for private property, nor did they against the logarithm of the settler mortality
provide checks and balances against rates per thousand for a sample of 75
government expropriation. In fact, the main countries (see below for data details). It
purpose of the extractive state was to transfer shows a strong negative relationship.
as much of the resources of the colony to the Colonies where Europeans faced higher
colonizer. At the other extreme, many mortality rates are to-day substantially poorer
Europeans mi-grated and settled in a number than colonies that were healthy for
of colonies, creating what the historian Alfred Europeans. Our theory is that this relationship
Crosby (1986) calls "Neo-Europes."The reflects the effect of settler mortality working
settlers tried to replicate European through the institutions brought by
institutions, with strong emphasis on private Europeans. To substantiate this, we regress
property and checks against government cur-rent performance on current institutions,
power. Primary examples of this include and instrument the latter by settler mortality
Australia, New Zealand, Canada, and the rates. Since our focus is on property rights
United States. and checks against government power, we
use the protection against "risk of
2. The colonization strategy was influenced
expropriation "index from Political Risk
by the feasibility of settlements. In places
Services as a proxy for institutions. This
where the disease environment was not
variable measures differences in institutions
favorable to European settlement, the cards
originating from different types of states and
were stacked against the creation of Neo-
state policies.3 There is a strong (first-stage)
Europes, and the formation of the extractive
relationship between settler mortality rates
state was more likely.
and current institutions, which is interesting
3. The colonial state and institutions persisted in its own right. The regression shows that
even after independence. Based on these mortality rates faced by the settlers more than
three premises, we use the mortality rates 100 years ago explains over 25 percent of the
expected by the first European settlers in the variation in current institutions.4 We also
colonies as an instrument for current document that this relationship works through
institutions in these countries.2 More the channels we hypothesize: (potential)
specifically, our theory can be schematically settler mortality rates were a major
summarized as determinant of settlements; settlements were
a major determinant of early institutions (in
practice, institutions in 1900); and there is a
strong correlation between early institutions fact lower than, the annual mortality rates of
and institutions to-day. Our two-stage least- British troops serving in Britain, which were
squares estimate of the effect of institutions approximately 15 in 1,000. In contrast, the
on performance is relatively precisely mortality rates of British troops serving in
estimated and large. For example, it implies these colonies were much higher because of
that improving Nigeria's institutions to the their lack of immunity. For example,
level of Chile could, in the long run, lead to mortality rates in Bengal and Madras for
as much as a 7-fold increase in Nigeria's British troops were be-tween 70 and 170 in
income (in practice Chile is over 11 times as 1,000. The view that the disease burden for
rich as Nigeria). indigenous adults was not unusual in places
like Africa or India is also supported by the
FIGURE 1. REDUCED-FORM
relatively high population densities in these
RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN INCOME
places before Europeans arrived (Colin
AND SETTLER MORTALITY
McEvedy and Richard Jones, 1975).
The exclusion restriction implied by our
We document that our estimates of the effect
instrumental variable regression is that,
of institutions on performance are not driven
conditional on the controls included in the
by outliers. For example, excluding Australia,
regression, the mortality rates of European
New Zealand, Canada, and the United States
settlers more than 100 years ago have no
does not change the results, nor does
effect on GDP per capita today, other than
excluding Africa. Interestingly, we show that
their effect through institutional development.
once the effect of institutions on economic
The major concern with this exclusion
performance is con-trolled for, neither
restriction is that the mortality rates of settlers
distance from the equator nor the dummy for
could be correlated with the current disease
Africa is significant. These results suggest
environment, which may have a direct effect
that Africa is poorer than the rest of the world
on economic performance. In this case, our
not because of pure geographic or cultural
instrumental-variables estimates may be
factors, but because of worse institutions.
assigning the effect of diseases on income to
institutions. We believe that this is unlikely to The validity of our approach-i.e., our
be the case and that our exclusion restriction exclusion restriction-is threatened if other
is plausible. The great majority of European factors correlated with the estimates of settler
deaths in the colonies were caused by malaria mortality affect income per capita. We adopt
and yellow fever. Although these dis-eases two strategies to substantiate that our results
were fatal to Europeans who had no are not driven by omitted factors. First, we
immunity, they had limited effect on investigate whether institutions have a
indigenous adults who had developed various comparable effect on income once we control
types of immunities. These diseases are for a number of variables potentially
therefore unlikely to be the reason why many correlated with settler mortality and
countries in Africa and Asia are very poor economic outcomes. We find that none of
today (see the discussion in Section III, these overturn our results; the estimates
subsection A). This notion is supported by the change remarkably little when we include
mortality rates of local people in these areas. controls for the identity of the main colonizer,
For example, Curtin (1968 Table 2) reports legal origin, climate, religion, geography,
that the annual mortality rates of local troops natural re-sources, soil quality, and measures
serving with the British army in Bengal and of ethnolinguistic fragmentation.
Madras were respectively 11 and 13 in 1,000. Furthermore, the results are also robust to the
These numbers are quite comparable to, in inclusion of controls for the current disease
environment (e.g., the prevalence of malaria, Our argument is most closely related to work
life expectancy, and infant mortality) and the on the influence of colonial experience on
current fraction of the population of European institutions. Frederich A. von Hayek (1960)
descent. argued that the British common law tradition
was superior to the French civil law, which
Naturally, it is impossible to control for all
was developed during the Napoleonic era to
possible variables that might be correlated
restrain judges' interference with state
with settler mortality and economic
policies (see also Seymour M. Lipset, 1994).
outcomes. Furthermore, our empirical
More recently, Rafael La Porta et al. (1998,
approach might capture the effect of settler
1999) emphasize the importance of colonial
mortality on economic performance, but
origin (the identity of the colonizer) and legal
working through other channels. We deal
origin on current institutions, and show that
with these problems by using a simple over
the common-law countries and former British
identification test using measures of
colonies have better property rights and more
European migration to the colonies and early
developed financial markets. Similarly, David
institutions as additional instruments. We
Landes (1998 Chapters 19 and 20) and North
then use over identification tests to detect
et al. (1998) argue that former British
whether settler mortality has a direct effect on
colonies prospered relative to former French,
current performance. The results are
Spanish, and Portuguese colonies because of
encouraging for our approach; they generate
the good economic and political institutions
no evidence for a direct effect of settler
and culture they inherited from Britain. In
mortality on economic outcomes.
contrast to this approach which focuses on
We are not aware of others who have pointed the identity of the colonizer, we emphasize
out the link between settler mortality and the conditions in the colonies. Specifically, in
institutions, though scholars such as William our theory-and in the data-it is not the identity
H. McNeill (1976), Crosby (1986), and Jared of the colonizer or legal origin that matters,
M. Diamond (1997) have discussed the but whether European colonialists could
influence of diseases on human history. safely settle in a particular location: where
Diamond (1997), in particular, emphasizes they could not settle, they created worse
comparative development, but his theory is institutions. In this respect, our argument is
based on the geographical determinants of the closely related to that of Stanley L. Engerman
incidence of the Neolithic revolution. He and Kenneth L. Sokoloff (1997) who also
ignores both the importance of institutions emphasize institutions, but link them to factor
and the potential causes of divergence in endowments and inequality.
more recent development, which are the main
Empirically, our work is related to a number
focus of our paper. Work by Ronald E.
of other attempts to uncover the link between
Robinson and John Gallagher (1961), Lewis
institutions and development, as well as to
H. Gann and Peter Duignan (1962), Donald
Graziella Bertocchi and Fabio Canova (1996)
Denoon (1983), and Philip J. Cain and
and Robin M. Grier (1999), who investigate
Anthony G. Hopkins (1993) emphasizes that
the effect of being a colony on postwar
settler colonies such as the United States and
growth. Two papers deal with the
New Zealand are different from other
endogeneity of institutions by using an
colonies, and point out that these differences
instrumental variables approach as we do
were important for their economic success.
here. Mauro (1995) instruments for
Nevertheless, this literature does not develop
corruption using ethnolinguistic frag-
the link between mortality, settlements, and
mentation. Hall and Jones (1999), in turn, use
institutions
distance from the equator as an instrument for
social infrastructure because, they argue, Section IV presents our main results. Section
latitude is correlated with "Western V investigates the robust-ness of our results,
influence," which leads to good institutions. and Section VI concludes.
The theoretical reasoning for these
instruments is not entirely convincing. It is
not easy to argue that the Belgian influence in
the Congo, or Western influence in the Gold
Coast during the era of slavery promoted
good institutions. Ethnolinguistic I. THE HYPOTHESIS AND
fragmentation, on the other hand, seems HISTORICAL
endogenous, especially since such BACKGROUND
fragmentation almost completely disappeared
in Europe during the era of growth when a We hypothesize that settler mortality affected
centralized state and market emerged (see, settlements; settlements affected early
e.g., Eugen J. Weber, 1976; Benedict institutions; and early institutions persisted
Anderson, 1983). Econometrically, the and formed the basis of current institutions.
problem with both studies is that their In this section, we discuss and substantiate
instruments can plausibly have a direct effect this hypothesis. The next subsection discusses
on performance. For example, William the link be-tween mortality rates of settlers
Easterly and Ross Levine (1997) argue that and settlement decisions, then we discuss
ethnolinguistic fragmentation can affect differences in colonization policies, and
performance by creating political instability, finally, we turn to the causes of institutional
while Charles de Montesquieu [1748] (1989) persistence.
and more recently David E. Bloom and
A. Mortality and Settlements
Jeffrey D. Sachs (1998) and John Gallup et
al. (1998) argue for a direct effect of climate There is little doubt that mortality rates were
on performance. If, indeed, these variables a key determinant of European settlements.
have a direct effect, they are invalid Curtin (1964, 1998) documents how both the
instruments and do not establish that it is British and French press informed the public
institutions that matter. The advantage of our of mortality rates in the colonies. Curtin
approach is that conditional on the variables (1964) also documents how early British
we already control for, settler mortality more expectations for settlement in West Africa
than 100 years ago should have no effect on were dashed by very high mortality among
output today, other than through its effect on early settlers, about half of whom could be
institutions. Interestingly, our results show expected to die in the first year. In the
that distance from the equator does not have "Province of Freedom" (Sierra Leone),
an independent effect on economic European mortality in the first year was 46
performance, validating the use of this percent, in Bulama (April 1792-April 1793)
variable as an instrument in the work by Hall there was 61-percent mortality among
and Jones (1999). Europe-ans. In the first year of the Sierra
Leone Company (1792-1793), 72 percent of
The next section outlines our hypothesis and
the European settlers died. On Mungo Park's
provides supporting historical evidence.
Second Expedition (May-November 1805),
Section II presents OLS regressions of GDP
87 percent of Europeans died during the
per capita on our index of institutions.
overland trip from Gambia to the Niger, and
Section III de-scribes our key instrument for
all the Europeans died before completing the
institutions, the mortality rates faced by
expedition.
potential settlers at the time of colonization.
An interesting example of the awareness of of land and live-stock was well established
the disease environment comes from the Pil- very early ..." (p. 35).
grim fathers. They decided to migrate to the
When the establishment of European-like
United States rather than Guyana because of
institutions did not arise naturally, the settlers
the high mortality rates in Guyana (see
were ready to fight for them against the
Crosby, 1986 pp. 143-44). Another example
wishes of the home country. Australia is an
comes from the Beauchamp Committee in
interesting example here. Most of the early
1795, set up to decide where to send British
settlers in Australia were ex-convicts, but the
convicts who had previously been sent to the
land was owned largely by ex-jailors, and
United States. One of the leading proposals
there was no legal protection against the
was the island of Lemane, up the Gambia
arbitrary power of land-owners. The settlers
River. The committee rejected this possibility
wanted institutions and political rights like
because they decided mortality rates would
those prevailing in England at the time. They
be too high even for the convicts. Southwest
demanded jury trials, freedom from arbitrary
Africa was also rejected for health reasons.
arrest, and electoral representation. Although
The final decision was to send convicts to
the British government resisted at first, the
Australia.
settlers argued that they were British and
The eventual expansion of many of the deserved the same rights as in the home
colonies was also related to the living country (see Robert Hughes, 1987). Cain and
conditions there. In places where the early Hopkins write (1993 p. 237) "from the late
settlers faced high mortality rates, there 1840s the British bowed to local pressures
would be less incentive for new settlers to and, in line with observed constitutional
come changes taking place in Britain herself,
accepted the idea that, in mature colonies,
B. Types of Colonization and
governors should in future form ministries
Settlements
from the majority elements in elected
The historical evidence supports both the legislatures." They also suggest that "the
notion that there was a wide range of enormous boom in public investment after
different types of colonization and that the 1870 [in New Zealand] ... was an attempt to
presence or absence of European settlers was build up an infrastructure.... to maintain high
a key determinant of the form colonialism living standards in a country where voters
took. Historians, including Robinson and expected politicians actively to promote their
Gallagher (1961), Gann and Duignan (1962), economic welfare." (p. 225).6
Denoon (1983), and Cain and Hopkins
This is in sharp contrast to the colonial
(1993), have documented the development of
experience in Latin America during the
"settler colonies," where Europeans settled in
seventeenth and eighteenth centuries, and in
large numbers, and life was modeled after the
Asia and Africa during the nineteenth and
home country. Denoon (1983) emphasizes
early twentieth centuries. The main objective
that settler colonies had representative
of the Spanish and the Portuguese
institutions which promoted what the settlers
colonization was to obtain gold and other
wanted and that what they wanted was
valuables from America. Soon after the
freedom and the ability to get rich by
conquest, the Spanish crown granted rights to
engaging in trade. He argues that "there was
land and labor (the encomienda) and set up a
undeniably something capitalist in the
complex mercantilist system of monopolies
structure of these colonies. Private ownership
and trade regulations to extract resources
from the colonies. 7
Europeans developed the slave trade in Africa cash crops to be sold to and distributed by the
for similar reasons. Before the mid-nineteenth state at con-trolled prices." Jean-Philippe
century, colonial powers were mostly Peemans (1975) calculates that tax rates on
restricted to the African coast and Africans in the Congo approached 60 percent
concentrated on monopolizing trade in slaves, of their income during the 1920's and 1930's.
gold, and other valuable commodities-witness Bogumil Jewsiewicki (1983) writes that
the names used to describe West African during the period when Leopold was directly
countries: The Gold Coast, the Ivory Coast. in charge, policy was "based on the violent
Thereafter, colonial pol-icy was driven in part exploitation of natural and human resources,"
by an element of super-power rivalry, but with a consequent "destruction of economic
mostly by economic motives. Michael and social life ... [and] ... dismemberment of
Crowder (1968 p. 50), for example, notes "it political structures."
is significant that Britain's largest colony on
Overall, there were few constraints on state
the West Coast [Nigeria] should have been
power in the non-settler colonies. The
the one where her traders were most active
colonial powers set up authoritarian and
and bears out the contention that, for
absolutist states with the purpose of
Britain ... flag followed trade."8 Lance E.
solidifying their control and facilitating the
Davis and Robert A. Huttenback (1987 p.
extraction of resources. Young (1994 p. 101)
307) conclude that "the colonial Empire
quotes a French official in Africa: "the
provides strong evidence for the belief that
European commandant is not posted to
government was at-tuned to the interests of
observe nature, ... He has a mission ... to
business and willing to divert resources to
impose regulations, to limit individual
ends that the business com-munity would
liberties..., to collect taxes." Manning (1988
have found profitable. "They find that before
p. 84) summarizes this as: "In Europe the
1885 investment in the British empire had a
theories of representative democracy won out
return 25 percent higher than that on
over the theorists of absolutism.... But in
domestic investment, though afterwards the
Africa, the European conquerors set up
two converged. Andrew Roberts (1976 p.
absolutist governments, based on reasoning
193) writes: "[from] ... 1930 to 1940 Britain
similar to that of Louis XIV."
had kept for itself 2,400,000 pounds in taxes
from the Copperbelt, while Northern There is a variety of historical evidence, a s
Rhodesia received from Britain only 136,000 well as our regressions in Table 3 below,
pounds in grants for development." Similarly, suggesting that the control structures set up in
Patrick Manning (1982) estimates that the non-settler colonies during the colonial
between 1905 and 1914, 50 percent of GDP era persisted, while there is little doubt that
in Dahomey was extracted by the French, and the institutions of law and order and private
Crawford Young (1994 p. 125) notes that tax property established during the early phases
rates in Tunisia were four times as high as in of colonialism in Australia, Canada, New
France. Zealand, the United States, Hong Kong, and
Singapore have formed the basis of the
Probably the most extreme case of extraction
current-day institutions of these countries.9
was that of King Leopold of Belgium in the
Congo. Gann and Duignan (1979 p. 30) argue Young emphasizes that the extractive
that following the example of the Dutch in institutions set up by the colonialists persisted
Indonesia, Leopold's philosophy was that "the long after the colonial regime ended. He
colonies should be exploited, not by the writes "al-though we commonly described the
operation of a market economy, but by state independent polities as 'new states,' in reality
intervention and compulsory cultivation of
they were successors to the colonial regime, elite. When this elite is small, each
inheriting its structures, its quotidian routines member would have a larger share of
and practices, and its more hidden normative the revenues, so the elite may have a
theories of governance" (1994 p. 283). An greater incentive to be extractive. In
example of the persistence of extractive state many cases where European powers
institutions into the independence era is set up authoritarian institutions, they
provided by the persistence of the most dele-gated the day-to-day running of
prominent extractive policies. In Latin the state to a small domestic elite.
America, the full panoply of monopolies and This narrow group often was the one
regulations, which had been created by Spain, to control the state after
remained intact after independence, for most independence and favored extractive
of the nineteenth century. Forced labor institutions. 10
policies persisted and were even intensified (3) If agents make irreversible
or reintroduced with the expansion of export investments that are complementary
agriculture in the latter part of the nineteenth to a particular set of institutions, they
century. Slavery persisted in Brazil until will be more willing to support them,
1886, and during the sisal boom in Mexico, making these institutions persist (see,
forced labor was reintroduced and persisted e.g., Acemoglu, 1995). For example,
up to the start of the revolution in 1910. agents who have invested in human
Forced labor was also reintroduced in and physical capital will be in favor
Guatemala and El Salvador to provide labor of spending money to enforce
for coffee growing. In the Guatemalan case, property rights, while those who have
forced labor lasted until the creation of less to lose may not be.
democracy in 1945. Similarly, forced labor
TABLE1 -DESCRIPTIVSET ATISTICS
was reinstated in many independent African
countries, for example, by Mobutu in Zaire. II. INSTITUTIONS AND
PERFORMANCE: OLS ESTIMATES
There are a number of economic mechanisms
that will lead to institutional persistence of A. Data and Descriptive Statistics
this type. Here, we discuss three possibilities.
Table 1 provides descriptive statistics for the
(1) Setting up institutions that place key variables of interest. The first column is
restrictions on government power and for the whole world, and column (2) is for our
enforce property rights is costly (see, base sample, limited to the 64 countries that
e.g., Acemoglu and Thierry Verdier, were ex-colonies and for which we have
1998). If the costs of creating these settler mortality, protection against
institutions have been sunk by the expropriation risk, and GDP data (this is
colonial powers, then it may not pay smaller than the sample in Figure 1). The
the elites at independence to switch GDP per capita in 1995 is PPP adjusted (a
to extractive institutions. In contrast, more detailed discussion of all data sources is
when the new elites inherit extractive provided in Appendix Table Al). Income
institutions, they may not want to (GDP) per capita will be our measure of
incur the costs of introducing better economic outcome. There are large
institutions, and may instead prefer to differences in income per capita in both the
exploit the existing extractive world sample and our basic sample, and the
institutions for their own benefits. standard deviation of log income per capita in
(2) The gains to an extractive strategy both cases is 1.1. In row 3, we also give
may depend on the size of the ruling output per worker in 1988 from Hall and
Jones (1999) as an alternative measure of we report the mean and standard deviation of
income today. Hall and Jones (1999) prefer constraints on the executive in the first year
this measure since it explicitly refers to of independence (i.e., the first year a country
worker productivity. On the other hand, given enters the Gurr data set) as an alternative
the difficulty of measuring the for-mal labor measure of institutions. The second-to-last
force, it may be a more noisy measure of row gives the fraction of the population of
economic performance than income per European descent in 1900, which is our
capita. measure of European settlement in the
colonies, constructed from McEvedy and
We use a variety of variables to capture
Jones (1975) and Curtin et al. (1995). The
institutional differences. Our main variable,
final row gives the logarithm of the baseline
re-ported in the second row, is an index of
settler mortality estimates; the raw data are in
protection against expropriation. These data
Appendix Table A2.
are from Political Risk Services (see, e.g.,
William D. Coplin et al., 1991), and were The remaining columns give descriptive
first used in the economics and political statistics for groups of countries at different
science literatures by Knack and Keefer quartiles of the settler mortality distribution.
(1995). Political Risk Services reports a value This is useful since settler mortality is our
between 0 and 10 for each country and year, instrument for institutions (this variable is
with 0 corresponding to the lowest protection described in more detail in the next section).
against expropriation. We use the average
B. Ordinary Least-Squares
value for each country between 1985 and
Regressions
1995 (values are missing for many countries
before 1985). This measure is appropriate for Table 2 reports ordinary least-squares (OLS)
our purposes since the focus here is on regressions of log per capita income on the
differences in institutions originating from protection against expropriation variable in a
different types of states and state policies. We variety of samples. The linear regressions are
expect our notion of extractive state to for the equation (1)
correspond to a low value of this index, while
'
the tradition of rule of law and well-enforced log y i=μ+ α Ri γ + ε i
property rights should correspond to high
values.11 The next row gives an alternative where yi is income per capita in country i, Ri
measure, constraints on the executive in is the protection against expropriation
1990, coded from the Polity III data set of measure, Xi is a vector of other covariates,
Ted Robert Gurr and associates (an update of and ei is a random error term. The coefficient
Gurr, 1997). Results using the constraints on of interest throughout the paper is a, the
the executive and other measures are reported effect of institutions on income per capita.
in Acemoglu et al. (2000) and are not Column (1) shows that in the whole world
repeated here. sample there is a strong correlation between
The next three rows give measures of early our measure of institutions and income per
institutions from the same Gurr data set. The capita. Column (2) shows that the impact of
first is a measure of constraints on the the institutions variable on income per capita
executive in 1900 and the second is an index in our base sample is quite similar to that in
of democracy in 1900. This information is not the whole world, and Figure 2 shows this
available for countries that were still colonies relationship diagrammatically for our base
in 1900, so we assign these countries the sample consisting of 64 countries. The R2 of
lowest possible score. In the following row, the regression in column (1) indicates that
over 50 percent of the variation in income per (approximately 145 percent) poorer even
capita is associated with variation in this after taking the effect of institutions into
index of institutions. To get a sense of the account. Finally, in columns (7) and (8), we
magnitude of the effect of institutions on repeat our basic regressions using the log of
performance, let us compare two countries, output per worker from Hall and Jones
Nigeria, which has approximately the 25th (1999), with very similar results.
percentile of the institutional measure in this
Overall, the results in Table 2 show a strong
sample, 5.6, and Chile, which has
correlation between institutions and economic
approximately the 75th percentile of the
performance. Nevertheless, there are a
institutions index, 7.8. The estimate in
number of important reasons for not
column (1), 0.52, indicates that there should
interpreting this relationship as causal. First,
be on average a 1.14- log-point difference
rich economies may be able to afford, or
between the log GDPs of the corresponding
perhaps prefer, better institutions. Arguably
countries (or approximately a 2-fold
more important than this reverse causality
difference-e1 . 14- 1 2.1). In practice, this
problem, there are many omit-ted
GDP gap is 253 log points (approximately 1-
determinants of income differences that will
fold). Therefore, if the effect estimated in
naturally be correlated with institutions.
Table 2 were causal, it would imply a fairly
Finally, the measures of institutions are
large effect of institutions on performance,
constructed ex post, and the analysts may
but still much less than the actual income gap
have had a natural bias in seeing better
between Nigeria and Chile.
institutions in richer places. As well as these
TABLE 2-OLS REGRESSIONS problems introducing positive bias in the
OLS estimates, the fact that the institutions
Many social scientists, including
variable is measured with consider-able error
Montesquieu [1784] (1989), Diamond (1997),
and corresponds poorly to the "cluster of
and Sachs and coauthors, have argued for a
institutions" that matter in practice creates
direct effect of climate on performance, and
attenuation and may bias the OLS estimates
Gallup et al. (1998) and Hall and Jones
downwards. All of these problems could be
(1999) document the correlation between
solved if we had an instrument for
distance from the equator and economic
institutions. Such an instrument must be an
performance. To control for this, in columns
important factor in accounting for the
(3)-(6), we add latitude as a regressor (we
institutional variation that we observe, but
follow the literature in using the absolute
have no direct effect on performance. Our
value measure of latitude, i.e., distance from
discussion in Section I suggests that settler
the equator, scaled between 0 and 1). This
mortality during the time of colonization is a
changes the coefficient of the index of
plausible instrument.
institutions little. Latitude itself is also
significant and has the sign found by the FIGURE 2. OLS RELATIONSHIP
previous studies. In columns (4) and (6), we BETWEEN EXPROPRIATION RISK AND
also add dummies for Africa, Asia, and other INCOME
continents, with America as the omitted
III. MORTALITY OF EARLY
group. Although protection against
SETTLERS
expropriation risk remains significant, the
continent dummies are also statistically and A. Sources of European Mortality in
quantitatively significant. The Africa dummy the Colonies
in column (6) indicates that in our sample
African countries are 90 log points
In this subsection, we give a brief overview The more recent books on malariology
of the sources of mortality facing potential confirm this conclusion. For example, "In
settlers. Malaria (particularly plasmodium stable endemic areas a heavy toll of
falciparum) and yellow fever were the major morbidity and mortality falls on young
sources of European mortality in the colonies. children but malaria is a relatively mild
In the tropics, these two diseases accounted condition in adults" (Herbert M. Gilles and
for 80 percent of European deaths, while David A. Warrell, 1993 p. 64; see also the
gastrointestinal diseases accounted for classic reference on this topic, Leonard J.
another 15 percent (Curtin, 1989 p. 30). Bruce-Chwatt, 1980 Chapter 4; Roy Porter,
Throughout the nineteenth century, areas 1996).12 Similarly, the World Health
without malaria and yellow fever, such as Organization (WHO) points out that in
New Zealand, were more healthy than Europe endemic malaria areas of Africa and the
because the major causes of death in Europe- Western Pacific today "... the risk of malaria
tuberculosis, pneumonia, and small-pox-were severity and death is almost exclusively
rare in these places (Curtin, 1989 p. 13). limited to non-immunes, being most serious
for young children over six months of age...
Both malaria and yellow fever are transmit-
surviving children develop their own
ted by mosquito vectors. In the case of
immunity between the age of 3-5 years" (Jose
malaria, the main transmitter is the
A. Najera and Joahim Hempel, 1996).
Anopheles gambiae complex and the
mosquito Anophelesfunestus, while the main People in areas where malaria is endemic are
carrier of yellow fever is Aedes aegypti. Both also more likely to have genetic immunity
malaria and yellow fever vectors tend to live against malaria. For example, they tend to
close to human habitation. In places where have the sickle-cell trait, which discourages
the malaria vector is present, such as the the multiplication of parasites in the blood, or
West African savanna or forest, an individual deficiencies in glucose-6-phosphate
can get as many as several hundred infectious dehydrogenase and thalassemia traits, which
mosquito bites a year. For a person without also protect against malaria. Porter (1996 p.
immunity, malaria (particularly Plasmodium 34) writes: "In such a process..., close to 100
falciporum) is often fatal, so Europeans in percent of Africans acquired a genetic trait
Africa, India, or the Caribbean faced very that protects them against vivax malaria and
high death rates. In contrast, death rates for probably against falciparum malaria as well."
the adult local population were much lower Overall, the WHO estimates that malaria kills
(see Curtin [1964] and the discussion in our about 1 million people per year, most of them
introduction above). Curtin (1998 pp. 7-8) children. It does not, how-ever, generally kill
describes this as follows: adults who grew up in malaria-endemic areas
(see Najera and Hempel, 1996).
Children in West Africa ... would be infected
with malaria parasites shortly after birth and Although yellow fever' s epidemiology is
were frequently reinfected after-wards; if quite different from malaria, it was also much
they lived beyond the age of about five, they more fatal to Europeans than to non-
acquired an apparent immunity. The parasite Europeans who grew up in areas where
remained with them, normally in the liver, yellow fever commonly occurred.13 Yellow
but clinical symptoms were rare so long as fever leaves its surviving victims with a
they continued to be infected with the same lifelong immunity, which also explains its
species of P. falciporum. epidemic pattern, relying on a concentrated
nonimmune population. Curtin (1998 p. 10)
writes: "Because most Africans had passed
through a light case early in life, yellow fever the late nineteenth century that Europeans
in West Africa was a strangers' disease, started to control these diseases.14
attacking those who grew up else-where."
These considerations, together with the data
Similarly, Michael B. A. Oldstone (1998 p.
we have on the mortality of local people and
49) writes:
population densities before the arrival of
Most Black Africans and their descendants Europeans, make us believe that settler
respond to yellow fever infection with mild to mortality is a plausible instrument for
moderate symptoms such as headache, fever, institutional development: these diseases
nausea, and vomiting, and then recover in a affected European settlement patterns and the
few days. This out-come reflects the long type of institutions they set up, but had little
relationship be-tween the virus and its effect on the health and economy of
indigenous hosts, who through generations of indigenous people.15
exposure to the virus have evolved resistance.
A final noteworthy feature, helpful in
In contrast, fatality rates among nonimmune interpreting our results below, is that malaria
adults, such as Europeans, could be as high as prevalence depends as much on the
90 percent. microclimate of an area as on its temperature
and humidity, or on whether it is in the
Advances in medical science have reduced
tropics; high altitudes reduce the risk of
the danger posed by malaria and yellow
infection, so in areas of high altitude, where
fever. Yellow fever is mostly eradicated
"hill stations" could be set up, such as Bogota
(Oldstone, 1998 Chapter 5), and malaria has
in Colombia, mortality rates were typically
been eradicated in many areas. Europeans
lower than in wet coastal areas. However,
developed methods of dealing with these
malaria could sometimes be more serious in
diseases that gradually became more effective
high-altitude areas. For example, Curtin
in the second half of the nineteenth century.
(1989 p. 47) points out that in Ceylon
For example, they came to understand that
mortality was lower in the coast than the
high doses of quinine, derived from the
highlands because rains in the coast washed
cinchona bark, acted as a prophylactic and
away the larvae of the transmitter
prevented infection or reduced the severity of
mosquitoes. Similarly, in Madras many
malaria. They also started to undertake
coastal regions were free of malaria, while
serious mosquito eradication efforts and
northern India had high rates of infection.
protect themselves against mosquito bites.
Curtin (1998 Chapter 7) also illustrates how
Further, Europeans also learned that an often
there were marked differences in the
effective method of reducing mortality from
prevalence of malaria within small regions of
yellow fever is flight from the area, since the
Madagascar. This suggests that mortality
transmitter mosquito, Aedes aegypti, has only
rates faced by Europeans are unlikely to be a
a short range. Nevertheless, during much of
proxy for some simple geographic or
the nineteenth century, there was almost a
climactic feature of the country.
complete misunderstanding of the nature of
both diseases. For example, the leading B. Data on Potential Settler Mortality
theory for malaria was that it was caused by
Our data on the mortality of European set-
"miasma" from swamps, and quinine was not
tlers come largely from the work of Philip
used widely. The role of small collections of
Curtin. Systematic military medical record
water to breed mosquitoes and transmit these
keeping began only after 1815, as an attempt
diseases was not understood. It was only in
to understand why so many soldiers were
dying in some places. The first detailed stud-
ies were retrospective and dealt with British also provides estimates of mortality in naval
forces between 1817 and 1836. The United squadrons for different regions which we can
States and French governments quickly use to generate alternative estimates of
adopted similar methods (Curtin, 1989 pp. 3, mortality in South America. Appendix B in
5). Some early data are also available for the Acemoglu et al. (2000), which is available
Dutch East Indies. By the 1870's, most Euro- from the authors, gives a detailed discussion
pean countries published regular reports on of how these data are constructed, and
the health of their soldiers. Appendix Table A5 (available from the
authors), shows that these alternative methods
The standard measure is annualized deaths
produce remarkably sim-ilar results.
per thousand mean strength. This measure
Appendix Table A2 lists our main estimates,
reports the death rate among 1,000 soldiers
and Table Al gives information about
where each death is replaced with a new
sources.
soldier. Curtin (1989, 1998) reviews in detail
the construction of these estimates for IV. INSTITUTIONS AND
particular places and campaigns, and assesses PERFORMANCE: IV RESULTS
which data should be considered reliable.
A. Determinants of Current Institutions
Curtin (1989), Death by Migration, deals Equation
primarily with the mortality of European
(1) describes the relationship be-tween
troops from 1817 to 1848. At this time mod-
current institutions and log GDP. In addition,
ern medicine was still in its infancy, and the
we have
European militaries did not yet understand
how to control malaria and yellow fever.
These mortality rates can therefore be
interpreted as reasonable estimates of settler
mortality. They are consistent with
substantial evidence from other sources (see,
for example, Curtin [1964, 1968]). Curtin
(1998), Dis-ease and Empire, adds similar
data on the mortality of soldiers in the second where R is the measure of current institutions
half of the nineteenth century. 16 In all cases, (protection against expropriation between
we use the earliest available number for each 1985 and 1995), C is our measure of early
country, reasoning that this is the best (circa 1900) institutions, S is the measure of
estimate of the mortality rates that settlers European settlements in the colony (fraction
would have faced, at least until the twentieth of the population with European descent in
century. 1900), and M is mortality rates faced by
settlers. X is a vector of covariates that affect
The main gap in the Curtin data is for South all variables.
America since the Spanish and Portuguese
militaries did not keep good records of The simplest identification strategy might be
mortality. Hector Gutierrez (1986) used to use Si (or Ci) as an instrument for Ri in
Vatican records to construct estimates for the equation (1), and we report some of these
mortality rates of bishops in Latin America regressions in Table 8. However, to the extent
from 1604 to 1876. Because these data that settlers are more likely to migrate to
overlap with the Curtin estimates for several richer areas and early institutions reflect other
countries, we are able to construct a data characteristics that are important for income
series for South America.17 Curtin (1964) today, this identification strategy would be
invalid (i.e., Ci and Si could be correlated
with sk). Instead, we use the mortality rates MORTALITY AND EXPROPRIATION
faced by the settlers, log Mi, as an instrument RISK
for Ri. This identification strategy will be
Both constraints on the executive and
valid as long as log Mi is uncorrelated with ei
democracy indices assign low scores to
- that is, if mortality rates of settlers between
countries that were colonies in 1900, and do
the seventeenth and nineteenth centuries have
not use the earliest post-independence
no effect on income today other than through
information for Latin American countries and
their influence on institutional development.
the NeoEuropes. In columns (5) and (6), we
We argued above that this exclusion
adopt an alternative approach and use the
restriction is plausible.
constraints on the executive in the first year
Figure3 illustrates the relationship between of independence and also control separately
the (potential) settler mortality rates and the for time since independence. The results are
index of institutions. We use the logarithm of similar, and indicate that early institutions
the settler mortality rates, since there are no tend to persist.
theoretical reasons to prefer the level as a
Columns (7) and (8) show the association be-
determinant of institutions rather than the log,
tween protection against expropriation and
and using the log ensures that the extreme
European settlements. The fraction of
African mortality rates do not play a
Europeans in 1900 alone explains
disproportionate role. As it happens, there is
approximately3 0 percent of the variation in
an almost linear relationship between the log
our institutions variable today. Columns (9)
settler mortality and our measure of
and (10) show the relationship between the
institutions. This relationship shows that ex-
protection against expropriation variable and
colonies where Europeans faced higher
the mortality rates faced by settlers. This
mortality rates have substantially worse
specification will be the first stage for our
institutions today.
main two-stage least-squares estimates
In Table 3, we document that this relationship (2SLS). I t shows that settler mortality alone
works through the channels hypothesized in explains 27 percent of the differences in
Section I. In particular, we present OLS institutions we observe today.
regressions of equations (2), (3), and (4). In
Panel B of Table 3 provides evidence in
the top panel, we regress the protection
support of the hypothesis that early
against expropriation variable on the other
institutions were shaped, at least in part, by
variables. Column (1) uses constraints faced
settlements, and that settlements were
by the executive in 1900 as the regressor, and
affected by mortality. Columns (1)-(2) and
shows a close association between early
(5)-(6) relate our measure of constraint on the
institutions and institutions today. For
executive and democracy in 1900 to the
example, past institutions alone explain 20
measure of European settlements in 1900
percent of the variation in the index of current
(fraction of the population of European
institutions. The second column adds the
decent). Columns (3)-(4) and (7)-(8) relate
latitude variable, with little effect on the
the same variables to settler mortality. These
estimate. Columns (3) and (4) use the
regressions show that settlement patterns
democracy index, and confirm the results in
explain around 50 percent of the variation in
columns (1) and (2).
early institutions. Finally, columns (9) and
FIGURE 3. FIRST-STAGE (10) show the relation-ship between
RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN SETTLER settlements and mortality rates.
B. Institutions and Economic Does the 2SLS estimate make quantitative
Performance sense? Does it imply that institutional
differences can explain a significant fraction
Two-stage least-squares estimates of equa-
of income differences across countries? Let
tion (1) are presented in Table 4. Protection
us once again compare two "typical"
against expropriation variable, Ri, is treated
countries with high and low expropriation
as endogenous, and modeled as
risk, Nigeria and Chile (these countries are
typical for the IV regression in the sense that
they are practically on the regression line).
Our 2SLS estimate, 0.94, implies that the
where Mi is the settler mortality rate in 1,000 2.24 differences in expropriation risk between
mean strength. The exclusion restriction is these two countries should translate into 206
that this variable does not appear in (1). log point (approximately7- fold) difference. I
TABLE 3-DETERMINANTS OF n practice, the presence of measurement error
INSTITUTIONS complicates this interpretation, because some
of the difference between Nigeria and Chile's
Panel A of Table 4 reports 2SLS estimates of expropriation index may reflect measurement
the coefficient of interest, a form equation (1) error. Therefore, the 7-fold difference is an
and Panel B gives the corresponding first upper bound. In any case, the estimates in
stages.18 Column (1) displays the strong Table 4 imply a substantial, but not
first-stage relationship between (log) settler implausibly large, effect of institutional
mortality and current institutions in our base differences on income per capita.
sample, also shown in Table 3. The
corresponding 2SLS estimate of the impact of Column (2) shows that adding latitude does
institutions on income per capita is 0.94. This not change the relationship; the institutions
estimate is highly significant with a standard coefficient is now 1.00 with a standard error
error of 0.16, and in fact larger than the OLS of 0.22.20 Remarkably, the latitude variable
estimates reported in Table 2. This suggests now has the "wrong" sign and is insignificant.
that measurement error in the institutions This result suggests that many previous
variables that creates attenuation bias is likely studies may have found latitude to be a
to be more important than reverse causality significant determinant of economic
and omitted variables biases. Here we are performance because it is correlated with
referring to "measurement error" broadly institutions (or with the exogenous
construed. In reality the set of institutions that component of institutions caused by early
matter for economic performance is very colonial experience).
complex, and any single measure is bound to Columns (3) and (4) document that our
capture only part of the "true institutions”, results are not driven by the Neo-Europes.
creating a typical measurement error When we exclude the United States, Canada,
problem. Moreover, what matters for current Australia, and New Zealand, the estimates
income is presumably not only institutions remain highly significant, and in fact increase
today, but also institutions in the past. Our a little. For example, the coefficient for
measure of institutions which refers to 1985- institutions is now 1.28 (s.e. = 0.36) without
1995 will not be perfectly correlated with the latitude control, and 1.21 (s.e. = 0.35)
these. 19 when we control for latitude. Columns (5)
TABLE4 -IV REGRESSIONOSF LOG and (6) show that our results are also robust
GDP PERC APITA to dropping all the African countries from our
sample. The estimates without Africa are
somewhat smaller, but also more precise. For with the inclusion of these variables, and
example, the coefficient for institutions is many variables emphasized in previous work
0.58 (s.e. = 0.1) without the latitude control, become insignificant once the effect of
and still 0.58 (s.e. = 0.12) when we control institutions is controlled for.
for latitude.21
La Porta et al. (1999) argue for the
In columns (7) and (8), we add continent importance of colonial origin (identity of the
dummies to the regressions (for Africa, Asia, main colonizing country) as a determinant of
and other, with America as the omitted current institutions. The identity of the
group). The addition of these dummies does colonial power could also matter because it
not change the estimated effect of might have an effect through culture, as
institutions, and the dummies are jointly argued by David S. Landes (1998). In
insignificant at the 5-percent level, thought he columns (1) and (2) of Table 5, we add
dummy f or Asia is significantly different dummies for British and French colonies
from that of America. The fact that the (colonies of other nations are the omit-ted
African dummy is insignificant suggests that group). This has little effect on our results.
the reason why African countries are poorer Moreover, the French dummy in the first
is not due to cultural or geographic factors, stage is estimated to be zero, while the British
but mostly accounted for by the existence of dummy is positive, and marginally
worse institutions in Africa. Finally, in significant. Therefore, as suggested by La
column (9) we repeat our basic regression Porta et al. (1998), British colonies appear to
using log of output per worker as calculated have better institutions, but this effect is
by Hall and Jones (1999). The result is very much smaller and weaker than in a
close to our baseline result. The 2SLS specification that does not control for the
coefficient is 0.98 instead of 0.94 as in effect of settler mortality on institutional
column (1).22 This shows that whether we development.25 Therefore, it appears that
use income per capita or output per worker British colonies are found to perform
has little effect on our results. Overall, the substantially better in other studies in large
results in Table 4 show a large effect of part because Britain colonized places where
institutions on economic performance. In the settlements were possible, and this made
rest of the paper, we investigate the British colonies inherit better institutions. To
robustness of these results. 3 further investigate this issue, columns (3) and
(4) estimate our basic regression for British
V. ROBUSTNESS
colonies only. They show that both the
A. Additional Controls relationship be-tween settler mortality and
institutions and that between institutions and
The validity of our 2SLS results in Table 4 income in this sample of 25 British colonies
depends on the assumption that settler are very similar to those in our base sample.
mortality in the past has no direct effect on For example, the 2SLS estimate of the effect
current economic performance. Although this of institutions on income is now 1.07 (s.e. =
presumption appears reasonable( at least to 0.24) without controlling for latitude and 1.00
us), here we substantiate it further by directly (s.e. = 0.22) with latitude. These results
controlling for many of the variables that suggest that the identity of the colonizer is
could plausibly be correlated with both settler not an important determinant of colonization
mortality and economic outcomes, and patterns and subsequent institutional
checking whether the addition of these development.
variables affects our estimates.24 Overall, we
find that our results change remarkably little
von Hayek (1960) and La Porta et al. (1999) One might be worried that we are capturing
also emphasize the importance of legal the direct effect of having more Europeans
origin. In columns (5) and (6), we control for (who perhaps brought a "European culture"
legal origin. In our sample, all countries have or special relations with Europe). To control
either French or British legal origins, so we for this, we add the fraction of the population
simply add a dummy for French legal origin of European descent in columns (3) and (4) of
(many countries that are not French colonies Table 6. This variable is insignificant, while
nonetheless have French legal origin). Our the effect of institutions remains highly
estimate of the effect of institutions on significant, with a coefficient of 0.96 (s.e. =
income per capita is unaffected.26 0.28). In columns (5) and (6), we control for
measures of natural resources, soil quality (in
An argument dating back to Max Weber
practice soil types), and for whether the
views religion as a key determinant of
country is landlocked. All these controls are
economic performance. To control for this, in
insignificant, and have little effect on our
columns (7) and (8), we add the fraction of
2SLS estimate of the effect of institutions on
the populations that are Catholic, Muslim,
in-come per capita.
and of other religions, with Protestants as the
omitted group. In the table we report the joint In columns (7) and (8), we include ethno-
significance level (p-value) of the linguistic fragmentation as another control
corresponding F-statistic for these dummies and treat it as exogenous. Now the coefficient
as well as the 2SLS estimate of the effect of of protection against expropriation is 0.74
institutions.27 Finally, column (9) adds all (s.e. = 0.13), which is only slightly smaller
the variables in this table simultaneously. than our baseline estimate. In Appendix A,
Again, these controls have very little effect we show that the inclusion of an endogenous
on our main estimate. variable positively correlated with income or
institutions will bias the coefficient on
TABLE 5-IV REGRESSIONS OF LOG
institutions downwards. Since ethnolinguistic
GDP PER CAPITA WITH ADDITIONAL
fragmentation is likely to be endogenous with
CONTROLS
respect to development (i.e., ethnolinguistic
Another concern is that settler mortality is fragmentation tends to disappear after the
correlated with climate and other geographic formation of centralized markets; see Weber
characteristics. Our instrument may therefore [1976] or Andersen [1983]) and is correlated
be picking up the direct effect of these with settler mortality, the estimate of 0.74
variables. We investigate this issue in Table likely understates the effect of institutions on
6. In columns (1) and (2), we add a set of income. In column (9) of Table 6, we include
temperature and humidity variables (all data all these variables together. Despite the large
from Philip M. Parker, 1997). In the table we number of controls, protection against
report joint significance levels for these expropriation on income per capita is still
variables. Again, they have little effect on our highly significant, with a somewhat smaller
estimates coefficient of 0.71 (s.e. = 0.20), which is
again likely to understate the effect of
TABLE6 -ROBUSTNESS CHECKSF ORI institutions on income because
V REGRESSIONOSF LOG GDP ethnolinguistic fragmentation is treated as
PERCAPITA exogenous.
A related concern is that in colonies where Finally, in Table 7, we investigate whether
Europeans settled, the current population our instrument could be capturing the general
consists of a higher fraction of Europeans. effect of disease on development. Sachs and a
series of coauthors have argued for the (2001) discuss the role of geography and
importance of malaria and other diseases in institutions in determining economic
explaining African poverty (see, for example, performance. They accept our case for the
Bloom and Sachs, 1998; Gallup and Sachs, importance of institutions, but argue that
1998; Gallup et al., 1998). Since malaria was more general specifications show that the
one of the main causes of settler mortality, disease environment and health
our estimate may be capturing the direct characteristics of countries (their
effect of malaria on economic performance. "geography") matter for economic
We are skeptical of this argument since performance. In particular, they extend our
malaria prevalence is highly endogenous; it is work by controlling for life expectancy and
the poorer countries with worse institutions infant mortality, and they also instrument for
that have been unable to eradicate malaria.28 these health variables using geographic
While Sachs and coauthors argue that malaria variables such as latitude and mean
reduces output through poor health, high temperature. Table 7 also expands upon the
mortality, and absenteeism, most people who specifications that McArthur and Sachs sug-
live in high malaria areas have developed gest. Columns (3)-(6) include life expectancy
some immunity to the disease (see the and infant mortality as exogenous controls.
discussion in Section III, sub-section A). The estimates show a significant effect of
Malaria should therefore have little direct institutions on income, similar to, but smaller
effect on economic performance (though, than, our baseline estimates. Infant mortality
obviously, it will have very high social costs). is also marginally significant. Since health is
In contrast, for Europeans, or anyone else highly endogenous, the coefficient on these
who has not been exposed to malaria as a variables will be biased up, while the
young child, malaria is usually fatal, making coefficient of institutions will be biased down
malaria prevalence a key determinant of (see Appendix A). These estimates are
European settlements and institutional therefore consistent with institutions being
development. the major determinant of in-come per capita
differences, with little effect from
In any case, controlling for malaria does not
geography/health variables.
change our results. We do this in columns (1)
and (2) by controlling for the fraction of the TABLE 7-GEOGRAPHY AND HEALTH
population who live in an area where VARIABLES
falciparum malaria is endemic in 1994 (as
Columns (7)-(9) report estimates from
constructed and used by Gallup et al., 1998).
models that treat both health and institutions
Since malaria prevalence in 1994 is highly
as endogenous, and following McArthur and
endogenous, the argument in Appendix A
Sachs, instrument for them using latitude,
implies that control-ling for it directly will
mean temperature, and distance from the
underestimate the effect of institutions on
coast as instruments in addition to our
performance. In fact, the co-efficient on
instrument, settler mortality. McArthur and
protection against expropriation is now
Sachs (2001) report that in these regressions
estimated to be somewhat smaller, 0.69
the institution variable is still significant, but
instead of 0.94 as in Table 4. Nevertheless,
geography/health are also significant. In
the effect remains highly significant with a
contrast to McArthur and Sachs' results, we
standard error of 0.25, while malaria itself is
find that only institutions are significant. This
insignificant.
difference is due to the fact that McArthur
In a comment on the working paper version and Sachs include Britain and France in their
of our study, John W. McArthur and Sachs sample. Britain and France are not in our
sample, which consists of only ex-colonies exogeneity of the others, such as settler
(there is no reason for variation in the mortality. This approach is useful since it is a
mortality rates of British and French troops at direct test of our exclusion restriction.
home to be related to their institutional However, such tests may not lead to a
development). It turns out that once Britain rejection if all instruments are invalid, but
and France are left out, the McArthur and still highly correlated with each other.
Sachs' specification generates no evidence Therefore, the results have to be interpreted
that geography/health variables have an with caution.
important effect on economic performance.29
Overall, the over identification test will reject
As a final strategy to see whether settler the validity of our approach if either (i) the
mortality could be proxying for the current equation of interest, (1), does not have a
disease environment, we estimated models constant coefficient, i.e., log yi = jt + aiRi +
using a yellow fever instrument. This is a si, where i denotes country, or (ii) C or S has
dummy van-able indicating whether the area a direct effect on income per capita, log yi
was ever affected by yellow fever (from (i.e., either S or C is correlated with si), or
Oldstone, 1998; see Appendix Table Al). (iii) settler mortality, M, has an effect on log
This is an attractive alternative strategy yi that works through another variable, such
because yellow fever is mostly eradicated as culture.
today, so this dummy should not be
The data support the over identifying
correlated with the current disease
restrictions implied by our approach.31 This
environment. The disadvantage of this
implies that, subject to the usual problems of
approach is that there is less variation in this
power associated with over identification
instrument than our settler mortality variable.
tests, we can rule out all three of the above
Despite this, the yellow fever results, reported
possibilities. This gives us additional
in columns (10) and (11) of Table 7, are
confidence that settler mortality is a valid
encouraging. The estimate in our base sample
instrument and that we are estimating the
is 0.91 (s.e. = 0.24) comparable to our
effect of institutions on current performance
baseline estimate of 0.95 reported in Table 4.
with our instrumental-variable strategy (i.e.,
Adding continent dummies in column (11)
not capturing the effect of omitted variables).
reduces this estimate slightly to 0.90 (s.e. =
0.32).30 TABLE8 –OVERIDENTIFICATION TESTS
B. Over identification Tests The results of the over identification tests,
and related results, are reported in Table 8. In
We can also investigate the validity of our
the top panel, Panel A, we report the 2SLS
approach by using over identification tests.
estimates of the effect of protection against
Ac-cording to our theory, settler mortality
expropriation on GDP per capita using a
(M) affected settlements (S); settlements
variety of instruments other than mortality
affected early institutions (C); and early
rates, while Panel B gives the corresponding
institutions affected current institutions (R)-
first stages. These estimates are always quite
cf., equations (2), (3), and (4). We can test
close to those reported in Table 4. For
whether any of these variables, C, S, and M,
example, in column (1), we use European
has a direct effect on income per capita, log
settlements in 1900 as the only instrument for
y, by using measures of C and S as additional
institutions. This results in an estimated effect
instruments. The over identification test
of 0.87 (with standard error 0.14), as
presumes that one of these instruments, say S,
compared to our baseline estimate of 0.94.
is truly exogenous, and tests for the
The other columns add latitude, and use other
instruments such as constraint on the argued that differences in colonial experience
executive in 1900 and in the first year of could be a source of exogenous differences in
independence, and democracy in 1900. institutions.
Panel D reports an easy-to-interpret version Our argument rests on the following
of the over identification test. It adds the log premises: (1) Europeans adopted very
of mortality as an exogenous regressor. If different colonization strategies, with
mortality rates faced by settlers had a direct different associated institutions. In one
effect on income per capita, we would expect extreme, as in the case of the United States,
this variable to come in negative and Australia, and New Zealand, they went and
significant. In all cases, it is small and settled in the colonies and set up institutions
statistically insignificant. For example, in that enforced the rule of law and encouraged
column (1), log mortality has a coefficient of investment. In the other extreme, as in the
-0.07 (with standard error 0.17). This Congo or the Gold Coast, they set up
confirms that the impact of mortality rates extractive states with the intention of transfer-
faced by settlers likely works through their ring resources rapidly to the metropole. These
effect on institutions. institutions were detrimental to investment
and economic progress. (2) The colonization
Finally, for completeness, in Panel C we re-
strategy was in part determined by the
port the p-value from the appropriate X^2
feasibility of European settlement. In places
over identification test. This tests whether the
where Europeans faced very high mortality
2SLS coefficients estimated with the
rates, they could not go and settle, and they
instruments indicated in Panels A and B
were more likely to set up extractive states.
versus the coefficients estimated using (log)
(3) Finally, we argue that these early
settler mortality in addition to the "true"
institutions persisted to the present.
instruments are significantly different (e.g., in
Determinants of whether Europeans could go
the first column, the coefficient using
and settle in the colonies, therefore, have an
European settlements alone is compared to
important effect on institutions today. We
the estimate using European settlements and
exploit these differences as a source of
log mortality as instruments). We never reject
exogenous variation to estimate the impact of
the hypothesis that they are equal at the 5-
institutions on economic performance.
percent significance level. So these results
also show no evidence that mortality rates There is a high correlation between mortality
faced by settlers have a direct effect- or an rates faced by soldiers, bishops, and sailors in
effect working through a variable other than the colonies and European settlements;
institutions- on income per capita between European settlements and early
measures of institutions; and between early
VI. CONCLUDING REMARKS
institutions and institutions today. We
Many economists and social scientists believe estimate large effects of institutions on
that differences in institutions and state income per capita using this source of
policies are at the root of large differences in variation. We also document that this
income per capita across countries. There is relationship is not driven by outliers, and is
little agreement, however, about what deter- robust to controlling for latitude, climate, cur-
mines institutions and government attitudes rent disease environment, religion, natural
to-wards economic progress, making it resources, soil quality, ethnolinguistic
difficult to isolate exogenous sources of fragmentation, and current racial
variation in institutions to estimate their composition.
effect on performance. In this paper we
It is useful to point out that our findings do
not imply that institutions today are
predetermined by colonial policies and
cannot be changed. We emphasize colonial
experience as one of the many factors
affecting institutions. Since mortality rates
faced by settlers are arguably exogenous,
they are useful as an instrument to isolate the
effect of institutions on performance. In fact,
our reading is that these results suggest
substantial economic gains from improving
institutions, for example as in the case of
Japan during the Meiji Restoration or South
Korea during the 1960's.
There are many questions that our analysis
does not address. Institutions are treated
largely as a "black box": The results indicate
that reducing expropriation risk (or
improving other aspects of the "cluster of
institutions") would result in significant gains
in income per capita, but do not point out
what concrete steps would lead to an
improvement in these institutions.
Institutional features, such as expropriation
risk, property rights enforcement, or rule of
law, should probably be interpreted as an
equilibrium outcome, related to some more
fundamental "institutions," e.g., presidential
versus parliamentary system, which can be
changed directly. A more detailed analysis of
the effect of more fundamental institutions on
property rights and expropriation risk is an
important area for future study.
APPENDIX A : BIAS IN THE EFFECT OF
INSTITUTIOWNSH ENO THERE
NDOGENOUS VARIABLEASR E
INCLUDED

You might also like