Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 19

Applied Economics

ISSN: 0003-6846 (Print) 1466-4283 (Online) Journal homepage: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/raec20

Effects of transparency, monetary policy signalling


and clarity of central bank communication on
disagreement about inflation expectations

G. C. Montes, L. V. Oliveira, A. Curi & R. T. F. Nicolay

To cite this article: G. C. Montes, L. V. Oliveira, A. Curi & R. T. F. Nicolay (2016) Effects
of transparency, monetary policy signalling and clarity of central bank communication
on disagreement about inflation expectations, Applied Economics, 48:7, 590-607, DOI:
10.1080/00036846.2015.1083091

To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00036846.2015.1083091

Published online: 03 Sep 2015.

Submit your article to this journal

Article views: 241

View related articles

View Crossmark data

Citing articles: 2 View citing articles

Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at


http://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=raec20

Download by: [University of Sussex Library] Date: 22 September 2017, At: 12:16
APPLIED ECONOMICS, 2016
VOL. 48, NO. 7, 590–607
http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00036846.2015.1083091

Effects of transparency, monetary policy signalling and clarity of central bank


communication on disagreement about inflation expectations
G. C. Montesa,b, L. V. Oliveiraa, A. Curia and R. T. F. Nicolaya
a
Department of Economics, Fluminense Federal University, Niterói, Brazil; bResearcher of the National Council for Scientific and
Technological Development (CNPq), Niterói, Brazil

ABSTRACT KEYWORDS
The literature on transparency and central bank communication and the literature on disagree- Transparency;
ment about expectations are evolving; however, both have been evolving separately. Despite the communication; clarity;
advances in the literature, several key issues remain open and there are gaps to be filled. disagreement; central bank
Therefore, this study analyses the effects of monetary policy signalling and clarity of central
JEL CLASSIFICATION
Downloaded by [University of Sussex Library] at 12:16 22 September 2017

bank communication on disagreement about inflation expectations. It also investigates whether


E44; E58; E37
greater transparency coincides with lower levels of disagreement in inflation expectations in
Brazil. The findings suggest that transparency is important to reduce disagreement about infla-
tion expectations. Moreover, our estimates indicate that central bank communication and clarity
affect disagreement about inflation expectations in Brazil.

I. Introduction the same expectation. The literature on disagreement


has discussed issues like its sources, its consequences,
Central bank transparency is a key instrument in
how to measure the phenomenon and how to link
monetary policy-making (Geraats 2002; De Haan,
disagreement with macroeconomic uncertainty
Eijffinger, and Rybiński 2007). The literature high-
(Patton and Timmermann 2010; Dovern, Fritsche,
lights that, if economic agents use all available infor-
and Slacalek 2012; Andrade et al. 2014).
mation when forming their expectations, then
Since the early 2000s, the literature on transpar-
transparency is important because it improves the
ency and central bank communication and the lit-
perception of the public regarding central bank’s
erature on disagreement about expectations are
actions. In this sense, transparency and central bank
evolving; however, both are evolving separately. So
communication play an essential role (Svensson 1999;
far, there are few studies relating transparency with
Blinder et al. 2008; De Mendonça and Galveas 2013).
disagreement about inflation expectations (e.g.,
Although many advances have already been made,
Ehrmann, Eijffinger, and Fratzscher 2010; Siklos
the literature on central bank communication con-
2013). Regarding the literature on the factors deter-
tinues to evolve and studies have been drawing
mining the disagreement in expectations, only one
attention to the importance of clarity of central
study deals at the same time with the influence of
bank communication (Jansen, 2011a; Bulíř, Čihák,
transparency and central bank communication on
and Jansen 2013; Bulíř, Čihák, and Šmídková 2013).
disagreement (Ehrmann, Eijffinger, and Fratzscher
Recently, the key question is: how beneficial are
2010). However, the study developed by Ehrmann,
transparency, monetary policy signalling and the
Eijffinger, and Fratzscher (2010) does not consider
clarity of central bank communication for the expec-
the influence of clarity of central bank communica-
tation formation process?
tion on disagreement. Furthermore, the measures of
In turn, analysing survey data on expectations,
transparency and central bank communication used
either of the general public or professional forecasters,
by the authors are different from those we use in the
it is observed that disagreement in expectations is
present work. Finally, Ehrmann, Eijffinger, and
substantial and varies over time; as stated by
Fratzscher (2010) and Siklos (2013) do not examine
Mankiw, Reis, and Wolfers (2003), not everyone has

CONTACT: G. C. Montes gabrielmontesuff@yahoo.com.br


© 2015 Taylor & Francis
APPLIED ECONOMICS 591

these issues in developing economies adopting the II. Central bank transparency, monetary policy
inflation targeting regime. signalling and clarity of communication
This study analyses the influence of monetary pol-
Central bank transparency and communication play
icy signalling, transparency and clarity of central bank
important roles in the task of managing inflation
communication on disagreement about inflation
expectations, as both can reduce the asymmetric
expectations in Brazil.1 The use of transparency and
information between the central bank and the pub-
central bank communication in emerging economies
lic. According to van der Cruijsen, Eijffinger, and
is not easy. In a general way, these economies have
Hoogduin (2010), transparency improves consensus
weak institutions and have experienced hyperinfla-
across forecasters, anchor inflation expectations and
tions. Therefore, the analysis of the effects caused by
improves policy anticipation.
central bank communication and transparency on
Few works empirically study the relationship
disagreement about inflation expectations is particu-
between transparency and inflation expectations.
larly relevant for emerging economies. This study is
Siklos (2003) shows how the release of inflation
the first to present evidence for these effects in an
reports can influence private sector inflation fore-
Downloaded by [University of Sussex Library] at 12:16 22 September 2017

important inflation targeting emerging economy


casts. His findings indicate that inflation reports help
(Brazil).
to reduce inflation forecast errors. Van der Cruijsen
The study contributes to the literature in the
and, Demertzis (2007) studied the link between
following aspects:
inflation and inflation expectations with central
(1) We analyse the effects of monetary policy
bank transparency. Using data obtained from eight
signalling on disagreement about inflation
industrialized countries, the authors find that infla-
expectations. The analysis makes use of the
tion expectations are better anchored when the cen-
standard approach based on dummy variables
tral bank has a higher degree of transparency.
as proposed by Rosa and Verga (2007).
Once transparency is important to reduce infla-
(2) We analyse the influence of clarity of central
tion and anchor inflation expectations, central bank
bank communication on disagreement about
communication becomes an important tool to
inflation expectations. Thus, following the still
monetary policy. Central bank communication can
incipient literature on the clarity of central
be defined as the provision of information by the
bank communication (Jansen 2011a, 2011b;
central bank to the public regarding present and
Bulíř, Čihák, and Jansen 2013), we use a
future monetary policy, the economic outlook and
well-established statistic from the literature
the goals of the central bank (Blinder et al. 2008). In
on readability, the Flesch (1948) statistic (or
turn, it is impossible to reach a high degree of
the Flesch reading ease score).
transparency and accountability without central
(3) We investigate whether greater transparency
bank communication. Thus, central bank communi-
coincides with lower levels of disagreement in
cation acts in a helpful way since it guides agents’
inflation expectations. The analysis uses the
expectations; therefore, it plays an important role in
two indices of central bank transparency pre-
the decision-making process (Jansen 2011a).
sented by De Mendonça and Galveas (2013).
In the last two decades, the literature on central
We estimate a set of regressions whose dependent
banking has shown empirical evidence for the
variable is a measure of disagreement about inflation
importance of central bank communication in the
expectations. Besides the control variables com-
process by which agents form their expectations. The
monly used in the literature (see Mankiw, Reis, and
main findings suggest that financial markets, equity
Wolfers (2003) and Dovern, Fritsche, and Slacalek
markets and inflation expectations react to monetary
(2012)), we also use other explanatory variables that
policy announcements and signalling (Blinder et al.
capture the effects of transparency, monetary policy
2008).
signalling and the clarity of central bank
The studies regarding the effect of central bank
communication.
communication on inflation expectations are scarcer

1
We consider the expectations formed by financial market experts. According to Ullrich (2008), financial market experts watch the central bank very closely;
we would expect that an influence on their expectation formation is more likely than an influence on expectations of consumers.
592 G. C. MONTES ET AL.

in the literature. Kuttner and Posen (1999) analysed (Kincaid et al. 1975) to measure the clarity. Both
the link between inflation expectations and inflation studies use the Humphrey–Hawkins testimonies.
targeting coupled with more communication in the Jansen (2011a) analysed the effect of clarity over
UK, New Zealand and Canada. The study of Kliesen financial market volatility. The author points out
and Schmid (2004) investigates the influence of sur- three important results: central bank clarity matters,
prises in macroeconomic data releases, monetary it reduces volatility and its effect varies over time. In
policy surprises and central bank communication turn, Jansen (2011b) analysed the difference between
of the Federal Reserve on inflation expectations. Paul Volcker’s and Allan Greenspan’s styles of com-
Their findings suggest that Federal Reserve commu- munication. The results indicate that there is no
nication reduces uncertainty about the future infla- significant difference between the clarity of the two
tion rate, while surprises in monetary policy actions Federal Reserve chairmen.
increase uncertainty about the future path of the Bulíř, Čihák, and Jansen (2013) also measured the
inflation rate. The study of Jansen and De Haan clarity with Flesch (1948) and Kincaid et al. (1975).
(2007) relates central bank communication regard- They examined whether the clarity of central bank
Downloaded by [University of Sussex Library] at 12:16 22 September 2017

ing risks to price stability (measured on the basis of communication about inflation varies with the eco-
the frequency and strength of the keyword ‘vigi- nomic environment in six countries (Chile, Czech
lance’) and break-even inflation in the euro area; Republic, Poland, Sweden, Thailand and the UK)
this work finds a negative relationship between and the euro area. The results suggest that a single
both variables. Ullrich (2008) analysed the informa- model for clarity of central bank communication is
tional content of the monthly introductory state- not appropriate. Rather, when studying the clarity of
ments of the European Central Bank (ECB) communication, country-specific and institution-
president explaining interest rate decisions and specific factors are highly relevant.
their impact on inflation expectations formed by In turn, Bulíř, Čihák, and Šmídková (2013) con-
financial market experts in the euro area. The results structed a clarity index based on the idea that com-
suggest that communication about the path of future munication tools should send consistent signals in
monetary policy helps in explaining inflation order to make communication clearer. The absence
expectations. of ambiguity makes the communication clear. The
The increase in monetary policy communication in index measures ambiguity between an estimated
the past decades has been justified by benefits of policy projection update and the content presented in the
transparency (Čihák 2007; Geraats 2002). Most of the statement. The results indicate that the ECB has
empirical literature on central bank communication accomplished a clear communication between 1999
has focused either on quantitative measures of mone- and 2007.
tary policy transparency or short-term effects of central Considering inflation targeting emerging econo-
bank announcements, with much less attention paid to mies, De Mendonça and Simão Filho (2007) argued
the overall clarity of the communication (Bulíř, Čihák, that central banks with greater transparency contri-
and Jansen 2013). However, an important question bute to decrease both inflation and the interest rate.
arose: does clarity of central bank communication Their findings for the Brazilian economy show that
matter? So far, few studies were developed aiming to an increase in information quality (clarity) brings
answer this question. about a significant change in the speed with which
The clarity of central bank communications refers market expectations evolve. Furthermore, central
to the quality of information provided and the capa- bank transparency contributes to anchor public
city of comprehension the public has regarding what expectations and to affect long-run interest rates.
central bank communicates. Thus, since clearer Moreover, De Mendonça and Simão Filho (2008)
communication is more easily understood (Jansen analysed the impact of transparency at the Central
2011a), it is suggested that clarity of central bank Bank of Brazil (CBB) on macroeconomic variables.
communication reduces the information asymmetry They consider the effects of CBB’s announcements
between central bankers and the public. and publications on several variables that are impor-
Jansen (2011a, 2011b) used the Flesh ease level tant to the inflation targeting system, including
(Flesch 1948) and the Flesh–Kincaid grade level expectations. Their findings suggest that increases
APPLIED ECONOMICS 593

in CBB’s transparency and information quality bring In turn, Ehrmann, Eijffinger, and Fratzscher
about a significant shift in the speed with which (2010) investigated whether and to what extent cen-
market expectations change. tral bank communication and increased transpar-
So far, the studies have focused on the asymmetry ency have affected disagreement among private
between the central bank and the public, but when agents’ forecasts of key macroeconomic variables.
one looks more closely at individual players (fore- The hypothesis is that the reduction in forecast dis-
casters), it is easy to see that there is disagreement in persion should occur if (i) information-related
their expectations. In this sense, do transparency, deviations from the rational expectation assump-
central bank communication and clarity of informa- tions hold, and if (ii) central banks manage to
tion affect this disagreement? increase the signal-to-noise ratio of their public
communication, or alternatively to reduce the cost
of information processing by making relevant pieces
III. Empirical evidence on disagreement in
of information available more readily. They use data
inflation expectations
for seven countries of the European Union (France,
Downloaded by [University of Sussex Library] at 12:16 22 September 2017

The literature on disagreement has investigated this Germany, Italy, the Netherlands, Spain, Sweden and
issue from many angles. Regarding studies based on the UK) and five other countries (Canada, Japan,
time series analysis, one should place extra emphasis Norway, Switzerland and the United States). The
on those seeking to explain disagreement by looking paper finds empirical evidence that the announce-
at the behaviour of potentially relevant macroeco- ment of a quantified inflation objective and
nomic variables – for example, the output gap and enhanced transparency about economic dimensions
the volatility of shocks affecting the economy (e.g., of the conduct of monetary policy – such as the
Mankiw, Reis, and Wolfers (2003) and Dovern, release of the central bank’s internal forecasts of
Fritsche, and Slacalek (2012)). There are also studies inflation and output – are effective in that regard.
aiming to explain disagreement by looking at mone- The reduction in forecast disagreement is not only
tary policy actions and monetary authorities’ char- statistically significant, but also economically impor-
acteristics (e.g., Ehrmann, Eijffinger, and Fratzscher tant. The findings of the paper indicate that this
(2010) and Siklos (2013). The groundbreaking work reduction has been achieved because forecasters in
of Mankiw, Reis, and Wolfers (2003) analyses countries with more transparent and open central
50 years of inflation expectations extracted from banks manage to update their forecasts in response
three different sources.2 The main conclusions of to news in a smoother fashion, generating less
the paper are unveiling the substantial differences disagreement.
in expectations about future inflation among consu- The study of Dovern, Fritsche, and Slacalek
mers and professional economists; furthermore, the (2012) analyses countries forming the G74 and uses
paper shows that disagreement varies significantly data from the period between October 1989 and
over time, being sensitive to the level and the varia- October 2006. The authors investigate the determi-
bility of the inflation rate. nants of disagreement in expectations regarding the
Another important study on this subject was done future behaviour of real variables (GDP, consump-
by Filardo and Guinigundo (2008). The authors use tion, investment and unemployment) and nominal
a database comprised of forecasts prepared by pro- variables (inflation and interest rates). Regarding
fessional forecasters in 12 Asian-Pacific countries.3 disagreement about future inflation, the results
They not only argue that greater transparency leads achieved by panel data analysis show that cross-sec-
to less disagreement about the inflation outlook, but tional dispersion increases with the uncertainty
also suggest that disagreement about inflation expec- inherent to inflation developments. Furthermore,
tations lowers after a country adopts the inflation individual regressions for each country indicate
targeting regime as its monetary policy framework. that disagreement about inflation expectations is

2
The Michigan Survey of Consumer Attitudes and Behaviour, the Livingston Survey and the Survey of Professional Forecasters.
3
Australia, China, Hong Kong, India, Indonesia, Japan, Korea, Malaysia, New Zealand, Philippines, Singapore, Thailand. The primary source is compiled by the
consulting firm Consensus Economics.
4
Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, United Kingdom and United States.
594 G. C. MONTES ET AL.

more sensitive to the inflation level in Italy, Japan thus improves the accuracy of inflation expectations.
and the UK, countries where central banks have The explanation for this is as follows: assuming that
become independent only around the mid-1990s. an increase in central bank transparency reduces the
Finally, Siklos (2013) studied inflation forecast dis- asymmetric information between the central bank
agreement in Australia, Canada, New Zealand, and the public, it is possible to make a connection
Sweden, the UK, Japan, Switzerland, the USA and with the first welfare theorem of economics. Thus,
the euro area. He estimates a model of inflation fore- an increase in central bank transparency increases
cast disagreement which considers the influence of welfare because there is reduction in forecast errors,
central bank transparency. His findings suggest that which comes from a lower uncertainty about central
central bank transparency tends to increase forecast bank preferences.
disagreement. However, he points out that this result
can be explained by the negative consequences of
greater openness (e.g., van der Cruijsen, Eijffinger, V. Data and methodology
and Hoogduin 2010 and Ehrmann, Eijffinger, and
Data
Downloaded by [University of Sussex Library] at 12:16 22 September 2017

Fratzscher 2010) or by the push on the diversity of


views brought about by the provision of information The database contains 143 monthly observations of
to the public; the precise reason is yet unclear. macroeconomic and financial variables, as well as
expectations regarding future inflation. Data are
taken from the period between May 2003 and
IV. Inflation targeting in Brazil: transparency March 2015. The source is the CBB website, in
and central bank communication which researchers and market practitioners can
Brazil adopted the inflation targeting regime in June find information regarding macroeconomic and
1999. Since then, the main task of the CBB has been financial variables,5 as well as expectations about
to guide the public’s expectations towards the infla- the future paths of some key variables.6 Agents can
tion target. In this sense, the CBB has experienced a also find the summaries of COPOM’s discussions,
higher level of transparency and independence of detailed information on economic conditions and
instruments to control inflation and achieve its goals. COPOM’s inflation projections.7
In terms of transparency, according to De In Brazil, the minutes of the COPOM meeting are
Mendonça and Galveas (2013), a good example that the main document of the CBB. They are prepared
CBB transparency has improved is that the Monetary aiming to explain monetary policy decisions and
Policy Committee (COPOM) minutes provide a sum- signal the future intentions of the CBB in relation
mary of the meeting discussion. The minutes are to monetary policy. Regarding COPOM minutes, the
divided into two sections. One section explains the database refers to the first decade of their regular
reasons for the COPOM’s decision. In this section, a publication, which always happens 8 days after the
CBB evaluation on current and future inflation and meeting that decides the basic interest rate (SELIC).
the measures adopted to ensure that the inflation The series used in our analysis are:
target will be reached are presented. The other section
presents a survey that covers the economic environ- Disagreement in inflation expectation (disag)
ment and considers the main points on the first day This series is built upon inflation expectations pro-
of the COPOM’s meeting. vided by the Investor Relations Group (Gerin) of the
According to De Mendonça and Galveas (2013), CBB through the so-called ‘Focus-Market Readout’.8
central bank transparency reduces uncertainty and In order to better understand its construction, it is
5
http://www.bcb.gov.br/?TIMESERIESEN.
6
https://www3.bcb.gov.br/expectativas/publico/consulta/serieestatisticas.
7
http://www.bcb.gov.br/?MINUTES.
8
Focus-Market Readout presents the results of Gerin’s market expectations survey, a daily survey of forecasts of roughly 120 banks, asset managers and other
institutions (real sector companies, brokers, consultancies and others) for the Brazilian economy. The survey of market expectations began in May 1999 as
part of the transition to the inflation targeting system. The survey was created in order to monitor market expectations regarding the main
macroeconomic variables, and improve the inputs for the monetary policy decision-making process. The system calculates sample statistics from the
data gathered in real time, and thereby enables the generation of daily reports for the members of the Board. One of these reports, the Focus-Market
Readout, is published every Monday at the Central Bank website at the internet.
APPLIED ECONOMICS 595

worth presenting the following notation: t is the forecasting horizon does not vary with the passage of
instant of time the projection is made,9 i identifies time. As proposed in the work of Dovern, Fritsche,
the agent who calculates the forecast (i 2 I, where I and Slacalek (2012), the conversion of fixed event
is the set of agents surveyed10), X is the variable to be forecasts into fixed horizon ones is accomplished by
forecasted (in this case, inflation) and Ei,tXa+j repre- applying the formula below:
sents the projection that the ith agent calculates at
12  ðm  1Þ m1
time t about the value that the variable X will take in Et X12ðjþ1Þ ¼ Et Xaþj þ Et Xaþjþ1 ;
the end of year a þ j.11 The average of the distribu- 12 12
tion of expectations calculated by the I agents at time j ¼ 0; 1; 2; 3; . . . ;
t about the value that X will take in the end of year
where m represents the month in which the projec-
a + j is given by EtXa+j = 1/I ∑Ei,tXa+j. In turn,
  tion is made (or the month containing period t) and
Emin
t X
aþj
¼ min Ei;t Xaþj ; i 2 I denotes the mini-
EtX12(j+1) denotes the average of agents’ expectations
mum value of the distribution, while Emax t X
aþj
¼
  about the value that the variable X will take in the
max Ei;t X ; i 2 I denotes its maximum value.
aþj
end of the next 12ðj þ 1Þ months. The same formula
Downloaded by [University of Sussex Library] at 12:16 22 September 2017

The range of the distribution is defined as is used to interpolate minimum and maximum pro-
Dt Xaþj ¼ Emaxt X
aþj
 Emin
t X
aþj 12
. As the CBB does jections, which are inserted into it to calculate the
not provide the expectations reported by each values of the range. In the end of the process, we
agent (turning unfeasible the computation of other derive a term structure of disagreement in expecta-
disagreement measures – e.g. the inter-quartile tions, which is comprised of the ‘vertices’ DtX12,
range), the measure of disagreement that we use DtX24, . . ., etc. As the CBB discloses forecasts for
throughout this article is DtXa+j. the current and the next four years, the formula
Forecasts such as Ei,tXa+j are known as fixed event above can be applied by taking j = 0,1,2,3.
ones because the forecasting horizon varies with the Therefore, we can always interpolate forecasts for
passage of time; indeed, the prospective period of the fixed time horizons of 12, 24, 36 and 48 months.
forecasts made at t for the value that the variable X The procedure described above is performed
will take in the end of year a + j decreases as t pro- daily, allowing us to derive term structures of dis-
gresses within a, the year in which expectations are agreement for each business day. Time series com-
made.13 This pattern of decreasing forecasting hori- prised of daily observations are converted to the
zons as t advances through the year brings about a monthly frequency by calculating monthly averages.
seasonal behaviour in disagreement measures based on The final step is performing a principal component
fixed event forecasts, since expectation dispersion analysis, extracting the first principal component of
tends to decrease as the forecasting horizon shrinks.14 the four time series DtX12, DtX24, DtX36 and DtX48;
It is to avoid the seasonal behaviour inherent to this component is a good proxy for their common
disagreement measures based on fixed event fore- trend. The application of this technique has a long
casts that most articles in the literature (e.g., tradition in the study of conventional yield curves
Mankiw, Reis, and Wolfers 2003; Patton and (Litterman and Scheinkmann 1991), which justifies
Timmermann 2010; Dovern, Fritsche, and Slacalek its application to the term structures that we study
2012) recur to fixed horizon forecasts, in which the here. It also allows filtering out erratic shifts on a

9
This instant is characterized by a specific date, namely, a day d, a month m and a year a.
10
The number of agents in I is I.
11
j = 0: current year; j = 1: next year immediately after the current year; j = 2: two years after the current year; j = 3: three years after the current year; j = 4:
four years after the current year.
12
It is worth mentioning that the Gerin informs to the public only the main statistics of the distributions of expectations, that is, means, medians, minimum
and maximum values, SDs and coefficients of variation.
13
An example could help to clarify this issue. Suppose that an agent, in March 2000, computes his expectation about the value of the inflation rate in the
end of 2000. In this case we can say that the time horizon of the forecast is 10 months because the first 2 months of 2000 have already passed and
inflation figures for January and February are known. By the same line of reasoning, when this agent computes his inflation expectation in September 2000
about the value of the inflation rate at the closing of 2000, the time horizon of his forecast decreases to only 4 months.
14
Indeed, the disagreement measure observed in March 2000 for the value that the inflation rate will take in the end of 2000 tends to be greater than the
disagreement measure observed in September 2000 for the value that the same variable will take at the closing of 2000. The divergence measure tends to
increase again in March 2001, since the current year becomes 2001 and the time horizon of the forecast becomes 9 months.
596 G. C. MONTES ET AL.

given disagreement measure (say, DtX12), which do Clarity of central bank communication (f_index)
not reflect upon the others. Such movements can be The standard statistic from the literature on clarity
regarded as outliers, thus they should be ignored. of central bank communication is used: the Flesch
(1948) statistic, or the Flesch reading ease score. The
Inflation (inflation_ipca) Flesch (1948) reading ease score uses three variables:
This series uses the inflation rate accumulated in 12 the number of words (#word), the number of sen-
months (Índice de Preços ao Consumidor Amplo tences (#sentences) and the number of syllables
(IPCA) – series code 13522 obtained from the CBB). (#syllables) used in the text. On the basis of these
variables, the Flesch reading ease score is calculated
Inflation volatility (vol_ipca) as follows:
The measure for inflation volatility is calculated by f_index = 206.835 − 1.015 × (#word/#sentences)
means of the series representing the inflation rate − 84.6 × (#syllables/#words).
accumulated in 12 months (IPCA – series code Therefore, when the indicator (f_index) increases,
13522 obtained from the CBB). The measure is it means that the clarity has increased.
Downloaded by [University of Sussex Library] at 12:16 22 September 2017

derived by applying the formula vol_ipca = (inflatio-


n_ipcat – inflation_ipcat-1)2. Transparency indices (transp_bl and transp_fl)
Most of the empirical literature on central bank
Dummy variable for the subprime crisis (d_subprime) transparency is based on transparency indices that
To capture the effect of the subprime mortgage crisis consider a number of questions related to informa-
on the Brazilian economy, we included a dummy tion disclosure by the central bank or actual practice
variable that assumes value 1 for the period between (e.g., Fry et al. 2000; Chortareas, Stasavage, and
September 2008 and June 2009, and zero otherwise. Sterne 2002; Eijffinger and Geraats 2006; Dincer
and Eichengreen 2010; Siklos 2011). However, it is
Monetary policy signaling (d_sig, d_down and d_up) important to note that these indices are subject to
Dummy variables of monetary policy signalling are subjectivity because researchers attribute scores to
built based on the glossary prepared (Table B1, each question. Besides, institutional features of the
Appendix B), which is intended to codify the central banks do not change in short periods.
words and expressions contained in the minutes of Therefore, the use of this type of index is not ade-
the COPOM meetings. The methodology and the quate for an analysis with time series data (De
glossary are based on the work of Rosa and Verga Mendonça and Galveas 2013).
(2007). The first dummy variable, d_sig, can take In order to avoid the abovementioned problems
three values: −1 (dovish), 0, +1 (hawkish). The in the analysis of central bank transparency with
value of zero suggests that the current level of the time series data, we use the central bank transpar-
Selic rate is appropriate to maintain price stability ency indices proposed by De Mendonça and
over the medium term; the value −1 characterizes an Galveas (2013). Due to the fact that central bank
easing period, i.e., it is possible that the Selic rate will transparency is associated with the reduction of
be cut in the near future; the value +1 signals a asymmetric information between the central bank
future monetary policy tightening. This variable and the public (Walsh 2003), the convergence
(d_sig) seeks to capture the effect of signalling future between inflation and the inflation target can be
monetary policy on disagreement. In turn, when considered to be a measure of transparency. The
there is an indication that the COPOM will reduce paper of De Mendonça and Galveas (2013) presents
the Selic rate at its next meeting, the dummy variable two indices for measuring CBB transparency: the
denoted d_down is used, which assumes value 1 backward-looking transparency index (transp_bl)
according to this signalling and zero otherwise. and the forward-looking transparency index
When there is an indication that the COPOM will (transp_fl), which are built based on inflation and
increase the Selic rate at its next meeting, the inflation expectations, respectively.
dummy variable denoted d_up is used, which The transp_bl depends on the success of the CBB
assumes value 1 according to this signalling and in achieving the inflation target. This is particularly
zero otherwise. relevant because it indicates the central bank’s
APPLIED ECONOMICS 597

performance in managing monetary policy. The Therefore, if Et ðπtþ12 Þ exceeds the tolerance inter-
transp_bl is a result of: val, then transp_ fl is equal to 0; such circumstances
may suggest that the central bank is failing in its role
transp bl ¼
8 in leading inflation expectations to the inflation tar-
>
> 1 if πt ¼ πt get. This case reveals that monetary policy manage-
<  
1  πbound1 π πt  πt if πlower
upper bound
i
bound
< πt <πi ; ment may not be clear to the public, bringing about
>
> i i
a high level of asymmetric information. On the other
: upper bound
0 if πt  πi or πt  πlower
i
bound
hand, the case where transp_ fl is equal to 1 indicates
where πt is the inflation accumulated in 12 months that central bank transparency improves the mone-
(measured by the National Consumer Price Index tary policy efficiency, since it promotes the conver-
(extended) – IPCA – official price index); πi is the gence between inflation expectation and the
weighted inflation target (last 12 months)15; πbound is inflation target. The variable transp_ fl also varies
i
the limit of the tolerance interval defined for the between 0 and 1. In short, the closer this index is
inflation rate observed in the end of the current to 1 (0), the greater is the central bank’s transpar-
Downloaded by [University of Sussex Library] at 12:16 22 September 2017

year and πi is the inflation target (current year). ency (opacity).
In this sense, when there is maximum transpar-
ency (πt ¼ πt and thus there is no surprise to the
Methodology
public), the transp_bl is equal to 1. Contrary to this,
when the inflation exceeds the bounds of the toler- Our interest in this study is the empirical signifi-
ance interval, the transp_bl is equal to 0. Hence, the cance of the determinants of disagreement about
variable transp_bl ranges between 0 and 1. inflation expectations in Brazil. Based on Mankiw,
In turn, since the success of inflation targeting Reis, and Wolfers (2003), the following benchmark
depends to a great degree on the public’s expecta- econometric model (Equation 1) is estimated:
tions concerning inflation, an important point in the
disag ipca ¼ β0 þ β1 inflation ipcat
inflation targeting analysis is the forward-looking
behaviour of the public regarding inflation. In this þ β2 vol ipcat2
sense, any divergence between inflation expectations þ β3 d subprime þ 1 ;t ; (1)
and the inflation target may reveal a high level of where ξ1 is a random error term.
asymmetric information, which can be induced by The lag of two periods, present in the inflation
strong central bank’s opacity. On the contrary, a volatility variable, was determined on an empirical
great convergence between inflation expectations basis, following the general-to-specific method, and
and the inflation target is an indication that the on the principle of parsimony according to data
central bank is successful in coordinating expecta- release. This methodology takes into consideration
tions. Thus, the transp_fl variable results from: not only the statistical significance of the parameters,

8 9
>
< 1 if Et ðπtþ12 Þ ¼ πtþ12 >
=
1  
 upper bound
transp fl ¼ bound E t ðπ tþ12 Þ  π if π lower bound
< Et ðπ tþ12 Þ < π ;
πiþ1  πiþ1 >
: 0 if E ðπ
tþ12 i
upper bound
i
>
;
t tþ12 Þ  πi or Et ðπtþ12 Þ  πi lower bound

where Et ðπtþ12 Þ is the inflation expectation for the but also diagnostic tests, in order to ensure that the
next 12 months; πtþ12 is the weighted inflation target chosen model has explanatory power and thus guar-
for the same period16; πbound
iþ1 is the limit of the antees a parsimonious equation (Hendry 2001). In
tolerance interval defined for the inflation rate addition, it is reasonable that agents take some time
observed in the next 12 months and πiþ1 is the to observe inflation volatility and its effects on
inflation target pursued for the next year. expectations.

15
For example, the weighted inflation target in June of 2003 is a result of (6 × target 2003 + 6 × target 2002).
16
For example, the weighted inflation target in July 2004 is a result of (5 × target 2004 + 7 × target 2005).
598 G. C. MONTES ET AL.

Aiming at analysing the effects of monetary policy this task, the equations presented below are modified
signalling and the clarity of central bank communi- relative to those found in the work of Mankiw, Reis,
cation on disagreement about inflation expectations, and Wolfers (2003). Indeed, Equations (8)–(16) (see
we estimate different variants of the benchmark below) try to incorporate the potential effects of
econometric model. In order to capture the role of transparency.
clarity of central bank communication in the poten-
tial link between monetary policy signalling and disag ipca ¼ α0 þ α1 vol ipcat2
disagreement about inflation expectations þ α2 transp bl þ α3 d subprime
(Equations 5, 6 and 7), we add interaction terms þ ε1 ; t ; (8)
between the variable measuring clarity (f_index)
and the variables capturing monetary policy signal- disag ipca ¼ α4 þ α5 vol ipcat2
ling (d_sign, d_down and d_up). þ α6 transp fl þ α7 d subprime
þ ε2 ;t ; (9)
disag ipca ¼ β4 þ β5 inflation ipcat
þ β6 vol ipcat2 þ β7 d subprime
Downloaded by [University of Sussex Library] at 12:16 22 September 2017

(2) disag ipca ¼ α8 þ α9 vol ipcat2


þ β8 d up þ 2 ;t ; þ α10 transp bl þ α11 transp fl
þ α12 d subprime þ ε3 ;t ; (10)
disag ipca ¼ β9 þ β10 inflation ipcat
þ β11 vol ipcat2 þ β12 d subprime (3) disag ipca ¼ α13 þ α14 vol ipcat2 þ α15 transp bl
þ β13 d down þ 3 ;t ; þ α16 transp fl þ α17 d subprime (11)
þ α18 d up þ ε4 ;t ;
disag ipca ¼ β14 þ β15 inflation ipcat
þ β16 vol ipcat2 þ β17 d subprime (4) disag ipca ¼ α19 þ α20 vol ipcat2
þ β18 d sig þ 4 ;t ; þ α21 transp bl þ α22 transp fl
þ α23 d subprime
disag ipca ¼ β19 þ β20 inflation ipcat þ α24 d down þ ε5 ;t ; (12)
þ β21 vol ipcat2
(5) disag ipca ¼ α25 þ α26 vol ipcat2 þ α27 transp bl
þ β22 d subprime
þ β23 d up  f index þ 5 ;t ; þ α28 transp fl þ α29 d subprime (13)
þ α30 d sig þ ε6 ;t ;
disag ipca ¼ β24 þ β25 inflation ipcat
þ β26 vol ipcat2 disag ipca ¼α31 þ α32 vol ipcat2
þ β27 d subprime (6) þ α33 transp bl þ α34 transp fl
(14)
þ β28 d down  f index þ α35 d subprime
þ 6 ;t ; þ α36 d up  f index þ ε7 ;t ;

disag ipca ¼ β29 þ β30 inflation ipcat disag ipca ¼ α36 þ α37 vol ipcat2
þ β31 vol ipcat2 þ β32 d subprime (7) þ α38 transp bl þ α39 transp fl
þ β33 d sig  f index þ 7 ;t : þ α40 d subprime
þ α41 d down  f index þ ε8 ;t ; (15)
In the equations above, ξ2, ξ3, ξ4, ξ5, ξ6 and ξ7, are
random error terms. disag ipca ¼ α42 þ α43 vol ipcat2 þ α44 transp bl
Due to the facts that, under inflation targeting, the þ α45 transp fl þ α46 d subprime
main task of the central bank is guaranteeing that
both inflation and inflation expectations converge to þ α47 d sig  f index þ ε9 ;t :
the target and that transparency plays a key role in (16)
APPLIED ECONOMICS 599

In these equations, ε1, ε2, ε3, ε4, ε5, ε6, ε7, ε8 and ε9 Table 1. Correlations.
are random error terms. Variables disag_ipca
disag_ipca 1.000
The econometric analysis makes use of ordinary inflation_ipca 0.785
least squares (OLS), the generalized method of vol_ipca 0.297
transp_bl −0.343
moments (GMM) and two-step GMM. Due to the transp_fl −0.445
problems of autocorrelation and heteroscedasticity, f_index −0.032
d_up −0.105
which are common in macroeconomic time series, d_down 0.171
and since there is a risk of endogeneity problems, d_sig −0.157
Notes: Authors’ elaboration.
GMM is chosen to deal with these problems (Hansen
1982).
For a more efficient GMM estimator than OLS, Before estimating Equations (1)–(16), unit root
overriding restrictions need to be considered tests – augmented Dickey–Fuller (ADF), Phillips–
(Wooldridge 2001). Therefore, with the intention Perron (PP) and Kwiatkowski–Phillips–Schmidt–
of testing the validity of the overriding restrictions, Shin (KPSS) – were made (Table 2). The results
Downloaded by [University of Sussex Library] at 12:16 22 September 2017

a standard J-test is performed (Hansen 1982). GMM show that all series are I(0) according to the follow-
estimates adopted a standard procedure based on ing criterion: when at least two of the three tests
Johnston (1984), i.e., the chosen instruments were indicate that the series does not have a unit root,
dated to the period t – 1 or earlier. Cragg (1983) then the series is considered to be stationary.
pointed out that overidentification analysis has an We now turn to the econometric results. Tables 3
important role in the selection of instrumental vari- and 4 show the estimates. Table 3 provides: (i) the
ables to improve the efficiency of the estimators. In results obtained using the benchmark model
addition, we estimate the two-step GMM with (Equation 1); (ii) the results obtained by considering
Windmeijer (2005) corrections to address small- the effects of monetary policy signalling (Equations
sample downward biases on SEs (the results for the 2, 3 and 4) and (iii) the results obtained by consider-
two-step GMM estimates are present in Tables A3 ing the joint effect of monetary policy signalling and
and A4, Appendix A). clarity of central bank communication (Equations 5,
6 and 7). In turn, Table 4 provides the results
obtained by considering the effects of transparency,
VI. Evidence
the influence of monetary policy signalling and the
Aiming at observing the relationship between the role played by clarity of central bank
main regressors and the general level of disagree- communication.
ment about inflation expectations in the Brazilian Regarding the estimates in Table 3, the coeffi-
economy, the first empirical procedure is presenting cients for the influence of both inflation and infla-
ordinary correlations (Table 1). As expected, Table 1 tion volatility have the expected signs and statistical
reveals: (i) a positive correlation between disagree- significance in all specifications. These findings are
ment and inflation, (ii) a positive correlation compatible with those reported in other studies such
between disagreement and inflation volatility, (iii) a as Mankiw, Reis, and Wolfers (2003), Capistrán and
negative correlation between disagreement and Timmermann (2009) and Dovern, Fritsche, and
transparency and (iv) a negative correlation between Slacalek (2012).
disagreement and clarity of central bank communi- The novelty in our estimates concerns the effects
cation. In addition, we observe: (v) a negative corre- of monetary policy signalling and clarity of central
lation between disagreement and the variable bank communication on disagreement about infla-
indicating that the COPOM will increase the Selic tion expectations. The findings presented in Table 3
rate at its next meeting (d_up), (vi) a positive corre- suggest that the act of signalling future monetary
lation between disagreement and the variable indi- policy (d_sig) reduces the general level of disagree-
cating that the COPOM will reduce the Selic rate at ment about inflation expectations; indeed, estimated
its next meeting (d_down) and (vii) a negative cor- coefficients are negative and statistically significant.
relation between disagreement and the act of issuing Furthermore, the act of signalling future monetary
monetary policy signals (d_sig). policy with clarity (d_sig*f_index) is also beneficial
Downloaded by [University of Sussex Library] at 12:16 22 September 2017

600

Table 2. Unit root tests.


ADF PP KPSS
Variables Test Eq. Lag t-Stat 10% Eq. Band. t-Stat 10% Eq. Band. t-Stat 1%
disag_ipca Level I 1 −6.06 −2.58 I 9 −4.989 −2.578 I/T 9 0.306 0.216
1st difference I/T 5 0.094 0.216
2nd difference
f_index Level I 11 −1.76 −2.579 I/T 1 −4.866 −3.145 I/T 8 0.155 0.216
1st difference N 0 −15.35 −1.61521
2nd difference
vol_ipca Level I/T 0 −7.441 −3.146 I/T 3 −7.437 −3.146 I/T 6 0.176 0.216
G. C. MONTES ET AL.

1st difference
2nd difference
transp_fl Level I/T 7 −4.315 −3.146 I/T 4 −2.936 −3.145 I 9 0.593 0.739
1st difference N 9 −11.692 −1.615
2nd difference
transp_bl Level I 1 −3.092 −2.578 I 5 −3.216 −2.578 I 9 0.221 0.739
1st difference
2nd difference
inflation_ipca Level I 12 −1.902 −2.578 I/T 5 −4.570 −3.145 I 9 0.318 0.739
1st difference N 3 −3.233 −1.615
2nd difference
Source: Authors’ elaboration.
Notes: ADF – the final choice of lag was made based on modified Akaike criterion. PP and KPSS tests – lag is the lag truncation chosen for the Bartlett kernel. ‘I’ denotes intercept; ‘I/T’ denotes intercept and trend and ‘N’
denotes none.

Table 3. OLS and GMM regressions: influence of inflation, inflation volatility, subprime crisis, monetary policy signalling and clarity of central bank communication on disagreement
(May 2003–March 2015).
Dependent Equation OLS Equation GMM
Variable: Disag_Ipca 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
C −2.155*** −2.095*** −2.304*** −2.211*** −2.105*** −2.338*** −2.238*** −1.633*** −1.698*** −2.193*** −1.904*** −1.684*** −2.275*** −1.955***
(0.310) (0.265) (0.250) (0.235) (0.264) (0.258) (0.237) (0.226) (0.211) (0.230) (0.325) (0.222) (0.253) (0.333)
[−6.946] [−7.91] [−9.2] [−9.395] [−7.971] [−9.06] [−9.452] [−7.237] [−8.055] [−9.52] [−5.863] [−7.575] [−8.98] [−5.87]
inflation_ipca 0.29*** 0.308*** 0.296*** 0.304*** 0.309*** 0.302*** 0.308*** 0.206*** 0.248*** 0.264*** 0.254*** 0.244*** 0.277*** 0.263***
(0.049) (0.039) (0.039) (0.038) (0.039) (0.039) (0.038) (0.039) (0.041) (0.033) (0.058) (0.044) (0.034) (0.060)
[5.854] [7.834] [7.619] [8.02] [7.854] [7.687] [8.136] [5.225] [6.088] [8.112] [4.384] [5.576] [8.102] [4.389]
vol_ipca (−2) 0.092*** 0.055** 0.085*** 0.065*** 0.054** 0.088*** 0.066*** 0.167*** 0.074* 0.086* 0.082* 0.079* 0.089** 0.079*
(0.031) (0.026) (0.023) (0.023) (0.025) (0.024) (0.023) (0.042) (0.044) (0.047) (0.044) (0.047) (0.043) (0.045)
[2.936] [2.112] [3.666] [2.886] [2.129] [3.647] [2.948] [3.969] [1.664] [1.848] [1.85] [1.686] [2.062] [1.748]
d_subprime −0.842*** −1.005*** −0.968*** −1.025*** −1.005*** −0.948*** −1.012*** −1.455*** −1.619*** −1.458*** −1.483*** −1.621*** −1.423*** −1.476***
(0.107) (0.123) (0.118) (0.120) (0.124) (0.114) (0.117) (0.459) (0.447) (0.273) (0.335) (0.453) (0.277) (0.336)
[−7.856] [−8.151] [−8.207] [−8.523] [−8.108] [−8.323] [−8.632] [−3.171] [−3.624] [−5.332] [−4.423] [−3.578] [−5.133] [−4.393]
d_up −0.382** −0.388**
(0.155) (0.166)
[−2.471] [−2.33]
d_down 0.34** 0.579***
(0.151) (0.214)
[2.258] [2.706]
d_sig −0.227*** −0.238***
(0.085) (0.091)
[−2.671] [−2.618]
(Continued )
APPLIED ECONOMICS 601

to reduce disagreement about inflation expectations,

Notes: marginal significance levels: *** denotes 0.01, ** denotes 0.05 and *10%. SEs in parentheses and t-statistics in square brackets. Regarding OLS estimates, due to the problems of autocorrelation and
−0.01***

12.8946
0.3767
0.3575
0.3377
(0.004)
[−2.628]
as indicated by the negative signs and their statistical
7

17
significance.
It is also found that, when there is an indication
0.025**

13.8309
0.1808
0.3881
0.3696
(0.010)
[2.528]
that the COPOM will increase the Selic rate at its next
6

meeting, the general level of disagreement about infla-

15
tion expectations decreases, i.e., we found that d_up
−0.015**

heteroscedasticity (Table A1 in Appendix A shows the residual diagnostics tests), the reported t-statistics in the OLS estimates are based on the estimator of Newey and West (1987).
13.7046
0.2498
0.3993
0.3811
and disag_ipca are negatively related and the esti-
(0.007)
[−2.185]
5

mated coefficients are statistically significant. In

16
turn, when there is an indication that the COPOM
Equation GMM

will reduce the Selic rate at its next meeting, the

12.8793
0.3779
0.3559
0.3361
4

general level of disagreement about inflation expecta-

17
tions increases, i.e., we found that d_down and dis-
13.6664
ag_ipca are positively related and the estimated
0.1888
0.3907
0.3722
3
Downloaded by [University of Sussex Library] at 12:16 22 September 2017

coefficients are statistically significant. Finally, when


15
joint effects are estimated, i.e., when the interaction
terms between the clarity of central bank communi-
13.4652
0.2640
0.4033
0.3852
2

cation and variables capturing monetary policy sig-


16

nalling (d_up*f_index and d_down*f_index) are taken


into consideration, the results show robust signals
14.4426
0.2095
0.3501
0.3355
1

and statistical significance.


15

These results are particularly interesting and


make sense when we consider the Brazilian economy
−0.01***

0.5898
0.5776
0.6574
0.4189
0.4942
0.6112
48.5259
0.0000
(0.003)
[−2.786]

during the inflation targeting period. Since Brazil


7

adopted the inflation targeting regime in 1999, only


in 2000, 2006, 2007 and 2009 the inflation rate was
0.014**

0.5757
0.5631
2.0284
0.1567
1.6304
0.1997
45.7893
0.0000
(0.006)
[2.304]

equal to or below its target. In other words, the


6

inflation rate was above its target – or even above


its upper limit – most of the time (see Table 5). In
−0.016**

0.5842
0.5718
1.3399
0.2491
1.1059
0.3339

0.0000
47.4123
(0.006)
[−2.557]

this sense, one should conjecture that, when agents


5

observe a hawkish central bank, they expect that


both inflation and inflation expectations will con-
Equation OLS

0.5893
0.5771
0.6235
0.4311
0.4250
0.6547
48.4239
0.0000

verge to the inflation target; as a consequence, dis-


4

agreement about inflation expectations decreases.


On the other hand, when agents observe a dovish
0.5754
0.5628
1.8035
0.1816
1.4223
0.2448
45.7388
0.0000

central bank, they realize that inflation will not con-


3

verge to the target due to the history of inflation


episodes in the country; indeed, the central bank will
0.5842
0.5719
1.4234
0.2350
1.0428
0.3553
47.4203
0.0000

have a hard time in making inflation and inflation


2

expectations converge to the target, thus disagree-


ment about inflation expectations actually increases.
With regard to the results shown in Table 4, the
0.5376
0.5274
9.1086
0.0030
7.5347
0.0008
52.7029
0.0000
1

estimated coefficients for the influence of inflation


Source: Authors’ estimates.
Table 3. (Continued).

volatility are all positive and statistically significant;


Prob. Ramsey RESET (1)

Prob. Ramsey RESET (2)


Variable: Disag_Ipca

this result does not depend on the specific regression


Ramsey RESET (1)

Ramsey RESET (2)

being estimated. Once again, these findings are com-


d_down*f_index

Prob. F-statistic

p-value(J-STAT)
d_sig*f_index

Adj R-squared
d_up*f_index
Dependent

patible with other results reported in the literature.


R-squared

F-statistic

Estimation results also suggest that more transpar-


J-STAT

RANK

ency reduces disagreement. Indeed, the coefficients


Downloaded by [University of Sussex Library] at 12:16 22 September 2017

Table 4. OLS and GMM regressions: influence of inflation volatility, transparency, subprime crisis, monetary policy signalling and clarity of central bank communication on disagreement (May
602

2003–March 2015).
Dependent Equation OLS Equation GMM
Variable:
Disag_Ipca 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16
C −0.139 0.132 0.144 0.417 0.083 0.266 0.46 0.098 0.28 −0.332*** −0.12 −0.211 0.078 −0.245** −0.092 0.117 −0.239* −0.084 Coef
(0.193) (0.337) (0.341) (0.393) (0.282) (0.324) (0.404) (0.299) (0.334) (0.084) (0.152) (0.132) (0.153) (0.118) (0.114) (0.163) (0.121) (0.117) Std
Dev
[−0.718] [0.393] [0.423] [1.063] [0.294] [0.82] [1.138] [0.329] [0.84] [−3.94] [−0.789] [−1.597] [0.508] [−2.073] [−0.805] [0.719] [−1.977] [−0.715] T-stat
vol_ipca (−2) 0.208*** 0.25*** 0.236*** 0.204*** 0.236*** 0.217*** 0.202*** 0.241*** 0.221*** 0.436*** 0.397*** 0.45*** 0.41*** 0.432*** 0.42*** 0.414*** 0.455*** 0.436***
(0.077) (0.075) (0.077) (0.073) (0.069) (0.068) (0.072) (0.072) (0.070) (0.077) (0.061) (0.074) (0.076) (0.104) (0.093) (0.074) (0.090) (0.084)
G. C. MONTES ET AL.

[2.685] [3.345] [3.07] [2.797] [3.432] [3.181] [2.797] [3.325] [3.178] [5.676] [6.558] [6.118] [5.415] [4.17] [4.529] [5.59] [5.078] [5.174]
transp_BL −0.833*** −0.48* −0.649*** −0.449 −0.553** −0.675*** −0.456* −0.561** −0.78*** −0.536** −0.568** −0.427* −0.497** −0.589** −0.434* −0.505**
(0.302) (0.276) (0.247) (0.273) (0.262) (0.247) (0.272) (0.261) (0.166) (0.270) (0.253) (0.229) (0.233) (0.251) (0.229) (0.231)
[−2.761] [−1.74] [−2.628] [−1.645] [−2.109] [−2.733] [−1.679] [−2.151] [−4.689] [0] [−1.981] [−2.242] [−1.861] [−2.131] [−2.344] [−1.891] [−2.18]
transp_FL −1.068** −0.748 −0.794* −0.868 −0.863* −0.826* −0.863 −0.884* −0.725*** −0.344 −0.502** −0.558** −0.53** −0.541** −0.552** −0.545**
(0.483) (0.524) (0.476) (0.529) (0.499) (0.480) (0.542) (0.512) (0.217) (0.271) (0.221) (0.245) (0.229) (0.222) (0.249) (0.232)
[−2.209] [−1.429] [−1.667] [−1.642] [−1.73] [−1.722] [−1.593] [−1.727] [0] [−3.333] [−1.27] [−2.268] [−2.277] [−2.31] [−2.434] [−2.219] [−2.349]
d_subprime −0.889*** −0.635*** −0.72*** −0.896*** −0.827*** −0.898*** −0.904*** −0.791*** −0.874*** −1.024*** −0.852*** −0.925*** −1.023*** −0.951*** −1.001*** −1.038*** −0.912*** −0.983***
(0.138) (0.129) (0.134) (0.128) (0.125) (0.128) (0.133) (0.120) (0.124) (0.313) (0.262) (0.297) (0.255) (0.219) (0.236) (0.259) (0.230) (0.242)
[−6.432] [−4.92] [−5.361] [−6.999] [−6.635] [−7.037] [−6.816] [−6.616] [−7.069] [−3.275] [−3.249] [−3.118] [−4.013] [−4.338] [−4.232] [−4.005] [−3.964] [−4.057]
d_up −0.415* −0.419**
(0.236) (0.179)
[−1.758] [−2.348]
d_down 0.356 0.35**
(0.241) (0.144)
[1.48] [2.426]
d_sig −0.245* −0.198**
(0.142) (0.079)
[−1.724] [−2.497]
d_up*f_index −0.019* −0.018**
(0.010) (0.007)
[−1.862] [−2.386]
d_down*f_index 0.013 0.013**
(0.009) (0.006)
[1.386] [2.189]
d_sig*f_index −0.01* −0.008**
(0.006) (0.003)
[−1.729] [−2.396]
R-squared 0.2370 0.2555 0.2812 0.3320 0.3217 0.3393 0.3386 0.3107 0.3351 0.1622 0.2154 0.1984 0.2459 0.2353 0.2542 0.2507 0.2193 0.2455
Adj R-squared 0.2202 0.2391 0.2599 0.3071 0.2964 0.3146 0.3139 0.2850 0.3103 0.1434 0.1979 0.1743 0.2173 0.2063 0.2260 0.2223 0.1897 0.2170
Ramsey RESET (1) 3.5412 1.7026 2.2803 1.1505 2.9716 3.8650 1.1481 0.6939 2.4217
Prob. Ramsey RESET 0.0620 0.1942 0.1334 0.2854 0.0871 0.0514 0.2859 0.4063 0.1220
(1)
Ramsey RESET (2) 4.4245 1.7818 2.7260 1.8759 1.5804 1.9456 1.4764 1.1960 1.4348
Prob. Ramsey RESET 0.0138 0.1723 0.0691 0.1573 0.2098 0.1470 0.2322 0.3056 0.2418
(2)
F-statistic 14.0826 15.5579 13.2008 13.3209 12.7099 13.7614 13.7188 12.0798 13.5085
Prob. F-statistic 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
J-STAT 15.4410 14.7587 14.8239 13.5032 14.4740 14.2839 13.3886 14.4757 14.2351
p-value(J-STAT) 0.3487 0.3948 0.3185 0.3336 0.2715 0.2829 0.3414 0.2714 0.2860
RANK 18 18 18 18 18 18 18 18 18
Source: Authors’ estimates.
Notes: marginal significance levels: *** denotes 0.01, ** denotes 0.05 and *10%. SEs in parentheses and t-statistics in square brackets. Regarding OLS estimates, due to the problems of autocorrelation and heteroscedasticity
(Table A2 in Appendix A shows the residual diagnostics tests), the reported t-statistics in the OLS estimates are based on the estimator of Newey and West (1987).
APPLIED ECONOMICS 603

Table 5. Observed inflation and inflation targets in Brazil. This article finds empirical evidence that trans-
Period Observed inflation Lower limit Upper limit Inflation target parency is an important tool to reduce disagreement
1999 8.9 6.0 10.0 8.0
2000 6.0 4.0 8.0 6.0
about inflation expectations in Brazil. Besides, given
2001 7.7 2.0 6.0 4.0 that we use the central bank transparency indices
2002 12.5 1.5 5.5 3.5
2003 9.3 - - 8.5 proposed by De Mendonça and Galveas (2013), our
2004 7.6 3.0 8.0 5.5 findings also suggest an interesting interpretation for
2005 5.7 2.0 7.0 4.5
2006 3.1 2.5 6.5 4.5 an inflation targeting economy: a stronger anchorage
2007 4.5 2.5 6.5 4.5 of both inflation and inflation expectations towards
2008 5.9 2.5 6.5 4.5
2009 4.3 2.5 6.5 4.5 the inflation target is an important attribute to
2010 5.9 2.5 6.5 4.5 reduce disagreement about inflation expectations.
2011 6.5 2.5 6.5 4.5
2012 5.8 2.5 6.5 4.5 Regarding monetary policy signalling and clarity
2013 5.9 2.5 6.5 4.5
2014 6.4 2.5 6.5 4.5
of central bank communication, our findings indi-
Source: Central Bank of Brazil. cate that the act of signalling future monetary policy
reduces disagreement. We also find that the act of
Downloaded by [University of Sussex Library] at 12:16 22 September 2017

signalling future monetary policy with clarity is also


attached to our proxies of transparency (variables
beneficial in terms of reducing disagreement about
transp_bl and transp_fl) are always negative. They
future inflation. Moreover, when the COPOM indi-
are also statistically significant at conventional con-
cates that the basic interest rate will rise at its next
fidence levels in most cases, although transp_fl seems
meeting, the general level of disagreement about
to exert a stronger effect on the general level of
inflation expectations decreases. Finally, when there
disagreement than transp_bl. These findings also
is an indication that the COPOM will reduce the
suggest an interesting interpretation for inflation
basic interest rate at its next meeting, the general
targeting economies: a stronger anchorage of both
level of disagreement about inflation expectations
inflation and inflation expectations towards the
increases.
inflation target is an important tool to reduce dis-
agreement about inflation expectations.
Regarding the influence of both monetary policy Disclosure statement
signalling and clarity of central bank communica- No potential conflict of interest was reported by the authors.
tion on the general level of disagreement about
inflation expectations, results shown in Table 4
reinforce those presented in Table 3. As before, References
the signs of the coefficients attached to (d_sig),
Andrade, P., R. K. Crump, S. Eusepi, and E. Moench. 2014.
(d_sig*f_index), (d_up), (d_up*f_index), (d_down) Fundamental Disagreement. Federal Reserve Bank of New
and (d_down*f_index) are the same as those York Staff Reports No. 655. New York: Federal Reserve
shown in Table 3. This finding highlights the Bank of New York.
robustness of our results. The reasons discussed Blinder, A., M. Ehrmann, M. Fratzscher, J. DeHaan, and D.-
before aiming at explaining estimation results J. Jansen. 2008. “Central Bank Communication and
Monetary Policy: A Survey of Theory and Evidence.”
remain valid.
Journal of Economic Literature 46: 910–945. doi:10.1257/
jel.46.4.910.
Bulíř, A., M. Čihák, and D. Jansen. 2013. “What Drives
VII. Conclusion Clarity of Central Bank Communication about
Inflation?.” Open Economies Review 24: 125–145.
This study has considered the main determinants of doi:10.1007/s11079-012-9259-z.
the general level of disagreement about inflation Bulíř, A., M. Čihák, and K. Šmídková. 2013. “Writing
expectations in Brazil. In particular, this article has Clearly: The ECB ‘S Monetary Policy Communication.”
studied to what extent central bank transparency, German Economic Review 14: 50–72. doi:10.1111/
geer.2012.14.issue-1.
communication and clarity have contributed to
Capistrán, C. and A. Timmermann. 2009. “Disagreement
match expectations formed by financial market and Biases in Inflation Expectations.” Journal of Money,
experts with the inflation target, thus reducing dis- Credit and Banking 41: 365–396. doi:10.1111/
agreement about inflation expectations. jmcb.2009.41.issue-2-3.
604 G. C. MONTES ET AL.

Chortareas, G., D. Stasavage, and G. Sterne. 2002. “Does It Hansen, L. P. 1982. “Large Sample Properties of Generalized
Pay to Be Transparent? International Evidence from Method of Moments Estimators.” Econometrica 50: 1029–
Central Bank Forecasts.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. 1054. doi:10.2307/1912775.
Louis Review 84: 99–118. Hendry, D. F. 2001. “Achievements and Challenges in
Čihák, M. 2007. “The Art and Science of Monetary Policy Econometric Methodology.” Journal of Econometrics 100:
Communication.” Czech Journal of Economics and Finance 7–10. doi:10.1016/S0304-4076(00)00045-2.
57: 490–498. Jansen, D. 2011a. “Does the Clarity of Central Bank
Cragg, J. G. 1983. “More Efficient Estimation in the Presence Communication Affect Volatility in Financial Markets?
of Heteroscedasticity of Unknown Form.” Econometrica Evidence from Humphrey-Hawkins Testimonies.”
51: 751–763. doi:10.2307/1912156. Contemporary Economic Policy 29: 494–509. doi:10.1111/
De Haan, J., S. C. W. Eijffinger, and K. Rybiński. 2007. coep.2011.29.issue-4.
“Central Bank Transparency and Central Bank Jansen, D. 2011b. “Mumbling with Great Incoherence: Was
Communication: Editorial Introduction.” European It Really So Difficult to Understand Alan Greenspan?.”
Journal of Political Economy 23: 1–8. doi:10.1016/j. Economics Letters 113: 70–72. doi:10.1016/j.
ejpoleco.2006.09.010. econlet.2011.05.034.
De Mendonça, H. F. and K. A. S. Galveas. 2013. Jansen, D. and J. De Haan. 2007. The Importance of Being
“Transparency and Inflation: What Is the Effect on the Vigilant: Has ECB Communication Influenced Euro Area
Downloaded by [University of Sussex Library] at 12:16 22 September 2017

Brazilian Economy?.” Economic Systems 37: 69–80. Inflation Expectations? CESifo Working Paper No. 2134.
doi:10.1016/j.ecosys.2012.06.003. Munich: CESifo.
De Mendonça, H. F. and J. Simão Filho. 2007. “Economic Johnston, J. 1984. Econometric Methods. 3rd ed. Singapore:
Transparency and Effectiveness of Monetary Policy.” McGraw-Hill Book Co.
Journal of Economic Studies 34: 497–514. doi:10.1108/ Kincaid, J. P., R. P. Fishburn, R. L. Rogers, and B. S. Chissom.
01443580710830961. 1975. Derivation of New Readability Formulas (Automated
De Mendonça, H. F. and J. Simão Filho. 2008. Readability Index, Fog Count and Flesch Reading Ease
“Macroeconomic Effects of Central Bank Transparency: Formula) for Navy Enlisted Personnel. Research Branch
The Case of Brazil.” Cato Journal 28: 117–137. Report 8-75. Millington, TN: U.S. Naval Air Station
Dincer, N. and B. Eichengreen. 2010. “Central Bank Kliesen, K. L. and F. A. Schmid. 2004. “Monetary Policy Actions,
Transparency: Causes, Consequences and Updates.” Macroeconomic Data Releases, and Inflation Expectations.”
Theoretical Inquiries in Law 11: 75–123. doi:10.2202/ Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis Review 86 (3): 9–21.
1565-3404.1237. Kuttner, K. N., and A. S. Posen. 1999. “Does Talk Matter
Dovern, J., U. Fritsche, and J. Slacalek. 2012. “Disagreement After All? Inflation Targeting and Central Bank Behavior.”
among Forecasters in G7 Countries.” The Review of Institute for International Economics Working Paper No.
Economics and Statistics 94: 1081–1096. doi:10.1162/ 99–10, Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report
REST_a_00207. No. 88. New York: Federal Reserve Bank of New York.
Ehrmann, M., S. Eijffinger, and M. Fratzscher. 2010. The Litterman, R. and J. Scheinkmann. 1991. “Common Factors
Role of Central Bank Transparency for Guiding Private Affecting Bond Returns.” The Journal of Fixed Income 1:
Sector Forecasts. European Central Bank Working Paper 54–61. doi:10.3905/jfi.1991.692347.
1146, January. Mankiw, N. G., R. Reis, and J. Wolfers. 2003. Disagreement
Eijffinger, S. C. W. and P. Geraats. 2006. “How about Inflation Expectations. NBER Working Paper No.
Transparent are Central Banks?” European Journal of 9796. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic
Political Economy 22: 1–21. doi:10.1016/j.ejpoleco. Research.
2005.09.013. Newey, W. K., and K. D. West. 1987. “A Simple, Positive
Filardo, A. and D. Guinigundo. (2008) Transparency and Semidefinite, Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrelation
Communication in Monetary Policy: A Survey of Asian Consistent Covariance Matrix.” Econometrica 55 (3):
Central Banks.Paper presented during the BSP-BIS Joint 703–708.
High-Level Conference on Transparency and Patton, A. J. and A. Timmermann. 2010. “Why Do Forecasters
Communication in Monetary Policy on 1 February 2008 Disagree? Lessons from the Term Structure of Cross-
in Manila, Philippines. Sectional Dispersion.” Journal of Monetary Economics 57:
Flesch, R. 1948. “A New Readability Yardstick.” Journal of 803–820. doi:10.1016/j.jmoneco.2010.07.001.
Applied Psychology 32: 221–233. doi:10.1037/h0057532. Rosa, C. and G. Verga. 2007. “On the Consistency and
Fry, M., D. Julius, L. Mahadeva, S. Roger, and G. Sterne. Effectiveness of Central Bank Communication: Evidence
2000. “Key Issues in the Choice of Monetary Policy from the ECB.” European Journal of Political Economy 23:
Framework.” In Monetary Policy Frameworks in a Global 146–175. doi:10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2006.09.016.
Context, edited by L. Mahadeva and G. Sterne, 1–216. Siklos, P. L. 2003. “Assessing the Impact of Changes in
London: Routledge. Transparency and Accountability at the Bank of Canada.”
Geraats, P. M. 2002. “Central Bank Transparency.” Economic Canadian Public Policy – Analyse de Politiques 29 (3):
Journal 112: F532–565. doi:10.1111/ecoj.2002.112.issue-483. 279–299.
APPLIED ECONOMICS 605

Siklos, P. L. 2011. “Central Bank Transparency: Another Survey.” Chap. 9 in Challenges in Central Banking: The
Look.” Applied Economics Letters 18: 929–933. Current Institutional Environment and Forces
Siklos, P. L. 2013. “Sources of Disagreement in Inflation Affecting Monetary Policy, edited by Siklos, P., M.
Forecasts: An International Empirical Investigation.” Bohl, and M. Wohar. New York: Cambridge University
Journal of International Economics 90: 218–231. Press.
doi:10.1016/j.jinteco.2012.09.005. van der Cruijsen, C. A. B., S. C. W. Eijffinger, and L. H.
Svensson, L. E. O. 1999. Monetary Policy Issues for the Hoogduin. 2010. “Optimal Central Bank Transparency.”
Eurosystem. NBER Working Paper 7177. Cambridge, MA: Journal of International Money and Finance 29: 1482–
National Bureau of Economic Research. 1507. doi:10.1016/j.jimonfin.2010.06.003.
Ullrich, K. 2008. “Inflation Expectations of Experts and ECB Walsh, C. 2003. “Accountability, Transparency, and Inflation
Communication.” The North American Journal of Targeting.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 35: 829–
Economics and Finance 19: 93–108. doi:10.1016/j. 849. doi:10.1353/mcb.2003.0041.
najef.2008.03.002. Windmeijer, F. 2005. “A Finite Sample Correction for the
van der Cruijsen, C. A. B. and M. Demertzis. 2007. “The Variance of Linear Efficient Two-Step GMM Estimators.”
Impact of Central Bank Transparency on Inflation Journal of Econometrics 126 (1): 25–51. doi:10.1016/j.
Expectations.” European Journal of Political Economy 23: jeconom.2004.02.005.
51–66. doi:10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2006.09.009. Wooldridge, J. M. 2001. “Applications of Generalized
Downloaded by [University of Sussex Library] at 12:16 22 September 2017

van der Cruijsen, C. A. B. and S. Eijffinger. 2010. “The Method of Moments Estimation.” Journal of Economic
Economic Impact of Central Bank Transparency: A Perspectives 15: 87–100. doi:10.1257/jep.15.4.87.

Appendix A
Table A1. Residual diagnostics tests for OLS regressions in Table 4.
1 2 3 4 5 6 7
LM(1) test 123.0828 112.8143 108.8228 111.9267 114.9318 107.7458 112.1813
Prob. LM(1) test 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
LM(2) test 73.6796 64.6128 61.6453 64.7445 66.0684 61.5634 65.3737
Prob. LM(2) test 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
ARCH(1) test 14.7649 52.3603 30.3789 47.1808 52.0632 29.0993 45.7315
Prob. ARCH(1) test 0.0002 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
ARCH(2) test 16.0784 35.3757 19.3962 29.1701 34.4245 18.7432 28.0041
Prob. ARCH(2) test 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
Jarque–Bera 34.3131 28.2288 44.4966 36.5035 24.5537 45.9958 34.5929
Prob. Jarque–Bera 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
Source: Author’s elaboration.

Table A2. Residual diagnostics tests for OLS regressions in Table 5.


8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16
LM(1) test 110.4410 122.4310 114.0613 111.4955 112.7258 115.7760 111.5495 111.4128 114.6062
Prob. LM(1) test 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
LM(2) test 66.3938 72.7633 68.9594 65.7888 67.2006 69.6301 65.7425 66.7225 69.0367
Prob. LM(2) test 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
ARCH(1) test 40.8035 24.9085 24.0806 26.1601 19.4206 23.3107 25.9026 20.3882 23.2024
Prob. ARCH(1) test 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
ARCH(2) test 62.3911 63.2047 54.1874 97.3991 59.1780 84.3874 102.8576 58.2380 83.0454
Prob. ARCH(2) test 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
Jarque–Bera 948.1691 606.9735 705.4177 651.9457 584.1525 591.4009 626.4915 635.0323 608.9114
Prob. Jarque–Bera 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
Source: Author’s elaboration.
Downloaded by [University of Sussex Library] at 12:16 22 September 2017

606

Table A3. Two step GMM regressions: influence of inflation, inflation volatility, subprime crisis, monetary policy signalling and clarity of central bank communication on disagreement
(May 2003–March 2015).
Dependent Equation two-step GMM Equation GMM
Variable: Disag_Ipca 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
G. C. MONTES ET AL.

C −1.5*** −1.673*** −1.98*** −2.037*** −1.665*** −2.023*** −2.076*** −1.5002 −1.6734 −1.9804 −2.0367 −1.6652 −2.0228 −2.0756
(0.347) (0.250) (0.453) (0.314) (0.252) (0.485) (0.390) 0.3466 0.2498 0.4529 0.3139 0.2519 0.4847 0.3899
[−4.329] [−6.7] [−4.373] [−6.488] [−6.612] [−4.173] [−5.323] −4.3288 −6.7002 −4.3727 −6.4879 −6.6117 −4.1731 −5.3232
inflation_ipca 0.182*** 0.242*** 0.229*** 0.279*** 0.24*** 0.234*** 0.282*** 0.1822 0.2420 0.2286 0.2789 0.2400 0.2338 0.2820
(0.065) (0.040) (0.067) (0.046) (0.041) (0.071) (0.063) 0.0645 0.0399 0.0667 0.0460 0.0406 0.0713 0.0627
[2.823] [6.064] [3.429] [6.059] [5.914] [3.279] [4.499] 2.8233 6.0638 3.4290 6.0589 5.9136 3.2787 4.4989
vol_ipca (−2) 0.173** 0.079* 0.089* 0.079* 0.083* 0.105* 0.062 0.1732 0.0790 0.0895 0.0792 0.0832 0.1055 0.0618
(0.075) (0.045) (0.053) (0.046) (0.047) (0.057) (0.038) 0.0751 0.0452 0.0528 0.0457 0.0474 0.0571 0.0380
[2.307] [1.747] [1.693] [1.734] [1.757] [1.846] [1.627] 2.3069 1.7466 1.6931 1.7336 1.7570 1.8462 1.6267
d_subprime −1.398** −1.618*** −1.358*** −1.62*** −1.629*** −1.327*** −1.395*** −1.3982 −1.6176 −1.3584 −1.6202 −1.6295 −1.3273 −1.3948
(0.675) (0.598) (0.391) (0.560) (0.608) (0.402) (0.393) 0.6748 0.5981 0.3907 0.5599 0.6077 0.4015 0.3933
[−2.072] [−2.705] [−3.477] [−2.894] [−2.681] [−3.305] [−3.546] −2.0721 −2.7045 −3.4770 −2.8936 −2.6814 −3.3054 −3.5461
d_up −0.357** −0.3574
(0.173) 0.1726
[−2.071] −2.0707
d_down 0.466* 0.4658
(0.214) 0.2481
[1.877] 1.8773
d_sig −0.219* −0.2186
(0.121) 0.1210
[−1.808] −1.8075
d_up*f_index −0.013** −0.0134
(0.007) 0.0066
[−2.026] −2.0258
d_down*f_index 0.02* 0.0203
(0.011) 0.0110
[1.851] 1.8510
d_sig*f_index −0.012*** −0.0122
(0.005) 0.0054
[−2.251] −2.2513
R-squared 0.3497 0.4012 0.3085 0.3786 0.3943 0.3084 0.4070 0.3497 0.4012 0.3085 0.3786 0.3943 0.3084 0.4070
Adj R-squared 0.3351 0.3831 0.2871 0.3597 0.3759 0.2870 0.3889 0.3351 0.3831 0.2871 0.3597 0.3759 0.2870 0.3889
J-STAT 13.6882 12.9338 13.5888 15.2040 12.9715 13.7727 13.0804 13.6882 12.9338 13.5888 15.2040 12.9715 13.7727 13.0804
p-value(J-STAT) 0.2507 0.3739 0.6293 0.3644 0.3711 0.6156 0.2192 0.2507 0.3739 0.6293 0.3644 0.3711 0.6156 0.2192
RANK 15 17 21 19 17 21 15 15 17 21 19 17 21 15
Source: Authors’ estimates.
Notes: marginal significance levels: *** denotes 0.01, ** denotes 0.05 and *10%. SEs in parentheses and t-statistics in square brackets.
APPLIED ECONOMICS 607

Table A4. OLS and GMM regressions for the influence of inflation volatility, transparency, subprime crisis, monetary policy signalling
and clarity of central bank communication on disagreement about inflation expectations in Brazil (May 2003–March 2015).
Dependent Equation two-step GMM
8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16
C −0.422*** −0.264 −0.378** 0.019 −0.366** −0.165 0.051 −0.364** −0.151
(0.099) (0.254) (0.154) (0.242) (0.143) (0.153) (0.253) (0.147) (0.158)
[−4.257] [−1.04] [−2.457] [0.078] [−2.553] [−1.074] [0.202] [−2.479] [−0.956]
vol_ipca (−2) 0.436*** 0.36*** 0.433*** 0.377*** 0.342*** 0.336*** 0.382*** 0.371*** 0.357***
(0.076) (0.070) (0.072) (0.083) (0.092) (0.085) (0.080) (0.081) (0.079)
[5.758] [5.115] [5.997] [4.529] [3.71] [3.96] [4.767] [4.595] [4.518]
transp_BL −0.825*** −0.725** −0.664* −0.552* −0.643** −0.695** −0.566* −0.655**
(0.215) (0.354) (0.337) (0.326) (0.320) (0.326) (0.316) (0.307)
[−3.84] [−2.05] [−1.968] [−1.689] [−2.012] [−2.133] [−1.792] [−2.133]
transp_FL −0.578* −0.112 −0.45 −0.444 −0.433 −0.48 −0.432 −0.454
(0.346) (0.292) (0.315) (0.347) (0.338) (0.319) (0.340) (0.333)
[−1.67] [−0.383] [−1.427] [−1.279] [−1.282] [−1.503] [−1.271] [−1.362]
d_subprime −0.646* −0.734* −0.655* −0.75** −0.839*** −0.855*** −0.773** −0.793*** −0.831***
(0.375) (0.401) (0.370) (0.314) (0.264) (0.308) (0.322) (0.273) (0.311)
[−1.723] [−1.83] [−1.773] [−2.392] [−3.172] [−2.776] [−2.401] [−2.906] [−2.669]
d_up −0.492*
(0.279)
Downloaded by [University of Sussex Library] at 12:16 22 September 2017

[−1.761]
d_down 0.452**
(0.210)
[2.158]
d_sig −0.25**
(0.079)
[−2.1]
d_up*f_index −0.02*
(0.011)
[−1.774]
d_down*f_index 0.018**
(0.009)
[2.012]
d_sig*f_index −0.01**
(0.003)
[−2.082]
R-squared 0.0852 0.1922 0.1164 0.1729 0.1806 0.2075 0.1862 0.1675 0.2021
Adj R-squared 0.0646 0.1740 0.0897 0.1413 0.1493 0.1773 0.1551 0.1357 0.1716
J-STAT 14.9250 17.8599 15.5132 15.5781 17.1196 17.7233 15.5665 17.3990 17.7541
p-value(J-STAT) 0.5301 0.3322 0.4874 0.3398 0.5149 0.4740 0.3406 0.4959 0.4720
RANK 20 20 21 20 24 24 20 24 24
Source: Authors’ estimates. .
Notes: marginal significance levels: *** denotes 0.01, ** denotes 0.05 and *10%. SEs in parentheses and t-statistics in square brackets..

Appendix B
Table B1. Glossary of key words and expressions from minutes of COPOM meetings to build the dummy variables of monetary
policy signalling.
Dummy variable Key words
D_up – The monetary policy should remain especially vigilant.
– Maintenance of the interest rate represents a nonnegligible risk for meeting the target (projected inflation above target).
– Risks to achieving the goal.
– Potential inflationary impacts of supply shocks yet to materialize.
– Monetary policy should remain vigilant in order to avoid the propagation of shocks and exchange rate depreciation.
– Monetary policy firmly committed to meeting the inflation targets.
– Inflation remains high/monetary policy should be firm.
– The monetary authority will be ready to adopt an active posture if projected inflation diverges from the target.
– Inflation trend incompatible with the target.
– COPOM will need to be less tolerant if shocks threaten to raise inflation above the target. – The Central Bank will not allow
supply shocks to lead to an increase in the inflation rate.
– The committee understands that it is appropriate to continue the adjustment pace of the monetary conditions underway.
– The monetary authority must remain vigilant so that short-term pressures do not contaminate longer time horizon t – the
monetary authority should be ready to adjust the pace and magnitude of the interest rate
adjustment process to the circumstances
D_down – COPOM decided to continue the process of monetary easing. – Expected inflation below target/expectations consistent with the
inflation risks/targets are less significant. – Consolidation of favourable perspectives for inflation in the medium term/COPOM
considers that there is still room for further cuts in the Selic rate in the future. – Benign scenario for the evolution of inflation
(with reduction of uncertainties/favourable external scenario). – Economic activity consistent with supply conditions, with low
probability of inflation pressures.
● The gradual easing of the monetary stance will not compromise the important achievements made in lowering inflation
Source: Authors’ elaboration.

You might also like