Download as docx, pdf, or txt
Download as docx, pdf, or txt
You are on page 1of 2

HISTORICAL EVOLUTION OF CORPORATE EVOLUTION IN THE US

1. Manager-oriented model

In the United States, there existed an important strain of normative thought from the 1930s
through the 1960s that extolled the virtues of granting substantial discretion to the
managers of large business corporations. At the core of this view was the belief that
professional corporate managers could serve as disinterested technocratic fiduciaries who
would guide business corporations to perform in ways that would serve the general public
interest.
The normative appeal of this view arguably provided part of the rationale for the various
legal developments in U.S. law in the 1950s and 1960s that tended to reinforce the
discretionary authority of corporate managers, such as the SEC proxy rules and the Williams
Act. The collapse of the conglomerate movement in the 1970s and 1980s, however, largely
destroyed the normative appeal of the managerialist model. It is now the conventional
wisdom that, when managers are given great discretion over corporate investment policies,
they tend to serve disproportionately their own interests, however well-intentioned
managers may be. While managerial firms may be in some ways more efficiently responsive
to nonshareholder interests than are firms that are more dedicated to serving their
shareholders, the price paid in inefficiency of operations and excessive investment in low-
value projects is now considered too great. (Hansmann and Kraakman, 2001)

The shareholder-oriented model has emerged as the normative consensus not just because
of the failure of the alternatives, but because important economic forces have made the
virtues of that model increasingly salient. (Hansmann and Kraakman, 2001). In the 1980s a
relatively small number of giant corporations, employing tens or even hundreds of
thousands of people dominated the economy of the United States. These corporations
generated huge revenues and allocated these revenues according to a corporate governance
principle that we call ‘retain and reinvest’. These corporations tended to retain both the
money that they earned and the people whom they employed, and they reinvested in
physical capital and complementary human resources. (Ciccolo and Baum 1985; Hall 1994;
Corbett and Jenkinson 1996). (Lazonick and O’Sullivan, 2000)

In the 1960s and 1970s, however, the principle of retain and reinvest began running into
problems. The massive expansion of corporations that had occurred during the 1960s
resulted in poor performance in the 1970s, an outcome that was exacerbated by an unstable
macroeconomic environment and by the rise of new international competition, especially
from Japan (Lazonick and O’Sullivan 1997; O’Sullivan 2000: ch. 4).
As, during the 1970s, major US manufacturing corporations struggled with these very real
problems of excessive centralization and innovative competition, a group of American
financial economists developed an approach to corporate governance known as agency
theory. Agency theorists posited that, in the governance of corporations, shareholders were
the principals and managers were their agents. Agency theorists argued that, because
corporate managers were undisciplined by the market mechanism, they would
opportunistically use their control over the allocation of corporate resources and returns to
line their own pockets, or at least to pursue objectives that were contrary to the interests of
shareholders. Given the entrenchment of incumbent corporate managers and the relatively
poor performance of their companies in the 1970s, agency theorists argued that there was a
need for a takeover market that, functioning as a market for corporate control, could
discipline managers whose companies performed poorly. In addition, during the 1970s, the
quest for shareholder value in the US economy found support from a new source – the
institutional investor. The transfer of stockholding from individual households to institutions
such as mutual funds, pension funds and life insurance companies made possible the
takeovers advocated by agency theorists and gave shareholders much more collective power
to influence the yields and market values of the corporate stocks they held. The stage was
now set for institutional investors and S&Ls to become central participants in the hostile
takeover movement of the 1980s. An important instrument of the takeover movement was
the junk bond. By the early 1980s, and especially after the Garn-St. Germain Act of 1982
enabled S&Ls to enter the market, it became possible to use junk bonds to launch hostile
takeovers of even the largest corporations (Gaughan 1996: 302). The result was the
emergence of a powerful market for corporate control – something of which the agency
theorists of the 1970s had only dreamed. Takeovers, it was argued, were needed to
‘disgorge the free cash flow’ from companies (Jensen 1989). (Lazonick and O’Sullivan, 2000).

You might also like