Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 92

CLIMATE CHANGE, LIVELIHOODS, AND FORCED MIGRATION

A SYSTEMS DYNAMICAL ANALYSIS OF RURAL OUT-MIGRATION IN


WOLLO, ETHIOPIA

Master of Arts in Law and Diplomacy Thesis


Submitted by Justin Ginnetti
April 24, 2009

© 2009 Justin Ginnetti

http://fletcher.tufts.edu

1
T ABLE OF C O NTENT S

C HAPT ER 1: I NTR ODU CTI O N 3

The Scale an d S cope o f Climate Ch an ge -Ind uced M igrat ion

C HAPT ER 2: P R OBLEM D EFI NIT IO N A ND TH E P R OBLEM OF D EFIN ITI ON 6

Climate C han ge Re fu ge es , th e P rot e ction Ga p, an d Du ra ble S olut io ns

C HAPT ER 3: L IT ERA TURE R EVI EW 22

Effo rts t o Ex am in e th e R ela tions h ip Bet wee n C lim ate Cha n ge a nd

Hu ma n Migr atio n

C HAPT ER 4: S YST EMS D Y NA MI CS A ND C LI MAT E C H AN G E -F ORC ED M IGR ATI ON 41

Live liho od s an d Mig rat io n in Wo llo , Et hiop ia

C HAPT ER 5: C O NCLUSI O N 63

A Lo ok Ah ead a t Fu rt her Res ear ch O pp ort un it ies

2
C HAPT ER 1

I NTRO DUCT IO N : T H E S CAL E AN D S COP E OF C L I MAT E C H AN GE -I N DUC ED M I GRATI O N

Thanks to the scientific consensus that has emerged over the last two decades

about the existence of anthropogenic climate change, the discourse has shifted from

whether climate change was real to how humans can mitigate the change, and now the

dialogue includes substantial discussion about how to adapt to it. One such “adaptation

strategy” is migration. Some coastal populations will be displaced due to erosion, more

severe hydro-meteorological disasters, and rising sea levels attributed to the thermal

expansion of warming water and the melting of land-based ice masses in Greenland and

Antarctica. Climate-related phenomena at the other end of the spectrum, such as

desertification, drought, and irregular rainfall will put more pressure on populations that

are already vulnerable due to socio-economic factors. At the extreme, some have

speculated that future conflicts over scarce resources will become another, more

indirect, cause of human migrations. 1

What is the magnitude of climate change’s impact on human migration? Once

researchers established a conceptual link between predicted climatic changes and the

effects of those changes on human systems, they began publishing estimates of the

number of potential migrants, the most famous being Norman Myers. 2 Unfortunately,

there is little consensus when it comes to the definition of a “climate change migrant”

1
Clarke, John Innes and Leszek A. Kosinski. 1982. Redistribution of population in Africa . London
; Exeter, N.H.: Heinemann Educational, Edwards, Scott. 2008. Social Breakdown in Darfur. Forced
Migration Review 31: 23-24.
2
Myers, Norman. 1993. Environmental Refugees in a Globally Warmed World. BioScience 43, no.
11: 752-761.
3
or “environmental refugee”—in short, someone who has moved due to climate or

environmental change. For example, some estimates draw upon only one or two climate

change-related phenomena, often sea-level rise or desertification, while others draw

broader boundaries and include anthropogenic (but not climatic) changes such as

deforestation; some predictions consider environmentally driven labor migration, others

don’t; and some scholars look ahead as far as 2050, others run to the end of the

century, and some eschew emissions-contingent time horizons altogether and instead

measure migration flows against temperature rise. As expected, the differences in

underlying assumptions have yielded vastly different predictions.

Table 1 Sample of Estimates of Climate Change-Induced Migration


So urce : Esti m ate: Tim efra m e:
IPCC (1990)a 150 million 2050
Norman Myers (1993) 150 million 2050
“when global
Norman Myers (2005) 200 million "environmental refugees" warming takes hold”
IPCC (2007) No estimate N/A
“the exact number of people who will
actually be displaced or forced to
migrate will depend on the level of
investment, planning, and resources at a
government’s disposal to defend these
areas or provide access to public
Stern Review (2006) services and food aid” N/A
Christian Aid (2007) 1,000 million 2050
Christian Aid (2009) 250 million 2050
(a Based on previous estimates by Norman Myers, among others) Sources: IPCC (1990; 2007);
Myers (1993, 2007); Stern Review (2006); and Christian Aid (2007; 2009)

This paper will examine the effect of climate change on human migrations. First,

it will consider how this relationship has been conceptualized and described by experts

and will survey the existing scholarship on the subject. Second, it will develop a new

4
methodology that incorporates a sustainable livelihoods approach (SLA) and new

economic labor migration (NELM) into an integrated climate and migration systems

dynamics model. Third, the model will then be tested with actual data from Wollo,

Ethiopia, and the results and outputs will then be analyzed. Finally, gaps in existing

knowledge and avenues of future research will be highlighted.

Climate change may give rise to new migration patterns and novel

reorganizations of people and societies. However, this paper will argue that the most

profitable consideration of potential migration flows should be based upon existing

trends, data, and human experiences. Our understanding of climate change’s impact on

human migration patterns in the future ought to reflect how the former has affected

the latter already. The dominant migration trend for at least the last half-century has

been the relocation of people (and livelihoods) from rural to urban settings; more

importantly, “rural-urban migration and the transformation of rural settlements into

cities are important determinants of the high population growth expected in urban

areas of the less developed regions over the next thirty years.”3 This paper will argue

that climate change’s primary effect on migration will be an acceleration of this existing

rural-to-urban trend, and it will test this hypothesis by examining observed climatic

changes and human migration patterns in Ethiopia. The goal of this paper is to shed

light on the web of factors that explain how and when people decide to leave their rural

home and move to an urban center.

3
ECOSOC. 2002. World Urbanization Prospects: The 2001 Revision, Data Tables and Highlights.
New York: Population Division, Department of Economic and Social Affairs.
5
C HAPT ER 2

P ROBL EM D EFI NITI ON AN D TH E P R OBL EM OF D EFINITI O N : C LI M ATE C HA NG E R EFUG EES , TH E

P ROT ECTI ON G AP , A ND D URABL E S OLUTI O NS

In the 1980s and 1990s, Norman Myers predicted that the number of

“environmental,” “climate,” or “climate change” “refugees” could total 150 million

people by 2050. This prediction has been attacked from all sides and even revised by

Myers himself.4 Where do we stand now? Unfortunately, the definitional battle still

rages on as of this writing.

One crucial definitional problem, often understated even by the experts

discussed below, concerns the fact that even within the most narrowly defined

category of climate change-induced migrants, one must account for the fact that many

of these people migrate for only short time before returning to their home, especially if

they cannot find work. 5 Temporary migration is a strategy employed by both entire

households and by individuals within a household, and in the Horn of Africa many rural-

urban migrants leave their agricultural livelihood to seek off-farm work when they are

not needed on their household’s farm. 6 Another trend, not addressed in this paper, is

4
Black, Richard. 2001. Environmental Refugees: Myth or Reality? Geneva: UNHCR, Brown, Oli.
2007. Climate Change and Forced Migration: Observations, projections and implications. Geneva:
United Nations Human Development Report, Myers, Norman. 2002. Environmental Refugees: A
Growing Phenomenon of the 21st Century. Philosophical Transactions: Biological Sciences 357,
no. 1420: 609-613.
5
Basso, S., O. Casacchia, L. Cassata, C. Reynaud, and M. Said. 2001. The Geographical
Distribution of Urban and Rural Population. In Migration and Urbanization in Ethiopia, with Special
Reference to Addis Ababa:7-51. Addis Ababa, Ethiopia and Rome, Italy: Central Statistics
Authority (CSA) and Institute for Population Research (IPR).
6
Devereux, Stephen. 2000. Destitution in Ethiopia's Northeast Highlands (Amhara Region).
Addis Ababa: IDS and Save the Children (UK).
6
the large volume of rural-rural migration, which may occur after a household sells its

property and decides to sharecrop in a more productive region.

Recently, a number of important stakeholders have weighed in on the issue of

terminology to compel the acceptance of a common definition. The United Nations

Educational Scientific and Cultural Organization (UNESCO) published People on the

Move, a handbook of terms and concepts that advocates for “environmentally

displaced person(s)” or “environmental forced migrant(s).”7

In the October 2008 special edition of Forced Migration Review, which focuses

on climate change and forced migration, Dun and Gemenne observe that for academic

purposes, “the interest in developing a definition lies in understanding the factors

underlying migration decisions. While this is also of interest and concern to

policymakers, they have an additional need to know what rights such a person is

afforded. Without a precise definition, practitioners and policymakers are not easily able

to establish plans and make targeted progress.”8 However, Dun and Gemenne’s analysis

identifies two factors that hinder the realization of a commonly accepted definition. On

one hand, academic turf wars can generate confusion because scholars have a

professional incentive to define the climate change-induced migrants narrowly so that

they can “fence off” environmental migration within the larger field of migration

7
UNESCO. 2008. People on the Move: Handbook of selected terms and concepts. The Hague
and Paris: UNESCO.
8
Dun, Olivia and François Gemenne. 2008. Defining 'environmental migration'. Forced Migration
Review 31: 10-11.
7
studies. On the other hand, policymakers’ and the media’s “appetite for numbers”

compels researchers to hype their figures to make them seem more policy-relevant.9

Dun and Gemenne tentatively argue in favor of an inclusive definition and are

even comfortable with using the contentious word refugee. They reason that in many

instances, those vulnerable to climate change and hydro-meteorological disasters (i.e.,

those most likely to be forced to migrate) often suffer from persecution and economic

marginalization, which would entitle them to some protection of the 1951 Refugee

Convention.

Appearing in the pages of the same issue of Forced Migration Review, Maria

Stavropoulou argues more explicitly for the adoption of the phrase environmental

refugee “even though [it] is legally inaccurate,” because it “evokes a sense of global

responsibility and accountability, as well as a sense of urgency for impending

disasters.”10 According to Stavropoulou, the opposition to the term refugee—and,

therefore, the barrier to a common definition—is political because irresponsible

governments want to deny the rights that the word refugee confers upon those it

describes. Even when those displaced by climate or their environment are not

deliberately persecuted, they still have much in common with traditional Convention

refugees, because “[w]hen migration is forced, and when this is combined with absence

of protection by one’s own state, then international protection considerations arise.”11

9
________. 2008. Defining 'environmental migration'. Forced Migration Review 31: 10-11.
10
Stavropoulou, Maria. 2008. Drowned in definitions? Forced Migration Review 31: 11-12.
11
________. 2008. Drowned in definitions? Forced Migration Review 31: 11-12.
8
Given that Stavropoulou worked for the UN High Commissioner for Refugees

(UNHCR), her argument is shocking, as we shall soon see. As a direct rebuke of Myers,

Stavropoulou, and others who use the word refugee, Richard Black (writing in an official

capacity on behalf of the UNHCR) claims that there are no “climate,” “climate change,”

or “environmental” refugees. 12 Instead, Black argues that one’s decision to migrate is

caused by a multitude of factors of which the environment would count as just one.

Moreover, he also claims that the environmental component is overstated when it isn’t

trumped up altogether. 13 Black’s instinct to decry the use of the term refugee is

correct, but he ultimately carries his argument too far, to the point where he comes

across as a “climate denier.”

The UNHCR’s Etienne Piguet (writing in the UNHCR’s “New Issues in Refugee

Research” series) also argues against using refugee but still acknowledges the causal

role of climate change and environmental degradation in human migrations. Unlike

Black, Piguet focuses on the confusion that the term refugee generates in the context

of climate change as compared to its original legal meaning, which applies to “the

juridical status recognized by UN Convention of 1951, referring to any person having a

‘well-founded fear of being persecuted for reasons of race, religion, nationality,

membership of a particular social group or political opinion.’”14 As Piguet recognizes,

the issue at hand is that the word refugee has a precise, well-defined legal meaning,

one which is obscured by its misuse and exaggeration, or when it is used beyond proper

12
Black, Richard. 2001. Environmental Refugees: Myth or Reality? Geneva: UNHCR.
13
________. 2001. Environmental Refugees: Myth or Reality? Geneva: UNHCR.
14
Piguet, Etienne. 2008. Climate Change and Forced Migration. Geneva: UNHCR.
9
juridical context. This genealogical understanding of the legal definition of refugee has

since gained support beyond the UNHCR’s office. In January 2009, the Office of the

United Nations High Commissioner for Human Rights (OHCHR) released a special report

on the relationship between climate change and human rights. In the report’s discussion

of climate change, human rights, and displacement, it states:

Persons moving voluntarily or forcibly across an international border due

to environmental factors would be entitled to general human rights

guarantees in a receiving State, but would often not have a right of entry

to that State. Persons forcibly displaced across borders for environmental

reasons have been referred to as “climate refugees” or “environmental

refugees.” The Office of the United Nations High Commissioner for

Refugees, the International Organization for Migration, and other

humanitarian organizations have advised that these terms have no legal

basis in international refugee law and should be avoided in order not to

undermine the international legal regime for the protection of refugees. 15

The crucial distinction one must bear in mind is that there are not, and cannot

be, “climate,” “climate change,” or “environmental” refugees until the UN Convention

and Protocol framework on refugees is amended to incorporate this category of forced

migrants. 16 Furthermore, the majority of the so-called “climate refugees” are expected

to become internally displaced persons and remain inside their national boundaries—and

15
OHCHR. 2009. Report of the Office of the United Nations High Commissioner for Human
Rights on the relationship between climate change and human rights. Geneva: United Nations
High Commissioner for Human Rights and the Office of the High Commissioner for Human Rights.
16
Convention Relating to the Status of Refugees. 1951. United Nations, Protocol Relating to the
Status of Refugees. 1967. United Nations.
10
therefore not refugees. 17 So, unless the legal landscape changes, Black is correct—but

he’s correct only in the most narrow, technical sense because, as the Stern Review

points out, there have been refugees who fled their homes due to conflicts in which the

environment was a contributing causal factor. Additionally, there may be new

incidences of statelessness if the ocean, due to sea-level rise, completely swallows up

small island nations such as the Maldives, Kiribati, or Tuvalu.

Absent an expansion of the UNHCR’s official mandate as defined by the 1951

refugee convention and 1968 protocol, there will remain a “protection gap” for people

who have been displaced due to environmental disasters and climate change. Into this

vacuum have poured numerous suggestions for durable solutions. 18 Most proposals

begin by suggesting a new, more accurate term for these displaced people.

Kate Romer, for instance, posits “environmentally displaced person(s),” or

“EDPs,” and “encourages governments to recognize the plight of EDPs and support the

development of migration agreements to assist potentially displaced persons, [and] to

encourage governments to . . . adhere to the Guiding Principles for Internal

Displacement and to recognize the protection needs of those displaced as a result of

climate change within [their] borders.”19 This modest proposition may have the best

chance of being adopted, because it doesn’t impinge upon state sovereignty or the

17
Convention Relating to the Status of Refugees. 1951. United Nations, Black, Richard. 2001.
Environmental Refugees: Myth or Reality? Geneva: UNHCR.
18
Brown, Oli. 2007. Climate Change and Forced Migration: Observations, projections and
implications. Geneva: United Nations Human Development Report, Hugo, Graeme. 1996.
Environmental Concerns and International Migration. International Migration Review 30, no. 1:
105-131, Romer, K. 2006. "Environmental" Refugees? Forced Migration Review, no. 25: 1.
19
Romer, K. 2006. "Environmental" Refugees? Forced Migration Review, no. 25: 1.
11
right to develop (two frequently invoked excuses for states’ exceptionalism). That said,

because implementation measures would be left to the states, the efficacy of Romer’s

proposal would no doubt vary according to each state’s capacity and disposition

toward the rights of its citizens. Even if the regime in Myanmar adopted the proposal,

for example, one wonders how much less vulnerable coastal Burmese would be.

Sujatha Byravan and Sudhir Chella Rajan prefer “climate exiles” and provocatively

advocate for a form of environmental equity that would provide “immigration benefits,

in advance of disastrous impacts, to people in vulnerable communities on the basis of

the host countries’ historical greenhouse gas emissions”; they reason that such a

solution would benefit host countries economically and quell tensions relating to

international migration and refugees. “Legally, it can be argued to follow from Article 1

and Article 4.8 of the UNFCCC, which respectively call on Parties to use the principle of

equity in accordance with ‘common but differentiated responsibilities’ and to ‘meet the

specific needs and concerns of developing country Parties arising from the adverse

effects of climate change.’”20 As compelling as Byravan and Chella Rajan’s call for a

durable solution predicated on agreed-upon principles is, some might argue that they

are being disingenuous in the sense that they have chosen the principles after the fact

(i.e., after we have become aware of the consequences of our carbon emissions). That

said, given the intransigence of the biggest carbon-emitting nations, I am inclined to

overlook their retrospective fishing for the most advantageous ground rules for the

debate.

20
Byravan, Sujatha and Sudhir Chella Rajan. 2006. Providing New Homes for Climate Change
Exiles. Climate Policy 6, no. 2: 6.
12
Like Byravan and Chella Rajan, other academics and policymakers have argued

that current and future climate change-forced migrants are “already protected” by a

normative framework that draws upon an array of treaties and instruments ranging

from the Universal Declaration of Human Rights and the Covenant on Economic, Social,

and Cultural Rights to the “Pinheiro” Principles on Housing and Property Restitution for

Refugees and Displaced Persons. 21 One drawback to this strategy of drawing our

attention to already signed and ratified treaties is that it risks diverting our collective

attention to seemingly more urgent situations that would be addressed by the same

instruments. Furthermore, this gesture implicitly raises the question of whether a

multilateral legal framework would be the most effective way to address this problem

given its evident shortcomings: “Indeed, the prospects of this are truly daunting, and

will require leadership, commitment and creativity the likes of which the world has all

too rarely seen in recent decades. And this is where the necessity of adaptation and

human rights must converge and together build a stronger and more vibrant response

than we have witnessed to date.”22

Fabrice Renaud et al. endeavor to differentiate “environmentally motivated

migrants, environmentally forced migrants, and environmental refugees” by using the

following matrix of vulnerability and impact (Figure 1):

21
Leckie, S. 2008. The Human Rights Implications of Climate Change: Where Next? Male',
Maldives: United Nations Development Programme, Shahid, A. 2008. Life on the High(er) Seas:
Adapting to Climate Change in the Maldives. The Fletcher Forum of World Affairs 32, no. 2: 8.
22
Leckie, S. 2008. The Human Rights Implications of Climate Change: Where Next? Male',
Maldives: United Nations Development Programme.
13
Figure 1 Matrix of Vulnerability and Impact (Source: Renaud et al., 2007)

Renaud et al. choose to “retain the term refugee to characterize people precipitously

fleeing their place of residence because of an environmental stressor regardless of

whether or not they cross an international border,” or regardless of whether they meet

the other criteria for which one is recognized as a refugee.23 This linguistic sloppiness

infects the authors’ well-intentioned but scattershot cluster of policy

recommendations, which include requests for: better scientific understanding; increased

awareness; greater provision of (preventive) humanitarian assistance; improved

legislation; strengthening institutions and policies; and greater international

23
Renaud, F., J.J. Bogardi, O. Dun, and K. Warner. 2007. Control, Adapt or Flee: How to Face
Environmental Migration? Bonn: United Nations University Institute for Environment and Human
Security.
14
cooperation. 24

Graeme Hugo, by contrast, offers a nuanced historical overview of the problem

in “Environmental Concerns and International Migration” (1996). Although he never

settles on one given term (he uses “environmentally forced migration” and

“environmentally induced migration” interchangeably), Hugo thoroughly rehearses the

arguments against the use of refugee. Furthermore, he even lays some of the

lexicographical blame on the UNHCR, which, he correctly observes, has in practice

extended its mandate to provide humanitarian assistance to displaced victims of

natural disasters even though they do not satisfy the criteria for conventional status

determination. 25 Hugo advocates for broadening the protection measures to include

environmentally forced migrants, but he would argue that such protection is

tantamount to treating the symptom and not the underlying problem. Migration, he

asserts, is just one part of a much bigger global and human development picture:

“Migration is a logical and common immediate response to environmental degradation

and disaster, but is rarely a medium or long-term solution.”26 What’s needed instead, he

argues, are policies that effectively limit population growth (to reduce stress on the

environment), sustainable environmental policies, and better protection of human

24
________. 2007. Control, Adapt or Flee: How to Face Environmental Migration? Bonn: United
Nations University Institute for Environment and Human Security.
25
Hugo, Graeme. 1996. Environmental Concerns and International Migration. International
Migration Review 30, no. 1: 105-131.
26
________. 1996. Environmental Concerns and International Migration. International Migration
Review 30, no. 1: 105-131.
15
rights. 27 Unfortunately, what Hugo is talking about is mitigation rather than adaptation,

and he reasons that without effective mitigation, the resulting flows of humans would

be unfathomable, larger than any previous migration in history. Ideally, “international

relocation may provide an enduring solution only in very specific circumstances such as

in small island nations influenced by a significant rise in sea levels.”28

What of this claim, repeated by Hugo and others, that future climate change

induced migrations will represent the largest flows of people in human history? Oli

Brown (who efficiently critiques nearly all of the proposed terms above and finally

settles on simply “forced migrants”) commences his background paper for the United

Nations Development Programme’s 2007-2008 Human Development Report with a

historical consideration of this very issue. He cites archaeological evidence of mass

migrations that suggest that humans have always responded to changes in climate by

migrating: from ancient Egyptians and Mesopotamians to the Huns, Germanic hordes,

Visigoths, and Ottomans—and, within the last century, Depression-era farmers in the

Dust Bowl and temporary migrant laborers from the West African Sahel, a region that

has experienced prolonged drought. 29 According to Brown, climate change forced

migrations will build on or amplify previously established patterns: “even in the most

extreme, unanticipated natural disasters . . . migrants, if they have any choice, tend to

travel along pre-existing paths. . . . Most people displaced by environmental causes will

27
________. 1996. Environmental Concerns and International Migration. International Migration
Review 30, no. 1: 105-131.
28
________. 1996. Environmental Concerns and International Migration. International Migration
Review 30, no. 1: 105-131.
29
Brown, Oli. 2007. Climate Change and Forced Migration: Observations, projections and
implications. Geneva: United Nations Human Development Report.
16
find new homes within the boundaries of their own countries.”30 Echoing the above

policy recommendations, Brown also proposes solutions that are based on the

relaxation of border controls and a more robust form of legal protection via the

expansion of the term refugee. 31

If migration has always been an adaptation strategy, particularly for nomadic

pastoralists, the two most important differences concerning the current situation are:

1) that this particular climate change is driven by human activity; and 2) that we have

at least some ability to observe, anticipate, and plan for these massive displacements.

What most of the above stakeholders discussed above have in common is a

predisposition to accept these displacements and facilitate these flows of forced

migrants. As we shall see below, the UNHCR remains somewhat outside the

mainstream.

“Dur ab le So lutio ns”

The UNHCR’s involvement has given rise to another definitional—or

jurisdictional—dilemma. In the early 2000s, the UNHCR redefined its “Agenda for

Protection” around the concept of “durable solutions.” The “durable solutions”

approach focused long-term resettlement issues, but it also began to think about

states of origin and even the underlying causes of refugee flows such as the links

30
________. 2007. Climate Change and Forced Migration: Observations, projections and
implications. Geneva: United Nations Human Development Report.
31
CSA. 2009. Atlas on Selected Welfare Indicators of Ethiopian Households. Addis Ababa:
Central Statistics Agency.
17
between vulnerability to hydro-meteorological disasters and refugee flows. 32 Once this

connection was established it was a small step to envision “durable solutions” to

refugee crises through the lenses of humanitarian action and development. 33 And by

contextualizing refugee issues within this context, the UNHCR implicitly broadened the

parameters that might explain refugee flows.

This link also encouraged development-oriented “durable solutions” based on

technological rather than legal solutions and advocates for decreasing vulnerability in

order to keep would-be forced migrants where they are by reducing the vulnerability of

rural livelihoods in the developing world. These solutions resonate within the economic

development community and frequently incorporate the diffusion of new efficient

technologies like drip irrigation, synthetic fertilizers, or water purification systems.

Upon implementation, these technologies might indeed pay tremendous dividends, but

they can also unintentionally “lock in” path-dependent patterns that ultimately trap

rural populations in vulnerable livelihoods over the longer term. 34 For example, a new

irrigation system might temporarily yield greater crop production within a rural village

that had been struggling to produce adequate crops due to declining (and climate

32
UNHCR. 2008. Climate change, natural disasters and human displacement: a UNHCR
perspective. Geneva: UNHCR.
33
________. 2006. Rethinking durable solutions. In The State of the World's Refugees 2006.
Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press, UNHCR. 2006. Protracted refugee situations: the searchfor
practical solutions. In The State of the World's Refugees 2006. Oxford, UK: Oxford University
Press.
34
Beniston, Martin. 2004. Issues Relating to Environmental Change and Population Migrations. A
Climatologist's Perspective. In Environmental Change and its Implications for Population
Migration, ed. J. Unroh, M.S. Krol and N. Kliot. Dordrecht, The Netherlands: Kluwer Academic
Publishers, Berger, Thomas. 2004. Innovation as an Alternative to Migration? Exemplary Results
from a Multiple-Agent Programming Model Applied to Chile. In Environmental Change and its
Implications for Population Migration, ed. J. Unroh, M.S. Krol and N. Kliot. Dordrecht, The
Netherlands: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
18
change associated) annual rainfall. Improved crop production due to the new, more

efficient irrigation system might encourage local farmers to expect greater productivity

in the future, and as a result, they may decide to have more children (or, more likely,

more of their children will survive into adulthood). By eventually increasing the village’s

population, the introduction of this technological solution will have placed more people

at risk if the water supply dwindles due to overexploitation or the persistence of the

drought. Or, by building a sea wall around their capital, Maldivians might believe they

have provided themselves with protection from the ocean; although adequate to stave

off the slow encroach of rising sea levels, the wall may not provide protection from

cyclones or another tsunami.

This kind of speculation is obviously fraught with uncertainty, but it

encapsulates the challenge facing anyone who proposes durable solutions. Moreover,

this oversimplified, contrived example also highlights the ethical quandary associated

with this problem. Those who uncritically accept the fact that there will be enormous

migrations on a scale previously unseen must reconcile this approach with their

obligation to mitigate environmental damage and strengthen vulnerable livelihoods

wherever this is possible—their failure to do so might well contradict the desires (to

remain in place) of the very people they intend to serve. They forget that migration is

a combination of push and pull, not just a push. On the other hand, technological

solutions that mitigate the impact of climate change will almost certainly not work

absent more comprehensive policies that address other facets of peoples’ livelihoods.

19
Use o f T er m in olo g y in t his Re po rt

Strategies such as using the term refugee and/or employing the broadest

possible definition of people who will be displaced by climate change (in order to

generate outsized estimates of migrants) have succeeded in gaining the media’s and

the public’s attention. However, when researchers or policymakers employ these

tactics, they ultimately fail to advance our understanding of this phenomenon because

they have tended to sidetrack valuable conversations about methodology with

sensationalistic arguments and claims. The juxtaposition of these arguments’

sensationalism and cynical calculation with the conservatism and painstaking

methodological self-criticism of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC)

only highlights the absurdity of the former. As we shall see below, the IPCC may be

conservative, but the appropriate response should be objective, not politically self-

interested.

Therefore, this paper will employ contextually specific, conservative parameters,

and will make underlying assumptions explicit; this practice derives from the belief that

the seriousness of this problem needs no further sensationalization and that accurate

numbers will serve as a better basis for sound policymaking than hyped numbers. In

practical terms, this means that the figures generated by this paper’s systems

dynamics model will be scrutinized and checked against reality and common sense.

A final word about terms and definitions. Researchers have been calling for

terminological consensus for the better part of a decade—or longer. Because the word

refugee already has a specific legal definition and its use is contested by numerous

20
stakeholders, this paper will eschew it. Except when quoting others, this paper will use

the following two phrases interchangeably to refer to those people forced to migrate

as a result of climate change: “climate change-forced migrants” and “climate change-

induced migrants.” The decision to avoid use of refugee should in no way be

interpreted as an attempt to dispel claims about the marginalization and persecution

that many climate change-forced migrants face. Indeed, the relative marginalization and

failure of development (so called) to reach agro-pastoral communities serves as a

starting point of this paper’s analysis, and is addressed in its systems dynamics model.

In fact, one of the outputs of the present study is the realization that the existing

debate overlooks one of the most critical populations in this system: temporary

migrants who may leave farms for months each year to supplement the diminishing

returns on their farm assets with income from off-farm labor in towns and cities.

21
C HAPT ER 3

L IT ERATUR E R EVI EW : E FFORTS T O E XA MI NE TH E R ELATI O NSHIP B ET W EEN C L IM ATE

C HA NG E A ND H U MA N M IGRA TIO N

The definitional disparities delineated above concerning the identity of people

forced to migrate due to climate and environmental change have not prevented experts

from studying the relationship between these phenomena. Below, I will consider four

different attempts to address the scale and scope of the problem of forced migration

due to climate change: Norman Myers, the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change

(IPCC), Britain’s Stern Review, and the International Organization for Migration’s (IOM)

research on the subject (International Dialogue on Migration Expert Seminar: Migration

and the Environment and “Climate Change and Migration: Improving Methodologies to

Estimate Flows”). There are may other published estimates, but most can be traced

back to Myers, the IPCC, the Stern Review, and the IOM.

Each of the four perspectives incorporates its own particular set of assumptions

and inconsistent, competing terminology; yet, at the same time, these viewpoints also

draw extensively on one another’s work in a potentially confusing and self-reinforcing

manner. In the hope of establishing greater clarity, I will consider each effort

individually—starting with earliest (Norman Myers) and working up to the most recent

(IOM)—to parse the differences in methodology and establish the reliability of their

estimates. The literature review reveals that significant conceptual and methodological

improvements have been made since Norman Myers’s first estimates, but many of the

key issues have not yet been resolved adequately, such as how to count temporary

22
migrants who leave their rural households but do not return permanently in urban

centers.

Nor ma n M ye rs

For many years, the most frequently cited estimates of the number of people

who will be—or already have been—forced to migrate due to climate change have come

from the British academic Norman Myers. By 1993, Myers had joined the growing

number of critics who had identified climate change as a potential driver of human

migration. He defined “environmental refugees” as: “people who can no longer gain a

secure livelihood in their erstwhile homelands because of drought, soil erosion,

desertification, and other environmental problems. In their desperation, they feel they

have no alternative but to seek sanctuary elsewhere. . . . Not all of them have fled their

countries; many are internally displaced.”35 Given his use of the past and present tense,

Myers has accurately situated this issue as an immediate concern rather than a problem

of the remote future. It has been more than fifteen years since Myers initially raised

this issue, so it’s fair to ask: Who are these “environmental refugees”? And how many

of them are there? Unfortunately, as we shall see, there is no easy way to begin

answering these questions.

Thanks to his prolonged engagement with this subject, Myers has frequently

updated his own calculations. For example, at the 13th Organization for Security and

Co-operation Economic in Europe’s (OCSE) Economic Forum in Prague, he declared,

35
Myers, Norman. 1993. Environmental Refugees in a Globally Warmed World. BioScience 43,
no. 11: 752-761.
23
“[In] 1995, these environmental refugees totaled at least 25 million people, compared

with 27 million traditional refugees. . . . The environmental refugees total could well

double between 1995 and 2010[, and] when global warming takes hold, there could be

as many as 200 million people . . .”36 This new figure is a 50-million-person increase

from his original “rough estimate.”37

To address the reliability and accuracy of Myers’s numbers, we must consider

their provenance, his methodology, and the assumptions he makes in order to derive

them. First, he assumes the worst-case, business-as-usual scenario from the IPCC; next

he designates 2050 as the “marker year” (i.e., the year through which he counts

aggregate “environmental refugees”); he assumes a 2050 world population of 10

billion; finally, he limits his analysis to exclusively developing countries. 38 As for specific

categories of “environmental refugees,” Myers identifies broad and diverse groups,

such as:

• people in drought-stricken parts of Africa who have had to migrate in order to

receive food aid;

• river delta and small island nation residents displaced by the loss of dry land due

to sea level rise;

• economic migrants in Mexico who have lost their rural livelihoods and have

moved either to cities in Mexico or to the U.S.;

36
Myers, N. 2005. Environmental Refugees: An Emergent Security Issue. Prague: Organization
for the Security and Co-operation in Europe.
37
Myers, Norman. 1993. Environmental Refugees in a Globally Warmed World. BioScience 43,
no. 11: 752-761.
38
________. 1993. Environmental Refugees in a Globally Warmed World. BioScience 43, no.
11: 752-761.
24
• farmers in China and India who have been overtaken by population growth and

shortages of agricultural plots, or who have been displaced by public works

projects like the Three Gorges Dam. 39

These figures do not include people displaced by chronic water shortages, nor do they

account for those who have fled conflicts over natural resources that have become

more scarce due to climate change—chiefly because many of these people also fit into

one of the other categories listed above. 40 To determine an aggregate total of likely

“environmental refugee” from these groups of affected populations, Myers relies on a

set of assumptions about the percentage of what fractions of the affected populations

are likely to migrate.

How reliable are these numbers? On the one hand, Myers is justified in focusing

on the developing world, particularly Africa and Asia, given developing world

demographics and the nature (and vulnerability) of livelihoods in these regions. On the

other hand, Myers’s numbers may be dramatically inflated due to the same factors. For

example, the World Health Organization predicts that the incidence of infectious

diseases like malaria and dengue will increase due to global warming. 41 There are

currently 1.2 billion people at high risk of malaria, 86 percent of whom live in Africa and

39
________. 1993. Environmental Refugees in a Globally Warmed World. BioScience 43, no.
11: 752-761, Myers, Norman. 2002. Environmental Refugees: A Growing Phenomenon of the
21st Century. Philosophical Transactions: Biological Sciences 357, no. 1420: 609-613, Myers,
N. 2005. Environmental Refugees: An Emergent Security Issue. Prague: Organization for the
Security and Co-operation in Europe.
40
Myers, N. 2005. Environmental Refugees: An Emergent Security Issue. Prague: Organization
for the Security and Co-operation in Europe.
41
WHO. 2007. Climate Change and Human Health-Risks and Responses Summary. Geneva: World
Health Organization, World Meteorological Organization, United Nations Development
Programme.
25
Southeast Asia.42 Given that these are the same people whose livelihoods are most

vulnerable to climate change, how many of the tens of millions potentially displaced

Ethiopians, Kenyans, Indians, and Bangladeshis might contract and die from malaria

before migrating? More ominously, we do not know how the malaria prevalence among

migratory populations will affect the policies of potential receiving nations in Oceana,

North America, and Europe—nations, that is, with low or zero prevalence of malaria. It

is reasonable to conclude that potential host nations will set policy to ensure that

Myers’s “environmental refugees” are kept in situ and do not pose a public health

threat to their own populations, especially if their own populations become more

vulnerable to malaria due to global warming.

Figure 2 Estimated Incidence of Malaria per 1,000 people, 2006. Source: WHO, 2008.

42
________. 2008. World Malaria Report 2008. Geneva: World Health Organization.
26
Or, taking a more optimistic approach, what if economic growth or the

implementation of new technologies reduced the vulnerability livelihoods in the

developing world? Alternatively, what if Myers’s assumption of the IPCC’s worst-case

scenarios proves to be inaccurate and carbon emissions are dramatically reduced due

to technological innovations, prohibitively expensive fuel costs, or some combination of

the two? Given the current concentration of atmospheric greenhouse gases and the

lifetime of those gases in the atmosphere (e.g., 100 years for carbon dioxide), global

warming and anthropogenic climate change would result even if humans were to

somehow cut carbon emissions to zero today. 43 But, on the other hand, it is

unnecessarily alarmist of Myers to assume the worst-case, business-as-usual scenario

as he continues to do, especially given the progress at recent conferences of parties

since Bali in December 2007.

The I nter g ov er n ment al Pa nel o n Climat e C han ge (IP C C)

The scientists on the IPCC have accepted Myers’s holistic framing of this issue in

terms of livelihood vulnerabilities, but they also claim that all forecasts are, “at best,

guesswork,” and that “disaggregating the causes of migration is highly problematic, not

least since individual migrants may have multiple motivations and be displaced by

43
Freund, Paul, Anthony Adegbulugbe, Oyvind Christophersen, Hisashi Ishitani, William Moomaw,
and Jose Moreira. 2005. Introduction. In IPCC Special Report on Carbon Dioxide Capture and
Storage , ed. Eduardo Calvo and Eberhard Jochem:51-74. Cambridge, New York, Melbourne,
Madrid, Cape Town, Singapore, Sào Paulo: Cambridge University Press.
27
multiple factors.”44 For this reason, the IPCC’s Fourth Assessment Report eschews

numerical predictions of the number of people who will potentially be forced to migrate

due to climate change. By way of explanation, the report argues that “normative and

subjective elements are embedded in assessing the uniqueness and importance of the

threatened system, [as well as] equity considerations regarding the distribution of

impacts, the degree of risk aversion, and assumptions regarding the feasibility and

effectiveness of potential adaptations.”45 Some might contend that this explanation is

a dodge—another way of saying “there’s too much uncertainty”—but the IPCC is

structurally predisposed to err on the side of caution.

If, after Myers’s alarmism, the IPCC’s Fourth Assessment Report seems to

downplay the problem, one must recall that the panel’s publications are consensus-

driven documents written and edited, in part, by representatives from countries that

are most responsible for anthropogenic climate change. While it’s become common

knowledge that negotiations at the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate

44
Schneider, S.H., S. Semenov, A. Patwardhan, I. Burton, C.H.DD. Magadza, M. Oppenheimer,
A.B. Pittock, A. Rahman, J.B. Smith, A. Suarez, and F. Yamin. 2007. Addressing Key
Vulnerabilities and the Risk from Climate Change. In Climate Change 2007: Impacts, Adaptation
and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Fourth Assessment Report of the
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change , ed. S.H. Schneider, S. Semenov and A.
Patwardhan:31. Cambridge: Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, Wilbanks, T.J., P.
Romero Lankao, M. Bao, F. Berkhout, S. Cairncross, J.-P. Ceron, M. Kapshe, R. Muir-Wood, and R.
Zapata-Marti. 2007. Industry, Settlement and Society. In Climate Change 2007: Impacts,
Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Fourth Assessment Report
of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, ed. T. Wilbanks and P. Romero Lankao:58.
Cambridge: Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change.
45
Schneider, S.H., S. Semenov, A. Patwardhan, I. Burton, C.H.DD. Magadza, M. Oppenheimer,
A.B. Pittock, A. Rahman, J.B. Smith, A. Suarez, and F. Yamin. 2007. Addressing Key
Vulnerabilities and the Risk from Climate Change. In Climate Change 2007: Impacts, Adaptation
and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Fourth Assessment Report of the
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change , ed. S.H. Schneider, S. Semenov and A.
Patwardhan:31. Cambridge: Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change.
28
Change (UNFCCC) conferences of parties are rife with conflict, the same is also true of

the process by which the IPCC assessment reports themselves are drafted. 46

Disagreements over the scope and wording of these reports are frequently contentious

and nearly always result in compromised, cautious language. Again, this has less to due

with scientific caution and more to do with politics. Before the publication of the IPCC’s

Fourth Assessment Report in 2007, the Boston Globe reported that, “[a]ccording to

IPCC rules, all governments had to sign off on the document; its release was preceded

by four days of intense negotiations with officials from more than 100 countries.”47

Most importantly, one must also remember that any predictions that the IPCC

does make are carefully stated and described by the degree of uncertainty that informs

the prediction. The IPCC’s published estimates are almost always based on not one but

many simulations of numerous different climate models. As yet, rigorous, peer-

reviewed models that combine climate and migration are almost nonexistent (and the

one included in this document should only be considered a first draft of one). In short,

there has been no scientific basis upon which IPCC scientists could generate a

prediction or support any one figure.

The Ste rn Re vie w

Although the 2006 Stern Review was published some months prior to the IPCC’s

Fourth Assessment Report, I consider the two sources to be more or less

46
McDonald, Frank. 2007. U.S. and EU Deadlocked at Climate Talks. The Irish Times, December
14, 2007, 1.
47
Daley, Beth. 2007. A Climate Change Warning: Panel Says Humans Are Probably Causing Shifts
Around World. Boston Globe , April 7, 2007.
29
contemporaneous, especially given the long negotiation process inherent to producing

each IPCC report. In many ways, the Stern Review and IPCC are interrelated: the Stern

Review and the IPCC authors both draw upon the same source material; and the Stern

Review often cites previous IPCC reports while the Stern Review is itself cited in IPCC’s

Fourth Assessment Report.

Situated somewhere between Myers’s alarmism and the IPCC’s obfuscation, the

Stern Review relies on the work of the former, which it augments with additional work

from experts at the Tyndall Centre for Climate Change Research. Wherever possible,

the Stern Review relies on straightforward objective criteria and mathematic

formulations along the lines of:

Number of Forced Migrants = Area of Land Lost x Population Density

The equation shown here is a simplification of those used in the Stern Review, and is

based on the work of Warren. 48 But, unlike the IPCC, the Stern Review also incorporates

more heterogeneous criteria, based on case studies (discussed below), to estimate the

full scale and scope of the problem. As a result, the report discusses potential numbers

of displaced people, “rising sea levels and other climate-driven changes could drive

millions of people to migrate: more than a fifth of Bangladesh could be under water

with a 1m rise in sea levels, which is a possibility by the end of the [21st] century.”49

Of course, the drawback to equations such as the one above is that they tell you

nothing about when or why or how people might be induced to migrate. In short, this

48
Stern, N. 2006. Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, Warren, Rachel, Chris Hope, Michael Mastrandrea, Richard Tol, Neil Adger, and
Irene Lorenzoni. 2006. Spotlighting Impacts Functions in Integrated Assessment: Research
Report Prepared for the Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change. Norwich, England:
Tyndall Centre for Climate Change Research, 91.
49
Stern, N. 2006. Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
30
type of modeling overemphasizes the climatic component and fails to accommodate

the human systems. For example, the calculation above does not take account of the

key factors that explain (as will be shown below) migration. Indeed, the IOM has found

that existing models have failed to replicate observed human migrations to

environmental changes such as deforestation and desertification. 50

Rather than address the proximate causes of migration, the Stern Review

authors tacitly side with the IPCC against Myers: they stop short of offering half-

century projections of climate change-forced migrants. And they do so for much the

same reasons as the IPCC: “the exact number of people who will actually be displaced

or forced to migrate will depend on the level of investment, planning, and resources at

a government’s disposal to defend these areas or provide access to public services and

food aid.”51 However, the Stern Review does accept Myers’s disaggregated climate-

driven migration projections by region and vulnerability, and it bases its figures on

particularized population-growth estimates much the same way he does. For example,

the report indicates that between 30 and 550 million people would be at risk of hunger

with a temperature rise of 2-3°C, and that as many as 4.4 billion people would also

experience water shortages. 52 Unfortunately, the report neglects to say how many of

these people are double counted for both food and water shortages, or what fraction

of the people who experience these shortages would be likely to migrate as a coping

strategy.

50
IOM. 2008. Expert Seminar: Migration and the Environment. Red Book Series: International
Dialogue on Migration. Geneva: International Organization for Migration.
51
Stern, N. 2006. Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
52
________. 2006. Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
31
The Stern Review includes case studies that highlight the connection between

forced migrants, climate change, and conflicts over scarce natural resources. The

conflicts could either be caused by migrants who are in search of pasture land and

water, as has been the case between Ugandans and Kenyan pastoralists and Ethiopians

and Somalis, or intrastate conflicts could result in cross-border refugees as was the

case in Mali in the 1970s and 1980s and is currently the case in Darfur. 53 This

conflation of potential cause and effect of forced migration—or of multiple causes

resulting in migration—demonstrates both how complicated this situation can be as

well as the necessity of using clear, precise language when discussing these issues.

(Unfortunately, as we shall see below, productive discourse has been hampered by

experts’ failure to do so.)

The I nter nat io na l O r gan iza tion for M igr ation (I O M)

In 2008, the IOM published two important texts, its Expert Seminar: Migration

and the Environment and Climate Change and Migration: Improving Methodologies to

Estimate Flows. The former is a product of a two-day expert seminar on migration and

the environment that was organized by the IOM and the United Nations Population Fund

(UNFPA) and attended by policymakers, researchers, and practitioners. Seminar

participants defined the climate and migration relationship by dividing it into four

categories, which are addressed discretely in the final report:

1. the impact of gradual environmental change on migration;

53
________. 2006. Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
32
2. the impact of extreme environmental events on migration;

3. the impact of migration on the environment; and

4. the interaction of these phenomena with the potential for conflict.

These four typologies also push the definitional boundaries of the relationship in such a

way that implicitly critiques the first methodologies discussed above. Whereas those

sources took the phenomenon of climate change as a starting point and then sought to

explain how it could impact migration, the IOM Expert Seminar approaches the subject

from the opposite direction, from a migration perspective, which opens up the field of

inquiry and addresses the root causes of climate change-driven migration.

The IOM’s classification and analysis demonstrate that there is no one cause-

and-effect process through which climate and environment factor into one’s decision to

migrate. The same economic, cultural, and social forces still apply and should therefore

be used to explain climate change-induced migration.

Whether or not households turn to migration as a coping strategy and

what form and duration this migration assumes can be explained partly by

factors that are: economic—e.g. differences in available financial

resources, security of land tenure, in transport/relocation costs and in

host area employment opportunities; social—e.g. family composition, age,

availability of networks to facilitate relocation, level of social mobility and

educational attainment; and cultural—e.g. differences in the cultural costs

of moving.

Predicting the exact nature of migration patterns in relation to

gradual deterioration in environmental conditions is complicated by these

33
factors and how they interact at the individual, household, community

and national levels. 54

The strength of the IOM approach here is that it draws together practitioners and

researchers. But models such as the Tyndall Centre’s, which describe particular human

behavior patterns without accounting for those humans’ livelihoods, will be hindered by

significant blind spots because they are likely to incorporate the impact of the

livelihoods on the local environment (i.e., more intensive farming in response to erratic

rainfall).

Another benefit to the IOM’s approach is that it understands that the climatic,

environmental, and human systems are interdependent: “Participants noted that . . .

poor small-scale producers tend to live in degraded areas with marginal plots of land

and little freshwater. To cope with these challenges many have overexploited the land,

fueling a downward spiral of more degradation and more poverty.”55 Indeed, these are

the factors that contribute to the familiar “overshoot and collapse” pattern of growth,

as well as desertification of marginal agricultural lands.

The IOM Expert Seminar delineates a general framework for understanding the

relationship between climate change and human migration. Thanks to the report’s

clearly defined purpose and its input from both practitioners and researchers, it proves

a more cogent roadmap than even the academic Forced Migration Review’s special

issue on “Climate Change and Migration” from October 2008. The Expert Seminar,

54
IOM. 2008. Expert Seminar: Migration and the Environment. Red Book Series: International
Dialogue on Migration. Geneva: International Organization for Migration.
55
________. 2008. Expert Seminar: Migration and the Environment. Red Book Series:
International Dialogue on Migration. Geneva: International Organization for Migration.
34
however stops short of authorizing specific analytical methodologies. Kniveton et al.’s

IOM-sponsored research paper Migration: Improving Methodologies to Estimate Flows

takes up this subject, first by considering the effects of climate change and the drivers

of migration separately, and then “exploring the methodological options for quantifying

the additional numbers of migrants that may be expected in response to changes in the

climate caused by human activities.”56 These options, which may be used in concert

with one another, include a Sustainable Livelihoods Approach (SLA), New Economics of

Labor Migration (NELM), and Agent-Based Modeling (ABM).

The SLA is rooted in development discourse and was conceived by the UK’s

Department for International Development (DFID), and its “underlying idea is that

families possess a variety of natural, physical, financial, human, and social assets, which

are all used to maintain a family’s livelihood. If one of the assets suffers a loss, it can be

compensated for by falling back on the other available assets in the so-called asset-

pentagon.”57

56
Kniveton, Dominic, Kerstin Schmidt-Verkerk, Christopher Smith, and Richard Black. 2008.
Climate Change and Migration: Improving Methodologies to Estimate Flows. Geneva: International
Organization for Migration.
57
DFID. 1999. Sustainable Livelihoods Guidance Sheet. London: Department for International
Development, Kniveton, Dominic, Kerstin Schmidt-Verkerk, Christopher Smith, and Richard Black.
2008. Climate Change and Migration: Improving Methodologies to Estimate Flows. Geneva:
International Organization for Migration.
35
Figure 3 Sustainable Livelihoods Framework. Source: DFID, 1999.

The power behind SLA’s ability to explain climate change-induced migration is its

holistic viewpoint—it treats people like people and seeks to understand their means of

supporting themselves and coping with stresses and shocks. The problem with this

approach, however, is that it takes time and painstaking effort to truly understand a

group’s livelihood; another drawback is that it may still aggregate data (at the

community rather than national level) and thereby overlook more subtle local

inequalities. 58

As its name suggests, the NELM approach conceives of migration primarily as an

economic decision taken at the level of the household, whereby the migrant

58
Kniveton, Dominic, Kerstin Schmidt-Verkerk, Christopher Smith, and Richard Black. 2008.
Climate Change and Migration: Improving Methodologies to Estimate Flows. Geneva: International
Organization for Migration.
36
coordinates with nonmigrants and seeks employment elsewhere to supplement the

nonmigrants’ financial assets through remittances. In short, the NELM framework

equates migration with an attempt to diversify a household’s sources of income and

reduce collective risk. The real value of the NELM framework, however, is when it is

used conjointly with an SLA analysis, because when they are used together “the SLA

and NELM approaches provide a way of understanding how households respond to

climate shocks, and the extent to which migration is part of their response”; however,

the most common impediment to this combined approach is the lack of detailed

livelihood data for a community over an extended period of time. 59

Figure 4 SLA and NELM Approaches. Source: Knivedon et al., 2008

The second benefit of the combined SLA-NELM approach is that once one has

identified the key livelihood indicators, one can then devise a mathematical model that,

ultimately, can generate a numerical estimate of climate-induced migration flows based

59
________. 2008. Climate Change and Migration: Improving Methodologies to Estimate Flows.
Geneva: International Organization for Migration.
37
on individuals preferences, the predicted effects of climate change, and other situation-

specific inputs such as social assets, distance to a city, and other variables that affect

one’s ability to cope with stresses and shocks.

The IOM team advocates for Agent-Based Modeling (ABM) precisely because this

type of modeling allows modelers to program the way individuals will respond in certain

situations based on their beliefs and perceptions. “While numerous assets and

economic opportunities,” such as those accounted for in SLA and NELM analysis, “will

no doubt affect an individual’s wish to undertake migration as an adaptive response to

climate stresses and shocks, the decision will also be influenced by deeper cognitive

stimuli required to account for human bounded rationality.”

This idea of “bounded rationality” is crucial to our understanding of climate

change-forced migration. Agriculturalists may not migrate as soon as they perceive

that they can gain additional financial assets (as would the rational actor homo

economicus of the NELM approach). Instead, the potential migrant must make a series

of decisions based on historic trends (“This land is my ancestors’, many generations of

whom survived worse droughts than this.”), their current state (“My crops may be

failing, but I can borrow some money or eat fewer meals per day.”), and their

expectations about the future (“If I leave, then my neighbors who remain will take over

my landholding, and I will have nothing to return to.”).

The question remains: How should one account for individuals’ bounded

rationality and decision-making in one’s model? Kniveton et al. address this question

head-on:

38
As a statistical summary of the atmosphere over a prolonged period of

time, climate, and therefore climate change, is an abstract concept. In

simulating the migratory response of a community to the manifestations

of the climate system, one is therefore modeling people’s perceptions of

an abstract phenomenon. The influence of the unique cognitive responses

and attitudes of individuals towards these manifestations is therefore of

considerable importance in identifying the livelihood impact perceived to

occur by individuals and the importance of these in their current

existence. By including such aspects into the agent attributes of an ABM

and developing rules for the interaction of such agents, agent-based

modeling presents a means of simulation far more powerful than those of

alternative statistical analysis. 60

Some attributes may be “included” via the model’s original assumptions, such as a

coefficient that signifies how much emphasis potential migrants’ place on the expected

robustness of their livelihood relative to its current or past robustness. Alternatively,

one might “include” these attributes by modeling them dynamically, allowing them to

change as conditions change. Either way this information must be tested against

historical data or, where none exists, proxy measurements. But the key is to include

these seemingly nonnumerical “soft variables” in one’s model.

As we shall see below, one might just as easily use a systems dynamics model to

replicate the same behavior—or produce the same results as—an agent-based model,

but the advantage of a systems dynamics model is the way it graphically depicts the

structure of the system and reveals the relationships among numerous factors. In

60
________. 2008. Climate Change and Migration: Improving Methodologies to Estimate Flows.
Geneva: International Organization for Migration.
39
short, a systems model is better equipped to represent the key reinforcing and

balancing feedback loops, rather than the behavior of individual agents.

40
C HAPT ER 4

S YSTEMS D Y NA MI CS AN D C LI MA TE C HA NG E -F O RCED M I GRATI O N : L I VEL IHO ODS A ND

M I GRATI O N I N W OLLO , E TH IOP IA

There are no side effects—only effects. Those we thought of in advance, the ones we like, we call the

main, or intended, effects, and take credit for them. The ones we didn’t anticipate, the ones that came

around and bit us in the rear—those are the “side effects.” —John Sterman, “All Models Are Wrong,” 2002

Once the definitional problem has been solved, it should be easier to identify and

protect the different types of forced migrants. Indeed, one of the key challenges

remains distinguishing between internally displaced environmentally induced migrants

and economic migrants. Most of the experts above, from Black to Brown to Myers,

make use of some form of modeling to generate their predictions of climate change-

induced migrants. The Stern Review, for example, draws upon a Tyndall Centre model

that generates a number of displaced coastal peoples by examining the expected

amount of coastal land loss due to soil erosion. The only problem with this model is

that it draws upon climate inputs while not making use of the related human systems.

Other models rely on Pareto-type optimizations that examine one variable.

The advantage of a systems dynamical model is that it can replicate both detail

complexity and dynamic complexity. Systems models can incorporate both a huge array

of diverse inputs and account for the way they interact in a dynamic fashion over time.

This integrated model below shows how climate-driven, rural-to-urban migrations

(resulting from drought, floods, or sea-level rise) may accelerate existing rural-urban

41
migration patterns. Moreover, it can help us differentiate between environmentally

induced migrants and economic migrants.

Figure 5 Climate change and Agricultural Production. Source: Ginnetti, 2009.

42
Figure 6 Livelihoods Inputs and Rural-Urban Migration. Source: Ginnetti, 2009.

Another critical advantage to a systems dynamics model is that the data, structure, and

assumptions are all presented with maximum transparency. Norman, Black, and Brown all employ

heuristics or modeling strategies, but in their work, it is much more difficult to determine what

the authors’ assumptions are and how they define the relationships between variables to

generate predictions. The difference in transparency is important for two reasons—clarity and

comprehensibility on the one hand, and adaptability on the other. In a systems model, anyone

can change the initial parameters to generate new results. One might want to do this if they

disagree with the model’s assumptions or dispute its source data; more importantly, one might

also want to change the parameters to adapt the model to other communities. This model limits

its focus to one region of Ethiopia that is characterized by a fairly homogenous livelihood

strategy. To apply this model to a comparable subsistence farming community in Bangladesh

one would change the initial population data and assumptions about variables like birth rate.

43
Instead of land loss due to soil erosion, one would add expected land loss due to sea-level rise

and increased river delta flooding but the overall structure of the model would largely remain

intact.

Met ho do log y

Location: For this analysis, I chose to model the robustness of rural livelihoods in (and

migration out of) the Wag Hemra, Northern Wollo, and Southern Wollo zones in

Ethiopia’s northeastern highlands region of Amhara (hereafter referred to collectively

as Wollo).

Figure 7 Map of Ethiopia and its Northeastern Highlands. Source: USAID/Ginnetti, 2009.

44
There are a number of reasons to test the model on this region. First, these

three zones are rural, with more than 90 percent of the population deriving livelihoods

from agricultural (or agricultural and livestock) production: “The undiversified nature of

local livelihoods is disturbing: despite recurring droughts, falling soil fertility and

shrinking per-capital land and livestock resources, smallholder rain-fed farming remains

the core of Wollo’s economy.”61 Second, livelihood data for Wollo is relatively abundant

for the period from 1990 to today, which is likely the result of the high-profile food-

security crises during the 1980s. Third, there is also data on Wollo for two interrelated

trends: increased dependence on food aid due to a shortfall in per-capita production

and on rural-urban out-migration. 62

Model: As shown in Figures 5 and 6 above, this model integrates the climate-affected

agro-pastoral production system into Wollo’s primary livelihood system, which in turn

provides a major input into the region’s rural-urban migration trend. In short it

quantifies the effect of climate change on livelihoods and the effect of livelihood

robustness on migration.

61
Sharp, Kay and Stephen Devereux. 2004. Destitution in Wollo (Ethiopia): chronic poverty as a
crisis of household and community livelihoods. Journal of Human Development and Capabilities
5, no. 2: 227 - 247.
62
Golini, Antonio, Mohammed Said, Oliviero Casacchia, Celia Reynaud, Sara Basso, Lorenzo
Cassata, and Massimiliano Crisci. 2001. Migration and Urbanization in Ethiopia, with Special
Reference to Addis Ababa. In-Depth Studies from the 1994 Population and Housing Census in
Ethiopia. Addis Ababa, Ethiopia and Rome, Italy: Central Statistics Authority (CSA) and Institute
for Population Research (IPR), Sharp, Kay and Stephen Devereux. 2004. Destitution in Wollo
(Ethiopia): chronic poverty as a crisis of household and community livelihoods. Journal of Human
Development and Capabilities 5, no. 2: 227 - 247.
45
The model simulations run for 60 years (720 months, in 1-month time steps) so

that I could: a) compare available data from 1990–2000 with the model-generated

data; and b) project results out through 2050, which has become such a widely used

target year in climate negotiations and climate changed-forced migration predictions.

The sources of data on agricultural production and livestock holdings come from

USAID, and from the UN’s Food and Agricultural Organization and World Food

Programme. Demographic and migration data come from Ethiopia’s 1994 census, a

1999 Labor Force Survey, and a joint analysis of them produced by Ethiopia’s Central

Statistics Authority (CSA) and the Institute for Population Research in Rome. The two

systems are bridged using DFID’s livelihoods framework and based upon Maxwell, Sharp,

and Devereux’s research on Ethiopian livelihoods.

In this model, agricultural production is dependent upon Wollo’s carrying

capacity and the erosion of it due to climate change and intensive farming practices, as

well as by previous production. Livestock production also depends upon Wollo’s

livestock carrying capacity, the livestock population, and the population’s reproduction

and mortality rates.

When “activated”, climate change impacts the model in two ways: first, by

reducing the yield of the harvest by 10 percent during months 120–240 (i.e., 1

percent/year). This would be due to climate’s effect on the weather during the growing

season by increasing the frequency of droughts and floods and by changing

precipitation patterns). The second way that climate impacts the system is more

46
indirect, and occurs after a delay, by reducing the capacity of the land to regenerate its

carrying capacity.

Agricultural (cereal) and livestock (cows and oxen) production are measured

first in a disaggregated fashion. To integrate these assets into a more useful livelihoods

framework and derive per-household measures of financial and physical capital (i.e.,

agricultural and livestock production, respectively), the model weighs the region’s

aggregate harvest and herd size against the rural population and the number of people

per household. For example:

Physical Capital Per Household = Cows / (Rural Population / People/Household) =

Cows x People Household / Rural Population

The model produces per-household natural assets by weighing the carrying capacity (in

hectares of arable land and grazing land) against the population and number of people

per household; and it calculates per-household human capital by measuring the

educated population against the total population. This model does not account for per-

household social and political capital.

Household livelihood robustness is computed by adding each type of capital into

an aggregate livelihood score. I assigned an individual weight to each of the dynamic

capital factors based on individuals’ ranking of them in surveys conducted by Sharp and

Devereux. They found that financial and physical capital were the most important

factors, though in part because the majority of households already sharecropped their

47
land. 63 Sharp and Devereux surveyed individuals to examine the correlation between

different types of capital and destitution, which is based upon a household’s ability to

meet its subsistence needs, its access to productive assets, and its dependence on aid

or assistance.64 They also found that individuals place a higher value on assets over

income: “The centrality of productive resources in the definition and quantification) of

destitution reflects the now widely accepted observation that, in defining poverty,

‘poor people focus on assets rather than income.’”65 Whereas Sharp and Devereux

incorporate the different types of household capital into a snapshot of livelihood from

which they analyze poverty and destitution, I incorporate those variables into an

aggregate livelihood score that I use to model migration flows.

The change in livelihood robustness is then used to generate a measure of

expected livelihood robustness, which is in turn interpreted as migration pressure. The

reason for generating a value for expected livelihood robustness is that one’s decision

to migrate is informed by one’s current livelihood robustness and one’s expectation of

future livelihood outlook. The household strategy depends on two sets of factors: one

has to do with the available assets; the other has to do with physical and economic

63
Sharp, Kay and Stephen Devereux. 2004. Destitution in Wollo (Ethiopia): chronic poverty as a
crisis of household and community livelihoods. Journal of Human Development and Capabilities
5, no. 2: 227 - 247.
64
Devereux, Stephen. 2000. Destitution in Ethiopia's Northeast Highlands (Amhara Region).
Addis Ababa: IDS and Save the Children (UK), Sharp, Kay and Stephen Devereux. 2004.
Destitution in Wollo (Ethiopia): chronic poverty as a crisis of household and community
livelihoods. Journal of Human Development and Capabilities 5, no. 2: 227 - 247, Sharp, Kay,
Stephen Devereux, and Yared Amare. 2003. Destitution in Ethiopia's Northeastern Highlands
(Amhara National Regional State). Addis Ababa, Ethiopia: Institute of Development Studies and
Save the Children (UK).
65
Sharp, Kay and Stephen Devereux. 2004. Destitution in Wollo (Ethiopia): chronic poverty as a
crisis of household and community livelihoods. Journal of Human Development and Capabilities
5, no. 2: 227 - 247.
48
conditions: The household has to take into account both potential returns from a given

action, and the probability of realizing those returns. While potential returns are a

function of factors like soil fertility, levels of input, and prices, the probability of

realizing those returns has to do with less predictable variables such as rainfall, pest

infestations, and market conditions, and this is where the weight of history on decision-

making comes into effect. 66 In short, this paper hypothesizes that the decision to

migrate is based less than the state of one’s livelihood at any given moment in time

than it is by the overall directional trend in one’s livelihood.

Despite the availability of livelihood data, there is at least one major assumption

that informs this model: that the need for food assistance correlates with food

production. I felt confident making this assumption based upon the fact that Sharp and

Devereux found that Wollo’s economy is almost exclusively based on subsistence

farming.

The second major caveat concerns droughts and floods, which I deliberately left

out of the model. Floods and, especially, droughts may “shock the system” and

undermine livelihoods in Wollo, but disasters ironically generate a greater humanitarian

response than do gradual, “slow-onset” crises like the ongoing one in Wollo. 67 In short,

thanks to factors like the “CNN effect” whereby aid flows fastest to newsworthy

extreme events, there is a greater likelihood of a robust humanitarian response to

66
Evans, Hugh Emrys and Gazala Pirzada. 1995. Rural Households as Producers: Income
Diversification and the Allocation of Resources. In The Migration Experience in Africa , ed. J.
Baker and Tade Akin Aida:87-108. Uppsala, Sweden: Nordiska Afrikainstitutet.
67
Webster, Mackinnon, Justin Ginnetti, Peter Walker, Daniel Coppard, and Randolph Kent. 2008.
The Humanitarian Costs of Climate Change. Medford, MA: Feinstein International Center.
49
hydro-meteorological disasters than to a gradual “livelihood” disaster such as the

spread of destitution in Wollo. Even after the humanitarian reforms pursuant to the

Ethiopian famines of the 1980s, this continues to be a problem today, especially for

slow-onset crises driven by droughts.68 Therefore, while some disasters may trigger the

long-term deterioration of livelihoods not all of them do so, and it is due to this

uncertainty of response that I omitted extreme events from this model. If so desired,

one could add these phenomena very easily: one would simply build in a “pulse” event

that normally occurs once every 20 years; if climate change were to increase the

frequency of these events by 20 percent, one would simply adjust the amplitude and

frequency via a sine function.

A third caveat relates to its precursor and concerns food assistance and the

decision not to build it into the model. The advantage of including international food aid

and domestic food assistance (as delayed responses to the perceived shortfall in per-

capita crop production) is that these factors are certainly at play in the existing

system. Therefore, modeling them would more accurately reflect the structure of the

system and its state at any given moment in time. I chose not to incorporate them,

however, because these are endogenous factors controlled by exogenous forces

(international food-aid contributions). The humanitarian response to an ongoing, “slow-

onset” crisis like the on in Wollo depends not only on the conditions in Wollo but also

other crises and geopolitical forces. Modeling food assistance would have introduced

68
Glenzer, Kent. 2007. We Aren't the World: The Institutional Production of Partial Success. In
Niger 2005: Une Catastrophe si Naturelle, ed. Xavier Crombe and Jean-Herve Jezequel:117-144.
Paris: Medecins Sans Frontieres.
50
much more complexity into this model; furthermore, because poorly designed food-

assistance responses can even undermine the livelihood of intended beneficiaries by

distorting local market prices upon which their well being depends as has been the case

in recent humanitarian crises in Niger and the Horn of Africa. 69 Therefore, while adding

these variables would give the appearance of precision, there is no guarantee that

incorporating them would generate more accurate results.

A fourth assumption has to do with the focus on rural-urban migration. Given the

high rates of rural-rural migration within Ethiopia, many would argue that the out-

migrants from Wollo identified in this model would seek a new livelihood, or simply look

for temporary employment, in another rural locale.70 While rural-rural migration is

certainly an important trend at present, I choose to focus on rural-urban migration due

to the fact that it will likely become more pronounced if/when negative climate impacts

undermine rural livelihoods more generally in Ethiopia.

Finally, the model starts in a state of disequilibrium with respect to permanent

rural-urban migrants. Because rural-urban migration has been an ongoing phenomenon

in Ethiopia for more than half a decade, some of these forced migrants were “already in

the pipeline” as labor migrants.

Res ults an d Dis cuss io n

69
Lewin, Alexandra C. 2007. Niger's Famine and the Role of Food Aid. Ithaca, NY: Cornell
University, Maxwell, Daniel. 2007. Global Factors Shaping the Future of Food Aid: The
Implications for WFP. Disasters 33, no. S1: S25-S39.
70
Ezra, Markos and Gebre-Egziabher Kiros. 2001. Rural Out-Migration in the Drought Prone
Areas of Ethiopia: A Multilevel Analysis. International Migration Review 35, no. 3: 749-771.
51
The primary analysis compares a “climate change” scenario with a baseline case

with no climate impacts. The difference in results (agricultural and livestock production,

temporary and permanent migrants) allows one to measure the impact of climate

change on existing trends. For example, Figure 8 below shows the difference in

agricultural harvests with and without climate change:

Figure 8 Harvested Crops. Source: Ginnetti, 2009.

What we can see from this first graph is that climate change exacerbates the trend of

decreased crop yields that result from intensive farming practices. When we take into

account this change and population growth together, to derive a per-household

measure of financial capital (tons of cereal harvested/household), we observe a similar

pattern (Figure 9):

52
Figure 9 Financial Capital Per Household. Source: Ginnetti, 2009.

Figures 10-13 below reveal the impact of climate change and rural populating

growth on other measures of household capital. As one would expect, physical capital

(livestock/household) and natural capital (arable and grazing hectares/household) both

decay exponentially, whereas human capital is more stable because rural inhabitants are

consuming a truly renewable resource: education.

53
Figure 10 Cows. Source: Ginnetti, 2009.

Figure 11 Physical Capital Per Household. Source: Ginnetti, 2009.

54
Figure 12 Natural Capital Per Household. Source: Ginnetti, 2009.

Figure 13 Human Capital Per Household. Source: Ginnetti, 2009.

55
Figures 14-18 represent the how the declining household capital stocks impact

livelihood, expected livelihood, and migration pressure. The shape of the curves in

Figure 18 clearly illustrate that declining expectations of future livelihood robustness

result in a proportional increase in migration pressure.

Figure 14 Aggregate Livelihood Score Source: Ginnetti, 2009.

56
Figure 15 Livelihood Robustness. Source: Ginnetti, 2009.

Figure 16 Expected Livelihood Robustness. Source: Ginnetti, 2009.

57
Figure 17 Migration Pressure. Source: Ginnetti, 2009.

Figure 18 Expected Livelihood Robustness vs. Migration Pressure. Source: Ginnetti, 2009.

58
Finally, Figures 19-21 below show how climate change impacts population distribution.

Figure 19 Rural Population. Source: Ginnetti, 2009.

Figure 20 Temporary Rural-Urban Migrants. Source: Ginnetti, 2009.

59
Figure 21 Permanent Rural-Urban Migrants. Source: Ginnetti, 2009.

The most interesting result of the graphs is how little climate change impacts

livelihood robustness and rural-urban migration compared to population growth (were it

to continue growing at its current rate). As hypothesized, climate change does clearly

amplify the trends driven by population growth, but this effect is marginal. For

example, if one subtracts the number of permanent rural-urban migrants who would

have left their agro-pastoral livelihoods with climate change turned “off” from those

that migrated with climate change “on,” the accounts for slightly less than 300,000

out of more than 5 million migrants. So 300,000 “extra” people migrated due to the

climate impact. Had we let climate change continue to reduce yields at the rate of 10

percent/decade, the result is rather surprising:

60
Figure 22 Three Climate Scenarios: No Change, Temporary Change, Permanent Change. Source:
Ginnetti, 2009.

If one compares the model-generated population figures during months 1–120,

the results mirror the actual census data. For month 120, or 2001, both the model and

Ethiopia’s CSA predict a rural population of 4.2 million in Wollo; and for 2005 both the

model and the CSA indicate a rural population of just under 4.5 million. 71 And given

what we know about the rural/urban Wollo’s population distribution and its birth rate,

we can confirm that the number of out-migrants also match. What we do not know for

certain is precisely how many of Wollo’s out-migrants moved to urban or rural areas.

71
CSA. 2005. Population. Addis Ababa: Central Statistics Agency, Golini, Antonio, Mohammed
Said, Oliviero Casacchia, Celia Reynaud, Sara Basso, Lorenzo Cassata, and Massimiliano Crisci.
2001. Migration and Urbanization in Ethiopia, with Special Reference to Addis Ababa . In-Depth
Studies from the 1994 Population and Housing Census in Ethiopia. Addis Ababa, Ethiopia and
Rome, Italy: Central Statistics Authority (CSA) and Institute for Population Research (IPR).
61
The continued climate change produces just a few more migrants than

temporary climate change. This suggests that once livelihoods have deteriorated to a

certain point, the extra impact of climate change is less significant than other factors.

Does this mean that climate change is not going to be a problem for residents of

Wollo? Of course not, and the reason is that livelihoods have not deteriorated, and are

not likely to deteriorate, as they do in the model. This is due to the fact that that

remittances, development aid, and humanitarian responses to Wollo’s disasters will

continue to support local livelihoods. What the model does say about climate change

and agro-pastoral livelihoods in Wollo is that the latter will remain very vulnerable to

the former, especially if the rural population continues to grow at the current rate.

What model also suggests is that in a world of limited resources the funds that are

allocated to Wollo should support measures that reduce population growth.

62
C HAPT ER 5

C O N CLUSIO N : A L OOK A H EAD A T F URTHER R ESEARCH O PP ORTU NIT IES

Can one extrapolate from this paper’s model to generate a global total number

of climate migrants? The answer is clearly No. Each climate-driven migration depends

on “push” and “pull” factors particular to the potential migrant’s livelihood.

Instead, what is needed most is additional livelihood mapping and data collection.

Modeling discrete livelihood clusters would be the best way to overlay anticipated

climate scenarios on top of livelihood zones. Combining these two types of regionally

specific data is the best way to scale up this research if one were interested in

generating global estimates of climate change-forced migrants.

Another pressing concern is the need to build consensus around a description to

replace “environmental,” “climate,” and “climate change” refugees. If the

sensationalism of these terms initially drew interest to this issue, that utility has long

since diminished. Within the last year, Forced Migration Review, IOM, UNHCR, and

UNESCO, have each published articles and reports that eschew the use of the terms

climate change refugee and environmental refugee and call for the adoption of a

common terminology. The recent movement away from these terms represents a step

in the right direction, but it’s just the first step. There are still gaps in the mental

models, such how to account for temporarily displaced climate migrants. Academics

and policy makers both need to begin using the same language in the same way when

writing or speaking about this complex problem.

63
With the publication of each new assessment report, IPCC scientists have stated

with increasing confidence that climate change is real and that its impacts will be felt

sooner rather than later. In step with the growing consensus, much of the recent

scholarship about the relationship between climate change and forced migration has

privileged the climate scenarios over other factors such as population growth,

economic development, the impact of infectious diseases, border and immigration

policies, or numerous other important issues.72 While it makes sense to base one’s

projections on sound footing, the authors cited above too often discount the role of—

and the interrelationship between—the other factors. Even something like timing could

play a major role, for instance, if large numbers of environmentally forced migrants

tried to cross international boundaries amid an outbreak of SARS, after a terrorist

attack on the India-Bangladesh border, or a skirmish between Kurds and Turks. One

thing this paper does reveal, however, is that the likelihood of a sudden pulse of many

thousand forced migrants would be slim.

What are especially needed are more precise epidemiological and public health

forecasts to complement our understanding of demographics and the way they relate

72
Beniston, Martin. 2004. Issues Relating to Environmental Change and Population Migrations. A
Climatologist's Perspective. In Environmental Change and its Implications for Population
Migration, ed. J. Unroh, M.S. Krol and N. Kliot. Dordrecht, The Netherlands: Kluwer Academic
Publishers, Brown, Oli. 2007. Climate Change and Forced Migration: Observations, projections
and implications. Geneva: United Nations Human Development Report, Byravan, Sujatha and
Sudhir Chella Rajan. 2006. Providing New Homes for Climate Change Exiles. Climate Policy 6, no.
2: 6, Piguet, Etienne. 2008. Climate Change and Forced Migration. Geneva: UNHCR, Stern, N.
2006. Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, Warren, Rachel, Chris Hope, Michael Mastrandrea, Richard Tol, Neil Adger, and Irene
Lorenzoni. 2006. Spotlighting Impacts Functions in Integrated Assessment: Research Report
Prepared for the Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change. Norwich, England: Tyndall
Centre for Climate Change Research, 91.
64
to climate change. More research is also needed to look for correlations from parallel

research on animal and plant migrations. There already exists a wealth of research on

changing ecosystems and on the way climate change has impacted migratory animal

species upon which many pastoral livelihoods are based; using past human and animal

migration patterns as a base line, anthropologists can anticipate future transformations

(beyond the obvious rural-to-urban migration).

The majority of research on climate change as a cause of forced migration takes

either desertification, sea-level rise, or water/food shortages as the point of departure.

More analysis is needed on other less obvious ways that environmental change will

impact vulnerable livelihoods. For example, coral bleaching and ocean acidification

threaten oceanic life as we know it and will almost certainly affect coastal populations

(if not the entire world food supply) before sea level rise becomes a problem—yet very

little is known about how people would adapt to these kinds of potentially catastrophic

changes.

Lastly, what will certainly be needed are more works like the Stern Review, which

weighs the costs of adapting now to climate change against waiting until we are forced

to adapt. Additional benefit-cost analyses like the Stern Review can be used to

convince developed states that acting now—in terms of both climate change mitigation

and anticipating adaptation measures—is in their own economic and national security

interests. Even if one were to set aside contentious issues such as past contributions

to climate change, the fact remains that wealthy industrial nations are the best

equipped to address this problem and are likely to be target destinations of climate

65
change-forced migrants. In other words, those in the North and West will pay for it one

way or another, sooner or later. The better the policy-makers from Washington to Cairo

understand the full scale of this phenomenon, the better equipped they should be to

plan for it.

66
Bib lio gr ap h y

General Assembly Resolution 428 (V) Statute of the Office of the United Nations High
Commissioner for Refugees. 1950. United Nations.
Convention Relating to the Status of Refugees. 1951. United Nations.
Protocol Relating to the Status of Refugees. 1967. United Nations.
Border Protection Bill. 2001.
Howard's 'Cynical' Pacific Solution Over. 2008. Herald Sun, February 9, 2008, 1.
Adepoju, A. 1995. Migration in Africa: An Overview. In The Migration Experience in Africa, ed.
Jonathan Baker and Tade Akin Aida:87-108. Uppsala, Sweden: Nordiska Afrikainstitutet.
AI. 2002. Australia-Pacific: Offending human dignity--the 'Pacific Solution'. Amnesty
International.
Aid, Christian. 2007. Human Tide: The Real Migration Crisis. London: Christian Aid.
________. 2009. Our work on climate change. Christian Aid. Accessed March 19, 2009
2009. Available from
http://www.christianaid.org.uk/whatwedo/issues/climate_change.aspx.
Baker, J. 1995. Migration in Ethiopia and the Role of the State. In The Migration Experience in
Africa, ed. Jonathan Baker and Tade Akin Aida:234-56. Uppsala, Sweden: Nordiska
Afrikainstitutet.
Barrett, C., T. Reardon, and P. Webb. 2001. Nonfarm Income Diversification and Household
Livelihood Strategies in Rural Africa: Concepts, Dynamics, and Policy Implications:1-31.
Basso, S., O. Casacchia, L. Cassata, C. Reynaud, and M. Said. 2001. The Geographical
Distribution of Urban and Rural Population. In Migration and Urbanization in Ethiopia,
with Special Reference to Addis Ababa:7-51. Addis Ababa, Ethiopia and Rome, Italy:
Central Statistics Authority (CSA) and Institute for Population Research (IPR).
Becker, Charles M. Beyond urban bias in Africa : urbanization in an era of structural adjustment
/ Charles M. Becker, Andrew M. Hamer, Andrew R. Morrison.
Bem, K., N. Field, N. Maclellan, S. Meyer, and A. Morris. 2007. A Price Too High: The cost of
Australia's approach to asylum seekers. Glebe, Australia and Carlton Australia: A Just
Australia
Beniston, Martin. 2004. Issues Relating to Environmental Change and Population Migrations. A
Climatologist's Perspective. In Environmental Change and its Implications for Population
Migration, ed. J. Unroh, M.S. Krol and N. Kliot. Dordrecht, The Netherlands: Kluwer
Academic Publishers.
Berger, Thomas. 2004. Innovation as an Alternative to Migration? Exemplary Results from a
Multiple-Agent Programming Model Applied to Chile. In Environmental Change and its
Implications for Population Migration, ed. J. Unroh, M.S. Krol and N. Kliot. Dordrecht,
The Netherlands: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Black, Richard. 2001. Environmental Refugees: Myth or Reality? Geneva: UNHCR.
Black, Richard and Mohamed Sessay. 1997. Forced Migration, Land-Use Change and Political
Economy in the Forest Region of Guinea. African Affairs 96, no. 385: 587-605.
Boano, C. 2008. Forced Migration Online (FMO) Research Guide on Climate Change and
Displacement. Oxford, UK: Forced Migration Online, Refugee Studies Centre, Oxford
Department of International Development (ODID) University of Oxford.
67
Boano, C., R. Zetter, and T. Morris. 2008. Environmentally Displaced People: Understanding the
linkages between environmental change, livelihoods, and forced migration. Oxford, UK:
Refugee Studies Centre, Oxford Department of International Development (ODID),
University of Oxford.
Bonaventure, Rutwina. 2002. Prima Facie Status and Refugee Protection. Geneva: UNHCR.
Bradshaw, William E., Peter A. Zani, and Christina M. Holzapfel. 2004. Adaptation to
Temperate Climates. Evolution 58, no. 8: 1748-1762.
Brown, Dwight A. and Philip J. Gersmehl. 1985. Migration Models for Grasses in the American
Midcontinent. Annals of the Association of American Geographers 75, no. 3: 383-394.
Brown, Oli. 2007. Climate Change and Forced Migration: Observations, projections and
implications. Geneva: United Nations Human Development Report.
Bryceson, D. 2000. Rural Africa at the Crossroads: Livelihood Practices and Policies. London:
Overseas Development Institute.
Byerlee, Derek. 1974. Rural-Urban Migration in Africa: Theory, Policy and Research
Implications. International Migration Review 8, no. 4: 543-566.
Byravan, Sujatha and Sudhir Chella Rajan. 2006. Providing New Homes for Climate Change
Exiles. Climate Policy 6, no. 2: 6.
CIA. March 6, 2008 2008. CIA World Factbook: Maldives. Accessed Last accessed March 19,
2008. 2008. Available from https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-
factbook/geos/mv.html.
Clark, William A. V. 2008. Social and Political Contexts of Conflict. Forced Migration Review
31: 22-23.
Clarke, John Innes and Leszek A. Kosinski. 1982. Redistribution of population in Africa. London
; Exeter, N.H.: Heinemann Educational.
Crisp, Jeff. 2003. A New Asylum Paradigm? Globalization, migration and the uncertain future
of the international refugee regime. Geneva: UNHCR.
CSA. 2005. Population. Addis Ababa: Central Statistics Agency.
________. 2009. Atlas on Selected Welfare Indicators of Ethiopian Households. Addis Ababa:
Central Statistics Agency.
Daily, Gretchen C. and Paul R. Ehrlich. 1990. An Exploratory Model of the Impact of Rapid
Climate Change on the World Food Situation. Proceedings: Biological Sciences 241, no.
1302: 232-244.
Daley, Beth. 2007. A Climate Change Warning: Panel Says Humans Are Probably Causing Shifts
Around World. Boston Globe, April 7, 2007.
deMenocal, Peter B. 2001. Cultural Responses to Climate Change during the Late Holocene.
Science 292, no. 5517: 667-673.
Devereux, Stephen. 2000. Destitution in Ethiopia's Northeast Highlands (Amhara Region).
Addis Ababa: IDS and Save the Children (UK).
DFID. 1999. Sustainable Livelihoods Guidance Sheet. London: Department for International
Development.
Dorigo, Guido and Waldo Tobler. 1983. Push-Pull Migration Laws. Annals of the Association of
American Geographers 73, no. 1: 1-17.
Dun, Olivia and François Gemenne. 2008. Defining 'environmental migration'. Forced Migration
Review 31: 10-11.
68
ECOSOC. 2002. World Urbanization Prospects: The 2001 Revision, Data Tables and Highlights.
New York: Population Division, Department of Economic and Social Affairs.
Edwards, Scott. 2008. Social Breakdown in Darfur. Forced Migration Review 31: 23-24.
Evans, Hugh Emrys and Gazala Pirzada. 1995. Rural Households as Producers: Income
Diversification and the Allocation of Resources. In The Migration Experience in Africa,
ed. J. Baker and Tade Akin Aida:87-108. Uppsala, Sweden: Nordiska Afrikainstitutet.
Ezra, Markos and Gebre-Egziabher Kiros. 2001. Rural Out-Migration in the Drought Prone Areas
of Ethiopia: A Multilevel Analysis. International Migration Review 35, no. 3: 749-771.
FAO/GIEWS. 1996. FAO/WFP Crop and Food Supply Assessment Mission to Ethiopia.
FAO/WFP.
________. 1998. FAO/WFP Crop and Food Supply Assessment Mission to Ethiopia.
FAO/WFP.
Fields, Scott. 2005. Continental Divide: Why Africa's Climate Change Burden Is Greater.
Environmental Health Perspectives 113, no. 8: A534-A537.
Fratkin, Elliot. 2001. East African Pastoralism in Transition: Maasai, Boran, and Rendille Cases.
African Studies Review 44, no. 3: 1-25.
Frayne, Bruce and Wade Pendleton. 2001. Migration in Namibia: Combining Macro and Micro
Approaches to Research Design and Analysis. International Migration Review 35, no. 4:
1054-1085.
Freund, Paul, Anthony Adegbulugbe, Oyvind Christophersen, Hisashi Ishitani, William Moomaw,
and Jose Moreira. 2005. Introduction. In IPCC Special Report on Carbon Dioxide
Capture and Storage, ed. Eduardo Calvo and Eberhard Jochem:51-74. Cambridge, New
York, Melbourne, Madrid, Cape Town, Singapore, Sào Paulo: Cambridge University Press.
Glenzer, Kent. 2007. We Aren't the World: The Institutional Production of Partial Success. In
Niger 2005: Une Catastrophe si Naturelle, ed. Xavier Crombe and Jean-Herve
Jezequel:117-144. Paris: Medecins Sans Frontieres.
Golini, Antonio, Mohammed Said, Oliviero Casacchia, Celia Reynaud, Sara Basso, Lorenzo
Cassata, and Massimiliano Crisci. 2001. Migration and Urbanization in Ethiopia, with
Special Reference to Addis Ababa. In-Depth Studies from the 1994 Population and
Housing Census in Ethiopia. Addis Ababa, Ethiopia and Rome, Italy: Central Statistics
Authority (CSA) and Institute for Population Research (IPR).
Goodwin-Gill, Guy S. 1989. International Law and Human Rights: Trends Concerning
International Migrants and Refugees. International Migration Review 23, no. 3: 526-546.
________. 1999. Refugee Identity and Protection's Fading Prospect. In Refugee Rights and
Realities: Evolving International Concepts and Regimes, ed. Frances Nicholson and P.
Twomey:220-249. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Gould, W.T.S. 1995. Migration and Recent Economic and Environmental Change. In The
Migration Experience in Africa, ed. Jonathan Baker and Tade Akin Aida:122-48. Uppsala,
Sweden: Nordiska Afrikainstitutet.
Hance, William Adams. 1970. Population, migration, and urbanization in Africa. New York,:
Columbia University Press.
Held, I. M., T. L. Delworth, J. Lu, K. L. Findell, and T. R. Knutson. 2005. Simulation of Sahel
Drought in the 20th and 21st Centuries. Proceedings of the National Academy of
Sciences of the United States of America, 102, no. 50: 17891-17896.
69
Hugo, Graeme. 1996. Environmental Concerns and International Migration. International
Migration Review 30, no. 1: 105-131.
Illinois, University of. 2007. New Ideas about Human Migration from Asia to the Americas. In
Science Daily.
IOM. 2007. Refugee Protection. International Organization for Migration. Accessed February 2,
2008 2008. Available from http://www.iom.int/jahia/Jahia/pid/281.
________. 2007. The Framework for Refugee Protection. International Organization for
Migration. Accessed February 2, 2008 2008. Available from
http://www.iom.int/jahia/Jahia/pid/612.
________. 2008. Expert Seminar: Migration and the Environment. Red Book Series:
International Dialogue on Migration. Geneva: International Organization for Migration.
Jenkyns, Hugh C. 2003. Evidence for Rapid Climate Change in the Mesozoic-Palaeogene
Greenhouse World. Philosophical Transactions: Mathematical, Physical and Engineering
Sciences 361, no. 1810: 1885-1916.
John Pender, Berhanu Gebremedhin Samuel Benin Simeon Ehui. 2001. Strategies for
Sustainable Development of Less-Favoured Areas: Strategies for Sustainable
Agricultural Development in the Ethiopian Highlands. American Journal of Agricultural
Economics 83, no. 5: 1231-1240.
Jones, David K. C. 1993. Slope Instability in a Warmer Britain. The Geographical Journal 159,
no. 2: 184-195.
Keane, D. 2004. The Environmental Causes and Consequences of Migration: A Search for the
Meaning of "Environmental Refugees". Georgetown International Environmental Law
Review.
Keenlyside, N. S., M. Latif, J. Jungclaus, L. Kornblueh, and E. Roeckner. 2008. Advancing
decadal-scale climate prediction in the North Atlantic sector. Nature 453, no. 7191:
84-88.
Kloos, Helmut. 1982. Farm Labor Migrations in the Awash Valley of Ethiopia. International
Migration Review 16, no. 1: 133-168.
Kniveton, Dominic, Kerstin Schmidt-Verkerk, Christopher Smith, and Richard Black. 2008.
Climate Change and Migration: Improving Methodologies to Estimate Flows. Geneva:
International Organization for Migration.
Krokfors, C. 1995. Poverty, Environmental Stress and Culture as Factors in African Migrations.
In The Migration Experience in Africa, ed. Jonathan Baker and Tade Akin Aida:54-63.
Uppsala, Sweden: Nordiska Afrikainstitutet.
Krovvidi, Adityam, Simon Francis, E.M. Rajesh, Dr. Rakesh Mohindra, Dr. Annes Hassankunju,
Mayank Dubney, Samit Shrivastava, and Satya Prasad. 2006. Developing a Disaster Risk
Profile for the Maldives (Volumes 1 & 2). Noida, India: United Nations Development
Programme.
Laney, Rheyna M. 2002. Disaggregating Induced Intensification for Land-Change Analysis: A
Case Study from Madagascar. Annals of the Association of American Geographers 92,
no. 4: 702-726.
Leckie, S. 2008. The Human Rights Implications of Climate Change: Where Next? Male',
Maldives: United Nations Development Programme.
Lee, Everett S. 1966. A Theory of Migration. Demography 3, no. 1: 47-57.
70
Lenton, Timothy M., Hermann Held, Elmar Kriegler, Jim W. Hall, Wolfgang Lucht, Stefan
Rahmstorf, and Hans Joachim Schellnhuber. 2008. Inaugural Article: Tipping elements in
the Earth's climate system. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 105, no.
6: 1786-1793.
Lewin, Alexandra C. 2007. Niger's Famine and the Role of Food Aid. Ithaca, NY: Cornell
University.
Liu, Junguo, Steffen Fritz, C. F. A. van Wesenbeeck, Michael Fuchs, Liangzhi You, Michael
Obersteiner, and Hong Yang. 2008. A spatially explicit assessment of current and
future hotspots of hunger in Sub-Saharan Africa in the context of global change. Global
and Planetary Change 64, no. 3-4: 222-235.
Makowski, Marek. 2001. Modeling Techniques for Complex Environmental Problems. In Natural
Environment Management and Applied Systems Analysis, ed. M. Makowski and H.
Nakayama:41-77. Laxenburg, Austria: International Institute for Applied Systems
Analysis.
Mannion, A. M. 1998. Global Environmental Change: The Causes and Consequences of
Disruption to Biogeochemical Cycles. The Geographical Journal 164, no. 2: 168-182.
Mattar, Vanessa and Paul White. 2005. Consistent and Predictable Responses to IDPs: A
review of UNHCR's decision-making process. Geneva: UNHCR.
Maxwell, Daniel. 2007. Global Factors Shaping the Future of Food Aid: The Implications for
WFP. Disasters 33, no. S1: S25-S39.
McDonald, Frank. 2007. U.S. and EU Deadlocked at Climate Talks. The Irish Times, December
14, 2007, 1.
McNeill, William H. 1984. Human Migration in Historical Perspective. Population and
Development Review 10, no. 1: 1-18.
Mooney, E. 2005. The Concept of Internal Displacement and the Case for Internally Displaced
Persons as a Category of Concern. Refugee Survey Quarterly 24, no. 3: 9-26.
Morawska, Ewa. 2000. Intended and Unintended Consequences of Forced Migrations: A
Neglected Aspect of East Europe's Twentieth Century History. International Migration
Review 34, no. 4: 1049-1087.
Myers, Norman. 1993. Environmental Refugees in a Globally Warmed World. BioScience 43, no.
11: 752-761.
Myers, N. 1994. Eco-refugees: a crisis in the making. People Planet 3, no. 4: 6-9.
Myers, Norman. 2002. Environmental Refugees: A Growing Phenomenon of the 21st Century.
Philosophical Transactions: Biological Sciences 357, no. 1420: 609-613.
Myers, N. 2005. Environmental Refugees: An Emergent Security Issue. Prague: Organization
for the Security and Co-operation in Europe.
Newbold, K. Bruce. 2001. Counting Migrants and Migrations: Comparing Lifetime and Fixed-
Interval Return and Onward Migration. Economic Geography 77, no. 1: 23-40.
OHCHR. 2009. Report of the Office of the United Nations High Commissioner for Human Rights
on the relationship between climate change and human rights. Geneva: United Nations
High Commissioner for Human Rights and the Office of the High Commissioner for
Human Rights.
Ott, Hermann E. 2001. Climate Change: An Important Foreign Policy Issue. International Affairs
(Royal Institute of International Affairs 1944-) 77, no. 2: 277-296.
71
Pallis, Mark. 2002. Obligations of States towards Asylum Seekers at Sea: Interactions and
Conflicts Between Legal Regimes. International Journal of Refugee Law 14, no. 2/3:
329-364.
Pankhurst, Alula and Francois (eds) Piguet. 2004. People, Space, and the State: Migration,
Resettlement and Displacement in Ethiopia. Addis Ababa: Addis Ababa University.
Piguet, Etienne. 2008. Climate Change and Forced Migration. Geneva: UNHCR.
Reardon, Thomas. 1997. Using evidence of household income diversification to inform study
of the rural nonfarm labor market in Africa. World Development 25, no. 5: 735-747.
Renaud, F., J.J. Bogardi, O. Dun, and K. Warner. 2007. Control, Adapt or Flee: How to Face
Environmental Migration? Bonn: United Nations University Institute for Environment and
Human Security.
Rignot, Eric, Jonathan L. Bamber, Michiel R. van den Broeke, Curt Davis, Yonghong Li, Willem
Jan van de Berg, and Erik van Meijgaard. 2008. Recent Antarctic ice mass loss from
radar interferometry and regional climate modelling. Nature Geosci 1, no. 2: 106-110.
Roberts, Bryan R. 1989. Urbanization, Migration, and Development. Sociological Forum 4, no.
4: 665-691.
Romer, K. 2006. "Environmental" Refugees? Forced Migration Review, no. 25: 1.
Roseman, Curtis C. 1971. Migration as a Spatial and Temporal Process. Annals of the
Association of American Geographers 61, no. 3: 589-598.
Rystad, Goran. 1992. Immigration History and the Future of International Migration.
International Migration Review 26, no. 4: 1168-1199.
S. Benin, J. Pender. 2001. Impacts of land redistribution on land management and productivity
in the Ethiopian highlands. Land Degradation & Development 12, no. 6: 555-568.
S. Benin, M. Smale J. Pender B. Gebremedhin S. Ehui. 2004. The economic determinants of
cereal crop diversity on farms in the Ethiopian highlands. Agricultural Economics 31, no.
2-3: 197-208.
Schneider, S.H., S. Semenov, A. Patwardhan, I. Burton, C.H.DD. Magadza, M. Oppenheimer, A.B.
Pittock, A. Rahman, J.B. Smith, A. Suarez, and F. Yamin. 2007. Addressing Key
Vulnerabilities and the Risk from Climate Change. In Climate Change 2007: Impacts,
Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Fourth
Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, ed. S.H.
Schneider, S. Semenov and A. Patwardhan. Cambridge: Intergovernmental Panel on
Climate Change.
Sell, Ralph R. 1983. Analyzing Migration Decisions: The First Step--Whose Decisions?
Demography 20, no. 3: 299-311.
Shahid, A. 2008. Life on the High(er) Seas: Adapting to Climate Change in the Maldives. The
Fletcher Forum of World Affairs 32, no. 2: 8.
Sharp, Kay and Stephen Devereux. 2004. Destitution in Wollo (Ethiopia): chronic poverty as a
crisis of household and community livelihoods. Journal of Human Development and
Capabilities 5, no. 2: 227 - 247.
Sharp, Kay, Stephen Devereux, and Yared Amare. 2003. Destitution in Ethiopia's Northeastern
Highlands (Amhara National Regional State). Addis Ababa, Ethiopia: Institute of
Development Studies and Save the Children (UK).
Smith, Doug M., Stephen Cusack, Andrew W. Colman, Chris K. Folland, Glen R. Harris, and
72
James M. Murphy. 2007. Improved Surface Temperature Prediction for the Coming
Decade from a Global Climate Model. Science 317, no. 5839: 796-799.
Stavropoulou, Maria. 2008. Drowned in definitions? Forced Migration Review 31: 11-12.
Sterman, John D. 2002. All Models Are Wrong: Reflections on becoming a systems scientist.
Systems Dynamics Review 18, no. 4: 501-531.
Stern, N. 2006. Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Travis, J. M. J. 2003. Climate Change and Habitat Destruction: A Deadly Anthropogenic
Cocktail. Proceedings: Biological Sciences 270, no. 1514: 467-473.
Truscott, Claire. 2008. Giant Antarctic ice shelf breaks into the sea. The Guardian,
Wednesday, March 26, 2008.
UN. 1982. United Nations Convention on the Law of the Sea, ed. United Nations, 98: United
Nations.
UNESCO. 2008. People on the Move: Handbook of selected terms and concepts. The Hague
and Paris: UNESCO.
UNHCR. 2002. UNHCR Statistical Yearbook 2001: Refugees, Asylum-seekers and Other
Persons of Concern--Trends in Displacement, Protection and Solutions. Geneva: UNHCR.
________. 2003. Agenda for Protection. Geneva: UNHCR.
________. 2006. Rethinking durable solutions. In The State of the World's Refugees 2006.
Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.
________. 2006. Protracted refugee situations: the search for practical solutions. In The
State of the World's Refugees. 2006. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.
________. 2007. UNHCR Global Appeal 2008-2009. In Mission Statement:1. Geneva: UHNCR.
________. 2007. Protecting Refugees & The Role of UNHCR 2007-2008. Geneva: UNHCR.
________. 2007. UNHCR Statistical Yearbook 2005: Trends in Displacement, Protection and
Solutions. Geneva: UNHCR.
________. 2008. Climate change, natural disasters and human displacement: a UNHCR
perspective. Geneva: UNHCR.
Verstraete, Michel M., Andreas B. Brink, Robert J. Scholes, Martin Beniston, and Mark Stafford
Smith. 2008. Climate change and desertification: Where do we stand, where should we
go? Global and Planetary Change 64, no. 3-4: 105-110.
Wallen, Carl Christian. 1986. Impact of Present Century Climate Fluctuations in the Northern
Hemisphere. Geografiska Annaler. Series A, Physical Geography 68, no. 4: 245-278.
Ward, R. Gerard. 1989. Earth's Empty Quarter? The Pacific Islands in a Pacific Century. The
Geographical Journal 155, no. 2: 235-246.
Warren, Rachel, Chris Hope, Michael Mastrandrea, Richard Tol, Neil Adger, and Irene Lorenzoni.
2006. Spotlighting Impacts Functions in Integrated Assessment: Research Report
Prepared for the Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change. Norwich, England:
Tyndall Centre for Climate Change Research, 91.
Webster, Mackinnon, Justin Ginnetti, Peter Walker, Daniel Coppard, and Randolph Kent. 2008.
The Humanitarian Costs of Climate Change. Medford, MA: Feinstein International Center.
Whiting, John W. M., John A. Sodergren, and Stephen M. Stigler. 1982. Winter Temperature as
a Constraint to the Migration of Preindustrial Peoples. American Anthropologist 84, no.
2: 279-298.
73
WHO. 2007. Climate Change and Human Health-Risks and Responses Summary. Geneva: World
Health Organization, World Meteorological Organization, United Nations Development
Programme.
________. 2008. World Malaria Report 2008. Geneva: World Health Organization.
Wilbanks, T.J., P. Romero Lankao, M. Bao, F. Berkhout, S. Cairncross, J.-P. Ceron, M. Kapshe, R.
Muir-Wood, and R. Zapata-Marti. 2007. Industry, Settlement and Society. In Climate
Change 2007: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II
to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change,
ed. T. Wilbanks and P. Romero Lankao:58. Cambridge: Intergovernmental Panel on
Climate Change.
Wiles, Gregory C., Ryan P. McAllister, Nicole K. Davi, and C. Jacoby Gordon. 2003. Eolian
Response to Little Ice Age Climate Change, Tana Dunes, Chugach Mountains, Alaska,
U.S.A. Arctic, Antarctic, and Alpine Research 35, no. 1: 67-73.
Wilson, Franklin D. 1985. Migration and Occupational Mobility: A Research Note. International
Migration Review 19, no. 2: 278-292.
Woldeamlak Bewket, Declan Conway. 2007. A note on the temporal and spatial variability of
rainfall in the drought-prone Amhara region of Ethiopia. International Journal of
Climatology 27, no. 11: 1467-1477.
Zolberg, Aristide R. 1989. The Next Waves: Migration Theory for a Changing World.
International Migration Review 23, no. 3: 403-430.
Zuberi, Tukufu, Sibanda Amson, Ayaga Bawah, and Amadou Noumbissi. 2003. Population and
African Society. Annual Review of Sociology 29: 465-486.

74
Appe nd ix : Mo del Do cu me nta tion

(01) "% Households Owning Livestock"=0.816

Units: Dmnl

This is the percentage of households that own livestock. In a


region of many farmers with small individual landholdings,
ownership of cattle must be spread across the entire community
for the cattle to have a postive impact on aggregate yield.
(Source: Sharp and Devereaux, 2004)

(02) Aggregate Livelihood Score=(Financial Capital Score^1.112)+(Human Capital


Score^1.144)+(Natural Capital Score^1.157)+(Phyiscal Capital Score^1.165)

Units: Dmnl

Aggregate livelihood score based on each type of capital. Each


individual score is then scaled/weighted depending on its
importance in livelihoods surveys of residents of Wollo.
(Source: Sharp and Devereux, 2004)

(03) Agricultural Carrying Capacity= INTEG (Carrying Capacity Regeneration-Carrying


Capacity Degradation, 1.1294e+006)

Units: Hectares

Given the parameters of the climate signal and soil exhaustion,


the carrying capacity will only be eroded or maintained in this
model. The three distrcits considered in ths case study compose
41,829 square kilometers, 27 percent of which is devoted to
grazing. This works out to 11,294 square kilometers, or
1,129,400 hectares, allocated for cultivation. Source (USAID,
2000).

(04) Average Duration of Temporary Migration=5

Units: Months

Average duration of temporary migration is less than a growing


season due to the difficulty of finding work (which leads to
75
return migration) and the risk of losing one's farm-based assets.

(05) Bovine Birth Rate=0.8*0.6

Units: Calves/Cow

I have assumed that 80 percent of the female cows (which compose


60 percent of the herd) have a calf each year. The reason the
herd is not split 50/50 between bulls and heiffers is that the
bulls are consumed more quickly than the heiffers, because each
individual bull (after the first bull) is marginally less useful
than the heiffers. Furthermore, most of the cattle in Ethiopia's
highlands are owned by relatively few households. If the
region's aggregate herd were divided more equitably, then the
female/male split would probably be closer to 50/50, rather than
60/40. (Source: Sharpe and Devereaux, 2004).

(06) Bovine Mortality Rate=Effect of Overgrazing on Bovine Mortality(Herd Utilization)

Units: 1/Month

Total bovine mortality is informed by beef consumption and


normal mortality; yet during droughts and floods mortality can
rise to as much as 62 percent over a 12-month period.

(07) Carrying Capacity Degradation=MIN(Planting Intensity*Planted Crops*Crop


Utilization/Degradation Delay, Maximum Degradation of Agricultural Carrying
Capacity)

Units: Hectares/Month

Amount at which carrying capacity is degraded due to the


intensity of crop cultivation (i.e., planting above the carrying
capacity).

(08) Carrying Capacity Regeneration=Agricultural Carrying Capacity*(1-Climate


Signal)/Soil Regeneration Time

Units: Hectares/Month

76
Change in carrying capacity is based upon the existing carrying
capacity and is modified by the utilization of the land for
agricultural and grazing as well as the climate signal.

(09) Cattle Deaths=Cows*Bovine Mortality Rate

Units: Cows/Month

Number of cows that die each month in these districts of


Ethiopia.

(10) Change in Financial Capital=(Harvested Crops-Financial Capital)/TIME STEP

Units: Tons/Month

Change in financial capital due to harvest of crops.

(11) Change in Household Natural Capital=((Agricultural Carrying Capacity+Livestock


Carrying Capacity)-Natural Capital)/TIME STEP

Units: Hectares/Month

Change in natural capital. This rate is tracked on a 12-month


basis on the assumption that farmers would sell their land only
once per year, resulting in a 12-month delay in the change of
natural capital.

(12) Change in Human Capital=(Potentially Educated Population*Enrollment-Human


Capital)/Length of Primary School

Units: People/Month

This takes a measure of change in the rural labor force as a


function of the rural population, fraction of the population
that receives education, and the average number of months of
schooling the educated population receives.

(13) Change in Livelihood Robustness=(Aggregate Livelihood Score-Livelihood


Robustness)/TIME STEP
77
Units: 1/Month

Change in aggregate livelihood robustness due to input from


individual indicators.

(14) Change in Physical Capital=(Cows-Physical Capital)/TIME STEP

Units: Cows/Month

The change in natural capital as compared to existing natural


capital. This can be growth or decay.

(15) "Climate Change On/Off Switch"=1

Units: Dmnl

0 = Off, 1 = On

(16) Climate Signal=RAMP(0.1/(120), 120, 240)*"Climate Change On/Off Switch"

Units: Dmnl

The climate signal is a 10 percent "worsening" (spread over 10


years) that begins in Month 1 of Year 10 and which ends in Month
1 of Year 20, after which the climate change would no longer
effect yields and soil regeneration.

(17) Consumption=Harvested Crops/Consumption Period

Units: Tons/Month

I have assumed that there are no surpluses--all harvested food


assets are consumed or traded.

(18) Consumption Period=12

Units: Months
78
Each harvest must last 12 months for there to be enough to last
until the following harvest.

(19) Cow Births=Cows*Bovine Birth Rate/Gestation Period

Units: Calves/Month

Number of calf births based on bovine birth rate and the number
of heifers. I have assumed that everyone tries to breed each
heifer every year. I have also assumed that all births are live
births and that no heifers die in childbirth; I accounted for
the cows who die due to drought by elevating the bovine
mortality rate in response to the climate signal.

(20) Cows= INTEG (Cow Births-Cattle Deaths, 1.25485e+006)

Units: Cows

The initial number represents total number of cows that can be


supported by these three districts of the Amhara region
multiplied the percent estimated to be by calves at the start of
the simulation.

(21) Crop Utilization=Planted Crops*Planting Intensity/Agricultural Carrying Capacity

Units: Dmnl

Amount of the potential carrying capacity that is being used by


the planted crops.

(22) Cultivation=Planted Crops*Yield Fraction*(1-Climate Signal)/Growing Season

Units: Tons/Month

Cultivation is the percent of the potential tons of agricultural


production (i.e., seeds) that reach harvest, divided by the
length of the growing season.

79
(23) Degradation Delay=12

Units: Months

Average length of time it takes for the soil erosion/exhaustion


(due to overgrazing or intensive agriculture) to take effect.

(24) Effect of Overgrazing on Bovine Mortality([(0,0)-


(2,0.1)],(0,0),(0.1,0.0125),(0.9,0.0125),(1,0.0125),(1.1,0.04),(1.5,0.045),(2,
0.05))

Units: 1/Month

Effect of overgrazing and soil degradation on bovine mortality.


In this part of Ethiopia during droughts (i.e., when the size of
the herd relative to the carrying capacity is highest), the
mortality rate is as high as 60 percent/year.

(25) Effect of Utilization on Yield([(0,0)-


(6,2)],(0,0),(0.1,0.05),(0.2,0.2),(0.3,0.3),(0.4,0.4),(0.5,0.6),(0.6,0.7),(0.7,0.8
3),(0.8,0.95),(0.9,1.05),(1,1.1),(2,1.15),(5,1.15))

Units: Dmnl

A low yield for cereals is 0.83 tons/hectare, whereas a high


yield is 1.15 tons/hectare. (Source: FAO/WFP, 1998).

(26) Enrollment=0.33

Units: Dmnl

Enrollment is shown here as the percentage of school-age


children that are enrolled in school in the Northeastern
Highlands region of Ethiopia. (Source: CSA, accessed 2009)

(27) Expected Livelihood Robustness= INTEG (Livelihood Trend,10)

Units: Dmnl

80
The expected livelihood robustness is based upon past
livelihoods: at any point in time in this model, one's expected
livelihoods is based on moving average one's livelihood over the
preceding three years.

(28) FINAL TIME = 720

Units: Month

The final time for the simulation.

(29) Financial Capital= INTEG (Change in Financial Capital, Harvested Crops)

Units: Tons

Since food is traded, and more than 90 percent of the region


earns its livelihood through food production, I have used food
assets as a proxy for financial capital. (Sources: Sharp and
Devereux, 2004; and FAO/WFP, 1998)

(30) Financial Capital Per Household=Financial Capital*People per Household/Rural


Population

Units: Tons/Household

Amount of food assets (financial capital) per person.

(31) Financial Capital Score=Financial Capital Per Household*Household Tons

Units: Dmnl

(32) "Fractional Rural-Urban Migration Rate"=0.125/12

Units: Dmnl

Portion of the population that is likely to migrate based on


demographic indicators such as age and gender. This takes into
81
account the fact that unmarried young men (i.e., not heads of
households) are most likely to migrate. (Source: Devereux 2000)
(Cf. Casacchia et al. 2001, p.61, for a lower figure.)

(33) Fractional Urban Growth Rate=0.031/12

Units: 1/Month

Fraction of the population that permanently settles in urban


areas. If Ethiopia's annual urban birth rate is roughly 2
percent, the death rate ranges from 1.4-1.8 percent, and its
annual urban growth rate is 5.05 percent, the difference in
growth must be accounted for by in-migration from rural
areas--at least 3 percent annually.

(34) Gestation Period=12

Units: Months

This reflects the fact that cows will not birth more than one
cow per year (allowing for gestation, nursing, etc.).

(35) Growing Season=8

Units: Months

Average number of months between planting and harvest seasons.

(36) Harvested Crops= INTEG (Cultivation-Consumption, 941167/(0.83*(1-Climate


Signal)))

Units: Tons

Amount of food tons that reach harvest and can be used for
consumption or trading. In this model, cereals are standing in
for all crop production because they account for most of Wollo’s
agriculture.

(37) Hectares Per Cow=1.3


82
Units: Hectares/Cow

Number of hectares needed for the average farmer in this region


to support each cow.

(38) Herd Utilization=Hectares Per Cow*Cows/Livestock Carrying Capacity

Units: Dmnl

Represents how much of the land is being utilized by the cattle


herd, based on the carrying capacity, the required amount of
grazing land needed per cow, and the number of cows.

(39) Household Cows=1

Units: Household/Cow

Normalization variable.

(40) Household Hectares=1

Units: Household/Hectares

Normalization variable needed to remove units from the natural


capital per household variable, which is necessary to calculate
the per-household natural capital score.

(41) Household People=1

Units: Household/People

Normalization variable needed to remove units from the human


capital per household variable, which is necessary to calculate
the per-household human capital score.

(42) Household Tons=1

83
Units: Household/Ton

Normalization variable needed to calculate the financial capital score.

(43) Human Capital= INTEG (Change in Human Capital, (Enrollment*Potentially


Educated Population))

Units: People

This model defines human capital as a function of people and


education.

(44) Human Capital Per Household=Human Capital*People per Household/Rural


Population

Units: People/Household

Number of educated people per household.

(45) Human Capital Score=Household People*Human Capital Per Household

Units: Dmnl

(46) INITIAL TIME = 0

Units: Month

The initial time for the simulation.

(47) Length of Primary School=72

Units: Months

Maximum number of months (including time between sessions) that


children would be in primary school. (Source: CSA, accessed 2009)

(48) Livelihood Robustness= INTEG (Change in Livelihood Robustness, Aggregate


Livelihood Score)
84
Units: Dmnl

This is the stock of livelihood. It grows or is depleted by the


variables from Wollo's agricultural production. The initial
livelihood is merely the aggregate livelihood score.

(49) Livelihood Trend=(Livelihood Robustness-Expected Livelihood


Robustness)/Weight of History

Units: 1/Month

(50) Livestock Carrying Capacity= INTEG (Regeneration-Overgrazing, 1.6313e+006)

Units: Hectares

The three districts considered in this case study compose 41,829


square kilometers, 39 percent of which is devoted to grazing.
This works out to 16,313 square kilometers, or 1,631,300
hectares. (Source: USAID, 2000).

(51) Maximum Degradation of Agricultural Carrying Capacity=0.4*Agricultural


Carrying Capacity/Degradation Delay

Units: Hectares/Month

Absolute limit to how much the agricultural carrying capacity


can be degraded each month. Here we have limited it at 40
percent of the total agricultural carrying capacity because we
will allow that some land is being set aside to fallow or that
some crops are rotated.

(52) Maximum Degradation of Livestock Carrying Capacity=0.4*Livestock Carrying


Capacity/Degradation Delay

Units: Hectares/Month

Absolute limit to how much the livestock carrying capacity can


be degraded each month. This is capped at 80 percent per year in
this model to accommodate for the fact that at a certain point
85
farmers will shift their cattle onto someone else's land,
legally or not.

(53) Migration Delay=1

Units: Month

Average length of it takes someone to migrate after having


decided to do so. Where distances are great and more preparation
is required, this delay may be more than one month. On the other
hand, some research suggests that for many forced migrants there
is no delay.

(54) Migration Pressure=(Robustness of Reference Livelihood-Expected Livelihood


Robustness)/Expected Livelihood Robustness

Units: Dmnl

Pressure to migrate based on a comparison of one's Expected


Livelihood Robustness to the Robustness of a Reference
Livelihood (i.e., the robustness of the livelihood to which one
had been accustomed).

(55) Natural Capital= INTEG (Change in Household Natural Capital, (Agricultural


Carrying Capacity+Livestock Carrying Capacity))

Units: Hectares

In this model, natural capital is the total area of available


arable land available at a given time.

(56) Natural Capital Per Household=Natural Capital*People per Household/Rural


Population

Units: Hectares/Household

This is the natural capital expressed normalized per household.


As population grows the number of households proliferates,
particularly given a pyramidal population distribution weighted
toward a younger demographic, there will be significant decrease
86
in natural capital per household even without climate change.

(57) Natural Capital Score=Household Hectares*Natural Capital Per Household

Units: Dmnl

(58) Overgrazing=MIN(Hectares Per Cow*Cows*(1+Herd Utilization)/Degradation


Delay, Maximum Degradation of Livestock Carrying Capacity)

Units: Hectares/Month

Amount of grazing land lost each month due to too many cattle
for the region's carrying capacity.

(59) People per Household=5

Units: People/Household

Average number of people/household in this part of the Amhara


district. It ranges from 4 (in the poorest households) to 7 (in
the wealthiest). (Source: Devereux, 2000)

(60) Per Hectare Planting Limit=0.83

Units: Tons/Hectare

Maximum amount of grains one would plant per hectare of their


available arable land.

(61) "Permanent Rural-Urban Migrants"= INTEG (Settlement, 0)

Units: People

This is the number of permanent migrants. They have found some


form of livelihood and are sending remittances back to family
members.

(62) Phyiscal Capital Score=Household Cows*Physical Capital Per Household


87
Units: Dmnl

(63) Physical Capital= INTEG (Change in Physical Capital, Cows)

Units: Cows

Amount of physical capital on hand, using livestock as a proxy


(Source: Devereux, 2000)

(64) Physical Capital Per Household="% Households Owning Livestock"*Physical


Capital*People per Household/Rural Population

Units: Cows/Household

Number of cows per household.

(65) Planted Crops= INTEG (Planting-Cultivation, 941167)

Units: Tons

Number of potential tons of crops planted in the ground.


Potential tons rather than "tons" because the seeds weigh less
than the final plant organisms.

(66) Planting=Agricultural Carrying Capacity*Per Hectare Planting Limit/Planting Delay

Units: Tons/Month

Tons/month of potential agricultural capital (i.e., seeds)


planted.

(67) Planting Delay=4

Units: Months

This artificial planting delay was created to account for the


fact that the cereal growing season is 8 months and that there is
88
only one harvest per year for Wollo’s main crops. If one ran the
model simulations without the delay, there would be three harvests
every 24 months rather than two.

(68) Planting Intensity=1.2

Units: Hectares/Ton

Average number of hectares required to produce one ton of


cereals and pulses in the northeastern highlands of Ethiopia.
(Source: FAO/GIEWS, 1996)

(69) Potentially Educated Population=Rural Population-Rural Births*TIME STEP/12*7

Units: People

Number of Potential Students. This model normalizes monthly


births on an annual basis and then subtracts the children under
seven years old from the larger population.

(70) Regeneration=Livestock Carrying Capacity*(1-Climate Signal)/Soil Regeneration


Time

Units: Hectares/Month

Rate at which the soil recovers from grazing. The soil


regeneration time for the cattle grazing has been reduced from
three years to one year

(71) Return Migration="Temporary Rural-Urban Migrants"/Average Duration of


Temporary Migration

Units: People/Month

People per month who return to their pastoral livelihood after a


temporary stay in a city.

(72) Robustness of Reference Livelihood=15

89
Units: Dmnl

This variable refers to livelihood robustness of a viable rural


livelihood in Wollo. Potential migrants and temporary
rural-urban migrants weigh the expected rural livelihood
robustness against this one, and if there is a discrepancy it
will generate pressure to migrate. Given the poverty rates and
destitution in Wollo, the reference livelihood score must, by
definition, be greater than the inputs from the agro-pastoral
production model--at least when initializing the model.

(73) Rural Birth Rate=0.038/12

Units: 1/Month

Amhara's annual birth rate is 38 births per 1,000 people, which


has been rephrased here as a per-month rate. Initially, I
established this using a fertility rate (using births/woman) and
percent of the female population of childbearing age, but the
results were similar and these extra steps added unnecessary
complexity to the model; this may be useful however if one were
testing a more demographic hypothesis (i.e., the effect of
education on migration) rather than climate change on
rural-urban migration).

(74) Rural Births=Rural Birth Rate*Rural Population

Units: People/Month

Monthly Rural Births.

(75) Rural Deaths=Rural Mortality Rate*Rural Population

Units: People/Month

Monthly deaths in rural areas of the Northeastern Highlands.

(76) Rural Mortality Rate=0.016/12

90
Units: 1/Month

The mortality rate is 16 per 1000 people, rephrased here as a


monthly rate. (Source: CSA, accessed 2009)

(77) Rural Population= INTEG (Return Migration+Rural Births-Rural Deaths-"Rural-


Urban Migration", 3.32381e+006)

Units: People

Total rural population of Wag Hamra, Southern Wello, and


Northern Wello Administrative Zones of Ethiopia in 1994,
initially 91 percent of total population for these districts.
(Source: Sharp and Devereux, 2004)

(78) "Rural-Urban Migration"="Fractional Rural-Urban Migration Rate"*Rural


Population*Migration Pressure

/Migration Delay

Units: People/Month

Number of people per month who seek temporary employment in an


urban area. These are seasonal migrations, which have been
aggregated here on an annual basis (because it is not crucial
for this model and analysis to capture the seasonality).

(79) SAVEPER = TIME STEP

Units: Month [0,?]

The frequency with which output is stored.

(80) Settlement="Temporary Rural-Urban Migrants"*Migration Pressure*Fractional


Urban Growth Rate

Units: People/Month

Number of people per month who have decided to stay in the urban
destination area.
91
(81) Soil Regeneration Time=36

Units: Months

Time it takes for agricultural fields to recover their full


productivity after having been cultivated.

(82) "Temporary Rural-Urban Migrants"= INTEG ("Rural-Urban Migration"-Return


Migration-Settlement, (Rural Population*"Fractional Rural-Urban Migration Rate"))

Units: People

People who have temporarily left their agricultural livelihood


to seek employment in an urban area.

(83) TIME STEP = 1

Units: Month [0,?]

The time step for the simulation.

(84) Weight of History=36

Units: Months

This "information delay" captures how much one weighs one's


current livelihood against historical norms. The greater the
length of time, the greater the weight of history on one's
expected livelihood. Here, I have estimated that one's
perspective will be three years (36 months).

(85) Yield Fraction=Effect of Utilization on Yield(Crop Utilization)

Units: Dmnl

The actual yield is based on the yield-increasing effect of


owning at least one cow or ox to plow, as well as the
yield-reducing effects of floods and droughts.
92

You might also like