Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 20

Accounting, Organizations andSocie(y, Vol. 10, No. 2, pp. 129-148, 1985. 0361-3682/85 $3.00+.

00
Printed in Great Britain @ 1985 Pergamon Press Ltd

CHANGING MANAGEMENT CONTROL STRATEGIES:


THE ROLE OF COMPETITION BETWEEN ACCOUNTANCY AND
OTHER ORGANISATIONAL PROFESSIONS

PETER ARMSTRONG
Department of Management and Administration, The Polytechnic, Queensgate, Huddersfield

Abstract

This paper seeks to account for the prominence in management hierarchies ofaccountants and other finan-
cial specialists relative to other professions. It is argued that a key to understanding this is the extent of the
adoption of each profession’s characteristic strategy for controlling labour. Animated by a desire for collec-
tive mobihry within the management hierarchies of large corporations, it is shown that engineers, accoun-
tants and personnel specialists have all sought to advance by developing, from their original speciahsed
techniques, relatively comprehensive strategies for controlling labour. It is also argued that this perspective
offers a useful corrective to the functionahsm of many accounts of changes in the mode of control of the
labour process which seek to explain later forms of control solely in terms of the problems encountered
with earlier forms.

As far as can be ascertained, British company This comparative ascendancy of accountants


directors with backgrounds in banking or (broadly defined) in management hierarchies,
accountancy substantially outnumber those although it is the occasion for thanksgiving in the
with technical training (BIM, 1972) member- profession itself- and corresponding grumbles
ship of the Institute of Chartered Accountants from engineers - has attracted little analysis
being the single most common academic or from either. The dominant view is probably that
professional qualification in British boardrooms of Stacey ( 1954), who portrays British
(Institute of Directors Survey, 1965, quoted in capitalism as emerging from darkness into light
Tricker, 1967, p. 20). Further, although the most as the potential of accounting controls gradually
common first degrees amongst the members of dawns on sceptical senior managements. To be
the British Institute of Management (BIM) are in sure the Institute of Cost and Management
science or engineering (Melrose-Woodman, Accountants, in its analysis of the competition
1978. p. I 6; Mansfield et al., 198 1, p. Et), the pat- for management posts which might be faced by
tern of post-graduate study is such that qualifica- its members, has shown an awareness that not all
tions in business, economics or accountancy management positions currently filled by
predominate amongst the minority (roughly accountants need necessarily be so (Banyard,
one third) of members who are qualified to 1983). The general tone of this report, however,
degree level. Moreover the trend over time is (though it is not, at the time of writing, fully pub-
strongly in favour of qualification in the business lished) appears to be sanguine. Accountants, it is
and finance subjects (Melrose-Woodman, 1978, evidently felt, are generally well equipped to
p. 1J). Small wonder then, that between 15 and handle themselves in the competitive corporate
20% of final vear accounting students expect to environment. The future of the profession looks
become managers (Solomon% 1974 ). as assured as its advance to its present promi-

129
130 PETER MMSTRONG

nence. agement - to be characteristic and defining of


A cursory cross-cultural comparison, how- fully developed capitalism. Unfortunately from
ever, makes it quite clear that there is a question. the point of view of understanding the corporate
German management, for instance, is dominated position of accountancy, this literature sulfers
by engineers. Accountancy in the manufacturing from two defects. Firstly it rarely makes explicit
enterprise is thought of as mere book-keeping mention of accounting systems, though (for
and is carried out by comparitive subordinates. example) in the work of Edwards ( 1979) these
Strangely, to the Anglo-Saxon ethnocentric, it is are clearly a component of what he terms
virtually unknown for a German managing direc- “bureaucratic control”. Secondly the accounts
tor to have an accounting background (Hutton, given of changes in the mode of control of the
et al., 1977, pp. 69-87; Lawrence, 1980, pp. 67- labour process tend, in certain respects. to be
74). The situation in Japan is somewhat similar defective. If the argument of this paper is cor-
and qualified accountants in the Western sense rect, these two problems can be tackled
are almost unknown (Coke, 1983). It is clear, together. I will therefore begin by re-examining
then, that the development of sophisticated the manner in which post-Braverman writers
accounting controls and the rise of an industrial have accounted for one particular change in the
branch of an accounting profession to adminis- mode of control of the labour process - the
ter them cannot simply be equated with the coming of scientific management and its deriva-
“maturation” of capitalism. tive techniques.
If it is clear that there are alternatives to man-
agement accounting systems as these are under-
stood in late twentieth-century Anglo-Saxon TWO WAYS OF LOOKING AT THE ORIGIN OF
capitalism, in order to understand the position of SCIENTIFIC MANAGEMENT
accountants in the management hierarchies of
the West, we have to ask the question, “alterna- For Braverman, scientific management was
tives in what respect?“. In the terminology of nothing less than the “explicit verbalisation of
Chandler & Daems ( 1979) modem corporate the capitalist mode ofproduction”( 1974, p. 85).
accounting systems serve the functions of Earlier forms of work organisation which relied
monitoring operations and of allocating on traditional craft controls or systems of inter-
resources between them. nal contract were merely transitional forms in
Though not immediately concerned with the which the formal subordination of labour to cap-
control of “labour power” (the purchased ital had not yet been fully transformed into the
potential for labour) both of these activities only real subordination characteristic of the full
make sense as components of an organisation for development of capitalism (Braverman, 1974, p.
doing so. In other words, although accountants 63; Marx, 1976, p. 1054).
in capitalist enterprises perform other functions A great deal of valuable work has arisen out of
(e.g. stock control, minimisation of taxes, criticism of this apparently simple thesis, nota-
appropriation of surplus from other capitals) bly on the grounds that it confines within the
their importance in management hierarchies factory the analysis of the means used by capital
depends on the adoption of their particular to control labour, that it romanticises the craft
approach to the control of the “labour process” skills supposed to antedate scientific manage-
(the conversion of labour power into particular ment, and that it neglects the role of workers’
forms of labour so as to yield a surplus). resistance in shaping the strategies adopted by
Following the work of Braverman ( 1974) capital (Elger. 1982, pp. 2+27). From the pre-
there has arisen a considerable literature on the sent point of view however, the most relevant
alternative means used to control the labour criticism is that of Littler Ji Salaman ( 1982 ).
process, although Braverman himself consi- namely that Braverman, by positing a single con-
dered only one of thcsc means -Scientific Man- trol problem and de-skilling as a global means of
CHANGING MANAGEMENT CONTROL STRATEGIES 131

solving it, prematurely foreclosed analysis of the ved. Moreover they are made to appear as the
real means used by capital to control labour. only solution, a position which is quite obvi-
However, opening up the debate in this man- ously untenable in the light of Littler’s own study
ner raises afresh the question of the origins of of the very different development of the
scientific management, a question which for Japanese labour process ( 1982, p. 46).
Braverman was resolved virtually as a matter of A related dil3iculty occurs in the attempts of
definition: no scientific management, no fully some of the accounts to periodise changes in
developed capitalism. It is the contention of this control strategies by relating them to economic
paper that there are lacunae in what might be the crises. The problem here is that there are always
“labour process tradition” in dealing with ques- crises somewhere in capitalist economies; nor is
tions of this type. In order to show what these it established that the search for a competitive
are, 1 will first briefly outline the “modal” edge is absent when and where there is no crisis.
account of the advent of scientific management At the empirical level the work of Littler ( 1982)
and allied techniques which is offered by a again underlines this difficulty: whereas the
sample of prominent post-Braverman writers experiments with scientific management
(Friedman, 1977; Edwards, 1979: Clawson, occured in the U.S.A. in boom conditions, the
1980: Gordon et al., 1982; Littler, 1982). Strip- derivative techniques of the Bedaux system
ped of historical detail and allowing for differ- were implemented in this country during a
ences of terminology, their argument runs that slump.
employers’ reliance on craft traditions (Fried- The treatment of the techniques of scientific
man, 1977; Gordon et al., 1982) or systems of management within the “labour process tradi-
internal contract (Clawson, 1980; Littler, 1982) tion”, then, is arguably deficient in its account of
proved inadequate as means of work intensifica- the reasons for their advent, in accounting for
tion under the increased stress of competition the precise nature of the techniques and in locat-
brought about by slump conditions. There fol- ing them historically. In these reipects the work
lowed a period of experimentation with piece- of Layton ( 1969, 1971) offers an important
rates (Friedman, 1977; Edwards, 1979; Clawson, supplementary perspective.
1980; Littler. 1982), a technique of control For Layton, scientific management, in its criti-
which began to fail, in its turn, as workers cisms of traditional supervision and in its claim
learned to regulate their efforts as a defence that the administration of labour should be
against rate-cutting. It was therefore the monopolised by the “planning department”, was
employers’ need to combat effort regulation a product of the ‘ideology of engineering’. This,
which first exposed the necessity for direct in turn was an expression of the resentment of
physical intervention in the process of produc- the American mechanical engineers of the day,
tion. and it was noticeable that Taylor explicitl) hitherto accustomed to the ownership or sub-
directed his methods against “systematic sol- stantial control of small jobbing machine shops
diering”. In post-Braverman writings. then, sci- (Calvert, 1967, Ch. 1) at their subordination in
entific management and similar techniques growing bureaucratic organisations as industrial
appear at the moment when earlier attempts at concentration proceeded.
work intensification were failing for want of pre- There was nothing even mildly reformist
cisely the kind of control of production methods about this ideology: far from expressing hostility
which the new strategies promised. If this to big business it constituted a claim that
account is read, not simply as a narrative, but as engineers were those best fitted to dominate it.
an explanation of the evolution of employers’ Thus, at the same time as scientific management
control strategies. it is. as Salaman ( 1982, p. 5 1) offered techniques for, and an ideological justifi-
has pointed out. a functionalist one: the cation of, the control of labour by capital, it
techniques of scientific management seem to derived those techniques from a particular
appear because of the problems which they sol- analysis of the management task - an engineer-
132 PETER ARMSTRONG

ing analysis - and made the claim that an ment was advocated by engineers in an attempt
application of those techniques called for the to install themselves at the apex of the global
installation of a particular group - engineers - function of capital and if its techniques are now.
at the apex of the developing differentiation as Braverman claims, the bedrock of all modern
within the “global function of capital’ (a term management (1974, p. 87) how is it that
used by Carchedi (1977) to denote that engineers themselves do not now dominate the
assemblage of roles which, in modern managements of all major corporations? The ans-
capitalism, performs the function once carried wer appears to lie in Larson’s (1977, Ch 4)
out by the individual capitalist). analysis of the conditions under which a profes-
What this perspective offers is first of all a con- sional body of knowledge can form the basis of a
vincing periodisation of the advent of scientific “collective mobility project”. Whilst the know-
management: it arose as an expression of the ledge base needs to be sufficiently codifiable to
“ideology of engineering” at the moment when be transmitted as a professional culture it also
American mechanical engineers, as a group, needs to contain sufficient indeterminacy to
experienced an abrupt transition from indepen- debar outsiders from professional practice. In
dence to subordination within the developing other words, however important their function,
industrial hierarchies. More importantly it offers professionals can only use it as a basis for social
an explanation of the nature of the solution mobility (in this case within the global function
which scientific management offered to the of capital), if professional knowledge (in this
problem of controlling labour. The approach to case a technique for controlling labour) is suffi-
the physical process of production grew out of ciently indeterminate to prevent the detach-
the engineers’ previous experience of machine ment of the function horn the professionals
design. Workers’ movements were analysed and themselves. Unfortunately for the engineers, the
redesigned so as to achieve the most economical techniques of scientific management proved too
sequence, an approach which inherently pre- lucid and could too easily be detached from the
supposes the subordination of manual to mental ambitions of the engineers, despite Taylor’s pro-
labour and close directive supervision. testations that scientific management could only
Moreover there is an analogy between the be installed as a total system. Thus Bedaux,
reduction of skilled to simple labour and the ear- though a technocrat by personal inclination, was
lier development by mechanical engineers of acute enough to market the techniques of scien-
interchangeable parts as a solution to the prob- tific management to the family-dominated firms
lem of co-ordinating production (Clawson, of England in a form shorn of Taylor’s messanaic
1980, pp. 76-79). Of course these considera- pretentions (Littler, 1982, pp. 105-S).
tions do not, by themselves explain why
businessmen adopted the techniques of scien-
tific management (when they did): for that we THE ROLE OF INTER-PROFESSIONAL
need to return to the considerations emphasised COMPETITION IN THE GENERATION OF
by the labour process writers. What is being CONTROL STRATEGIES
claimed is that the two perspectives are com-
plementary and that Salaman (1982, p. 59) is Though the development of the techniques of
correct in calling for a consideration of the influ- scientific management occurred early in the dif-
ence of intra-organisational relationships on the ferentiation of management hierarchies, it has
development of control strategies and also of the features which point towards a more general
influence of previous systems of ideas on the model of the development of management con-
form they take. trol strategies. For brevity, in what follows I will
Although it anticipates some later arguments, loosely refer to specialisms within the global
it is as well at this point to anticipate a major function of capital as “professions”. Such a usage
posssible objection: that if scientific manage- calls for some explanation since professionalism
CHANGING MANAGEMENT CONTROL STRATEGIES 133

has traditionally been thought of as in some ( 1) At the time of the development of scien-
degree antipathetic to the values of business tific management, American mechanical
organisations. engineers had developed a relatively clear occu-
This supposition was derived largely from the pational ideology, one element of which was a
assumption that professions could be defined b) belief that their position within the global func-
the possession of certain traits, notably indepen- tion of capital had become unjustifiably subordi-
dent ethical or technical standards of perfor- nate. This suggests that, beyond a certain stage of
mance and collegiate control of these. Besides differentiation, the global function of capital can
tending to accept at face value the professionals’ be seen as a collection of relatively selfconscious
own account of the reasons behind their specialisms which compete at a group level for
exclusionary practices and demands for access to the key positions of command. At stake
autonomy (Roth, 1974 ), this assumption ignores is both access to the relative dominance of the
the possibility that some of the techniques profession as a whole and the promotion pros-
which certain professions attempt to pects of individuals whose careers originate
monopolise can form components of the global within it. There is every incentive for such a
function of capital and that, in the context of bus- competition if Wright ( 1979) is correct in argu-
iness organisation, demands for autonomy may ing that there exists an economic return to the
express not so much a desire for independence function of control, and (for exampe) the 45%
but an ambition to be numbered amongst the salary advantage enjoyed by British engineers
controllers rather than the controlled. Thus who move into “general” management (Berth-
Child et al. ( 1983) see professionalism amongst oud and Smith, 1980, p. 38) strongly suggests
the staff positions in British industry not simply that he is.
as a demand to be allowed to work according to (2) As an expression of the ideology of
the professions’ own conception of proper stan- engineering, scientific management sought to
dards but also as an imposition of these standards remedy the subordination of the engineer b)
on managers in the production function. offering an engineering solution to one of the
It should also be pointed out that, in using the key problems within the global function of capi-
term “professionals” to denote competing tal - that of controlling labour. Though the
specialisms within the global function of capital, problem was, of course, real, the urgency of solv-
I am not endorsing the notion that all mental ing it was also ideologically emphasised by
labour lies within the capital function (cf Taylor’s criticisms of the inadequacies of tradi-
Poulantzas, 1975). It is simply that I am not tional management. Generalising, this indicates
directly concerned in this discussion with those that collective mobility for a profession within
elements of professional work which constitute the global function of capital depends on iden-
productive labour. And whereas certain seg- tifying a key problem confronting capital (which
ments of a profession may lie within what Aber- need not necessarily be that of controlling
crombie 8r Urry ( 1983) call the “service class” labour), ideologically stressing the inadequacy
(i.e. that class which discharges the functions of of existing methods of coping with it (which
capital). other sections of the same profession may be associated with competing professions)
may nof - although they may nevertheless and developing a solution based on the
aspire to do so. techniques of the profession.
Into this last category fell a section of the (3) As has already been pointed out, scientific
American engineering profession at the time of management was based on an extrapolation of
the development of scientific management. The the principles of mechanical engineering design
related trajectories of the profession and the in that most of its key characteristics derived
techniques which it originated suggest a more from an assumption that human labour could
general model of the development of manage- and, for optimum efficiency, should, be designed
ment control strategies. in the same way as machine movements. Thus
134 PETER hRMSTRONG

the solutions offered by professions to crises analysed in the case of accountancy by Johnson
within the global function of capital are likely to (1977a, b, 1980). However, whereas Johnson
be generated from their existing bodies of pro- argues that horizontal fission tends to occur at
fessional knowledge and their specialised the boundary between capital and worker func-
techniques. Pre-professional examples of this tions I would maintain that his analysis of
process were the systems of internal contract accountancy demonstrated that it can also serve
and the piecework payment methods which suc- to isolate different levels of access to decison-
ceeded them. Both can be regarded as attempts making power and economic privilege within
to generahse the petty capitalist motives of the the global function of capital. There are at least
small entrepreneur into methods of controlling three reasons for expecting this to occur:
labour in relatively large organisations (Littler, (a) By consigning the routine and codifiable
1982, pp. 8182). elements of its professional knowledge to subor-
(4) Professions which achieve a pre-emi- dinates, the elite secures for itself the elements
nence within the global function of capital on of indeterminacy and thus reinforces its grip on
the basis of solving a problem other than that of the strategy on which its collective mobility pro-
the control of labour (for example, that of the ject is based.
realisation of surplus), may still influence the (b) By reducing the size of the elite for whom
control strategy simply on account of their gen- key positions are claimed, competition for these
eral dominance. Seeing the problem in terms of at the individual level is reduced.
their professional expertise (or their origin in (c) An internal hierarchy within the profes-
the case of senior managers who no longer prac- sion creates a managerial element in senior posi-
tice one), they may favour systems of control tions within it which reinforces the claim of the
which they best understand. elite that their professional practice inherently
(5) One reason for the evolution of control involves managerial responsibility.
(and other) strategies from pre-existing Having sketched out a model of the role of
specialist knowledge is that, for a strategy to competition within the global function of capital
function as a means of collective mobility for a in the development of control strategies, I will
profession, the profession needs to retain a now attempt to apply it to the cases of accoun-
monopoly of it. As already pointed out, scientific tancy, engineering and personnel management
management let the engineers down badly in since these are the three professions picked out
this respect: it was too lucid. Its techniques by Gospel ( 1983, p. 11) as having influenced
could be divorced from the overall dominance managerial strategies from the time of the inter-
of the engineering profession despite Taylor’s war years. After a brief discussion of the place of
warnings of the perils of doing so. As Braverman each profession within the managerial and direc-
put it, though not with quite the same meaning, toral elite, the discussion of each will follow the
the techniques of scientific management are no model as laid out above.
longer the property of a faction ( 1974, p. 87).
Speaking more generally, the continued posses-
sion of a control (or other) strategy depends on ACCOUNTANTS AND OTHER FINANCIAL
the profession maintaining a certain mystique SPECLALISTS
and indeterminacy about it so that the strategy
can be operated only by themselves. Understanding accountancy, not as a specific
(6) A feature of internal competition within professional training but as that broader range of
the global function of capital which is not illus- subjects which include its technologies as core
trated by the case of scientific management is elements, there can be little doubt of its heavy
the development of clear-cut differentiations of and increasing representation at the key deci-
power, privilege and status (horizontal fissures ) sion-making levels within the global function of
within competing professions, of the kind capital. Although we are here concerned with
CHANGING MANAGEMENT CONTROL STRATEGIES 135

the fortunes and consequences of accountancy begun. Nor had the correlative advance of
in this broad sense, much of what follows per- accountants and former accountants to posi-
force draws on a literature which has been con- tions of command within the global function of
cerned with the profession specifically. capital.
Nevertheless this will still serve to illuminate the What changed matters was the depression of
processes which have led to the comparative the mid 1930’s. If the wide profit margins of
dominance of accountancy as a means of man- early manufacturing industry had forgiven the
agement and its consequences for the control of primitive accounting techniques of the indust-
labour. rial revolution, economic crisis, by a reversal of
In this country, the accounting methods used the same logic, helped to advance the cause of
by early manufacturers originated in the book accountancy by stimulating a drive to locate and
keeping techniques used by estate managers, contain costs and it was the evolution of manage-
mercantile capitalists and putting-out manufac- ment accountancy in response to this pressure
turers. Although these were quite unreliable, which completed the consolidation of accoun-
even as a basis for pricing. let alone internal con- tancy as a major profession. However despite
trol, these deficiencies were masked for a long proddings from Government during and
time by the characteristic wide profit margins of immediately after World War II, the new
the era. In the firms of the industrial revolution, techniques were not adopted without the vigor-
the clerks who performed this accounting work ous advocacy of the profession itself against the
remained few in number and comparatively resistance of “entrepreneurs”, suspicious of any
poorly paid whilst their employers were more “new fangled administrative overhead” (Stacey,
preoccupied with shortages of engineers and 1954).
metalworkers (Pollard, 1965. pp. 144, 223). Although Stacey is not very clear about the
Accountants owed a more substantial early sources of resistance and not very sophisticated
position in the structures of capitalism to the in his analysis of its motivation, these develop-
audit requirements imposed by capitalists on ments fit well with the model of an organisa-
each other, some of which were incorporated tional profession developing its original
into law, both here and in the U.S.A. (Portwood specialism into a comprehensive technique of
& Fielding, 1981, p. 755; Boland, 1982, p. 116) managerial control in response to a crisis within
just as later specialists in taxation were able to the global function of capital and using the pos-
prosper by employing their “impartiality and session of this technique as a means of collective
dispassionateness” (Stacey, 1954, p. 178) to mobility in competition with other potential or
minimise the tax liabilities of the firms which actual incumbents of positions of command.
employed them (Thompson, 1978, p. 397; Studies of the evolution of giant corporations
Boland, 1982, p. 122). in the U.S.A., carried out by Chandler and his co-
However, at least until the mid 1920’s, it was workers, cast further light on the rise of accoun-
not understood by investors and entrepreneurs tancy although, as Littler (1982, p. 50) points
that “In helping to boost company profits, the out, it is necessary to be careful when applying
accountant has been and remains to this day, American experience to this country. In viewing
perhaps the most important management tool of giant corporations essentially as alternatives to
private enterprise” and members of the profes- competitive markets or cartel arrangements for
sion “rarely ascended to leading positions in carrying out the economic functions of co-ordi-
trade, industry or commerce” (Stacey, 1954, pp. nation, monitoring and allocation, Chandler
168, 176-8. 200-2). In other words, the adapta- could be said to be using concepts and a frame of
tion of auditing techniques to the problem of reference which virtually define the develop-
internal control within capitals as opposed to ment of accounting controls as fundamental to
that of regularising relations between them or the development of giant corporations (Chan-
between capitals and the state. had not yet dler & Daems, 1979, pp. 3-4). However his his-
136 PETER ARMSTRONG

torical accounts show that the rise of the tal because decisions of allocation between dis-
accountants was accomplished not as a matter of similar operations could only be made on a com-
definition but by a purposeful restructuring of mon abstract - and therefore financial - basis.
large corporations in response to the economic However, in applying such an analysis to the
crisis of 1920-22. Until that time, the organisa- United Kingdom, it is necessary to bear in mind
tional structures of large American corporations a number of contextual differences: importantly
were modelled on the line/staff structure first that family capitalism persisted far longer in this
developed on the railways, in which accountants country than in the U.S.A. and that here the coin-
and other financial specialists were amongst the cidence of mass markets and mass production
staff advisory to line managers. When applied to techniques which stimulated the development
multi-product enterprises, the fundamental of giant multi-divisional American corporations
weakness of this structure was that it provided was less common and occurred later (Chandler,
no rational way of allocating resources. Because 1977,198O; Chandler & Daems, 1979). Whereas
line managers reported only to senior managers in the United States of America, the multi-divi-
who themselves had functional responsibilities, sional form became predominant amongst large
allocation remained a matter for bargaining and corporations in the period 1945-1950, in the
in-fighting between interested parties. The con- United Kingdom, the transition was still in prog-
sequent inability to adjust inventories to ress during the years 1965-L 970 (Steer & Cable,
demand led to a severe crisis for American cor- 1978).
porations in the recession of the early 1920’s. It is important to note that the growth of giant
In the pioneering and prototypical restructur- corporations itself is not sufftcient to explain the
ing of General Motors, this problem of allocation relative ascendancy of the accounting profes-
was solved by creating a multi-divisional struc- sion. For this it was critical that accountants
ture, co-ordinated and controlled by a general were already represented in the management
office of financial and advisory staff who hierarchies of British and American companies
developed, from the original techniques for con- at the time of their growing pains so that they
trolling inventories, new statistical techniques could profit by offering their characteristic
for more generally controlling, co-ordinating remedies. As has been already pointed out, this
and evaluating the performance of operating early presence was partly a consequence of the
divisions (and consequently of their managers). audit requirements imposed by the securities
Senior managers were thus divorced from day- market. In Germany and Japan, where the major
to-day operations and, what is more significant sources of industrial finance were respectively
from the present point of view, they became the banking system (Habakkuk, 1967, p. 167)
financial rather than operational or technical and government (Littler, 1982, p. 146), it is also
decision-makers. Thus although it was an the case that accountants are both less numer-
engineer, Alfred P. Sloan Jr, who played a promi- ous and less senior in the management hierar-
nent part in the restructuring of General Motors, chies of large companies (Hutton et al., 1977,
the re-organisation was possible because the pp. 69-87; Lawrence, 1980, pp. 67-74; Coke,
accounting and hnancial staffs, formerly in advis- 1983). German management, in particular, is
ory positions, possessed the techniques of audit- dominated by engineers and the techniques of
ing and cost accounting (the latter, ironically, financial control, instead of forming the stock-in-
first developed by the early industrial engineers) trade of a specialist accounting profession as in
from which could be developed more general Great Britain and the United States of America,
methods of control which offered a solution to are taught to these engineering managers at
the crisis faced by the corporation. To put the undergraduate and post-graduate levels.
matter very crudely, accountants displaced Although German accounting controls may, in
engineers and other operational managers from consequence, appear primitive to American
key positions within the global function of capi- eyes, this appears to be compensated by the gre-
CHANGING MANAGEMENT CONTROL STRATEGIES 137

ater emphasis on manufacture ( Lawrence, 1980, likely to impinge on its practice rather than suf-
pp. 89-95). Interestingly, in a Germany com- fer the consequences of the monopolisation of
pany studied by Millar ( 1981) the engineer- these by other specialists ( Banyard, 1983 ). On
managers had devised a de-centralised system of another front, the more recently evolved sub-
production and a “special” stock-control system, specialisms of operational research and manage-
both of which eliminated the need for certain rial economics appear to be competing for part
accounting procedures common in the United of the traditional control function of manage-
Kingdom. ment accountancy (Tricker, 1967, pp. 37 l-5 ) to
The involvement of accountancy in key deci- the accompaniment of mutually denigratory
sion-making positions within the global function occupational ideologies (cf. Esland, 1980, p.
of capital has, in Johnson’s view ( 1977a, b, 240).
1980) created a horizontal fission within the As a system of control. management accoun-
profession whereby the activities of the elite tancy does not, in its pure form, involve physical
which creates, installs and supervises control intervention in the labour of production. How-
systems have the effect of routinising, fragment- ever, in the larger sense, it serves to control the
ing and de-skilling the work of their nominal labour process in at least three inter-related
professional colleagues. For the elite, on the ways. In one of its aspects it is a solution to the
other hand, the delegation of routine tasks to problem posed by the demise of the internal
subordinates has the effect of sustaining the contract system: that of how to ensure the loy-
“indetermination” of its own activities, thus alty and motivation of salaried managers and so
serving to reinforce its monopoly of them. This avoid the ‘negligence and profusion’ which
monopoly persists, suggests Johnson, not so Adam Smith believed would be the inevitable
much as a result of the esoteric nature of the result of their relative economic security (Pol-
knowledge base but only so long as it operates in lard, 1965, p. 12; Edwards, 1979, p. 31). Budget
the interests of capital. Testifying to the qualita- allocations are used to discipline and control
tive differences in different levels of accounting department managers (Tricker, 1967, pp. 73-5)
work are the problems of adjustment faced by and the development of measures of departmen-
accountants if and when they are promoted tal performance has been linked with practices
(McKenna, 1978). for the evaluation and reward of their managers
Besides these tensions internal to the profes- (Burchell et al., 1980, p. 16). In this aspect, man-
sion, claims are being made for the territorial agement accountancy supplements the
extension of the accounting domain, particu- engineering transformation of the physical pro-
larly into production management (Burchell et cess of production by linking managers’ careers
al.. 1980) and, in reaction, resistance by opera- to their success in increasing the rate of exploita-
tional managers to the control exercised by tion in their particular departments. Secondly,
accountants is a continuing feature of modern by rationahsing decisions of allocation (see, for
corporations. Amongst accountants themselves, example, McKenna, 1978, p. 13) it enables the
at least the Institute of Cost and Management concentration of capital and labour on those
Accountants is keenly aware that its members operations which yield the greatest surplus, so
are in competition with other professions and indirectly acting as a disciplinary pressure on
with the members of other accounting institu- those whose livelihoods are linked with those
tions for positions of corporate power. At the operations which yield the least. Finally, the lan-
time of writing, this institute is preparing a guage and pre-suppositions of accounting sys-
report identifying the sources of competition tems (BurcheIl et al., 1980) function as voc-
and strategies to deal with it. In particular, it is abularies of motive which set the terms of and
seen as necessary in the interests of the profes- limit any challenge by workers and subordinate
sion that it should succeed in annexing those managers to senior management decisions
parts of information technology which look (Batstone, 1979).
138 PETER hRMSTRONG

ENGINEER5 “troublesome” categories of labour (Habakkuk,


1967, p. 152; Bruland. 1982; Noble, 1979). In
According to Gerstl & Hutton ( 1966, pp. 87- other words, if engineers are subordinate, they
9), about one third of all mechanical engineers are subordinate within the global functions of
are in managerial positions of some kind, a prop- capital, as well as to it. At least in the Engineering
ortion which rises to over haIf in the over 5 5 age Industry itself, this does not seem to have been
group. However, such figures give quite a mis- the case from the outset.
leading impression of the place of engineers in In Victorian England, the rapid mechanisation
the corporate power structure since most of of textile production created the first large scale
these “managerial” positions appear to involve market for the embryo mechanical engineering
only the supervision of other engineers or industry. At the time, the manner in which this
technologists. Only a small proportion of market was supplied ensured that the engineers
engineers have line supervisors reporting to themselves participated fully in the global func-
them (Vanning, 1975, pp. 62-3). To look at the tion of capital: they set up and ran their own
matter another way: even in the engineering machine shops in the centres of textile manufac-
industry, only one-quarter of the managers have ture (Rolt, 1970, pp. 131-l 38). In other indus-
training or experience in engineering (Vanning, tries too, salaried managers were often
1975, p. 106). In industry generally, qualifac- engineers by the standards of the day, if only
tions in business economics or accountancy, because the lack of differentiation of function
substantially outnumber those in science or made it difficult to separate management from
engineering amongst members of the British technical expertise (Pollard, 1965, p. 126). The
Institute of Management. At board level, British path from this heavy involvement in the giobal
companies are far more likely to appoint direc- function of capital to the comparative contem-
tors with purely financial backgrounds, or even porary subordination of the engineer in Great
persons possessing only a general aura of emi- Britain is more-or-less uncharted. For example
nence than those with any form of technical there are instances in which the persistence of
training (BIM, 1972). More specifically in the family capitalism in this country (Hannah, 1980,
engineering industry, in 1952 only one-fifth of p. 53) ensured the dominance of the engineer-
all directors had any form of technical qualitica- ing interest until as late as the 1950’s, but how
tion whilst fully one-third of the companies had widespread this pattern was, where it was
no technically qualified director at all (Monck, located and what ended it are matters for future
1954). research. With due caution, we shall have to turn
This cannot simply be a case of the subordina- to the United States for clues.
tion of productive labour to capital functions. Until the end of the 19th century, many
Though Marxist thinkers such as Poulantzas American mechanical engineers either owned
(1975) and Gorz (I976 a,b) vastly overstate their own small machine shops or, where they
their case in arguing that all “mental labour” is were employed by larger firms, had wide-rang-
unproductive, it remains true that there are ing managerial powers including (for example)
aspects of engineering which are implicated in responsibility for industrial relations (Calvert.
the extraction and realisation of surplus value, 1967, Ch. 1 and pp. 14 l-2). Similarly the early
rather than its creation (for example, in produc- civil engineers had considerable autonomy in
tion and sales engineering). What Edwards overseeing the work of subcontractors on behaLf
( 1979) called the “technical control” of labour of their employers although the efforts of some
is at least implicit in the design of production of them to achieve contractor status for them-
systems (c.f. Hales, 1980, pp. 55-8) and there is selves were firmly resisted (Calhoun, 1960, pp.
evidence that certain key innovations in produc- 68 and 91-103). This broad and, by today’s stan-
tion techniques have been the product of a quite dards, “managerial” interpretation of their role
conscious desire to substitute or eliminate by the American engineers of the day is further
CHANGING MANAGEMENT CONTROL STRATEGIES 139

evidenced by the fact that it was the early indust- engineering profession itself is probably not the
rial engineers who pioneered the techniques of whole reason for the relative contemporary sub-
cost accountancy in America (Chandler, 1977, ordination of the mass of engineers in Great Bri-
p. 464) not to mention the technocratic vision tain. A few years after the American engineer,
of scientific management. For Noble (1977) it Alfred P. Sloan Junior, reorganised General
was the industrial engineers “who shaped and Motors so as to place operational managers
rationalised the modern corporation, creating a under the financial control of the general office,
technology of social production in the image of the British accountant, D’Arcy Cooper, created
science, and in the process, generated modern a central technical investigating committee as
management”. Yet, only a decade or so later, part of his reorganisation of Unilever. This com-
large numbers of college-trained engineers were mittee -chaired as a matter of deliberate policy
having to be content with routine and increas- by a non-technical manager-was to investigate
ingly specialised work within the developing every technical department in the company and
industrial bureaucracies, often in positions sub- report directly to the board (Wilson, 1970, p.
ordinate to men without technical training (Cal- 299). In other words, it appeared to a non-tech-
vert, 1967, pp. 145-l 52 ). Instructively the cost nical senior manager that the solution to a lack
accounting techniques pioneered by engineers of co-ordination of technical operations was to
found their way onto college syllabi and, by subordinate technical to non-technical decision-
1926, they were annexed by the specialist making.
National Association of Cost Accountants (Chan- The typicality of this case is, at the current
dler, 1977, pp. 464-5). state of research, very much an open question.
This strongly suggests that the loss of position However, the current situation is that the mass
by engineers within the global function of capi- of the engineering profession in this country is
tal during the transformation of the American considerably obsessed with its “low status”,
corporation described earlier, is partly due to a despite the fact that engineers’ earnings are said
process of horizontal fission on the model of that to compare well with those of other professions
described in the case of accountancy by Johnson (Berthoud 81 Smith, 1980, pp. 45,34; Finniston,
( 1977a, b, 1980). The more narrowly technical 1980, pp. l&%5,60-5). Engineers themselves are
work performed by the later (and larger) gener- clear about who are their more successful com-
ation of college-trained engineers, though argu- petitors within the hierarchies of management
ably based on a body of knowledge more - “The status of Engineering depends on the
esoteric than that of their forebears schooled in outlook of higher management. All too
the “shop culture”, was fatally (from their point frequently, these consist of salesmen and
of view) shorn of its role in the appropriation of accountants . .” (Feilden, 1963. p. 18). Whilst
surplus value. The new engineers were not sim- pre-occupied with the possibility ofa “collective
ply the updated counterparts of the old. Those mobility project” (cf. Larson, 1977, p. 66) for
parts of the professional body of knowledge engineering within the global function of capital,
most intimately concerned with the functions of engineers also accept individual moves into
capital were appropriated by an elite which, semi- or non-technical management (the former
although it continued to recruit from the ranks, preferred) as a legitimate professional goal (for
also had heirs who might be called organisation American evidence on this, see Perrucci &
and methods managers or even management Gerstl, 1969, p. 102; Rothstein, 1969, p. 85).
accountants rather than engineers, whilst the Attempts to provide for engineers’ ambitions by
more purely technical work and the name of means of “dual career ladders” so thay they can
engineering passed to men who were subordi- attain high salaries and status whilst performing
nate both in the corporations and in the profes- purely technical work have been interpreted as
sional associations. a strategy (presumably thought up by non-
However, horizontal fission within the engineering senior managers) aimed at deflect-
140 PETER ARMSTRONG

ing engineers from the positions of real corpo- pp. 25-3 1) and Collins ( 19’9. p. l--i) have
rate power which are seen as the proper objects argued, professionals are in the strongest posi-
of professional ambition (Goldner & Ritti, tion in relation to their clients when they can
1967). monopolise the competence not only to prac-
In the United Kingdom, discussion amongst tice but to judge the results of that practice.
engineers of the “problem” of low status has Engineering activity, however. though esoteric
created a well-formed ideology which stresses and inaccessible to lay judgement in itself. must
the dire effects on the nation of allowing the pro- end in a physical product or process which can
fession’s grievances to fester, an ideology which be judged by outsiders (unlike, say, the work of
has found forceful expression in a sequence of accountants which ends as a balance sheet
government enquiries which were run, as it hap- drawn up by themselves). In the face of this, the
pens, by engineers themselves. This ideology profession’s ideology must somehow sustain the
stresses the importance of manufacturing indus- position that the subordination of engineers to
try to the British economy, the crucial role of non-engineers is still undesirable. This it notably
engineers in ensuring that designs and produc- attempts, arguing that technological innovation
tion methods in that industry are competitive in British industry suffers due to the caution of
and that this cannot be achieved so long as senior managers ignorant of the “engineering
engineers are subordinate to non-engineers, dimension” (Finniston, 1980, p. 30-35) and that
with the happy corollary that action should the quality of design work suffers when super-
urgently be taken to ensure that engineers vised by non-engineers (Feilden, 1963, Ch 5 ),
quickly move into the command positions of Nevertheless the “problem” of the openness of
British manufacturing industry (Feilden, 1963; engineering to lay judgement remains.
Dainton, 1968; Finniston, 1980). Thus the key The other diJBculty is that of formulating a
positions within the global function of capital policy, a problem exacerbated by the horizontal
are now being claimed, not on the grounds of fissures within the profession. Both Feilden and
offering a superior means of appropriating Finniston proposed reforms to engineering edu-
surplus value as was the case with scientific man- cation on the one hand and a campaign aimed at
agement, but on the basis of a distinctive and convincing senior managements of the impor-
vital contribution to the productive work itself. tance of engineering on the other. The first
The outcome of these attempts will prove a course of action premised that it was engineers’
severe test of Johnson’s ( 1977, p. 106) assertion lack of business sense and their inability to com-
that the persistence of indeterminacy on which municate with non-engineers which kept them
depends the monopolisation of a body of know- from senior positions. In the debates within the
ledge by an organisational profession depends, profession, this analysis is supported by com-
not so much on the inherent mystery of the pro- parisons with the situation in West Germany
fessional knowledge itself, but on whether the where engineering education includes substan-
monopoly coincides with the interests of capital. tial “business” elements and where the senior
In this connection, it is worth remarking managements of manufacturing companies are,
that, ominously for engineers, computer indeed, dominated by engineers (Hutton et al.,
technologies are being developed in the direc- 1977, pp. 69-87; Lawrence, 1980, pp. 67-74).
tion of routinising, fragmentary and de-skilling However it is questionable whether the former
the work of engineering designers (Cooley, is the cause of the latter. As mentioned in the ear-
1977, p. 39; Cooley, 198 1; Rosenbrock, 1977, p. lier discussion of the accountancy profession,
392). the incorporation of business elements into
Even if this analysis proves fallacious, German engineering education may be a COYZ-
engineers face other difficulties in claiming pos- sequence of the relative dominance of engineer-
itions of corporate power on the basis of their ing and subordination of accountancy in Ger-
technological contributions. As Larson ( 1977, man management. This, in turn is probably
CHANGING MANAGEMENT C;ONTROL STRATEGlliS 141

related historically to the major role played by Ford’s “Sociology Department” (Beynon, 1973,
the German banking system rather than the sec- pp. 21-3) the profession in this country, as has
urities market in providing long-term industrial been mentioned. claims its origins in factory
finance (Habakkuk, 1967, p. 174; Millar, 198 1, p. welfare work. Perhaps the discrepancy arises
63). because, in the more fragmented conditions of
British industry, the less benign approaches to
the control of labour were performed by
THE PERSONNEL SPECIALISTS employers’ associations rather than by managers
as such (Clegg, 1979, p. 125). However these
More explicitly aware than either accountants aspects of its origin are not emphasised in the
or engineers of the nature of the competition for accepted histories of the profession, though
corporate power, the personnel profession has, Anthony & Crichton ( 1969, p. 160) do mention
in recent years, conducted a semi-public debate the bargaining activities of employers’ associa-
on how best to further its own interests. Its tions as antecedents.
success, however. remains partial: despite the History is written by the victors, and that of
assertion of Cherns ( 1972. quoted in Watson, the personnel profession is represented as a
1977, p. 168 ) that “organisational leadership” in struggle whereby “professionalism” emerged
post-war Britain had successively passed from through and was finally emancipated from the
engineers, accountants and marketing “welfare image” (Anthony & Crichton. 1969, p.
specialists to personnel departments, Brookes 149). For example, in the inter-war years, wel-
( 1979, p. 53) found that only seven of the 173 fare workers based outside the factory were
companies he surveyed had directors responsi- excluded from membership of the Central
ble solely for personnel and industrial relations. Association of Welfare Workers, care was taken
Similarly, despite the recommendations of the to define welfare work as an aspect of manage-
1968 Royal Commission on Trades Unions and ment and even the name of the association was
Employers’ Associations (Donovan, 1968, paras changed so as to emphasise its industrial con-
95, 102) that boards of directors should take cerns (Niven, 1967, pp. 51, 52, 61). In the
responsibility for industrial relations, over half of account of Anthony & Crichton ( 1969, p. 164)
the companies had no director whose respon- the former welfare workers “struggled to find
sibilities included these matters (Brookes, other jobs to do for management which would
1979) and the characteristic directoral entitle them to a place on the management team,
approach to industrial relations appears to be in order that they could be brought in on discus-
one of studied ignorance (Winkler, 1974). On sions of importance such as the determination of
the other hand success is relative: the profession wage rates or the deployment of staff”. In other
itself traces its origins to the 60 or so female wel- words it is claimed that corporate power was
fare workers in British factories on the eve of the sought, not in the self interest of the profession,
First World War (Niven, 1967. p. 42) whereas, but as a means of more effectively performing
by 1980 membership of the institute of Person- welfare work (see also Watson, 1977, pp. 52-
nel Managers stood at over 20,000 (ACAS, 1980, 55). Niven’s account of the progress of the pro-
p. 55). fession during the recession of 1925-1939 is
According to the literature there is a curious more robust: “in the recession, welfare workers
difference between the origins of British and had to justify their immediate usefulness or foun-
American personnel management. Whereas in der . welfare supervisors had the courage and
the U.S.A.. personnel departments were appa- adaptability to turn course from welfare to
rently created in order to administer a battery of labour and staff management in order to meet
techniques aimed at dividing and weakening the new and pressing needs” (Niven, 1967, p. 7 1).
workforce (Gordon et al., 1982, p. 138) and the Given that the welfare needs of workers can
devices of paternalistic despotism such as Henry scarcely have declined during the hungry thir-
142 PETER ARMSTRONG

ties, it is likely that these “new and pressing interests.


needs” had more to do with maintaining the wel- Perhaps because they have not yet succeeded
fare workers’ position in industry than with any in gaining the autonomy which they believe pos-
thing else. Niven’s passage suggests that they did sible and necessary (Thomason, 1980, p. 35)
so by adapting the existing means of their trade personnel specialists are highly conscious that
(interviewing, record-keeping and so on) so as they face competition for positions of corporate
to create a new means of labour administration. power from engineers, financial and sales
As late as the early 1970s this aspect of the ori- specialists. The kind of interpersonal tactics
gin of the techniques of personnel management used by individual personnel managers in such
was, according to Timperley & Osbaldeston situations are most illuminatingly described by
(1975, p. 619) still reflected in the clerical/ Watson (1977, pp. 178-189) in an account
administrative backgrounds of many practising which also stresses the active role played by
personnel managers. them in defining the problems for which they
Having developed its techniques of control purport to offer solutions.
before the Second World War, the profession Personnel specialists have tried to expand
was well placed to offer them on a post-war sel- their sphere of influence into production plan-
ler’s market when full employment made the ning and have competed with foremen and cost-
control of labour a more pressing problem. By ing departments for the function of rate-furing
the 1970’s, the adaption of professional values to on the grounds that they possess specialist
the opportunities of the market had proceeded knowledge of the effects of incentives. After
to the point where a concern for welfare World War II, they increasingly appropriated the
appeared to be entirely submerged beneath a training of first line supervisors and middle man-
concentration on “efficiency” (Watson, 1977, p. agers on the grounds that the hire and fire
198) and this tradition of relatively self-con- methods of control traditional amongst these
sciously adjusting the service provided so as to groups, were no longer appropriate in an era of
advance the profession within the global func- full employment (Anthony & Crichton, 1969,
tion of capital has continued (Thomason, 1980, pp. 166-70). In the industrial context they have
pp. 32,37). become the prophets of a particular kind of
However useful the personnel specialists may behavioural science. much of which, as Rose
or may not have been, they could only have (1975, p. 213) points out of the Tavistock
advanced their profession on the basis of that researches, can be interpreted as an attack on
usefulness by establishing a monopoly of compe- the trained incapacities of production engineers.
tence. Thus Niven ( 1967, p. 59) saw a key task of Moreover, in the industrial relations field, the
the association as that of combating the general message of the kind of industrial rela-
employers’ tendency to assume that anyone tions policies advocated, for example by Haw-
could do the job and persuading them to employ kins (1979) is that short-term expediency in
only trained welfare workers. For Thomason solving industrial relations problems (charac-
( 1980, p. 32) the essential difficulty in this is teristic of production managers) should be sub-
that the human relations and social skills which ordinated to a broader, more consistent policy
are part of the profession’s stock-in-trade are too (administered by personnel specialists, and,
indeterminate to form a sufficiently exclusive naturally, from the boardroom).
and distinct basis on which to claim a monopoly All this is a particular case of a phenomenon
(in a way, the opposite difficulty to that faced by remarked by Child et al. (1983) and earlier by
the engineers). Like Niven, and with disarming Fores & Clover ( 1978) as particularly prevalent
frankness, he proposes a somewhat artificial cre- in Britain: that the professionalisation of staff
dentialism as a solution (Thomason, 1980, pp. positions outside production involves a claim
32, 33), without burdening his readers with the for decision-making autonomy which results in
usual claims that this is really in the clients’ own the imposition of the practices of the professions
CHANGING MANAGEMENT CONTROL STRATEGIES I43

concerned on, and thus the subordination of, the ( 1968) personnel managers have stimulated the
production function. In other words, personnel development of shop steward organisation and
specialists have ascended within the global func- the expectation that something was to be gained
tion of capital partly by exposing the by participating in the new bargaining proce-
inadequacies of, and at the expense of, engineers dures. However, because they lacked influence
in line management. on top management financial policies, personnel
The major crisis within the function of capital specialists have been unable to satisfy these new
which has enabled them to do this concerned expectations. The result has been an increased
the control of labour and it resulted from the incidence of conflict with a better organised
persistence of relatively full employment from workforce.
the end of World War II until the early 1970’s, Another development during the years of full
although a part may also have been played by the employment worked in favour of the personnel
development of capital intensive technologies specialists. As part of a high-level strategy for sec-
which made it necessary for employers to bar- uring the co-operation of labour, governments
gain for their workers to take a responsible have introduced, from the 1960s onwards, a
attitude towards capital plant in this “primary” mass of legislation offering “individual rights” to
sector of the labour market (Edwards, 1975). workers on the one hand and regularising the
Full employment created the conditions for the position of their trade unions and officials on the
growth of shop steward organisation to which other. Though some of these “rights” proved
the response, firstly of academics then later of more apparent than real when put to the test
the Royal Commission, was that the techniques (Lewis, 1981) the complication of the legisla-
of industrial relations pluralism were a more tion provided personnel specialists with a major
realistic strategy than the bluff anti-unionism of opportunity to supplement their somewhat
an earlier generation of engineer/managers indeterminate human relations skills with a
(Fox. 1966, Flanders, 1975, Donovan, 1968, p. genuinely codifiable and esoteric body of profes-
264). sional knowledge. As Thomason (1980, p. 33)
The appropriation by the profession of indust- puts it, “The spate of employee legislation and
rial relations pluralism with its assumption of codes of practice have enabled both the IPM and
permanent underlying conflicts of interest pro- individual practitioners to acquire status
vides the perfect rationale for the curious dual enhancing power” and again “the state response
relationship of personnel specialists to the con- changed the balance of power as between per-
trol of labour. On the one hand this obviously sonnel practitioners and line managers which
presents problems which must be solved at the allowed the former to enhance their discretion”.
level of day-to-day operations, and on the other, Put more crudely, personnel managers have
their own organisational power and intluence used the threat of industrial tribunals to impose
depends on the long-term persistence of the their own methods of discipline on lower line
problem (Watson, 1977, pp. 1839). In Turner managers and to remove from them altogether
et aZ.‘s (1977. pp. 35-9) finding that labour the right to sack.
problems are most prevalent where personnel If the personnel profession has traditionally
specialists are most heavily represented, there is sought its advances within the corporate hierar-
even the suggestion that they may play a part in chy by exposing the shortcomings of production
sustaining the very problems which provide the and other line managers, with a view to taking
rationale for their presence. A survey by the over certain of their former roles within the
Industrial Relations Research Unit reported by global function of capital, there are signs that a
Batstone ( 1980) points towards a mechanism by different strategy is being adopted in relation to
which this may occur. By centralising and for- financial specialists. Recognlsing the corporate
malising company-level procedures in line with ascendancy of these, personnel thinkers are now
the recommendations of the Donovan report seeking to present their specialist contribution
I44 PETER hh\lSTRONG

to the control of labour in forms which they take managers. Whereas the ultimate logic of the
to be acceptable in terms of the “dominant engineers’ claim to design the physical process
utilitarian values and bureaucratic relation- of production leads to attempts to destroy work-
ships” of the organisations which employ them. ers’ resistance to this claim, that of the personnel
Thus quantitative and computerised techniques specialists’ position demands that the control of
of manpower planning have been developed in labour, both at the individual and collective
answer to the criticism that personnel depart- levels, should continue to pose a problem, albeit
ments have not, in the past, provided “hard” data one containable by the specialist techniques
(Legge, 1978, p. 79 et seq). There have also possessed by them. Perhaps this contradiction is
appeared the significantly labelled techniques of one reason for the rapidly changing hit-parade of
“Human resource, accounting” and the “Indust- psycho-sociological gimmickry deployed by the
rial relations audit”, but it is not clear whether profession (the other being product dilferentia-
these attempts to present personnel work as a tion under the stress of competition amongst the
species of accountancy are meeting with much associated consultants and semi-academics). In
success. a profession with such a strong tradition of offer-
As with accountancy and engineering, the ing whatever service promises to advance or
stress of competition for corporate power secure its own position, more will surely follow,
appears to be producing a hierarchy within the provided, that is, it can find a way of surviving
profession. There are five grades of membership the comparative quiescence of labour imposed
in the Institute of Personnel Management, with by the current recession.
the “Member” grade, which numbers about one
fifth of the total, dominating the policy of the
Institute and setting increasingly rigorous SOME BRIEF REiMARKS ON OTHER
requirements for entry to its own ranks (Timper- COMPETING GROUPS
ley & Osbaldeston, 1975). However, the
reported infrequency of formal qualihcations Financial, engineering and personnel
amongst personnel managers in industry (Daniel specialists by no means exhaust the catalogue of
& IMillward, 1983, p. 122) indicates that the cre- identifiable groups engaged in the competing
ation of this hierarchy has not enabled the elite collective mobility projects within the global
of the profession to monopolise the available top functions of capital. Unspecialised “general”
corporate positions. Though there probably are managers - and almost half of all British mana-
hierarchies within personnel practice in indus- gers have no higher education at all (Fidler.
try (in a case observed by the writer, such mat- 198 1, pp. 85-6) -defend their position in man-
ters as interviewing, issuing warnings and even agement hierarchies, and incidentally their own
the more straightforward sackings were all hand- brand of face-to-face labour control by denigrat-
led by female subordinates), these seem to have ing the “impracticality” and “academicism” of
developed in an ad hoc manner, unrelated to the any profession which requires higher eduation.
formal hierarchy of the profession. Sales and marketing specialists, whose positions
Though subject to negotiation and attempts at originally developed with the expanding labour
territorial expansion the role of personnel of realisation, now appear to be intluencing an
specialists in the control of labour has histori- approach to the control of labour which
cally been that of delivering a suitable supply of involves exposing work groups, both economi-
it to operational departments and helping to cally and socially, to their markets (Pignon &
motivate or at least prevent its insurrection once Querzola. 1975 ). Though as yet ill-defined, the
it is there. Such a specialism can prosper in the spccialisms associated with computer
corporate hierarchy only when these tasks are. technologies have already undergone a horizon-
or can be made to appear, sufticiently grave a tal fission into the routinised tasks of the compu-
problem not to he handled incidentally by other ter programmer and the “managerial” role of the
CHANGING MANAGEMENT CONTROL STRATE<;Il:.S 145

systems analyst (K&t. 1979). Systems analysts the advent of new control strategies and their
appear to be advancing in corporate hierarchies nature. In contrast to such a perspective this
partly by displacing, de-skilling and devising paper has argued that control strategies are
new systems for the surveillance of productive based on generalisations of the techniques and
labour. and partly by cannibalising the tasks of knowledge possessed by “professional” groups
the “traditional” organisational professions in competition for the key positions within the
(Haug. 1977). The profession of management global function of capital. The response of capi-
accountancy has recently shown itself to be tal to its crises (which need not be specifically of
keenly aware of this last threat (Banyard, 1983). control) is mediated by these professions which
Given the stakes. it is virtually certain that new are poised to engage on collective mobility pro-
organisational specialisms will emerge, each jects within the global function of capital in
offering a characteristic means of coping with virtue of their possession of techniques which
the changing exigencies of capitalist production. offer responses to these crises. However if the
Each consequent shift in the intra-corporate knowledge basis of a response strategy is too
balance of power carries with it the potential for accessible to outsiders, it can be implemented
a modification of the means used by capital to whilst failing as a means of group mobility, since
control labour. the “profession” may then be dispossessed of its
strategy. For this reason the elites within a pro-
fession may attempt to monopolise for them-
CONCLUSIONS selves the esoteric indeterminate aspects of
professional practice whilst delegating the
It has been argued that the representation of routine elements to subordinates thus produc-
accountants and other financial specialists in the ing what Johnson ( 1977 a, b, 1980) called a
management hierarchies of capitalist enterprises “horizontal fission” within the profession.
depends on the adoption of accounting proce- Relationships between the control strategies
dures as part of the strategy for controlling the produced by the engineering, financial, person-
labour process. Since the extent to which this is nel and other professions have been reviewed
the case varies markedly between different and appear to be consistent with such a perspec-
capitalist cultures, the comparative promin- tive, although there are considerable gaps in the
ence of accounting controls in Anglo-Saxon evidence. For accountants and other financial
capitalism needs explanation. specialists the implication is that their increasing
This leads naturally to the literature on representation in Anglo-Saxon management
changes in the means used by capital to control hierarchies is not simply a consequence of the
the labour process. Unfortunately writers on “objective” needs of capitalism but is the result
the labour process have tended towards of efforts by the profession to develop their
functionalism in their accounts of variations in original techniques into a system of managerial
the control strategies adopted by capital (Sala- control - competitive with other approaches
man, 1982). Thus successive crises within the - precisely as a means of achieving managerial
function of capital are made to account both for ascendancy.

BIBLIOGRAPHY

Abercrombie. N. 8i Urry. J.. Capital, La&ourand the Middle Classes (Allen and Unwin, 1983)
ACAS (Advisory. Conciliation and Arbitration Service), Industrial Relations Handbook (London: HMSO.
1980)
Anthony. P. & Crichton. A.. Industrial Relations and the Personnel Specialists(Batsford, 1969)
Banyard. C.. Future Prospects for Management Accountants. Management Accounting (June 1983)
pp. 262’.
146 PETER ARMSTRONG

Batstone, E., Systems of Domination, Accommodation and Industrial Democracy, in Burns, T. (ed.) Work
andPower Ch. 7 (Sage, 1979)
Batstone, E., What have Personnel Managers done for Industrial Relations? Personnel .Management (June
1980) pp. 36-41.
Berthoud, R. & Smith, D. J., The Education, Training and Careers of Professional Engineers (London:
Department of Industry, HMSO, 1980)
Beynon, H., Working for Ford (Allen Lane,Penguin, 1973)
Boland, R. Jr., Myth and Technology in the American Accounting Profession, Journal of Management
Studies (1982) pp. 109-126.
Braverman, H., La&orandMonopoly Cap&al (Monthly Review Press, 1974)
British Institute of Management, The Board of Directors: a Suruqyof its Structure,Composition and Role
(Management Survey Report No. 10, 1972).
Brookes, C., Boards ofDirectors in Britisbhdustty (Social Science Branch Research and Planning Division,
Department of Employment Research Paper No. 9, 1979)
Brown. W., The Changing Contours of British Industrial Relations (Blackwell, 198 1)
Bruland, T., Industrial Conflict as a Source of Technical Innovation: Three Cases. Economy and Sociefy
(1982)~~. 91-121.
Burchell. S., Clubb. C., Hopwood, A, Hughes, J. & Nahapiet. J., The Roles of Accounting in Organisations and
Society. Accounting, Organizations and Society ( 1980) pp. 5-27.
Calhoun, D. H., The American Civil Engineetl Origins and Conflict (Cambridge, MA: The Technology
Press, MIT, 1960)
Caivert, M. A., TheMechanicalEngineer in America 1830-1910: Professional Cultures in Conflict (John
Hopkins Press, 1967)
Carchedi, G., On the Economic Identification of Social CIasses (Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1977)
Chandler, D. Jr., The Visible Hand tbeManagerialReuolution in American Business (Harvard UP, 1977)
Chandler, A. D. Jr., The United States: Seedbed of Managerial Capitalism, in Chandler, A. D. Jr. and Daems, H.
(eds) Managerrai Hierarchies: Comparative Perspectives on the Rise of Modern Industrial Enterprise
Ch. 1 (Harvard UP, 1980)
Chandler, A. D. Jr. & Daems, H., Administrative Co-ordination, AIlocation and Monitoring: a Comparative
Analysis of the Emergence of Accounting and Organisation in the USA and Europe. Accounting,
Organizations andsociety ( 1979), pp. 3-20.
Child, J., Fores, M., Glover, I. & Lawrence, P., A Price to Pay? Professionalism and Work Organisation in
Britain and West Germany, Sociology ( 1983). pp. 6378.
Clawson, D., Bureaucracyand the LaborProcess: the Transformation of USIndustry 1850-1920 (Monthly
Review Press, 1980)
Clegg, H. A., The Changing System of Industrial Relations in Great Britain (Blachwell, 1979)
Coke, S.. Putting Professionalism in its Place, Personnel Management ( 1983) pp. i&+5.
Collins, R., The Credential Society an Historical Sociology of Education and Stratification (Academic
Press, 1979)
Cooley, M.. The Contradictions of Science and Technology in the Productive Process, in Boyle, G.,
Elliot, D. & Roy, R. (eds), The Politics of Technology Ch. I .5. pp. 36-45 (Longmans. 1977)
Cooley, M.. The Taylorisation of Intellectual Work, in Levidow, L. and Young, R. ( rds)Science, Fechno~og~~
and the Labour Process:Marxist Studies. Vol. I, pp. 35-65 (CSE Books, 198 I )
Dainton. F. S. (Chairman) Enquiry into the FIow of Candidates in Science atzd Tccfmolocgyinto Higbr,
Education (London: Council for Scientific Policy, HMSO, 1968)
Daniel. W. W. & Millward. N.. Workplace Industrial Relations in Britaitz: The DE’l?Sl SSRC Sunx?
( Heinemann Educational, 1983)
l>onovan, Lord (Chairman ). Report of the Royal Cornmtssioil on Trades 1‘nirms and Enzpl~~~~ws’.4ssuci-
ations (London: HMSO. Cmnd 3623, 1968)
Edwards. R. C, Social Relations of Production and Labour Market Structure. in l%lwards. R. C.. Reich, M. and
Gordon, D. M. (eds ), LahourMar&etSegmentation Ch. I ( London: D.C Heath, I‘j7i )
Edwards.K.,Contested Terrain: the Transfhmation of the Workplace in the Tuvnfreth Cerztuq, (Uwc
I~ooks,1979) (p”gc references to Heincmann edition )
Elger, A., Hraverman. Capital Accumulation and De-skillinp. in Wood. S. (ccl.). 7710IIegradation of Work,:
skill, de-skilling and the Iahourproccss Ch. 2 pp. 2.3-53 ( Hutchinson. 19%)
Fsland. G, Professions and Professionalism. in Mand. <;. ant1 Salaman. (i. ( ds 1. 77~ Polifics o/Work and
Occtr/~ations(:h. - pp. 2 1.3-50 (Open l’niversity Press. 1980)
CHANGING MANAGEMENT CONTROL STRATEGIES 14’

Fidler. J.. The British Business Elite: its uttitudes to cluss, stufus und power (Routledgeand Kegan Paul.
1981)
Feilden. G. B. R. (Chairman )~??gi,zc~L1_ingDesi~~n(Department ofscientific and Industrial Research, HMSO)
Finniston. Sir M.. FRS (Chairman ) Engineering Our Future: Report o/the Committee of Inquiry into Ihe
Engineering Profession (London: HMSO. Cmnd 7793, 1980)
Flanders, A., Collective Bargaining: Prescriptton for Change, in Munugement and Unions: the fbeo?y und
reform o~~industrial relations 2nd ed.. pp. 155-2 I 1 (Faber. 1975)
Forest, M. & Glover. 1.. The British Disease: Professionulism (Times Higher Educational Supplement.,
24.2.3978)
Fox. A.. Industrial Sociolog]* und Industriul Relutions (London: Donovan Commission Research Paper
No. 3. HMSO. 1966)
Friedman. A. L..Indust~urzdLubour: classstmggle at workund monopo!ycupitulism (Macmillan, 1977)
Gersti, J. E. 8; Hutton. S. P.. Engineers: the unuton?.)~ of a profession (Tavistock. 1966)
Goldner. F. H. & Ritti. R. R.. Professionalisarion as Career immobility American Journal ofSociolog~~
( 196:) pp. 489-502.
Gordon, D. M.. Edwards, R. 8r Reich, M., Segmented Work: Divided Workers the historical transformation
oflubor in fbheUnifed States (Cambridge University Press, 1982)
Gorz. A.. Technology, Technicians and Class Struggle, in Gorz. A. (ed), TheDivision oflabourpp. 159-189
(Harvester Press. 1976a )
Gorz. A.. On the Class Character of Science and Scientists, in Rose, H. and Rose, S. (eds), The Political
Economy of Science Ch. 4. pp. 59-9 1 (Macmillan, 1976b)
Gospel, H. F.. Managerial Structures and Strategies, in Gospel. H. F. and Littler, C. (eds), Managerial
Strategies and Industrial Relations Ch. 1 pp. l-24 (Heinemann Education, 1983)
Habakkuk, H. J.. American and British Technology in the Nineteenth Century: The Search for Labour-
Saving Inventions (Cambridge University Press, 1967)
Hales. M., Living Thinkwork: Where do Lubour Processes come from? (CSE Books, 1980)
Hannah. L. Visible and Invisible Hands in Britain, in Chandler, A. D. Jr. and Daems, H. (eds), ManugeriaI-
Hierarchies comparative Perspectives on the Rise of the Modern Industrial Entetpri3e Ch. 2, pp. 4 1-76
(Harvard University Press, 1980)
Haug. M.. Computer Technology and the Obsolescence of the Concept of Profession, in Haugh, R M. and
Dofny, J. (eds) Work and Technology Ch. 14, pp. 215-26 (Sage, 1977)
Hawkins. K, A Handbook of Indushial Relations Practice (Kogan Page, 1979).
Hutton. S. P.. Lawrence, P. A. 81 Smith, J. H., The Recruitment, Deployment and Status of the Mechanical
Engineer in the German Federal Republic (University of Southampton, Department of Mechanical
Engineering, 1977)
Johnson. Terry, What is to be known?, Economy and Society ( 1977a) pp. 194-233.
Johnson. T. J.. The Professions in the Class Structure, in Scase, R. (ed) Industrial Society: Cluss, Cleavage
and Control Ch. 5. pp. 93-I 10 (Allen and Unwin, 1977b)
Johnson. Terry. Work and Power, in &land, G. and S&man, G. (eds) ThePolitics ofWork andOccupations
Ch. 1. pp. 335-71 (Open University Press, 1980)
Kraft. P., The lndustrialisation of Computer Programming: From Programming to “Sofiware production”, in
Zimbalist. A. (ed). CaseStudies in the LaborProcess pp. 1-17 (Monthly Review Press, 1979)
Larson. M. S.. The Rise of Professionalism: a Sociological Analysis (University of California Press, 1977)
Lawrence, P.. Managers and Management in West Germany (Groom Helm, 1980).
Layton, E. T. Jr., Science. Business and the American Engineer, in Perrucci, R. and Gerstl, J. E. (eds), The
Engineers and the Social System Ch. 2, pp. 5 l-72 (John Wiley, 1969)
Layton. E. T. Jr.. The Revolt of the Engineer: Social Respotzsibility and the American Engineering Profes-
sion (Press of Case Western Reserve University, 1971)
Legge. K Poue~ innovation andproblem-solving in personnel management (New York, McGraw-Hill,
19’8)
Lewis, P., An AnaQsis of why Legislation bus Failed to Provide Employment Protection for Unfairly
Dismissed Emplo_>)ees, British Journal of Industrial Relations pp. 3 16-2 16 ( 198 1)
Littler. C. R.. The Development of the Labour Process in Capitalist Societies (Heinemann Educational,
1982)
Littler, C. R. & Salaman. G.. Bravermania and Beyond: Recent Theories of the labour Process. Sociology
(1982)~~. 251-69.
148 PETER ARVlSTRONG

Mansfield, R., Poole, M.. Blyton, P. & Frost. P., The British .Vfunuger in Profile (Brmsh Institute of
Management Foundation Survey Report No. 5 1, 198 1)
IMarx, K, Capital. Vol. 1 (Pelican, 1976).
McKenna. E. F., TheManagement Style of the Chief Accountant (Saxon House, 19’8)
IMelrose-Woodman, J., Profile oftbe BritishManager (British Institute of Management Foundation Surve!-
Report No 38, 1978)
Millar, J., British Management versus German Management: a comparison oforganisational effectil’e.
ness in West German and UKFactories (Gower Press Edition, 1981)
Monck, B., The Eclipse of the Engineer in Management, Engineering ( 195+) pp. 329-31.
Niven, M. M., PersonnelManagement 1913-63 (Institute of Personnel Management, 196’)
Noble, D. F.. America &yDesign (Oxford University Press, 197’).
Noble. D. F., Social Choice in IMachine Design: The Case of Automatically Controlled Machine Tools. in
Zimbalist. A. (ed) Case Studies in the La&orProcess pp. 18-50 (Monthly Review Press. 19-9 )
Perrucci, R. & Gerstl. J. E., Profession Without Community: Engineers in American Societ_]l(Random
House, 1969).
Pignon, D. & Querzola, J., Dictatorship and Democracy in Production. in Gorz, A. (rd ). The Diz+siorzof
La&ourpp. 62-99 (Harvester Press, 1976).
Pollard, S., The Genesis of Modem Management: a study in the Industrial Rezjolution in Great Britain
(Edward Arnold, 1965).
Portwood, D. & Fielding, A.. Privilege and the Professions, Sociological Review ( 198 1) pp. 7t9-‘3.
Poulantzas, N., Classes in Contemporary Capitalism (Verso, 1975)
Rolt. L. T. C.. Victorian Engineering (Allen Lane, 1970)
Rose. M.. Industrial Bebaviour: TheoreticalDevelopments Since Taylor (Allen Lane. Penguin, 19-j)
Rosenbrock H., TheFuture of Control, Automatica. ( 1977) pp. 389-92.
Roth. J,. Professionalism: the Sociologist’s Decoy, Sociology of Work and Occupations ( 19-t) pp. 6-23.
Rothstein, W. G., Engineers and the Functionalist Model of Professions, in Perrucci. R. and Gerstl. J. E. (eds ).
Engineers and tbe Social System Ch. 3, pp. 73-98 (John Wiley, 1969)
Salaman. G., Managing the Frontier of Control. in Giddens. A. and Mackenzie. G. (eds ), Social Class and the
Division of La&ourpp. 46-62 (Cambridge University Press, 1982)
Solomons. D. (with T. IM.Berridge), Prospectusforaprofession: the report of the long range equq’ into
the education and trainingfor tbeAccountancyprofession (Advisory Board for Accounting Education.
1974)
Serge. A. & Warner, M., IManpower Training and Manufacturing Organisation and Workplace Relations in
Great Britain and West Germany. BritishJournal of Industrial Relations ( 1980) pp. 3 13-333
Stacey, N. A. H., English Accountancy: a study in social and economic histo? IBOO-195-t (Get and Co.
1954)
Steer, P. & Cable. J., International Organisation and Profit: an Empirical Invrsttgarion of Large LX
Companies, Journal of Industrial Economics ( 1978) pp. 1 J-30.
Thomason, G.. Corporate Control and the Professional Association. in Poole. M .md Xmsfield. R. (cds ).
Managerial Roles in Industrial Relations Ch. +. pp. 26-37 (Gover, 1980 )
Thompson, G.. Capitalist profit calculation and inflation accounting, Econont.~~ rrnd .Socie[]s ( 1973) pp.
j95-429.
Timperley. S. R. & Osbaldeston. M. D.. The Professionalisation Process: an aspiring occupanonal organia-
ation, Sociologicul Review ( 1975) pp. 395i29.
Tricker. R.. TheAccountant in Management( Batsford. 1967)
Turner, H. A., Roberts, G. 8r Roberts, D., .Munqgemenl characteristicsand Icrhrxrr cfmjlict (Cambridge
Universitv Press 11977)
Vanning, M., Pro/&ssionalEngineers,Scientistsand Technologists in the Engineering Itulrrst~ ( Engineer-
ing Industry Training Board, 1975)
Watson, 7‘. J.. The Personnel ,Managers(Routledge and Krgan Paul. 1977)
Wilson. C., Tbrllistoryof Unilever:astudy in economic~~rr~u~thantlsocictl cbange( CasscllEdition. 19’0 )
Winkier, T. J., The Ghost at the Bargaining Table: Directors and lndustrtal Relations. BritisbJoumal oj.
Industrial Relations ( 197-i) pp. 19 I-.? 12.
Wrght. E. 0.. Cfclss Structureand Income Determirtation (Academic Press. 19’9 )

You might also like