Gender Diversity On Corporate Boards Evaluating The Effectiveness of Shareholder Activism

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 16

G Model

QUAECO-1406; No. of Pages 16 ARTICLE IN PRESS


The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/qref

Gender diversity on corporate boards: Evaluating the effectiveness of


shareholder activism夽
Mahdi Rastad ∗ , John Dobson
Department of Finance, Orfalea College of Business, California Polytechnic State University, San Luis Obispo, CA, 93407, United States

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: In this paper, we examine the effectiveness of shareholder activism as a change mechanism for improving
Received 19 June 2017 gender diversity on corporate boards. We provide evidence that shareholders use both internal pressure
Received in revised form through private negotiations that lead to a withdrawn proposal, and external pressure by submitting a
21 September 2020
proposal to vote in the annual shareholders’ meeting to draw public attention. While both are impactful,
Accepted 30 September 2020
we find that improvement in board gender diversity is more responsive to private negotiations than to
Available online xxx
social pressure. We also find that shareholders’ votes in favor of diversity proposals are higher when a
board is less diverse; but it’s the very existence of a proposal that matters and not how many votes it
JEL classification:
G38
receives. Finally, we find that proposals sponsored by institutional investors are more effective in bringing
J16 gender diversity to corporate boards.
M14 © 2020 Board of Trustees of the University of Illinois. Published by Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.

Keywords:
Gender diversity
Gender diversity quota
Women on board
Shareholder activism
Board of directors
Corporate boards
Shareholder proposals
Social responsibility

1. Introduction roughly reflects that in other sectors of the economy, the glass ceil-
ing remains firmly in place once the focus shifts to senior positions.
Since issues surrounding gender inequality came to the fore in For example, in the case of the S&P 500, only about 5 % of senior
western societies in the 1960s, great strides have been made in management positions are currently held by women, and this has
many aspects of women’s personal and professional lives (Harnois, been the case for decades (Daily, Certo, & Dalton, 1999; Welbourne
2008; Rampton, 2008; Heywood, 2006). Female involvement in the & Andrews, 1996; Carter & Wagner, 2011; McIntyre, 2020; Stych,
general workforce, and in professions such as politics and law has 2020).
significantly increased (Collins, 2012). However, one area where In this paper we focus on another position of power and influ-
change has been notably slower is that of business, specifically, the ence in business, namely that of membership in a company’s board
attainment of senior positions of power and influence in business of directors. Corporate boardrooms have historically been, and con-
(Bertrand & Hallock, 2001; Schwartz, Dunfee, & Kline, 2005). While tinue to be today, heavily dominated by men (Adams & Funk, 2012;
female involvement at the level of junior and middle management Azmat & Petrongolo. 2014). And while there is general agreement
that this gender inequality is a problem, there is a marked disagree-
ment on how to pursue a solution (Kogut, Colomer, and Belinky,
夽 We thank Heitor Almeida, Brian Ayash, Bradyn Breon-Drish, Carlos Flores, Math- 2014; Ahern & Dittmar, 2012; Corinne Post & Kris Byron, 2015).
ias Kronlund, Mahdi Mohseni, George Pennacchi, Cyrus Ramezani, and participants Interestingly – although perhaps not surprisingly – this disagree-
at Philosophy of Management Conference at Oxford University and California Poly- ment closely maps the broad EU versus US debate on the degree to
technic State University seminar for helpful comments. All remaining errors are which government should intervene in business to promote social
ours.
∗ Corresponding author. change. In the current context of gender diversity, for example,
E-mail addresses: mrastad@calpoly.edu (M. Rastad), jdobson@calpoly.edu many European governments have imposed legal quotas which,
(J. Dobson). in essence, force diversity within the private sector, and the EU has

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.qref.2020.09.007
1062-9769/© 2020 Board of Trustees of the University of Illinois. Published by Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.

Please cite this article as: Rastad, M., & Dobson, J, Gender diversity on corporate boards: Evaluating the effectiveness of shareholder
activism, The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.qref.2020.09.007
G Model
QUAECO-1406; No. of Pages 16 ARTICLE IN PRESS
M. Rastad, J. Dobson The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

plans to impose quotas across all 27-member countries in the near gender resolutions do indeed typically fail to be formally adopted
future (Terjesen & Sealy, 2016; Isidro & Sobral, 2015). – they nonetheless have a positive significant future influence on
But while the EU imposes strict legal quotas to force gender corporate board gender diversity. This influence may not be as
diversity, the US continues to rely more on the endogenous mecha- blatant and headline grabbing as government mandated quotas,
nism of shareholder-initiated board diversity resolutions (Perrault, but in reality, it is quite impactful. In short, failed gender diver-
2015; The European Commission, 2012). An exception to this is sity resolutions, brought by shareholders in US companies, are,
the state of California’s recent initiative SB 826 that requires some in fact, bringing about board gender diversity in liberal capitalist
board diversity; however, this legislated quota is already facing sig- economies the same way that mandated EU government quotas do
nificant legal opposition in the California courts while achieving in coordinated capitalist economies. Thus, the evidence we present
some success (Posner, 2020). Governments in the UK and US typ- here indicates that this ‘failure’ may actually lead to future success.
ically provide a passive regulatory shell while the achievement of We find that, although the majority of board diversity resolutions
desirable societal ends is left to the ‘invisible hand’ of minimally do indeed fail in terms of formal adoption, they nonetheless have
constrained market forces. In the US, for example, the Securities a positive future impact on board diversity. In particular, within a
and Exchange Commission (SEC) mandates that companies disclose year after a proposal goes to vote, 25 % of the proposals are imple-
whether and how board diversity is considered in the board hiring mented. Similarly, but even more strongly, 40 % of proposals that
process1 . But this SEC disclosure requirement clearly falls far short are withdrawn from the voting process are implemented within
of, and is far less intrusive than, the mandated quotas imposed by a year, implying an agreement between the company and the pro-
European governments. As such, evaluating the success of the US posal sponsor. These implementation rates are substantially higher
approach to gender diversity yields valuable policy implications, when compared to firms that are never targeted by a proposal but
not only for corporate boards, but also for the general ability of still increase diversity on their board for other reasons, or com-
coordinated-versus-liberal forms of capitalism to successfully pro- pared to the implementation rates for other types of proposals2 .
mote and achieve gender diversity. Thus, regardless of whether proposals are directly voted down or
Although superficially appealing, European board gender quo- withdrawn before the vote, we find that these ‘failed’ resolutions
tas have raised a variety of concerns. These range from basic do, in fact, lead directly to greater future female participation on
practical questions (i.e., Do they work?), to more nuanced issues corporate boards.
such as their effect on women’s personal and professional sta- We next consider the effectiveness of withdrawn versus voted
tus, board quality, financial performance, etc. (Terjesen, Sealy, and proposals. Our difference in difference approach reveals that, with-
Singh, 2009). In this paper we recognize these concerns, and take drawn proposals are more effective in bringing gender diversity to
a closer look at the US non-governmental alternative to quotas, corporate boards than are voted proposals; especially in the same
namely board diversity resolutions brought by shareholders. We year as that in which a proposal is filed. We interpret these obser-
ask if, as an alternative to quotas, shareholder resolutions on gender vations as reflecting a stronger and faster effect for withdrawn
diversity provide an effective mechanism for change in corporate proposals (the majority) as compared to voted proposals (Bauer,
boardrooms. More specifically, we evaluate and compare the effec- Moers, & Viehs, 2015).
tiveness of two levels of shareholder activism: promoting change To study the effect of the magnitude of voter support and
via private negotiations with management that results in a with- sponsor characteristics, we re-estimate a modified version of the
drawn proposal, versus building social pressure on management difference in difference model for each case. The estimation results
that leads to a proposal going to vote at the shareholder annual indicate that voting results do not significantly change the likeli-
meeting. To find out, we track board structure in the years following hood of implementation. Although not impactful, the board gender
a diversity proposal to see if there have been any net improvements diversity voting results reveal shareholders’ preferences. When
in board diversity. In doing so, we answer a set of questions: Does analyzing a subset of proposals that go to vote, we find that share-
board diversity improve in response to shareholder proposals? If holders’ votes in favor of diversity proposals are higher when a
so, how quickly are proposals implemented? Does the resulting board is less diverse and when a proposal is sponsored by an insti-
change differ for proposals that go to vote versus those that are tutional investor or a member of the 30 % Coalition.3 Next, we
withdrawn from the voting process? Are diversity proposals with ask if a proposal’s impact varies by sponsor characteristics. Con-
greater voter support more likely to be implemented? Does it mat- trary to Marquardt and Wiedman (2016), we find that proposals
ter who sponsors the withdrawn proposals, versus the ones that go sponsored by institutional investors are more effective in bringing
to vote? gender diversity to corporate boards than those of other spon-
Superficially, it would appear that this endogenous shareholder- sors.
resolution approach to board gender diversity has failed: the Our study is not the first to propose and empirically test share-
vast majority of diversity resolutions brought by shareholders in holder activism as a change mechanism for improving gender
US-based companies fail to be formally adopted. For example, Flam- diversity on corporate boards. We follow the lead of Marquardt
mer’s survey of around 2,000 US companies – spanning the period and Wiedman (2016) who also study the ability of shareholder
from 1997 to 2014 – identified a total of 79 shareholder proposals resolutions to improve board gender diversity. However, to our
promoting diversity on corporate boards (Flammer, 2015). But of knowledge this is the first paper that finds contrasting results in the
these 79 proposals, only 2 were approved by shareholders. These success of withdrawn vs. voted proposals. Marquardt and Wiedman
high failure rates have led to a growing folk wisdom that the US (2016) also provide empirical evidence that shareholder activism
liberal approach is far less successful than the pro-active European increases board gender diversity but find no differential impact
approach. The title of a recent editorial in the Financial Times reflects
this consensus: “Only the government can ensure women get on to
boards” (Gordon, 2016).
The results we present here, however, do not support the above 2
See for example Thomas and Cotter (2007), Guo et al. (2008), Ertimur, Ferri,
folk wisdom. We provide evidence to indicate that – although the Stubben et al. (2010), Cai and Walkling (2011), Ertimur, Ferri, Muslu et al. (2010),
Chidambaran and Woidtke (1999), Bauer et al. (2015), Barua et al. (2016), Armstrong
et al. (2013), Monks et al. (2004), Lee and Lounsbury (2011) and Baloria et al. (2013).
3
30% Coalition is an organization founded in 2011 that advocates for at least a
30% share of board seats for women in US public companies. For more information
1
SEC Release No. 33-9089, December 16, 2009 see: http://www.30percentcoalition.org/.

2
G Model
QUAECO-1406; No. of Pages 16 ARTICLE IN PRESS
M. Rastad, J. Dobson The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

based on the motivation of the sponsors (i.e., financially vs. socially 2. Theoretical background and hypothesis
motivated). Our study differs from Marquardt and Wiedman (2016)
in several respects. First, while Marquardt and Wiedman (2016) Given that the focus of our study is gender diversity resolu-
focus on the sponsor’s motivation (i.e., social vs. economic), we tions brought by shareholders in public corporations, we essentially
focus on different stages of activism (i.e., private negotiations that build on two broad streams of related research: that pertaining to
lead to a withdrawn proposal vs. building social pressure by putting shareholder activism, and that pertaining to gender diversity. In the
a proposal to vote). We thus shed light on the nature and effective- case of shareholder activism, research focuses around the funda-
ness of these private negotiations between the shareholder activist mental issue of corporate democracy, namely the extent to which
and management. shareholders can overcome the agency conflicts inherent in the sep-
Distinguishing between these stages is important as suggested aration of ownership and control that lie at the heart of the modern
by Ferri (2012). By distinguishing between withdrawn and voted- public corporation (Berle & Means, 1932; Jensen & Meckling, 1976).
on proposals, our results capture the increasing share of withdrawn In the case of gender diversity specifically gender diversity on the
diversity proposals in recent years, from 50 % of all proposals in boards-of-directors of public corporations – previous research falls
1997, to 79 % in 2013 (Chidambaran & Woidtke, 1999). Moreover, into two broad, but not mutually exclusive, categories: namely
there seems to be a pattern in the negotiation dynamics of different those pertaining to the ethics of board diversity, and those pertaining
sponsors: institutional sponsors’ (pension and socially responsible to the economic instrumentality of board diversity. By ‘ethics’ here
investment (SRI) funds) negotiations result in withdrawn proposals we mean the broad question of whether board diversity should
relatively more frequently than do individual and religious spon- be pursued for philosophical or sociological reasons, regardless of
sors’ negotiations. More importantly, we contrast the effect and its effect on any economic measures of corporate worth. By com-
dynamics of withdrawn and voted proposals and find that the parison, the economic studies of board diversity are more prosaic,
impact of withdrawn proposals is stronger than that of voted pro- focusing on the instrumental abilities of board gender diversity
posals. Finally, another distinctive feature of our study is that we to affect some measure of a corporation’s economic performance;
analyze the determinants of voting results and find that sharehold- most obviously the effect, or lack of effect, on the company’s stock
ers’ votes in favor of diversity proposals are higher when a board is price.
less diverse.
This study contributes to the broad literature on determi- 2.1. General impacts of shareholder activism
nants of board gender diversity (Terjesen and Sealy (2016). We
find that shareholder activism does indeed generate internal or A central mechanism by which external shareholders can exert
external pressure, leading to the addition of more female direc- influence over the management and governance of the corpora-
tors (Farrell & Hersch, 2005; Marquardt & Wiedman, 2016). We tion in which they own shares is their ability to submit resolution
also contribute to the growing debate surrounding board gen- proposals. Once submitted, these proposals are either voted on at
der quotas (Terjesen & Sealy, 2016; Balafoutas, Davis, & Sutter, the next annual general meeting of the corporation, or they are
2016). As noted earlier, while the lack of female representation withdrawn by mutual consent of the share- holders submitting the
in boardrooms is a problem both in the US and in Europe, the proposal and the respondent managers. Most diversity proposals
two regions have chosen different strategies in tackling the prob- fall into the latter category and are withdrawn (Bauer et al., 2015;
lem (Ahern & Dittmar, 2012; Fichtl, 2013; Lansing & Chandra, Tkac, 2006). The majority of diversity proposals that do go to vote
2012). We present new evidence in support of the endogenous end up failing to pass (Rojas, M’zali, Turcotte, & Merrigan, 2009).
US approach of shareholder resolutions, documenting its effec- Also, even if they do pass, they are non-binding on management.
tiveness as an alternative approach to the exogenous European In other words, even if a proposal does receive a majority approval
system of imposed quotas. Finally, we contribute to the broad lit- by shareholders, management is not legally obligated to act on this
erature on shareholder activism in general as a tool for corporate proposal (Bauer et al., 2015). In light of this, how much influence do
governance. Various recent studies have examined the effective- shareholder resolutions actually exert on management’s internal
ness of shareholder activism in tackling governance and social governance practices? Perrault (2015) argues that these resolutions
responsibility issues: examples include Ertimur, Ferri, and Muslu do indeed exert power over management: “when shareholders
(2010) and Cai and Walkling (2011) on CEO pay; Ertimur, Ferri, and file a resolution against a firm, they essentially question a firm’s
Stubben (2010) on board of directors’ responsiveness to proposals; legitimacy, as such the process of shareholder resolution filing rep-
Armstrong, Gow, and Larcker (2013) on equity compensation plans; resents [a means by which] shareholders can significantly influence
Barua, Raghunandan, and Rama (2016) on auditor dismissals; and the firm’s policies.”
finally, Guo, Kruse, and Nohel (2008) and Thomas and Cotter (2007) In addition, Perrault observes that resolutions are important
on dropping anti-takeover measures. As for social responsibility embodiments of broad social changes about which firms need to
issues, Baloria, Klassen, and Wiedman (2013) study the effective- be aware: managers need to be aware of “issues that arise from
ness of shareholder proposals on disclosures of political spending; changing perceptions of legitimacy in regards to institutionalized
and Monks, Miller, and Cook (2004) and Lee and Lounsbury (2011) practices given emerging societal trends. [S]hareholders are quick
study environmental issues. We contribute to this broad litera- to grasp that their leverage is deeply anchored in a broad social
ture on shareholder activism by comparing the relative success of dimension, one that appeals to normative ideals and is conveyed
withdrawn and voted proposals in improving gender diversity on through moral language.” So, the longer-term influence and impli-
corporate boards. cations of shareholder resolutions may be broad and not easily
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section quantified.
1 reviews existing literature on shareholder activism and board However, several recent studies have attempted to quantify
gender diversity and develops hypotheses regarding the relative the influence of shareholder resolutions in a variety of cate-
effectiveness of the different levels of shareholder activism. Sec- gories. Although the literature is not extensive, recent empirical
tion 2 describes the data used in our analysis. Section 3 presents studies have investigated the impacts of shareholder resolutions.
an empirical analysis measuring the effectiveness of shareholder Most studies focus specifically on either withdrawn resolutions
proposals. The estimation results are reported in Section 4. The (Chidambaran & Woidtke, 1999; Bauer et al., 2015), or those that
issue of endogeneity is discussed in Section 5, and Section 6 go to vote (Ertimur, Ferri, Stubben et al., 2010; Guo et al., 2008;
concludes. Thomas & Cotter, 2007; Cai & Walkling, 2011; Ertimur, Ferri, Muslu

3
G Model
QUAECO-1406; No. of Pages 16 ARTICLE IN PRESS
M. Rastad, J. Dobson The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

et al., 2010). The general conclusion is that withdrawn proposals is essentially a mechanism to give voice to shareholders to put
are significantly more successful (Rojas et al., 2009). For example, pressure on management for a change. There are two typical out-
in a study of proposals relating to corporate disclosure practices, comes: a withdrawn proposal (WP), or a voted-on-proposal (VP).
Baloria et al. (2013) find that only 8 % of proposals that go to In fact, filing a proposal is not the first step by activist investors
vote are eventually implemented, whereas in the case of with- seeking a change in their portfolio companies. Prior to filing a pro-
drawn proposals the implementation rate is a much healthier 56 %. posal, some activists first request governance changes via letters
These percentages, however, may understate the long-term impact in direct engagement with the firm (private negotiations). When
of shareholder proposals. For example, as Ferri (2012) points out, those requests fail, they then resort to filing proposals, which in
in its endeavors to identify areas for future legislation, the SEC turn can be withdrawn before the vote. Consider the example of
monitors all proposals, regardless of whether they are internally CalSTRS: “In a similar effort, CalSTRS recently submitted 125 letters
implemented by management. Similarly, Baloria et al. (2013) note to boards at California corporations whose boards had no women
that over their sample period, some 80 % of firms adopting corpo- directors; in response, 35 of the companies appointed female board
rate disclosure policies did so after receiving a shareholder proposal members. CalSTRS has indicated that if its private approaches are
within the previous 12 months; thus, indicating a lagged effect of unsuccessful, it will proceed with shareholder proposals.” Similar
‘failed’ shareholder proposals (more on this later). Thus, even failed statements are provided in Table A1 in the Appendix. The table
proposals, if they are numerous, could lead to internal action on the includes statements by asset management and pension fund insti-
part of management, or external regulatory action on the part of tutions, which indicate that they begin their engagement activities
the SEC or other government agencies. As we will see, this fact has with private contact with the company and a direct dialogue with
particular relevance to our study of gender diversity resolutions. As senior management or board of directors. These statements indi-
Flammer (2015) points out: “proposals may be ‘symbolic’ in nature. cate that, only if the direct dialogue fails, would they move forward
Shareholders submit them not so much because they expect the with filing a proposal as the next step. For example, Walden Asset
proposals to pass but rather to bring social issues to the attention Management describes their corporate governance policy on their
of management and the public.” website as “In cases where companies are not sufficiently respon-
What issues are most commonly addressed in shareholder pro- sive or where dialogue breaks down, we are able to take our
posals? A recent study by Baloria et al. (2013) examine some 12,000 concerns directly to other shareholders through the shareholder
shareholder proposals submitted to S&P 1500 firms between 1997 resolution process.”
and 2009. They find that, not surprisingly, almost half the proposals Thus, the activist’s decision to target firms with shareholder pro-
relate directly to issues of corporate governance such as executive posals is not random. Intuition suggests that diversity proposals
and non-executive (i.e., board member) hiring practices (48 %). Also, must be more frequently used where the issue is more severe, i.e.,
not surprisingly, some 21 % relate directly to executive compensa- in firms with less gender diversity. This observation leads to our
tion; while the remainder relate to ‘social’ issues such as charitable first hypothesis:
contributions, global climate change, labor standards, pay disparity,
Hypothesis 1. Companies that are targeted by diversity proposals
and sustainability reporting.
are more likely to have no woman on the board or are generally less
Resolutions directly addressing the issue of board gender diver-
gender-diverse.
sity are trending upward in popularity (Bauer et al., 2015; Rojas
et al., 2009). Furthermore, although these gender resolutions are To provide more texture about the effect of withdrawn pro-
typically brought by relatively peripheral shareholder groups such posals, we collect more information about the circumstances
as CSR advocates or religious organizations, they are often later surrounding withdrawn proposals using public disclosures and
adopted by larger institutional investors who wish to cham- media coverage of the terms of agreement between the proponent
pion trending societal trends (Gillan & Starks, 2007; Johnson, and the firms. We present examples of company statements that
Daily, & Ellstrand, 1996). For example, these observations lead explain the reasoning behind a withdrawal decision in Table A3
Perrault (2015) to conclude that “proposals requesting board in the Appendix. The table includes disclosures by asset manage-
gender diversity are [increasingly] powerful instruments of insti- ment and pension fund institutions that explicitly state that the
tutional change”. withdrawal decision was the result of specific diversity enhancing
In summary, to what extent is corporate democracy facilitated actions taken by the firm. Examples of such actions include appoint-
through shareholder resolutions? The above evidence indicates ing a woman to the board, showing their commitment to enhance
that shareholder resolutions are indeed an effective tool through board diversity by amending their bylaws, and enhancing disclo-
which shareholders have a voice in corporate governance. The fact sures in the proxy statement or creating explicit processes to ensure
that most resolutions are withdrawn or, if they do go to vote, fail to diversity is a search criterion when hiring directors. For example, on
pass in no way means they are unimportant. As we will see below, 6/3/2003 Businesswire reports Calvert Asset Management’s state-
this fact has particular resonance in the case of gender diversity ment on the Modex Corporation: C̈alvert withdrew its shareholder
resolutions. resolution asking the company to bring race and gender diversity
to its board of directors after Molex appointed the first woman to
2.2. Methods for achieving board diversity its board.F̈or more examples see Table A3 in the Appendix. The
evidence therefore suggests that the proponents withdraw their
Turning to the specific case of shareholder diversity resolutions, proposals after reaching an agreement with the firms in their pri-
Perrault (2015) observes: “Not only does the publicity surrounding vate negotiations.
the resolution disrupt the status quo, it also focuses attention on As discussed earlier, previous studies both on gender diversity
those marginalized or under-represented groups who are already in particular, and shareholder activism in general, have found dis-
within the corporate hierarchy.” Thus, by excluding or ignoring tinct differences in outcome based on whether a proposal ends up
women directors, the firm in essence propounds an impoverished going to vote or is withdrawn. Whether the proposal is withdrawn
and biased ethical outlook. As such, managers and regulators have or voted upon depends on the outcome of the negotiation with
a social responsibility to promote gender equality in-and-of itself the firm and the firm’s willingness to have a vote. When lobbying
(Burke, 2000; Singh, 2001; Ingley & Walt, 2003). internally for a change via private negotiations with management
What avenues are available to shareholders to ensure that man- (Bauer et al., 2015) is successful, the proposal is withdrawn by its
agement pursue gender diversity? Filing a shareholder resolution sponsor and therefore does not go to vote. However, when those

4
G Model
QUAECO-1406; No. of Pages 16 ARTICLE IN PRESS
M. Rastad, J. Dobson The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

private negotiations fail the proposal is put to vote to exert social Table 1
Frequency of Proposals by Sponsor Type and Out.
pressure on management by drawing public attention to the sub-
ject (Rojas et al., 2009). Having said that, it is important to note (1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
that successful private negotiations is not the only reason for with- Sponsor Type Voted Withdrawn Omitted Not Filed Total
drawal. A proposal may be withdrawn due to reasons other than its Individual 6 3 4 1 14
adoption (e.g. some other concession to the proponent). As such, Public Pension Fund 7 12 0 1 20
as a crude signal, a WP indicates the reaching of a compromise Religious Organization 39 49 2 4 94
SRI Fund 18 50 1 5 74
between management and shareholder activists, whereas VP’s are
Union 0 1 0 0 1
a sign of negotiation failure that leads to publicizing the subject All Proposals 70 115 7 11 203
(Chidambaran & Woidtke, 1999). That is, a WP is often viewed as
This table presents the outcome frequency for shareholder proposals on board gen-
a ‘success’ because it implies that the resolution proposers were der diversity classified by the sponsor types (individual sponsor, public pension
able to pressure management into acquiescing on at least some fund, religious organizations, SRI funds and unions) between 1997 and 2013. Poten-
aspects of the resolution. As Tkac (2006) observes, a withdrawal tial outcomes for a proposal is either to go to vote (column 1), to be withdrawn
resolution usually signals some type of action on the part of the (column 2), to be omitted (column 3), or not to be filed (column 4).

corporation: dialogue, agreement to resolution, or some other com-


promise. Withdrawal [WP] can be viewed as indicating some level Hypothesis 5. Proposals sponsored by shareholders with stronger
of success. These observations lead to our second hypothesis: private negotiation skills, i.e., institutional investors, are more suc-
Hypothesis 2. While both VP’s and WP’s are positively associated cessful than those sponsored by other investors.
with subsequent improvements in gender diversity on corporate
boards, WP’s are more effective. 3. Data and empirical strategy

Furthermore, we investigate whether the magnitude of the Shareholder proposals are matters raised by shareholders of
shareholders’ support matters or not. We ask, for diversity resolu- public companies to be voted on in an annual shareholder meeting.
tions that do go to vote, how important is the outcome of that vote? Under SEC Rule 14a-8, a shareholder must own the equivalent of
Even though, as discussed above, the vote will likely fail to gain a at least $2000 value or 1 % of the company shares (whichever is
majority, is the size of the loss important in terms of achieving sub- smaller) to be eligible to submit a maximum of one proposal per
sequent improvements in diversity? This question concerning the meeting. In response, the company has three options: (1) to let the
size of the vote, whether won or lost, leads to our third hypothesis: proposal go to vote by including it in the company’s proxy state-
Hypothesis 3. The more votes a VP receives; the higher the like- ment (form DEF 14a); (2) to withdraw the proposal by reaching an
lihood of its effectiveness in terms of achieving board diversity. agreement with the proposal’s sponsor; and (3) to try to exclude the
proposal by submitting a “no-action” request to the SEC. Depend-
When private negations fail, and management has no hesita- ing on the facts and circumstances set forth in the request, the SEC
tion, a proposal goes to vote in an annual shareholders meeting. staff may or may not grant a “no-action” letter to exclude a proposal.
We next ask what are the determinants of the voting results? Does Even if the proposal ultimately goes into the proxy statement and
the type of proposal, board and governance characteristics, or past receives a majority vote, it is still non-binding. Despite this fact, as
performance impact the voting outcome? For example, are share- summarized by Baloria et al. (2013), previous studies suggest that
holders sensitive to the current gender diversity level of a board shareholder proposals work as a mechanism to give shareholders
when casting their vote? Or does the voting result depend on who a voice for change. Consistent with this view, in what follows, we
the proposal sponsor is? More formally: provide evidence that shows the diversity proposals do provide a
Hypothesis 4. Diversity-related proposals tend to receive more mechanism for change.
supportive votes in annual meetings (a) in firms with less gender We use two databases from Institutional Shareholder Services
diversity, and (b) when the proposal is proposed by an institutional (ISS) to obtain data on the structure of boards of directors and
sponsor or a sponsor with more public visibility (i.e., the members shareholder proposals. The Directors database provides data on the
of the 30 % coalition). number of directors on a given board, and their characteristics such
as age and gender4 . The Shareholder Proposals database provides
We follow Marquardt and Wiedman (2016) in recognizing a information about the proposals that a company receives from its
distinction between different types of proposer. They attempt to shareholders each year. Among all types of proposals related to cor-
dichotomize proposers on the basis of motivation – socially moti- porate governance and corporate social responsibility we focus on
vated, versus financially motivated – but they fail to find any diversity-related proposals. To add companies’ financial data, next
impact differential. This is perhaps not surprising given that their we merge the ISS datasets with COMPUSTAT database.
categorization is somewhat arbitrary when “motivations cannot Our main sample consists of 150 companies that received 203
be observed directly”; e.g., all individual proposers are socially diversity-related proposals between 1997 and 2013. Both gen-
motivated, whereas all institutional investors (even SRI funds) are der diversity and racial/minority diversity concerns are raised in
financially motivated. However, here we address this difference in virtually all the diversity-related proposals for which the proxy
terms of the relative power of the proposer as an effective agent statement (form DEF 14a) is available on the SEC website.
for change. The initiators and filers of diversity proposals can vary
broadly, from individuals and small focus groups to large reli- 3.1. Analysis of the content of proposals and board responses
gious organizations, SRI funds, and pension funds. In terms of the
likelihood of success from the proposal, is the originator impor- We review all 70 proxy statements related to diversity proposals
tant? Which sponsors are more influential in private negotiations that go to vote available on the SEC website. A typical diversity
in building social pressure? Earlier studies (e.g., Chidambaran and
Woidtke (1999) and Bauer et al. (2015)) and the analysis in Table 1
in the next section suggest that proposals sponsored by institu- 4
For directors whose gender is missing from the ISS database we use the name
tional investors are more likely to be withdrawn, and therefore files on the Census Bureau website to determine their gender based on their first
these investors may be more influential using private negotiations. names. The name files are available on their website, here: http://www.census.gov/
These questions lead to our fifth hypothesis: topics/population/genealogy/data/1990census/1990censusnamefiles.html.

5
G Model
QUAECO-1406; No. of Pages 16 ARTICLE IN PRESS
M. Rastad, J. Dobson The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

proposal includes two sections: the requests by the shareholders Calvert Asset Management Company, an SRI fund with 55 propos-
sponsoring a proposal, and the board’s response containing voting als, and the Interfaith Center on Corporate Responsibility (ICCR)
recommendations. with 43 proposals. Together these two entities account for nearly
The first section includes a list of concrete actions shareholders half of the diversity-related proposals. This shows that the push for
want the board to take. This typically includes asking the board to more diversity in corporate boards is coming mainly from religious
routinely include women and minorities in the pool of candidates and socially responsible institutions in the US. Moreover, similar to
for board seats, publicly committing to a policy of board inclu- findings by Chidambaran and Woidtke (1999), Bauer et al. (2015)
siveness, providing a timeline for implementing the policy, and and Baloria et al. (2013), we also find a higher likelihood of a pro-
reporting by a pre-set deadline on the board’s efforts to encour- posal withdrawal for institutional investors. Given that a proposal is
age diversified representation on the board. The language used in withdrawn only if its sponsor and the company reach an agreement,
these cases is quite straightforward, as the shareholders consider this can be interpreted as stronger negotiating power for institu-
it “necessary for corporations to abandon the cozy clubbiness that tional investors compared to individual investors. Table 1 shows
has all too often characterized boards in the past. . . in order to that the probability of withdrawing a proposal for SRI funds and
enhance the independence, accountability and responsiveness of pension funds is 68 % (= 50/74) and
corporate boards.” The proponent of a proposal usually cites aca- 60 % (= 12/20) respectively, whereas it is only 21 % (= 3/14) for
demic research advocating for more gender diversity on corporate individual sponsors. Religious organizations stand somewhere in
boards, or makes reference to the success of other companies who between with 52 % (= 49/94) withdrawal likelihood.
have adopted diversity policies and have committed themselves
to the ethics of inclusion in governance. In summary, all proposals
3.3. Sample selection
are either directly asking companies for a more diverse board by
making sure their pool of candidates is diverse, or indirectly asking
Are targeted boards different from non-targeted boards? Table 2
them by requiring them to commit to a policy and a timeline that
answers this question by contrasting board characteristics of the
results in board inclusiveness. Therefore, we consider a proposal to
companies targeted by shareholder proposals versus all the com-
be implemented when ultimately a female director is added to the
panies for which Institutional Shareholder Services provides data.
board.
The two samples have very different board structures. Targeted
The second section includes the board’s recommendation to
companies have 40 % larger boards, with an average board size
shareholders to vote for or against the proposal. Not surprisingly,
of 9.2 members versus 5.51 for all companies. In targeted boards,
the board recommends a vote against the proposal in all 70 cases.
the directors are slightly older and have slightly more director-
This is due to the fact that if the board agreed with the proposal, it
ship positions outside the company. Not surprisingly, the targeted
would have been adopted and thus withdrawn. The very fact that
boards are less diverse. 54 % (= 1–46 %) of targeted boards are all-
there is a vote indicates that the board opposed the proposal, so
male boards, whereas this number is 38 % (= 1–62 %) for all the US
obviously it also recommends against it (see Ertimur, Ferri, Muslu
companies that are not targeted. As an alternative measure, while
et al., 2010). The board’s recommendation is usually justified by
the percentage of the corporate board seats allocated to women in
emphasizing commitment to the unbiased search criteria of using
the entire sample is 10 %, it is only 6 % in targeted companies.
a nominating process designed to identify the best possible nomi-
In summary, targeted boards are larger, older and strictly less
nees for the board regardless of gender, racial background, religion,
diverse. Because of these differences we use a propensity score
or ethnicity. Moreover, they argue that the methods requested in
matching algorithm to carefully select a control group that mir-
the proposal are too restrictive in general, and implementing the
rors the characteristics of the targeted (treated) firms. By picking
requirements set forth in the proposal would add administrative
firms in our control group which are similar to the firms targeted
burdens and costs, without necessarily resulting in the selection of
by diversity proposals, we will make sure that this is a balanced
the best director candidates for the company.
comparison.

3.2. Sponsor type and proposal outcome


4. Empirical analysis
As illustrated in Table 1, 70 out of the total 203 proposals were
4.1. Voting results
put to vote, and only one proposal passed. In 115 cases, the pro-
ponent of the proposal and the company reached an agreement
If the success of diversity proposals is measured by whether
before the proposal was put to vote and therefore was withdrawn.
they received enough votes to pass, it looks like almost every case
The remaining
was a failure. The last row of Table 3 shows that except for one
18 proposals were either not filed or were omitted, meaning that
proposal that marginally passed with 50.7 % votes, no other pro-
they were allowed by the SEC to be excluded from proxy materials
posal passed the 50 % passage threshold. Classifying the proposals
because they did not qualify to go to vote under the exchange act
based on their sponsor in reveals that proposals put forth by SRI and
rule of 14a-85 .
pension funds on average received significantly more votes (23.8
Table 1 also presents the frequency of proposals by proponent
%) compared to religious organizations (16.7 %) and individuals (9
type and proposal outcome (i.e., whether it went to vote, was with-
%). This is another piece of evidence consistent with the view that
drawn, omitted or not filed). We use ISS classification for proponent
institutional investors have more negotiation power, which is at
type: individual sponsors, public pension funds, religious orga-
least partially due to the larger size of those investors.
nizations, Socially Responsible Investment (SRI) funds, and labor
Based on the voting results in Table 3 it may seem that gen-
unions. More than 92 % of proposals are put forth by non-individual
der diversity related proposals are not an effective reform channel
sponsors of which 46 % are religious organizations, 36 % are SRI
because they almost never pass. If this is the case, there must be
funds and 10 % are public pension funds. Two proponents play a
no impact on the gender diversity of targeted boards following a
dominant role in terms of the number of proposals they sponsor:
proposal. However, if what matters is just raising shareholders’
diversity concerns through shareholder activism and putting for-
ward a proposal– and not the fact that it passed or failed – one
5
See Boylan, Cebula, Foley, and Liu (2014) for an analysis of omitted proposals. would expect an improvement in board diversity as a result of the

6
G Model
QUAECO-1406; No. of Pages 16 ARTICLE IN PRESS
M. Rastad, J. Dobson The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

Table 2
Comparison of Board Characteristics in Targeted vs. All Boards.

Targeted Companies All Companies

Variables N Mean Median SD N Mean Median SD Diff

Board Size 1494 9.2 9 2.74 31194 5.51 5.48 3.35 3.7***
Average Age 1494 61.06 61 4.21 31193 60.26 60.55 4.78 0.79***
Average No. of Outside Boards 1494 0.89 0.8 0.61 27823 0.83 0.75 0.65 0.06***
Share of Female Directors 1494 0.06 0 0.08 31194 0.1 0.1 0.1 −0.03***
Any Women on Board 1494 0.46 0 0.5 31194 0.62 1 0.49 −0.16***

This table presents the summary statistics and contrasts the characteristics of boards that are targeted by a gender diversity proposal vs. all boards between 1997 and 2013.
The unit of observation is at the firm/board level. Significance at the 10 %, 5 %, and 1 % levels is indicated by *, **, and ***, respectively.

Table 3
Voting Results by Sponsor Type.

Sponsor Type N Mean SD Min Quantile#1 Quantile#2 Quantile#3 Max

Individual 6 9.0 4.7 5 6 7.5 10 18


Public Pension Fund 7 23.8 14.9 7 7.8 24 29 50.7
Religious Organizations 39 16.7 11.3 3 10 12 20 48
SRI Fund 18 23.8 9.6 6 16 25.9 29 39
Total 70 18.6 11.6 3 10 15 27.9 50.7

This table shows the distribution of shareholder votes in annual meetings, classified based on the identity of the proposal sponsor, on gender diversity proposals that are
filed between 1997 and 2013.

proposal, even if it fails. In the remainder of the paper, we study the Table 4
Analysis of Target Firms.
effectiveness of this channel by examining the diversity changes on
company boards by conducting analysis of proposal implementa- Dependent Variable: Target
tion rates, an unconditional analysis of the introduction of female
(1) (2) (3)
directors to all male boards, and a similar conditional (regression)
Any Women on Board −0.953** −1.245***
analysis.
(0.01) (0.00)
% of Women on Board −5.242** −6.372**
4.2. Choice of control group (0.03) (0.02)
Board Size 0.113*** −0.053
(0.00) (0.18)
To pick our control group, we could consider all the universe of
% of Independent Directors −0.537 −0.857*
boards covered by ISS. However, as Table 2 shows, non-targeted (0.16) (0.07)
boards are drastically different from targeted boards. Therefore, a Average Age of Directors 0.021 0.011
potential concern is that being targeted by diversity proposals can (0.18) (0.58)
be driven by observable and even unobservable factors and there- ROA 2.081*** 2.890***
(0.00) (0.00)
fore can be endogenous to the gender diversity. We try to mitigate Log(Assets) 0.385*** 0.627***
this effect by picking a control group that is chosen using propensity (0.00) (0.00)
scoring matching algorithm. Therefore, we estimate a Logit model Tobin’s Q 0.006 0.086**
to characterize the determinants of being targeted by shareholder (0.22) (0.04)
Capex 3.488*** 3.199***
proposals. More formally, we estimate
(0.00) (0.00)
Constant −5.421*** −8.487*** −8.682***
Pr(Target)it = ˚(ˇ0 +ˇ1 AnyWomanonBoardit
(0.00) (0.00) (0.00)
+ˇ3 PercentageofWomenonBoardit +ˇ5 X it +ˇ6 Z it +t +εit ) (1) R2 0.0588 0.0656 0.1451
N 28206 28154 16882
where  is the cdf of normal distribution, the dependent variable, This Table presents the estimation results for the Logit model in Eq. (2) for the
Target, is an indicator variable that switches on when a firm is tar- companies that were targeted by gender diversity proposals at least once between
geted by a diversity proposal. The independent variables are board 1997 and 2013. The dependent variable, Target, is an indicator variable that switches
on when a firm is targeted by a diversity proposal. The independent variables are
and firm characteristics. Any Women on Board is an indicator vari-
board and firm characteristics. Any Women on Board is an indicator variable that
able that switches on when there is at least one female director on switches on when there is at least one female director on the board. % of Women on
the board. % of Women on Board is the fraction of board seats that Board is the fraction of board seats that are assigned to women. Board Size is total
are assigned to women. We use both Any Women on Board and % of number of directions on a board. % of Independent Directors is the fraction of the board
Women on Board, although both measure board gender diversity. members that are independent. Average Age of Directors is the arithmetic mean of
directors’ age. Firm characteristics include ROA; return on assets, Log(Assets); firm
Note, the latter is a continuous variable capturing the degree of
size, Tobin’s Q; the ratio of firm’s market value of equity to its book value, Capex; the
board diversity whereas the former is an indicator variable captur- ratio of investment in capital expenditure to total assets. All specifications include
ing whether or not there are any woman on board. This is because year fixed-effects. Standard errors are clustered at the firm level. *, **, and *** denotes
the majority of US firms have no women on their board which cre- significance at the 10 %, 5 %, and 1 % level, respectively.
ates a discontinuity in percentage of women on board. Variables
X and Z are control variables for firm and board characteristics
described in Table 4. less diverse, measured by the percentage of women on their board,
Estimation results are reported in Table 4. In column (2) we and more likely to have no women on their board. Switching to
observe that firms that are targeted by diversity proposals are other board characteristics, although not statistically significant,
larger, measured by log of asset size, more profitable and have the direction of the estimation result suggests that firms with
higher levels of capital expenditures. More importantly, columns younger and more independent directors are less likely to be tar-
(1) and (3) show that the board of directors of targeted firms are geted. This is perhaps because those boards are less likely to have a

7
G Model
QUAECO-1406; No. of Pages 16 ARTICLE IN PRESS
M. Rastad, J. Dobson The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

cozy ‘clubiness’ environment and therefore are less need of a female


director to break such an environment. Therefore, our findings sup-
port Hypothesis 1. It is interesting to note that although in column
(1) the positive and significant coefficient on board size may seem
to suggest that larger boards are more likely to be targeted by diver-
sity proposals, it loses its significance when we add other controls in
column (3); especially the log of assets. This is because larger firms
(especially S&P 500 firms) are more likely to receive shareholder
proposals, and larger firms have larger boards.
We use the result of this model to estimate a propensity score
(the probability of being targeted by a diversity proposal), which
we use to select companies for our control group. For each targeted
firm we pick a matched company from the non-targeted pool of
more than 15,000 observations from a merged COMPUSTAT and ISS
dataset. We achieve this by finding a company that has the closest Fig. 1. The Effect of Filing a Diversity Proposal on Board. The sample includes firm-
propensity score to the targeted company’s propensity score in the year observations in Directors database from ISS for which its Shareholder Proposals
database shows at least one gender diversity proposal between 1997 and 2013. The
same year. This results in losing 60 observations and reduces the
figure presents the cumulative proportion of companies that add a female director
total sample to 143 matched proposals. in each of the targeted treatment (squares) and control (circles) groups starting in
t=−1, where t = 0 is the year in which a proposal is filed and treatment is defined as
4.3. Implementation of proposals being a target of a gender diversity proposal.

The simplest way to evaluate the effectiveness of shareholder


proposals is to track what percentage of proposals is implemented
in subsequent years. We mark a proposal as implemented if a
female director is added to the board following a proposal. To do
this, we match the proposal database with board structure data in 4.4. Graphical analysis
the following 2 years to study the potential changes in board diver-
sity after a proposal. Table 5 shows the implementation rates across To discuss the empirical results related to Hypothesis 2, we
different outcomes. The last row of panel A of the table shows that begin by visualizing the pattern of trends in board gender diversity.
overall, out of 143 matched diversity proposals, 11.9 % are imple- We compare the dynamics of board diversity in targeted vs. non-
mented in the same year and 23.1 % in the next year, which adds targeted companies following a proposal. More specifically, we ask:
up to an average implementation rate of 35 % in a two-year win- does putting forward a diversity proposal (regardless of whether it
dow. This ratio is close to the higher end of implementation rates passes or not) improve the likelihood of female representation on
that other studies have found for different types of proposals, espe- the board? To answer this question, we split the sample in each
cially given that diversity proposals almost never pass. For example, year assigning those companies with a diversity proposal as the
Baloria et al. (2013) report 20 % implementation rate for political treatment group and those with no diversity proposal as the con-
spending proposals, and Ertimur, Ferri, Muslu et al. (2010) report a trol group. We start our graphical analysis by examining the pattern
5.3 % implementation rate for pay-related proposals, and 40 % for for all diversity proposals in Fig. 1.
majority vote proposals. If filing a proposal is effective in improving corporate board gen-
The proposals that are omitted by the SEC or not filed, as well der diversity, one would expect to observe an increase in gender
as withdrawn proposals, have the highest implementation rates of diversity on boards that are targeted by those proposals, relative
46.7 % and 39.5 % respectively; this is followed by proposals that to boards that are not. This is exactly the pattern we find in Fig. 1.
are voted on, with a 25 % implementation rate. Except for voted We compare the percentage of companies in each of the treatment
proposals that take a year to be implemented, the implementation (targeted) and control (non-targeted) groups that add at least one
for other proposals begins in the same year and continues in the female director. This number represents the likelihood of adding at
subsequent year. Although not reported in Table 5, we find that least one female director to the board in each group. The dashed
absent any proposal there is still an upward trend in the number line in Fig. 1 shows an overall increase in the fraction of firms in
of companies adding a female director to their board among non- the control group that add a female director, from 2 % in the year
targeted companies, with 8 % of companies allocating more seats to before a proposal is filed to 24 % after 3 years, an annual increase of
female directors each year; a total of 16 % in two years. This suggests 5.5 %. Even more strongly, the proportion of the firms in the treat-
that any impact analysis must compare board diversity improve- ment group that add a female director increases from 0 in the year
ments to a benchmark (control group) that reflects the trend in the before a proposal is filed to 42 % after 3 years, an annual increase of
absence of proposals (counterfactual). This is exactly why we used 10.5 %. This finding is consistent with Hypothesis 2. It suggests that
the propensity score matching method to choose the control group. in a 3-year window, filing a diversity proposal is associated with
Comparing the last column of Table 5 indicates that the percentage an increase in the proportion of diversity enhancing companies of
of companies that add a female director to their board for targeted 19 % (= 42 % - 24 %) with no reversal pattern. This is a significant
companies is significantly higher than for non-targeted companies. increase of about 80 % when compared to the baseline of 24 % for
In a two-year window, the implementation rates in targeted com- non-targeted firms.
panies for voted, withdrawn and other proposals are 25 %, 39.5 %6 In summary, consistent with Hypothesis 2, a simple difference
and 46.7 % respectively, rates that are significantly higher than the in difference comparison suggests that diversity proposals indeed
16 % rate for non-targeted firms. improve gender diversity on corporate boards. The empirical evi-
dence above suggests that both withdrawn and voted proposals
increase the likelihood of having at least one woman on a corporate
6
board. Finally, note that this result is an unconditional compari-
The fact that implementation rate for withdrawn proposals, 39.5%, is less than
100% is consistent with our earlier observation that successful private negotiation
son. A more rigorous result based on multiple regression analysis
that results in adoption of a proposal is not the only reason for a withdrawal. is presented in the next section.

8
G Model
QUAECO-1406; No. of Pages 16 ARTICLE IN PRESS
M. Rastad, J. Dobson The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

Table 5
Implementation Rate of Proposals.

Outcome Total Number of Proposals Percent Implemented at t Percent Implemented at t + 1 Percent Implemented at t and t + 1

Proposals Voted on 52 1.9 % 23.1 % 25.0 %


Proposals Withdrawn 76 15.8 % 23.7 % 39.5 %
Proposals with other Outcomes 15 26.7 % 20.0 % 46.7 %
All Proposals 143 11.9 % 23.1 % 35.0 %

This table presents the implementation rate for shareholder proposals on gender diversity between 1997 and 2013 in t and t + 1, where t is the year at which the proposals
is filed. Implementation here is defined as adding a female director to the board. Implementation rates are compared across different proposal outcomes (voted, withdrawn
and omitted/not filed).

5. Estimation results rows in columns (3) and (4) show that voted proposals are rela-
tively less effective compared to withdrawn proposals especially
To examine Hypothesis 2 more formally, we present the esti- in the same year. Again, this finding is robust to the inclusion of
mation result for proposals that are put to vote and proposals that control variables. Finally, to measure the net effect of voted pro-
are withdrawn all in one model. posals on improving board gender diversity, the last two rows of
Table 6 report the results for testing if the sum of the coefficients
5.1. Baseline results for Proposalt and Proposalt ×Votedt (ˇ1 + ˇ2 in Eq. (2)) are signifi-
cantly different from zero. The estimation results show that this is
Table 6 presents the estimation results for the impact of pro- not the case. This finding suggests that although the net impact of
posals on board diversity as illustrated in Eq. (4). It compares the voted proposals on enhancing gender diversity is positive this
the board gender diversity, measured by the change in number impact is not statistically significant, possibly due to the smaller
of female directors, for firms targeted by diversity proposals (the sample size of voted versus withdrawn proposals.
treatment group) versus a matched sample of firms selected using Overall, our findings provide strong evidence for shareholder
the propensity score matching method based on the propensity activism as a strategy for improving gender diversity on corporate
scores estimated using Eq. (3). Given that some of the firms in boards. While both proposals that are put to vote, and those that are
the control group lost a female director, our outcome variable may withdrawn and do not go to vote, contribute positively to increas-
take three possible values: +1, −1 and 0 for firms who added, lost, ing board diversity, this impact is statistically significant only for
or neither added or lost at least one female director respectively. withdrawn proposals. This effect is larger in the same year when a
Therefore, we use an ordered Logit model given the ternary nature proposal is filed but continues in the next year at a smaller scale.
of the outcome variable. Overall, we find evidence consistent with While the impact is similar for both proposals in the second year,
the effectiveness of proposals in improving gender diversity on it is larger for withdrawn proposals in the first year. Therefore, our
corporate boards. findings support Hypothesis 2.
Focusing on the control variables, we find that younger boards
Pr(AddingaFemaleDirector)it =ˇ0 +ˇ1 Proposalit +ˇ2 Proposalit ×Votedit are more diverse; the coefficient on average board age is negative
+ˇ3 Proposalit ×Votedit ×VotePercentageit +ˇ4 Proposalit -1 and statistically significant. If the average age of directors on a board
increases, the likelihood of adding a female director to the board
+ˇ5 Proposalit -1 ×Votedit-1 +ˇ5 Proposalit -1 decreases. Moreover, consistent with Agrawal & Knoeber, 2001,
Carter, Simkins, and Gary Simpson (2003) and Ahern and Dittmar
×Votedit-1 ×VotePercentageit-1 +ˇ6 X it +t +εit (2)
(2012), we find evidence that suggests larger boards are more
open to more diversity; the coefficient for Board Size is positive
The dependent variable, Adding a Female Director, equals to +1 but statistically insignificant. Finally, the insignificant but negative
(−1) when there is an increase (decrease) in number of female coefficient on board independence suggest that boards with more
directors on the board, and 0 when there is no change. The treat- independent directors are less likely to add female directors pos-
ment variable, Proposal, is also an indicator variable that switches sibly because there is less need for an outsider to break the circle
on when the company is the target of a gender diversity proposal. of insiders. The impact of proposals is robust whether or not we
Voted is an indicator variable that switches on for proposals that go control for board size and age.
to vote and off for proposals that are withdrawn. The independent It is important to note that when we examine withdrawn pro-
variable of interest is Institutional Investor, which is an indicator posals, we miss a big chunk of private negotiations that started
variable that switches on when the proposal sponsor is either a before any proposal is put forward; as mentioned before and
pension fund or an SRI fund. Control variables, Xit ’s are the board supported by Table A2 in the Appendix. This means that many non-
characteristics described in Table 6, and t is the year fixed effect. targeted firms may have actually been targeted by these private
The estimation results in columns (1) and (2) show that a pro- negotiations, biasing our findings against the hypothesized results.
posal which is put to vote or withdrawn significantly increases the This works in our favor given the significant resulting impact we
likelihood of allocating an additional seat to a woman. This effect is find.
not immediate though. The first and the third rows of Table 6 show
that while the coefficient of the treatment variable, Proposal, is sig- 5.2. The impact of the magnitude of votes
nificant in both the same year that a proposal is filed and the next
year, the former is larger than the latter. The impact of proposals is To test Hypothesis 3, which establishes a link between the mag-
robust whether or not we control for board size, age and director’s nitudes of votes a proposal receives and its effectiveness, we ask if
independence. This result is consistent with Hypothesis 2 diversity proposals with greater voter support are more likely to be
To compare the withdrawn versus voted proposals, the model implemented. To measure the impact of magnitude of the votes, the
is expanded in columns (3) and (4) by adding an interaction term model in Table 6 is further expanded in columns (5) and (6) by fur-
for voted proposals; i.e., an indicator variable that is equal to one ther interacting with voting outcome, i.e., the percentage of votes
for voted proposals and zero for withdrawn proposals. The nega- in favor of a proposal. The estimation results seem not to support
tive coefficients for the interaction terms on the third and fourth Hypothesis 3. The insignificance of the coefficient of this interac-

9
G Model
QUAECO-1406; No. of Pages 16 ARTICLE IN PRESS
M. Rastad, J. Dobson The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

Table 6
Estimation Results for the Effect of both Withdrawn and Voted on Proposals on Board’s Diversity.

Dependent Variable: Likelihood of Adding a Female Director

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Proposalt 1.574*** 1.640*** 2.149*** 2.102*** 2.107*** 2.117***


(0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00)
Proposalt ×Votedt −1.329* −1.397** −1.571 −1.379
(0.05) (0.04) (0.20) (0.31)
Proposalt -1 1.828** 1.816** 1.858**
(0.02) (0.02) (0.01)
Proposalt -1 ×Votedt -1 −1.441 −1.433 −2.135
(0.15) (0.16) (0.26)
Proposalt ×Votedt ×Vote Percentaget 0.009 −0.002
(0.81) (0.97)
Proposalt -1 ×Votedt -1 ×Vote Percentaget -1 0.033
(0.61)
Board Sizet 0.107 0.087 0.089 0.090 0.096
(0.22) (0.29) (0.28) (0.28) (0.25)
Average Age of Directorst −0.107** −0.098** −0.102** −0.103** −0.103**
(0.01) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.03)
% of Independent Directorst −1.011 −1.433 −1.394 −1.388 −1.358
(0.44) (0.30) (0.30) (0.29) (0.30)
Pseudo R2 0.108 0.135 0.153 0.155 0.155 0.157
N 282 282 282 282 282 282
2 for H0 : ˇ1 + ˇ2 = 0 1.76 1.23
p-value for H0 : ˇ1 + ˇ2 = 0 0.1847 0.2671

This Table presents the estimation results for Eq. (2) for the companies that were targeted by gender diversity proposals at least once between 1997 and 2013. The dependent
variable is an indicator variable capturing board gender diversity that equals to +1 (−1) when there is an increase (decrease) in number of female directors on the board, and 0
when there is no change. The treatment variable (Proposal) is also an indicator variable that switches on when the company was a target of a gender diversity proposal. Voted
is an indicator variable that switches on for proposals that go to vote and off for proposals that are withdrawn. Vote Percentage is the percentage of shareholder votes in favor
of a diversity proposal. As for board characteristics, X, Board Size is the total number of directors on a board. % of Independent Directors is the fraction of the board members
that are independent. Average Age of Directors is the arithmetic mean of directors’ age. P-values are reported in parentheses. All specifications include year fixed-effects.
Standard errors are clustered at the firm level. *, **, and *** denotes significance at the 10 %, 5 %, and 1 % level, respectively.

tion term suggests that the magnitude of votes has no additional Because of collinearity of other potential determinants of the
impact. Therefore, we conclude that despite failing, it is the very voting results, we had to estimate separate empirical models for
existence of a diversity proposal that improves board diversity, not different sets of variables. Results in columns (2) and (3) show that
how much vote support it receives from the shareholders. proposals, whose sponsor is an institutional investor or a member
of 30 % Coalition, tend to receive higher votes. Results in column (4)
suggest that other board characteristics such as board size, direc-
5.3. Determinants of voting results
tors’ independence and average directors age don’t seem to have
any significant impact on the voting results. Finally, results in col-
To assess Hypothesis 4, we examine empirically the determi-
umn (5) show that firms with lower Tobin’s Q and lower levels of
nants of voting results for the proposals that end up going to vote.
capital expenditures receive more votes while firm size and prof-
We conduct an empirical analysis for the subset of proposals that
itability seem not to as important. In an unreported table, when we
go to vote (70 proposals) to study if board and firm characteristics
add the percentage of Institutional Ownership obtained from Fact-
can explain variation in voting results.
Set to our model to control for ownership composition, we find
that our main result for the % of Women on Board is robust to this
VotePercentageit = ˇ0 +ˇ1 %ofWomenonBoardit
change. Moreover, we find that institutional ownership and share-
+ˇ2 InstitutionalInvestorSponsorit +ˇ3 30%CoalitionSponsor it holder pressure, as manifested by the number of other proposals,
significantly increase the voting results, but the small sample size
+ˇ4 Xit +ˇ5 Zit +t +εit (3) makes it hard to interpret these results. Overall, our results show
that when shareholders vote on diversity proposals they are more
where the dependent variable, Vote Percentage, is the percentage
sensitive to the current level of board gender diversity as well as
of shareholder votes a proposal receives in an annual meeting, %
who is the sponsor of a proposals. Therefore, our findings support
of Women on Board is the fraction of board seats that are assigned
Hypothesis 4.
to women. Institutional Investor Sponsor is an indicator variable
that switches on if the sponsor is either pension fund or an SRI
fund. Variables X and Z are control variables for board and firm 5.4. The sponsor effect
characteristics as described in Table 7.
Estimation results in all columns of Table 7 show that the lower To investigate the importance of the proposal sponsor as stated
the board gender diversity, the higher the voting results. The coef- in Hypothesis 5, we ask if proposals sponsored by institutional
ficient on board gender diversity, measured by the percentage of investors are more effective? To examine this formally, we add a
women on the board, ranges from -65.33 to -82.91 across different new term to Eq. (2) for the interaction between the sponsor and
columns. Adding a female director to an average board with the proposal types as illustrated in Eq. (4):
size of 9 (see Table 2), which increases the percentage of women on
board by 11 %, lowers the votes in favor of a proposal by 7.3%–9.2%.
Pr(AddingaFemaleDirector)it =ˇ0 +ˇ1 Proposalit +ˇ2 Proposalit
The large magnitude of this coefficient suggests that shareholders
indeed are sensitive to board diversity when casting their votes. ×Votedit +ˇ3 Proposalit ×Sponsorit +ˇ4 Proposalit -1 +ˇ5 Proposalit -1

10
G Model
QUAECO-1406; No. of Pages 16 ARTICLE IN PRESS
M. Rastad, J. Dobson The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

Table 7
Estimation Results for the Determinants of Voting Results.

Dependent Variable: Vote Percentage for Diversity Proposals

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

% of Women on Board −82.912*** −66.703** −66.773** −65.335** −71.553**


(0.00) (0.02) (0.01) (0.04) (0.02)
Institutional Investor Sponsor 5.971**
(0.04)
30 % Coalition Sponsor 6.267**
(0.05)
% of Independent Directors 4.722
(0.49)
Average Age of Directors 0.316
(0.38)
Board Size −0.581
(0.24)
ROA 29.482
(0.22)
Log(Assets) −1.126
(0.32)
Tobin’s Q −2.873**
(0.04)
Capex −59.748**
(0.02)
Constant 21.384*** 18.780*** 18.763*** 3.971 37.105***
(0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.85) (0.00)
R2 0.130 0.187 0.183 0.163 0.220
N 65 65 61 65 54

This Table presents the estimation results for equation (3) for proposals that go to vote between 1997 and 2013, where the dependent variable, Vote Percentage, is the
percentage of shareholder votes a proposal receives in an annual meeting, and % of Women on Board is the fraction of board seats that are assigned to women. Institutional
Investor Sponsor is an indicator variable that switches on if the sponsor is either pension fund or an SRI fund. Variables X and Z in Eq. (3) represent board and firm characteristics.
As for board characteristics, Board Size is total number of directions on a board. % of Independent Directors is the fraction of the board members that are independent. Average
Age of Directors is the arithmetic mean of directors’ age. Firm characteristics include ROA; return on assets, Log(Assets); firm size, Tobin’s Q; the ratio of firm’s market value of
equity to its book value, Capex; the ratio of investment in capital expenditure to total assets. P-values are reported in parentheses. All specifications include year fixed-effects.
Standard errors are clustered at the firm level. *, **, and *** denotes significance at the 10 %, 5 %, and 1 % level, respectively.

×Votedit-1 +ˇ6 Proposalit -1 ×Sponsorit-1 +ˇ7 X it +t +εit (4) Table 8


Estimation Results for the Effect of Sponsor of a Proposal on Board Diversity.

Dependent Variable: Likelihood of Adding a Female Director


The definition of the dependent variable, Adding a Female Direc-
(1) (2) (3) (4)
tor, and independent variables, Proposal, and Voted are the same
as in Eq. (2). The independent variable of interest is Institutional Proposalt 1.774*** 2.174** 1.801*** 2.137**
(0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
Investor, which is an indicator variable that switches on when the
Proposalt ×Votedt −1.233* −1.499** −1.165 −1.457*
proposal sponsor is either a pension fund or an SRI fund. Control (0.08) (0.03) (0.11) (0.05)
variables, Xit , are the same as in Table 6. Institutional Investor t × Proposal t 0.923 0.393 0.934 0.466
Table 8 shows the estimation results. Similar to Table 6, an (0.12) (0.61) (0.13) (0.54)
Proposalt -1 2.001*** 2.370***
ordered Logit model is used here to capture both adding and remov-
(0.01) (0.00)
ing of a female director to the board. The main difference between Proposalt -1 ×Votedt -1 −2.827** −3.041**
Tables 8 and 6 is that here the second interaction term is between (0.04) (0.01)
the Proposal and Institutional Investor, which is the variable of Institutional Investor t -1 × Proposal t -1 3.034** 2.917**
interest here. Similar to Table 6, the coefficients of Proposal and Pro- (0.03) (0.03)
Board Sizet 0.107 0.114
posal*Voted are both positive and significant for t and t-1 confirming
(0.20) (0.20)
the overall effectiveness of proposals and relative more effective- Average Age of Directorst −0.091** −0.092**
ness for withdrawn proposals. More importantly, in columns (1) (0.02) (0.02)
and (2) the coefficients of the new interaction terms for institu- % of Independent Directorst −1.178 −1.113
(0.38) (0.43)
tional sponsors and proposal, ˇ4 and ˇ6 , are positive and significant
Pseudo R2 0.145 0.168 0.168 0.191
at the 12 %-level in t in column (1) and at the 3 %-level in t-1 in N 282 282 282 282
column (2) respectively. The large size of these coefficients sug-
This Table presents the estimation results for Eq. (4) for the companies that were
gests that perhaps proposals sponsored by institutional investors
targeted by a gender diversity proposal at least once between 1997 and 2013. The
are more likely to result in the addition of a female director than dependent variable is an indicator variable capturing board gender diversity that is
proposals sponsored by individuals or religious organizations. This equal to +1 when a new female director is added to the board, -1 when a female
finding does not change when we include control variables as illus- director is removed from the board, and 0 when there is no change. Proposal is also
an indicator variable that switches on when the company was a target of a gender
trated in columns (3) and (4) of Table 8. Therefore, our finding are
diversity proposal. Voted is an indicator variable that switches on for proposals that
consistent with Hypothesis 5. go to vote and off for proposals that are withdrawn. Institutional Investor is an indi-
cator variable that switches on when the proposal sponsor is either a pension fund
or a SRI fund. P-values are reported in parentheses. All specifications include year
6. Endogeneity of proposals and the instrument variable
fixed-effects. Standard errors are clustered at the firm level. *, **, and *** denotes
approach significance at the 10 %, 5 %, and 1 % level, respectively.

The result of our empirical findings up to this point must be


interpreted with an important caveat in mind. There are two pos-

11
G Model
QUAECO-1406; No. of Pages 16 ARTICLE IN PRESS
M. Rastad, J. Dobson The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

Table 9 estimate equation (2) using a 2SLS model (instead of ordered Logit
Estimation Results for the Instrument Variable Model.
as in Tables 6 and 8) because of difficulties with combining the
Dependent Variable: Likelihood of Adding a Female Director instrument variable approach with the ordered Logit model. The
estimation results are presented in Table 9.
(1) (2) (3) (4)
To eliminate any contemporaneous effect of diversity on pro-
Withdrawn Proposalt 0.461*** 0.463***
posals, we only include the lagged values of the withdrawn and
(0.01) (0.00)
Voted Proposalt 0.199*** 0.227*** voted proposal variables in the model. Consistent with our ear-
(0.00) (0.00) lier findings, the coefficients reported on the first two rows of
Board Sizet 0.007*** 0.009*** Table 9 show a significant and positive impact of proposals on board
(0.00) (0.00) diversity. Not surprisingly, these coefficients are larger than the
Average Directors Aget −0.005*** −0.006***
(0.00) (0.00)
unreported OLS version of the ones in previous tables, reflecting
% of Independent Directorst −0.079* 0.006 the fact that they capture the effect of treatment-on-the-treated
(0.06) (0.87) instead of average treatment. As pointed out by Card (1999) in the
Constant 0.112** 0.437*** 0.164*** 0.481*** context of the effect of years of education on wages, the literature
(0.01) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00)
2
finds that the instrumental variable estimates are generally larger
R 0.0195 0.0252 0.0453 0.0550
N 1810 1810 1810 1810 than OLS estimates. The sign and significance of control variables
also remain similar to the earlier tables. Consistent with the first
This Table presents the estimation results of the second stage of an instrumental
variable approach that is used to address the endogeneity issue in equation (2).
view, this result suggests that diversity proposals impact diver-
The sample includes companies that were targeted by gender diversity proposals at sity, reinforcing the shareholder activism channel as an effective
least once between 1997 and 2013. The instruments are lagged values of treatment mechanism for change.
variable Voted Proposal. The dependent variable is an indicator variable capturing In sum, the instrumental variable approach provides suggestive
board gender diversity which switches on when a new female director is added
evidence that confirms the significance of the initiation of diver-
to the board, and other variables are defined as before. P-values are reported in
parenthesis. sity proposals as a mechanism for improving diversity in corporate
boards. The fact that we find a similar significant impact for with-
drawn or omitted7 proposals as for voted proposals shows that it’s
sible explanations for the link between shareholder proposals and not the appearance of proposals on proxy filings that causes the
changes in board diversity that are not fully distinguished by our change. The fact that a proposal is initiated, even though it is omit-
analysis so far. First, diversity-related proposals are the reason ted or withdrawn, still impacts board diversity. Further research to
behind the improvement in gender diversity on corporate boards. assess the causality impact of proposals on diversity would require
They play a key role by bringing the problem to the attention of more information on how the desire to change impacts board diver-
the company’s management, as well as other stakeholders, creat- sity in the absence of any proposals. Unfortunately, data limitation
ing enough pressure for a change. In this view, proposals are the makes it difficult to measure the desire to change. Perhaps, with
cause for more diversity. Second, the improvement in corporate more data from the minutes of annual shareholder meetings, a tex-
board diversity is the result of a desire to change, and not the share- tual analysis of those minutes could provide a way to quantify the
holders’ proposals per se. That is to say, the improvements in board demand for change.
diversity would have happened even if there were no proposal. In
this view, the proposals simply reflect the demand for a change 7. Conclusion
but do not cause the change. In other words, both proposals and
changes in the board diversity are caused by an omitted variable, Rather than exogenous government mandated quotes,
the desire to change. Although our findings so far provide some economies such as the US predominantly rely on the endoge-
suggestive evidence, they do not distinguish between these two nous approach of shareholder resolutions to effect social change.
alternative explanations. Superficially in the case of gender, it would appear that this
To distinguish between these two explanations, we need an endogenous approach has failed, given that the vast majority
exogenous shift in the likelihood of putting forth a proposal. We of diversity resolutions fail to be formally adopted. However,
exploit the dynamics of voted and withdrawn proposals in the data the empirical results that we present here indicate otherwise.
by using the lag of a Voted Proposal variable as an instrument that Specifically, failure actually means success: whether proposals
shifts the likelihood of having a voted or withdrawn proposal. As are directly voted down or withdrawn before the vote, they still
illustrated in Table A1 in the Appendix, proposals that are put to have the power to effect change. Our results indicate that these
vote usually come in a series that ends with a withdrawn proposal. failed resolutions do in fact lead directly to greater future female
For example, the board of Coastal Corporation received a diversity participation on corporate boards.
proposal in 1997 which was followed by another in 1998. They We show that the relevant way to characterize shareholder pro-
both went to vote and only received 12 % and 16 % of votes respec- posals is based on the negotiation level of shareholder activists to
tively. The following year they received another proposal which generate internal or external pressure on management to promote
this time was withdrawn from the voting process, indicating an board gender diversity. We provide empirical evidence that is con-
agreement between the company and the sponsor of the proposal, sistent with more effectiveness for private negotiations (internal
the ICCR. Consistent with this observation, Table 9 shows that the pressure), which result in a withdrawn proposal, as opposed to the
lag of the Voted Proposal variable is a strong predictor for both social (external) pressure resulting in a voted-on-proposal. Private
its contemporaneous value and for the Withdrawn Proposal vari- negotiations that result in a withdrawn proposal generate imme-
able. This means that having a proposal that goes to vote this year diate and stronger change and are thus generally considered as a
does indeed increase the likelihood of observing another proposal “success.” Contrarily, a proposal that goes to vote signals a failure of
(voted or withdrawn) next year. Thus, our instrument satisfies the
first condition to be a valid instrument: inclusion restriction. As for
the second condition, exclusion restriction, we argue that the only 7
Analysis of omitted proposals provides similar results to the ones we found
way a proposal in the past can affect board diversity in the future for voted and withdrawn proposals. Despite the very small sample size (only 8
is by raising the probability of having more proposals that are put proposals), our unreported estimation results show that omitted proposals also
to vote or withdrawn in the future. Using this instrument, we re- significantly improve board gender diversity.

12
G Model
QUAECO-1406; No. of Pages 16 ARTICLE IN PRESS
M. Rastad, J. Dobson The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

private negotiations, which leaves no choice for the proposal spon- can clarify the nuances and distinctions between these two stages
sor but to generate social pressure thorough putting a proposal to of shareholder activism. We also find a stronger and more rapid
vote. We show that no matter how many votes those proposals positive reaction from shareholders to a withdrawn proposal as
receive, they are still an effective way to improve board gender compared to one that goes to vote. These results raise a variety of
diversity. Although this suggests that the voting result is not rele- empirical questions concerning the power of, and market reaction
vant to the outcome, investor voting results show that they indeed to, shareholder activism.
support diversity proposals more in less diverse firms. Finally, our results have broad policy implications for regulators
Our study has important implications for practitioners, man- concerning the ability of endogenous shareholder-activist channels
agers, policy makers and the research community. Our results to achieve social ends. Policy makers with concerns regarding the
indicate that company management responds to shareholder pres- current level of diversity in corporate boards can promote share-
sure. Our results can also provide insight for proposal sponsors. holder activism as a promising alternative reform mechanism to
Proposal sponsors can use these results to gauge the effectiveness the European quota approach that is not subject to the negative
of the activism channel they use for promoting board gender diver- side effects (stereotypes) associated with the latter. Our results
sity: institutional investors are the more effective sponsors. demonstrate that, in the context of board gender diversity, share-
Our findings indicate several channels for future research. In the holder resolutions are a viable alternative to government-mandated
context of achieving diversity, we shed light on the relative suc- quotas.
cess of shareholder activism stages (internal pressure resulting in
withdrawal versus external social pressure resulting in sharehold- Appendix A.
ers’ vote) in promoting board gender diversity. Further research

Table A1
Intertemporal Correlation Matrix for Voted Proposals (VP) and Withdrawn Proposals (WP).

VPt VPt -1 VPt -2 WPt WPt -1 WPt -2

VPt 1
VPt -1 0.4258*** 1
VPt -2 0.1517*** 0.4347*** 1
WPt −0.0552*** 0.1916*** 0.0545* 1
WPt -1 −0.0570*** −0.0568*** 0.1912*** −0.0517* 1
WPt -2 −0.053* −0.0557* −0.0539* −0.0186 −0.0505* 1

This Table presents the correlation matrix for treatment variables and their lagged values. VP and WP are indicator variables for a voted and withdrawn proposals. Significance
at the 10 %, 5 %, and 1 % levels is indicated by *, **, and ***, respectively.

Table A2
Examples of private negotiations before filing a proposal.

Company Report Title Corporate Governance Engagement Principles URL

California State Teachers’ Retirement Corporate Governance "All of CalSTRS’ engagement activities begin https://www.calstrs.com/sites/main/
System (CALSTRS) Principles-Stewardship Code with private contact with the company. We are files/file-attachments/corporate
for Engagement always open to having dialogue with the governance principles 1.pdf
companies in which we invest and hope
companies seek our input on matters
important to shareholders, as we are the
ultimate long-term shareholder. At times we
do submit shareholder proposals at companies,
but once again we are very open to having a
dialogue with companies on issues important
to us." "The first step upon the evidence of the
existence of social injury is engagement by
CalSTRS Corporate Governance staff directly
with the company. CalSTRS will notify the
company of the issue and seek a direct dialog
with top ranking management and if needed
directly with the board of directors."
Calvert Asset Management Shareholder Advocacy Report "One of the most important advocacy tools at https://www.calvert.com/tools-of-
Calvert’s disposal is informed and constructive change.php
direct dialogue with senior management, built
on a foundation of trust and an understanding
of shared goals. Calvert engages directly with
companies both on its own and as part of
investor or broader stakeholder coalitions. . .If
no successful action is taken with dialogue, we
may file a shareholder resolution to facilitate
positive change within a company."
Connecticut Retirement Plans and Corporate Governance "Engagements often begin with discussions http://www.ott.ct.gov/about
Trust Funds (CRPTF) Overview between the Office and board members, chief corporate governance.html
executive officers, and/or senior management
of portfolio companies, and may last several
years. The CRPTF has also utilized the
shareholder resolution process, as an
engagement tool with portfolio companies."

13
G Model
QUAECO-1406; No. of Pages 16 ARTICLE IN PRESS
M. Rastad, J. Dobson The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

Table A2 (Continued)

Company Report Title Corporate Governance Engagement Principles URL

Domini Impact Investments Activism Approach When we have a concern with a company, we https://www.domini.com/responsible-
often begin by encouraging corporate investing/making-difference/activism-
management to come to the table to discuss approach
our concerns. Many companies respond to this
offer, and are willing to listen to our
perspective.
Evangelical Lutheran Church in Shareholder Advocacy "If companies don’t respond favorably to https://porticobenefits.org/
America (Portico Benefit Services is dialogue, Portico may file a shareholder PorticoBenefits/Overview/
responsible for the Corporate Social resolution." ReponsibleInvesting/
Responsibility ministry of the ELCA) ShareholderAdvocacy.aspx
Interfaith Center on Corporate The Art (and Science) of "When dialogues are unproductive, ICCR may http://www.iccr.org/sites/default/files/
Responsibility (ICCR) Shareholder Engagement issue shareholder resolutions to engage cevol38no5.pdf
management and other investors’ attention
around a specific issue."
Walden Asset Management Shareholder Engagement "In cases where companies are not sufficiently http://waldenassetmgmt.com/
responsive or where dialogue breaks down, we investing-for-change/shareholder-
are able to take our concerns directly to other engagement/
shareholders through the shareholder
resolution process."
CALSTRS Corporate Governance Update: “In a similar effort, CalSTRS recently submitted https://corpgov.law.harvard.edu/2017/
Prioritizing Board Diversity 125 letters to boards at California corporations 01/30/corporate-governance-update-
whose boards had no women directors; in prioritizing-board-diversity/
response, 35 of the companies appointed
female board members. CalSTRS has indicated
that if its private approaches are unsuccessful,
it will proceed with shareholder proposals.”
Wespath Investment Management Shareholder Engagement: "Many of the conversations continue over https://www.wespath.com/
(formerly, General Board of Pension Dialogue and Resolutions several years and result in changes to investment philosophy/shareholder
and Health Benefits) corporate policy and business practices– clear advocacy/advocacy dialogue/
evidence that advocacy can have a real impact
on investment performance. If attempts at
direct dialogue are not productive, Wespath or
its partners will file a public shareholder
resolution to encourage action by the
company."

Table A3
Examples of withdrawn proposals and reasons behind the withdrawal decision.

Sponsor Date Companies Reason for Withdrawal Source

CALSTRS 9/26/10 Liberty Global, INC.; C̈alSTRS submitted nine proposals on board diversity. https://www.calstrs.com/news-
Nutrisystem, INC.; six other All but one was withdrawn after the companies release/calstrs-reports-corporate-
unspecified companies amended their governing documents to ensure that governance-success-2010-proxy-
diversity was one characteristic they considered when season
developing a pool of board candidates. In two cases, at
NutriSystem Inc. and Liberty Global Inc., the
companies added a woman to their board so the
proposals were withdrawn.¨
Calvert Asset 6/3/03 Molex Corporation C̈alvert withdrew its shareholder resolution asking the https://www.businesswire.com/news/
Management company to bring race and gender diversity to its home/20030606005035/en/Calvert-
board of directors after Molex appointed the first Shareholder-Resolutions-Receive-
woman to its board.¨ Record-Support-Results
Connecticut 12/17/09 EOG Resources, INC T̈he purpose of this letter is to withdraw the https://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/
Retirement Plans & shareholder resolution co-filed by the Connecticut vprr/1001/10010418.pdf
Trust Funds (CRPTF) Retirement Plans & Trust Funds (“CRPTF”) and
submitted to EOG Resources on November 19, 2009.
We are withdrawing our resolution based on the
commitment of the Company’s Nominating &
Governance Committee to amend their governance
documents to reflect additional considerations of
diversity including specific mentions of race and
gender.¨
Connecticut 4/24/15 Monster Beverage M̈onster Beverage agreed to amend its charter to say: http://www.ott.ct.gov/pressreleases/
Retirement Plans & ’Diversity of race, ethnicity, gender, sexual orientation press2015/PR042415TreasurerNappier
Trust Funds (CRPTF) and gender identity are factors in evaluating suitable AnnouncesMonsterBeverageAgreement.
candidates for Board membership. The [Nominating] pdf
Committee will consider diverse candidates in the pool
from which Board nominees are chosen, including
without limitation nominees from both corporate
positions beyond the executive suite and non -
traditional environments.’ Monster Beverage also will
nominate a woman for the first time to its board. The
name will be announced when it releases its proxy
statement for its 2015 annual meeting. As a result of
the agreement, the CRPTF has withdrawn the board
diversity proposal it filed at Monster Beverage.¨

14
G Model
QUAECO-1406; No. of Pages 16 ARTICLE IN PRESS
M. Rastad, J. Dobson The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

Table A3 (Continued)

Sponsor Date Companies Reason for Withdrawal Source

Trillium Asset 4/2/13 Superior Energy Services, Ïn the autumn of 2012, Trillium filed board diversity http://www.trilliuminvest.com/
Management INC.; Zimmer Holdings, shareholder proposals at Superior Energy (NYSE: SPN), trillium-successfully-withdraws-four-
INC. Hartford Financial (NYSE: HIG), Zimmer Holdings board-diversity-proposals-6/
(NYSE: ZMH) and Lowe’s Companies (NYSE: LOW). The
proposals asked each company to: “publicly commit
[themselves] to a policy of Board inclusiveness to
ensure that women are routinely sought as part of
every Board search the company undertakes” At the
time of the filings, each company had either no women
or only one woman on its board of directors. Further,
none of the four companies disclosed diversity,
inclusive of gender or race, as part of its board
nominee search process. Following Trillium’s
successful engagement this spring, all four companies
agreed to amend their governance documents to
include a clear definition of diversity, inclusive of
gender and race, and make diversity an intentional
part of board nominee search criteria. Subsequently,
Trillium withdrew our proposals.¨
Walden Asset 2015 Cohen & Steers Ẅalden’s shareholder proposal urging Cohen & Steers http://waldenassetmgmt.com/new/
Management to take additional steps to increase board diversity was waldens-2015-shareholder-
withdrawn when the company agreed to amend its resolutions/
corporate governance documents to reference gender
and race as factors considered in nominating directors
and enhance disclosure in its proxy statement and
website.¨
Walden Asset 2013 NetApp T̈echnology company NetApp is among the small http://waldenassetmgmt.com/new/
Management minority (10 percent) of S&P 500 companies currently summary-waldens-2013-shareholder-
without a woman director. Walden’s shareholder resolutions/
proposal asking NetApp to take additional steps to
increase board diversity was withdrawn with an
agreement to enhance disclosure in its proxy
statement on the value of diversity as well as on
implementation processes to help identify women and
people of color for the director candidate pool.¨

Declaration of Competing Interest Carter, N. M., & Wagner, H. M. (2011). The bottom line: Corporate performance and
womens representation on boards (2004–2008). Catalyst, 1.
Carter, D. A., Simkins, B. J., & Gary Simpson, W. (2003). Corporate governance,
The authors report no declarations of interest. board diversity, and firm value. The Financial Review, 38(1), 33–53.
Chidambaran, N. K., & Woidtke, T. (1999). The role of negotiations in corporate
governance: Evidence from withdrawn shareholder-initiated proposals. EFA,
References 458, 99–12.
Collins, E. C. (2012). Global diversity initiatives. The International Law, 46,
Adams, R. B., & Funk, P. (2012). Beyond the glass ceiling: does gender matter? 987–1006.
Management Science, 58(2), 219–235. Post, C., & Byron, K. (2015). Women on boards and firm financial performance: A
Agrawal, A., & Knoeber, C. R. (2001). Do some outside directors play a political meta- analysis. The Academy of Management Journal, 58(5), 1546–1571.
role? The Journal of Law & Economics, 44(1), 179–198. Daily, C. M., Certo, S. T., & Dalton, D. R. (1999). Research notes and communications
Ahern, K. R., & Dittmar, A. K. (2012). The changing of the boards: The impact on a decade of corporate women: Some progress in the boardroom, none in the
firm valuation of mandated female board representation. The Quarterly Journal executive suite. Strategic Management Journal, 20(1), 93–99.
of Economics, 127(1), 137–197. Ertimur, Y., Ferri, F., & Muslu, V. (2010). Shareholder activism and ceo pay. The
Armstrong, C. S., Gow, I. D., & Larcker, D. F. (2013). The efficacy of shareholder Review of Financial Studies, page hhq113.
voting: Evidence from equity compensation plans. Journal of Accounting Ertimur, Y., Ferri, F., & Stubben, S. R. (2010). Board of directors’ responsiveness to
Research, 51(5), 909–950. shareholders: Evidence from shareholder proposals. Journal of Corporate
Azmat, G., & Petrongolo, B. (2014). Gender and the labor market: What have we Finance, 16(1), 53–72.
learned from field and lab experiments? Labour Economics, 30, 32–40. Farrell, K. A., & Hersch, P. L. (2005). Additions to corporate boards: The effect of
Balafoutas, L., Davis, B. J., & Sutter, M. (2016). Affirmative action or just gender. Journal of Corporate Finance, 11(1), 85–106.
discrimination? a study on the endogenous emergence of quotas. Journal of Ferri, F. (2012). ‘Low-cost’ shareholder activism: A review of the evidence. In Research
Economic Behavior & Organization, 127, 87–98. handbook on the economics of corporate law. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Baloria, V. L. P., Klassen, K. J., & Wiedman, C. I. (2013). Shareholder activism and Fichtl, A. (2013). Gender quotas on boardroom representation in Europe. DICE
voluntary disclosure initiation: The case of political spending. CAAA Annual Report, 11(3), 62.
Conference, Flammer, C. (2015). Does corporate social responsibility lead to superior financial
Barua, A., Raghunandan, K., & Rama, D. V. (2016). Shareholder votes on auditor performance? a regression discontinuity approach. Management Science,
ratification and subsequent auditor dismissals. Accounting Horizons. 61(11), 2549–2568.
Bauer, R., Moers, F., & Viehs, M. (2015). Who withdraws shareholder proposals and Gillan, S. L., & Starks, L. T. (2007). The evolution of shareholder activism in the
does it matter? an analysis of sponsor identity and pay practices. Corporate United States. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 19(1), 55–73.
Governance an International Review, 23(6), 472–488. Gordon, S. (2016). Only the government can ensure women get on to boards.
Berle, A. A., & Means, G. C. (1932). The modern corporation and private property, New Financial Times, 9. URL. http://on.ft.com/2aLeFeN
York, world. Guo, R.-J., Kruse, T. A., & Nohel, T. (2008). Undoing the powerful anti-takeover force
Bertrand, M., & Hallock, K. F. (2001). The gender gap in top corporate jobs. of staggered boards. Journal of Corporate Finance, 14(3), 274–288.
Industrial & Labor Relations Review, 55(1), 3–21. Harnois, C. (2008). Re-presenting feminisms: Past, present, and future. NWSA
Boylan, R., Cebula, R., Foley, M., & Liu, X. (2014). An analysis of omitted shareholder Journal, 20(1), 120–145.
proposals. Joural of Financ and Accountancy, 17, 1–16. Heywood, L. L. (2006). The womens movement today. In An encyclopedia of the
Burke, R. J. (2000). Company size, board size and numbers of women corporate third.
directors. In Women on corporate boards of directors. pp. 157–167. Springer. Ingley, C., & Walt, N. V. (2003). Board configuration: Building better boards.
Cai, J., & Walkling, R. A. (2011). Shareholders say on pay: Does it create value? The Corporate Governance International Journal of Business in Society, 3(4), 5–17.
Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 46(02), 299–339. Isidro, H., & Sobral, M. (2015). The effects of women on corporate boards on firm
Card, D. (1999). The causal effect of education on earnings. In O. Ashenfelter, & D. value, financial performance, and ethical and social compliance. Journal of
Card (Eds.), Handbook of labor economics (vol. 3A) (pp. 1801–1863). Elsevier. Business Ethics, 132(1), 1–19.

15
G Model
QUAECO-1406; No. of Pages 16 ARTICLE IN PRESS
M. Rastad, J. Dobson The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, Rojas, M., M’zali, B., Turcotte, M., & Merrigan, P. (2009). Bringing about changes to
agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4), corporate social policy through shareholder activism: Filers, issues, targets,
305–360. and success. Business and Society Review, 114(2), 217–252.
Johnson, J. L., Daily, C. M., & Ellstrand, A. E. (1996). Boards of directors: A review Schwartz, M. S., Dunfee, T. W., & Kline, M. J. (2005). Tone at the top: An ethics code
and research agenda. Journal of Management, 22(3), 409–438. for directors? Journal of Business Ethics, 58(1–3), 79–100.
Kogut, B., Colomer, J., & Belinky, M. (2014). Structural equality at the top of the Singh, S. (2001). A pilot study on gender differences in conversational speech on
corporation: Mandated quotas for women directors. Strategic Management lexical richness measures. Literary and Linguistic Computing, 16(3), 251–264.
Journal, 35(6), 891–902. Stych, A. (2020). Best buy, NASDAQ on the best companies for women to advance July,
Lansing, P., & Chandra, S. (2012). Quota systems as a means to promote women URL. BizWomen: The Business Journals. https://www.bizjournals.com/
into corporate boardrooms. Employee Relations Law Journal, 38(3), 3–14. bizwomen/news/latest-news/2020/07/best-buy-clorox-on-list-of-best-
Lee, M.-D. P., & Lounsbury, M. (2011). Domesticating radical rant and rage: An companies-for-wom.html?page=all
exploration of the consequences of environmental shareholder resolutions on Terjesen, S., & Sealy, R. (2016). Board gender quotas: exploring ethical tensions
corporate environ- mental performance. Business and Society, 50(1), 155–188. from a multi- theoretical perspective. Business Ethics Quarterly, 26(01), 23–65.
Marquardt, C., & Wiedman, C. (2016). Can shareholder activism improve gender Terjesen, S., Sealy, R., & Singh, V. (2009). Women directors on corporate boards: A
diversity on corporate boards? Corporate Governance an International Review, review and research agenda. Corporate Governance an International Review,
24(4), 443–461. 17(3), 320–337.
McIntyre, D. A. (2020). Only 11% of S&P Companies have CEOs of color, and it gets The European Commission. (2012). Proposal for a directive of the European
worse . . .., 24/7 Wall Street, July URL. https://247wallst.com/investing/2020/07/ Parliament and of the Council on improving the gender balance among
07/only-11-of-sp-500-companies-have-ceos-of-color-and-it-gets-worse/ non-executive directors of companies listed on stock exchanges and related
Monks, R., Miller, A., & Cook, J. (2004). Shareholder activism on environmental measures. Brussels: European Commission.
issues: A study of proposals at large us corporations (2000–2003). Natural Thomas, R. S., & Cotter, J. F. (2007). Shareholder proposals in the new millennium:
Resources Forum, 28(4), 317–330. Shareholder support, board response, and market reaction. Journal of Corporate
Perrault, E. (2015). Why does board gender diversity matter and how do we get Finance, 13(2), 368–391.
there? the role of shareholder activism in deinstitutionalizing old boys Tkac, P. (2006). One proxy at a time: Pursuing social change through shareholder
networks. Journal of Business Ethics, 128(1), 149–165. proposals. Economic Review-Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, 91(3), 1.
Posner, C. (2020). New report on California’s board gender diversity mandate. URL. Welbourne, T. M., & Andrews, A. O. (1996). Predicting the performance of initial
Harvard Law School Forum on Corporate Governance. https://corpgov.law. public of- ferings: Should human resource management be in the equation?
harvard.edu/2020/03/18/new-report-on-california-board-gender-diversity- The Academy of Management Journal, 39(4), 891–919.
mandate/
Rampton, M. (2008). The three waves of feminism. Pacific. The Magazine of Pacific
University.

16

You might also like