Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 301

Microeconomic

s 20
Session-20_

IES

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


1
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
A Little Something From Us:-
Ecoholics is committed to providing the best
academic assistance to its students. One should note
however, your own practice and determination will
lead you to your final achievement in exams.
Economics is a scientific study of abstract knowledge
and one should always strive to be inquisitive and
logical to aid better understanding of the subject. We
wish you all the best , get ready for economics. Don’t
stress! You can totally do it.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


2
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Microeconomics Syllabus
• 1. Theory of Consumer’s Demand—Cardinal utility Analysis: Marginal utility and
demand, Consumer’s surplus, Indifference curve Analysis and utility function, Price,
income and substitution effects, Slutsky theorem and derivation of demand curve,
Revealed preference theory. Duality and indirect utility function and expenditure function,
Choice under risk and uncertainty. Simple games of complete information, Concept of
Nash equilibrium.
• 2. Theory of Production: Factors of production and production function. Forms of
Production Functions: Cobb Douglas, CES and Fixed coefficient type, Translog
production function. Laws of return, Returns to scale and Return to factors of production.
Duality and cost function, Measures of productive efficiency of firms, technical and
allocative efficiency. Partial Equilibrium versus General Equilibrium approach. Equilibrium
of the firm and industry.
• 3. Theory of Value: Pricing under different market structures, public sector pricing,
marginal cost pricing, peak load pricing, cross-subsidy free pricing and average cost
pricing. Marshallian and Walrasian stability analysis. Pricing with incomplete information
and moral hazard problems. For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
3
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Microeconomics Syllabus
• 4. Theory of Distribution: Neo classical distribution theories; Marginal productivity
theory of determination of factor prices, Factor shares and adding up problems. Euler’s
theorem, Pricing of factors under imperfect competition, monopoly and bilateral
monopoly. Macrodistribution theories of Ricardo, Marx, Kaldor, Kalecki.
• 5. Welfare Economics: Inter-personal comparison and aggression problem, Public
goods and externalities, Divergence between social and private welfare, compensation
principle. Pareto optimality. Social choice and other recent schools, including Coase and
Sen.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


4
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Consumer behaviour
• Consumer is rational
• Axiom of utility maximisation
• Consumer has complete knowledge
• 2 approaches:
• i. Cardinal Approach
• Ii. Ordinal approach

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


5
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Cardinal Utility Analysis
• Provides explanation for consumer demand and explain law of demand
• Economist: Alfred Marshall
• Assumptions:
• 1. Cardinal measurability of utility
• 2. The hypothesis of independent utilities
• 3. Constant marginal utility of money
• 4. Rationality
• 5. Diminishing marginal utility

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


6
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Cardinal Utility Analysis
• Total utility: U= f(x1, x2, ••• , xn)
• Total utility is additive,
• U = U1(x1) +U2(x2) +···+Un(xn)

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


7
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Consumer equilibrium
• Law of equi-marginal utility:
• It states that the consumer will distribute his money income between the
goods in such a way that the utility derived from the last rupee spent on
each good is equal.
푀 �
• =푀 푀
��

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


8
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Consumer equilibrium
• Multiple commodities:

• The utility derived from spending an additional unit of money must be the
same for all commodities. If the consumer derives greater utility from any
one commodity, he can increase his welfare by spending more on that
commodity and less on the others, until the above equilibrium condition is
fulfilled.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


9
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Derivation of demand curve
• The derivation of demand is based on the axiom of diminishing marginal
utility.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


10
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Critique of the cardinal approach
• The assumption of cardinal utility is extremely doubtful. The satisfaction
derived from various commodities cannot be measured objectively. The
attempt by Walras to use subjective units (utils) for the measurement of
utility does not provide any satisfactory solution.
• The assumption of constant utility of money is also unrealistic. As income
increases the marginal utility of money changes. Thus money cannot be
used as a measuring-rod since its own utility changes.
• Finally, the axiom of diminishing marginal utility has been 'established'
from introspection, it is a psychological law which must be taken for
granted.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


11
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Indifference curve approach
• Assumptions about consistency of preferences
• 1. Complete: we assume that any two bundles can be compared.
Consumer is indifferent between two bundles.
• 2. Reflexive: any bundle is at least as good as itself.
• 3. Transitive: if a consumers thinks that X is at least as good as why and
why is at least as good as Z, then the consumer thinks that X is at least as
good as Z.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


12
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Indifference curves
• Indifference curves it is a curve which presents the bundles for which the
consumers is just indifferent.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


13
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Perfect substitutes
• Two goods are perfect substitutes if the consumers is willing to substitute
one good for the other at a constant rate.
• Example: red pencils and blue pencils
• The indifference curve of perfect substitutes have a constant slope.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


14
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Perfect complements
• Perfect complements are goods that are
always consumed together in fixed
proportions.
• Example: right shoes and left shoes
• Their indifference curves are L shaped
• The important thing about perfect
complements is that the consumer
prefers to consume the goods in fixed
proportions, not necessarily that the
proportion is one-to-one.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


15
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Bads
• Goods that give negative utility are called as
bads.
• Good on x-axis and bad on y-axis.
• Their indifference curves are upward sloping.
• The direction of increasing preference is down
and to the right

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


16
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Neutrals
• Goods that provide zero utility are classified as
neutrals.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


17
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Satiation
• There is some overall best bundle for the
consumer, and the “closer” he is to that
best bundle, the better off he is in terms
of his own preferences.
• The best point is (x1,x2) and points
farther away from this bliss point lie on
“lower” indifference curves.
• In this case the indifference curves have
a negative slope when the con- sumer
has “too little” or “too much” of both
goods, and a positive slope when he has
“too much” of one of the goods.
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
18
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Satiation
• When he has too much of one of the
goods, it becomes a bad—reducing the
consumption of the bad good moves him
closer to his “bliss point.”
• If he has too much of both goods, they
both are bads, so reducing the
consumption of each moves him closer
to the bliss point.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


19
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Well-behaved preferences
• 1. More is better: we will typically assume that more is better, that is, that
we are talking about goods, not bads. This assumption is sometimes
called monotonicity of preferences.
• More is better would probably only hold up to a point. (Satiation point)
• Implication of monotonicity on ICs: It implies that they have a negative
slope.
• 2. Averages are preferred over extremes: That is, if we take two bundles
of goods (x1,x2) and (y1,y2) on the same indifference curve and take a
weighted average of the two bundles such as

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


20
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Well-behaved preferences
• then the average bundle will be at least as good as or strictly preferred to
each of the two extreme bundles.
• What does this assumption about preferences mean geometrically? It
means that the set of bundles weakly preferred to (x1,x2) is a convex set.
• For suppose that (y1, y2) and (x1, x2) are indifferent bundles. Then, if
aver- ages are preferred to extremes, all of the weighted averages of
(x1,x2) and (y1,y2) are weakly preferred to (x1,x2) and (y1,y2).
• A convex set has the property that if you take any two points in the set
and draw the line segment connecting those two points, that line segment
lies entirely in the set.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


21
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Well-behaved preferences

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


22
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Well-behaved preferences
• Concave preferences: Preferences where the consumer would be willing
to consume only one good at a time. But consuming both of them
together equally makes him worse off.
• Why do we want to assume that well-behaved preferences are convex?
Because, for the most part, goods are consumed together.
• one extension of the assumption of convexity is the assumption of strict
convexity. This means that the weighted average of two indifferent
bundles is strictly preferred to the two extreme bundles.
• Convex preferences may have flat spots, while strictly convex preferences
must have indifferences curves that are “rounded.” The preferences for
two goods that are perfect substitutes are convex, but not strictly convex.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


23
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Marginal rate of substitution
• the slope of an indifference curve is known as the marginal rate of
substitution
• the rate Δx2/Δx1 measures the marginal rate of substitution of good 2 for
good 1.
• MRS is typically a negative number.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


24
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Marginal rate of substitution
• Thus the slope of the indifference curve,
the marginal rate of substitution, measures
the rate at which the consumer is just on
the margin of trading or not trading.
• At any rate of exchange other than the
MRS, the consumer would want to trade
one good for the other.
• But if the rate of exchange equals the
MRS, the consumer wants to stay put.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


25
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Other interpretation of MRS
• the slope of the indifference curve measures the marginal willingness to
pay.
• The MRS measures the amount of good 2 that one is willing to pay for a
marginal amount of extra consumption of good 1.
• How much you actually have to pay for some given amount of extra
consumption may be different than the amount you are willing to pay.
• How much you have to pay will depend on the price of the good in
question.
• How much you are willing to pay doesn’t depend on the price—it is
determined by your preferences.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


26
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Behaviour of the MRS
• the “perfect substitutes” indifference curves are characterized by the fact
that the MRS is constant at −1.
• The “neutrals” case is characterized by the fact that the MRS is
everywhere infinite.
• The preferences for “perfect complements” are characterized by the fact
that the MRS is either zero or infinity, and nothing in between.
• For strictly convex indifference curves, the MRS—the slope of the
indifference curve—decreases (in absolute value) as we increase x1. Thus
the indifference curves exhibit a diminishing marginal rate of substitution.
• the more you have of one good, the more willing you are to give some of
it up in exchange for the other good.
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
27
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Utility
• Originally, preferences were defined in terms of utility: to say a bundle
(x1,x2) was preferred to a bundle (y1,y2) meant that the x-bundle had a
higher utility than the y-bundle.
• A utility function is a way of assigning a number to every possible
consumption bundle such that more-preferred bundles get assigned
larger numbers than less-preferred bundles.
• That is, a bundle (x1,x2) is preferred to a bundle (y1,y2) if and only if the
utility of (x1,x2) is larger than the utility of (y1, y2): in symbols, (x1, x2) >
(y1, y2) if and only if u(x1, x2) > u(y1, y2).

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


28
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Utility
• The magnitude of the utility function is only important insofar as it ranks
the different consumption bundles; the size of the utility difference
between any two consumption bundles doesn’t matter.
• this kind of utility is referred to as ordinal utility.
• If u(x1,x2) represents a way to assign utility numbers to the bundles
(x1,x2), then multiplying u(x1,x2) by 2 (or any other positive number) is just
as good a way to assign utilities.
• Multiplication by 2 is an example of a monotonic transformation.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


29
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Utility
• Monotonic transformation is a way of transforming one set of numbers
into another set of numbers in a way that preserves the order of the
numbers.
• We typically represent a monotonic transformation by a function f(u) that
transforms each number u into some other number f(u), in a way that
preserves the order of the numbers in the sense that u1 > u2 implies f(u1)
> f(u2).
• A monotonic transformation and a monotonic function are essentially the
same thing.
• Examples of monotonic transformations are multiplication by a positive
number (e.g., f (u) = 3u), adding any number (e.g., f (u) = u + 17).

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


30
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Utility
• if u(x1,x2) is a utility function that represents some preferences, and f(·) is
any increasing function, then f(u(x1,x2)) represents the same preferences
• why? Because u(x1,x2) > u(y1,y2) only if f(u(x1,x2)) > f(u(y1,y2))
• So if u(x1,x2) is a utility function then any positive monotonic
transformation of it is also a utility function that represents the same
preferences.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


31
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Utility
• The rate of change of f(u) as u changes can be measured by looking at
the change in f between two values of u, divided by the change in u:

• For a monotonic transformation, f(u2)−f(u1) always has the same sign as


u2 − u1. Thus a monotonic function always has a positive rate of change.
This means that the graph of a monotonic function will always have a
positive slope.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


32
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Utility
• If f(u) is any monotonic transformation of
a utility function that represents some
particular preferences, then f(u(x1,x2)) is
also a utility function that represents
those same preferences.
• A monotonic transformation of a utility
function is a utility function that
represents the same preferences as the
original utility function.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


33
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Utility function
• Geometrically, a utility function is a way to label indifference
curves.
• Since every bundle on an indifference curve must have the
same utility, a utility function is a way of assigning numbers to
t h e d i f f e re n t i n d i f f e re n c e c u rv e s i n a w a y t h a t h i g h e r
indifference curves get assigned larger numbers.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


34
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Some examples of Utility function
• In mathematics, the set of all (x1,x2) such that u(x1,x2) equals a constant
is called a level set. For each different value of the constant, you get a
different indifference curve.
• EXAMPLE: Indifference Curves from Utility
• Suppose that the utility function is given by: u(x1,x2) = x1x2. What do the
indifference curves look like?
• We know that a typical indifference curve is just the set of all x1 and x2
such that k = x1x2 for some constant k. Solving for x2 as a function of x1,
we see that a typical indifference curve has the formula:
• x2 = k/x1

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


35
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Some example of Utility function
• Suppose that we were given a utility
function v(x1,x2) = �21 �22 . What do its
indifference curves look like? By the
standard rules of algebra we know that:
• v(x1, x2) = �21 �22 = (x1x2)2 = u(x1, x2)2
• Thus the utility function v(x1,x2) is just the
square of the utility func- tion u(x1, x2).
• Since u(x1, x2) cannot be negative, it follows
that v(x1, x2) is a monotonic transformation
of the previous utility function, u(x1,x2).
• This means that the utility function v(x1,x2) =
x21x2 has to have exactly the same shaped
indifference curves For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
36
Perfect substitutes
• red pencil and blue pencil example
• utility function u(x1, x2) = x1 +x2
• Any other monotonic transformation of this utility function will also
represent the same utility.
• What if the consumer is willing to substitute good 1 for good 2 at a rate
that is different from one-to-one?
• Suppose, for example, that the consumer would require two units of good
2 to compensate him for giving up one unit of good 1.
• This means that good 1 is twice as valuable to the consumer as good 2.
The utility function therefore takes the form u(x1, x2) = 2x1 + x2. Note that
this utility yields indifference curves with a slope of −2.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


37
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Perfect substitutes
• In general, preferences for perfect substitutes can be represented by a
utility function of the form
• u(x1,x2)=ax1 +bx2.
• Here a and b are some positive numbers that measure the “value” of
goods 1 and 2 to the consumer. Note that the slope of a typical
indifference curve is given by −a/b.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


38
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Perfect complements
• left shoe–right shoe case.
• In these preferences the consumer only cares about the number of pairs
of shoes he has, so it is natural to choose the number of pairs of shoes as
the utility function.
• The number of complete pairs of shoes that you have is the minimum of
the number of right shoes you have, x1, and the number of left shoes you
have, x2.
• Thus the utility function for perfect complements takes the form
• u(x1, x2) = min{x1, x2}.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


39
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Perfect complements
• To verify that this utility function actually works, pick a bundle of goods
such as (10,10).
• If we add one more unit of good 1 we get (11,10), which should leave us
on the same indifference curve. Does it? Yes, since min{10, 10} = min{11,
10} = 10.
• What about the case where the consumer wants to consume the goods in
some proportion other than one-to-one?
• For example, what about the consumer who always uses 2 teaspoons of
sugar with each cup of tea?
• If x1 is the number of cups of tea available and x2 is the number of
teaspoons of sugar available, then the number of correctly sweetened
cups of tea will be
• min{x1, 1/2 x2} For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
40
Perfect complements
• Of course, any monotonic transformation of this utility function will
describe the same preferences. For example, we might want to multiply
by 2 to get rid of the fraction. This gives us the utility function u(x1,x2) =
min{2x1, x2}.
• In general, a utility function that describes perfect-complement
preferences is given by
• u(x1, x2) = min{ax1, bx2},
where a and b are positive numbers that indicate the proportions in which
the goods are consumed.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


41
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Quasilinear preferences
• Suppose that a consumer has indifference
curves that are vertical translates of one
another.
• This means that all of the indifference curves
are just vertically “shifted” versions of one
indifference curve.
• The equation for an indifference curve takes
the form x2 = k−v(x1), where k is a different
constant for each indifference curve.
• This equation says that the height of each
indifference curve is some function of x1,
−v(x1), plus a constant k.
• Higher values of k give higher indifference
curves. For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
42
Quasilinear preferences
• Solving for k and setting it equal to utility, we
have
• u(x1, x2) = k = v(x1) + x2.
• In this case the utility function is linear in
good 2, but (possibly) non- linear in good 1;
hence the name quasilinear utility, meaning
“partly linear” utility.
• Specific examples of quasilinear utility would
be u(x1, x2) = √x1 + x2, or u(x1, x2) = ln x1 +
x2.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


43
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Cobb-Douglas preferences
• Another commonly used utility function is
the Cobb-Douglas utility function

• where c and d are positive numbers that


describe the preferences of the consumer.
• In Figure 4.5A, we have illustrated the
indifference curves for c = 1/2, d = 1/2. In
Figure 4.5B, we have illustrated the
indifference curves for c = 1/5, d = 4/5.
• Note how different values of the
parameters c and d lead to different
shapes of the indifference curves.
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
44
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Cobb-Douglas preferences
• a monotonic transformation of the Cobb-Douglas utility function will
represent exactly the same preferences, and it is useful to see a couple of
examples of these transformations.
• First, if we take the natural log of utility, the product of the terms will
become a sum so that we have

• The indifference curves for this utility function will look just like the ones
for the first Cobb-Douglas function, since the logarithm is a monotonic
transformation.

• For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


45
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Cobb-Douglas preferences
• For the second example, suppose that we start with the Cobb-Douglas
form

• This means that we can always take a monotonic transformation of the


Cobb-Douglas utility function that make the exponents sum to 1.
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
46
• Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Marginal utility and MRS
• Consider a change in the consumption of each good, (Δx1,Δx2), that
keeps utility constant—that is, a change in consumption that moves us
along the indifference curve. Then we must have

• The algebraic sign of the MRS is negative: if you get more of good 1 you
have to get less of good 2 in order to keep the same level of utility.
However, it gets very tedious to keep track of that pesky minus sign, so
economists often refer to the MRS by its absolute value.
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
47
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Calculation of MRS using partial
differentiation

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


48
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Calculation of MRS for C-D function

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


49
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Optimal choice
Optimal choice: When BL is tangent to the IC.
Exceptions:
1. Kinked preferences
2. Boundary optimum

Equilibrium:

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


50
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Consumer demand
• The demand function is the function that relates the optimal
choice—the quantities demanded—to the different values of
prices and incomes.
• We will write the demand functions as depending on both
prices and income: x1(p1, p2, m) and x2(p1, p2, m). For each
different set of prices and income, there will be a different
combination of goods that is the optimal choice of the
consumer.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


51
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Perfect substitutes
• If p2 > p1, then the slope of the budget line is flatter
than the slope of the indifference curves.
• In this case, the optimal bundle is where the
consumer spends all of his or her money on good 1.
• If p1 > p2, then the consumer purchases only good 2.
• Finally, if p1 = p2, there is a whole range of optimal
choices—any amount of goods 1 and 2 that satisfies
the budget constraint is optimal in this case.
• Thus the demand function for good 1 will be

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


52
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Perfect Complements
• The optimal choice must always lie on the diagonal,
where the consumer is purchasing equal amounts of
both goods, no matter what the prices are.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


53
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Neutrals and bads
• In the case of a neutral good the consumer spends all of her money on
the good she likes and doesn’t purchase any of the neutral good. The
same thing happens if one commodity is a bad. Thus, if commodity 1 is a
good and commodity 2 is a bad, then the demand functions will be

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


54
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Concave preferences
• The optimal choice for these preferences is
always going to be a boundary choice, like
bundle Z.
• Think of what nonconvex preferences mean. If
you have money to purchase ice cream and
olives, and you don’t like to consume them
together, you’ll spend all of your money on one
or the other.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


55
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Cobb-Douglas preferences
• Derivation of demand curves

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


56
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Cobb-Douglas preferences
• The Cobb-Douglas preferences have a convenient property. Consider the
fraction of his income that a Cobb-Douglas consumer spends on good 1.
If he consumes x1 units of good 1, this costs him p1x1, so this represents
a fraction p1x1/m of total income. Substituting the demand function for x1
we have

• Similarly the fraction of his income that the consumer spends on good 2
is d/(c + d).
• Thus the Cobb-Douglas consumer always spends a fixed fraction of his
income on each good. The size of the fraction is determined by the
exponent in the Cobb-Douglas function.
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
57
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Choosing taxes
• A quantity tax is a tax on the amount consumed of a good, like a gasoline
tax of 15 cents per gallon.
• An lump sum tax is just a tax on income. If the government wants to raise
a certain amount of revenue, is it better to raise it via a quantity tax or an
lump sum tax?
• First we analyze the imposition of a quantity tax. Suppose that the original
budget constraint is
• p1x1 + p2x2 = m.
• What is the budget constraint if we tax the consumption of good 1 at a
rate of t? The answer is simple. From the viewpoint of the consumer it is
just as if the price of good 1 has increased by an amount t. Thus the new
budget constraint is
• (p1 + t)x1 + p2x2 = m. For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
58
Choosing taxes
• Therefore a quantity tax on a good increases the price perceived by the
consumer.
• At this stage, we don’t know for certain whether this tax will increase or
decrease the consumption of good 1, although the presumption is that it
will decrease it. Whichever is the case, we do know that the optimal
choice, (x∗1,x∗2), must satisfy the budget constraint
• (p1 + t)x∗1 + p2x∗2 = m.
• The revenue raised by this tax is R∗ = tx∗1.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


59
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Choosing taxes
• Let’s now consider an lump sum tax that
raises the same amount of revenue.
• The form of this budget constraint would be
p1x1 + p2x2 = m − R∗
• or, substituting for R∗,
• p1x1 + p2x2 = m − tx∗1
• It is easy to see that it has the same slope as
the original budget line,
• −p1/p2, but the problem is to determine its
location. As it turns out, the budget line with
the income tax must pass through the point
(x∗1,x∗2).
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
60
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Choosing taxes
• Is it true that
• p1x∗1 +p2x∗2 =m−tx∗1?
• Yes it is, since this is just a rearrangement of equation
• This establishes that (x∗1,x∗2) lies on the income tax
budget line: it is an affordable choice for the
consumer.
• But is it an optimal choice? It is easy to see that the
answer is no.
• At (x∗1,x∗2) the MRS is −(p1 +t)/p2. But the income
tax allows us to trade at a rate of exchange of −p1/p2.
• Thus the budget line cuts the indifference curve at
(x∗1,x∗2), which implies that there will be some point
on the budget line that will be preferred to (x∗1,x∗2).
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
61
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Choosing taxes
• Therefore the income tax is definitely superior to the
quantity tax in the sense that you can raise the same
amount of revenue from a consumer and still leave
him or her better off under the income tax than under
the quantity tax.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


62
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Demand function for quasilinear
preferences

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


63
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Demand
• The consumer’s demand functions give the optimal amounts of each of
the goods as a function of the prices and income faced by the consumer.
We write the demand functions as
• x1 =x1(p1,p2,m) x2 =x2(p1,p2,m).

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


64
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Normal and inferior goods
• If good 1 is a normal good, then the demand for it
increases when income increases, and decreases when
income decreases. For a normal good the quantity
demanded always changes in the same way as income
changes:

• an example of nice, well-behaved indifference curves


where an increase of income results in a reduction in the
consumption of one of the goods. Such a good is called
an inferior good.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


65
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Income offer curve
• We have seen that an increase in income corresponds to shifting the
budget line outward in a parallel manner. We can connect together the
demanded bundles that we get as we shift the budget line outward to
construct the income offer curve.
• The income offer curve is also known as the income expansion path. If
both goods are normal goods, then the income expansion path will have a
positive slope.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


66
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Engel curve
• For each level of income, m, there will be some optimal choice for each of
the goods.
• Let us focus on good 1 and consider the optimal choice at each set of
prices and income, x1 (p1 , p2 , m). This is simply the demand function for
good 1.
• If we hold the prices of goods 1 and 2 fixed and look at how demand
changes as we change income, we generate a curve known as the Engel
curve.
• The Engel curve is a graph of the demand for one of the goods as a
function of income, with all prices being held constant.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


67
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Perfect substitutes
• If p1 < p2, so that the consumer is
specializing in consuming good 1, then if his
income increases he will increase his
consumption of good 1. Thus the income
offer curve is the horizontal axis,
• Since the demand for good 1 is x1 = m/p1 in
this case, the Engel curve will be a straight
line with a slope of p1

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


68
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Perfect complements
• Since the consumer will always consume the
same amount of each good, no matter what,
the income offer curve is the diagonal line
through the origin.
• We have seen that the demand for good 1 is
x1 = m/(p1 + p2), so the Engel curve is a
straight line with a slope of p1 + p2.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


69
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
ICC in case of one good being inferior

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


70
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
ICC in case of necessity and luxury
goods

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


71
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Engel Curve in case of necessity and
luxury goods

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


72
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Cobb-Douglas preferences
• If u(x ,x ) = x1a x21-a, the Cobb-Douglas demand
for good 1 has the form x1 = am/p1.
• For a fixed value of p1, this is a linear function
of m.
• Thus doubling m will double demand, tripling
m will triple demand, and so on.
• In fact, multiplying m by any positive number t
will just multiply demand by the same amount.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


73
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Cobb-Douglas preferences
• The demand for good 2 is x2 = (1−a)m/p2, and
this is also clearly linear.
• The fact that the demand functions for both
goods are linear functions of income means
that the income expansion paths will be
straight lines through the origin.
• The Engel curve for good 1 will be a straight
line with a slope of p1/a.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


74
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Homothetic preferences
• Suppose that the consumer’s preferences only
depend on the ratio of good 1 to good 2.
• This means that if the consumer prefers (x1,x2) to (y1,
y2), then she automatically prefers (2x1, 2x2) to (2y1,
2y2), (3x1, 3x2) to (3y1,3y2), and so on, since the
ratio of good 1 to good 2 is the same for all of these
bundles.
• In fact, the consumer prefers (tx1,tx2) to (ty1,ty2) for
any positive value of t.
• Preferences that have this property are known as
homothetic preferences.
• It is not hard to show that the three examples of
preferences given above—perfect substitutes,
perfect complements, and Cobb-Douglas—are all
homothetic preferences.
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
75
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Homothetic preferences
• If the consumer has homothetic preferences, then
the income offer curves are all straight lines through
the origin.
• If the indifference curve is tangent to the budget line
at (x∗1,x∗2), then the indifference curve through
(tx∗1,tx∗2) is tangent to the budget line that has t
times as much income and the same prices.
• This implies that the Engel curves are straight lines
as well.
• If you double income, you just double the demand
for each good.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


76
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Quasilinear preferences
• This is the case where all indifference curves are
“shifted” versions of one indifference curve.
• Equivalently, the utility function for these preferences
takes the form u(x1,x2) = v(x1)+x2.
• What happens if we shift the budget line outward?
• In this case, if an indifference curve is tangent to the
budget line at a bundle (x∗1,x∗2), then another
indifference curve must also be tangent at (x∗1, x∗2 +k)
for any constant k.
• Increasing income doesn’t change the demand for
good 1 at all, and all the extra income goes entirely to
the consumption of good 2.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


77
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Quasilinear preferences
• If preferences are quasilinear, we sometimes say that
there is a “zero income effect” for good 1.
• Thus the Engel curve for good 1 is a vertical line—as
you change income, the demand for good 1 remains
constant.
• Ex: Pencils, all other goods

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


78
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Ordinary goods and Giffen goods

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


79
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Price Offer Curve and Demand Curve
• Suppose that we let the price of good 1 change
while we hold p2 and income fixed.
• Geometrically this involves pivoting the budget
line.
• We can think of connecting together the optimal
points to construct the price offer curve.
• The result is the demand curve depicted in
Figure 6.11B. The demand curve is a plot of the
demand function, x1 (p1 , p2 , m), holding p2
and m fixed at some predetermined values.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


80
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Types of PCC
• Downward-sloping price consumption curve
for good X means that as price of good X falls,
the consumer purchases a larger quantity of
good X and a smaller quantity of good Y.
• We obtain downward- sloping price
consumption curve for good X when demand
for it is elastic (i.e., price elasticity is greater
than one).

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


81
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Types of PCC
• We obtain the upward-sloping price
consumption curve for good X when
the demand for good is inelastic, (i.e.,
price elasticity is less than one).

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


82
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Types of PCC
• It means that when the price of the good X
declines, its quantity purchased increases
proportionately but quantity purchased of
good Y remains the same.
• We obtain horizontal price consumption
curve of good X when the price elasticity of
demand for good X is equal to unity.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


83
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Types of PCC
• Backward-sloping price consumption
curve for good X indicates that when
price of X falls, after a point smaller
quantity of it is demanded or
purchased.
• This is the case of giffen goods.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


84
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Perfect substitutes
• The demand for good 1 is zero when p1 > p2,
any amount on the budget line when p1 = p2,
and m/p1 when p1 < p2. The offer curve traces
out these possibilities.
• In order to find the demand curve, we fix the
price of good 2 at some price p∗2 and graph
the demand for good 1 versus the price of
good 1

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


85
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Perfect complements
• Whatever the prices are, a consumer will
demand the same amount of goods 1 and
2.
• Thus his offer curve will be a diagonal line.
• The demand for good 1 is given by

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


86
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Substitutes and complements
• Recall that the demand function for good 1, say, will typically be a
function of the price of both good 1 and good 2, so we write x1(p1,p2,m).
We can ask how the demand for good 1 changes as the price of good 2
changes: does it go up or down?
• If the demand for good 1 goes up when the price of good 2 goes up, then
we say that good 1 is a substitute for good 2. In terms of rates of change,
good 1 is a substitute for good 2 if

• On the other hand, if the demand for good 1 goes down when the price of
good 2 goes up, we say that good 1 is a complement to good 2. This
means that

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


87
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Inverse Demand Function
• The inverse demand function is the demand function viewing price as a
function of quantity. That is, for each level of demand for good 1, the
inverse demand function measures what the price of good 1 would have
to be in order for the consumer to choose that level of consumption.
• It measures the same relationship as the direct demand function.
• Recall, for example, the Cobb-Douglas demand for good 1, x1 = am/p1.
• We could just as well write the relationship between price and quantity as
p1 = am/x1. The first representation is the direct demand function; the
second is the inverse demand function.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


88
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Inverse Demand Function
• The inverse demand function has a useful economic interpretation. Recall
that as long as both goods are being consumed in positive amounts, the
optimal choice must satisfy the condition that the absolute value of the
MRS equals the price ratio:

• This says that at the optimal level of demand for good 1, for example, we
must have p1 = p2|MRS|.
• Thus, at the optimal level of demand for good 1, the price of good 1 is
proportional to the absolute value of the MRS between good 1 and good
2.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


89
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Inverse Demand Function
• Suppose for simplicity that the price of good 2 is one.
• Then equation tells us that at the optimal level of demand, the price of
good 1 measures how much the consumer is willing to give up of good 2
in order to get a little more of good 1.
• In this case the inverse demand function is simply measuring the absolute
value of the MRS.
• At each quantity x1, the inverse demand function measures how many
dollars the consumer is willing to give up for a little more of good 1.
• When x1 is very small, the consumer is willing to give up a lot of money—
that is, a lot of other goods, to acquire a little bit more of good 1.
• As x1 is larger, the consumer is willing to give up less money, on the
margin, to acquire a little more of good 1.
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
90
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Quasilinear preference example
•x

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


91
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Revealed preferences
• The underlying preferences—whatever
they may be—are known to be strictly
convex.
• The bundle (y1,y2) is certainly an
affordable purchase at the given
budget—the consumer could have
bought it if he or she wanted to, and
would even have had money left over.
• Since (x1,x2) is the optimal bundle, it
must be better than anything else that the
consumer could afford.
• Hence, in particular it must be better than
(y1,y2).
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
92
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Revealed preferences
• In Figure 7.1 all of the bundles in the shaded area underneath the budget
line are revealed worse than the demanded bundle (x1,x2).
• This is because they could have been chosen, but were rejected in favor
of (x1,x2).
• Let (x1, x2) be the bundle purchased at prices (p1, p2) when the
consumer has income m.
• What does it mean to say that (y1,y2) is affordable at those prices and
income?
• It simply means that (y1,y2) satisfies the budget constraint
• p1y1 + p2y2 ≤ m.
• Since (x1,x2) is actually bought at the given budget, it must satisfy the
budget constraint with equality p1x1 + p2x2 = m.
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
93
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Revealed preferences
• Putting these two equations together, the fact that (y1,y2) is affordable at
the budget (p1, p2, m) means that
• p1x1 + p2x2 ≥ p1y1 + p2y2.
• If the above inequality is satisfied and (y1,y2) is actually a different bundle
from (x1, x2), we say that (x1, x2) is directly revealed preferred to (y1,y2).
• Thus revealed preference is a relation that holds between the bundle that
is actually demanded at some budget and the bundles that could have
been demanded at that budget.
• When we say that X is revealed preferred to Y , all we are claiming is that
X is chosen when Y could have been chosen; that is, that p1x1 + p2x2 ≥
p1y1 + p2y2.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


94
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
The principle of revealed preference
• The Principle of Revealed Preference: Let (x1,x2) be the chosen bundle
when prices are (p1,p2), and let (y1,y2) be some other bundle such that
p1x1 + p2x2 ≥ p1y1 + p2y2.
• Then if the consumer is choosing the most preferred bundle she can
afford, we must have (x1, x2) > (y1, y2).
• “Revealed preferred” just means that X was chosen when Y was
affordable; “preference” means that the consumer ranks X ahead of Y.
• Suppose that we happen to know that (y1, y2) is a demanded bundle at
prices (q1,q2) and that (y1,y2) is itself revealed preferred to some other
bundle (z1, z2). That is,
• q1y1 + q2y2 ≥ q1z1 + q2z2.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


95
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
The principle of revealed preference
• Then we know that (x1,x2) > (y1,y2) and that
(y1,y2) > (z1,z2). From the transitivity
assumption we can conclude that (x1, x2) >
(z1, z2).
• Revealed preference and transitivity tell us
that (x1,x2) must be better than (z1,z2) for
the consumer who made the illustrated
choices.
• It is natural to say that in this case (x1,x2) is
indirectly revealed preferred to (z1,z2).
• If a bundle is either directly or indirectly
revealed preferred to another bundle, we will
say that the first bundle is revealed preferred
to the second. For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
96
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
The weak axiom of revealed
preference
• If the consumers are choosing the best things they can afford, then things
that are affordable, but not chosen, must be worse than what is chosen.
• Weak Axiom of Revealed Preference (WARP). If (x1, x2) is directly
revealed preferred to (y1,y2), and the two bundles are not the same, then
it cannot happen that (y1, y2) is directly revealed preferred to (x1, x2).
• In other words, if a bundle (x1,x2) is purchased at prices (p1,p2) and a
different bundle (y1, y2) is purchased at prices (q1, q2), then if
• p1x1 + p2x2 ≥ p1y1 + p2y2
• it must not be the case that q1y1 + q2y2 ≥ q1x1 + q2x2.
• if the y-bundle is affordable when the x-bundle is purchased, then when
the y-bundle is purchased, the x-bundle must not be affordable.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


97
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Violation of WARP

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


98
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
SARP
• The Weak Axiom of Revealed Preference requires that if X is directly
revealed preferred to Y , then we should never observe Y being directly
revealed preferred to X.
• The Strong Axiom of Revealed Preference (SARP) requires that the same
sort of condition hold for indirect revealed preference.
• Strong Axiom of Revealed Preference (SARP). If (x1,x2) is revealed
preferred to (y1,y2) (either directly or indirectly) and (y1,y2) is different
from (x1, x2), then (y1, y2) cannot be directly or indirectly revealed
preferred to (x1, x2).
• if the observed choices satisfy SARP, we can always find nice, well-
behaved preferences that could have generated the observed choices.
• In this sense SARP is a sufficient condition for optimizing behavior: if the
observed choices satisfy SARP, then it is always possible to find
preferences for which the observed behavior is optimizing behavisor.
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
99
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Index numbers
• Suppose that at time t prices are (pt1,pt2) and that the consumer chooses
(xt1,xt2). In the base period b, the prices are (pb1,pb2), and the
consumer’s choice is (xb1,xb2). We want to ask how the “average”
consumption of the consumer has changed.
• If we let w1 and w2 be some “weights” that go into making an average,
then we can look at the following kind of quantity index:

• If we use the base period prices for the weights, we have something
called a Laspeyres index, and if we use the t period prices, we have
something called a Paasche index.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


100
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Index numbers

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


101
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Index numbers
• It turns out that the magnitude of the Laspeyres and Paasche indices can
tell us something quite interesting about the consumer’s welfare. Suppose
that we have a situation where the Paasche quantity index is greater than
1:

• What can we conclude about how well-off the consumer is at time t as


compared to his situation at time b?
• The answer is provided by revealed preference. Just cross multiply this
inequality to give

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


102
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Index numbers
• which immediately shows that the consumer must be better off at t than
at b, since he could have consumed the b consumption bundle in the t
situation but chose not to do so.

• which says that when the consumer chose bundle (xt1, xt2), bundle (xb1,
xb2) was not affordable. But that doesn’t say anything about the
consumer’s ranking of the bundles.
• Just because something costs more than you can afford doesn’t mean
that you prefer it to what you’re consuming now.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


103
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Numerical example of WARP
•x

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


104
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Numerical example of SARP
•x

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


105
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Slutsky equation: The substitution
Effect
• The substitution effect
• When the price of a good changes, there are two sorts of effects: the rate
at which you can exchange one good for another changes, and the total
purchasing power of your income is altered.
• If, for example, good 1 becomes cheaper, it means that you have to give
up less of good 2 to purchase good 1.
• The change in the price of good 1 has changed the rate at which the
market allows you to “substitute” good 2 for good 1.
• The trade-off between the two goods that the market presents the
consumer has changed.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


106
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
The substitution Effect
• At the same time, if good 1 becomes cheaper it means that your money
income will buy more of good 1.
• The purchasing power of your money has gone up; although the number
of dollars you have is the same, the amount that they will buy has
increased.
• The first part—the change in demand due to the change in the rate of
exchange between the two goods—is called the substitution effect.
• The second effect—the change in demand due to having more
purchasing power—is called the income effect.
• The way that we will do this is to break the price movement into two
steps: first we will let the relative prices change and adjust money income
so as to hold purchasing power constant, then we will let purchasing
power adjust while holding the relative prices constant.
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
107
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
The substitution Effect

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


108
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
The substitution Effect
• Here we have a situation where the price of good 1 has declined.
• This means that the budget line rotates around the vertical intercept m/p2
and becomes flatter.
• We can break this movement of the budget line up into two steps: first
pivot the budget line around the original demanded bundle and then shift
the pivoted line out to the new demanded bundle.
• This decomposition is only a hypothetical construction—the consumer
simply observes a change in price and chooses a new bundle of goods in
response.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


109
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
The substitution Effect
• Economic meanings of pivoted and shifted budget lines
• Pivoted line: Here we have a budget line with the same slope and thus
the same relative prices as the final budget line.
• However, the money income associated with this budget line is different,
since the vertical intercept is different.
• Since the original consumption bundle (x1,x2) lies on the pivoted budget
line, that consumption bundle is just affordable.
• The purchasing power of the consumer has remained constant.
• Let us calculate how much we have to adjust money income in order to
keep the old bundle just affordable. Let m′ be the amount of money
income that will just make the original consumption bundle affordable

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


110
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
The substitution Effect
• Since (x1,x2) is affordable at both (p1,p2,m) and (p′1,p2,m′), we have
• m ′ = p ′1 x 1 + p 2 x 2
• m = p1x1 + p2x2
• Subtracting the second equation from the first gives
• m ′ − m = x 1 [ p ′1 − p 1 ]
• This equation says that the change in money income necessary to make
the old bundle affordable at the new prices is just the original amount of
consumption of good 1 times the change in prices.
• Δm = x1Δp1.
• Note that the change in income and the change in price will always move
in the same direction: if the price goes up, then we have to raise income
to keep the same bundle affordable.
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
111
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
The substitution Effect
• When a price goes down, a consumer’s purchasing power goes up, so we
will have to decrease the consumer’s income in order to keep purchasing
power fixed.
• Although (x1,x2) is still affordable, it is not generally the optimal pur-
chase at the pivoted budget line.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


112
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
The substitution Effect

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


113
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
The substitution Effect
• In Figure 8.2 we have denoted the optimal purchase on the pivoted
budget line by Y .
• The movement from X to Y is known as the substitution effect. It indicates
how the consumer “substitutes” one good for the other when a price
changes but purchasing power remains constant.
• More precisely, the substitution effect, Δxs1, is the change in the demand
for good 1 when the price of good 1 changes to p′1 and, at the same time,
money income changes to m′:
• Δx1s =x1(p′1,m′)−x1(p1,m).
• In order to determine the substitution effect, we must use the consumer’s
demand function to calculate the optimal choices at (p′1, m′) and (p1, m).

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


114
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
The substitution Effect
• The substitution effect is sometimes called the change in compensated
demand.
• The idea is that the consumer is being compensated for a price rise by
having enough income given back to him to purchase his old bundle.
• Of course if the price goes down he is “compensated” by having money
taken away from him.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


115
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Calculating the substitution Effect

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


116
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
The income effect
• A parallel shift of the budget line is the movement that occurs when
income changes while relative prices remain constant. Thus the second
stage of the price adjustment is called the income effect.
• We simply change the consumer’s income from m′ to m, keeping the
prices constant at (p′1 , p2 ).
• More precisely, the income effect, Δxn1 , is the change in the demand for
good 1 when we change income from m′ to m, holding the price of good
1 fixed at p′1:

• We saw that the income effect can operate either way: it will tend to
increase or decrease the demand for good 1 depending on whether we
have a normal good or an inferior good.
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
117
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Calculating the income effect
•x

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


118
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Sign of the substitution effect
• We have seen above that the income effect can be positive or negative,
depending on whether the good is a normal good or an inferior good.
• What about the substitution effect? If the price of a good goes down, as
in Figure 8.2, then the change in the demand for the good due to the
substitution effect must be nonnegative.
• That is, if p1 > p′1, then we must have x1(p′1, m′) ≥ x1(p1, m), so that
Δxs1 ≥ 0.
• If the consumer is always choosing the best bundle he can afford, then X
must be preferred to all of the bundles on the part of the pivoted line that
lies inside the original budget set.
• This means that the optimal choice on the pivoted budget line must not
be one of the bundles that lies underneath the original budget line.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


119
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Sign of the substitution effect
• The optimal choice on the pivoted line would have to be either X or some
point to the right of X.
• The substitution effect always moves opposite to the price movement.
• We say that the substitution effect is negative, since the change in
demand due to the substitution effect is opposite to the change in price: if
the price increases, the demand for the good due to the substitution
effect decreases.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


120
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
The total change in demand
• The total change in demand, Δx1, is the change in demand due to the
change in price, holding income constant:

• We have seen above how this change can be broken up into two
changes: the substitution effect and the income effect. In terms of the
symbols defined above,

• This equation is called the Slutsky identity.


For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
121
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
The total change in demand
• While the substitution effect must always be negative—opposite the
change in the price—the income effect can go either way.
• Thus the total effect may be positive or negative.
• However, if we have a normal good, then the substitution effect and the
income effect work in the same direction.
• An increase in price means that demand will go down due to the
substitution effect.
• If the price goes up, it is like a decrease in income, which, for a normal
good, means a decrease in demand.
• Both effects reinforce each other. In terms of our notation, the change in
demand due to a price increase for a normal good means that

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


122
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
The total change in demand

• Note carefully the sign on the income effect. Since we are considering a
situation where the price rises, this implies a decrease in purchasing
power—for a normal good this will imply a decrease in demand.
• On the other hand, if we have an inferior good, it might happen that the
income effect outweighs the substitution effect, so that the total change in
demand associated with a price increase is actually positive. This would
be a case where

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


123
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
The total change in demand
• If the second term on the right-hand side—the income effect—is large
enough, the total change in demand could be positive. This would mean
that an increase in price could result in an increase in demand.
• if a good is a normal good, then the income and substitution effects
reinforce each other, so that the total change in demand is always in the
“right” direction.
• Thus a Giffen good must be an inferior good. But an inferior good is not
necessarily a Giffen good: the income effect not only has to be of the
“wrong” sign, it also has to be large enough to outweigh the “right” sign
of the substitution effect.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


124
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
The total change in demand

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


125
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Rates of change

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


126
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Slutsky equation in elasticity form
PYQ
Write down the Slutsky equation in elasticity form and prove that the ordinary
demand curve will have greater demand elasticity than the compensated
demand curve for a normal commodity. How does your result change if the
commodity becomes inferior? (2019)

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


127
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Examples of income and substitution
effects
• Perfect complements
• When we pivot the budget line around
the chosen point, the optimal choice at
the new budget line is the same as at
the old one—this means that the
substitution effect is zero.
• The change in demand is due entirely
to the income effect.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


128
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Examples of income and substitution
effects
• Perfect Substitutes
• Here when we tilt the budget line, the
demand bundle jumps from the vertical
axis to the horizontal axis. There is no
shifting left to do!
• The entire change in demand is due to
the substitution effect.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


129
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Examples of income and substitution
effects
• Quasilinear preferences
• We have already seen that a shift
in income causes no change in
demand for good 1 when
preferences are quasilinear.
• This means that the entire change
in demand for good 1 is due to
the substitution effect, and that
the income effect is zero

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


130
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Another substitution effect: Hicks
• Suppose that instead of pivoting the budget line around the original
consumption bundle, we now roll the budget line around the indifference
curve through the original consumption bundle.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


131
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Another substitution effect: Hicks
• In this way we present the consumer with a new budget line that has the
same relative prices as the final budget line but has a different income.
• The purchasing power he has under this budget line will no longer be
sufficient to purchase his original bundle of goods—but it will be sufficient
to purchase a bundle that is just indifferent to his original bundle.
• Thus the Hicks substitution effect keeps utility constant rather than
keeping purchasing power constant.
• The Slutsky substitution effect gives the consumer just enough money to
get back to his old level of consumption, while the Hicks substitution
effect gives the consumer just enough money to get back to his old
indifference curve.
• Despite this difference in definition, it turns out that the Hicks substitution
effect must be negative.
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
132
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Compensated demand curves
• We have seen how the quantity demanded changes as a price changes in
three different contexts: holding income fixed (the standard case), holding
purchasing power fixed (the Slutsky substitution effect), and holding utility
fixed (the Hicks substitution effect).
• This gives rise to three different demand curves: the standard demand
curve, the Slutsky demand curve, and the Hicks demand curve.
• Furthermore the ordinary demand curve is a downward sloping curve for
normal goods.
• However, the Giffen analysis shows that it is theoretically possible that the
ordinary demand curve may slope upwards for an inferior good.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


133
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Compensated demand curves
• The Hicksian demand curve—the one with utility held constant—is
sometimes called the compensated demand curve.
• This terminology arises naturally if you think of constructing the Hicksian
demand curve by adjusting income as the price changes so as to keep
the consumer’s utility constant.
• Hence the consumer is “compensated” for the price changes, and his
utility is the same at every point on the Hicksian demand curve.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


134
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Compensated demand curves

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


135
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Compensated demand curves
• As a consumer moves downward along the ordinary demand curve, he
goes to a higher indifference curve on the price consumption curve and
his satisfaction or real income increases. It may be noted that in deriving
ordinary demand curve, money income of the consumer is held constant.
• The demand curve which incorporates the effects of changes in price of a
commodity, real income remaining constant is called income
compensated demand curve or simply compensated demand curve.
• Thus, whereas ordinary demand curve describes the effects of both the
substitution and income effects of the changes in price of a commodity,
compensated demand curve includes the effect of only substitution effect.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


136
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Relation between compensated and
ordinary demand curves
• On the ordinary demand curve D0D0, we take
a point E corresponding to the tangency point
of a given budget line and an indifference
curve which represents a given level of real
income (i.e., satisfaction).
• At price P0, quantity demanded of the
commodity is OX0.
• Now suppose price of the commodity falls
from P0 to P1. In the absence of
compensating variation in income, at the lower
price P1, the consumer moves downward
along the ordinary demand curve D0D0 and
buys Ox2 quantity of the commodity.
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
137
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Relation between compensated and
ordinary demand curves
• Note that, in the absence of compensating
variation in income, at a lower price P1 and
quantity Ox2 on the ordinary demand curve,
purchasing power will increase as he would move
to a higher indifference curve on the price
consumption curve.
• However, in order to prevent him from gaining in
utility his money income is reduced large
enough to keep him on the same indifference
curve, he will buy less than Ox2 quantity of
the commodity.
• It will be seen from Fig. 9.5. that at a lower price
P1 together with compensation variation in
income the
consumer buys Ox1 quantity of the commodity
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
138
Consumer Surplus
• Suppose that the price of the discrete good is p.
• Then the value that the consumer places on the first unit of consumption
of that good is r1, but he only has to pay p for it.
• This gives him a “surplus” of r1 − p on the first unit of consumption.
• He values the second unit of consumption at r2, but again he only has to
pay p for it.
• This gives him a surplus of r2 − p on that unit.
• If we add this up over all n units the consumer chooses, we get his total
consumer’s surplus:
• CS = r1 − p + r2 − p + · · · + rn − p = r1 + · · · + rn − np.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


139
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Consumer Surplus
• Suppose the price of a good changes from p′
to p′′. How does the consumer’s surplus
change?
• In Figure 14.3 we have illustrated the change in
consumer’s surplus associated with a change
in price.
• The rectangle measures the loss in surplus due
to the fact that the consumer is now paying
more for all the units he continues to consume.
• After the price increases the consumer
continues to consume x′′ units of the good,
and each unit of the good is now more
expensive by p′′ −p′.
• This means he has to spend For free(p′′ − p′)x′′
counseling more
call us on:-7880107880
140
money than he did before just to consume x′′
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Consumer Surplus
• Due to the increase in the price of the x-good, the consumer has decided
to consume less of it than he was before.
• The triangle T measures the value of the lost consumption of the x-good.
• R measures the loss from having to pay more for the units he continues to
consume, and T measures the loss from the reduced consumption.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


141
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Compensating and equivalent
variation
• in some applications it may be convenient to use certain monetary
measures of utility.
• For example, we could ask how much money we would have to give a
consumer to compensate him for a change in his consumption patterns.
• A measure of this type essentially measures a change in utility, but it
measures it in monetary units. What are convenient ways to do this?

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


142
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Compensating and equivalent
variation
• Here the consumer initially faces some prices (p∗1,1)
and consumes some bundle (x∗1, x∗2).
• The price of good 1 then increases from p∗1 to pˆ1,
and the consumer changes his consumption to (xˆ1,
xˆ2).
• How much does this price change hurt the consumer?
• One way to answer this question is to ask how much
money we would have to give the consumer after the
price change to make him just as well off as he was
before the price change.
• In terms of the diagram, we ask how far up we would
have to shift the new budget line to make it tangent
to the indifference curve that passes through the
original consumption point For (x∗1,x∗2).
free counseling call us on:-7880107880
143
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Compensating and equivalent
variation
• The change in income necessary to restore the
consumer to his original indifference curve is called
the compensating variation in income, since it is the
change in income that will just compensate the
consumer for the price change.
• The compensating variation measures how much
extra money the government would have to give the
consumer if it wanted to exactly compensate the
consumer for the price change.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


144
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Compensating and equivalent
variation
• Another way to measure the impact of a price change
in monetary terms is to ask how much money would
have to be taken away from the consumer before the
price change to leave him as well off as he would be
after the price change.
• This is called the equivalent variation in income since
it is the income change that is equivalent to the price
change in terms of the change in utility.
• we ask how far down we must shift the original
budget line to just touch the indifference curve that
passes through the new consumption bundle. The
equivalent variation measures the maximum amount
of income that the consumer would be willing to pay
to avoid the price change.
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
145
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Compensating and equivalent
variation
• In general the amount of money that the consumer would be willing to pay
to avoid a price change would be different from the amount of money that
the consumer would have to be paid to compensate him for a price
change.
• In geometric terms, the compensating and equivalent variations are just
two different ways to measure “how far apart” two indifference curves are.
• In each case we are measuring the distance between two indifference
curves by seeing how far apart their tangent lines are.
• In general this measure of distance will depend on the slope of the
tangent lines—that is, on the prices that we choose to determine the
budget lines.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


146
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Numerical example
•x

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


147
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Compensating and equivalent variation for
quasilinear preferences
• For quasilinear preferences, the indifference curves are all the same
shape, except they are vertically shifted up.
• It also turns out that for quasi-linear preferences the CV and EV are
always equal to the change in consumers’ surplus.
• The intuition for this is not difficult: because the indifference curves are
parallel (which means that the MRS at a particular quantity of x is the
same on every indifference curve) then the distance on the y axis between
the tangents to any two indifference curves at a particular value of x must
be equal to the constant vertical distance between them.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


148
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Compensating and equivalent variation for
quasilinear preferences
• So, because the consumer’s indifference curves are parallel, they will
always require the same amount of good y, to move back to their original
indifference curve (the compensating variation), regardless of the values
of px before and after the price change which changed their optimal
bundle.
• This value is also the amount of cash income that the consumer would be
willing to pay to avoid having the change in the price of good x in the first
place (the equivalent variation).

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


149
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Compensating and equivalent variation for
quasilinear preferences

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


150
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Producer’s Surplus
• The supply curve measures the amount that will be supplied at each price.
• Just as the area under the demand curve measures the sur- plus enjoyed
by the demanders of a good, the area above the supply curve measures
the surplus enjoyed by the suppliers of a good.
• The area above the supply curve is known as producer’s surplus.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


151
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Producer’s Surplus
• The difference between the minimum amount she would be willing to sell
the x∗ units for and the amount she actually sells the units for is the net
producer’s surplus.
• we can ask how producer’s surplus changes when the price increases
from p′ to p′′.
• The rectangle measures the gain from selling the units previously sold
anyway at p′ at the higher price p′′. The roughly triangular region
measures the gain from selling the extra units at the price p′′. i

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


152
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Market Demand
From individual to market demand
• Let us use �1� (p1, p2, mi) to represent consumer i’s demand function for
good 1 and �2� (p1,p2,mi) for consumer i’s demand function for good 2.
Suppose that there are n consumers. Then the market demand for good 1,
also called the aggregate demand for good 1, is the sum of these
individual demands over all consumers:

• Since each individual’s demand for each good depends on prices and his
or her money income, the aggregate demand will generally depend on
prices and the distribution of incomes.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


153
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Market Demand
• The aggregate demand function will have the form
X1(p1,p2,M), where M is the sum of the incomes of
the individual consumers.
• Note that this curve is drawn holding all other
prices and incomes fixed. If these other prices and
incomes change, the aggregate demand curve will
shift.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


154
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Adding up linear demand curves
• Suppose that one individual’s demand curve is D1(p) = 20−p and another
individual’s is D2(p) = 10−2p. What is the market demand function?

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


155
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
156
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Elasticity
• In symbols the definition of elasticity is

• Elasticity of a linear demand curve


• Consider the linear demand curve, q = a − bp, depicted in Figure 15.4.
The slope of this demand curve is a constant, −b. Plugging this into the
formula for elasticity we have

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


157
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Elasticity
• When p = 0, the elasticity of demand is zero. When q = 0, the elasticity of
demand is (negative) infinity. At what value of price is the elasticity of
demand equal to −1?

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


158
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Elasticity

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


159
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Measurement of elasticity at a point on
the demand curve
푙표�  푠 푔� 懲 표  푑 � 푑 푐푢
• Elasticity =
푢푝푝  푠 푔� 懲 표  푑 � 푑 푐푢

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


160
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Elasticity and demand
• If a good has an elasticity of demand greater than 1 in absolute value we
say that it has an elastic demand.
• If the elasticity is less than 1 in absolute value we say that it has an
inelastic demand.
• And if it has an elasticity of exactly −1, we say it has unit elastic demand.
• In general the elasticity of demand for a good depends to a large extent
on how many close substitutes it has.
• If a good has many close substitutes, we would expect that its demand
curve would be very responsive to its price changes. On the other hand, if
there are few close substitutes for a good, it can exhibit a quite inelastic
demand.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


161
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Elasticity and revenue
• If demand drops a lot when the price increases, then revenue will fall.
• If demand drops only a little when the price increases, then revenue will
increase.
• This suggests that the direction of the change in revenue has something
to do with the elasticity of demand.
• there is a very useful relationship between price elasticity and revenue
change.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


162
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Elasticity and revenue

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


163
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Elasticity and revenue

Thus revenue increases when price increases if the elasticity of demand is less than 1 in
absolute value. Similarly, revenue decreases when price increases if the elasticity of
demand is greater than 1 in absolute value.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


164
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Elasticity and revenue
• Another way to see this is to take the formula for ΔR/Δp and rearrange it
as follows:

• In this formula it is easy to see how revenue responds to a change in


price: if the absolute value of elasticity is greater than 1, then ΔR/Δp must
be negative and vice versa. For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
165
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Elasticity and revenue
• The intuitive content of these mathematical facts is not hard to remember.
• If demand is very responsive to price—that is, it is very elastic—then an
increase in price will reduce demand so much that revenue will fall.
• If demand is very unresponsive to price—it is very inelastic—then an
increase in price will not change demand very much, and overall revenue
will increase.
• The dividing line happens to be an elasticity of −1. At this point if the price
increases by 1 percent, the quantity will decrease by 1 percent, so overall
revenue doesn’t change at all.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


166
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Constant elasticity demand
• What kind of demand curve gives us a constant elasticity of demand? In a
linear demand curve the elasticity of demand goes from zero to infinity,
which is not exactly what you would call constant, so that’s not the
answer.
• We know that if the elasticity is 1 at price p, then the revenue will not
change when the price changes by a small amount.
• So if the revenue remains constant for all changes in price, we must have
a demand curve that has an elasticity of −1 everywhere.
• We just want price and quantity to be related by the formula

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


167
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Constant elasticity demands
• The general formula for a demand with a
constant elasticity of ε turns out to be

• where A is an arbitrary positive constant and


ε, being an elasticity, will typically be
negative.
• A convenient way to express a constant
elasticity demand curve is to take logarithms
and write
• lnq = lnA + εlnp.
• In this expression, the logarithm of q
depends in a linear way on the logarithm of p.
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
168
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Constant elasticity demands
• Calculation of elasticity

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


169
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Elasticity and marginal revenue
• the change in revenue is given by
• ΔR = pΔq + qΔp.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


170
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Elasticity and marginal revenue
• When there is a danger of confusion due to the fact that elasticity is a
negative number we will sometimes write this expression as

• This means that if elasticity of demand is −1, then marginal revenue is


zero—revenue doesn’t change when you increase output.
• If demand is inelastic, then |ε| is less than 1, which means 1/|ε| is greater
than 1. Thus 1−1/|ε| is negative, so that revenue will decrease when you
increase output.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


171
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Elasticity and marginal revenue
• Marginal revenue is given by

• We will find it useful to plot these marginal revenue curves.


• First, note that when quantity is zero, marginal revenue is just equal to the
price.
• For the first unit of the good sold, the extra revenue you get is just the
price. But after that, the marginal revenue will be less than the price, since
Δp/Δq is negative. For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
172
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Elasticity and marginal revenue
• Think about it. If you decide to sell one more unit of output, you will have
to decrease the price.
• But this reduction in price reduces the revenue you receive on all the units
of output that you were selling already.
• Thus the extra revenue you receive will be less than the price that you get
for selling the extra unit.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


173
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Elasticity and marginal revenue

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


174
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Elasticity and marginal revenue
• The marginal revenue curve has the same vertical intercept as the
demand curve, but has twice the slope.
• Marginal revenue is negative when q > a/2b.
• The quantity a/2b is the quantity at which the elasticity is equal to −1. At
any larger quantity demand will be inelastic, which implies that marginal
revenue is negative.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


175
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Elasticity and marginal revenue
• The constant elasticity demand curve provides another special case of
the marginal revenue curve. (See Figure 15.7B.)
• If the elasticity of demand is constant at ε(q) = ε, then the marginal
revenue curve will have the form

• Since the term in brackets is constant, the marginal revenue curve is


some constant fraction of the inverse demand curve.
• When |ε| = 1, the marginal revenue curve is constant at zero. When |ε| > 1,
the marginal revenue curve lies below the inverse demand curve, as
depicted. When |ε| < 1, marginal revenue is negative.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


176
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Income elasticity
• The income elasticity of demand is used to describe how the quantity
demanded responds to a change in income; its definition is

• Recall that a normal good is one for which an increase in income leads to
an increase in demand; so for this sort of good the income elasticity of
demand is positive.
• An inferior good is one for which an increase in income leads to a
decrease in demand; for this sort of good, the income elasticity of
demand is negative.
• Economists sometimes use the term luxury goods. These are goods that
have an income elasticity of demand that is greater than 1: a 1 percent
increase in income leads to more than a 1 percent increase in demand for
a luxury good. For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
177
Income elasticity
• As a general rule of thumb, however, income elasticities tend to cluster
around 1. We can see the reason for this by examining the budget
constraint. Write the budget constraints for two different levels of income:

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


178
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Income elasticity
• This equation says that the weighted average of the income elasticities is
1, where the weights are the expenditure shares.
• Luxury goods that have an income elasticity greater than 1 must be
counterbalanced by goods that have an income elasticity less than 1, so
that “on average” income elasticities are about 1.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


179
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Cross elasticity of demand
• The degree of responsiveness of change in the demand for one good in
response to change in price of another good represents the cross
elasticity of demand of one goods for the other.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


180
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Cross elasticity of demand

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


181
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Cross elasticity of demand
• The cross elasticity of demand between the two substitute goods is
positive, that is, in response to the rise in price of one good, the demand
for the other good rises.
• The cross elasticity of demand between the two complementary goods is
negative.
• Take two goods X and Y where the demand for good X is inelastic.
• Suppose the price of good X falls and as a result real income of the
consumer increases.
• Since the demand for good X is inelastic, the less money would now be
spent on good X when its price has fallen.
• In this way, a good amount of money income would now be released from
good X which will be spent on good Y.
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
182
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Cross elasticity of demand
• Thus, the income effect of the fall in price of X on the demand for good Y
will be very large and, as a result, the quantity demanded of good Y will
increase (the demand curve for good Y will shift to the right).
• We thus see that the fall in price of good X has resulted in the increase
in demand for good Y and therefore the cross elasticity and demand of
good Y for good X is negative.
• But this negative cross elasticity of demand of Y for X is not due to the
complementary relationship between the two but due to the strong
income effect as compared to the substitution effect on the demand for
good Y produced by the fall in price of good X.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


183
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Elasticity of substitution
• The elasticity of substitution between two goods is a measure of the ease
with which one can be substituted for the other.
• the elasticity of substitution is a relative measure of the substitution effect.
• When it is difficult to substitute one good for another, a small change in
the proportion of the two goods will bring about a large change in the
marginal rate of substitution between the two goods.
• When the substitution between the two goods is easy, a small change in
the proportion of two goods possessed by the consumer, the change in
the marginal rate of substitution between the two goods will not be much.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


184
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Elasticity of substitution

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


185
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Elasticity of substitution
• In the following two Figures, 14.26 and 14.27 on points A and B of the two
indifference curves, two tangents CD and EF are drawn whose slopes
indicate the marginal rates of substitution at them.
• In Figures 14.26 and 14.27 the change in marginal rate of substitution
between points A and B respectively is equal because the corresponding
tangents in the two figures are parallel to each other, that is, CD in Figure
14.27 is parallel to CD of Figure 14.26 and EF of Figure 14.26 is parallel to
EF of Figure 14.27.
• In other words, in both the indifferences curves, on switching from A to B
there is same charge in the marginal rate of substitution.
• Whereas in both the indifference curves, the fall in the marginal rate of
substitution of X for Y between A to B is the same, the increase in the
quantity of X in indifference curve in Figure 14.26 is much greater than the
increase in quantity of X inForindifference curve of Figure 14.27.
free counseling call us on:-7880107880
186
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Elasticity of substitution
• When the two goods X and Y are perfect substitutes of each other, then
the proportion between them (that is, Qx/Qy ) can be increased infinitely
without any change in the marginal rate of substitution between them,
that is, elasticity of substitution between the perfect substitutes is infinite.
That is why the indifference curve of the two perfectly substitute goods is
a straight line.
• On the other hand, the goods which are perfect complements to each
other, they are used in a fixed proportion and no substitution between
them is possible. Therefore, the goods which are perfect complements of
each other, the elasticity of substitution between them is zero.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


187
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Laffer Curve
• Laffer Curve explains how tax revenue changes when the tax rate
changes.
• Suppose that we graph tax revenue versus the tax rate.
• If the tax rate is zero, then tax revenues are zero; if the tax rate is 1,
nobody will want to demand or supply the good in question, so the tax
revenue is also zero.
• Thus revenue as a function of the tax rate must first increase and
eventually decrease.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


188
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Laffer Curve
• The interesting feature of the Laffer curve is that it suggests that when the
tax rate is high enough, an increase in the tax rate will end up reducing
the revenues collected.
• The reduction in the supply of the good due to the increase in the tax rate
can be so large that tax revenue actually decreases.
• let’s consider the following simple model of the labor market.
• Suppose that firms will demand zero labor if the wage is greater than w
and an arbitrarily large amount of labor if the wage is exactly �.
• This means that the demand curve for labor is flat at some wage �.
• Suppose that the supply curve of labor, S(p), has a conventional upward
slope. The equilibrium in the labor market is depicted in Figure 15.9.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


189
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Laffer Curve
• If we put a tax on labor at the rate t, then if the
firm pays w, the worker only gets w = (1 − t) �.
• Thus the supply curve of labor tilts to the left,
and the amount of labor sold drops, as in Figure
15.9.
• The after-tax wage has gone down and this has
discouraged the sale of labor.
• Tax revenue, T, is therefore given by the formula

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


190
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Laffer Curve
• The Laffer effect occurs when revenues decline when t increases—that is,
when this expression is negative.
• Now this clearly means that the supply of labor is going to have to be
quite elastic—it has to drop a lot when the tax increases.
• So let’s try to see what values of elasticity will make this expression
negative.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


191
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Laffer Curve

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


192
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Another expression for elasticity
• It turns out that elasticity can also be expressed as

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


193
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Another expression for elasticity

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


194
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Equilibrium
• Inverse demand and supply curves
• Inverse demand functions that measure the price that someone is willing
to pay in order to acquire some given amount of a good.
• The same thing holds for supply curves. They can be viewed as
measuring the quantity supplied as a function of the price. But we can
also view them as measuring the price that must prevail in order to
generate a given amount of supply.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


195
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Equilibrium
• if we let PS(q) be the inverse supply function and PD(q) be the
inverse demand function, equilibrium is determined by the
condition
• PS(q∗) = PD(q∗)

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


196
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Taxes
• The fundamental thing to understand about taxes is that when a tax is
present in a market, there are two prices of interest: the price the
demander pays and the price the supplier gets.
• These two prices—the demand price and the supply price—differ by the
amount of the tax.
• A quantity tax is a tax levied per unit of quantity bought or sold. Gasoline
taxes are a good example of this.
• The gasoline tax is roughly 12 cents a gallon. If the demander is paying
PD = $1.50 per gallon of gasoline, the supplier is getting PS = $1.50 − .12
= $1.38 per gallon. In general, if t is the amount of the quantity tax per unit
sold, then
• PD = PS + t.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


197
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Taxes
• A value tax is a tax expressed in percentage units. If your state has a 5
percent sales tax, then when you pay $1.05 for something (including the
tax), the supplier gets $1.00.
• In general, if the tax rate is given by τ, then PD =(1+τ)PS.
• Let us consider what happens in a market when a quantity tax is imposed.
• For our first case we suppose that the supplier is required to pay the tax,
as in the case of the gasoline tax.
• Then the amount supplied will depend on the supply price—the amount
the supplier actually gets after paying the tax—and the amount
demanded will depend on the demand price—the amount that the
demander pays.
• The amount that the supplier gets will be the amount the demander pays
minus the amount of the tax.
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
198
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Taxes

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


199
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Taxes
• As far as the equilibrium price facing the demanders and the suppliers is
concerned, it really doesn’t matter who is responsible for paying the tax—
it just matters that the tax must be paid by someone.
• The equilibrium quantity traded is that quantity q∗ such that the demand
price at q∗ minus the tax being paid is just equal to the supply price at q∗.
In symbols:

• If the tax is being imposed on the suppliers, then the condition is that the
supply price plus the amount of the tax must equal the demand price:

• But these are the same equations,


For free counselingso the
call us same equilibrium prices and
on:-7880107880
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
200
Taxes
• We want to find the quantity where the curve PD(q)−t crosses the curve
PS(q). In order to locate this point we simply shift the demand curve down
by t and see where this shifted demand curve intersects the original
supply curve.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


201
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Taxes
• Alternatively we can find the quantity where PD(q) equals PS(q)+t. To do
this, we simply shift the supply curve up by the amount of the tax.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


202
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Taxation with linear demand and
supply
• Suppose that the demand and supply curves are both linear. Then if we
impose a tax in this market, the equilibrium is determined by the
equations

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


203
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Taxation with linear demand and
supply

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


204
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Passing along a tax
• How much of a tax gets passed along will therefore depend on the
characteristics of demand and supply?
• This is easiest to see in the extreme cases: when we have a perfectly
horizontal supply curve or a perfectly vertical supply curve.
• These are also known as the case of perfectly elastic and perfectly
inelastic supply.
• If an industry has a horizontal supply curve, it means that the industry will
supply any amount desired of the good at some given price, and zero
units of the good at any lower price.
• In this case the price is entirely determined by the supply curve and the
quantity sold is determined by demand.
• If an industry has a vertical supply curve, it means that the quantity of the
good is fixed. The equilibrium price of the good is determined entirely by
demand. For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
205
Passing along a tax
• In the case of a perfectly elastic supply curve it is
easy to see that the price to the consumers goes
up by exactly the amount of the tax.
• The supply price is exactly the same as it was
before the tax, and the demanders end up paying
the entire tax.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


206
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Passing along a tax
• If the supply curve is vertical and we “shift the
supply curve up,” we don’t change anything in the
diagram.
• The supply curve just slides along itself, and we
still have the same amount of the good supplied,
with or without the tax.
• In this case, the demanders determine the
equilibrium price of the good, and they are willing
to pay a certain amount, p∗, for the supply of the
good that is available, tax or no tax.
• Thus they end up paying p∗, and the suppliers end
up receiving p∗ − t. The entire amount of the tax is
paid by the suppliers.
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
207
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Passing along a tax
• In this situation, the amount of the tax that gets
passed along will depend on the steepness of the
supply curve relative to the demand curve.
• If the supply curve is nearly horizontal, nearly all of
the tax gets passed along to the consumers.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


208
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Passing along a tax
• If the supply curve is nearly vertical, almost none
of the tax gets passed along.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


209
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Deadweight loss of a tax
• Taxing a good will typically increase the price paid by the demanders and
decrease the price received by the suppliers.
• This certainly represents a cost to the demanders and suppliers, but from
the economist’s viewpoint, the real cost of the tax is that the output has
been reduced.
• The lost output is the social cost of the tax.
• This depicts the equilibrium demand price and supply price after a tax, t,
has been imposed.
• Output has been decreased by this tax, and we can use the tools of
consumers’ and producers’ surplus to value the social loss.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


210
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Deadweight loss of a tax
• The loss in consumers’ surplus is given by the
areas A + B, and the loss in producers’ surplus is
given in areas C + D
• The government gains revenue from the tax.
• The net benefit to the government is the area A +
C—the total revenue from the tax.
• Since the loss of producers’ and consumers’
surpluses are net costs, and the tax revenue to
the government is a net benefit, the total net cost
of the tax is the algebraic sum of these areas:
the loss in consumers’ surplus, −(A + B), the loss
in producers’ surplus, −(C + D), and the gain in
government revenue, +(A + C).
• The net result is the area −(B
For free+ D). This
counseling area is
call us on:-7880107880
211
known as the dead- weight loss of the tax or the
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
212
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
213
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
214
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
215
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
216
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
217
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
218
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
219
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Applications of ICs: exchange between 2
individuals
• An important application of indifference curves is to explain the mutual
exchange between two individuals of two goods possessed by each.
• Suppose there are two individuals, A and B. Both individuals A and B
have some amount of goods X and Y. They are to exchange these goods
between themselves.
• with the help of indifference curves it can be proved that the exchange of
two goods between the two individuals will be of mutual advantage to
both of them, that is, the exchange of goods between the two individuals
will add to their combined welfare.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


220
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Applications of ICs: exchange between 2
individuals

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


221
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Applications of ICs: exchange between 2
individuals
• There are several points at which the indifference curves of two
individuals are tangent to each other.
• If all these tangency points between the two sets of indifference curves
are joined together we get a curve CC which is called the Contract Curve.
• It is at any point on this contract curve that the exchange or trade of
goods between the two individuals will take place.
• Further, it will be to the mutual advantage of the individuals to move from
a point away from the contract curve to a point on the contract curve.
• Since the initial distribution of two goods is that individual A has OM of
good X and ON of good Y and individual B has O′M′ of X and O′N′ of Y,
the two will be at point H in the Edgeworth Box.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


222
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Applications of ICs: exchange between 2
individuals
• Exchange of goods between the two individuals involved in moving from
point H to either L or K is to their advantage; it makes one better off
without making other worse off than before (that is, it increases the
welfare of one without reducing the welfare of the other).
• if they move from H to R, both individuals A and B are put at higher
indifference curves A3 and B3 respectively and both are better off than at
H where they are on their lower indifference curves A2 and B2
respectively.
• In welfare economics, the points on the contract curve are known as
Pareto optimum, since they indicate the situation of maximum social
welfare where no individual can be made better off without making other
worse off, and the points off the contract curve are known as Pareto sub-
optimum where there is possibility of making all individuals better off or
some better off without making others
For free counseling call us worse off.
on:-7880107880
223
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Applications of ICs: exchange between 2
individuals
• All points on the contract curve are not equally advantageous to both the
individuals.
• On the contract curve, where the two individuals will end up in their
exchange depends on their respective bargaining strengths which will
determine the rate of exchange between the two goods possessed by
them.
• Therefore that the trade or exchange between the two individuals will
ultimately take place at any point on the contract curve between K and L.
• Thus moving along the contract curve means the increase in the
satisfaction or welfare of one and reduction in the welfare of the other.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


224
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Applications of ICs: exchange between 2
individuals
• For assessing whether the aggregate welfare (that is combined welfare of
the two individuals) increases or decreases as we move along the
contract curve, we have to make interpersonal comparison of utility.
• So far as movement from a point off the contract curve to the point on
the contract curve is concerned, it definitely and unambiguously increases
the aggregate welfare of the two individuals.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


225
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Subsidy to consumers: price subsidy v/s
lump-sum grant
• Suppose that under food-subsidy programme,
the needed families are entitled to purchase
food at half the market price, the other half of
the market price is paid by the Government as
subsidy.
• The effect of this subsidy on consumer’s welfare
and money value of this subsidy to the
consumer is illustrated in Figure.
• Let us suppose that the individual has OP
money income. Given this money income and
given the market price of food, the budget line is
PL1.
• with subsidy the individual will face the budget
line PL2 where OL1 = L1L2. For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
226
Subsidy to consumers: price subsidy v/s
lump-sum grant
• With budget line PL2, the individual is in equilibrium at point R on the
indifference curve IC at which he is purchasing OA quantity of food. By
purchasing OA quantity of food, the individual is spending PT amount of
money.
• Now, if no food subsidy was given and therefore the budget line was PL1
then for buying OA quantity of food, the individual would have spent PN
amount of money.
• In other words, PN is the market price of OA quantity of food. Since PT
amount of money is paid by the individual himself, the remaining amount
TN or RM is paid by the Government as food subsidy for the individual.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


227
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Subsidy to consumers: price subsidy v/s
lump-sum grant
• What is the money value of this food subsidy (RM) to the individual?
• In order to find the money value of the subsidy to the individual, draw a
line EF parallel to PL1 so that it touches the same indifference curve IC
where the individual comes to be in equilibrium when subsidy is paid.
• budget line EF touches the indifference curve IC at a point S and is
buying OB quantity of food.
• This means that if individual is paid PE amount of money (say as a cash
grant), he reaches the same indifference curve IC (same level of welfare)
at which he is when subsidy is paid by the Government. Thus PE, is
money value of the subsidy to the individual.
• PE is less than RM which is the amount of money paid by the
Government as subsidy.
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
228
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Subsidy to consumers: price subsidy v/s
lump-sum grant
• If instead of giving RM as price subsidy on food, Government pays the
individual cash money equal to PE, the individual will reach the same
level of welfare as he does with RM subsidy.
• Thus, the money equivalent of the subsidy to the individual is less
than the cost of the subsidy to the Government.
• Thus the cost of giving subsidies to consumers is always greater than the
money equivalent of the subjective gain to the consumers”.
• “The value of the subsidy to the subsidised person is smaller than
the cost of subsidy to the Government. This is so whatever the shape
of a particular indifference curve as long as it has a smooth
curvature.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


229
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Subsidy to consumers: price subsidy v/s
lump-sum grant
• Now, if instead of providing price subsidy on food, the Government gives
lump-sum cash grant to the consumer equivalent to the cost of price
subsidy on food, what will be its impact on the individual’s welfare and
consumption of food by him.
• If the Government provides the consumer lump-sum cash grant of RM
instead of price subsidy on food, this will amount to increasing the money
income of the consumer by RM amount.
• With this extra cash transfer equal to RM (= PC), the budget line will shift
to the right to the position CD and pass through point R.
• With the budget line CD though the individual can buy the same market
basket R, if he so desires, which he was purchasing with price subsidy on
food, he is actually in equilibrium at point H on higher indifference curve
IC2.
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
230
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Subsidy to consumers: price subsidy v/s
lump-sum grant
• Thus, the cash transfer equivalent to the cost of price subsidy has led to
the greater increase in welfare or satisfaction of the individual as
compared to the price subsidy.
• With a cash grant the individual buys less food and more of other
goods relative to the situation under price subsidy with equivalent
monetary cost.
• In case of lump-sum cash transfer, the consumer will be better off
and consume less food relative to the equilibrium position under price
subsidy on food.
• Under cash grant, the individual is free to buy different goods
according to his own tastes and preferences which ensures higher
level of welfare as compared to the policy of price subsidy on food
which imposes a certain pattern of consumption favouring food.
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
231
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Rationing and indifference curve
analysis
• Indifference curve analysis can be used to explain under what conditions
rationing of goods by the Government can act as binding or a constraint
on consumer’s choices and further how it affects his welfare
• This budget constraint can be written as follows :
• Px.X + Py.Y ≤ M
• The above inequality implies that consumer can choose a combination of
goods from within or on the market opportunity set.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


232
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Rationing and indifference curve
analysis

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


233
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Rationing and indifference curve
analysis

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


234
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Income-leisure choice
• In economics leisure is regarded as a normal commodity the enjoyment of
which yields satisfaction to the individual.
• While leisure yields satisfaction to the individual directly, income
represents general purchasing power capable of being used to buy goods
and services for satisfaction of various wants. Thus income provides
satisfaction indirectly.
• Therefore, we can draw indifference curves between income and leisure,
both of which give satisfaction to the individual.
• However, the actual choice of income and leisure by an individual would
also depend upon what is the market rate of exchange between the two,
that is, the wage rate per hour of work. It is worth noting that wage rate is
the opportunity cost of leisure.
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
235
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Income-leisure choice
• Figure 11.14 displays income-leisure
equilibrium of the individual.
• With the given wage rate, the
individual will choose a combination
of income and leisure lying on the
income-leisure line MT that
maximises his satisfaction.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


236
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Need for higher over-time wage rate
• With the given wage rate and given trade-off
between income and leisure the individual
chooses to work for TL1 hours per day.
• To do overtime work, he will have to
sacrifice more leisure-time and therefore to
provide him incentive to forego more leisure
and thus to work for more hours it is
required to pay him higher wage rate.
• This is depicted in Figure11.15 where at the
equilibrium point E a steeper leisure- income
line EK than MT has been drawn. TL1 is the
hours worked at the wage rate w
represented by the slope of the income-
leisure line MT. For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
237
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Need for higher over-time wage rate
• If the higher overtime wage rate w’
represented by the line EK is fixed, the
individual is in equilibrium at point H on
indifference curve IC2 where he chooses to
have OL2 leisure time and OM2 amount of
income.
• Thus, he has sacrificed L1L2 more leisure to
do overtime work and earns M1M2 more
income than before.
• He now works for TL2 hours per day, TL1, at
hourly wage rate w and L1L2 at higher wage
rate w’.
• Further, he is better off than before as he is
now at higher indifferenceForcurve IC2.
free counseling call us on:-7880107880
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
238
Wage-offer curve and supply curve of
labour

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


239
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Backward bending supply curve of
labour
• on theoretical grounds it cannot be predicted which effect will be stronger.
• It has, however, been empirically observed that when the wage rate is
small so that the demand for more income or goods and services is very
strong, substitution effect is larger than the income effect so that the net
effect of rise in wage rate will be to reduce leisure and increase the supply
of labour.
• But when he is already supplying a large amount of labour and is earning
sufficient income, further increases in wage rate may induce the individual
to demand more leisure so that income effect may outweigh the
substitution effect at higher wage rates.
• This implies that at higher wage rates, labour supply may be reduced in
response to further rise in wage rates.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
240
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Backward bending supply curve of
labour
• This means up to a point substitution effect is stronger than income effect
so that labour supply curve slopes upward, but beyond that at higher
wage rates, supply curve of labour bends backward.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


241
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Welfare effects of direct and indirect
taxes
• An important application of indifference curves is to judge the welfare
effects of direct and indirect taxes on the individuals.
• In other words, if the Government wants to raise a given amount of
revenue whether it will be better to do so by levying a direct tax or an
indirect tax from the viewpoint of welfare of the individuals.
• an indirect tax such as excise duty, sales tax causes ‘excess burden’ on
the individuals, that is, indirect tax reduces welfare more than the direct
tax, say lump-sum tax, when an equal amount of revenue is raised
through them.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


242
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Welfare effects of direct and indirect
taxes

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


243
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Homogeneous functions
• a function f(x1 , x2 , ..., xn) is said to be homogeneous of degree k if

• The most important examples of homogeneous functions are those for


which k=1 or k=0.
• In words, when a function is homogeneous of degree one, a doubling of
all of its arguments doubles the value of the function itself.
• For functions that are homogeneous of degree 0, a doubling of all of its
arguments leaves the value of the function unchanged.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


244
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Homogeneous functions
• PYQ
• Consider the utility function U = xαyβ, α > 0, � > 0. which is to be
maximised subject to the budget constraint m = px.x + py.y, where m =
income (nominal) and px and py are the prices respectively per unit of the
goods X and Y.
Derive the demand function for X and Y. Show that these demand
functions are homogenous of degree zero in prices and income.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


245
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Indirect utility functions
• For a set of ’n’ commodities, the demand functions can be given as

• If we take the optimum values of X’s, we can write,


For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


246
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Indirect utility functions
• Because of the individual’s desire to maximize utility given a budget
constraint, the optimal level of utility obtainable will depend indirectly on
the prices of the goods being bought and the individual’s income.
• This dependence is reflected by the indirect utility function V .
• If either prices or income were to change, the level of utility that could be
attained would also be affected.
• Examples

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


247
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Expenditure function
• The expenditure function is derived from the problem of
minimizing the total expenditure necessary for the consumer to
achieve a specified level of utility u:

• we can write the Lagrange function for the problem (with μ as


the Lagrange multiplier) as

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


248
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Expenditure function
• the necessary conditions for a solution are

• In case of 2 goods, we can obtain the condition


푝� 푀 �
• = 
푝� 푀 �

• The problem confronting the utility-maximizing consumer is to move along


the budget line until the highest indifference curve is reached. The
expenditure-minimizing problem is to move along the indifference curve
until the lowest isoexpenditure line is reached.
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
249
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Expenditure function
• The optimal x*i in problem will depend on the prices and the utility level u:

• and Hi(p, u) is the Hicksian demand function for xi. Substituting the
optimal values of the xi in ∑ pixi gives

• m( p, u) is the expenditure function, showing the minimum level of


expenditure necessary to achieve a given utility level as a function of
prices and the required utility level.
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
250
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Expenditure function
• The optimal x*i in problem will depend on the prices and the utility level u:

• and Hi(p, u) is the Hicksian demand function for xi. Substituting the
optimal values of the xi in ∑ pixi gives

• m( p, u) is the expenditure function, showing the minimum level of


expenditure necessary to achieve a given utility level as a function of
prices and the required utility level.
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
251
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Expenditure function
• Properties of the expenditure function
• 1. The expenditure function is concave in prices.
• 2. The partial derivative of the expenditure function with respect to the ith
price is the compensated demand for the ith good.

• 3. The expenditure function is non-decreasing in the price vector p and


strictly increasing in at least one price. Higher prices mean higher
expenditure to reach a given utility.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


252
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Expenditure function
• 4. The expenditure function is homogeneous of degree 1 in prices.
• 5. The expenditure function is increasing in u.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


253
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Individual choice under risk and
uncertainty
• Risk
• The risk refers to a situation when the outcome of a decision is
uncertain but when the probability of each possible outcome is
known or can be estimated.
• The greater the variability of possible outcome, the greater the risk
involved in making the investment decision.
• Therefore, in the theory of choice or decision making under uncertainty it
is necessary to know the meaning of probability of outcome and its
variability.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


254
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Individual choice under risk and
uncertainty
• Uncertainty
• The uncertainty refers to the situation when there is more than one
possible outcome of a decision but where the probability of
occurrence of each particular outcome is not known or even cannot
be estimated. This may be due to lack of sufficient past information or
the great instability of the variables involved that determine the outcome.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


255
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
St. Petersburg Paradox and Bernoulli’s
hypothesis
• St. Petersburg paradox refers to the problem why most people are
unwilling to participate in a fair game or bet.
• For example, offer of participating in a gamble in which a person has even
chance (that is, 50-50 odds) of winning or loosing ` 1000 is a fair game.
• To put in mathematical terms, a gamble whose expected value is zero, or
more generally, the game in which the fee for the right to play is equal to
its expected value is a fair one.
• Thus, according to St. Petersburg in an uncertain game a most individuals
will not make a fair bet or, in other words, will not play the fair game.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


256
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
St. Petersburg Paradox and Bernoulli’s
hypothesis
• Daniel Bernoulli provided a convincing explanation of the said behaviour
of rational individual.
• According to him, a rational individual will take decisions under risky and
uncertain situations on the basis of expected utility rather than expected
monetary value.
• He further contended that marginal utility of money to the individual
declines as he has more of it.
• Since the individual behaves on the basis of expected utility from the
extra money if he wins a game and the marginal utility of money to him
declines as he has extra money, most individuals will not ‘play the game’,
that is, will not make a bet.
• It is in this way that Bernoulli resolved ‘St. Petersburg paradox’.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


257
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
St. Petersburg Paradox and Bernoulli’s
hypothesis
• Consider Figure l7.1 in which on the X-axis, the
quantity of money (thousands of rupees) and on
the Y-axis, marginal utility of money (rupees) to
an individual are measured.
• Suppose an individual has 20 thousands of
rupees with him and can make a bet at even odd
(i.e., 50-50 chance) of winning or losing rupees
one thousand.
• If he wins the bet, money with him will rise to 21
thousand (20 + 1) rupees.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


258
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
St. Petersburg Paradox and Bernoulli’s
hypothesis
• If as a result of an increase in money with him,
his expected marginal utility of money declines,
then the expected marginal utility of extra one
thousand rupees to him which is depicted by the
rectangle CDFE is less than the extra marginal
utility of the previous one thousand (i.e., 20th
thousand) rupees which is measured by the
rectangle ABDC.
• In other words, the gain in utility in case of his
winning the bet is less than the loss of utility in
case of his losing the bet, though the gain and
loss is the same in terms of monetary amount
(i.e., ` one thousand).

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


259
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
St. Petersburg Paradox and Bernoulli’s
hypothesis
• Thus, given the diminishing marginal utility of
money the expected gain in utility is less than
the expected loss of utility from one
thousand rupees involved in the bet, a
rational individual will therefore not make a
bet with 50-50 odds.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


260
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Utility theory and attitude towards risk
• People’s preferences toward risk greatly differ.
• Most individuals generally prefer the less risky situation (that is, the
situation with less variability in outcomes or rewards).
• In other words, most individuals seek to minimise risk and are called risk
averter or risk averse.
• However, some individuals prefer risk and are therefore called risk-
seekers or risk lovers.
• Some other individuals are indifferent toward risk and are called risk-
neutral.
• But it is important to note that these different preferences toward risk
depend on whether for an individual marginal utility of money
diminishes or increases or remains constant.
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
261
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Utility theory and attitude towards risk
• for a risk averse individual marginal utility of money diminishes as he
has more money, while for a risk-seeker marginal utility of money
increases as money with him increases. In case of risk-neutral
individual marginal utility of money remains constant as he has more
money.
• Risk Averter. To explain the attitude toward risk we will consider a single
composite commodity, namely, money income. An individual’s money
income represents the market basket of goods that he can buy.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


262
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Utility theory and attitude towards risk
• the utility function of the individual who is risk averter is concave towards
the income axis (i.e. X-axis) indicating that the though the total utility of
the risk-averse individual increases as his income increases but at a a
diminishing rate.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


263
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Choice of an individual under risk and
uncertainty
• Suppose the individual is currently employed on a fixed monthly salary
basis of ` 20,000. There is no uncertainty about the income from this
present job on a the fixed salary basis and hence no risk.
• Now, suppose that the individual is considering to join a new job of a
salesman on a commission basis. This new job involves risk because his
income in this case is not certain.
• This is because if he proves to be a successful salesman his income may
increase to ` 30 thousand per month but if he does not happen to be a
good salesman his income may go down to ` 10 thousand per month.
• Suppose in this new job there is 50-50 chance of either earning ` 30
thousands or ` 10 thousands (that is, each has a probability of 0.5).

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


264
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Choice of an individual under risk and
uncertainty
• But given the probabilities of alternative outcomes, we can calculate the
expected utility.
• Whether the individual will choose the new risky job or retain the present
salaried job with a certain income can be known by comparing the
expected utility from the new risky job with the utility of the current job.
• Given that the probability of success or failure as a salesman is 0.5, the
expected utility of the new job is given by

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


265
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Choice of an individual under risk and
uncertainty
• In the new risky job, the expected value of income is 20,000 which is
given by E(X) = 0.5 × 10,000 + 0.5 × 30,000 = ` 20,000.
• Corresponding to expected value of income of 20 thousands, the
expected utility is 60 (point D on the chord AC).
• Since the expected utility of the new risky job is less than the utility of the
present job with a certain income, he will reject the offer of new job
involving risk.
• Let us change the data, suppose the individual’s subjective probability of
proving to be a successful salesman is 90 per cent (i.e., probability of
being a successful salesman is 0.9), then given the above income data
and utility function (as shown in Fig. 17.3 (a)), then the expected utility
from joining the new job of a salesman on a commission basis is:

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
266
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Choice of an individual under risk and
uncertainty

• in these changed probabilities, the expected utility (equal to 72) of a


riskier choice is greater than the utility of a certain income of 20,000, the
individual even though he is risk-averse will choose the risker option.
• To conclude a risk averter will choose a riskier option only if it has a
sufficiently large expected value and therefore higher expected utility from
the new option.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


267
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Choice of an individual under risk and
uncertainty
• Risk Lover. On the other hand, a person is risk-preferer or risk-loving
who prefers a risky outcome with the same expected income as a
certain income. In case of a risk-loving individual, marginal utility of
income to the individual increases as his money income increases.
• Suppose this risk-loving individual has a present job with a certain income
of ` 20 thousands.
• It will be seen from Fig. 17.4 that the utility of ` 20 thousands is 43 units to
this individual.
• Now, if he is offered a risky job with his income of ` 30 thousands if he
happens to be highly efficient and ` 10 thousands if he happens to be not
so efficient in the new job with the equal probability of 0.5 in these two
jobs, then the expected utility from the new job is given by
• E(U) = 0.5 U (10,000) + 0.5 U (30,000)
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
268
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Choice of an individual under risk and
uncertainty
• It will be seen from Fig. 17.4 that the utility of ` 10 thousands to this
individual is 20 while utility of ` 30 thousands to him is 83. Therefore,

• Since the expected utility from the new risky job is 51.5 which is greater
than the utility of 43 from the present job with a certain income of ` 20
thousands, the risk-loving individual will prefer the new risky job even
though the expected income in the new risky job is also ` 20,000 as
(0.5 × 10,000) + 0.5 (30,000) = ` 20,000).

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


269
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Choice of a risk averse individual under
risk and uncertainty
• A person is called risk neutral, if he is indifferent between a certain
given income and an uncertain income with the same expected value.
• An individual will be risk neutral if his marginal utility of money income
remains constant with the increase in his money.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


270
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Choice of a risk averse individual under
risk and uncertainty
• utility of a certain income of ` 20 thousands is 80. Now, in a risky job when
income increases to ` 30 thousands if he proves to be a successful
salesman, the utility of ` 30 thousands is 120 units.
• On the other hand, if in a new risky job, he proves to be a bad salesman,
his income goes down to `10,000 whose utility to the individual is 40 units.
• Note that expected value of income in the new job with an uncertain
income is 20,000 as (0.5 × 10,000 + 0.5 (30,000) = 20,000. The expected
utility of the new risky job is given by

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


271
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Choice of a risk averse individual under
risk and uncertainty
• It is seen from above that in case of risk-neutral person expected utility of
an uncertain income with the same expected value (` 20,000 in the
present case), is equal to utility of an assured or a certain income. That is,
risk-neutral person is indifferent between them.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


272
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Risk aversion and insurance
• Most people are risk averters and therefore they buy insurance to avoid
risk.
• Now an important question is how much money or premium a risk-averse
individual will pay to the insurance company to avoid risk and uncertainty
facing him.
• Suppose the individual buys a house which yields him income of ` 30
thousands per month.
• But if the house catches fire and due to the damage caused, his income
from it falls to ` 10 thousands per month and thus he suffers a loss of
income.
• For the sake of simplifying analysis suppose there is 50 per cent chance
of the house catching fire. Then the expected value of income in this risky
and uncertain situation is
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
273
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Risk aversion and insurance
• It is important to note that expected income of ` 20,000 is the weighted
average of the two uncertain alternatives (30 thousands and 10
thousands) using their probabilities as weights.
• Further note that the expected income is not the actual income that a
person would get; it is weighted average of the two uncertain outcomes.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


274
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Risk aversion and insurance
• The utility function OU with a diminishing marginal utility of money income
of a risk- averse individual is shown in Fig. above.
• With money income of ` 30 thousands, his utility is 75 and with his lower
income of 10 thousands his utility is 45.
• Given that there is probability of 0.5 for each outcome, expected utility of
the two outcomes is given by

• we have drawn a straight line AB joining the utilities of 75 and 45. It is on


this straight line or chord AB that the amount of expected utility will be
corresponding to the expected value of income.
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
275
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Risk aversion and insurance
• On this straight line AB and corresponding to the expected value of
income of ` 20 thousands, the expected utility is 60 which corresponds to
point D on the straight line AB.
• But it will be seen from the individual’s utility function OU, that utility of 60
is equal to that of an assured and certain income of ` 16 thousands.
• Thus the individual with an expected uncertain income of ` 20 thousands
will be willing to forego ` 4 thousands (or DC) to get a certain or
guaranteed income of ` 16 thousands as the expected utility of uncertain
expected income of ` 20 thousands is equal to the utility of a certain
income of ` 16 thousands.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


276
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Risk aversion and insurance
• This means that if the individual gives up ` 4 thousands (20 – 16 = 4) from
his uncertain expected income he will get the same utility of 60 as with a
certain income of ` 16 thousands.
• ` 4 thousands equal to distance DC is called the risk premium. Therefore,
the risk premium is the amount of money that a risk-averse individual
will be willing to pay to avoid the risk.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


277
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Risk preference and gambling: risk
lover
• In sharp contrast to risk-averse individual, the risk lover or risk preferrer
will play a gamble.
• a risk lover prefers uncertain outcome having the same expected value of
income to the equivalent income with certainty. In case of risk preferring
or loving individual, marginal utility of money increases as his income
increases.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


278
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Risk preference and gambling: risk
lover
• In fig. 17.8 the N–M utility curve of a risk lover has been drawn that is
convex.
• The convexity of the utility curve implies that marginal utility of money
income increases as his money income increases.
• Now suppose that present income of the individual is 25 thousand rupees
and is offered a gamble with 50-50 chance of winning or losing ` 15
thousand rupees.
• Therefore, if he wins, his money income will rise to ` 40,000 and if be loses,
his money income will fall to ` 10 thousand rupees. The expected money
value of the gamble is given by

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


279
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Risk preference and gambling: risk
lover
• In order to find out the expected utility of 25 thousand rupees we draw a
chord AB which connects the utility M1A at income of ` 10 thousand and
utility M3B at income level of ` 40 thousand.
• Corresponding to the expected value of income of ` 25 thousand the
expected utility is M2D whereas point D lies on the chord AB
corresponding to income of ` 25 thousand.
• It will be seen from Fig. 17.8 that expected utility M2D of expected
income of ` 25 thousand is greater than the utility M2C of certain income
of ` 25 thousand.
• Since his expected utility from gamble is greater than that from his
income with certainty, he will accept the gamble. Further, it can be shown
that risk lover, a person whose marginal utility of money increases with
increase in his income will prefer a gamble having greater risk, that is, the
gamble which has a largerForvariability of outcome to a gamble with less
free counseling call us on:-7880107880
risk Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
280
Friedman-Savage Hypothesis
• Based on Neumann-Morgenstern cardinal utility analysis, Milton Friedman
and L. J. Savage in their well-known article put forward a hypothesis that
explains why the same persons buy insurance and also engage in
gambling.
• In buying insurance they seek to avoid risk and in engaging in gambling
they take risk. In other words, people behave both as risk averters (i.e.,
when they buy insurance), and also as risk lovers.
• Friedman and Savage abandoned Bernoullian hypothesis of diminishing
marginal utility of money for all ranges of income and instead adopted
another hypothesis.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


281
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Friedman-Savage Hypothesis
• According to Friedman-Savage hypothesis, for most people marginal
utility of money income diminishes up to a certain level of money
income, it increases from that middle level to a certain higher level of
money income and thereafter at very high levels of income it again
diminishes.
• With this hypothesis and using Neumann-Morgenstern Utility Curve
Friedman and Savage explain both types of behaviour of buying
insurance to avoid risk and of indulging in gambling and thereby to take
risks.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


282
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Friedman-Savage Hypothesis

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


283
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Friedman-Savage Hypothesis
• This implies that at the lower levels of income marginal utility of income of
the person diminishes and between middle incomes corresponding to
point E and F, marginal utility of income is increasing and beyond B
onwards marginal utility of income again diminishes with further increases
in income.
• Suppose the person’s present income is 35 thousand rupees which lies at
the concave part of the N–M utility curve corresponding to point C where
marginal utility of income is diminishing.
• Suppose the individual feels that he has a 50:50 chance of losing the sum
of money income equal to 30.
• This means that there is probability of 0.5 that he may have income of 35
and probability of 0.5 that his income may fall to 5 thousand rupees.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


284
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Friedman-Savage Hypothesis
• The person with diminishing marginal utility of money will try to avoid this
uncertain prospect (which is a kind of gamble) and will therefore buy
insurance to eliminate risk and thereby have an income with certainty
giving the insurance premium.
• Note that his expected value of income in this case is

• It will be seen from Figure 17.9 that expected utility from ` 20 thousand is
ML lying at chord AC which is less than utility MB of income of ` 20
thousand with certainty. To avoid risk, he can pay insurance premium LD
or 7.5 thousand to have certain income of ` 12.5 thousands.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


285
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Friedman-Savage Hypothesis
• Now, assume that the same person with the present income of ` 35
thousands is considering to buy a lottery ticket that offers him chance of
winning a large sum of money, say 40 thousand rupees, the first prize of
the lottery and thereby raising his income to ` 75 thousands.
• If he does not win, his income will fall to ` 30 thousands; 5 thousands
being the price of the lottery ticket.
• Now, if there is 20 per cent chance of winning the lottery, its expected
value will also be equal to 0.2 × 75 + 0.8 (30) = 15 + 24 = 39 and as it will
be seen from Figure 17.9 the expected utility from the sum of ` 39
thousands is M1R (note that point R lies on the straight line segment GH)
which is greater than utility M1K which he gets from income of ` 39
thousands with certainty.
• Thus, the person would purchase the lottery ticket, that is, he will gamble.
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
286
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Friedman-Savage Hypothesis
• Now, assume that the same person with the present income of ` 35
thousands is considering to buy a lottery ticket that offers him chance of
winning a large sum of money, say 40 thousand rupees, the first prize of
the lottery and thereby raising his income to ` 75 thousands.
• If he does not win, his income will fall to ` 30 thousands; 5 thousands
being the price of the lottery ticket.
• Now, if there is 20 per cent chance of winning the lottery, its expected
value will also be equal to 0.2 × 75 + 0.8 (30) = 15 + 24 = 39 and as it will
be seen from Figure 17.9 the expected utility from the sum of ` 39
thousands is M1R (note that point R lies on the straight line segment GH)
which is greater than utility M1K which he gets from income of ` 39
thousands with certainty.
• Thus, the person would purchase the lottery ticket, that is, he will gamble.
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
287
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Risk-return trade off and choice of a
portfolio
• For analysis of choice of a portfolio of assets by individuals or firms we
require to explain the concept of risk-return trade-off function which are
represented by indifference curves between degree of risk and rate of
return from investment.
• Each indifference curve or what is also called risk-return trade off curve
shows all those combinations of degree of risk (i.e. standard deviation)
and expected return that give the individual same level of utility.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


288
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Risk-return trade off and choice of a
portfolio
• Here 8 per cent is a risk-free return as corresponding to it standard
deviation (σ), which measures the level of risk, is zero.
• The difference between the required rate of return on a risky
investment and the return on risk-free investment is called risk
premium.
• For a more risk-averse individual the higher rate of return is required for a
risky investment with a given standard deviation.
• Therefore, for a more risk-averse manager risk-return trade- off curve will
be steeper than AU curve.
• Thus, with a more risk-averse individual, a steeper indifference curve or
risk-return trade-off curve AU′′ (dotted) has been drawn.
• Similarly, for a less risk-averse individual trade-off curve will be less steep
such as AU′ (dotted).
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
289
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Risk-return trade off and choice of a
portfolio
• Choice of a portfolio
• The individuals try to reduce risk by diversification. individuals investors
choose a portfolio of assets to reduce overall risk of their investment.
• To explain the choice of an optimum portfolio we need another concept
generally called a budget frontier.
• A budget frontier which represents the combinations of risk and
return that are obtainable with the given available funds from mixed
portfolios of two assets, say, shares of Reliance Industries and Tata
Steel.
• If a portion Wi of the given available funds are invested in Reliance
Industries and the remaining funds Wt are invested in Tata Steel, the
expected return of the portfolio of these two assets is given by

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


290
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Risk-return trade off and choice of a
portfolio

• Note that Wi +Wt =1 and different portfolios or combinations of two


assets will involve different degrees of risk (σ) and also yield different
returns. Note that rate of return from a portfolio is the weightage
average of the returns from the two assets.
• Budget frontier BF which shows the combinations or portfolios of two
assets which are obtainable with the given funds.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


291
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Risk-return trade off and choice of a
portfolio
• Budget frontier BF which shows the combinations or
portfolios of two assets which are obtainable with
the given funds.
• Budget frontier BF is tangent to the trade-off
function curve U2 at point E which represents the
optimum portfolio of two assets which yield return of
rp and involve a risk (σ) of 1.0.
• The combination of two assets represented by E is
an optimally diversified portfolio containing a mix of
the two assets.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


292
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Risk-return trade off and choice of a
portfolio

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


293
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Risk-return trade off and choice of a
portfolio

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


294
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Neumann-Morgenstern method of
constructing utility index under risky
conditions
• Neumann- Morgenstern method seeks to assign a utility number, or in
other words, construct a N–M utility index of the marginal utility of money
which a person gets from extra amounts of money income.
• The choices by an individual under risky and uncertain situations depend
on the N–M utility index (i. e., expected numerical utilities) and changes in
it with the changes in money income.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


295
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Neumann-Morgenstern method of
constructing utility index under risky
conditions
• Assumptions
• it is assumed that the individual possesses a scale of preferences that is
quite comprehensive and complete.
• unlike the indifference curve analysis of demand, the question here is the
choices of “events”. The events refer to the amounts of money some of
which are “certain” and others uncertain, monetary amounts with
probabilities or odds attached to them.
• Secondly, it is assumed that the individual can always say whether he
prefers one event to another or he is indifferent between the two.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


296
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Neumann-Morgenstern utility index
• Suppose the purchase of a lottery ticket is under consideration of an
individual.
• Let the prize be ` 5,000 which he will get if he wins and suppose if he
loses, he will get the consolation prize of ` 10.
• Further, suppose that odds are 60:40, that is, the probability of his
winning is 0.6 and the probability of his losing (and therefore getting the
consolation prize) is 0.4.
• With this the expected monetary value (generally called standard acturial
evaluation) of lottery ticket;
• = π (W) + (1 – π) F
• where π stands for probability of winning and W the monetary amount of
the first prize and (1 – π) the probability of his losing and therefore of
getting the consolation prize of the monetary value of F.
For free counseling call us on:-7880107880
297
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Neumann-Morgenstern utility index
• In our above numerical example, expected monetary value of lottery ticket
• = 0.6 (5000) + (0.4) 10
• = 3,000 + 4
• = 3,004.
• But, as said above, Neumann and Morgenstern seek to measure the
expected utility from the monetary gain rather than the expected value of
monetary gain itself.
• Thus the problem is to convert the monetary value of gains into expected
utility terms.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


298
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Neumann-Morgenstern utility index
• In N-M utility analysis, the lottery ticket would be evaluated from the
following formula.
• Expected utility of the above lottery ticket with the aforesaid two prizes =
π.U(W) + (1 – π) . U(F)
• where U(W) is the expected utility of the first prize in case of winning and
U(F) the utility of the consolation prize, if he loses. Thus in our above
numerical example, the expected utility of lottery ticket is:
• = 0.6 × U(5,000) + 0.4 × U(10)
• Now in Neumann and Morgenstern method we have to assign utility
numbers to ` 5,000 and ` 10 arbitrarily and then with reference to these,
utility of a certain sum of money has to be evaluated.

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


299
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Neumann-Morgenstern utility index
• Let the utility of ` 5,000 to the individual be 500 utils and `10 be
1 util. With this the expected utility of the above lottery ticket is
• = 0.6 × 500 utils + 0.4 × 1 util = 300 utils + .4 util
= 300.4 utils

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


300
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in
Can’t get enough??? We know. For more information just scan the QR code.

Visit us on:

www.ecoholics.in
Download our App

http://ecoholics.in/mobile-app/

For free counseling call us on:-7880107880


301
Visit our website: www.ecoholics.in

You might also like