Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 18

16

Conflict Resolution
and Negotiation
I. William Zartman

Negotiation, the process of combining con- Faure 2005). It may block agreement that
flicting positions into a joint agreement, is would permit cooperation to resolve a prob-
synonymous with conflict resolution, and is lem, or it may continue to rise to the point
the most common (although not the only) of violence. Conflict continues to escalate
way of preventing, managing, resolving, and until one of three outcomes are reached:
transforming conflicts. Indeed, there is little victory of one side, painful stalemate forcing
negotiation that does not have to do with the parties to consider deescalation, and
conflict resolution. If one adopts a rational stable stalemate. Thus, negotiation as conflict
choice definition of war or violent conflict as resolution may be used to prevent conflict
bargaining failure (Fearon 1995; Reiter 2003), from escalating or from turning violent; it
then successful bargaining or negotiation is may be used to manage conflict—that is
the means of preventing or resolving violent deescalate the means of its pursuit from
conflict. violence to politics; or it may be the means
Such an understanding requires a return to actually resolve the basic incompatibilities
to the antecedent notion of conflict. Conflict of positions or to transform them into
arises from incompatible positions; it is cooperative relationships.
ubiquitous, and not especially troublesome— Since World War II, negotiation to produce
worthy of resolution—in its static phase a peace agreement has accounted for only
(Coser 1956; Aron 1957; Bernard 1957; about a sixth of the inter- and intrastate
Schelling 1960; Powelson 1972; Pruitt & conflicts terminated and an eighth of those
Kim 2004). But when conflict becomes active temporarily managed in a ceasefire, together
and the parties take measures to make their accounting for something less than the number
particular position prevail, it does become terminated by victory of one side over the
troublesome; thus, escalation is the active other. Fully a quarter of those conflicts
form of conflict (Smoke 1977; Zartman & terminated by a conflict-resolving peace
CONFLICT RESOLUTION AND NEGOTIATION 323

Table 16.1 Conflict outcomes over time, 1946–2005


Victory Peace Accord Ceasefire Other Total Ended Ongoing
1946–50 17 3 0 9 29 41
1951–55 6 4 1 4 15 27
1956–60 8 5 1 9 23 36
1961–65 11 4 4 6 25 47
1966–70 11 3 3 10 27 47
1971–75 11 4 4 7 26 51
1976–80 11 1 1 4 17 52
1981–85 9 1 1 10 21 59
1986–90 12 4 4 22 42 79
1991–95 14 14 12 30 70 96
1996–2000 6 7 10 21 44 75
2001–05 4 7 6 16 33 66
All episodes 120 57 47 148 372
Source: Kreutz 2006

agreement during this period occurred in the two types are irreconcilably different and
immediate aftermath of the Cold War and only the case of violent conflict resolution
another quarter in the decade since then. An need be considered here, they are integrally
equal number were terminated by a simple tied together by the fact that untreated
conflict-managing ceasefire during the same problems of cooperation may turn violent
period. or may give rise to secondary violence.
These distinctions are all subsumed under In addition, negotiation analysis is often
the label of conflict resolution as used in equally relevant to cooperative and (violent)
this volume but they break down into two conflict negotiations, even though at times
very distinct negotiation subtypes (Zartman the distinction becomes analytically important
2007). Negotiating can be used to deal with and will be highlighted below at those
conflict in the more common sense of reduc- junctures. Other distinctions in the type of
ing violence, either by deescalating violent conflict, between intrastate and interstate, may
conflict or by preventing impending vio- also have an impact that will be noted where
lence from occurring: peace-making, peace relevant.
enforcement, and part of peace-building, Given the relation of negotiation to conflict
in UN Secretary-General Boutros Boutros resolution, this chapter will focus on the
Ghali’s (1994) operative distinctions. But it is ways in which negotiation is studied, in
also used in building cooperation, to reduce order to bring out current advances in
incompatibilities in positions even where no the conceptualization of the subject and to
violence is involved, for conflict prevention highlight salient questions and areas where
or conflict transformation. Cooperative nego- further advances are needed (Jönsson 2000;
tiations contain conflicts too or else there Telhami 2002; Carnevale & deDreu 2004).
would be no need for negotiation, but they To do so, it will use as a framework
are not impelled by impending prospects of the categorization of analytical frameworks
violence (Taylor 1987; Stein 1990; Stein & into structural, strategic, processual, and
Pauly 1993; Zartman & Touval 2008). In behavioral (Zartman 1988; Hopmann 1996;
addition, cooperative negotiations are most Kremenyuk 2003). The following review will
frequently multi- (or pluri-) lateral and only especially emphasize the practical value of
recently have been subject to systematic conceptual findings for the better achievement
analysis, whereas bilateral negotiations have of conflict resolution, in the belief that the
been the subject of most advanced theo- purpose of theory is to inform understanding
rization. While one might object that the and improve practice.
324 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF CONFLICT RESOLUTION

Within the definition as the process of their influence both for the smooth conduct
combining conflicting positions into a joint and for the breakdown of negotiations.
agreement, negotiation has certain character- But first, the question of Why negotiate?
istics that distinguish it from the two other needs to be addressed, before discussing the
basic types of decision-making, voting (coali- question, How negotiate? While parties—
tion) and adjudication (hierarchy) (Zartman states, groups or individuals—generally pre-
1978; Lewicki et al. 2003, 4–6). It operates fer to resolve their problems unilaterally,
under a decision rule of unanimity, with where they can be in control of decisions
a three-fold choice: yes, no, or continue and do not have to bend to other parties’
negotiating (Ikle 1964). It creates a positive- interests, they find they have to involve
sum outcome, in that no party would agree others when resolution of the problem or
to the outcome unless it feels itself to conflict is beyond their unilateral means.
be better off than without an agreement Resolution may mean ending a conflict with
(its security point). Thus, negotiation involves another party or overcoming a problem that
an exchange of goods rather than a unilateral needs the participation of another party;
victory: negotiation is giving something to it may mean ending a costly situation or
get something, so it involves moves by creating a beneficial one. However, since
both/all sides, although not necessarily to an there are a number of ways to provide
equal degree. It can be conducted in one of social decisions with their own decision rules,
three ways: concession, compensation, and including voting and hierarchy, parties resort
construction (reframing). Power in the process to negotiation when there is no authoritative
lies not in numbers or in authority but in hierarchy and no decision rule of division.
alternatives (security point, again) and in Those conditions describe the anarchy of
persuasion. the international relations system and the
The negotiation process operates under a informality of personal relations. In addition,
loose bundle of norms that can be termed parties turn to negotiation when they want a
the Ethos of Equality. Like any norm, this sense of ownership over the outcome, which
ethos is not absolute, but it does underlie neither voting nor hierarchy provides (at least
the conduct of negotiation around the world in the same measure).
(Faure 2002). It begins with the formal Between the inability unilaterally to end
structural equality of the parties, based on the (i.e. win) the conflict or solve the problem and
fact that each has a veto over any agreement; the decision to negotiate (and then to agree on
therefore, the parties need to grant each the terms created) bi- or multilaterally lies a
other recognition with equal standing in the large area of indecision, dominated primarily
negotiations. From this, it extends to the by the cost of alternatives, above all the cost of
behavioral setting that facilitates exchanges continued conflict or unsolved problems. The
through the courtesy of symmetry that each cost/benefit value of what a party can obtain
party gives the other, even if the encounter is without negotiating has many names, includ-
asymmetrical in other terms. The ethos also ing security point, best/worst alternative to
covers the process, where requitement—the a negotiated agreement (BATNA/WATNA),
sense that concessions will be reciprocated— reservation price, threat point, and others,
is expected. While the overarching principles and is the most important reference point in
of any agreement, or formula, are the primary understanding and conducting a negotiation
subject of any negotiation, they always refer (Pillar 1983). It is the source of relative
to some mutually agreed notion of justice, the power and determines whether a party can
basis of which is equality or equalizing, what- play it tough or soft in negotiating (tough,
ever the specific referent (Zartman et al. 1996; if the security point is close to the expected
Korm 1998). Neglected or ignored though outcome; soft, if the gap is great and there
they may be in any particular negotiation, is much benefit to gain or much loss to
these elements of the ethos of equality have be protected) (Kahneman & Tversky 1979;
CONFLICT RESOLUTION AND NEGOTIATION 325

Zartman 2006). If the estimated gap between deserves a separate treatment, fully presented
the two is too small, parties are likely to let the in the next chapter by Jacob Bercovitch.
unresolved conflict or problem continue, and Mediation turns the dyadic relation between
may even bog down in an S5 situation (soft, the parties into a triad, in which the third
stable, self-serving stalemate). angle serves to facilitate negotiation between
the other two by overcoming the obstacles
which keep them from negotiating directly.
STRUCTURE Power at the hands of a mediator is (for
some unknown reason) termed leverage and
Structural approaches explain outcomes of it comes in limited amounts and forms,
negotiation by examining the distribution all of them ultimately dependent on the
of the parties’ means of attaining them, parties’ need for a settlement (again in
frequently referred to as power.1 Power can comparison to their security point). The forms
be thought of as exercises or measures of of leverage, in general order of availability, are
contingent gratification and deprivation that persuasion, limitation (closing alternatives),
a party attaches to negotiating offers and extraction (getting one party to articulate a
security points in order to change their value, solution attractive to the other), termination
the elements which provide an ability of the (mediator’s threat to leave), and again (but
parties to move each other in an intended least available) gratification and deprivation.
direction (Dahl 1951; Zartman & Rubin Assistant Secretary of State Chester Crocker
2000). Yet very little is known about the (1992) made sure that his mediation was
relative merits and moments of gratification “the only game in town,” urged the parties
(promises) vs deprivation (threats), or about to “make an offer,” and threatened to end
the dynamics associated with security points, mediation on occasion, but had little to offer
other than that they are important, in analysis in the way of carrots and sticks, and was
and in practice. Where continued conflict is left above all with the power of persuasion,
the parties’ shared security point, the parties comparing an agreement to the cost of
in negotiation seek to provide a better alter- continued conflict. Similar arguments can be
native (gratification) or to make continuing wielded by the parties themselves.
conflict more costly (deprivation) (Zeuthen Structure refers primarily to the relative
1930; Jönsson 1981; Zartman and Touval position of perceived power of the parties.
2007). The use of deprivation (coercion) is It is known that a sense of equality, or
generally associated with distributive or zero- symmetry, is beneficial to the efficient and
sum bargaining, and of gratification (benefits) effective achievement of results, and nego-
with integrative or positive-sum bargaining tiators are well advised to cultivate that
(Hopmann 1996, 2001; Wagner 2007). It is sense so they can move from tending the
likely that both are necessary, a fact often atmospherics to resolving the problem. But,
forgotten. in fact, symmetry is nonexistent in the real
When the parties are not able to change world; even close equals are never sure of
each other’s calculus to provide a jointly their relative position and parties base their
acceptable alternative to violence, they may perceptions on different aspects of power. All
require the services of a mediator (Wall, negotiations are asymmetrical, to a greater or
Stark & Sandifer 2001). Mediation is con- lesser degree; there is no absolute equality
sidered here to be a subset of negotiation, in the real world, equality between parties,
an activity made necessary by the inability and parties that are nearly or presumptively
of the conflicting parties to overcome their equal will spend much of their time protecting
conflict and produce a joint agreement on that equality or seeking to overturn it in
their own; it is, however, such an important their favor. While symmetry has long been
subset, with its own characteristics provided thought to be the most favorable situation
by the presence of a third party, that it for efficient and effective negotiations, both
326 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF CONFLICT RESOLUTION

social psychology and political science have negotiation setting to its formal equality, in
recently shown that its real-world equivalent, which each party holds a veto. The other
near-symmetry (small asymmetry), is the element, which often underlies commitment,
least productive structure because the parties is justice. Even when outgunned, parties may
will spend most of their time and effort hold out because they hold their cause to
in position politics, seeking to maintain or be just, and negotiators have been known to
upset (and therefore counter-maintain) the turn down deals offered by stronger parties
near-symmetry (Hornstein 1965; Vitz & Kite because they were judged unjust. Mexicans
1970; Hammerstein & Parker 1982; Pruitt & offered a fair market price for their gas by the
Carnevale 1993; Zartman & Rubin 2000). USA rejected the deal because they were not
Asymmetrical parties know their roles and getting a price they considered just by rather
goals and seek absolute gains, whereas rivals extraneous criteria and so lost any income at
at any level of the totem pole contest each all (Odell 2000), and despite repeated painful
other’s position and seek relative gains at the impasses. India and Pakistan reject a salient
other’s expense (Powell 1991). solution (along the Line of Control) for the
Weaker parties have a potential array of Kashmir dispute because both consider it
means at their disposal to reduce the degree unjust.
of asymmetry, by borrowing power from Power structures also operate within insti-
third parties, opponents, context, and process tutional structures, which can have important
(Zartman & Rubin 2000). Whether the conflict effects on power relations. Much of the
is interstate or intrastate, parties weaker in work in this approach has been done on
power also tend to overcome their power multilateral, cooperative negotiations rather
deficit by emphasizing commitment. Smaller than on violent conflicts. States institutional-
parties tend to concentrate on a single issue ize their relations into international regimes,
whereas larger parties are burdened by many informal and formal, in order to reduce
issues and are easily distracted; the latter transaction costs, and such regimes both
focus on setting the formula for a solution at expand and limit their negotiating possi-
the beginning of the negotiations, leaving the bilities (Hasenclever, Mayer & Rittberger
smaller partner to win back initial losses in 1997; Jönsson and Talberg 1998; Spector &
the detail phase (Crump and Zartman 2003). Zartman 2003). Regimes provide information,
In intrastate conflicts, the government has monitor progress, expand linkages, establish
the structural advantage but the conditions agendas, and generally reduce uncertainties
and tactics are the same, as the rebellion and regulate expectations; but they also limit
emphasizes commitment and concentrates options and strategies (Odell 2005). In this,
on recognition— formal symmetry—as its they tend to equalize member parties and
goal and the key to its equality (Zartman reduce asymmetries. Multilateral bargaining
1995). The role of imperfect information (and analysis) also depends largely on the
in conflict decisions between asymmetrical formation of temporary, informal institutions
parties is currently the subject of a surge such as party and issue coalitions, involving
of rational choice literature, but it ignores some very distinct strategies, typologies, and
negotiations, assuming bargaining failure negotiations (Hampson 1994; Zartman 1994,
instead of exploring it. 2006; Sebenius 1996; Bottom et al. 2000;
Weaker parties also have other elements Nalikar 2003; Crump & Zartman 2003; Odell
outside the power structure that can compen- 2005).
sate for their weaker position. One, already Since institutions have their own rules,
noted, is commitment, the determination to relations and constraints, drawn in turn from
overcome odds. Since power is sometimes their own internal structures and from their
characterized as “resources + skill + will,” relative positions toward each other, they
commitment emphasizes the last element can have an important impact on nego-
over the first. Commitment also returns the tiators’ capabilities. The European Union,
CONFLICT RESOLUTION AND NEGOTIATION 327

for example, is essentially an institutional- exist a set of negotiated agreements that have
ized negotiating system where outcomes are greater utility for both sides than the gamble of
strongly affected by the paths the process is war…So to explain…war,…why might states
required to take, although it has only rarely fail either to locate or to agree on an outcome
been analyzed as such (Meerts & Cede 2003; in this range …?” The subsequent work in the
Elgström & Jönsson 2005). An enormous field intervening decade then focuses on bargaining
of inquiry is opened by other institutionalized failures without looking at the bargaining
negotiation fora, from the UN Security process itself and explaining its outcomes.
Council and the World Trade Organization Yet the basic presentations of Prisoners’
(WTO) (and other agencies) (Odell 2006) Dilemma (PDG) and the lesser-used Chicken
to regional organizations (Rothchild 1997) Dilemma Games (CDG) launched a whole
to national legislatures, constituting a rich body of literature on negotiation. In these
subject for negotiation analysis of conflict meta-games, both power and process were
resolution, much the same way as behavioral explicitly excluded, the outcome being
analysis overtook judicial studies or socio- explained by the values assigned to various
economic analysis electoral studies. outcomes (Nash 1950, 1953; Powell 2002;
Another form of structural analysis that has Avenhaus & Zartman 2007). Again, the
developed some insights in regard to coop- analysis showed that for parties caught in
erative negotiations concerns the negotiatory a perceived PDG situation, the determinate
relation between the negotiations and their outcome or Nash equilibrium is not to
domestic constituencies in two-level games. negotiate, lest their concession leave them
The approach has not been used as much open to be zapped by the other party. As
as possible in regard to either interstate or a result, the challenge of negotiation is
intrastate conflicts (Druckman 1978; Evans, to find ways of building trust that would
Jacobson & Putnam 1993; Putnam 1998). establish requitement, the sense that conces-
The idea that negotiating parties need also sions will be reciprocated. The best known
negotiate with their home constituencies and device is to establish a reputation in order
reach an agreement on the domestic level that to “teach requitement” by opening “soft”
corresponds to the parameters of an agreement with a concession and playing Tit-for-Tat
on the inter-party level is as applicable to thereafter (Cross 1969; Bartos 1978; Axelrod
conflict negotiations as to cooperation. It 1984; Brams 1990). The analysis coincided
opens up a window of enormous complexity, with the introduction of GRIT (Gradual
however, when relating to intrastate civil Reciprocation in Tension Reduction) strategy
wars, where the internal politics of rebel by Charles Osgood (1962) during the Cold
movements are often inchoate at best. For that War. If it had questionable application during
very reason, analysis would be useful, even if the Cold War, Tit for Tat could be seen
difficult. in as diverse negotiations as those later
on in South Africa and Macedonia. Other
ways of establishing trust include making
STRATEGY public commitments, negotiating with institu-
tional frameworks, signing enforceable con-
Contrasted with structural analysis’ focus on tracts, and employing a mediator (Schelling
means as the explanatory concept, strategic 1960).
analysis uses the rational choice of ends as Although it has limited direct use for
its terms of analysis, as portrayed in game portraying situations of negotiation, PDG is a
theory and other rational choice approaches. cartoon portrayal of many situations of inter-
Unfortunately, the rational choice work on national conflict that long defy negotiation,
negotiation has literally fled from the subject as discussed by Avenhaus in this volume.
through its assumptions as well as its analysis. Its popularity was doubtless enhanced by its
As Fearon (1995, p 390) posits, “There should accurate depiction of the Cold War in general
328 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF CONFLICT RESOLUTION

(“Better dead than Red”), although by that is unlikely to be welcomed in situations of


fact it inhibited or hid real possibilities of sharp conflict over indivisibles or over non-
East–West negotiation (Kanet & Kolodziej tradables, situations where process ownership
1991). Another situation captured by PDG is important, or situations where the stakes
has been the Arab–Israeli conflict, but here include high political commitment, in other
the delicate process of getting around the words, most intrastate and many interstate
dilemma by establishing trust and requitement conflicts. In this as in other types of
is well exemplified in the tactics leading to and formal modeling for and of negotiation, the
through the Oslo Agreement of 1993 (Pruitt analysis removed from real world relevance
1996), subsequently abandoned. PDG also by its absence of process, often based on
accurately captures such territorial conflicts Rubenstein’s (1982) take-it-or-leave-it games
as the Indo-Pakistani conflict over Kashmir that avoid Ikle’s (1964) basic three-fold choice
and the Morocco–Algeria conflict over the (yes, no, keep on talking) as the essence of
Western Sahara, among others. There is a huge negotiation.
literature on the role of mediators as a crutch The task of assigning end values and
of trust to permit negotiation, covered in the rankings is often difficult enough but a more
following chapter by Bercovitch. precise analysis requires identification of
Another important way of escaping the cardinal values for outcomes, which tends
inhibitions of the PDG is to change the game, toward the impossible, at least in non-
through a reevaluation of the end values. One monetary cases of conflict. An additional
important change is to a CDG, wherein the complication has been introduced by a
worst outcome is deadlock (mutual defection significant reinterpretation of end values,
or security point) rather than being zapped termed prospect theory (Farnham 1992;
by the opponent (“Better Red than dead”). Tversky & Kahneman 1995; MacDermott
Here there is no determinate outcome but 2007). Prospect theory indicates that losses
two Nash equilibria favoring each party, are more highly valued than gains, that parties
respectively, creating a coordination rather are more risk-taking over losses and risk-
than a collaboration problem (Snyder & averse over gains, and that the referent frames
Diesing 1977; Stein 1983 Wagner 1999). But that parties use determine the comparative
CDG like PDG is a situation of perceived value of ends. These considerations make
symmetry, so another change in the game end-based analysis much less reliable while
would be to introduce asymmetry and thus introducing tactical elements that are crucial
power. This represents the tactic used by to effective negotiation.
the USA under President Kennedy to end Another way of analyzing negotiation using
the Cuban Missile standoff (1962) and by game theoretic concepts is to focus on the
President Reagan to end the Cold War in 1989 strategies of the parties, their “general plan[s]
(Brams 1985). of action containing instructions as to what
The study of end value asymmetry has to do in every contingency” (Shubik 1964,
given rise to a large literature sometimes p. 13) or “the overall orientation adopted
termed negotiation analysis or models for by an actor to achieve his goal,” as defined
negotiation which seeks to obviate the lengthy by Faure in his chapter. Most strategies in
and inefficient process of negotiation by conflict resolution are mixed and therefore
indicating fair outcomes based on end values hard to capture in rigorous analysis, but they
assigned by the parties (Young 1994; Raiffa lie between the two poles of distributive
with Richardson & Metcalfe 2003; Brams & or value-taking and integrative or value-
Taylor 1996). While such a procedure might making, departures from the usual minimax
be of use in arbitration-type situations of a strategy (Lax & Sebenius 1986). Research on
CDG, where any end of conflict is preferable these strategies has primarily been on coop-
to continuing conflict but where the parties erative multilateral negotiations, where the
are satisfied by a division deemed fair, it differences often appear clearly: minilateral
CONFLICT RESOLUTION AND NEGOTIATION 329

interest-based coalitions conglomerate their rebellion turn to confrontation, in combat and


way into larger aggregations bargaining for diplomacy (although the two work against
future gains, maximizing positive-sum out- each other) (Stedman 1991; Zartman 1995,
comes and using promises and predictions 2006). However, at this stage, if victory or
as exercises of power, whereas maxilateral negotiation do not take place, the rebellion
or hegemon-based coalition accrete their way often turns inward, using its means as ends,
to dominance, using threats and warnings, and enters a phase of Greed that is much less
trading security for support, avoiding losses amenable to negotiation (Collier et al. 2003;
rather than focusing on gains (Chasek 1997; Arnson & Zartman 2005).
Baç 2000, 2001; Crump & Zartman 2003; Parties consider positively the notion of
daConceição-Heldt 2006; Narlikar & Odell conflict resolution through direct or mediated
2006; Odell 2006). However, in conflict- negotiation when they perceive the conditions
type negotiations, Richard Holbrooke tended of ripeness (Touval 1982; Touval & Zartman
toward the distributive pole at Dayton, 1985; Zartman 1982, 1989, 1995, 2000;
whereas George Mitchell mediated integra- Gregg 2001). Ripeness occurs when the
tively at Belfast (Curran et al. 2004); non- parties feel that they can no longer expect
mediated examples, especially of integrative to win the conflict through escalation (or
strategies, are harder to find. simply holding out) at an acceptable cost
and that there is a possibility of a jointly
acceptable solution. These two conditions,
PROCESS termed a Mutually Hurting Stalemate (MHS)
and a Way Out (WO), are perceptional and
Negotiation is a process, and its outcome subjective, although they generally have an
can be best explained—and hence obtained— objective referent. Ripeness is a necessary
by process analysis: “Where you get is a but insufficient condition for negotiations to
function of how you get there,” as Henry begin; it has to be seized and acted upon.
Kissinger was to have said. “How you get In order to reach a successful conclusion,
there,” however, is in turn a function of the elements need to be reversed: the parties
two processes, the conflict process and the need to turn the WO into a Mutually Enticing
negotiation process. The conflict process leads Opportunity complementing the push factor
to a decision to negotiate when the conflict of the MHS with a pull factor that draws
is ripe. The ensuing negotiation process then the parties to a conclusion (Mitchell 1995;
goes through a succession of stages, whose Pruitt & Olczak 1995; Ohlson 1998).
proper accomplishment makes for a coherent Ripeness was found in the mediated
agreement that maximizes the payoffs for the negotiations that resolved the South West
parties involved. African conflict in 1988 (Crocker 1992) and
Active conflict or escalation typically the Salvadoran conflict in 1989 (deSoto 1992)
contains sets of steps to negotiation. One and in the direct negotiation in South Africa in
begins with a stage of petition (or diplomacy, 1990–94 (Sisk 1995). It was carried through
in interstate conflicts), where grievances are to a minimal outcome (agreeing formula) in
broadly felt as Needs and the aggrieved party Nagorno Karabagh (Mooradian & Druckman
seeks to negotiate redress, recognizing the 2003) and to more or less resolving formulas
government’s authority. The protest moves in Dayton in 1993 (Holbrooke 1998), in the
on to consolidation, where the rebellion Israeli disengagements (Rubin 1982) and the
turns inward to build its own solidarity Israeli–Egyptian Washington Treaty (1979).
and unity; often using identity or Creed to Ripeness was absent in the failed Carter
articulate the grievances and to build support; mediation between Eritrea and Ethiopia in
negotiation is unlikely and antithetical to 1990 (Ottaway 1995) and Clinton mediation
the rebellion’s focus at this stage. Only between Palestine and Israel in 2000 (Enderlin
when consolidation is completed can the 2002), and was present but not seized in
330 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF CONFLICT RESOLUTION

Liberia in 1990 or Lebanon in 1976 (Zartman never answered (Jones 2001; Leader 2001).
2005). But the absence of the IRA on one side
Once it has become a perceived option and the DUP and the UKUP on the other
by the parties, either directly or through the made the Good Friday Agreement possible in
help of a mediator, negotiation typically goes 1998 (Curran & Sebenius 2003). In between,
through its own process involving a number excluded parties at the Arusha negotiations on
of stages and turning points (Zartman & Burundi after 2000 were gradually brought
Berman 1982; Bendahmane & McDonald in as the agreement evolved. Similarly, the
1986; Druckman 1986, 2001; Hopmann question of what issues to include without
1996). These may overlap and parties may breaking the back of an agreeable agenda is
backtrack; their passage maybe explicit or also crucial; it is unlikely that the Jerusalem
implicit; but their functions need to be question could have been included at Oslo
observed or else the negotiations will fail or or the Kosovo question at Dayton, but the
produce an incoherent result. decision to put off a resolution of Brcko
The first stage is diagnosis, without which at Dayton (1994) and of the Panguna mine
the parties cannot get the most out of at Arawa (2001) were the keys to the
the negotiations for themselves and at the last lock on the Bosnian and Bougainville
same time find terms of agreement that are agreements.
acceptable to the other party. Parties need to Although diplomats may assume that
answer such questions as: What are my real such preparation is natural to negotiation,
interests in this conflict, as opposed to stated it is frequently neglected. A comparison
positions (Fisher & Ury 1985)? What is my of President Carter’s (1979) and President
security point? What is this conflict like? How Clinton’s (2000) preparation for their Camp
were other similar conflicts handled?And then David Mideast negotiations goes far to explain
similar questions need to be ascertained from the relative success of the first and the
the other side’s point of view. Parties must failure of the second. Rebel groups often need
also—separately or jointly—establish such training in negotiation, beginning with the
preparatory elements as: parties to be included diagnosis phase, as the painful experiences
and issues to be covered in negotiation, risks of Renamo in Mozambique leading up to
and costs incurred in negotiating, support for the 1990 negotiations, the Tamil Tigers in
resolving rather then pursuing the conflict, and Sri Lanka leading up to the 2005 ceasefire,
preliminary contacts (Stein 1995). and the Lord’s Resistance Army in Uganda
Parties and issues are some of the most diffi- leading up to the 2006 negotiations all show,
cult prenegotiation problems. While agreeing among others.
that negotiations among both sides’moderates The second phase is one of formulation.
only are likely to leave the mass of the Negotiators do not immediately start estab-
rebellion outside the agreement, scholarship lishing a meeting point from fixed positions;
and practice are still out on whether to include implicitly or explicitly, they first establish
diehard spoilers in the hopes of carrying them a formula for their agreement, consisting
along in the momentum of the negotiations of a common definition of the problem
or to leave them out in marginalized isolation and its solution (emerging directly from the
(Stedman 2001; Zahar 2007). Inside they diagnosis components), a common sense of
may wreck the talks, and outside they may justice, and/or an agreed set of terms of
torpedo the results, the critical variable being trade. This set of principles serves as the
the weight that they command within the basis for the subsequent allocation of details.
rebellion. Whether the hardline akazu and the Establishing a satisfying formula is the key to
Committee for the Defense of the Republic a subsequent agreement, and if it is not done,
(CDR) should have been included in the the resolution of the conflict will be slower,
Arusha negotiations on Rwanda in 1993 is less coherent, and less satisfactory (Narlikar &
a question that will be long debated and Odell 2006). There are two different types
CONFLICT RESOLUTION AND NEGOTIATION 331

of formulas: a minimal agreeing formula the Israeli Jordan Treaty (1995), and the Oslo
that ends or suspends the violence without Accords (1993), and were not managed or
touching the basic conflict issues, and a resolved with Syria or Palestine because the
resolving formula that takes on the more formula was not applied. The formula may
difficult challenge of managing both the orig- provide one (or a mixture) of three ways by
inal issues, the complications that have arisen which conflicting positions are combined into
during the conflict, and mechanism for dealing a joint agreement: concession, compensation,
with old conflict that may reemerge and and construction.
new conflicts that may arise. The distinction Concession involves mutual movement
raises a major dilemma in negotiated conflict from initial positions on a single item to
resolution: should peace be achieved, even a meeting point somewhere in the middle.
if through a minimal agreeing formula that It is initiated by the establishment of a
may leave issues unresolved and grievances range where the potential positions of the
unaddressed, or should negotiation focus on parties overlap, termed the bargaining range
the achievement of a final resolving formula, or zone of possible agreement (ZOPA),
even if the search prolongs the violence and absence of which agreement is not possible
killing that come with the struggle for justice (Pillar 1983). Pioneering work by economists
(Zartman & Kremenyuk 2005)? Rather than introduced process analysis in the early
find an answer in the absolute, the optimal twentieth century, but, while theoretically
strategy involves sequencing, focusing first elegant, it was hampered by two assump-
on conflict management and the reduction of tions: fixed initial positions and constant
violence and then turning to the search for concession rates (Edgeworth 1881; Zeuthen
the ingredients of a just, resolving formula, 1930). Concession behavior occurs most
recognizing that conflict management both frequently toward the end of the negotiation
undermines and promises conflict resolution process, often in the form of split-the-
since it reduces pressure for a solution (a less difference, after a general framework has
hurting stalemate) but also implies subsequent been established (see below) (Tracy 1987).
attention to underlying causes lest they return Camp David (1979), for example, cannot
to bring back the conflict. be understood by analyzing the parties’
The notion of justice, which enters the movement from given numbers of Israeli
negotiation process through its formula, is settlements or predetermined definitions of
important both in understanding the process Palestinian autonomy to a compromise figure
and in tying negotiation analysis to other somewhere in the middle. But the Caricom
elements of social science and diplomatic proposal for resolution of the Haitian conflict
practice. While some have held that there in 2004 or the Zairean conflict in 1996 did
is a single overarching notion of justice involve concessions from opposite positions
governing negotiated outcomes (Rawls 1971; favoring removal of the president vs those
Barry 1986) and others have held that justice favoring his maintenance in power, with the
has no place at all in negotiation, it has been middle point—maintenance in position but
found that justice is an important element in with power diverted to the prime minister—
the search for a formula but that the particular the basis of the compromise, adopted in
version of justice to be applied is negotiated the Zairean case and finally rejected in
between the parties before they can move on Haiti. In the prolonged negotiation over
to the disposition of specific items in dispute Aceh, mediator Martti Ahrtissari successfully
(Gauthier 1986; Elster 1992; Zartman et al. proposed self-government as the midpoint
1996; Albin 2001, 2003). resulting from concessions from Indonesia’s
Formulas abound. The Arab–Israeli dis- discredited autonomy and the Acehnese inde-
putes were handled on the basis of the UNSCR pendence (Kingsbury 2006). Concession is
242 formula of “Peace for security” in the conceptually zero-sum, although the outcome
Israeli–Egyptian Washington Treaty (1979), of the negotiation becomes positive-sum
332 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF CONFLICT RESOLUTION

when compared to the security point of dispute, decades of competing territorial


continued conflict. claims produced only war, a real bargaining
Compensation overcomes the zero-sum failure, but redefinition of the problem as one
problem by bringing in other items as a trade- of mutual development made a cooperative
off. It is expressed in the penetrating insight settlement possible (1998). In Ulster, the
of the Homans (1961, p 62) Maxim: “The redefinition of the conflict by the mediator
more the items at stake can be divided into into three strands—intra-Ulster, Ulster–Eire,
goods valued more by one party than they Eire–UK—took it out of a distributive, zero-
cost to the other and goods valued more sum confrontation.
by the other party than they cost to the While these three forms are ideal types,
first, the greater the chances of successful they are starting points for variations that
outcome,” and also in the Nash (1950) make negotiations possible. They indicate that
Point. Compensation not only underscores the sharing in a coveted payoff, bringing in new
importance of establishing terms of trade as a values to make a larger pie, and redefining
key to successful negotiation but also reminds the problem to bring out all parties’ interests
negotiators not to leave unclaimed value on in a solution are approaches that negotiators
the table (Lax & Sebenius 1982). need to take to find jointly acceptable solu-
In the South West African negotiations tions. Present-day understanding of process
(1981–88), South Africa insisted on the is in terms of stages gained in realism by
withdrawal of Cuban troops from Angola, overcoming the two limiting assumptions at
whose presence justified South African troops the cost of quantitative theoretical elegance.
in South West Africa, whereas Angola (and
the South West African People’s Organization
[SWAPO]) insisted on the withdrawal of the BEHAVIOR
South African Defense Force (SADF) from
South West Africa, whose presence justified Behavioral analysis uses the negotiator as
Angolan troops in Angola. Negotiations the analytical variable, and in so doing
looking for a midpoint between zero and faces serious conceptual challenges that it
50,000 for either troops would have been has not yet fully worked out. The approach
meaningless, but using each proposal as is doubtless the oldest and most persistent,
compensation for agreement on the other, for it prevails today at the hands of many
as the US mediator got the parties to do, diplomats who feel that they alone know
produced a highly positive-sum agreement how to negotiate, in nontransmissible ways.
with relatively balanced terms and Namibian However, at that level, it becomes totally
independence as well. Similarly, in the famous idiosyncratic. To serve as a basis for analysis,
Cuban Missile negotiations (1972), Soviet the approach must group individuals into
missile evacuation was bought by a US pledge meaningful behavioral categories.
not to invade, compensating an action with a The basic dichotomy of the previous
promise that was deemed a fair set of terms of century between Shopkeepers and Warriors
trade by the parties. (Nicolson 1939) has been repeated in many
Construction,2 sometimes termed inte- forms, notably as Softliners and Hardliners
gration or problem-solving, refers to the (Snyder & Diesing 1975) and Doves and
reframing of the conflict or its solution Hawks. While intuitively attractive, it is far
in such a way that an outcome beneficial too manichean a division, to the point where
to both sides can be envisaged. There are even the Hawks–Doves added Owls to com-
many conflicts where Homans Maxim—and plete their world. The most recent and more
all the more so, a concession strategy— complex attempt divides personalities into
simply cannot be made to apply, and where five categories—competitor, avoider, accom-
a redefinition of the conflict is necessary to modator, collaborator/problem-solver, and
make a solution. In the Peru–Ecuador border compromiser (or shark, turtle, teddy bear, owl,
CONFLICT RESOLUTION AND NEGOTIATION 333

and fox, in another formulation) (Thomas & are still looking for the best way to handle it
Killman 1974), which have in turn been (Cohen 1997; Faure & Rubin 1997; Avruch
correlated as appropriate strategies (and hence 1998.) One way is to look at crosscutting
not personalities at all) for situations of trans- variables of the same sort that run across
action, tacit cooperation, relationships, and national boundaries. Work on professional
balanced concerns, with the compromiser/fox culture has only begun, showing that such
a jack-of-all-conflicts (Shell 1999).3 commonalities do matter too, although not
Personalities are often key to the resolution definitively (Sjöstedt 2003). The “which when
or nonresolution of conflict by negotiation, why?” question still poses its challenge.
but their categorization still remains elusive.
One can analyze the crucial role of Nelson
Mandela and Frederik de Klerk in making a CONFLICT TYPES
resolution of the South Africa conflict (Sisk
1995; Zartman 1995), and of Menachem The study of negotiation has made enormous
Begin, Anwar Sadat, and Jimmy Carter in strides since it became a field of research less
Camp David I and Ehud Barak, Yasir Arafat, than a half century ago (Schelling 1960; Ikle
and Bill Clinton at Camp David II, but putting 1964; Walton & McKersie 1965). In this, it has
these distinct personalities into meaningful kept up with the need for negotiated conflict
typologies has not yet been accomplished. resolution, as intrastate conflicts persist (after
Collective personality, in the form of cul- a rise and then a drop in the 1990s, after
ture, constitutes another focus of negotiation the Cold War restraints and supports were
research for conflict resolution, as discussed withdrawn) even though interstate conflicts
in the chapter by Faure in this work. A surge have declined (Wallensteen 2007 ).
of studies on national negotiating styles has Negotiation can count many successes in
produced a better understanding of how Conflict Resolution to its credit in the same
nations negotiate (Janosik 1987; Graham & period, more or less resolving intrastate con-
Sano 1989; McDonald 1996; Lebedeva & flicts (in addition to decolonization conflicts)
Kremenyuk 1997; Schecter 1998; Snyder in Mozambique (1992), Aceh (2005), Sudan
1999; Solomon 1999; Diamant 2000; Blaker (2005), Senegal (2006), Liberia (1997 and
et al. 2002; Smyser 2003; Wittes 2005), but at 2003), Sierra Leone (1999), Bosnia (1994),
the risk of stereotyping, thus reducing the cre- Kosovo (1999), Congo (1999), Bougainville
ativity that is the key to successful negotiation. (2001), among others. It also provided
More work is needed to find the appropriate either agreeing or resolving formulas to
collectivity to which the term “culture” can end interstate conflicts through the Middle
be applied and to identify negotiating traits East Peace Process in the Israeli–Syrian
that are crosscultural compared to those that Disengagements (1977), Israeli–Egyptian
are intrinsic (and to explain their presence by Treaty (1979), the Oslo Agreements (1993),
some other variable than a tautological use of and the Israeli–Jordanian Treaty (1995); the
“culture”). Thus, culture is a delicate variable Geneva Agreements on Afghanistan (1988),
on which to hang an analysis of process and the Ethiopian–Eritrean Agreements (1991
outcomes, yet undeniably it matters. Analysts and 2000); the Brazzaville Agreement on

Table 16.2 Outcome and type of conflict, 1946–2005


Victory Peace Accord Ceasefire Other Total Ended Ongoing
Extrastate 4 8 0 9 21 0
Interstate 13 9 19 21 62 0
Intrastate 103 40 28 118 289 31
All Conflicts 120 57 47 148 372 31
Source: Kreutz 2006; see also Pfetsch & Rohloff 2000
334 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF CONFLICT RESOLUTION

Table 16.3 Outcome and regions, 1946–2005


Victory Peace Accord Ceasefire Other Total Ended Ongoing
Europe 10 7 9 12 38 2
Middle East 18 4 8 22 52 5
Asia 25 16 17 64 122 15
Africa 38 23 12 44 117 7
America 29 7 1 6 43 2
All Regions 120 57 47 148 372 31
Source: Kreutz 2006

Namibia (1988); the Peru–Ecuador Border of negotiation ask how weak states can win
Agreement (1999); the Tashkent (1966) and something, and often a lot, attributing the
Simla (1972) Agreements on Kashmir, not to result to strategies of borrowing power and
speak of the agreements in the construction of phasing, as already discussed (Zartman &
of Europe, among others. Rubin 2003). Negotiations to end interstate
And it has led to the establishment of wars, whether mediated or direct, generally
a growing web of international regimes, tend to be conflict-driven and depend on the
beginning with the security regime in the elements of ripeness to be perceived before
UN itself (1945), and going on to the they can begin; thereafter they tend to stop
Convention on the Law of the Sea (UNCLOS) at agreeing formulas, sometimes surprisingly
(1982), the General Agreement on Trade and long-lasting, rather then being able to reach
Tariffs (GATT) (1947) and then the World into the basic issues to come up with a
Trade Organization (WTO) (1995), the Ozone resolving formula for agreement.
Treaty (1994) and Framework Convention Intrastate conflict negotiations are charac-
on Climate Change (1995), the Conven- teristically asymmetrical, both informally in
tion/Organization on Security and Coopera- regard to power and formally in regard to
tion in Europe (C/OSCE) (1975/1992), and a status. In the first, the rebellion opposes its
myriad of other regimes. Each of these types commitment to state power and its fixation on
has its dynamics and analyses. the conflict—an existential struggle to—the
There has been less analysis of interstate state’s many other problems; in the second,
conflict negotiations, because there have been it seeks recognition as spokesman for its
fewer interstate wars in the postwar and cause, denying the state legitimacy as national
especially post-Cold War period. Parties to authority, and status as an equal. Recognition
interstate conflicts enjoy formal equality as is necessary for negotiation; negotiation
states, and usually in the post-World War II confers recognition. This situation constitutes
era their existence is not in question in the major obstacle to substantive negotiating,
the conflict; they will continue to exist and once it is overcome, the parties can begin
when the war is over and the conflict is discussing the range of issues lying between
only one of their concerns. That said, their integration and independence or takeover.
levels of power and commitment may vary A whole range of intermediate solutions—
greatly, leading to a greater or lesser degree various forms of autonomy, executive, and
of asymmetry. Much of the work that has legislative power-sharing, elections—is avail-
been done on negotiating interstate conflicts able for the negotiating, but the biggest
focuses on territoriality, as discussed in the obstacle is generally the absence of trust.
chapter by Vasquez, and on asymmetry, The longer negotiations drag on, the greater
which is also an angle used by research the number of additional issues, including
on war itself. Studies of war asked why wounds and hatreds, that encumber the
weak states attack, attributing the decision agenda: the longer it lasts, the harder it
to imperfect information (Paul 1994); studies is to end, and so the still longer it lasts.
CONFLICT RESOLUTION AND NEGOTIATION 335

Intrastate conflicts frequently involve iden- of the need and opportunity to negotiate.
tity issues that are highly impervious to Conflict itself is the preparation for its
negotiation. Such issues require constructive own resolution; how can this preparation
formulas, since concession and compensation be accelerated more economically, and the
are ill suited to deal with the problem. costs of conflict reduced? The important work
In interstate cooperation, the path to already done on these topics does not exhaust
prevention through the establishment of the subject; to the contrary, it only opens it to
standards and institutions is entirely a matter further research.
of negotiation, as is the matter of maintaining In the analysis of the process itself, the
and adjusting such regimes (Hasenclever strategic situation demanding coordination, as
et al. 1997; Chesterman, Ignatief & Thakur in CDG or the Battle of the Sexes where there
2005). As in conflict negotiations, parties are are two Nash equilibria and the challenge
formally equal but have different weights in becomes the choice or combination between
power and, in addition, different roles in the them, as opposed to the PDG challenge of
negotiation. As a result, the challenge is one collaboration, poses a major problem for
of managing complexity, involving largely the analysis and practice, as Avenhaus discusses
creation of coalitions of parties and of issues in his chapter on game theory. Since many
(Dupont 1994; Hampson 1995; Sebenius situations do not fall under Homans Maxim
1996). Negotiations to create regimes are or have a Nash Point where compensation
problem-solving negotiations, designed to and trade-offs are possible, the challenge of
economize on transaction costs by setting up concession or construction is mighty.
standard procedures for handling recurrent The other of the processes calling for
problems. further study has to do with closure, a topic
on which there is essentially nothing. When is
enough and when can one side ask for a little
NEW CHALLENGES more without breaking down the process? The
question is crucial to the judgment of whether
As scholarship has come face to face with the parties did the most they could or whether
the growing number of cases in reality, and they left unclaimed gains on the table. Do the
as it has focused increasing attention on the negotiations in question end on an agreeing
negotiation process itself, it has spread out formula or a resolving formula, and how can
in new directions. Indeed, what is termed the one lead to the other?
negotiation is in fact (or in concept) three The third direction concerns what hap-
sets of negotiations: negotiations to negotiate, pens after successful negotiations, as in
negotiations to end conflict (violent or not), implementation, postagreement negotiations
and negotiations to implement the agreement. (Spector & Zartman 2003), reconstruction,
All of these invite further work. One is durability (Licklider 1995; Walter 2002;
the matter of what happens before formal Fortna 2004a, 2004b), fully discussed in
negotiations begin, as in negotiability (Dupont the chapter by Gartner and Mellin in this
2006), diagnosis (Zartman and Berman 1982), volume. More than the previous subject area,
prenegotiation (Stein 1997), ripening (Haas these topics are open-ended and so hard
1990; Zartman 2008), escalation (Zartman & to subject to bounded inquiry. In fact, one
Faure 2005), entry (Crocker et al. 1999; of the problems plaguing durability studies
Maundi et al. 2006), etc. While ripeness theory is, How long does an agreement have to
provides an important key to the decision have lasted (meaning?) to be judged durable?
to negotiate, it is dependent on perception, A challenging implication of postagreement
a condition the parties often cannot achieve negotiations is, How constraining is a regime
alone or together. Much negotiation is usually if renegotiation is a normal part of its nature?
required by a mediator and within the parties Indeed, some have indicated that negoti-
themselves to come to the subject realization ation should not be regarded as a process
336 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF CONFLICT RESOLUTION

with an end but rather as the beginning of a following section. Most of these can be included
process of continuing cooperation (Thuderoz within the general category of power structures, the
2003). This may be a cultural question: element to which they all contribute.
2 The term was used by Mary Follett 1942, p. 147,
Americans like their negotiations to end with cited in Walton & McKersie 1965, p. 128.
a solid agreement and go home, whereas 3 For a similar categorization of strategies, see
other cultures (not necessarily Asian) and Pruitt & Kim 2004.
particularly students of social negotiations see
negotiation as merely opening a door. In any
case, the viewpoint would be a useful addition REFERENCES
to conflict resolution approaches, where
Albin, Cecilia 2001. Justice and Fairness in International
parties not only conduct forward-looking
Negotiation. Cambridge
negotiations to take care of future possible
—— 2003. “Negotiating International Cooperation:
conflict but where they also seek to build Global Goods and Fairness.” Review of International
mechanisms for transforming relationships Studies, XXIX 3: 368–385.
(Zartman & Kremenyuk 2005). Aron, Raymond 1957. “Conflict and War from the
Probably the most challenging issue of Viewpoint of Historical Sociology,” in International
the time concerns the profound change in Sociological Association, ed., The Nature of Conflict.
negotiation brought on by a changing nature UNESCO.
of the parties. Negotiation with armed bands, Avenhaus, Rudolf & Zartman, I William, eds. 2007.
terrorists, antiglobalist movements, among Diplomatic Games: The Use of Formal Models in, of,
others, are not the neat two-party negotiations and for Negotiation. Springer.
Avruch, Kevin 1998. Culture and Conflict Resolution.
that current analysis so often assumes. Not
USIP.
only does it involve internal politics (as do
Axelrod, Robert 1984. The Evolution of Cooperation.
all negotiations) but the other party frequently Basic Books.
does not exist as a corporate body. There is no Baç, Mehmet 2000. “A Note on Efficient Signaling of
leader who can make a decision and hold an Bargaining Power,” International Journal of Game
agreement, and no delegates who represent the Theory XXIX 1: 119–126.
central organization. Furthermore, the “party” —— 2001. “On Creating and Claiming Value in
frequently does not know what it wants: its Negotiations,” Group Decision and Negotiation X 2:
actions call for attention, express protest, look 237–251.
to millennial outcomes, and expect conversion Barry, Brian 1986. Theories of Justice. University of
and surrender from the other side (or eternal California Press.
Bartos, Ottomar 1978. “A Simple Model of Negotia-
war), as in Uganda and Sri Lanka in current
tion,” in Zartman, ed., 1978.
conflicts. Finally, these “parties” usually do
Bendahmane, Diane & McDonald, John, eds., Perspec-
not know how to negotiate and often have tives in Negotiation. US Government Printing Office.
to be taken aside and given training, as Bernard, Jessie 1957. “The Sociological Study of
in Darfur, Mozambique, and Sri Lanka in Conflict,” in International Sociological Association,
recent conflicts. Negotiating with or between ed., The Nature of Conflict. UNESCO.
amorphous parties needs entirely different Blaker, Michael, Giarra, Paul, & Vogel, Ezra 2002. Case
models to capture its process, in concept and Studies in Japanese Negotiating Behavior. USIP.
in reality. Bottom, William, Holloway, James, McClury, Scott &
There is still much life left to live in the old Miller, Gary 2000. “Negotiating a Coalition,” Journal
practice and its relatively new analysis. of Conflict Resolution XXXXIV 2: 147–169.
Brams, Steven J. 1990. Negotiation Games: Apply-
ing Game Theory to Bargaining and Arbitration.
Routledge.
NOTES —— & Taylor, Alan D. 1996. Fair Division. Cambridge
University Press.
1 Other elements can be structured too, of course, Carnevale, Peter & deDreu, Carsten, eds. 2006. Methods
such as number of parties, locations, array of issues, of Negotiation Research. Nijhoff (also appeared as
and even evaluation of outcomes discussed in the International Negotiation IX 3 (2004) and X 1 (2005).
CONFLICT RESOLUTION AND NEGOTIATION 337

Chasek, Pamela 1997. “A Comparative Analysis of Bargaining and Domestic Politics. University of
Multilateral Environmental Negotiations,” Group California.
Decision and Negotiation VI 4: 437–61. Farnham, Barbara, ed., 1992. Avoiding Losses/Taking
Chesterman, S., Ignatief, M. & Thakur, R., eds., 2005. Risks: Prospect Theory and International Conflict.
Making States Work: State Failure and the Crisis of University of Michigan.
Governance. UNU Press. Fearon, James 1995. “Rationalist Explanations of War,”
Cogan, Charles 2003. French Negotiating Behavior. International Organization IL 3: 379–414.
USIP. Fisher, Roger & Ury, William 1985. Getting to Yes.
Cohen, Raymond 1997. Negotiating Across Cultures. Follett, Mary 1942. Dynamic Administration. Harper &
USIP. Row.
Coser, Lewis 1956. The Functions of Social Conflict. Free Fortna, Page 2004a. “International Intervention and
Press. the Duration of Peace after Civil War,” International
Crocker, Chester A. 1992. High Noon in South Africa. Studies Quarterly IIL 2: 269–292.
Norton. —— 2004b. Peace Time: Cease-Fire Agreements and
Cross, John G. 1969. The Economics of Bargaining. the Durability of Peace. Princeton.
Basic. Gauthier, David 1986. Morals by Agreement. Oxford.
Crump, Larry & Zartman, I. William, eds., 2003. Graham, John & Sano, Yoshihiro 1989. Smart Bargain-
Multilateral Negotiation and Complexity, a special ing. Sano Publishing.
issue of International Negotiation VIII 1. Gregg, J. Michael 2001. “Moment of Opportunity:
Curran, Daniel & Sebenius, James, 2003. “The Mediator Recognizing Conditions of Ripeness in International
as a Coalition Builder,” International Negotiation VIII Mediation between Enduring Rivals,” Journal of
1: 111–147. Conflict Resolution VL 6: 691–718.
——, ——& Watkins, Michael, 2004. “Two Paths to Hammerstein, P. & Parker, G. A. 1982. “The asymmetric
Peace: Contrasting George Mitchell in Northern Ire- war of attrition,” Journal of Theoretical Biology IVC
land and Richard Holbrooke in Bosnia-Herzegovina,” 4: 647–682.
Negotiation Journal XX 4: 513–538. Hampson, Fen Osler 1994. Multilateral Negotiations.
daConceição-Heldt, Eugenia 2006. “Integrative and The Johns Hopkins University.
Distributive Bargaining Situations in the European Hasenclever, Abdreas, Mayer, Peter & Rittberger, Volker
Union,” Negotiation Journal XXII 2: 145–166. 1997. Theories of International Regimes. Cambridge.
Dahl, Robert 1951. Holbrooke, Richard 1996. To End a War.
DeSoto, Alvaro 1992. “Ending Violent Conflict in El Holl Lute, Jane, ed. 1997. Preventing Deadly Conflict.
Salvador,” in Chester A. Crocker, Fen Osler Hampson Carnegie Corporation.
and Pamela Aall, eds., Herding Cats: Multiparty Hopmann, P. Terrence 1996. The Negotiation Process
Mediation in a Complex World. USIP. and the Resolution of International Conflicts.
Diamant. Niel 2000. “Conflict and Conflict Resolution University of South Carolina.
in China,” and Wall, James, Blum, Michael & Jin, —— 2001. “Bargaining and Problem-Solving,” in
Dengjian, “Response,” Journal of Conflict Resolution Chester A. Crocker, Fen O. Hampson & Pamela Aall,
XXXXIV 4: 523–551. eds., Turbulent Peace: The Challenges of Managing
Druckman, Daniel 1978. “Boundary Role Conflict,” in International Conflict. USIP.
I. William Zartman, ed., . Hornstein, H. A. 1965. “Effects of different magnitude
—— 1986. “Stages, Turning Points and Crises,” in of threat upon interpersonal bargaining,” Journal of
Journal of Conflict Resolution XXX 2: 327–360. Experimental Psychology I 3: 282–293.
—— 2001. “Turning Points in International Negoti- Human Security Centre. 2005. Human Security Report
ation: A Comparative Analysis,” Journal of Conflict 2005. New York: Oxford.
Resolution XXXV 4: 519–544. Ikle, Fred Charles. 1964. How Nations Negotiate. Harper
Edgeworth, Francis 1881. Mathematical Physics. Kegan & Row.
Paul. Janosik, Robert 1987. “Rethinking the Culture-
Elgström, Ole and Christer Jönsson, eds., 2005. Negotiation Link,” Negotiation Journal III 3:
European Union Negotiations: Processes, Networks 385–396.
and Institutions. Routledge. Jones, Bruce D. 2001. Peacemaking in Rwanda: The
Elster, John 1992. Local Justice. Russel Sage. Dynamics of Failure. Lynne Riener.
Enderlin, Charles 2002. Le rêve brisé. Fayard. Jönsson, Christer 1981. “Bargaining Power: Notes on
Evans, Peter, Jacobson, Harold & Putnam, Robert, an Elusive Concept,” Cooperation and Conflict XVI
eds., 1993. Double-Edged Diplomacy: International 2: 249–257.
338 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF CONFLICT RESOLUTION

—— 2000. “Bargaining, Negotiation and Diplomacy,” Ottaway, Marina 1995. “Eritrea and Ethiopia: Negoti-
in Walter Carlsnaes, Thomas Risse & Beth Simmons, ations in a Transitional Conflict,” in Zartman, ed.,
eds., Handbook of International Relations. Sage. Elusive Peace.
Kahneman, Daniel & Tversky, Amos 1979. “Prospect Paul, T. V. 1994. Asymmetric Conflicts: War Initiation by
Theory: An Analysis of Decision under Risk,” Weaker Powers. Cambridge.
Econometrica IIIL 2: 263–292. Pfetsch, Frank & Rohloff, Christoph 2000. National and
Kanet, Roger & Kolodziej, Edward, eds., 1991. Cold War International Conflicts, 1945–1995: New empirical
as Cooperation. Macmillan. and theoretical approaches. Routledge.
Kingsbury, Damien 2006. Peace in Aceh. Equinox. Pillar, Paul 1983. Negotiating Peace. Princeton.
Kremenyuk, Victor, ed., 2003. International Negotiation. Powell, Robert 1991. “Absolute and Relative Gains in IR
Jossey-Bass, 2nd ed. Theory,” American Political Science Review LXXXV
Kreutz, Joakim 2006. “How Wars End,” Uppsala 4: 1303–1320.
Conflict Data Program, www.pcr,uu.se/publications/ —— 2002. “Bargaining Theory and International
UCDP_pub_Kreutz_how_conflicts_end061013.pdf Conflict,” Annual Review of Political Science
Leader, Joyce 2001. Rwanda’s Struggle for Democracy 5: 1–30.
and Peace. Fund for Peace. Powelson, John 1972. Institution of Economic Growth:
Lebedeva, Marina & Kremenyuk, Victor 1997. “Nego- A Theory of Conflict Management in Developing
tiations in the former Soviet Union,” International Countries. Princeton.
Negotiation I 3: 351–364, 409–421. Pruitt, Dean G, ed., 1997. Lessons Learned from
Licklider, Roy 1995. “The Consequences of the Middle East Peace Process. Special issue of
Negotiated Settlement in Civil Wars 1945– International Negotiation II 2.
1993,” American Political Science Review XIC 3: —— and Kim, Sung-Hee 2004. Social Conflict:
681–690. Escalation, Stalemate and Settlement. McGraw-Hill.
MacDermott, Rose 2007. “Prospect Theory and —— & Carnevale, Peter 1993. Negotiation in Social
Negotiation Risks,” in Rudolf Avenhaus and Gunnar Conflict. Brooks/Cole.
Sjösted, eds., Negotiating Risks. Springer. Putnam, Robert 1988. “Diplomacy and Domestic
McDonald, John, ed. 1996. Defining a US Negotiating Politics: The Logic of Two-Level Games,” International
Style. Special issue of International Negotiation I 2. Organization XXII 3: 428–460.
Meerts, Paul & Cede, Franz 2003. Negotiating European Raiffa, Howard with Richardson, John & Metcalfe,
Union. Palgrave. David 2003. Negotiation Analysis: The Sci-
Mitchell, Christopher 1995. “The Right Moment,” ence and A of Collaborative Decision-Making.
Paradigms: The Kent Journal of International Harvard.
Relations IX 2: 35–52. Rawls, John. 1971. A Theory of Justice. Harvard.
Mooradian & Druckman, Daniel 2003. “Hurting Rothchild, Donald 1997. Managing Ethnic Conflict in
Stalemate or Mediation? The Conflict over Nagorno- Africa. Brookings.
Karabakh,” Journal of Peace Research XXXVI 6: Rubenstein, A. 1982. “Perfect Equilibrium in a
709–727. Bargaining Model,” Econometrica L 1: 97–110.
Narlikar, Amrita 2003. International Trade and Devel- Schecter, Jerrold 1998. Russian Negotiating Behavior.
oping Countries: Coalitions in the GATT and WTO. USIP.
Routledge. Sebenius, James 1996. Negotiating the Law of the Sea.
—— & Odell, John 2006. “Negotiating International Harvard.
Institutions,” Paper presented to the International Shell, G. Richard 1999. Bargaining for Advantage.
Studies Association, San Diego. Penguin.
Nash, John 1950. “The Bargaining Problem,” Econo- Shubik, Martin, ed. 1964. Game Theory and Related
metrica XVIII 2: 155–162. Approaches to Social Behavior. Wiley.
—— 1953. “Two-Person Cooperative Game,” Econo- Smoke, Richard 1977. War: Controlling Escalation.
metrica XXI 2: 128–140. Harvard.
Nicolson, Harold 1939. Diplomacy. Oxford. Smyser, W. R. 2003. How Germans Negotiate. USIP.
Odell, John 2000. Negotiating the World Economy. Snyder, Scott 1999. Negotiating on the Edge: North
Cornell University Press. Korean Negotiating Behavior. USIP.
—— ed. 2006. Negotiating Trade: Developing Coun- Snyder, Richard and Diesing, Paul 1975. Conflict among
tries in the WTO and NAFTA. Cambridge. Nations. Princeton.
Osgood, Charles 1962. An Alternative to War or Solomon, Richard 1999. Chinese Negotiating Behavior.
Surrender. University of Illinois Press. USIP.
CONFLICT RESOLUTION AND NEGOTIATION 339

Spector, Bertram I. & Zartman, I. William, eds., 2003. Walton, Richard and McKersie, Robert 1965. A Behav-
Getting It Done: Post-Agreement Negotiations and ioral Theory of Labor Negotiations. McGraw-Hill.
International Regimes. USIP. Werner, Suzanne 1999. “The Precarious Nature of
Stein, Arthur 1983 Peace,” American Journal of Political Science XXXXIII
—— 1990. Why National Cooperate . Cornell University 3: 912–934.
Press. Young, Oran 1968. The Politics of Force. Princeton.
Stein, Janice, ed. 1995. Getting to the Table. The Johns Zartman, I. William 1988. “Common Elements in the
Hopkins University Press. Analysis of the Negotiation Process,” Negotiation
—— & Pauly, Louis, eds. 1993. Choosing to Cooperate: Journal IV 1: 31–44 (January).
How States Avoid Loss. The Johns Hopkins University —— 1989. Ripe for Resolution. Oxford.
Press. —— 2000. “Ripeness: The Hurting Stalemate and
Taylor, Michael 1987. The Possibility of Cooperation. Beyond,” in Paul Stern and Daniel Druckman, eds.,
Cambridge. International Conflict Resolution after the Cold War.
Telhami, Shibley, ed. 2002. Establishing a Data Set National Academy Press.
on Intrastate and International Negotiation and —— 2005. Cowardly Lions: Missed Opportunities to
Mediation, special issue of International Negotiation Prevent Deadly Conflict and State Collapse. Lynne
VII 1. Rienner.
Thomas, Kenneth & Killman, Ralph 1974. “Developing a —— 2006. “Multilateral Negotiations,” in Encyclope-
Forced-Choice Measure of Conflict-Handling Behav- dia on Life Support Systems (EOLSS). UNESCO.
ior,” Educational and Psychological Measurement —— 2008. Handbook for Mediators: Ripening.
XXXVII: 309–325. USIP/SAIS.
Tracy, Brian 1978. “The Spanish Base Negotiations,” in ——, ed. 1978. The Negotiation Process. Sage, also
Zartman, ed., appearing as a special issue of Journal of Conflict
Tversky, Amos & Kahneman, Daniel. 1986. “Rational Resolution XXI 4 (1977).
Choice and the Framing of Decisions,” Journal of ——, ed. 1994. International Multilateral Negotiations.
Business IL 4, pt 2: S251–278. Jossey-Bass.
Vitz, P. C. and Kite, W. R. 1970. “Factors affecting ——, ed. 1995. Elusive Peace: Negotiating to End Civil
conflict and negotiation within an alliance,” Journal Wars. Brookings.
of Experimental Social Psychology V 3: 233–247. ——, ed. 2007. Peacemaking in International Conflict,
Wagner, Lynn 2007. Problem-Solving and Convergent 2nd edn. USIP.
Bargaining: An Analysis of Negotiation Processes and —— & Rubin, Jeffrey Z, eds. 2000. Power and
their Outcomes. Nijhoff. Negotiation. University of Michigan.
Wagner, R. Harrison 1999. “Bargaining and Conflict —— & Faure, Guy Olivier, eds. 2005. Escalation and
Resolution,” paper presented to the International International Negotiation. Cambridge.
Studies Association in Washington. —— & Touval, Saadia 2007. “Mediation before and
Wall, James A., Stark, John B., & Standlifer, Rhetta 2001. after 9/11,” in Chester Crocker, Fen Hampson &
“Mediation: A Current Review of Theory Develop- Pamela Aall, eds., Unleashing the Dogs of
ment,” Journal of Conflict Resolution VL 2: 370–390. War.USIP.
Wallensteen, Peter 2007. Understanding Conflict —— & ——, eds. 2008. Cooperation: Gains and Pains
Resolution. Sage. of Multilateralism. In press.
Walter, Barbara 2002. Committing to Peace. Princeton Zeuthen, Frederik 1930. Problem of Monopoly and
University Press. Economic Warfare. Routledge and Kegan Paul.

You might also like