Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 26

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/360462765

Intellectual rivalry in American economics: intergenerational social cohesion


and the rise of the Chicago school

Article  in  Socio-Economic Review · May 2022


DOI: 10.1093/ser/mwac024

CITATIONS READS

2 34

3 authors, including:

Leonard Seabrooke Kevin Young


Copenhagen Business School University of Massachusetts Amherst
120 PUBLICATIONS   3,570 CITATIONS    60 PUBLICATIONS   1,161 CITATIONS   

SEE PROFILE SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

Embedding Groupthink: Assessing the Rise and Influence of Neoliberal Economics View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Leonard Seabrooke on 08 June 2022.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


Socio-Economic Review, 2022, Vol. 00, No. 0, 1–25
https://doi.org/10.1093/ser/mwac024
Article

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ser/advance-article/doi/10.1093/ser/mwac024/6582368 by guest on 08 June 2022


Article

Intellectual rivalry in American economics:


intergenerational social cohesion and the
rise of the Chicago school
Lasse Folke Henriksen ,1 Leonard Seabrooke 1,
* and
Kevin L. Young 2
1
Department of Organization, Copenhagen Business School, Frederiksberg, Denmark and
2
Department of Economics, University of Massachusetts, Amherst, MA, USA

*Correspondence: lse.ioa@cbs.dk

Abstract
Neoliberal economics has reshaped societies. How did this doctrine ascend? While
existing explanations emphasize a variety of factors, one neglected aspect is
intellectual rivalry within the US economics profession. Neoliberalism had to attain
prestige against the grain of the intelligentsia prior to becoming a force to organize
political power. Using qualitative and quantitative evidence, we examine key rivals
in US economics from 1960 to 1985: the Chicago School of Economics, neoliberal
pioneers and the ‘Charles River Group’ (Harvard University and the Massachusetts
Institute of Technology), the mainstream Keynesian stronghold. We identify sociali-
zation mechanisms from historical accounts, which suggest forms of social cohe-
sion between elite professors and their students. We measure social cohesion and
network structure from salient relations within and between generations, using a
new a dataset focused on elite economics professors and their graduate students.
What differentiated the Chicago School from Charles River was its fostering of social
cohesion and its effective transmission of value orientations across generations.

Key words: intellectual networks, neoliberalism, social cohesion, sociology of economics,


Chicago School of Economics, Charles River Group

JEL classification: A14—Sociology of Economics, B3—History of Economic Thought: Individuals,


N01—Development of the Discipline: Historiographical; Sources and Methods, Z13: Economic
Sociology, Social and Economic Stratification.

1. Introduction
The ascendance of neoliberal economic thought is one of the most wide-reaching intellectual
trends of the last half-century. From a relatively marginal and radical position in the 1950s

C The Author(s) 2022. Published by Oxford University Press and the Society for the Advancement of Socio-Economics.
V
This is an Open Access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-
NoDerivs licence (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/), which permits non-commercial reproduction
2 L. F. Henriksen et al.

and 1960s, neoliberal economics became the prevailing operational ideology not just of the
economics discipline but of much economic policy by the mid-1980s (Kogut and
MacPherson, 2011). The common sense of economic theory and policy was profoundly
transformed to favor market competition as a solution to socio-economic problems and the
governing of societies (Mudge, 2018). Numerous accounts have documented the rise of neo-

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ser/advance-article/doi/10.1093/ser/mwac024/6582368 by guest on 08 June 2022


liberal thought within economics, within policy making and within intellectual environments
at large (Fourcade-Gourinchas and Babb, 2002; Backhouse, 2005; Gibbon and Henriksen,
2012; Reay, 2012; Mandelkern, 2021). Our account focuses on the neoliberal rise and re-
lated decline of Keynesian economics in the US by focusing on the intellectual rivalry be-
tween the two elite communities contending to define mainstream economics.
Historical accounts have emphasized a wide variety of factors contributing to the rise of
neoliberal economics in the US, ranging from the role of particular think tanks and founda-
tions (Mirowski and Plehwe, 2009; Hirschman and Berman, 2014), orchestration within the
business community (Kotz, 2015; Van Horn, 2018), the center-left’s embrace of economic
reforms for white collar and business constituencies (Mudge, 2018), intergovernmental
organizations (Kentikelenis and Babb, 2019) and changes to the global economic environment
(Slobodian, 2018). Most of these accounts suggest selection pressures in the environment as
the key explanation for the emergence of neoliberal economics. Some refer to direct resource
dependencies in the Chicago School’s institution-building process, while others point to more
diffuse factors such as shifting demand for ideas favoring neoliberal economic solutions.
An alternate strand of scholarship on the rise of neoliberal economics has pointed to
more strategic considerations related to the professional environment when accounting for
the rise of the Chicago School. These historical accounts suggest that the founding fathers at
Chicago promoted and enforced a strong collective culture around a professoriate through-
out the 1960s (Van Overtveldt, 2007; Emmet, 2011). From this view, Chicago professors
were aware that to challenge the dominance of Keynesian ideas, they would have to work
not just on producing alternative economic ideas but also organize a cadre of scholars that
could disseminate them. Existing accounts do not pay sufficient attention to how Chicago
organized vis-à-vis the core community of what was then mainstream economics: varieties
of Keynesianism.1 We undertake such a systematic comparison, focusing on the two most
prominent elite communities vying for dominance in US economics during the 1960s and
1970s. The first is the Chicago-based Chicago School of Economics. The second is the com-
munity of economics scholars based in Cambridge, MA, that included both Harvard and
MIT, and sometimes referred to as the ‘Charles River Group’.
The term ‘Charles River Group’ of economists refers colloquially to economists at both
Harvard and MIT that represented the mainstream Keynesian–Neoclassical synthesis of its
heyday during the 1960s and early 1970s. The term has been used in a variety of historical
depictions of the era, especially with reference to governmental policy advising by econo-
mists. The ‘Charles River approach’ was promoted by social scientists, mainly economists,

1 Often contained within the neoclassical synthesis of its day, post-WWII US economics was, by the
1960s, dominated by a Keynesian orientation that is clearly distinguished from what later became to
be known as neoliberalism, especially in its orientation around government intervention and the op-
eration of markets. We say ‘varieties’ here because there were different levels to which Keynesian
ideas were adopted, some more ’synthesized’ with neoclassical ideas and models, and some more
institutionalist than others.
Intellectual rivalry in American economics 3

from MIT and Harvard, directly influenced Kennedy and had a distinct set of messages
(Packenham, 1973, pp. 61–62). Reference to the ‘Charles River school of economics’ has
also been made in retrospective histories of the 1960s (Karaagac, 2002).2 We use this term
here for convenience, to refer to the collection of economists at both Harvard and MIT,
which represented the group of established intellectuals that Chicago had to surmount in or-

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ser/advance-article/doi/10.1093/ser/mwac024/6582368 by guest on 08 June 2022


der to ascend.
While many sophisticated accounts exist on the drivers behind the rise of neoliberal eco-
nomics, the puzzle remains how such a rapid shift from Keynesian to neoliberal ideas could
occur. Previous scholarship has demonstrated how changing socio-economic and political
conditions—notably the oil crises, stagflation and the rise of Reagan and Thatcher—contrib-
uted to this development. We argue that to understand the timing and speed of this transition,
it is not sufficient to only account for selection pressures in the institutional environment in
which economics operates. Prior to the development of an institutional environment condu-
cive to neoliberal policies, intellectual development to foment the neoliberal revolution was al-
ready taking place, among academics. While the existence of important neoliberal ideas has
been recognized in extant work, what we argue is that the Chicago School tradition possessed
a social dynamic that outcompeted their entrenched rivals among the more Keynesian main-
stream of American economics. Chicagoans were not only intellectually vociferous, but they
also fostered strong solidarity and tight intergenerational cohesion.
To make sense of the neoliberal ascent, we need to understand that the intellectual advo-
cates for what became neoliberalism had to professionally compete with a mainstream wed-
ded to an opposing set of ideas. While the institutional environment in favor of neoliberal
ideas surged from the mid-1970 onwards, the social networks of competing groups within
American economics started to change in favor of the neoliberals as early as 1965. The resil-
ience of neoliberal ideas, in terms of their embedding in an elite intellectual community, was
on the rise a decade before key institutional shifts. This, in turn, compounded the simulta-
neous fracturing of the Keynesian elite community as the resilience of their ideas was in-
creasingly tested. We agree that the institutional shifts emphasized by existing scholarship
are key to explaining the ascent of neoliberal ideas, but these shifts arrived when
Chicagoans were primed and ready to exploit and cement a new common sense (Forder,
2014).3 Neoliberals were not only able to compete in this context but they were also able to
endure, intergenerationally. The two contending groups’ preparedness to adapt to institu-
tional shifts was shaped by the underlying social networks between professors and students.
A significant historical divergence in these social networks suggests they played a role in
speeding up ideational change, making neoliberal ideas more readily matched to an emerg-
ing institutional context than their Keynesian counterparts.

2. Theoretical motivation
Our study builds on previous work in the sociology of science and empirical historical work
on intergroup dynamics. To identify community structures tied to schools of thought,

2 In addition, in reviewing the fading of Keynesian dominance, Barraclough (1977) refers to ‘the bright
boys along the Charles river’. ‘Charles River economists’ are also referred to colloquially by critiques
of mainstream economists coming out of the area into the early 1990s (Clark, 1994).
3 Keynesians arguably did the same thing in the 1940s and the 1950s.
4 L. F. Henriksen et al.

scholars have studied collaboration and citation networks at the level of entire scientific dis-
ciplines (Price, 1965; Crane, 1972; Lievrouw, 1989), and linked such communities to scien-
tific paradigms (Small, 1980; McMahan and McFarland, 2021). Moody (2004), in
particular, stresses network cohesion as the key structural property of community strength.
Within intellectual communities, social cohesion occurs through shared ideas and inter-

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ser/advance-article/doi/10.1093/ser/mwac024/6582368 by guest on 08 June 2022


personal relationships (Friedkin, 1978; Moody, 2004), which can be maintained across gen-
erations. Randall Collins’ work on the ‘sociology of philosophies’ points to how the driving
force behind intellectual networks is ‘divergent factions that make it go’, and that intergen-
erational social cohesion between teachers and pupils is especially important in propelling
groups forward (Collins, 1989, pp. 112, 115). It is the personal relationships among profes-
sors and students that affirm what is considered an intellectual innovation and what should
be esteemed (Collins, 1989, 1998; Polillo, 2020). Such ‘academic familism’ fosters intellec-
tual momentum (Bandelj, 2019). Specifically, Collins suggests that cohesion within intellec-
tual movements can be studied through citation networks, vertical (teacher–pupil) and
horizontal networks (generational peers), and organizational memberships (Collins, 1989,
p. 115). Ties within these networks should include ‘both friends and foes’ where the groups
involved have physical presence (Collins, 2004, pp. 191–192). Intellectual rivalries in these
networks are common since key groups ‘depend tacitly upon each other, and structure each
other’s direction of thought’ as they compete for the same ‘attention space’ (Collins, 1998,
p. 790, 2004, p. 194).
We draw on Collins’ work on intellectual networks to explain how the Chicago School
of Economics fostered cohesion across scholarly generations in the 1960s and 1970s. We
contrast the Chicago School to their nearest rivals in elite US economics, the Charles River
Group composed of Harvard and MIT. Compared to Chicago, this group, especially
Harvard, produced less social cohesion within and across generations. The Chicago School’s
fostering of cohesion over generations allowed it to become an entrenched group that could
effectively promote its professional, political and economic interests and alliances.
To conduct this comparison, we locate an elite set of professors who were associated
with, respectively, the Chicago School and the Charles River Group environments, and then
trace the hundreds of graduate students that they trained and socialized. As Collins (1998,
p. 78) reminds us, to ‘say that the community of creative intellectuals is small is really to say
that the networks are focused at a few peaks’. To understand the relationship between the
elite professoriate and the broader intellectual network, we study the intellectual networks
among the professors, and between the professors and their students. As such, we investigate
the role of doctoral training programs and the mentorship of doctoral dissertation supervi-
sors, as these act as critical staging environments affecting social cohesion across genera-
tions, enabling the promotion and reproduction of particular intellectual traditions (Collins,
1989, p. 115). We assemble data on the intellectual networks of the professors and students
from 1960 to 1985, a period of heightened intellectual struggle. We show that group repro-
duction is stronger when social cohesion within and in-between generations is actively
fostered.
We contribute to scholarship in the sociology of science, including that on the rise of par-
ticular economic ideas (Van Gunten et al., 2016; Polillo, 2020), by linking changes in the
level of social cohesion among elite scientists and their students to the timing of when certain
ideas become resilient enough to be perceived as mainstream scientific knowledge. We also
contribute to the scholarship on the history of economics that combines qualitative and
Intellectual rivalry in American economics 5

quantitative methods (Cherrier and Svorencık, 2018), including the use of prosopographic
methods to trace groups of economists and their shared biographical characteristics
(Svorencık, 2018; Rossier, 2020). Such methods can identify ‘hidden hierarchies’ that are
obscured if one focuses only on the known leading stars (Svorencık, 2014, p. 110). We show
empirically that a peculiar divergence in how elite intellectual rivals organized socially

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ser/advance-article/doi/10.1093/ser/mwac024/6582368 by guest on 08 June 2022


played a significant role in how the Chicago School could rapidly become mainstream
(Helgadóttir, 2021), after having been considered radical outsiders for decades.

3. The context for rivalry among elite American economists


The US economics profession is characterized by high levels of hierarchy and centrality in
decision making, which is protected by elite status and prestige (Fourcade et al., 2015). This
hierarchy affords elite professors an extraordinary amount of control over knowledge pro-
duction and what is considered prestigious work. This context means that toppling an
entrenched group is no easy feat. While Chicago was clearly an elite department among US
economics departments, with Harvard and MIT, its self-identity reflected an underdog status
that contributed to their social cohesiveness (Reder, 1982).4
Relative to Harvard, in particular, the professoriate associated with Chicago was less
prestigious and much less integrated into the economic policy establishment at the onset of
our observation period. Keynesian economics dominated textbooks, classroom discussion
and policymaking forums in the 1950s and 1960s, in addition to policy (Frazer, 1988, pp.
436–437). Buchanan (1987, p. 131) remarked that ‘. . .by the middle of the 1940s, econo-
mists almost everywhere had become ‘Keynesians’ in their conceptualization of the macro-
economy. They had quickly learned to look at their world through the Keynesian window.’
As Samuelson noted in 1946, ‘Keynesian analysis has begun to filter down into the elemen-
tary textbooks; and, as everybody knows, once an idea gets into these, however bad it may
be, it becomes practically immortal’ (Samuelson, 1946, p. 189).
The 1960s were a high point for the professoriate associated with the Charles River
Group, especially for those identifying as Keynesian economists. There was strong confi-
dence in the Keynesian-Neoclassical synthesis from the Kennedy and Johnson administra-
tions at the time (see Frazer, 1988, pp. 436–437). The ‘Charles River approach’ to
development economics, from MIT and Harvard economists, directly influenced Kennedy
and had a distinct set of messages (see Packenham, 1973, pp. 61–62). By the early 1960s
overtures by the US Federal government were seen as evidence that ‘the American
Government, a generation after the General Theory, had accepted the Keynesian revolution’
(Schlesinger, Jr, 1964 , p. 769). Scholars at Harvard and MIT were ensconced within the ar-
chitecture of US economic policymaking.
In this environment, there was social stigma attached to being associated with the body
of knowledge coming out of the Chicago School. Duke University refused to carry Milton
Friedman’s books, for example (Skousen, 2005, p. 73). As another former Chicago student
wrote, ‘The phrase Chicago Economics was often uttered with the same contempt that com-
monly characterized unsavory ethnic and religious epithets’ (Manne, 2005, pp. 311–312). In

4 We justify the selection of Harvard and MIT specifically as rivals to Chicago drawing on range of his-
torical prestige and training metrics (see Data and Network Measures below, and Supplementary
Appendix A).
6 L. F. Henriksen et al.

his memoirs, Milton Friedman describes the social environment outside Chicago as
inhospitable:

Those of us who were deeply concerned about the danger to freedom and prosperity from the
growth of government, from the triumph of the welfare state and Keynesian ideas, were a small

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ser/advance-article/doi/10.1093/ser/mwac024/6582368 by guest on 08 June 2022


beleaguered minority regarded as eccentrics by the great majority of our fellow intellectuals.
(Friedman, 1982, p. vi)

Not only Friedman but also other scholars were questioned about their Chicago School
affiliations. Exchanges in the archival record reveal a real sensitivity to labels such as the
Chicago School, because it was seen as ideological. Important for our intergenerational ap-
proach is the fact that the particular costs of a Chicago reputation followed recent PhD
graduates around at the time (Bronfenbrenner, 1962, p. 72). What Chicagoans later referred
to as ‘the dark ages of Keynesian despotism’ was eventually overturned to a considerable de-
gree (Johnson 2003, p. 170). The professoriate associated with the Chicago School required
particular forms of socialization to challenge the Charles River Group’s dominance.

4. What was so special about the Chicago school of economics?


The importance of the University of Chicago to the advance of neoliberal thought is well
established in the extensive literature on the history and sociology of economics (van
Overtveldt, 2007; van Horn et al., 2011). This literature has been concerned with the exter-
nal as well as the internal conditions for success. Amadae (2003) and Van Horn (2007) view
the Chicago School as ‘rationalizing agents’, responding to the emerging institutional condi-
tions of a new postwar democratic capitalism. Several of these accounts stress the instrumen-
tal role that Chicago had in building a coherent intellectual project around neoliberalism, as
well as enrolling a transnational network based on a perception of marginalized outsider sta-
tus—the Mont Pèlerin Society in particular—to promote their doctrine (Van Horn and
Mirowski, 2010; Mudge, 2018, pp. 60–61, 241–242; Van Horn, 2018).
There are several existing qualitative accounts of a unique organizational culture at
Chicago fostered in the 1950s and 1960s (Bronfenbrenner, 1962, p. 72; Hammond, 1999).
In the early 1960s, Miller asserted that ‘Chicagoans do in fact form an interconnected group
with a set of common attitudes and interest which distinguishes them from the rest of the
economics profession’ (Miller, 1962, p. 64). Van Overtveldt (2007) points to a distinct orga-
nizational culture centered on: a strong work ethic; a strong belief in economics as a true,
positive science; academic excellence as the only criterion for advancement; a fierce debating
culture designed to cultivate disciplined thinkers around a doctrine; and the University of
Chicago’s physical isolation from other elite universities (see also Shils, 1991; Fand, 1999, p.
12). It is worth elaborating on intensive training, debate within a doctrine and selective iso-
lation as key socialization mechanisms that encouraged vertical and horizontal cohesion
within the Chicago School.
First, on intensive training, the Chicago Economics Department had a very strong com-
mitment to graduate student training and support (Patinkin, 1981, pp. 10–11) and focused
intensely on its graduate student cohorts (Rossi, 1989, p. 290). Early on in his tenure,
Friedman made a series of critical changes to the graduate curriculum and to PhD examina-
tion processes, and remained a pivotal figure in graduate training (see Reder, 1982, p. 10).
Intellectual rivalry in American economics 7

All Chicago graduate students were steeped in price theory to forge a common foundation
of knowledge. Emmet (2011) discusses how graduate students were trained in the core
courses by star professors and then placed into a battery of intensive workshops. The sys-
tem, emerging in the mid-1950 and fully developed by the mid-1960s, developed a collective
sense of belonging among the students. The business school was also kept intentionally close

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ser/advance-article/doi/10.1093/ser/mwac024/6582368 by guest on 08 June 2022


to social sciences, most notably to economics (cf. Fourcade and Khurana 2017).
Second, on debate within a doctrine, Van Horn and Mirowski (2009) point to the role
played by institutional entrepreneurs such as Aaron Director, Friedrich Hayek and Milton
Friedman in developing collective doctrine development projects such as the ‘Free Market
Project’ and the ‘Antitrust Project’ as a way of working together toward a common doctrine.
Within the bounds of the doctrine intense debating was strongly encouraged. Weekly semi-
nars were a unique contribution to the field at the time (McCloskey, 1992, p. 19) and
regarded as extremely ‘bloodthirsty’ (see Van Overtveldt, 2007, p. 39–41). Faculty and
graduate students met in professors’ homes to vote on the validity of theoretical discussions
and applications to economic policy (Medema, 2009, p. 104).
Third, on selective isolation, those in the Chicago School worked ‘more or less inde-
pendently’ of the ‘intellectual academic setting elsewhere’ (Fand, 1999, p. 11). This was
in part due to geography, being isolated from the large and prestigious incumbent uni-
versities, and also even within the city of Chicago itself (on the poor South Side) (Peck,
2010, pp. 84–85, 107–108). But isolation was also encouraged, with selective ties to
allies in academia and industry. By one account the economics department ‘provided a
relatively insular and protected atmosphere similar to that of a seminary’ (Fand, 1999, p.
12). At the same time, the department developed ties to Chicago’s financial sector pro-
vided them with alternative intellectual sparring partners with a common free market
purpose. The combination of these various unique conditions culminated in both faculty
and students being a unique, disciplined and coherent group with an ‘anti-Keynesian
professional identity’ married to rational expectations and a belief in the positive capaci-
ties of the free market (Van Gunten, 2015, p. 334).
Established accounts of the Charles River Group suggest that intensive training, debate
within a doctrinal culture and selective isolation were less intensively fostered. On intensive
training, Harvard had the most prestigious graduate training program in the country in the
1950s and 1960s. The courses were embedded in the dominant Keynesian thinking of the
time. Integration with the postwar policymaking establishment meant that professors were
often occupying key government positions and advising roles. While this enhanced the repu-
tation of the department in the short term, it did introduce costs to the graduate curriculum.
Correspondingly, some of the star professors, such as Galbraith, had little time for graduate
student supervision and did not supervise many graduate students. While graduate students
were exposed to the Keynesian cutting edge in economics, there was not a robust culture of
debate within a doctrine, and this was not a prominent feature of professor–student interac-
tions (See Gintis in Colander et al., 2004; Parker, 2005).
During the 1950s and 1960s, MIT focused on ascending in the ranks for graduate train-
ing prestige by maintaining intensive training within a relatively smaller cohort (Cherrier,
2014, p. 85). MIT produced fewer graduate students than its rivals until the 1970s, with fig-
ures like Solow and Dornbusch fostering the early generation of students, followed by
Kindleberger (Svorencık, 2014, pp. 113, 120). MIT worked to inculcate a distinctive brand
of economics that emphasized macroeconomics, growth models, mathematical training and
8 L. F. Henriksen et al.

the application of simple models to real-world problems. Debate was encouraged within this
broader focus rather than a concentrated doctrine. While MIT prided itself on focusing on
real-world economic problems as part of its curricula, by the late 1960s, MIT ‘was perceived
as too theoretically oriented and remote from real world issues’ (Fischer, 2004, p. 249).
On selective isolation, faculty at both Harvard and MIT were thoroughly involved in the

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ser/advance-article/doi/10.1093/ser/mwac024/6582368 by guest on 08 June 2022


world of policymaking, from the Council of Economic Advisors to presidential advisory
roles and special government committee assignments. The Kennedy and Johnson administra-
tions featured a great degree of Harvard faculty involvement, in particular. Unlike Chicago,
due to its isolation, Harvard and MIT were institutionally shaken up by the civil rights and
anti-war protests of the late 1960s. At Harvard, the late 1960s protests further fomented
divisions already brewing among faculty, putting them in different camps based on alignment
with anti-war protesters (Galbraith, 1981; Parker, 2005). This led to prominent disagreements
among key Harvard Faculty, such as between Galbraith and Gershenkron (Davidoff, 2002,
pp. 306–309). MIT economics was under political strain when it was disclosed that they did
extensive work for the Central Intelligence Agency and the US defense department. This led
not only to social agitation and protests (occupation of buildings where the economics depart-
ment was located, suspension of classes) but also to MIT failing to recruit several targeted fac-
ulty at the time (Cherrier, 2014, pp. 38–39). The rise of the New Left also saw demands for
radical political economy courses. At both Harvard and MIT, the Union of Radical Political
Economics had a presence and connected the protest movements to curricular reform, as well
as the politicization of tenure and promotion cases (Katzner, 2011). Given these external pres-
sures, graduate students in the Charles River Group were enmeshed in larger ideological strug-
gles in which their professors did not coordinate to offer a unified position.
Informed by this qualitative evidence, we ask if institutionally embedded socialization
mechanisms contributed to cohesion in network structures in the Chicago School and the
Charles River Group.

5. Data and network measures


Our data and analysis proceeds in three empirical steps, and uses a wide range of data sour-
ces and methods, as summarized in Figure 1 below. Empirical step 1 establishes how we
identified the core-set professors and their students. Empirical step 2 analyzes network cohe-
sion within and between the two rival groups. We focus on network measures associated
with group cohesion. We construct the network measures drawing on bibliometric data.
Empirical step 3 compares value orientations among the professors and students using peti-
tion data. The logic here is that if socialization mechanisms in intensive training, doctrine
and debate and selective isolation are present they should be reflected through scholarly peer
recognition in citations, in peer support through acknowledgements, and in enduring value
orientations associated with policy doctrines. We track the historical evolution of these
measures during a period of intellectual rivalry in US economics.

5.1 Sample population


Our initial analytical task was to establish two populations, which are by no means taken
for granted or already established. First, the prominent scholarly proponents associated with
the Chicago School and the Charles River Group were located. Second, a population of their
doctoral students was identified to establish the intellectual lineage from the professors.
Intellectual rivalry in American economics 9

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ser/advance-article/doi/10.1093/ser/mwac024/6582368 by guest on 08 June 2022


Figure 1 Steps in the research process.

Although our archival work extended beyond these years, we focus on the period from
1960 to 1985, when rivalry among these groups was most intense. It is clear that during this
period Chicago challenged the place of two key departments which shuffled for elite suprem-
acy in US economics, Harvard and MIT. As communities of professors and their students,
the Chicagoans and the Charles River Group sought to occupy similar attention space, vied
for elite status and informed each other’s work.
We document the logic behind this matching, which entailed a wide range of historical
data on university and department prestige, as well as the perceived caliber of graduate
training.5 Choosing Harvard and MIT as a contrast to Chicago is also appealing because
they form a geographically proximate community of scholars, and the professors we select
from each were both part of a similar intellectual milieu at the time and recognized each
other as peers involved in the production of next generation scholars. This minimizes varia-
tion in propinquity, which is strongly associated with network formation and intellectual
production (Jaffe et al., 1993). Harvard and MIT were known for being strongholds of the
Keynesian–Neoclassical synthesis and institutional economics, theoretical paradigms that
the Chicagoans were explicitly attacking.
To obtain our cast of prominent scholarly proponents, we collected and coded 100 dif-
ferent texts that described either the neoliberal transition in economics or the professional

5 For details see Supplementary Appendix A.


10 L. F. Henriksen et al.

lives of economists linked to the intellectual environments of interest. We call these ‘mem-
oire’ texts, as they are usually backward-looking retrospectives on professional develop-
ments within the field, most often centered around one individual economist. These include
book chapters, published articles commemorating a career, festschrifts and many published
interviews. By coding each of the economists that was mentioned in these texts, we gener-

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ser/advance-article/doi/10.1093/ser/mwac024/6582368 by guest on 08 June 2022


ated a large network of mutual regard, wherein we could establish lists of key individuals
who should be included in our study. Thus, in contrast to an approach that identifies com-
mon biographical attributes of individuals (cf. Svorencık, 2018), we opted to utilize the rela-
tional structure of narratives—provided by economists themselves—that identify
individual’s mutual regard for one another, thus allowing us to assess which economists
showed regard and esteem toward each other (Brennan and Pettit, 2004).
We coded our 100 texts in a large matrix, locating memoir texts on one axis and individual
economist names on the other. Of the 543 economists found in the memoires, we located 142
that were mentioned at least three times. We then conducted professional profiles on each to as-
certain inclusion criteria regarding whether the economist was professionally active or retired in
the period under study and whether or not they had moved through Chicago, Harvard and
MIT in their careers, a process that left 57 economists and their ties to one another through
memoire texts. From a two-mode bipartite network of memoire texts and economists, we gener-
ated a one-mode network consisting of only economists connected through their co-presence in
memoire texts, illustrated in Figure 2 below. The resultant network provides important infor-
mation on three aspects. First, it establishes a list of key economists which we can then sample
from. Second, it allows us to check whether economists selected are close to the core of this net-
work, or dispersed throughout. Third, it allows us to visualize the relational space of intellectual
rivalry within the network as an emergent structure, through community detection. Figure 2
provides the output of our network following community detection, using the Louvain commu-
nity detection algorithm (previously used in Seabrooke and Young, 2017). It shows two distinct
groups: the Chicago School (blue, at top) and the Charles River Group (red, at bottom).6
Our prosopographic approach helps to establish key actors among elite economists dur-
ing their day, rather than those that achieved recognition later in their careers. Our method
is thus an alternative to using professional achievement or formal recognition, such as lists
of Nobel Laureates or John Bates Clark medal holders, as has been done in other recent
scholarship (see Bjork et al., 2014; Cherrier and Svorencık, 2020).
Table 1 sets out the academic economists selected for our study, 13 from each group. All
of these individuals contributed significantly to debates in US economics during the period
of analysis and, importantly, are key figures within their respective intellectual tradition.
These economists are marked with square rather than circular nodes in Figure 2 below.
Existing scholarship usually emphasizes only a subset of the figures in our list, such as
Friedman and Stigler (Van Horn et al.. 2011; Nik-Khah and Van Horn, 2016, p. 27).
Our selection follows Collins’ view that it is not a particular individual who determines an
intellectual network, but the ‘action of the entire network across generations that determines
how much attention is paid to the ideas that are formulated at any particular point in it’
(Collins, 2004, p. 191).

6 Stanley Fischer is in the blue community, although it cannot be seen here. Further details are
explained in Supplementary Appendix B. Full details and the methodological considerations can be
found in Young et al., 2022.
Intellectual rivalry in American economics 11

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ser/advance-article/doi/10.1093/ser/mwac024/6582368 by guest on 08 June 2022


Figure 2. Community detection of core-set economists from memoire network.

Table 1 Economists in our sample

Chicago Charles River

Becker, G. S. (Chicago) Duesenberry, J.S. (Harvard)


Fama, E. F. (Chicago) Dunlop, J.T. (Harvard)
Fogel, R. W. (Chicago) Eckstein, O. (Harvard)
Friedman, M. (Chicago) Galbraith, J.K. (Harvard)
Harberger, A. (Chicago) Gerschenkron, A. (Harvard)
Johnson, H.G. (Chicago) Hirschman, A. (Harvard)
Lewis, H.G. (Chicago) Leontief, W. (Harvard)
Lucas, R. E. Jr. (Chicago) Musgrave, R. A. (Harvard)
Miller, M. H. (Chicago) Smithies, A. (Harvard)
Shultz, G. (Chicago) Kindleberger, C. P. (MIT)
Schultz, T. W. (Chicago) Modigliani, F. (MIT)
Stigler, G. J. (Chicago) Samuelson: A. (MIT)
Telser, L. G. (Chicago) Solow, R. M. (MIT)
Students found ¼ 276 Students found ¼ 308
12 L. F. Henriksen et al.

To obtain student–supervisory lineages from 1960 to 1980 we followed a multi-faceted


procedure. We consulted online repositories such as RepEc and Mathematics Genealogy,
festschrifts, memorial dedications, transcripts of oral histories, student lists from department
archives, extensive library searches for PhD theses and American Economics Association
student member biographies. Historical archives were also consulted. These archival materi-

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ser/advance-article/doi/10.1093/ser/mwac024/6582368 by guest on 08 June 2022


als offered more than just additional raw data on supervisor–student name links, but were a
rich source of contextual information about local institutional environments, professional
strategies, and intergenerational relationships. For Chicago we found 276 students and for
Charles River Group 308 students.
Despite this exhaustive and multi-faceted approach, we knew that our sample could po-
tentially still have unknown selection bias issues. Some selection bias was certainly mitigated
by the use of multiple sources, but we also pursued additional strategies involving the sam-
pling of large student cohorts, as well as verifying that we had obtained a good sample based
on the numbers of PhD graduates from each department.7

5.2 Measuring network cohesion


Having established 26 supervisors and 584 students from the rival groups, we set out to
identify salient social ties within the population. The aim is to measure the respective level of
group cohesion within and between supervisors and students of each group over time, using
common network analytic measures. We focus on two types of social ties: citations and
acknowledgements.
We collected data from Web of Science (WoS) on citations among the professors and their
students, focusing on the citation network from 1960 to 1985. Citations are explicitly directed
social acts that tie together papers and scholars through overlaps in substantive research inter-
ests (Hummon and Doreian, 1989). They also function as social rewards (Merton, 1968), as
well as indicating where scientific ideas flow (Lynn, 2014). All the professors were identified in
the data. 218 of the 276 total Chicago School students found were identified in the WoS data,
and 240 of the total 308 Charles River Group students. We included articles, letters, and notes
in our sample of citing works, matching the author names in our sample to citing works. We
then extracted the reference lists from the citing work and matched author names in the refer-
ence lists to our sample names, combining string matching with manual quality checking and
coding. This gave us a total of 426 unique authors, 404 of which were citing authors and 359
of which were cited authors. Self-citations were excluded. The resulting citation network con-
sisted of all the professors from both groups and the matched students, and record all ties be-
tween the entire population of professor and students.
We focused on horizontal citation (within professors and students) as well as vertical
citations (between professors and students) in the entire intellectual network. Within this
network, we measured the relative share of in-group and out-group citations. Given that we
observed all citations between professors and students in our population, the share of in-
group citations out of the total number of citations a group send is our first indicator of in-
group cohesion.
In addition to citations we also measured reciprocity and transitivity via scholarly sup-
port networks, detected through article acknowledgements. Social Exchange Theory sug-
gests that people invest in those they perceive as friends and expect rewards from these

7 These additional strategies are explained in Supplementary Appendix C.


Intellectual rivalry in American economics 13

investments (Emerson, 1976). In the context of friendship, ‘reciprocity entails responding to


other people’s friendly gestures in kind’ (Block, 2015, p. 164). When exchange parties deem
the balance between investment and returns satisfying, the friendship can continue. This
logic extends to transitive triads where support is received indirectly from a friend of a friend
(Newcomb, 1961). Acknowledgements are a common way of listing the peers that have

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ser/advance-article/doi/10.1093/ser/mwac024/6582368 by guest on 08 June 2022


been directly involved in providing feedback on a paper through participation in workshops
or through direct dyadic involvement in the paper writing process. These directed ties indi-
cate support in intellectual production. To gather acknowledgement ties, we took the publi-
cation records collected for the citation networks and coded the individuals listed in the
acknowledgements section of these articles, when these were available. Treating each article
author i and their acknowledged peers j as directed ties, we generated an ‘acknowledgement
network’ from these data. From this data we measured levels of reciprocity and transitivity
within the groups. 260 Chicago students and 302 Charles River students were identified and
acknowledgement coded. All of the listed professors were identified and coded.

5.3 Assessing value orientations


We suggest that when strong socialization mechanisms are at play, being trained in the same
school of thought produces similar value orientations which, in turn, is associated with
tighter in-group network cohesion.8 We used data from Hedengren et al. (2010), who gath-
ered 35 petitions and their signatories, from 1994 to 2009—a period in which Chicago
School-style neoliberal economics was dominant in US economics (Reay, 2012)—and classi-
fied each petition according to left versus right value orientations. Importantly, these data
not only have face validity but have been used in other scholarship and corroborated with
other measures of ideology. Jelveh et al. (2018) have used these petition data and show that
they accord well with two other sources of data: campaign contributions to either
Republicans or Democrats on the one hand and, on the other hand, the kinds of language
used in the publications of these authors. We found 5 professors and 64 of their students
from the Charles River Group in the petition data, and 6 professors and 61 of students from
the Chicago School. To compare value orientations, we focused on the relationship between
professors and students, tracing the reproduction of value orientations across generations.

6. Results
6.1 In-group versus out-group citations
Figure 3 below presents the share of in-group ties in the citation network. The top panel
illustrates the total share of in-group citations for each group. Note that in our analysis we
observe only citations sent to the sampled professors and students. The share of in-group
ties in the total sample of professors and students is relatively constant, hovering around
0.65 throughout the period. Breaking down the distribution by groups reveals a striking de-
velopment. Whereas the share of in-group citations for the Charles River Group in the early
1960s—a period still associated with Keynesian dominance—was high and stable just above
0.7, this steeply decreased and dropped from 0.76 to 0.5 in the period 1965–1980. In

8 Similarly, Ash et al. (2022) study the consequences of training judges through the Manne economics
training program, which leads to stronger use of economics language in sentencing and harsher
sentences.
14 L. F. Henriksen et al.

contrast, the Chicago School group share of in-group ties increased from 0.35 to 0.67 during
the same period. If we interpret this as one form of social cohesion, the two groups experi-
enced a profound change in their overall levels of cohesion. The Charles River Group moved
from being highly cohesive in the early 1960s (which also confirms that they were a cohesive
intellectual collective despite their location at two different institutions within the same city)

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ser/advance-article/doi/10.1093/ser/mwac024/6582368 by guest on 08 June 2022


to being much less cohesive from the mid-1960s onwards. An important point to stress here
is that the network of citations is made up of professors and students from two rival groups,
which makes it likely that an out-group citation from i ! j is a significant social act, suggest-
ing that not only is a low share of in-group citations an indication of little social cohesion
but also an indication of a strong orientation towards the out-group.
Subpanel (A) in Figure 3 displays the share of in-group citations among professors citing
other professors. On this measure of cohesion within the professorial groups only, the
Chicago School and Charles River Group professors steadily diverged with the Chicago
School becoming more cohesive over time and the Charles River Group less so. At the outset
of our observation period, the Charles River professors had a share of in-group citations
around 0.75, a number which drops to below 0.25 by the late 1960s and remained well be-
low .5 until 1980. The opposite is true for the Chicago School professors, which rose from
0.4 to 0.8 between 1960 and 1980.
Subpanel (B) shows the share of in-group citations among students citing other students,
and illustrates an initially lower but ultimately growing social cohesion among the Chicago
School students. Again, the opposite pattern repeats for the Charles River Group students,
who in the early period were far more likely to cite their fellow students than in the later pe-
riod. On this measure of cohesion within the junior generation the trend is clear but the dif-
ference toward the end of the observation period is less significant. Subpanel (C) illustrates a
similar pattern but for professors citing students. Subpanel (D) shows the perhaps most noti-
cable divergence of all: the share of in-group citations among the Charles River Group
students were high during most of the 1960s but dropped from 0.75 to 0.27 from 1968 to
1980. Although the student to professor cohesion in the Charles River Group was very high
at the outset, the Chicago School quickly outpaced them by the end of the 1960s. The
Chicago students share of in-group citations when citing professors rose from 0.48 in 1962
to 0.9 in 1980. Given this analysis is of citations within the overall sample, subpanel (D)
shows that after 1976 Charles River Group students were more likely to cite Chicago School
professors than their own.
Focusing on panels (A) and (D) reveals that by the end of the period 68% of the citations
sent by Chicago School faculty and students were addressed to scholars within the group,
representing the apex of an ever-growing amount of social cohesion. At the same time the
Charles River professors, while highly cohesive in the early 1960s, failed to reproduce their
initial high levels of cohesion and by 1980 only 50% of citations were in-group. The fact
that these trends occur before neoliberal economics truly takes off suggests that social cohe-
sion is a one of several causes, and not just a consequence, of the neoliberal ascent.

6.2 Reciprocity and transitivity in scholarly support


We also calculate reciprocity and transitivity, dividing the overall acknowledgement net-
work into separate networks for the Chicago School and the Charles River Group. These
generate unique networks cumulated over time from 1960 to 1980, including the professors
and their students. Figure 4 presents our acknowledgement network. The green highlighted
Intellectual rivalry in American economics 15

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ser/advance-article/doi/10.1093/ser/mwac024/6582368 by guest on 08 June 2022

Figure 3 Share of within group citations out of the total citations made by the group (dashed line is fit-
ted using a simple linear regression).

ties are acknowledgement ties that were reciprocated, which predominated among the blue
(Chicago) nodes. Figure 5 presents the cumulated reciprocity and transitivity in the acknowl-
edgement network, tracing the prevalence of each mechanism across the period.
In the leftmost panel of Figure 5, we observe cumulative reciprocity. In this case, it liter-
ally means ‘I thank you, you thank me’ dynamics within the journal publications of the
time. The Chicago School was more frequently engaging in reciprocation, and their share of
reciprocated ties increased over the period. In the beginning of the observation window,
16 L. F. Henriksen et al.

reciprocity was rare for both groups since a set of directed ties needs to be established before
they can be reciprocated. For the Charles River Group, it took 6 years before a tie had been
reciprocated, whereas for the Chicago School it took only 3 years. After their first reciproca-
tion, the Charles River Group’s share of reciprocated ties remained just below 2%. For
Chicago, the share was 0.05 in the early 1960s, then dropping to ca. 0.03 but in the early

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ser/advance-article/doi/10.1093/ser/mwac024/6582368 by guest on 08 June 2022


1970s increasing to 0.06—three times higher than the Charles River Group—and staying
there throughout the 1970s. This lends credence to the idea that mutual support was an im-
portant aspect in building social cohesion within the group. This is also exemplified in the
different venues that Chicago School professors and students published in during this pe-
riod, such as Journal of Political Economy—itself based at the University of Chicago—
rather than in establishment journals such as the American Economic Review.
We also measured transitivity in acknowledgments, indicating closed triadic triplets
where i ! j ! h ! i. This is a measure of in-group mutual support in that it measures the
extent of clique formation when it comes to helping one another with scientific production.
As the right-hand panel of Figure 5 illustrates, the transitivity scores were significantly
higher for the Chicago School economists than for their Charles River Group rivals.
Transitivity increased for both groups over the observation period, with a peak in the mid-
1970s for both groups—the Charles River Group at 0.04 and the Chicago School at 0.07.
The fact that the Chicago School had higher scores of both reciprocity and transitivity
throughout this period, including in the 1960s before their triumph by the late 1970s, lends
credence to the idea that these social cohesion dynamics played a causal role, rather than the

Figure 4 Acknowledgement network, with Chicago in Blue and Charles River in Red.
Intellectual rivalry in American economics 17

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ser/advance-article/doi/10.1093/ser/mwac024/6582368 by guest on 08 June 2022


Figure 5 Reciprocity and Transitivity in Acknowledgement Networks over time, 1960–1980.

acceptance of neoliberal economics in the US economics profession then making Chicagoans


more cohesive.

6.3 Value orientations


Our analysis above stresses the differences in social cohesion, which we argue was important
for neoliberal economists’ ascent. But social cohesion in the form of scholarly citations and
acknowledgements does not necessarily entail a shared normative understanding about the
future governance of the economy and instead could be driven by other factors, such as dif-
ferences in methodological style. The collective intellectual project known as Chicago
School was about changing the shared understanding of how economies are governed,
which was at the heart of socialization processes at Chicago (Van Overtveldt, 2007;
Mirowski and Plehwe, 2009). We propose that such value orientation was also an important
feature in which the Chicago School stood out, with a higher degree of shared value among
the professors, and between the professors and their students. This further strengthened so-
cial cohesion and produced a core doctrine that anchored the Chicago School as a collective
agent in the academy and beyond (Mudge, 2018).
Figure 6, below, illustrates the result of mean left-right scores for all the economists in
our sample that matched with the petitions data described above. Because Hedengren et al.
(2010) and Jelveh et al. (2018) represent different scorings, we included both to see if any
results would be sensitive to different scorings of left-right. We first generated simple counts
using - and þ values for the number of left or right-coded petitions a given economist signed.
In Figure 6 below, we show the percentage score, whereby the left-right count is compared
to the total number of petitions signed by a given economist. The error bars represent the
standard deviation in each set of values, oriented about the mean. We observe these value
18 L. F. Henriksen et al.

orientations within the group much later than our other network data, which means that se-
lection and survivor bias could skew our indicators. On the other hand, this is a powerful in-
dicator of generational transfer of attitudes and its endurance into several decades after
these economists received their training.
We compared each set of professors for the Chicago School and the Charles River

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ser/advance-article/doi/10.1093/ser/mwac024/6582368 by guest on 08 June 2022


Group, with their corresponding student group, to compare differences in value orientations
across generations. To facilitate a baseline, we included the mean score for all economists
who signed petitions in these data, which represents approximately 6000 economists, show-
ing a slightly right-leaning orientation in general.
These results show the rightward orientation of the Chicago School professors, which con-
forms with our knowledge of this group. Notably, however, Chicago School students are rela-
tively close in their orientation to their professors, across all scoring methods. The situation for
Harvard and MIT is largely the opposite—these professors were more left-leaning in their
petition-signing and this orientation did not translate over to their students as clearly, who
gravitated closer to the center with a wide variation among the center indicating large differen-
ces in value orientations across generations.
One potential objection to this analysis is that students self-selected into different gradu-
ate programs based on their ideological proclivities. Yet, there are several important histori-
cal facts about how top graduate programs in economics operated that suggest that such
selection effects are ameliorated. One is that economics during this period was seen as a
highly technical subject, not dissimilar to how mainstream representations of the profession
operate today. While there were important debates and dividing lines within economics
from the postwar period to the 1970s, there was also a strong general confidence, related to
the Keynesian–Neoclassical synthesis prevailing at the time, that technical fixes to economic
problems were both possible and technocratic in nature (Fourcade-Gourinchas and Babb,
2002; Helgadóttir, 2021).
Second, top US economics departments clearly competed for graduate students and the
terrain of competition was funding. Archival evidence from Harvard in the 1950s
reveals how its economics department competed with Chicago and many other schools.
While Harvard was more prestigious at the time, there was grave concern, from scholars
like Galbraith, that Harvard would lose ground because of less generous funding packages.
Many students were recruited into the MIT program though their interests in mathematics
and physics, reflecting the cultural milieu of the school (Cherrier, 2014).
The third piece of evidence that supports the notion that ideological selection into eco-
nomics programs was ameliorated has to do with biographical accounts of individuals’ ide-
ology at the beginning of the program versus the end. Several prominent Chicago School
graduates entered the program as leftists but did not leave the program that way (Stoller,
2018, p. 230). Accounts of the Chicago School environment in the 1950s suggest that most
incoming students did not come to study for ideological motivations. According to Fand
(1999), when it comes to the big questions of free enterprise and government planning, most
students entered the program as social democrats.

7. Discussion
This article argues that the group identified with Chicago was more successful in reproduc-
ing social cohesion, even when the main rivals at Harvard and MIT were more initially
Intellectual rivalry in American economics 19

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ser/advance-article/doi/10.1093/ser/mwac024/6582368 by guest on 08 June 2022


Figure 6 Ideological Orientation of Economists, 1994–2009.

prominent in the US economics profession. Cohesion in the Chicago group carried across
generations, supporting the rise of neoliberal economics. Our analysis demonstrates that so-
cial cohesion in the Chicago School was quite limited during the early 1960s, when the
Charles River Group was highly cohesive and mainstream. This relative distribution of social
cohesion then flipped during the 1960s and 1970s. We posit that respective increases and
declines in social cohesion was a central enabling factor in the tectonic epistemic shift from
Keynesian dominance to the mainstreaming of neoliberal ideas during the 1970s and 1980s.
The Chicago School started from a position as self-perceived underdog, needing to build
cohesion within their own peer group with heavily concerted action from key figures like
Friedman and Stigler. Extant qualitative accounts stress how the Chicago School fostered so-
cialization through intensive training, an organized system of debate within a doctrine, and
selective isolation from other university environments while creating ties to the finance
20 L. F. Henriksen et al.

community. Chicago economists established close bonds with their students and a national
reputation for their bloodlust and ambition. Over time the group became more cohesive
both within its professoriate and in relations between professors and students. Value orien-
tations of Chicago students also resembled their professors to a great extent. The label
‘Chicago School’, initially rejected as ideological slander, was later embraced as a marker of

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ser/advance-article/doi/10.1093/ser/mwac024/6582368 by guest on 08 June 2022


scientific rigor, conceptual clarity, and policy relevance. Textbooks were produced that
propagated neoliberal economics and replicated myths about the failures of Keynesian eco-
nomics (Forder, 2014). This is how neoliberal knowledge was supported in US economics,
from which they entered into governments and corporations to promote economic reforms.
In contrast, the Charles River Group during the 1960 to 1985 period moved from a posi-
tion of strong social cohesion and intellectual dominance to one where supportive relation-
ships among the professoriate and between professors and students were less frequent.
Compared to their Chicagoan peers, Harvard and MIT professors were more distant from
their students and not known for maintaining ideological coherence. Their students increas-
ingly cited Chicago professors more than their own and the value orientations of the stu-
dents did not resemble their professors and were highly dispersed. Charles River Group
professors and students also displayed far lower levels of reciprocal acknowledgement.
While Keynesian economic models were modified, the lack of social cohesion to support
their propagation is likely to have weakened their position in US economics. Importantly,
these effects preceded the rise of the Chicago School. As such, they are not reducible to being
merely a consequence of professional ascent but a cause of it.
While the rise of neoliberal economics is a causal process involving multiple factors, our
evidence suggests that the Chicago School’s process of building a cohesive community of se-
nior and junior scholars that could propagate the neoliberal gospel was not simply an effect
of broader institutional developments: their cohesion was clearly on the rise in the 1960s
when Keynesian thinking was still dominant. Our analysis contributes to, rather than com-
petes with, existing accounts of the rise of neoliberal economics. Focusing attention on the
group-level dynamics within the economics profession itself is valuable because of the im-
portance of neoliberal ideas, which were generated and fostered within economics depart-
ments. The neoliberal turn was not only championed by politicians—but also forged in the
academy—and its continued development was guided by leading figures who could propa-
gate the simplicity and scientific character of neoliberal economic ideas (Reay, 2012;
Mandelkern, 2021).
Our study of intellectual networks and how they foster social cohesion, within and
across generations, provides new evidence on the rise of the Chicago School and contributes
to our understanding of neoliberalism’s rise. Not only do we show that the Chicago School
became more cohesive, but that their main rival lost cohesion. This ‘origin story’ is impor-
tant to understand given the wide-reaching effects of the Chicago School. Research has
shown how US economists’ opinions on issues like the diffusion of privatization converged
among Chicago-trained economists in the 1990s (Macpherson, 2006, p. 196). Such conver-
gence was important in propagating neoliberal economic reforms in Central and South
American countries (Babb, 2001; Louç~a and Ash, 2018), as well as in former communist
Eastern European countries (Bockman and Eyal, 2002; Bandelj, 2008; Ban, 2016).
Neoliberal economic thought has also been important in altering the policy direction of in-
ternational organizations away from their original more Keynesian mandates (Ban, 2015;
Kentikelenis and Seabrooke, 2017; Kentikelenis and Babb, 2019).
Intellectual rivalry in American economics 21

Such outcomes have a deeply social origin in how professors organized themselves and
socialized their students to give to their intellectual network momentum. Studying how intel-
lectual currents are sustained over generations is important in understanding what forms of
science are valued over others, as well as how mentor–mentee networks affirm power asym-
metries, including methodological and gender hierarchies within scholarly fields (Bandelj,

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ser/advance-article/doi/10.1093/ser/mwac024/6582368 by guest on 08 June 2022


2019). In the context of an intellectual rivalry with the Charles River Group, the Chicago
School of Economics developed institutionally embedded socialization mechanisms that sup-
ported high levels of social cohesion over generations. These social foundations are impor-
tant in explaining the rise of neoliberal economics in the US, which then transformed the
rest of the world.

Acknowledgments
We thank Jacob Lunding, Elizabeth Sullivan-Hasson, Eric Winkler, Elliot Jerry and Pamela
Eisner, who all worked as research assistants on different parts of this project. We also acknowl-
edge Jenny Andersson, Michael Ash, Cornel Ban, Jens Beckert, Bruce Carruthers, Carol Heim,
Oddny Helgadóttir, Larry King, Elisa Klüger, Francisco Louç~
a, Doug McAdam, Mathieu Dufour,
Elsa Massoc, David Stark, Mitchell Stevens and Marc Ventresca for their comments. Our special
thanks also go to Thomas Ferguson for generative discussions about the project. Previous versions
of this paper were presented at seminars at the Copenhagen Business School, Columbia
University, Stanford University and at SASE conferences in 2016 and 2019. We are grateful to
staff at the Hoover Institute archive, the JFK Memorial Library archives, the Harvard University
Archives, the Duke University Rosenstein Library Archive, as well as staff in the Harvard and
Chicago economics departments for assistance with historical PhD graduation data.

Funding
This project received funding from the Velux Foundation (#00021820-NICHE), the
Institute for New Economic Thinking (#INO1500030) and the Independent Research Fund
Denmark grant (#5052-001143-B).

Supplementary material
Supplementary material in the form of appendices are available here.

References
Amadae, S. M. (2003) Rationalizing Capitalist Democracy: The Cold War Origins of Rational
Choice Liberalism, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
Ash, E., Chen, D. L., & Naidu, S. (2022) Ideas have consequences: The impact of law and eco-
nomics on american justice (No. w29788). National Bureau of Economic Research.
Backhouse, R. E. (2005) ‘The Rise of Free Market Economics: Economists and the Role of the
State Since’, History of Political Economy, 37, 355–392.
Ban, C. (2015) ‘Austerity versus Stimulus? Understanding Fiscal Policy Change at the
International Monetary Fund since the Great Recession’, Governance, 28, 167–183.
Ban, C. (2016) Ruling Ideas: How Global Neoliberalism Goes Local, Oxford, Oxford University
Press.
22 L. F. Henriksen et al.

Bandelj, N. (2008) From Communists to Foreign Capitalists: The Social Foundations of Foreign
Direct Investment in Postsocialist Europe, Princeton, Princeton University Press.
Bandelj, N. (2019) ‘Academic Familism, Spillover Prestige and Gender Segregation in Sociology
Subfields: The Trajectory of Economic Sociology’, The American Sociologist, 50, 488–508.
Barraclough, G. (1977) ‘The Keynesian Era in Perspective’. In Skidelsky, S. (ed) The End of the

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ser/advance-article/doi/10.1093/ser/mwac024/6582368 by guest on 08 June 2022


Keynesian Era: Essays on the Disintegration of the Keynesian Political Economy, New York,
Holes and Meier, pp. 106–117.
Bjork, S., Offer, A. and Söderberg, G. (2014) ‘Time Series Citation Data: The Nobel Prize in
Economics’, Scientometrics, 98, 185–196.
Block, P. (2015) ‘Reciprocity, Transitivity, and the Mysterious Three-Cycle’, Social Networks, 40,
163–173.
Bockman, J. and Eyal, G. (2002) ‘Eastern Europe as a Laboratory for Economic Knowledge: The
Transnational Roots of Neoliberalism’, American Journal of Sociology, 108, 310–352.
Brennan, G. and Pettit, P. (2004) The Economy of Esteem: An Essay on Civil and Political
Society, Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Bronfenbrenner, M. (1962) ‘Observations on the ‘Chicago School(s)’, Journal of Political
Economy, 70, 72–75.
Buchanan, J. M. (1987) ‘The Constitution of Economic Policy’, American Economic Review, 77,
243–250.
Cherrier, B. (2014) ‘Toward a History of Economics of MIT, 1940’, History of Political
Economy, 46, 15–44.
Cherrier, B. and Svorencık, A. (2018) ‘The Quantitative Turn in the History of Economics:
Promises, Perils and Challenges’, Journal of Economic Methodology, 25, 367–377.
Cherrier, B. and Svorencık, A. (2020) ‘Defining Excellence: Seventy Years of the John Bates Clark
Medal’, Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 42, 153–176.
Clark, M. (1994) ‘Wither the Nation-State? The Subaltern and the Redeployment of Latin
American Nationalism in the Era of Globalization’, Dispositio, 19, 27–44.
Colander, D., Holt, R. P. F. and Barkley, J. (2004) The Changing Face of Economics:
Conversations with Cutting Edge Economists, Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press.
Collins, R. (1989) ‘Towards a Theory of Intellectual Change: The Social Causes of Philosophies’,
Science, Technology, & Human Values, 14, 107–140.
Collins, R. (1998) The Sociology of Philosophies: A Global Theory of Intellectual Change,
Cambridge, Harvard University Press.
Collins, R. (2004) Interaction Ritual Chains, Princeton, Princeton University Press.
Crane, D. (1972) Invisible Colleges: Diffusion of Knowledge in Scientific Communities, Chicago,
Chicago University Press.
Davidoff, N. (2002) The Fly Swatter: Portrait of an Exceptional Character, New York, Random
House.
Emerson, R. M. (1976) ‘Social Exchange Theory’, Annual Review of Sociology, 2, 335–362.
Emmett, R. B. (2011) ‘Sharpening Tools in the Workshop: The Workshop System and the
Chicago School’s Success’. In Van Horn, R., Mirowski, P. and Stapleford, T. (eds) Building
Chicago Economics, Cambridge University Press, pp. 93–115.
Fand, D. I. (1999) ‘Friedman’s Price Theory: Economics 300 at the University of Chicago in
1947–1951’. In Hammond, J. D. (ed) The Legacy of Milton Friedman as Teacher, Vol. 1,
Northampton, Edward Elgar, pp. 9–21.
Fischer, S. (2004) ‘An Interview with Stanley Fischer’, by Oliver Blanchard’, Macroeconomic
Dynamics, 2, 244–262.
Forder, J. (2014) Macroeconomics and the Phillips Curve, Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Fourcade-Gourinchas, M. and Babb, S. L. (2002) ‘The Rebirth of the Liberal Creed: Paths to
Neoliberalism in Four Countries’, American Journal of Sociology, 108, 533–579.
Intellectual rivalry in American economics 23

Fourcade, M. and Khurana, R. (2017) ‘The Social Trajectory of a Finance Professor and the
Common Sense of Capital’, History of Political Economy, 49, 347–381.
Fourcade, M., Ollion, E. and Algan, Y. (2015) ‘The Superiority of Economists’, Journal of
Economic Perspectives, 29, 89–114.
Frazer, W. J. (1988) Power and Ideas: Milton Friedman and the Big U-Turn, Gainsville, Gulf,

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ser/advance-article/doi/10.1093/ser/mwac024/6582368 by guest on 08 June 2022


Atlantic Publishing Company.
Friedkin, N. E. (1978) ‘University Social Structure and Social Networks among Scientists’,
American Journal of Sociology, 83, 1444–1465.
Friedman, M. Capitalism and Freedom, University of Chicago Press, Chicago , 1982.
Galbraith, J. K. (1981) A Life in Our Times, New York, Random House.
Gibbon, P., and Henriksen, L. F. (2012) ‘A Standard Fit for Neoliberalism’, Comparative Studies
in Society and History, 54, 2, 275–307.
Hammond, J. D. (ed.) (1999). The Legacy of Milton Friedman as Teacher: Volume 1,
Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.
Hedengren, D., Klein, D. B. and Milton, C. (2010) ‘Economist petitions: Ideology revealed’, Econ
Journal Watch, 7, 288–319.
Hirschman, D. and Berman, E. P. (2014) ‘Do Economists Make Policies? On the Political Effects
of Economics’, Socio-Economic Review, 12, 779–811.
Helgadóttir, O. (2021) ‘How to Make a Super Model: Professional Incentives and the Birth of
Contemporary Macroeconomics’, Review of International Political Economy, 1–29. https:
//doi.org/10.1080/09692290.2021.1997786.
Hummon, N. P. and Doreian, P. (1989) ‘Connectivity in a Citation Network: The Development of
DNA Theory’, Social Networks, 11, 39–63.
Jaffe, A. B., Trajtenberg, M. and Henderson, R. (1993) ‘Geographic Localization of Knowledge
Spillovers as Evidenced by Patent Citations’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 79, 957–970.
Jelveh, Z., Kogut, B. and Naidu, S. (2018) ‘Political language in economics’, In Columbia Business
School Research Paper No. 14-57. Available at SSRN: http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2535453.
Johnson, H. (2003) ‘The Keynesian revolution and the monetarist counter-revolution’, In Leeson,
R. (ed.) Keynes, Chicago and Friedman, London, Pickering & Chatto, Vol. 1, pp. 169–182.
Katzner, D. (2011) At the Edge of Camelot: Debating Economics in Turbulent Times, Oxford,
Oxford University Press.
Karaagac, J. (2002) Between Promise and Policy: Ronald Reagan and Conservative Reformism,
Lanham, MD, Lexington Books.
Kentikelenis, A. E. and Babb, S. (2019) ‘The Making of Neoliberal Globalization: Norm
Substitution and the Politics of Clandestine Institutional Change’, American Journal of
Sociology, 124, 1720–1762.
Kentikelenis, A. E. and Seabrooke, L. (2017) ‘The Politics of World Polity: Script-writing in
International Organizations’, American Sociological Review, 82, 1065–1092.
Kogut, B. and Macpherson, J. M. (2011) ‘The Mobility of Economists and the Diffusion of Policy
Ideas: The Influence of Economics on National Policies’, Research Policy, 40, 1307–1320.
Kotz, D. 2015. The Rise and Fall of Neoliberal Capitalism, Cambridge, Harvard University Press.
Louç~a, F. and Ash, M. 2018. Shadow Networks: Financial Disorder and the System That Causes
Crisis, Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Lievrouw, L. A. (1989) ‘The Invisible College Reconsidered: Bibliometrics and the Development
of Scientific Communication Theory’, Communication Research, 16, 615–628.
Lynn, F. B. (2014) ‘Diffusing through Disciplines: Insiders, Outsiders, and Socially Influenced
Citation Behavior’, Social Forces, 93, 355–382.
Manne, H. (2005) ‘How Law and Economics Was Marketed in a Hostile World: A Very Personal
History’. In Parisi, F. and Rowley, C. K. (eds) Essays by the Founding Fathers, Northampton,
Edward Elgar, pp. 309–325.
24 L. F. Henriksen et al.

Macpherson, J. M. (2006) ‘Palace Wars and Privatization: Did Chicago Beat Cambridge in
Influencing Economic Policies’, European Management Review, 3, 190–198.
Mandelkern, R. (2021) ‘Neoliberal Ideas of Government and the Political Empowerment of
Economists in Advanced Nation-States: The Case of Israel’, Socio-Economic Review, 19,
659–679.

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ser/advance-article/doi/10.1093/ser/mwac024/6582368 by guest on 08 June 2022


McCloskey, D. (1992) ‘Alexander Gerschenkron: By a Student’, The American Scholar, 61,
241–246.
McMahan, P. and McFarland, D. A. (2021) ‘Creative Destruction: The Structural Consequences
of Scientific Curation’, American Sociological Review, 86, 341–376.
Medema, S. G. (2009) The Hesitant Hand: Taming Self-Interest in the History of Economic Ideas,
Princeton, Princeton University Press.
Merton, R. K. (1968) ‘The Matthew Effect in Science’, Science, 159, 56–63.
Miller, H. L. Jr. (1962) ‘Chicago School of Economics’, Journal of Political Economy, 70, 64–69.
Mirowski, P. and Plehwe, D. (eds) (2009) The Road from Mont Pèlerin: The Making of the
Neoliberal Thought Collective, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Moody, J. (2004) ‘The Structure of a Social Science Collaboration Network: Disciplinary
Cohesion from 1963 To 1999’, American Sociological Review, 69, 213–238.
Mudge, S. (2018) Leftism Reinvented: Western Parties from Socialism to Neoliberalism,
Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.
Newcomb, T. M. (1961) The Acquaintance Process, New York, Holt, Rinehart and Winston.
Nik-Khah, E. and. Van Horn, R. (2016) ‘The Ascendancy of Chicago Neoliberalism’. In Springer,
S., Birch, K. and MacLeavy, J. (eds) The Handbook of Neoliberalism, London, Routledge, pp.
13–24.
Parker, R. (2005) John Kenneth Galbraith: His Life, His Politics, His Economics, New York,
Harper Collins.
Patinkin, D. (1981) Essays on and in the Chicago Tradition, Durham, Duke University Press.
Peck, J. (2010) Constructions of Neoliberal Reason, Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Packenham, R. A. 1973. Liberal America and the Third World: Political Development Ideas in
Foreign Aid and Social Science, Princeton, Princeton University Press.
Polillo, S. (2020) The Ascent of Market Efficiency: Finance That Cannot Be Proven, Ithaca,
Cornell University Press.
Price, S. (1965) ‘Networks of Scientific Papers’, Science (New York, N.Y.), 149, 510–515.
Reay, M. J. (2012) ‘The Flexible Unity of Economics’, American Journal of Sociology, 118,
45–87.
Reder, M. W. (1982) ‘Chicago Economics: Permanence and Change’, Journal of Economic
Literature, 20, 1–38.
Rossi, P.E. (1989) ‘The ET Interview: Professor Arnold Zellner’, Econometric Theory, 5,
287–317.
Rossier, T. (2020) ‘Accumulation and Conversion of Capitals in Professorial Careers. The
Importance of Scientific Reputation, Network Relations, and Internationality in Economics
and Business Studies’, Higher Education, 80, 1061–1080.
Samuelson, P. A. (1946) ‘Lord Keynes and the General Theory’, Econometrica, 14, 187–200.
Schlesinger, Jr, A. M. A Thousand Days: John F. Kennedy in the White House, Mayflower-Dell,
London, 1964.
Seabrooke, L. and Young, K. (2017) ‘The Networks and Niches of International Political
Economy’, Review of International Political Economy, 24, 288–331.
Shils, E (1991) Remembering the University of Chicago: Teachers, Scientists, and Scholars,
Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
Skousen, M. (2005) Chicago and Vienna, Washington, DC, Capital Press.
Intellectual rivalry in American economics 25

Slobodian, Q. (2018) Globalists: The End of Empire and the Birth of Neoliberalism, Cambridge,
MA, Harvard University Press.
Small, H. (1980) ‘Co-Citation Context Analysis and the Structure of Paradigms’, Journal of
Documentation, 36, 183–196.
Stoller, M. (2018) Goliath: The 100-Year War between Monopoly Power and Democracy, New

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ser/advance-article/doi/10.1093/ser/mwac024/6582368 by guest on 08 June 2022


York, Simon & Schuster.
Svorencık, A. (2014) ‘MIT’s Rise to Prominence: Outline of a Collective Biography’, History of
Political Economy, 46, 109–133.
Svorencık, A. (2018) ‘The Missing Link: Prosopography in the History of Economics’, History of
Political Economy, 50, 605–613.
Van Gunten, T. S. (2015) ‘Cycles of Polarization and Settlement: Diffusion and Transformation in
the Macroeconomic Policy Field’, Theory and Society, 44, 321–354.
Van Gunten, T. S., Martin, J. L. and Teplitskiy, M. (2016) ‘Consensus, Polarization, and
Alignment in the Economics Profession’, Sociological Science, 3, 1028–1052.
Van Horn, R. D. (2007) ‘The Origins and Rise of Chicago Law and Economics’, Doctoral
Dissertation, Graduate Program in Economics, University of Notre Dame.
Van Horn, R. (2018) ‘Corporations and the Rise of Chicago Law and Economics’, Economy and
Society, 47, 477–499.
Van Horn, R. and Mirowski, P. (2009) ‘The Rise of the Chicago School of Economics and the
Birth of Neoliberalism’, In Mirowski, P. and Plehwe, D. (eds) The Road from Mont Pèlerin:
The Making of the Neoliberal Thought Collective, Cambridge, Harvard University Press, pp.
139–178.
Van Horn, R., and Mirowski, P. (2010) ‘Neoliberalism and Chicago’, In Emmett, R. B. (ed.) The
Elgar Companion to the Chicago School of Economics, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar Publishing,
pp. 196–206.
Van Horn, R., Mirowski, P. and Stapleford, T. A. (eds) (2011) Building Chicago Economics: New
Perspectives on the History of America’s Most Powerful Economics Program, Cambridge,
Cambridge University Press.
Van Overtveldt, J. (2007) The Chicago School: How the University of Chicago Assembled the
Thinkers Who Revolutionized Economics and Business, Chicago, Agate Publishing.
Young, K. L., Seabrooke, L. and Henriksen, L. F. (2022). ‘Memoire Networks as Method of
Discovery’, Mimeo, Copenhagen Business School.

View publication stats

You might also like