Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 17

Accelerat ing t he world's research.

Academy o/ Management Review


STAKEHOLDER INFLUENCE
STRATEGIES
Donghyun Kim

Related papers Download a PDF Pack of t he best relat ed papers 

St akeholder influences on sust ainabilit y pract ices in t he Canadian forest product s indust ry
Irene Henriques

Pat hways of st akeholder influence in t he Canadian forest ry indust ry


Irene Henriques

T he development of Universit y Technology Transfer st akeholder relat ionships at a regional level: Les…
Krist el Miller
* Academy o/ Management Review
1999. Vol. 24. No. 2. 191^205.

STAKEHOLDER INFLUENCE STRATEGIES


JEFF FROOMAN
University of Pittsburgh

When seeking to iniluence firm decision making, what types oi influence strategies do
stakeholders have available, and what determines which type the stakeholders
choose to use? In this article I use resource dependence theory to investigate these
two questions. I propose that the resource relationship (who is dependent on whom)
determines which of the four types of strategies identified in this article will be used:
direct withholding, direct usage, indirect withholding, or indirect usage.

Freeman's (1984) Strategic Management: A this missing part of stakeholder theory and ulti-
Stakeholder Approach brought stakeholder the- mately enable managers to better understand
ory into the mainstream of management litera- and manage stakeholder behavior.
ture. As clearly expressed in the title of the book, Specifically, in this article I seek to investi-
one central purpose of stakeholder theory has gate these two research questions regarding
been to enable managers to understand stake- stakeholder influence strategies:
holders and strategically manage them. As
Freeman states, "The stakeholder approach is 3a. What are the different types of influence
about groups and individuals who can affect the strategies?
organization, and is about managerial behavior 3b. What are the determinants of the choice of
influence strategy?
taken in response to those groups and individ-
uals" (1984: 48). In developing such response In investigating these two questions, I merge
strategies, it seems that we need to answer stakeholder theory with resource dependence
three general questions about stakeholders: theory to propose that the types of influence
1. Who are they? (This question concerns their
strategies can be understood in terms of re-
attributes.) sources and that a determinant of the choice of
2. What do they want? (This question concerns strategies will be the type of resource relation-
their ends.) ship the firm and stakeholder have and where
3. How are they going to try to get it? (This the balance of power lies within that relation-
question concerns their means.) ship.
Here, I intend to suggest that although re-
searchers have been addressing the first two
questions, they have given the third question, MAJOR CONTRIBUTIONS OF THIS ARTICLE
regarding stakeholder means-—or stakeholder Throughout much of this article, I use Free-
influence strategies—only piecemeal attention. man's (1984) work on stakeholders as my point of
Nowhere in the literature have scholars made departure. Although almost 15 years old now, no
any systematic attempt to treat stakeholder in- one can underestimate this work's effect on the
fluence strategies in the broadest sense—that management literature or undervalue its worth
is, as phenomena that can be categorized and today. In the work Freeman presents the stake-
built into a descriptive model. That is the objec- holder model as a map in which the firm is the
tive of this article—to build a model of stake- hub of a wheel and stakeholders are at the ends
holder influence strategies that will address of spokes around the wheel. This conceptualiza-
tion has become the convention from which
stakeholder theory has developed. However, in
I thank the following for their helpful comments during this hub-and-spoke conceptualization, relation-
the development of this work: Gaurab Bwardwaj, Craig ships are dyadic, independent of one another,
Caldwell, Ray Jones, Tim Rowley, Alyssa Sankey, and three
anonymous reviewers. I especially thank Barry M. Mitnick
viewed largely from the firm's vantage point,
for the guidance and insight he has provided me throughout and defined in terms of actor attributes. In pre-
this project. senting my theory of stakeholder influence strat-
191
192 Academy oi Management Review April

egies. I expand the stakeholder model in each of Missing from the theory, then, has been an
these respects. account of how stakeholders manage a firm to
For example, in this article I discuss a conflict enable them to achieve their interests, possibly
involving StarKist, its consumers, and the Earth at the expense of the firm's. Such an account is
Island Institute (EII). I argue that the StarKist- unidirectional in nature, although with relation-
consumer relationship was not independent of ships viewed from the stakeholder's vantage
the StarKist-EII relationship; in reality, the two point. For anyone building theory, this should be
dyadic relationships were imbedded in a triadic interesting in its own right, but even from a
one. To be meaningful for a firm intent on man- pragmatic managerial standpoint, this has to be
aging its stakeholders, then, stakeholder theory of interest. After all, if firms such as StarKist do
needs to be able to place firms in their proper exist in a stakeholder context, how such firms
context—that of multiactor relationships, like act to achieve their interests must be, in part,
the one StarKist had with its consumers and the dependent on how they expect their stakehold-
EII. In this article I incorporate strategies of ers will act (Brenner & Cochran, 1991). And, if
stakeholders acting through allies to influence what a firm should do is partly determined by
firms, thereby explicitly introducing triads con- what its stakeholders will do, we need an ac-
sisting of nonindependent relationships and count of what its stakeholders will do. Therefore,
to be really useful to a firm trying to manage its
suggesting that the same approach will work for
stakeholders, stakeholder theory must provide
higher-order stakeholder combinations.
an account of how stakeholders try to manage a
Regarding the theory's prevailing directional- firm. Again, that is the central purpose of this
ity— or the vantage point from which things are article: to provide an account of how stakehold-
viewed—Freeman's original definition, which is ers try to act to influence the firm's decision
still widely used, provides insight. His definition making and, ultimately, the firm's behavior.
labels a stakeholder as "any group or individual
Finally, stakeholder theory's emphasis, to
who can affect or is affected by the achievement
date, has been on the individuals in the relation-
of the firm's objectives" (1984: 25). Goodpastor ships—not on the relationships themselves.
(1991) has observed that this definition implies Consider the simplest variant of a stakeholder
two types of stakeholders—strategic and mor- analysis: a firm with only one stakeholder. In
al—and so one way to view the stakeholder lit- general, only the firm and the stakeholder have
erature, broadly speaking, is in terms of two been brought under the lens. There is, however,
branches. common in the organization theory literature a
With the strategic stakeholder (the one who way to view a firm and a stakeholder so that
can affect a firm), there is a managing of inter- there is a third component to gain insight from:
ests; these stakeholders and their interests must the relationship between the two actors. In other
be "dealt with" (Freeman, 1984: 126) so that the words, just as two actors have attributes, their
firm may still achieve its interests. Here, the relationship does too. Indeed, the relationship
stakeholder literature intersects the strategy lit- may tell as much or more about how the actors
erature (e.g., Clarkson, 1995; Freeman, 1984; Hill will interact as the individual attributes of the
& Jones, 1992; Huse & Eide, 1996; Rowley, 1997). actors will.
The emphasis on managing the stakeholder In this article I consider the resource dimen-
makes this approach unidirectional in nature, sion of a relationship and the power that stems
with relationships viewed from the firm's van- from it, viewing power, then, as an attribute of
tage point. the relationship between the actors—not of the
With the moral stakeholder (the one who is actors themselves. This differs from previous ac-
affected by the firm), stakeholder theorists seek counts of power in the stakeholder literature
some balancing of interests. Here, the stake- (e.g.. Freeman. 1984; Mitchell, Agle. & Wood.
holder literature intersects the ethics literature 1997), where power has been treated as an at-
and gives a more bidirectional account of the tribute of the individual. In short, considering
firm and its stakeholders (e.g.. Burton & Dunn. the relationship between two actors means in-
1996; Cohen. 1995; Donaldson & Preston. 1995; cluding a structural component in stakeholder
Evan & Freeman. 1988; Freeman & Evan. 1990; analysis that so far has been lacking, except in
Phillips. 1997; Wicks. Gilbert. & Freeman. 1994). Jones's (1995) work involving contracts and Row-
1999 Frooman 193

ley's (1997) work on networks, and that may hold utilitarian, and normative (Etzioni. 1964; Mitchell
further promise for future work in stakeholder et al.. 1997). Rowley (1997) recently has defined
theory. stakeholder power in terms of network structure
and position. In addition. Carroll (1989) has sug-
LITERATURE REVIEW gested that size in terms of budget and staff, as
well as amount of and source of funding, could
Three research streams of strategic stake- serve as measures of the degree of stakeholder
holder theory suggest themselves in the form of power. In this article I give another account of
the three general questions stated earlier: (1) a power—one yet untapped in the stakeholder lit-
stream devoted to identifying stakeholder at- erature—suggesting that resource dependence
tributes, to answer the question "Who are they?" theory gives a useful account of stakeholder
(2) a stream focused on stakeholder ends, or power, although not in the form of a stakeholder
interests, to answer the question "What do they attribute but, rather, as a structural component.
want?" and (3) a stream directed toward stake- In response to "What do they want?" authors
holder influence strategies, to answer the ques- have generated numerous lists of stakeholder
tion "How are they going to try to get it?" I interests, one of the most comprehensive ap-
discuss each of the three streams in the para- pearing in Frederick, Post, and Davis's book
graphs that follow. (1992). Wood (1994) has suggested various cate-
Many of the answers to the question "Who are gorization schemes for these stakeholder inter-
they?" have taken the form of lists of stakehold- ests, including concrete versus symbolic, eco-
ers and categorization schemes of stakeholders nomic versus social, and local versus domestic
(e.g., generic versus specific: Carroll, 1989; pri- versus international. There is no doubt that the
mary versus secondary: Clarkson, 1995). In re- lists and sorting schemes are important. I sug-
cent years, however, stakeholder attributes
gest, however, that although simple in concept,
have received increasing attention. The most
the mere recognition that stakeholder and firm
comprehensive work to date is probably that of
interests do diverge is as important a step to-
Mitchell et al. (1997). The authors, in that article,
ward managing stakeholders as is identifying
identify urgency, legitimacy, and power as the
and classifying those interests. In other words, I
three key attributes of a stakeholder, arguing
that in their various combinations these at- wish to surface here an assumption that I be-
tributes are indicators of the amount of attention lieve underlies all of stakeholder theory: stake-
management needs to give a stakeholder. holder theory is about managing potential con-
flict stemming from divergent interests.
Although urgency has received little prior at-
tention in the stakeholder literature, controversy Although this does not seem to be discussed
has surrounded the importance of legitimacy as much in the stakeholder literature. Freeman
a stakeholder attribute. From a firm's strategic does note that an early stakeholder scholar. Dill
planning standpoint, does it matter whether so- (1975), was the first to extend the stakeholder
ciety deems appropriate a stakeholder's claims? concept beyond such groups as shareholders
The appropriateness of a stakeholder's claim and customers to "groups who are usually
may not matter nearly as much as the ability of thought of as having adversarial relationships
the stakeholder to affect the direction of the firm. with the firm," and that in doing so Dill "set the
As Freeman (1984) notes, strategies for dealing stage for the use of the stakeholder concept as
even with groups well beyond the fringe will be an umbrella for strategic management" (Free-
put in place if those groups pose a threat to the man. 1984: 38). In other words, it was upon ap-
firm. plying the stakeholder concept to groups where
What this debate suggests is that although the potential for conflict existed that the stake-
disagreement may exist regarding the impor- holder model became meaningful. I suggest,
tance of legitimacy as an attribute, most schol- then, that if the potential for conflict did not
ars probably agree that power is an important exist—that is, if the firm and all its stakeholders
one. Various taxonomies have been suggested were largely in agreement—managers would
to serve as the means of categorizing the types have no need to concern themselves with stake-
of power, including formal, economic, and polit- holders or stakeholder theory. In short, conflict,
ical (Freeman & Reed. 1983). as well as coercive. resulting from the opposition of firm and stake-
194 Academy of Management Review April

holder interests, is an unstated premise of the tify my choice of resource dependence theory
theory. from among those. Because power is a central
I want to make this assumption explicit and theme in the argument. I review that construct
an integral part of the theory, because this arti- as it exists within resource dependence theory
cle can give an account of how that conflict and distinguish that theory's conceptualization
plays out, at least in terms of how stakeholders of power from the closely related, but different,
exert their influence in accordance with their conceptualization that exchange theory takes.
interests. In addition, part of this article draws Second, I use resource dependence theory to
on the bargaining literature, which is an appro- generate four types of stakeholder influence
priate approach for resolving some conflicts, strategies: withholding, usage, direct, and indi-
and, therefore, belongs in the stakeholder liter- rect. This section. Types of Influence Strategies,
ature, from which it has been missing. then, provides an answer to the first research
Finally, answers to the question "How are question: "What are the different types of influ-
they going to try to get it?" have always taken ence strategies?"
the form of analyses of particular stakeholder Third. I derive four types of firm-stakeholder
influence strategies. The first such analysis was relationships from resource dependence theory:
probably Vogel's (1978) work, which focused on firm power, high interdependence, low interde-
such strategies as proxy resolutions and boy- pendence, and stakeholder power. Fourth, then.
cotts. In recent years stockholder resolutions I demonstrate how resource dependence theory
(Davis & Thompson. 1994). boycotts (Paul & Ly- provides an argument for mapping the types of
denberg. 1992), and modified vendettas (Corlett, influence strategies onto the types of relation-
1989; Shipp, 1987) have all been subject to theo- ships, thereby suggesting that the type of rela-
retical treatment. Researchers have performed tionship is a determinant of the choice of influ-
empirical studies on many of these same stake- ence strategy. These two sections combined
holder influence strategies. In these empirical provide an answer to the second research ques-
studies scholars generally have considered the tion: "What are the determinants of the choice of
effectiveness of the strategies, or the market's influence strategy?"
reaction to such strategies, and have included Last (and fifth). I put forward propositions and
examinations of boycotts (Garrett. 1987; Pruitt. discuss empirical methods for testing them. The
Wei, & White, 1988), divestitures (Davidson, Wor- article ends with a concluding section summa-
rell, & El-Jelly, 1995), and letter-writing cam- rizing the article's key points.
paigns (Smith & Cooper-Martin, 1997). The example I refer to throughout this article
As already noted, however, nowhere has any- is the clash that took place between the EII, an
one attempted to go beyond the listing and dis- environmental organization, and StarKist. The
cussion of particular influence strategies to con- confrontation between the two had been sim-
struct a model of those strategies. In this article mering throughout much of the 1980s, because
I aim to do just that, presenting a model that will the foreign tuna fishing industry, from whom
specify the types of stakeholder influence strat- StarKist purchased much of its tuna, was using
egies available and identify one determinant of a very efficient method of netting tuna, called
the choice amongst those strategies. As a first "purse-seining." This method was also trapping
step toward a more comprehensive answer to and killing over 100,000 dolphins yearly. As a
how stakeholders go about getting what they result, the United States had banned this
want from management, this model develops method of catching tuna, so the domestic fleet
the third research stream of strategic stake- was using other methods of netting tuna.
holder theory, which, to date, has been left In January of 1988, the EII announced its inten-
largely unattended. tion of ending StarKist's practice of canning
purse-seined tuna purchased from the foreign
tuna fishing fleet. First, the EII called upon con-
THE ARGUMENT
sumers to boycott StarKist. In conjunction with
The argument of this article proceeds as fol- this call, the EII produced an 11-minute video
lows. First. I propose that open systems theories full of gruesome scenes of half-drowned dol-
may be a sensible starting point for understand- phins being mangled in a ship's net-hauling
ing stakeholder influence strategies, and I jus- machinery and then being heaved overboard as
1999 frooman 195

shark bait. The video ended with the call for the of the organization's dependence on the environ-
boycott. ment that makes the external constraint and con-
In March of 1988, the video was aired in parts trol of organizational behavior both possible and
almost inevitable (Pfeffer & Salancik, 1978: 43).
or in its entirety on all the major networks. The
EII then mass produced the video and began In short, it is the dependence of firms on envi-
distributing it to schools around the country. ronmental actors (i.e.. external stakeholders) for
During the rest of 1988 and 1989, first the envi- resources that gives those actors leverage over
ronmental media and then, gradually, the gen- a firm.
eral media began reporting on the story. Because those situations where the interests
By March of 1990, 60 percent of the public was of a stakeholder and a firm are in conflict form
aware of the issue and the call for a boycott of the more interesting class of stakeholder-firm
StarKist tuna (Ramirez, 1990). In the following interactions, and because, as already argued,
month. StarKist announced it would purchase they seem to lie at the core of stakeholder the-
only tuna caught by methods other than purse- ory. I focus on them. Now, in those cases where
seining and would insist that foreign tuna boats interests diverge and the firm is unwilling to
carry on-board impartial observers (from the In- change its behavior to accommodate a stake-
ter-American Tropical Tuna Commission) to holder, power is likely to decide the outcome
monitor the methods the crews were using. (Pfeffer, 1981, 1992, 1997). Of course, there are
many treatises on power; however, exchange
theory (e.g., Blau, 1964; Emerson, 1962, 1972, 1981)
THE POWER TO EXTERNALLY CONTROL and resource dependence theory (Pfeffer &
ORGANIZATIONS Salancik, 1978) have focused on power in the
The questions this article addresses, regard- context of resource exchange and dependence;
ing available influence strategies and selection thus, their perspectives on the sources of power
amongst them, constitute a narrowed version of are the most relevant to this article.
a broader question in the management litera- Exchange theory and resource dependence
ture: How can external entities influence an or- theory are closely related. The latter is essen-
ganization's behavior? This framing of the ques- tially a customized version of the former, de-
tion suggests looking to the open-systems (Katz signed largely to explain the external control of
& Kahn, 1966) theories as a possible approach organizations, which is why it is the more suit-
for understanding influence strategies, because able theory of the two for this article's purposes.
these theories examine how the environment The theories are similar in how they define a
affects organizations. Among these theories, resource and how they define dependence: a
agency and resource dependence (and, to some resource is essentially anything an actor per-
degree, network) focus more on how particular ceives as valuable, whereas dependence is a
social actors within the environment affect a state in which one actor relies on the actions of
focal organization and assume that the focal another to achieve particular outcomes (Emer-
organization can actively respond to those so- son, 1962; Pfeffer, 1992).
cial actors (Donaldson, 1995; Nohria & Gulati, Operationalized, resource dependence is said
1994; Oliver, 1991). to exist when one actor is supplying another
Although agency theory (Hill & Jones, 1992) with a resource that is marked by (1) concentra-
and network theory (Rowley, 1997) have been tion (suppliers are few in number), (2) controlla-
shown to be productive approaches to develop- bility, (3) nonmobility, (4) nonsubstitutability
ing stakeholder theory, in this article I have (Barney. 1991; Emerson, 1962; Jacobs. 1974; Pfeffer
chosen the yet untapped theory of resource de- & Salancik. 1978), or (5) essentiality. Essentiality
pendence as a framework, for as Pfeffer and of a resource is itself a function of two factors:
Salancik (1978) have argued. (1) relative magnitude of exchange and (2) criti-
cality. The relative magnitude of exchange has
Because organizations are not self-contained or to do with the percent of inputs/outputs ac-
self-sufficient, the environment must be relied counted for by an exchange. In other words, if
upon to provide support. For continuing to pro-
vide what the organization needs, the external organization A supplies a large proportion of
groups or organizations may demand certain ac- inputs to organization B. or absorbs a large pro-
tions from the organization in return. It is the fact portion of outputs from B. then B will be depen-
196 Academy of Management Review April

dent on A. The criticality of a resource has to do determining whether it can use them in the way
with whether an organization can exist without it wants. These I term resource control strate-
it. if the resource is an input, or exist without a gies, which I consider to be one type of influence
market for it, if the resource is an output Jacobs, strategy.
1974; Pfeffer & Salancik, 1978). In addition, because I seek to expand stake-
Power in both theories could be defined as holder theory beyond the simple hub-and-spoke
"the structurally determined potential for ob- conceptualization with its independent dyadic
taining favored payoffs in relations where inter- ties, and to recognize that resource relationships
ests are opposed" (Wilier, Lovaglia, & Mark- can be and often are embedded in other rela-
ovsky, 1997: 573). Power is structurally tionships, I assert that there may be more than
determined in the sense that the nature of the one route of influence for a stakeholder to fol-
relationship—that is. who is dependent on low: direct, or indirect via another stakeholder.
whom and how much—determines who has These I term pathways of influence, which I con-
power. However, although exchange and re- sider to be a second type of influence strategy.
source dependence theorists may agree on this Both resource control strategies and pathway
definition of power, they disagree on how to strategies are detailed in the sections below.
operationalize it. Proponents of exchange the-
ory, the earlier of the two theories, state that the
power of agent A over agent B is "equal to, and Types of Resource Control
based upon, the dependence of B upon A" (Em- As indicated above, actors providing re-
erson. 1962: 33). Power, then, is stated in absolute sources to a firm are said to have two general
terms; to find if A has power over B, one need means of control over a firm: (1) determining
only look to see if B is dependent on A. whether the firm gets the resources it needs and
However, proponents of resource dependence (2) determining whether the firm can use the
theory operationalize power as follows: "For the resources in the way it wants. These two ways of
dependence between two organizations to pro- manipulating resources were characterized as
vide one organization with power over the other, discretion over resource allocation and discre-
there must be asymmetry in the exchange rela- tion over resource use by Pfeffer and Salancik
tionship" (Pfeffer & Salancik, 1978: 53). So. in (1978) and Pfeffer (1992). I refer to them in this
order to know if A has power over B. one must article as withholding and usage strategies.
verify both that B is dependent on A and that A In the exchange theory literature, my with-
is not dependent on B. Power, thus, is defined in holding and usage strategies differ mainly in
relative terms—that is, A has power over B if B is terms of emphasis from the hostile and concil-
more dependent on A relative to A's dependence iatory tactics found in Lawler and Bacharach
on B (Lawler & Yoon, 1995). Because I feel that (1987) and Lawler (1992). Their terminology tends
resource dependence theory is customized for to refer to the emotive quality of the tactics (e.g.,
the purposes of this article, I draw upon its no- Lawler & Yoon, 1993, 1995, 1996), whereas my
tion of relative power later in the article when terminology focuses more on the means of lever-
characterizing the types of relationships organi- age the stakeholder has over the firm.
zations can have. Withholding strategies. Discretion over allo-
cation translates to a stakeholder influence
strategy only if a stakeholder chooses not to
TYPES OF INFLUENCE STRATEGIES
allocate—that is, it withholds—its resource. In
Central to resource dependence theory is the other words, a stakeholder with discretion over
notion that a firm's need for resources provides allocation only has power if it has the "ability to
opportunities for others to gain control over it. In articulate a credible threat of withdrawal" of
discussions of resources, a simple input-output those resources (Pfeffer & Leong, 1977: 779). With-
model can be a useful way to conceptualize the holding strategies are defined quite simply,
flow of resources. That resources flow into a firm then, as those where the stakeholder discontin-
and are then converted by that firm into outputs ues providing a resource to a firm with the in-
suggests that there are two ways in which oth- tention of making the firm change a certain be-
ers can exert control over a firm: (1) in determin- havior. Of course, every stakeholder providing a
ing whether the firm gets the resources and (2) in resource to a firm has a method of withholding
1999 Frooman 197

it. and a different term is used to label the Quite simply, in terms of approach, a stake-
method of practically every stakeholder. For ex- holder that employs a withholding strategy is
ample, employees withhold labor by striking, prepared to shut off the flow of resources to a
and creditors withhold debt financing by nonre- firm, whereas a stakeholder that employs a us-
newal of loans. In the StarKist-EII example, it age strategy is not. Clearly, what will make the
was a consumer boycott—customers withhold- threat of withholding credible is the ability of
ing their dollars—that influenced StarKist's de- the stakeholder to simply walk away from the
cision to confront the foreign tuna fishing indus- relationship with no harm to itself. This will
try over its practices. occur when the firm is unilaterally dependent
I should probably note that the mere threat of on the stakeholder.
using withholding (or any of the influence strat- In other situations, however, such as one in
egies) may be as effective a tool for influencing which there is reciprocal exposure—that is.
firm behavior as the actual use of the strategy. when the stakeholder and firm are mutually de-
In this article, however, I do not really examine pendent—the stakeholder will not be in a posi-
the factors determining effectiveness but, tion to walk away from the relationship (Lawler
rather, the factors determining choice of strat- & Bacharach, 1987; Williamson. 1979. 1983). In
egy. For the purposes of this article, then, it such a scenario the welfare of each will be
really does not matter whether the stakeholder linked to the other, so each will do well only by
actually ever withholds or simply threatens to attending to the needs of the other.
do so. In the StarKist-EII scenario, for example, the
Usage strategies. Usage strategies are those sales of the foreign tuna fishing industry were
in which the stakeholder continues to supply a linked to the sales of StarKist. That industry
resource, but with strings attached. In the knew that if a boycott were to begin affecting
StarKist-EII example, StarKist employed a usage StarKist's sales, the fleet's sales to StarKist
strategy against the foreign tuna fishing indus- eventually would have to be affected too. Thus,
try: while StarKist continued to purchase tuna, it the industry could do well only by acceding to
StarKist's demands regarding choice of netting
did so with the conditions that the industry use
and on-board observers.
other types of nets besides purse-seins and that
Finally, provisions for which party pays
observers be on board tuna boats to assure this.
costs is also a distinguishing characteristic
So, in short, withholding strategies determine
between withholding and usage strategies. If
whether a firm obtains a resource, whereas us-
we assume that a firm seeks profits and, there-
age strategies seek to attach conditions to the
fore, chooses efficient actions, then a stake-
continued supply of that resource. holder that requests a change in firm behavior
Now, in either case (withholding or usage is implicitly asking the firm to choose a less
strategies), the stakeholder demands that the efficient means to its end. Economic costs,
firm change some behavior. In either case, the thus, will presumably be involved in a change
stakeholder uses its resource relationship with of firm behavior. Indeed, in the StarKist-EII
the firm to leverage that demand. And, in either case, the reason the foreign tuna fishing in-
case, if the stakeholder is successful in employ- dustry purse-seined was that it was the most
ing its strategy, the firm will change its behav- efficient method of netting tuna, so any devi-
ior. From the firm's point of view. then, withhold- ation from that practice was going to be costly
ing and usage strategies may appear to amount to that industry. Similarly, the reason StarKist
to the same thing. From the stakeholder's point canned purse-seined tuna was that from an
of view, however, withholding and usage strat- efficiency standpoint, as the lowest-costing
egies differ markedly: they differ in their ap- tuna, it was the preferred tuna to can, so any
proach, they differ in what ultimately makes deviation from that practice was going to be
them credible threats (Schelling. 1956; William- costly to that company.
son. 1983), and they differ in terms of the provi- In addition to economic costs, negotiating,
sions they include regarding who pays the costs monitoring, and enforcement costs also could be
that may accrue to a firm if the firm is to change involved. Costs of changing behavior, then, will
its behavior according to the stakeholder's de- be a major issue in any given stakeholder-firm
mands. dispute; in fact, from the firm's point of view.
198 Academy oi Management Review April

again assuming that firms are first and foremost principal, although there is no formal agency
profit maximizers, it will be the major issue. relationship between them. In network theory
Authors of the social exchange literature that Rowley (1997) has used the term indirect stake-
pertains to bargaining (Bacharach & Lawler, holders to refer to influential agents of a focal
1981; Lawler, 1986, 1992; Lawler & Bacharach, organization that do not have direct relation-
1987) would predict that with withholding strat- ships with that organization, but still work in the
egies, it would typically be the firm that would focal firm's interests. In the context of resource
be expected to pay the greatest portion of the dependence theory. I define indirect strategies
costs, whereas with usage strategies, costs as those in which the stakeholder works through
would tend more to be shared. As will be dem- an ally, by having the ally manipulate the flow
onstrated later in this article, this is because of resources to the firm (by either withholding or
withholding strategies are used when the bal-
usage).
ance of power lies on the side of the stakeholder.
In other words, when the firm is more dependent Taking an ongoing resource relationship and
on the stakeholder than the stakeholder is on embedding into it a new relationship is the es-
the firm, the stakeholder can afford to withhold sence of the indirect strategy. The purpose of
and try to push costs onto the firm. Usage strat- adding this new relationship is to shift the bal-
egies, however, are used when power lies more ance of power to favor the weaker actor. This is
evenly between the two, and, thus, costs are akin to both the process described by Granovet-
more evenly divided. ter (1985), where organizations gain control over
economic transactions by embedding them in
social relationships, and the social structure
Types of Influence Pathways analysis approach of Burt (1982, 1992), where
A second source of power that exists in re- constraint results from dependence on coordi-
source dependence is the one that arises from nated actors.
relationships with others who supply resources As indicated, in the StarKist-EII controversy,
to a focal firm. In other words, withholding and the EIFs efforts to organize consumers to boycott
usage do not have to be performed by a stake- StarKist was an example of a stakeholder group
holder but, instead, could be performed by an (the EII) using an indirect strategy against a
ally of the stakeholder with whom the focal firm firm. Of course, the first step in any indirect
has a dependence relationship. The existence of strategy has to be a communication strategy,
such allies determines the pathway of influence which the stakeholder directs at the ally. Specif-
the stakeholder can use to exercise resource ically, communication strategies are those
control. Gargiulo (1993) has divided these path- where the stakeholder informs a potential ally
ways into "direct" and "multistep" and has dem- about (1) a firm's behavior, (2) why the stake-
onstrated that they do exist as interorganization- holder perceives that behavior to be undesir-
al power strategies and do occur within the able, and (3) what the ally ought to do (i.e., ini-
context of resource dependence theory. In this tiate a resource strategy against the firm or a
article I refer to the pathways as direct and
communication strategy directed at an ally of
indirect.
the ally).
Direct strategies. Direct strategies I define
In the StarKist-EII example, the 11-minute
simply as those in which the stakeholder itself
manipulates the flow of resources to the firm video EII filmed on the Panamanian tuna boat
(again, either by withholding or usage). In the formed the center of the Ell's communication
StarKist-EII example, when the consumers did strategy. Aired on all of the major television
choose to boycott StarKist tuna, they were exer- networks and then mass produced and distrib-
cising a direct strategy against that firm. uted, the video was the primary vehicle by
Indirect strategies. Indirect action against a which the EII communicated its request for a
target organization is a notion that exists else- boycott to consumers. In short, the indirect strat-
where in the open systems theories. For exam- egy employed by the EII against StarKist en-
ple, in agency theory Mahon (1993) has used the tailed a communication strategy between the EII
term manufactured agents to refer to indirect and consumers and a direct strategy (the boy-
agents—those that work in concordance with a cott) between consumers and StarKist.
1999 Frooman 199

TYPES OF RESOURCE RELATIONSHIPS that each party either is or is not dependent on


To begin to address the second research ques- the other. The horizontal axis has to do with
tion posed in this article's introduction, "What dependence of the stakeholder on the firm and
are the determinants of the choice of influence the vertical axis with dependence of the firm on
strategy?" I introduce, in this section, a typology the stakeholder.
of stakeholder-firm relationships based on re- Two quadrants along one diagonal (northeast
source dependence theory. As already sug- and southwest) capture Pfeffer and Salancik's
gested, power will be a central determinant of notion of asymmetry in the exchange relation-
outcomes in those situations where a stake- ship leading to power. I label these stakeholder
holder and a firm find their interests opposed. In power and firm power. The former, for example,
the resource and exchange literature, power occurs when the stakeholder is less dependent
stems from the dependencies of the two parties on the firm than the firm is on the stakeholder.
on one another; in other words, power is struc- The other two quadrants along the other diago-
tural in nature, arising from the relationship nal illustrate Pfeffer and Salancik's conception
between the two parties. How, then, can the dif- of interdependence, which occurs when there is
ferent types of resource relationships be charac- symmetry in the exchange relationship—either
terized in terms of dependencies? both parties are highly dependent on one an-
Pfeffer and Salancik posit that "when the net other, or both parties are not very dependent on
exchange between organizational entities is each other. I label these high interdependence
asymmetrical, some net power accrues to the and low interdependence, accordingly.
less dependent organization. This power may In the StarKist-EII example, using the essen-
be employed in attempting to influence or con- tiality of a resource as a criterion for determin-
strain the behavior of the other more depen- ing dependency, I argue that the relationships
dent organization" (1978: 53). However, if the between the adversaries were as follows.
net exchange is symmetrical, so that the two First, between the EII and StarKist, neither
organizations are equally dependent on each was dependent on the other for a resource, so
other, neither "possesses a particular power this indicates that a low-interdependence re-
advantage, reducing the likelihood that one lationship existed between them. Second, in
organization will dominate interorganization- the relationship between consumers and
al influences" (1978: 53). This argument sug- StarKist, StarKist was highly dependent on
gests a typology of the possible relationships, tuna consumers for sales revenues, because
based on dependencies, between two organi- StarKist's only business line is tuna products.
zations (e.g., between a stakeholder and a Consumers, however, were not dependent on
firm). Pfeffer and Salancik never presented tuna, and many appeared to be happy doing
such a typology, but the one that appears in without it for months at a time. This combina-
Table 1 stems directly from their work (1978: tion of dependencies suggests a relationship
52-54). that can be characterized as one of stake-
Each axis has to do with dependence, which, holder power. Third and last, between StarKist
of course, can range from low to high. For sim- and the foreign tuna fishing industry, I believe
plification purposes, however, dependence is a high-interdependence relationship existed.
treated as a dichotomous variable here, such At the time, StarKist was the largest tuna can-
ner in the world—canning 35 percent of the
TABLE 1 tuna consumed in the United States (Lan-
Typology of Resource Relationships caster, 1990)—so StarKist was the primary cus-
tomer of the foreign tuna fishing industry. The
Is the stakeholder dependent on the firm? foreign tuna fishing industry, in turn, was the
c2 No Yes primary supplier to StarKist, providing it with
II Low interdependence Firm power
70 percent of its tuna (Oceans, 1988). This sug-
gests a high level of interdependence be-
cause, given the huge volume of business
•£ Yes Stakeholder power High interdependence
moving between the two parties, neither could
~c
n O have replaced the other easily or quickly.
200 Academy oi Management Review April

CHOICE OF STRATEGY critical resource from the firm; rather, the stake-
holder will tend to focus on usage strategies as
The second research question posed in this
its means of influence.
article, "What are the determinants of the choice
of influence strategy?" remains unanswered at
this point. The preceding two sections, however, Typology of Influence Strategies and Resource
Relationships
have laid the groundwork for an answer by first
defining the types of influence strategies that Using these two assumptions regarding strat-
exist and then defining the types of resource egy choices, one can construct a simple two-by-
relationships that exist. In this section I demon- two typology of strategies of the four possible
strategies and the circumstances under which
strate how resource dependence theory sug- each will be chosen (see Table 2).
gests that relationship drives the choice of strat- The high-interdependence cell is of particular
egy- interest. As already noted, the foreign tuna fish-
Level of Firm Dependence Determines Type of ing industry and StarKist were in this category.
Pathway Chosen Their relationship was a mixture of mutual de-
pendence and conflict: they were partners in
First, as Pfeffer notes, organizations will be that neither could do well without the other and
responsive to others in their environment who that both stood to lose by a successful consumer
provide them with valuable resources: boycott, and, yet, as firms in the same value-
Resource dependence theory suggests that organ- added chain, they were adversaries—each try-
izational behaviors become externally influenced ing to extract from the chain as much profit as
because the focal organization must attend to the possible at the expense of the other. Schelling
demands of those in its environment that provide
resources necessary and important for its contin- (1960) labels actors in such situations as "mixed-
ued survival. . .organizations will (and should) re- motive" (mixed, that is, in their relationship to
spond more to the demands of those organiza- one another—half-partner, half-competitor—not
tions or groups in the environment that control in terms of their clarity of mind regarding pref-
critical resources (Pfeffer, 1982: 193). erences).
Put another way, a low level of dependence of a Common sense would suggest that such
firm on a stakeholder implies that the firm does mixed-motive players would negotiate and find
not need to be responsive to the stakeholder. a mutually acceptable solution regarding be-
The firm, then, is somewhat impervious to stake- haviors they engage in jointly, in order to avoid
holder influence. Thus, the stakeholder will tend mutual disaster. Recent empirical studies in the
to use indirect strategies (i.e., act through an social exchange literature on bilateral deter-
ally on whom the firm is more dependent and, rence (Lawler, 1992; Lawler & Bacharach, 1987;
therefore, more responsive to) to influence the Lawler & Yoon, 1995, 1996) support this intuition
firm. about mixed-motive players.
Common sense might also suggest that in
high-interdependence relationships the costs
Level of Stakeholder Dependence Determines that accompany behavioral changes will be
Type of Resource Control Chosen shared by both parties. Game theory literature
Pfeffer and Salancik (1978) also note that when
resource dependence exists, it means that the
welfare of the focal firm is linked to the organi- TABLE 2
zation providing key resources. As the degree of Typology of Influence Strategies
dependence increases, the more tightly the focal
firm's outcomes become tied to its resource pro- I8 the stakeholder dependent on the firm?
viders. Therefore, a high level of dependence of IIax
0) o
No Yes
the stakeholder on the firm means that the wel- TI J« No Indirect/withholding Indirect/usage
fare of the stakeholder is closely tied to the E 2 (low interdependence) (firm power)
welfare of the firm. The stakeholder, then, will --E m
^ Yes Direct/withholding Direct/usage (high
not wish to see the firm's success threatened £ ~ (stakeholder power) interdependence)
m O
and, therefore, will not choose to withhold a
1999 Fiooman 201

supports this intuition: in game theory the high- wanted observers on the boats to verify the prac-
interdependence relationship would be charac- tices the boats were using. This is a direct usage
terized as a two-person, non-zero-sum, explicit- strategy: StarKist attached strings to its busi-
bargaining game (Lawler, 1992; Schelling, 1960; ness with the foreign tuna fishing industry.
Straff in, 1993). Researchers have shown, in such Foremost among the costs associated with the
games, that in any round of bargaining, the above change in behaviors by StarKist and the
player with the lower ratio of cost of concession foreign tuna fishing industry would be the eco-
to cost of exit must rationally concede to the nomic costs involved with the switch to netting
other (Zeuthen. 1930/1968) and that, after enough methods less efficient than purse-seining and
rounds, players eventually will move away from the monitoring costs associated with the main-
all-or-nothing solutions and arrive at a compro- tenance of on-board observers. These costs were
mise point. Where, theoretically, this point ex- split roughly evenly between StarKist and the
ists is a matter of controversy (e.g., Gauthier, foreign tuna fishing industry. (The cost per ton of
1986; Hampton, 1991; Harsanyi, 1977; Nash, 1953)! tuna at the dock increased only slightly, even
What everyone agrees on, however, is that a though it cost the industry more to catch it, and
compromise solution does exist and that ration- the cost per tin of tuna on the supermarket shelf
al players will seek it. In short, two actors find- remained the same, even though it was costing
ing themselves in a high-interdependence rela- StarKist slightly more to purchase it at the dock.)
tionship can be expected to bargain over the So, where StarKist was the target of a with-
costs involved and eventually to agree to share holding strategy by consumers, the balance of
those costs in some manner. power lay with the stakeholder (the consumers),
and the costs of behavioral change fell on the
StarKist-EII Example firm—StarKist. When StarKist turned on the for-
eign tuna fishing industry, however, and made
As an illustration of the theory, consider the it the target of a usage strategy, the balance of
StarKist-EII confrontation again. Given the rela- power lay more evenly between the two, owing
tionships among the players, does the theory to the nature of the relationship (high interde-
account for what strategies the players chose to pendence); thus, the costs were ultimately split
try? between the two, as would be predicted in a
Consider the first pair of adversaries—the EII two-person, non-zero-sum, explicit-bargaining
and StarKist—which, I have argued, was an ex- game.
ample of a low-interdependence relationship.
Accordingly, the theory would predict that the
EII would try indirect withholding. The EII
sought out consumers as an ally and communi- PROPOSITIONS
cated to them (via its video) its desire for a In this article I have been arcfuing that who is
boycott—an indirect withholding strategy. dependent on whom and by how much deter-
The second pair of adversaries—consumers mines the type of influence strategy that will be
and StarKist—was engaged in a relationship chosen. The questions "Is the stakeholder de-
marked by stakeholder power. The theory would pendent on the firm?" and "Is the firm depen-
predict, then, the use of a direct withholding dent on the stakeholder?" determine the inde-
strategy by the consumers. The consumers, in pendent variable: the type of resource
large numbers, did boycott tuna—a direct with- relationship. The dependent variable is the
holding strategy. choice of influence strategy.
Finally, consider StarKist versus the foreign Corresponding, then, to each of the four cells
tuna fishing industry, which were in a high- in the second typology (Table 2) is a testable
interdependence relationship—one we have ob- proposition. Each proposition identifies the rela-
served is marked by both partnership and com- tionship between the stakeholder and firm in
petition. The theory would predict a direct usage terms of their dependence on one another (the
strategy here. StarKist, never once threatening independent variable) and then states which
to withhold its business, informed the foreign strategy the stakeholder would choose to influ-
tuna fishing industry that it wanted tuna netted ence the firm's decision making (the dependent
by methods other than purse-seining and that it variable):
202 Academy oi Management Review April

Proposition 1: When the relationship is dence of the members on the United Way was
one of low interdependence, the measured in terms of the proportion of the mem-
stakeholder will choose an indirect ber's own budget received from the United Way,
withholding strategy to influence the whereas dependence of the United Way on the
firm. members was a function of the size of the mem-
ber.
Proposition 2: When the relationship is These studies all make use of nonprofit and
marked by firm power, the stake- public sector data, presumably because they are
holder will choose an indirect usage publicly available. Resource dependence stud-
strategy to influence the firm. ies with for-profit data are lacking, however,
Proposition 3: When the relationship is except at the industry level (e.g., Pfeffer &
marked by stakeholder power, the Nowak, 1976), despite criticism that resource de-
stakeholder will choose a direct with- pendence theory is an organization theory and,
holding strategy to influence the firm. therefore, should not be tested at the industry
level (Davis & Powell, 1990; Nohria & Gulati,
Proposition 4: When the relationship is 1994).
one of high interdependence, the A better approach, then, might be to look at
stakeholder will choose a direct usage the work done on wholesaler-sponsored volun-
strategy to influence the firm. tary chains (Kotler, 1997), such as True Value
In an empirical test of this article's four propo- hardware stores. Retailers join such voluntary
sitions, the dependent variable could be categor- chains to achieve buying economies and to
ical—withholding, usage, direct, or indirect—or standardize their products. Within these chains,
could be, in part, numeric, with a proportion of the each store carries national brands, in addition
cost of behavioral change bome by the firm serv- to the wholesaler's private label, and the owner
ing as a proxy for withholding and usage strate- of each store decides that mix. Although there is
gies. In other words, we can distinguish between effort at standardization, special deals and ad-
withholding and usage operationally by deter- vertising arrangements may be negotiated be-
mining whether almost all of the costs involved tween a retailer and the wholesaler on a case-
are absorbed by the firm (withholding) or whether by-case basis, and participation in wholesaler-
the costs are more evenly split between the firm organized advertising, for example, may vary
and stakeholder (usage). from store to store.
Most of the methodological issues, then, Given the existence of such chains, the influ-
would probably revolve around the independent ence strategies used by the wholesaler to en-
variable. Although determining who is depen- force initiatives (e.g., use of advertisements pic-
dent on whom may not be problematic, deter- turing minorities) could be examined. The
mining the extent of that dependence may be. dependence of the wholesaler on any given re-
The simplest way of addressing this problem tailer could be measured by the proportion of
would be through a laboratory study in which the wholesaler's revenues provided by that re-
the level of dependence could be manipulated tailer (note that some individuals own two or
straightforwardly. For example, games similar more retail stores), whereas the dependence of
to the prisoner's dilemma have been devised, the retailer on the wholesaler could be mea-
where the level of dependence of each party on sured by the percentage of total purchases the
the other is varied systematically across four retailer obtains from the wholesaler. In short,
versions of the conflict scenario (Ford & Blegan, the approach would be similar to that taken by
1992; Lawler & Yoon, 1993). Pfeffer and Leong (1977), except the researcher
Many have questioned the generalizability of would use data from the for-profit sector as op-
results garnered from such laboratory experi- posed to the nonprofit sector.
ments (Gilbert, 1996), and several have per-
formed studies using business data (Pfeffer.
CONCLUSION
1972; Randall. 1973; Salancik. 1979). In one study
Pfeffer and Leong (1977) examined allocations to When stakeholders seek to influence corpo-
members of local United Ways to see if alloca- rate behavior, what types of influence strategies
tions were a function of dependence. Depen- do they have available and what factors can
1999 Frooman 203

explain which strategies they choose to use? Brenner, S. N., & Cochran, P. 1991. The stakeholder theory of
The theory in this article suggests the following: the firm: Implications for business and society theory
(1) that four types of stakeholder influence strat- and research. In J. F. Mahon (Ed.), Proceedings of the
second annual meeting of the International Association
egies— direct withholding, indirect withholding, for Business and Society: 449-467.
direct usage, and indirect usage—exist; (2) that
Burt, R. S. 1982. Toward a structural theory of action. New
four types of resource relationships—stake- York: Academic Press.
holder power, high interdependence, low inter-
Burt, R. S. 1992. Structural holes: The social structure of com-
dependence, and firm power—exist; and (3) that
petition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
the balance of power implied by the relation-
ship determines which of the types of strategy a Burton, B. K., & Dunn, C. P. 1996. Feminist ethics as moral
grounding for stakeholder theory. Business Ethics Quar-
stakeholder will use. High dependence of the terly, 6: 133-148.
stakeholder on the firm implies the stakeholder
Carroll, A. B. 1989. Business and society: Ethics and stake-
will employ usage strategies; low dependence holder management. Cincinnati: South-Western Pub-
implies the use of withholding. High depen- lishing.
dence of the firm on the stakeholder implies the Clarkson, M. B. E. 1995. A stakeholder framework for analyz-
use of direct strategies; low dependence implies ing and evaluating corporate social performance. Acad-
indirect ones. The theory, then, provides one emy of Management Review, 20: 92-117.
possible answer to the question regarding how Cohen, S. 1995. Stakeholders and consent. Business & Profes-
stakeholders go about trying to get what they sional Ethics, 14(1): 3-16.
want from firms—one of three key questions this Corlett, J. A. 1989. The "modified vendetta sanction" as a
article's introduction suggested lay at the heart method of corporate collective punishment. Journal of
of strategic stakeholder theory. Business Ethics, 8: 937-942.
As I have argued in this article, putting the Davidson, W. N., Worrell, D. L., & El-Jelly, A. 1995. Influencing
focus on the influence strategies of stakeholders managers to change unpopular corporate behavior
through boycotts and divestitures: A stock market test.
instead of on the response strategies of firms
Business & Society, 34: 171-196.
(Oliver, 1991) may, at first, seem a counterintui-
tive approach to strategic stakeholder theory. Davis, G. F., & Powell, W. W. 1990. Organization-environment
relations. In M. D. Dunnette & L. M. Hough (Eds.), Hand-
After all, if stakeholder theory is managerial in book of industrial and organizational psychology, vol. 3:
orientation (Donaldson & Preston, 1995), it seems 316-375. Palo Alto, CA: Consulting Psychologists Press.
that articles ought to focus on firm actions—not Davis, G. F., & Thompson, T. A. 1994. A social movement
stakeholder actions. However, knowing how perspective on corporate control. Administrative Sci-
stakeholders may try to influence a firm is crit- ence Quarterly, 39: 141-173.
ical knowledge for any manager. After all. for Dill, W. 1975. Public participation in corporate planning:
managers to act strategically and plan the ac- Strategic management in a kibitzer's world, iong Aange
tions they intend their firm to take presupposes Planning, 8(1): 57-63.
that they have some idea of how others in their Donaldson, L. 1995. American anti-management theories of
environment will act. organizations. Cambridge, England: Cambridge Univer-
sity Press.
In short, I have contended in this article that
understanding the actions of those one may Donaldson, T., & Preston, L. E. 1995. The stakeholder theory of
need to respond to is a part of good manage- the corporation: Concepts, evidence, and implications.
Academy of Management Review, 20: 65-91.
ment and, thus, is rightfully part of stakeholder
theory. I believe this approach to strategic Emerson, R. M. 1962. Power-dependence relations. American
Socio/ogical Review, 27: 31-41.
stakeholder theory holds promise for the ongo-
ing development of stakeholder theory. Emerson, R. M. 1972. Exchange theory: Part II. Exchange
relations in networks. In J. Berger, M. Zelditch, &
B. Anderson (Eds.), Sociological theories in progress, vol.
2: 58-87. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.
REFERENCES
Emerson, R. M. 1981. Social exchange theory. In M. Rosen-
Bacharach, S. B., & Lawler, E. J. 1981. Bargaining: Power, berg & R. H. Turner (Eds.), Sociai psychology: Sociologi-
tactics, and outcomes. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass. cal perspectives: 30-65. New York: Basic Books.
Barney, J. B. 1991. Firm resources and sustained competitive Etzioni, A. 1964. Modem organizations. Englewood Cliffs, NJ:
advantage. Journal of Management, 17: 99-120. Prentice-Hall.
Blau, P. 1964. Exchange and power in social life. New York: Evan, W. M., & Freeman, R. E. 1988. A stakeholder theory of
Wiley. the modern corporation: Kantian capitalism. In
204 Academy oi Management Review April

T. Beauchamp & N. Bowie (Eds.), Ethical theory in busi- Lancaster, J. 1990. Three tuna firms move to save dolphins.
ness; 75-93. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. The Washington Post. April 13: Al, 14.
Ford, R., & Blegan, M. A. 1992. Offensive and defensive use of Lawler, E. J. 1986. Bilateral deterrence and conflict spiral: A
punitive tactics in explicit bargaining. Social Psychol- theoretical analysis. In E. J. Lawler (Ed.), Advances in
ogy Quarterly, 55: 351-362. group processes: 107-130. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.
Frederick, W. C, Post, J. E., & Davis, K. 1992. Business and Lawler, E. J. 1992. Power processes in bargaining. The Socio-
society: Corporate strategy, public policy, ethics (7th ed.). logical Quarterly, 33: 17-34.
New York: McGraw-Hill.
Lawler, E. J., & Bacharach, S. B. 1987. Comparison of depen-
Freeman, R. E. 1984. Strategic management: A stakeholder dence and punitive forms of power. Social Forces, 66:
approach. Boston: Pitman Publishing. 446-462.
Freeman, R. E., & Evan, W. M. 1990. Corporate governance: Lawler, E. J., & Yoon, J. 1993. Power and the emergence of
A stakeholder interpretation. Journal oi Behavioral commitment behavior in negotiated exchange. Ameri-
Economics, 19: 337-359. can Sociological Review. 58: 465-481.
Freeman, R. E., & Reed, D. L. 1983. Stockholders and stake- Lawler, E. J., & Yoon, J. 1995. Structural power and emotional
holders: A new perspective on corporate governance. processes in negotiation: A social exchange approach
California Management Review, 25(3): 88-106. In R. M. Kramer & D. M. Messick (Eds.), Negotiation as a
Gargiulo, M. 1993. Twro-step leverage: Managing constraint social process: 143-165. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
in organizational politics. Administrative Science Quar- Lawler, E. J., & Yoon, J. 1996. Commitment in exchange rela-
terly, 38: 1-19. tions: Test of a theory of relational cohesion. American
Garrett, D. E. 1987. The effectiveness of marketing policy Sociological Review. 61: 89-108.
boycotts. Journal oi Marketing, 51: 46-57. Mahon, J. F. 1993. Shaping issues/manufacturing agents:
Gauthier, D. 1986. Morals by agreement. Oxford, England: Corporate political sculpting. In B. M. Mitnick (Ed), Cor-
Oxford University Press. porate political agency: The construction oi competition
in public aiiairs: 187-212. Newbury Park, CA: Sage.
Gilbert, D. R. 1996. The prisoner's dilemma and the prisoners
of prisoner's dilemma. Business Ethics Quarterly, 6: Mitchell, R. K., Agle, B. R., & Wood, D. J. 1997. Toward a theory
165-178. of stakeholder identification and salience: Defining the
principle of who and what really counts. Academy oi
Goodpastor, K. 1991. Business ethics and stakeholder anal-
Management Review, 22: 853-886.
ysis. Business Ethics Quarterly, 1: 53—71.
Nash, J. 1953. Two-person cooperative games. Econometrica,
Granovetter, M. 1985. Economic action and social structure:
21: 128-140.
The problem of embeddedness. American Journal oi So-
ciology. 91: 481-510. Nohria, N., & Gulati, R. 1994. Firms and their environments.
In N. J. Smelser & R. Swedberg (Eds.), Handbook oi eco-
Hampton, J. 1991. Equalizing concessions in the pursuit of
nomic sociology: 529-555. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Uni-
justice: A discussion of Gauthier's bargaining solution.
In P. Vallentyne (Ed), Contractarianism and rational versity Press.
choice: Essays on David Gauthier's Morals by Agree- Oceans. 1988. Setting on dolphins. 21 (October): 69.
ment: 149-161. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Oliver, C. 1991. Strategic responses to institutional pro-
Harsanyi, J. 1977. Rational behavior and bargaining equilib- cesses. Academy of Management Review, 16: 145-179.
rium in games and social situations. Cambridge, Paul, K., & Lydenberg, S. D. 1992. Applications of corporate
England: Cambridge University Press. social monitoring systems. Journal oi Business Ethics, 11:
Hill, C. W. L., & Jones, T. M. 1992. Stakeholder-agency theory. 1-10.
Journal oi Management Studies, 29: 131-154. Pfeffer, J. 1972. Interorganizational influence and managerial
Huse, M., & Eide, D. 1996. Stakeholder management and the attitudes. Academy oi Management Journal 15: 317-330.
avoidance of corporate control. Business & Society. 35:
Pfeffer, J. 1981. Power in organizations. Marshfield, MA: Pit-
211-243.
man Publishing.
Jacobs, D. 1974. Dependency and vulnerability: An exchange
Pfeffer, J. 1982. Organizations and organization theory.
approach to the control of organizations. Administrative
Marshfield, MA: Pitman Publishing.
Science Quarterly, 19: 45-59.
Pfeffer, J. 1992. Managing with power: Politics and influence
Jones, T. M. 1995. Instrumental stakeholder theory: A synthe-
in organizations. Boston: Harvard University Press.
sis of ethics and econometrics. Academy oi Manage-
ment Review, 20: 404-437. Pfeffer, J. 1997. New directions for organization theory: Prob-
lems and prospects. New York: Oxford University Press.
Katz, D., & Kahn, R. L. 1966. The social psychology oi organi-
zations. New York: Wiley. Pfeffer, J., & Leong, A. 1977. Resource allocations in United
funds: Examination of power and dependence. Social
Kotler, P. 1997. Marketing management: Analysis, planning,
forces. 55: 775-790.
implementation, and control. Upper Saddle River, NJ:
Prentice-Hall. Pfeffer, J., & Nowak, P. 1976. Joint venture and interorganiza-
1999 frooman 205

tional dependence. Administrative Science Quarterly Shipp, S. 1987. Modified vendettas as a method of punishing
21:98-118.
corporations. Journal of Business Ethics, 6: 603-612.
Pfeffer, J., & Salancik, G. R. 1978. The external control of Smith, N. C, & Cooper-Martin, E. 1997. Ethics and target
organizations. New York: Harper & Row. marketing: The role of product harm and consumer vul-
Phillips, R. A. 1997. Stakeholder theory and a principle of nerability. Journal oi Marketing, 61: 1-20.
fairness. Business Ethics Quarterly. 7: 51-66. Straffin, P. D. 1993. Game theory and strategy. Washington,
Pruitt, S. W., Wei, K. C , & White, R. E. 1988. The impact of DC: Mathematical Association of America.
union-sponsored boycotts on the stock prices of target Vogel, D. 1978. Lobbying the corporation: Citizen challenges
firms. Journal of Labor Research. 9: 285-289. to business authority. New York: Basic Books.
Ramirez, A. 1990. "Epic debate" led to Heinz tuna plan. New Wicks, A. C, Gilbert, D. R., & Freeman, R. E. 1994. A feminist
York Times. April 16: Dl, 6. reinterpretation of the stakeholder concept. Business
Randall, R. 1973. Influence of environmental support and Ethics Quarterly, 4: 475-497.
policy space on organizational behavior. Administrative Wilier, D., Lovaglia, M. J., & Markovsky, B. 1997. Power and
Science Quarterly. 18: 236-247. influence: A theoretical bridge. Social Forces, 76- 571-
Rowley, T. J. 1997. Moving beyond dyadic ties: A network 603.
theory of stakeholder influences. Academy of Manage- Williamson, O. E. 1979. Transaction-cost economics: The gov-
ment Review. 22: 887-910. ernance of contractual relations. Journal of Law & Eco-
Salancik, G. R. 1979. Interorganizational dependence and nomics, 22: 233-261.
responsiveness to affirmative action: The case of Williamson, O. E. 1983. Credible commitments: Using hos-
women and defense contractors. Academy of Manage- tages to support exchange. American Economic Review,
ment Journal, 22: 375-394. 73: 519-540.
Schelling, T. C. 1956. An essay on bargaining. American Wood, D. J. 1994. Business and society (2nd ed.). New York:
Economic Review, 46: 281-306. Harper Collins.
Schelling, T. C. 1960. The strategy of conflict. London: Oxford Zeuthen, F. 1930. (Reprinted in 1968.) Problems of mono-poly
University Press. and economic warfare. New York: Augustus M. Kelley.

Jeff Frooman is a Ph.D. candidate at the University of Pittsburgh. His current research
interests include business ethics, corporate social performance, stakeholder theory,
and interorganizational relations.

You might also like